View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
Report of the Federal Reserve Board pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978,
PX. 95-523
and The State of the Economy

HEARING
BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON
DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
OF THE

COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND
FINANCIAL SERVICES
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED FOURTH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION

FEBRUARY 20, 1996

Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking and Financial Services

Serial No. 104-43

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
22-798 CC

WASHINGTON : 1996
For sale by the U.S. Government Printing Office
Superintendent of Documents, Congressional Sales Office, Washington, DC 20402
I S B N 0-16-052868-2




HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES
JAMES A. LEACH, Iowa, Chairman
BILL MCCOLLUM, Florida, Vice Chairman
HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
DOUG BEREUTER, Nebraska
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota
TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin
RICHARD H. BAKER, Louisiana
CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York
BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
RICK LAZIO, New York
SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
MICHAEL CASTLE, Delaware
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York
PETER KING, New York
TOM CAMPBELL, California
MAXINE WATERS, California
EDWARD ROYCE, California
BILL ORTON, Utah
FRANK D. LUCAS, Oklahoma
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
JERRY WELLER, Illinois
LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois
J.D. HAYWORTH, Arizona
LUCILLE ROYBAL-ALLARD, California
JACK METCALF, Washington
THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin
SONNY BONO, California
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
ALBERT R. WYNN, Maryland
ROBERT NEY, Ohio
CLEO FIELDS, Louisiana
ROBERT L. EHRLICH, Maryland
BOB BARR, Georgia
MELVIN WATT, North Carolina
DICK CHRYSLER, Michigan
MAURICE HINCHEY, New York
FRANK CREMEANS, Ohio
GARY ACKERMAN, New York
JON FOX, Pennsylvania
KEN BENTSEN, Texas
FREDERICK HEINEMAN, North Carolina
JESSE L. JACKSON, JR., Illinois
STEVE STOCKMAN, Texas
CYNTHIA A. McKINNEY, Georgia
FRANK LOBIONDO, New Jersey
J.C. WATTS, Oklahoma
BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont
SUE W. KELLY, New York

SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY
MICHAEL CASTLE, Delaware, Chairman
EDWARD ROYCE, California, Vice Chairman
FRANK LUCAS, Oklahoma
FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York
JACK METCALF, Washington
BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
BOB BARR, Georgia
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
DICK CHRYSLER, Michigan
LUCILLE ROYBAL-ALLARD, California
FRANK LOBIONDO, New Jersey
THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin
J.C. WATTS, Oklahoma
CLEO FIELDS, Louisiana
SUE W. KELLY, New York
MELVIN WATT, North Carolina
ROBERT NEY, Ohio
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
JON FOX, Pennsylvania
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
TOM CAMPBELL, California
BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont




CONTENTS
Page

Hearing held on:
February 20, 1996
Appendix:
February 20, 1996

1
33
WITNESS
TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 20, 1996

Greenspan, Hon. Alan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System
APPENDIX
Prepared statements:
Castle, Hon. Michael N
LoBiondo, Hon. Frank A
Greenspan, Hon. Alan

34
36
38

ADDITIONAL MATERIAL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
Greenspan, Hon. Alan:
Biography
"Monetary Policy Report to the Congress"

55
56




(III)

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 20, 1996

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC AND
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICY,
COMMITTEE ON BANKING AND FINANCIAL SERVICES,
Washington, DC.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to call, at 2 p.m., in room 2128,
Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Michael N. Castle [chairman
of the subcommittee] presiding.
Present: Chairman Castle, Representative LoBiondo.
Also present: Representatives Leach and Hinchey.
Chairman CASTLE. The subcommittee will come to order.
This subcommittee is meeting today to once again receive the
semiannual report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on the conduct of monetary policy and the state of
the economy as mandated in the Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act of 1978, also known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
Chairman Greenspan, it is always a pleasure to welcome you to
the Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy
of the House Banking and Financial Services Committee, whicn
may be the longest name of any in Congress. We have fewer Members than usual because the House is in recess. Nevertheless, those
who are present look forward to our exchange. As usual, any prepared remarks submitted by Members will be accepted for the
record.
Since our last hearing 6 months ago, we have seen the Fed continue on its new course of gradually lowering interest rates. Currently, the U.S. economy is in its 60th month of economic expansion, approximately 10 months beyond the average expansion.
While we welcome continued expansion, concern tempers our enthusiasm. The economy is slowing to a growth rate of 1.4 percent
for the first three quarters of 1995; this growth rate is below Fed
targets. Pundits divide on whether the soft landing to slower
growth has been achieved or the economy is being pushed back into
recession. Some dispute whether the economy is softening too much
or, alternatively, we are merely experiencing a current inventory
draw-down cycle which will be succeeded by increased demand and
additional noninflationary growth. Interpreting the indicators at
these junctures is a chancy business, so we welcome your comments on what you see ahead with regard to inflationary pressures,
the international value of the dollar and the future of interest
rates, to name a couple of items.
(l)




As you know, there is increasing debate over whether the economy can grow faster than 2.5 percent a year without reigniting inflation. Strong economic growth creates jobs and higher incomes for
working Americans, but an overheated economy could lead to higher inflation. Inflation is bad for all Americans, but higher costs especially hurt those with low and moderate incomes. Anyone who remembers the double-digit inflation of the 1970's knows that we do
not want to return to those days. My view is that we should not
ignore the threat of inflation. However, while we are in a period
of low inflation, there is very real anxiety among many Americans
over corporate downsizing, wage stagnation, corporate expansion
overseas, and what these mean for the creation of new jobs. Every
government official must consider how to address these issues. Is
there more that can be done through monetary policy to spur
growth?
Since we are in an election year, the rhetoric over the issue of
balancing the budget is certain to be heated on both sides, but we
cannot overlook the fact that balancing the budget is a tremendously important goal that will impact the lives of every American.
You have spoken out on this subject, and the subcommittee would
like to hear your opinions on the impact of a balanced budget on
interest rates, the financial markets, the economy in general and
how these affect the lives of ordinary Americans.
The Humphrey-Hawkins Act of 1978 requires the Federal Reserve Board to report to Congress on its conduct of monetary policy
and the state of the economy. That is the reason for this hearing.
The Humphrey-Hawkins Act also sets goals for the Administration
and the Federal Reserve System to pursue that may be outdated,
inconsistent or conflicting. Most of the bill's mandates have been
more honored in the breach, especially those that apply to the Executive. To the extent that these inconsistent goals actually hamper the Fed's ability to optimize its operations, Congress may want
to revisit this legislative charter. We might then consider improvements or adjustments to your mandate that would make monetary
operations more effective. Specifically, should Humphrey-Hawkins
be reformed and narrowed to allow the Federal Reserve to concentrate on monetary policy and controlling inflation? Are the mandates in the act too broad? Congress will review these issues and
your comments on the proper role of the Federal Reserve will assist
Congress in this process.
Your chairmanship of the Federal Reserve continues to be
marked by unprecedented openness both with Congress and the
public. You have personally become a symbol of probity and stability that markets and the public look to for reassurance on the economy. We appreciate this and look forward to your timely reappointment although, let me hasten to add, it is beyond my jurisdiction
to so reappoint you.
We are prepared today for a lively discussion.
Because we have a limited number of Members, I thought I
would offer the others, if they wish to make opening statements,
to do so. I will turn first to the ranking Democrat Member today,
Mr. Hinchey.
Mr. HlNCHEY. Thank you very much.




Chairman Greenspan, welcome. It is always a great pleasure to
see you and to have the opportunity to listen to your words of wisdom with regard to the Nation's economy, particularly the activities
of the Fed as those activities are conducted under your stewardship
in a way that is designed to promote economic growth and, of
course, stable prices.
We have experienced, as the chairman has said, a period of almost unprecedented growth. I think there have been only a few
times in the recent history of the Nation's economy when the economy has grown at a steady rate for such a prolonged period of time.
We have almost become accustomed to new records in the stock
market being made almost every other day. Certainly that was true
within the last few weeks. This week it is going in the other direction somewhat, but it has moved steadily upward. That, of course,
is something that we all welcome and are very happy about.
However, the growth of the economy is not being shared by all
Americans equally. There are a great many people in this economy
who are being left behind and who look at the increase in the stock
market only with some form of wonder and amazement as to how
this can be happening, why should the economy be doing so well,
why do all the normal indicators indicate that the economy is doing
well while they are not doing well in their own personal lives, their
own economic circumstances.
Many people are being left behind. We are even hearing from
major business leaders that the downsizing in the economy is
something, obviously, that has affected large numbers of workers
who had formerly regarded themselves as being in very stable positions, but that downsizing is likely to continue. We are told by
some prominent business leaders, one in a recent speech in Washington, that perhaps fully one-third of those people employed in the
economic circumstances today can regard their jobs to be in jeopardy in the future. This of course is very, very disconcerting.
The Humphrey-Hawkins Act, which is the subject of this hearing
today particularly, stipulates that it is the responsibility of the
Federal Reserve Board to promote stable prices, to hold down inflation, but also to promote full employment. The promotion of full
employment is something that is increasingly on the minds of the
American people, on the minds of Members of Congress, and, I note
from the statements that are being made up in the State of New
Hampshire, increasingly on the minds of those people who would
be President of the United States.
So I would hope that in your remarks today, Mr. Chairman, that
you would address yourself to that aspect or the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, that which is designed to encourage the Federal Reserve
Board to promote full employment. It seems to me, and I think—
this is quite obvious—that we have two tools at our disposal. That
is the government and its agencies have two tools at their disposal
to promote economic growth, fiscal policy and monetary policy. Fiscal policy is in the hands of the Congress, but the Congress has in
recent years tied its hands, has reduced its ability to manipulate
fiscal policy in ways to promote economic growth. So therefore increasingly the American people have looked toward the Federal Reserve Board as an agency to try to promote economic growth and
developments.




I know that this has been on your mind particularly recently, I
presume, in that we have seen you recommend and the Federal Reserve Board follow a recommendation to reduce interest rates twice
in recent months. That has been encouraging to people because we
anticipate that that will improve economic conditions.
But we also believe that the economic growth that we are currently experiencing, which is below 2 percent, far below traditional
growth that we have become accustomed to since the Second World
War, that that growth of 2 percent is far too low and that we ought
to be doing something to promote additional growth beyond that.
Perhaps the interest rate increases that were occasioned by Federal
Reserve Board decisions back in 1994 and 1995 have something to
do with the fact that our economy is growing at such a low rate.
I would hope that you might direct yourself in your remarks to
those subjects as well.
Let me say again, welcome, and I am delighted to see you and
always interested in what you have to say.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you Mr. Hinchey.
Next we will turn to the chairman of the full Committee on
Banking and Financial Services. It is sort of like being a son and
being a principal and your father is a teacher in this circumstance.
Mr. Leach is my boss on the committee, and he would like to bring
words of welcome. Mr. Chairman.
Mr. LEACH. I thank Chairman Castle, at whose feet we sit today.
Let me just say, Mr. Chairman, that the policies of the Federal
Reserve Board should always be open to question. That is why we
have hearings of this nature. But the integrity and the independence of the Federal Reserve Board should always be above reproach, and in my judgment that is the circumstance we are dealing with.
So we welcome you at a time when we can probe your judgments
as well as reflect on the economy both in the past and, more importantly, in the immediate future. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. LoBiondo, I know, has a written statement but perhaps he
would like opening words.
Mr. LoBiONDO. Chairman Greenspan, I, too, would like to welcome you. I look forward to your remarks. We have a great deal
of concern for jobs and the economy and where we are going. I look
forward with anticipation to your comments today.
Chairman Castle, I would like to submit my remarks for the
record.
Chairman CASTLE. Without objection, your statement and those
of any Member of the subcommittee are more than welcome, and
we appreciate that. Thank you for your comments.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Frank A. LoBiondo can be
found on page 36 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Mr. Chairman, we have reached that time
which is on the mind of most people in this room, and that is for
you to review with us where we are vis-a-vis the Federal Reserve
pursuant to the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. We have before us a policy report and a statement. You are welcome to excerpt from that
or do as you please. We turn to you for your words of wisdom.




STATEMENT OF ALAN GREENSPAN, CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF
GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have indeed made
significant deletions in my prepared remarks but request, as usual,
that the total statement be included in the record.
Mr. Chairman, I, as always, appreciate the opportunity to appear
before this subcommittee to present the Federal Reserve's semiannual report on monetary policy.
The U.S. economy performed reasonably well in 1995. One and
three-quarter million new jobs were added to payrolls over the
year, and the unemployment rate was at the lowest sustained level
in 5 years. Despite the relatively high level of resource utilization,
inflation remained well contained with the consumer price index
rising less than 3 percent, the fifth year running at 3 percent or
below. A reduction in inflation expectations, together with anticipation of significant progress toward eliminating Federal budget deficits, was reflected in financial markets where long-term interest
rates dropped sharply and stock prices rose dramatically over the
year.
With inflation contained and inflation expectations dropping, the
Federal Reserve was able to ease monetary conditions twice in the
second half of the year. As we entered 1996, information becoming
available raised additional questions about the prospective pace of
expansion. The situation was difficult to judge, but several indicators appeared to signal some softening in the economy.
A number of factors have prompted the recent tendency toward
renewed weakness. Some are clearly transitory, related, tor example, to bad weather or the Federal Government shutdown. Others
may be somewhat more significant but still temporary. The constraint on government spending while permanent budget authorizations are being negotiated is one. Another may be a temporary
reduction in output in some industries as businesses have further
adjusted inventories to disappointing sales. As I noted last July,
the change in the pace of inventory investment when the economy
shifts gears can be substantial. Inventory investment surged in
1994 and into the early months of 1995 but proceeded to fall markedly throughout the rest of the year. This has placed significant
downward pressure on output, which should lift as inventory adjustments subside. But for the moment, the pressures remain, in
the motor vehicle industry and elsewhere.
Ultimately, of course, it is the path of final demand after the
temporary influences work themselves out that determines the trajectory of the economy. There are some factors, such as high
consumer debt levels, that may be working to restrain the spending. But as I shall be detailing shortly, a number of fundamentals
point to an economy basically on track for sustained growth, so any
weakness is likely to be temporary. Nonetheless, the subcommittee
decided in late January that the evidence suggested sufficient risk
of subpar performance going forward to warrant another slight easing of the stance of monetary policy. Given the subdued trends in
costs and wages, the odds that such a move would boost inflation
pressures seemed low.
In assessing the likely course of the economy and the appropriate
stance of policy, one question is the significance, if any, of the age




of the business expansion. Some analysts, viewing recent weakness, have observed that the expansion is approaching the start of
its sixth year and is now one of the longest peacetime spans of
growth in the past century, as you, Mr. Chairman, have pointed
out. Economic expansions, however, do not necessarily die of old
age. Although the factors governing each individual business cycle
are not always clear, expansions usually end because serious imbalances eventually develop.
When aggregate demand exceeds the economy's potential, for example, inflationary pressures pick up. The inevitable increase in
market interest rates, as inflation expectations rise and price pressures intensify, depresses final demand. Lagging demand in turn
sets off an inventory correction that frequently triggers a downturn
in the economy.
Capital expenditures by households and firms can also contribute
significantly to the development of cycle-ending imbalances. The
level of stocks of such real assets have effects on output very similar to those of business inventories. In typical cycles, capital expenditures tend to grow rapidly in the early stages of recovery.
Pent-up demands coming out of a recession by consumers and businesses are satisfied by rapid growth of spending on capital assets.
There is a limit, however, on, say, how many cars people choose to
own or how many square feet of floor space retailers need to service
customers. Spending on such assets generally tends to grow more
slowly after the pent-up demand is met. As with business inventories, the downshifting of spending on consumer durable goods or
business plant and equipment may not occur smoothly. The dynamics of expanding output and rising profit expectations often create
a degree of exuberance which, as in much of human nature, tends
on occasion to excess, in this case a form of a temporary overaccumulation of assets. The ensuing correction in demand for such
assets triggers production adjustments that can significantly mute
growth for a time or even cause a downturn if the imbalances are
large enough.
The current extent of any asset overhang is very difficult to determine. The growth of demand for durables in some categories of
capital goods evidently has slowed, but the available evidence does
not suggest a degree of saturation in capital assets which would tip
the economy into a downturn.
Moreover, financial conditions are likely to be generally supportive of spending. The low level of long-term interest rates should
have an especially favorable effect. In addition, with the condition
of most financial institutions strong, lenders are likely to remain
willing to extend credit to firms and households on favorable terms.
Against this backdrop, Federal Reserve policymakers expect the
most likely outcome for 1996 as a whole is further moderate
growth. The unemployment rate is expected to remain around current levels.
The Federal Open Market Committee also anticipates a continuation of reasonably good inflation performance in 1996. The success
during 1995 in keeping the increase in the Consumer Price Index
below 3 percent in the fifth year of an expansion illustrates that
an extended period of growth with low inflation is possible. Keeping inflation from rising significantly during economic expansions




will permit a gradual ratcheting down of inflation over the course
of successive business cycles that will eventually result in the
achievement of price stability.
Determining whether further changes in the stance of monetary
policy will be necessary in the months ahead to foster progress toward our goals will be a continuing challenge. In formulating monetary policy, while we have in mind a forecast of the most likely
outcome, we must also evaluate the consequences of other possible
developments. Thus it is sometimes the case that we take out monetary policy "insurance," so to speak, when we perceive an imbalance in the net costs or benefits of coming out on one side or the
other of the most probable scenario. For example, in our most recent actions, we saw a decline in the Federal funds rate as not increasing inflationary risks unacceptably while addressing the
downside risks to the most likely forecast. In assessing the costs
and benefits of adjustments to the stance of policy, Members of the
subcommittee recognize that policy affects the economy and inflation with a lag and thus needs to be formulated with a focus on
the future. Over the past year, we have kept firmly in mind pur
goals of containing inflation in the near term and moving over time
toward price stability, and they will continue to guide us in the period ahead.
Structural forces may be assisting us in this regard. Increases in
producers' costs and in output prices proved to be a little lower last
year than many had anticipated. While it is too soon to draw any
definitive conclusions, this experience provides some tentative evidence that basic ongoing changes in the structure of the economy
may be helping to hold down price increases. These changes stem
from the introduction of new technologies into a wide variety of
production processes throughout the economy.
The more rapid advance of information and communications
technology and the associated acceleration in the turnover of the
capital stock are being mirrored in a brisk restructuring of firms.
In line with their adoption of new organizational structures and
technologies, many enterprises are finding that their needs for various forms of labor are evolving just as quickly. Partly for that reason, most corporate restructurings have involved a significant number of permanent dismissals.
An important consequence of the layoffs and dismissals associated with restructuring activity is a significant and widely reported
increase in the sense of job insecurity. Concern about employment
has been manifested in unusually low levels of indicators of labor
unrest.
Of particular relevance to the inflation outlook, the sense of job
insecurity is having a pronounced effect in damping labor costs. For
example, the increase in the employment cost index for compensation in the private sector, which includes both wage and salary
payments and benefit costs, slowed further in 1995, to 2.75 percent,
despite labor market conditions that by historical standards were
fairly tight.
The more rapid pace of technological change is also reducing
business costs through other channels. Initially most important,
the downsizing of products resulting from semiconductor technologies together with the increasing proportion of national output




accounted for by high-tech products, has reduced costs of transporting the average unit of the gross domestic product. Quite simply,
small products can be moved more qfuickly and at lower cost.
More recently, dramatic advances in telecommunications technologies have lowered the costs of production for a variety of products by slashing further the information component of those costs.
Increasingly, the physical distance between communications endpoints is becoming less relevant in determining the difficulty and
cost of transporting information.
To be sure, advancing technology, with its profound implications
for the nature of the economy, is nothing new, and the pace of improvement has never been even. But it is possible that we may be
in the midst of a quickening of the process. Nonetheless, we have
to be careful in projecting a further acceleration in the application
of technology indefinitely into the future. Similarly, suppressed
wage cost growth as a consequence of job insecurity can be carried
only so far. While it is difficult to judge the timeframe on such adjustments, the risks to cost and price inflation going forward are
not entirely skewed to the downside, especially with the economy
so recently operating at high levels of resource utilization.
In light of the quickened pace of technological change, the question arises whether the U.S. economy can expand more rapidly
without adding to inflationary pressures. The Federal Reserve
would certainly welcome faster growth, provided that it is sustainable.
The particular rate of maximum sustainable growth in an economy as complex and ever-changing as ours is very difficult to pin
down. Fortunately, the Federal Reserve does not need to have a
firm judgment on such an estimate, for persistent deviations of actual growth from that of capacity potential will soon send signals
that a policy adjustment is needed. Should the Nation's true
growth potential exceed actual growth, for example, the disparity
and lessened strain would be signaled in shorter lead times on the
delivery of materials, declining overtime, and ebbing inflationary
pressures. Conversely, actual growth in excess of the economy's
true potential would soon result in tightened markets and other
distortions which, as history amply demonstrates, would propel the
economy into recession.
The hypothesis that advancing technology has enhanced productivity growth would be more persuasive if national data on productivity increases showed a distinct improvement. To a degree, the
lack of any marked pickup may be a shortcoming of the statistics
rather than a refutation of the hypothesis. Faulty data could be
arising in part because business purchases are increasingly concentrated in items that are expensed but which market prices suggest should be capitalized.
In addition, the output of services, and the productivity of labor
in that sector, is particularly hard to measure.
There is still a nagging inconsistency. The evidence of significant
restructurings or improvements in technology and real costs within
business establishments does not seem to be fully reflected in our
national productivity measurements. It is possible that some of the
frenetic pace of business restructuring is mere wheel spinning,
changing production inputs without increasing output, rather than




real increases in productivity. One cause of wheel spinning, if that
is what it is, may be that it takes some time for firms to adapt in
such a way that major new technology is translated into increased
output.
It may be that the full advantage of even the current generation
of information and communication equipment will be exploited over
a span of quite a few years and only after a considerably updated
stock of physical capital has been put in place.
To be fully effective in achieving potential productivity improvements, technological innovations also require a considerable
amount of human investment on the part of workers who have to
deal with these devices on a day-to-day basis. On this score, we
may still not have progressed very far. Many workers still possess
only rudimentary skills in manipulating advanced information
technology. In these circumstances, firms and employees alike need
to recognize that obtaining the potential rewards of the new technologies in the years ahead will require a renewed commitment to
effective education and training, especially on-the-job training.
Our Nation faces many important and difficult challenges in economic policy. Nonetheless, we have made significant and fundamental gains in macroeconomic performance in recent years that
enhance the prospects for maximum sustainable economic growth.
Lower rates of inflation have brought a variety of benefits to
the economy, including lower long-term interest rates, a sense of
greater economic stability, an improved environment for household
and business planning, and more robust investment in capital
expenditures.
We have also made considerable progress on the fiscal front.
Over the past 10 years and especially since 1993, our elected political leaders, through sometimes prolonged and even painful negotiations, have been successful in reaching several agreements that
have significantly narrowed the budget deficit.
But more, obviously, remains to be done. As I have emphasized
many times, lower budget deficits are the surest and most direct
way to increase national saving. Higher national saving would help
to reduce real interest rates further, promoting more rapid accumulation of productive capital embodying recent technological
advances.
Lower inflation and reduced budget deficits will by no means
solve all of the economic problems that we face, but the achievement of price stability and Federal budget balance or surplus will
provide the best macroeconomic climate in which the Nation can
address other economic challenges.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
[The prepared statement of Hon. Alan Greenspan can be found
on page 38 in the appendix.]
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We appreciate
your statement always. It is very cogent and, I think, leads to a
number of questions.
I think what we will do in this process is each take turns asking
questions. Rather than use a clock, I am going to let it run for a
bit for each of us, perhaps up to 10 minutes or so. We will go on
a rotating basis so that we can fully develop the particular areas
that we are interested in.




