View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

pd
papers

NUMBER 30

by Paul Gomme

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R

Evaluating the Macroeconomic
Effects of a Temporary Investment
Tax Credit

J A N UA R Y 2 0 0 2

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Evaluating the Macroeconomic
Effects of a Temporary Investment
Tax Credit

Paul Gomme is an economic
advisor at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. He thanks
Ed Nosal and Mark Sniderman
for helpful comments.

by Paul Gomme
As part of a fiscal stimulus package, some members of Congress have recently proposed a temporary
investment subsidy. This paper uses the neoclassical growth model to evaluate the likely macroeconomic effects of such a subsidy. The model predicts a 0.8 percentage point increase in output
growth in the quarter that the policy is implemented. In subsequent quarters, the output growth effects
are negligible. As the subsidy ends, output growth falls 1 percentage point before returning to its trend
growth rate. While a permanent subsidy will lead to more capital deepening in the long term, it also
represents a permanent fall in government revenues. Under a temporary subsidy, there is less capital
deepening, but the decline in government revenues is likewise more modest.

Materials may be reprinted if the
source is credited. Please send
copies of reprinted materials to
the editor.
We invite questions, comments,
and suggestions. E-mail us at
editor@clev.frb.org.

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland. To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050.
Policy Discussion Papers are available electronically through the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World
Wide Web: www.clev.frb.org/Research.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Introduction
As part of a fiscal stimulus package, some members of Congress have recently proposed a temporary
investment subsidy. A candidate proposal is to allow companies to immediately expense 30 percent of
investment purchases made in the three-year period starting September 11, 2001; the remaining 70
percent is subject to the standard expensing provisions. This proposal may be motivated by the fact
that capital deepening has been an important source of economic growth, particularly during the last
expansion. This paper evaluates the likely consequences of implementing such a policy within a neoclassical growth model.
The proposed investment subsidy is temporary, but the available empirical evidence tells us only
about the effects of permanent investment subsidies. Because of the lack of empirical data on the
effects of temporary subsidies, we use a model to evaluate the effects of both permanent and temporary subsidies. Lucas (1976) shows that we should expect a temporary subsidy to have much different
quantitative implications than a permanent one. In particular, when the subsidy is temporary, firms
will have an incentive to change the timing of some of their capital spending in order to qualify for it.
Obviously, government policies change over time. We want to consider an environment in which
firms rationally entertain the possibility of changes in government policy. In such an environment, there
is a sense in which it would be irrational for firms to believe that any government policy is truly
permanent. However, we can consider policies that are very long lived. So even for a permanent
subsidy, our model allows a 1 percent probability that the subsidy will end. In particular, when a permanent subsidy is in place, there is a 99 percent probability that it will also be in place in the next
quarter. Likewise, if no subsidy is currently in force, this situation will also persist into the next quarter with a probability of 99 percent. Naturally, firms’ decisions take these probabilities into account.
It is straightforward to show that, on average, periods of no subsidy will last 100 quarters (25 years);
subsidy periods, likewise, last an average of 25 years. Of course, the probabilistic nature of changes in
government policy imply that these periods may be longer or shorter than 25 years.
Next, we consider a temporary tax subsidy as currently proposed, and treat it as follows: We assume
that there is a 1 percent likelihood that a three-year (12-quarter) investment subsidy will be put in place
in the current quarter if no subsidy was in place during the previous quarter. At the end of that time,
the investment subsidy ends; there is no uncertainty about either the length of the subsidy period, or
the fact that the subsidy will end on the date announced. In future periods (after the end of the subsidy), there is a 1 percent chance of a temporary subsidy, again lasting 12 quarters. As with permanent
subsidies, firms’ decisions incorporate the likelihood of these changes in policy. Notice that while temporary subsidy periods last exactly 12 quarters, periods of no subsidy will last on average 100 quarters.

