Full text of Money Market Essays
The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
MONEY MARKET ESSAYS Federal Reserve Bank of New York March 1952 MONEY MARKET ESSAYS Federal Reserve Bank of New York March 1952 FOREWORD This booklet is the second of a series of publications designed to furnish the student of banking with informa tion not readily available elsewhere, concerning various aspects of the national money market and factors affect ing it. The first of the series, Bank Reserves—Some Major Factors Affecting Them, was published in March 1951. All but the first of the articles in this second booklet appeared originally in the Monthly Review of Credit and Business Conditions of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York; the first article—“ The Money Market” —is the text of a talk given by its author at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. All have been brought up to date for this reprinting. The booklet comprises brief discussions of the more important elements in the private sector of the money market; we hope in the future to publish a com panion piece that will consider Governmental instruments and operations important to that market. Copies of this and the earlier booklet are available for classroom use and for similar purposes. A llan S pboul, President. New York City March 1952 MONEY MARKET ESSAYS Page The Money Market ................................................................................. 1 Member Bank Borrowing from the Federal Reserve Banks......................... 8 Federal Funds.......................................................................................... 13 The Commercial Paper Market................................................................ 17 Bankers’ Acceptances............................................................................... 22 Financing Security Brokers and Dealers.................................................... 27 THE MONEY MARKET ly H a r o ld V. 'TpHE financial pages of the newspapers, economists’ professional publications, and other periodicals make frequent reference to "the money market,” but the term is rarely defined. Probably the reason is that the money market is, in fact, a rather nebulous affair, consisting of interrelationships and transactions among varying participants, rather than a definite group of in dividuals like the members of the New York Stock Exchange or the Chicago Board of Trade; it has no specific location, as does an organized security or commodity market; and its principal activities have changed gradually but markedly over the years. In earlier periods, references to the money market were frequently so narrowly limited as to mean chiefly the market in which security trading and speculation was financed— the market for "call’' and "time” loans to security brokers and dealers, or "street loans” as they used to be called.1 At other times, the term has been used so broadly as to include long-term borrow ing and lending operations in the form o f security flotations. For the purposes of this discussion, "the money market” may be defined as the central national market in New York City where temporary surplus funds of various types of organizations (including secondary reserves of the banks) go to find in come-producing employment without sacrifice of liquidity, and where short-term needs for funds are satisfied, usually at interest rates that are ad vantageous to the borrower. It is a place where final adjustments between the supply of funds and the demand for funds are made for the country as a whole, after much regional clearing has been effected. In general, it is an impersonal market involving the usual lender-customer re lationships only to a limited extent. The openmarket borrower frequently has certain sources from which he expects to obtain part o f the funds he needs fairly regularly, but he usually 1 See the article beginning on p. 27. R o e ls e feels no obligation to go to any particular lender or group of lenders for his financing any longer than he considers that to be in his interest, and he gets his money from whatever source he can on the most favorable terms. Similarly, the lender in the money market ordinarily assumes no re sponsibility for financing the borrower any longer than suits his convenience. So u r c e s of F unds By far the most important source of money mar ket funds, usually, is commercial banks. For many years considerable amounts of the secondary re serves (and even primary reserves) of the com mercial banking system have tended to concentrate in New York City through the correspondent banking system, the amounts varying with the fluc tuations in public demands for currency and credit and the flow of funds throughout the country. This condition was especially true before the estab lishment of the Federal Reserve System when the large New York City banks provided a kind of limited central banking system. At that time, some of the funds of out-of-town banks were loaned or invested for them in "street loans,” short-term business paper, or securities, but considerable amounts were simply deposited with the New York City banks and those banks employed them in the money market if suitable outlets were available. In addition to facilitating deposits and withdrawals of funds by correspon dent banks, the New York City banks could to some extent (within the limits of their own re serve positions) increase the total volume of bank reserves by making loans to their correspondents. But their own reserve requirements were high and they seldom had very large amounts of excess reserves, so that their ability to supply additional funds to correspondent banks was rather narrowly limited. Consequently, when demands for funds from other parts o f the country were heavy, they tended to cause stringencies in the New York money market, which occasionally reached the 1 M o n e y M arket Essays 2 point of becoming money panics. It was this kind o f situation that led to the creation of the Federal Reserve System. portunities. Another, distinctly minor and quite irregular, source of funds is State and local governments It was expected that the establishment o f the and their subsidiary organizations, as well as some twelve regional Reserve Banks would end the agencies of the National Government. For ex concentration of bank reserve funds in New York ample, if a State government sells a bond issue and the dependence of the commercial banking for purposes which will involve disbursements system on the liquidity of the New York money over an extended period, such as a veterans’ bonus market after a transitional period. To a consider or a construction program, or accumulates funds able extent it did. But the practice o f sending to pay off a bond issue, it may wish to invest secondary reserves to New York (also primary some of the proceeds temporarily in the money reserves in the case o f many nonmember banks) market. For many years, especially since the first World continued and still prevails on a large scale. And, of course, the New York City banks lend or War, during the period in which New York City invest in the money market not only the funds has gained in importance as an international finan of their correspondents, but also considerable cial center, it has been the custom o f many foreign amounts of their own funds. Some of their most central banks to keep some of their reserves in temporary lending is to other banks, in the form New York in the form of earmarked gold or of sales of "Federal funds,” which will be dis dollar assets of various kinds. To a considerable extent dollar assets are kept on deposit in the cussed later. Reserve Banks, but frequently the foreign central The second major source of supply o f funds banks like to obtain some income on dollar funds for the New York money market has been tem they do not need to draw upon immediately. The porary surplus funds of business concerns. Many Federal Reserve Bank of New York began more national corporations maintain accounts with the than 25 years ago to buy bankers’ acceptances for New York City banks in which they deposit funds, foreign central banks in the market, and added for meeting interest and dividend payments, taxes, its guarantee of payment (for a fee), in behalf and other general expenses, and also such addi of all Federal Reserve Banks. But in recent yean, tional funds as are not needed at other points the supply of bankers’ acceptances has been insuf around the country for the conduct of their ficient to supply all such demands and several business. When these funds accumulate in foreign central banks have requested the invest amounts in excess of needs for current working ment o f some of their dollar funds in Treasury balances, and appear likely to remain idle at bills and other short-term Government securities. least for some foreseeable period ahead, it has New York agencies of foreign commercial been the common practice o f corporations to em banks also supply fairly sizable amounts of funds ploy them in short-term loans or investments if to the money market through loans to security suitable outlets are available and offer sufficient dealers and short-term investments. return to make it worth while. Furthermore, Finally, the Federal Reserve Banks serve as a business concerns frequently invest the proceeds residual source of supply of funds for the New of long-term security issues temporarily, pending York money market, but further discussion of that their use for capital expenditures. matter will be left until later. A smaller source of money market funds is in vesting institutions, such as insurance companies. So u r c e s o f D e m a n d f o r F u n d s These institutions normally employ most o f their Reference was made previously to the predomi funds in longer-term investments, but sometimes nance of brokers loans ("street loans” ) as a source enter the money market for substantial amounts o f o f . demand for funds in the money market in short-term securities, pending disbursements on earlier years. For many years security brokers their investment commitments or the development and dealers have borrowed on either a demand or of more attractive long-term investment op a time basis to finance their customers’ trading on F ederal R eserve B a n k o f N e w Y o rk margin, and to carry their own holdings of securities, to the extent that their "portfolios" have been in excess of their capital funds. Usually the greater part of their borrowing has been on a "call loan” basis— that is, it has been repayable on demand in clearing house funds, so that the lender could get his money back on one day’s no tice. These "street loans” were for many years considered the safest and most liquid available use for temporary surplus funds of banks and others. The only disadvantage— and frequently it proved to be an advantage— was that the yield was unpredictable, depending upon the relation ships between the total supply of funds and total demand for funds in the money market, and the consequent fluctuations in interest rates. The amount of such loans has fallen far below the volume of earlier years— to a range of about 200 to 800 million dollars since 1945, as compared with several billion dollars in the late ’20’s. In recent years borrowings on a demand basis by Government security dealers have been substantial (frequently 500 million to 1 billion dollars or more), but they have by no means taken the place of the "street loans” of earlier years. At least until the '20’s the next most important outlet for money market funds was open market commercial paper2— that is, short-term notes of well-known business concerns with strong credit ratings (for example, some o f the big milling companies and mail order houses), which are purchased by commercial paper dealers and resold by them, chiefly to banks. Such paper has long been attractive to banks all over the country (es pecially the "country” banks) as a means of employing their secondary reserves. This is still an active market, but not as important as in earlier years. Another type of business paper which was de veloped in the United States after the Federal Reserve System was established, and with its en couragement and support, is bankers’ acceptances8 or "bankers bills” (which were commonly referred to simply as "bills” until a new type of bill— the Treasury bill—was created about 20 years ago). These bankers’ acceptances, which are used a See the article beginning on p. 17. 8 See the article beginning on p. 22. 3 mainly in the financing of exports, imports, and storage of staple commodities, soon attained the rating of top-quality business paper, as in the form in which they are sold in the open market they represent two-name paper—that is, the bankers’ acceptance is not only the obligation of the concern on which it is drawn, but it is alsothe unconditional obligation of the "accepting” bank. In some instances it may also carry the en dorsement of the dealer by whom it is sold. Use of bankers’ acceptances has diminished considerably in the past 20 years because of low rates on direct loans, but has shown some revival recently. A minor and sporadic source of demand for money market funds is short-term borrowing by State and local governments. The commonest form is tax anticipation notes, which are frequently issued by local governments to provide them with funds, pending the receipt of large periodic tax payments. A considerable part of such borrowing is done in the local communities, but a fair amount is done in the New York money market. A far more important type of government borrowing in the money market developed from the adoption by the United States Treasury in 1929 of the practice of selling securities in the form of discount bills, generally maturing in 91 days, through competitive bidding.4 This represented an adaptation of British practices to the financial system of the United States. These Treasury bills are, of course, offered throughout the country, but a large proportion has been absorbed in the New York money market, and most of the trading subsequent to issuance is done in the New York money market. Even earlier—as far back as the first World War—short-term Treasury obligations in the form o f certificates of indebtedness had been a fairly important money market instrument. The certificates were sold at a fixed price, and for a number of years were commonly of one-year ma turity, whereas the Treasury bill provided weekly issues and redemptions of securities with shorter maturities (most commonly three months), and 4 These Treasury bills carry no interest coupons but are sold at prices slightly below par, the difference between the purchase price and the par value at maturity pro viding the income, or yield, on the investment (See article on "Marketing o f Treasury Bills” in the October, 1951 issue o f the Monthly Review o f the Federal Reserve Bank o f New York.) 4 M o n e y M arket Essays at prices and yields to be fixed in the market. For several years, Treasury bills replaced certificates of indebtedness entirely, but the use o f certificates was resumed during the second World War, and the volume of both types rose to unprecedented levels. Certificates were rapidly replaced by short-term Treasury notes during 1950, and disappeared en tirely at the beginning of 1951, but their use was resumed after a few months. In addition, obligations of Government-spon sored organizations, such as Federal Intermediate Credit Bank debentures, are minor sources of demand for funds in the money market. A final source of demand for short-term funds in the money market is the banks themselves, chiefly the large city banks. The reference here is to interbank borrowings of immediately available reserve funds or "Federal funds.” 