10

I am told, by the way, that because a lot of people are very interested in your statement, the testimony that you have just given can
be found on the Internet at http://www.house.gov/castle/banking/.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That sounds longer than my testimony.
Chairman CASTLE. It may be. I don't use the Internet on a regular basis.
In any event, I want to start with a question that is going to be
an amalgamation of a number of things. It may be a little difficult
to tie this together, but it is current in New Hampshire today as
the voters vote in the first primary. Mr. Hinchey referred to it. I
referenced some of this. You referenced some of it. It is something
that is a little bit different. Even though it is in your testimony,
one way some people are viewing some of this is in sort of a negative sense. I think we need to address the issue and see if there
is anything that we can be doing about it, maybe not from the
point of view of the Federal Reserve Board. Maybe we need to balance budgets and straighten out problems of young people, whatever it may be.
Starting with the concept of wage differentiation, in recent years
there has been more and more discussion of slow wage growth and
a greater differentiation between wages of the average employee of
a corporation and the top management. We have heard that again
and again, that perhaps the policies of the Fed are leading to that,
and that is a problem.
We also know, as you have referenced, that there is corporate
downsizing. The cover of this week's Newsweek may be an exaggeration, but it says corporate killers. It has corporate CEOs and
discusses job cuts. In my State, Delaware, we know about some of
those job cuts. In fact, some of these people on the cover of this
magazine have been involved with the people in Delaware not
being employed right now. When you have individuals coming to
you who have lost jobs, that is different than corporate downsizing.
That is family, which is a significant element. So we have the problem of corporate downsizing.
Employment taxes have grown in your work lifetime, my work
lifetime. It has gone from the point of very little being taken out
of your pay, to some 7.5 percent being taken out directly for employment taxes before income taxes. Probably the employer side of
that gets shifted over to the employee as well, so you are looking
at a lot less take-home pay even if one stayed even with the rate
of inflation over all those years.
Then we have the further discussion of corporations moving offshore. I have seen that. I am not just talking about NAFTA. I am
talking about the decision that it is less expensive to make certain
products in other parts of the world. I think that can be expected
because of huge wage differentials between the United States and
other countries.
This is not to suggest that these same jobs have not been filled
in some other way. Unemployment is relatively low. This is not to
suggest that we don't still have good wages in many instances—we
do—that we are basically sloughing off the jobs of less monetary reward to make room for others. But there is a growing discomfort
among many people we talk to on a daily basis about where this
economy is going. There are many people who are very uncertain.




11
I see it with major corporations in Delaware. I am sure everybody
in Congress does. And you have heard it as well, have heard about
this particular problem.
I would like, I guess in the way of questions, to ask you if you
believe that these factors are a problem in the country in general
without regard to what the Fed may be doing. Would a loosening
of monetary policy or any other adjustments which the Fed could
make be helpful in this? Or are some of the things you are doing,
such as lowering interest rates, aimed at helping in this particular
area? Are Federal Reserve policies in general in some part responsible for this or not? If so, what adjustments can be made?
I know it is a broad question, but I think it combines many elements that a lot of us are concerned about. If you could take a
crack at it, I would appreciate it.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I will try, Mr. Chairman.
It is raising issues with respect to really the fundamental
changes that are going on in our economy and those which I think
we are going to have to address as we move into the 21st century.
Let me say first that probably since the dawn of the industrial revolution we have had a process by which there has been a significant shift in the nature of the goods and services we produce to
increasingly more intellectual conceptual products. This has been
especially the case in recent years when the major changes in
computer-based technologies have created a very extraordinary set
of changes which are only now in the process of really beginning
to take hold.
The result of all this is that ideas are becoming increasingly
more important in value added in the system. Therefore, education
or knowledge is becoming increasingly more a major factor in who
gets what type of wage payout. As a result, going back now about
15 years, there has been a very pronounced tendency in this country for the spread between the average income of college educated
people relative to, say, high school graduates to increase fairly significantly, and indeed for high school graduates' income to increase
relative to those who are high school dropouts. Indeed, we have
been seeing this fairly pronounced dispersion in the income distribution, which is effectively a consequence of the dramatic
changes in technology, which essentially go back to the extraordinary advances which occurred as a result of the invention of the
semiconductor and the whole proliferation of technologies which
have come as a consequence of this. This, I think, is a very important aspect of what our economy is doing. Even if the technology
is not now creating major increases in productivity overall, there
is every reason to believe that within a few years we will really
begin to see those changes.
Indeed, I remark in my prepared statement the example that
Professor David of Stanford brought out with respect to the analogy
between the advent of the electric motor's development in the latter
part of the 19th century and how long it took for that new technology to have a significant impact on national productivity. My expectation is that that analogy is probably correct and that we can
envisage a significant pickup in overall productivity in the United
States as we move out toward the beginning of the 21st century.




12

It is difficult, however, to know precisely what the timeframe of
that is.
But while that is in the process of occurring, we are nonetheless
confronted with this very difficult and personally very disturbing
concern in which we are seeing a major widening in tne spread of
incomes among various different segments of our work force. This
is creating a very high degree of general insecurity which is not
only related to jobs, but it is an insecurity which is created to a
large extent by the rapid changes that technology is bringing us.
If you look at the basic data, what it shows is that the average
age of our capital stock is falling very dramatically as we move toward high technology products. Since, on a day-by-day basis, all of
our work force interfaces with this rapidly changing set of technologies, it is pretty obvious that the degree of insecurity one feels
with respect to one's skills has got to be fairly significant. The extreme analogy I use is a skilled typist who finds that every 2 years
somebody comes in and changes the structure of the keyboard. You
can't adjust all that quickly.
I think what this says effectively is that we have got to address
the issue of making the work force sufficiently skilled to deal with
this. I think that we are making considerable progress; that is, a
number of our younger people are doing exceptionally well on the
new technologies, and the number of people who have been able to
learn and pick it up in middle age is, in my judgment, quite persuasive. It has been quite extraordinary.
The problem is that there is something fundamental going on out
there, and we have to address broad economic policies to meet it.
There are several which I have mentioned and will mention again.
One is the issue of getting the budget deficit down and creating far
greater private saving to be made available for new equipment to
adjust to the new technologies that will enhance the rate of increase in productivity and raise the overall level of everyone's incomes on average.
However, I do think that the old notion that we could somehow
finish our schooling in our teens or in our early twenties and that
will hold us for our life's work is rapidly changing. The issue of ongoing education and especially on-the-job training is a crucial issue
in getting human capital, as economists like to call it, up to levels
which enable the physical capital to function. It is in that context
that I think maximum economic growth can be enhanced. The Federal Reserve has an indirect role in that. The indirect role is to
make sure that longer-term inflationary expectations are subdued
so that the real cost of capital can be sufficiently low that the rate
of capital investment can be at a level which is consistent with the
maximum sustainable economic growth.
It is a very complex issue. I don't think it is easy. The degree
of frustration that a significant part of our work force feels is real.
It is legitimate. They should have considerable concerns for the
policies which have created that type of phenomenon.
I therefore think it is essential that we focus on this in a manner
which addresses the fundamental causes of the problem but recognize that, as difficult as technology is in many respects as we
change the structure of our economy, it has propelled the United
States to the highest standard of living the world has ever known.




13

If we proceed in that regard, I suspect we are going to find that
we will maintain that position well into the 21st century.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you. Clearly that question didn't catch
you by surprise. You have thought about those issues a lot. We appreciate it, because that is a very important subject to all of us.
You did touch on something that I would like to follow up on and
which is a little bit different but interesting. That is, and I agree
with the hypothesis, and that is that Americans must save more.
That means as individuals we must save more, as I perceive it. My
question to you is, what role, if any, should government play in
that?
I realize we should spend less and be more conservative in terms
of what we do, but should we be changing laws with respect to, for
example, IRAs or pension plans, or even Social Security? The
Kerrey-Danforth entitlement commission recommended looking at
that. Chile and other places are beginning to go toward equity investments of Social Security type funds. Are these the kinds of
things that Congress should be considering? Or should it be a matter of human restraint and living under the laws we presently
have?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, I think the Congress has a significant role
in a number of areas. I would agree that the Kerrey-Danfprth commission raised some very important issues. It is very difficult to
look at the arithmetic of Social Security as we get well into the
21st century without recognizing that there are significant problems out there which have to be addressed. And the longer we wait
to address them, the more difficult they are going to be to alter.
There has been considerable discussion of late about the prospect
of trying to envisage how one can alter the Social Security/personal
savings interrelationship. It is very important and very useful for
the Congress to delve into that.
It is a very complex subject. I don't think there are simple ways
out of that. But the arithmetic is daunting. If you don't get to it
now, when marginal, relatively minor changes can solve the longterm problem, it is going to become extraordinarily difficult if you
wait until after the turn-of-the-century to start looking at this sort
of thing.
The one thing we are reasonably sure of is what the structure
of our population is going to look like as we move into the 21st century. It is very difficult to argue that some of those various trends
are not pretty much locked in cement in the sense that the deviations that a lot of those trends can take are reallv relatively
minor. The crucial issue out there is it is difficult to mate the problem go away by saying maybe the economy will change or something else will change. It is very unlikely.
The question of how one views the educational structure is important. What role government has in that I am not sure, but it
is clearly an issue which I think has to be addressed. There are a
number of corporations who have found it to their advantage to require a lot of their people, maybe once or twice a week, to take certain skilled training courses, either in-house or in some other place,
specifically directed toward the type of work that they do. And I
would suspect that on-the-job-training is going to become and
should become important, if we are going to confront this particular

22-798 -96-2



14

technological structure that we are looking toward. We are going
to have to do numbers of things to change the incentive structure
of businesses to focus on this issue in the same sense that they now
focus on long-term capital investment. They are going to have to
start to look at their human capital in a way which they have not
looked at people in the past. Human beings have got certain characteristics that will not be replicated by computers, and I think it
is getting to a point we ought to start to recognize how important
those things are.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I guess
the recent chess match showed that computers aren't ready for
human beings yet.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I was thinking of that.
Chairman CASTLE. Close, but not ready. I would like to ask dozens of other questions and maybe I will have the chance to, but in
fairness, I think we should cycle the questioning a little bit. I will
turn now to Mr. Hinchey who has, I am sure, some questions.
Mr. HINCHEY. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
And thank you, Mr. Chairman for your testimony. I think as always, your testimony is not just interesting, but fascinating, I
think very important, and it should be studied by all the Members
of the Congress.
I would like to focus for a moment on what you said about the
need for education and job training, and I think that that is undeniably true and this is something that has been observed by a
number of other people, as a matter of fact, in recent years. In fact,
I closed my eyes for a moment while you were speaking and
thought I heard the voice of Robert Reich. In any case
Mr. GREENSPAN. He and I actually agree on a lot of this, I must
say, quite to the surprise of both of us.
Mr. HINCHEY. Well, I am not surprised, actually. I might have
been, but I am not surprised after your testimony today. There are
a lot of things that you said today which I think make a great deal
of sense, not that other things you have said in the past haven't
made a great deal of sense, but in my particular frame of mind,
they make a great deal of sense.
My concern is that although it is undeniably true that our focus
on education, that is, our Nation's focus on education, dating back
to the time of our creation of the first system of free elementary
and secondary education, has been a major if not the major driving
force in stimulating economic growth and making us the economic—the number one economic engine in the world.
However, as you point out in your testimony, there are disturbing indications and trends in the present economic framework that
may lead us to conclude that the lessons of the past may not in
every instance be applicable to the present and indeed future circumstances. I observe, for example, that one out of every four BA
graduates is now working; those who are working, are working in
jobs that do not require the application of the learning that they
have been exposed to. They are underperforming and they are
underutilizing their skills.
I think that what we may be seeing is the creation of an economic and technological elite, which will be essential to the continuing economic progress that our country has to make, but at the




15

same time, the danger that more and more people are going to be
left behind and that education in and of itself is not the answer to
our economic problems, if we include among our economic challenges the provision of economic opportunity for all of our citizens.
As you noted in your testimony, more and more people are indeed being left behind by this present economy. Others have used
that metaphor, first coined I think by John Kennedy, of the rising
tide lifting all boats, observing that this rising tide is lifting the
yachts but leaving a lot of the smaller boats behind. And we have
to ask ourselves what is it that we can do, how are we going to
face this challenge; the challenge being how to ensure that the
growing, enormous economic products of this economy and this society are being shared with some degree of equanimity with all of
our citizens and not just by a select few. And I know that this is
not entirely within the province of the Federal Reserve Board, but
there are certain aspects of your responsibilities that do deal with
this, and certainly this is of concern to you because you addressed
it in your remarks, and I know that you think about these things.
Let me just ask you, what in addition to our concentration on
education ought we be thinking about? Is it something—some
thing, for example, as simple as raising the minimum wage to a
standard of where it ought to be, had it followed its historical
precedent? Should we be investing more in our economy to upgrade
our infrastructure? The regional plan in the New York metropolitan area, for example, Regional Planning Agency just issued a
report, I am certain that you are aware of it, that makes the observation that the 31 counties in New York, New Jersey, and Connecticut surrounding the metropolitan area are going to be in a
state of increasing decay as a result of the decline of the infrastructure in that area, which is particularly observable in the New York
City metropolitan region. Are there things that we ought to be
doing to stimulate our economy in that regard, upgrading our infrastructure, investing in the future of our country so that, in fact,
more people can share in these economic benefits?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Hinchey, let me just say one of the areas
where I find myself in disagreement with my friend Bob Reich is
on the minimum wage. There is a big dispute among economists recently as to whether in fact increasing the minimum wage significantly decreases employment, and there is, as you are probably
aware, debate going on. I happen to come out on the side where
the evidence is pretty persuasive that it increases unemployment
and is not an effective tool.
The issue you raise about a significant portion of BA's, for example, working on lower skilled jobs has always been the case and
probably will always continue to be the case in the same sense that
there are always high school graduates who get to the top of the
heap, too. There is some interesting evidence which does suggest
that although we were confronted with significant technological
change in the 1950's, 1960's and 1970's, we were not confronted
with a significant spreading of income distribution; indeed, it is my
recollection the income distribution actually tightened. And one of
the reasons was that there was a relative plethora of higher educated people so that the supply did apparently effectively constrain




16

the dispersion of the income distribution, and that is why I suspect
that that still is the most effective tool.
If what we are dealing with is a fundamental problem, on which
the evidence is overwhelming, that it is technology which is creating this dispersion of incomes, then the best and most effective way
to address it is to bring up the skills of all segments of our population and in that sense contain it. I am not saying it is the only
thing that can or should be done; I suspect there are other things.
And it is a type of issue which I don't think we have ever really
confronted in this Nation, and so it is easy to hypothesize lots of
different solutions, a number of which are surely not going to work,
but I do think that what we are observing at this stage is strongly
suggestive that education is what the issue is. It mignt not be the
total answer, but without it, I don't think we can confront this
issue in an adequate manner and I don't think it is in the interest
of this country to have a society in which there are very considerable increasing numbers of people who do not participate in the
overall growth of the system.
Mr. HINCHEY. Well, that is my point exactly, that there are increasing numbers of people who are not participating in the overall
growth of the system, and I was hoping that you might give us
some direction as to what we might—direction we might pursue to
try to deal with that problem.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, Mr. Hinchey, a major emphasis on what
we used to call adult education is probably where the emphasis
ought to be. The longevity of one's skills is becoming increasingly
foreshortened because the capital stocks' age is shortening because
of very significant turnover. What that implies is that you have to
be continuously learning what it is you need to know on the job as
the types of things with which you deal on a day-by-day basis are
themselves continually changing.
I find that I have to sit down and learn a word processor. The
reason I have to do that is over time, I won't be able to find any
replacement parts for my old typewriter. The system will change
and the skills that one must continue to enhance, I think, are there
all the time. I mean I have had to learn a lot of the mathematics
of the derivatives business. I spent an awful lot of time on what
would ordinarily be termed education, and the reason I have to do
it is I couldn't do my job if I didn't, and I suspect that is true of
a very significantly increasing part of this population.
So my own guess is that if we can find a way to create a combination of work and learning that exists at all levels of the income
distribution, I think we will finally come to grips with this issue.
Unless we do something like that, I frankly don't know how we do
it.
Mr. HINCHEY. Then at a minimum we should conclude, I suspect,
that the Congress should not be decreasing funds for education at
all levels but should in fact be increasing those funds.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, I don't want to comment on basically
whether it is private or government, because there is no doubt that
a very substantial part of this, no matter what government does,
is going to have to be private because it is in the interests, the very
clear interests of corporate America to do this, and we are already
beginning to see it emerging.




17

I would think that in discussing any governmental programs, it
is important to ask ourselves does it help or does it hinder the
overall process? But I don't think it is basically either a private or
ublic solution. I think the question essentially is how do we do it
est.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Hinchey. We will come back
for another round of questions if you have further. Let's go to Mr.
Leach.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am just trying to parse
your testimony, and it strikes me that what you presented us is a
lot of good news in the immediate past, tempered by some large
question marks for the immediate future: the good news being 60
months of sustained growth, inflation at less than 3 percent, wnich
is extraordinary, and the transition occurring in the economy
from one kind of industrial job base to another, which is rather
impressive.
The tempered news is that the share of economic growth going
to workers is declining, and I understand the Fed has studies indicating that in the 1980's, about 60 percent of economic growth was
returned to the workers; in the last 3 years it has probably been
about 53 percent, which is an awkward circumstance in the sharing of newly created wealth.
Second, you have indicated that there appears to be a not exactly
bullish outlook on the economy this year with 2 to 2Y4 percent
fourth quarter to first quarter growth, and so the obvious question
becomes does the Fed consider that adequate? Are we looking at
the possibility of breakage, either months or on the quarterly basis,
of sustained growth? Might we see a quarter or so of negative
growth? And let me first begin with that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is very difficult to say, Mr. Chairman. The
numbers that we saw for the month of January, obviously were dismal. It seems that February is doing a shade better, looking at
some of the weekly data, but we have very little on the month of
February to tell us much about that. I would be doubtful that we
will get to negative growth, but there is no question that this is a
soft economy. The fourth quarter was soft. The first quarter is soft.
The issue of whether in fact we consider a particular growth rate
adequate, as I tried to indicate in my prepared testimony, is not
the way we come at the issue.
Our view—and I have said this many times before this subcommittee—is that our goal, the ultimate goal, is to maximize longterm sustainable growth. It is our judgment, and we think the evidence very strongly supports the view, that low inflation or stable
prices enhances that. In other words, maximum sustainable growth
is achievable when individuals and businesses no longer have to be
concerned about what is going to be happening to prices over the
longer run. As a consequence of that, we will respond to evidences
of distortions which imply imbalances that could create significant
contractions, whether the underlying growth rate is 2 percent, 3
percent, 4 percent, or 5 percent.
Mr. LEACH. I appreciate that. Let me just make a couple of observations, though, on this. One of the things, I think Congress has
been looking to the Fed with the understanding that monetary policy to some degree has to accommodate fiscal policy and fiscal pol-

E




18

icy to some degree drives monetary policy, and so we are all—have
been hopeful of some sort of budget agreement that could lay forth
the framework where there could be greater confidence of Fed
action.
And I would only like to add, as one who strongly believes a
budget agreement is important and can be achieved at this time
with some question mark of the political will, that from the Federal
Reserve's perspective, it has struck me that as I listened to the inside leadership kind of decisions on the budget this year, that lack
of an agreement will lead to lower spending rates this year; that
is, the alternative to no budget agreement is going to be a fiscal
circumstance where there is going to be increasing uncertainty and
almost no likelihood of anything except lower levels of spending.
The reason I raise this is that from the Federal Reserve's perspective, the notion of waiting for a budget agreement may be less consequential than I would have thought a month or 3 or 4 or 5
months ago in terms of making decisions and whether to accommodate certain things in the economy. And so I think the impulse of
fiscal stimulus is likely to be lessened without an agreement and,
ironically, at least for this year, increased with an agreement. And
I think that is something the Fed should take into consideration.
Having said that, I also think the long-term circumstance is one
that has gotten very little attention in public policy debate, and
that relates to the demographics of America. We are looking at this
particular time, with the best competition for jobs we are likely to
see for the next half century, with the 3.3 working Americans supporting every retiree, with the prospect in a generation that that
starts to come down to two. If we don't have higher but sustained
levels of growth in a highly competitive job market, I think we are
in some difficulty. And the reason I say this is that one never
wants to get in the position of competing with numbers. I mean,
the President of the United States last week hinted that he would
like to see 2.7 percent growth, and that if you have 2.7 percent
growth, some of the deficit issues become much more manageable.
A competitor can say I—they favor 2.8 or 2.9—so you can always
leapfrog.
But it strikes me that given the competition for jobs, given the
restructuring that is going on in the economy, that very substantial
rates of growth above those levels that have been in existence the
last decade could well be in reach. And I think this economic
growth theme is one that we are all going to have to spend an
awful lot of attention to, and I am wondering if you would care to
comment on that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, Mr. Chairman. There is no question that
when you are dealing with an economy as complex as ours, that it
had better grow and grow at a reasonably good rate if we are not
going to run into all sorts of significant types of problems. As you
point out, we run into changing demographies which require everincreasing notions of saving, investment, and economic growth to
basically allow an increasing part of our population—as we move
through the 21st century—to retire with the wherewithal to enable
that to happen.
The short-term issue that you raise, namely the question of the
issue of government spending slowing down quite significantly,




19

which I mentioned in my remarks, is something that we at the
Federal Reserve obviously are aware of and follow very closely. As
I have said before this subcommittee on numerous occasions, we respond to fiscal policy as it affects the economy. In other words, to
the extent that a budget agreement or significant curtailment in
outlays or various different appropriations programs affect what is
going on in the economy, we respond to that. We don't respond directly to what fiscal policy is, only to its consequences. And because
of that, it is an issue of numerous different things which affect the
economy, and therefore I wouldn't want to say that we do or should
respond to any particular configuration of nscal policy, except to
recognize that it has a very important impact on what is going on
in the economy. It has certainly been a factor in the short run, and
if, hopefully, a budget balance deal can be reached, I think the effects will be quite extraordinary.
There is a deterioration in expectations that that is going to happen, and that is probably having some market effect. But I do
think that the dramatic decline that we saw in long-term interest
rates throughout 1995 was very significantly affected by the expectation that, contrary to the general cynicism which tends to pervade the financial sector, something real was happening and indeed something real has been happening. I mean, the deficit has
been coming down and that has been a very major factor in the decline in long-term interest rates and, over the long run, a necessary
condition for significant growth in this economy.
Mr. LEACH. I thank you, Mr. Chairman. My time has expired.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I just want to basically say that the importance
of getting that budget under control in the intermediate period so
that we are in a state after the turn of the century that we can
address these broader questions, I think is terribly urgent.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Leach. Mr. LoBiondo.
Mr. LoBiONDO. Thank you, Chairman Castle.
Chairman Greenspan, you were talking about the progress that
we have been making with working on the budget and the result
that that has had with decline of long-term interest rates and the
need to continue with that. Would you care to speculate if we were
to reach an agreement that would result in a balanced budget, a
true agreement, what that could or would mean in terms of lower
interest rates?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I have said before, Congressman, that I expect
that, as indeed a number of analysts have, there is probably IOC
to 200 basis points in a significant credible agreement, and we
picked up a chunk of that through 1995 as the market began tc
discount that particular agreement. If the agreement is finalh
reached and it is credible, we will find that long-term rates will fal
quite a bit further. If we fail and there is an expectation in th<
market that we have lost interest in resolving this issue, we ar<
going to find that long-term rates, as I indicated in public state
ments in the last month or so, could back up some. And therefor
what we are observing is we have gotten a down payment in th
marketplace in the expectation of a significant agreement, and
we get the agreement, there will be more to come. But if we do no
some of that down payment, I suspect, will have to be refunded.




