View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

pd
papers

NUMBER 13

By Michael D. Bordo

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER

Globalization and Imbalances in
Historical Perspective

JANUARY 2006

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Globalization and Imbalances in
Historical Perspective
By Michael D. Bordo

Global imbalances associated with the U.S. current account deficit have given rise to
speculation about the nature of the impending adjustment: Will it be smooth and gradual, or
will it be sudden and costly? This Policy Discussion Paper summarizes the two views and
then considers three historical periods with similar pressures—an earlier era of globalization
from 1870 to 1914, the interwar gold standard, and Bretton Woods. A comparison of the
periods and their outcomes suggests current global imbalances might resolve themselves
quietly. This paper was originally presented to the Cleveland Committee on Foreign
Relations at the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland on March 9, 2005.

Michael D. Bordo is a
professor of economics
Rutgers University and a
research associate at the
National Bureau of Economic
Research.

Materials may be reprinted,
provided that the source is
credited. Please send copies
of reprinted materials to the
editor.

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4dsubscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050. Please send your questions
comments, and suggestions to us at editor@clev.frb.org.
Policy Discussion Papers are available on the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World Wide Web:
www.clevelandfed.org/Research.
Views stated in Policy Discussion Papers are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

The Current Situation
The Gloomy View
Recent concerns over global imbalances associated with the U.S. current-account-deficit-to-GDP ratio in excess of 5 percent (see figure 1) and U.S. net foreign liabilities of $2.7 trillion or 25 percent of
GDP (see figure 2) have raised fears of a drastic readjustment involving a massive depreciation of the
dollar (as large as 90 percent in some scenarios [Blanchard et al. 2005]). It has already fallen about 30
percent in nominal trade-weighted terms against our major trading partners (see figure 3)—with attendant potentially serious effects on the U.S. and global economies (see, for example, Obstfeld and
Rogoff 2004).The adjustment would involve reallocation of consumption and production in the United States from nontraded to traded goods and a possible rise in inflation, which would lead to greater
tightening of monetary policy, which would, in turn, induce a recession.The decline in income would
reduce both the demand for imports and domestic consumption and encourage domestic saving, simultaneously improving the two faces of imbalance—the current account and the savings investment gap.
At the same time, the adjustment would have opposite effects in Europe and Japan, areas with current account surpluses and excess savings (see figures 4 and 5).To the extent that European nominal
rigidities prevent it from adjusting to the decline in demand for its exports to the United States, its real
economy could suffer. China, with its currency pegged to the dollar, would not have to adjust much
and would gain a competitive advantage in the U.S. market—especially against Europe.
In addition, it is argued that, to the extent that the imbalances have been financed by foreign—especially East Asian—central banks’ accumulation of U.S. treasury bills (up to 65 percent of their international reserves), some point will be reached where these central banks will dump their depreciating dollar assets and shift their portfolios towards the euro, thereby aggravating the situation.
The current situation is often attributed to the IT boom of the 1990s, which induced a massive
private capital inflow to U.S. equity markets.The bursting of the tech boom (bubble) in 2000, followed
by 9/11, a U.S. recession, and the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq, led to a shift of the U.S. budget deficit
from surplus to a deficit of close to 4 percent of GDP. This twin deficit problem is viewed as a key
determinant of the deteriorating situation (Frankel 2004).

The Benign View
An alternate view does not regard the outlook in such bleak terms. It posits that adjustment will be
smooth, protracted, and benign, very much like what happened in the late 1980s, when the U.S. current account deficit recorded a peak of about 4 percent of GDP.This view (see, for example, Greenspan 2003) stresses the underlying force of financial globalization—a burgeoning phenomenon since
the 1970s and one which has encouraged residents of open economies to increase their holdings of
foreign assets as a way to diversify portfolios and smooth out shocks to consumption.
Global assets and liabilities have mushroomed in the past three decades, especially in the 1990s
(Lane and Milesi-Ferreti 2005). Globalization and a decline in home bias—a tendency of domestic investors to prefer domestic assets in their portfolios—have deepened and broadened financial markets
around the world and, above all, in the United States, which has seen a disproportionate growth in the
demand for its assets because it offers a higher real rate of return based on the economy’s long-run
good performance.