6 These dealings involve the transfer of reserve balances on the books of the Federal Reserve Bank, from the reserve account of the lending bank to the reserve account of the borrowing bank, generally through an exchange of checks, one drawn by the lending bank on the Federal Reserve Bank payable im mediately, and the other by the borrowing bank on itself payable through the clearing house the next business day (i.e., "clearing house funds” ) . In other words, they represent day-to-day loans between banks. Most of the transactions are be tween New York Gty banks, although not infre quently large banks in other cities are also in volved—probably more often as lenders than as borrowers— in which case borrowings and repay ments of reserve funds are effected by telegraphic transfers. O r g a n iz a tio n of the M oney M arket Several different types of organizations are in volved in the mechanism of the money market: 1. The large New York Gty banks, sometimes referred to as the "money market banks” or the "Wall Street” banks (although most o f them are not located on Wall Street); 2. Dealers in securities, especially Government security dealers; 3. Commercial paper dealers; 4. Bankers’ acceptance or "bill” dealers; 5. Money brokers, whose function it is to 6 See the article beginning on p. 13. know who in the money market is in need of quickly available funds, and who has money to lend (although much less is heard now of this function than in earlier times); 6. Federal Reserve Banks. There is no clean-cut separation of functions among all these various types of organizations. For example, the dealer in bankers’ acceptances is likely to be a dealer in Government securities, and at times may also serve as a money broker. The Government security dealer may be a dealer in other securities as well; he may act as a broker as well as a buyer and seller on his own account; he is almost always a borrower. The role of the commercial bank in the money market is pre dominantly that of a lender of funds, either on its own account or on behalf of its correspondent banks or other customers; but the commercial bank is also a buyer and seller of short-term Govern ment securities and frequently of other types of open market paper; and, as was noted previously, the large city banks are often day-to-day borrowers of reserve funds. A few o f the large New York Gty and Chicago banks serve as dealers in Govern ment securities, in which case they are sometimes referred to as "dealer-banks.” While all the different organizations have im portant functions to perform in facilitating the smooth operation of the money market, easily the most important and essential (with the possible exception of the Federal Reserve Banks) are the New York Gty banks. Most money market trans actions are cleared through their books, and all inflows or outflows of funds between New York Gty and other parts of the country (except for Federal Reserve or Treasury account) go through their reserve accounts on the books o f the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The Federal Reserve Banks were referred to earlier as residual suppliers of funds to the money market. Federal Reserve credit may be considered a balancing factor in the market—supplying funds when they are needed and absorbing them when there is a surplus. There has never been any question but that the Reserve System should supply, through the money market or directly to the banks (at a price), whatever amount of funds is needed to enable member banks to main F ederal R eserve Ba n k o f N e w Y o rk tain their reserves at the required levels. But the Reserve System has never willingly accepted the obligation to supply passively, at a fixed level of rates and at the option of the market, all the funds that might be in demand (except perhaps in periods of national emergency when major national objectives, such as the winning of a war, could not be permitted to be impeded by a lack of adequate financial support), since that would con flict with its responsibility for maintaining, as far as it is able, the monetary conditions necessary for economic stability. Fa c t o r s A f f e c t in g C o n d it io n s and M O oney pen M M arket arket In terest R ates Conditions in the money market and changes in the levels of open market interest rates reflect, of course, the interaction of changes in the supply of and demand for funds. While the aggregate demands from Federal, State, and local govern ments and from business organizations in the open market fluctuate considerably over fairly long periods, the day-to-day and week-to-week changes in money market conditions are usually determined much more largely by changes in the supply of funds. As was mentioned earlier, the commercial banks are by far the most important single source of funds in the market, and that supply is determined chiefly by the banks’ reserve position, especially that of the large New York Gty banks. The reserve position o f the commercial banking system as a whole reflects the various factors that are shown in the weekly statements published by the Board o f Governors of the Federal Reserve System, such as gold inflows or outflows and changes in the deposits of foreign central banks in the Federal Reserve Banks, changes in public demands for currency, net receipts or disburse ments by the Treasury reflected in changes in its balances .with the Federal Reserve Banks, fluctua tions in the volume o f Federal Reserve "float,” and changes in the reserve requirements of the banks.* It is through the last named factor that business and public demands for credit in the • These factors and their influence on bank reserves are discussed in a companion booklet, Bank Reserves— Some Major Factors Affecting Them, available on request to the Federal Reserve Bank o f New York. 5 form of direct borrowings from the banks have their indirect effect upon money market conditions. As bank loans expand or contract, the volume o f deposit liabilities and the reserve requirements of the commercial banks change correspondingly. Changes in the banks’ reserve requirements as a result of action taken by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System to increase or decrease the percentages of reserves which member banks are required to maintain are, of course, also an occasional influence of some consequence upon the money market. Changes in Federal Reserve credit, which are also included in the weekly statement— especially Federal Reserve credit in the form of discounts and advances to member banks and holdings of United States Government securities— constitute the balancing factor, and the readiness and the rates at which such credit is supplied to the banking system are a major factor in determining money market conditions. Not all the changes reflected in the weekly statement have an immediate impact upon the money market, but their influence usually is not long delayed. For example, a demand for cur rency in the Dallas Federal Reserve District may be met initially by drawing upon the excess re serves of banks in that area, but if it attains con siderable volume it is likely to result in withdrawals of balances from city correspondents or sales of short-term Government securities in the New York money market. Similarly, an increased de mand for credit in the San Francisco District, and a resulting rise in the reserve requirements of banks in that area, may be met for a while by drawing upon excess reserves or borrowing from the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, but if continued it is likely sooner or later to have some reflection in the money market. The most important immediate determinant of day-to-day money market conditions is the reserve position of the New York Gty banks, .through which practically all transfers of funds in and out of the money market are made. The reserve position of the New York Gty banks is, of course, affected by the local impact of all the factors mentioned above which affect the reserve position of com mercial banks generally, but in addition there are day-to-day movements o f funds between New 6 M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays York City and other parts of the country which frequently amount to' 100 million dollars or more. Consequently, even though banks in other areas may be experiencing an’ increase in their excess reserves, if the New York City banks are short of reserves, firm money market conditions are likely to prevail at least temporarily. Similarly, when New York City banks have substantial amounts of excess reserves, money market con ditions are likely to be easy, and the most sensi tive open market interest rates are likely to decline temporarily, even though banks in other areas may be losing reserve funds through Government tax collections, public demands for currency, or other factors. Through deposits or withdrawals o f cor‘respondent bank balances and business transfers of funds, however, such disparities between the reserve positions of the New York City banks and of banks in other areas are likely to be equalized quite rapidly. Thus by putting funds into the 'money market or taking funds out of the market, the Reserve System can exert an immediate in fluence on money market conditions and, fairly quickly, an influence on credit conditions through out the country, even though the initial effect is reflected only in the reserve position o f the New York City banks. The essence of effective regulation o f credit and the money supply is to retain control over the amount and cost of reserve funds supplied to the commercial banks, and the manner in which they are supplied. Reserve funds can be made available to the banking system on the initiative of the Federal Reserve System through the pur chase of Government securities in the market, or by forcing the banks to come to the Reserve Banks and borrow the reserve funds they require. Offer ings o f securities to the Reserve System can be greatly influenced by the willingness or unwill ingness of the System to take the securities at current market prices, and the extent to which the banks are ready and willing to borrow can be influenced by the Reserve Bank discount rate. In general, it is the policy of the Reserve System to limit the availability of reserve funds to the banks in periods of inflation, and to make reserve funds easily available in periods of business recession and deflation. Changes in O the M ver th e oney Y M arket ears Aside from major changes in supply and de mand conditions which have been reflected in broad movements in the general levels of interest rates, the money market has been subject to gradual but important changes in its functioning and principal activities over the years. The crea tion of the Federal Reserve System itself was probably the most important single development affecting the functioning of the money market. It lessened the dependence of the commercial banks of the country on the New York City banks (or, more broadly, on the New York money market) by providing twelve regional institutions to hold the reserves of banks that became members and to provide facilities for supplying banks in their respective areas with additional reserve funds and with currency to meet the demands of their customers. As was noted earlier, however, it did not break down correspondent bank relations, nor end the use by commercial banks of the facilities of the New York money market for employment of their surplus funds and secondary reserves. Other major changes (some of which have been more gradual, so that their significance was not at first so readily recognized) include: 1. The great change in supply and demand relationships in the money market, which grew out of the depression of the '30’s and the great inflow of gold that followed, and the resulting major lowering of the general levels of interest rates; 2. The virtual disappearance, as an important factor in the money market, of call loans to security brokers and dealers; 3. The shrinkage in business borrowing through the open market in the form of sales of commercial paper and bankers’ acceptances, be cause of the diminished advantages of such forms of borrowing, compared with direct borrowing from the banks; 4. The great increase in the volume of short term Government securities available for trading in the money market; 5. The growth of the market for "Federal funds” (rates on which have now taken the place of the call loan rate as the most sensitive and the F ederal R eserve B a n k o f N e w Y ork most widely fluctuating interest rate in the money market). The extent of some of these changes may be illustrated by a few figures comparing the present volume of loans and short-term securities avail able for trading in the money market with the amounts available 25 years ago. (Approximate amount in millions of dollars) 1925 1950 Brokers loans* 2,400-3,5OOe Commercial paper 600- 800 Bankers’ acceptances 600- 800 U. S. Treasury bills, certificates of in debtedness, and short-term notesf 2,500-3,000 500250200- 800 350 400 42,000-46,000 * Borrowings in New York G ty by members o f the New York Stock Exchange; 1925 figures estimated on basis of related data; 1950 figures represent borrowings on collateral other than Government securities, f Certificates and notes only in 1925; Treasury bills initiated in 1929; notes maturing within two years are included in both 1925 and 1950. e Estimated. It is evident from these figures that the impor tance of business borrowing (including the securi ties business) as a source o f demand for funds in the money market has greatly diminished, both absolutely and even more relatively. Short-term Government securities have become by far the most important type of money market instrument. The present predominance of Government se curities (and the growth in the public debt which it reflects) has important implications for the freedom of the money market, since it involves, of 7 course, greatly increased interest and influence of the Government in money market conditions. One reflection of this influence is the very narrow range of fluctuation in most interest rates during recent years; day-to-day changes in rates now are usually not even in, eighths of one per cent— on short-term Government securities they are in "basis points” or l/100ths of 1 per cent. (The one exception is the rate on "Federal funds” which has fluctuated between rates as low as 1/16 of one per cent and rates only slightly below the Federal Reserve discount rate.) Nevertheless, the tremendous growth in public debt and the dominant position of Government securities in the over-all debt structure of the country and in the investments of its financial institutions have induced much greater sensitivity to small changes in interest rates, and especially to changes in the direction of rates. There is reason to believe, therefore, that the Federal Reserve System may in the foreseeable future be able to carry out its credit policies effectively within the limits of considerably narrower fluctuations in interest rates than was the case some years ago. In fact, it does not seem likely that, even if the System had a completely free hand to influence the money market as it deemed most appropriate, without having to consider the effect of its actions on the market for Government securities, this country will again in the near future witness any thing like the rate fluctuations of earlier days, when the rate for call loans to security brokers fluctuated by 1 or 2 per cent (and sometimes much more) from day to day. MEMBER BANK BORROWING FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS ly M a d e l in e M buy (borrow) Federal funds.1 If they are not available in adequate volume at a satisfactory price, it will borrow or sell securities, depending upon cost. (If the market is tight, the sale of even short-term securities may be relatively costly.) If a reserve deficiency is expected to be o f some duration, the bank will probably sell securities, although it may have to borrow until it finds an acceptable bid for its securities. Smaller banks have generally not made as much use of the borrowing privilege. They usually try to keep their deposits