20

Mr. LoBlONDO. Thank you, Chairman Greenspan.
Mr. Castle, that is all I have.
Chairman CASTLE. Actually, I would like to ask some questions
along that same line Mr. LoBiondo did. You said that before that—
actually I have 200 points or 2 percent rather than 100, but you
indicated if there was a significant credible agreement. Let me, by
the way, urge you to look at the 6-year balanced budget which I
and some others have proposed, without a tax increase, which the
Concord coalition and others have endorsed. We hope that is a significant and credible agreement, and if you really like it, you can
endorse it as well.
But not having the time to do that right now, let me ask you this
question. I think I understood what you said, but I have wondered
about this for some time, and that is a time line on all of this. Let's
assume, setting aside kidding about what particular budget may
be, we really ao have a significant credible budget agreement—
have we already entered into that phase, is this the down payment
on that that we are talking about—and that we have had slightly
reduced rates and the expectation during this last 6 months or so
that we might get there and therefore interest rates, long-term interest rates are down a little bit now, and then if we don't get
there, they might go back up, whereas if we do get there they
might go down more. Can you give us some rough diagram of
where we might be in that cycle or if I said it correctly?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is very tough to, in a sense.
Chairman CASTLE. I realize that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me say this. We brought long-term interest
rates down from a little over 8 percent to a little under 6 percent
over a little more than a year. Part of that was a changing sense
of inflation expectations in the economy, I think for reasons which
I outlined about the technological changes that are going on in our
society which are bringing costs down. The rest is, in my judgment,
anticipation of a significant improvement in our long-term fiscal
stance.
It is very difficult to judge how much of that particular decline,
which has backed up some as you know in recent days, was directly
attributable to an expected budget agreement, how much was expectation that underlying long-term forces are improving on the inflation side. However one divides that, a fairly large part of the 2
percentage point decline that we saw is down payment on the
budget agreement; and even if we don't get an agreement but there
is a general expectation that fiscal restraint will be in place, we
won't lose all the down payment. But we also will not get the rest
of the decline, which is probably still in the pipeline and available,
should an agreement of credible nature be passed and signed into
law and implemented.
Chairman CASTLE. As you well know, the various budget agreements with which we have dealt here have been realistically 7
/ears, some 6 years, but basically 7 years. Obviously we don't balince the budget in the first year; we balance it in the seventh year,
50 we continue the deficit. But we have a fiscal policy in which we
vill have a less percentage of GNP being debt and a less percentige of the budget being interest payments, so that we start to adIress that. And as to that remaining part of the—and also it is all




21

a series of variables, as you know, and as anyone who has really
looked at it knows, the economy could do something completely different next year and completely offset whatever we do to try to balance the budget.
But I was just curious as to whether or not if we did do that if
we would get the rest of that down payment, the full payment on
it, almost immediately; or it would be a period of 6 or 7 years in
which you probably would see an easing of interest costs upwards
of perhaps 2 percent or whatever?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It depends on the structure of the agreement.
Assume you locked into law a set of agreements which, unless the
Congress did something, would get the deficit reduction, which I
understand is, without entitlements not easy to do. Needless to say,
my expectation is that the markets would look upon that with some
degree of credibility, largely because it has become increasingly evident that the issue of midget deficits is not something which is
taken as an unimportant issue anymore. People who advocate increasing the deficit are few and far between in this House and in
the other House, compared to the way it was, say, 30 years ago.
There has been a really quite dramatic change. For example, I
thought the pay-go rules, which can be overthrown with a majority,
are holding relatively firm, much to my surprise, and I think it is
the culture that has evolved against deficits which has done that.
Consequently, if you have comparable type of legislation in a 7-year
agreement or a 6-year agreement or whatever it is we are talking
about, the evidence of recent years probably works in favor of that
being accepted as reasonably credible, and I think the markets
would respond to that. But smoke and mirrors won't work.
Chairman CASTLE. Right. And I agree with that. I point that out
to people back home when I speak to them, because I think sometimes we don't tell the story of the importance of balancing the
budget. But when you apply it to people's mortgages, for example,
or their car loans or student loans or just general credit loans, be
it credit cards or other loans they may have, and you apply it
against the budget of a household and you start to reduce it by a
oint or two of interest, frankly it is a significant impact, probably
ir beyond any tax reduction we could possibly propose.
I think it is important we all understand that and it is the reason I wanted to—and I think you more than anyone else is looked
to as an expert in this particular subject and why it is so important
to all of us.
Let me go on to just one more question—I will turn to Mr
Hinchey on the same subject of interest rates—and that is the tim
ing of all that you are doing. I think of all the things that the Fed
eral Reserve does which would seem to get notoriety is your meet
ings in which the white smoke or the black smoke goes up th
chimney, and you have cut interest rates or you have raised ther
or you have kept them the same or whatever it may be. I can't usi
ally predict what you are going to do, don't even really try to.
I did think that—I guess in 1994 there were more tax—more ir
terest rate increases than I had expected in that particular yea
now they seem to be going down. Sometimes I worry that mayt
we adjust too quickly, we are too hyper—or the Fed is, the Boai
of Governors is too hypersensitive to inflation or to the nuances

E




22

the economy, and adjustments and shifts are made on too rapid a
basis, and therefore people—it doesn't have time to flow through
the economy and it doesn't have the impact that one would have
expected it to have, or we may get into a situation in which we
don't move quickly enough to go back to increasing again, as opposed to decreasing, whereas if we kept them level for a while it
would be more obvious what you have to do.
I was just interested in your comments on all that. I am not suggesting I am correct, but those things have gone through my mind
as I have watched the transactions of the Board over the years.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, Mr. Chairman, that is one of the key issues which we are concerned about as well. In theory, if one could
find an economy in which you could lock in a specific interest rate
and it would be the equilibrium interest rate which would prevail
for all time and one needn't do anything beyond that, that would
be just fine. However, in a free market, complex society, the type
that we have, the dynamics of it coupled with the fact that people
get excessively exuberant on occasion and inordinately depressed
on occasion, you get a cycle that gets built into the system. What
we try to do is to try to clip the top and the bottom, so to speak,
to flatten it out to the extent that we can on both sides, and that
is not an easy thing to do because it implies that one is forecasting
how the economy is going to develop.
We are trying to understand the dynamics of the system which
sometimes says don't change rates for a long period of time. In
1993, for example, we hardly changed the rates at all. In 1994, we
changed them quite often. In earlier periods, we did it in small increments quite often, in still other periods we did it fairly rarely,
but in large chunks.
It depends to a large extent what type of problem or issue you
are confronting. There are different types of policies that have to
be addressed to different types of situations, and that is basically
the major part of our analysis and Federal Open Market Committee deliberations in which we focus on those types of questions.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Hinchey.
Mr. HINCHEY. Mr. Chairman, in the context of the discussions
here about the budget deficit, let me invite your remarks about—
or your comments on an issue that was raised in an article that
was in the Washington Post this past Sunday. The article makes
a rather convincing argument that President Clinton's 1993 deficit
reduction plan has been very instrumental in improving the economy. It cites a number of facts, notably that in November of 1992,
the annual budget deficit stood at nearly $300 billion. It is now at
$164 billion. In 1992, inflation was 3 percent. In December of 1995,
it was at 2V2 percent. Unemployment was at 7.3 percent, and has
dropped to 5.8 percent. Mortgage rates have dropped from 8.29 percent to 6.94 percent, and finally, as we all have witnessed, the Dow
Tones Industrial Average increased from 3,244 to 5,503.
You have in the past commented on that 1993 deficit reduction
>rogram. To what extent do you believe that was instrumental in
>romoting the kind of improvements that have been cited in this
irticle on the economy?




23

Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, Mr. Hinchey, I said at the time without
getting into the composition of how the deficit reduction was imple
mented—that were that to occur, that is, a deficit reduction of th(
type that had been talked about, I would have expected that we
would have seen lower long-term interest rates, improved economi<
growth and a number of the issues that you cite.
Without getting into the question of whether the mix was righl
or anything else like that, the fact of the deficit reduction ir
and of itself was very positive and an unquestioned factor in con
tributing to the improvement in economic activity that occurrec
thereafter.
Mr. HINCHEY. You have said that the economy the last quartei
was very soft and the recent indicators were dismal, to use youi
phrase a moment ago. In retrospect, given the circumstances thai
you see existing today in the economy, is there anything that yoi:
would have done differently in 1994 and 1995? Would you have
raised interest rates less rapidly, perhaps, than you did?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, I think not. Let me say why, very specif!
cally. The type of pattern of problems that were emerging in 1994
were the classic business-cycle expansion, inflation-prone type 01
economy. It is the type of economy which, if interest rates were
kept at the levels that they were in 1993, would have almost surel>
engendered a huge increase in inventory excess, probably kept the
economy at very strong levels through a goodly part of the firsl
half, probably maybe more, of 1995, but we would have run intc
a very severe inventory excess and, in my judgment, probably othei
forms of excess, which would have created a very marked cyclica
decline and ended like so many previous business expansions have
ended.
In retrospect, I think we cut the top off of that expansion anc
in so doing prolonged the recovery, hopefully, for quite a consider
able period of time. I do not believe that long-term interest ratei
would have come down as much as they did, even with the budge
agreement, as they did through 1995, because I don't think infla
tion expectations would have fallen in any material degree as the;
did. We would have had a situation which by now I think woul
have been pretty much intolerable.
So if we look back and say would we have done it differently c
if we could go back and change the pattern, I don't really see whei
we would have done it all that differently, and indeed I think tt
timing struck me as pretty reasonable. The way we worked it ou
sometimes we were a little behind the curve, sometimes we we]
a little ahead of it, but on average I thought it worked out reasoi
ably well.
Mr. HlNCHEY. You say you would not have expected inflation e
pectations to have fallen, and I think that that is a very poigna
phrase in this context because there was in fact inflation expect
tions. There was no real inflation in the economy. One looked ve
hard to find evidence of inflation, and while obviously some peop
could see evidence, a lot of others found none. So your actions we
based upon inflation expectations which in fact might have be
illusory.
Mr. GREENSPAN. No. The evidence is pretty persuasive.
Mr. HINCHEY. What is that evidence?




24

Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me give you an analogy. There is a sense
in which you can argue that if the river which runs by your shore
has got a flood crest coming down and you take sandbags and you
build them all up and the crest goes by, and the screaming, the
yelling that you were going to be flooded never happened, and you
could basically say well, look, we didn't get flooded, we didn't have
to go through all of this activity—well, the sandbags are basically
the interest rates.
The reason we know that had we not moved we would have been
in trouble is that we were beginning to get very significant evidences of the type of stress in the economy which historically has
almost invariably preceded significant actual inflation accelerations. The lead time on the deliveries of products, for example,
which had been quite subdued through 1993 and earlier, started to
rise very dramatically. Overtime hours in manufacturing and elsewhere went up quite dramatically, evidencing the type of strain
that one usually foresees.
Had we not raised rates in that type of environment, history tells
us, with very strong conviction, that we would have been confronted with an inflationary problem with prices accelerating and
the economy running into trouble. I don't know whether it would
have been in late 1995, whether it would have been now, I am not
sure. But that it would likely happen was too high a probability for
us not to confront that. I think it would have been irresponsible on
our part not to address the problems that we saw emerging.
Mr. HINCHEY. Well, the analogy about the river is interesting.
Rivers, I guess, are in the eye otthe beholder. Many of us looked
at that same river and saw a mere trickle of a stream, not threatening anyone at all, and placing of sandbags up around such a benign trickle of a stream seemed in themselves extreme, so
Mr. GREENSPAN. I put my scuba diver stuff on, so I got a good
look at it.
Mr. HINCHEY. Well, many of us were very high and dry and in
fact feeling very thirsty during that period of time.
Chairman CASTLE. Chairman Leach.
Mr. LEACH. Well, I think what we want you to do is now put on
/our astronaut gear and look to the future. It strikes me there is
ibsolute consensus in both political parties that we would like to
ee greater economic growth and greater sharing of the wealth. The
^reat question at this time is how we achieve it. And here I just
/ant to leave with whether or not you—the question of are we
oing to achieve it through greater spending of money we don't
ave or are we going to achieve it more likely through a little more
estraint in Congress and some long-term planning. And that is
sally the question we in Congress face. And that comes back to
le—whether or not we can achieve a budget agreement, whether
r not we can create certainty in the economy on that basis.
Frankly, my own guess is we will have a little more restrained
>ending
this year without an agreement because of the way Con%
ess controls the appropriations process, but that we will have
'eater benefits with an agreement because we will have longerrm certitude.
And so the only question I would leave for you is can you tell us
Aether we will have greater economic growth with an agreement,




25

without an agreement, with greater restraint or without greater re
straint, and isn't that the real message the Federal Reserve Board
has for the Congress of the United States?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would say over the long run that a credible
budget agreement, or more importantly the implementation of ar
important budget balancing agreement, would enhance long-tern
growth conceivably significantly. If we fail to do that, if we continuously have heavy drains on our aggregate private saving through
government deficits and are required to import saving from abroad
to finance our domestic capital investment, I think we cut the path
of long-term growth by a not immaterial amount; and consequently
while it is hard to know exactly where or how or what the numbers
are, I have very little doubt that there is something very important
in play here.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, sir. I have no further questions.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Chairman Leach.
I would just like to ask a couple of random questions in an effort
to try to get a few more things in, if we could, that I think are
important.
I keep going back to this whole balancing of the budget, which
obviously I believe is very, very important, and you have indicated
the same. And the question I have is the Consumer Price Index
the CPI figure, which is in practically all—is at least faced in al
of the budget plans which I have seen. A lot of them don't adjusl
it at all, or adjust it very minimally in accordance with what the
Bureau of Labor statistics says it has already done. Others adjusl
it quite significantly, up to I think .66, a two-thirds of 1 percent
reduction per year. This obviously impacts certain payments which
go out by the Federal Government which would reduce those expenditures, most notably Social Security, but other pensions of Fed
eral employees and a variety of other entitlement type programs
It also impacts our revenues because they are adjusted by inflation
and so we would see them also impacted in a sense that would hel]
balance the budget, because if you don't have that adjustment, thei
you are going to receive more revenue.
I believe—I don't mean to misstate this, but I believe you hav
stated on occasion that you also have concluded that the CPI is to
high and perhaps should be looked at. I don't know where you ar
today on that subject, but I don't think it is one that we should it
nore, for better or for worse. It is one that we as a Congress shoul
at least be aware of. I am not sure if any of us have much desii
to vote on it one way or another, but I think the awareness factc
is very important; and as an expert, I would just like to ask yoi
opinion of the status of the CPI today as you see it.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, Mr. Chairman, there are two issues, ar
I emphasize them as being distinct because I hear too often wh
appears to be a mixing of two separate tracks: Track number on
which does not require any legislation except funding of the Burei
of Labor Statistics so that they can proceed with major changes
the way they calculate the index, which will remove some of t
bias. At the moment, I think in the President's budget, they ha
calculated that the CPI, strictly for technical reasons removi
some of the biases in the system, will be reduced by an average
.3 percent a year after a certain period of time as a consequer




26

)f superior statistical techniques which remove the bias. That will
automatically affect the indexing of retirement programs and the
avenue income tax, which are indexed, and other elements of our
Federal system which are indexed, as well as all the private conTacts outside which are linked to the CPI. I say that requires no
egislation and I put that aside.
There is a wholly different issue which gets to the point. No mater what the BLS does, so long as they do not revise the data historically and hence be able to pick up new products, for example,
which only get picked up late, and so long as they have a fixed
weight system and a number of other things which they do to calculate the index, you will never be able to statistically remove from
bhe Consumer Price Index enough of the bias which enables it to
be truly a cost-of-living index. And indeed, the BLS says in its discussion of the CPI that it is not a cost-of-living index.
Nonetheless, I interpret the indexing that the Congress implemented with respect to all of these programs to keep retirees whole
with respect to changes in the cost of living, real changes in the
cost of living, and to do similarly to the tax structure.
Therefore, a wholly second issue is something which does require
some legislative initiative. That would be, for example, to say that
3n the basis of a commission of experts meeting every year to deermine that as of this year or last year that the bias in the CPI
:hat had not been corrected by the statisticians in the BLS was X.
Then it would be appropriate for a new index calculated as the CPI
minus X to be employed as a cost-of-living index to escalate all government programs, retirement and tax.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. That is interestng. On a somewhat related subject to that is what it means to
ndividuals.
I would like to ask another question, because sometimes I think
he issues of interest rates and debt come down again to the famiies and of the individuals in this country; and that is, the wav
hey view it as opposed to a monetary policy that we may talk
ibout in this subcommittee or in the board room of the Federal
leserve.
And one of the things that interested me in a conversation you
nd I had in a private meeting one day was the whole business of
idividual consumer debt and credit cards and what is happening
i the country. My father, who is no longer with us, essentially
ever really had credit cards or used credit cards. They were
round but he just never got in the habit of using them, and I
link that is the way a whole generation lived. And now we are
; the point where a lot of us are borrowing up to the limits and
iking on new credit cards or whatever, and there is a belief, I
dnk by some that the long-term consequences of this to individils and maybe even to the economy as a whole is potentially negate if we don't watch it carefully and keep it under some control,
would be interested in your views on that if you wish to share
em.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Credit cards have become ubiquitous, to say the
ist. The numbers that people tell me are issued each year are so
•ge that I can never remember the number. I think we all see the
braordinary number of cards that just keep coming in the mail.




27

The problem that they have created is that, while they have
clearly served a very important purpose and thev have been very
useful to consumers, there is a limited number of people who tend
to use the cards up to their limits and then keep jockeying the limits and keep everything in play until all of a sudden one day they
are broke. And they go not from 30-day delinquencies or 60-day
delinquencies to bankruptcy; they go from paying on time to
bankruptcy.
Now, the way that most issuers of cards have endeavored to try
to prevent that from occurring is that there are central clearinghouses in various different areas that exchange information. And
if it were immediately current, in other words, if they literally
knew exactly what everybody was doing as of 5 minutes ago, then
clearly we wouldn't be getting into these relatively minor situations
where you find an increase in bankruptcies in which people go off
the cliff without any evidence beforehand that they are in trouble.
The answer to this is probably technology in the sense that the
types of things we have been talking about earlier today are enabling us to get ever closer to real-time transactions and real-time
evaluations so that it would not be possible for somebody to be
playing games with borrowing against one card to pay off another
because it would become immediately evident and the whole system would become quite restrictive.
It is not an issue that is a big problem. I don't want to say here
that we are on the edge of some serious issue. We are not. It is
true that delinquencies have risen on credit cards whereas they
have not risen particularly in other consumer debt or in mortgage
debt. It is certainly the case that personal bankruptcies have risen,
and it is probably in part related to the extent that we have cards.
It is not a serious issue at this stage, but it could be. It is important to be looked at, and I do think that one of the reasons why
recently we have seen evidence of certain credit card issuers beginning to tighten up is precisely this issue. We are going to find that,
after we get over this particular episode, that there will be more
rational use of cards and greater control. And as I said before, they
are clearly a very extraordinary advance in consumer finance, and
it is not something we should forget. It is very useful to the average household.
Chairman CASTLE. They are an advance when you are using
them but are a little more questionable when you are trying to pay
them, I might say, on a personal level. Are you suggesting there
be an electronic clearinghouse? Will that be the way that will function so that debt as a whole can be watched as opposed to individual card debt?
Mr. GREENSPAN. If you look into the 21st century and ask what
is our financial system going to look like and what is the central
bank going to look like, I think we will move increasingly toward
a type of system which will be closer and closer to a real-time
transaction settlement clearing system in which everything occurs
at the same time. That means that the float, which is very substan
tial, will eventually be squeezed out of the system to a greater o:
lesser extent. That is a long way away. It is not imminent, but tha
is the direction in which we are going.