1

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

FIGURE 1

NUMBER 13, JANUARY 2006

CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCE
Billions of dollars
200

Percent of GDP
2

100

1

0

0

–100

–1

–200

–2

–300

–3

–400

–4

–500

–5

–600

–6

–700

–7
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Services.
FIGURE 2

NET INTERNATIONAL INVESTMENT POSITION—CURRENT COST BASIS

Trillions of dollars
2

Percent of GDP
20

1.1

15

1

10

0.5

5

0

0

–0.5

–5

–1

–10

–1.5

–15

–2

–20

–2.5

–25

–3

–30

–3.5

–35
1980

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Services.

FIGURE 3

NOMINAL TRADE-WEIGHTED MAJOR CURRENCY EXCHANGE RATE

Index, March 1973 = 100
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
70

1973

1977

1981

1989

1989

1993

1997

2001

2005

Sources: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, “Selected Interest Rates,”
Federal Reserve Statistical Releases, H.15; and Bloomberg Financial Services.

2

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Thus in this view, the current account deficit and the rise in U.S. net foreign liabilities reflect the
demand for U.S. instruments by foreigners. Adjustment, to the extent it needs occur, will be benign
because the underlying long-run positive fundamentals will continue, and for two additional reasons:
valuation and a reduced pass-through. Valuation effects refer to the fact that, to the extent dollar depreciation is unexpected, it will reduce the value of U.S. foreign liabilities (Gourinchas and Rey 2004).
A reduced pass-through is suggested by recent empirical evidence, which shows that only a very
small fraction of dollar depreciation passes through to higher inflation (Greenspan 2005).

Globalizing Capital Flows and the Adjustment Mechanism:
A Benign Outcome a Century Ago
A different and perhaps enlightening perspective on the issue is to delve into economic history for
earlier episodes of global imbalances, which may have some resonance for today and which may tell
us what is in store for the future. An important precedent for the benign outcome view is the previous era of financial globalization, which took place from 1870 to 1914. It was characterized by a rapid
FIGURE 4

EURO-AREA’S CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCE

Percent of GDP

Billions of euros
30

1.5

20

1.0

10

0.5

0

0.0

–10

–0.5

–20

–1.0

–30

1980

–1.5

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

FIGURE 5

JAPAN’S CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCE

Trillions of yen

Percent of GDP

6

6

5

5

4

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

–1

–1

–2

–2

–3
1980

–3
1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

3

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 13, JANUARY 2006

global buildup of external assets and liabilities and also of long-standing current account imbalances
comparable to today’s experience.
The 50 years before World War I saw massive net private flows of capital from the core countries of
Western Europe to the countries of recent settlement overseas (mainly the rapidly developing Americas and Australasia), financing railroads and other infrastructure as well as budget deficits (especially
in the form of bonds but also in the form of foreign direct investment). At the peak, the associated
current account surpluses in Britain reached 9 percent of GDP and were almost as big in France,
Germany, and the Netherlands (See figure 6). For the principal capital importers in the late nineteenth
century (Argentina, Australia, and Canada), current account deficits exceeded 5 percent of GDP on
average. Earlier in the century, the United States experienced similar flows but by the century’s end it
began to run current account surpluses.
In addition, data on ratios of stocks of foreign assets and liabilities to GDP for selected countries
and regions, compiled in Obstfeld and Taylor (2003), presents a picture of a u-shaped pattern. At its
pre–1914 peak, the share of foreign assets to world GDP was approximately 20 percent. It declined
from that level to a low of 5 percent in 1945, with the prewar level only being reached by 1985.After
that point, it rose to 57 percent by 1995.A similar picture emerges from the ratio of liabilities to overall
GDP.
The British held the lion’s share of overseas investments in 1914—50 percent—followed by
France at 22 percent, Germany at 17 percent, the United States at 6.5 percent, and the Netherlands at
3 percent. By comparison, the United States held 25 percent of global assets in 1995. These funds in
turn represented up to one-half of the capital stock of one of the major debtors (Argentina) and close
to one-fifth for Australia and Canada.