at the Reserve Banks above the required level, since the expense of keeping a constant watch on their reserve posi tions and of making continual adjustments in their assets is likely to be greater than the additional income which they could realize by keeping fully invested. However, some of the smaller banks, particuarly those in agricultural or resort areas, have strong seasonal swings in both deposits and demands for loans. These banks often borrow from the Reserve Banks prior to their lending sea son in order to be able to meet their customers’ demands for working capital, and they repay their borrowings after crops are marketed or the vaca tion season draws to a close. Although many more banks have borrowed for seasonal purposes in recent years than have borrowed for day-to-day reserve adjustment purposes, seasonal loans have accounted for only a small proportion of the dol lar volume of total member bank borrowing. Two developments o f recent months have tended to increase the amount of borrowing done by the member banks. The first is the TreasuryFederal Reserve "accord” announced last March and the Reserve System’s subsequent withdrawal of its support of Government securities at fixed prices. The sharp decline in security prices which followed this announcement and the uncertainty T'XURING the early postwar years member bank borrowing from the Federal Reserve System was for the most part a tool by which large money market and correspondent banks could keep their cash reserves at a minimum and their earning assets at a maximum. Toward the end of 1951, however, as the Reserve Banks, in their open market operations, began to show an increasing reluctance to supply the market with reserves to carry it over periods of temporary stringency, the resort to borrowing became much more wide spread. Banks regularly assess their future needs for funds, and attempt to manage their loan and investment portfolios so as to be able to meet those needs as they arise. But most banks, and particu larly those in money market centers, encounter periods of temporary money market tightness when they lose reserves unexpectedly .through a withdrawal o f funds from the market in con nection with unforeseen security transactions, gold outflows, or other factors. Since large banks find it profitable to keep their resources as fully in vested as possible and therefore seldom maintain substantial excess reserves for more than a few days at most, such losses of funds are likely to draw their reserves down below the required level. Banks may obtain funds to tide them over such periods in one o f three ways: (1 ) sell securities; (2 ) buy reserves ("Federal funds” ) from other banks which have excess reserves; or (3 ) borrow from a Reserve Bank. (A bank could also call loans, but this is not a likely procedure today, particularly for the short run.) The choice of method depends primarily on two factors— the cost and the length o f time the funds will be needed. If a bank expects its money position to ease shortly, as a result of such factors as an in flow of funds from correspondent banks or a return flow of currency, it is likely first to try to cW h i n n e y 1 See the discussion o f this procedure in the article be* ginning on p. 13. 8 Federal R eserve B a n k o f N e w Y o rk engendered as to the future trend o f prices have 1951 may be attributed to a number of reasons. tended to discourage the sale of securities. In First, the large amounts of excess reserves acquired addition, the Federal Reserve System’s open market by the banks during the late 1930’s largely obvi policy has been directed toward keeping the ated the banks’ need to borrow. Second, a tradition money market fairly tight as an anti-inflationary developed against incurring a substantial indebted measure. The second factor is the widening of the ness for an extended period of time. Third, the spread between the bid and offer prices of Govern wartime arrangement whereby banks could sell ment securities. Such a development increases the Treasury bills to the Federal Reserve Banks under cost of a "turn-around,” i.e., the repurchase of a repurchase option largely eliminated the neces the same or similar securities previously sold dur sity for borrowing during the time it was in effect. ing a period of strain.2 Finally, during a large part of the period it was Member bank borrowings in the first 15 years cheaper to sell Government obligations than to of Reserve System history were large. They were borrow, and most banks had relatively large port often close to or above the billion dollar mark. folios of Government securities from which such The peak, which was reached in November 1920, sales could be made. Yields on short-term Govern was 2.8 billion dollars. During the Great Depres ment securities generally were lower than the dis sion they dropped off sharply and remained at a count rate, and prices moved within a relatively negligible level until the latter part of World War narrow range. This stability reduced the risk of II. At that time the banks began to borrow heavily loss for banks holding Government obligations. in connection with the payment periods for the A bank which sold Government securities, instead last three War Loan drives. This borrowing was of borrowing, to meet a temporary demand for facilitated by the special wartime discount rate of funds felt fairly confident that it could buy them y 2 of 1 per cent on advances secured by short back at approximately the same price as it had term Government obligations. After the end o f the sold them. war and especially after the elimination of the A bank which wishes to borrow may do so in special discount rate in the spring of 1946, the one of two ways: it may rediscount eligible paper amount of borrowing again declined. In 1950 the with the Reserve Bank, or it may obtain a direct average amount outstanding on statement dates advance on its promissory note, which in turn is was only about 125 million dollars, although secured by either Government securities or eligible amounts on these days ranged from 25 million to paper. Eligible paper is defined in the regulations 394 million dollars. As the result of the moder of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve ately restrictive credit policy followed by the System as "a negotiable note, draft, or bill of Reserve System since the announcement of the exchange, bearing the endorsement of a member Treasury-Federal Reserve accord in March 1951, bank . . . the proceeds of which have been used or however, banks are finding it increasingly neces are to be used, in producing, purchasing, carrying, sary to borrow to meet temporary reserve deficien or marketing goods in one or more of the steps of cies (see the accompanying chart). During a the process of production, manufacture, or distri period of tight money market conditions in De bution, or in meeting current operating expenses cember 1951, borrowings outstanding reached an of a commercial, agricultural, or industrial busi 18-year high of 959 million dollars. ness, or for the purpose o f carrying or trading in The relatively limited use o f the borrowing direct obligations of the United States . . . .” Fur privilege during most of the period from 1929 to thermore, to qualify as "eligible,” commercial or industrial paper must have a maturity of not more 2 Another, possibly temporary, consideration tending to than 90 days, while agricultural paper must ma increase the use of borrowing when banks need funds is the inclusion of such borrowings in the excess profits ture within nine months of the date of discount. tax base when the invested capital method o f computing N o maturity restrictions apply to Government this tax is used. Unnecessary borrowing to obtain a tax benefit is discouraged by the Reserve Banks, however, obligations, although at some periods in the past, and there is no evidence that it is being done to any special preferential rates have been available on appreciable extent. 9 M o n e y M arket Essays 10 Member Bank Borrowing from Federal Reserve Banks All Member Banks and Second District Banks (Wednesday dates, December 31, 1949 —January 16, 1952) M illions of d o lla rs 1000 M illions o f dollars IOOOi--------- 900 900 800 e oo 7 00 A ll other member banks 6 00 5 00 •400 Second D istrict member banks '3 0 0 200 I 00 1950 loans against short-term Government obligations. As a result of the banking crisis of 1931-33, the Federal Reserve Act was amended (Section 10[b ]) to permit member banks to borrow, in case of emergency, against any asset acceptable to the Reserve Banks. This extension of the borrow ing privilege beyond the holdings of normally eligible paper was enacted in 1932 to enable the banks to obtain additional cash reserves in periods of declining.business activity, when their volume of eligible paper would tend to be low. Since 1933, borrowing of this emergency type has been rare. Section 10(b) loans carry an interest charge at least ^ of 1 per cent higher than the rate for loans against eligible paper, and may be out standing for as long as four months. 1951 1952 In the first two decades of Reserve System history member banks used the rediscount and direct advance methods about equally, but nowadays almost all member banks employ the direct advance method. The mechanics of the direct advance method are simpler and, in the case of renewals, more flexible. Most loans are currently made against Government obligations— partly because of the relatively simple procedures involved and the large holdings of Government securities available for use as collateral. Applica tions for loans secured by eligible paper must be accompanied by a complete financial statement of the original borrower for each piece of paper of $ 1,000 or more that is to be used as security. For the past ten years Government securities have F e d e r a l R e serve B a n k been almost the only collateral offered to secure advances in the Second District; in some other sections of the country, however, minor amounts are advanced on some types of eligible paper, principally loans guaranteed by the Commodity Credit Corporation. On November 30, 1951, less than 1 million dollars, out o f a total of 624 mil lion in outstanding loans to member banks, was secured by some type of paper other than Govern ment obligations. Under normal conditions, loans to member banks may have a maturity of up to 90 days and arrangement can be made for renewals.8 In recent years, however, most advances to member banks have been outstanding for short periods only. The large city banks which still account for the bulk of the dollar volume of borrowing usually want the money overnight or for a few days at the most. Loans to banks outside the large money centers occasionally have fairly long maturities. Of the 624 million dollars of advances outstanding on November 30, 596 million dollars matured within 15 days. In the 1920's sometimes as much as 30 per cent of the total amount outstanding had a maturity of 31 days or more. Total member bank borrowings fluctuate fairly widely over a year without any clear seasonal pat tern, depending for the most part on money market conditions. While there are periods each year when the money market is apt to be relatively tight or easy, other factors which do not follow seasonal patterns, such as Reserve System open market operations or inflows or outflows o f gold, may counteract the tendency. In 1951, however, changes in the amount of borrowings outstanding began to show a high degree of inverse correlation with changes in excess reserves. The amounts bor rowed by individual banks at any one time range from a few thousand to 100 million dollars or more, depending on the size of the bank, the char acter of its operations, and its need for reserves at any given moment. Although the central reserve New York City banks normally account for a large percentage o f the dollar volume o f loans outstanding, both in the Second District and in the country as a whole, 8 Loans secured by the securities o f certain Government corporations may f>e outstanding only 15 days. of N ew Y ork 11 they usually account for only a small fraction of the number. At peak periods, as many as 80 or 100 of the 735 member banks in the Second District may borrow at a time, but only 5 or 10 of them are likely to be central reserve city banks. In 1951 the twelve Reserve Banks combined made 11,077 loans to 1,168 member banks; the total amount of credit extended was 43.4 billion dollars. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York made 3,118 loans, to 333 banks, totaling about 13.5 billion dollars, or about 28 percent of both the total dollar volume and the total number of loans extended by the System. In earlier years New York’s share of the total was larger. The repurchase agreements which the Federal Reserve Bank of New York makes with qualified Government security dealers are somewhat analagous to member bank borrowings. Under such agreements the dealers sell Treasury bills or other short-term Government securities to the Bank sub ject to repurchase within 15 days at the same price. These agreements are arranged to help dealers over periods of temporary market stringency and to assist them in carrying sufficiently large "posi tions” to do their part in maintaining markets for Government securities. The Board of Governors, in promulgating Regulation A (Discounts for and Advances to Member Banks by Federal Reserve Banks) noted: The guiding principle underlying the dis count policy of the Federal Reserve banks is the advancement of public interest . . . In extending accomodation to any member bank, the Federal Reserve banks are required to have due regard to the demands of other member banks, as well as to the maintenance o f sound credit conditions and the accommoda tion o f commerce, industry, and agriculture, and to consider not only the nature o f the paper offered, but also the general character and amount o f the loans and investments of the member bank, and whether the bank has been extending an undue amount o f credit for speculative purposes in securities, real estate, or commodities, or in any other way has con ducted its operations, in a manner inconsistent with the maintenance o f sound credit conditions. The Reserve Banks are thus in a position not only to control to some extent the amount of member bank borrowing through the discount rate, but also to refuse credit accommodation to member banks in some circumstances. The Federal Reserve Act provides that the Board of Directors of each Reserve Bank shall set its discount rate, 12 M oney M arket subject to "review and determination” by the Board o f Governors of the Federal Reserve System. On occasion in the past, different rates have been set in the various sections o f the coun try, and at times there have been differential rates on various types of paper, but a single uniform rate has prevailed throughout the System since 1942.4 At the beginning of 1952, the rate at all Federal Reserve Banks was 1% per cent per annum. In the past the rate has ranged as high as 7 per cent and as low as 1 per cent. During World War II a special preferential rate of y 2 of 1 per cent for borrowing against short-term Government securities was in effect.5 Changes in the discount rate are concrete evidence of the Federal Reserve System’s view of economic conditions and the need for facilitating or restricting the extension of credit. Furthermore, such changes tend to set the pattern for other market rates. Since the Federal Reserve discount rate is the rate of "last resort,” rates on open E ssays market commercial paper, bankers’ acceptances, and prime business loans usually move up or down when a change is made in the discount rate, but they may, of course, change at other times as well even though no change in rediscount rates occurs. 4 Since the Boards o f Directors o f each o f the Reserve Banks do not always act on the discount rate the same day, there may be differences for a few days in the rate charged by the various Reserve Banks. 