View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
Report of the Federal Reserve Board pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978,
PX. 95-523
and The State of the Economy

HEARING
BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON
ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT FORMATION
OF THE

COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND
URBAN AFFAIRS
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED THIRD CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION

JULY 22, 1994
Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs

Serial No. 103-155

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
81-438 CC

WASHINGTON : 1994

For sale by the U.S. Government Printing Office
Superintendent of Documents, Congressional Sales Office, Washington, DC 20402


81-438 - 94 - 1


I S B N 0-16-045885-4

HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS
HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas, Chairman
STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota
CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York
BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York
KWEISI MFUME, Maryland
MAXINE WATERS, California
LARRY LAROCCO, Idaho
BILL ORTON, Utah
JIM BACCHUS, Florida
HERBERT C. KLEIN, New Jersey
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
PETER DEUTSCH, Florida
LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois
BOBBY L. RUSH, Illinois
LUCILLE ROYBAL-ALLARD, California
THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin
ELIZABETH FURSE, Oregon
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
ALBERT R. WYNN, Maryland
CLEO FIELDS, Louisiana
MELVIN WATT, North Carolina
MAURICE HINCHEY, New York
CALVIN M. DOOLEY, California
RON KLINK, Pennsylvania
ERIC FINGERHUT, Ohio

JAMES A. LEACH, Iowa
BILL McCOLLUM, Florida
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
DOUG BEREUTER, Nebraska
THOMAS J. RIDGE, Pennsylvania
TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin
ALFRED A. (AL) McCANDLESS, California
RICHARD H. BAKER, Louisiana
JIM NUSSLE, Iowa
CRAIG THOMAS, Wyoming
SAM JOHNSON, Texas
DEBORAH PRYCE, Ohio
JOHN LINDER, Georgia
JOE KNOLLENBERG, Michigan
RICK LAZIO, New York
ROD GRAMS, Minnesota
SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama
MIKE HUFFINGTON, California
MICHAEL CASTLE, Delaware
PETER KING, New York
BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont

SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT FORMATION
PAUL E. KANJORSKI,
STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BILL ORTON, Utah
HERBERT C. KLEIN, New Jersey
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
CALVIN M. DOOLEY, California
RON KLINK, Pennsylvania
ERIC FINGERHUT, Ohio




Pennsylvania, Chairman
THOMAS J. RIDGE; Pennsylvania
BILL McCOLLUM, Florida
TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin
JIM NUSSLE, Iowa
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
PETER KING, New York

CONTENTS
Hearing held on:
July 22, 1994
Appendix:
July 22, 1994

33
WITNESS
FRIDAY, JULY 22, 1994

Greenspan, Alan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System
APPENDIX
Prepared statement:
Greenspan, Alan
ADDITIONAL MATERIAL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
Kanjorski, Hon. Paul E.:
Questions submitted to Mr. Greenspan
Responses to questions
Ridge, Hon. Tom, questions to Chairman Greenspan with responses thereto ...




(HI)

51
54
59




CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
FRIDAY, JULY 22, 1994

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND
CREDIT FORMATION,
COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS,
Washington, DC.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room
340, Cannon House Office Building, Hon. Paul E. Kanjorski [chairman of the subcommittee] presiding.
Present: Chairman Kanjorski, Representatives Neal, Orton,
Klein, Dooley, Klink, Fingerhut, Roth, and Nussle.
Also present: Representative Leach.
Chairman KANJORSKI. The subcommittee will come to order.
The subcommittee meets today to receive the biennial report of
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on the conduct of the monetary policy and the state of the economy as mandated in the Full Employment Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Under President Clinton, the Nation's economy has undergone a
significant recovery and growth since emerging from the recession
in the early 1990's. Our gross national product has increased at a
healthy rate, but unemployment rates continue to decline and inflation remains at a low level.
Mr. Chairman, we will have other members of the subcommittee
join us today and I am sure some of them will ask you to play the
role of prognosticator, as you tend to do very well. I suspect that
in the 10 years that I have been in Congress we probably have had
better cooperation between the Federal Reserve and the Office of
the President in attempting to resolve budget problems and the
economy and improve the economy than we have had in a long
time.
So this subcommittee appreciates that effort on your part and, of
course, recognizes the fact that the administration is different from
the standpoint of political persuasion of the last administration and
it obviously indicates that America is capable in this very tough
time to have a bipartisan economic policy that is successful.
To that end, I congratulate you and I think that you deserve
merit and recognition for the Federal Reserve portion of what we
can attribute to the American recovery. I am a little disturbed and,
unfortunately, the American people and the business community of
America haven't quite recognized the importance of the accomplishments of the Clinton administration economically, and particularly
as you have stated in your prior testimony, the major accomplishment of the balanced budget process that we went through last
(l)




year or the attempt to decrease the deficit significantly that we
went through last year.
It is well on track, as I gather. It is more optimistic than any
of us would imagine. We have got work to do and we look forward
to your recommendations on that point.
On the other hand, during the questioning today I would like you
to give some thought later on, perhaps we could discuss it, I am
a little bit—still interested in the Bank of International Settlements and I have given it some thought. We have not had a chance
to discuss it personally in the intervening weeks since we originally
discussed that, but I have some thought processes that both myself
and the subcommittee probably needs the ability to get the best
economic and constitutional minds in the country to give us some
advice on that area and perhaps discuss some format that you
would think would be relatively worthwhile to pursue along that
end.
Senator Gore, when he was a Senator, before he was Vice President, used to say the wrong things are up and the wrong things
are down and suddenly July 1994 you have seen a significant
change of the wrong things being up and the wrong things being
down and now we see the right things being up and the right
things being down.
We would like some anticipation from you what we could expect
over the next year or 2 years and whether or not it is your opinion
the recovery is sufficiently supported and on a strong enough foundation that we can look at the rest of the 1990's to encourage the
American business community to become as competitive as we
know they can be in the world market for the remainder of the
20th century.
So I thank you for your presence today and I would be happy to
recognize my colleague from Iowa.
Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have no opening
comment.
Chairman KANJORSKI. And the gentleman from Utah.
Mr. ORTON. I would just like to welcome the Chairman here and
look forward to your statement.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Chairman, you may proceed.
STATEMENT OF ALAN GREENSPAN, CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF
GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, gentlemen.
It is a pleasure to appear before this subcommittee to discuss
with you recent economic developments and the Federal Reserve's
conduct of monetary policy.
The favorable performance of the economy continued in the first
half of 1994. Economic growth was strong, unemployment fell appreciably, and inflation remained subdued. To sustain the expansion, the Federal Reserve adjusted monetary policy over recent
months so as to contain potential inflation pressures.
Our actions this year can be understood by reference to policy
under the previous several years. Through that period, the Federal
Reserve moved toward and then maintained for a considerable time
a purposefully accomodative stance of policy. During 1993, that




stance was associated with low levels of real short-term interest
rates—around zero. We judged that low interest rates would be
necessary for a time to overcome the effects of a number of factors
that were restraining the economic expansion, including heavy debt
burdens of households and businesses and tighter credit policies of
many lenders.
By early this year, however, it became clear that many of these
impediments had diminished and that the economy had consequently gained considerable momentum. In these circumstances,
it was no longer appropriate to maintain an accomodative policy.
Indeed, history strongly suggests that maintenance of real shortterm rates at levels prevailing last year ultimately would have
fueled inflationary pressures and imbalances.
Accordingly, the Federal Open Market Committee at its meeting
in early February decided to move away from its accommodative
posture by tightening reserve market conditions. Given the level of
real short-term rates and the evident momentum in the economy,
it seemed likely that a substantial cumulative adjustment of policy
would be needed. However, committee members recognized that financial markets were not fully prepared for this action. Many were
concerned that a marked shift in the stance of policy, while necessary, could precipitate an exaggerated reaction in financial
markets.
With this in mind, we initially tightened reserve conditions only
slightly, just enough to raise the Federal funds rate a quarter of
a percentage point. And the financial markets did indeed react
sharply, with substantial increases in longer term interest rates
and declines in stock prices. Markets remained unsettled for several months and we continued to move cautiously in M^rch and
April in the process of moving away from our accommodative
stance. By mid-May, however, a considerable portion of the adjustment in portfolios to the new rate environment appeared to have
taken place. With financial markets evidently better prepared to
absorb a larger move, the Federal Reserve could substantially complete the removal of the degree of monetary accommodation that
prevailed throughout 1993.
The Board raised the discount rate a half a percentage point, a
move that was fully passed through to reserve market conditions
by the FOMC. Partly to minimize any market confusion about the
extent of and rationale for our moves, the Federal Reserve has announced each action and in relevant instances, provided an explanation. At its meeting in early July, the FOMC faced considerable
uncertainty about the pace of expansion and pressures on prices
going forward. And it made no further adjustment in its policy
stance.
Nonetheless, it is an open question whether our actions to date
have been sufficient to head off inflationary pressures and thus
maintain favorable trends in the economy. Labor demand has been
quite strong, pointing to robust growth in production and incomes.
To be sure, some hints of moderation in the growth of the domestic
final demand have appeared, and the recent indications of accelerating inventory accumulation may suggest an unwanted backing
up of stocks. Conversely, the inventory accumulation may reflect
pressures on firms who had brought inventories down to




suboptimal levels and now need to replenish them. In the latter
case, stock-building may continue at an above-normal rate supporting production for quite some time. Moreover, the improving economic conditions of our trading partners should add impetus to aggregate demand from the external sector.
How these forces balance out in the coming months could be critical in determining whether inflation will remain in check, for the
amount of slack in the economy, while difficult to judge, appears
to have become relatively small. An increase of inflation would
come at considerable cost. We would lose hard-won ground in the
fight against inflation expectations, ground that would be difficult
to recapture later; our long-run economic performance would be impaired by the inefficiencies associated with higher inflation if it
persisted, and harsher policy actions would eventually be necessary
to reverse the upsurge in inflationary instabilities. We are determined to prevent such an outcome and currently are monitoring
economic and financial data carefully to assess whether additional
adjustments are appropriate.
The economic figures that have formed the backdrop of our policy
actions so far this year confirm that a rapid expansion has been in
rogress. Following growth at an annual rate of 7 percent in the
mrth quarter of last year, real gross domestic product rose at
nearly a 3.5 percent rate during the first quarter. A conceptually
equivalent measure of aggregate output, gross domestic income, exhibited even larger gains in the fourth and first quarters. At this
stage, available data leave some uncertainty regarding the pace of
economic activity over the past 3 months. Nonetheless, the evidence in hand makes it reasonably clear that growth remained appreciably above its longer run trend. The robust expansion over the
first half of 1994 has been reflected in substantial increases in
employment.
The accumulating evidence of stronger than expected economic
growth here and abroad, combined with changing expectations of
policy actions by the Federal Reserve, as well as other central
banks, prompted considerable increases in long-term interest rates
in occasionally volatile markets over the first half of the year.
The recent weakness in bond prices was not limited to the United States, but was accompanied by a surge in foreign interest
rates.
Rising foreign interest rates, concerns in markets about the prospects for reduced trade tensions and about U.S. inflation contributed to considerable activity directed at rebalancing international
investment portfolios. One effect of this activity appears to have
been a substantial decline of the foreign exchange value of the dollar on net over the past 6 months. Foreign exchange rates are key
prices in the American economy with significant implications for
the volumes of exports and imports as well as the prices of imports
and domestically produced items that compete with imports. The
foreign exchange value of the dollar can also provide useful insights into inflation expectations. If we conduct an appropriate
monetary policy—and appropriate economic policies more generally—we shall achieve our goals of solid economic growth and
price stability and such economic results will ensure that dollardenominated assets remain attractive to global investors, which is

E




essential to the dollar's continuing role as the world's principal reserve currency.
Rising interest rates have contributed to another substantial
gain in the velocity of the broad monetary aggregates this year. As
a consequence, growth of both aggregates near the lower ends of
the 1994 ranges is considered to be consistent with achieving our
objectives for economic performance, and the ranges were left
unchanged.
The committee also decided, on a provisional basis, to carry forward the current ranges of the monetary aggregates of 1995.
Regarding domestic nonfinancial sector debt, we made no adjustment to this year's monitoring range, but elected to set a provisional monitoring range for 1995 of 3 to 7 percent, a percentage
point lower than last year's. A lower range would conform with
some deceleration in nominal income, in the process of containing
inflation and ultimately making progress toward price stability.
With appropriate monetary policies, the Board members and the
Reserve Bank presidents see the economy settling into more moderate rates of growth over the next six quarters and inflation remaining relatively subdued.
In view of rapid economic growth recently and narrowing margins of slack in productive capacity, there has been considerable interest of late in the Federal Reserve's ideas about the longrun
trends in output and employment consistent with avoiding pressures on prices. My colleagues and I don't think the numerical estimates of these trends by the FOMC would be useful in helping
Congress and the public gauge our policy strategy. We believe, instead, that our intentions are best conveyed in terms of our declared objective of fostering as much growth of the output and employment as can be achieved without placing destabilizing inflationary pressures on productive resources. There is considerable
uncertainty about what that goal implies for the expansion of gross
domestic product and rates of unemployment at the economy's full
potential.
Uncertainties around these variables arise because identifying
economic relationships is always difficult, partly owing to limitations of the data. But more fundamentally, all policymakers recognize that notions of potential GDP growth and the so-called natural
rate of unemployment are considerable simplifications, useful in
conceptual models but subject to a variety of real world complications. Our economy is a complex, dynamic system, comprising
countless and diverse households, services, products, and prices,
interacting in a multitude of markets. Estimates of macroeconomic
relationships, as best we can make them, are useful starting points
for analysis, but they are just starting points.
Given questions about the aggregate relationships, policymakers
need to look below the surface into the markets themselves for evidence of tightness that might indicate whether inflationary pressures are indeed building.
If the economy were nearing capacity, we would expect to see
certain patterns in the statistical and anecdotal information. With
increasing frequency and intensity, reports of shortages of skilled
labor, strikes, and instances of difficulties in finding workers in
specific regions, for example, all would be more likely. Businesses




might have difficulty obtaining certain materials and the price of
these materials would rise.
In recent months we have seen some of these signs. There are
reports of shortages of some types of labor: Construction workers
and truck drivers, for instance. Indexes of vendor performance have
deteriorated considerably, and manufacturers are paying higher
prices for materials used in their production processes. As yet,
these sorts of indications do not seem to be widespread across the
economy. Nonetheless, we shall need to be particularly alert to
these emerging signs in considering further adjustments to policy
in the period ahead.
In light of the uncertainties about aggregate measures of economic potential, the Federal Reserve cannot rely heavily on any
one estimate of either the natural rate of unemployment, as it is
called, or potential GDP growth. Most important, we have no intention of setting artificial limits on employment or growth.
A more significant issue for economic policymakers than the precise values of such estimates is what can be done to maximize sustainable employment and economic growth. We need, for example,
to give careful attention to the problem of unemployment as noted
by the G-7 leaders at their recent summit. We could raise output
and living standards around the world and at the same time ease
many social problems if more people were working.
We ought to be encouraging measures to increase the flexibility
of our work force and labor markets. Improving education and
training and facilitating better and more rapid matching of workers
with jobs are essential elements in making more effective use of
the American workers.
Congress and the administration also can continue to contribute
to the growth of our economy's capital and productivity through a
sound fiscal policy. The extension of the spending caps in last
year's budget agreements was a significant step in putting fiscal
policy on a more sustainable longrun path. But under current law,
the deficit as a percent of GDP will begin to expand again as we
move into the next century with unacceptable consequences for financial stability and economic growth. Only by reducing the
growth in spending is ultimate balance achievable.
As I have emphasized many times, Mr. Chairman, the Federal
Reserve also can contribute to the achievement of our overriding
goal—maximum sustainable economic growth—by pursuing and ultimately achieving a stable price level.
There is some evidence to suggest that the stronger trend of productivity growth we have witnessed over the recent past is due at
least partly to the beneficial effects of low rates of inflation.
Our Nation has made considerable progress in putting the economy on a sound footing in the past few years. To preserve and extend these advances, our monetary and fiscal policies will need to
remain disciplined and focused on our long-term objectives. We
would be foolish to squander our recent gains for near-term benefits that would prove ephemeral. Indeed, by fostering progress toward price stability, achieving lower Federal budget deficits, and
encouraging competitive markets both here and abroad, we will
help ensure the continued vitality of our Nation's economy now and
for many years into the future.