28

Indeed, when we look at another issue, which is not quite related
to this but very important to us, the whole question of systemic
risk, one of the most important ways in which we can reduce the
possibilities of a significant breakdown financially, internationally,
domestically or whatever, is to remove a good deal of this float
from the system. Indeed, a lot of it is already coming out.
They are moving in the direction which will make everything
electronic in the payment system. That will be a major contribution
to the effectiveness of finance. This particular type of central clearing issue for credit cards is likely to be part of the overall system.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you. One final question and then we
will see if any of the others have final questions to ask.
We have been hearing a lot more lately about a flat tax. We also
hear in our budget proposals that we may have a capital gains tax
reduction. We also hear of a tax break for children. These all have
huge implications to the economy of the United States of America,
to dealing with the revenues of the United States as well as balancing our budget. I was wondering if you would be willing to
make a comment concerning whether you conclude that we need
any changes in our present tax policy or there are certain changes
that you would prefer more than others or some which are anathema such as one that might not work at all.
I would like to put on record your thoughts about basic tax policy
as it exists now or might be changed in the near future, because
we as Members of Congress may be dealing with this, if not this
year, sometime in the near future.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, I don't mind discussing in detail
some of the technical aspects of a lot of these programs, and I am
sure you will have me before the subcommittee doing just that at
some point. The issue, however, is a very complex one which gets
far beyond the question of really the technical aspects of taxation.
The reason I say that is when we look at our tax system, we are
reflecting some of the fundamental values in our society.
I have recently been reviewing, for example, the degree of pro^ressivity in taxes over the last couple of hundred years to get a
sense as to why it varies from period to period. What is very clear
s that it is the underlying view of whether in fact the private martet system is perceived of as just or whether it is perceived of as
jxploitive. In the periods where it is perceived of as exploitive, you
lave a high degree of progressivity. Those where it is perceived of
is just rewards, taxation is perceived of as government
onfiscation.
There is a very broad set of issues here, and I think really to talk
i terms wholly of what the economics are, is to miss a lot of these
ssues. I would just as soon, as part of the central bank, at this
articular point to stay out of this particular discussion. At the molent, it is really talking about fundamental values, fundamental
olitical values in the good sense, and that is not something which
think that we at the central bank should basically be involved
ith.
Chairman CASTLE. That is a very good answer, Mr. Chairman.
am not sure I totally agree with whether or not you should be
volved in it, but we will let it go for now.




29

I appreciate your earnest attempts to answer all my questions.
Mr. Hinchey.
Mr. HINCHEY. We have kept you awhile, Mr. Chairman. I want
to pose one last question in sort of a larger context. We have been
talking about the deficit today to some extent and the impact of the
deficit on the economy and what might happen to the economy if
the deficit came down, and so forth. In fact, the deficit is down substantially in real terms and also as a function of the gross domestic
product. The deficit today, I think, is about 2.5 percent of GDP
whereas just a few years ago, at the end of 1992, it was 4.5 percent
of GDP. The political rhetoric is changing also, and it seems to be
changing at least from moving away from denying people benefits
in the society to talking more about growth.
That to me raises a question about this deficit and our present
economic circumstances in its historical context. We have a national debt now of almost $5 trillion, most of which was accumulated during the decade of the 1980's, ostensibly in the struggle
during the cold war, the struggle against the Soviet Union. That
national debt is about, as I understand it, 60 percent of GDP. At
the end of the Second World War we had a national debt of about
120 percent of GDP. We didn't embrace a program of austerity at
this particular moment to deal with that particular circumstance,
but, rather, in the Truman and the Eisenhower Administrations we
moved forward with the interstate highway system. We created the
GI Bill of Rights, and we sought to expand opportunities within the
society and to promote growth and to stimulate economic development in transportation and other areas.
None of that discussion seems to be relevant today, or at least
very few people are talking about addressing our economic problems in the context of promoting that kind of growth although Mr.
Buchanan, I believe to his credit, recently has said something to
the effect that no one can tell me that there is no relationship between the deficit and the loss of jobs that pay a good salary; he
said $40 to $50 an hour. They would be very good jobs indeed, but
in any case, the loss of jobs that pay a decent salary.
My question to you is, should we be in this context of, if we continue to talk about the deficit and the debt and that continues to
dominate our political discussion, should we be talking about it in
the context of austerity, taking people's health care away, cutting
back on education, removing financing from environmental protection? Or should we more profitably be talking about it in the
sense of economic growth, increasing opportunity, expanding the
economy?
Mr. GREENSPAN. First let me put a little perspective on the immediate post-World War II issue. We came out of the war and the
Great Depression of the 1930's with a huge pent-up demand which
created an extraordinary period of very strong growth for a protracted number of years. A not insignificant element in that was
the fact that the population was growing fairly rapidly, that the
labor force and household formation, for example, were moving
fairly rapidly as we moved into the 1960's and the 1970's. And as
a consequence of that, with labor force growth probably twice wha
it is now, you actually had a very dramatic increase in overall eco
nomic growth from which very large revenues, Federal revenues




30

were achieved. Where at the same time, even though we had a very
large military budget, a goodly part of the retirement programs
which we put in place in that period did not take hold until a couple of decades later. So you had a situation there in which you kept
the budget balanced. And with nominal GDP rising reasonably fast,
even though inflation wasn't a big issue, the debt level did not increase; but as a ratio to gross domestic product, it came down very
dramatically.
In today's environment we do not have the demographics which
enable us to have the type of growth in employment and labor force
and household formation which we did back then. So we are fighting the demographic problem, which is not insignificant.
If we knew for certain that we could create a major increase in
economic growth, yes, that would resolve our budget problems in
the same way that it did back then. We cannot know for certain.
But we can know for certain that, if we don't address these issues
and we get the types of numbers which research operations are indicating—for example, for Social Security in the year 2030—we are
going to have some very serious problems in this country.
So my judgment is we try to do both. We recognize that getting
increased growth will be very helpful for a lot of reasons in this
country. But we also have to recognize that it is not easy to increase growth and that, if we count on it and fail, we are putting
at risk too much of the standard of living of this country.
So I would say to you that in the event that you aggressively address the expenditure side of the budget and get the deficit down
under very modest economic assumptions, and find after the fact
that you are also able to get economic growth moving at a fairly
pronounced rate, and suppose this issue I raised earlier about the
technology kicks in sooner rather than later, we will be in a very
fortunate position. Then we will have far more in the way of resources both private and public to do lots of things.
But my own judgment is that is not a foregone conclusion. I don't
know what the timing of it is, but if we count on it and we are
wrong and we don't do anything, I think the costs are wholly
unacceptable.
Mr. HlNCHEY. I thank you for that. I would just suggest that, insofar as the demographics are concerned, that there are substantial
similarities between the demographics of today and those of the
post-World War II era, and they exist in this country in a very dramatically increasing underclass in which there is extraordinary
pent-up demand, and in the shrinking middle class and the uncertainty that exists as a result of declining job availability, and that
unless we deal with those problems, unless we deal with the problems of job opportunities for what is rapidly becoming almost half
of the American population, then we will have placed ourselves in
a very serious situation indeed. Those demographics when you consider them in that way, I think, are not too dissimilar from the circumstances that existed just after the end of the Second World
War.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I think that the issue of job opportunities and
,he reduction of the pervasive sense of job insecurity is an issue
vhich I think we have to address and address as expeditiously as
ve can.




31

Mr. HlNCHEY. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Thank you, Mr. Hinchey. Mr. Leach or Mr.
LoBiondo.
Mr. LoBiONDO. I have a brief question.
Gold has been used by many as an indicator of inflationary pressure. Yesterday it was trading at just over $405, and we have seen
even higher than that this year. Last week Ed Baney, the President of the Philadelphia Federal Reserve, was quoted as saying,
there are many nonmonetary influences on the price of gold, and
he wouldn't necessarily read any monetary or inflationary implications into what is happening in the price of gold. To look at the
price of gold to automatically derive an inflationary message from
it, he thinks, just isn't compatible with our experience.
Could you please tell us what kind of message we should get
from these rather high gold prices?
Mr. GREENSPAN. My colleague here just indicated to me that the
price of gold is now $399 bid, which is down significantly. I have
said before this subcommittee on many occasions that I think the
price of gold itself is a very good indicator, useful indicator of inflationary expectations. The reason is that virtually all of the gold
that has ever been produced still exists in the world. Small changes
in production or consumption in any particular year do not really
affect that base.
As a consequence, what you are looking at over the years is a
metal which people have classically run to in periods where there
have been concerns about the nature of the currency or paper
money, so to speak. It is important for us to know when inflationary expectations are rising and when they are falling. Indeed, we
can do that in a number of ways, of which gold is a very important
indicator.
I don't want to say in any particular instance exactly how we
evaluate it, because that is getting into the details of how we look
at the world as a whole and the degree of potential problems which
might or might not require central bank policy to adjust to it. But
I would say to you that we do watch the price of gold, as indeed
we watch a lot of other indicators, because we find that they are
very useful in giving us an insight into the overall process, namely
the inflation process, which over the years has been very detrimental to the structure of our economy when it has been pervasive and
very detrimental to growth.
So we are concerned when we see the gold price fluctuate significantly, because it is probably telling us something. And we better
find out whether it is telling us something about inflationary expectations that are changing or whether there are, as there occur on
occasion, short-term technical factors which create changes in the
price which are not necessarily directly related to change in inflation expectations.
Mr. LoBiONDO. Thank you.
Chairman CASTLE. Does any Member of the subcommittee have
anything further they wish to ask or state?
If not, Mr. Chairman, let me again thank you for being here. You
have always impressed me when you come here at your willingness
to listen to our questions and actually answer the questions. That




32

doesn't always happen when one deals with politicians, and we appreciate that.
I haven't seen a question on the economy that you could not answer. I have seen some that you would not answer, but maybe next
time we will get some of those answered as well. I think your appearance here and before the Senate, which I believe is tomorrow,
is reassuring to all of us who do have questions. We hope we represent our constituents when we ask these questions to make sure
we understand how the economy is doing, what steps are being
taken at the Federal Reserve. While it is somewhat of a mystery
to a number of individuals, it is vitally important to this country.
We thank you again and wish you the very best of luck in the
future and look forward to having you before us the next time
around in 6 months or so. Thank you.
The subcommittee stands adjourned.
[Whereupon, at 4:20 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]







33

APPENDIX

February 20, 1996

34
House Committee on Banking and Financial Services
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary policy
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearing with testimony from Alan Greenspan,
Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, February 20, 1996, Room
2128 Rayburn House Office Building
Chairman Michael N. Castle's Opening Remarks:
The Subcommittee will come to order.
This subcommittee is meeting today to once again receive the
semi-annual report of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System on the conduct of monetary policy and the state of
the economy as mandated in the Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act of 1978.
Chairman Greenspan, it is always a pleasure to welcome you
to the Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy
of the House Banking and Financial Services Committee. Today, we
have fewer members than usual because the House is in recess.
Nevertheless, those who are present look forward to our exchange.
As usual, any prepared remarks submitted by members will be
accepted for the record.
Since our last hearing, we have seen the Fed continue on its
new course of gradually lowering interest rates. Currently, the
US economy is in its sixtieth month of economic expansion,
approximately ten months beyond the average expansion. While we
welcome continued expansion, concern tempers our enthusiasm. The
economy slowed to a growth rate of 1.4% for the first three
quarters of 1995; this growth rate is below Fed targets. Pundits
divide on whether the "soft landing" to slower growth has been
achieved or the economy is being pushed back into recession.
Some dispute whether the economy is softening too much, or
alternatively, we are merely experiencing a current inventory
draw-down cycle which will be succeeded by increased demand and
additional non-inflationary growth. Interpreting the indicators
at these junctures is a chancy business, so we welcome any
comments you care to make on what you see ahead with regard to
inflationary pressures, the international value of the dollar and
the future of interest rates, to name a couple of items.
As we are in the run up to a national election, we would be
most interested in hearing your opinion on the impact of a
balanced budget agreement on the financial markets and on
inflationary expectations both here and abroad.
Your Chairmanship of the Federal Reserve continues to be
marked by unprecedented openness both with Congress and the
public. Indeed, you have personally become a symbol of probity
and stability that markets and the public look to for reassurance




35
on the economy. We appreciate this and look forward to your
timely reappointment.
Finally, the Humphrey-Hawkins bill sets goals for the
Administration and the Federal Reserve System to pursue that are
outdated, inconsistent or conflicting. Most of the bill's
mandates have been more honored in the breach, especially those
that apply to the Executive. To the extent that these
inconsistent goals actually hamper the Fed's ability to optimize
its operations, we may have an opportunity to revisit this
legislative charter in conjunction with the other house. We
might then consider improvements or adjustments to your mandate
that would make monetary operations more effective.
We are prepared for a lively discussion.




36
FRANK A. LoBIONDO

BANKING AND FINANCIAL
SERVICES

n 513 CANNON House OFFICE BUILDINI
WASHINGTON, DC 20515-3002

202-225-6572
FAX 202-225-3318
5914 MAIN STREET
IAVS LANDING. NJ 08330
609-625-5008

,_
^

. .
„ ,.
,„,_., ^ , , , .
„ . ^,^, „ _ - .,.„
_,^....^^
.^..^.^^
--- ....--^
^. .^. ». ^

Congress of tjje Bntteb
~" "

- - - - - — " —-

SMALL BUSINESS

: o! ^epresfentatibe^
tjtngton, BC 20515-3002
Statement of Congressman Frank A. LoBiondo
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy
Committee on Banking and Financial Services
Humphrey-Hawkins Hearing
February 20, 1996

I would like to welcome Chairman Greenspan to the Subcommittee again. I look
forward to hearing the Chairman both today and later this summer once he has been
reappointed and confirmed as head of the Federal Reserve Board.
This is the third time that I have had the pleasure of participating in the semiannual
Humphrey-Hawkins hearings. One thing that I have learned from the two previous occasions
is that there are many different statistics and indicators used by economists to predict future
trends in our economy. I have further found that many of these predictions can be likened to
necromancy. That is why having the Chairman to testify is so very helpful and enlightening.
In July, Chairman Greenspan told us that inventory overhang had been substantial in
several important areas, and that "attempts to control inventory levels triggered cutbacks in
orders and output that inevitably put a damper on employment and income."1 Last Friday, the
Federal Reserve reported that industrial production had fallen by .6 percent in January. While
some of this is attributable to the severe weather, I would like to know how much of this the
Chairman would attribute to continued inventory cutbacks.
TJI its recent decision to reduce both the federal funds rate and the discount rate by 25
basis points, the Federal Open Market Committee cited "moderating economic expansion."
This decision has provided additional impetus to a discussion over what the appropriate rate of
economic growth should be. J-ast fall, different people began to argue for a sustainable
growth rate of anywhere between 3 and 4 percent. In the past week, we have heard another
call for a "debate" on what is the appropriate rate of growth for the economy.
At first glance, a call for higher growth and more jobs seems like an excellent idea that
benefits everyone. However, closer examination of this issue in the context of monetary
policy brings many other questions to the surface. One of the most significant impacts of
higher growth estimates occurs in the budgetary process. By predicting higher "sustainable

1
Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Testimony before the House
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy, July 19, 1995, p. 3.




37
growth" which implies more economic development without surges in inflation that increase
the cost of government borrowing, it becomes very easy to balance the budget in seven years.
Taken in concert with calls for higher levels of government expenditure and taxes, the problem
with this approach is that is has been tried before and proven to work only on paper and in
rhetoric. We quickly learned the opinion of the bond market in this debate when it responded
with falling prices and increased interest rates.
I am deeply concerned about the economy in my district in Southern New Jersey and
am working to promote economic growth in the region. According to data from the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, we have seen unemployment rates fall from double digits in
1994 to 8.9 percent in the Vineland-Millville-Bridgeton area and to 8.6 percent in the Atlantic
City area. While this is very encouraging, we must do whatever we can to bring this rate down
even more. I do not believe, however, that continued deficit spending will help the situation.
Even John Maynard Keynes did not support the notion of constant government interference.
As he wrote in 1934, "I see the problem of-recovery [from the Depression] in the following
light: how soon will normal business enterprise come to the rescue? On what scale, by which
expedients, and for how long is abnormal government expenditure advisable?"2 I believe that
it is clear to most of us that deficit spending of more than $200 billion each year, in
conjunction with $4.9 trillion in debt, qualifies as abnormal and that it is no longer advisable
to continue down such a path.
Chairman Greenspan has told us repeatedly that "[e]conomic prospects for the long run
will be further enhanced if Congress and the Administration succeed in making further
progress in reducing the federal budget deficit."3 Rather than debating whether monetary
policy should allow a growth rate of 3 to 4 percent which might cause the economy to overheat
and thereby spur inflation, I believe that we should finish the work that we have begun on
balancing the budget and allow the private sector to come to the rescue and operate without the
market distortions caused by massive government borrowing and spending.
•s.

I have several questions for Chairman Greenspan and look forward to his answers.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I yield back the balance of my time.

2
John Maynard Keynes. New York Times, June 10, 1934, quoted in Robert L. Heilbroner, The Worldly
Philosophers 277 (Updated sixth ed, Touchstone 1992).

'Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Monetary Policy Report to the Congress Pursuant to the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, Feb. 21, 1995, p. 4.




38
For release on delivery
2:00 p.m. E.S.T.
February 20. 1996

Statement by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Subcommittee on Domestic and International Monetary Policy




Committee on Banking and Financial Services
U.S. House of Representatives

February 20, 1996

39
I appreciate the opportunity to appear before this Committee
to present the Federal Reserve's semiannual report on monetary policy.
The United States economy performed reasonably well in 1995.
One-and-three-quarter million new jobs were added to payrolls over the
year, and the unemployment rate was at the lowest sustained level in
five years.

Despite the relatively high level of resource

utilization, inflation remained well contained, with the consumer
price index rising less than 3 percent — the fifth year running at 3
percent or below.

A reduction in inflation expectations, together

with anticipation of significant progress toward eliminating federal
budget deficits, was reflected in financial markets, where long-term
interest rates dropped sharply and stock prices rose dramatically over
the year.
This outcome was influenced in part by monetary policy
actions taken by the Federal Reserve in recent years.

Responding to

evidence that inflationary pressures were building, we progressively
raised short-term interest rates over 1994 and early 1995.

Rates had

been purposely held at quite low, stimulative levels in 1993.

We

moved in 1994 to levels more consistent with sustainable growth.

Our

intent was to be preemptive--to head off an incipient increase in
inflationary pressures and to forestall the emergence of imbalances
that so often in the past have undermined economic, expansions.
As we entered the spring of 1995, it became increasingly
evident that our policy was likely to succeed.

Although various price

indexes were rising a bit more rapidly, there were indications that
pressures would not continue to intensify, and might even reverse to a
degree.

Moderating overall demand growth left businesses with excess

inventories.

In response, firms initiated production cutbacks to

prevent serious inventory imbalances, and the growth of economic




40
activity slowed substantially.

With inflation pressures apparently

receding, the previous degree of restraint in monetary policy was no
longer deemed necessary, and the Federal Open Market Committee
consequently implemented a small reduction in reserve market pressures
last July.
During the summer and early fall, aggregate demand growth
strengthened.

As a result, business stocks of raw materials and

finished goods appeared somewhat better aligned with sales.

In sum,

the economy, as hoped, appeared to have moved onto a trajectory that
could be maintained--one less steep than in 1994, when the rate of
growth was clearly unsustainable, but one that nevertheless would
imply continued

significant growth in employment and incomes.

Importantly, the performance of the economy seemed to be
consistent with maintaining low inflation.

Despite the step-up in

growth and the relatively high levels of resource utilization,
measured inflation abated a little, and many of the signs that had
been pointing toward greater price pressures gradually disappeared.
Expectations of both near- and longer-term inflation

fell

substantially over the second half of the year, as gauged by survey
results as well as by the downward movements in longer-term interest
rates.

The fall in bond rates was also encouraged by improving

prospects for significant
deficit.

progress in reducing the federal budget

The declines in actual and expected inflation meant that

maintaining the existing nominal federal funds rate would raise real
short-term interest rates, implying a slight effective firming in the
stance of monetary policy.

Such a shift would have been particularly

inappropriate because economic growth near the end of the year seemed
to be slowing, and some FOMC members were concerned about the risks of




41
prolonged sluggishness.

Consequently, the Committee "decided in

December that a further reduction in the funds rate was warranted.
Information becoming available in late December and January
raised additional questions about the prospective pace of expansion.
The situation was difficult to judge, partly because economic
statistics were more sparse than usual, owing mainly to the government
shutdowns.

In addition, harsh weather in January disrupted both data

flows and patterns of economic activity.

But several indicators--

including initial claims for unemployment insurance, purchasing
managers' surveys, and consumer confidence measures--appeared to
signal some softening in the economy.

Consonant with this pattern,

some Reserve Bank Presidents reported that they seemed to be detecting
anecdotal indications of weakness in the expansion within their
districts with somewhat greater frequency than previously.

Moreover,

growth in several of our major trading partners seemed to be lagging,
which could tend to moderate demand for exports.
A number of factors have prompted the recent tendency toward
renewed weakness.

Some are clearly quite transitory--related, for

example, to bad weather or the Federal government shutdown.
may be somewhat more significant, but still temporary.

Others

The constraint

on government spending while permanent budget authorizations are being
negotiated is one.

Another may be a temporary reduction in output in

some industries as businesses have further adjusted inventories to
disappointing sales.

As I noted last July, the change in the pace of

inventory investment when the economy shifts gears can be substantial.
Inventory investment surged in 1994 and into the early months of 1995,
but proceeded to fall markedly throughout the rest of the year.

This

has placed significant downward pressure on output, which should lift




42
as inventory adjustments subside.

But"for the moment, the pressures

remain, in the motor vehicle industry and elsewhere.
Ultimately, of course, it is the path of final demand after
the temporary influences work themselves out that determines the
trajectory of the economy.

There are some factors, such as high

consumer debt levels, that may be working to restrain spending.

But

as I shall be detailing shortly, a number of fundamentals point to an
economy basically on track for sustained growth, so any weakness is
likely to be temporary.

Nonetheless, the Committee decided in late

January that the evidence suggested sufficient risk of subpar
performance going forward to warrant another slight easing of the
stance of monetary policy.

