View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CONDUCT OF MONETARY POLICY
Report of the Federal Reserve Board pursuant to the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, P.L. 95-523
and
The State of the Economy

HEARING
BEFORE THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON
ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT FORMATION
OF THE

COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND
URBAN AFFAIRS
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
ONE HUNDRED THIRD CONGRESS
FIRST SESSION

FEBRUARY 23, 1993
Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs

Serial No. 103-10

U.S.

GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON ! 1993

For sale by the U.S. Government Printing Office
Superintendent of Documents, Congressional Sales Office, Washington, DC 20402




ISBN 0-16-040771-0

HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS
HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas, Chairman
STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota
CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York
BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts
PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania
JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts
FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York
KWEISI MFUME, Maryland
MAXINE WATERS, California
LARRY LAROCCO, Idaho
BILL ORTON, Utah
JIM BACCHUS, Florida
HERBERT C. KLEIN, New Jersey
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
PETER DEUTSCH, Florida
LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois
BOBBY L. RUSH, Illinois
LUCILLE ROYBAL-ALLARD, California
THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin
ELIZABETH FURSE, Oregon
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
ALBERT R. WYNN, Maryland
CLEO FIELDS, Louisiana
MELVIN WATT, North Carolina
MAURICE HINCHEY, New York
CALVIN M. DOOLEY, California
RON KLINK, Pennsylvania
ERIC FINGERHUT, Ohio

JAMES A. LEACH, Iowa
BILL McCOLLUM, Florida
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
DOUG BEREUTER, Nebraska
THOMAS J. RIDGE, Pennsylvania
TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin
ALFRED A. (AL) McCANDLESS, California
RICHARD H. BAKER, Louisiana
JIM NUSSLE, Iowa
CRAIG THOMAS, Wyoming
SAM JOHNSON, Texas
DEBORAH PRYCE, Ohio
JOHN LINDER, Georgia
JOE KNOLLENBERG, Michigan
RICK LAZIO, New York
ROD GRAMS, Minnesota
SPENCER BACKUS, Alabama
MIKE HUFFINGTON, California
MICHAEL CASTLE, Delaware
PETER KING, New York
BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont

SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT FORMATION
PAUL E. KANJORSKI,
STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina
JOHN J. LAFALCE, New York
BILL ORTON, Utah
HERBERT C. KLEIN, New Jersey
NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York
CALVIN M. DOOLEY, California
RON KLINK, Pennsylvania
ERIC FINGERHUT, Ohio




Pennsylvania, Chairman
THOMAS J. RIDGE, Pennsylvania
BILL McCOLLUM, Florida
TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin
JIM NUSSLE, Iowa
MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jersey
PETER KING, New York

CONTENTS
Pa e

Hearing held on:
February 23, 1993
Appendix:
February 23, 1993

s
1

45
WITNESS
TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 23, 1993

Greenspan, Hon. Alan, Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board
APPENDIX
Prepared statements:
Kanjorski, Hon. Paul E
Ridge, Hon. Thomas J.
Greenspan, Hon. Alan

46
3
48

ADDITIONAL MATERIAL SUBMITTED FOR THE RECORD
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, ' 'Monetary Policy Report
to the Congress Pursuant to the Full Employment and Balanced Growth
Act of 1978"
Greenspan, Hon, Alan, supplemental statement




75
72




SEMI-ANNUAL HEARING ON THE CONDUCT OF
MONETARY POLICY
TUESDAY, FEBRUARY 23, 1993

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES,
SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND
CREDIT FORMATION,
COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS,
Washington, DC.
The subcommittee met, pursuant to notice, at 10:10 a.m., in room
2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Paul E. Kanjorski
[chairman] presiding.
Present: Chairman Kanjorski, Representatives Neal of North
Carolina, LaFalce, Klink, Fingerhut, Ridge, McCollum, Nussle,
Roukema, and King.
Also present: Representatives Schumer, Bachus, Klein, Watt,
McCandless, Pryce, Knollenberg, and Grams.
Chairman KANJORSKI. The subcommittee will come to order.
The subcommittee meets today to receive the Semi-Annual
Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System on
Economic and Monetary Policy as mandated under the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, popularly known as
the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
Under the act, the Federal Reserve is required to set forth a
review and analysis of recent developments affecting economic
trends in the Nation, including changes in the exchange rate; the
objectives and plans of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors and
the Federal Open Market Committee with respect to the ranges of
growth and diminution of money supply, taking into account past
and prospective developments in employment, unemployment, production, investment, real income, productivity, international trade,
and prices; and the relationship between the Federal Reserve's
plans and short-term goals set forth in the most recent Economic
Report of the President, and any goals set by the Congress.
As the new chairman of this subcommittee, I want to welcome
Chairman Greenspan. I look forward to working with the Chairman, his colleagues at the Federal Reserve, and my colleagues on
both sides of the aisle, to achieve the overall goals of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act—full employment and balanced growth.
As we sit here today, the single most significant development in
economic policy since the last time the Chairman testified before
the House Banking Committee comes not as a result of any action
by the Federal Reserve, the Federal Open Market Committee, or
(l)




this subcommittee. The single most significant development is that
the American people have delivered a mandate for change.
In the election of 1992, the American people told the executive
branch, the legislative branch, and independent agencies like the
Federal Reserve, that this is not the time for politics as usual, that
the time for gridlock and divided government is over.
I am extremely encouraged by Chairman Greenspan's statements
that President Clinton's deficit reduction proposal is both "serious"
and "credible." The Chairman's statements indicate that not only
is the President heading in the right direction, but also that cooperation is possible between a President from one party and a Board
of Governors appointed by Presidents from the other party. For my
own part, I can only hope that this bipartisan spirit of cooperation
will spill over to the legislative branch. I will certainly do my best
to encourage it in this subcommittee.
The Chairman's appearance today comes at a time when shortterm interest rates are at relatively historical lows. Few Americans
today are complaining about the price of money. Low interest rates
usually mean an ample supply of money—"easy money."
The anomaly we find ourselves in today is that while interest
rates are low, many Americans still cannot find access to it at any
price. This continuing "credit crunch" is particularly acute for
small- and medium-sized businesses which are the lifeblood of our
economy, and which have historically created the majority of new
jobs in our economy. It is the inability of small- and medium-sized
businesses to obtain access to credit which has undoubtedly caused
unemployment to remain unacceptably high.
Our inner cities, our second and third tier cities, and our minority communities have been particularly hard hit by the inability to
obtain access to credit. Small communities in northeastern Pennsylvania, and the riot-torn sections of Los Angeles may be thousands of miles apart and have vastly different social and cultural
backgrounds, but they share one important thing in common: Both
feel that their economic recovery has been blocked by inadequate
access to capital for business expansion and job creation.
In our economy today, big businesses have avenues other than
commercial banks through which they can obtain credit. They can
go directly to the capital markets. They can obtain loans from pension funds and insurance companies. Individuals who seek home
loans and credit for consumer loans benefit from the secondary
market which has been created to increase the flow of funds for
these purposes.
Virtually alone among borrowers, small- and medium-sized businesses have little or no alternatives other than borrowing from
commercial banks. Yet, banks are too often reluctant to make
loans, claiming they are struggling under the weight of increased
capital requirements and regulations. Where are these businesses
to turn at a time when short-term interest rates are low, and there
are capital requirements and regulators who make it easier and
more profitable for a bank to invest in government securities than
in small- and medium-sized commercial loans?
I hope the Chairman will address the question of how we can
ensure that small- and medium-sized businesses obtain access to
credit they need to make our economic recovery complete and to




ensure that we meet the goals of full employment, which is an integral part of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
If artificial restrictions imposed by either regulators or the Congress are impeding bank lending to small- and medium-sized businesses, please tell us how we can remove these impediments. If
new incentives or a secondary market for commercial loans need to
be created, tell us the most effective way to create them.
If nothing we can do will convince banks to make commercial
loans, then who can we find or create who will make them, and
why are we in the business of chartering and insuring commercial
banks?
Mr. Chairman, I welcome you to today's hearing and I look forward to hearing your testimony and to working with you in the
months and years ahead to revitalize our economy.
Mr. Ridge's plane is delayed. With unanimous consent, I will
enter into the record at this time, Mr. Ridge's opening statement.
[The opening statement of Hon. Thomas Ridge follows:]
OPENING STATEMENT OF HON. THOMAS RIDGE, MEMBER OF
THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON ECONOMIC GROWTH AND CREDIT
FORMATION

Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to welcome Mr. Greenspan to
our new subcommittee today. Traditionally, we have not had jurisdiction over Federal Reserve policy and operations, so we're on a
learning curve here. I want to say, however, that those of us who
entered Congress not long after the days of double-digit inflation,
when all Americans were clear losers, are behind you in your efforts to spur steady long-term growth and, indeed, have an abiding
interest in maintaining a healthy, independent Federal Reserve.
I must comment on the package proposed by our new President.
Certainly all Americans wish to see him succeed. We cannot wish
for him to fail, since we would be, in effect, wishing for our home
States and our country to fail. And I agree with Mr. Clinton that
the status quo cannot be maintained without jeopardizing our children's future. It will be no easy job to ensure the recession's end
(and stimulate the job-producing sector) while also closing a stubborn deficit.
And so while I applaud the hard work he has done, and support
the general thrust of the spending cuts he advocates, I must say I
do not believe the voters had $160 billion in new spending in mind
when they sent him to the White House. And I say without reservation that they did not want to see the deficit problem tackled primarily through higher taxes. Over the last 14 years, government
revenue has averaged between 18 and 20 percent of GNP, while
government spending has grown to 25 percent of GNP. We have a
spending problem, nothing else.
But look at what will happen under this plan: According to an
analysis presented by the American Enterprise Institute, in fiscal
year 1994 the Clinton plan will raise $36 billion in new taxes while
cutting just $3.6 billion, for a 10-to-l ratio of new taxes to reduced
spending. The spending cuts come later, we're told. And the deficit
reduction comes later. Pennsylvanians are willing to share in the
sacrifice, but government needs to share in the pain.




Of course, dissenters will have to be specific. I think we need to
go back and enact precise spending cuts before we enact any tax
increases. I think we need to make real distinctions—distinctions
not made in the Clinton plan—between spending for infrastucture
and children, which are truly investment, and the many other
types of spending which must be considered only for what they are:
Private sector funds taken for less efficient public spending.
In the end, I don't think a ratio of $2.5 to $3 in tax hikes for
every dollar of spending cut will do the country justice, and most
voter will not accept this balance. I wish Mr. Panetta, who is very
knowledgeable in budget matters, could have prevailed with his
view of $2 in spending cuts for every dollar of new taxes. Maybe he
will yet prevail.
Finally, I suspect Mr. Greenspan will tell us that he can manage
monetary policy just fine if we control the deficit. He will tell us
that long-term bond rates will fall if we close the deficit. I think
he's right. But if we start down the wrong path and interest rates
fall, we may get surprised. Interest rates, particularly short-term
rates, fell all through this recession and still, today, small business
is not creating the jobs we would expect at the end of a recession.
If long-run rates fall but employers have no expectation of future
growth, if government regulatory and taxation policy indicate a
distinct bias against business, then the lowest bond rates in the
world will not be enough to start the research, investment, marketing, and production functions that we need to put everyone back to
work and keep them there.
The deficit is an elusive target indeed. We must bring it down.
But in the woods of northeastern Pennsylvania, where every year
the older generation teaches the younger one how to hunt, they say
there's two ways to bring down the deer. You can bring the deer
down with patience and planning and a good, clean shot and have
yourself a feast afterward. Or you can bring it down with wild, erratic shots that only leave you with a stinking mess on your hands.
I'm hoping that when we get out of the woods, we'll have a feast
instead of a mess.
Mr. Chairman, I look forward to our time spent together today.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. King, if you have an opening statement you would like to make.
Mr. KING. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I certainly did not expect
to acquire this much seniority so quickly. Very seriously, I look forward to the testimony of Chairman Greenspan, not only as it relates to the narrow issue of Humphrey-Hawkins, but also, of
course, as it relates to the overall economy; specifically, President
Clinton's economic proposals, and the impact that those proposals
are going to have on the recovery, which is just now beginning, the
extent to which the increased taxes could impair that recovery, the
extent to which it could have an impact on business expansion, and
on the creation of jobs.
As the chairman indicated, I think this subcommittee has very
significant questions regarding the impact of regulations on the
banking industry, the extent to which banks are precluded from
providing credit so that businesses can expand so that jobs can be
created, and also whether or not there is a need for secondary markets.




I look forward to your testimony. Thank you, Mr. Greenspan.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Neal.
Mr. NEAL OF NORTH CAROLINA. Thanks, Mr. Chairman.
I want to first say that I am delighted that you are chairman of
this subcommittee. I know you will do an outstanding job. I had the
privilege of chairing the committee that had part of your jurisdiction for several years, and I was on that committee for many years.
This jurisdiction dealing with the Fed is most fascinating and most
important.
The Fed does has an even larger impact on our economy than
the fiscal policy that we all deal with. I want to say to Mr. Greenspan, and to my colleagues, Paul is a good friend of mine. He is an
outstanding Congressman. He is a very thoughtful, intelligent man,
and will do an outstanding job with this subcommittee.
I also want to say to Mr. Greenspan, I appreciate the job you
have done over recent years. You know, a lot of people say you
cannot bring inflation down in light of or in the face of a big deficit. Mr. Volker and Mr. Greenspan did just that. They did a most
difficult job.
While the Federal deficit was being quadrupled, the rate of inflation was lowered dramatically, largely under the leadership of Mr.
Greenspan. If you understand that there is a way to accomplish all
of the sometimes seemingly conflicting goals of the HumphreyHawkins mandate—that is, for maximum employment, maximum
growth, the lowest possible interest rates, and so on—there is a
way of doing that. That way is to bring inflation to as close to zero
as possible and to keep it there.
By doing that, we create the essential condition for maximum
sustained economic growth, maximum sustained job creation, maximum savings and, therefore, investment productivity growth, competitiveness—everything we want for our economy. We create the
condition for the lowest possible sustained interest rates.
So, Mr. Chairman, I appreciate your continuing this effort to
bring down inflation. I hope you will let nothing stand in your way.
There is no sensible tradeoff, as you know. There is no benefit to be
gained from higher inflation.
I have been very heartened by the comments that President Clinton has made on this subject. He has made several major statements on this during the campaign and since then. In every case,
he has supported the idea of low inflation. Not once has he suggested that we ought to politically manipulate the Fed or go to high
inflation.
So I thank you for the job well done and hope you will keep it
up. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Neal.
Mr. Nussle.
Mr. NUSSLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Welcome, Chairman
Greenspan.
I spent this last weekend talking to real budget cutters, back in
Iowa—people who cut budgets on the farm, and cut budgets at
home, and cut budgets in their small business on Main Street.
They are the real budget cutters. I have not met too many budget
cutters around here since I have been in Congress my first 2 years.




