View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
Report of the Federal Reserve Board Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978,
PX. 95-523
and the State of the Economy

HEARING
BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON
DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
OF THE

COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND
FINANCIAL SERVICES
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED FIFTH CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION

MARCH 5, 1997

Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking and Financial Services

Serial No. 105-6

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1997
For sale by the U.S. Government Printing Office
Superintendent of Documents, Congressional Sales Office, Washington, DC 20402
I S B N 0-16-054987-6




HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES
JAMES A. LEACH, Iowa, Chairman
BILL McCOLLUM, Florida, Vice Chairman
HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
DOUG BEREUTER, Nebraska
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota
RICHARD H. BAKER, Louisiana
CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York
RICK LAZIO, New York
BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
SPENCER BACKUS, Alabama
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
MICHAEL N. CASTLE, Delaware
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
PETER T. KING, New York
TOM CAMPBELL, California
FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York
EDWARD R. ROYCE, California
MAXINE WATERS, California
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois
JACK METCALF, Washington
LUCILLE ROYBALrALLARD, California
ROBERT W. NEY, Ohio
THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin
ROBERT L. EHRLICH JR., Maryland
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
BOB BARR, Georgia
MELVIN L. WATT, North Carolina
JON D. FOX, Pennsylvania
MAURICE D. HINCHEY, New York
SUE W. KELLY, New York
GARY L. ACKERMAN, New York
RON PAUL, Texas
KEN BENTSEN, Texas
DAVE WELDON, Florida
JESSE L. JACKSON JR., Illinois
JIM RYUN, Kansas
CYNTHIA A. McKINNEY, Georgia
MERRILL COOK, Utah
CAROLYN C. KILPATRICK, Michigan
VINCE SNOWBARGER, Kansas
JAMES H. MALONEY, Connecticut
BOB RILEY, Alabama
RICK HILL, Montana
DARLENE HOOLEY, Oregon
PETE SESSIONS, Texas
JULIA M. CARSON, Indiana

STEVEN c. LATOURETTE, Ohio

BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont

SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
MICHAEL N. CASTLE, Delaware, Chairman
JON D. FOX, Pennsylvania, Vice Chairman

STEVEN c. LATOURETTE, Ohio

EDWARD R. ROYCE, California
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
JACK METCALF, Washington
ROBERT W. NEY, Ohio
BOB BARR, Georgia
RON PAUL, Texas
DAVE WELDON, Florida




FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York

BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
MAURICE D. HINCHEY, New York
KEN BENTSEN, Texas
JESSE L. JACKSON JR., Illinois

(II)

CONTENTS
Page

Hearing held on:
March 5, 1997
Appendix
March 5, 1997

.

1
43

WITNESS
WEDNESDAY, MARCH 5, 1997
Greenspan, Hon. Alan, Chairman, Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System

12

APPENDIX
Prepared statements:
Castle, Hon. Michael N
Flake, Hon. Floyd H
Jackson, Hon. Jesse L. Jr
Maloney, Hon. Carolyn B
Paul, Hon. Dr. Ron
Sanders, Hon. Bernard
Greenspan, Hon. Alan (with attachment)

?

44
48
55
59
53
61
63

ADDITIONAL MATERIAL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
LaFalce, Hon. John J., prepared statement
Greenspan, Hon. Alan:
Report to Congress from the Board of Governors, Federal Reserve System
dated February 26, 1997




57
81

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
WEDNESDAY, MARCH 5, 1997

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY POLICY,
COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES,

Washington, DC.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 2:03 p.m., in room
2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Michael N. Castle
[chairman of the subcommittee] presiding.
Present: Chairman Castle, Representatives Leach, Fox, Lucas,
Metcalf, Paul, Weldon, Roukema, Flake, Frank, Kennedy, Sanders,
Kanjorski, Maloney, Hinchey, Bentsen, and Jackson.
Chairman CASTLE. The hearing will come to order.
The subcommittee meets today to receive the semiannual report
of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on the
Conduct of Monetary Policy and the State of the Economy, as mandated in the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Chairman Greenspan, welcome back to the House Committee on
Banking and Financial Services, Subcommittee on Domestic and
International Monetary Policy. You will note that this subcommittee has done its best to accommodate the Fed while meeting the
schedule required by the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. We have followed your appearance before our Senate colleagues as closely as
we could, so that the same testimony can serve for both hearings.
I trust that in turn, you will be as candid as possible in addressing
issues raised over the past week.
Today, we will have 5-minute opening statements by the
Members present. In addition, some Members of the full Committee
may sit with us today and participate in the questioning. As always, any prepared remarks presented by a Member will be
accepted for the record.
Today the U.S. economy continues to be healthy with inflation
apparently in check. We welcome the continued sound performance
of the economy which evidently has been assisted by the Fed's
monetary policy. Having witnessed what even one of your carefullycalibrated characterizations of the stock market can accomplish, it
is clear that what you say can have a significant impact on the
market, at least over the short term.
Following your testimony last week, many analysts have argued
both that the current prices of common stocks are justified and
that external factors are also somewhat responsible in making this
market the investment vehicle of choice. Others dispute the actual
(1)




amount of influence the Fed is able to exercise using the traditional
mechanisms of monetary policy.
If you believe that any of your earlier remarks were misinterpreted or unfairly taken out of context, today's hearing offers the
opportunity to correct such misreading. Certainly, several percentage points of exuberance have been wrung out of the stock markets, and we can hope that some seeds of inflation have been
destroyed as well.
I am also interested in your assessment of whether the run-up
in relative value of the dollar is becoming a limiting factor in the
conduct of monetary policy by the Federal Reserve.
Your chairmanship of the Federal Reserve System Board of Governors continues to be successful as judged by results. Nevertheless, aside from monetary policy there are other aspects of Federal
Reserve operations that merit review by Congress. This subcommittee is planning oversight hearings on the Federal Reserve System
that will review Fed activity, including the transition from physical
to electronic forms of money as the digital age looms in our future.
Of particular concern to me, it seems that with the current level
of technology available, the Fed's proposal to add an additional day
to the current check-clearing process seems to be going in the
wrong direction, especially from the point of view of the consumer
needing access to his or her money.
We also hope to review the role of the central bank as a competitor with private sector clearing facilities. We look forward to hearing how the Fed is planning for the potential of new technology to
affect systemic security, safety, soundness, and consumer privacy
as well as the future conduct of monetary policy.
In this future hearing, we hope to engage in a discussion of the
various ways that the approaching digital revolution in money will
affect the operations of the Federal Reserve System. I am increasingly persuaded that dramatic change in how we define and employ
money may soon be upon us. This in turn, must affect the payment
system and institutions charged with its stewardship. Thus, we
should be prepared for the threshold at which this impending
change becomes significant in your models of the economy.
As always, we are delighted to have you with us and look
forward to a lively discussion.
Before recognizing Mr. Frank for his statement, I want to recognize and welcome the participation of Members of the Banking
Committee not appointed to the Monetary Policy Subcommittee
and ask unanimous consent that to the extent they wish to participate and ask questions of the witness they may be permitted to do
so.
[The prepared statement of Chairman Castle can be found on
page 44 in the appendix.]
Hearing no objection, it is ordered. At this time I will turn to Mr.
Frank for his opening statement.
Mr. FRANK. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I welcome this in part as
a chance to, I hope, demonstrate my commitment to the value of
civility which we talk about a lot. I say that because civility is
something that is most important when we have profound disagreements. Mr. Greenspan, you are the perfect subject for this because
I cannot think of many people now in Government for whom I have




greater respect or with whom I have greater disagreement. I think
it is important for us to be able to show that personal respect and
very profound disagreement can exist side-by-side.
The disagreement is that I believe through the performance of
your role, given how you have interpreted it, the Federal Reserve
System under your governance, with the support of those who work
with you, has become an engine for inequality in our society. I
think that has terribly negative consequences.
A lot of people have talked recently about a poll of the Republican Party done by Mr. Fabrizio in which he talks about various
segments of the Republican Party. He found five segments. What
I found very interesting was that all five segments, when asked,
were negative as to whether or not we should expand NAFTA.
There is, I think, almost a certainty that a poll of Democrats would
show an even heavier negative. All five of the sectors of the Republican Party which differ on a lot of things were opposed to,
according to this poll, to expanding NAFTA.
We have an increasing degree of resistance on the part of the
American people to the kinds of international economic cooperation
that you believe are very important to the prosperity of this country and the world, and I agree with you to a great extent. But the
problem we have is, I think illustrated by a comment John Kennedy made when he initiated the Alliance for Progress. He said
Franklin Roosevelt, who was the model here with the Good Neighbor policy, was able to be a good neighbor abroad because he was
seen as a good neighbor at home.
Increasingly, a lot of Americans do not see this Government, the
Federal Reserve System, Congress, the Executive Branch as a good
neighbor at home. They see increased inequality. You talk about
job insecurity. It is, as you know, a terrible thing to live with. I realize you understand the anguishing factor of it, but most of your
statement is about the centrality of job insecurity as a factor in
America. Living with job insecurity, which means uncertainty as to
whether or not you are going to be able to feed and clothe and educate and care for your children, is a terribly anguishing thing.
Recently, you have come out very strongly in favor of what, I understand your technical justification for, but what is in fact one of
the most regressive policies being proposed: telling old women who
live on $7,000 and $8,000-a-year in America that they are getting
too much compensation for inflation and that we ought to cut them
$100 or $200 every so often. I cannot think of a more regressive
policy.
Wage increases are, as you see the world, a problem. The lower
the rate of wage increases, the better. Meanwhile, of course, there
are elements in the economy where things go up that are not a
problem.
It also has to do with tax policy, and I am going to ask you to
address this, if not in my 5 minutes, at some later point in writing.
We passed a tax bill in 1993 that increased taxes on upper-income
people. I thought that helped promote equity and helped reduce the
deficit. You said in testimony that you and I discussed that you
were committed to the view that this was going to cause problems
for the economy. I remember in 1994 you said that this would




reduce the growth in the economy, when you raise taxes on upperincome people, or taxes on anybody.
I asked you this about 1994 or 1995 and you said it was too early
for those effects to show. Well, I would have to ask you. We passed
that tax increase nearly 4 years ago. In the intervening years since
we passed the tax increase your view has been that the economy
was growing, if anything, more rapidly than it should. You have
leaned more toward restraint. Your policy has been caution.
So I have to ask, if we damaged the economy by raising taxes,
why then has your view been tnat the economy was, if anything,
a little bit too exuberant, to use a word? Does that not mean if we
had not raised taxes, presumably you would have shown us less
restraint?
I understand this is not your goal, but it does seem to me, in
closing, as you add up the specific policy positions you have taken:
let us cut the cost-of-liying increase for Social Security recipients
which will have its major social impact on the elderly poor; let us
worry if wages go up too much; let us worry if unemployment goes
down too much; let us oppose a tax increase on the wealthy.
The consequence of this is, we pay for lower inflation, if that is
in fact what we had to do to get it, with an increase in inequality
or, at best, an absence of any measures to fight the inequality that
the market inevitably sets forward. That is, as I said, not just a
problem of equity. But I have never seen America in a more antiinternationalist mood, and I think that that is one of the consequences of this set of policies.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Frank.
Mr. Lucas is recognized for his opening statement.
Mr. LUCAS. I do not have one, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you.
Now we recognize the distinguished Ranking Member of this
subcommittee, and a pleasure to have him back. Mr. Flake.
Mr. FLAKE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to welcome Mr. Greenspan to our biennial Humphrey-Hawkins hearings to discuss the Federal Reserve's conduct
of monetary policy and its opinion on the current state of this economy. Given last week's reactionary activity on the stock market
and the persistent political commentary of our Nation's economic
health, I certainly look forward to hearing your statements today,
Mr. Greenspan.
I will be brief in these comments, but I do wish to express to you
one area of specific concern for me. This concern is the continued
neglect of our Nation's poorer communities. The Federal Reserve
appears to focus its efforts on macro-economic issues that in general have been good for the overall economic health of our Nation.
But in its zeal to control inflation and to stave off economic
downturns, the Federal Reserve seems to have forgotten that there
are communities in America that are in a persistent cycle of
poverty and stagnation.
These communities are not hearing policies from the Fed that
speak directly to their needs. The question thus becomes, does the
Federal Reserve focus on all participants in the economy, or does
it need to improve its communications process with respect to its
concern and compassion for all of society?




Whichever conclusion we come to, I do believe that these hearings tend to focus too much on macro-economic issues that do not
speak very well to Mr. and Mrs. America. I recognize the old saying
that a rising tide lifts all boats, arid to an extent that your macroeconomic decisions are prudent for the Nation as a whole, I do
commend you.
But let us not forget that the rising tide also has the real potential to set the small boat adrift without direction. Mr. Chairman,
there are many communities in America adrift in a sea of unemployment, poor education, deteriorated commercial areas, overall
hopelessness. Inside the Beltway, economic and political discourse,
unfortunately is often detached from these realities of everyday
life.
So I invite you, Mr. Chairman, to join with us in trying to participate in a means by which we bring about the necessary change
that lifts all of our communities so that we might have the kind
of civilization that we dare to dream about. I would encourage you
to speak directly to those of us who represent these types of communities, give illustrations and ideas or policies that you and your
colleagues believe will directly benefit what I have come to call
America's Third World nation.
Chairman Greenspan, I come here today not to single out the
Federal Reserve, but with the belief that all of us here in Washington need to become better stewards of the people's Government.
Democrats need to come to the realization that social programs to
help the poor are not the exclusive answer for social ills, and Republicans should not blindly enact slash-and-burn policies in the
name of a balanced budget. Entrenchment of these partisan positions is not good government and only leads to pessimistic opinions
about Washington's ability to govern in a responsible manner.
Obviously, the solution is somewhere in the middle, and thus is
the result of compromise between Democrats and Republicans. It
is a solution defined by cooperation between Government and the
private sector, and is a solution that has Government and the private sector working together in an effort to uplift the poorer communities. This partnership I believe includes improving job growth,
education, and the moral fiber of our Nation.
Therefore, in the coming months I intend to work with all Members in a bipartisan effort to encourage the Federal Reserve to communicate its thoughts on possible efforts for the revitalization of
these often neglected and overlooked communities.
With that, Mr. Chairman, I close. I will listen intensely to the
testimony and I thank you, Mr. Greenspan, for coming to share
with us this afternoon.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much, Mr. Flake.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Floyd H. Flake can be found on
page 48 in the appendix.]
Dr. Paul is recognized for an opening statement if he wishes to
make one.
Mr. PAUL. No statement, Mr. Chairman.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Ron Paul can be found on page
53 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you.
Mr. Kennedy.




Mr. KENNEDY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, welcome once again to the Banking Committee. I, first and foremost, want to say that I think that despite
some of my pessimism about your policies in the past, I think the
record that has been established in terms of the continued economic growth as well as the decline in the unemployment rate indicates tnat there have been times in the past when you perhaps
have proven more correct in terms of your analysis of how the economy should be handled than some of the rest of us, myself
included.
But having said that and having reviewed your testimony for
today, I think that there are certain issues that need to be addressed more completely in terms of how you actually feel certain
issues are going to be resolved. I notice that you talk a lot about
stagnant wages. But when it gets to the actual corrective actions
that you feel are going to be taken you say, in other words, that
the relatively modest wage gains we have experienced are temporary, rather than a lasting phenomenon, because there is a limit
to the value of additional job security people are willing to acquire
in exchange for lesser increases in living standards.
I am not sure that the notion of simple supply-and-demand is
going to necessarily take care of those stagnant wages. I think that
when you see the kind of wage increases that have occurred, particularly at the top end of many of the corporations that are holding these wages down, that just as you are willing to jawbone the
advancements in the stock market, that there is a necessity for you
as the leader of this country's economy to take on more actively the
issues of justice in terms ot the economy as well.
I think the issue of the CPI is one where it is very difficult to
argue the technical issue of the COLA increase. Take for example
my neighbor in Brighton who earns around $8,000. When I first
moved there she had a husband and two sons. Her husband died.
One son moved to New Jersey. The other son became a fireman on
Cape Cod. She lives by herself. Even though she worked most of
her life, her total income is Social Security benefits, because she
never earned a pension. That woman has to tape blankets across
her doorways in order to stay warm enough in the wintertime.
The ultimate result of not granting a full COLA increase is to
say that she should remain cold in the winter because there is a
technical glitch in how the CPI is treated. I just think that underneath the CPI issue we need to hear from you not on just those
technical questions, but as to whether or not the amount of money
that Social Security pays the lowest wage earners in this country
enables people to have what Social Security promised.
What I am asking for is a sense of your weighing in on some of
the issues pertaining to not just the growth of the economy but who
wins and who loses. I firmly believe that is well within your
jurisdiction and you can have an important impact.
Then finally, just very briefly, my concern is that simply because
the unemployment rate drops to a certain number, an automatic
result of that will be to increase the interest rates of this country.
I would like to hear you address that directly. I think, again, that
this is an issue that pertains to justice and to whether or not people who are unemployed can ever expect, particularly with the




changes that have taken place in the welfare laws, whether they
can ever actually expect to be employed in our workforce.
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Kennedy.
Mr. Sanders.
Mr. SANDERS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and welcome, Mr.
Greenspan. Thank you for joining us today.
Like Mr. Frank, I have respect for you personally. I have very,
very strong disagreements with your policy. It is incomprehensible
to me that President Clinton would have reappointed you in fact.
Mr. Greenspan, like every American, you are entitled to your political views. According to newspaper reports, over the years you
have made political contributions to Jesse Helms, to George Bush,
to Bob Dole. You have served on the Committee to Reelect or Elect
President Reagan, as I understand it. And of course, you worked
as a key economic advisor for President Nixon and President Ford.
I respect that. There is nothing wrong. We are all entitled to our
points of view.
In 1985, as I understand it, you served as a consultant to many
in the savings and loan industry. According to Time Magazine, you
suffered your "greatest embarrassment in 1985 when as a private
economist you wrote letters to regulators and Congress endorsing
Charles Keating and his Lincoln Savings and Loan. Lincoln subsequently collapsed at a cost to taxpayers of $2.6 billion and Keating
landed in jail." That was from Time Magazine. You also served as
a consultant for 15 other savings and loans, 14 of whom eventually
failed.
In your confirmation hearings 1 year ago, despite the fact that
the minimum wage of $4.25 is at its lowest point in 40 years—millions of people working for $4.25-an-hour—you noted your opposition to raising the minimum wage. This January, you told the Senate Budget Committee that "the appropriate capital gains tax rate
is zero." Currently, many Senate Republicans are calling for a capital gains tax cut. According to the Center on Budget and Policy
Priorities, 70 percent of the benefits of that tax cut will go to
households earning over $100,000-a-year, and their proposal is far
more limited than your proposal suggests.
Mr. Greenspan, I will grant you consistency in your support for
trickle-down economics. In your career up to today, it is clear that
you have advocated tax and monetary policies which have benefited
the very richest Americans, while at the same time your views reflect policies that come down very heavy on the middle class, the
working class, and low-income people.
In 1983, you were appointed to chair, as I understand it, the Social Security Commission. Under your leadership, the highly regressive payroll tax was increased by about $200 billion. You chose
to solve the Social Security crisis by raising the payroll tax on
working Americans, while at the same time as an economic advisor
you advocated huge tax decreases for the richest people in America.
Now currently, as others have suggested, you are a proponent of
reducing the Consumer Price Index. Like Mr. Kennedy, I have
neighbors and friends, elderly people, who are trying to survive on
$7,000- or $8,000-a-year, and I regard it as horrendous and vulgar,
to be frank with you, that there are people in Government who




8

want to balance the budget on the weakest and most vulnerable
people in this society, and then advocate huge tax breaks for the
richest people in this country as you continuously do.
Now I would like to ask you—and later on maybe you can respond to that. I do not know where you get your information from.
I go, and as I am sure many of my colleagues do, we talk to elderly
people who are trying to make it. They cannot afford their prescription drugs. In my State it gets 20 below zero. Elderly people cannot
afford to heat their homes. Maybe you will tell this subcommittee
the last time you have sat in a room with low-income senior citizens and asked them how they are going to survive if they lose
$100-a-year in their Social Security benefits, what kind of pain
they go through now trying to survive on $7,000- or $8,000-a-year.
Mr. Greenspan, the United States of America today, not alone
through your work but through the help of a lot of other people,
both parties, has the most unfair distribution of wealth and income
in the industrialized world. The richest 1 percent of the population
own 42 percent of the wealth, more than the bottom 90 percent.
And the last 20 years, that unfair distribution of wealth has become even worse. I would ask you in your comments to tell us what
we can do to equalize wealth in this country so that we do not have
such an unfair distribution of wealth.
You would about economic growth. Between 1983 and 1989, 62
percent of the increased wealth in this country went to the richest
1 percent. You can have all the growth that you want, but the middle class continues to shrink. People in my State are working two
and three jobs just to survive because their wages have not kept
pace with inflation. I want to ask you what your policies are doing
for the middle class, for the working class, for low-income people
rather than the wealthy people who I think you end up
representing?
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Bernard Sanders can be found
on page 61 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much, Mr. Sanders.
Mr. Kanjorski, do you wish to follow that, sir?
Mr. KANJORSKI. Yes. I have to apologize for my colleague's
inability to be direct.
[Laughter.]
Mr. KANJORSKI. Mr. Chairman, I too however, following this line,
am very much interested in what the policy of the Administration
and the Congress and the Federal Reserve will be in regard to the
Consumer Price Index. I have previously introduced into Congress,
and most recently went over the numbers with the Bureau of Labor
Statistics, that the Consumer Price Index if geared to senior citizens in America actually are Vioths of 1 percent understated in
that application of people over 62 years of age.
I know we are attempting to use that mechanism for two purposes really. I hope the first purpose is to have a legitimate
Consumer Price Index that we can all rely on without being driven
by politics. But the second purpose, obviously, is a very quick fix
to the budget deficit and imbalance that would occur out in the
next century.