Investment Behavior

1. A detailed description of the
model is presented in the
technical appendix.

For the purposes of analyzing the effects of a subsidy to investment, the key relationship is the one governing firms’ investment decisions.1 Firms face a cost of financing capital expenditures; we express that
cost as an interest rate and call it the required rate of return.2 We can think of this required rate of return
as the interest rate that firms would have to pay on a bank loan or corporate bonds. Each firm has a
large number of potential investment projects that it could finance. The firm will implement those
projects that have a rate of return at least equal to the required rate of return.

2. In the model, this required rate of
return is determined by shareholders’
preferences for goods today versus
goods in the future. By investing
more today, the firm reduces its current dividends, and so its shareholders’ current consumption. This
investment pays off in the form of
higher future dividends, and so
higher future consumption.

1

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 3 , J A N UA R Y 2 0 0 2

The investment subsidy affects the effective price paid by firms for investment goods, and so the
rate of return earned on investments. Consider a project that previously yielded a rate of return just
equal to the required rate of return. Since this project still yields the same output and profits as before,
the rate of return on the project must rise since its price has fallen. Intuitively, this situation is similar
to what happens when the price of a bond falls while the coupon payments are unchanged; the effective yield of the bond rises. Since the return on all potential investment projects rises with the implementation of an investment subsidy, firms will increase the number of investment projects that they
fund. This basic intuition, implying that firms will increase their capital spending, holds within the
model despite the fact that there are general equilibrium effects at work that serve to increase the
required rate of return. Specifically, there are strong consumption-smoothing forces in the model that
imply the level of the capital stock adjusts gradually over time rather than all at once.
This paper uses a variant of the neoclassical growth model to analyze the effects of the investment
subsidy. An important property of the model is that it has a unique steady state.3 That is to say, if we
thought about running an arbitrarily long simulation of the model during which all sources of
randomness are suppressed (in the current context, the investment subsidy remains at, say, zero), then
eventually all variables will remain constant. A positive subsidy will result in a new steady state. While
we could compare these steady states, we are more interested in the time paths of things like capital,
investment, and output. If we only compared steady states, it would be difficult to make sensible statements about the effects of a temporary subsidy since, by its very nature, the temporary investment
subsidy does not affect steady-state variables. Furthermore, by looking at time paths, we can consider
the extent to which investment subsidies shift the timing of firms’ investment.

A Permanent Investment Subsidy
To understand the longer-term effects of investment subsidies, we start by considering a permanent
investment subsidy of 1.5 percent. Because there is a 99 percent likelihood that the subsidy persists into
the next quarter, the expected value of the subsidy next quarter is slightly less than in the current quarter. In fact, it is 99 percent of the current subsidy rate. Consequently, firms act as if the subsidy will be
in place into the indefinite future.
Recall that the subsidy raises the effective return on all investment projects. As a result, we expect
the level of investment to rise permanently. Since an increase in investment leads to a higher capital
stock, we expect the capital stock to rise as well. These predictions are borne out as can be seen in
figure 1. In the long run, the capital stock rises almost 5.1 percent above its previous level (that is, without the investment subsidy). However, it takes a long time for the capital stock to fully adjust to its
new level. Roughly half of the adjustment is achieved within seven years of the implementation of the
subsidy. Investment responds a bit differently. It immediately rises 7.5 percent above its previous level,
but in the longer run, the level of investment rises only 5.1 percent, the same percentage increase as
the capital stock. This is not a coincidence. The increase in the capital stock implies that there will be
more depreciation. Consequently, (gross) investment must rise in the long run to replace the depreciating capital. As the model economy settles into a new steady state, net investment (that is, net additions to the capital stock) falls to zero.

2

3. Strictly speaking, a second steady
state exists in which there is no economic activity.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

We can, alternatively, express the effects of the permanent subsidy in terms of its effects on the
growth rates of investment and output. As shown in figure 2(a), the growth rate of investment spikes
up 7.5 percent in the quarter that the subsidy is put in place. Thereafter, the growth rate of investment
is actually slightly negative, reflecting the gradual decline in investment shown in figure 1(b). The
effect on the growth rate of output is similar to that on investment. On impact, the growth rate of
output rises almost 0.65 percent; in subsequent quarters, the subsidy has a small but positive effect on
output growth as shown in figure 2(b).
FIGURE 1