So I went and talked to the real budget cutters. They told me
their impression of the plan that the President has put forth. They
are glad he is serious. They think he is serious about it. What
strikes them is that instead of saying, let us tighten our belt, what
the President is saying is, let us buy a bigger belt. Then let us
tighten it, maybe on down the line.
Your testimony to the Senate, to me, was intriguing, and sounded a little bit more like the budget cutters I had met back in Iowa
during my weekend home, where you said, I think—and I am paraphrasing, and I am sure we can go into this in the questions—I
think you were suggesting that cutting or reducing spending is the
most effective way to deal with budget deficits, as opposed to raising taxes. Obviously, those are alternatives, both of them, but I
think you suggested that cutting spending was the most effective
way.
That is what my people back home are telling me as well. They
are saying before you send any more money out to Washington,
particularly mine, out of my pocket, my business, my farm, my
household, I want to see you do what I have to do, and that is, cut
spending.
So those budget cutters are going to be keeping an eye on us as
budget cutters during this next round. I would be interested in
going into a little bit more detail on some of the testimony that you
gave in the Senate.
I appreciate your attendance here. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I trust there are operating rooms in Iowa,
and not butcher shops, Mr. Nussle.
Mr. LaFalce.
Mr. LAFALCE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I am delighted to be on this subcommittee, under your leadership.
As Mr. Neal has indicated that he was chairman of one of the
predecessor subcommittees, the Domestic Monetary Polices, so, too,
I had the pleasure of being on one of the predecessor subcommittees that was merged into this, the Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization, from 1983 to 1986, where we worked so arduously with
you as a member, especially on the whole issue of industrial competitiveness. I am glad to see that issue is finally coming to the
forefront.
Mr. Greenspan, it is always a pleasure to have you. I have
been—well, thrilled is probably an appropriate word—to see that
there appears to have been, if not an explicit compact, but at least
an implicit compact that, given the fact that you consider the proposals of President Clinton to be both serious and credible, it will
enable you to adopt a monetary policy that accommodates such a
fiscal policy in order to help continue economic growth and even
accelerate it.
Of course, the devil is in the details, as everyone wants to say,
both with respect to implementation of the fiscal end of the monetary policy, and of the timing, too.
During the course of your testimony, I hope that you will come
to grips with the comments, however, of some of those who are critical of the approach that the President has embarked on. I am certainly not one of them; but there are some individuals who say you




just cannot stimulate the economy if you ever have any kind of tax
cuts.
Others, such as Professor Feldstein, former Chairman of the Economic Advisors—did you have an opportunity to read his piece in
this morning's Wall Street Journal! Well, I would appreciate your
shared thoughts on his perspective, because he is an individual
whose credentials are too impressive to dismiss. I know we must
consider them and account for them.
Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Knollenberg.
Mr. KNOLLENBERG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, I want to welcome you here this morning.
I look forward to your monetary policy report, as well as your
thoughts on the economy and, of course, the Clinton economic plan.
I may not be quite as embracing of the plan as my colleague who
just spoke. I am strongly opposed to the direction that I see the
Clinton economic plan taking this country.
The Congress has been presented with a package that contains
nearly three times as much in tax increases as spending cuts. One
of the most alarming aspects of the proposal is the fact that in
1997, Federal spending under the plan will probably approach
something like $203 billion above what it is this year. I know that
most Americans would have a lot of difficulty calling that a budget
cut.
The attraction of this plan to some is that it will allegedly reduce
the deficit. A recent history tells the story. You will only have to
remember the 1990 budget summit, with which I know you are
very familiar. The cornerstone of that agreement was $165 billion
in new taxes. The deficit was supposed to go down.
As a result of that agreement, it has skyrocketed. When you look
at 1993 under the budget agreement, the 1993 deficit was supposed
to have been reduced to $75 billion. Instead, it appears to be going
to $332 billion.
It seems to me that the reason is clear. The tax increases hampered the economy, and spending continued through the roof. The
history of these budget deals, it seems, is clear, that they do raise
taxes, they raise spending, and they raise the deficit.
I would be very interested in hearing from you as to how you
might propose a challenge to that. I look forward to your testimony.
Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Klein.
Mr. KLEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I am delighted to participate in the work of this subcommittee,
which I consider to be among the most vital of all of the work that
we, in Congress, are performing this year. I am particularly happy
to hear Chairman Greenspan, who, of course, has a great reputation. We look forward to his testimony.
I was particularly glad, Chairman Greenspan, to hear of your
reference in your Senate testimony to the President's economic
plan as—if I heard you correctly—a very positive force for the
American economy. Certainly, our economy needs that kind of direction. I look forward to your testimony and your comments on
that subject.




Thank you very much.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. McCandless.
Mr. MCCANDLESS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I appreciate the opportunity to attend today. I do not have an
opening statement. I look forward to Chairman Greenspan's testimony.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. McCandless.
Mr. Klink.
Mr. KLINK. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I will be very brief, because I want to hear Chairman Greenspan.
I am very honored that he is here with us today.
I am also honored that I have two chairmen here today. Chairman Kanjorski, I think, has shown great leadership on this subcommittee. He and I, both coming from Pennsylvania, realize that
particularly in our State, that everything that this subcommittee
stands for is what we must accomplish. That is why, Mr. Chairman, we look forward to the words of wisdom that we, hopefully,
will hear from you today.
Also, Chairman LeFalce being here is particularly enlightening
for me, because the way we see the economy in western Pennsylvania turning around, as well as in the entire Nation, is the strength
of small business. I know that, again, it gets back to the Fed and
the policies that you will recommend to us.
I am also interested in what I have heard from the other side of
the table. Like my colleague from Iowa, we have got some great
budget cutters in Pennsylvania, too, so we are going to have to
keep our eye on the ball and make sure that we can keep up with
them. I hope that we will be able to see—since the President has
chosen to use CBO assumptions—that we will all be able to say,
well, we are comparing apples with apples, and maybe we will take
the lead and come up with some additional cuts.
There is no doubt, we are at a crossroads. That is why I think
that you being here today can tell us, as Yogi Berra once said,
"When you come to a crossroads, take it." We hope that you can
tell us which one to take, or at least give us some indication as to
where the sign points.
Thank you for being here.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you, Mr. Klink.
Mr. Grams.
Mr. GRAMS. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I want to
thank you for the opportunity and the invitation to be a part of the
hearing here this morning. I want to thank Mr. Greenspan for
taking the time, and I look forward to the comments that you will
be making this morning.
As you know, last November, the American people sent the message that they were sick and tired of business as usual in Washington; that they had had enough of the skyrocketing deficits, runaway spending, and government that no longer represented the
true needs of the American people. As a result, this year, we have
a new President, and we have 110 new Members of Congress,
which is really the recipe for change here in Washington.
Last Wednesday, President Clinton had a tremendous opportunity to show the American people that their votes counted; that the
time for reckless government spending had come to an end, and