However, I join my colleagues, Mr. Frank, Mr. Kennedy, and Mr.
Sanders in asking the question of where fairness is. If in reality,
the Consumer Price Index today is understated by Vioths of 1 percent if it is applied to people over 62, why do we see there will be
any major savings? I understand that about 82 percent of the programs that use the Consumer Price Index for automatic COLAs are
senior programs in the budget. So if we were to change that and
give the reflection, it does not really give us a great deal of latitude
to save any money, if indeed it may cost the Government more
money and drive us further into debt.
But this casual addressing of this issue that I see that is being
driven by budgetary considerations as opposed to humanitarian
considerations. And it is one thing if we are going to affect the
index to reflect truth. I certainly do favor that. Ana if we need to
have an application of a formula of adjustment to help in the budget, I can understand that. But it does not mean mat it should
apply across the board.
I think if you went into areas like mine where the average Social
Security recipient receives $480 a month, that is hardly in this day
and age a sufficient amount to survive on. And 92 percent of the
people who receive that, that is their major source of income for
sustenance.
So I would hope that you would exercise the influence of your office in this total debate in seeing that fairness prevail, looking at
the means-testing nature of how it applies across the board. Maybe
there ought to be people that are exempt from a change. Maybe
some people should get more at the lower end of the scale than
some that are in more beneficiary positions as a result of their
earning capacity where they may not have the need. Call it a
means-test, if we will, but we should look at that.
Certainly, I hope this all is not driven from the harsh accounting
position of merely budgetary means and easy political decisions,
whether it be here in the Congress or in the Administration. This
is too important an issue for the American people, and senior citizens of today and in the future, for us to be callous about it. So
I would appreciate anything you can address yourself on that issue.
Thank you, sir.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Kanjorski.
Mr. Hinchey.
Mr. HlNCHEY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Greenspan, welcome. It is very nice to see you again. We are
happy to have the opportunity to discuss with you once again the
provisions of the Humphrey-Hawkins Bill. I was just looking at the
purpose of that bill. It says, to maintain long-run growth of monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy's longrun potential to increase production so as to promote the goals of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest rates.
Now I know that you have quarreled with the language of that
law, and as a matter of fact at one point you were advocating that
the law be changed so that the imperative to focus attention on
economy growth and increased employment be excised, taken out
of the law and that the focus of the Federal Reserve be exclusively
on maintaining stable prices. Nevertheless, that has not occurred




10

and the charge of the Federal Reserve is to promote economic
growth as welFas to stabilize prices.
It is disturbing to those of us who believe that the economy can
grow at a rate much faster than 2 percent and still not suffer the
adverse consequences of inflation, to see the Federal Reserve continually holding back economic growth. Historically, we have experienced economic growth far beyond 2 percent. In the 1960's, this
economy was growing at the rate of about 5 percent a year. In the
1970's, we were growing at the rate of about 4 percent a year. In
the 1980's, we were growing appreciably faster tnan we are at the
present time.
Nevertheless, the attitude of the Fed seems to be that anything
beyond a 2 percent rate of growth, and any unemployment—it used
to be 6 percent. Now I guess you have accepted 5.5 percent. Any
unemployment level that goes lower than that is going to produce
inflation.
Now when you add to that some of the things that you have said
recently in your admonitions, apparently to Wall Street, with regard to their stock market, talking about the kind of exuberance,
or excess exuberance that exists in the market, people are very
fearful that when the Federal Open Market Committee meets later
this month on the 25th of March that you will be advocating before
that committee and that the Federal Reserve will in fact raise interest rates above the level where they are presently. We are fearful of that because we believe that if that happens, that will have
the consequence of reducing economic growth even further.
It may be that you are justified in being concerned about some
of the aspects of Wall Street and the rise in prices on the stock
market and the fact that the market has gone up above 7,000, although it has settled back a little bit below that now. I do not want
to argue that with you. You may be justified in that. You may not
be.
I would argue with you, sir, though that if you advocate raising
interest rates to deal with that phenomenon, if it is a problem, that
the use of raised interest rates to deal with that situation is a
blunt instrument which will have broad-ranging consequences
throughout the economy, far beyond Wall Street and on every Main
Street all across this country.
People, as you note in your testimony, are struggling to make a
living. Every American family is struggling in one way or another,
with this low economic growth that we have been experiencing. You
note stagnant wages. I would say to you that those stagnant wages
are a consequence of long-term economic policies that have existed
for a long-term, one of them being the trade legislation that we are
living with currently.
The other is a situation that has to do with the oversupply globally of both production and labor at the moment, and the fact that
American workers are forced increasingly to compete with labor in
other parts of the world because of the multinational corporations,
transnational corporations. These are the problems that we are
deeply concerned about.
So I would urge you, sir, to perhaps continue to be concerned
about the stock market. But do not attempt to use the blunt instrument of interest rates to deal with any perceived problems in the




11
stock market because that act will have broad-ranging consequences far beyond Wall Street on every Main Street across the
country.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Hinchey.
Let me go next to Mr. Jackson, who gets a gold star. He has been
in his seat since 2:00. Then if Mr. Bentsen wishes to make a statement, we will come back to him.
Mr. JACKSON. Thank you, Chairman Castle, Ranking Member
Flake. I would first like to express how pleased I am to have the
opportunity to join the Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy for my first hearing with this subcommittee. I have just oeen recently, Mr. Greenspan, granted the honor
of serving on this distinguished panel. I very much look forward to
learning from your leadership, Chairman Castle, and Mr. Flake,
and working with you during this Congress as we address the critical matters which fall in the purview of this subcommittee's
jurisdiction.
There is no better illustration of the significance of this subcommittee's role than the subject matter of the present hearing and
the distinguished witness who is before us to testify today. Chairman Greenspan, it is with great pleasure and admiration that I
welcome you here today to apprise us of the status of the American
economy and your judgments as to the activities of the Federal Reserve System in fulfilling its duty, among others, of conducting
monetary policy in pursuit of the objectives of price stability ana
full employment.
To that end, Mr. Chairman, in your semi-annual report to Congress, first delivered to the Senate last week, you clearly hailed the
strength of the economy, highlighting a 2 percent increase in gross
domestic product as evidence of expanding economic opportunities.
Relative to previous decades, however, we know that 2 percent is
less than the 1980's, 1970's, and the 1960's. You tempered your optimism however with a call for caution when you stated that history is strewn with visions of new eras that in the end have proven
to be a mirage.
I agree completely with your assessment, and today while conventional economic wisdom speaks to expansion and growth, my
view deviates just slightly from this conclusion. For the Second District of Illinois, I have devised a vigorous and a stringent economic
test. I call it the eyeball test. In order to assess the relevant economic indicators, I merely open my eyes and look around to determine whether my constituents on the south side of Chicago and in
the south suburbs are experiencing this relative economic growth.
Sadly, Mr. Chairman, my results do not render the same optimistic
projections. In my district, things have never been good and they
are now getting worse.
Nationally, the unemployment rate is 5.4 percent, which means
that 7.3-million people who receive unemployment compensation
have no job. The actual number of unemployed and underemployed
people is closer to 15- to 20-million Americans. These numbers include those who are unemployed, underemployed, working parttime when they want to be working full-time, they have never had
a job or they have given up looking for one. These numbers are
compounded by those who are faced by corporate and Government




12

downsizing, are on the brink of or worried about the reality that
they may fall into one of these categories.
Mr. Chairman, I believe that those in my district and these particular explanations explain the widespread levels of economic anxiety currently plaguing the American people. In light of the foregoing, Chairman Greenspan, I will listening intently to your testimony, particularly your views on how the Fed can encourage and
guide the economy toward attaining true levels of full employment.
I have been most concerned, Mr. Chairman, most recently with the
reality that whenever unemployment dips beneath a certain percentage point, the Federal Reserve turns off the spigot. It shuts
opportunity down and slows down job growth and creation.
In light of the reality that we most recently passed a welfare reform bill in this Congress, I am very concerned that we could slow
the economy down at a time when our Nation's most-vulnerable
can no longer turn to the Government for assistance.
Once again, thank you, Mr. Greenspan, for joining us today and
I look forward to hearing your testimony.
Thank you, Chairman Castle.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Jesse L. Jackson Jr. can be
found on page 55 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much, Mr. Jackson.
We will now call on Mr. Bentsen.
Mr. BENTSEN. No statement, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Mr. Bentsen has no opening statement. I
think that concludes our opening statements at last, Mr. Chairman. We turn to you now for your statement, sir. We appreciate
your patience.
STATEMENT OF HON. ALAN GREENSPAN,
CHAIRMAN, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I want to
say, I certainly appreciate the opportunity, as always, to appear before this subcommittee to present the Federal Reserve's
Semiannual Report on Monetary Policy.
The performance of the American economy over the past year has
been quite favorable. The growth of real gross domestic product
picked up to more than 3 percent over the four quarters of 1996,
as the economy progressed through its 6th year of expansion. Employers added more than 2.5-miflion workers to their payrolls in
1996, and the unemployment rate fell further. Nominal wages and
salaries have increased faster than prices, meaning workers have
gained ground in real terms, reflecting the benefits of rising productivity. Outside the food and energy sectors, increases in
consumer prices actually have continued to edge lower, with core
CPI inflation only 2.5 percent over the past 12 months.
Looking ahead, the members of the FOMC expect inflation to remain low and the economy to grow appreciably further. However,
as I shall be discussing, tne unusually good inflation performance
of recent years seems to owe in large part to some temporary factors of uncertain longevity. Thus, the FOMC continues to see the
distribution of inflation risks skewed to the upside, and must remain especially alert to the possible emergence of imbalances in financial and product markets that ultimately could endanger the




13

maintenance of the low-inflation environment. Sustainable
economic expansion for 1997 and beyond depends on it.
For some, the benign inflation outcome of 1996 might be considered surprising, as resource utilization rates, particularly of labor,
were in the neighborhood of those that historically have been associated with building inflation pressures. To be sure, an acceleration
in nominal labor compensation, especially its wage component, became evident over the past year. But the rate of pay increase still
was markedly less than historical relationships with labor market
conditions would have predicted.
Atypical restraint on compensation increases has been evident
for a few years now and appears to be mainly the consequence of
greater worker insecurity, possibly owing to the rapid evolution of
technologies in use in the workplace. Technological change almost
surely has been an important impetus behind corporate restructuring and downsizing. Also, it contributes to the concern of workers
that their job skills may become inadequate.
Certainly, other factors have contributed to the softness in compensation growth in the past few years. The sharp deceleration in
health care costs, of course, is cited frequently. Another is the
heightened pressure on firms and their workers in industries that
compete internationally. Domestic deregulation has had similar effects on the intensity of competitive forces in some industries. In
any event, although I dp not doubt that all of these factors are relevant, I would be surprised if they were nearly as important as job
insecurity.
If heightened job insecurity is the most significant explanation of
the break with the past in recent years, then it is important to recognize that suppressed wage cost growth as a consequence ofiob
insecurity can be carried only so far. At some point, the tradeoff of
subdued wage growth for job security has to come to an end. In
other words, the relatively modest wage gains we have experienced
are a temporary rather than a lasting phenomenon. The unknown
is when this transition period will encL
Indeed, some recent evidence suggests that the labor markets
bear especially careful watching for signs that the return to more
normal patterns may be in process. The Bureau of Labor Statistics
reports that people were somewhat more willing to quit their jobs
to seek other employment in January than previously. The possibility that this reflects greater confidence by workers accords with a
recent further rise in the percent of households responding to a
Conference Board survey who perceive that job availability is plentiful. Wages rose faster in 1996 than in 1995 by most measures,
perhaps also raising questions about whether the transitional
period of unusually slow wage gains may be drawing to a close.
To be sure, the pickup in wage gains has not shown through in
underlying price inflation. Increases in the core CPI, as well as in
broader measures of prices, have stayed subdued or even edged off
further in recent months. As best we can judge, faster productivity
growth last year meant that rising compensation gains did not
cause labor costs per unit of output to increase any more rapidly.
Non-labor costs, which are roughly a quarter of total consolidated
costs of the non-financial corporate sector, were little changed in
1996.




14

Owing in part to this subdued behavior of unit costs, profits and
rates of return on capital have risen to high levels. As a consequence, businesses believe that, were they to raise prices to boost
profits further, competitors with already ample profit margins
would not follow suit. Instead, they would use the occasion to capture a greater market share. This interplay is doubtless a significant factor in the evident loss of pricing power in American
business.
Intensifying global competition also may be further restraining
domestic firms' ability to hike prices as well as wages. Clearly, the
appreciation of the dollar on balance over the past 18 months or
so, together with low inflation in many of our trading partners, has
resulted in a marked decline in non-oil import prices that has
helped to damp domestic inflation pressures. Yet it is important to
emphasize that these influences, too, would be holding down inflation only temporarily. They represent a transition to a lower price
level than would otherwise prevail, not to a permanently lower rate
of inflation, as distinct from levels.
Against the background of all of these considerations, the FOMC
has recognized the need to remain vigilant for signs of potentially
inflationary imbalances that might, if not corrected promptly, undermine our economic expansion. The FOMC in fact has signaled
a state of heightened alert for possible policy tightening since last
July in its policy directives. But, we have also taken care not to act
prematurely. The FOMC refrained from changing policy last
summer. In the event, inflation has remained quiescent since then.
Given the lags with which monetary policy affects the economy,
however, we cannot rule out a situation in which a preemptive policy tightening may become appropriate before any sign of actual
higher inflation becomes evident. If the FOMC were to implement
such an action, it would be judging that the risks to the economic
expansion of waiting longer had increased unduly and had begun
to outweigh the advantages of waiting for uncertainties to be reduced by the accumulation of more information about economic
trends.
I wish it were possible, Mr. Chairman, to lay out in advance exactly what conditions have to prevail to portend a buildup of inflation pressures or inflationary psychology. However, the circumstances that have been associated with increasing inflation in
the past have not followed a single pattern.
In general, our analysis will need to encompass all potentially
relevant information, from financial markets as well as the economy, especially when some signals, like those in the labor market,
have not been following their established patterns.
This year overall inflation is anticipated to stay restrained. The
central tendency of the forecasts made by the Board members and
Reserve Bank presidents has the increase in the total CPI slipping
back into a range of 2.75 to 3 percent over the four quarters of the
year.
The unemployment rate, according to Board members and bank
presidents, should stay around 5.25 to 5.5 percent through the
fourth quarter, consistent with their projections of measured real
GDP growth of 2 to 2.25 percent over the four quarters of the year.




15

The Federal Reserve will be endeavoring to help extend the current period of sustained growth. Participants in financial markets
seem to believe that in the current benign environment the FOMC
will succeed indefinitely. There is no evidence, however, that the
business cycle has been repealed. Another recession will doubtless
occur some day owing to circumstances that could not be, or at
least were not, perceived by policymakers and financial market
participants alike.
History demonstrates that participants in financial markets are
susceptible to waves of optimism, which can in turn foster a general process of asset-price inflation that can feed through into markets for goods and services. When unwarranted expectations ultimately are not realized, the unwinding of these financial excesses
can act to amplify a downturn in economic activity, much as they
can amplify the upswing. As you know, last December I put the
question this way: "How do we know when irrational exuberance
has unduly escalated asset values, which then become subject to
unexpected and prolonged contractions?"
We have not been able, as yet, to provide a satisfying answer to
this question, but there are reasons in the current environment to
keep this question on the table. Clearly, when people are exposed
to long periods of relative economic tranquility, they seem inevitably prone to complacency about the future. This is understandable.
We have had 15 years of economic expansion interrupted by only
one recession, and that was 6 years ago. As the memory of such
past events fades, it naturally seems ever less sensible to keep up
one's guard against an adverse event in the future. Thus, it should
come as no surprise that, after such a long period of balanced expansion, risk premiums for advancing funds to businesses in
virtually all financial markets have declined to near record lows.
Is it possible that there is something fundamentally new about
this current period that would warrant such complacency? Yes, it
is possible. Markets may have become more efficient, competition
is more global, and information technology has doubtless enhanced
the Stability of business operations. But, regrettably, as has been
commented, history is strewn with visions of such new eras that in
the end have proven to be a mirage. In short, history counsels
caution.
Such caution seems especially warranted with regard to the
sharp rise in equity prices during the past 2 years. These gains
have obviously raised questions of sustainability. Caution also
seems warranted by the narrow yield spreads that suggest perceptions of low risk, possibly unrealistically low risk, not just in the
stock market but throughout the financial system.
Why should the central bank be concerned about the possibility
that financial markets may be overestimating returns or mispricing
risk? It is not that we have a firm view that equity prices are necessarily excessive right now or risk spreads patently too low. Our
goal is to contribute as best we can to the highest possible growth
of income and wealth over time, and we would be pleased if the favorable economic environment projected in markets actually comes
to pass. Rather, the FOMC has to be sensitive to indications of
even slowly building imbalances, whatever their source, that, by




16

fostering the emergence of inflation pressures, would ultimately
threaten healthy economic expansion.
Mr. Chairman, I will conclude on the same upbeat note about the
U.S. economy with which I began. Although a central banker's occupational responsibility is to stay on the lookout for trouble, even
I must admit that our economic prospects in general are quite favorable. The flexibility of our market system and the vibrancy of
our private sector remain examples for the whole world to emulate.
The Federal Reserve will endeavor to do its part by continuing to
foster a monetary framework under which our citizens can prosper
to the fullest possible extent.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am available for questions.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Greenspan can be found on page
63 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. May I ask, incidentally, that the full testimony
be included for the record?
Chairman CASTLE. Without objection, it will be included in the
record and we do appreciate that, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. We appreciate your testimony and we appreciate your commitment to being here for this process. As you know,
we now enter into a period in which we each have 5 minutes in
which to ask you questions and get your answers in, which is always a little bit difficult for each Member, so we will try to go as
efficiently as we can. I will take the Chairman's prerogative and
start the process.
You said yesterday that there was 100 percent probability that
the CPI overstates inflation. As I understand it, you have proposed
a two-track approach toward improving the accuracy of the CPI by
urging the Bureau of Labor Statistics to accelerate its efforts to
correct some errors in the creation of a rotating expert advisory
committee that would periodically select the inflation adjustment
factor that in its judgment best represents the modification of the
CPI rise needed to measure the increase in the cost-of-liying. Is
this correct? Did I state it correctly, and how do you envision this
two-pronged approach would work in practice?
Finally, is it your feeling, based on what you know, read, have
seen, discussions with the White House, that the time has come
that this or some similar mechanism may be put into place at some
time in the near future? I know that is conjecture and you may not
wish to, but I wanted to ask you the question.
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, I cannot answer that, largely because I
really do not know. You probably have more insight in that than
Chairman CASTLE. I doubt that, but it is- kind of you to sav so.
Mr. GREENSPAN. The issue is clearly on the table. It is rairly
clear that Senator Moynihan has considered it a very high priority
over in the Senate. Let me, if I might, address the questions that
your other colleagues on your right have been raising with respect
to this issue as I respond to your question.
There has been an extraordinary amount of analysis of the
Consumer Price Index which the BLS stipulates, and I think quite
correctly, is not a cost-of-living index. It was the intent of the




17

Congress, as best I can judge, in 1972 to endeavor to insulate Social Security recipients from increases in the cost-of-living and in,
I believe it was 1980, to insulate taxpayers similarly from bracket
creep as a consequence of cost-of-living increases. In both instances,
there was a general view that what was involved was adjustment
for the cost-oi-living increases only.
I fully recognize that in removing the bias from the CPI—and indeed the evidence in my judgment is just overwhelming, and I can
go into it in detail, that that is in fact the case—if the Congress
decides that it wants to do more than the cost-of-living, then I
think it is perfectly appropriate as a third track to bring forward
legislation to increase the real benefits. I think it is inappropriate
for the Government of the United States to be using an index as
a proxy for the cost-of-living, which clearly does not reflect cost-ofliving.
I regret that this issue is in the context of the budget, and it does
have significant momentum because of the budget issue. But my
main concern is that the index is a very crucial statistic for policy
purposes and a lot of other purposes, and I think to improve it in
a significant manner would be very useful to this country.
What I had in mind is that there are a number of technical adjustments which the BLS can implement, and indeed, are in the
process of doing so. They are moving forward at a fairly pronounced clip at this stage. As I understand it, the Administration
has put additional funds for the BLS in this year's budget.
Nonetheless, as hard as they may endeavor to move, there are
certain things that are going to take quite a number of years to adjust, and I am referring mainly to the biases very obviously in the
quality area of the statistics and in so-called new products. That
is, the statistics are not picking up the very dramatic improvements in quality in a number of major areas.
I suggested, in line with the Boskin Commission and in earlier
comments that I made with respect to this issue a couple of years
ago, that there be a second track in which an additional adjustment would be made on the basis of the evaluation of professionals
in this area, appointed by the President and confirmed by the Senate, to make judgments on the basis of what studies have been
made about what the remaining bias is. And say every October,
that commission would meet to define in its judgment what the appropriate estimate should be. In my belief, Mr. Chairman, that
would address this issue in the most reasonable way.
As I indicated before, should the Congress decide that there are
many recipients who would be unduly affected by correcting what
is an incorrect measure, then I think a third track would be
perfectly appropriate to address those issues.
I might say with respect to the question of changing the cost-ofliving index to reflect the expenditures of the population over age
65, the BLS does have an index of that nature at this stage. The
spread incidentally is less than .4. Last year it was only .1. But it
is true, Mr. Kanjorski, the index is somewhat higher. And if the
Congress chooses to make that sort of adjustment, I think that is
a perfectly appropriate thing for you to be examining.
Chairman LEACH, [presiding]. Thank you, Chairman.
Mr. Flake.




18

Mr. FLAKE. Thank you very much.
Mr. Chairman, going back to my statement and the concerns that
I raised earlier, I would like to just ask, as you consider where the
Nation is going now, I think most of us agree that you have to
make changes in welfare. That is not a big issue.
The question becomes, as you talk about moving toward
workfare, and the people who are most affected are living in certain communities where there has been devastation and deterioration to the degree that it is impossible to attract industry. It is impossible in many instances even to attract the small sector jobs
from franchisors. It is impossible to get banks to see these communities as necessary places for making investment. Corporate entities really do not even look at them as a potential place for
opportunities for building businesses.
Yet, those same corporate entities will go abroad where the environment is much worse than it is in many of these urban and poor
rural communities, will make the investments, will take the risk,
and in many instances take a loss. I would just like to know if
within the scope of your analysis, has there been or will there be
some means of looking at what might be done over the next 5 years
or so in trying to determine what kind of industries can go into
these communities, and how we might be able to assure that the
same corporations that look abroad in these Third World countries
will look at these communities as places of opportunity?
Is that something that you think you can influence? If so, what
kind of direction would you suggest we might go in trying to assure
that it happens?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Flake, you are raising one of the most difficult but important problems that this country has. I know our colleague Jack Kemp has addressed this with his enterprise zones in
an endeavor to find a means to go in there to enhance economic
development. We have so far made very little progress in the area
of our knowledge of how to induce companies to go into areas to
expand plants and to gain profitable opportunities. I have been
dealing with this issue for many, many years and I must tell you,
I feel very frustrated by the terribly small amount of results that
have been achieved.
Monetary policy itself cannot do anything. We only have one sinle instrument and that can only affect the economy as a whole,
ut I do think all of us who are involved in trying to observe what
the various forces engendering growth in this economy are doing
are also trying to understand better what is causing the locational
differences among various areas and see whether we can alter
them. There has probably been some progress, but I would suspect
that you would argue, and with some reason, that the results have
been far inferior to what you would like to see happen.
Mr. FLAKE. I think on the question from a monetary side, obviously corporations do not see these as the fertile fields of opportunity that I would see. I think on the other side though, the level
of your influence as primary spokesperson as it relates to the monetary policy of this Nation can probably influence in a much more
positive and meaningful way. We created a way abroad with
NAFTA, and we create other means through taxing capability, or
changing tax law.

f




19

It would seem to me to suggest that if we indeed want a Nation
that is strong enough to be able to absorb these individuals without
having to make the kind of expenditures, capital expenditures for
what is a growing industry, which is the penal system, that somehow the transference of even those dollars would make a major difference and a major impact in helping to solve problems, not only
unemployment problems, but clearly, I think give an advantage to
many of those corporations who were looking for a marketplace
where there is a labor base, but a labor base that has nowhere to
work.
So that long-term, I think it represents a drain on the Nation.
If you have all of those persons unemployed in jail, either way, the
long-term benefits are not in the best interest of developing
positive kind of monetary policy for the Nation.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I must say I agree with you, Mr. Flake.
Mr. FLAKE. And that is it?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I agree that we all should be endeavoring to do
something. We, as you know, have been trying through the Community Reinvestment Act indirectly to come at this issue. It does
not, as you know, work directly because it only refers to lending,
and to a very large extent to mortgage lending. But there has been
some general awareness, growing awareness, that there are foregone loan opportunities, profitable loan opportunities, in small
business in a number of our urban communities which are not
being exploited.
I tnink that the one thing we can do is to try to find the ways
in which that can be expanded. Because it is true, if you bring a
large corporation in, that helps a lot. If you cannot bring a large
corporation in, at least have a lot of small ones because they can
grow. They may, in fact, be a better investment than the larger
ones.
Mr. FLAKE. Thank you, sir.
Yield back, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE, [presiding]. Thank you, Mr. Flake.
Mr. Chairman, I apologize for departing in the middle of your answering my question. My mother would not have been happy about
that, but I am on the Education and Workplace Committee which
is 179 running steps away, and if I get a phone call I can go vote
in our markup over there. So that is why I had to go. It may
happen again.
Mr. FRANK. If the gentleman would yield?
Chairman CASTLE. I yield.
Mr. FRANK. If you guys would reinstate proxies, you would not
have to run around like a nut.
[Laughter.]
Chairman CASTLE. If you think I have enough influence to reinstate or not reinstate proxies, you are wrong. You are sadly
mistaken.
Chairman Leach.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
As I listened to several of the comments in the opening statements, I must say I think as Chairman of the Federal Reserve you
see a distinction between this body and the other body. We are the
people's House. We have a little bit broader perspectives sometimes




20

than the other body. We are represented by socialists, libertarians,
Republicans, Democrats, and combinations of those.
I consider myself a little bit toward the center right in American
politics, but I must say that not infrequently those at the outer
edges describe problems better than the rest of us. When Congress'
only socialist defined the problem of income inequality, I think he
was speaking very profoundly about an American issue.
As I am sitting here thinking of the problems of wage stagnation,
which may or may not be now on the move a bit, I am wondering
if as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board you would care to
comment on what I consider to be an ethical umbrage in corporate
governance. This whole precept that not only do we have wage
stagnation at certain levels, but we also have incredible compensation escalation at other levels. The notion in the last month that
a head of a given company received a $771-million compensation
package describes to me a problem in our system. I am wondering,
as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board if this is an issue that
you would wish to jawbone on?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, but I must say that when I was in the private sector, when I actually had some capability as a member of
a number of boards, I argued that stock options should not be
priced directly but priced as a ratio to the overall stock price level.
If one is doing something in corporate governance which is competitively superior to everyone else, one should be rewarded. But one
should not be rewarded if the stock market overall goes up, which
drags up all prices irrespective of whether a company is doing well
or not well.
I would suggest to you that if that type of view had prevailed—
which it clearly has not—many of these outsized compensation
packages which you are looking at would not at this stage exist.
Mr. LEACH. I appreciate your decision not to totally bite on that
bone. Turning a little bit differently, in a historical sense, in Humhrey-Hawkins hearings the Chairman of the Federal Reserve
oard speaks to levels of interest rates, levels of unemployment,
now increasingly, levels of the Dow Jones Industrial Average.
Would you care to comment, and perhaps with the historical perspective of, for example, the 1987 downturn and the role of the
Federal Reserve Board in terms of being a liquidity-supplying institution, of the rationale for commenting on the market itself? How
appropriate or inappropriate is that?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It has become ever clearer in recent years that
as the economy has become more complex, internationalized, and
as balance sheets, both household and corporate have increasingly
become factors in the economic outlook, and in the production of
goods and services, we have had to broaden our view of the particular range of issues which we cover in the context of developing
monetary policy.
It is probably inevitable as our standards of living overall rise
that the assets that individuals have become an increasing part of
their decisions to spend or not spend. Therefore, because of that
fact, and because of the lag that monetary policy invariably has
with respect to the economy, we have to forecast what we think is
developing in the economy. Were we not to be looking at balance
sheets and asset spillovers as I like to call it, I do not think we

g




21

would be getting a full, comprehensive understanding of what the
forces driving the economy are.
I decided that we cannot be making changes up or down in the
Federal funds rate without a fairly extensive explanation to the
Congress and the American people of what the factors are we that
are looking at. Years ago, we looked mainly at the money supply
in a fairly restricted range and we communicated that as best we
could. As a consequence of that, it was pretty easy to communicate
why we were moving policy one way or the other.
Since the money supply has grown in recent years in a manner
which has been inconsistent with economic events, and only recently has seemed to get closer to its historical norm, we have been
forced to broaden the whole area of indicators to make judgments
as to how the economy functions. We therefore concluded that it
was necessary for us to express the fact that we were doing that,
and to evaluate various changes in balance sheets and markets in
much the same way we do home building, personal consumption
expenditures, consumer debt, and export markets.
I recognized that as soon as we raised the issue in my speech
back in December about the nature of the stock market that it
would probably have some effect. I, however, did not speculate as
to which direction I thought the market was going. I was merely
raising a broad question. Today, in my prepared remarks you will
find that I take a look at the various factors affecting the stock
market and conclude that if profit margins continue to rise as analysts on Wall Street expect them to, tnen the market is properly
priced, as best we can judge on the basis of the level of interest
rates.
If, however, profit margins, which are quite high but below
where they were in the 1960's, fail to rise further, then the market
will run into some difficulty. I think in the process of evaluating
that, we do not know what is likely to happen. Is it possible for
margins to rise further? It certainly is. At this rate of inflation
back in the 1960's, margins were indeed higher from where thev
are now. So that despite the fact that they have come up a considerable ways since 1991, they could very well continue further as
analysts expect them to.
Our basic judgment is that we need to look at all of these various
things, and we nave to communicate our views to the Congress if
we are going to give you an essential view of the types or things
we are going to look at.
The one thing I was not endeavoring to do, because I do not
think it is possible to do, was to jawbone the stock market. Stock
markets in this world, especially in the United States, are extremely sophisticated, complex, very liquid markets with millions
of investors. You cannot talk those markets up or down. Anyone
who thinks they can has just not looked at the evidence.
What we will inevitably be required to do as the years go on, and
as this economy becomes increasingly more complex, and especially
as an ever-increasing proportion of American households own all
sorts of assets, is evaluate how they will respond to price changes,
whether it is in real estate, whether it is in residences, whether it
is in any of a variety of other things which appear on the balance
sheets.