8 The rate charged by the Federal Reserve Banks on loans to member banks under Section 10(b) have ranged from V2 to 2V2 Per cent above the regular discount rate. However, since 1941 this rate has been held uniformly by all the Reserve Banks at Vi of 1 per cent above the discount rate. Rates under the last paragraph o f Section 13 on loans secured by direct obligations o f the Govern ment to borrowers other than member banks are not tied to the discount rate. They have ranged from 2 to 4y 2 per cent, although from the fall o f 1939 to the spring of 1946 a special rate of 1 per cent was in effect on loans to nonmember banks secured by direct Government obli gations. At the beginning o f 1952 the rate was 2 ^ /2 per cent at eight o f the Reserve Banks and 2% per cent at the other four. FEDERAL FUNDS ly H obart 0 . C arr enough to cover the expense of writing checks and making bookkeeping entries. A helpful rule of thumb used in the money market is the calculation that interest at 1 per cent per annum for one day on $1 million is about $28. Since millions of dol lars are being exchanged in the Federal funds market on many days, the interest return available to the seller and the savings available to the buyer (when the rate is below the discount rate) are more than enough to justify the transactions to cost-conscious bankers. During the last quarter of 1951, as the chart shows, there were a number of days when the rate was below I per cent. are Federal funds? Who wants them W HAT and who supplies them? Essentially, Federal funds represent the title to reserve balances with the Federal Reserve Banks. They are thus immediately available funds, as contrasted with other types of balances, such as clearing house funds (checks or drafts on clearing house banks), which in New York are not available to the holder of the check or draft until the day after receipt. To put it another way, a check drawn on a mem ber bank’s account at the Federal Reserve Bank is collectible (upon presentation there) in funds immediately available at the Reserve Bank, while a check drawn on a clearing house bank is collect ible in funds available at the Reserve Bank the next day, when clearing balances are settled on the books of the Reserve Bank. The principal supply of Federal funds comes, therefore, from banks with balances at the Federal Reserve Bank beyond their needs for meeting reserve requirements and from non-banking in stitutions holding drafts on the Federal Reserve Bank. For example, if the ABC National Bank is required to have a balance in its reserve account of $22 million on a given day, and it actually has on deposit $25 million, it is in a position to let another bank use the excess of $3 million. The ABC National Bank, then, might let the X Y 2 State Bank use the $3 million so that the latter could thereby avoid incurring a deficiency in its own required reserves. The rate on Federal funds varies from day to day as buyers and sellers negotiate in the money market. The X Y Z State Bank normally would not pay more for the use of the funds than it would have to pay if it borrowed from the Federal Reserve Bank at the discount rate. Under present conditions the upper limit, o f course, is the current discount rate;1 the lower limit is usually barely Sales of Federal funds between banks in dif ferent banking centers are made by using the Federal Reserve wire transfer service. The lending bank transfers funds to the borrower on one day and a reverse shift is made the next day. In New York City, these transfers to and from out-of-town banks have increased of late. Or dinarily, only the large banks in other centers are involved. When banks in the City need Federal 1 If the discount rate is IV2 per cent, the upper limit of the Federal funds rate is usually I t ’ s per cent; if the discount rate is V/4 per cent, the Federal funds rate usually does not exceed i l l per cent. * Transactions are usually for a single day; but over week ends they are for two or three days, depending upon whether the participating institutions are open for business on Saturday. The actual transfer of Federal funds within a given locality usually involves an exchange of checks. The buying bank gets a check on the Re serve Bank and gives a check drawn on itself, which becomes payable in Federal funds the fol lowing business day. Ordinarily, the interest pay ment based on the number of calendar days2 of use is included in the clearing house check, but some banks prefer a separate check covering the interest payment. Sometimes no interest is charged and the borrowing bank merely makes a commit ment to return the same amount of funds upon demand or at a specified later date. Since this com mitment involves risk in terms of the cost of the funds at the time of "returning the favor,” such "swapping” of funds is not a common practice. 13 14 M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays Federal Funds Rate in New York City (Daily for the Fourth Quarter of 1951*) Per cent P e r cen t 1951 * The figures shown represent the modal rate for each week day’s transactions; holidays are indicated by dashed lines. Source: Garvin, Bantel & Company. funds, their requirements are so great that the borrowing of small amounts of Federal funds is not worth the trouble. When funds are scarce elsewhere and relatively plentiful in New York City, the same reasoning applies with respect to the lending of Federal funds by the City banks. A bank with an ’’overage” of 10 million dollars, for example, would not care to put itself to the trouble of parceling it out in lots of, say, 100 thousand dollars. The increase in out-of-town participation in the New York City market has contributed to a widening of fluctuations in the flow of funds in and out of this area. One day large amounts of funds will flow into the Gty and the next day large sums will flow out. The magnitude of these daily flows is often upwards of a hundred million dollars. Under such conditions the Federal Reserve System’s problem in gauging money market pros pects and in conducting its operations in Govern ment securities is made more difficult. The System, and the New.York Federal Reserve Bank in par ticular, must take into account not only country wide developments affecting member bank reserve positions but also the situation in New York Gty, which is by far the most important money market in the country. Anything that causes money market conditions in New York Gty to depart widely and unpredictably from those in the country as a whole complicates the System’s problems, for it may give rise to a situation where one type of operation may be called for locally and another in the country as a whole. It is obvious from the nature of the trans actions that the sale of Federal funds is a loan and that their purchase constitutes borrowing; member banks have been directed by the System to treat them as such on their statements.8 This results in limiting the amounts of Federal funds which may be sold by either National or State banks. With certain exceptions, a National bank is prohibited by the National Bank Act from lending to any one borrower more than 10 per cent of its paid-in capital and unimpaired surplus. New York State banks are subject to a similar limitation, except that undivided profits are in cluded in the base. National banks, moreover, may be restricted in their purchases of Federal funds by the provision that aggregate borrowings of such banks cannot exceed their capital stock; there are some exceptions to this rule, however. 8 The Bureau o f Internal Revenue o f the Treasury De partment so views them, too. It permits their inclusion in the "capital base” used in calculation o f excess profits tax liabilities. F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k There are no restrictions on borrowing by New York State banks. In practice, borrowing limitations would be a hardship only to those National banks whose capital stock is very small relative to the fluctua tions in their deposits and reserves. The loan limitation, on the other hand, makes it difficult at times for banks to dispose of large excess reserves. The over-all supply of Federal funds is deter mined by the familiar factors of supply and use of reserve balances. For example, when currency in circulation or Treasury balances with the Reserve Banks go down, Federal funds tend to become more plentiful. On the other hand, when the gold stock, Federal Reserve "float,” 4 or System holdings o f Government securities fall, Federal funds tend to become scarce. The reservoir of available Federal funds at times is smaller than the aggregate amount of excess reserves o f member banks— first, because not all member banks wish to make their excess bal ances available to the market, second, because considerable amounts of excess reserves which are usually held in relatively small sums by banks all over the country do not reach the market, and third, because excess reserves o f certain banks may be immobilized to offset a previous (or an antic ipated) deficiency in the current reserve require ment period. On the other hand, a bank may sell Federal funds even when its reserves are temporarily deficient if it is protected by "over ages” (excess reserves) during the earlier part of the same reserve requirement period. Generally, however, a bank will supply Federal funds in the market only when it has excess reserves. In each banking center, local banks are normally the chief source of supply of Federal funds. O f late, however, sales of Federal funds have been made, on an increasing scale, by out-of-town banks also. Banks, moreover, are not the only suppliers and users of Federal funds. In fact, the supply of Federal funds which is put on the market by non banking institutions is quite significant. Chief among such suppliers are the Government security dealers. In the course of their operations these 4 For a discussion o f the nature o f "float,” see Bank Reserves— Some Major Factors Affecting Them (page 25 ), available on request to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. of N ew Y ork 15 dealers frequently acquire title to Federal funds, either before such funds reach commercial banks or on the way from one bank to another. For example, when a dealer sells Government securities to the Federal Reserve System he receives payment in Federal funds. The dealer may sell the funds for other means of payment (such as clearing house funds), which he may deposit with his bank or use to repay his borrowings. Government security dealers also acquire Federal funds in other ways. They may have contact with nonmember banks or with local agencies of foreign banks in posses sion of Federal funds. In addition, they may ac quire such funds through the sale of Government securities to nonbank investors which have ob tained Federal funds (in the form of Treasury checks) from redemptions of Treasury issues. The demand for Federal funds stems mainly from member banks which need to adjust their reserve positions. Many times it is cheaper to buy such funds than to borrow at the Reserve Bank. In addition, some banks have a tradition of not being in debt to the Reserve Bank. A few of the New York City banks, for example, have not borrowed from the New York Federal Reserve Bank for years. Banks, however, are not the sole source of demand. When dealers buy Government securities from the Federal Reserve System, they need Federal funds in order to be able to make payment on the day the securities are delivered. They may need this means of payment also in order to do business with other investors who require cash settlement on the date of sale. Among such in vestors are corporations and State and local governments, all of which have been increasingly anxious to keep their funds invested in Govern ment securities up to the day when the funds are needed for actual disbursements. Thus, they may sell Government securities on the day when their own securities must be paid off, or on the day when funds are needed for transfer to distant areas. As a result of such close timing, these groups of investors need immediately available funds. Owing to their strategic position, Government security dealers not only participate in the Federal funds market but also contribute greatly to its M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays functioning. For example, a tank in need o f funds may indicate its needs to a dealer who, if he does not have the funds himself, may know some bank that does. He will also know approximately what the going rate is and will put the buyer in touch with the seller. Some dealers will perform, even for a bank, the function of agent in placing or obtaining Federal funds. In rendering such services, for which they make no charge, the offices o f many Government security dealers become, in effect, a market place. Probably the most important single New York Gty market in terms of daily dollar volume of transactions, however, is in the offices o f a Stock Exchange firm. This particular firm merely per forms the service function o f bringing buyers and sellers of Federal funds together and is in no way a participant in the market. After having determined their reserve positions from the clear ing house settlements and from other transactions, some banks telephone the broker's office in the morning and indicate whether they are in need of funds or have them for sale; sometimes they also indicate approximate amounts. Buyers and sellers are then brought together by the broker and rates are agreed upon. This service and that of recording rate changes (or prospective changes) during the day is performed by the intermediary without fee or differential. Other banks in the City make little use o f the services of an inter mediary in their Federal funds operations, prefer ring to deal directly with one another. Most of the above discussion of Federal funds relates to the New York Gty market, since that market is by far the most important one in the country. The trading in Federal funds in New York City consists for the most part of transactions between City buyers and sellers or between Gty banks and out-of-town institutions, but some of the trading involving out-of-town banks exclusively is also consummated here. Local markets do exist in a number of other banking centers, and the bonds between some of them (particularly the Philadelphia market) and the New York market are very strong. A few outside markets used to have rates which bore no close relationship to the New York City rates. This was true, for example, on the West Coast and in the St. Louis area, where a flat rate was charged to participating banks. Now, however, most o f the rate quotations in mar kets outside New York Gty are based on City rates. THE COMMERCIAL PAPER MARKET ly C l if t o n H. T)USINESS concerns may obtain short-term credit accommodation either by borrowing from banks directly or by disposing of their promissory notes through an intermediary— the commercial paper dealer—who in turn places the notes with financial institutions seeking investment outlets for short-term funds.1 Transactions of the former type are said to take place in the customers’ loan market, those of the latter type in the commercial paper market. While the term "commercial paper” may refer, in a broad sense, to all types o f short term negotiable instruments, its more restricted meaning (and the one used in this article) is that of short-term promissory notes discounted with dealers for resale to financial institutions, mainly banks. For the banks, commercial paper, besides providing an investment outlet for short-term funds, may also give access to reserve funds, when needed, by serving as eligible collateral for bor rowing from Federal Reserve Banks. The commercial paper market is the oldest of the several segments of the open market for short term funds. It developed to substantially its present form shortly after the turn of this century, but its antecedents can be traced in our financial history for over a hundred and fifty years. An outstanding characteristic of this market is the impersonality of its operations. All borrowing and lending is effected through commercial paper dealers, except in the case o f paper sold by certain large finance companies. O f the ten dealers in the market, five handle commercial paper only, while the other five are engaged in various lines of the brokerage and securities business as well. Nationwide distribution of paper is achieved through branch offices and correspondent relation ships. Formerly it was customary for dealers to accept paper from would-be borrowers for sale on a commission basis, but presently prevailing practice 1 Businesses may also secure short-term funds by sell ing accounts receivable to factors or borrowing against them from commercial receivables companies. 