9

that we were finally going to get serious about making a debt-free
future for our children and grandchildren.
Unfortunately, I do not think that was the case. Instead of proposing any serious cuts in government spending and tax incentives
to stimulate our economy, Mr. Clinton gave us just the opposite:
$273 billion in new taxes, $108 billion in new Federal spending, and
enough smoke and mirrors to make even David Copperfield jealous.
President Clinton was right about one thing. It is time for a
change, but not the kind of illusionary change he spoke of Wednesday night. We have to reduce the deficit, but through spending
cuts, not higher taxes. We have got to reduce the national debt, but
not on the backs of middle-income class taxpayers. The time has
come for sacrifice, but the sacrifices must begin here, in Congress.
Chairman Greenspan, I look forward to hearing your report
today on the national economy. I know, like the rest of the people
on the panel, the people back home are asking for spending cuts
and real deficit reduction. I hope we can depend on you for your
honest and candid remarks.
I want to thank you, and I yield back my time.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you, Mr. Grams.
Mr. Fingerhut.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, it is an honor for me to have the opportunity to hear from you and to speak with you as a new Member of
this Congress and this subcommittee.
While I understand that it is preeminent on everyone's mind to
talk about the subject of the President's economic plan and what
response may come from Congress, I hope we will not lose sight in
this hearing this morning of Chairman Kanjorski's opening statement, with respect to the role of the availability and the cost of
credit to businesses throughout this country. That is the primary
function of this subcommittee and, obviously, the primary function
of the Federal Reserve.
It is, without question, the number one issue on the minds of the
business people back home that I have talked to. Every time I have
the opportunity to ask them, on a scale of 1 to 10, what would do
the most to permit their businesses to grow and for them to hire
additional people in my district, number one is always the availability or the cost of credit.
So I look forward to your remarks in that regard. I do not think
we should lose sight of the chairman's opening remarks, which I
think were on point and insightful.
I have one comment of my own on the subject of the President's
economic plan, that I hope you will address. Obviously, the preeminent subject on everyone's mind is that which you alluded to when
you testified before the Senate. That is the subject of cuts in spending versus taxes.
I note with a certain degree of irony and, I guess, a little bit of
partisanship that none of the speakers who have called for more
cuts here this morning have taken up the President's challenge
and specified where they would make those cuts.
I am wondering if it is possible for you in your comments to help
us, to the extent that it can be done in a nonpartisan way, on this
subject of cuts versus taxes. It is clear that additional taxes in an




10

indirect way, are not a boon to the economy, certainly. To the
extent that they impact on areas such as energy and other costs of
business, they can possibly be a negative.
What we do not hear nearly enough about is the impact that
cuts in government spending can potentially have on our economy.
I come from the school of thought that believes that a lot of the
economic growth that we saw in the 1980's and the early 1990's, to
the extent that we saw growth in any of those years, was attributable to government spending in a classic sense, particularly in the
defense industry.
It is no secret that the areas that are experiencing the toughest
economic problems in our country are those areas that had received the bulk of the government's largess through the defense
and other sectors.
Every one of the President's 150 spending cut proposals that I
have seen will have some impact on employment in those areas of
the country, and will have some impact on the purchasing of contracts and services by the government through private businesses
that will then impact unemployment in a secondary nature.
So as you discuss, and I am sure you will find it impossible to
avoid, the subject of the deficit reduction course we are on, and the
relative credibility of cuts versus taxes, if you could, in your best
nonpartisan way—and you are very good at it, and we are not
quite so good at it on this side of the table—share with us how
taxes impact on the economy, but also how cuts impact on the
economy. It might broaden and enlighten the discussion.
Again, I thank you for the opportunity. I look forward to your
testimony.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you very much, Mr. Fingerhut.

Mrs. Roukema.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. I have no introductory comments, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you, Ms. Roukema.
Ms. Pryce.
Ms. PRYCE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would also like to express my appreciation for being invited to share the benefits of Mr.
Greenspan's testimony this morning.
Mr. Chairman, I am very grateful to you for taking the time to
be here with us today. You are one who has worked through different administrations and across party lines. It is essential that we
all listen very carefully to your wisdom on this subject. I am very
happy to be a part of it, and look forward to your comments.
Thank you, sir.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Schumer.
Mr. SCHUMER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
First, let me congratulate you on your ascending to the chairmanship of this very important subcommittee, and thank you for
inviting the members of the Banking Committee to attend.
I would like to make two quick points. First, Chairman Greenspan, I noticed throughout your testimony, there are all sorts of
new problems in terms of the relationship of money supply to the
economy, and why things are going up and down at the same time.
The only thing I would say to that is, I do want to tell you that I
part water with many of my colleagues on this side of the aisle in




11
thinking that we need to put more political interference on the
Fed.
You have a lot of missions, but your greatest is to wipe out the
fear of inflation in this economy. As the world economy expands, as
money flows out of banks and into money market funds, you may
have actually less to do with that than most people think.
However, what most people think is very, very important. Any
idea that Congress or any others of us who are sort of motivated by
more short-term goals—and that is what the political system
does—to then tinker with the Fed, I think would be a serious mistake. I want you to know that. I do not think you should be afraid
about standing up to that to anybody.
On the other point, I just reiterate what Mr. Fingerhut said to
my colleagues, particularly, the two gentlemen from Minnesota
and Michigan. It is very easy to get up there and say, "Cut, cut,
cut/' Ronald Reagan did it, and George Bush did it. They could not
get cuts through.
I would like to hear specific cuts that 90 percent of the Republican caucus would vote for. Then they might find 20 percent of the
Democratic caucus joining with them. I, for one, would love to cut
the space station. Are all you folks going to vote for that? I do not
know. I see some are shaking their heads.
There are a number of other cuts that many of us on this side of
the aisle might make. Defense spending—I think the cut did not go
deep enough. Where are the specific cuts? As President Clinton
said yesterday, "Put up or shut up/' It is easy to talk about
cuts
Mr. NUSSLE. Would the gentleman yield?
Mr. SCHUMER. Not until I am finished, and only with the chairman's permission.
It is easy to talk about cuts in the abstract. It is also easy for
each of us to put out a list of the cuts that we would make that do
not affect our own communities or our own districts. It is very hard
to put together a list of cuts that are going to pass this place.
So that would be my concern about getting the deficit down. Because even if you prefer cuts, it is my view—and I believe the
Chairman said this before the Senate—it is better to reduce the
deficit in a balanced package of taxes and cuts, than not do it at
all.
I do not know if the chairman wants to entertain a discussion; if
he does, I would welcome it.
Chairman KANJORSKI. That would be out of order, Mr. Schumer,
during the opening statements.
Mr. SCHUMER. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. McCollum, do you have an opening
statement?
Mr. McCoLLUM. I do not have much to say in the way of an opening statement, except it is certainly good to see you, again, Mr.
Chairman, up here. We all look forward to your appearances. You
are more insightful than most are about our economy, and it is certainly timely that you are here today. I look forward to hearing
you.
Thank you.