FIGURE 6

CURRENT ACCOUNT BALANCES (PERCENT OF GDP)

SURPLUS COUNTRIES (DURING GOLD STANDARD)
10
8

United Kingdom

6
4

Germany

2
0
–2

France

–4
–6
1880 1883 1886 1889 1892 1895 1898 1901 1904 1907 1910 1913

DEFICIT COUNTRIES (DURING GOLD STANDARD)
15
10
5
0
–5
–10
–15
Canada
Australia
–20
Argentina
–25
–30
–35
1880 1883 1886 1889 1892 1895 1898 1901 1904 1907 1910 1913

SOURCE: Obsteld and Taylor (2003).

4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

A striking feature of the pre–1914 data is the persistence of imbalances in the current account.
Bordo, Eichengreen, and Kim (1998), using the coefficients of an AR(1) regression as well as an augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, find evidence of significantly greater persistence in both the deficits
of the principal capital recipients and the capital exporters compared to the recent experience. Similar evidence is seen in variance ratios calculated by the authors.
Finally, the mechanism of adjustment to the massive capital transfer worked very smoothly. It occurred through the price-specie-flow mechanism of the classical gold standard (Bordo 1984). The
transfer of long-term capital from Europe to the New World to finance railroads and other infrastructure was also accompanied by gold flows as the demand, for example, for U.S. railroad bonds by British
investors led to a demand for dollars, pushing the dollar to the gold-import point.The gold inflows in
turn tended to raise the price of U.S. exports relative to imports, that is, to improve the terms of trade,
(as well as raise the ratio of the prices of traded and nontraded goods). It also allowed the United
States to import more goods than otherwise—much of these imports consisting of capital goods such
as rails from Britain.As relative prices adjusted, the gold flows would tend to be reversed, closing the
imbalance. Moreover, short-term capital movements speeded up adjustment as gold flows into the
United States reduced interest rates relative to Britain.
Many believe that the smooth adjustment to the capital transfers of the pre–1914 era reflects the
fact that the world was on the gold standard, which provided a stable and credible nominal anchor.
The gold standard also served as a signal of fiscal rectitude (“a good housekeeping seal of approval”),
which assured investors that their debt would be repaid and serviced (Bordo and Rockoff 1996).Also,
many of the capital recipients were part of the British Empire, which established institutions and
safeguards that virtually eliminated country risk. For example, colonial (Dominion) governments were
given debt trustee status in the United Kingdom (which meant they had a de facto British government
guarantee).
However, the adjustment mechanism in the earlier era of globalization was not always benign.
Although current account imbalances were more long-lived in the pre–1914 era than in the recent
period, they were punctuated in some countries by severe reversals, especially in the crisis-ridden
1890s (Bordo and Eichengreen 1999). The classic financial crisis of the era was the Barings crisis of
1890, which began with a debt default in Argentina and spread like wildfire to the rest of the emerging world. Lenders in London and Paris cut off capital flows to emerging countries like Brazil (Triner
and Wandschneider 2005) with fundamentals similar to those of Argentina, while other countries
deemed sound, such as Canada, were only marginally affected (Bordo and Murshid 2000). Thus the
emerging-market crisis problem had historical precedents. Most of the countries affected, those of
Latin America and Southern Europe, lacked the fundamentals, specifically, institutions and policies,
associated with the more successful recipients.
Although the imbalances of the previous age of globalization has considerable resonance for today—especially the fact that both eras were characterized by stable meta regimes (the gold standard
then and the adherence by many countries today to credible domestic nominal anchors, such as
inflation targeting and norms for fiscal balance), there are also considerable differences. First, under
the gold standard, countries of new settlement—the emerging markets of the time—ran current account deficits, while the major European economies ran surpluses. In the current era, there is no such
delineation: some major economies run persistent deficits, some persistent surpluses, and the same is
true of emerging-market economies.