Mr. Chairman, as I am sure you have noted, I have excerpted
quite considerably from my prepared text and request my full remarks be included for the record.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Greenspan can be found in the
appendix.]
Chairman KANJORSKI. Without objection, so ordered.
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, you referred in your closing remarks in the statement to the fact that we
have to get a handle even further on the budget deficit if we are
to have expanded, continued growth in the economy in the years
ahead. Do you have a preference?
Does it matter if the policy of the Congress and government is
in terms of whether we are spending money in consumption or investment? Is there a need for us to evaluate the quality of government expenditures over the next several years that would have a
major impact on where the American economy was going?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, obviously, it does matter what
we spend it on and clearly investment-type outlays have a more
important positive effect and less of a negative effect than strictly
consumption. But I would be hesitant to conclude from that that
we move toward a capital budget as distinct from our simple unified budget.
And the reason is that while, from analytical and public policy
points of view, it is important to distinguish whether or not the
types of outlays that we are expending are consumption-rated or
investment-rated, at the end of the day, all differences between
receipts and outlays of all types have to be funded by the sale of
Federal obligations in the markets. And the markets cannot distinguish in the intermediate period whether the financing is for investment or whether it is for consumption. History suggests to us
that we have to be very careful in this area, and I suggest that
while we should look at the composition of what we spend, we
should be very careful not to veer away from the unified budget in
our projections into the future, because the financial markets
around the world, all of the individuals who hold dollar-denominated assets, look, as best as I can judge, at the financing requirements of the U.S. Treasury and are not focused very much on the
composition of what those expenditures are which led to it. And,
therefore, the presumption that somehow deficit spending on consumption items alone is really all that the markets would look at
is surely not the case, at least history clearly indicates that it has
not been the case.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Chairman, at the conclusion of the
falling dollar, do you have any observations for the American people as to what we can expect and anticipate as our over-adjustment, as a matter of fact, is in fact a reflection of the fundamental
weaknesses of the currency?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, I have been disinclined to try to
forecast what the dollar will or will not do at any particular point
in time. It is obviously a very complex issue and all I can say is
I would reiterate basically what Under Secretary Summers said
yesterday before the Senate Banking Committee about the nature
offerees which are.driving th^ dollar.




8

Clearly, it is in our interest to have a stronger dollar. It is in our
interest because we are the reserve currency in the world, particularly, and as you may note what I indicated in my prepared remarks, there are technical issues with respect to the effect of the
falling dollar on inflation and that clearly is adverse. But it is very
important that the U.S. Government in all its areas and aspects
recognize, as indeed Secretary Bentsen's and Under Secretary
Summers' comments in recent days have indicated that a stronger
dollar essentially helps the United States and indeed helps our
trading partners as best we can judge.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I guess one last question in that regard,
have the foreign central banks contacted or coordinated with the
Fed regarding purchase of dollars? Have you had any cooperation
using the Federal Reserve with the foreign central banks?
Mr. GREENSPAN. We talk to them all the time. Indeed, we have
been embarked upon numerous coordinated interventions in the
international financial currency markets over the years and this results from a fairly close relationship that exists among the major
central banks in the world. I speak to my colleagues quite often
trying to get a sense from them as to what is happening in Europe
and Japan and elsewhere.
And since we are in a global economy, the presumption that the
United States somehow can exist as an independent entity from
the rest of the world—a notion which may have had some validity
40 years ago—is increasingly less apparent today and it is quite
important for us to make certain that we coordinate as best we can
with our colleagues.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Roth.
Mr. ROTH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, it is nice to have you with us again.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you very much.
Mr. ROTH. Mr. Chairman, the last time that we were together,
I think we basically came down to a form—at least I did, right or
wrongly—that as inflation goes up, interest rates go up. Inflation
stabilized, interest rates will stabilize. Is that still pretty well the
formula that we have today?
Mr. GREENSPAN. There is no question that a significant part of
the level of interest rates, both short and long, reflect inflation expectations. Now, inflation expectations, remember, are not the
same thing as inflation. These are expectations of players in the
market of what they think inflation is going to be. They could be
wrong, but nonetheless that is what sets those particular relationships. So very clearly we see that inflation is a factor.
We also have to remember that there are other elements which
move real interest rates, those already adjusted for inflation. And
that largely is a consequence of the changes in the underlying supply and demand for credit in the international markets of capital
and savings. Some interest rates levels reflect that and so I would
say inflation expectations are very important elements, in certain
instances overriding elements, in the level of interest rates but not
the only element.
Mr. ROTH. What significance do you attach to the recent slowdown of single-family housing starts in America?




Mr. GREENSPAN. We saw a really quite extraordinary rise as
mortgage interest rates fell and affbrdability improved very measurably in a period when there was a significant backlog of demand
for single-family residences. We had an extraordinary period of
very strong demand and, of course, we even had a very strong demand for existing homes which turned over quite significantly during the period.
Partly because we have gone through part of the backlog, partly
because mortgage interest rates have turned back up, we are getting a somewnat slower pace of single-family residences and the
data that we are looking at with respect to home sales, permits,
and starts are all consistent with that view of gradual coming off
the peaks that we experienced last year.
Mr. ROTH. So you feel that we are slowing down somewhat, as
I interpret what you are saying. You don't expect it to go back up
again. We are sort of leveling off now at a lower rate, is that what
you are saying?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I really don't know, and I don't want to comment, because it is going to depend on a number of other things,
but what I am reasonably sure of is it is not going to go straight
down. There is no evidence of that. The demand is still strong.
Even though mortgage interest rates have gone up, by historical
standards they remain quite low and the affordability of houses is
really quite solid.
Mr. ROTH. Mr. Chairman, here on Capitol Hill, you know, we are
really wrestling with an issue on health care and one of the key
elements in that, of course, is employer mandates. Now, we have
had all kinds of testimony on both sides, people saying you impose
an employer mandate, you are going to lose a lot of jobs in America. Other people say you have to have employer mandates to pay
for health care.
What is your opinion? Do you think if we had employer mandates that it would impact on our economy negatively?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, I very purposefully stayed away
from trying to get involved in the details of
Mr. ROTH. I am trying to get you involved because I want you
to help me make up my mind.
Mr. GREENSPAN. All I can say, Congressman, is to date I have
been rather successful in being rather evasive on this issue, and I
have learned how to do it with a great degree of skill.
Mr. ROTH. That is true.
Mr. GREENSPAN. In all seriousness, though, the central bank's
real interest is the bottom line. All we are fundamentally interested in is the issue of what are the volume requirements of the
U.S. Treasury because as a central bank our policies are crucially
involved with that. So we have stayed away from the issue of evaluating or giving our comments on the nature of the composition of
receipts and expenditures.
Mr. ROTH. I just had one more question because I want to limit
my time—we have a lot of other Congressmen here that want to
ask questions this morning—and that deals with Social Security
and the chairman asked a question before about the deficit and so
on. Last year we had some $53 billion in surplus in Social Security
which was used by the government for other purposes. Now, senior




10

citizens around the country are very upset because they feel all
this surplus money went out and put lOUs into their fund and that
is it. What they would like to see is this money invested for Social
Security other than giving it to the government in the form of
lOUs. What is your opinion about that?
Mr. GREENSPAN. As you know, Congressman, this issue has come
up over decades and, indeed, I recall when I was involved with the
Social Security Commission over a decade ago, we went through
that issue in some detail. It is a very complex question and the
only thing that I would say in this regard, which is not really addressing the question you raise which is a very important question,
is that one must be careful not to view the Social Security surpluses off budget.
In other words, I know that the statute says you do it that way.
But from an economic point of view, it is important to stay with
the unified budget concept if we are going to get the appropriate
measure of how the Federal Government's budget impacts our
economy.
Mr. ROTH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Klink.
Mr. KLINK. Thank you very much, Chairman Greenspan. It is
nice to have you with us.
I wanted to just touch on one point that you made toward the
end of your speech. You were talking about the fact of deficit reduction has been very timely, the Federal Government's deficit reduction. Can I get you to expand upon that a little bit and talk more
because, as you know, we had a discussion yesterday and some
votes on the floor on entitlement caps. I am not sure if what we
do and what you do is an exact science or not. The question is
Mr. GREENSPAN. I can't speak for your
Mr. KLINK. How fast do we do this. I mean what are the ramifications of imposing even tighter caps on discretionary spending
and tightening the caps on the entitlements? Where are we heading and how does that help you do your job?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, as I indicated in my prepared remarks, and I believe my colleagues would agree with this, the extension and the enforcement of the spending caps, in this case discretionary, have really been quite a surprise. Because when they
were initially put in place, as you may recall, it was quite feasible
to presume that either the President would declare that certain expenditures were an emergency, because that word could be used
very loosely, or at the extreme, that it would only require a majority of both Houses to break the caps.
In the event, and I think this is a very important issue which
is very positive for the future, it has been politically extraordinarily
difficult to do either and I interpret that as meaning that the
American people have increasingly become aware of the significant
problems which the chronic long-term budget deficit can have on
our economy in the short term, but just as importantly for the next
generation, and the notion that caps are working and that they are
feasible is the best fiscal policy surprise that we have all had. The
administration and the Congress should be congratulated for pressing this type of structure forward because you would know far bet-




11
ter than I how many motions and bills die because they didn't meet
the caps or they couldn't find pay-go offsets.
And that more than anything has been a very crucial factor in
bringing the budget deficit down and if we can resolve the longterm budget problem, after all of these decades, we could find that
we will have a materially positive effect on the financing of our
budget and a major reduction in the drain on what I would call a
meager saving flow in the United States.
So ideally, I would even argue that we should move toward a
budget surplus and contribute to national saving because of the
particular problems that we have. I discussed this at some length
in my prepared remarks and I don't want to get into it here, but
on the issue of the caps on entitlements per se, I haven't come to
a conclusion because I haven't had a chance to look at the approach
of the legislation that is in the bill.
Mr. KLINK. The thing that we wrestle with here obviously as you
mentioned that bills that die because you can't find offsets. When
we are spending less, there are certain segments of our manufacturing where the government is a purchaser that is adversely affected and some of that is manufacturing that is very important to
our Nation because it may be defense-related, it may have some
other specific need. Is that of concern to you that there will be segments of our manufacturing that would be left behind as we become more fiscally responsible?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is not so much that we would become more
fiscally responsible because in the longer run there is nothing that
helps American manufacturing and competitiveness better than
having a noninflationary environment and a noninflationary environment is very significantly fostered by budget discipline.
So while I have no doubt that when you change the composition
of the types of procurement that are involved in our manfacturing
sector from defense to nondefense, or within the defense area
where there has been a tremendous shuffle—that is something that
has been going on for decades—some individual institutions, manufacturing firms, and companies have prospered. Others have faded
away or shrunk to negligible proportions. I see no reason to suspect
that that process will not continue.
It is important to recognize that one of the great strengths of the
American economy is the dynamism, the churning that is going on
all the time for competitive reasons and the impact of that is to
make a very substantial positive contribution to productivity and
economic growth.
I like to cite the figure, for example, Congressman, that there are
300,000 people a week who lose their jobs but a substantially larger number now who are getting jobs, so it is a very big turnover.
This is much larger than in Europe and I believe in Japan. And
it is one of our really major strengths. So I see no alternative to
allowing that process to happen. While I recognize it requires some
adjustments in a lot of companies, these are basically the mechanisms which produce higher standards of living.
Mr. KLINK. Thank you, Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Klink.
Mr. Leach.