12

Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Watt, do you have a statement you
would like to make?
Mr. WATT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for the opportunity to be
here. I just came to hear Chairman Greenspan. I will reserve an
opening statement.
Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Bachus.
Mr. BACHUS. I have no opening statement, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Well, I think we have gone through our
opening statements, as usual, in our fast order.
Mr. Chairman, if you will proceed.
STATEMENT OF HON. ALAN GREENSPAN, CHAIRMAN OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD

Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I appreciate this opportunity to appear before you and your subcommittee members to discuss the developments in the economy
and the conduct of monetary policy.
Nineteen hundred and ninety-two saw an improved performance
of our economy. It is clear now that the expansion firmed and inflation moderated. Nevertheless, the expansion seemed to exhibit
little momentum through much of the year, unemployment remained high, and money and credit growth was sluggish.
In response, the Federal Reserve took steps to increase the availability of bank reserves on several occasions. These actions brought
short-term interest rates to their lowest levels in 30 years. Longterm interest rates also fell in 1992 and early 1993 as inflation expectations gradually moderated and optimism developed about a
potential for genuine progress in reducing Federal budget deficits.
In the view of the vast majority of business analysts, as well as
our Federal Reserve policymakers, prospects appear reasonable for
continued economic expansion and further declines in the unemployment rate. Before discussing the outlook in more detail, however, I would like to reflect on how monetary policy has interacted
with the forces that have shaped developments over recent years.
I have often noted before this subcommittee the distinctly different nature of the current business cycle. A number of extraordinary factors contributed to the earlier weakening in the economy
and have worked against a brisk and normal rebound from the recession.
These factors have included balance sheet restructuring in response to record debt burdens, overbuilding in commercial real
estate, business restructuring, and a substantial cutback in defense
spending.
Balance sheet restructuring has been, perhaps, the most important of these factors. In the 1980's, debt growth, hand in hand with
rising asset prices, considerably exceeded that of income, and debt
burdens rose to record levels. Debt-financed construction in the
commercial real estate market was an extreme manifestation of
this development. It was apparent as well in the other sectors of
the economy.
The difficulties faced by borrowers in servicing their debts as the
expansion slowed and the leveling out or decline in asset prices




13

prompted many to cut back expenditures and divert abnormal proportions of their cash-flows to debt repayment. This, in turn, fed
back into slower economic growth.
In addition, financial institutions were faced with impaired
equity positions, owing to sizable loan losses as well as more stringent supervision and regulation and demands by investors and regulators for better capital ratios. In response, they limited the availability of credit, with particular effects on smaller businesses.
Intensive business restructuring has been another important
characteristic of the evolving economic situation. In an environment of weak demand and intense competition here and abroad,
many firms have found it necessary to take aggressive measures to
reduce costs.
The contraction in defense spending has been an additional development restraining the expansion. Real Federal defense expenditures dropped about 6 percent in 1992, and are down 9 percent
from their 1987 peak.
Another less discussed factor that contributed to the formulation
of our recent monetary policy dates not from the 1980's, but rather
from the 1970's—inflation and inflation expectations. Over the past
decade or so, the importance of the interactions of monetary policy
with these expectations has become increasingly apparent.
Through the first two decades of the post-World War II period, this
interaction was less important. Savers and investors, firms and
households made economic and financial decisions based on an implicit assumption that inflation over the long run would remain
low enough to be inconsequential.
There was a sense that our institutional structure and culture,
unlike those of many other nations of the world, were alien to inflation. As a consequence, inflation premiums embodied in longterm interest rates were low and effectively capped.
Even during the rise in inflation of the late 1960's and 1970's,
there was a clear reluctance to believe that the inflation being experienced was other than transitory. It was presumed that inflation would eventually retreat to the 1- to 2-percent area that prevailed during the 1950's and the first half of the 1960's. Consequently, long-term interest rates remained contained.
But the dam eventually broke, and the huge losses suffered by
bondholders during the 1970's and early 1980's sensitized them to
the slightest sign, real or imagined, of rising inflation. At the first
indication of an inflationary policy, monetary or fiscal, investors
dumped bonds, driving up long-term interest rates.
This heightened sensitivity affects the way monetary policy
interacts with the economy. An overly expansionary monetary
policy, or even its anticipation, is imbedded fairly soon in higher
inflation expectations and nominal bond yields. A stimulative monetary policy can prompt a shortrun acceleration of economic activity. But the experience of the 1970's provided convincing evidence
that there is no lasting tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. In the long run, higher inflation buys no increase in employment.
This view of the capabilities of monetary policy is entirely consistent with the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. As you know, the act requires the Federal Reserve to "maintain long-run growth of the




14

monetary and credit aggregates, commensurate with the economy's
long-run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates/'
The goal of moderate long-term interest rates is particularly relevant in the current circumstances in which balance sheet constraints have been a major—if not the major—drag on the expansion. The halting but substantial declines in intermediate and longrun interest rates that have occurred over the past few years have
been the single most important factor encouraging balance sheet
restructuring by households and firms and fostering the very significant reductions in debt service burdens.
Although the easing actions over the past few years have been
purposefully gradual, cumulatively they have been quite large.
Short-term interest rates have been reduced since their 1989 peak
by nearly 7 percentage points.
Some have argued that monetary policy has been too cautious,
that rates should have been lowered more sharply, or in larger increments.
In my view, these arguments miss the crucial features of our current experience: the sensitivity of inflation expectations and the
necessity to work through structural imbalances in order to establish a basis for sustained growth. In these circumstances, monetary
policy clearly has a role to play in helping the economy to grow.
The process by which monetary policy can contribute, however, has
been different in some respects than in past business cycles. Lower
intermediate- and long-term interest rates and inflation are essential to the structural adjustments in our economy. Monetary policy,
thus, has given considerable weight to helping these rates move
lower.
Some have suggested that the decline in inflation permitted
more aggressive moves, and had the downward trajectory of shortterm interest rates been a bit steeper, that aggregate demand
would have been appreciably stronger. I question that as well.
Basing this argument on the lower inflation that has occurred is a
non sequitur. The disinflation very likely would not have occurred
in the context of an appreciably more stimulative policy, and such
a policy could have led to higher inflation in the next few years.
Moreover, such a policy would not have dealt fundamentally with
the very real imbalances in our economy that needed to be resolved
before sustainable growth could resume. The credibility of noninflationary policies would have been strained, and longer term interest rates likely would be higher, inhibiting the restructuring of balance sheets, and reducing the odds on sustainable growth.
Recent evidence suggests that pur approach to monetary policy
in recent years has been appropriate and productive. Even by last
July, when I presented our midyear report to the Congress, some
straws in the wind suggested that the easing of monetary policy to
that date and the various financial adjustments underway in the
economy were proving successful in paving the way for better economic performance.
It is now apparent that our July expectation of a firmer trajectory of output has been borne out. Gross domestic product growth is
estimated to have picked up to a SVk-percent rate during the




15

second half of 1992, following a more modest increase in the first
half. Indications are that the expansion is continuing in the early
months of 1993. The news on inflation in 1992, likewise, was quite
encouraging.
These favorable outcomes occurred despite slow growth of the
money and credit aggregates. Both of the monetary aggregates, M2
and M3, finished the year about one-half percentage point below
their ranges, and debt was just at its lower bound.
Interpreting this slow growth was one of the major challenges
faced by the Federal Reserve last year. You may recall that, in establishing the ranges in February and reviewing them in July, the
committee took note of the substantial uncertainties regarding the
relationships between income and money in 1992. As we moved
into 1992, there appeared to be an appreciable likelihood that unusual weakness in M2 growth relative to spending that had been
experienced in 1991 would continue.
In the event, the nominal gross domestic product was even
stronger, relative to the broad monetary aggregates in 1992 seemed
likely when their ranges were established.
What accounts for this unusual behavior? Why is it that our financial system was able to support 5l/2 percent growth in nominal
GDP, with only 2 percent growth in M2, and one-half percent
growth in M3? We cannot be entirely certain we have all of the
answers, but certain elements of our evolving financial picture,
which are detailed in the full testimony, clearly have played a
major role. A number of factors inducing savers to place funds outside M2, and borrowers to concentrate demands in long-term markets, have accelerated a longstanding process of channeling credit
flows outside of depository institutions. With reduced needs to fund
asset growth, banks and thrifts have bid less vigorously for deposits.
As a result of these developments, the relationship between
money and the economy may be undergoing a significant transformation. If this is true, the liabilities of depository institutions will
not be as good a gauge of financial conditions as they once were.
This is not to argue that money growth can be ignored in formulating monetary policy. The Federal Reserve in 1992 paid substantial attention to developments in the money supply, and we will
continue to do so in 1993 and beyond. Selecting ranges for monetary growth over the coming year consistent with desired economic
performance, however, is especially difficult when the relationship
between money and income has become uncertain.
Eventually, the monetary aggregates may resume a more stable
relationship with the economy, or experience may suggest useful
new definitions for the aggregates. In the meantime, the Federal
Open Market Committee necessarily has given less weight to monetary aggregates in the conduct of policy, and has relied on a broad
range of indicators of future financial and economic developments
and price pressures. In particular, the FOMC judged in 1992 that
more determined efforts to push the aggregates into their ranges
would not have been consistent with achieving the Nation's longer
term objectives of maximum sustainable economic growth.
This use of a broad range of indicators is appropriate because
achievement of the ranges of growth of particular measures of