5

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 13, JANUARY 2006

Second, before 1914, gross capital flows were much smaller than they are today, and gross asset and
liability positions were very close to net positions, in contrast to today, where most major industrial
countries are either major creditors or debtors. The earlier pattern reflects the prevalence of longterm investment by the core countries in the countries of new settlement.The substantial growth of
two-way flows between advanced countries since 1980 has been associated with both international
financial diversification and intertemporal consumption smoothing.
Third, the adjustment mechanism is different. The historical record shows that adjustment to the
significant and persistent external imbalances in the pre-1914 era occurred largely through the Humean price-specie-flow mechanism of the classical gold standard. In contrast, the global economy is
now on a managed floating exchange rate regime, and instead of gold flows, the brunt of the external
adjustment occurs through changes in the exchange rate and international reserves, along with relative price movements, short-term capital flows, and valuation effects (Obstfeld 2004).
Finally, in the pre–1914 era, Great Britain was the dominant country. Its currency, the pound, served
as the international medium of exchange and as a key reserve asset. Great Britain ran considerable current account surpluses throughout the period. By contrast, the United States is the dominant economy
today and the dollar is the key currency, but the United States has been running persistent current
account deficits.

Further Lessons from History: Some Bad Outcomes
History also gives two other, not-so-rosy scenarios of global imbalances and how they were adjusted
to: the interwar gold exchange standard and the Bretton Woods system.

The Interwar Adjustment
World War I ended the classical gold standard as all of the belligerents except the U.S. abandoned gold
convertibility. Private capital flows also ceased.After the war, by 1926, the major countries returned to
a variant of the gold standard, the gold exchange standard in which members held most of their international reserves in dollars, sterling, and francs, and the U.S., Great Britain, and France held gold.
But the interwar gold exchange standard had serious flaws, which prevented smooth adjustments
to the imbalances that built up (Meltzer 2003, Eichengreen 1992).The key problem was that the major
countries returned to gold at misaligned real exchange rates.All the belligerents had serious inflations
during the war, and the restoration of the original gold parities involved deflation and recession. As it
turned out, Britain restored parity at $4.86 with an overvalued real exchange rate while France and
Germany each greatly devalued their currencies and restored parities at undervalued real levels (see
figure 7). Although the United States never left the gold standard during the war, U.S. prices did not
return to the prewar level, so that the country’s postwar real exchange rate was also undervalued.
This misalignment meant that the United States, France, and Germany tended to run current account
surpluses while Britain, its empire, and the countries economically linked to it ran deficits. Under the
gold standard, this meant that gold tended to flow toward the surplus countries. Also, under the gold
standard rules, both creditors and debtors were supposed to adjust to the imbalances—creditors by
allowing domestic price levels to rise, debtors by deflation. As it turned out, both the United States
and France continuously sterilized their gold flows and prevented adjustment (Meltzer 2003). As a
consequence, they imposed deflationary pressure on Britain and on the rest of the world.
Another important difference between the classical and interwar gold standards that impaired the
adjustment mechanism in the latter was the lack of credibility in the member countries’ adherence to

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

gold convertibility. Unlike in the earlier period, markets had limited confidence that countries would
always put external balance considerations before domestic policy concerns (Eichengreen 1992).
This meant that short-term capital movements could be destabilizing. In the end, the system collapsed
after 1929 in the face of the Great Depression. Speculative attacks against countries that used expansionary monetary policy to alleviate banking panics and to stabilize the real economy forced country
after country to abandon the gold standard (Eichengreen 1992).This was not the case for the United
States however; it had adequate gold reserves to withstand speculative attacks (Bordo, Choudhri, and
Schwartz 2002). The United States left the gold standard in 1933 as part of Roosevelt’s policy package
to reflate the U.S. economy (Meltzer 2003).