Given the subdued trends in costs and

wages, the odds that such a move would boost inflation pressures
seemed low.
In assessing the likely course of the economy and the
appropriate stance of policy, one question is the significance, if
any, of the age of the business expansion.

Some analysts, viewing

recent weakness, have observed that the expansion is approaching the
start of its sixth year and is now one of the longer peacetime spans
of growth in the past half century.
not necessarily die of old age.

Economic expansions, however, do

Although the factors governing each

individual business cycle are not always clear, expansions usually end
because serious imbalances eventually develop.
When aggregate demand exceeds the economy's potential, for
example, inflationary pressures pick up.

The inevitable increase in

Tiarket interest rates, as inflation expectations rise and price
pressures intensify, depresses final demand.

Lagging demand in turn

;ets off an inventory correction that frequently triggers a downturn
n the economy.




As I noted, we acted in 1994 to forestall such a

43
process.

Monetary policy began to tighten in advance of the buildup

of inflationary pressures and, at least to date, these pressures
appear to have been held in check.
Capital expenditures by households and firms can also
contribute significantly to the development of cycle-ending
imbalances.

The level of stocks of such real assets have effects on

output very similar to those of business inventories.

In typical

cycles, capital expenditures tend to grow rapidly in the early stages
of recovery:

Pent-up demands coming out of a recession by consumers

and businesses are satisfied by rapid growth of spending on capital
assets.

There is a limit, however, on, say,.how many cars people

choose to own, or how many square feet of floor space retailers need
to service customers.

Spending on such assets generally tends to grow

more slowly after the pent-up demand is met.

As with business

inventories, the downshifting of spending on consumer durable goods or
business plant and equipment may not occur smoothly.

The dynamics of

expanding output and rising profit expectations often create a degree
of exuberance which, as in much of human nature, tends on occasion to
excess--in this case, in the form of a temporary over-accumulation of
assets.

The ensuing correction in demand for such assets triggers

production adjustments that can significantly mute growth for a time
or even cause a downturn if the imbalances are large enough.
The current extent of any asset overhang is difficult to
determine.

The growth of demand for durables and some categories of

capital goods evidently has slowed, but the available evidence does
not suggest a degree of saturation in capital assets that would tip
the economy into a downturn.
Moreover, financial conditions are likely to be generally
supportive of spending.




The low level of long-term interest rates

44
should have an especially favorable effect.

Low rates increase the

affordability of housing for consumers and foster investment in
productive plant and equipment by businesses.

The decline in interest

rates also has contributed to a pronounced rise in stock prices.

The

spread of mutual fund investments has meant that the gain in wealth as
financial asset prices have risen has been shared by an ever-wider
segment of households.

These developments should tend to counter, in

part, the depressing effects on spending of rising debt burdens.

In

addition, with the condition of most financial institutions strong,
lenders are likely to remain willing to extend credit to firms and
households on favorable terms.

We have seen some move by lenders

toward tighter standards, but these actions are a modest correction
after a marked swing toward ease and should not constrain the
availability of funds to creditworthy borrowers.
Against this backdrop. Federal Reserve policymakers

expect

the most likely outcome for 1996 as a whole is further moderate
growth.

On the new chain-weighted basis, the central tendency of the

forecasts of Board members and Reserve Bank Presidents is for real
gross domestic product to expand 2 to 2-1/4 percent on a fourthquarter to fourth-quarter basis, similar to the Administration's
outlook.

With output expanding roughly in line with standard

estimates of the increase in the productive capacity of the economy,
the unemployment

rate is expected to remain around recent levels, as

is also forecast by the Administration.
The Federal Open Market Committee expects a continuation of
reasonably good inflation performance in 1996.

The success during

1995 in keeping the increase in the consumer price index below 3
percent in the fifth year of an expansion illustrates that an extended
period of growth with low inflation is possible.




And most on the

45
Committee anticipate consumer price inflation at or somewhat below 3
percent in 1996.

Although well-known biases in the CPI, as well as

the more favorable price performance of business equipment, which is
not included in that index, indicate that the true rate of inflation
for the whole economy would be significantly lower than 3 percent, the
Committee recognized that its expectations for inflation do not imply
that price stability has as yet been reached.

Nonetheless, keeping

inflation from rising significantly during economic expansions will
permit a gradual ratcheting down of inflation over the course of
successive business cycles that will eventually result in the
achievement of price stability.
To emphasize its continued commitment to price stability, the
Committee chose to reaffirm the relatively low ranges for money growth
in 1996 that it had selected on a provisional basis last July.

These

ranges are identical to those employed in 1995--1 to 5 percent for M2
and 2 to 6 percent for M3.
percent range for debt.

The Committee also reaffirmed the 3 to 7

Patterns of money growth and velocity have

been erratic in recent years, but should the monetary aggregates at
some point re-establish their previous trend relationships with
nominal income, average growth near the center of these ranges should
be consistent with the eventual achievement of price stability.
Determining whether further changes to the stance of monetary
policy will be necessary in the months ahead to foster progress toward
our goals will be a continuing challenge.

In formulating monetary

policy, while we have in mind a forecast of the most likely outcome,
we must also evaluate the consequences of other possible developments.
Thus, it is sometimes the case that we take out monetary policy
"insurance" when we perceive an imbalance in the net costs or benefits
of coming out on one side or the other of the most probable scenario.




46
For example, in our most recent actions, we saw a decline in the
federal funds rate as not increasing inflationary risks unacceptably,
while addressing the downside risks to the most likely forecast.

In

assessing the costs and benefits of adjustments to the stance of
policy, members of the Committee recognize that policy affects the
economy and inflation with a lag and thus needs to be formulated with
a focus on the future.

Over the past year, we have kept firmly in

mind our goals of containing inflation in the near term and moving
over time toward price stability, and they will continue to guide us
in the period ahead.
Structural forces may be assisting us in this regard.
Increases in producers' costs and in output prices proved to be a
little lower last year than many had anticipated.

While it is too

soon to draw any definitive conclusions, this experience provides some
tentative evidence that basic, ongoing changes in the structure of the
economy may be helping to hold down price pressures.

These changes

stem from the introduction of new technologies into a wide variety of
production processes throughout the economy.

Successive generations

of these new technologies are being quickly embodied in the nation's
capital stock and older technologies are, at a somewhat slower pace,
being phased out.

As a consequence, the nation's capital stock is

turning over at an increasingly rapid pace, not primarily because of
physical deterioration but reflecting technological and economic
obsolescence.
The more rapid advance of information and communications
technology and the associated acceleration in the turnover of the
capital stock are being mirrored in a brisk restructuring of firms.
In line with their adoption of new organizational structures and
technologies, many enterprises are finding that their needs for




47
various forms of labor are evolving just as quickly.

In some cases,

the job skills that were adequate only five years ago are no longer as
relevant.

Partly for that reason, most corporate restructurings have

involved a significant number of permanent dismissals.
The phenomenon of restructuring can be especially unfortunate
for those workers directly caught up in the process.

Many dedicated,

long-term workers in all types of American businesses-- including longestablished, stable, and profitable firms--have been let go.
An important consequence of the layoffs and dismissals
associated with restructuring activity is a significant and widely
reported increase in the sense of job insecurity.

Concern about

employment has been manifested in unusually low levels of indicators
of labor unrest.
low last year.

Work stoppages, for example, were at a fifty-year
And contract negotiators for labor unions have sought

to obtain greater job security for their members through very longterm labor contracts, including some with virtually unprecedented
lengths of five or six years.
Of particular relevance to the inflation outlook, the sense
of job insecurity is having a pronounced effect in damping labor
costs.

For example, the increase in the employment cost index for

compensation in the private sector, which includes both wage and
salary payments and benefit costs, slowed further in 1995, to 2-3/4
percent, despite labor market conditions that, by historical standards, were fairly tight.

With productivity also expanding, the

increase in unit labor costs was even lower.

In manufacturing, such

costs have actually been falling in recent years.

While the link

between labor costs, which account for two-thirds of consolidated
business sector costs, and prices is not rigid, these very limited




48
increases in labor expenses nonetheless constitute a significant
restraint on inflation.
In addition to its effect on labor costs, the more rapid pace
of technological change is reducing business costs through other
channels.

Initially most important, the downsizing of products

resulting from semiconductor technologies, together with the
increasing proportion of national output accounted for by high-tech
products, has reduced costs of transporting the average unit of GDP.
Quite simply, small products can be moved more quickly and at lower
cost.
More recently, dramatic advances in telecommunications
technologies have lowered the costs of production for a variety of
products by slashing further the information component of those costs.
Increasingly, the physical distance between communications

endpoints

is becoming less relevant in determining the difficulty and cost of
transporting information.

Once fiber-optic and satellite technologies

are in place, the added resource cost of another 200 or 2,000 miles is
often quite trivial.

As a consequence, the movement of inputs and

outputs across geographic distance is progressively becoming a smaller
component of overall business expenses, particularly as intellectual-and therefore immaterial--products become proportionately more
important in the economy.

This enables an average- business firm to

broaden markets and sales far beyond its original domicile.
Accordingly, fixed costs are spread more widely.

For the world market

as a whole, the specialization of labor is enhanced to the benefit of
standards of living of all market participants.
To be sure, advancing technology, with its profound
implications for the nature of the economy, is nothing new, and the
pace of improvement has never been even.




But it is possible that we

49
may be in the midst of a quickening of the process.

It is possible

that the rate at which earlier computer technologies are being applied
to new production processes is still increasing.
the recent decline in the growth of unit costs.

This would explain
Nonetheless, we have

to be careful in projecting a further acceleration in the application
of technology indefinitely into the future, as would be required for
technological change to depress the rate of increase in unit business
costs even more.

Similarly, suppressed wage cost growth as a

consequence of job insecurity can be carried only so far.

At some

point in the future, the tradeoff of subdued wage growth for job
security has to come to an end.

While it is difficult to judge the

time frame on such adjustments, the risks to cost and price inflation
going forward are not entirely skewed to the downside, especially with
the economy so recently operating at high levels of resource
utilization.
In light of the quickened pace of technological change, the
question arises whether the U.S. economy can expand more rapidly on an
ongoing basis than the 2 to 2-1/4 percent range for measured GDP
forecasted for 1996 by government agencies and most private
forecasters without adding to inflationary pressures, which in turn
would undermine growth.

The Federal Reserve would certainly welcome

faster growth--provided that it is sustainable.
The particular rate of maximum sustainable growth in an
economy as complex and ever-changing as ours is difficult to pin down.
Fortunately, the Federal Reserve does not need to have a firm judgment
on such an estimate, for persistent deviations of actual growth from
that of capacity potential will soon send signals that a policy
adjustment is needed.

Should the nation's true growth potential

exceed actual growth, for example, the disparity and lessened strain




50
would be signaled in shorter lead times on the delivery of materials,
declining overtime, and ebbing inflationary pressures.

Conversely,

actual growth in excess of the economy's true potential would soon
result in tightened markets and other distortions which, as history
amply demonstrates, would propel the economy into recession.
Consequently, we must be cautious in reaching conclusions that growth
in productivity and hence of potential output has as yet risen to
match the evident step-up in technological advance.
The hypothesis that advancing technology has enhanced
productivity growth would be more persuasive if national data on
productivity increases showed a distinct improvement.

To a degree,

the lack of any marked pickup may be a shortcoming of the statistics
rather than a refutation of the hypothesis.

Faulty data could be

arising in part because business purchases are increasingly
concentrated in items that are expensed but which market prices
suggest should be capitalized.

Growing disparities between book

capital and its valuation in equity markets may in part reflect
widening effects of this misclassification.

If this problem is indeed

growing, we may be underestimating the growth of our GDP and
productivity.
This classification problem compounds other difficulties with
measuring output in the increasingly important service sector.

The

output of services--and the productivity of labor in that sector--is
particularly hard to measure.

In part, the statisticians have simply

thrown up their hands, gauging output in some service industries just
in terms of labor input.

By construction, such a procedure will miss

improvements in productivity caused by other inputs.

In

manufacturing, where output is more tangible and therefore easier to




51
assess, measured productivity has been rising briskly, suggesting that
technological advances are indeed having some effect.
Nonetheless, there is still a nagging inconsistency:

The

evidence of significant restructurings and improvements in technology
and real costs within business establishments does not seem to be
fully reflected in our national productivity measurements.

It is

possible that some of the frenetic pace of business restructuring is
mere wheel spinning--changing production inputs without increasing
output--rather than real increases in productivity.

One cause of the

wheel spinning, if that is what it is, may be that it takes some time
for firms to adapt in such a way that major new technology is
translated into increased output.
In an intriguing parallel, electric motors in the late
nineteenth century were well-known as a technology, but were initially"
integrated into production systems that were designed for steam-driven
power plants.

It wasn't until the gradual conversion of previously

vertical factories into horizontal facilities, mainly in the 1920s,
that firms were able to take full advantage of the synergies implicit
in the electric dynamo, thus achieving dramatic productivity
increases.

Analogously, existing production systems today to some

degree cannot be integrated easily with new information and
communication technologies.

Some existing equipment is not capable of

control by computer, for example.

Thus, it may be that the full

advantage of even the current generation of information and
communication equipment will be exploited over a span of quite a few
years and only after a considerably updated stock of physical capital
has been put in place.
While the Federal Reserve does not need to establish




52
targets--and definitely not limits --for" long-term growth, it is
helpful in coming to shorter-run policy insights to have some
judgments about the growth in potential GDP in the past and what it is
likely to be in the future.
are based on experience.

Judgments of potential, quite naturally,

Through the four quarters of 1994, for

example, real GDP, pressed by strong demand, rose 3-1/2 percent.

If

that were the true rate of increase in the economy's long-run
potential, then we would have expected no change in rates of resource
utilization.

Instead, industrial capacity utilization

percentage points and the unemployment
point.

rose nearly 3

rate dropped a percentage

Moreover, we began to see signs of strains on facilities:

deliveries of materials slowed appreciably and factory overtime rose
sharply.

These signs of developing pressures on capacity suggest that

the growth rate in economic potential in 1994 was below 3-1/2 percent.
In general, as we get close to presumed potential, we are required to
step up our surveillance

for inflationary pressures.

Estimates of potential growth necessarily recognize that
expansion in the economy over time comes essentially

from three

factors--growth in population, increases in labor force participation,
and gains in average labor productivity.

Of these factors, the first

two are determined basically by demographic and social factors and
seem unlikely to change dramatically over the next few years.

Thus,

the source of any significant pickup of output growth would need to be
a more rapid pace of productivity growth.

Here, the uncertainty of

the pace of conversion of rapid technological advance into
productivity gains is crucial to the determination.
To be fully effective in achieving potential productivity
improvements, technological innovations also require a considerable
amount of human investment on the part of workers who have to deal




53
with these devices on a day-to-day basis.
not have progressed very far.

On this score, we still may

Many workers still possess only

rudimentary skills in manipulating advanced information technology.
In these circumstances, firms and employees alike need to recognize
that obtaining the potential rewards of the new technologies in the
years ahead will require a renewed commitment to effective education
and training, especially on-the-job training.

This is especially the

case if we are to prevent the disruptions to lives and the nation's
capacity to produce that arise from mismatches between jobs and
workers.

We need to improve the preparation for the job market our

schools do, but even better schools are unlikely to be able to provide
adequate skills to support a lifetime of work.

Indeed, the need to

ensure that our labor force has the ongoing education and training
necessary to compete in an increasingly sophisticated world economy is
a critical task for the years ahead.
Our nation faces many important and difficult challenges in
economic policy.

Nonetheless, we have made significant and

fundamental gains in macroeconomic performance in recent years that
enhance the prospects for maximum sustainable economic growth.
Inflation, as measured by the consumer price index, has been gradually
reduced from a peak of more than 13 percent in 1979 to 2-1/2 percent
last year.

Lower rates of inflation have brought a variety of

benefits to the economy, including lower long-term interest rates, a
sense of greater economic stability, an improved environment for
household and business planning, and more robust investment in capital
expenditures.

The years ahead should see further progress against

inflation and the eventual achievement of price stability.
We have also made considerable progress on the fiscal front
Over the past ten years and especially since 1993, our elected




54
political leaders, through sometimes prolonged and even painful
negotiations, have been successful in reaching several agreements that
have significantly narrowed the budget deficit.
be done.

But more remains to

As I have emphasized many times, lower budget deficits are

the surest and most direct way to increase national saving.

Higher

national saving would help to reduce real interest rates further,
promoting more rapid accumulation of productive capital embodying
recent technological advances.

Agreement is widely shared that

attaining a higher national saving rate quite soon is crucial,
particularly in view of the anticipated shift in the nation's
demographics in the first few decades of the next century.
Lower inflation and reduced budget deficits will by no means
solve all of the economic problems we face.

But -the achievement of

price stability and federal budget balance or surplus will provide the
best possible macroeconomic climate in which the nation can address
other economic challenges.




55
Alan Greenspan
Alan Greenspan was appointed in March of 1992 for a second fouryear term as Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.
Mr. Greenspan also serves as Chairman of the
Federal Open Market Committee, the System's principal monetary
policymaking body. He is currently serving a second full term as
a member of the Board of Governors, ending in January of 2006. His
reappointment status as Chairman is expected to be announced in
March of 1996.
Mr. Greenspan served as Chairman and President of TownsendGreenspan & Co., Inc., an economic consulting firm in New York
City.
He was Chairman of the President's Council of Economic
Advisors under President Ford and was Chairman of the National
Commission of Social Security Reform.
Mr. Greenspan has also
served as a member of President Reagan's Economic Policy Advisory
Board, a member of Time magazine's Board of Economists, a senior
advisor to the Brookings Panel on Economic Activity, and a
consultant to the Congressional Budget Office.
Former presidential appointments have included the President's
Foreign Intelligence Advisory Board, the Commission on Financial
Structure and Regulation, the Commission on an All-Volunteer Armed
Force, and the Task Force on Economic Growth.
His education was received at New York University.
He earned a
B.S. in economics in 1948, a M.A. in economics in 1950, and a Ph.D.
in economics in 1977. Mr. Greenspan has also performed advanced
graduate study at Columbia University.




56
For use at 2:00 p.m., E.S.T.
Tuesday
February 20,1996

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Monetary Policy Report to the Congress
Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978

February 20, 1996




57

Letter of Transmittal

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Washington, D.C., February 20, 1996
THE PRESIDENT OF THE SENATE
THE SPEAKER OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely,

Alan Greenspan, Chairman




58
Table of Contents
Page
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook

1

Section 2:

The Performance of the Economy

5

Section 3:

Financial, Credit, and Monetary Developments




59
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook
The economy performed well in 1995. Moderate
economic growth kept the unemployment rate at a
relatively low level, and inflation, as measured by the
change in the consumer price index, was in a range
of 3 percent or less for the fifth straight year, the
first such occurrence in thirty years. This desirable
combination of low inflation and low unemployment provided further substantiation of a fundamental
point that the Board has made in past reports—
namely, that there is no trade-off in the long run
between the monetary policy goals of maximum
employment and stable prices set in the Federal
Reserve Act. Indeed, it is by fostering price stability
that a central bank can make its greatest contribution to the efficient operation and overall ability of the
nation's economy to create jobs and advance living
standards over time.
As economic prospects changed in 1995 and early
1996, the Federal Reserve found that promoting full
employment and price stability required several
adjustments in its policy settings. Last February,
the economy still seemed to be pressing against its
potential, and prices were tending to accelerate. To
reduce the risk that inflation might mount, with the
attendant threat to continued economic expansion, the
Federal Open Market Committee raised the federal
funds rate an additional V6 percentage point, to 6 percent. Inflation did, in fact, pick up in the first part
of 1995, but data released during the spring indicated that price pressures were receding, and the
Committee reduced the federal funds rate V* percentage point at its July meeting. Through the remainder of the year, inflation was even more favorable
than had been anticipated in July, and inflation
expectations decreased. In addition, an apparent
slowing of economic activity late in the year further
reduced the potential for inflationary pressures going
forward. To forestall an undue increase in real interest
rates as inflation slowed, and to guard against the
possibility of unnecessary slack developing in the
economy, the Committee eased reserve conditions in
December and again at the end of January 1996,
reducing the federal funds rate by a total of l/2 percentage point.
Monetary policy casings since mid-1995 contributed to declines in short-term market interest rates,
which by mid-February were down 1 to 2 percentage
points from the highs reached early last year.
Intermediate- and long-term rates also moved sharply




lower last year as the risks of rising inflation receded
and as prospects for substantial progress in reducing
the federal budget deficit seemed to improve. As of
mid-February, these rates were !3/4 to 23/4 percentage
points below their levels at the beginning of 1995.
Helped by lower interest rates and favorable earnings,
major equity price indexes rose 30 to 40 percent last
year and have moved still higher in early 1996. These
financial developments reduced the cost to businesses
of financing investment and to households of buying
homes and consumer durables; households were also
aided by substantial additions to financial wealth from
rising bond and equity prices.
The foreign exchange value of the U.S. dollar,
measured in terms of the currencies of the other G-10
countries, fell about 5 percent, on net, during 1995.
The dollar appreciated substantially from the summer
on and has advanced further on balance in 1996 but
not enough to offset a sharp decline that took place in
the first four months of 1995. Interest rates fell in
most other foreign industrial countries, which also
were experiencing slower economic growth, but by
less than the decline in rates in the United States.
Early in 1995, the dollar also was pulled down by the
reactions to the crisis in Mexico, but the negative
influence on the dollar from this source appeared to
lessen as Mexican financial markets stabilized over
the balance of the year. Inflation rates in major industrial countries held fairly steady in 1995 at levels
somewhat lower than those prevailing in this country;
thus, depreciation of the dollar in real terms against
other G-10 currencies was less than the depreciation
in nominal terms. Against the currencies of a broader
group of U.S. trading partners, the dollar's real depreciation in 1995 was even smaller.
Borrowing and spending in the United States was
facilitated not only by lower interest rates but also by
favorable supply conditions in credit markets. Spreads
between interest rates on securities issued by private
firms and those issued by the Treasury generally
remained narrow, and banks continued to ease terms
and qualifying standards on loans to businesses and
households through most of the year. Total debt of
domestic nonfinancial sectors grew slightly more than
5 percent last year, just above the midpoint of the
Committee's 3 percent to 7 percent monitoring range.
Rapid growth of business spending on inventories and
fixed capital early in the year boosted the credit
demands of firms, despite strong corporate profits.