22

What I was endeavoring to do, and I have hopefully effectively
tried to communicate today and to your Senate colleagues last
week, is to say that is what has evolved as a natural consequence
of the increased complexity of the economic system with which we
are dealing. It is not any longer, if it ever was, a simple thing with
which to deal. And we use a number of different techniques for
evaluating where we are with respect to what our fundamental objective is; namely, we believe that our goal is maximum sustainable
economic growth. But that, in our judgment, requires low inflation,
or more appropriately, stable prices.
Our evaluation of that process, whether we look at the supply
and demand forces which are driving the economy, or direct measures of inflationary expectations such as the gold price or money
supply, if it ever gets back into place, and the newly issued index
bonds, these are all elements involved in how we endeavor to determine what is going on, as best we can, and to make a judgment
as to what as a consequence is the most appropriate policy stance.
So it is not a stock market issue we are involved with, and to
answer Congressman Hinchey, who has left, specifically, we do not
view monetary policy as a tool to—I do not know how he put it—
prick the stock market bubble, or something like that. What we do
is look at a wide variety of things, income and consumption, assets
and liabilities, combining them all to make judgments as to what
it is that one should be doing with respect to our policy stance.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Chairman Leach.
Mr. Frank.
Mr. FRANK. Mr. Chairman, I take you at your word that you
were not trying to jawbone the stock market. But when you say
that it is impossible, looking at what happened, I guess I am not
sure whether I am supposed to believe you or my own eyes, to
quote Marx. But let me get on to a couple—let me just ask you
Mr. GREENSPAN. Can I just answer very quickly?
Mr. FRANK. Yes. The stock market does not seem to know that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I ask the Chairman to put this on my time, not
his.
Mr. FRANK. I thank you.
Mr. GREENSPAN. There is a lot of volatility in the market, and
markets will move on rumors. They will move on statements by
myself or my colleagues. But what you cannot do is affect the underlying forces. You can do it on a day-by-day basis. If you try to
do it more than that, you will fail.
Mr. FRANK. That I would accept.
I was also pleased to actually hear your articulation that your
concern on the CPI is with its role as a measure for use in the
economy. By the way, I note parenthetically, because you refer for
instance to the generally steady performance of the CPI and no
great increases, in fact I gather the news is even better than the
number might look. Because to the extent that the CPI overstates
inflation, that means there has been even less inflation in the economy than that low number shows, and that is an encouraging sign.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct. But it has been that way for a
very long time.




23

Mr. FRANK. I understand. But people do not often talk about that
side of it as much as they talk about the other. But I also take it,
what you are saying then is that you express no opinion then on
whether or not we should be reducing the cost-of-living adjustment,
or whatever adjustment we give—let us forget cost-of-living. You
are not expressing any opinion that we are overcompensating
Social Security recipients as a matter of policy.
If we were to decide that low-income recipients should be treated
separately and that the CPI calculation should be separate, that is
not a problem for you?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Correct.
Mr. FRANK. Thank you, because I think that helps remove some
of what people have been arguing as a driver of Social Security. As
a statistical, that is a separate issue.
Two other points. One, you conclude by saying you are going to
conclude on an upbeat note. It is partly professional and partly the
style that you think appropriate, but you upbeat is most peoples'
depressed, you realize.
[Laughter.]
Mr. GREENSPAN. I fully understand that.
Mr. FRANK. What you say is, in your upbeat phase, Mr. Greenspan, you say, even I must admit that our economic prospects are
quite favorable. This is not what most of us would consider to be
the source of an admission.
What I am concerned about is this, it does seem to me over the
years that you have been somewhat pleasantly surprised by the
fact that we have had as steady a growth and as great a reduction
in unemployment as we have had with so little inflation. Am I correct in inferring that you have been somewhat pleasantly surprised; that your expectations were somewhat more pessimistic
over the past say 4- or 5-years?
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct, Congressman.
Mr. FRANK. I think that is a fact. Because I think what some of
us are worried about when you talk about preemptive strikes is,
that you might be a little bit too preemptive because there has
been this historic mis-estimate. A lot of people missed it, and you
did as well as anyone could. But that is part of our problem, where
you have a history of a little bit more pessimism than turned out.
We just hope that that correction gets factored in.
I do want to talk specifically then about the question I asked you
before. I recall when I was on the Budget Committee I think it
was, asking you your view of the effect of the tax increases of 1993,
and you did say to me in either late 1994 or 1995, you believed
they would have a negative effect on the economy but it was too
early for that to happen. They are now over 3 years.
I guess the question is, do you still believe that the tax increases
of 1993 had a negative effect on growth? Then the second part of
the question is, if they did and growth would have been even higher, would that not have simply meant you would have been more
restrictive?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me put it this way. It is certainly the case,
as you point out quite correctly, that the economy is doing exceptionally well from our point of view. It is almost certainly the case




24

that there is no direct evidence that you can see at this stage that
capital investment or other things have slowed down.
Nonetheless, it is very hard for me to believe that when you increase marginal tax rates it has no effect. But there are so many
other things going on in the economy that it is hard to disentangle
them. So all I can say to you is that the hypothesis that it has had
a demonstrable negative effect is not capable of being proved.

Mr. FRANK. That is a very comfortable
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is as much as I can say.

Mr. FRANK. We just voted on that. That could be the llth Commandment. It is OK to invoke faith, because that is all we voted
on this week was religion, and we were in favor of it by two-thirds.
But I do think it was relevant to note that this is not an assertion
that you believe provable.
But I do have to say the second part, to the second extent that
your ideological view, your view was correct that the tax increases
of 1993 did slow the economy down, is it not the case that had that
not happened you would have then been more restrictive?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Not necessarily. It is hard to know what would
have happened in the context of inflation, because it is not growth,
per se, that we respond to. It is evidences of imbalances, inflationary imbalances which upend the economy. But it is not growth,
per se.
Mr. FRANK. I appreciate that. If I can just have my last 30 seconds. That I am particularly glad to hear, because what you are
saying, and I am pleased to hear this is, that the fact that unemployment could drop further and growth would continue, in and of
itself is no reason for people to get nervous or to make preemptive,
absent some specific—I think that is something that you reassure
me when you say that. Because there has been this view that your
position might be that too much good news, even absent specific indications of imbalances, might lead to that preemptive strike.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I want you to understand that a very substantial part of the academic community does believe that. I am very
skeptical about that relationship myself.
Mr. FRANK. That growth necessarily leads to that.

Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Frank.

Mr. Lucas.
Mr. LUCAS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, I certainly want to reiterate, in a sense,
the words of our Committee Chairman, Mr. Leach, when he described the differences of economic philosophy on this subcommittee. We are certainly very diverse in our views. Could you reassure
me for just a moment, after listening to a number of my distinguished colleagues that I respect intensely about the nature of
these things. I sometimes get the feel that there are those who
have the goals of maybe affecting how we allocate the income and
resources in this country.
On page 15 of your testimony you state that the goal is the highest possible growth of income and wealth over time. Just reassure
me a little bit that that is indeed the goal of the Fed.
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is. Indeed, you have to remember that prices,
employment and the like, are all intermediary goals. The ultimate




25

goal has got to be the physical well-being of the American people,
meaning maximum sustainable economic growth. The financial relationships are only important as they contribute to those goals.
We function in the financial market and therefore must deal with
them. But we deal with them in the context, as we see the relationships over the years develop, which in our judgment contributes to
maximum growth.
Mr. LUCAS. So as we would say in Oklahoma, our goal is to make
the economic pie of this country larger?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes.
Mr. LUCAS. Thank you. One other question I have and an issue
close to my own heart. I am a proponent of either eliminating, or
at the very least, providing substantial decreases in the capital
gains tax rate. It is my view that such action would encourage a
more productive use of our investment resources. Could you elaborate whatever point of view you might have on that subject for a
moment?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I have always argued, since I came out of graduate school I guess, that the capital gains tax is an inappropriate
tax for purposes of raising revenue. All taxes suppress economic
growth one way or another. This, because it focuses very directly
on entrepreneurial activity, in my judgment, has the most restrained effect on economic growth. If you are going to raise revenue, I think it is far better to do it with a different form of
taxation.
Mr. LUCAS. I share that view completely. On that note, thank
you, Mr. Greenspan.
Mr. Chairman, I yield back my time.
Chairman LEACH, [presiding]. Thank you.
Mr. Kennedy.
Mr. KENNEDY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Chairman, I want to go back to the issues that I tried to
bring up in my opening statement, which were your quote on this
issue of wage stagnation where you explain why the suppressed
wages have been caused by worker anxiety about job security. But
then you seem to conclude that there will be an end to that, because there is a limit to the value of additional job security people
are willing to acquire in exchange for lesser increases in standards
of living.
I wonder what your thoughts are on the idea that in 1974, as I
understand it, statistically, the typical CEO earned 34 times the
pay of the lowest worker. Today, that has risen to about 173 times.
It just seems to me that there is perverse equality going on
where we end up seeing the stock market having these huge runups for companies that lay off more and more workers, sending a
very strange message to the American worker in general. As a result of those stock run-ups, we see the salaries of the top CEOs
skyrocketing, and there does not seem to be anywhere near a
comparable rise in wages.
I wonder if you might just comment on the phenomenon, and
whether or not you feel that you could in fact take a more aggressive role in this phenomenon of these huge corporate wages versus
the average wage to the average worker?




26

Mr. GREENSPAN. First of all, let me just say that there are two
reasons of which I am aware which are engendering this type of
opening up of the gap. One is the stock option issue and the way
that is paid is tied to the stock market. The stock market goes up
for everybody. In other words, the underlying key evaluation process affects all individual stocks. Once the average has been set in
that regard, then differences between companies emerge largely as
a result of differences in overall outlooks.
Were you here when I was mentioning to Chairman Leach about
the stocK option question?
Mr. KENNEDY. No, I do not think I was.
Mr. GREENSPAN. What I was mentioning is that when I was in
the private sector I was a very strong advocate of tying stock options not to the price of a stock, but to the ratio of the price of a
stock to some overall price index, so that the general change in
stock prices does not accrue to the benefit of individuals who really
had nothing to do with it.
Second, however, there has been, as we know and discussed over
the years, a significant opening up of income spreads, largely as a
function of technology and of education with the increased premium of college education over high school, and high school over
high school dropouts becoming stronger. That whole spread goes
right through the basic system. It is a development which I feel uncomfortable with. There is nothing monetary policy can do to address that, and it is outside the scope, as far as I am concerned,
of the issues with which we deal.
Mr. KENNEDY. But, Mr. Chairman, excuse me. I think the problem with that is that somebody else could make the same argument about your statements about the stock market.
Mr. GREENSPAN. They have and I think they are wrong. And I
think they are wrong because I think that is part of the bailiwick
of the overall financial system and affects what it is we do.
Mr. KENNEDY. But do you now think that the idea that we are
having a greater and greater disparity between the incomes of
working families and the poor as well as the very, very rich—do
you not think ultimately that this will have an effect on the
economy of this country?
Mr. GREENSPAN. The answer is yes, in the very broadest sense
that all things have an effect. But that is very indirectly related
to our particular portfolio. It is there only to the extent that as private citizens we obviously are concerned about the status of our society, and I am concerned when I see very significant changes in
income distribution. I cannot demonstrate to you that it has a significant effect on the way in which we implement monetary policy.
If I saw that way, then I would say I would have to agree with you.
There would have to be some way we could address it, if we could
figure out what we could do to change it.
Mr. KENNEDY. I would have some ideas on that.
Mr. Chairman, if I could just ask one very brief question that
would require a one-word answer.
Is there an unemployment rate number at which the unemployment rate falls to where you automatically feel interest rates nave
to rise?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No.




27

Mr. KENNEDY. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Kennedy.
Mr. Metcalf.
Mr. METCALF. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have three questions
so I will hurry.
As is Chairman Leach, I am deeply concerned about wage stagnation. In your speech you highlighted the fact that workers are
becoming more and more concerned about job security. As you
know, we talk a lot about modernization; specifically in this subcommittee, financial modernization. Do you see any indication that
with the growing concentration of economic power that that could
exacerbate unemployment and also heighten job security? Should
this not be a major concern of this subcommittee as we move
forward on financial modernization?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is a very difficult question to answer because
we know very little as to the impacts that are likely to arise as we
move into a very complex and evolving state of technology in the
21st Century. It is a complex issue which I do not think I can add
terribly much to, unless you want me to be very specific to a
specific question.
Mr. METCALF. That is OK, I just have that concern and want to
register it.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I understand it and it is the right type of question that should be on the table when you are discussing the
modernization issue.
Mr. METCALF. Thank you. Last week in the Senate hearings, the
issue of paying interest on sterile reserves was brought up. I authored a bill last year and I will reintroduce it shortly, to allow
sterile reserves to gain interest, and also allow small businesses to
earn interest on their demand deposits, which they cannot do now
under Regulation D and Regulation Q. There are significant budget
implications; specifically, the way CBO scores this issue.
Do you see the benefits of this action outweighing the budget
scoring process, and would the Fed support such action?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, we have supported the payment
of interest on required reserve balances for a very long period of
time, and indeed, the elimination of the prohibition on the payment
of interest on overall demand deposits as well. We continue to do
so. There is no question that there would be a not insignificant loss
to the Treasury as a consequence of that; somewhere between
$300-million and $500-million annually.
Mr. METCALF. Thank you. The Feas open market intervention
rpcedures were changed as of the first of the year. Could you
riefly outline to us what the changes were and why they were
needed? And also, any impact the changes might nave on the
ability of the Fed to execute monetary policy.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I am sorry, I am not familiar with what
particular changes you are referring to.
Mr. METCALF. I heard or read that the Fed's open market
intervention procedures were changed as of the first of the year.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I am sorry. We, for a long period of time, used
to enter into the market, which we do daily, later in the morning
than the period where maximum transactions were occurring.

E




28

What we have done is speed up our process of evaluating the various needs for reserves during the day that might accrue over the
so-called maintenance period. What we have been able to do is to
enter the market at an earlier part of the day and engage a thicker
part of the market, the part where more transactions are going on.
I do not consider this an important issue and I do not think it has
been creating a particular problem for us, Congressman.
Mr. METCALF. Thank you very much. I read about it and I just
wanted to ask about it in case it was something more than
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, it is an interesting issue. I am just, quite
frankly, surprised that anyone noticed.
Mr. METCALF. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Metcalf.
Mrs. Maloney? Excuse me, I am sorry, the gentleman from
Vermont. I apologize.
Mr. SANDERS. I may be an independent, Mr. Chairman, but geez.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Greenspan, the wealthiest 1 percent of Americans now own
42 percent of the Nation's wealth; more than the bottom 90 percent. In 1976, the wealthiest 1 percent owned 19 percent of the
wealth. So we have seen the upper 1 percent more than double the
percentage of the wealth in this country that they own.
Does this concern you, the fact that we today have, by far, the
most unequal distribution of wealth and income in the industrialized world? A, does it concern you? And B, what do you intend
to do about it? And I have a number of questions to ask you, so
I would appreciate if your answers could be brief.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, the answer is, it does concern me. It is not
clear to me what monetary policy can dp to alter that in any
material way.
Mr. SANDERS. Mr. Greenspan, from what I just heard a moment
ago you talked that from your point of view the economy is doing
"very well." Did I hear you correctly?
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct.
Mr. SANDERS. I would love to take you to the State of Vermont
where you can talk to working families where workers are working
two or three jobs trying to pay their bills; where women who would
prefer to stay home with the kids are now being forced to work;
where jobs in our economy which used to pay $15-an-hour in
manufacturing are now paying $5-an-hour working for McDonald's.
But more importantly, during the past 20 years we have seen a
decline in wages, or stagnation, for 80 percent of all American families while the people on top nave never had it so good. Twenty
years ago, American workers were the best compensated in the
world. Today, we rank 13th in the world. In 1973, the average
American worker earned $445 a week, and 20 years later in 1993,
that worker was making $373 a week. Please tell the working people of Vermont and the working people of this country how the
economy is doing so good for them as opposed to the very rich who
have never had it so good.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, at any time throughout our history there have always been areas in our economy which are doing
far less well than others. All we can measure is the average
changes. I can suggest to you that in terms of the average changes,




29

the economy by any measure which we have available to us, is
doing well.
Mr. SANDERS. But Mr. Greenspan, is not the concept average
change totally meaningless? If you make $l-million-a-year and I
make $10,000-a-year, on average we are making a little bit less
than $500,000-a-year. You are doing very well. I am dead broke.
Does not this whole on average concept perpetuate a fraud when
the vast majority of the people in this country have seen a decline
in their wages, working longer hours; when the new jobs that are
being created are terribly low wage jobs? So what are we talking
about average? If the rich are getting richer, that distorts the
whole figure.
Mr. GREENSPAN. First of all, let me question your data. It is not
true that the vast majority of people have lower wages at this
stage.
Mr. SANDERS. You question the statistic that I gave you?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I do. I do indeed.
Mr. SANDERS. What do you believe? You believe that the working
people of this country have seen higher wages?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, I am just saying, you said the vast majority.
Mr. SANDERS. That is right.
Mr. GREENSPAN. So that is a number which means 60, 70
percent?
Mr. SANDERS. I have said that in 1973, the average American
worker earned $445 a week. Twenty years later that worker was
making $373. That 80 percent of our working people have seen a
significant decline.
Mr. GREENSPAN. You are using BLS' payroll employment figure,
and the average weekly earnings that is associated with that. That
figure is questionable, I must tell you that.
Mr. SANDERS. Why do you think it is questionable, sir?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is questionable basically because of the fact
that those data are not produced in an appropriate sample. The
employment figures are, but not the wages and they are not revised. Let me just say this, the Bureau of Census has alternate
data which they do on a more scientific basis which are far less
pessimistic than that.
Mr. SANDERS. I believe it was the Labor Department came out
recently with statistics which says that for high school graduates
who are entering the labor market, for young men the wages are
30 percent less than they were 15 years ago; for women I oelieve
it was 27 percent less. Significant drop in wages for high school
graduates. Is that also not a good figure?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I can believe that figure.
Mr. SANDERS. Given that reality, what about the figure that the
inflation-adjusted median income for young people are doing worse
than older families, with children? Young families with children
headed by persons younger than 30 plunged 32 percent between
1973 and 1990. Meanwhile, we have seen a proliferation of billionaires going from 12 to 135 from 1982 to today. Do you really deny
that while the wealthiest people of this country have never had it
so good, the vast majority of the people have seen a decline in their
standard of living?




30

Mr. GREENSPAN. The Consumer Price Index, which is employed
to deflate those data is precisely the index which I have been arguing is mis-specified. If you make the appropriate adjustments, that
declining trend disappears. Nonetheless, I grant you that it is
pretty stagnant.
Mr. SANDERS. I would simply say, I would welcome vou. Please
give me a ring. You come to the State of Vermont with me and I
will take you around our State, and I would love to hear the response when you tell the working families of our State that the
economy is doing very well. It is not doing well for the middle class,
for the working class. It may be doing well for upper-income people,
but not for the vast majority of the people.
Mr. Chairman, thank you very much.
Thank you, Mr. Greenspan.
Chairman CASTLE, [presiding]. Thank you very much.
Dr. Paul.
Mr. PAUL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Chairman, I want to bring up the subject again about the
CPI. We have talked a lot about the CPI and an effort to calculate
our cost-of-living in this country, and specifically here, to measure
how much we are going to increase the benefits that we are responsible for. But in reality, is not this attempt to measure a CPI or
a cost-of-living nothing more than an indirect method or an effort
to measure the depreciation of a currency? And that we are looking
at prices, but we are also dealing with a currency problem.
When we debase or depreciate a currency we do get higher
prices, but we also have malinvestment. We have distorted interest
rates. We contribute to deficits. And also, we might not always be
looking at the right prices. We have commodity prices, which is the
usual conceded figure that everybody talks about as far as measuring inflation. But we might at times have inflated prices in the
financial instruments.
So to say that inflation is under control and we are doing very
well, I would suggest that we look at these other areas top, if indeed we recognize that we are talking about the depreciation of a
currency.
One other thing that I would like to suggest, and it might be of
interest to my colleagues, is that one of the characteristics of a currency of a country that depreciates its currency systematically is
that the victims are not always equal. Some suner more than others. Some benefit from inflation of the currency and the
debasement of the currency. So indeed, I would expect the complaints that I hear. I would suggest that maybe this is related to
monetary policy in a very serious manner.
The consensus now in Washington, all the important people have
conceded that we should have a commission. But when we designate a commission, this usually means everybody knows what the
results are. I mean, nobody complains that the CPI might undercalculate inflation or the cost-of-living for some individuals, which
might be the case. So we have this commission.
But is it conceivable that this is nothing more than a vehicle to
raise taxes? the New York Times just this week editorialized in
favor of this because it raised taxes, and also it cuts benefits, and
they are concerned about cutting benefits. But would it not be




31

much more honest for Congress to deal with tax increases in an
above-board fashion, especially if we think the CPI is not
calculable? I think it is very difficult.
Also, I think that if it is a currency problem as well, we cannot
concentrate only on prices. There have been some famous economists in our history who say, look to the people who talk about
prices because they do not want to discuss the root cause of our
problem, and that has to do with the inflation of the monetary
system or the depreciation of the currency.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Dr. Paul, the concept of price increase is conceptually identical, but the inverse of the depreciation of the value of
the currency. The best way to get a judgment of the value of the
currency as such, if one could literally do it, is to separate the two
components of long-term nominal interest rates into an inflation
premium component and a real interest rate component. The
former would be the true measure of the expected depreciation in
the value of the currency.
We endeavor to capture that in these new index bonds that have
been issued in which the Consumer Price Index, for good or ill, is
used to approximate that. It does not exactly, and I think that is
what I have been arguing with respect to the commission is to take
the statistical bias out of the CPI and get a true cost-of-living
index.
It is certainly the case that that is a measure of inflation. There
are lots of different measures of inflation. I would argue that commodities, per se, steel, copper, aluminum, hides, whatever, used to
be a very good indicator of overall inflation in the economy when
we were heavily industrialized. Now they represent a very small
part of the economy and services are far more relevant to the purchasing power of the currency than at any time, so that broader
measures of price, in my judgment, are more relevant to
determining what the true rate of inflation is.
Mr. PAUL. Can the inflated prices in the financial instruments
not be a reflection of this same problem?
Mr. GREENSPAN. They are. This is a very important question and
one which I was implicitly raising: do asset
price changes affect the
economy? And the answer is clearly, "yes-" What you call it, whether it is inflation or not inflation, that is a nomenclature question.
But the economics of it clearly means that if one is evaluating the
stability of the system, you have to look at product prices, that is,
prices of goods and services, and asset prices, meaning prices on
items generally which have rates of return associated with them.
Mr. PAUL. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much, Dr. Paul.
Mrs. Maloney.
Mrs. MALONEY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. First, may
I request that my opening statement be submitted in the record as
read?
Chairman CASTLE. Without objection, so done.
[The prepared statement of Mrs. Maloney can be found on page
59 in the appendix.]
Mrs. MALONEY. Second, I would like to welcome a former constituent from the great city of New York, Mr. Greenspan. It is
always good to see you.