12

Mr. LEACH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Well, I would like, Mr.
Chairman, to return for a minute to the foreign currency issue.
I, personally, thoroughly agree with that, that a stronger dollar
is in the country's best interest at this time. Where I have some
differentiation judgment, though, is on this issue of free market
versus government intervention. And it strikes me that the administration is sending some signals over the past year that they could
accept a weaker dollar and based upon perhaps some misreading
of judgment or misreading of this circumstance, the government
has chosen to indicate that that isn't the policy and so in essence
has taken resources that are public and put them at risk; that is,
it has intervened in the markets.
If the markets go the right direction, the taxpayer ends up, just
as one plays the commodities market, with a profit. If they go the
wrong way, the reverse. But here, I mean one of the great changes
over the last several decades has been that reserves of governments are much less in relationship to the size of the market and
every day they are getting smaller and smaller.
In fact, one set of calculations, although it is an exaggerated set
because it isn't just the dollar, but the total reserves of the Treasury and the Fed together are only one-sixteenth of an average day's
trading. So when the Fed and the Treasury intervene, it strikes me
two things occur. One is that the assumption is that the government knows best, not on what is best for the economy although
that is the premise, but in what direction the markets are going
to go and therefore you end up with a speculative situation.
The second thing that occurs is when it speaks in terms of foreign coordination which is always a very responsible and sensible
thing because it is better to act in concert in some ways than not,
that, by definition, implicit quid pro quos develop; that is, if we ask
the Japanese or the British or the French or Germans to intervene
on behalf of what we want the direction of dollar to go, does that
make the Federal Reserve Board and the Treasury then obligated
at another point in time to intervene at the request of those
governments?
The history of the last few years has been that private sector actors have not only been larger but they have been wiser than governments and almost psychologically have wanted to bet against
governments.
And so my question to you is, as a general proposition, how long
can we sustain the notion that governments can correctly intervene
and with regard to this intervention, because as a general proposition but on any day-to-day basis there could be differentiations,
it appears the dollar has weakened versus—again, despite
intervention.
Have we lost any monies that you want to report to the Congress
and the American people and have other foreign governments lost
any money and is that an awkward signal?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, we have obviously debated this at
great length within the Federal Reserve, with the Treasury, and
the general conclusion is that in the broadest sense, the fundamentals will determine where the exchange rate will go over time.
Nonetheless, there have been instances where in retrospect, and
even at the time, it appeared as though there was some temporary




13

imbalance in the markets which we have effectively countered, preventing the market, for example, cumulating downward or cumulating upward.
If you can catch the markets at the appropriate time, I think you
can break the pattern that exists. I don't think you can do it often.
I think you can do it at important points in time and we, with the
Treasury, discuss those issues at quite considerable length before
we do it, and we always do it jointly—or I should say that we come
together and make judgments as to how we should do it, and with
very rare exceptions it is a 50-50 Treasury-Federal Reserve deal.
In my experience, which has been 7 years at the Federal Reserve, we have never lost any money. Indeed, our capital gains
have been rather substantially positive. But I wouldn't argue that
that is the purpose, that one is doing exchange rate intervention
for the purpose of obtaining capital gains, but we are very much
acutely aware that we are dealing ultimately with taxpayer money
and we have to be certain that we protect the taxpayer from any
losses.
When I say that as far as my 7 years at the Fed are concerned,
and I assume it goes back probably a longer period than that, there
have been no material losses, that is partly the result of a general
awareness on the part of monetary authorities. I don't also recall
that there are these obligations to other governments although it
is true that we are often approached by some of our central bank
colleagues or finance ministers and there is a lot of ongoing
discussion.
But it is basically that each action, to the extent that we do coordinate it, is taken on its own and on its own merits. We try to
be cooperative, in the sense that when we see there are a destabilizing set of forces which may be only marginally related to the
dollar, we would obviously consider whether it is in our interest to
be of help in that regard, but those are very rare instances.
Mr. LEACH. With regard to this intervention, there have been no
losses?
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct.
Mr. LEACH. Good. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Orton.
Mr. ORTON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and Dr. Greenspan a
pleasure to see you again.
A few weeks ago as you appeared before the Budget Committee
on which I sit, we had a brief interchange about the international
exchange rate of the dollar, at which point you indicated you didn't
have a lot that you could say.
I appreciate the comments you made today. I apologize I had to
step out of the room a few minutes to deal with an issue back in
my home district, so I didn't hear other responses you may have
had, but there seems to be some confusion, at least on the part of
many people I represent, about the dollar and the exchange rate
of the dollar. And when the dollar is high, the reports from government are usually that the dollar is very strong, that it is very bad
for foreign trade we get flooded with imports. Our exports are too
costly, that slows down our economy. Therefore, we need to do
something to intervene to lower the value of the dollar.

81-438 - 94 - 2



14

On the other hand, when the dollar is low, we are told the argument that you have made that this is now injuring our economy.
We cannot have a dollar that is low and people are confused by
saying, well, you know, what is a high dollar and what is a low dollar and when it is high, why does it have to be lowered and when
it is low why does it have to be highered. And who is out there
pushing this thing up and down and so forth? And there is a growing skepticism among the population that if we do know what we
are doing, we are keeping it hidden from the public and that in fact
someone is out there manipulating the dollar up and down and so
forth.
When you see the new derivatives actions in the markets and
you see a great deal of activity taking place there, this even fuels
the skepticism and the speculation that there those bankers go
again. You know, they are just controlling this policy and feathering their own nests and on and on and on.
It is my concern, I think, that we in government need to understand monetary policy. I think that we need to show the confidence
to the public that we do know what is going on and why it is going
on and that in fact either there is an open and free market or if
it is a controlled market that it is controlled, but it is controlled
by someone who knows what is going on and they are doing it for
a good public purpose.
I am not asking you to disclose to us and the world what the
basic secrets of monetary policy might be, if there are any such, but
I guess I would like from you some indication about the extent of
intervention, how often the Federal Reserve and the Treasury Department get together and intervene in the value of the dollar and
the mechanism that is used for that intervention when it is required so that we can set to rest this skepticism that we are never
satisfied or we don't have any policy or that we are running it up
and down for some private gain or government gain.
Do you have any comments that you could help us?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, actually the first part of the
question I was asked at the Kerrey Commission a week ago Friday
in which the notion was raised of whether speculators can manipulate the dollar up and down. I would suspect that within very short
periods of time—minutes, seconds—it is possible that somebody can
unload a big loss and the amount purchased back or something like
that. But these markets are extraordinarily efficient in the sense
that they are free and open, and I know of really no incidences of
where a significant private individual or a group of private individuals acting in concert were able to do very much with respect to
moving any of the major currencies.
With respect to central bank and finance ministry intervention,
the first step is for the senior staff in the Federal Reserve and the
Treasury to consult with each other. Then I will talk with Under
Secretary Summers or Secretary Bentsen and we will eventually
come to a conclusion as to whether it is desirable to intervene or
not. When a judgment to intervene is reached, the action is carried
out by the fiscal agency of the Treasury which is the operating
desk of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
This is a relatively rare action and is not a continuing issue. We
either announce the action concurrently or eventually make a full




15

report. We have not had in any memory that I can recall any major
disputes. Sure, we have differences over the years but when it is
apparent that some intervention should occur, it is usually a consensus view.
Mr. ORTON. Is there some level at which every time it is down
you want it up and every time it is up we want it down? Is there
some basic policy that identifies it is at the right place or are we
really just relying on international markets and what happens with
interest rates overseas and here and trade levels and so on?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I don't want to get into the details of that sort
of thing.
All I can say is we endeavor to get a sense of what these markets
are doing and from the American point of view recognize when we
are dealing with these very large global international financial systems we have no alternative but to make certain that we are aware
and if we find actions are helpful, initiate them. I don't think we
would basically have a list of A, B, C, D. These are much too complex issues to have a simple laundry list of what you do, and if we
did, I would be very uncomfortable.
Mr. ORTON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Orton.
The gentleman from Ohio, Mr. Fingerhut.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It is good to see you
again, Chairman Greenspan.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.
Mr. FINGERHUT. I want to just stay for a moment longer on this
issue of the dollar because I think it has given those of us who
have been trying to watch the monetary and fiscal policy closely
some concern. And fairly or unfairly, the reports of this same testimony that you gave before the Senate has focused on and the
media reports of your testimony has focused on the impression that
you indicated that the low dollar is a primary concern of yours with
respect to inflation and that in itself might trigger the Fed to move
again on the subject of interest rates, so it has become the focus
of this round of testimony whether you intend it to be or not.
The question that I would ask you to explore a little further for
us is two things. One, is it the value of the dollar itself that concerns you and concerns our central bank and that might lead you
to act, or is it only to the extent that the value of the dollar, in
fact, translates itself into inflationary pressures as a result of rising cost of imports, and so forth, so that if those inflationary pressures do not materialize, if, for example, the foreign companies,
particularly Japanese companies who export their products to this
country, eat some of the profits or eat some of the losses, as has
been suggested, that some imports they might strategically use to
maintain market share or for other reasons that you would then
say, well, we watched with concern appropriately but we don't see
this translating into actual impact and therefore we find it prudent
not to act.
The second part of that as you answer is how much of this truly
is a reflection of what is happening in the dynamic and changing
economies of our trading partners and how much of it relates to our
own economy which for better or for worse—some of us on this side
think for better, some of our colleagues on the other side may think




16

for worse—has been at a relatively stable fiscal monetary policy
now for about 18 months to almost 2 years.
Mr. GREENSPAN. The focus that we have on the dollar is because
it has an impact on the American economy. It has an impact one,
for the reasons of the internal price effect which I mentioned in my
prepared remarks, and also because of the crucial importance that
with the very large amount of dollar-denominated assets in the
world, what we don't wish to see happening is a loss in confidence
in the productiveness of dollar-denominated assets. As a consequence of that, we are very much aware of how among a number
of other things the dollar, the trend of the dollar affects the view
as to what is happening in the United States.
The dollar often signals what the rest of the world's view is of
the American economy which is quite relevant to us as a policy
matter. I grant you that you have to be very careful when you have
an exchange rate. There are two parties and it is quite conceivable
that one party may have an impact on the economy of the other
party that may be quite relevant to what is going on and that is
one of the things we basically look at. We don t, as far as the overall focus of monetary policy is concerned, look to stabilizing the exchange rate merely to stabilize the exchange rate.
It is only to the extent that it has an important impact and implication on how the American economy is doing and it is one factor, a rather important one, of what determines on many occasions
what our policy stance is. I can tell you, there are times when
movements in the dollar are really of very marginal significance to
policy. There are other times when they are quite important and
important as to what they indicate about what may be going on
among investors around the world in dollar-denominated assets.
So I can't give you a specific set of rules. As I said, we don't have
a laundry list but the issues you raised are ones that we think
about and we are concerned about in making appropriate
judgments.
Mr. FENGERHUT. I appreciate the exchange will never get us the
recision that we are seeking, but I guess I would just ask one fol)wup to this point before moving on to another subject and ask
whether you have any tentative conclusions that you would care to
share with us as to whether this current round of instability and
the exchange rates reflects fundamental long-term problems that
you think need to be addressed by policy changes or whether it is
simply one of those periods of time where there is instability because there is so much instability and uncertainty that surrounds
the world economy?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Under Secretary Summers addressed this issue
in the Senate yesterday and I found his evaluation a reasonable
one, and indeed, prior to that statements by the Secretary of Treasury. And I would have very little to add to those statements.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you.
Mr. Chairman, I know that my time is expired, if I could have
one other question. It strikes me that one of the areas for which
there is occasionally some speculation, and some are critical, you
deserve a great deal of praise and this administration deserves a
great deal of praise as it is appropriately seeking to coordinate
monetary and fiscal policy.

R




17

I don't mean coordinate in advance, I mean coordinate in fact
when the Congress and the administration together sought to begin
to address the budget deficit which necessarily results in a contract
of fiscal policies. The Federal Reserve, I think, appropriately accommodated that policy effort by maintaining its accommodative
monetary policy until you no longer felt that was necessary. That
was the gist of your testimony. You have also correctly identified,
I think, the continued progress on the Federal budget deficit is a
desirable policy goal, and I think that certainly the members I see
up at this table wouldn't disagree with that.
But continued progress on the Federal budget deficit problem requires a continued, indeed, a racheted-up, further tightening of fiscal policy from this body and from the administration. The question
is whether you would see the Federal Reserve to be in a position
to continue to reflect its monetary policy, continue to balance its
monetary policy, or accommodate its monetary policy to the fiscal
policy if indeed the Congress is successful in making the steps on
the Federal budget deficit that you indicated are desirable.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, last year when the Budget Program was put in place, I testified I believe before this subcommittee, and certainly before the Budget Committee, and it was my
judgment that we would find that interest rates would fall as a
consequence of budget actions because there was an inflation premium, as best as I could judge, embodied especially in long-term
interest rates which reflected the concerns that markets had that
after the turn of the century the deficit would begin to move up.
So we did not in conscious manner feel the necessity in addressing monetary policy to that particular fiscal policy stance because
it wasn't, as we say in the textbooks, fiscal drag; that is, suppression of the economy, because from what we could judge, the decline
in long-term interest rates, occurred as a consequence of budget
policy, to a large extent and offset the so-called fiscal drag. In our
judgment, that led us to conclude that no offsetting action was either appropriate or called for, and all I can say to you is that we
consider what the Treasury is doing in this financing operation as
a major element in the decision which we at the central bank are
involved in with respect to policy and we have to coordinate because there is only one economic policy in the country.
You cannot have divergent policies and in the context which is
very important to us and the Nation—the independence of the Federal Reserve as a central bank—we have endeavored to find the appropriate pattern of mix that in our judgment leads to a noninflationary economic growth. And in that regard, I must say we
obviously talk quite often, I talk to Secretary Bentsen probably
more than once a week in discussing this.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Would you judge—I promise, Mr. Chairman, I
will absolutely stop after this followup. But would you judge that
based on that answer to the actions last summer that further fiscal
tightening on the part of the Congress to further efforts to reduce
the deficit would result in the same impact on the markets at this
stage or would it create a fiscal drag that would require some
offset? Do you think that same inflation premium is there to be
reduced?