The Bretton Woods Adjustment
Under the post–World War II Bretton Woods system, a distant variant of the gold standard, the United
States was the dominant country, with the largest gold reserves (Bordo 1993). Under Bretton Woods’
rules, the United States had to peg the dollar to gold at $35.00 per ounce, and the rest of the world
pegged to the dollar.The rest of the world used dollars as international reserves, and the dollar served
as the international medium of exchange.The United States was also supposed to follow stable monetary and fiscal policies.
During the period 1959–1971, when the system fully operated (most members had current account convertibility), the United States ran persistent current account and trade surpluses and also
engaged in considerable foreign investment.The overall balance of payments was generally in deficit
and the rest of the world absorbed dollar claims (see figure 8). At the same time it is argued that the
principal continental European countries and Japan kept their real exchange rates deliberately undervalued in order to foster export-driven growth in their economies (Dooley et al. 2002).This policy
meant that they kept accumulating dollars, which they sterilized, just as the United States and France
had during the interwar period. It has been argued that during this period, the United States acted
as financial intermediary to the rest of the world, importing short-term capital (dollar claims) and
exporting long-term capital (McKinnon 1969).
From 1961 to 1967, Europe and Japan’s holding of dollar claims convertible into gold kept increasing relative to gold holdings in the United States, suggesting the possibility of a run on the dollar (see
figure 9).

FIGURE 7

REAL EXCHANGE RATES (CPI)
U.S. dollar/U.K. pound

U.S. dollar/French franc
$0.03

$5.40
$5.20

$0.02

United States

$5.00
$0.02

$4.80
$4.60

France

$0.01

$4.40
$0.01

$4.20

$0.00

$4.00
1924

1925

1926

1927

1928

1929

1930

1931

Note: The dollar–pound parity in 1925 was $4.86, and the dollar–franc parity
in 1927 was $0.0392.
Source: Bordo et al. 2001.

7

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 13, JANUARY 2006

McKinnon (1969), Meltzer (1991), and others have argued that the system could have continued
for an extended period as a de facto dollar standard. However, two factors led to the collapse of the
Bretton Woods system. First, the French resented the United States’“exorbitant privilege” of not having to adjust to its payments imbalances because it was the principal reserve country.They wanted
a return to a pure gold standard, and to facilitate this outcome, they converted their outstanding
dollar claims into gold. Second, the United States began to follow inflationary monetary and fiscal
policies beginning in 1965—to finance the Vietnam War and the Great Society.
The expansionary policies increased both the U.S. payments deficit and European central bank
reserves, as the United States exported its inflation abroad.As a consequence, the Europeans began
converting their dollar claims into gold, threatening U.S. gold reserves.The system collapsed when
Richard Nixon closed the gold window in August 1971.
It has been argued that a reincarnated Bretton Woods system exists today. China, possibly India,
and other countries are seen as deliberately running an undervalued peg against the dollar to encourage export-driven growth the way Europe and Japan did 40 years ago (Dooley et al. 2002).The
central banks of these countries willingly accumulate dollar assets consequent upon their current
FIGURE 8

BALANCE OF PAYMENTS: UNITED STATES, 1950–1971 (MILLIONS OF U.S. DOLLARS)

8,000
Current account
4,000
0
Long-term capital
–4,000
Short-term capital
–8,000
–12,000
Change in reserves

–16,000

–20,000
1950 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70

SOURCE: Bordo (1993).
FIGURE 9

MONETARY GOLD AND DOLLAR HOLDINGS: THE UNITED STATES AND THE REST OF
THE WORLD, 1945–1971 (BILLIONS OF U.S. DOLLARS)

70
60
50
External dollar liabilities

40
U.S. monetary gold stock
30

Rest of the world
monetary gold stock

20
10

External dollar liabilities
held by monetary authorities

0
1945 47

49

51

53

55

SOURCE: Bordo (1993).

8

57

59

61

63

65

67

69

71

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

account surpluses. Dooley et al. argue that such a relationship could persist for as long as a decade to
allow China to absorb its 200 million surplus agricultural workers into the manufacturing sector.
Others argue that the reincarnated system will not last for 10 years but will collapse much sooner
because, unlike the Europeans in the 1960s, Asian central banks do not have a stable cartel (Eichengreen 2004). Furthermore, in the Bretton Woods era, there were no good substitutes for the dollar as
the world’s reserve asset (the pound was a reserve asset, but it was weak), but today we have the euro.
They predict the system will collapse quickly.

What Will Happen?
We have illustrated three historical episodes of external imbalances and their adjustment.Two ended in
a collapse.The third worked remarkably well. Which episode is more relevant to today’s environment?
My bet is a benign outcome, like that of the prewar gold standard era. In today’s world, the underlying
fundamental of globalization and the basic strength of the U.S. economy—which will continue to underpin the dollar as a reserve asset—suggest that adjustment to the present set of imbalances will be
gradual, and, when all is said and done, the experience will be viewed as similar to what happened in
the late 1980s.