32

First of all, I would like to know, why are you as a central banker commenting on the stock market? I have never heard of other
central bankers doing that. I thought that the law, the 1946 Employment Act intended the Fed to stabilize the price of goods and
services.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct, Congresswoman. As I mentioned
to your colleagues earlier today, the reason why we are moving our
analysis to a far broader plane than merely what we used to do is
because it is becoming increasingly evident in this increasingly
complex economy that asset prices generally are having an important impact on the production and consumption of goods and services and on the general state of inflation. As a consequence, what
we are doing ana have been doing in recent years, is to gradually
broaden what we are evaluating in the economy as the economy
becomes more complex.
While it is certainly the case that our mandate, as you put it, is
on goods and services, if we are to appropriately fulfill that mandate, it is required that we evaluate and endeavor to look at asset
price changes in the same manner we look at changes in residential construction, exports, consumption, or various other elements
of demand.
Mrs. MALONEY. But your statement on irrational exuberance
rolled the stock market by 100 points, and it is a concern to me
because it may have been a move potentially designed to impact on
Wall Street, but it had a far further impact on every Main Street
in our country. It seemed to me like a tremendous broadening of
your mandate.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me say this
Mrs. MALONEY. And the met that it was a broadening, maybe
there was an over-reaction to your statement.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I was fully aware, as were my colleagues, that
just merely mentioning the word stock market or something of that
nature would create a price reaction. We are also aware of the fact
that we are dealing with very sophisticated markets which are
international in scope, have millions of investors.
While, to be sure, you can, as rumors do, as statements by myself
and my colleagues do periodically, induce short term changes, you
cannot fundamentally affect the broad trend in market prices. That
requires real economic changes, and I do not care what any central
banker endeavors to do, we will never succeed in altering the path
of major economic markets.
Mrs. MALONEY. But you rolled it 100 points. Let us go on to your
statement on page seven. In your opening statement you said, "We
cannot rule out a situation in which a preemptive policy tightening
may become appropriate before any sign of actual higher inflation
becomes evident." Yet in the other materials that you submitted,
it showed that the real economic growth that you predicted is 2
percent to 2.25 percent. The Clinton Administration predicts it at
2 percent. This is not great growth. This is a very limited growth.
Then when you talked about inflation, some people say that in
1996 it was at 3.2 percent, the rate of inflation represented by the
CPI which many people today have said are overstated. In your
former statements you said that you thought inflation may be




33

overstated by 1.5 percent, which means that inflation really could
be 1.7 percent, which is low. The economic growth is low.
Why are you talking about a preemptive policy with numbers
like that?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is not the expected forecasts which drive policy, it is the various distribution of risks on that policy, meaning
wnat happens if we make a projection and we are wrong? What we
try to do is to evaluate the consequence of mistakes in judgment.
The reason we have to do that is that monetary policy, by all of
our measures, has a very delayed effect on the economy. So, we are
forced to make projections pretty far out—a year or more. As a consequence of that, we have to recognize that inflationary pressures
can start to mount well before they become evident in any of the
published statistics.
We have made judgments in the past that the economy was
weakening well before it became evident and we started to ease
monetary conditions. In that sense, it was preemptive in the other
direction. There is no alternative—and I really wish it were otherwise—to acting preemptively because of that long lag between what
we do and what happens.
Mrs. MALONEY. I do not believe ever in my lifetime there has
been a preemptive action with a 1.7 percent inflation and a 2
percent growth.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, but remember that the inflation rate has
been biased upward for a very long period of time. So you cannot
compare it with earlier data. In short, if you took the inflation bias
out of the Consumer Price Index going all the way back, the inflation rate data at a very earlier period would have been much lower
than they are now.
It is the type of situation in which you are doing more than making an average expectation. In other words, if we were assured that
inflation would stay down, that is a forecast which in my judgment
would mean we would do nothing.
Mrs. MALONEY. But we have no indication that it is going up.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I am not saying we
Chairman CASTLE. Mrs. Maloney, we are going to have on. I am
sorry.
Mrs. MALONEY. Mr. Chairman, may I do one brief follow-up
question that really feeds on
Chairman CASTLE. Let us try to come back to you. We are trying
to be—several of us have other subcommittee problems today, so
we are trying to run through the questions, if you will excuse us.
I am sorry, we are without relief here at this point. We will try to
come back if we go quickly.
Mr. Bentsen, please.
Mr. BENTSEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Greenspan, it is good to see you again since I guess yesterday morning in the Budget Committee. I want to follow up on a
couple things we talked about yesterday and then I have some
other questions for you.
First of all*. I appreciate in your testimony today you made some
comments regarding education. That issue was raised yesterday at
the Budget Committee. Today, you did underscore I think the importance of enhancing our education, trying to invest in human




34

capital potential. I think that is correct as well and I am glad that
you have gone on the record in doing so, regardless of whether it
is through tax credits or whatever form we might take. I realize
that you do not want to get into taking a position on that.
I do want to follow up very briefly on the CPI question which I
did not get to ask yesterday. This may be more of a political question, but you state you believe there is a 100 percent probability
that we are understating
Mr. GREENSPAN. Virtually.
Mr. BENTSEN.
Virtually a 100 percent probability that we are
understating CPI; that we should form a commission. Now a commission quite possibly might not come to a 100 percent perfect solution as to what real CPI is, but they would presumably try and
get as close as they could. But there would obviously be some error
and they would be working on an average.
Do you think in that case that it would be better, if Congress
were to take that route, for us to enact some sort of flat CPI or flat
COLA or dollar-average COLA? In effect, means-test the COLA to
make up for the inexactness of what a commission might come up
with?
Mr. GREENSPAN. So you mean like CPI minus X; is that what you
mean?
Mr. BENTSEN. Something along those lines.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is surely an alternative approach.
Mr. BENTSEN. But also to say, perhaps those that may be at the
mean or at the median would be held harmless, those above might
get less, those below might get more?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, the Congress can certainly do that.
Mr. BENTSEN. Let me ask you also with respect to CPI, you stated yesterday that if we are understating CPI, we are probably understating productivity because we are looking at companies that
continue to have increasing earnings; therefore, we must be understating productivity. Therefore, would that mean that a 5 percent
to 5.5 percent unemployment rate is not necessarily as dangerous
from an inflationary standpoint as we once thought it might be?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, I think you are raising the question of so-called "NAIRU" that is the unemployment rate in which
the rate of inflation, by hypothesis, neither rises nor falls. I have
been quite skeptical about that as a stable notion. In other words,
I think that there is a reasonable concept of a NAIRU for a metropolitan area, for example, where there is competition in the labor
market and people can go from one part of the area to another part
and take another job.
I am very skeptical that that concept can be globalized for the
United States as a whole, implying that the demand and supply for
labor can somehow operate between Portland, Maine and Portland,
Oregon, for example.
Implicit in a national NAIRU is that somehow all of these metropolitan area NAIRUs average out in a fixed way. I think the evidence is very questionable on that, and I think tnat the concept itself is so unstable that I would be very careful in employing it as
a means for any form of monetary policy. I do not deny that it is
useful to give you a hint as to the way things are going, but




35

certainly not something which in any way is sufficiently stable to
give one confidence that it works.
Mr. BENTSEN. Let me ask you this, your comments before the
Senate Banking Committee a week ago set off fear within the markets that there will be a rate hike sometime in the near future. Yet
when I look at your testimony, I look at the report that you all
have provided to the Congress, I am not sure I see where that is
coming from.
There is a little pressure in the employment cost index. Are you
looking at the monetary aggregates? You have some that are at the
top of the span, some that are near the top of the span. Interest
rates, in your report you talk briefly about the last time you took
action in early 1994, and yet you look at interest rates today compared to where they were in late 1993, early 1994 and rates are
higher today.
So I am curious as to where—is this all based on price-earning
ratios and concern about the market? How does that now play into
the Fed's calculations?
Mr. GREENSPAN. The market does not know anything more than
you read. They get the same information. So what we try to do is
detail as fully as we can what it is we tend to look at. As I indicated in my formal remarks, it is not easy to give you a road map
because we do not have one at this stage of exactly the types of
things which are likely to emerge which could create a
destabilizing of the expansion.
As a result of that, the only point that I wanted to make, which
is an important point, is that we have to recognize that monetary
policy acts with a lag. And if it acts with a lag, it is conceivable
that we will, on certain occasions, be required to move policy in either direction in advance of particular events becoming clearly evident. The economy at this particular stage in time, as we have indicated in previous comments, is clearly running very close to any
measure of capacity. As I have said in my prepared remarks, it is
not indicating one that is clearly overheated; one in which inflation
is clearly accelerating. That is not the case at this particular point
as I have suggested.
But the question that is on the table for all of us, in fact really
since July, is that when you are in this particular zone the risks
are on the upside. But we monitor it very closely, and as I indicated, we chose not to move through all of the second half of last
year even though we were in that zone because the evidence of
inflation acceleration was clearly lacking.
Mr. BENTSEN. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Bentsen.
Mr. Jackson has earned his second star because he got here on
time and he stayed through the whole proceedings and we
appreciate that. Mr. Jackson?
Mr. JACKSON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I just have two
questions of the Chairman.
In the past when the economy slowed and millions of our country's workers lost their jobs, people knew there was a safety net
that would allow them to scrape by even if they exhausted their
unemployment benefits. Under the new welfare reform law the




36

Federal floor under the poor has been removed because welfare
benefits have been terminated after 2 continuous years on welfare.
The new rules then dictate that the poor find a job or join the
homeless or beg for food.
I would like your assessment of the need for full employment policy in light of the new welfare reform law, and whether or not you
think that the Federal Reserve has a role to play in accomplishing
full employment, particularly as those of us on Capitol Hill keep
dictating and mandating that the poor beyond their public
assistance find some work.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Did you say full employment law?
Mr. JACKSON. Full employment policy as a goal.
Mr. GREENSPAN. What I trying to get at is, where is the incidence of the policy? Because as far as the Fed is concerned, we
agree with you in the sense that we should think there should be
maximum sustainable economic growth, and that translates into
the lowest sustainable rate of unemployment implicitly.
Mr. JACKSON. Let me comment on that quickly, Mr. Chairman.
In 1972, respectfully, sir, that was 3 percent. In 1997, it is about
5.3 percent, 5.4 percent. So that is 7.5-million Americans, not
counting the underemployed or the unemployed. So we move people
off of public benefits, welfare to work, that is the policy we passed
in the 104th Congress, my question is does the Federal Reserve
have a role to play in making sure that an expanded economy remains expansive so that it reaches those who have been
unemployed or underemployed?
Mr. GREENSPAN. As I said before, our goal is maximum sustainable economic growth. That is about as strong a commitment as I
think one could make toward maintaining the job creation and sustainable income levels. With respect to the structural problems
which are clearly there as you point out, there is very little that
monetary policy can do. That is an issue for other forms of policy.
That is the reason why I raised the question about where is the
locus of the policy as such, because it has got to be broader than
just mainly monetary policy.
Mr. JACKSON. That may be a source of concern, respectfully, Mr.
Chairman, for all of us. I know the President most recently in his
State of the Union Address congratulated several companies for
hiring people and expanding their hiring programs to reach out to
welfare recipients.
But if in fact there is a rate hike, it slows the economy down.
It obviously slows down job creation at a time where we are operating here on Capitol Hill under the assumptions that an expanded
economy is going to employ people that we are going to move off
of public assistance. Any effort to slow the economy down really
runs contrary to many of the assumptions that we have been
functioning with here on Capitol Hill.
I am interested in your comments, sir.
Mr. GREENSPAN. First of all, we do not raise rates for the purpose of slowing the economy. When we raise rates it usually is for
the purpose of stabilizing elements which threaten the growth of
the economy. So all I can say to you is that we do not believe that
the purpose of the Federal Reserve is to restrain growth, as is often
the comment and indeed some of your colleagues have made that




37

statement. I will tell you, that is not the purpose of monetary
policy, and it should not be.
Mr. JACKSON. I appreciate your answer. Let me move on to my
second question, if I can. You said in your testimony that wages
are not rising rapidly because of workers' job insecurity. That was
on page four and global competition on page six. And on page six
of your written testimony you said that these influences would be
holding down inflation only temporarily. Then you go on to say on
page seven that preemptive policy tightening may become
appropriate before any sign of actual tightening becomes evident.
Mr. Chairman, there are many hard-working people in my district who have not seen a significant wage increase in many years.
Their wages corrected for inflation have, quite frankly, been stagnant. I wanted to know, do you really want to slow down the economy if these workers receive a raise even if the prices of goods and
services rise at the present levels of inflation?
Mr. GREENSPAN. All I can say to you, Congressman, is that one
must measure, from the point of view of monetary policy, what we
call unit labor costs, meaning the change in compensation adjusted
by productivity. So to the extent over the long-run that wages go
up on average with the rate of growth in productivity, there is no
inflationary bias that is perceivable.
If inflation begins to take hold and as a consequence, as it invariably has in the past, unbalances the economy, what then happens
is that economic growth comes to a halt and more often than not
we move into a recession. I scarcely want to see that happen, and
it strikes me as an outcome which is one which would create far
more difficult problems for everybody. I think that a little inflation
may sound like it is harmless. A little leads to more, and more
leads to slower economic growth.
Chairman CASTLE. Mr. Jackson wants to ask a follow-up and we
will allow it. Then Dr. Paul had one or two brief other questions
he wanted to ask, and Mr. Bentsen has one brief question. I want
to try to wrap it up, but I do not want to cut anybody off. So let
us go in that order. We will start with Mr. Jackson.
Mr. JACKSON. Thank you, Mr. Castle.
Very quickly, in the last 3 years I did a little analysis of the salaries of senior staff at the Fed and I have also noticed that they
have been rising somewhat rapidly. In 1993, there were 35 employees at the Board of Governors earning $125,000-per-year with tne
highest at about $174,100. I was really wondering, were these inflationary wage increases, and what could my constituents and
workers throughout the country come to understand about salaries
at the Fed seeing as though they are being paid for by their taxes?
That is my follow-up.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. We observed a few years that we were having
very considerable difficulty hiring the types of people that we needed to accomplish the particular responsibilities that the Congress
has given to us. What we then did at that point is to come up to
both the leadership of the House Banking Committee and the Senate Banking Committee and indicated that since we were not required by law to stipulate any particular level of wages that we decided that it would be wise for us to move up the whole structure,




38

which is what we have done. Since then, the average increase has
slowed very dramatically.
Mr. JACKSON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much.
Dr. Paul.
Mr. PAUL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Much has been said about your statements regarding the stock
market and I wanted to address that for just 1 minute. In December when you stated this, of course, the market went down and this
past week there was as sudden drop. The implication being that if
you are unhappy with it, they assume that you will purposefully
push up interest rates. But really since the first time you made
that statement it seems that almost the opposite has occurred. M3
actually has accelerated, to my best estimate in the last 2 months
it has gone up at a 10 percent rate. The base actually has perked
up a little bit. Prior to this time it was rising at less than a 5 percent rate and now it is rising a little over 8 percent.
But then too we have another factor which is not easy to calculate, and that is what our friends in the foreign central banks
do. During this short period of time they bought $23 billion worth
of our debt. We dp know that Secretary Rubin talks to them and
that maybe there is an agreement that they help you out; they buy
some of these Treasury bills so you do not have to buy quite so
many.
Mr. GREENSPAN. There is no such agreement, Dr. Paul.
Mr. PAUL. You read about that though.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Sometimes what you read is not true.
Mr. PAUL. OK, we will get your comments on that. But anyway,
they are accommodating us, whether it is policy or not. Their rate
of increase on holding our bills are rising at over 20 percent, and
even these 2 months at maybe 22 percent.
My suggestion here and the question is, instead of the sudden
policy change where you may increase interest rates, it seems like
to me that you may be working to maintain interest rates from not
rising. Certainly, you would have a bigger job if we had a perfect
balance of trade. I mean, they are accumulating a lot of our dollars
and they are helping us out. So if we had a penect balance of trade
or if their policies change, all of a sudden would this not put a
tremendous pressure on interest rates?
Mr. GREENSPAN. We have examined the issue to some extent on
the question of what foreign holdings of U.S. Treasuries have done
to U.S. interest rates. I think the best way of describing it is that
you probably have got some small effect in the short run when very
large changes in purchases occur. There is no evidence over a long
run that interest rates are in any material way affected by
purchases.
The reason, incidentally, is that they usually reflect shifts—in
other words, some people buy, some people sell. Interest rates will
only change if one party or the other is pressuring the market.
There is no evidence which we can find which suggests that that
is any consistent issue, so that the accumulation of U.S. Treasury
assets, for example, is also reflected in the decumulation by other
parties. We apparently cannot find any relationship which suggests
to us that that particular process is significantly affecting




39

Mr. PAUL. For the past 2 years, the accumulation has been much
greater.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct, it has been.
Mr. PAUL. Thank you.
Chairman LEACH, [presiding]. Thank you, Dr. Paul.
We are going to have two more questions, one coming from Mr.
Bentsen. But I think it is fair to place in the record at this moment
in time that when the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board of
the United States speaks with confident exuberance, the market
goes up, as it just has 90 points.
Mr. Bentsen.
Mr. BENTSEN. Now it is too late to do anything about it.
[Laughter.]
Mr. BENTSEN. Mr. Chairman, first of all, last year in your response to my previous question we talked a little bit about capacity
utilization; I think it was last year or the year prior. At that time—
and my numbers are probably incorrect—we were seeing somewhere around 81 percent, 82 percent, I think. It was near the level
where in the past we had said, or economists had said, you are
about to breach the wall of capacity utilization which will cause
bottlenecks and price increases. You said, I think at that time, that
has probably changed because of new efficiencies and production
and all.
I guess it is coming down, and what your response was to that
question in trying to look at that, monetary aggregates and other
things is the old rules of determining or foreseeing inflation have
changed and now it is almost, you know what it is when you see
it.
But let me move to a question. I would be remiss if I did not ask
a question regarding the oil economy, since it is important to my
State. Your report states that you expect oil prices, which have declined quite dramatically in recent years, to stay relatively flat and
not be a pressure point on the price index.
There was an article in yesterday's Wall Street Journal, however,
where some are speculating that oil prices in fact may rise, for a
couple of reasons. But one of the points they made was that worldwide oil production is now at about 95 percent of capacity, which
seems quite high. I would like your comments on that.
And I would also like your comments on the fact that the article
goes on to say, some argue that a potential price increase in oil
might be tempered by the fact that North Sea and other world
markets could flood the oil market and drive prices back down.
But it comes back to the fact that in the United States, the capacity of the oilfield services industry has declined so much as we
have seen imports continue to rise, and now we may be seeing the
effect of that on domestic prices. It is good for Houston. It is good
for the oilfield services economy that is still around, but perhaps
that is bad for the general economy of the United States. I would
appreciate your comments on that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. We have a fairly broad set of data, some of
which are good, some of which are less good on oil production
around the world. What I was saying in my prepared remarks was
essentially, that analysts are projecting or something of that
nature. What they are saying effectively, and we have no direct




40

verification on this, is that projections of increases in the North
Sea and in the Gulf are more than adequate to meet the expected
worldwide demand for crude, and in addition build some
inventories back into the system.
As a consequence, what we observe is a fairly significant decline
recently in West Texas intermediate crude prices. They had gotten
as high as $28 a barrel. Now I guess they are down to a little over
$20. Forward markets are projecting a price a little lower, as you
know.
It is true, nonetheless, that the oil services industry is very tight,
and the drilling rig availability, especially offshore, is very tight.
There are people, and this was expressed in that article to which
you refer, who think that the exploration and development requirements to keep the oil flowing in an adequate way is being constrained by service industry capacity. I am not aware that tnat is
a general view.
I am aware that there is difficulty in getting equipment, but I
am not aware that there is a significant concern that crude availability will be foreshortened in a manner which could induce significant acceleration of prices. That can happen, obviously, in the
sense that there are many things we have seen in the past which
have induced major increases in crude prices, and I would certainly
not rule that out. But the evidence at this particular stage seems
to be more consistent, as the forward markets are pricing, that increases in supply in the next year should be marginally larger than
increases in consumption.
Mr. BENTSEN. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE, [presiding]. Thank you very much, Mr.
Bentsen.
For our final question we will turn to Chairman Leach.
Mr. LEACH. To skip issues slightly, one of the responsibilities of
this subcommittee this year is going to relate to a whole spectrum
of issues related to the IMF, including possible increases in quotas,
and so forth. As Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board would you
give us your opinion on the wisdom of Congress moving in this
direction or not:
Mr. GREENSPAN. We work, as you know, with the Secretary of
the Treasury and his colleagues on this issue and we give them our
advice on various things and then support them, because so far as
international affairs are concerned, monetary authorities should be
one. We have supported directly the new borrowing facility, which
we think is wise, and we have communicated that to the Secretary.
In general, we think that our international responsibilities are
such that it is important that we make certain that we maintain
the effectiveness within those institutions that we have had over
the years. In that regard, we are supportive of the Secretary of the
Treasury in his initiatives.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, everybody, particularly those who
were able to stay with us. We thank you, Chairman Greenspan.
Chairman Leach has already announced that the Dow Jones average is up 93-some-points today, which is good, which indicates to
us that you should always testify before the House and not the




41

Senate because the results are better. But I should warn you that
gold was down $6 today. So there may be some repercussions on
that side of it for you to worry about.
But again, we thank you. You are always very patient with all
of us, and we thank all of our Members who participated.
We stand adjourned.
[Whereupon, at 4:28 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]










APPENDIX

March 5, 1997

44
House Committee on Banking and Financial Services
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary policy
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearing with testimony from Alan Greenspan,
Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board,
2:00 p.m., March 5, 1997
Room 2128 Rayburn House Office Building

Chairman Michael N. Castle's Opening Remarks:
The Subcommittee will come to order.
The Subcommittee meets today, to receive the semi-annual report of
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on the conduct of
monetary policy and the state of the economy, as mandated in the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.

Chairman Greenspan, welcome back to the House Committee on
Banking and Financial Services, Subcommittee on Domestic and
International Monetary Policy. You will note that this subcommittee has
done its best to accommodate the Fed while meeting the schedule
required by the Humphrey - Hawkins Act. We have followed your
testimony before our Senate colleagues as closely as we could, so that the
same testimony can serve for both hearings. I trust that in turn, you will be
as candid as possible in addressing issues raised over the past week.
Today, we will have five minute opening statements by the members
present. In addition, some members of the full Committee may sit with us
today and participate in the questioning. As always, any prepared remarks




45
presented by a member will be accepted for the record.

Today the US economy continues to be healthy with inflation
apparently in check. We welcome the continued sound performance of the
economy which evidently has been assisted by the Fed's monetary policy.
Having witnessed what even one of your carefully calibrated
characterizations of the stock market can accomplish, it is clear that what
you say can have a significant impact on the market, at least over the short
term.
Following your testimony last week, many analysts have argued
both that the current prices of common stocks are justified and that
external factors are also somewhat responsible in making this market the
investment vehicle of choice. Others dispute the actual amount of
influence the Fed is able to exercise using the traditional mechanisms of
monetary policy.
If you believe that any of your earlier remarks were misinterpreted or
unfairly taken out of context, today's hearing offers the opportunity to
correct such misreading. Certainly, several percentage points of
exuberance have been wrung out of the stock markets, and we can hope
that some seeds of inflation have been destroyed as well.

I am also interested in your assessment of whether the run up in
relative value of the dollar is becoming a limiting factor in the conduct of




46
monetary policy by the Federal Reserve.

Your Chairmanship of the Federal Reserve System Board of
Governors continues to be successful as judged by results. Nevertheless,
aside from monetary policy there are other aspects of Federal Reserve
operations that merit review by Congress. This subcommittee is planning
oversight hearings on the Federal Reserve System that will review Fed
activity including the the transition from physical to electronic forms of
money as the digital age looms in our future. Of particular concern to me it seems that with the current level of technology available, the Fed's
proposal to add an additional day to the current check clearing process
seems to be going in the wrong direction, especially from the point of view
of the consumer needing access to his money. We also hope to review the
role of the central bank as a competitor with private sector clearing
facilities. We look forward to hearing how the Fed is planning for potential
of new technology to affect systemic security, safety, soundness,
consumer privacy as well as the future conduct of monetary policy. In this
future hearing, we hope to engage in a discussion of the various ways that
the approaching digital revolution in money will affect the operations of the
Federal Reserve System. I am increasingly persuaded that dramatic
change in how we define and employ money may soon be upon us. This
in turn, must affect the payment system and institutions charged with its
stewardship. Thus, we should be prepared for the threshold at which this




47
impending change becomes significant in your models of the economy.
As always, we are delighted to have you with us and look
forward to a lively discussion.

Before recognizing the distinguished Ranking Member, I want to recognize and
welcome the participation of Members of the Banking Committee, not appointed to the
Monetary Policy Subcommittee, and ask unanimous consent that to the extent they wish to
participate and ask questions of the witness, they may be permitted to do so.