R E S P O N S E O F C A P I TA L A N D I N V E S T M E N T T O
PERMANENT AND TEMPORARY SUBSIDIES
(a) Capital
Percent
6

5
Permanent
4

3

2
Temporary
1
Steady state (no subsidy)
0

–1
2005

2010

2015

2020

2025

2030

2020

2025

2030

(b) Investment
Percent
12

10

8
Permanent
6

4
Temporary
2
Steady state (no subsidy)

0

–2
2005

2010

2015

3

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 3 , J A N UA R Y 2 0 0 2

A Temporary Subsidy
As described above, under this scenario firms know that the investment subsidy will be in place for
exactly 12 quarters, or three years. Returning to figure 1, we can see the effect of such a subsidy. The
capital stock rises while the investment subsidy is in place, then gradually falls back to its previous level.
Compared to the permanent subsidy case, the capital stock rises faster while the subsidy is in place.
At its peak in 2004:IIIQ, capital is 2.2 percent above its previous level when the subsidy is temporary,
compared with 1.5 percent when it is permanent. As shown in figure 1(b), the level of investment is
also correspondingly higher under a temporary subsidy. Again, the peak is in 2004:IIIQ. When the
subsidy is temporary, investment rises 11.4 percent above its presubsidy level; in the same quarter,
investment is 6.8 percent above trend under a permanent subsidy. Thus, the temporary subsidy
increases the amount of investment 4.6 percent more than the permanent subsidy.
FIGURE 2

G R O W T H R AT E R E S P O N S E S T O P E R M A N E N T A N D T E M P O R A R Y S U B S I D I E S

(a) Investment
Percent
10

5

Permanent

0

–5
Temporary
–10

–15
2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

(b) Output
Percent
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
Permanent
0
–0.2
–0.4
–0.6
Temporary
–0.8
–1.0
2001

4

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Once the subsidy ends, the price of capital rises, and firms lower their investment levels. The last
quarter the subsidy is in place is 2004:IIIQ, so firms reduce their investment starting in 2004:IVQ.
In the model, firms react in a predictable way to the temporary nature of the investment subsidy.
Specifically, they change the timing of some of their capital spending, moving it from quarters beyond
2004:IIIQ to quarters for which the investment subsidy is in place. Thus, we observe that the increase
in the level of investment is as temporary as the investment subsidy. Figure 1(b) shows that the level
of investment falls sharply after the investment subsidy expires in 2004:IVQ. In fact, investment is
about 1 percent below its previous level for two years after the end of the subsidy as firms adjust their
capital stocks back to their previous (presubsidy) levels.
In terms of growth rates, the growth of investment rises over 9.3 percentage points on impact, compared with 7.5 percentage points under a permanent subsidy. Throughout the subsidy period, investment
remains slightly above its previous level with a temporary subsidy—about 0.1 percent in 2001:IVQ,
rising to 0.25 percent in 2004:IIQ. However, in 2004:IVQ, the growth in investment plunges to –11.2
percent. Thereafter, investment growth is slightly positive. The effects on output growth are fairly similar. In particular, on impact the investment subsidy raises output growth by 0.8 percentage point (compared with 0.65 percentage point when the subsidy is permanent). Through the remainder of the subsidy period, output growth is enhanced by less than 0.1 percentage point. In 2004:IVQ, output growth
falls 1 percentage point. In subsequent quarters, output growth is almost unchanged.