16

money and credit is not, and should not be, the objective of monetary policy. Rather, the ranges are a means to an end. The Humphrey-Hawkins Act, incorporating this view, does not require that
the ranges be obtained in circumstances in which doing so would
not be consistent with achieving the more fundamental economic
objectives.
Mr. Chairman, in establishing the ranges for the monetary and
credit aggregates for the current year, the FOMC took into account
the likelihood that many of the factors that have acted in recent
years to restrain money and credit growth relative to income,
would continue, though perhaps with somewhat diminishing intensity.
The Federal Open Market Committee has elected to reduce the
ranges for M2 and M3 for 1993 by one-half percentage point. The
FOMC does not view the reductions in the monetary ranges as signaling a change in the stance of monetary policy. Most emphatically, these reductions do not indicate a desire on the part of the Federal Reserve to thwart the expansion. The Federal Reserve, to the
contrary, is endeavoring to conduct monetary policy in a way that
promotes sustainable economic expansion. The lowering of these
ranges does not imply any change in our fundamental objectives.
The necessity for a reduction in the monetary ranges at this time
is wholly technical in nature, and is the result of forces that are
altering the money income relationship.
Several of the forces affecting relationships between money and
income also complicate the task of assessing the economic outcome
itself. For example, the prospects for an easing of supply restrictions on credit from banks and other intermediaries are difficult to
assess; but any major change in this situation could have important implications for the economy.
While uncertainties remain, the economy appears to have entered the year with noticeable momentum to spending. In addition,
inventories are at relatively low levels, and factory orders have
been rising. Consumer confidence has recovered, and spending on
durables and homes appears to be moving at a brisker pace. Recent
surveys suggest an appreciable increase in business investment this
year.
Against this background, members of the Board and Federal Reserve Bank Presidents project a further gain in economic activity
in 1993, and inflation is expected to remain low.
As I have often emphasized, monetary policy, by achieving and
maintaining price stability, can foster a stable economic and financial environment that is conducive to private economic planning,
savings, investment, and economic growth.
The contributions that monetary policy can make to maximum
sustainable economic growth would be complemented by a fiscal
policy focused on long-term deficit reduction.
Mr. Chairman, as I indicated last week, the President is to be
commended for placing on the table a serious proposal that is activating debate on our burgeoning structural budget deficit.
Unless addressed, the deficit will increasingly threaten the stability of our economic system. Time is no longer on our side. After
declining through 1996, the current services deficit starts on an inexorable upward path again. The deficit and the mounting Federal




17

debt as a percent of gross domestic product are corrosive forces
slowly undermining the vitality of our free market system.
If we fail to resolve our structural deficit at this time, the next
opportunity will undoubtedly confront us with still more difficult
choices. How the deficit is reduced is very important, but that it be
done, is crucial.
With current services outlays from 1997 and beyond rising faster
than the tax base, stabilizing the deficit as a percent of nominal
gross domestic product, not to mention a reduction, would require
ever-increasing tax rates. This could undercut incentives for risk
taking, and inevitably dampen the long-term growth potential of
our economy.
Hence, there is no alternative to achieving much slower growth
of outlays. This implies not only the need to make cuts now, but to
control future spending impulses. I trust the President's endeavor
to rein in medical costs will contribute importantly to this goal.
The hope that we can possibly inflate or grow our way out of the
structural deficit is fanciful. Certainly, greater inflation is not the
answer. Aside from its serious debilitating effects on our economic
system, higher inflation, given the explicit and implicit indexing of
receipts and expenditures, would not reduce the deficit.
As I indicated in testimony last month to the Joint Economic
Committee, there is a possibility that productivity growth may be
moving into a faster long-term channel, boosting real growth over
time. Even if that turns out to be the case, it would not, by itself,
resolve the basic long-term imbalance in our budgetary Accounts.
Finally, I find misplaced the fears that some have expressed that
significant reductions in structural deficits will exert an insurmountable drag on the economy.
The Federal Reserve recognizes that it has an important role to
play in this regard. In formulating monetary policy, we certainly
need to take into account fiscal policy developments. However, it is
not possible, for the Federal Reserve to specify, in advance, what actions might be taken in the presence of particular fiscal policy
strategy.
Clearly, the course of interest rates and financial market conditions more generally will depend importantly on a host of forces, in
addition to fiscal policy, affecting the economy and prices. In any
event, I can assure you of our shared goal for the American economy: The greatest possible increase in living standards for our citizens over time.
Thank you very much. I would appreciate my full statement
being included for the record, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Without objection, it is so ordered.
[The prepared statement of Mr. Greenspan can be found in the
appendix.]
If I understand what you said, Mr. Greenspan, I think that you
are indicating that this administration finally is coming to grips
with the structural problems of our economy; that speed is of the
essence, however, that we put the plan in place. That is not necessarily that it be identical to what the President has suggested, but
along those lines, as long as we make the long-term commitment.
Is that, substantially, your position?




18

Mr. GREENSPAN. That is correct, Mr. Chairman. As I have indicated to your colleagues in the Senate Banking Committee, we at
the Federal Reserve, in our role as central bankers, have a fundamental interest in the financial stability of our system. As a necessary condition for that, the structural budget deficit must be
brought down.
Obviously, the process which you are currently going through is
extraordinarily difficult. It is fairly clear that this is quintessentially political in the best sense of the word. Because of that fact, we at
the Federal Reserve will, of course, step back and not be involved,
and should not be involved, in the decisions of how the budget deficit is brought down.
I did indicate in my remarks a number of general economic principles which I have enunciated before this subcommittee over the
years. They, in that sense, suggest certain limits of how the process
has to occur. It is more an arithmetical, technical evaluation.
Fundamentally, the choices are political. These are very difficult
choices which must be made because the budget will restructure
how the governmental resources of this country are distributed.
Obviously, how they are distributed, and to whom, have very important economic and political implications.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Greenspan, we, of course, have jurisdiction, on this subcommittee, over other areas. One of the areas
that we will be addressing early this year will be the Community
Development Bank concept, which I do not really look to go into
with you today.
The second area we will be addressing in the near future is the
creation of a secondary market for commercial business loans to
help protect business slumps. I am particularly struck with the
lack of credit in our system today. Some people call it the credit
crunch. I am not quite certain why it exists.
I talk to bankers all over the country, and they are awash with
money. Their .answer, generally, is they want to lend money out,
but they cannot find responsible borrowers. Then, I run into businessmen that are saying they are being choked off, that they are
not being given the type of credit that is necessary to even sustain
their operations, let alone expand them.
I would like your opinion, on this apparent contradiction. If
there is fault to be had, is it with the regulators, is it with the
bankers; or is it possible that with the lack of a secondary market
in business slumps, that it is less advantageous for the commercial
banking community to engage in business lending today, than it is
for residential lending, or school lending, or anywhere else that
there is a secondary market?
Mr. GREENSPAN. As I think I may have—and probably have—indicated before this subcommittee over the last 2 or 3 years, what
we are confronted with is an extraordinary circumstance which is
a consequence of the very heavy lending that was engaged in by
bankers in the 1980's and, very obviously, owing to lax underwriting standards, we ended up with a very large amount of nonperforming loans. This cut very severely into the capital positions of
commercial banks, threatened the franchise of the institutions,
and, frankly, frightened an awful lot of lending officers who had