Hearing no objection, so ordered. Mr. Flake




48

STATEMENT OF FLOYD H. FLAKE
HUMPHREY-HAWKINS HEARING BEFORE
THE COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND
FINANCIAL SERVICES
MARCH 5, 1997

I WOULD LIKE TO WELCOME CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN
FOR OUR BIENNIAL HUMPHREY HAWKINS HEARING TO
DISCUSS THE FEDERAL RESERVE'S CONDUCT OF MONETARY
POLICY, AND ITS OPINION OF THE CURRENT STATE OF THE
ECONOMY. GIVEN LAST WEEK'S REACTIONARY ACTIVITY IN
THE STOCK MARKET, AND THE PERSISTENT POLITICAL
COMMENTARY ON OUR NATION'S ECONOMIC HEALTH, I
LOOK FORWARD TO HEARING CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN'S
COMMENTS.
I WILL BE BRIEF IN MY COMMENTS, BUT I WISH TO
EXPRESS TO MR. GREENSPAN ONE SPECIFIC CONCERN. THIS
CONCERN IS THE CONTINUED NEGLECT OF OUR NATION'S
POOR COMMUNITIES. THE FEDERAL RESERVE APPEARS TO
FOCUS ITS EFFORTS ON MACRO-ECONOMIC ISSUES THAT, IN




49

GENERAL, HAVE BEEN GOOD FOR THE OVERALL FINANCIAL
HEALTH OF OUR NATION. BUT IN ITS ZEAL TO CONTROL
INFLATION, AND TO STAVE OFF ECONOMIC DOWNTURNS,
THE FEDERAL RESERVE SEEMS TO HAVE FORGOTTEN THAT
THERE ARE COMMUNITIES IN AMERICA THAT ARE IN A
PERSISTENT CYCLE OF POVERTY AND STAGNATION. THESE
COMMUNITIES ARE NOT HEARING POLICIES FROM THE
FEDERAL RESERVE THAT SPEAK DIRECTLY TO THEIR NEEDS.
THE QUESTION THUS BECOMES; DOES THE FEDERAL
RESERVE FOCUS ON ALL PARTICIPANTS IN THE ECONOMY,
OR DOES IT NEED TO IMPROVE ITS COMMUNICATION
PROCESS WITH RESPECT TO ITS CONCERN AND COMPASSION
FOR ALL SOCIETY? WHICHEVER CONCLUSION WE COME TO, I
DO BELIEVE THAT THESE HEARINGS TEND TO FOCUS TOO
MUCH ON MACRO-ECONOMIC ISSUES THAT DON'T SPEAK
VERY WELL TO THE MR. & MRS. SMITHS OF AMERICA.
I RECOGNIZE THE OLD SAYING THAT "A RISING TIDE




50

LIFTS ALL BOATS," AND TO THE EXTENT THAT YOUR MACROECONOMIC DECISIONS ARE PRUDENT FOR THE NATION AS A
WHOLE, I COMMEND YOU. BUT LET US NOT FORGET THAT
THE RISING TIDE ALSO HAS THE REAL POTENTIAL TO SET
THE SMALL BOAT ADRIFT WITHOUT DIRECTION. MR.
CHAIRMAN, THERE ARE MANY COMMUNITIES IN AMERICA
ADRIFT IN A SEA OF UNEMPLOYMENT, POOR EDUCATION,
AND OVERALL HOPELESSNESS. INSIDE THE BELTWAY
ECONOMIC AND POLITICAL DISCOURSE, UNFORTUNATELY, IS
OFTEN DETACHED FROM THESE REALITIES OF EVERYDAY
LIFE. SO CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN, I WOULD ENCOURAGE YOU
TO SPEAK DIRECTLY TO THOSE OF US WHO REPRESENT
THESE COMMUNITIES, AND ILLUSTRATE IDEAS AND POLICIES
THAT YOU AND YOUR COLLEAGUES BELIEVE WILL DIRECTLY
BENEFIT WHAT I HAVE COME TO CALL AMERICA'S THIRD
WORLD COMMUNITIES.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN, I COME HERE TODAY NOT TO




51

SINGLE OUT THE FEDERAL RESERVE, BUT WITH THE BELIEF
THAT ALL OF US HERE IN WASHINGTON NEED TO BE BETTER
STEWARDS OF THE PEOPLE'S GOVERNMENT. DEMOCRATS
NEED TO COME TO THE REALIZATION THAT SOCIAL
PROGRAMS TO HELP THE POOR ARE NOT THE EXCLUSIVE
ANSWER TO SOCIETY'S ILLS, AND REPUBLICANS SHOULD
NOT BLINDLY ENACT SLASH AND BURN POLICIES IN THE
NAME OF A BALANCED BUDGET. ENTRENCHMENT IN THESE
PARTISAN POSITION IS NOT GOOD GOVERNMENT, AND ONLY
LEADS TO PESSIMISTIC OPINIONS ABOUT WASHINGTON'S
ABILITY TO GOVERN IN A RESPONSIBLE MANNER.
OBVIOUSLY THE SOLUTION IS SOMEWHERE IN THE
MIDDLE, AND THUS IS THE RESULT OF COMPROMISE
BETWEEN BOTH DEMOCRATS AND REPUBLICANS. IT IS A
SOLUTION DEFINED BY COOPERATION BETWEEN
GOVERNMENT AND THE PRIVATE SECTOR, AND IS A
SOLUTION THAT HAS THE GOVERNMENT AND THE PRIVATE




52

SECTOR WORKING TOGETHER IN AN EFFORT TO UPLIFT POOR
COMMUNITIES. THIS PARTNERSHIP, I BELIEVE, INCLUDES
IMPROVING JOB GROWTH, EDUCATION, AND THE MORAL
FIBER OF OUR NATION. THEREFORE IN THE COMING
MONTHS, I INTEND TO WORK WITH ALL MEMBERS IN A
BIPARTISAN EFFORT, AND ENCOURAGE THE FEDERAL
RESERVE TO COMMUNICATE ITS THOUGHTS ON POSSIBLE
EFFORTS TO REVITALIZE POOR COMMUNITIES.
WITH THAT I WILL CLOSE, AND I WILL LISTEN INTENTLY
TO THE TESTIMONY. THANK YOU CHAIRMAN CASTLE, AND
AGAIN WELCOME CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.




53

Opening remarks of Dr. Paul before the Humphrey-Hawkins
testimony of Alan Greenspan March 5,1997
The Consumer Price Index (CPI) is a bad indicator of inflation and makes no pretense of
being an index of the cost of living. Mr. Greenspan has made clear that he believes that the
current CPI does not do a very accurate job of measuring increases in prices. The Fed Chairman
has endorsed the idea of a commission to review the "bias" of the CPI which he believes
overstates the nation's inflation rate.
Adopting the recommendations of a so-called bipartisan commission would in fact be a
backdoor way to reduce the deficit by cutting the benefits of many Americans who receive a
government benefit check and also a way to increase the taxes that these people pay to the
government. The recommendations of these bipartisan commissions are almost always
preordained and are merely attempts to provide cover for politicians to take more of the people's
money. Government will just grow larger as a result.
Since even the Federal Reserve does not trust the ability of the government to measure
accurately the changes, and by changes we always mean increases, in prices for all urban
consumers, it is even less relevant to rural Americans for whom the CPI does not even pretend to
consider. Yet Mr. Greenspan is urging the federal government to use a quick fix with this index
to increase their taxes.
Rises in prices are just the symptom of an ailment that the CPI tries to quantify. Fudging
the numbers does not address the cause of the symptom. The problem with inflation is that it
represents a loss of value of the unit that it uses, in this case the dollar. Consumer prices fell
gently by roughly one-third from 1800 to 1912 (in 1912 dollars). Since 1912, the year before the
Fed was created, prices have risen to a level 15 times higher than they were when the Fed was
established. Thus, we should address the cause of the problem not play games with the
symptoms.
The value of the dollar, Americans' purchasing power, has since fallen to only onefifteenth what it was when the Fed was created. Mr. Greenspan himself wrote one of the most
persuasive articles warning against the use of fiat money and the tendency of government to
grow under its use. Inflation, the destruction of the value of the currency, is a natural by-product
of this paper tiger.
Before another banking subcommittee last week, Paul Volcker acknowledged a quote
attributed to him in The Central Banks by Marjorie Deane and Robert Pringle. Mr. Volcker said,
"It is a sobering fact that the prominence of central banks in this century has coincided with a
general tendency towards more inflation, not less. By and large, if the overriding objective is
price stability, we did better with the nineteenth-century gold standard and passive central banks,
with currency boards, or even with 'free banking'... The truly unique power of a central bank,
after all, is the power to create money, and ultimately the power to create is the power to
destroy."




54
There is a great concern now that the present increase in the money supply (M3),
currently running at an annual rate of approximately 15%, is creating a speculative boom in
financial investments planting the seeds for the coming bust. The easy credit scheme that the
Fed is pursuing to keep the market from moving interest rates higher is facilitating a nominal
appreciation in the value of speculative assets that by some measures is comparable to the bubble
that existed before the stock market crash of 1929. The Fed's power, the power to create money,
may be used to destroy the value of these speculative investments.
Dollar purchases by foreign central banks in Asia and Europe (primarily the Bank of
Japan) have augmented the Fed-created speculative bubble. This additional fueling of the US
credit markets into the US equity market adds to the size of the bubble and the likelihood of a
severe correction or worse.
Efforts of the Fed Chairman to warn against the ill effects of the Fed's own policies does
not exonerate Fed policy from the responsibility they must assume for their own culpability.




55
JESSE L. JACKSON, JR.

COMMITTEES:

2o DISTRICT, ILLINOIS

BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES

SUBCOMMITTEE ON HOUSI

Congress of tfje SJntteb &tate*
^ou^e of &epre$entattoes!
n, BC 20515-1302

STATEMENT BY CONGRESSMAN JESSE L. JACKSON, JR.
COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES
SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
HUMPHREY HAWKINS HEARING
THE STATE OF THE U.S. ECONOMY
MARCH 5, 1997
Chairman Castle, Ranking Member Flake, I would first like to express how
pleased I am to have the opportunity to join the Subcommittee on Domestic and
International Monetary Policy for my first hearing with this Subcommittee. I
have just recently been granted the honor of serving on this distinguished panel.
I very much look forward to learning from your leadership and working with
you during this Congress as we address the critical matters which fall under the
purview of this committee's jurisdiction.
There is no better illustration of the significance of this Subcommittee's role than
the subject matter of the present hearing and the distinguished witness who is
here to testify before us today. Chairman Greenspan, it is with great pleasure
and admiration that I welcome you today to apprise us of the status of the
American economy and your judgments as to the activities of the Federal
Reserve System in fulfilling its duty, among others, of conducting national
monetary policy in pursuit of the objectives of price stability and full
employment.
To that end, Mr. Chairman, in your semiannual report to Congress first
delivered to the Senate last week, you hailed the strength of the economy,
highlighting a two percent increase in the Gross Domestic Product as evidence
of expanding economic opportunities. Relative to previous decades, however, we
know that 2 percent is less than the 1980s, the 1970s, and the 1960s. You
tempered your optimism, however, with a call for caution when you stated that
"History is strewn with visions of new eras that in the end have proven to be a
mirage." I agree completely with your assessment. Today, while conventional
economic wisdom speaks to expansion and growth, my view deviates from this
313 CANNON BUILDING
WASHINGTON, DC 20515-1302
(202)225-0773




17926 SOUTH HALSTED
HOMEWOOD, IL 60430
(708)798-6000

56
Congressman Jesse L. Jackson, Jr.
March 5, 1997
Page 2
conclusion. For the Second Congressional District of Illinois, I have devised a
very rigorous and stringent economic test — a test that I call the "eyeball test."
In order to assess the relevant economic indicators, I merely open my eyes, and
look around to determine whether my constituents on the South Side of Chicago
and in the South Suburbs are experiencing this relative economic growth. Sadly,
Mr. Chairman, my test results do not render the same optimistic projections.
In my district, things have never been good and they are now getting worse.
Nationally, the official unemployment rate is 5.4 percent, which means that 7.3
million people who receive unemployment compensation have no job. The actual
number of unemployed (and underemployed) people is closer to 15 to 20 million
Americans. These numbers include those who are unemployed, underemployed,
working part-time when they want to be working full-time, have never had a job
or gave up looking for one (so that they are not even counted among the
unemployed). These numbers are compounded by those who are faced with
corporate and government downsizing, and are on the brink of and worried that
they may soon fall into one of those categories. Mr. Chairman, I believe that
this is a more accurate picture of the economic conditions of communities like
those in my district and explains the widespread levels of economic anxiety
currently plaguing the American people.
In light of the foregoing, Chairman Greenspan, I will be listening intently to
your testimony and particularly with respect to your views on how the Fed can
encourage and guide the economy towards attaining true levels of full
employment. Once again, thank you Chairman Greenspan for joining us today.
I look forward to hearing your testimony. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.




57
COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES
SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
Statement of
REP. JOHN J. LaFALCE
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearing
March 5, 1997
Chairman Greenspan, it is always a pleasure to welcome you to
the Committee and benefit from the insights and observations that
you provide on the state of the U.S. economy.
From my perspective, it appears that we are doing quite well-with the exception of our irrationally exuberant stock market, of
course, and the ballooning of our trade deficit.
Annual GDP growth in 1996 was 2.4 percent, and most economists
believe this steady growth will continue for another two years.
Inflation

rate remained

"quiet"

at 3 percent

growth

in

1996.

Business productivity increased at an annual 0.8 percent in 1996,
making it the best annual performance since 1992.

Real hourly wage

earnings rose a mere 0 .1 percent, and the Labor Department reported
in January that wage pressures were non-existent.
On the other hand, we have a real problem with our growing
trade deficit.

For 1996, the deficit registered $114.23 billion,

the highest deficit in eight years.

Economists are predicting a

stronger import surge in the months ahead, partly because of the
dollar's strength and because of weakened export demand from our
industrial trading partners.
For this reason, I believe we need to continue the path of
moderate to strong growth, growth that allows for job creation and




58
wage enhancement.

The trade deficit not only indicates that our

economy is importing to enhance productive capacity relative to our
trading partners;

but it also indicates that we are consuming

beyond our means.

Inevitably, a trade deficit the magnitude of

that which we reached last year will weaken our economic strength
and growth.

The deficit cannot go on indefinitely without negative

repercussions.
I

am

concerned,

too,

about

international

relationships, and the trend of the dollar.

currency

We seem never to hit

a level of dollar strength or weakness that is the "right" level
for everyone.

We hear criticism and concern from our trading

partners whether the dollar is rising or sinking against the yen,
mark or other currencies.
I also question why we in the U.S. are giving scant attention
to the impact of the Eurpean Union's path toward monetary union
with the single currency, the Euro.

We have heard little about the

potential impact of the Euro on the dollar and U.S. trade with the
EU.

This line of inquiry is not meddling in EU affairs;

it is

anticipating a major change in international monetary relationships
and how it will affect our own currency and economic transactions.
So, Mr. Chairman, in addition to your usual observations on
inflation and employment, I would welcome your comments on the
prospects

for controlling

the U.S. trade deficit, as well as

currency relationships with the yen and future Euro--in addition to
any stock market insights, of course,
(humphstm.ms)




59
Opening Statement of
Rep. Carolyn Maloney (D-NY)
March 5,1997 Humphrey-Hawkins Hearings
Thank you, Chairman Castle.
I welcome Chairman Greenspan to this important Humphrey-Hawkins hearing where Federal
Reserve policies can be openly discussed so that the public can better understand the nation's
central bank.
I want to thank you, Chairman Greenspan, for your March 3 response to questions I had asked
about the Alliance bill and the Fed's request to change the Expedited Funds Availability Act of
1987 so that banks could lengthen from two to three days the holding period for local checks
before consumers could access their funds.
About the Alliance bill — I sought your comments on the process and scope of granting
exceptions to Sections 23 A and 23B of the Federal Reserve Act — I gather you and I share a
similar conclusion that the bill's provisions as written do not provide adequate safety and
soundness protections for consumers. I look forward to working on these provisions to improve
them during the Committee's deliberations, and I am glad we agree on this point.
On the Federal Reserve's request to extend the hold period on local checks by one day, we still
differ. However, I think we can reach agreement on the shorter hold period for three-quarters of
the banks in the United States. In your letter you state:
"The Board's study indicated that 75 percent of banks provide better funds
availability than required for local checks."
Banks are doing a fantastic job of clearing checks and providing prompt credit to depositors.
Many banks are promoting electronic banking where customers can use their home computers to
initiate funds transfers that are cleared electronically. Since 1993 many banks have been offering
SWEEP accounts that allow business customers to use deposited funds in less than one day.




(more)

60

So I would suggest that the central bank encourage the remaining 25 percent of banks to utilize
new and faster check clearing methods. This cannot be done as rapidly as possible if the central
bank continues to heavily subsidize the use of paper checks. I have received information that the
Federal Reserve heavily subsidizes its Interdistrict Transportation System which supervises 47
airplanes the Fed uses each night to clear paper checks. These subsidies slow down the process of
utilizing the latest technology in transferring funds and prevent private banks from fully
competing with the Fed on a level playing field to provide check clearing services.
Chairman Greenspan, I look forward to working with you in resolving these issues.




61
BERNARD SANDERS

COMMITTEES;

MEMBER or CONGRESS

BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES

VERMONT, AT LARGE

GOVERNMENT REFORM AND OVERSIGHT

SHFNG

x (202> 225 6790

~

Congress of the United,
fupe of TEUpresentatioes
Washington, B£ 20515-4501

Statement of the Honorable Bernard Sanders
March 5,1997 Hearing on Monetary Policy
of the Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy
Mr. Greenspan:
Thank you very much for joining us today and for your presentation.
Mr. Greenspan. Like every other American, you have a political ideology and political
beliefs. According to newspaper reports, you have made campaign contributions to the political
campaigns of Jesse Helms, George Bush and Bob Dole, served on the committee to elect
President Reagan, and of course, worked as a key economic adviser for Presidents Nixon and
Ford. While I respect you for participating in the political process, I strongly disagree with your
views.
In 1985, as I understand it, you served as a consultant to many in the Savings and Loan
industry. According to Time magazine, you suffered your "greatest embarrassment in 1985 when,
as a private economist, [you] wrote letters to regulators and Congress endorsing Charles Keating
and his Lincoln Savings and Loan. Lincoln subsequently collapsed at a cost to taxpayers of $2.6
billion, and Keating landed in jail." You issued similar endorsements for 15 other S&Ls, 14 of
which eventually failed.
In your confirmation hearings one year ago, despite the fact that the minimum wage of
$4.25 had reached its lowest point in 40 years, you noted your opposition to raising the minimum
wage.
This January, you told the Senate Budget Committee that "the appropriate capital gains
tax rate is zero." Currently, many Senate Republicans are calling for a capital gains tax cut.
According to the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, 70% of the benefits of that tax cut
would go to households earning over $100,000 a year. And that proposal is much more limited
than what you have suggested.
Mr. Greenspan, I will grant you consistency in your support for trickle-down economics.
In your career up to today, it is clear that you have advocated tax and monetary policies which
benefit the richest Americans while, at the same time, your views reflect policies that come down
very hard on middle-income families, senior citizens, and the poor.
In 1983, you were appointed to chair the Social Security Commission. Under your
leadership, the highly regressive payroll tax was increased by about $200 billion a year. In
inflation-adjusted terms, this is often referred to as the largest tax increase in history, falling




62
disproportionately on working people because of the payroll tax ceiling which excludes most
income of the rich. At the same time, you strongly supported President Reagan's income tax cuts,
which reduced the contributions made by the wealthiest Americans.
Currently, you are a proponent of reducing the Consumer Price Index. As you know,
the CPI determines the cost of living increases upon which millions of senior citizens and others
depend. Yesterday, you told the Budget Committee that "The best available evidence suggests
that there is almost a 100 percent probability that we are overcompensating the average Social
Security recipient for increases in the cost of living."
Mr Greenspan, I am holding in my hand a study conducted over several years by
economists at the Bureau of Labor Statistics. This study suggests that, for our senior citizens
who spend disproportionately high amounts on health care, the CPI we use today may in fact be
too low an index, not too high. Given the controversy over the CPI among prominent
economists, I am surprised to hear you talk of "100 percent" clarity on the question.
Mr. Greenspan, as a public official, I talk to many senior citizens who live on seven or
eight thousand dollars a year. They tell me that a cut in the CPI would make it even harder than
today to pay for their health care needs, their heat, their food, and their housing.
What I would like to know from you, who throughout your career has advocated tax
breaks for the rich, is: Can you tell this committee the last time you sat in a public meeting with
low-income senior citizens and talked to them about how they are surviving on seven or eight
thousand dollars a year, and what a cut in the CPI of 100 dollars a year might mean?
And, my second question is: At a time when the richest people in this country are
becoming much richer, and we have seen a proliferation of millionaires and billionaires, why do
you think we should balance the budget on some of the most vulnerable people in this country low-income senior citizens - rather than asking the wealthy to pay their fair share of taxes.




63

Statement by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy




Committee on Banking and Financial Services
U.S. House of Representatives

March 5, 1997

64
I appreciate the opportunity to appear before this Committee
to present the Federal Reserve's semiannual report on monetary
policy.
The performance of the U.S. economy over the past year has
been quite favorable.

Real GDP growth picked up to more than

three percent over the four quarters of 1996, as the economyprogressed through its sixth year of expansion.

Employers added

more than two-and-a-half million workers to their payrolls in
1996, and the unemployment rate fell further.

Nominal wages and

salaries have increased faster than prices, meaning workers have
gained ground in real terms, reflecting the benefits of rising
productivity.

Outside the food and energy sectors, increases in

consumer prices actually have continued to edge lower, with core
CPI inflation only 2-1/2 percent over the past twelve months.
Low inflation last year was both a symptom and a cause of
the good economy.

It was symptomatic of the balance and solidity

of the expansion and the evident absence of major strains on
resources.

At the same time, continued low levels of inflation

and inflation expectations have been a key support for healthy
economic performance.

They have helped to create a financial and

economic environment conducive to strong capital spending and
longer-range planning generally, and so to sustained economic
expansion.

Consequently, the Federal Open Market Committee

(FOMC) believes it is crucial to keep inflation contained in the
near term and ultimately to move toward price stability.
Looking ahead, the members of the FOMC expect inflation to
remain low and the economy to grow appreciably further.




However,

65
2
as I shall be discussing, the unusually good inflation
performance of recent years seems to owe in large part to some
temporary factors/ of uncertain longevity.

Thus/ the FOMC

continues to see the distribution of inflation risks skewed to
the upside and must remain especially alert to the possible
emergence of imbalances in financial and product markets that
ultimately could endanger the maintenance of the low-inflation
environment.

Sustainable economic expansion for 1997 and beyond

depends on it.
For some/ the benign inflation outcome of 1996 might be
considered surprising, as resource utilization rates-particularly of labor—were in the neighborhood of those that
historically have been associated with building inflation
pressures.

To be sure, an acceleration in nominal labor

compensation, especially its wage component, became evident over
the past year.

But the rate of pay increase still was markedly

less than historical relationships with labor market conditions
would have predicted.

Atypical restraint on compensation

increases has been evident for a few years now and appears to be
mainly the consequence of greater worker insecurity.

In 1991, at

the bottom of the recession, a survey of workers at large firms
by International Survey Research Corporation indicated that 25
percent feared being laid off.

In 1996, despite the sharply

lower unemployment rate and the tighter labor market, the same
survey organization found that 46 percent were fearful of a job
layoff.




66
3
The reluctance of workers to leave their jobs to seek other
employment as the labor market tightened has provided further
evidence of such concern, as has the tendency toward longer labor
union contracts.
three years.

For many decades, contracts rarely exceeded

Today, one can point to five- and six-year

contracts—contracts that are commonly characterized by an
emphasis on job security and that involve only modest wage
increases.

The low level of work stoppages of recent years also

attests to concern about job security.
Thus, the willingness of workers in recent years to trade
off smaller increases in wages for greater job security seems to
be reasonably well documented.

The unanswered question is why

this insecurity persisted even as the labor market, by all
objective measures, tightened considerably.

One possibility may

lie in the rapid evolution of technologies in use in the work
place.

Technological change almost surely has been an important

impetus behind corporate restructuring and downsizing.

Also, it

contributes to the concern of workers that their job skills may
become inadequate.

No longer can one expect to obtain all of

one's lifetime job skills with a high-school or college diploma.
Indeed, continuing education is perceived to be increasingly
necessary to retain a job.

The more pressing need to update job

skills is doubtless also a factor in the marked expansion of onthe-job training programs, especially in technical areas, in many
of the nation's corporations.




67
4
Certainly, other factors have contributed to the softness in
compensation growth in the past few years.

The sharp

deceleration in health care costs, of course, is cited
frequently.

Another is the heightened pressure on firms and

their workers in industries that compete internationally.
Domestic deregulation has had similar effects on the intensity of
competitive forces in some industries.

In any event, although I

do not doubt that all these factors are relevant, I would be
surprised if they were nearly as important as job insecurity.
If heightened job insecurity is the most significant
explanation of the break with the past in recent years, then it
is important to recognize that, as I indicated in last February's
Humphrey-Hawkins testimony, suppressed wage cost growth as a
consequence of job insecurity can be carried only so far.

At

some point, the tradeoff of subdued wage growth for job security
has to come to an end.

In other words, the relatively modest

wage gains we have experienced are a temporary rather than a
lasting phenomenon because there is a limit to the value of
additional job security people are willing to acquire in exchange
for lesser increases in living standards.