18

Mr. GREENSPAN. I will say that long-term interest rates would be
lower than they would otherwise be if we address the long-term
post year-2000 deficit. Remember, when you are dealing with longterm bonds, it is the inflation expectation over the full maturity of
the bonds and supply and demand reflects that. As a consequence,
if the Congress makes a material change in the outvears, legislation that is enacted now but doesn't take effect until the outyears
would have a positive effect on the financial markets.
Mr. FINGERHUT. I thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Thank you, Chairman Kanjorski, for your indulgence.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much.
Now our friend from New Jersey, Mr. Klein.
Mr. KLEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, good morning. Good to see you again as always. I happen to subscribe to the view that a continuing robust
growth in the economy is more important than the question of inflation, and I know that that may be somewhat at odds with your
own view, but I do have some questions and I think most of them
are in the framework of that time fix.
First of all, to follow up on the questions of Mr. Fingerhut and
others who have asked about monetary policy, isn't the primary
weakness of the dollar against the yen, and to a certain extent the
German mark, rather than other countries' currency such as Canadian and other major trading partners?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Obviously, it differs in the sense that the dollar
versus the yen in the market has come down quite considerably recently and obviously recovered the last week or so.
But it is certainly the case that the Canadian dollar is a very relevant currency to the United States because of the extraordinary
amount of trade between us and the Canadians. There are a
number of our Latin America trading partners whose exchange
rates are important to us. We look at not only the individual currencies but also at what we call the trade-weighted data, depending
on whether or not it is the major countries exchange rates—the
G—10—or whether it is even broader. They actually tell you different things.
You use them for different purposes for evaluation and obviously
when you are dealing in the issues of psychology and inflation expectations and the like, the major currencies are far more important than a number of the other ones, but you can't disregard the
others. They ultimately determine whether or not there are
changes in import prices and therefore have an effect on domestic
prices. So you can't disregard those other currencies.
Mr. KLEIN. Well, I realize you can't disregard them, but I am not
sure you answered my question which specifically is—isn't the
weakness against primarily the yen and the German mark?
Mr. GREENSPAN. As against the European countries, yes.
Mr. KLEIN. And if that be the case, should we be directing our
policy primarily because of a weakness against those currencies?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I can't answer that very specifically, Congressman, because it depends on a lot of other issues that are involved
in the markets and how the American economy generally is moving. But all I can say to you is that we are aware of the distinction
and it does matter and it has different effects in different contexts




19

and we try as best we can judge to get a sense of the overall exchange rate or more importantly the position of the dollar in international finance and how it affects domestic American economy.
Mr. KLEIN. Let me ask you one more question on currency and
that is, is there any fear on the part of foreign investors that there
may be further rises in American interest rates and does that have
an effect on the strength of the dollar?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is hard for me to judge what the psychology
of markets is. Individual participants
Mr. KLEIN. Let's assume for the moment that there is some fear
on the part of foreign investors that that may occur. Would that
have an effect on the strength of the dollar?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I have sort of diverted myself as best I can over
the years from answering questions which are too hypothetical because the response would depend to a very large extent on what
other events were occurring.
Mr. KLEIN. Let me just switch to another area and you talked
earlier in response to one question about the fact that single-family
home starts had declined. And while you didn't say so directly, isn't
a major factor the fact that interest rates have gone up and to the
extent that they have gone up, we are now experiencing a very
sluggish experience in a major portion of the economy; namely, the
home building industry?
Mr. GREENSPAN. You could certainly say that housing starts have
come off their peaks; that is, housing sales are not as strong as
they were in the latter part of 1993, for example. They are still
quite solid and the crucial issue here is
Mr. KLEIN. I don't think the home building industry will agree
with you.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I do not deny that. The question really, basically, is if you want a viable home building industry, the thing that
we in government can do most effectively to ensure it is to keep
inflation expectations and inflation down.
Because under those conditions, you get far lower real interest
rates, real mortgage rates, and you get a much more viable residential market. Just to respond in part to the question that you
raised at the very beginning, Congressman, the question of growth
versus inflation; implicitly it is my view, and I think the evidence
is quite persuasive in this regard, is that a necessary condition to
sustain long-term growth, whether it is residential building, automobiles, or anything else, is a low inflation rate.
Mr. KLEIN. Well, since I am told that my time has expired, I will
not belabor the issue, but thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you, Congressman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Klein.
Mr. Chairman, earlier in order to let the whole panel have a
question, I want to get back to something that is important and
you just mentioned in your testimony the importance in your estimation of the independence of the Fed to be the determiner of domestic policy, and as you may be aware, this subcommittee has
been fairly supportive of that thought process, but there are forces
in the Congress and the United States that do not necessarily
agree with the maintenance of the independence of the Fed as it




20

is presently structured. And that brings us to some of the fears
that I have.
And we have not had an opportunity to go into it, but as you and
I know, there has been a request for the Federal Reserve to exercise prerogatives to take a seat on the banking international summits and I have always wondered whether or not that would constitute some sort of question on challenging the authority of the
President and the Constitution to carry on this mandate of being
the sole determiner of foreign affairs in the United States and to
carry out foreign policy or whether this would put the Federal Reserve at some point in time in some future Presidency potentially
in conflict with the domestic independence that they exercise.
And I understand, the decision on this has been run through the
highest level of the administration, I have read all of their letters,
some of the studies were forwarded to me by the Federal Reserve,
but in my own mind I am not yet satisfied that we are to maintain
the domestic independence of the Federal Reserve and the present
legislation and withhold the pressures within the Congress to examine that question, that it is a propitious time to exercise the taking of that seat unless we clearly define parameters in which that
seat would be exercised and operated by your membership on that
board.
And even though this administration has apparently no objection
to that, I am not sure this administration is viewing the long-term
constitutional ramifications to the Office of the President and his
effective carrying on of foreign policy for the United States and is
there a way that we can, as I asked you before, perhaps have the
time to have the best scholars in the country both from the constitutional standpoint and from an economic and international economic standpoint, help us out with this question.
In the past this issue has been brought up on two separate occasions, we took time to have very thorough studies by independent
determiners and in both instances the recommendation in the Congress was to hold off on the exercise of that right. I think now without the benefit of the study and without the support system, I
could see the pressures building in the Congress to look at the potentials of restructuring the structure of the Federal Reserve and
to interfere at some point in time with its independence in establishing domestic policy if it appears that there is a conflict in international monetary policy and domestic American policy.
What is your response?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, you are raising an issue which
is something we have all been considerably focused on. I might just
say that the reasons why we did not take up our seat earlier was
not, in my judgment, basically because of legal discussions that
went on in an earlier period, but it just struck us as not to be the
relevant time, although I was not involved, largely because it was
not clear that the relationships we have currently with the BIS and
have had for a very long period of time would oe particularly enhanced if we were involved in some of the management decisions
as to where the institution was going.
So I would say, first, that we did not perceive that there was any
real purpose in our getting involved at the management level
which is what being a member of the Board of Directors essentially




21

implies. That has changed, and the reason it has changed, and the
major issue that confronts, us is that as globalization of markets
moves apace, there are going to be a number of institutions which
are going to have a very important place in international finance.
The BIS, in my judgment, is going to be one of those major ones,
and, in my judgment, it is important for the United States to participate with our other colleagues in the institution to make certain
that where that institution is going at least coincides, as best we
can make it, with the interests of our country.
If we maintain the current position, which is essentially appearing at meetings periodically, we will not get the full benefits that
I perceive it is possible for the United States to have from being
on the board and having material impact.
I certainly don't deny that the issues you are raising concern
very profound constitutional questions and one of the reasons why
the very first thing that we did was to approach the Secretary of
the Treasury and the Secretary of State and get a judgment from
them on the legal, constitutional questions as they saw them, as
well as the other appropriate issues which are related to whether
or not we would gain benefits from being there.
As I indicated to you in a letter, Mr. Chairman, we are, of course,
already involved fairly heavily, that is the Federal Reserve, in a
number of other international financial institutions. I serve, for example, as the Alternate Governor in the International Monetary
Fund.
I and my colleagues spend a great deal of time in discussions
with a number of these international institutions and are heavily
involved with them. In all of that, however, we are acutely aware,
and we endeavor to make certain, that it is the decisions of the
President of the United States that ultimately prevail on issues of
international financial policy as it does on foreign policy.
We, as a consequence, have every intention of keeping the Secretary of the Treasury and the Secretary of State fully informed as
to what we are doing. And should they raise issues wnich we think
are relevant, it is important for us to make certain that we basically consult with them to make certain that whatever concerns
they may have are duly addressed.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Chairman, I appreciate the fact and
we are talking perhaps in the future and I appreciate the fact that
the United States should probably be represented on the bank
board, but I guess my problem is that I don't understand. And that
bank very easily may start to become a major international monetary policy bank.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would doubt that.
Chairman KANJORSKI. But it has the possibility. We, individually, have no control over what it may eventually evolve into.
Mr. GREENSPAN. My judgment is that that is not what it is structured for nor is it likely to emerge in that regard.
Chairman KANJORSKI. What will happen, Mr. Chairman, is as
you are exercising that seat as Chairman of the Federal Reserve,
if it has some conflict or effect on the domestic policy of the United
States, are you going to accept an order from the President of the
United States to restrict or change monetary policy on a domestic
level and interfere with the independence? That sets a precedence




22

to interfere with the independence if that order is issued with the
President carrying out the foreign policy of the United States.
Mr. GREENSPAN. First of all, it is an issue which I don't perceive
ever arising—the issue of monetary policy and independence,
which, of course, as you know, is that the decisions that we make
are not subject to question by the executive branch. Over the years,
and this goes back two or three generations, there has been an
awareness in the Federal Reserve of this whole question of our
international financial relationships.
I don't recall instances, although I suspect there may well be a
few, in which the issue of an independent monetary policy by the
central bank in this country has basically been undercut by the executive branch subsequent to the 1951 accord, in which, you may
recall, there was an agreement between the Treasury Department
and Federal Reserve to disengage from what really was mandated
support for certain Treasury securities issues.
We are sensitive to the questions and the concerns that you
raised and because we think that independence is such a crucial
question, I cannot imagine that we as an institution would allow
ourselves to be put in a position whereby the type of problem you
are concerned about would arise.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Rather than finding the support of discussion on the issue of some of the pending legislation that would restrict the nature and makeup of the Federal Reserve independent
banking institution, would you have any hesitancy in holding off a
final decision and in assuming that seat until this subcommittee is
able to have a roundtable hearing, perhaps even in camera, so that
we could have ultimate determination of what the scholars in constitutional law feel the ramifications of such a decision may be?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, I think that would create a problem for us because the process is very far advanced and the reason
we went to the State Department and indeed to the Foreign Relations Committees of both Houses very early on was to get precisely
this constitutional question addressed. I can conceive that there
will be those, as in all constitutional questions, who would find a
reason to suggest that this is inappropriate.
It is a very complex issue and it probably, Mr. Chairman, really
gets too far beyond the questions of the BIS. It really raises issues
of what our relationship is with the IMF and the World Bank and
a whole variety of other things.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Some of the pending legislation, Mr.
Chairman, would get into those issues and I am trying to avoid
Mr. GREENSPAN. All I can say to you, Mr. Chairman, is that it
is so crucial that we, as the most important central bank in the
world by size, in a very, very detailed manner integrate our views
and our actions with the international financial system because
that, in my judgment, very strongly serves the interests of this
country. Were we going to an isolationist mode, which would pull
us away from the extraordinary role that we have played since the
end of World War II, would be to America's disadvantage. If you
took this question very broadly about the constitutional issue, I am
not sure where it stops. I do think it probably means that the
central bank would have great difficulty dealing in the inter-




23

national financial sphere, and in my judgment that would probably
be most detrimental to our system.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I just think that the Representatives of
the United States of America should be responsive internationally
to the President of the United States and to his command in carrying out foreign policy, and I think if we interpose the independent
central bank of the United States in that role without fully examining what we are doing and understanding it, I think that delicate
balance could be set off and it could cause a great deal more pressure on the domestic policy to rein in the independence of the
Federal Reserve.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I must say I certainly hope not because if you
ask me academically whether or not I see some very major questions that relate to central bank involvement in these various different types of institutions, I would have to agree with you. In fact,
there is a question that comes up. I hope those issues have been
resolved as a practical matter because there are innumerable
things that institutions in this government with respect to which
the Constitution is too broad to specify what they should or should
not do, and we have considerable difficulty with that.
We have given a great deal of thought to this question. As I indicated earlier, it is one of the reasons why we approached the legal
advisor at the State Department very early on, to raise precisely
the questions that you are raising.
Chairman KANJORSKI. And I took that into consideration, but I
have also talked with a number of experts and officials who are
tangentially involved in the issue and they think that perhaps
there may be a very strong future constitutional question.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me say if there is an issue, Mr. Chairman,
it is such a broad issue that it goes way beyond the Bank for International Settlements, and it is a fundamental issue with respect to
an independent central bank in our society.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I agree with you, Mr. Chairman, but as
you know there is a great deal of legislation pending in the Congress to get into this whole thing. At this point, to defend the indeEendence of the Federal Reserve, we have not gone that distance
ut now this just may be the straw that requires that movement.
I would hope that we carry on some continued dialog on that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. By all means. This much broader question is
quite an important issue which I think all institutions in the American Government should be subject to.
Chairman KANJORSKI. My good friend from Utah, Mr. Orton.
Mr. ORTON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I do have one other brief
question which I will make sure that—I may have asked you previously; if so, I apologize and you can just tell me so.
But as most of us agree, the trade policy of this Nation and tax
policy do have an impact on monetary policy and vice versa as well
as economic growth. As we have examined tax policy around the
world, and see the United States being the only one of our major
trading partners that does not have a border adjustable type of tax,
like a value-added tax which is added on imports as they come into
the country and taken off exports as they go out, many have suggested that this is giving us an economic disadvantage in our own
and world trade markets and many, including the current chair-




24

man of Ways and Means, Mr. Gibbons, have recommended that we
adopt such a type of tax which could be border adjustable.
My question to you would be if the United States were to adopt
such a tax, do you believe that it would have any impact on monetary policy, positive, negative, or just tangential impact on economic growth and trade?
Is there any issue of monetary policy, anything that we in this
subcommittee should be concerned about or need to hear from you
with regard to that type of a tax system, assuming that it were not
just added to our current taxes so you are not taking more tax revenue out of the economy?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is a shift.
Mr. ORTON. If it were to replace a current type of tax so that the
same level of taxes were taken out of the economy but done so in
a different manner.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, I think that a value-added tax,
especially as a substitute for other taxes, has very profound implications with respect to savings and investment in the United
States and to the extent that that impacts on our underlying economy, the central bank has to address that. It is hard for me to tell
you in advance precisely how it would impact but there is nothing
in the procedure that you are discussing which in any way creates
a problem for us and there is no reason why we will not be able
to adjust accordingly if it is required. So how you pursue the discussions with respect to this question shouldn't need to be concerned with whether we would be able to appropriately adjust. I
see no reason why we should not be.
Mr. ORTON [presiding]. OK Thank you. Since the chairman is
currently tied up, I will turn to Mr. Neal.
Mr. NEAL. Thank you, sir. Mr. Chairman.
I would like to thank you again for your continuing good job
keeping an eye on inflation and keeping it as low as possible. I go
out of my way to say that every time I can because I think usually
you get criticism when you have to raise short-term rates to try to
look out for the longer term well-being of our economy. And I just
want you to know that I appreciate it and think that most people
do appreciate it. Most people do understand that the fight against
inflation is clearly the most important endeavor that you can engage in and you all have done a good iob with it in recent years.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me just say thank you.
Mr. NEAL. Well, thank you.
In that regard, I read some conflicting stories about your comments the other day concerning the use of monetary policy for purposes of possibly changing the dollar-yen relationship in particular
but essentially changing the value of the dollar.
As I understand it, the real problem is not a dollar problem, but
it is a yen problem. The dollar has maintained its fairly consistent
relationship with most of the currencies of the world. I understand
there has been a little change relative due to the German currency,
but other than that, the major change has taken place in the relationship between the dollar and the yen, and it seems to me that
that is primarily a yen problem. The Japanese are running a large
surplus with the rest of the world, and this is sort of the way the
world adjusts to that situation, by changing the value of their cur-