Summary
The neoclassical growth model described in this paper predicts that a temporary investment tax subsidy as described above will add roughly 0.8 percentage point to real output growth in the quarter that
the subsidy is implemented. In the model, firms know at the beginning of 2001:IVQ that the subsidy
will be in place in 2001:IVQ. Given the uncertainty over whether the subsidy will actually pass into
legislation, we would expect that firms are not yet incorporating the subsidy into their capital acquisition plans. Consequently, these growth effects may be delayed. In terms of growth effects, it is probably good that the proposed legislation applies to investments made since September 11, 2001. Were
this not the case, we would expect to see firms postponing their investment decisions, further lowering growth in the current quarter, until they see whether the legislation is enacted.
Under a temporary investment subsidy, the cost of boosting output and investment growth in
2001:IVQ is a subsequent fall in growth rates in 2004:IVQ as the subsidy ends. Specifically, the model
predicts that output growth will fall 1 percentage point in 2004:IVQ. However, just as the growthenhancing effect of the subsidy is felt primarily in the quarter that the subsidy is put in place, the growthreducing effect of the end of the subsidy is also a one-quarter phenomenon. The fall in investment and
output in 2004:IVQ could, of course, be avoided by making the subsidy permanent. Alternatively, the
effects could be smoothed out over time through a more gradual phaseout of the subsidy.
From a policymaker’s perspective, there are both costs and benefits of an investment subsidy. The
chief benefit is increased economic activity owing to capital deepening. An important cost is the shortfall in government revenues. While a permanent subsidy will lead to more capital deepening in the
long term, it also represents a permanent fall in government revenues. Under a temporary subsidy,
there is less capital deepening, but the decline in government revenues is likewise more modest.
5

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 3 , J A N UA R Y 2 0 0 2

There are a number of caveats to the analysis presented in this paper. First, the proposed legislation applies only to equipment and software with a life of 20 years or less. In the model, we assume
that all capital expenditures (that is, those with lifespans longer than 20 years) received the subsidy.
Consequently, the model likely overstates the growth rate effects. Since equipment and software investment is roughly two-thirds of total nonresidential investment, the impact of the subsidy may be closer
to a 0.5 percentage point increase in output growth. Given the differential treatment of short-lived
versus long-lived capital, the subsidy can be expected to distort the mix of capital in favor of shortlived capital. Since the model does not distinguish between these two types of capital, it is largely silent
on this distortionary effect.
Second, in the model, we assume the temporary subsidy definitely ends after three years. It is not
inconceivable that legislators may later decide to extend the subsidy. This possibility is absent from the
model. If firms believe legislators are likely to extend the subsidy, then the analysis for the permanent
subsidy case is the more relevant.
Third, a “capital overhang” is one of the stories that has been put forth as an explanation for why
the U.S. economy entered a slowdown early in 2001. The essence of the overhang story is that firms
overestimated the productivity-enhancing effects of the “New Economy” and acquired too much capital. Firms subsequently cut back on their investment expenditures in order to bring their
actual capital stocks back into line with desired levels. Our analysis does not consider this possibility.
If firms are still adjusting their capital stocks downward, then it is unlikely that an investment subsidy
will have much effect on investment.
Fourth, the model is largely silent on the source of revenues used to finance the investment subsidy. In particular, the tax rates on labor and capital income are held fixed, and the subsidy is, in effect,
paid for by a lump-sum tax. To the extent that the subsidy will be paid for through distortionary taxes
(as opposed to nondistortionary lump-sum taxes)—either now or in the future—the subsidy may lead
to negative economic consequences.
Finally, in the model firms are able to immediately increase their investment spending. Accounting
for time-to-plan lags would delay the effects of the subsidy by the length of the planning period. For
example, if it takes a quarter to plan capital projects, we would expect to see the growth rate effects
starting in 2002:IQ. Incorporating time to build would tend to smooth the effects of the subsidy over
the number of quarters it takes to build capital. If it takes four quarters to build new capital, then
instead of a single quarter with output growth boosted 0.8 percentage point, we would expect to see
four quarters during which output growth is roughly 0.2 percentage point higher. By the same token,
time to build may cause investment to start falling before the end of the subsidy period, since some of
the investment would take place in the postsubsidy period.

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Technical Appendix: Neoclassical Growth Model

Households
The representative household has preferences over time-dated streams of consumption, ct, and leisure,
lt, given by:
∞

E0 ∑ βtU(ct lt ).
t=0

The household faces several constraints. First, the household must divide its time between leisure,
lt, and work, ht:
lt + ht = 1.
Second, it faces the following budget constraint:
ct + (1 – θt)xt = (1 – τH )wtht + (1 – τK )rtkt + δτKkt + Tt .
The right-hand side of the above equation represents sources of income. Here, wt is the real wage
while rt is the rental rate on capital. Labor earnings, wtht , are taxed at the rate τH while capital earnings, rtkt , are taxed at the rate τK . The term δτK kt represents a capital consumption allowance. Finally,
Tt is a lump-sum transfer received from the government. The left-hand side gives uses of income. The
household divides its income between consumption, ct , and investment, xt . θt is the rate at which
investment purchases are subsidized.
The final constraint is the law of motion for capital, kt :
kt+1 = (1 – δ) kt + xt .