Even if real wages

were to remain permanently on a lower upward track than otherwise
as a result of the greater sense of insecurity, the rate of
change of wages would revert at some point to a normal
relationship with inflation.
period will end.




The unknown is when this transition

68
5
Indeed, some recent evidence suggests that the labor markets
bear especially careful watching for signs that the return to
more normal patterns may be in process.

The Bureau of Labor

Statistics reports that people were somewhat more willing to quit
their jobs to seek other employment in January than previously.
The possibility that this reflects greater confidence by workers
accords with a recent further rise in the percent of households
responding to a Conference Board survey who perceive that job
availability is plentiful.

Of course, the job market has

continued to be quite good recently; employment in January
registered robust growth and initial claims for unemployment
insurance have been at a relatively low level of late.

Wages

rose faster in 1996 than in 1995 by most measures, perhaps also
raising questions about whether the transitional period of
unusually slow wage gains may be drawing to a close.
To be sure, the pickup in wage gains has not shown through
to underlying price inflation.

Increases in the core CPI, as

well as in several broader measures of prices, have stayed
subdued or even edged off further in recent months.

As best we

can judge, faster productivity growth last year meant that rising
compensation gains did not cause labor costs per unit of output
to increase any more rapidly.

Non-labor costs, which are roughly

a quarter of total consolidated costs of the nonfinancial
corporate sector, were little changed in 1996.
Owing in part to this subdued behavior of unit costs,
profits and rates of return on capital have risen to high levels.




69
6
As a consequence, businesses believe that, were they to raise
prices to boost profits further, competitors with already ample
profit margins would not follow suit; instead, they would use the
occasion to capture a greater market share.

This interplay is

doubtless a significant factor in the evident loss of pricing
power in American business.
Intensifying global competition also may be further
restraining domestic firms' ability to hike prices as well as
wages.

Clearly, the appreciation of the dollar on balance over

the past eighteen months or so, together with low inflation in
many of our trading partners, has resulted in a marked decline in
non-oil import prices that has helped to damp domestic inflation
pressures.

Yet it is important to emphasize that these

influences, too, would be holding down inflation only
temporarily; they represent a transition to a lower price level
than would otherwise prevail, not to a permanently lower rate of
inflation.
Against the background of all these considerations, the FOMC
has recognized the need to remain vigilant for signs of potentially inflationary imbalances that might, if not corrected
promptly, undermine our economic expansion.

The FOMC in fact has

signaled a state of heightened alert for possible policy
tightening since last July in its policy directives.
have also taken care not to act prematurely.

But, we

The FOMC refrained

from changing policy last summer, despite expectations of a
near-term policy firming by many financial market participants.




70

In light of the developments I've just discussed affecting wages
and prices, we thought inflation might well remain damped, and in
any case was unlikely to pick up very rapidly, in part because
the economic expansion appeared likely to slow to a more
sustainable pace.

In the event, inflation has remained quiescent

since then.
Given the lags with which monetary policy affects the
economy, however, we cannot rule out a situation in which a
preemptive policy tightening may become appropriate before any
sign of actual higher inflation becomes evident.

If the FOMC

were to implement such an action, it would be judging that the
risks to the economic expansion of waiting longer had increased
unduly and had begun to outweigh the advantages of waiting for
uncertainties to be reduced by the accumulation of more
information about economic trends.

Indeed, the hallmark of a

successful policy to foster sustainable economic growth is that
inflation does not rise.

I find it ironic that our actions in

1994-95 were criticized by some because inflation did not turn
upward.

That outcome, of course, was the intent of the

tightening, and I am satisfied that our actions then were both
necessary and effective, and helped to foster the continued
economic expansion.
To be sure, 1997 is not 1994.

The real federal funds rate

today is significantly higher than it was three years ago.

Then

we had just completed an extended period of monetary ease which
addressed the credit stringencies of the early 1990s, and with




71
8
the abatement of the credit crunch, the low real funds rate of
early 1994 was clearly incompatible with containing inflation and
sustaining growth going forward.

In February 1997, in contrast,

our concern is a matter of relative risks rather than of expected
outcomes.

The real funds rate, judging by core inflation, is

only slightly below its early 1995 peak for this cycle and might
be at a level that will promote continued non-inflationary
growth, especially considering the recent rise in the exchange
value of the dollar.

Nonetheless, we cannot be sure.

And the

risks of being wrong are clearly tilted to the upside.
I wish it were possible to lay out in advance exactly what
conditions have to prevail to portend a buildup of inflation
pressures or inflationary psychology.

However, the circumstances

that have been associated with increasing inflation in the past
have not followed a single pattern.

The processes have differed

from cycle to cycle, and what may have been a useful leading
indicator in one instance has given off misleading signals in
another.
I have already discussed the key role of labor market
developments in restraining inflation in the current cycle and
our careful monitoring of signs that the transition phase of
trading off lower real wages for greater job security might be
coming to a close.

As always, with resource utilization rates

high, we would need to watch closely a situation in which demand
was clearly unsustainable because it was producing escalating
pressures on resources, which could destabilize the economy.




And

72
9
we would need to be watchful that the progress we have made in
keeping inflation expectations damped was not eroding.

In

general/ though, our analysis will need to encompass all
potentially relevant information, from financial markets as well
as the economy, especially when some signals, like those in the
labor market, have not been following their established patterns.
The ongoing economic expansion to date has reinforced our
conviction about the importance of low inflation--and the
public's confidence in continued low inflation.

The economic

expansion almost surely would not have lasted nearly so long had
monetary policy supported an unsustainable acceleration of
spending that induced a buildup of inflationary imbalances.

The

Federal Reserve must not acquiesce in an upcreep in inflation,
for acceding to higher inflation would countenance an insidious
weakening of our chances for sustaining long-run economic growth.
Inflation interferes with the efficient allocation of resources
by confusing price signals, undercutting a focus on the longer
run, and distorting incentives.
This year overall inflation is anticipated to stay
restrained.

The central tendency of the forecasts made by the

Board members and Reserve Bank presidents has the increase in the
total CPI slipping back into a range of 2-3/4 to 3 percent over
the four quarters of the year.

This slight falloff from last

year's pace is expected to owe in part to a slower rise in food
prices as some of last year's supply limitations ease.

More

importantly, world oil supplies are projected by most analysts to




73
10

increase relative to world oil demand, and futures markets
project a further decline in prices, at least in the near term.
The recent and prospective declines in crude oil prices not only
should affect retail gasoline and home heating oil prices but
also should relieve inflation pressures through lower prices for
other petroleum products, which are imbedded in the economy's
underlying cost structure.

Nonetheless, the trend in inflation

rates in the core CPI and in broader price measures may be
somewhat less favorable than in recent years.

A continued tight

labor market, whose influence on costs would be augmented by the
scheduled increase in the minimum wage later in the year and
perhaps by higher growth of benefits now that considerable
health-care savings already have been realized, could put upward
pressure on core inflation. Moreover, the effects of the sharp
rise in the dollar over the last eighteen months in pushing down
import prices are likely to ebb over coming quarters.
The unemployment rate, according to Board members and Bank
presidents, should stay around 5-1/4 to 5-1/2 percent through the
fourth quarter, consistent with their projections of measured
real GDP growth of 2 to 2-1/4 percent over the four quarters of
the year.

Such a growth rate would represent some downshifting

in output expansion from that of last year.

The projected

moderation of growth likely would reflect several influences: (1)
declines in real federal government purchases should be exerting
a modest degree of restraint on overall demand; (2) the lagged
effects of the increase in the exchange value of the dollar in




74
ii
recent months likely will damp U.S. net exports somewhat this
year; and (3) residential construction is unlikely to repeat the
gains of 1996.

On the other hand, we do not see evidence of

widespread imbalances either in business inventories or in stocks
of equipment and consumer durables that would lead to a substantial cutback in spending.

And financial conditions overall

remain supportive; real interest rates are not high by historical
standards and credit is readily available from intermediaries and
in the market.
The usual uncertainties in the overall outlook are
especially focused on the behavior of consumers.

Consumption

should rise roughly in line with the projected moderate expansion
of disposable income, but both upside and downside risks are
present.
upbeat.

According to various surveys, sentiment is decidedly
Consumers have enjoyed healthy gains in their real

incomes along with the extraordinary stock-market driven rise in
their financial wealth over the last couple of years.

Indeed,

econometric models suggest that the more than $4 trillion rise in
equity values since late 1994 should have had a larger positive
influence on consumer spending than seems to have actually
occurred.
It is possible, however, that households have been reluctant
to spend much of their added wealth because they see a greater
need to keep it to support spending in retirement.

Many

households have expressed heightened concern about their
financial security in old age, which reportedly has led to




75
12

increased provision for retirement.

The results of a survey

conducted annually by the Roper Organization, which asks
individuals about their confidence in the Social Security system,
shows that between 1992 and 1996 the percent of respondents
expressing little or no confidence in the system jumped from
about 45 percent to more than 60 percent.
Moreover, consumer debt burdens are near historical highs,
while credit card delinquencies and personal bankruptcies have
risen sharply over the past year.

These circumstances may make

both borrowers and lenders a bit more cautious, damping spending.
In fact, we may be seeing both wealth and debt effects
already at work for different segments of the population, to an
approximately offsetting extent.

Saving out of current income by

households in the upper income quintile, who own nearly threefourths of all non-pension equities held by households, evidently
has declined in recent years.

At the same time, the use of

credit for purchases appears to have leveled off after a sharp
runup from 1993 to 1996, perhaps because some households are
becoming debt constrained and, as a result, are curtailing their
spending.
The Federal Reserve will be weighing these influences as it
endeavors to help extend the current period of sustained growth.
Participants in financial markets seem to believe that in the
current benign environment the FOMC will succeed indefinitely.
There is no evidence, however, that the business cycle has been
repealed.




Another recession will doubtless occur some day owing

76
13

to circumstances that could not be, or at least were not,
perceived by policymakers and financial market participants
alike.

History demonstrates that participants in financial

markets are susceptible to waves of optimism, which can in turn
foster a general process of asset-price inflation that can feed
through into markets for goods and services.

Excessive optimism

sows the seeds of its own reversal in the form of imbalances that
tend to grow over time.

When unwarranted expectations ultimately

are not realized, the unwinding of these financial excesses can
act to amplify a downturn in economic activity, much as they can
amplify the upswing.

As you know, last December I put the

question this way: "...how do we know when irrational exuberance
has unduly escalated asset values, which then become subject to
unexpected and prolonged contractions ...?"
We have not been able, as yet, to provide a satisfying
answer to this question, but there are reasons in the current
environment to keep this question on the table.

Clearly, when

people are exposed to long periods of relative economic
tranquility, they seem inevitably prone to complacency about the
future.

This is understandable.

We have had fifteen years of

economic expansion interrupted by only one recession--and that
was six years ago.

As the memory of such past events fades, it

naturally seems ever less sensible to keep up one's guard against
an adverse event in the future.

Thus, it should come as no

surprise that, after such a long period of balanced expansion,




77
14

risk premiums for advancing funds to businesses in virtually all
financial markets have declined to near-record lows.
Is it possible that there is something fundamentally new
about this current period that would warrant such complacency?
Yes, it is possible.

Markets may have become more efficient,

competition is more global, and information technology has
doubtless enhanced the stability of business operations.

But,

regrettably, history is strewn with visions of such "new eras"
that, in the end, have proven to be a mirage.

In short, history

counsels caution.
Such caution seems especially warranted with regard to the
sharp rise in equity prices during the past two years.

These

gains have obviously raised questions of sustainability.
Analytically, current stock-price valuations at prevailing longterm interest rates could be justified by very strong earnings
growth expectations.

In fact, the long-term earnings projections

of financial analysts have been marked up noticeably over the
last year and seem to imply very high earnings growth and
continued rising profit margins, at a time when such margins are
already up appreciably from their depressed levels of five years
ago.

It could be argued that, although margins are the highest

in a generation, they are still below those that prevailed in the
1960s.

Nonetheless, further increases in these margins would

evidently require continued restraint on costs: labor compensation continuing to grow at its current pace and productivity
growth picking up.




Neither, of course, can be ruled out.

But we

78
15
should keep in mind that, at these relatively low long-term
interest rates, small changes in long-term earnings expectations
could have outsized impacts on equity prices.
Caution also seems warranted by the narrow yield spreads
that suggest perceptions of low risk, possibly unrealistically
low risk.

Considerable optimism about the ability of businesses

to sustain this current healthy financial condition seems, as I
indicated earlier, to be influencing the setting of risk
premiums, not just in the stock market but throughout the
financial system.

This optimistic attitude has become especially

evident in quality spreads on high-yield corporate bonds--what we
used to call "junk bonds."

In addition, banks have continued to

ease terms and standards on business loans, and margins on many
of these loans are now quite thin.

Many banks are pulling back a

little from consumer credit card lending as losses exceed
expectations.

Nonetheless, some bank and nonbank lenders have

been expanding aggressively into the home equity loan market and
so-called "subprime" auto lending, although recent problems in
the latter may already be introducing a sense of caution.
Why should the central bank be concerned about the possibility that financial markets may be overestimating returns or
mispricing risk?

It is not that we have a firm view that equity

prices are necessarily excessive right now or risk spreads
patently too low.

Our goal is to contribute as best we can to

the highest possible growth of income and wealth over time, and
we would be pleased if the favorable economic environment




79
16

projected in markets actually comes to pass.

Rather, the FOMC

has to be sensitive to indications of even slowly building
imbalances, whatever their source, that, by fostering the
emergence of inflation pressures, would ultimately threaten
healthy economic expansion.
Unfortunately, because the monetary aggregates were subject
to an episode of aberrant behavioral patterns in the early 1990s,
they are likely to be of only limited help in making this
judgment.

For three decades starting in the early 1960s, the

public's demand for the broader monetary aggregates, especially
M2, was reasonably predictable.

In the intermediate term, M2

velocity—nominal income divided by the stock of M2--tended to
vary directly with the difference between money market yields and
the return on M2 assets — that is, with its short-term opportunity
cost.

In the long run, as adjustments in deposit rates caused

the opportunity cost to revert to an equilibrium, M2 velocity
also tended to return to an associated stable equilibrium level.
For several years in the early 1990s, however, the velocities of
M2 and M3 exhibited persisting upward shifts that departed
markedly from these historical patterns.
In the last two to three years, velocity patterns seem to
have returned to those historical relationships, after allowing
for a presumed permanent upward shift in the levels of velocity.
Even so, given the abnormal velocity behavior during the early
1990s, FOMC members continue to see considerable uncertainty in
the relationship of broad money to opportunity costs and nominal




80
17
income.

Concern about the possibility of aberrant behavior has

made the FOMC hesitant to upgrade the role of these measures in
monetary policy.
Against this background, at its February meeting, the FOMC
reaffirmed the provisional ranges set last July for money and
debt growth this year:

1 to 5 percent for M2, 2 to 6 percent for

M3, and 3 to 7 percent for the debt of domestic nonfinancial
sectors.

The M2 and M3 ranges again are designed to be consis-

tent with the FOMC's long-run goal of price stability:

For, if

the velocities of the broader monetary aggregates were to
continue behaving as they did before 1990, then money growth
around the middle portions of the ranges would be consistent with
noninflationary, sustainable economic expansion.

But, even with

such velocity behavior this year, when inflation is expected to
still be higher than is consistent with our long-run objective of
reasonable price stability, the broader aggregates could well
grow around the upper bounds of these ranges.

The debt aggregate

probably will expand around the middle of its range this
year.
I will conclude on the same upbeat note about the U.S.
economy with which I began.

Although a central banker's

occupational responsibility is to stay on the lookout for
trouble, even I must admit that our economic prospects in general
are quite favorable.

The flexibility of our market system and

the vibrancy of our private sector remain examples for the whole
world to emulate.

The Federal Reserve will endeavor to do its

part by continuing to foster a monetary framework under which our
citizens can prosper to the fullest possible extent.




81

For use at 10:00 a.m., E.S.T.
Wednesday
February 26,1997

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Monetary Policy Report to the Congress
Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978

February 26, 1997




82

Letter of Transmittal

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Washington, D.C., February 26,1997
THE PRESIDENT OF THE SENATE
THE SPEAKER OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely,

Alan Greenspan, Chairman




83
Table of Contents
Page
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook

1

Section 2:

*




Economic and Financial Developments in 1996 and Early 1997

84
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook
The economy performed impressively this past
year, and members of the Board of Governors and
Reserve Bank presidents anticipate that 1997 will
bring further appreciable economic expansion with
relatively low inflation. In 1996, solid advances in the
real expenditures of households and businesses led to
sizable gains in output. Employment rose briskly, and
the unemployment rate edged down to its lowest level
of the current expansion. Consumer price inflation
increased owing to the likely temporary effects
of firmness in food and energy markets, but some
broader price measures showed inflation holding
steady or even declining. With the economy strengthening, intermediate- and long-term interest rates rose
on net, but credit continued to be amply available to
businesses and most households, and equity prices
Several factors helped to restrain price increases
this past year in the face of high levels of resource
utilizatioa With workers still concerned to some
degree about job security, acceleration in hourly
compensation was not so pronounced as in
comparable periods in the past; wage increases picked
up relatively moderately, and further success in
controlling health care costs helped to temper the rise
in benefits. Moreover, significant declines in the
prices of U.S. imports, owing to low inflation abroad
and appreciation of the dollar on foreign exchange
markets, tended to hold down domestic prices.
Damped inflation expectations probably contributed
as well to the favorable price performance: A lengthening run of years during which inflation has been in
a more moderate range, together with an understanding of the Federal Reserve's commitment to maintaining progress toward price stability, may have
discouraged aggressive pricing behavior. Business
firms continued to rely on cost control and gains in
productivity, rather than on price increases, as the
primary channels for achieving profit growth.
Still, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
recognized the danger that pressures emanating from
the tight labor market might trigger an acceleration of
prices, which could eventually undermine the ongoing economic expansion. Consequently, although
conditions last year were not deemed to warrant immediate policy action, the Committee's policy directives starting in mid-1996 reflected a perception that
the most likely direction of any policy action would
be toward greater restraint in the provision of reserves
to the banking system. Forestalling a disruptive




buildup of inflationary pressures in the near term and
moving toward price stability over time remain
central to the System's mission of promoting
maximum sustainable growth of employment and
production.

Monetary Policy, Financial Markets, and
the Economy in 1996
The FOMC eased the stance of monetary policy
twice around the beginning of last year—in December 1995 and in January—lowering the federal funds
rate Vi percentage point in total, to SVi percent
These actions were taken to offset the effect on the
level of the real federal funds rate of declines in inflation and inflation expectations in the second half of
1995 and thereby to help ensure the resumption
of moderate economic growth after the marked
slowdown and inventory correction in late 1995. By
the spring, economic growth had become more vigorous than either the Committee or financial markets
had foreseen. In response, intermediate- and longerterm interest rates as of mid-May were up around
a full percentage point from the two-year lows
reached early in the year. In combination with some
softening of economic activity abroad and declines in
interest rates in major foreign industrial countries,
these developments contributed to a further appreciation of the dollar, building on the rise that had
started in mid-1995. The Committee anticipated that
the increase in the cost of credit, along with the
higher exchange value of the dollar, would be sufficient to foster a downshift in economic expansion to
a more sustainable pace and contain price pressures;
thus, it left its policy stance unchanged at its spring
meetings.
By early summer, however, the continued
momentum in demand and pressures on labor
resources that were being reflected in faster growth in
wages were seen as posing a threat of increased inflation. Core inflation remained moderate, but in light
of the heightened risk that it would turn upward, the
Committee in its early July directive to the Manager
of the Open Market Account indicated its view that
near-term economic developments were more likely
to lead to a tightening of policy than to an easing.
Labor markets continued to be taut over the balance
of the year, and this bias toward restraint was
included in directives adopted at all of the Committee's remaining meetings in 1996.

85
Selected Interest Rates
Daily

7/6

8/22 9/26

11/1512/19 1/31/96

3/26

1996

6/21
1996

7/3

11/1312/17

2/5/97

1997

Note. Dotted vertical lines indicate days on which the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC) announced a monetary policy

action. The dates on the horizontal axis are those on which the
FOMC held scheduled meetings.

After peaking during mid-summer, interest rates
moved down on balance through the fall, as expansion of consumer spending and economic activity
in general appeared to be moderating and markets
saw less likelihood of a need for Federal Reserve
finning action. Equity prices fell back for a time during the summer, reversing some of the substantial
increase registered over the first half of the year, but
by autumn they had reached new highs. Interest rates
and dollar exchange rates turned back up late in the
year when signs of rapid growth and more intense use
of the economy's resources reemerged. Since yearend, interest rates have changed little, on net. The foreign exchange value of the dollar has posted further
gains, in part reflecting greater-than-expected weakness in Europe and renewed pessimism about economic and financial prospects in Japan. Equity prices
have registered new highs since the start of the year.
As of mid-February, intermediate- and long-term
interest rates were up about ¥z to 3/4 percentage point,
on balance, since early 1996, and the value of the dollar was up around 9 percent against an average of
other G-10 currencies.

some degree by an easing of lending terms at banks
and a narrowing of yield spreads on corporate bonds
over Treasuries, as well as by declines in the cost
of capital in the equity market. Encouraged, perhaps,
by the prospects of sustained economic expansion
and low inflation, banks, market lenders, and equity
investors displayed a strong appetite for business
obligations and seemed willing to require less compensation for the possible risks entailed. Some households, by contrast, faced a tightening of standards and
terms with respect to credit card debt and some other
types of consumer debt last year, as banks reacted to
a rising volume of delinquencies and charge-offs on
these instruments. However, credit availability under
home equity lines increased, particularly from finance
companies but also from banks. Overall debt growth
slowed slightly but remained near the midpoint of its
3 percent to 7 percent monitoring range. The growth
rates of M2 and M3 edged up last year and, as was
anticipated in the monetary policy reports to the
Congress last February and July, both aggregates
ended 1996 near or above the upper end of their
growth ranges. Again last year, the growth of M2
relative to nominal income and interest rates was
generally in line with historical relationships, in
contrast to its behavior during the early years of the
decade.

For the nonfinancial business sector, the effect of
the higher intermediate- and long-term interest rates
on the overall cost of funds last year was offset to




86
Economic Projections for 1997
Percent

Federal Reserve governors
and Reserve Bank presidents
Indicator

Range

Central
tendency

4V4to5V 4

4V2 to 4%

Administration

Change, fourth quarter
to fourth quartet
Nominal GDP

Real GDP2
Consumer price index*

4.6

2to2 1 / 2
2% to 31/fe

2to2 1 /4
2% to 3

2.0
2.6

51A to 5V£>

51A to 51/2

5.4

Average level, fourth quarter
Civilian unemployment

rate

1. Change from average for fourth quarter of 1996 to average for fourth quarter of 1997.

Economic Projections for 1997
With the economy free of serious imbalances,
prospects appear favorable for further growth of
activity and expansion of job opportunities in the
coming year, although resource constraints seem
likely to keep the pace of growth below that of 1996.
The central tendency of the GDP growth forecasts put
forth by members of the Board of Governors and
the Reserve Bank presidents is from 2 percent to
2V4 percent, measured as the change in real output
between the final quarter of 1996 and the final quarter
of 1997. Output growth of this magnitude is expected
to result in little change in the civilian unemployment rate, which is projected to be between
5V4 percent and 5Vj. percent in the fourth quarter
of this year. These forecasts of GDP growth and
unemployment are similar to those of the Administration. The central tendency of the policymakers' CPI
forecasts for 1997 spans the relatively narrow interval
of 23/4 percent to 3 percent, with the lower bound near
the inflation forecast of the Administration.
Consumer spending, which accounts for about twothirds of total GDP, should be supported in coming
quarters by further gains in income and the
substantial increase in household net worth that has
occurred over the past two years; debt problems,
although rising of late, do not seem to be so widespread as to threaten the ongoing expansion of household expenditures in the aggregate. In the business
sector, balance sheets are strong, profits have been




2. Chain-weighted
3. Alt urban consumers.

rising, and efforts to bolster efficiency through the use
of technologically advanced equipment are continuing at an intense pace. In the commercial real estate
market, the supply-demand balance has shifted in
many locales to a point at which interest in office
building projects has picked up noticeably. These
conditions, together with the ready access to a wide
variety of sources of finance that businesses currently are enjoying, should keep investment spending on an upward trajectory. Foreign demand for U.S.
products should continue to rise with growth of the
world economy, even in the wake of the significant
appreciation of the dollar since the first half of 1995;
however, imports also seem likely to remain on a
clear upward trend, given the prospects for continued expansion of the U.S. economy. Government
expenditures for consumption and investment probably will follow recent trends, with further cutbacks
in real outlays at the federal level and moderate
increases in the combined purchases of state and local
governments.
Although the risk of increased inflation pressures is
significant, especially in view of the tightness of the
labor market and the strength in activity that has been
evident recently, Federal Reserve policymakers
expect this year's rise in the consumer price index to
be somewhat smaller than that of 1996. The major
reason for expecting a smaller CPI increase this year
is a more favorable outlook for food and energy
prices. Prices of farm products have dropped back
from the highs of last summer, and, barring further

87
Ranges for Growth of Monetary and Debt Aggregates
Percent

1995

1996

1997

M2

1 to 5

1 to 5

1 to 5

M3

2 to 6

2 to 6

2 to 6

Debt

3 to 7

3 to 7

3 to 7

Aggregate

Note. Change from average for fourth quarter of preceding year to average for fourth quarter of year indicated.

weather problems, this year's rise in food prices at
retail should be considerably smaller than that of
1996. Oil prices have recently declined and seem
likely to ease further in coming months as world
production and consumption come back into better
balance; this price relief is important not only because
of the direct effects on the price of gasoline and other
consumer energy items but also because petroleum
is a major element in the cost of producing and
distributing many other goods. By contrast to the
favorable outlook for food and energy prices, some
risk exists that core inflation could turn up during the
coming year. The minimum wage will be moving up
further in 1997, compounding whatever cost pressures might be in train as a result of labor market
tightness, and the degree to which businesses can
continue to absorb stepped-up increases in labor costs
without raising prices more rapidly is not certain.
As noted in the July 1996 monetary policy report,
the CPI forecasts of the governors and Reserve Bank
presidents incorporate allowances for the technical
improvements to this index that have been made
by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. These technical
changes are estimated to have trimmed the reported
rate of CPI inflation slightly in each of the past two
years, and additional changes will be affecting the rise
in the index in 1997. In view of the remaining difficulties of accurately measuring price change in a
highly complex and rapidly changing economy,
alternative price indexes will continue to be given
substantial weight, along with the CPI, in monitoring progress toward the long-run goal of price stability. Some of the broad measures of inflation derived
from the GDP accounts slowed in 1996; the Committee is concerned that, even if the CPI decelerates as
expected in 1997, other indexes—with different scope
and weights—may pick up in reflection of the pressures on productive resources.