60
Borrowing was also lifted by the financing of heavy
net retirements of equity shares in connection with
mergers and share repurchase programs. Growth of
household debt slowed a bit but remained brisk: consumer credit continued to grow quite rapidly. Federal
debt growth was relatively modest for a second year,
influenced by a lower deficit and constraints on normal seasonal borrowing at year-end owing to the
federal debt ceiling. Outstanding state and local government debt ran off more rapidly than in 1994.
Commercial banks and thrift institutions again
financed a large portion of the borrowing last year;
their share of total outstanding debt of nonfederal
sectors edged up in 1994 and 1995 after declining for
more than fifteen years. The growth in depository
credit was funded primarily with deposits, boosting
the expansion of the broad monetary aggregates. M3
grew 6 percent, at the upper end of its 2 percent to
6 percent annual range established by the Committee
at midyear. Depositories relied heavily on largedenomination time deposits for funding, but retail
deposits also showed gains as declining market interest rates made these deposits more attractive to retail
customers. M2 advanced 41A percent, putting it in the
upper portion of its 1 percent to 5 percent annual
range. The expansion of M2 was the largest in six
years, and its velocity was unchanged after increasing
during the previous three years. Nonetheless, growth
of the aggregate was erratic through the year, and the
stability of its relationship to nominal spending
remains in doubt. Ml declined last year for the first
time since the beginning of the official series in 1959.
An increasing number of banks introduced retail
sweep accounts, which shift money from interestbearing checkable accounts to savings accounts in
order to reduce banks' reserve requirements. Without
these shifts. Ml would have risen in 1995, although
slowly.

Economic Projections for 1996
The relatively small amount of information that is
available for 1996 indicates that the economy has
started off slowly early this year, but fundamental
conditions appear to be more encouraging than
recent data might seem to suggest. Bad weather in
a number of regions and the partial shutdown of
the federal government have been disruptive to the
economy this winter. These influences seem likely to
leave only temporary imprints on spending and
production, creating volatility in incoming data over
the near term while having little effect on underlying trends.




The economy also has been slowed by production
adjustments in some industries in which efforts are
being made to bring stocks into better alignment with
sales. Inventory accumulation apparently slowed in
the fourth quarter, and with financial conditions
remaining broadly conducive to growth of private
final sales, inventory problems of a degree that might
prompt a sustained period of widespread production
adjustments do not seem likely. In the household
sector, the accumulation of financial wealth brought
on by the rise in the stock market has provided the
wherewithal for increases in consumption greater than
would otherwise have been expected—countering the
potential negative influences of more burdensome
levels of consumer debt. At the same time, reductions
in mortgage interest rates have put the cost of financing a house within reach of a greater number of
families and made it possible for a significant number
of households to ease their debt-service burdens by
refinancing their homes at lower rates. In the business
sector, reductions in the cost of financing investment
in new capital are providing some offset to the slowing tendencies that normally accompany a cyclical
moderation in the growth of aggregate output. In
addition, business investment in high-tech equipment
likely will continue to be boosted not only by the
ready availability of finance but also by technological
upgrades and ongoing steep declines in the effective
price of real computing power.
In the U.S. external sector, growth of exports
strengthened after some sluggishness early in 1995.
Expansion of income abroad seems likely to pick up
this year, although the prospects still are subject to
some downside risk. Imports, meanwhile, have
slowed from the very rapid pace seen earlier in the
expansion. On net, the underlying trends in exports
and imports of goods and services appear to be essentially canceling out in terms of their combined contribution to growth of U.S. real GDP.
Against the backdrop of these developments, members of the Board of Governors and the Reserve Bank
Presidents, all of whom participate in the deliberations of the Federal Open Market Committee, anticipate that the U.S. economy will grow moderately,
with little change in underlying inflation trends. The
central tendency of the participants' forecasts of real
GDP growth ranges from 2 percent to 21A percent,
measured as the cumulative change in output from the
final quarter of 1995 to the final quarter of 1996.
The rise in activity is expected to be accompanied
by further expansion of job opportunities and little
change, on net. in the civilian unemployment rate
over the four quarters of 1996. The central tendency

61
Economic Projections for 1996
Percent

Federal Reserve Governors
and Reserve Bank Presidents
Administration
Indicator

Range

Central
Tendency

4-5
1V2-2V
2V2-3

41/4-43/4
2-21/4
23A-3

Change, fourth quarter
to fourth quartet
Nominal GDP
Real GDP*
Consumer price index3

5.1
2.2

3.1

Average level, fourth quarter
Civilian unemployment rate

1. Change from average for fourth quarter of 1995 to average for fourth quarter of 1996.
2. Chain-weighted

of the unemployment rate forecasts for the fourth
quarter of 1996 is a range of 5V6 percent to 53/4 percent, compared with an average of 5.6 percent in the
final quarter of 1995. The Committee's forecasts of
economic growth and unemployment are quite similar
to those of the Administratioa
The central tendency of the Governors' and Bank
Presidents' forecasts of the rise in the consumer price
index over the four quarters of 1996 is a range of
23/4 percent to 3 percent, a shade to the high side of
the actual outcome of 1995. At this early point in
19%, with grain stocks exceptionally tight, there is
some risk that food price increases at retail could be
larger than those of recent years, especially if crop
production should remain subpar again this year, ani
even though recent upward pressures on energy prices
should diminish with the return of normal weather,
another year of declining prices cannot be taken as a
givea Nonetheless, the experience with inflation at
high levels of resource utilization was favorable in
1995, and with businesses still tightly focused on cost
control and efficiency gain, broad tendencies toward
increased rates of price increase are not anticipated.
The Administration forecast of inflation is higher than
the forecasts of the Federal Reserve officials, but the
difference is not significant, given the uncertainties of
forecasting.
Price increases like those being forecast for the
coining year would leave inflation no higher than it




5.74

5V2-6
3. All urban consumers,
4. Annual average.

was in the first year or so of the current economic
expansion, with the rate of increase holding appreciably below the average rate seen during the expansion
of the 1980s. Although the Federal Reserve's longrun goal of restoring price stability has not yet been
achieved, the capping of inflation and its diminution
over recent business cycles is a clear indication of the
substantial progress that has been made to date.

Money and Debt Ranges for 1996
The Committee's intention to make further
progress over time toward price stability formed the
basis for the selection of the growth ranges for the
monetary aggregates in 1996. In reaffirming the
ranges that were adopted on a provisional basis in
July, the Committee noted that it viewed them as
benchmarks for what would be expected under conditions of reasonable price stability and historical velocity behavior. The Committee set the range for M2 at
1 percent to 5 percent and the range for M3 at
2 percent to 6 percent.
Given its expectations for inflation in 1996, the
Committee anticipates that nominal GDP will grow
somewhat faster this year than would be the case if
the economy already were at price stability. If velocities of the aggregates were to exhibit roughly normal
behavior this year and nominal income were to

62
Ranges for Growth of Monetary and Debt Aggregates
Percent
Aggregate

1994

1995

1996

M2

1-5

1-5

1-5

M3

0-4

2-61

2-6

Debt*

4^8

3-7

3-7

Note. Change from average for fourth quarter of preceding year to average for fourth quarter of year indicated.
1. Revised at July 1995 FOMC meeting.

2. Monitoring range for debt of domestic nonfinancial
sectors

expand as anticipated by the Committee, M2 and M3
might grow near the upper ends of their ranges. In
assessing the possible outcomes, the Committee noted
that considerable uncertainty remains about the usefulness of the monetary aggregates in guiding the
pursuit of its macroeconomic objectives. Although
the monetary aggregates have been behaving more in
line with historical patterns than was the case earlier
in the decade, the effects of financial innovation and
deregulation over the years have raised questions
about the stability of the relationships between the

aggregates and nominal GDP that have yet to be
resolved.




The Committee also reaffirmed the 3 percent to
7 percent growth range for debt. Although there are
indications that lenders may no longer be easing
terms and conditions for granting credit to businesses
and households, the Committee anticipated that credit
supplies would remain ample and that debt would
grow at about the same pace as nominal GDP. Such
increases would be consistent with containing inflation and promoting sustainable growth.

63

Section 2: The Performance of the Economy
Measured in terms of the chain-type indexes that
are now being emphasized by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, growth of real GDP averaged
slightly less than 1V6 percent at an annual rate
over the first three quarters of 1995 after a gain of
3V-2 percent in 1994. The rise in aggregate output this
past year was accompanied by an increase in payroll
employment of !3/4 million, and the unemployment
rate, after having fallen sharply in 1994, held fairly
steady over the course of 1995, keeping to a range of
about 5 V2 percent to 53/4 percent. Consumer prices, as
measured by the CPI for all items, rose 23/4 percent
over the four quarters of 1995, an increase that was
virtually the same as those of the two previous years.
Growth of output during the past year was slowed
in part by the actions of businesses to reduce the pace
of inventory accumulation after a burst of stockpiling
in 1994. Final sales—a measure of current output
that does not end up in inventories—rose at an average rate of 2 percent over the first three quarters of
1995 after an increase of 3 percent over the four
quarters of 1994. The slowing of final sales was
largely a reflection of a downshifting in growth of
the real outlays of households and businesses, from
elevated rates of increase in 1994 to rates that were
more sustainable. Real government outlays for consumption and investment edged down slightly, on net,
during the first three quarters of 1995. Increases in
real exports and real imports of goods and services
were smaller than those of 1994; their combined
contribution to GDP growth in the first three quarters
was slightly negative.

Change in Real GDP
Percent annual rate

T
1990

1991

1992




1993

1994

1995

The Household Sector
Real personal consumption expenditures rose at an
annual rate of about 2Vi percent over the first three
quarters of 1995 after having risen slightly more than
3 percent over the four quarters of 1994. Available
data suggest that growth of real outlays slowed
further in the fourth quarter. The reduced rate of rise
in consumption spending this past year came against
the backdrop of moderate gains in employment and
income. The financial wealth of households surged,
but impetus to spending from this source evidently
was countered by other influences, such as increases
in debt burdens among some households and an
apparent rise, according to survey data, in consumers' concerns about job security.
Real consumer expenditures for durable goods
increased at an annual rate of 2:/4 percent over the
first three quarters of 1995, a slower rate of rise than
in other recent years. Consumer expenditures for
motor vehicles declined slightly, on net, over the first
three quarters after moving up nearly 20 percent over
the three previous years; in the fourth quarter, unit
sales of cars and light trucks, a key indicator of real
outlays for vehicles, were down slightly from iheir
third-quarter pace. Incentive programs that provided
price concessions of one sort or another to buyers
probably gave some lift to sales in 1995. However,
"pent-up" demand, which had helped to boost sales
earlier in the expansion, probably was no longer an
important factor. Recent sales data do not seem to
point to any big shifts in demand for vehicles around
the turn of the yean The average rate of sales of cars
and light trucks in December and January was a touch
above the average for 1995 as a whole.
Real outlays for durable goods other than motor
vehicles continued to rise at a brisk pace in 1995, but
not so rapidly as in other recent years. Spending for
furniture and household equipment hit a temporary
lull in the first part of 1995, but picked up again over
the next two quarters, lifted in part by a rebound
in construction of new houses. Fourth-quarter data on
retail sales seem to point to a further sizable increase
in outlays for household durables; according to most
anecdotal accounts, spending for home computers and
other electronic gear, which has been surging in recent
years, continued to move up rapidly through the latter
part of 1995.
Consumer expenditures for nondurables increased
at an annual rate of about 1V* percent, in real terms,

64
over the first three quarters of 1995, a little less than
the average of the previous ten years and considerably
less than in 1994. The growth of real expenditures on
apparel slowed sharply after three years of sizable
advances. In the fourth quarter, real outlays for nondurables appear to have been lackluster.
Real expenditures for services—which account for
more than half of total consumer outlays—increased
at an annual rate of about 23/4 percent over the first
three quarters of 1995, moderately faster than in either
1993 or 1994. After declining in 1994, outlays for
energy services increased sharply over the first three
quarters of 1995: The unusually mild weather of late
1994 gave way, first, to more normal winter conditions in early 1995 and, later on, to hot summer
weather that lifted fuel requirements for cooling.
Spending gains for other categories of services proceeded at an annual rate of about 2J/4 percent over the
first three quarters of 1995, about the same rate of rise
as in the two previous years.
Real disposable personal income rose at an average
annual rate of about 2l/2 percent over the first three
quarters of 1995, a gain that was about in line with the
previous year's increase. Monthly data through
November suggest that growth of real income may
have picked up a little in the fourth quarter. Nominal
personal income appears to have increased slightly
faster in 1995 than it did in 1994, and growth of
nominal disposable income, which excludes income
taxes, apparently held close to its 1994 pace. Inflation
continued to take only a moderate bite from increases
in nominal receipts: The chain-type price index for
personal consumption expenditures rose at an annual
rate of 2Vi percent over the first three quarters of

Change in Real Income and Consumption
Percent, annual rate

LJ Disposable personal income
| Personal consumption expenditures

TP
1990

1991

1992




1953

1994

1995

1995, matching, almost exactly, the increases in each
of the two previous years.
After little change during 1994, the real value of
household wealth surged in 1995. The value of assets
was boosted substantially by huge increases in the
prices of stocks and bonds. Liabilities continued to
rise fairly rapidly but at a rate well below the rate of
increase in household assets; rapid growth of consumer credit was again the most notable feature on
the liability side. Behind these aggregate measures of
household assets and liabilities was some wide variation in the circumstances of individual households.
Appreciation of share prices and the rally in the bond
market provided a substantial boost to the wealth of
households holding large amounts of those assets.
However, households holding few such assets benefited little from the rally in securities prices, and some
of these households began to experience greater financial pressure in 1995. Debts taken on earlier proved to
be difficult to repay in some instances, and a rising
number of households saw their loans fall into delinquency. Overall, however, the incidence of financial
stress among households appears to have been limited, as sustained increases in personal income helped
to facilitate timely repayment of obligations.
Consumers maintained relatively upbeat perceptions of current and future economic conditions during 1995. The measure of consumer confidence that is
prepared by the Conference Board held fairly steady
at a high level. The index of consumer sentiment that
is compiled by the University of Michigan Survey
Research Center edged down a little, on net, from the
end of 1994 to the end of 1995, but its level also
remained relatively high. By contrast, some survey
questions dealing specifically with perceptions of
labor market conditions pointed to increased concerns
about job prospects during the year; although employment continued to rise in the aggregate, announcements of job cuts by some major corporations may
have rekindled consumers' anxieties about job security. In January of this year, consumer assessments of
labor market conditions softened further, and the
broader indexes of sentiment also declined. The January levels of the indexes were on the low side of their
averages of the past couple of years but were well
above levels that were reported through most of the
first three years of the expansion.
Consumers tended to save a slightly higher proportion of their income in 1995 than they had in 1994.
Large increases in financial wealth usually cause
households to spend a greater share of their current
income, thereby reducing the share of income that is

65
saved. However, rising debt burdens and increased
nervousness about job prospects would work in the
opposite direction, and these influences may have
offset the effect of increases in wealth. Some households also may have started focusing more intently on
saving for retirement, especially in light of increased
political debate about curbing the growth of entitlements provided under government programs. Nonetheless, the personal saving rate for all of 1995, while
moving up a little, remained in a range that was
relatively low by historical standards.
Residential investment fell in the first half of 1995
but turned up in the third quarter. Both the downswing in the first half and the subsequent rebound
after midyear appear to have been shaped, at least in a
rough way, by swings in mortgage interest rates.
Although housing activity had been slow to respond
to increases in mortgage interest rates through much
of 1994, sizable declines in sales of new and existing
homes started to show up toward the end of that year,
and by early 1995, permits and starts also were dropping. However, the decline in activity proved to be
relatively short and mild. By March, mortgage interest rates already were down appreciably from the
peaks of late 1994, and midway through the second
quarter, most indicators of housing activity were starting to rebound. Sales of new homes surged to especially high levels during the summer, and permits and
starts of single-family units rose appreciably. In the
autumn, sales retreated from their midyear peaks.
Starts also slipped back somewhat during the autumn,
but permits held firm.
The intra-year swings in the various housing indicators left the annual totals for these indicators at
Private Housing Starts
Millions of units, annual rate

Quarterly average

1.5
Q4

Single-family

0.5

1989

1991

1993

Construction of multifamily units, after taking a
notable step toward recovery in 1994, rose only moderately further in 1995. Over the first eleven months
of 1995. starts of multifamily units amounted to
280.000 at an annual rate, compared with about
260,000 the previous year and a low of 162,000 in
1993. Financing for the construction of new multifamily projects appeared to be readily available this past
year. However, the national vacancy rate for multifamily rental units, while down from the peaks of a
few years ago. remained relatively high, and increases
in rents were not of a magnitude to provide much
incentive for the construction of new units.

The Business Sector
Most indicators of business activity remained
favorable in 1995, but strength was less widespread
than it had been in 1994, and growth overall was less
robust. The output of all nonfarm businesses rose at
an annual rate of slightly less than 2 percent over the
first three quarters of 1995, after a gain of 4 percent in
1994—a pace that could not have been sustained
given already high operating levels. Inventory
problems cropped up in some lines of manufacturing and trade in 1995 and prompted production
adjustments. Scattered structural problems were
apparent as well, especially in parts of retail trade in
which intense competition for market share caused
financial losses and eventual bankruptcy for some
enterprises. More generally, however, business profits
remained high in 1995. as firms continued to
emphasize strategies that have served them well
throughout the 1990s—most notably, tight control
over costs and rapid adoption of new technologies,
achieved by way of heavy investment in high-tech
equipment.

1995

Note. Data points for 1995:Q4 are the averages for October
and November.




fairly elevated levels. The average pace of sales of
existing homes over the first eleven months of 1995
was well above the average for the 1980s, even after
adjusting for increases in the stock of houses. Starts
and sales of new single-family dwellings in 1995
were about one-tenth higher than their averages for
the 1980s. So far in the 1990s, demographic influences have been less supportive of housing activity
than in the 1980s, as the rate of household formation
has lagged—in part because many young adults have
delayed setting up their own domiciles. However,
offsetting impetus to demand has come from the
improved affordability of housing, brought about in
particular by declines in mortgage interest rates.

In total, real business fixed investment increased ai
an annual rate of 8 percent over the first three quarter

66
Change in Real Business Fixed Investment
Percent, annual rate

D Structures
| Producers' durable

20

equipment

Q3

10

10

20
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

of 1995 after a gain of 10 percent in 1994. Growth in
business spending for equipment continued to outpace the growth of investment in structures, even
though the latter scored its largest gain of the past
several years. On a quarterly basis, investment
remained very strong through the first quarter of
1995. After slowing sharply in the spring, it then
picked up somewhat in the third quarter. Fragmentary
data for the fourth quarter suggest that investment in
plant and equipment recorded a gain of at least moderate size in that period.
Businesses continued to invest heavily in computers in 1995. In real terms, these expenditures rose at
an annual rate of nearly 30 percent over the first three
quarters of the year, an increase that was even more
rapid than that of 1994. Excluding computers, real
investment outlays increased less rapidly, on balance,
than in 1994, and growth after the first quarter was
modest, on net. In the equipment category, outlays for
information-processing equipment other than computers moved up at an annual rate of about 13 percent in
the first half of 1995 but fell back a little in the third
quarter. Spending for industrial equipment followed
a roughly similar pattern, with a small third-quarter
decline coming on the heels of large gains in the first
half of the year. Real outlays for transportation equipment declined in the second quarter but rebounded in
the third. Real investment in nonresidential structures
moved up in each of the first three quarters of 1995. at
an annual rate of more than 6 percent, on average,
after a gain of 3Vi percent during 1994; the most
recent year brought increased construction of most
types of nonresidential buildings.
In the industrial sector, elevated levels of investment in equipment and structures in 1995 led to a




gain of about 4 percent in industrial capacity. However, in a turnabout from the outcome of the previous
year, output of the industrial sector rose considerably
less rapidly than capacity: A gain of 1 Vi percent in
total industrial production over the four quarters of
1995 was a sharp slowdown from a 1994 rise of more
than 6J/2 percent. Production of consumer goods followed a choppy pattern during 1995 and rose less
than V2 percent over the year as a whole, the smallest
annual increase of the current expansioa The output
of business equipment advanced in each quarter, but a
cumulative gain of 4Vi percent for this category was
smaller than the increases of other recent years. Production of materials faltered temporarily in the second quarter, but production gains resumed thereafter,
leading to a rise of about 2V* percent over the four
quarters of the year.
Industrial Production
Index, 1987= 100

125
120
115
110
105
100
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

With capacity expanding rapidly and production
growth slowing, the rate of capacity utilization in
industry turned down sharply in 1995, backing away
from the high operating rates of late 1994. As of this
past December, the utilization rate in manufacturing
was about Vi percentage point above its long-term
average. In January of this year, utilization rates fell
noticeably: Vehicle producers reduced assembly rates
last month, and winter storms temporarily shut down
manufacturing operations more generally.
After rising rapidly during 1994, business inventories continued to build at a substantial pace in
the early part of 1995. By the end of the first quarter,
real inventories of nonfarm businesses were about
5V2 percent above the level of a year earlier. Meanwhile, strength that had been evident in final sales
during 1994 gave way to more subdued growth in the

67
Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Rate
Percent

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

first quarter of 1995, and the ratio of inventories to
sales rose. In the second and third quarters, growth of
inventories was roughly in line with growth of business final sales; consequently, aggregate inventorysales ratios held fairly steady during this period.
Although data on inventory change in the year's final
quarter are not yet complete, the available indicators
suggest that significant imbalances probably were
present in only a few industries at year-end. Potential
for wider inventory problems appears to have been
contained through a combination of production
restraint late in 1995, caution in ordering merchandise
from abroad, and discounting by some retailers during
the holiday shopping season. Wholesalers reduced
their inventories in the final two months of 1995, and
manufacturers' stocks rose only slightly; aggregate
inventory-sales ratios moved down in both sectors.