25

rency which will ultimately change the value of their trade
relationship.
And isn't it true that just as we wouldn't want to use monetary
policy to temporarily boost employment because we know that the
costs would be great to employment later on, we wouldn't want to
use monetary policy to manipulate the value of the currency? Is
that correct or not? I am really trying to understand that.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would say, Congressman, as I have testified
before this subcommittee on several occasions, that the value of the
dollar is one of the elements which we think are important in making judgments of what our domestic monetary policy should be. It
is very difficult to imagine a case where it would be the sole consideration. That would be an extreme which I find utterly unlikely,
but nonetheless it is a factor which we consider, and there are a
number of other factors which are involved in policy. We try to balance them and try to make judgments because we have only one
monetary policy. We only have a single activity which we can implement that largely in today's current context is the Federal funds
rate—in an earlier context it was the net borrowed reserves. But
the point of issue is that at any particular time there is only one
policy and there are innumerable things which are involved in
making a judgment as to how we calibrate that and the exchange
rate is clearly one of them.
I don't want to comment on the specifics of individual currencies,
but we endeavor to make judgments as to, when currencies move,
whether it is the dollar that is relevant or whether it is the other
currency. Obviously, it is a bilateral relationship and there are occasions when it is one and there are occasions when it is the other
and there are occasions when it is both.
Mr. NEAL. Let me ask a related question. I notice that you have
a brief discussion in your remarks of leading economic indicators
that you use to try to set the proper monetary policy or properly
control inflation. It often occurred to me—and again I am not a
technician in this area but an interested observer—that long-term
interest rates might be the very best indication of future inflation
because they reflect not only the current monetary policy but essentially a huge pool involving all the investors of the world which
then reflects inflationary expectations.
Now, as I understand it, the reason you couldn't use that as a
sole tool—I don't know if you want to or not—I would be interested
to know. I wish you would comment on that. It would be one of the
best indicators, but even if you did, you probably couldn't use it as
the sole tool because it would be hard to separate out real inflation
from inflationary expectations. And in that regard, I know that you
have commented before that you thought it might be a good idea
for us to be able to issue inflation indexed bonds which would give
us a more clear measure of that.
You know, Congressman Doug Barnard had introduced a bill to
encourage the issuance of inflation indexed bonds and I have introduced that bill again. Would you like to comment on that and tell
us if you think the passage of that would be useful to you and how?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Unquestionably, Congressman. The advantages
of having indexed bonds, especially if we have them across a spectrum of maturities, is it would give us and other members of the




26

economic policy fraternity in this government a reasonably good
sense of judgment as to what the inflationary expectations are at
various different maturity levels.
I think you are correct in distinguishing between actual inflation
and inflationary expectations. Inflationary expectations sometimes
are a good indicator of what actually materializes; sometimes they
are not.
Nonetheless, the very expectations themselves are a very crucial
variable in the way the economy functions. That is, even if inflation
expectations are wrong, their impact on the structure of the way
the economy goes is impervious. As to whether or not they are
right or wrong, the effect is 'there, and as a consequence we have
to focus on those variables to know what it is the markets are effectively assuming.
The basic question for the Treasury Department in considering
this is whether or not this can be done without any cost to the taxpayer, and there are those who argue that pension funds would be
very big buyers of these types of instruments. You might have a
larger market for your securities by disaggregating them into certain pieces where certain individual purchasers would find a use
for these indexed bonds.
There is another question as to whether in fact the volumes can
be large enough so that the bid-asked spread is the same as it is
in all of the nonindexed bonds, because if you have a larger spread,
even one basis point, it does have an effect on the economy, it does
have an effect on the cost to the taxpayers. So these are a lot of
judgments that have to be made, but from the point of view of economic policymaking and international monetary policymaking,
there is no question that such indexed bonds would make an important contribution to the policy deliberative process.
Mr. NEAL. Sounds like we should have some hearings on this and
look into the costs and benefits.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I think that would be useful.
Mr. NEAL. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. The gentleman from Ohio, Mr. Fingerhut.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you, Chairman Greenspan. You have
been very accommodating. I will be very brief, but Mr. Neal actually brought us to the only question that I had restrained myself
from in my first round and that was this very question of inflation
expectation versus inflation.
Mr. Klein previously stated, I think, what is a common view in
the public of a sense of frustration that just as the economy starts
to seemingly respond at a more rapid pace providing better opportunities for our people, all of a sudden we feel like we are restraining it. And I join Mr. Neal in applauding your diligence and believing that the fight against inflation is critically important for longterm prosperity, and I hope my comments to you are reflective of
that, but it is frustrating and indeed difficult to explain why we
must fight not only inflation, that I can explain to people, but why
we must fight expectations on the part of investors who are often
moved by real factors in the marketplace but are occasionally
moved by rumors and other factors.
I noted yesterday the dollar moved on the rumor the troops had
crossed the line between North and South Korea and after that




27

was not confirmed, that people backed off. I remember being on the
floor of the House one day knowing that the stock market was moving on rumors of assassination attempts which, of course, proved
to be untrue.
Is there not a role for the Federal Reserve to play in addressing
those expectations on the basis of your actual knowledge of whether those expectations are accurate or not?
In reading your testimony, both the portions you delivered and
the portions you didn't, you clearly—in the entire Federal Reserve
System clearly there is no stone unturned in trying to find out
whether or not inflation is a problem in our economy, the beige
book, all of the comparisons and detailed analyses of various
industries.
If you find that the exceptions don't correlate to your detailed investigation, is there not a role to play in saying that we believe
those expectations are wrong so that perhaps we can turn down
that premium without having to address it with higher interest
rates?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Let me just say that while I would argue that
inflation expectations are not a perfect forecaster of inflation, they
are really quite good; that is, they do pick up a reasonable proportion of the variance that we have in such situations with actual inflation so that it is not as though it is a wholly random and meaningless set of numbers. It is largely the consequence of a very fair
confluence of sophisticated views in the marketplace as to what is
going on.
Some of the views are a little bit flaky. Some of them are really
sort of dubious and even manipulative, maybe, but overall the system works remarkably well. It is a really impressive sight to see
how this very complex financial system which we have in the United States functions and in my judgment creates a significant
amount of real wealth for the average American. It is not just an
abstraction.
The problem that we would have if we were to comment on rumors—and I grant you some of the rumors we know are true or
false, indeed a lot of the rumors are about what we are doing—is
that if you comment on some but not on all, you run into the problem: The Fed is not denying X, therefore it is confirmation. Or if
one looks at the particular selection of the types of rumors that we
try to get straight, it won't take the markets very long to figure out
which ones we are avoiding and that will just merely cumulate the
problem. So I can't see any real solution to this.
I am going to agree with you that there are a lot of judgments
and actions that go on in the marketplace which are noises instead
of decisions and there is no systematic basic reason for them. But
I would say when you cut through all of that, it works pretty well,
and it is working increasingly well as the years go on and the techniques improve and communications and telecommunication complexes emerge on the scene.
We have a far more efficient financial system than we did 10
years ago, 20, 30 years ago. And it is very complex and it lends itself, as indeed any complex system does, to problems at the
margin.




28

I don't deny that there are problems, and, indeed, one of the reasons why we sometimes choose to intervene in the international financial markets is our judgment that some of the decisions that
are being made by people are inappropriate to the real world and
are having an effect which we think we can alter not by commenting but by action. And indeed that is one of the ways in which I
would explain why it is we intervene.
Mr. FlNGERHUT. Thank you. That is helpful. I think that my
point is not that I would desire you to monitor the rumor mills in
the markets and respond but rather to—and I think you do this
quite frequently, but occasionally these testimonies give us a
chance to say it again—to make clear that the Federal Reserve responds to those policies that they believe to be actually in fact occurring. Even if you believe the expectations are reasonable expectations, that is obviously a policy that needs to be responded or expectation that needs to be responded to as opposed to simply the
perception that investors may—that we would be trying to confirm
investors' expectations even if they have made a false judgment,
and I think that is an important statement for the American people
to have confidence to know that we are responding to actual policy.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Fingerhut.
Mr. Chairman, I just have one little question for you. I know that
you are working very closely with the Secretary of Treasury on the
introducing of the new $100 bills or currency to prevent counterfeiting, and I am just wondering whether or not we are going to
have some sort of forced redemption period where that money
would be introduced and to disqualify anyone keeping a horde of
money beyond a certain period of time, maybe with an exception
for widows finding $10,000 under the mattress, but other than that
if we had a short redemption period of necessity for disclosure and
cashing in for those funds, would that not serve as a major blow
to organized and drug cartels and terrorist groups that are stashing away a large amount of cash?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Chairman, I wouldn't suspect that wouldn't
have an effect on law enforcement. We have never in this country
disavowed any of the Federal Government's obligations. Indeed, it
is a fascinating thing to take a look at the statement of public debt.
Still outstanding are a lot of 50 cent pieces from the Civil War
which obviously are destroyed, a lot of gold certificates which are
destroyed, but they are still an official obligation of the United
States. The reason that choice was made is that there is a sense
in which the American people have a certain relationship to their
currency which I find extraordinary in the sense that if you try to
change it, if you alter it in a way which makes them feel uncomfortable, the response is really quite surprising.
There is something very important about a government claim,
and in my judgment, despite the fact that I don't deny that there
are fairly significant crime prevention advantages in trying to do
a number of these things, I think it is far more important that we
continue this policy, which goes back to the beginning of our Nation, of honoring all of our liabilities.
Alexander Hamilton made some very important choices very
early on in our country and that has essentially driven the Treas-




29

ury Department ever since. To my knowledge there is no interest
at this stage in trying to have a moratorium or I should say limit
the legal tender nature of some of the claims that are existing.
It is an interesting issue and you may want to talk to the Secretary of the Treasury on that, but it is one that we have periodically come to grips with, and I personally am fascinated with how
important the integrity of the currency is to American people.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I appreciate that, but I just thought this
was a great way to get the green market in this country, certainly
for the stashes of criminal activity as well, and at least giving the
Congress the opportunity of discussing with the Fed and Treasury
as to whether there should be a disclosure form with the capacity
of tracing where these large portions of money come from for further prosecution.
I am struck with the romance that we have with the currency
but presently pending on the floor, the FBI is attempting to have
us allow for telephonic communications to be tapped so the privacy
sometimes of Americans aren't necessarily thought of being as protected by this government as our currency is. That is interesting.
Mr. GREENSPAN. As best we can judge, more than half of our currency is abroad. That is an extraordinary phenomenon.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Chairman, we in our earlier discussion I sort of guaranteed I would try to get you out by noon. We
have other questions from Mr. Ridge, our ranking member of the
subcommittee and others. I would ask unanimous consent that they
have 2 weeks to submit in writing questions and if you would be
courteous enough to respond to that, we would appreciate it.
Are there other members of the subcommittee that would have
questions?
Mr. NEAL. Do you have time for another question, Mr.
Greenspan?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I will speak fast.
Mr. NEAL. If you do, let me ask you again on this question of
leading indicators. It just seems to me that the comments that people make about monetary policy that are critical lately have fallen
into two broad categories. One is that they say you are acting prematurely, that they can't see any inflation on the horizon and they
don't see how you can, and therefore it is totally unjustified to raise
short rates. And the other one has to do with this relationship between employment and inflation. People often say they think that
we would—that you are threatening employment when you fight
inflation.
Now, I think the evidence is pretty clear on the second point,
both in our country down throughout history and other countries
down throughout history, that employment is enhanced when we
keep inflation under control and that means sometimes taking
some unpopular actions to keep it under control, but the way to enhance employment is to keep inflation low and I think every opportunity I have to make that point I try to make it and you ought
to make it.
And it is fascinating just as an aside on this, a very fascinating
experience that occurred in another country, most fascinating because it appeared under a labor government and we often think of
labor governments being for inflation. I am thinking here of New




30

Zealand where over the last several years New Zealand's economy
was out of control. Huge deficits, runaway inflation, high unemployment, and so on. A labor government took the tough steps that
were necessary to get their economy back under control. Now they
have inflation under 2 percent, they have economic growth 6 or 7
percent, employment is rising, they still have some unemployment.
But they are moving in the right direction.
And then this other point on leading indicators, if you—I just
think if you said more about it, that it would help. It would just
help maintain support for the anti-inflation policy. I wonder if you
would just take a minute to comment on that. Aren't long-term interest rates one of the better leading indicators of future inflation?
Mr. GREENSPAN. To the extent, Congressman, that we can infer
the inflation expectation part of those long-term rate changes, then
I think it is very helpful and one of the things that we try to do
is differentiate between the real rate of increase in long-term bonds
and that component which represents changes in inflation expectations.
Mr. NEAL. I understand that is difficult. I think that was what
Mr. Fingerhut was trying to get at here. If you could separate
those out and then, of course, the way you said that, we can separate that out is to issue inflation index bonds, which we can talk
about in more detail later and we will have a hearing on that. But
that is a good indicator.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, sir.
Mr. NEAL. Do you have any hesitancy? Let me try to get at this
in another way. Is there some hesitancy about a full discussion
about what you use as leading indicators? Is there
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, the only hesitancy is that it varies from
time to time and there is a whole array of things that we look at,
depending on what we judge to be the important forces which are
driving the economy at any particular point in time. And while we
have an elaborate set of econometric models, they are actually too
simplistic no matter how complex they are because they basically
are fitted to a extended past period of time to get relationships, and
it is very questionable about whether the economy's structure stays
the same during that period.
There is no alternative to having a conceptual model of what we
think is driving the economy. And that would include all the indicators with respect to inflation expectation as well as a variety of
other elements. For example, back in the late 1980's, early 1990's,
when we were dealing with the credit crunch, it became very clear
to us that balance sheet strain was a very important element in
how the overall economy was going to behave. That is a very rare
event. Much of the time balance sheet strain doesn't exist, but for
a period of time it was the most effective element in a model which
guided us where we ought to be and we keep changing those roads
and there is really no alternative to making a forecast and trying
to understand the relationships as best we can.
And we have numbers of indicators. Some of them work well,
some of them work not so well. I don't know if it was Mr.
Fingerhut who raised the question of whether or not central banking is a science. The answer is it is not.