References
Blanchard, Olivier, Francesco Giavazzi, and Filipa Sa.“The U.S. Current Account and the Dollar.” National
Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 11137, February 2005.
Bordo, Michael D., Ehsan Choudhri, and Anna J. Schwartz. “Was Expansionary Monetary Policy
Feasible During the Great Contraction?” Explorations in Economic History, January 2002.
Bordo, Michael D., Barry Eichengreen, Daniela Klingebiel, and Maria Soledad Martinez-Peria.
“Is the Crisis Problem Growing More Severe?” Economic Policy, vol. 32 (April 2001), pp. 53–82.
Bordo, Michael D. , and Antu Murshid. 2001,“Are Financial Crises Becoming More Contagious: What
is the Historical Evidence on Contagion?” In Stijn Claessens and Kristin J. Forbes (eds.), International
Financial Contagion, Boston: Kluwer, 2001, pp. 367–403.
Bordo, Michael D., and Barry Eichengreen. “Is Our Current International Economic Environment
Unusually Crisis Prone?” In David Gruen and Luke Gower (eds.), Capital Flows and the International
Financial System, Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia, 1999, pp.18–75.
Bordo, Michael D., Barry Eichengreen, and Jong Woo Kim. “Was There Really an Earlier Period of
International Financial Integration Compared to Today?” In The Implications of Globalization of
world Financial Markets. Seoul:Bank of Korea, 1998.
Bordo, Michael D., and Hugh Rockoff. “The Gold Standard as a Good-Housekeeping Seal of Approval.”
Journal of Economic History, vol. 56 (1996), pp.389–428.
Bordo, Michael D. “The Bretton Woods International Monetary System: A Historical Overview.”
In Michael D. Bordo and Barry Eichengreen (eds.), A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993.

9

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 13, JANUARY 2006

Bordo, Michael D. “The Gold Standard: The Traditional Approach.” In Michael D. Bordo and
Anna J. Schwartz (eds.) A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, 1821–1931. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984.
Dooley, Michael P., David Folkerts-Landau, and Peter Garber. “An Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods
System.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 9971 (September 2002).
Eichengreen, Barry. “Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods.” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper, no. 10497 (2004).
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters. New York Oxford University Press, 1992.
Frankel, Jeffrey. “Twin Deficits and Twin Decades,” unpublished manuscript, Harvard University,
May 2004.
Greenspan, Alan. “Current Accounts,” remarks given at the Advancing Enterprise 2005 conference,
London, England, February 4, 2005.
Greenspan, Alan. Remarks on the 21st Annual Monetary Conference, cosponsored by the Cato
Institute and the Economist. Washington, D.C. , November 20, 2003.
Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. “Financial Globalization and Exchange Rates,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper, no. 05/03 (2005).
Mckinnon, Ronald.“Private and Official Money:The Case for the Dollar.” In Princeton Essays in International Economics. Princeton University, International Finance Section, 1969.
Meltzer, Allan. A History of the Federal Reserve, vol. I, 1913–1951. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 2003.
Meltzer,Allan.“U.S. Policy in the Bretton Woods Era.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Review, vol. 73
(May/June 1991), pp. 54–83.
Obstfeld, Maurice. “External Adjustment,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper, no. 10843 (October 2004).
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. “The Unsustainable Current Account Position Revisited,”
National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, no. 10869 (October 2004).
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Alan Taylor. Global Capital Markets: Integration, Crisis and Growth.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Helene Rey. “International Financial Adjustment” National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper, no. 11155 (2005).
Triner, Gail, and Kirsten Wandschneider. “International Capital and the Brazilian Encilhamento,
1889–1892: An Early Example of Contagion among Emerging Markets.” Financial History Review
(2005).

10

pd
papers
Presorted Standard
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND
RESEARCH DEPARTMENT
P.O. BOX 6387

U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit no. 385

CLEVELAND, OHIO 44101

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing
label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research
Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101.