Business profits rose further over the first three
quarters of 1995. Economic profits of all U.S. corporations increased at an annual rate of nearly 11 percent,
a pace similar to that seen over the four quarters of
1994. The profits of corporations from their operations in the rest of the world moved up sharply, on
net, and earnings from domestic operations also continued to advance. The strongest gains in domestic
profits came at financial corporations and reflected, in
part, an increased volume of lending by financial
institutions, reduced premiums on deposit insurance
at commercial banks, and rising profits of securities
dealers. The economic profits earned by nonfinancial
corporations from their domestic operations rose at an
annual rate of about 31/2 percent over the first three
quarters of 1995 after three years in which the annual
increases were 15 percent or more. A moderation of
output growth at nonfinancial corporations and a flattening of the rise in profits per unit of output both
worked to reduce the rate of growth in nominal earnings in 1995. Nonetheless, with unit costs also moving up at a moderate pace, the share of the value of
nonfinancial corporate output that ended up as profits
changed little, on net, in the first three quarters, holding in a range that was relatively high in comparison
to the average profit share over the past couple of
decades.
Before-Tax Profit Share of GDP
Percent
Nonfinancial corporations

10

Change in Real Nonfarm Business Inventories
Percent, annual rate

Q3

II

LJ.

i

i
1989

i
1991

i

i
1993

i
1995

Note. Profits from domestic operations with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments, divided by gross
domestic product of nonfinancial corporate sector.
The Government Sector

I
1990

1991

1992




1993

1994

1995

At the federal level, combined real outlays for
investment and consumption fell at an annual rate of
about 41A percent over the first three quarters of 1995,

68
dropping to a level about 13 percent below its annual
peak in 1990. Both investment and consumption were
cut back over the first three quarters of 1995. Outlays
for defense continued to contract, and nondefense
expenditures turned down, reversing a moderate
increase that took place over the four quarters of
1994.
Federal outlays in the unified budget, which covers
items such as transfers and grants, as well as consumption and investment expenditures other than the
consumption of fixed capital, rose 33/4 percent in
nominal terms in fiscal 1995, matching almost exactly
the percentage rise of the previous fiscal year. Nominal outlays for defense declined 3J/4 percent in both
fiscal 1995 and fiscal 1994. Outlays for social security
increased about 5 percent in both years. Spending for
Medicare and Medicaid continued to rise at rates
appreciably faster than the growth of nominal GDP.
Net interest payments jumped in fiscal 1995 after
three years of relatively little change, but, working in
the other direction, net outlays for deposit insurance
were more negative than in 1994 (i.e., the margin
between insurance premiums and the payout for
losses increased). Proceeds from auctions of spectrum
rights also helped to hold down expenditures; like the
premiums for deposit insurance, these proceeds enter
the budget as a negative outlay. In the first three
months of fiscal 1996—i.e., the three-month period
ended in December—federal outlays were about
1 percent lower in nominal terms than in the comparable period of fiscal 1995. Nominal outlays for
defense have continued to trend down this fiscal year,
and the spending restraint embodied in recent continuChange in Real Federal Expenditures
on Consumption and Investment
Percent, Q4 to Q4

10
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Note. Value for 1995 is measured from 1994:Q4 to 1995:Q3 at
an annual rate.




ing budget resolutions has translated into sharp cuts in
nondefense outlays.
Federal receipts rose 7V2 percent in fiscal 1995.
after having increased 9 percent in fiscal 1994. In
both years, categories of receipts that are most closely
related to the state of the economy showed sizable
increases. With receipts moving up more rapidly than
spending in fiscal 1995, the federal budget deficit fell
for a third consecutive year, to $164 billion. Progress
in reducing the deficit in recent years has come from
cyclical expansion of the economy, tax increases,
non-recurring factors such as the sale of spectrum
rights, and adherence to the budgetary restraints
embodied in the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 and
the Omnibus Budgetary Reconciliation Act of 1993.
Federal Unified Budget Deficit
Billions of dollars

- 300

- 200

- 100

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

The economic expansion also has helped to relieve
budgetary pressures that many state and local governments were experiencing earlier in the 1990s. Excluding social insurance funds, surpluses in the combined
current accounts of state and local governments were
equal to about V* percent of nominal GDP in the first
three quarters of 1995; this figure was more than
double the average for 1991 and 1992. when budgetary pressures were most severe.
Even so, state and local budgets remain at the
center of strongly competing pressures, with the
demand for many of the services that typically are
provided by these governments continuing to rise at a
time when the public also is expressing desire for tax
relief. Although states and localities have responded
to these pressures in different ways, the aggregate
picture is one in which expenditures and revenues
have continued to rise faster than nominal GDP—but

69
by smaller margins than in the early part of the 1990s.
In total, the current expenditures of state and local
governments, made up mainly of transfers and consumption expenditures, were equal to about l2Vz percent of nominal GDP in the first three quarters of
1995, up slightly from the percentages of the two
previous years and about 13A percentage points higher
than the comparable figure for 1989. Total receipts of
state and local governments were equal to about
133/4 percent of nominal GDP in the first three quarters of 1995, up just a touch from the comparable
percentages of the two previous years but about
11A percentage points higher than the percentage in
1989.

Change in Real State and Local Expenditures
on Consumption and Investment
Percent, Q4 to Q4

- 4

- 3

- 2

1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
Note. Value for 1995 is measured from 1994:Q4 to 1995:Q3 at
an annual rate.

State and local outlays that are included in GDP
have been rising less rapidly than the current expenditures of these jurisdictions, because GDP excludes
transfer payments, which have been growing faster
than other outlays. In real terms, combined state and
local outlays for consumption and investment
increased at an annual rate of about 2Vz percent over
the first three quarters of 1995. Real investment
expenditures, which consist mainly of outlays for
construction, moved up at an annual rate of almost
7 percent. By contrast, consumption expenditures,
which are about four times the size of investment
outlays, rose only modestly in real terms—at an average annual rate of about 1J/2 percent.

The External Sector
Growth of real GDP in the major foreign industrial countries other than Japan slowed sharply in




1995 from the robust rates of 1994. In Canada, where
economic activity had been particularly vigorous
through the end of 1994, the slowdown reflected
weaker U.S. growth and macroeconomic policies
intended to achieve improved fiscal balance and to
prevent the reemergence of inflationary pressures. In
Germany and the other European economies, appreciation of their currencies in terms of the dollar during the early months of the year and efforts to reduce
public sector deficits contributed to the decline in the
rate of real output growth. In contrast, Japan showed
some tentative signs of recovery late in 1995 after
almost no growth during the previous three years.
With the expansion of real GDP slowing in the
foreign G-10 countries at a time when some slack
remained, inflation stayed low. The average rate of
consumer price inflation in these countries remained
about 2 percent last year, essentially the same as in
1994 and somewhat less than in the United States.
Economic growth in the major developing countries slowed on average in 1995 from the strong pace
recorded for 1994. The substantial contraction of economic activity in Mexico had important effects on
U.S. trade, but real output also slowed in other developing countries, including Argentina. In response to
the December 1994 collapse of the Mexican peso,
the Mexican government adopted a set of policies
intended to tighten monetary conditions, maintain
wage restraint, and reduce government spending in
order to mitigate the inflationary impact of the peso's
devaluation and to achieve significant reduction in
the current account deficit in 1995. Through the third
quarter, the Mexican current account was approximately balanced; a deficit of about $20 billion had
cumulated during the comparable three quarters of
1994. The merchandise trade balance improved to
moderate surplus in 1995 from a substantial deficit
in 1994. The improved trade performance in part
reflected a severe contraction in aggregate demand.
Mexican real output fell sharply early in the year but
picked up toward the end of the year, for an annual
decline of nearly 7 percent.
The newly industrializing economies in Asia—for
example, Malaysia, Korea, and Taiwan—continued to
grow rapidly during 1995. at about the same rate as in
1994. Although growth in most of these countries was
driven by a strong expansion in internal demand,
especially in investment, most countries also benefited from very fast export growth. The marked acceleration in exports was attributable at least in part to a
real depreciation of their currencies against the yen
and key European currencies during the early part of
the year.

70
In the first eleven months of 1995 the nominal U.S.
trade deficit in goods and services reached about
$115 billion at a seasonally adjusted annual rate, a
level slightly greater than the $106 billion recorded
for 1994. U.S. income growth in 1995 was similar to
the average for our trading partners, but, as is typically the case, comparable increases in income
seemed to bring forth an increase in US. demand for
imports that was larger than the average increases in
demand for our exports by the foreign countries with
which we trade. Effects of the dollar's depreciation
during 1994 and early 1995 worked in the opposite
direction, tending to boost exports and hold down
imports. Overall, the result of these offsetting tendencies was that the dollar value of exports grew somewhat faster than the dollar value of imports through
November. Nonetheless, with the level of imports
exceeding the level of exports at the start of the year,
these growth rates translated into a slightly larger
deficit. The current account deficit averaged about
$160 billion at an annual rate during the first three
quarters of 1995. Both the trade deficit and the deficit
on net investment income widened somewhat, resulting in an increase from the $150 billion current
account deficit experienced in 1994.
U.S. Current Account
Billions of dollars, annual rate

50

100
150

i

i
1989

i

i
1991

i

I
1993

i

200
1995

Real exports of goods and services grew at an
annual rate of about 5 percent over the first three
quarters of 1995. Agricultural exports remained at
elevated levels, and the volume of computer exports
continued to rise sharply. Other merchandise exports
expanded in real terms at a marginally slower rate
than did the total; within this broad category, machinery and industrial supplies accounted for the largest
increases. Tabulation of the export data by country of




Change in Real Imports and Exports
of Goods and Services
Percent, Q4 to Q4
D Imports
1 Exports

15

10

1989

1991

1993

1995

Note. Values for 1995 are measured from 1994:Q4 to 1995:Q3
at an annual rate.

destination showed divergent patterns: Exports to
Mexico dropped in response to the economic crisis in
that country, but shipments to developing countries
in Asia rose sharply. Exports to Western Europe,
Canada, and Japan increased as well.
Imports of goods and services increased at an
annual rate of about 6 percent in real terms during the
first three quarters, a slower rate of advance than
during 1994. Imports of computers and semiconductors rose sharply, but imports of other machinery,
consumer goods and industrial supplies slowed.
Import prices increased about 2l/2 percent in the
twelve months ending in December 1995. An end to
the very rapid rise in world non-oil commodity prices
and low inflation abroad helped to restrain the rise in
import prices.
In the first three quarters of 1995, recorded net
capital inflows into the United States were substantial
and nearly balanced the deficit in the U.S. current
account. Sharp increases were reported in both foreign assets in the United States and U.S. assets abroad.
Foreign official asset holdings in the United States
increased almost $100 billion through September.
These increases reflected both intervention by certain
industrial countries to support the foreign exchange
value of the dollar and very substantial accumulation
of reserves by several developing countries in Asia
and Latin America. Private foreign assets in the
United States also rose rapidly. Net purchases of U.S.
Treasury securities by private foreigners totaled
$97 billion, an amount far exceeding previous

71
records. Net purchases of U.S. government agency
bonds and corporate bonds were also very large.
Direct investment inflows reached almost $50 billion in the first three quarters of 1995; this total was
about equal to the inflow during all of 1994 and
almost matched the record pace of 1989. Mergers and
acquisitions added substantially to the inflow of funds
from foreign direct investors in the United States.
U.S. direct investment abroad was even larger than
foreign direct investment in the United States and also
approached previous peak rates. U.S. net purchases of
foreign stocks and bonds were up from 1994, but
below the 1993 peak rate. The bulk of the net U.S.
purchases of foreign securities were from the industrial countries; net purchases from emerging markets
played a relatively small role.

Labor Markets
The number of jobs on nonfarm payrolls increased
!3/4 million over the twelve months ended in December 1995. After a sharp rise during 1994, gains in
employment slowed in the first part of 1995, and the
second quarter brought only a small increase.
Thereafter, increases picked up somewhat. Nearly
450,000 jobs were added in the final three months of
the year, a gain of about 1 1 /2 percent at an annual rate.
In January of this year, with the weather keeping
many workers at home during the reference week
for the monthly survey of establishments, payroll
employment fell sharply.
As in 1994, increases in payroll employment in
1995 came mainly in the private sector of the econ-

Net Change in Payroll Employment
Millions of jobs

Total nonfarm

k
i
1990

i
1991

1992




1993

1994

1995

omy, but gains there were more mixed than those
of 1994. In manufacturing, employment fell about
160,000 over the twelve months ended in December,
reversing almost half of the previous year's gain.
Losses were concentrated in industries that produce
nondurables. A decline this past year in the number of
jobs at apparel manufacturers was one of the largest
ever in that industry. Sizable reductions in employment also were reported by manufacturers of textiles,
tobacco, leather products, and petroleum and coal. In
many of these industries, cyclical deceleration of the
economy in 1995 compounded the effects of adjustments stemming from longer-run structural changes.
In contrast to the widespread contraction in employment among producers of nondurables, employment
at the manufacturers of durable goods increased
slightly during 1995. Hiring continued to expand
briskly at firms that produce business equipment.
Metal fabricators also sustained growth in employment but at a slower pace than in 1994. The number
of jobs in transportion equipment declined, on net.
In most other sectors of the economy, employment
rose moderately last year. The number of jobs in
construction increased 140,000 over the twelve
months ended in December, a rise of more than 3 percent. In the private service-producing sector, which
now accounts for about three-fourths of all jobs in the
private sector, employment increased 1.7 million in
1995 after having advanced 2.6 million in 1994.
Establishments that are involved in wholesale trade
continued to boost payrolls at a relatively brisk pace
in 1995. Retailers also added to employment but at a
considerably slower rate than in 1994: within retail
trade, employment at apparel outlets fell substantially
last year, and payrolls at stores selling general merchandise dropped moderately after a large increase in
1994. Providers of health services added slightly more
jobs than in other recent years. At firms that supply
services to other businesses, employment growth
was sizable again in 1995 but less rapid than in either
of the two previous years: in this category, providers
of computer services expanded their job counts at
an accelerated pace in 1995, but suppliers of
personnel—a category that includes temporary help
agencies—added jobs at a much slower rate than in
other recent years.
Results from the monthly survey of households
showed the civilian unemployment rate holding in a
narrow range throughout 1995, and the rate reported
in December—5.6 percent of the labor force—was
near the midpoint of that narrow range. In January
of this year, the unemployment rate ticked up to
5.8 percent.

72
Civilian Unemployment Rate

1994
1988
1992
1990
Note. The break in data at January 1994 marks the introduction of a redesigned survey; data from that point on are not
directly comparable with the data of earlier periods.

1996

The proportion of working-age persons choosing to
participate in the labor force edged down slightly, on
net, over the course of 1995. It has changed little, on
balance, since the start of the 1990s. By contrast,
the two previous decades brought substantial net
increases in labor force participation, although longerterm trends during the two decades were interrupted
at times by spells of cyclical sluggishness in the
economy. Two or three years ago, cyclical influences
also seemed to be a plausible explanation for the
sluggishness of labor force participation in the current
business expansion. But, with the participation rate
remaining sluggish as job opportunities have continued to expand, the evidence is pointing increasingly
toward a slower rate of rise in the trend of participatioa Slower growth of participation will tend to limit
the growth of potential output, unless an offsetting
rise is forthcoming in the trend of productivity
growth. So far in the current expansion, measured
increases in productivity seem to have followed a
fairly typical cyclical pattern, with larger increases
early in the expansion and smaller gains, on average,
in subsequent years. Overall, however, this pattern
has not yielded evidence of a significant pickup in the
longer-term trend of productivity growth.
The average unemployment rate for all of 1995 was
about l/2 percentage point below the average for 1994,
and it was only a little above the levels to which the
unemployment rate fell in the latter stages of the long
business expansion of the 1980s. The low unemployment rates reached back then proved to be unsustainable, as they eventually were accompanied by a significant step-up in the rate of inflation, brought on in




part by faster rates of rise in hourly compensation and
unit labor costs. The current expansion, in contrast,
has remained relatively free of increased inflation
pressures working through the labor markets. The
employment cost index for hourly compensation of
workers in private nonfarm industries rose only
2.8 percent over the twelve months ended in December, the smallest annual increase on record in a series
that goes back to the start of the 1980s. Hourly wages
increased 2.8 percent during the past year, the same
relatively low rate of increase as in 1994. The cost of
fringe benefits, prorated to an hourly basis, rose only
2.7 percent last year, the smallest annual rise on
record. With many firms still undergoing restructurings and reorganizations, many of which have
involved permanent job losses, workers probably have
been more reluctant to press for wage increases than
they normally would have been during a period of
tight labor markets. Also, firms have been making
unprecedented efforts to gain better control over the
rate of rise in the cost of benefits provided to employees, especially those related to health care. Although
some of these efforts may have only a one-time effect
on the level of benefit costs, groundwork also seems
to have been laid for slower growth of benefits over
time than would otherwise have prevailed.

Change in Employment Cost Index
Percent, Dec. to Dec.
Hourly compensation

1989
1991
1993
1995
Note. Private industry, excluding farm and household workers.

Prices
Early in 1995, inflation pressures that had started
building in 1994 seemed to be gaining in intensity.
Indexes of spot commodity prices continued to surge
in the early part of last year, and in the producer price
index, materials prices recorded some of the largest

73
monthly increases of the past decade and a half.
Consumer prices also began to exhibit some upward
pressure, with the index for items other than food and
energy moving up fairly rapidly over the first four
months of the year.
The surge in inflation proved to be relatively shortlived, however. The spot prices of industrial commodities turned down in the spring of the year and
fell further, on net, after midyear. Price increases for
intermediate materials slowed in the second and third
quarters of 1995, and by the final quarter of the year
these prices also were declining. Monthly increases in
the core CPI slowed in May; thereafter, increases
generally were small over the remainder of the year.
The slowing of the economy after the start of the year
appears to have cut short the buildup of inflationary
pressures before they could have much effect on the
underlying processes of wage and price determination. In the end, the rise in the CPI excluding food and
energy from the final quarter of 1994 to the final
quarter of 1995 amounted to 3 percent, an increase
that differed little from those of the two previous
years. The increase in the total CPI in 1995 came in at
23/4 percent, the fifth consecutive year in which it has
been in a range of 3 percent or less.
Change in Consumer Prices
Percent, Q4 to Q4

1989
1991
1993
1995
Note. Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

In the aggregate, rates of price increase held fairly
steady for both goods and services this past year. The
CPI for commodities other than food and energy rose
!3/4 percent over the four quarters of 1995 after
increases of 1 Va. percent in both 1993 and 1994. The
last three-year period in which prices of these goods
rose by such small amounts came in the middle part
of the 1960s. Apparel prices continued to decline last




Change in Consumer Prices Excluding
Food and Energy
Percent, Q4 to Q4

1989
1991
1993
1995
Note. Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

year but not so rapidly as in the previous year. Price
increases for vehicles moderated. The 1995 rise in the
CPI for services other than energy was 33/4 percent:
although this increase exceeded the 1994 rise by a
slight amount, the results for both years were among
the smallest increases for this category in the last
three decades.
Trends in food prices and energy prices remained
favorable to consumers in 1995. The rise in food
prices from the final quarter of 1994 to the final
quarter of 1995 was slightly more than 2Vi percent,
almost exactly the same as the increases of the two
previous years. The last yearly increase in food prices
in excess of 3 percent came five years ago. in 1990.
In the intervening years, production adjustments by
farmers and weather problems of one sort or another
have caused temporary surges in the prices of some
farm commodities, but these surges have not resulted
in widespread pressures on food prices at the retail
level. Moderate rates of increase in the costs of nonfarm inputs that contribute heavily to value added
have been an important anchor in the setting of food
prices at the consumer level. Also, if only by chance,
years of poor crops—like that of 1995. when grain
and oilseed production plummeted—have tended to
be interspersed with years of good crops, a pattern
that has prevented sustained upward pressures on
farm and food prices. In the energy area, prices at the
consumer level fell 1% percent, on net, over the four
quarters of 1995. more than reversing a moderate
1994 increase. Gasoline prices dropped nearly 5 percent, on net, over the four quarters of the year, and
consumer prices of natural gas also declined appre-

74
ciably. However, some upward pressures developed
late in 1995 and early this year, largely in response to
unexpectedly cold temperatures that boosted fuel
requirements for winter heating.
All told, the price developments of 1995 appear to
have left a favorable imprint on expectations of future
rates of inflation, if results from various surveys of
consumers and forecasters are an accurate reflection
of the views held by the broader public. Monthly
responses to the surveys tend to bounce around somewhat, but over 1995 as a whole, average readings of




anticipated price increases one year into the future
were slightly lower than those of 1994, and survey
responses about inflation prospects over the longer
term came down more substantially. Although the
responses regarding expected inflation still tended, on
balance, to run to the high side of actual rates of price
increase, the easing of inflation expectations this past
year provided another encouraging sign that inflation
processes that helped to undermine other recent business expansions are still in check in the current
expansion.

75

Section 3: Financial, Credit, and Monetary Developments
In 1995 and early 1996, the Federal Reserve had
to adjust its policy stance several times to promote
credit market conditions supportive of sustained
growth with low inflation. At the beginning of 1995,
some risk remained that inflation might rise. To
provide additional insurance against that development, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
tightened reserve conditions, raising the intended federal funds rate VT. percentage point, to 6 percent,
thereby extending the episode of policy firming that
had begun one year earlier. As time passed, it became
clear that these policy tightenings had been successful in containing inflationary pressures, and the
System initiated V* point reductions in the federal
funds rate in July and December of 1995 and January of 1996.
Domestic Interest Rates

Most market interest rates had peaked before the
policy tightening last February. During the spring,
interest rates declined appreciably, as market participants increasingly came to believe that no additional
policy restraint would be forthcoming, and, indeed,
that easing might be in the cards. Mounting evidence
that the growth of spending had downshifted and
price pressures were muted, along with greater hopes
that substantial progress would be made toward
reducing the federal budget deficit, contributed to the
change in attitudes and to the drop in interest rates,
especially longer-term rates. On balance during 1995,
interest rates dropped 1 to 2V6 percentage points,
with the largest declines registered on intermediateand long-term securities. This year, short- and
intermediate-term interest rates have fallen somewhat
further, while long-term rates are unchanged to a little
higher.

Short-Term
Percent
Monthly

Federal Funds

10

The course of interest rates during the year influenced overall credit flows and their composition. The
expansion of the total debt of domestic nonfinancial
sectors was relatively strong during the first half of
the year but moderated later in 1995. For the year,
debt grew 5V* percent, a bit above the midpoint of its
annual growth range. Initially, household and nonfinancial business credit demands were concentrated
in floating-rate or short-term debt instruments. As the
yield curve flattened, credit demands shifted to fixedrate, long-term debt instruments.