Firms
In this model, firms face a static problem: Taking factor prices as given, the typical firm hires capital
and labor to maximize its profits,
F(Kt , Ht ) – rt Kt – wt Ht .
It is assumed that the production function, F, is constant returns to scale. Since firms are also perfect competitors, in equilibrium firms earn zero profits. Consequently, we did not have to account for
profit income when we specify the representative household’s problem.
We could have accounted for firm ownership by introducing equity into the model and allowing
firms to directly “own” capital. Provided firms act in the best interests of their shareholders (the representative household), the quantity allocations from the model will be the same. Firm ownership is suppressed in presenting the model since it merely complicates specifying the problems of the relevant economic actors.

7

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 3 , J A N UA R Y 2 0 0 2

Government
The only role for government in this economy is to raise taxes, then redistribute the proceeds back to
households in a lump-sum fashion. Since the government runs a balanced budget each period, its
budget constraint is:
Tt + δτK Kt + θt Xt = τH wt Ht + τK rt Kt .

The Investment Subsidy
To keep matters simple, assume that when investment is subsidized, the government does so at the rate
–

θ. Consequently,
–

θt ∈ {0, θ}.
Notice that the absence of the investment subsidy is achieved by setting θt = 0.

Temporary Subsidy
If at date t, θt = 0, then with probability π, θt +1 = 0. Alternatively, with probability 1 – π,
–

θt = θt +1 = … = θt +11 = θ,

θt +12 = 0.

That is to say, the tax subsidy is in place for exactly 12 quarters. Notice that while the subsidy lasts
exactly 12 quarters, the length of time between subsidies is random. On average, periods of no subsidy
last 1/(1 – π) quarters.

Permanent Subsidy
The permanent subsidy case is handled as a two-state Markov chain. We assume that the probability
of remaining in a particular subsidy state is the same for the two subsidy rates. Thus,
–

–

Pr[θt+1 = 0 | θt = 0] = Pr[θt+1 = θ | θt = θ ] = π.
Notice, then, that the probability of making a transition (no subsidy to positive subsidy or vice versa)
is 1 – π. While the duration of a particular state is random, on average a state will last 1/(1 – π) quarters.

Functional Forms and Calibration
The period utility function is given by:
U (c,l ) =

8

{

(c ωl

1–ω

)1–γ – 1
1–γ
ωlnc + (1 – ω)lnl

if 0 < γ < 1 or γ > 1
if γ = 1.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

The production function is parameterized as:
F(K,H) = K α H1–α,

0 < α < 1.

Parameter values are summarized in table 1. With the exception of the parameters governing the
investment subsidy, these parameters are typical of those used in the real business cycle literature. The
parameter ω, which governs the labor–leisure trade-off, was chosen so that in steady state households
work 33 percent of the time. This fraction matches up with evidence from time-use surveys.
TA B L E 1

PA R A M E T E R VA LU E S

Preferences
Risk aversion
Labor–leisure weight
Discount factor

γ
ω
β

1.0
0.46
0.99

Technology
Capital share
Depreciation

α
δ

0.36
0.02

Taxes
Labor

τH

0.25

τK

0.5

Capital
Investment Subsidy
Subsidy rate
Persistence probability

–

θ
π

0.015
0.99

References
Lucas, Robert E., Jr., “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique,” Carnegie–Rochester Conference
Series on Public Policy I, 1976, pp. 19–46.

9

pd
papers
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND
R E S E A R C H D E PA R T M E N T
P. O. B OX 6 3 8 7

Presorted Standard
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

C L E V E L A N D , O H I O 4 4 10 1

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing
label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research
Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101.