17 K eeps, Jb. is for dealers to purchase paper outright. Interest at the current rate is deducted in advance, as is the dealer’s commission of one fourth of one per cent of the face value of each note. Notes ordinarily bear maturities of from four to six months, and are issued in convenient round de nominations.2 Dealers generally resell commercial paper on a ten-day option basis, although in some cases op tions may be granted for fourteen days. Options are usually granted for credit checking purposes only and dealers have refused to accept paper returned for reasons other than the unsatisfactory credit standing of the maker. The standards required of borrowers in the commercial paper market are so high as effectively to limit the number of firms which may employ this form of short-term financing. "Prime names” are found, however, in diverse lines of business and in every section of the country. The accom panying table shows how commercial paper bor rowers in 1951 were distributed among various lines of activity. The geographic location of these borrowers was very wide. The Chicago Federal Reserve District, where 64 business concerns used the market in 1951, had the largest number of borrowers. The New York District, with 58 borrowers, was second, and the Boston District, with 57 borrowers, was third. In other Federal Reserve Districts, the number of concerns borrow ing in the commercial paper market ranged from 47 in the Richmond District down to 12 in the San Francisco District. O f the total of 398 borrowers in 1951, 386 (97 per cent) used one-name, unsecured promis sory notes. Endorsed or guaranteed notes were given by only 9 borrowers, and notes secured by collateral were used in but 3 instances. Borrowing * Denominations o f 5, 10, 25, 50, 100, 250, and 500 thousand dollars are in use, but the larger denominations are infrequent. A borrower o f 1 million dollars might execute, for example, eight notes o f 50 thousand, 12 of 25 thousand, 24 o f 10 thousand, and 12 o f 5 thousand dollars. 18 M oney M arket Distribution of Commercial "Paper Borrowers by Line of Activity in 1951 Number of Line of activity borrowers Manufacturers Textiles .......................................................... 68 37 Grains, flour, fertilizers, and seed .............. Leather and leather products ...................... 21 Metal products ........................................... 18 Meat packers, canners, and sugar refiners.... 14 Lumber, wood, paper, and r o p e ................ 9 Food and dairy products............................... 9 9 Chemicals, drugs, and paints...................... Other ............................. ................................ 10 Total ......................................................... 195 Wholesalers Groceries and food products ...................... Hardware and paints ................................... Textiles and leather products .................... Other .............................................................. 31 20 8 17 Total ......................................................... 76 Retailers Department and chain stores ...................... Other .............................................................. 27 14 Total ....................................................... 41 Finance* Automobile ................................................... .......44 Small loan companies.......................................... 21 Commercial ................................................... .......14 Total ......................................................... Other .................................................................. Total ............................................. ’ 79 7 398 * Does not include General Motors Acceptance Corporation, Commercial Investment Trust, Inc., and Commercial Credit Com pany, which do not use dealers but instead place their paper directly with purchasers. Source: National Credit Office. concerns had a net worth ranging from 250 thousand to over 25 million dollars, but more than half of them were concentrated in a group with net worth o f from 1 to 5 million dollars. Commercial paper is not viewed as a source of permanent working capital. Firms borrowing in the commercial paper market do so normally for the seasonal financing o f inventory or other current working capital requirements, such as the carrying of trade receivables. Finance companies, however, are in the market more or less continuously,8 and some other concerns have at times borrowed for considerable periods. 8 Three of the largest finance companies now sell their paper direct, and do not use dealers at all. ^Paper of these companies outstanding totaled 884 million at the end of 1951, as compared with market outstandings of 434 million dollars at that time. E ssays The commercial paper market is properly conconsidered not as a substitute for direct bank lines of credit to borrowing firms, but as a supplement to them. Its use as a supplement to direct bank lines of credit in obtaining short-term accommoda tion has certain advantages for business concerns. Borrowing on commercial paper is generally less expensive than direct borrowing. It enables bor rowing concerns to secure part of their funds in a national market, and thus to obtain more favor able terms from their banks on direct borrowings. If properly coordinated with direct bank borrow ing, use of the commercial paper market permits a periodic '"clean-up” of bank loans, and also en ables firms whose banks are unable to supply the full amount of funds required to obtain additional accommodation in a market broader than the cus tomers’ loan market. In addition, concerns which are able to use commercial paper financing become better known in the financial world and are presumably thereby placed in a more favorable position for raising such long-term capital as they may from time to time require. Only firms in good financial and trade standing, as disclosed by statements audited by outside ac countants, have access to the commercial paper market. Borrowers must be willing to submit de tailed information on finances and operations to dealers and to prospective purchasers of their paper. A satisfactory current ratio, a reasonable amount of invested capital,4 and earnings in fair proportion to volume, as compared with similar concerns, must be shown. Funds borrowed must be used for current purposes, not for permanent investment. In addition, some commercial paper dealers have at times required firms using their facilities to borrow amounts sufficiently large to make the accounts profitable to handle. Although commercial paper was formerly held by a wide range of investors, participation on the lending side of the market has been limited in recent years almost exclusively to commercial banks. Traditionally, commercial paper has been regarded as well adapted for use by banks as 4 In recent years, the minimum invested capital figure appears to have been about 250 thousand dollars. Few firms this small enter the market, however. F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k secondary reserves. It can be purchased from dealers in amounts and maturities which suit the needs of the individual banker. Since open-market borrowing does not lend itself to renewals, com mercial paper can be relied on as a certain source of cash at maturity. Furthermore, eligible paper within ninety days of maturity may, if necessary, be rediscounted with or used as security for ad vances from Federal Reserve Banks. (Federal Reserve Banks cannot, however, purchase commer cial paper in the open market.) Finally, the ac quisition by banks of profitable new accounts may be facilitated by the purchase of commercial paper. Rates charged on commercial paper are generally lower than those on direct bank loans, even after allowance is made for the one fourth of one per cent commission customarily charged by dealers on each note handled. The differential reflects the fact that commercial paper represents prime risks, on which the possibility of loss is very small. In fact, judging from the experience of national banks, credit institutions have suffered much lower losses on commercial paper than on either customer loans or investments. Aggregate losses of all holders were negligible prior to 1932, and no losses have been experienced since 1937.5 This record largely explains the strength and. steadiness of the demand for commercial paper, which in recent years has enabled dealers to dispose readily of their offerings. In spite of the strong demand for commercial paper, and of low interest rates and other ad vantages connected with its use by borrowers, a downward trend in commercial paper financing has been evident since 1920. The volume of paper outstanding, the number of borrowers, the number of dealers, the number of lenders, and the relative importance o f this method of financ ing as compared with direct borrowing from banks have all declined since the end of World War I. Commercial paper outstanding is reported to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York by dealers ac tive in the market. The volume of such paper reached a peak in January 1920, when it totaled 1,296 million dollars. It declined to a low of 8 Defaults occurred in five o f the fourteen years since 1937, but full payment was subsequently made in every case. of N ew Y ork 19 60 million in May 1933, and although it had recovered to 388 million in February 1942, the impact of war brought another decline to 101 million in June 1945. The highest volume reached through the end of 1951 (435 million in Novem ber 1951) was only one third of the 1920 total, in spite of the great increase in the dollar value of national income. Part of this decline reflects the fact that while in earlier years some leading finance companies placed their paper through dealers, they now sell it directly to banks through out the country, and these borrowings, therefore, are not included in the totals compiled by this bank. On the other hand, the decrease in volume has been accompanied by, and in part results from, a corresponding fall in the number of borrowers using the market. This number declined from well over 4,000 in 1920 to a low of 375 in 1945. Thereafter, the number of borrowers rose to a postwar peak of 429 in 1947 and then declined to 397 in 1950, rising by one, to 398, in 1951. The shrinkage in the volume of commercial paper has greatly reduced the number of dealers, and has led also to a narrowing of the market on the buying side. About thirty dealers were operating in the country during the decade of the twenties, compared with only ten now (including one not recently active in the market). Purchases of paper from dealers by individuals and cor porations seeking short-term investments have long since come to an end, and the large banks in New York City and some other cities have not bought commercial paper for their own account for a number of years past. The withdrawal of these banks from the market has been explained as prob ably resulting from the decline of the rate on prime names below the minimum commercial lending rate to which banks in leading centers tend to adhere. Large increases in the volume of other instruments suitable for use as secondary reserves (e.g., short-term Government securities) must also have contributed to the withdrawal. The shortage of offerings and the attendant limitation on new account prospects in the existing small market, coupled with unwillingness to break the rate structure, seem likewise to be important reasons. 20 M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays In recent years, although there has been nation wide distribution of commercial paper, buying has been primarily by moderate-sized and smaller banks. The banks of New England, a section of the country which has always looked with favor on commercial paper financing, are among the most important purchasers. These developments have naturally led to a decline in the relative importance of commercial paper in the loan portfolios o f banks. Such paper probably never constituted an important part of these portfolios. Even at the end of 1919, openmarket commercial paper outstanding was less than five per cent of the total loans of all commercial banks. But this proportion had fallen by the end of 1932 to y10 of 1 per cent, an all-time low. By the end of 1946, it had risen to % o f 1 per cent of all commercial bank loans. It fell again, however, to 6/10 of 1 per cent at the end of 1950. Thereafter it rose slightly to % 0 of 1 per cent at the end of December 1951. Several broad reasons may be advanced in ex planation of the decline in the commercial paper market since 1920. First among these is changes in general business conditions. Generally lessening activity in the commercial paper market during the twenties has been attributed in part to the advantage taken by many companies o f inflated conditions in the stock market to acquire per manent working capital, and thus to reduce their need for open-market borrowing. Depressed economic conditions following 1929, resulting in a greatly decreased business demand for short-term funds, account for the sharp drop in the volume of commercial paper outstanding to the May 1933 low o f 60 million dollars. Our entry into World War II," and the subsequent development of special arrangements to finance war production, caused the termination, in 1942, o f a period of rising volume associated with the improvement in general business conditions after 1934. And dur ing the war and postwar periods, some business concerns have used part o f their prevailing high earnings to build up working capital positions, thus again, as in the twenties, reducing their need to use the commercial paper market. A second reason for the long-run shrinkage of the commercial paper market may be found in changes in business borrowing practices, including the large-scale resort to term loans. The develop ment by large finance companies of methods of direct placement for their paper, by-passing the dealers altogether, has doubtless had a substantial effect in reducing the volume of open-market paper outstanding, since the high figures of the twenties undoubtedly included considerable amounts of finance paper. The change in structure of the commercial bank ing system since World War I has also contributed to the decline of the commercial paper market. Mergers, the growth of branch banking, and de velopment of the practice of correspondent par ticipations have resulted since 1920 in the appear ance throughout the country of banks and groups o f banks with lending limits large enough to enable them to supply substantial lines of credit to single borrowers.8 Many large institutions have aggressively sought business on a national scale. This increased competition of the customers’ loan market with the commercial paper market has been favored by the low money rates generally prevail ing over the last two decades. Low interest rates tend to make the open market’s cost advantage over the customers' loan market seem less attrac tive than when higher rates prevail. ‘ Finally, the commercial paper market no longer fully enjoys one of the advantages claimed for it in years prior to 1920, namely, its usefulness in equalizing the supply of and demand for short term commercial credit between geographical areas of seasonal surplus and deficiency. The Federal Reserve System, by providing means for the ready movement of funds throughout the country and thereby leveling out local conditions of tight or easy money, has materially reduced the market’s appeal in this respect. Also, the growth of com mercial bank holdings of Government securities has given banks ready access to Federal Reserve funds. These factors have contributed inescapably to the market’s decline. Commercial paper borrowing expanded steadily in the first ten months following the beginning o f hostilities in Korea, rising from 240 million National banks are prohibited by law from lending an amount larger than 10 per cent of their unimpaired capital stock and surplus to any one borrower, and many State banks operate under similar restrictions. 