31

Mr. NEAL. So what you are saying is there are new elements that
impact on the economy that are impacting in a stronger way than
they have earlier. Today that might be the falling value of the yen,
for example, something that wasn't a problem several years ago.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I have been reluctant to be very detailed about
specific frameworks that we use because it creates problems for us
in implementing policy. But if we sense that there are forces which
are moving the economy one way or another, we try to understand
them as best we can. And one thing we know is that the presumption that somehow we can implement monetary policy without
making judgments about the future is false.
Mr. NEAL. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Does the gentleman from North Carolina
have any further questions?
Mr. NEAL. Well, not that I can't postpone.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I am going to prevail, if I can, on the more
junior members of the subcommittee. We made Mr. Greenspan a
promise and we haven't kept it by just a few minutes, but we
thank you very much for your indulgence, Mr. Chairman. We look
forward to our next meeting and we hope we can carry on the dialog we had a little earlier to see if we can we resolve some of those
questions.
Thank you.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
[Whereupon, at 12:07 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]










33

APPENDIX

July 22, 1994

34

Testimony by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Credit Formation




of the

Committee on Banking. Finance and Urban Affairs
U.S. House of Representatives
July 22. 1994

35
Mr. Chairman and members of the Subcommittee, I appreciate
this opportunity to discuss with you recent economic developments and
the Federal Reserve's conduct of monetary policy.
The favorable performance of the economy continued in the
first half of 1994.

Economic growth was strong, unemployment fell

appreciably, and inflation remained subdued.

To sustain the

expansion, the Federal Reserve adjusted monetary policy over recent
months so as to contain potential inflation

pressures.

Our actions this year can be understood by reference to
policy over the previous several years.

Through that period, the

Federal Reserve moved toward and then maintained for a considerable
time a purposefully accommodative stance of policy.

During 1993, that

stance was associated with low levels of real short-term interest
rates-- around zero.

We judged that low interes* rates would be

necessary for a time to overcome the effects of a number of factors
that were restraining the economic expansion, including heavy debt
burdens of households and businesses and tighter credit policies of
many lenders.

By early this year, however, it became clear that many

of these impediments had diminished and that the economy had
consequently gained considerable momentum.

In these circumstances, it

was no longer appropriate to maintain an accommodative policy.
Indeed, history strongly suggests that maintenance of real short-term
rates at levels prevailing last year ultimately would have fueled
inflationary pressures.
Accordingly, the Federal Open Market Committee at its meetingin early February decided to move away from its accommodative posture
by tightening reserve market conditions.

Given the level of real

short-term rates and the evident momentum in the economy, it seemed
likely that a substantial cumulative adjustment of policy would be




36

needed.

However, Committee members recognized that financial markets

were not fully prepared for this action.

About five years had passed

since the previous episode of monetary firming, and a number of market
participants in designing their investment strategies seemed to give
little weight to the possibility that interest rates would rise;
instead, many apparently extrapolated the then-recent, but highly
unusual, extended period of low short-term interest rates, fairly
steady capital gains on long-term investments, and relatively
conditions in financial markets.

stable

Many Committee members were

concerned that a marked shift in the stance of policy, while
necessary, could precipitate an exaggerated reaction in financial
markets.
With this in mind, we initially tightened reserve conditions
only slightly--just enough to raise the federal funds rat-- 1/4
percentage point.

And the financial markets did indeed react sharply,

with substantial increases in longer-term interest rates and declines
in stock prices.

Markets remained unsettled for several months, and

we continued to move cautiously in March and April in the process of
moving away from our accommodative stance.

By mid-May, however, a

considerable portion of the adjustment in portfolios to the new rate
environment appeared to have taken place.

With financial

markets

evidently better prepared to absorb a larger move, the Federal Reserve
could substantially

complete the removal of the degree of monetary

accommodation that prevailed throughout

1993.

The Board raised the

discount rate 1/2 percentage point, a move that was fully passed
through to reserve market conditions by the FOMC.

Overall, the

federal funds rate increased 1-1/4 percentage points during the first
half of the year, and real short-term rates likely rose a similar
amount.

Partly to minimize any market confusion about the extent of




37

and rationale for our moves, the Federal Reserve has announced each
action and. in relevant instances, provided an explanation.

At its

meeting in early July, the FOMC faced considerable uncertainty about
the pace of expansion and pressures on prices going forward, and it
made no further adjustment in its policy stance.
Nonetheless, it is an open question whether our actions to
date have been sufficient to head off inflationary pressures and thus
maintain favorable trends in the economy.

Labor demand has been quite

strong, pointing to robust growth in production and incomes.

To be

sure, some hints of moderation in the growth of domestic final demand
have appeared, and the recent indications of accelerating'inventory
accumulation may suggest an unwanted backing up of stocks.
Conversely, the inventory accumulation may reflect pressures on firms
who had brought inventories down to suboptimal levels and now need ^o
replenish them.

In the latter case, stock-building may continue at an

above-normal rate, supporting production for quite some time.
Moreover, the improving economic conditions of our trading partners
should add impetus to aggregate demand from the external sector.
How these forces balance out in the coming months could be
critical in determining whether inflation will remain in check, for
the amount of slack in the economy, while difficult to judge, appears
to have become relatively small.

Concerns that productive capacity

could come under pressure and prices accelerate are already evident in
commodity and financial markets, including the foreign exchange
market.

An increase of inflation would come at considerable cost:

Wf

would lose hard-won ground in the fight against inflation
expectations--ground that would be difficult to recapture later; our
long-run economic performance would be impaired by the inefficiencies
associated with higher inflation if it persisted; and harsher policy




38

actions would eventually be necessary to reverse the upsurge in
inflationary instabilities.

We are determined to prevent such an

outcome, and currently are monitoring economic and financial data
carefully to assess whether additional adjustments are appropriate.
The economic figures that have formed the backdrop for our
policy actions so far this year confirm that a rapid expansion has
been in progress.

Following growth at an annual rate of 7 percent in

the fourth quarter of last year, real gross domestic product rose at
nearly a 3-1/2 percent rate in the first quarter.

A conceptually

equivalent measure of aggregate output, gross domestic income,
exhibited even larger gains in the fourth and first quarters.

At this

stage, available data leave some uncertainty regarding the pace of
economic activity over the past three months.

Nonetheless, the

evidence in hand makes it reasonably clear that growth remained
appreciably above its longer-run trend.

The robust expansion over the

first half of 1994 has been reflected in substantial increases in
employment.

Since last December, nonfarm payrolls have risen by 1-3/4

million workers, bringing the gain in jobs since the expansion got
underway to 5 million.

Reflecting this hiring, the civilian

unemployment rate has fallen to 6 percent.
Although labor markets have tightened considerably in recent
months, aggregate measures of wage and compensation rates have not yet
evidenced persuasive signs of acceleration.

Similarly, the increases

in the consumer price index excluding food and energy, at about a 3
percent rate over the last six months, have remained near last year's
pace, while the overall CPI has risen at a reduced rate of about 2-1/2
percent.

To be sure, price pressures have been manifest at earlier

stages of processing:

Costs of many commodities and materials have

been climbing, in some cases reflecting the tightening of industrial




39

capacity utilization, which is now at its highest level in five years.
But these pressures have been offset by favorable trends in unit labor
costs resulting from marked improvements in productivity--especially
in manufacturing--in recent years.
The accumulating evidence of stronger-than-expected economic
growth here and abroad, combined with changing expectations of policy
actions by the Federal Reserve as well as other central banks,
prompted considerable increases in long-term interest rates in
occasionally volatile markets over the first half of the year.

Market

participants concluded that, with aggregate demand stronger, higher
real rates would be necessary to hold growth to a sustainable pace.
Inflation expectations may also have been revised higher, as the
performance of the economy seemed to make further near-term progress
against inflation less likely and raised questions about whether price
pressures might intensify.
To a degree, the very volatility of markets probably
augmented the backup in long-term interest rates.

One of the effects

of the extended market rallies of recent years was to promote a rather
complacent view among investors about the risks of holding long-term
assets.

In response, they gradually increased the proportions of

their portfolios devoted to stocks and bonds, driving up their prices
still further and narrowing risk spreads.

But when developments

earlier this year surprised investors and diminished their confidence
in predicting future market conditions, they pulled back from long
positions in securities until returns rose to compensate them for the
additional price risk.
The recent weakness in bond prices was not limited to the
United States, but was accompanied by a surge in foreign interest
rates.

This surge was particularly informative; ordinarily one would




40

expect that as interest rates go up in one country, they would not
increase to the same extent in others because exchange rates also
would be expected to adjust.

The initial jump in foreign interest

rates was a sign of the extraordinary increase in uncertainty as,
evidently, investors attempted to reduce their price-sensitive long
positions by selling stocks and bonds regardless of currency
denomination or economic conditions in the country of issuance.
Roughly concurrently, moreover, signs that the slump in some foreign
industrial economies was ending also were becoming apparent.

As a

result, market participants anticipated stronger credit demands abroad
and a reduced likelihood of further easing by some foreign central
banks, and intermediate- and longer-term rates in many of our trading
partners rose as much as or more than in the United States.
Rising foreign interest rates, concerns in markets about the
prospects for reduced trade tensions and clbout U.S. inflation
contributed to considerable activity directed at rebalancing
international investment portfolios.

One effect of this activity

appears to have been a substantial decline of the foreign exchange
value of the dollar on net over the past six months.

Foreign exchange

rates are key prices in the American economy, with significant
implications for the volumes of exports and imports as well as for the
prices of imports and domestically produced items that compete with
imports.

The foreign exchange value of the dollar also can provide

useful insights into inflation expectations.

If we conduct an

appropriate monetary policy--and appropriate economic policies more
generally--we shall achieve our goals of solid economic growth and
price stability, and such economic results will ensure that dollardenominated assets remain attractive to global investors, which is




41

essential to the dollar's continuing role as the world's principal
reserve currency.
Rising interest rates and considerable volatility in
financial markets do not seem to have slowed overall credit flows this
year.

At about a 5-1/4 percent annual rate through May. domestic

nonfinancial sector debt has increased within its 4-to-8 percent
monitoring range.

The composition of debt growth, however, has

differed from the patterns of the previous few years.

Expansion of

federal debt has slowed as the actions of the Congress and the
Administration as well as cyclical forces have narrowed the budget
deficit considerably.

The total debt of businesses, households, and

state and local governments, by contrast, has risen this year at a
brisker pace, though growth has remained quite moderate in comparison
with the average experience of recent decades.

The pickup this year

indicates both that private borrowers have become less cautious about
taking on debt and that lenders have become more comfortable lending
to them.

Although household debt-income ratios remain high, debt-

service burdens have fallen appreciably, partly reflecting the
refinancing of mortgages at lower interest rates.

The lower debt

burdens evidently have fostered a more favorable attitude toward
credit among households, and consumer installment borrowing has
accelerated, with strong growth of consumer loans at banks.

Banks

have been increasingly willing to extend credit, easing their terms
and standards on business loans considerably.

In addition, some firms

have turned to banks for financing because of the turbulence in bond
and stock markets this spring.

Total bank lending has

materially and. with continued acquisitions
credit has picked up as well.




strengthened

of securities, total bank

Nonetheless, growth of the monetary

42

aggregates remains damped, as banks have relied heavily on non-deposit
sources of funds to finance loan growth.
Expansion of M2 has been quite slow this year, leaving this
aggregate near the lower end of its l-to-5 percent annual range.

M3

actually has edged down, and thus is just below its O-to-4 percent
range for 1994.

The weakness in the broader aggregates has not been

reflected in the growth of income again this year, representing a
continuation of the substantial increases in velocity that we have
experienced over the past few years.

The factors behind this

behavior, however, have changed somewhat-.

The diversion of savings

funds from deposits to bond and stock mutual funds, which sharply
depressed money growth in past years, seems to have slowed
substantially; the experience with capital losses this spring
apparently has heightened some investors' appreciation of the risks of
such instruments.

On the other hand, rising short-term market

interest rates, combined with the usual lag in the adjustment

of

deposit rates, have been a significant restraint on growth of the
aggregates this year, in contrast to 1992 and 1993.
The increases in market rates this year have exerted a
particular drag on the narrower monetary aggregates, as well as on the
closely related reserves and monetary base measures.

Ml has expanded

at only a 4 percent rate so far this year, compared with 10-1/2
percent increases in each of the previous two years.

Mi's velocity

has continued to fluctuate sharply, limiting its usefulness in
formulating and interpreting monetary policy.

The growth of Ml this

year wovld have been even lower were it not for continued heavy
demands for U.S. currency abroad.

Flows of currency overseas have an

even greater effect proportionately on the monetary base, which




43

has growth rapidly this year despite declines in the reserves of
depository institutions.
In reviewing its ranges for money growth in 1994, the FOMC
noted that further increases in velocity of M2 and M3 were likely.
Although yields on deposits will probably continue to rise further in
lagged response to increases in market rates, the wider rate
disadvantage of deposits is likely to persist, and savers will
continue to redirect flows into market instruments.

As a result,

growth of both aggregates near the lower bounds of their 1994 ranges
is considered to be consistent with achieving our objectives for
economic performance, and the ranges were left unchanged.
The Committee also decided on a provisional basis to carry
forward the current ranges for the monetary aggregates to 1995.

We

were not Confident that we could predict with sufficient accuracy the
money-income relationships that were likely to prevail next year to
modify the ranges.

Moreover, further permanent reductions of the

monetary ranges did not seem necessary, as those ranges are already
low enough to be consistent with the goal of price stability and
maximum sustainable economic growth, assuming an eventual return to
more stable velocity behavior.

From that point of view, we felt that

maintenance of the current monetary ranges would give the clearest
indication of the long-run intentions of policy.
Regarding domestic nonfinancial sector debt, we made no
adjustment to this year's monitoring range, but elected to set a
provisional monitoring range for 1995 of 3 to 7 percent, a percentage
point lower than this year's.