Money and Debt Ranges for 1997
Again in 1997, the Committee has set ranges for
M2 and M3 that would encompass monetary growth
expected to be consistent with approximate price
stability and a sustainable rate of real economic
growth, assuming that the behavior of velocity is
in line with historical norms. These ranges are
unchanged from those for 1996:1 to 5 percent for M2
and 2 to 6 percent for M3.
As has been the case for several years, the 1997
ranges for M2 and M3 were set against a backdrop of
uncertainty about the stability and predictability of
their velocities. A long-run pattern of reasonably
stable velocity behavior broke down in the early
1990s when the public's holdings of monetary assets
were depressed by several factors: the contraction
of the thrift industry; a tightening of credit supplies
and deleveraging by businesses and households;
an extremely wide spread between short- and
intermediate-term interest rates that heightened the
attractiveness of capital market instruments relative to
bank deposits; and the expanding availability and
growing acceptance of stock and bond mutual funds
as household investments.
With the waning of all but the last of these influences, movements in velocity have become more
predictable over the past couple of years. This recent
evidence of stability, however, covers only a relatively brief period, and its durability remains uncertain. In these circumstances, the Committee has opted
to continue treating the ranges as benchmarks for
the trends of money growth consistent with price
stability rather than as short-run targets for policy.
Meanwhile, the actual behavior of the monetary
measures will be monitored for such information
as it may convey about underlying economic
developments.

88
The central tendency of the Committee's expectations for nominal GDP growth in 1997 is slightly
below that registered in 1996. Thus, if velocity
behaves as it did last year, M2 and M3 might decelerate a bit but even so would again expand around the




upper ends of their growth ranges. Debt of the
nonfinancial sectors is anticipated to increase this
year at around the pace of last year, remaining near
the midpoint of its unchanged 3 to 7 percent range,

89
Section 2: Economic and Financial Developments
in 1996 and Early 1997
The economy turned in a remarkably favorable
performance this past year. Preliminary estimates
indicate that real GDP rose more than 3 percent over
the four quarters of 1996, one of the larger gains
of the past several years and appreciably more than
the FOMC was expecting a year ago. Although
intermediate- and long-term interest rates moved up,
credit remained readily available to most borrowers,
and equity prices rose substantially. Expansion of the
debt of nonfinancial sectors continued at about the
5 percent rate it has maintained over the past several
years, and growth of the stock of money picked up
a little to its most rapid pace this decade. These
financial developments provided support for strong
advances in the real expenditures of households and
businesses, and the growth of exports held up well
in the face of an appreciating dollar. Tightness of
the labor market led to a moderate pickup in wage
increases in 19%. However, acceleration of prices
was confined largely to the food and energy sectors;
prices for other consumer products decelerated, as
did prices paid by businesses for capital goods and
materials. Economic data for early 1997 show the
unemployment rate holding in a low range with the
inflation trend still subdued.

23/4 percent in 1996. Although debt problems arose
with greater frequency this past year, households
benefited from healthy increases in real income and
another year of sizable gains in wealth. Consumers
were relatively optimistic about prospects for the
economy at the start of 1996, and they became more
so as the year progressed.

Change in Real GDP

Real outlays for consumer durables rose more than
5 percent in 1996 after a gain of only IV* percent
during 1995. As has been true for many years, real
expenditures on computers and electronic equipment
outpaced the growth of other household outlays by a
wide margin in 1996. Sizable increases were also
reported for most other types of consumer durables.
However, real expenditures on vehicles changed little
on net over the year, as gains achieved during the first
half were reversed after mid-year. Late in 1996, sales
of light vehicles may have been constrained to some
degree by supply shortages that arose during strikes
in the United States and Canada; early in 1997, vehicle sales strengthened. Consumer purchases of nondurables rose !3/4 percent in 1996 after increasing
1 percent during 1995. Spending for services rose
2J/2 percent last year, about the same as the average
gain in previous years of the expansion.

Percent annual rate

101 J
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

Economic Developments
The Household Sector
After rising less than 2 percent in 1995, real
personal consumption expenditures moved up




Change in Real Income and Consumption
Percent annual rate

[] Disposable personal income
| Personal consumption expenditures

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

After-tax personal income increased 5 percent in
nominal terms over the four quarters of last year.
Wages and salaries rose briskly, and the income of
farm proprietors surged. Other types of income generally exhibited moderate gains. Given the low level of

90
price inflation, the rise in nominal income translated
into another significant advance in real disposable
income—about 23/4 percent over the year.
As in 1995, strong cross-currents continued to
shape individual households' willingness—and
ability—to spend from current\ income. Huge
increases in stock market wealth provided some
households the wherewithal to boosispending at a
pace considerably faster than the growth of disposable income. But a number of households\were likely
held back by the need to divert income to the servicing of debt, and according to some survey evidence,
households have become more concerned about saving for retirement. Responding to these influences, the
annual average of the personal saving rate was up
slightly from that of 1995; however, it remained
relatively low compared with its longer-run average.
Residential investment expenditures posted a gain
of 4 percent in real terms over the four quarters of
1996, more than reversing a small decline in the
previous year. Demand for single-family housing was
especially strong. Although interest rates on longerterm fixed-rate mortgage loans moved up considerably in 1996, a substantial number of homebuyers
side-stepped at least the initial costs by using
adjustable-rate loans that were available at lower
rates. The effects of the rate increases on the singlefamily market were cushioned by other influences as
well, most notably the growth of employment and
income. Even for fixed-rate loans, mortgage financing costs held at a level that, by historical standards,
was low relative to household incomes. All told, sales
of new homes surged to the highest annual total of
the current expansion, and sales of existing homes
established a historical high. New construction of
single-family dwellings also rose but not so dramatically as sales, as builders apparently chose to work
off some of their inventories of unsold units, which
had climbed in 1995. Mild sluggishness in starts
toward the end of 1996—which was probably
exacerbated by poor weather in December—was followed by more upbeat indicators of new construction in January of this year.
Construction of multifamily units maintained a
path of recovery from the extreme lows of the early
1990s, moving up about 13 percent in terms of annual
totals. The number of multifamily units started—
about 315,000—was double the number started in
1993, when construction of these units was at a low.
However, compared with previous peaks, the 1996
total was less impressive—starts were twice as high
in some years of the 1970s and 1980s. Although




Private Housing Starts
Millions of units, annual rate

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

market conditions for multifamily properties varied
considerably from city to city in 19%, the national
average vacancy rate for multifamily rental units
remained relatively high, and demographic influences were probably less supportive of multifamily
housing than they were a decade or so ago. Also,
manufactured houses have provided an increased
number of families with an alternative to rental apartments in recent years.
The Business Sector
Business fixed investment recorded a fifth consecutive year of strong expansion in 1996, rising about
9 percent according to the initial estimate. As in other
recent years, investment was driven by rising profits,
favorable trends in the cost of capital, and the ongoing efforts of businesses to boost efficiency. Although
Change in Real Business Fixed Investment
Percent annual rate

1991

1992

1993 1994 1995 1996

91
much of the investment spending was to replace depreciated equipment, the net addition to the aggregate
capital stock appears to have been substantial. The
rate of rise in the stock has picked up over the past
two or three years after subpar growth through the
latter half of the 1980s and first few years of the
1990s; the resulting rise in the level of capital per
worker should enhance labor productivity and
potential output
Equipment outlays moved up almost 9l/z percent in
real terms in 1996. Business purchases of office and
computing equipment once again rose much faster
than the outlays for other types of equipment
Computer purchases were propelled by many of the
same forces that have been at work in other recent
years—most particularly, the expansion of networks
and the availability of new models of computers
embodying substantially improved computing power
at highly attractive prices. Outlays for communications equipment also rose quite rapidly in 1996. Gains
for other types of equipment were generally more
modest.
Investment in nonresidential structures also rose
substantially over the four quarters of 1996, posting
the largest advance in several years. Business spending on structures went through an extended contraction in the latter part of the 1980s and early 1990s,
and until recently, the subsequent recovery has been
relatively slow. That the 1996 gain in nonresidential
investment would be so large was not evident until
late in the year, when incoming data began to trace
out sizable increases in new construction for many
types of buildings. Investment in office buildings
scored an especially large gain over the year, amid
widespread reports of fuming market conditions and
reduced vacancy rates, and real outlays for other commercial structures moved up for a fifth consecutive
year. Financing appears to be in ample supply for
commercial construction, and according to reports
from the District Reserve Banks, speculative office
building projects—that is, those without precommitted tenants—are becoming more common.
Inventory investment was relatively subdued in
1996. The stock of nonfarm business inventories rose
less than 2 percent over the four quarters of the year,
the smallest increase since 1992. Businesses had been
moving toward a reduced rate of stockpiling over
much of 1995, and the rate of accumulation came
almost to a halt in early 1996, when stocks of motor
vehicles plummeted in conjunction with a strike at
two plants that manufacture auto parts. Thereafter,
inventory developments were relatively uneventful.




Change in Real Nonfarm Business Inventories
Percent annual rate

jl
1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

Stocks of vehicles changed little on net over the final
three quarters of the year, and accumulation of inventories by other nonfarm businesses was moderate on
average. Stocks at year-end generally appeared to be
at comfortable levels relative to recent trends in sales.
Business profits turned in another strong
performance in 1996. Economic profits of all U.S.
corporations rose at an annual rate of more than
10 percent from the final quarter of 1995 to the third
quarter of 1996. Profits earned by foreign subsidiaries of U.S. corporations fluctuated from quarter
to quarter but remained at high levels, and returns
from domestic operations rose substantially, for both
financial and nonfinancial firms. Domestic profits of

Before-Tax Profit Share of GDP
Percent
Nonfinancial corporations

i
1984

i

i

i

i

1987

1990

i

i

1993

i

i

i

1996

Note. Profits from domestic operations with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, dvided by gross
domestic product of nonfinancial corporate sector.

92
nonfinancial corporations amounted to 10.7 percent of
the nominal value of these firms' output in the third
quarter, the highest reading of the current expansioa
The Government Sector

est since 1979. Legislative restraint has led to cuts in
a number of discretionary programs in recent years,
and the expanding economy has relieved pressure on
those outlays that tend to vary inversely with the
strength of activity.

Real federal expenditures on consumption and
gross investment—the part of federal spending that is
included in GDP—rose about 2J/2 percent, on net,
from the fourth quarter of 1995 to the fourth quarter
of 1996, but the rise was mostly an artifact of late1995 real purchases having been pushed to especially low levels by government shutdowns. The
underlying trend of federal consumption and investment expenditures probably is better represented by
the 2V2 percent annual rate of decline from the fourth
quarter of 1994 to the final quarter of 1996. Reductions have been apparent over the past two years both
in real defense purchases and in real nondefense
purchases.

Federal receipts increased about 7V2 percent in fiscal 1996, the third year in which growth of receipts
outpaced growth of nominal GDP by a significant
margin. Receipts from individual income taxes
climbed more than 11 percent in the most recent
fiscal year, in conjunction with healthy increases in
households' taxable earnings from capital and labor.
Taxes on corporate profits also continued to rise
rapidly, more or less in step with the growth of business earnings. The rapid growth of receipts, coupled
with the restrained growth of expenditures, brought
the unified budget deficit down to $107 billion in fiscal 1996 from almost $165 billion in fiscal 1995. The
deficit as a share of nominal GDP was 1.4 percent,
the smallest in more than twenty years.

Change in Real Federal Expenditures
on Consumption and Investment

The aggregate consumption and investment
expenditures of state and local governments rose
J
2 /4 percent in real terms over 1996. This gain was
about the same as those of the two previous years.
Outlays for services, which consist mainly of
employee compensation and account for more than
two-thirds of all state and local purchases, rose
roughly 1V4 percent in real terms last year. Investment expenditures, which make up the next biggest
portion of state and local purchases, rose about
4l/2 percent in real terms. In the aggregate, the budget
picture for state and local governments was relatively
stable in 1996, as the surplus of nominal receipts over

Percent, Q4 to Q4

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

Federal expenditures in the unified budget
increased about 3 percent in nominal terms in fiscal
1996 after having increased 33/4 percent in fiscal
1995. Slower growth was recorded across many
budgetary categories this past year, and outright
declines were reported in some. Combined expenditures on health, social insurance, and income
security—items that account for more than half of all
federal outlays—moved up 4V4 percent, the smallest
increase this decade. Defense spending was down
about 21A percent in nominal terms, and net interest
outlays rose much less rapidly than in fiscal 1995.
Measured relative to the size of nominal GDP, total
outlays in the most recent fiscal year were the small-




Change in Real State and Local Expenditures
on Consumption and Investment
Percent, Q4 to Q4

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

93
nominal current expenditures changed little from the
positive readings of other recent years.
The External Sector
The nominal trade deficit for goods and services
widened to $115 billion in 1996 from $105 billion the
previous year. For the first three quarters of the year,
the current account deficit totaled $165 billion at an
annual rate, somewhat greater than the $150 billion
deficit recorded in 1995.
U.S. Current Account
Billions of dollars, annual rate

250

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

The quantity of imports of goods and services rose
strongly over the four quarters of 1996—about
81/2 percent according to the preliminary estimate—
after expanding only 4J/4 percent the previous year.
The pickup in U.S. real output growth boosted the
Change in Real Imports and Exports
of Goods and Services
Percent, Q4 to Q4

demand for imported goods, as did the declines in the
prices of non-oil imports. Sizable increases in import
volume were widespread among most major
merchandise trade categories, with the notable exceptions of oil and semiconductors.
Very strong export growth in the fourth quarter of
1996 raised the yearly gain in the quantity of exports
of goods and services to IVi percent. Growth in the
economies of our major trading partners was only
moderate on average but was somewhat faster than
in 1995. As a consequence, growth of exports was
similar to the 1995 rate despite the appreciation of the
dollar. Over the past year, most of the rise in the value
of merchandise exports went to Canada and Latin
America. Exports to Western Europe and Asia were
only marginally higher than they were a year earlier.
In most of the major industrial countries abroad,
real economic activity accelerated last year from a
relatively weak performance in 1995. In the United
Kingdom, real output growth firmed through the year,
as growth in consumption spending rebounded from
its low 1995 rate. In Germany and France, real GDP
growth strengthened but was still too low to prevent
a further rise in the unemployment rate in both
countries. In Italy, output growth slowed as the
rebound in the lira from its previous depreciation
sharply reduced the growth of exports and depressed
investment spending. For most continental European
countries, further fiscal restraint is planned this year
as governments hoping to participate in the third
stage of European Monetary Union strive to meet the
Maastricht Treaty's 1997 reference standard of a
budget deficit no larger than 3 percent of GDP. In
Japan, fiscal stimulus spurred economic expansion
early last year, subsequently, slower private consumption, reduced inventory accumulation, and decreased
government investment spending reduced output
growth. In contrast, Canada's real output growth rose
over 1996 as inventory adjustment was completed
during the first half of the year and as exports
strengthened.
Except in the United Kingdom, inflation pressures
in the foreign industrial countries continued to decline
or remained subdued during 1996. Consumer prices
in Japan were flat. Consumer price inflation fell
sharply in Italy and remained below 2 percent in
Germany and France. In the United Kingdom,
consumer prices excluding mortgage interest payments accelerated to an annual rate of more than
3 percent.

1991

1992




1993

1994

1995

1996

The Mexican economy continued on a course of
recovery that returned GDP to its pre-crisis level

94
in the fourth quarter of 1996. Increases in income and
a strengthening of the price-adjusted value of the
peso contributed to a reduction in the Mexican
merchandise trade surplus over 1996. Argentina and
Brazil also continued to recover from recessions. In
Chile, real GDP growth moderated from the very high
rate recorded in 1995 to about 6 percent in 1996. In
Venezuela, windfall oil revenues softened the decline
in real GDP in 1996 and improved the prospects for
1997.
In our major trading partners in Asia other than
Japan, real output growth generally slowed from its
1995 pace, despite a pickup in many countries toward
year-end in response to more accommodative monetary policies and a partial recovery in export markets.
In China, the slowdown of growth to about 10 percent
last year from the 12 to 14 percent annual rates
experienced during 1992-94 reflected a substantial
deceleration in investment spending, owing to
China's efforts to reduce inflation by tightening
central bank credit to state-owned enterprises and by
restricting investment.
Consumer price inflation in Mexico was around
28 percent in 1996, significantly lower than the 1995
inflation rate of over 50 percent. Venezuela's inflation rate in 1996 exceeded 100 percent, but inflation
in most other Latin American countries was at levels
well under 10 percent. Inflation rates generally
remained low in Asia.
The Labor Market
The number of jobs on nonfarm payrolls rose more
than 2V2 million from December 1995 to December
1996, an increase of about 2Vi percent. Employment
Net Change in Payroll Employment
Thousands of jobs, average monthly change
Total nonfarm

400

200

11
1990

200
1992




1994

1996

gains were substantial in each quarter last year, and
the labor market report for January of this year
showed a further sizable expansion of payrolls.
Employment in the private service-producing sector, in which nearly two-thirds of all nonfarm workers are employed, increased about 3 percent during
1996. Moderate employment gains were posted in
retail trade, transportation, and finance, and sizable
gains in hiring continued in some other serviceproducing industries, such as data processing, computer services, and engineering and management. Job
growth at suppliers of personnel—a category that
includes temporary help agencies—was about
6V2 percent, a touch faster than in 1995 but much
slower than it had been over 1992-94; with the
tightening of labor markets in the past couple of
years, longer-lasting commitments in hiring may
have come back into greater favor among some
employers.
Employment changes among producers of goods
were mixed in 1996. In construction, employment
climbed about SVz percent, to a new high that was
almost 4 percent above the peak of the last business
expansioa In manufacturing, increases in factory jobs
through the latter part of 19% were not sufficient to
reverse declines that had taken place earlier in the
year. On net, last year's loss of factory jobs amounted
to about */2 percent, a shade less than the average rate
of decline since 1979, the year in which manufacturing employment peaked. Manufacturers of durable
goods boosted employment slightly last year, but
many producers of nondurables implemented further
job cuts. As in many other recent years, reductions in
factory employment were accompanied by strong
gains in worker productivity. Consequently, increases
in output were sizable—the rise in the Federal
Reserve's index of manufacturing production
cumulated to 4V4 percent over the year.
Growth of output per hour in the nonfarm business sector as a whole picked up in 1996, rising about
P/4 percent over the year according to preliminary
data. However, coming after a three-year period in
which output per hour changed little, this rise left the
average rate of productivity growth in the 1990s a bit
below that of the 1980s and well below the average
gains achieved in the first three decades after World
War II. The sustained sluggishness in measured
productivity growth this decade is difficult to explain,
as it has occurred during a period when high levels of
investment in new capital and extensive restructuring of business operations should have been boosting the efficiency of workers. Of course, measure-

95
Change in Output per Hour
Percent, Q4 to Q4

I
1990

1992

1994

1996

Note. Nonfarm business sector.

ment problems could be distorting the data. As a
summary measure that relates aggregate output to
aggregate input of labor, the nonfann productivity
index is affected by whatever deficiencies might be
present either in adding up the nominal expenditures
for goods and services in the economy or adjusting
those expenditures for price change. A considerable
amount of recent research suggests that growth of
output and productivity is in fact understated, but
whether the degree of understatement has been
increasing over time is less clear.

accompanied by a sustained pickup in the labor force
participation rate. The rise in participation boosted the
labor supply and helped to relieve pressures on the
labor market. Nonetheless, hiring during 1996 was
sufficient to reduce the civilian unemployment rate
from a December 1995 rate of 5.6 percent to a
December 1996 rate of 5.3 percent. In January of this
year, the rate remained low, at 5.4 percent.
Tightness of the labor market appears to have
exerted some upward pressure on the cost of labor
in 1996, even as some workers continued to express
anxiety about job security. The employment cost
index (ECI) for the private nonfarm sector of the
economy showed compensation per hour moving
up 3.1 percent over the year. The index had risen
2.6 percent in 1995. The step-up in hourly pay
increases was to some extent the result of a hike in
the minimum wage that took place at the start of
October. More generally, however, businesses probably had to boost hourly compensation either to
attract workers or to retain them at a time when
alternative employment opportunities were perceived
to be more widely available.
Change in Employment Cost Index
Percent, Dec. to Dec.

Hourly compensation

In contrast to the experience of most other recent
years, this past year's rise in employment was

Civilian Unemployment Rate

1990

1992

1994

1996

Note. Private industry excluding farm and household workers.

1990

1992

1994

1996

Note. The break in data at January 1994 marks the introduction of a redesigned survey; data from that point on are not
directly comparable with the data of earlier periods.




As in 1995, increases in hourly compensation in
1996 came more as wage and salary increases than as
increases in fringe benefits. According to the ECI, the
rise in wage rates for workers in the nonfarm sector
amounted to nearly 3Vz percent this past year after
a rise of 23A percent in 1995. By contrast, the ECI
measure of the hourly cost of benefits rose only
2 percent, slightly less than it did in 1995 and much
less than it rose on average over the past decade.
Increases in the cost of benefits have been held down

96
in recent years by reduced inflation for medical services and by the actions that many firms have taken to
shift employees into managed care arrangements and
to require them to assume a greater portion of the cost
of health insurance and other medical benefits.

Change in Consumer Prices
Percent, Q4 to Q4

Prices
The consumer price index rose more rapidly than
in 1995, but the step-up was concentrated in the food
and energy sectors—areas in which prices were
affected by supply limitations that seemed likely to be
of temporary duratioa The CPI excluding food and
energy—often called the "core" CPI—rose just a
touch more than 2 V± percent after increasing 3 percent
during 1995. Both the total CPI and the core CPI
have been affected in the past two years by technical improvements implemented by the Bureau of
Labor Statistics that are aimed at obtaining more
accurate readings of price change; the rise in the CPI
in 1996 would have been somewhat greater if
procedures used through 1994 had not been altered.
Other price indexes generally rose less rapidly than
the CPI. Like the overall CPI, the chain type price
index for personal consumption expenditures (PCE)
accelerated somewhat in 1996, but its rate of rise,
shown in the accompanying table, was significantly
lower than that of the CPI. The two measures of consumer prices differ to some degree in their weights
and methods of aggregatioa They also differ some-

1990

Mini
1992

1994

1996

Note. Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

what in their selection of price data, with the PCE
measure relying on alternative data in some areas in
which the accuracy of the CPI has been questioned.
The chain type price index for gross domestic purchases, which takes account of the prices paid by
businesses and governments as well as those paid by
consumers, moved up 2J/4 percent during 1996, about
the same as the percentage rise during 1995. By contrast, price measures associated with GDP decelerated in 1996 to thirty-year lows of around 2 percent
or less. Conceptually, the GDP measures are indica-

Altemative Measures of Price Change
Percent

1995

1996

Fixed weight
Consumer price index
Excluding food and energy

2.7
3.0

3.2
2.6

Chain type
Personal consumption expenditures
Excluding food and energy
Gross domestic purchases
Gross domestic product

2.1
2.3
2.3
2.5

2.5
2.0
2.2

2.5

1.8

Price measure

2.1

Deflator

Gross domestic product

Note. Changes are based on quarterly averages and are measured to the fourth quarter of the year
indicated from the fourth quarter of the previous year.




97
tive of price changes for goods and services that are
produced domestically rather than price changes for
goods and services purchased domestically—foreign
trade accounting for the difference.
The 1996 outcomes for all these measures reflected
an economy in which inflation pressures were muted.
Sharp declines in non-oil import prices during the
year lowered input costs for many domestic firms and
likely caused other firms to restrain their product
prices for fear of losing market share to foreign
competitors. Also important, in all likelihood, were
the favorable imprints that several years of moderate and relatively stable rates of inflation have left on
inflation expectations. Despite the uptick in hourly
compensation and adverse developments in the food
and energy sectors, survey data showed little change
in consumers' expectations of inflation, and private
forecasters' views of the prospects for prices held
steady. Businesses commonly described the situation
as one in which competitive pressures were intense
and the "leverage" for raising prices simply was not
present.