19

not been aware of the extent of what could happen when they lent
in the manner in which they lent for a goodly part of the 1980's.
As a consequence of that, it should not be surprising that they
have pulled back and, in my judgment, overly so, in that they exaggerated in one direction and now they have exaggerated in the
other. So what has occurred is that we have seen a very stringent
set of conditions for lending, which has been characterized as fairly
tight.
We run a number of surveys, periodically. While we have picked
up some very mild degree of easing of some of the standards by the
bank, there is no question that they are still fairly rigid, and the
term "credit crunch" is, in my judgment, still appropriately applicable to the process.
An element which has clearly been a problem has been the dramatic decline in commercial real estate values, which were the collateral of a substantial part of the loan expansion of commercial
banks in recent years.
It would not be the type of problem it is today if the value of real
estate had come down dramatically, but the transactions had continued and the markets had been liquid, and as a consequence of
that, the average banker, even though he knew he had considerable loss on his real estate collateral, would nonetheless know that
if he had to he could sell at a known price expeditiously in the
market. Therefore he, or she, would know what the value of the
loan that he had made is to the bank.
Regrettably, we have not yet reached that stage. What I mean by
that is, while the values have clearly declined in the commercial
real estate market, we still do not have the liquidity or the turnover and the transactions that are required to give confidence to
lending officers about the values of the collateral that now exists in
their banks. As a result of that, there is a very great deal of uncertainty about whether they have really solid resources. They, therefore, are being extremely conservative.
There is no question in my mind that if we could find a way to
expedite the secondary market in small business loans, it would be
very helpful because, as I think you pointed out in your opening
remarks, it is the small businesses who have no alternative to
credit financing.
As a consequence of that, the credit crunch that we have perceived is disproportionately impacting on small businesses. Since
they, historically, are the source of employment growth, it has been
one of the key factors as to why we have had a sluggish recovery in
employment.
The feasibility of creating a secondary market in small business
loans is something which I think we ought to be looking into.
There is a bill that is being offered in the Senate to change some of
the legal impediments to the securitization of small business loans.
If we could find a way to make them homogeneous the way, for example, one- to four-family mortgages are, that would clearly facilitate the expansion of the securitization and the secondary market
in small business loans.
You are quite correct. It is easier to make a mortgage loan, because you can securitize it and sell it, than a small business loan,




20

which is, by its nature, different. This is because each business loan
has a certain characteristic reflecting the individuals.
So I certainly subscribe to anything that we can do that would
improve the homogeneity of the small business loan, and it is securitization, because there is no question that that would be a
major contribution to the financial vitality of this country.
Chairman KANJORSKI. That sounds very good, Mr. Chairman.
That is our major goal of this subcommittee this year. We look forward to working with you and the Federal Reserve. Getting your
assistance and help, we can create that secondary market.
Mr. Nussle.
Mr. NUSSLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
First of all, I would like to respond, very briefly, to some of the
opening comments that were made.
As far as the "put up or shut up" on the specific cuts, the Republicans have put up 12 years of specific cuts, and now it is your turn.
I still have not seen the specific cuts from the President. Until we
do that, I do not think it is responsible to say, "Put up or shut up."
My understanding is, those specific cuts that are now in just
vague generalities are not going to be available now until March
23. So until those specifics come down, I do not think it is responsible to say, "Put up or shut up."
As far as the spending cuts that are in the plan that we know of,
the generalities that are available to the press and to those of us
that are Members who have to try and work through the plan, we
understand that there may be some double counting; in other
words, that there were $123 billion worth of cuts that were actually
in the 1990 budget agreement, and have been double counted for
purposes of this new proposal. That was what came out in testimony at the Senate.
We understand that part of the cuts—maybe as many as half—
are really increases in user fees, and have nothing to do with
actual cuts in spending, or actual reductions in program baselines.
We understand that many of these cuts that have been made are
really illusory, and really not available to actually reduce the size
of the budget deficit.
This concerns me. It also concerns me that as such, the New
York Times would state—and I think it is putting words in your
mouth—in a headline last week, February 20, "Clinton's program
gets endorsement of the Fed Chairman."
Now I listened to your testimony, and I have read this news article. I never once heard you, Mr. Chairman, use the word "endorsement." I have heard you say, "It is serious." I have heard you say,
"It is credible."
I never once heard you come out and say, "This is the plan that I
would have introduced if I had the opportunity;" or, "I fully put
my stamp of approval behind this plan. This is my full endorsement as the Fed Chairman." I did not get that at all.
I got that—as I am—you are concerned about the budget deficit,
and concerned about trying to bring down spending. You are happy
that at least we have a start. That was the impression I got. However, fully endorsing this plan, saying that you have gone through
it, and this is the best thing we can have at this time—I did not get
that impression.




21

So I would like to give you the opportunity to maybe rewrite the
headline. [Laughter.]
I know that is not your job. However, I would like to find out
exactly what your position is on this plan. Do you fully endorse
this plan? Is everything in there exactly what this economy needs
right now in its history?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, as I said just a few moments ago,
we at the Federal Reserve, myself and my colleagues, are not going
to enter into the discussions on the specific details of how the
budget deficit is reduced. It is our purpose to indicate to the Congress how important the activity is, and that there is time urgency
about this.
Up to, say, maybe a year or two ago, we used to look at the
longer term budget projections, and they invariably went down to
zero, as far as the deficit is concerned, and even into surplus. What
is different about the current period is owing to the change in the
structure of the longer term deficit, it no longer does that.
As the defense decline comes to an end, and as the savings and
loan monies unwind, then what we find is an inexorable rise in the
deficit which is engendered by the laws which currently exist. One
may even go further and say that that problem exists with the expectation that the Congress and the administration will add nothing to that. Now, I would say to you that history suggests that that
assumption has some difficulties with it. I would want to impress
upon you that where our interests lie is in the total borrowing requirements of the Treasury. It is inappropriate for us to get involved into the specific details of the budget document because, as I
said earlier, that is the appropriate political decisionmaking of the
representatives of the American people.
Mr. NUSSLE. Well, Mr. Chairman, if you had a plan before you,
or if a plan was presented to you similar to—and I am not sure if
you are familiar with this plan or not—Gramm-Armey, which is a
plan that was introduced just this last week, which proposes not to
raise taxes, but, in fact, to cut spending and to have strict enforcement mechanisms within the plan; one that allows or actually demands the reauthorization of programs and policies. I think it is a
triannual basis. It actually goes into permanent changes of the
budgeting process.
If you had a plan before you that did the same thing, or actually
projected out and could demonstrate to you, through just cuts and
spending—not increases in taxes, but cuts and spending—that it
could do the same thing or better, would it receive the same kind
of headline as possibly being endorsed, or being serious or credible?
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is the important issue. The question is, to
be serious and credible, it has got to be very specific, line by line.
General goals, as we know, do not work.
Mr. NUSSLE. I just want to make sure. You do not have to raise
taxes, in your mind, to be serious and credible?
Mr. GREENSPAN. As I have said to a question raised by Senator
Kerry at the Senate Banking Committee, who asked me whether,
in fact, the reduction in the deficit required taxes, I said, "It did
not."
Mr. NUSSLE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate that.