A lower range would conform with some

deceleration in nominal income, in the process of containing inflation
and ultimately making progress toward price stability.

The reduction

is not intended to signal an increased emphasis on the debt measure.




44

but it is supported by our view that rapid debt growth, if sustained,
can eventually lead to significant imbalances that are inimical to
stable, noninflationary growth.

As usual, we shall review carefully

all of the provisional ranges for 1995 in February.
Given the rapid pace of financial change, considerable
uncertainties continue to attend the relationships of all of the
aggregates to the performance of the economy and inflation, and we do
not expect in the near term to increase the weight accorded in policy
formulation to these measures.

However, the processes of portfolio

reallocation that have generated these recent shifts may be slowing.
We shall continue to monitor monetary growth, and financial flows more
generally, for information about the course of the economy and prices
in coming to decisions regarding adjustments to the stance of monetary
policy.
We expect that expansion of money and credit within the
ranges we have established will be consistent with continuation of
good economic performance.

With appropriate monetary policies, the

Board members and Reserve Bank Presidents see the economy settling
into more moderate rates of growth over the next six quarters and
inflation remaining relatively subdued.

Specifically, the central

tendencies of our forecasts are for real GDP to expand 3 to 3-1/4
percent over 1994 and 2-1/2 to 2-3/4 percent next year.

The consumer

price index is projected to increase 2-3/4 to 3 percent this year.

In

1995, inflation may be about the same as in 1994 or slightly higher;
the recent depreciation in the dollar is likely to put upward pressure
on inflation over the next year if it is not reversed.

With the pace

of hiring likely to about match that of labor force growth, the
unemployment rate is expected to remain close to its recent level.




45

In view of rapid economic growth recently and narrowing
margins of slack in productive capacity, there has been considerable
interest of late in the Federal Reserve's ideas about the long-run
trends in output and employment consistent with avoiding pressures on
prices.

My colleagues and I don't think that numerical estimates of

these trends by the T?OMC would be useful in helping the Congress and
the public gauge our policy strategy.

We believe, instead, that our

intentions are best conveyed in terms of our declared objective of
fostering as much growth of output and employment as can be achieved
without placing destabilizing inflationary pressures on productive
resources.

There is considerable uncertainty about what that goal

implies for the expansion of GDP and rates of unemployment.
That said, it may be useful to note that the assumptions
underlying the medium-term projections by the Administration and the
Congressional Budg-et Office (CBO) are within the mainstream of
thinking among academics and private business economists.

These

projections do not attempt to anticipate cyclical movements, but
instead represent estimates of the likely performance of the economy
in the neighborhood of its potential.

The Administration, for

example, projected in its most recent forecast that the economy will
expand at a 2.5 percent rate in the second half of the 1990s and
unemployment will average 6.1 percent.

These projections are

consistent with common estimates of the economy's potential growth
rate and fall within the range of typical estimates of the so-called
"natural rate" of unemployment.
Uncertainties around these estimates arise because
identifying economic relationships is always difficult, partly owing
to limitations of the data.

But more fundamentally, all policymakers

recognize that notions of potential GDP growth and the natural rate of




46

unemployment are considerable simplifications, useful in conceptual
models but subject to a variety of real-world complications.

Our

economy is a complex, dynamic system, comprising countless and diverse
households, firms, services, products, and prices, interacting in a
multitude of markets.

Estimates of macroeconomic relationships, as

best we can make them, are useful starting points for analysis--but
they are just starting points.
Given questions about the aggregate relationships,
policymakers need to look below the surface, in markets themselves,
for evidence of tightness that might indicate whether inflationary
pressures are indeed building.

One important source of such evidence

is the reports we receive from our Reserve Banks through their
extensive contacts in their communities.

These reports are released

to the public in the "beige book" and are updated--frequently on the
basis of confidential information from individual firms and financial
institutions--by the Reserve Bank officials at our meetings and
through normal intermeeting communications.

Another source of useful

information is individual industries and trade groups, which provide
many timely indicators that are sensitive to supply-demand conditions
in particular sectors.
If the economy were nearing capacity, we would expect to see
certain patterns in the statistical and anecdotal information with
increasing frequency and intensity.

Reports of shortages of skilled

labor, strikes, and instances of difficulties in finding workers in
specific regions all would be more likely.

To attract additional

workers, employers would presumably step up their use of want-ads and
might begin to use nonstandard techniques, such as signing or
recruiting bonuses.

More firms might choose to bring on less skilled

workers and train them on the job.




All of these steps in themselves

47

could add to costs and suggest developing inflationary imbalances.
firms experienced difficulty

As

in expanding production to meet rising

demand, we would also expect to see increasingly frequent signs of
shortages of goods as well as labor.
in obtaining certain materials.

Businesses might have difficulty

Vendor performance would deteriorate,

and lead times on deliveries of new orders would increase.

Pressures

on supplies of materials and commodities would be reflected in rising
prices of these items.
Of course, we would not expect to see these phenomena occur
simultaneously throughout the economy-- quite the contrary.

And, to a

degree, these symptoms occur in a few sectors even in noninflationary
economies.

But a noticeable step-up' :?.n their incidence could

constitute evidence of an incipient inflationary process.
In recent months, we have

-T> some of "hese signs.

There

are reports of shortages of some typs.- of labor--construction workers
and truck drivers, for instance.

Indexes of vendor performance have

deteriorated considerably, and mnv*icturers are paying higher prices
for materials used in their produ-_r...o!i processes.

As yet, these sorts

of indications do not seem to be widespread across the economy.
Nonetheless, we shall need to be particularly alert to these emerging
signs in considering further adjustments to policy in the period
ahead.
Financial flows may also impart useful warnings of price
pressures.

For example, persistent unsustainably

low real interest

rates might prompt very rapid credit growth, as expectations of price
increases led households and firms to accelerate purchases of durable
goods and equipment and finance these expenditures by stepping up the
pace of borrowing.




Although consumer borrowing has accelerated

48

considerably of late, overall debt growth has so far remained
moderate.
In light of the uncertainties about aggregate measures of our
economic potential, the Federal Reserve cannot rely heavily on any one
estimate of either the natural rate of unemployment or potential GDP
growth.

Most important, we have no intention of setting artificial

limits on employment or growth.

Indeed, the Federal Reserve would be

pleased to see more rapid output growth and lower unemployment than
projected by forecasters such as the CBO and the Administration-provided they were sustainable and consistent with approaching price
stability.

I should note, however, that most Federal Reserve

policymakers would not regard the inflation projections of these other
forecasters, which generally do not foresee further progress toward
price stability over the medium term, as a desirable outcome.
A more significant issue for economic policymakers than the
precise values of such estimates is what can be done to maximize
sustainable employment and economic growth.

We n^ed, for example, to

give careful attention to the problem of unemployment,
G-7 leaders at their recent summit.

r noted by the

We could raise output and living

standards around the world and at the same time ease many social
problems if more people were working.
million Americans are looking for work.

Here at home, nearly eight
At this stage of the business

cycle--having experienced almost forty months of expansion and
particularly strong growth recently--most of this unemployment
probably is not due to a shortfall in aggregate demand.

Rather, a

good deal of it is likely "frictional." reflecting the ordinary
process of workers moving between jobs, or "structural," resulting
from longer-term mismatches between workers and available jobs.
Monetary policy, which works mainly by influencing aggregate demand,




49

is not suited to addressing such problems.

But we ought to be

encouraging other measures to increase the flexibility of our
workforce and labor markets.

Improving education and training and

facilitating better and more rapid matching of workers with jobs are
essential elements in making more effective use of the U.S. labor
force.

Just as important. Congress should avoid enacting policies

that create impediments to the efficient movement of individuals
across regions, industries, and occupations, or that unduly discourage
the hiring of those seeking work.

Competitive markets have shown a

remarkable ability to create rising standards of living when left free
to function.
Congress and the Administration also can continue to
contribute to the growth of our economy's capital and productivity
through a sound fiscal policy.

The extension of the spending caps .'n

last year's budget agreement was a significant step in putting fiscal
policy on a more sustainable long-run path.

Budget deficit reduction

has proved to be particularly timely, by reducing the government's
claim on savings just as households and firms are seeking more capital
to finance investments.

But under current law, the deficit as a

percent of GDP will begin to expand again as we move into the next
century, with unacceptable consequences for financial stability and
economic growth.

The primary cause of this increase will be federal

outlays, which will almost surely again be rising at a pace that will
exceed the growth of our tax base.

Only by reducing the growth in

spending is ultimate balance achievable.
As I have emphasized many times, the Federal Reserve also can
contribute to the achievement of our overriding goal--maximum
sustainable economic growth--by pursuing and ultimately achieving a
stable price level.




Without the uncertainties engendered by

50

inflation, households and firms are better able to plan for the
future.

And firms focus on maximizing profitability by holding down

costs and increasing productivity rather than by using
conditions to support price increases.

inflationary

There is some evidence to

suggest that the stronger trend of productivity growth we have
witnessed over the recent past is due at least partly to the
beneficial effects of low rates of inflation.
Our nation has made considerable progress in putting the
economy on a sound footing in the past few years.

To preserve and

extend these advances, our monetary and fiscal policies will need to
remain disciplined and focused on our long-term objectives; we would
be foolish to squander our recent gains for near-term benefits that
would prove ephemeral.

Indeed, by fostering progress toward price

stability, achieving lower federal budget deficits, and encouraging
competitive markets both here and abroad, we will help ensure the
continued vitality of our nation's economy now and for many years into
the future.




51

SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT FORMATION
COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS

WASHINGTON, DC 205 1 5-6054
TELEPHONE: (202) 226-7315

August 11, 1994
Hon. Alan Greenspan, Chairman
Federal Reserve System
20th Street & Constitution Avenue, NW
Room B-2125
Washington, D.C. 20551
Dear Mr. Chairman:
This letter is to thank you for your most recent participation in the Conduct of Monetary Policy hearing
held by the House Banking Economic Growth Subcommittee on July 22, 1994. In addition, as I had
mentioned at the close of the hearing, there are several questions which, in the interest of timeliness, I did not
ask you directly at the hearing but intended to forward to you so that you could answer these in written form
for the hearing record. As promised, I would like to submit the following five additional questions for your
consideration.
•

Recent concerns, regarding unprecedented stock market instability, the falling value of the dollar in the
international currency markets, and the sustained high level of long-term rates, have raised different
questions in regard to monetary intervention by the Federal Reserve. Particularly, in regard to the
value of the dollar, in testimony you delivered on Friday, July 15, before the Bipartisan Commission
on Entitlement and Tax Reform, you stated that the "U.S. economy has recently been experiencing the
ideal combination of rising activity, falling unemployment, and slowing inflation." Yet in your
testimony before the Senate on Wednesday, July 20, in addressing the falling value of the dollar, you
stated that "the weak value of the dollar internationally is often indicative of possible domestic
inflationary evidence" and is generally considered as bad for the economy. The value of the dollar in
foreign markets has in fact fallen 5 % since you testified before the Senate Banking Committee on May
27, and many have been expecting the Fed to raise rates as the most traditional way of defending a
currency. You mentioned to the Subcommittee that you see the decline in the dollar as resulting from
buying and selling trends for currency in foreign markets rather than from domestic inflation pressures.
At what point would you consider the falling value of the dollar to be severe enough in nature to
warrant Fed intervention regardless of the perceived reasons for the dollar's decline, and do you see
the value of the dollar as at all mitigating the positive statements you had about the state of the U.S.
economy at the Bipartisan Commission hearing?

•

Although the nation continues to experience an economic recovery, there is evidence that this recent
prosperity may not be widely dispersed. Despite strong GDP numbers and vigorous manufacturing
productivity, wages have remained flat. For the roughly 6% of Americans who remain unemployed,
job prospects for those at the low end of the skill level and wage spectrum are increasingly bleak. Is
there a role for monetary policy to play in alleviating this disparity, or as you suggested in your
testimony before the Bipartisan Commission, in reaching this segment of the unemployed population,
should we be concentrating on worker retraining and programmatic changes which connect dislocated
workers with pockets of the job market in need of qualified workers? In addition, as these goals closely
mirror the intent ofH.R. 4040, the Reemployment Act of 1994, do you believe that the enactment of this
legislation is desirable in order to alleviate the disparity which currently exists? Will enactment of




52
Chairman Alan Greenspan
August 11, 1994
Page 2

retraining and reemployment legislation help to achieve the mandate of the ^Humphrey-Hawkins' Act
to secure "the right of every American to full opportunity for useful employment at fair compensation?"
•

Under the mandate of the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, a principle portion of
your monetary policy report must contain a discussion of changes in the monetary aggregates and their
relevance to the state of the economy. In the last ten to fifteen years, as you have often noted, the
propensity for the aggregates, in particular M2, to meet their targets as outlined by the Fed has been
infrequent. Many economists, including Dr. Geoffrey Moore at Columbia University, with whose
work you are no doubt familiar, have attempted to include measures of non-monetary financial
instruments in explaining the divergence of the monetary aggregates from their targets. Has the
Federal Reserve System continued to review such new modeling techniques and have they been useful in
explaining why the aggregates have been declining in relevance for overall economic forecasting? If
other non-monetary financial instruments are more meaningful indicators, what are they? Do you
believe that the price of gold is a more reliable indicator for economic analyses?

•

The press release on the money supply issued by the Federal Reserve on July 21 showed that the
growth rate in the monetary aggregate M2 for the three months ending in June, 1994 was zero. The
smaller monetary aggregate, Ml, has decelerated rapidly from its much higher growth rates last year to
1.6% in the last three months. Some experts, such as Dr. Anna Schwartz, predict that a continuation
of this kind of slow or zero money growth could result in a recession. Would you please comment on
the implications of this slow money growth.

•

Many economists and analysts have been puzzled by the present levels for the price of gold which have
not reached the psychologically "magic level" of $400 per ounce even though recent market tendencies
such as flaccid bond values and a decrease in investor confidence would normally have caused an
increase to this level. Over the past decade in particular, the international currency markets have
become increasingly intertwined with activity in non-monetary markets, in particular that for gold. Do
you believe that it is within the mandate of the Federal Reserve System to participate financially in nonmonetary markets to more effectively implement or enhance the affect monetary policy, and if so, under
what circumstances ?