8 F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k dollars in June 1950 to 387 million dollars in April 1951. This substantial (61 per cent) in crease in volume reflected in part the waves of scare buying by consumers and in part business attempts to anticipate shortages by accumulating inventories. As scare buying and inventory ac cumulation waned in early 1951, commercial paper declined from its April peak to 364 million dollars in May and 331 million dollars in June. Some concern was expressed in the market at that time over the possibility that the nation’s rearmament program might soon have adverse effects on commercial paper financing similar in nature, though of lesser extent, to those associated with our participation in World War II. These adverse effects have not yet been felt, however. Instead, the volume o f commercial paper out standing increased steadily from its June low to a figure of 410 million at the end of October, the largest amount outstanding since November 1930. A further six per cent increase in November brought commercial paper outstanding to 435 million at the end of that month, and the year end figure (434 million) showed little change from this total. This considerable increase in volume during the last half of 1951 occurred in the face of a firming of rates on commercial paper which was evident throughout the year. The rate on prime, 4-to-6-month notes (1 % per cent at the end of December 1950) rose to a range o f 2 ^ -2 % Per cent by mid-May. By the end o f the year, partly as a result of two increases (in October and De cember) in the bank rate on prime business loans (which brought it to 3 per cent), prime four-tosix-month borrowers in the commercial paper mar ket were paying 2% per cent for accomodation. The commercial paper market still possesses a three-eighths per cent rate differential for prime borrowers over the customers’ loan market, how of N ew Y ork 21 ever, even after taking account of the dealers’ quarter per cent commission on each note. On the assumption that such a differential should assume more significance for prospective borrowers in a period of rising interest rates, this advantage might serve to explain some of the increase in volume of commercial paper outstanding which occurred in the last half of 1951. It might also be interpreted as a factor operating to increase volume still more in the future. Dealers and others close to the market, how ever, do not appear to attach much significance to this cost advantage as a factor influencing the volume of commercial paper borrowing. Instead, they tend to explain the recent increases in volume largely in terms of normal seasonal expansion, on a larger base than has existed in recent years, and to continue to express some concern over the pos sible adverse effects of the defense effort on com mercial paper financing. Thus the increase in the volume of commercial paper outstanding during the past six years (from 101 million dollars in June 1945 to the November 1951 peak of 435 million) does not necessarily presage any permanent revival of the market. It is measured from an abnormally low postwar level. It occurred, moreover, while economic activity was reaching heights never before achieved in peace time and it was influenced by unusual rates of consumer and business expenditure. The latest increases in volume have been attributed largely to seasonal factors, and the possibility still exists that conditions arising out of the defense program may eventually bring about a decline in the volume of commercial paper marketed. Finally, both the volume of paper currently outstanding and the present number of borrowers are seen to be small when compared with the figures associated with previous periods of prosperity. BANKERS’ ACCEPTANCES ly C l if t o n H. K *T*HE postwar period has witnessed some increase in the use of the bankers’ dollar ac ceptance as a device for financing trade and as a medium for short-term investment. The peak volume of acceptances outstanding from the end of World War II through the end of 1951 (490 million dollars in December 1951) was almost five times that recorded in the spring o f 1945, when the wartime low in acceptance financing was reached, and represented the highest level reached since February 1935. This postwar peak volume was still small compared with the prewar peak of 1,732 million dollars reached in December 1929, but the recent growth in acceptance use follows a period of continuous decline in the market which began in 1930. The bankers’ acceptance is a time draft which has been drawn on and accepted by a bank, trust company, or other institution engaged in the business of granting bankers' acceptance credits. Upon acceptance, such a draft becomes’ an un qualified promise to pay at maturity and is eligible, under certain conditions, for purchase or redis count by Federal Reserve Banks. After presentation and acceptance, bankers’ acceptances are either re turned to the presentor (the drawer or other owner, or his agent) for sale in the open market, or discounted for him by the accepting bank. The bankers’ acceptance thus makes possible the addition o f the credit of a bank or accepting in stitution to that of a purchaser or holder o f mer chandise. This addition of credit makes of the bankers’ acceptance a readily marketable, negotiable instrument, through the sale o f which sellers of goods may obtain funds quickly and easily. For accepting drafts on behalf of their customers financial institutions charge a commission, custom arily i y 2 per cent per annum,1 and a customer is required to provide the accepting institution 1 That is, Vs per cent on 30-day sight drafts, 1 /4 per cent on 60-day sight drafts, % per cent on 90-day sight drafts, etc. 22 eeps, Jr. with funds to meet his drafts before they mature. The financing of trade through the use of bankers’ acceptances is a practice of very long standing. Active markets for bankers’ "bills” have existed in Europe—notably in London— for cen turies. Prior to World War I, however, bankers' dollar acceptances were used but little in this country. It was not the practice of national banks to accept drafts drawn on them, and only a com paratively small amount of acceptance credit was created by State banks and private bankers. The Federal Reserve Act, enacted in December 1913, authorized member banks of the Federal Reserve System to accept drafts, subject to certain restric tions and to the regulations and rulings of the Federal Reserve Board. The Act also made accept ances eligible for discount at Federal Reserve Banks, subject to the usual requirements as to maturity and endorsement, and authorized Federal Reserve Banks to deal in eligible acceptances on the open market. The passage of the Federal Re serve Act (and its amendment in 1916 broadening the accepting powers of member banks) thus made possible the development of an acceptance market in the United States. The Federal Reserve Act authorizes member banks to accept drafts or bills of exchange drawn upon them to finance four broad categories of transactions: the import and export of goods; the shipment of goods within the United States; the storage of readily marketable staple commodities, either in the United States or in foreign countries; and the furnishing of dollar exchange. Drafts or bills accepted must have not more than six months to run, except for those drawn to furnish dollar exchange, which must have not more than three months to run. The use of bankers’ dollar acceptances for finan cing exports and imports is not limited to financ ing the foreign trade of the United States. Ameri can accepting banks are also permitted to extend dollar acceptance credits to finance the movement F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k of goods between foreign countries. Such broad acceptance powers were granted to facilitate finan cing the foreign commerce of the United States, to aid in establishing the dollar as an international currency, and to promote the development of an international money market in the United States. Drafts to finance exports and imports are often drawn for acceptance under authority of a letter of credit, issued to the drawer by the accepting bank.2 American accepting banks issue such "credits” on behalf o f their own customers and customers of their domestic correspondents. In addition, letters o f credit are issued on behalf of foreign residents by arrangement with foreign banks,8 which are usually correspondents or branches of the accepting bank. Acceptances covering domestic shipments of goods must have attached at the time of acceptance the shipping documents conveying title to the goods. Further, domestic shipment acceptances must have a maturity consistent with the customary credit terms in the particular business involved. These requirements are designed to prevent the improper use of this type of acceptance credit as a source of working capital. The storage of readily marketable staples in the United States or in any foreign country may be financed by means of bankers’ acceptances. Bills drawn for this purpose must be secured at the time of acceptance by warehouse, terminal, or similar receipts for the goods stored. Also, the acceptance must remain secured until paid.4 Since the purpose o f warehouse acceptances is to permit the temporary holding of readily marketable staples in storage pending their sale, shipment, or distribution, such acceptances ordinarily should not have maturities in excess of the time necessary to effect reasonably prompt sale, shipment, or distribution of the goods into the process of manufacture or consumption. 2 Letters o f credit authorize the drawing o f drafts in accordance with certain terms, and stipulate that all drafts drawn in conformity with these terms will be ac cepted and honored at maturity. 8 The arrangements provide that the foreign bank will supply the American accepting bank with funds to meet the drafts at maturity. Both banks charge a commission, the cost o f which is borne by the foreign customer in itiating the transaction. 4 Goods may be withdrawn from storage prior to the maturity of acceptances secured by them provided other acceptable security is substituted. of N ew Y ork 23 Member banks of the Federal Reserve System are also authorized by law, upon receipt of permis sion from the Board of Governors, to accept drafts having not more than three months to run for the purpose of furnishing dollar exchange to foreign countries, or to dependencies or insular possessions of the United States, where banks or bankers are justified by the usages of trade in drawing on member banks in this country to create such dollar exchange. The Board of Gov ernors publishes a list of these countries and areas.6 In an early ruling, the Board appeared to imply that "the usages of trade” referred primarily to the practices growing out of a lack of frequent, regular mail connections. In later years, however, the degree of seasonality in a country’s foreign trade became an important consideration. The use of dollar exchange credits makes it easier for foreign banks to provide dollar pay ment for imports from the United States during periods when exports to the United States suffer a seasonal decline. Their use may thereby also help to smooth out seasonal fluctuations in ex change rates between the dollar and other cur rencies. However, drafts are drawn to create dollar exchange in anticipation of actual exports, and Federal Reserve regulations prohibit the acceptance o f drafts drawn merely because dollar exchange is at a premium, or for any speculative purpose. Neither are member banks permitted to accept "finance bills,” which are not drawn primarily to meet the demand for dollar exchange arising out of the normal course of trade. O f a total of 490 million dollars of bankers’ dollar acceptances outstanding at the end of De cember 1951, 235 million was based on imports into the United States, 133 million on exports from the United States, 48 million on goods stored in the United States, 44 million on goods stored in or shipped between foreign countries and 7 million on goods shipped in the United States. Twenty-three million, an unusually large amount, was for the purpose of furnishing dollar exchange. With this exception, however, the order of relative importance indicated by these figures is one which 8 All countries o f Latin America (except Haiti and the Dutch West Indies), Australia, New Zealand, the Aus tralasian dependencies, and the Dutch East Indies (In donesia) are presently on the list. 24 M oney M arket has persisted with but slight change since the mid thirties. Since 1943, imports alone have been the basis for more than half of all dollar acceptance credits granted in every year. The market for bankers’ acceptances includes, in addition to the various sources o f supply, dealers and a variety of institutions which buy and hold acceptances. Acceptance dealers buy bills from holders seek ing to dispose o f them, sell bills to those seeking them, and generally make ready markets, for either purchases or sales. They ordinarily purchase ac ceptances outright, instead o f handling them on a commission basis. Dealers operate with small portfolios and endeavor to sell bills purchased as quickly as possible. The dealers’ compensation is represented by the spread between the rates at which they buy and those at which they sell, cur rently % of 1 per cent. Dealers were active in the acceptance market al most as soon as the market was established. One of the largest of present-day acceptance houses commenced business in January 1919, and by the spring of 1921 Eastern dealers had established branches on the Pacific Coast. Some dealers active during the twenties withdrew from the market following 1929, and in 1931 only eight dealers remained. At present, there are six dealers, of whom four account for the greater share o f the business. Only one of these deals exclusively in acceptances, the others being also engaged in one or more phases o f the securities business. Accepting banks discount some o f their own bills directly and also purchase the bills o f other acceptors from correspondents and in the open market. They purchase for their own account and for the account of foreign and domestic corre spondents. At the beginning of the American acceptance market, the number o f accepting banks increased rapidly, and in the years 1918-21 a total of several hundred was reached. The number has declined since then, as banks in smaller interior cities, and those without adequate knowledge of acceptance financing or properly equipped accep tance departments, dropped out of the market. By the end o f 1930, about 164 banks were listed as acceptors o f bankers’ bills, while at present there are about 125 accepting institutions. But through E ssays out the history of the American acceptance market, by far the greater part of the accepting has been done by 40 to 50 institutions. These large ac ceptors