Change in Consumer Prices Excluding
Food and Energy
Percent, Q4 to Q4

1990

Inn i
1992

1994

1996

Note. Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

Food and energy prices were the exceptions. In the
food sector, steep increases in grain prices in 1995
and the first few months of 1996 caused production
adjustments among livestock farmers and substantial
price increases for some livestock products. Later in
the year, grain prices fell back, but livestock production could not recover in time to prevent significant
price advances for some retail foods. Consumer
prices for pork, poultry, and dairy products registered
their largest increases in several years. Retail beef




prices also rose but only moderately: Expansion of
the cattle herd in previous years had laid the
groundwork for a high flow of product to consumers, and herd reductions that occurred in 1996
augmented that flow. Elsewhere in the food sector,
acceleration was reported in the price index for food
away from home—a category that has a weight of
almost 40 percent in the CPI for food; the rise in
the minimum wage appears to have been an important
factor in the acceleration. All told, the 1996 rise in
CPI food prices amounted to 41A percent, the largest increase since 1990.
The energy sector was the other major part of the
economy in which significant inflation pressures were
evident this past year. Crude oil prices, which had
started firming in the latter part of 1995, continued on
an upward course through much of 19%, rising more
than 30 percent in total. Stocks of crude oil and
petroleum products were tight during the year, even
after allowing for an apparent downward trend in
firms' desired inventories. Inventory building was forestalled by production disruptions at refineries, a string
of weather problems here and abroad that boosted
fuel requirements for heating or cooling, and a reluctance of firms to take on inventories that seemed
likely to fall in value once renewed supplies from Iraq
became available. Natural gas, too, was in tight supply at times, and its price surged. With retail prices of
gasoline, fuel oil, and natural gas all moving up
substantially, the CPI for energy rose about
7Vz percent over the four quarters of 1996, the largest increase since the Gulf War.
The CPI for goods other than food and energy rose
1 percent during 1996, one of the smallest increases
of recent decades. As in 1995, price increases for new
vehicles were moderate last year, and prices of used
cars turned down after several years of sizable
advances. Prices of apparel and house furnishings
also fell; these prices, as well as the prices of vehicles, may have been heavily affected by the softness
of import prices. Moderate increases were the rule
among most other categories of goods in the CPI. In
the producer price index, prices of capital equipment rose less than ¥2 percent over 1996; computer
prices continued to plunge, and the prices of other
types of equipment rose moderately, on balance.
Materials prices were weak: Prices of intermediate
materials excluding food and energy declined about
1V4 percent from the fourth quarter of 1995 to the
final quarter of 1996, and the producer price index for
crude materials excluding food and energy dropped
more than 6l/z percent over that period. Productive
capacity was adequate among domestic producers

98
of materials, and supplies of many materials were
readily available at competitive prices on the world
market.
The CPI for non-energy services increased
3/4 percent in 1996. The rise was somewhat smaller
than the increases of most other recent years. Prices
of medical services decelerated for a sixth consecutive year, and increases in the cost of shelter were
held down by another year of moderate advances in
residential rent and owners' equivalent rent Large
increases were evident only in scattered categories:
Airfares posted a large increase, and educational
costs, maintaining a long-established trend, continued
to rise quite rapidly relative to prices in general.

Financial Developments

Debt
Growth of the debt of nonfinancial sectors slowed
slightly last year, to 5Y4 percent. The growth of
household sector debt dropped from 8/4 percent to
7/2 percent, a deceleration accounted for entirely by
a sharp slowing of consumer credit. The expansion
of business borrowing was held below its 1995 pace
by an increase in internally generated funds, but
at 5/4 percent, it was faster than in any other year
since 1989. Its strength reflected robust spending,
extremely favorable credit conditions, and financing
needs associated with a high level of mergers
and acquisitions. Federal government debt grew
33/4 percent, the lowest rate in more than two decades.
The debt outstanding of the state and local sectors
was unchanged.

Debt: Annual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

Domestic nonfinancial sectors
14800
14600
14400
14200
14000
13800
O N D J F M A M J J A S O N O
1995
1996




13600

The Household Sector. Consumer credit grew
8l/4 percent last year, just a bit over half the pace of
the preceding two years. The sharp retrenchment
likely reflected the burdens associated with a
substantial accumulation of outstanding consumer
debt over recent years as well as some tightening of
lending terms and standards by commercial banks,
particularly with respect to credit cards.
The slowing in consumer credit growth also was
associated with a shift toward increased use of home
equity loans. These loans were marketed vigorously,
particularly by finance companies, in part as a vehicle for consolidating credit card and other outstanding consumer debt Some of the growth in home
equity loans reflected moves by finance companies
and banks into the sub-prime market—lending either
to higher-risk customers or on terms entailing unusually high loan-to-value ratios, or both. The push to
expand home equity lending last year offset to some
degree the effect of tighter lending standards and
terms on credit cards and other forms of consumer
credit
The shift toward home equity loans, along with a
strong housing market, led to a pickup in mortgage
debt growth last year to a rate of 7/2 percent, the
largest advance since 1990. Mortgage borrowing for
home purchases was restrained surprisingly little by
the increase in interest rates over the first half of the
year. As noted previously, many borrowers were able
to put off, at least for a time, much of the impact of
the increase in rates by shifting to adjustable-rate
mortgages, the rates on which rose much less last
year than those on fixed-rate mortgages.
Although the growth of household sector debt fell
off a bit from the pace of recent years, it still
exceeded that of disposable income. With loan rates
up on average for mortgages and down only a little on
consumer loans, debt service burdens continued to
rise last year, and some households experienced difficulties servicing certain kinds of debt Delinquency
rates on banks' consumer loans, particularly credit
card loans, posted a second year of considerable
increase, although they remained below levels in
the early 1990s. At finance companies that are subsidiaries of automakers, auto loan delinquency rates
rose to very high levels; but this rise apparently
resulted in large part from a business strategy to
compete in the vehicle market by easing lending
standards. Auto loan delinquency rates at commercial banks also rose but remained well within
historical ranges. Delinquency rates on residential
mortgages remained low.

99
Household Debt Service Burden
Percent of disposable personal income

Quarterly

16

15

i

i

i

i

i

i

1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996

14

Note. Debt service is the sum of required interest and principal
payments on consumer and household-sector mortgage debt

In the segment of the finance company market that
deals in "sub-prime" auto loans, some problems
emerged last month. A small firm in this market
defaulted on its commercial paper after it restated
earlier earnings at lower levels, and another firm filed
for bankruptcy. Although the share prices of these and
other firms primarily engaged in sub-prime lending
declined along with their earnings outlook, this sector constitutes a very small part of the overall auto
loan market, and the implications for the availability
of credit to the household sector overall appear slight
Charge-off rates on consumer loans rose at banks
in 1996 to around the peak levels of the last recession in 1990-91. According to Federal Reserve surveys of senior loan officers, banks had anticipated
Delinquency Rates on Household Loans
Percent
Quarterly

i i i i i i i i i i i i
1980

1984




1992

1996

some deterioration in the quality of their consumer
loan portfolios last year, but they were surprised by
its extent. These surveys also showed that banks
considered the rate of charge-offs last year to be high
relative to the level of delinquencies and that the
credit-scoring models most banks use to evaluate
consumer lending decisions have tended to be too
optimistic. An important reason for the high level
of charge-ofTs and the apparent shortcomings of the
credit-scoring models was a 30 percent increase in
personal bankruptcies. This surge stemmed in part
from changes in the bankruptcy code that became
effective at the beginning of last year against a
backdrop of an apparently reduced stigma associated with this method of dealing with financial
problems. Banks responded to the deterioration in
their consumer loan portfolios by tightening standards
and terms, especially on credit cards. In contrast,
banks eased terms and conditions on home equity
loans.
Despite the rise in delinquencies on consumer debt,
household balance sheets appear healthy overall, as
growth of household assets over the past two years
has more than kept pace with the growth of debt.
Although year-end balance sheet figures are not yet
complete, the net worth of households appears to
have risen approximately $5 trillion from the end of
1994 to the end of 1996, an amount that is equal to
almost a full year's personal disposable income.
Roughly two-thirds of that gain has been accounted
for by the surge in the prices of corporate shares,
which has lifted the value of a wide range of household investments, not only directly held stocks but
also assets held in other forms such as pension plans.
The ratio of household net worth to personal disposable income continued to climb this past year, moving to its highest level in recent decades.
The Business Sector. Although many interest
rates rose last year, businesses continued to find credit
readily available and at favorable terms. This accommodation likely resulted in part from the strong financial condition of this sector, reflected in minimal
delinquency rates on bank loans to businesses and
very low default rates on corporate bonds, including
those of low-rated issuers. With securitization of
household debt instruments proceeding apace and
with high levels of capital, banks appeared to have
ample room on their balance sheets for business
loans. This situation encouraged the development of a
highly competitive lending environment in which
banks further eased a variety of credit terms, such as
covenants and markups over base rates. In capital
markets, interest rate spreads of private debt instru-

100
ments over Treasuries narrowed, particularly in the
case of high-yield bonds. Surveys by the National
Federation of Independent Business revealed a rising tendency of small businesses to borrow over
1996, with credit availability reported to be in a range
more favorable than at any time in the current economic expansion.
On a gross basis, a pickup in bond issuance by
nonfinancial firms last year was accounted for mainly
by speculative-grade offerings, likely in part a reaction to the improved pricing. In the fourth quarter,
however, investment-grade issuance was substantial,
responding to the decline in interest rates that began
in late summer. Commercial paper declined in the
final months of the year, primarily because of paydowns from bond proceeds, but bank lending to businesses was strong, owing in some part to robust
merger activity. Despite a marked increase in gross
stock issuance—with strong gains both for initial
public offerings and for seasoned offerings—equity
continued to be retired on net last year, as merger
activity remained brisk and businesses used ample
cash resources to repurchase their outstanding shares.
The Government Sector. The growth of federal debt was held down in 1996 by legislative
constraints on spending and by the boost to tax
receipts from both the stronger economy and a booming stock market. Two years of contraction of state
and local government debt ended last year. The
declines had occurred as issues that were prerefunded earlier in the decade, when interest rates
were unusually favorable, matured or became eligible
to be called. Pre-refunded debt continued to be called
last year, albeit at a reduced pace, but this decline was
just offset by gross issuance, which picked up.
Depository Intermediation. The expansion of
depository credit slowed last year, entirely reflecting a
slower advance in bank credit. Growth at thrift
institutions picked up, benefiting from strong demand
for residential mortgages and improved capital positions. Growth of commercial bank loans moderated,
as loans to businesses and, especially, consumers
decelerated from elevated rates of growth in 1995.
Bank portfolio expansion also appears to have been
damped somewhat by a faster pace of asset securitization, likely spurred by receptive capital markets. For
example, real estate loan growth at banks was a
subdued 4 percent last year, despite a robust housing market and a pickup in commercial real estate. At
the same time, outstanding securities backed by mortgage pools expanded at a $179 billion annual rate in
the first three quarters of last year, well above the




pace of 1995. Commercial banks are a major source
of securitized mortgages. The outstanding amount of
consumer credit that had been securitized by banks
also rose at a brisk pace last year, although not so
rapidly as in 1995. As a result of the slowing of bank
credit, the share of last year's advance in nonfederal
debt that ended up on the books of depositories fell to
about 38 percent, down from around 44 percent in the
preceding two years.
The balance sheets and operating results of depositories remained strong in 1996. Bank profits through
the third quarter were at historically high levels for
the fourth consecutive year, reflecting the maintenance of relatively wide interest rate margins,
further loan growth, and substantial fee income
related to sales of mutual funds as well as to securitization and other off-balance-sheet activities. As of
the third quarter, almost 99 percent of commercial
bank assets were held at banks classified as "well
capitalized." Underlying thrift profits were also
stronger last year. However, profits at thrift institutions and at banks with deposits insured by the Savings Association Insurance Fund (SAIF) were held
down temporarily by a special assessment on deposits to recapitalize SAIF. (Some bank deposits are
SAIF-insured because of mergers with thrifts or
acquisitions of them.)
The Monetary Aggregates

Despite the slowing of depository credit, growth of
the broader monetary aggregates strengthened last
yean M3 expanded 7 percent, up 1 percentage point
from 1995 and also 1 percentage point above the
upper end of its 2 to 6 percent annual range. M2 grew
M3: Annual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

4700

4600

O N D J F M A M J J A S O N O
1995

1996

4500

101
M2: Annual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

3850
3800
3750
3700
3650

O N O J F M A M J J A S O N D
1995

3600

1996

4Yi percent, up !/2 percentage point and in the upper
portion of its 1 to 5 percent range. As noted in Section 1, the ranges for monetary growth last year had
been chosen to be consistent with approximate price
stability and a sustainable rate of real economic
growth, rather than as indicators of the range of
money growth rates likely to prevail under expected
economic conditions.
The acceleration of M3 was caused partly by a shift
in the way banks financed their credit—specifically,

substituting issuance of large time deposits for
borrowings from offices abroad. Both foreign and
domestically chartered banks paid down net borrowing from foreign head offices and branches last year.
For domestic banks, this paydown may have been
related to the reduction to zero of insurance assessments on deposits, beginning with the last quarter of
1995. In addition, the greater growth of M3 relative to
that of M2 reflected the need to fund particularly
strong loan growth at U.S. branches and agencies of
foreign banks, which do not offer the retail accounts
that dominate deposits in M2.
Growth of both M2 and M3 was supported again
last year by continuing robust advances in money
market mutual funds (MMMFs). Because the yields
on these funds are based on the average return earned
on their assets, they lag changes in yields on new
market instruments; thus, the funds tend to attract
additional inflows when market rates are falling.
Accordingly, MMMFs advanced most rapidly in the
early part of last year, when the monetary casings of
December and January pulled down short-term rates,
and also later in the year, when short-term rates
were again declining. However, these instruments
expanded briskly even in the third quarter, when
short-term rates were rising, suggesting that part of
the attractiveness of MMMFs is the convenience they
offer those investors engaged in moving funds in and
out of stock and bond mutual funds, which expanded

M2 Velocity and the Opportunity Cost of Holding M2
Ratio scale

Percentage points, ratio scale

Quarterly
2.0
25

10

1.8

1978

1980

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

Note. M2 opportunity costis a two-quarter moving average of the three-month Treasury bill rate
less the weighted average rate paid on M2 components.




1994

1996

102
at a record pace last year. In addition, institutiononly funds seem to be having considerable success in
marketing cash management programs that capture
excess cash of corporations and municipalities. Likely
reflecting the attractiveness of money market and
capital market mutual funds last year, deposits in M2
actually showed little growth in 1996. Retail deposit
growth also may have been damped by a lack of
aggressive pricing of deposits on the part of banks, as
demand for their loans slipped and they apparently
found it cheaper to finance a larger share of loan
originations through securitizations and large time
deposits.
The behavior of M2 relative to income last year,
as summarized by its income velocity, again bore a
fairly systematic relationship to M2's opportunity
cost—the return on M2 assets relative to yields available on alternative instruments. The relationship of
velocity to opportunity costs was reasonably stable
historically, but it broke down in the early 1990s, a
period characterized by extensive restructuring of
balance sheets by households, businesses, and banks.
In the process, M2 velocity rose substantially and,
apparently, permanently. Since 1993, velocity no
longer appears to be shifting higher, and M2 velocity and opportunity costs are moving together about
as they did before 1990. However, the recent period
of relative stability in this relationship has been too
short for the Federal Reserve to place increased reliance on M2 as a guide to policy at this time.
Ml contracted 4Vi percent last year, as the pace at
which new arrangements were established to sweep
reservable retail transactions deposits to nonreservable nontransaction accounts accelerated. The initial
amounts removed from transaction accounts by
sweep arrangements established last year amounted
to $116 billion, compared with $45 billion in 1995.
Ml continued to be supported by currency growth
last year, when foreign demands, which were
depressed earlier in the year partly in anticipation of
the new $100 bill, picked up in the second half.
Adjusted for the initial amounts removed from
transaction accounts by sweep arrangements, Ml
grew 5V4 percent last year. The sweeping of transaction deposits contributed to a contraction of almost
12 percent in required reserves—twice the rate of
decline of the previous year. The monetary base
decelerated only a little, however, as growth of its
major component, currency, was little changed
between 1995 and 1996.

eral Reserve's ability to exert close day-to-day
control over the federal funds rate—the overnight rate
on reserves traded among depository institutions.
Depositories hold balances at Reserve Banks to meet
daily clearing needs in addition to satisfying statutory reserve requirements. At low enough levels,
reserve balances may provide inadequate protection
against adverse clearings, and banks' attempts to
avoid overdrafts could generate highly variable daily
demands for balances at the Federal Reserve and a
volatile federal funds rate. To date, however, no serious problems have emerged, in part because the
substantial drop in depositories' required reserve balances attributable to sweeps has been partially offset
by increases in their holdings of required clearing
balances—an arrangement whereby depositories pay
for services provided by the Federal Reserve through
the holding of specified amounts in reserve account
balances. In addition, advances in banks' techniques
of monitoring balances at the Federal Reserve and
gauging their clearing needs have enabled them to
operate efficiently and smoothly at relatively low
levels of balances. Sweeps have had an effect on Federal Reserve earnings and the amounts it remits to the
Treasury. The decline in reserve balances of around
$12 billion owing to sweeps must be matched by an
accompanying lower level of Treasury securities on
the books of Reserve Banks. The Federal Reserve
continues to monitor sweep activity closely.
Interest Rates, Equity Prices,
and Exchange Rates
Interest Rates. Declines in interest rates during
the second half of last year on evidence that ecoSelected Treasury Rates
Monthly

15
Thirty-year
Treasury*

1965

Continued declines in the levels of required
reserves have the potential to impinge on the Fed-




1975

1985

10

1995

•The twenty-year Treasury bond rate is shown until the first
issuance of the thirty-year Treasury bond in February 1977.

103
nomic growth had moderated only partially reversed
the increases over the first half. Reflecting the surprising strength in economic activity last year, longerterm Treasury rates rose on balance on the order of
V* percentage point over the year, and intermediate
rates were up somewhat more. Spreads between most
private rates and Treasuries narrowed markedly last
year, reflecting the high quality of business balance
sheets. Municipal rates moved up comparatively little
over the first half of 1996 as earlier relative increases
in these yields associated with discussions of
fundamental tax reform were reversed when the
likelihood of such changes to the tax code diminished. Movements in interest rates over the year
appeared to be basically in their real component, as
inflation expectations were little changed, according
to surveys.

Weighted Average Exchange Value
of the U.S. Dollar
Index, March 1973 = 100

Nominal

100

80

70

1991

Equity Prices. The substantial rise in equity
prices last year was only a bit below that registered in
1995. However, in contrast to 1995, when bond rates
declined substantially, the equity gains last year came
despite the net rise in bond rates. Corporate earnings were robust last year, but their advance fell short
of share price increases, and price-earnings ratios rose
to unusually high levels; dividend-price ratios were
even more out of line with historical experience.
Market participants appear to be anticipating further
robust earnings growth, and they also seem to be
requiring much less compensation for the extra risk of
holding equities compared to, say, Treasury bonds.
Such evaluations may be based on a perceived
environment of persisting low inflation and balanced economic growth that would lower the odds of
disruptions to economic activity. Other asset prices

Major Stock Price Indexes
Index (December 29,1995=100)

J FMAMJ JA3ONDJ FMAMJ JASONOJ F

1995




1996

1997

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996

Note. In terms of the currencies of the other G-10 countries.
Weights are based on 1972-76 global trade of each of the ten
countries.

were generally subdued. Commodity prices were flat
to down. Commercial real estate prices, although no
longer falling, rose at little more than the rate of
inflation. Residential real estate prices increased
moderately.
Exchange Rates. The foreign exchange value of
the dollar in terms of the currencies of the other G-10
countries rose about 4 percent during 1996. When
measured in terms of the currencies of a broader
group of U.S. trading partners and adjusted for differences in consumer price inflation, the appreciation of
the dollar last year was also about 4 percent Much of
the rise in the exchange value of the dollar occurred
during the first half of the year. Indications of greaterthan-expected underlying strength in the U.S. economy and signs of weakness in some European
economies in the first two quarters reinforced market
expectations that U.S. monetary policy was less likely
to be eased than was policy in the other industrial
countries. These expectations boosted U.S. longterm interest rates relative to those abroad and
contributed to upward pressure on the dollar. The dollar fluctuated somewhat from June through December but on balance changed little. Over the course of
1996, the dollar appreciated 12 percent in terms of the
yen and 73A percent in terms of the mark. During the
first weeks of 1997, the dollar's average value against
the G-10 currencies has again moved up, appreciating about 7 percent since the end of December,
as economic data have suggested additional strength
in the U.S. economy and have raised questions about

104
U.S. and Foreign Interest Rates

abroad have moved down slightly further so far this
year. Short-term market rates in the foreign industrial countries on average declined about 120 basis
points during 19%. Except in Japan, official central
bank lending rates were lowered in the foreign G-10
countries last year, contributing to the decline in
market rates.

Three-month
Monthly
Average foreign

Equity prices in most industrial countries rose
strongly last year. The major exception was Japan,
where prices on balance fell slightly. The general
decline in long-term interest rates abroad and moves
toward monetary ease were among the factors contributing to the upward movement in stock prices.

i

i

i

i i

Ten-year
Monthly

12
Average foreign

1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996
Note. Average foreign rates are the global trade-weighted
average, for the other G-10 countries, of yields on instruments
comparable to U.S. instruments shown.

the vigon of economic expansions in several foreign
industrial countries.
On average, yields on ten-year government securities in the major foreign industrial countries fell about
80 basis points last year, with most of the decline
coming in the second half. In Italy, long-term rates
declined much more, about 375 basis points, in
response to low growth in real output, substantial
progress in lowering inflation, and sizable, credible
measures to reduce the government deficit. In contrast, long-term rates in the United Kingdom rose
slightly as the economy strengthened. Rates in Japan
rose early in the year as the economy spurted, but
subsequent indicators of a weakening expansion
caused rates to turn back down; over the year, they
declined about 40 basis points on net. Long-term rates




The dollar appreciated in nominal terms about
2J/2 percent on balance against the Mexican peso during 1996, with much of that appreciation coming over
a few weeks in October. After fluctuating in a narrow range for most of the year, the Mexican peso
depreciated in terms of the dollar when market
participants became concerned about the loss of
competitiveness of Mexican exports during the year
and about the partial nature of the government's
planned privatization of the petrochemical industry.
Peso interest rates rose in October and November, but
have since more than retraced that increase as the
peso has stabilized. In January, Mexican officials
repaid all remaining outstanding obligations to the
Exchange Stabilization Fund of the U.S. Treasury,
completing repayment to the United States of all borrowings that were made following the peso crisis in
late 1994; a partial early repayment was made to the
International Monetary Fund as well.
In the first three quarters of 1996, large increases
were reported in both foreign ownership of assets in
the United States and U.S. ownership of assets
abroad. Over the same period, foreign official assets
in the United States increased almost $90 billion. Part
of this increase was associated with exchange market
intervention by the Japanese authorities to counter a
brief strengthening of the exchange value of the yen
early in the year, but a larger part reflected the repurchase of reserves by several European countries
whose currencies strengthened against the mark.
About half reflected increases in reserves of newly
industrializing countries.
Private foreigners also added substantially to their
assets in the United States in the first three quarters of
1996. Net purchases of U.S. Treasury securities by
private foreigners amounted to $85 billion through
September, and net purchases of corporate and
government agency bonds were equally large. Foreign direct investment in the United States surged to

105
a record $71 billion in the first three quarters, reflect- States, U.S. portfolio investors favored foreign stocks
ing numerous mergers and acquisitions of U.S. comover bonds. Net purchases in Japan were particularly
panics by foreigners.
large in the first half of the year. In addition, U.S.

1996. In contrast to foreign investors in the United




106
Growth of Money and Debt
Percent

Period

M1

M2

M3

7.5

9.6
12.4
9.7
9.5
10.8

Domestic
nonftnancial
debt

Annual

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984

8.8
10.3
5.4

8.7
9.0
8.8
11.8
8.1

1985
1986
1987
1988
1989

12.0
15.5
6.3
4.3
0.5

8.6
9.1
4.2
5.7
5.2

7.7
9.0
5.8
6.3
4.0

1990
1991
1992
1993
1994

4.1
7.9
14.4
10.6
2.5

4.1
3.1
1.8
1.3
0.6

1.8
1.2
0.6
1.1
1.7

6.9
4.6
4.7
5.1
5.2

1995
1996

-1.6
-4.6

4.0
4.6

6.2
6.9

5.5
5.3

-3.5
-1.4
-6.5
-7.4

5.3
4.5
3.4
5.0

6.6
6.3
5.4
8.5

5.0
5.7
5.3
4.9

5.4 (2.5)2

9.5
10.2

9.9
11.9
14.5
14.2
13.2
10.0

9.0
7.9

Quarterly
(annual rate)3

1996

Q1
Q2
03
04

1. From average for fourth quarter of preceding year to
average for fourth quarter of year indicated
2. Adjusted for shifts to NOW accounts in 1981.




3. From average for preceding quarter to average for
quarter indicated

23