In addition, Congressman Tom Ridge, the Ranking Minority Member of the Economic Growth
Subcommittee, who was unable to attend the hearing, asks that you respond for the record to the list of
questions enclosed with this letter.
Thank you again for your consideration.
Sincerely,

Paul E. Kanjorski
Chairman, Subcommittee on Economic
Growth and Credit Formation
PEK/cpb




53
Questions for the Federal Reserve System Chairman from Congressman Tom Ridgef
Ranking Minority Member of the House Banking Subcommittee on Economic Growth:

1. Mr. Chairman, have the monetary aggregates lost all significance to the point where we should
transition to a gold-based system?
2. Is a return to the $350 gold price range desirable, and if so, why haven't the recent interest rate
raises been successful in returning gold to this level?
3. How is it that this country was able to finance a larger proportion of its national wealth during
World War II and yet maintain interest rates at very low levels? Is it true that after every major
previous war, the country has reverted to a gold standard in order to stabilize long-term rate markets
and reduce the cost of the overhanging national debt?
4. With some commodity prices now rising and the stock and bond markets in a period of
stagnation, are we seeing the beginning of stagflation here? What evidence do we have that the
economy is going to grow in any meaningful sense, short of a small bubble that may be simply the
result of buyers anticipating future price rises?
5. Mr. Greenspan, on the Senate side you mentioned that the country had 100 year bonds at the
turn of the century, and these bonds had very low interest rates. Was this in effect the direct result
of a gold standard? If so, what would be the down side of returning to a gold standard, particularly
when the current Administration was boasting that its effectiveness (until early this year) was
measured by the dropping long bond rates?
6. Apparently, the proportion of health costs paid by the U.S. government has been growing
steadily since the early 1960s, from about 20% of total costs to about 50% today. The percent paid
directly by consumers, who are the only players immediately sensitive to cost savings, has declined
from 60% to 20%. During this time we have seen a steady rise in health costs. Is there a
connection, and if so, does the current Administration bill presage higher or lower health care costs
from your viewpoint?




54
B O A R D OF G O V E R N O R S

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON, D. C. 20551
ALAN

GREEN5PA

September 9, 1994

The Honorable Paul E. Kanjorski
Chairman
Subcommittee on Economic Growth
and Credit Formation
Committee on Banking, Finance
and Urban Affairs
House of Representatives
Washington, D.C. 20515
Dear Mr. Chairman:
Thank you for your letter of August 11 enclosing follow-up questions to the
July 22, 1994, hearing on the conduct of monetary policy.
Enclosed are my responses to your questions and to those of Congressman
Ridge for inclusion in the hearing record.

Enclosures




55
CHAIRMAN PAUL E. KANJORSKI
QUESTIONS FOR THE RECORD FOR CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN
HEARING ON FED'S CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
JULY 22, 1994

1. Recent concerns, regarding unprecedented stock market instability, the
falling value of the dollar in the international currency markets, and the sustained
high level of long-term rates, have raised different questions hi regard to monetary
intervention by the Federal Reserve. Particularly, in regard to the value of the
dollar, in testimony you delivered on Friday, July 15, before the Bipartisan Commission on Entitlement and Tax Reform, you stated that the "U.S. economy has recently
been experiencing the ideal combination of rising activity, falling unemployment, and
slowing inflation." Yet in your testimony before the Senate on Wednesday, July 20,
in addressing the falling value of the dollar, you stated that "the weak value of the
dollar internationally is often indicative of possible domestic inflationary evidence"
and is generally considered as bad for the economy. The value of the dollar in
foreign markets has in fact fallen 5% since you testified before the Senate Banking
Committee on May 27, and many have been expecting the Fed to raise rates as the
most traditional way of defending a currency. You mentioned to the Subcommittee
that you see the decline hi the dollar as resulting from buying and selling trends for
currency in foreign markets rather than from domestic inflation pressures. At what
point would you consider the falling value of the dollar to be severe enough hi nature
to warrant Fed intervention regardless of the reasons for the dollar's decline, and do
you see the dollar as at all mitigating the positive statements you had about the state
of the U.S. economy at the Bipartisan Commission hearings?
There is no predetermined extent or speed of decline in the dollar's foreign
exchange value that might prompt the U.S. monetary authorities (Treasury and Federal
Reserve) to intervene in foreign exchange markets. Such decisions depend very importantly on the surrounding circumstances: Are exchange markets extremely disorderly?
Does the dollar's decline seem to be having important spillover effects on U.S. financial
markets? Is the dollar's decline severe enough to materially threaten progress toward
price stability? Would intervention seem to have a chance of being effective?
Part of the reason for the dollar's decline in the first half of this year was the
unexpected signs of stronger growth abroad and the associated implications for foreign
interest rates. Nevertheless, the dollar's weakness was troubling on at least two counts—it
may have signalled market concerns that U.S. monetary policy tightening thus far had not
been enough to forestall a pickup in inflation, or, apart from market expectations, the
decline in the dollar itself could have undesirable effects on the U.S. price level, whether
directly through the price of imports or, indirectly, through a boost to aggregate demand
at a time when the U.S. economy was nearing potential. Thus, U.S. monetary authorities




56

did intervene on several occasions, and we were pleased that the dollar seemed to
stabilize after mid-July.

2. Although the nation continues to experience an economic recovery, there is
evidence that this recent prosperity may not be widely dispersed. Despite strong
GDP numbers and vigorous manufacturing productivity, wages have remained flat.
For the roughly 6% of Americans who remain unemployed, job prospects for those
at the low end of the skill level and wage spectrum are increasingly bleak. Is there a
role for monetary policy to play in alleviating this disparity, or as you suggested in
your testimony before the Bipartisan Commission, in reaching this segment of the
unemployed population, should we be concentrating on worker retraining and programmatic changes which connect dislocated workers with pockets of the job market
in need of qualified workers? In addition, as these goals closely mirror the intent of
H.R. 4040, the Reemployment Act of 1994, do you believe that the enactment of this
legislation is desirable in order to alleviate the disparity which currently exists? Will
enactment of retraining and reemployment legislation help to achieve the mandate of
the "Humphrey-Hawkins" Act to secure "the right of every American to full
opportunity for useful employment at fan* compensation?"
The labor market problems to which you refer cannot be effectively addressed
through monetary policy. We do need to focus on other instruments of public policy to
deal with the structural unemployment and low real wages that afflict too many in our
country. H.R. 4040 is intended to make a contribution by improving the nation's systems
for assisting workers who lose their jobs, by integrating a variety of income support,
training, and job-matching programs. I am not in a position to offer a judgment on the
likely efficiency and effectiveness of the proposed system, which would require a detailed
examination of the experience with a variety of programs that have existed over the
years. Undoubtedly, many insights in that regard will surface during hearings on the bill.

3. Under the mandate of the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of
1978, a principle portion of your monetary policy report must contain a discussion of
changes in the monetary aggregates and then* relevance to the state of the economy.
In the last ten to fifteen years, as you have often noted, the propensity for the
aggregates, in particular M2, to meet then* targets as outlined by the Fed has been
infrequent. Many economists, including Mr. Geoffrey Moore at Columbia University, with whose work you are no doubt familiar, have attempted to include measures
on non-monetary financial instruments in explaining the divergence of the monetary
aggregates from then* targets. Has the Federal Reserve continued to review such
new modeling techniques and have they been useful in explaining why the aggregates
have been declining in relevance for overall economic forecasting? If other




57

non-monetary financial instruments are more meaningful indicators, what are they?
Do you believe that the price of gold is a more reliable indicator for economic
analyses?
The relationship of M2 to the economy has been changing, and as a consequence
the Federal Reserve has de-emphasized this variable in making its monetary policy
decisions. Because of these changes, there have been times when the Federal Reserve
judged that fostering good performance of the economy required that M2 grow outside
our preannounced ranges. As you note, an important reason for the anomalous behavior
of M2 appears to be the greater variety and easier availability of non-monetary financial
instruments, and we have emphasized this in our research efforts. For example, a study
by two members of our staff, Feinman and Porter, which was published in September
1992, tested whether changes in the demand and supply of M2 could be explained by
including returns on a very wide variety of alternative uses of funds, including
intermediate-term Treasury securities and the cost of consumer debt (reasoning that one
use for M2 is to pay down high cost debt). Another staff study-by Orphanides, Reid and
Small published in December 1993~looked at the influence of stock and bond mutual
funds on the public's holdings of M2. Both of these studies had some, but limited,
success; questions about the behavior of M2 persist, and we are continuing to research
the properties of this monetary aggregate.
In our policy making, we look at the prices and quantities of a number of nonmonetary financial instruments. Among these, some Federal Reserve officials have found
the price of gold to be useful for reading market participants' expectations of inflation.

4. The press release on the money supply issued by the Federal Reserve on
July 21 showed that the growth rate in the monetary aggregate M2 for the three
months ending hi June, 1994 was zero. The smaller monetary aggregate, Ml, has
decelerated rapidly from its much higher growth rates last year to 1.6 percent in the
last three months. Some experts, such as Dr. Anna Schwartz, predict thai a continuation of this kind of slow or zero money growth could result in a recession.
Would you please comment on the implications of this slow money growth.
As noted in the previous question, the relationship of money to the economy has
been shifting in recent years. Ml has become much more sensitive to movements in
interest rates, obscuring its relationship to current and future economic activity or prices;
M2 velocity has behaved anomalously as households take advantage of a wider variety of
savings instruments.
As a consequence, double-digit growth in Ml in 1992 and 1993 did not mean that
inflation was taking off, and slow growth this year does not imply recession. Moreover,




58
-4-

sluggish M2 in 1992 and 1993 was compatible with a strengthening economic expansion.
As noted in our report to Congress, the Federal Reserve expects the expansion of M2 to
remain damped, and modest Ml growth also would not be surprising, given the rise in
interest rates this year. The Federal Reserve will continue to monitor the behavior of
money and credit as it seeks to foster sustainable economic expansion. Looking at these
variables in the context of a wide variety of other economic and financial data, the
members of the Federal Open Market Committee projected continued economic expansion
over the balance of 1994 and in 1995.

5. Many economists and analysts have been puzzled by the present levels for
the price of gold which have not reached the psychologically "magic level" of $400
per ounce even though recent market tendencies such as flaccid bond values and a
decrease in investor confidence would normally have caused an increase to this level.
Over the past decade in particular, the international currency markets have become
increasingly intertwined with activity in non-monetary markets,, hi particular that for
gold. Do you believe that it is within the mandate of the Federal Reserve System to
participate financially in non-monetary markets to more effectively implement or
enhance the effect of monetary policy, and if so, under what circumstances?
The Federal Reserve does have the statutory authority to deal in gold, though this
authority has not been exercised since the mid-1930s. Unless we are willing to alter a
number of institutional arrangements and a tendency toward chronic budget deficits, it is
difficult to envision gold playing a central role in monetary policy. Nonetheless, a
number of Federal Reserve policymakers, myself included, have found the price of gold
to be a useful indicator of inflationary expectations, especially when viewed in the context
of other economic and financial indicators.




59
CONGRESSMAN TOM RIDGE
QUESTIONS FOR THE RECORD FOR CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN
HEARING ON FED'S CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
JULY 22, 1994

1. Mr. Chairman, have the monetary aggregates lost all significance to the
point where we should transition to a gold-based system?
Unless we are willing to alter a number of institutional arrangements and a
tendency toward chronic budget deficits, it is difficult to envision gold playing a central
role in monetary policy. Nonetheless, a number of Federal Reserve policymakers, myself
included, have found the price of gold to be a useful indicator of inflationary
expectations, especially when viewed in the context of other economic and financial
indicators.

2. Is a return to the $350 gold price range desirable, and if so, why haven't
the recent interest rate raises been successful in returning gold to this level?
The recent increases in the price of gold may have been associated in part with
some deterioration in inflationary expectations, despite the increase in interest rates.
Such a deterioration might reflect concerns about pressures on available resources and
potential inflationary credit expansions in light of sustained strength in the economy.

3. How is it that this country was able to finance a larger proportion of its
national wealth during World War II and yet maintain interest rates at very low
levels. Is it true that after every major previous war, the country has reverted to a
gold standard in order to stabilize long-term rate markets and reduce the cost of the
overhanging national debt?
During World War II, the Federal Reserve supported the price of Treasury debt at
artificially high levels (interest rates were held artificially low) to facilitate financing the
government's deficit in an emergency situation. The inflationary consequences of this
policy were held in check by controls on wages and prices and on credit and by rationing
of scarce goods. As controls and rationing were removed after the war, the Federal
Reserve had to let interest rates rise to contain inflation.
The historical record of the United States does indicate that policymakers
ultimately returned to a gold standard after major wars, which is testimony to the ability
of that regime to contain inflation. In such circumstances, market participants are more
likely to be confident that inflation would not get out of hand and, therefore, be more




60

willing to purchase a heavy volume of Treasury securities at relatively low nominal
interest rates.
As a general rule, the assurance that policymakers seek to foster price stability will
be associated with low short- and long-term nominal interest rates.

4. With some commodity prices now rising and the stock and bond markets
in a period of stagnation, are we seeing the beginning of stagflation here? What
evidence do we have that the economy is going to grow in any meaningful sense,
short of a small bubble that may be simply the result of buyers anticipating future
price rises?
My assessment of the current economic picture is, I think, considerably more
positive than that conveyed by your question. The firmness of consumer sentiment and
the deepening order books of U.S. companies bode well for sustained growth of the
economy.

5. Mr. Greenspan, on the Senate side you mentioned that the country had
100 year bonds at the turn of the century, and these bonds had very low interest
rates. Was this in effect the direct result of a gold standard? If so, what would be
the down side of returning to a gold standard, particularly when the current
Administration was boasting that its effectiveness (until early this year) was
measured by the dropping long bond rates?
As I noted above, the confidence of market participants that inflation will be
contained in the future is critical in keeping both short- and long-term nominal interest
rates at low levels. For part of the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, the gold standard
bolstered that confidence.

6. Apparently, the proportion of health costs paid by the U.S. government
has been growing steadily since the early 1960s, from about 20% of total costs to
about 50% today. The percent paid directly by consumer, who are the only players
immediately sensitive to cost savings, has declined from 60% to 20%. During this
time we have seen a steady rise in health costs. Is there a connection, and if so, does
the current Administration bill presage higher or lower health care costs from your
viewpoint?
I would prefer to defer to those who are more expert in the field of health
economics for an assessment of the effects of specific legislative proposals.




o

ISBN 0-16-045885-4

""""

""

""" 9 0 0 0 0

"458859"
81-438 (64)