are located in major financial centers. New York, the country’s foremost financial center, is the principal acceptance market. Prior to 1932, both Federal Reserve Banks and "others” (that is, all other buyers except accepting banks) were much larger holders of acceptances than the accepting banks. But during the period 1932-45, accepting banks held well over half of the total volume of acceptances outstanding in every year. Yields on acceptances in the years be fore the depression were low in comparison with commercial paper, Government securities, and call loans secured by stock exchange collateral. Banks therefore held acceptances only in moderate amounts, for use in adjusting their reserve posi tions. However, between 1932 and the outbreak of war, when excess reserves were large, accepting banks retained larger amounts of their own ac ceptances than before, and also sought bills more aggressively in the market. Starting in 1930, on the other hand, the total volume o f acceptances outstanding declined sharply. As a result of these factors, bill portfolios of accepting banks came to represent a much larger proportion of total ac ceptances outstanding than had previously been the case. By 1945, when the low point in volume of acceptances outstanding was reached, accepting banks held over three fourths o f the total, com pared with only 11 per cent in 1929. Also, within their portfolios, the accepting banks’ own bills increased markedly in importance relative to bills bought, rising from less than one third in 1929 to almost 60 per cent in 1945. In the postwar period, as acceptances outstanding increased in volume from their wartime low, and as short-term interest rates became firmer, the proportion of total acceptances outstanding •held by accepting banks declined (to 40 per cent in December 1951). But the proportion of accepting banks’ own bills to their total acceptance portfolios (60 per cent in December) showed little change. In the earlier years, as already indicated, Federal Reserve Banks were large purchasers of accep tances. They bought both for their own account and for the account of foreign central banks. Tra F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k ditionally, Reserve Banks never sought actively to buy acceptances for their own account; instead, they stood ready to purchase, at specified rates, all prime, eligible, endorsed acceptances offered by banks. Also, it was the policy of the Reserve Banks not to sell acceptances acquired for their own account, but to hold them until maturity. Reserve Banks did enter the market actively in order to purchase and sell for foreign central bank corres pondents, however. of N ew Y ork 25 offered to the Reserve Banks from 1934 through 1945. The small purchases of 1946 and 1947 coincided with a relatively sharp increase in the supply of acceptances in these years. By 1948, private demand for acceptances had accommodated itself to the larger supply and Federal Reserve purchases for own account ceased until the end of March 1951, when an offering of 2 million dol lars was taken by the Reserve Banks. During one or more stages in the life of the American acceptance market, bankers’ acceptances have been held by various categories of investors other than the Federal Reserve Banks (for own or foreign account) and the accepting banks (for their own account). Such categories include non accepting banks (for their own account), custo mers and correspondents of domestic commercial banks, dealers in bankers’ acceptances, foreign banks with agencies in the United States, savings banks and insurance companies, and individuals, partnerships, associations, and corporations in many other lines of activity. The great decline since 1929 in the volume of acceptances outstand ing, however, has caused a considerable narrow Reserve Bank acceptance portfolios shrank very rapidly in 1932, but rose slightly in 1933, owing ing of the market. The major holders of accep to the banking crisis. Thereafter, the Federal. tances today, other than accepting banks for their Reserve Banks held no acceptances for their own own account and Federal Reserve Banks for the account until 1945, and they made only nominal account of foreign correspondents, are believed purchases for foreign correspondents in scattered to be foreign banks with agencies in the United years. In 1946, in 1947, and again in the spring States and domestic commercial banks for the ac of 1951, small amounts offered at Reserve Bank count of foreign customers and correspondents.® Holders other than the Reserve Banks and ac buying rates were purchased by the Reserve Banks for their own account. In 1946 also, there was a cepting banks were an important source of demand resumption of purchases at market rates for the for bankers’ acceptances prior to 1932. Their account of foreign correspondents. These purchases holdings from 1925 through 1930, for example, have continued throughout the postwar period, were in most months larger than those of the though in amounts greatly reduced from those of Reserve Banks, and exceeded holdings of accepting banks in every year. But from 1932 through 1945 the late twenties. they played a subsidiary role to accepting banks as The almost complete cessation since 1934 of buyers of acceptances. After 1945, as the supply Federal Reserve acceptance purchases for their own of acceptances began to increase, both accepting account is primarily the result of two factors— (1 ) the spectacular decrease in the supply of accep banks and other holders added to their portfolios through 1947. Holdings of accepting banks de tances following 1929 and continuing until the spring of 1945, and (2 ) the concomitant growth * Foreign correspondents o f domestic commercial banks of demand by accepting banks (which had not are usually also commercial banks, although some for eign central banks maintain deposits with American com been large holders of acceptances during the mercial banks. Like the foreign correspondents o f Federal twenties) for the smaller supply. As a result of Reserve Banks, they have for years followed the practice o f investing part o f their dollar holdings in bankers’ these influences, practically no acceptances were acceptances. When private demand for acceptances was strong, open market rates tended to fall below the buying rates of the Reserve Banks. But throughout the period from 1916 to 1931, private demand was generally insufficient to clear the market. Market rates therefore rose toward Federal Reserve buying rates, and the Reserve Banks were offered large quantities of acceptances. Between 1916 and 1924, they bought each year from 25 to 60 per cent of all bills drawn. And from 1925 through 1931, their holdings for their own account at the end o f each year averaged from one fifth to one half of total acceptances outstanding. 26 M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays dined in 1948 and 1949; those of other holders, however, continued to increase. Thus in 1949, for the first time since 1930, other holders provided a larger source of demand for bankers’ acceptances than accepting banks. They continued in 1950 and 1951 to be the most important factor in the demand for acceptances. At the end of December, they held 272 million (56 per cent) of the total of 490 million dollars of acceptances outstanding. This compares with holdings at the same time of 197 million (40 per cent) by accepting banks and 21 million (4 per cent) by Federal Reserve Banks for the account of foreign correspondents. Two reasons may be advanced in explanation of the strong demand for acceptances by "others” in the postwar period. First, as indicated above, this demand is mostly foreign in origin, and bankers’ acceptances have long enjoyed a high degree of popularity abroad as a short-term investment medium. Second, the income (discount) earned on bankers’ dollar acceptances owned by nonresident, foreign corporations has been held by the Treasury Department (in a 1947 ruling) to be exempt from Federal income taxation. From the standpoint of foreign investors, this gives the bankers’ accep tance a considerable advantage over other com parable, short-term, dollar investment media (Treasury bills, for example), the income from which is subject to a 30 per cent withholding levy. Further growth in the use of bankers’ dollar ac ceptances depends on the future course of privately financed international trade. Domestic uses of acceptances have never been important in this country, since the practice of open-account financ ing was firmly established here before an accept ance market developed. It is the international uses, particularly the financing of merchandise imports and exports, which have traditionally accounted for the bulk of the bankers’ dollars acceptances drawn. Substantial increases in the volume o f ac ceptances outstanding, therefore, can be expected only from expansion of these international uses. Such expansion presupposes a growth of inter national trade in nongovernmental channels, whether through an over-all increase in trade (both private and governmental) or through a shift of existing trade from governmental to private channels. FINANCING SECURITY BROKERS AND DEALERS by S ta n le y 'FUNDAMENTAL changes have occurred since -*• the thirties in the market for bank loans secured by stock exchange and other security collateral. In slightly more than two decades the call loan market has contracted greatly both in volume and in its relative importance in the money market. Although at one time call loans were the most important means used by banks to employ surplus funds and to adjust reserve positions, they have now become a comparatively small outlet for loans direct to borrowers and the formal arrange ments of an impersonal market no longer exist. While students of the money market need no longer focus as much of their attention as they did in the past upon the fluctuations of call loan rates, the volume of call loan activity, the mechanics of market operations in call loans, and upon the degree of interdependence between this market, the money market, and bank reserves, it is impor tant to understand the institutional arrangements which have succeeded to the functions formerly served by the call loan. In 1929, before the stock market break, security loan rates in New York varied from day to day over a range from about 5 to 15 per cent, generally remaining well above the rates for prime com mercial paper. The aggregate volume o f security loans extended by banks and others was several times the volume of recent years. The market then was impersonal, with transactions occurring largely through the money desk on the New York Stock Exchange; that desk was discontinued in 1946, after more than a decade of negligible activity at an unchanging interest rate o f 1 per cent, and for many years security loans have largely been made by banks through direct negotiation with the borrowers. Loans "for the account of others” (than banks) have been legally prohibited since mid-1933. The proportion of their earning assets which the weekly reporting banks in New York city lodged in security loans at the end of December 1951'was about one third of the 1929 L. M ille r ratio; for all other banks, the proportion was only about one ninth that of 1929. To a degree, secu rity loans have tended to become comparable with customer loans and so are part of the normal lend ing business, rather than representing primarily a residual employment for excess funds, or the first means of obtaining funds from the money market in the event of a drain on bank reserves. Bank reserve adjustments have not for some time centered on the call loan market, and for nearly a decade short-term Treasury securities have been relied upon as the principal (negotiable) money market instrument. As a result, the liquidity of the money market no longer depends upon call loans that reflect activity and prices in the stock markets; nor are the stock markets heavily influenced by short-run changes in the availability o f money market funds. Thus, an institutional arrangement that was at one time an important source of cyclical instability in the financial sector of the economy has largely disappeared. This article will describe, in part, the kind of security loan market that has emerged, following these fundamental changes. It discusses the present characteristics of one of the most important seg ments of that market, the loans to brokers and dealers. The review will include a brief summary of the purposes for which brokers and dealers borrow, the sources of funds for these loans, the principal types of loans made, the legal margin re quirements, and the customary practices of the banks in relating their own margin requirments and interest charges to the nature of the securities offered as collateral. W hy B rokers and D ealers Borrow Brokers and dealers in securities require bank credit in order to finance: (1 ) their customers’ purchases of securities, (2 ) their own "positions” or inventories of securities held either in short term trading accounts or in longer-term investment accounts, (3 ) their purchasing and carrying of new security issues pending sale to ultimate in27 M 28 oney M a r k e t E ssays Chart ‘I Borrowing on Collateral by Members of the New York Stock Exchange* Billions of dollars B illio n s o f d o lla rs * Amounts outstanding at end o f month, January 1929— December 1951. Loans on U. S. Government securities first shown for March 1943. The figures in this chart differ from those shown in Chart II. Chart I represents loans exclusively to members o f the New York Stock Exchange. They include loans from banks and all other sources in and outside of New York City. Source: New York Stock Exchange. vestors, and (4 ) the delivery or clearance of securities traded. Available data are not sufficiently detailed to show the actual volume of bank funds used in satisfying the various purposes for which brokers and dealers borrow. It is possible, however, to indicate thfeir order of magnitude within the two broad classes into which broker and dealer loans are subdivided— those for "purchasing or carrying other securities” and those for "purchasing or carrying Government, securities” . On December 26, 1951, loans on other securities at the weekly reporting member banks were about 1.0 billion dollars; those on Government securities were roughly 390 million dollars. The total of 1.4 billion dollars included practically all loans made to brokers and dealers by banks in the United States; and the reporting banks in New York City accounted for more than three quarters of this total. Although the reporting banks themselves do not submit data indicating the amount of their loans used for each of the four purposes men tioned above, rough approximations can be esti mated from data released by the New York Stock F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k of N ew Y 29 ork Chart II Outstanding Loans to Brokers and Dealers for Purchasing or Carrying Securities by New York City Weekly Reporting Member Banks* Bi I lions of dollars B illio n s of dol lars 2.0 2.0 1.5 1.5 Government securities 1.0 0.5 1943 1944 1945 1946 J________L 1947 1948 1949 J________L 1950 1951 * Amounts outstanding on last Wednesday o f the month, March 1943— December 1951. See also footnote to Chart I. f Change in the number of weekly reporting member banks. Exchange and other sources. Loans on "other securities” are largely o f the first type (broker borrowing to finance customer purchases— mainly of stocks), although at times perhaps as much as one fourth of the total might be accounted for by either the second or the third purpose (that is, financing broker or dealer "positions” , or their holding of new securities pending sale to ultimate investors). The fourth purpose relates largely to over-the-counter market transactions, which may have to be financed briefly during the process of transferring ownership; but since the greater part of these loans