Three-month Treasury bill
Coupon equivalent basis

Long-Term
Monthly

Home Mortgage

Primary Conventional

12

Thirty-year Treasury bond
i

i
1984

i

i
1986

i

i
1988




i

i

1990

i
1992

During the first part of last year, expectations of
lower U.S. interest rates relative to other G-10 countries and other factors such as the crisis in Mexico
contributed to a 10 percent depreciation of the tradeweighted exchange value of the dollar. By year-end,
though, the dollar had retraced about half of these
losses, and it has appreciated further on balance in
1996.

i

i
1994

i

i
1996

i

Because depository institutions are important
sources of short-term and floating-rate credit to households and businesses, depository assets grew rapidly
early on and then backed off. The need to fund the
increase in assets, along with declines in market interest rates relative to yields on retail deposits, led to the
fastest growth in M2 and M3 since the late 1980s: M2
ended the year in the upper part of its annual range,
and M3 was at the upper end of its range. In contrast.
Ml declined for the first time since the beginning of
the official series in 1959. as many banks introduced
retail sweep accounts that shifted deposits from

76
marked rise in materials prices during the last half of
1994, seemed indicative of emerging resource constraints and building inflationary pressures. In these
circumstances, the FOMC agreed on a VT. percentage
point increase in the federal funds rate, and the Board
of Governors approved an equal increase in the discount rate.

interest-bearing checking accounts to savings-type
accounts in order to reduce reserve requirements.

The Course of Policy and Interest Rates
The Federal Reserve entered 1995 having tightened
policy appreciably during the previous year. Shortterm interest rates had risen more than 2Vz percentage points from the end of 1993, and long-term rates
were up 2 percentage points. Policy tightening had
been necessitated by the threat of rising inflation
posed by unusually low real short-term interest rates
earlier in the 1990s. Rates had been kept low to
counter the effects of impediments to credit flows and
economic growth. But as these impediments were
reduced, the economy expanded at an unsustainable
pace and margins of underutilized labor and capital
began to erode. Ultimately, absent a firmer policy,
excessive demands on productive resources and
resulting higher inflation would have produced
strains, threatening economic expansioa

During the remainder of the winter and through the
spring, incoming data signaled that economic growth
was finally moderating. At first, it was unclear if the
slowdown was temporary or if it was a lasting shift
toward a sustainable rate of economic expansion in
the neighborhood of the economy's potential. Adding
to the uncertainty was a pickup of consumer price
inflation and a pronounced weakening in the foreign
exchange value of the dollar. At the March meeting,
the FOMC determined that it would be prudent to
await further information before taking any additional
policy actions, but it alerted the Manager of the
System Open Market Account that, if intermeeting
action were to be required, the step would more likely
be to firm than to ease.

In early February the policy actions taken in 1994
did not appear to be sufficient to head off inflationary
pressures. The growth of economic activity had not
shown convincing signs of slowing to a more sustainable pace, and available information, including a

By the May meeting, substantial evidence had
accumulated that the threat of rising inflation had
lessened. Economic growth had slowed; although the

The Discount Rate and Selected Market Interest Rates
Daily

1

I

12/31 2/4/94

I

I

I

3/22 4/18 5/17

\

I

t

7/6

8/16

9/27

I

I

I

11/1512/20 2/1/95

i
3/28

I
5/23

I
7/6

i

i

8R29/26

Note. Dotted vertical lines indicate days on which the Committee announced a monetary policy action.
Asterisks indicate days on which the FOMC held scheduled meetings.




i

l

l

11/1512/191/31/96

77
adjustment to inventory imbalances that had developed earlier in the year was contributing to the slowdown, the underlying trajectory of final sales was still
uncertain. The FOMC determined that the existing
stance of policy was appropriate and expressed no
presumption as to the direction of potential policy
action over the intermeeting period, issuing a symmetric directive to the Account Manager.

a softening in spending after the third quarter, but the
extent of any slowing of spending and inflation was
unclear. Although short-term rates remained above
long-term averages on a real, inflation-adjusted basis,
substantial rallies in bond and stock markets were
thought likely to buoy spending. Against this backdrop, the FOMC voted to maintain the existing stance
of monetary policy.

Intermediate- and long-term interest rates had
fallen throughout the winter and spring, as evidence
accumulated that the expansion of economic activity
was slowing and that inflationary pressures were ebbing. Furthermore, budget discussions in the Congress
seemed to foreshadow significant fiscal restraint over
the balance of the decade, putting additional downward pressure on these rates. Short-term rates had
declined less, but in late spring, financial market
participants had begun to anticipate an easing of
monetary policy. By midyear, the three-month Treasury bill rate had declined about V* percentage point
from its level at the beginning of the year, while rates
on securities with maturities greater than one year had
dropped as much as 2 percentage points.

The generally positive news about inflation and
hopes for a budget agreement had helped propel the
bond market higher throughout the fall. By the
December meeting, intermediate- and long-term interest rates were 13/4 to 2V6 percentage points below their
levels at the beginning of the year. The bond market
rally, along with strong earnings reports, pushed
equity prices higher during the year, and by midDecember, equity price indexes were up about 35 percent from levels at the beginning of the year. Since
the last easing in July, inflation had been somewhat
more favorable than anticipated, and the expansion of
economic activity had moderated substantially after
posting a strong third quarter. With both inflation and
inflation expectations more subdued than expected,
and with the slowing in economic growth suggesting
that price pressures would continue to be contained,
the FOMC decided to reduce the intended federal
funds rate an additional V* percentage point, bringing
it to 5l/2 percent.

Employment data released shortly after the May
FOMC meeting were surprisingly weak, and by the
July meeting it appeared that growth of aggregate
output had sagged markedly during the second quarter as businesses sought to keep inventories from
rising to undesirable levels. This deceleration of output growth was accompanied by a softening of industrial prices and a marked reduction in the pace at
which materials prices were rising. With the economy
growing more slowly than had been anticipated and
potential inflationary pressures receding, the FOMC
voted to ease reserve pressures slightly with a x/4 percentage point decline in the intended federal funds
rate.
Although financial market participants had anticipated a decline in the federal funds rate at some point,
bond and equity markets rallied strongly immediately
after the change in policy was announced. However, a
pickup in economic growth during the summer made
further reductions in the funds rate appear less likely,
and interest rates backed up for a time.
The Committee did keep rates unchanged at the
August and September meetings. Although inflation
had improved, the slowdown had been anticipated to
a considerable extent. Moreover, uncertainties about
federal budget policies and their effects on the economy remained substantial.
At the November meeting, the economic signals
were mixed. Anecdotal information tended to suggest




The data available at the time of the FOMC meeting in late January gave stronger evidence of slowing
economic expansion. This development reduced
potential inflationary pressures going forward and
raised questions about whether monetary policy might
unduly restrain the pace of expansioa The Committee
believed that a further slight easing in monetary policy was consistent with keeping inflation contained
and fostering sustainable growth, given that price and
cost trends were already subdued. In these circumstances, the Committee lowered the intended federal
funds rate J/4 percentage point, to 51A percent, and the
Board approved an equivalent reduction in the discount rate, to 5 percent.
Partly as a consequence of the System actions in
December and January, short- and intermediate-term
interest rates have fallen V* to Vz percentage point
since mid-December. However, on balance, longerterm rates are unchanged to a little higher. The
absence of a firm agreement to reduce the federal
budget deficit, and some tentative signs most recently
that the economy might not be so sluggish as some
market participants had feared, have held up longerterm rates.

78
Household Financial Condition

Debt: Annual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

Nonfinancial

13900
13600
13300
13000

o N D
1994

12700
M J J A S O N D

Credit and Money Flows
On balance in 1995, the debt of the domestic
nonfinancial sectors grew at about the same pace as
in the previous year, although within the year, debt
growth was much stronger in the first half than in the
second. Credit supplies remained plentiful: Banks
continued to be willing lenders, and in securities
markets most interest-rate spreads remained quite
narrow. Debt burdens for households increased, but
except for a few types of consumer credit obligations, delinquency rates remained at low levels. Rising equity prices bolstered the overall financial condition of households.
Federal debt rose 33/4 percent in 1995, slightly less
than in 1994. The federal government's demands for
credit fell largely because the budget deficit shrank
about 20 percent for the calendar year. Federal debt
growth also slowed toward year-end as the Treasury
drew down its cash balance to keep borrowing within
the $4.9 trillion debt ceiling.
State and local government debt fell 5l/2 percent—
more than in 1994. A few years earlier, municipalities
had taken advantage of low long-term rates to prerefund a substantial volume of issues, many of which
were eligible to be called in 1995. As those securities
were called, and with gross issuance light, the stock
of municipal securities contracted for a second consecutive year. Despite the overall reduction in debt
outstanding, the ratios of tax-exempt to taxable yields
jumped in the first half of the year and, for long-term
debt, held at an elevated level during the remainder of
the year. This increase was associated with concerns
about the effect on demands for tax-free municipal




1985

1980

1995

1990

1995
debt of proposals for changes in federal taxation that
would sharply reduce the tax advantages of holding
municipal bonds.
Household borrowing remained robust in 1995,
moderating only a bit from 1994, and the ratio of
household debt to disposable personal income rose
further. Even so. the financial condition of this sector
remained good on balance, although there were signs
of deterioration. The rally in the domestic equity
markets supported household balance sheets by boosting net worth sharply. In addition, delinquency rates
on home mortgages and closed-end consumer loans
at banks, while rising, remained at low levels.
Other indicators, however, provided evidence that
some households were likely beginning to experience
increased financial pressures. For instance, delinquency rates on credit card debt held by banks and on
Delinquency Rates on Household Loans
Percent

Closed-end consumer
loans at banks

Auto loans at
finance companies
Mortgages

I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I I II
1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

79
auto loans booked at captive finance companies rose
sharply. Furthermore, the average household debt service burden—calculated as the share of disposable
income needed to meet required payments on mortgage and consumer debt—continued to rise last year.
This measure of debt burden has now reversed about
one-half of the decline it posted earlier in the decade.

Distribution of Bank Assets
by Capital Status
Percent of industry assets

Under Capitalized

31.3

.5

The average debt service burden of nonfinancial
corporations—the ratio of net interest payments to
cash flow—also rose last year, but it remained well
beneath the most recent peak reached in 1990. The
increase in debt burden was in part associated with
the relatively strong growth of the debt of nonfinancial businesses. This sector's debt growth was especially robust early in the year, when business fixed
investment picked up further and inventory accumulation was rapid. Debt issuance was also boosted by the
rising wave of mergers, although a good number
involved stock swaps. Financing needs fell back later
on as investment growth slowed and profits increased.
Funding patterns also shifted as bond yields fell,
and firms relied more heavily on longer-term debt.
Despite the increase in credit demands, interest rate
spreads of investment-grade private securities over
comparable Treasuries widened only slightly and
remained narrow by historical standards, suggesting
that lenders continued to view balance sheets of nonfinancial corporations as remaining healthy on the
whole. Spreads on below-investment-grade debt rose
more sharply but stayed well beneath levels reached
early in the decade.

Adequately Capitalized

38.6

2.9

Well Capitalized

30.1

Securities as a Percent of Bank Credit

50

40

30

20

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Commercial banks met a significant portion of the
increase in business credit demands last year, which,
in turn, contributed to the rapid expansion of bank




1990:04

1995:Q3

96.6

Note. Adjusted for examiner ratings.

balance sheets. Banks funded a portion of the loan
increase by reducing their securities holdings,
although higher market prices of securities and offbalance sheet contracts left reported securities holdings slightly higher for the year. In fact, bank security
holdings relative to the size of their balance sheets
remained elevated and, together with banks' strong
capital positions, indicated that late in the year banks
were well positioned to continue accommodating
the credit demands of households and businesses.
Although qualitative information suggested that banks
were no longer reducing the standards businesses
needed to meet to qualify for loans, some easing of
credit terms continued, with interest-rate spreads on
business loans narrowing further. Growth of real
estate loans held by banks slowed over the year as the
share of fixed-rate mortgages in total originations rose
with the decline in long-term rates. Banks tend to
securitize fixed-rate mortgages more than adjustablerate loans. Consumer loans on the books of banks
began the year growing at very high rates; this growth
decelerated throughout 1995 as the volume of securitization increased. In response to rising delinquency
rates, some banks tightened terms and standards for
consumer loans toward the end of 1995 and early
1996.
Total assets of thrift institutions are estimated to
have risen slightly last year. Growth at healthy thrifts
more than offset a substantial transfer of thrift assets
to commercial banks through mergers. The revival of
growth in thrift assets, along with the strong showing
of bank credit, helped to nudge up depository credit
as a share of domestic nonfinancial debt for the second straight year after fifteen years of declines. Banks
and thrifts still account for more than one-third of all
credit to nonfinancial sectors.
Banks and thrifts funded a large share of their asset
growth with deposits, and M3 grew 6 percent. The
non-M2 portion of M3 was especially strong, in part

80
M3: Actual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

4600
4550

market instruments were not the whole story for the
growth of M2, however. As the yield curve flattened,
the relative gains from holding longer-term assets
with less certain price behavior fell and probably
strengthened household demand for components of
M2. Even so, M2 velocity was about unchanged after
having increased for four years.

4500
4450
4400
2%

4350
4300
4250
O N D J F M A M J J A S O N D
1995

1994

as depository institutions substituted large time deposits for nondeposit sources of funds. The sharp reduction in deposit insurance premiums, which made large
time deposits a more attractive source of funds, probably contributed to this shift. Late in the year,
branches and agencies of Japanese banks, facing some
resistance in U.S. funding markets, ran off time deposits while continuing to increase their funding from
overseas offices.

Ml fell almost 2 percent in 1995, the first annual
decline since the beginning of the Board's official
series in 1959. Sweeps of deposits from reservable
checking accounts, a component of Ml, to nonreservable money market deposit accounts were a major
influence. Without these sweeps, Ml would have
risen 1 percent. By the end of last year, sweeps had
spread to thirty-two bank holding companies, and the
initial amounts swept by these programs totaled
$54 billion. The corresponding decline of more than
$5 billion in required reserves largely showed through

M1: Actual Level
Billions of dollars

1220
1200
1180

M2 rose as lower market interest rates and a flatter
yield curve increased the relative attractiveness of
retail deposits. As is typical, deposit interest rates,
and to a lesser extent returns on money market mutual
funds, adjusted slowly to declines in market rates last
year. Falling interest rates for comparable maturity

M2: Actual Range and Actual Level
Billions of dollars

3700
3650
3600
3550
3500

O N D J F M A M J J A S O N D
1995

1994




3450

1160
1140
1120

O N D J
1994

F M A M J J A S O N D
1995

1100

to reserve balances maintained at Federal Reserve
Banks. As banks continue to introduce retail sweep
programs in the future, the aggregate level of required
reserve balances will tend to fall further. Although it
has not happened yet, one possible consequence of
the declining required reserve balances is greater
instability in the aggregate demand for reserves and in
overnight interest rates. In 1991, following the cut in
reserve requirements at the end of 1990, unusually
low levels of required reserve balances were associated with greater variability in the federal funds rate,
as banks' volatile clearing needs began to dominate
the demand for reserves, making daily reserve
demand more difficult to estimate.

81
The runoff in reserve balances held down the
growth of the monetary base to 4 percent in 1995. In
addition, currency growth slowed, primarily owing to
reduced shipments abroad. Foreign demand moderated with the stabilization of financial conditions in
some countries where dollars circulate widely. Indeed,
reduced demands from abroad contributed to a rare
decline in the currency component of Ml this past
summer, the first decrease since the early 1960s. The
demand for existing Federal Reserve notes also slackened in anticipation of the introduction of a newly
designed $100 bill that will be harder to counterfeit.

Foreign Exchange Developments
The weighted-average foreign exchange value of
the dollar in terms of the other G-10 currencies
declined about 5 percent on balance last year. The
dollar fell sharply through April and reached a low
almost 10 percent below its value at the end of 1994.
The downward pressure against the dollar was
sparked by indications of some slowing of the pace
of U.S. real output growth, which contributed to
expectations that further increases in U.S. interest
rates were unlikely, and by the acrimony surrounding the ongoing trade dispute between the United
States and Japan. The crisis in Mexico also weighed
on the dollar. On several occasions in March and
early April the Trading Desk at the New York Federal Reserve Bank, joined by some other central
banks, intervened to buy dollars on behalf of the

Treasury and the Federal Reserve System in an
effort to counter the pressure for dollar depreciation.
The release by the G-7 officials of the communique
from their meeting in late April supporting an orderly
reversal of the dollar's decline and the signing of a
trade agreement between the United States and Japan
at the end of June helped to stabilize the dollar, which
fluctuated narrowly until early August. The dollar
then rebounded somewhat and remained within a
narrow range through the end of the year. The recovery of the dollar stemmed, in pan, from perceptions
that its earlier decline, particularly in terms of the yea
had been excessive in light of the underlying fundamentals. Moreover, weakness in the economies of
some other major industrial countries began to
emerge, reducing prospective returns available

U.S. and Foreign Interest Rates
Three-month
Percent

Average foreign

10

U.S. large CD

Weighted Average Foreign Exchange Value
of the U.S. Dollar

i

December 1993 = 100

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

Ten-year

Daily

Percent

100

12
Average foreign

90




U.S. Treasury

80

NDJFMAMJJASONDJFMAMJJASONDJFM
1993
1994
1995
1996
Note. Index of weighted average foreign exchange value of
U.S. dollar in terms of currencies of the other G-10 countries.
Weights are based on 1972-76 global trade of each of the foreign countries.

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

i

1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
Note. Average foreign rates are the trade-weighted average,
for the other G-10 countries, of yields on instruments comparable
to U.S. instruments shown. The data are monthly.

82
abroad. At times from May through August, the Trading Desk again entered the market in conjunction with
other central banks to intervene in support of the
dollar, reinforcing the view that U.S. authorities were
committed to a strong dollar.
In all of the major foreign industrial countries,
long-term interest rates declined during 1995, nearly
reversing the increases that had occurred during the
previous year. On average, rates on foreign government issues with maturities of ten years fell about
150 basis points in the twelve months to December,
somewhat less than the decline that occurred in the
comparable U.S. rate. In Canada, where economic
activity slowed sharply, the drop in long-term rates
nearly matched that in the United States, while in
Italy, where political uncertainty remained a concern
throughout the year, rates fell only 100 basis points.
During the first few weeks of this year, long-term
rates abroad generally moved down somewhat more,
but then most recently returned to their December
average levels. An important exception is Japan,
where rates have risen from their late-December levels, apparently reflecting market perceptions that the
stage is set for a Japanese economic recovery. Shortterm market rates in the major foreign industrial countries were mixed, but on average rates moved down.
On balance, the dollar depreciated about 8 percent
in terms of the German mark during 1995 and by
similar amounts in terms of most other currencies
participating in the Exchange Rate Mechanism of the
European Union. After substantial depreciation
against the mark early in the year, the dollar stabilized
Foreign Exchange Value of the Dollar
in Terms of Selected Currencies
December 1993 = 100
Daily

100

90

80
Japanese yen

i i
i ii
L i
70
NOJFMAMJ J A S O N D J F M A M J J A S O N D J F M
1993
1994
1995
Note. Foreign currency units per dollar.




1996

and then partly recovered as economic indicators
revealed significant softening in economic activity in
Germany. Easing by the Bundesbank during the second half of the year reinforced the view that mark
interest rates were not likely to rise and might fall
further. The dollar depreciated slightly, on balance, in
terms of the Canadian dollar, despite periods of selling pressure on the Canadian dollar during the year
related to Canada's fiscal situation and possible secession by Quebec.
Although the dollar did fall to a record low, below
80 yen to the dollar in mid-April, by year-end the
dollar had appreciated slightly in terms of the yen
from its level at the end of 1994. So far this year, the
dollar has appreciated somewhat further against the
yen. Resolution of the trade dispute and repeated
episodes of exchange market intervention by the Bank
of Japan, sometimes in conjunction with U.S. and
foreign monetary authorities, contributed to the appreciation of the dollar in terms of the yen during the
second half of the year. However, the fundamental
cause of the yen's decline during that period probably
was the easing of monetary policy by the Bank of
Japan that pushed short-term market interest rates to
extremely low levels.
In terms of the Mexican peso, the dollar appreciated sharply from the onset of the crisis in late
December 1994 to March. The dollar subsequently
retraced some of those gains, and the peso-dollar rate
fluctuated narrowly through the middle of the year.
Uncertainty about the prospects for Mexican economic performance and macroeconomic policy
sparked renewed appreciation of the dollar in terms of
the peso in November. Since November, data indicating that the decline in Mexican real economic activity
may have ended, some intervention by the Bank of
Mexico in support of the peso, and a perception that
the decline in the peso may have gone too far given
the underlying fundamentals have contributed to some
rebound of the peso. During the year, the Mexican
authorities drew $3 billion on short-term swap lines
with the Federal Reserve and Exchange Stabilization
Fund (ESF) of the U.S. Treasury and $10.5 billion on
a medium-term swap facility provided by the ESF. By
the end of January 1996, the short-term drawings had
been entirely repaid.
Adjusted for relative consumer price inflation, the
dollar was little changed, on balance, against a
multilateral-trade-weighted average of the currencies
of eight developing countries that are important U.S.
trading partners. The dollar's 30 percent real appreciation against the Mexican peso was about offset by
real depreciations against the other seven currencies.

83
Growth of Money and Debt
Percent

Period

M1

M2

M3

Domestic
Nonfinancial
Debt

9.6

9.5

12.4
9.7
10.8

10.2
9.8
11.9
14.6

8.6
9.2
4.2
5.7
52

7.7
9.0
5.9
6.3
4.0

14.3
13.3
9.9
9.0
7.8

4.2
7.9
14.3
10.5
2.4
-1.8

4.1
3.1
1.8
1.4
.6
42

1.8
1.2
.6
1.0
1.6
6.1

6.8
4.6
4.7
5.2
5.2
5.3

-.1
-.5
-1.5
-5.1

1.4
4.3
7.0
4.0

4.8
6.7
8.0
4.4

5.3
7.0
4.6
3.9

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984

7.5
5.4 (2.5)2
8.8
10.3
5.4

1985
1986
1987
1988
1989

12.0
15.5
6.3
4.3
.5

1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995

8.7
9.0
8.8
11.8
8.1

9.5

Quarter (annual rate)3
1995:01
Q2
Q3
Q4

3. From average for preceding quarter to average for
quarter indicated.

1. From average for fourth quarter of preceding year to
average for fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Adjusted for shifts to NOW accounts in 1981.




25

O




ISBN 0-16-052868-2

9"780160"528682"