are made and repaid within the same day they are not shown in bank data on outstand ing loans (which are reported as of the close of business on the reporting date). As far as the broker and dealer loans on Government securities are concerned, these are predominantly for financ ing "positions,” although a small portion often represents overnight loans arranged to finance the "carry” while a transfer of ownership is being effected. The aggregate volume of loans to brokers and dealers has fluctuated between two thirds of a 30 M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays for several years. Treasury refunding operations have often been an important influence on the volume of dealer loans on Government securities. At such times there is ordinarily an increase in the volume of trading in Government securities, as those investors whose needs are not exactly met by the newly offered security attempt their own re funding through sales of the maturing issue in the market. In the course of facilitating this redis tribution within the market, dealers tend to in During the war and early postwar years, dealer crease their own positions. It is, to a large extent, loans on Government securities constituted the only after the new securities are actully issued largest single category of loans to brokers and that sales bring about a reduction in dealer posi dealers. Toward the end o f 1945, for example, tions and dealer loans. Dealer positions may also the loans on Governments amounted to close to be increased by the shifting of securities within 2 billion dollars, more than twice the volume of the market that precedes Treasury new money borrowings on other collateral at that time. There offerings. has been a sharp reduction in dealer loans on So u r c e s o f F u n d s Governments since 1947. And, as already noted, Security loans are mainly an outlet for the funds on December 26, 1951 loans to brokers and dealers of banks in the leading financial centers. The for "purchasing or carrying Government securi member bank call report for June 30, 1951 showed ties” at all weekly reporting member banks were that loans to brokers and dealers by central reserve less than two fifths of the loans on other securities. city banks in New York and Chicago were about In aggregate amount, broker borrowings on listed 11 per cent of the total loans of these institutions securities at the end of 1951 constituted the larg and 87 per cent of all member bank loans to est outlet for bank loans to security brokers and brokers and dealers. The loans of the New York dealers, although they have not changed materially City banks, furthermore, were 11 times those of in volume over the past several years. Dealer the Chicago banks. Within New York City, only borrowing on Government securities ranked second banks located in the financial district in lower in volume, and loans to finance dealer positions Manhattan make loans to brokers and dealers on a in unlisted bonds and stocks appeared to rank large scale. Other banks apparently have neither third. A large segment of this third type probably the experience nor the large volume of demand represented funds borrowed to carry dealer posi necessary to make this kind of loan profitably tions in State and local government issues. at the comparatively low interest rates prevailing billion and two billion dollars over a large part of the post-World War II period (through the end of 1951). The variation is influenced by such factors as the current volume of trading in securities, the amount and rate of sale o f market offerings o f securities by business and govern mental bodies, changes in security prices and in interest rates, and variations in the readiness of investors (including dealers) to take speculative positions. New security financing plays at times an im portant part in the fluctuations in outstanding security loans. As a rule, new publicly offered security issues will have been largely sold by the underwriters before payment is due to the issuing corporation. Loans to carry the remainder, pending sale to investors, are usually outstanding no more than one week. But a turnabout in security prices, creating difficulties in the sale of new issues and congestion in the market, can become an important factor leading temporarily at least to an increase in security loans. Some new bond issues floated dur ing past periods o f market weakness have been carried by the underwriters on a call loan basis over the last two decades. Brokerage firms which are members of an or ganized stock exchange have a second important source of funds, the "free" cash credit balances of their customers. Member firms may utilize such balances to finance the margin purchases of other customers. Thus, on June 30, 1951, New York Stock Exchange member firms reported that while customer and firm accounts had debit balances of about 1.3 billion and 375 million dollars, respec tively, outside borrowing amounted to only 680 million dollars. The difference of more than one billion dollars was largely supplied by the free credit balances in the accounts of other customers. F e d e r a l R eserve B a n k T ypes of Se c u r i t y L o a n s Security loans may be divided into two types, those which finance holding and those which are made for a few hours to finance a change in ownership. The former may be either demand (call) or time loans; the latter are either day or overnight loans. The call and time loan agreements between brokers or dealers and the banks are similar in that under either form the borrower agrees to keep the loan properly margined (that is, a specified proportion of his own funds invested in the securities) and to permit securities pledged against the loan to be sold by the lender in satis faction of the debt in the event of default or of failure to maintain adequate margin. The time loan takes the form o f a note in a specific amount with a specified maturity date, and may be renewed at the current renewal rate o f interest. The call loan, on the other hand, takes the form of a general agreement, in which the amount of the loan is not specified. Under this agreement succes sive loans and repayments are made, and any in debtedness may be terminated at short notice either on demand of the lender or repayment by the borrower. In both cases, substitution of collateral is freely permitted with due regard for the quality of the new collateral and the margin required. Most security loans are made on a call basis, and in current practice such loans are rarely called. Repayment is normally at the initiative of the borrower. Interest costs are usually computed daily at the prevailing rate. The maximum amount of call (and time) loans outstanding to any one borrower is governed by the quality of the collateral, the credit standing of the broker or dealer, and the loan limit of the bank. The New York Stock Exchange stipulates that the aggregate indebtedness of a member firm may not exceed 15 times its net capital. The loan officer o f an individual bank determines the credit limit for each broker or dealer on the basis of the borrower’s credit standing and the quality of the pledged securities. The aggregate amount of loans to any one broker or dealer may not, of course, exceed 10 per cent of the capital and surplus of a national bank (or 10 per cent of the capital, surplus, and undivided profits of a New York State member bank), except that for certain of N ew 31 Y ork security loans including those on Government securities the maximum is 25 per cent. The practice in this countiy of making full cash payment daily for security purchases (in contrast with the fortnightly settlements in Great Britain, for example) has necessitated the creation of special types of temporary credit accommodation for dealers in securities. These are known as the day loan and the overnight loan, which are used primarily by those dealing in Government securi ties and various over-the-counter issues (most payments for stock exchange transactions are offset through clearing arrangements). Day loans, pay able on the same day they are made, enable dealers (1 ) to pay for securities they have contracted to purchase and receive, and (2 ) to pay off a loan against which securities have been pledged in order to release those securities for delivery to a buyer against payment. Overnight loans provide dealers with funds to pay off day loans, and thus enable them to hold overnight the securities they have not been able to deliver during the day. Both the day and the overnight loans are evi denced by a note for a specific sum of money. The overnight loan is fully secured by securities pledged against the loan. The day loan is safe guarded by a lien or chattel mortgage on the securities in the process of receipt or delivery, and a list of the securities involved may be attached as part of the day loan note, but the lender does not have possession of the securities. Day loans require no margin and the rate of interest in New York has remained fixed at one per cent since the middle of 1929. Overnight loans are subject to the same maximum loan values and interest rates as other security loans. R e g u l a t io n s T and U Under powers delegated by the Securities Ex change Act of 1934, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System has issued Regulations T and U which, in general, place limits on borrow ing to purchase or carry "listed” securities (i. e., securities listed on national security exchanges registered with the Securities and Exchange Com mission). Regulation T applies to extensions of credit which brokers and dealers (including members of national security exchanges) make to their customers; Regulation U applies to loans M o n e y M a r k e t E ssays 32 made by banks on any stock for the purpose of purchasing or carrying listed stocks. The Board has the power to vary the borrowing limits, through stipulating ‘ maximum loan values,” with changing conditions. At the present time, the effect of the Regulations is to require customers (in cluding brokers when operating for their own account) to use their own funds, that is to provide "margin,” for 75 per cent of the purchase price of a security. Federal Government, State, and municipal bonds are exempt from both Regula tions. Other bonds are exempt from Regulation U (loans made by banks) but not Regulation T (loans made by brokers). Regulation T, in addi tion, prohibits brokers and dealers from extend ing credit for the purpose of purchasing or carry ing those securities which are both unlisted and nonexempt. , In extending credit to firms which are members of a stock exchange, the New York Gty banks re quire such firms to sign a statement declaring that they are subject to Regulation T. In the case of loans on listed issues, borrowing firms are also required to segregate their customers’ securi ties from their own holdings. Among other pur poses, this segregation permits the banks to lend to brokers somewhat more freely against cus tomers’ securities, which have already been "mar gined” by the customers under Regulation T, than on securities owned by the broker himself, since the banks must treat these in conformity with Regulation U. The legal prescription of maximum loan values, generally referred to as the regulation o f margin requirements, has been effective in limiting the volume of bank credit used to finance speculative transactions in listed stocks. The security loan, and more particularly the call loan, has in the process been made a relatively more stable money market instrument, much less vulnerable than formerly to forced sales because o f changes in security prices; In flu en ce Loan V alues of Collateral and on In terest R ates As shown in the accompanying table, the maxi mum loan values which banks themselves permit for security loans, and, to a lesser extent, the in terest rates charged on such loans, vary with the Terms o f Call Loans to Brokers and Dealers on Securities by New York G ty Banks (as o f December 31, 1951)* Type of issue Outstanding Stocks Listed Customer accounts.................. Firm accounts ........................ Unlisted ....................................... Loan values Interest rates (In per cent of (In per cent) market price) 66% 25 2l/2-23/4 21/2-23/4 50-60 2Y2-2Y4 75-95 80-98 2-2Yi 95-100 95-98 2-2l/2 2-21/a N ew issues Stocks Listed ........................................... Unlisted ....................................... 90-95 90-95 2-234 2-23/4 Bonds Corporate ..................................... Municipal .................................. 90-95 90-95 2-234 2-23/4 Bonds§ Corporate..................................... Municipal .................................. Government! .............................. Maturing in 1 year or less.... Maturing in over 1 year....... 2-23/4 * Data are a composite o f lowest and highest loan values and interest rates found in a survey o f four leading New York G ty banks. § Includes short-term securities. f Loans to dealers maintaining active markets in Govern ment securities. type of security offered as collateral. Inquiries at four leading New York Gty banks showed that as of December 31, 1951, the loan values which the banks specified for brokers’ loans on listed stocks generally amounted to two thirds of the market value of such securities whenever the purpose of the loan was to finance customer deal ings already subject to Regulation T. Banks may permit these loan values to rise to, but not often over, 75 per cent. To carry listed stocks (apart from underwriting operations) in their own portfolios on borrowed money, however, stock exchange firms and others could borrow no more than 25 per cent of the market value, as required by Regulation U. The loan values which the banks specified on loans secured by unlisted stocks were in the neighborhood of 50 per cent. Progressively higher loan values are customarily allowed on loans secured by corporate bonds, the securities of State and local governments, and ob ligations of the Federal Government Loans on F e d e ra l R eserve B a n k new corporate and municipal security issues, held in underwriting syndicates pending distribution to the public, are regularly permitted to represent a higher proportion of market value than would normally be allowed for loans on outstanding issues. Rates charged brokers and dealers on security loans also vary somewhat depending on the quality o f the collateral and the character of the business of the broker or dealer. Interest rates charged by the New York City banks on loans secured by stock exchange collateral are usually 1/4 to y 2 of one per cent higher than those charged when the collateral consists of Government securi ties. The interest rate on call loans secured by stocks was raised to 2% per cent on December 18 by most banks, although a few banks continued to quote the previous prevailing rate of i y 2 per cent. Most New York Gty banks also charge the stock exchange call rate on broker and dealer loans secured by corporate and municipal bonds of N ew Y 33 ork and unlisted stocks. Only those dealers who ac tively maintain markets in Government securities are granted the lower rate on Government security loans. Call rates on Governments fluctuate daily with money market conditions. Toward the close of 1951, the rate ranged from a minimum of 2 per cent to a maximum of 2 y 2 per cent. Se c u r i t y L o a n s N o Longer a M arket In str u m ent The present characteristics of the security loan market are markedly different from those of the late twenties. As presently organized, on an overthe-counter basis, the market for loans to brokers and dealers accounts for a relatively small pro portion of the earning assets of the commercial banking system. Despite the fact that most of these loans are made in demand (call) form, the possibility no longer exists for a repetition of the type of "call money panic" that at times proved so disastrous in the past. The call loan has ceased to be an important money market instrument.