22

Chairman KANJORSKI. The headline should read, "Greenspan declares specificity of Clinton plan, above all others/'
Mr. NUSSLE. You may have a new career, Mr. Chairman. That is
pretty good. [Laughter.]
Chairman KANJORSKI. Well, it is always tempting to write headlines. I hope that the subcommittee does not engage in writing any
more headlines, and that we take the benefit of the Chairman's testimony here to get serious testimony and make the atmosphere less
politicized, if we can.
Mr. McCollum, I apologize. I should have recognized you next,
but I am going to take you out of order.
Mr. McCoLLUM. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I certainly thought Mr. Nussle's questions were very appropriate,
with respect to the question of clarifying, perhaps, for the headline
writers.
I have one area of question in relationship to that, and then I
want to ask you some very serious monetary policy questions.
In looking at this Clinton proposal, Mr. Chairman, it appears
that most analysts are concluding that the amount of taxes that
are being raised in this proposal over the 4- or 5-year period versus
spending cuts is a ratio of about 5 to 1—5 times as much taxes as
spending cuts. It depends upon, again, your interpretation, but it
certainly looks like this is the largest tax increase in history in dollars—the $328 billion.
Is there a point—and, again, I am not asking you to criticize or
critique Mr. Clinton's proposal—but is there a point where we can
go, as a body, on the fiscal side, too heavily on the tax increase proportion in relation to spending reductions where it will damage the
economy and hurt your job? I do not know whether this is true in
this case or not; but in principle, is there a point where we could be
imbalanced by overemphasizing the tax increase side as a body?
Mr. GREENSPAN. In principle, the argument is, yes, one can. The
trouble is that we do not know where that number is; but, obviously, as I think most everyone has acknowledged, nobody likes taxes.
They are, of necessity, types of instruments which do dampen economic activity. I mean, there is no way in which I can conceive of a
tax, except in certain very extraordinary circumstances, where it
does not, by itself, have a negative effect.
The question that the Congress has to confront at this stage is
the issue of getting the structural budget deficit down. What one
very clearly senses by the debate that is emerging at this stage is
that there are very great differences on this issue.
If I knew that there was very strong evidence that says at a certain point of taxation, you do considerable damage to the economy,
I would certainly cite the reference.
The trouble is, we economists have not been able to come to a
specific conclusion although there is a very general belief that if
you undercut incentives, and if you put too much taxation on the
system, it is bound to dampen growth, and, at the extreme, create
very destabilizing forces.
Mr. McCoLLUM. I believe I have heard you say in the past, and I
think you were quoted last week as saying, in response to a Senate
question, if you had your personal preference, you would prefer
spending reductions to tax increases.




23

Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, no, I did not put it as a personal issue. I
put it as an issue of how one should look at the process, analytically if our fundamental purpose is to get the budget deficit down.
What I said to the Senate was that it is easier to do that from the
expenditure side than from the tax side. What I was saying then
was that expenditure cuts tend to have a more permanent impact
on the deficit than increases on the revenue side; but, as I also
said, the composition is partly an economic question but more fundamentally a political question with respect to how resources are
distributed through the budget process.
Mr. McCoLLUM. I understand, and I appreciate that. Rather than
torture you with those type of questions, I want to ask you a monetary policy-specific question. Should we include in the monetary aggregates the stock and bond mutual funds that are not now counted? Is that something you are considering?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. McCollum, we have looked at that in some
detail, obviously, in endeavoring to understand what has happened
to M2 and it is very obvious that one can trace funds basically held
in so-called M2 deposits, moving directly into mutual funds. However, it is not just a simple question of looking at what has happened recently. There is a question of how do those data or those
indicators behave over history, as an indication of economic activity and spending. We are looking at that, as we are looking at a
number of other things. It is by no means obvious that that is
something which we would grab onto and say this is a much better
indicator than other elements in the economic system.
Mr. McCoLLUM. It is too early to tell right now?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would think it is, yes.
Mr. McCoLLUM. Well, to wrap up—my time is running out very
rapidly already. It probably technically has. I would like to know
what those other range of indicators are, if you would just one, two,
three, summarize them, that you look at. You have alluded to
them. I have heard you say some of them in the past, but I think
they should be on the record here. They are not specifically in your
testimony that I see.
Mr. GREENSPAN. What are the other indicators we would look at?
Mr. McCoLLUM. Yes. Besides the aggregates, right.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes, let me be more general, Congressman. We,
as you know, have a number of econometric models which, through
complex mathematical relations, try to infer what the economy is
going to do in the future under certain circumstances, depending
on what it has done in the past. The problem we have is that, in
recent years, the economy—its structure, that set of relationships
which drive it—is clearly changing, and hence to rely on the past
solely has not been a useful indicator of what is going on.
Nonetheless, in order to formulate monetary policy, it is essential that we have a concept of what causes what to happen. My discussions, over the last 2 or 3 years about how the balance sheet effects have impacted on economic activity, the allusion that I have
often made to much earlier periods in American history where we
saw asset values rise, followed by debt financing, followed then by
a decline in assets and balance sheet restraints, is the type of evaluation we make. As a consequence of that, and as I have mentioned before this subcommittee in the past, we now think in this




24

particular environment, that the major driving force of a positive
nature is lower intermediate- and long-term interest rates because,
very specifically, of the nature of the real estate markets, the
nature of the balance sheets, and the like. As a consequence, we
would look at that very closely, as well as the credit aggregates,
and all of the other elements in the system which drive this type of
phenomenon.
Mr. McCoLLUM. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Neal.
Mr. NEAL OF NORTH CAROLINA. Thank you, sir.
Along those lines, Mr. Chairman, since we know that we can
maximize sustainable employment and growth through lower inflation, and lower interest rates, and, since we know that the only
way to get long-term rates down, in a sustainable way, is to get inflation down, my question is, why wouldn't you want then to bring
down your target range for money growth? I believe you said that
even that one-half a percent drop that you have set as your target
range is really—I think you called it a technical change, as opposed
to a policy shift.
Mr. GREENSPAN. That's correct.
Mr. NEAL OF NORTH CAROLINA. I am just wondering why you
would not want to make a little bit of a policy shift and help us
achieve these great benefits a little bit sooner. May I ask you to do
me a favor? I have one other question I want to ask you before the
time runs out. So, if you would give me not the complete answer,
but a summary of the complete answer.
Mr. GREENSPAN. The basic reasons why we moved the targets
down for technical reasons is largely that, obviously, M2 has veered
off its course, and we are trying to capture it. The reason we would
not do it for policy reasons at this stage is that we are not sure
what the proper relationships are. It is also clear that because of
the fact that a noninflationary environment, or one of stable prices
if you want to put it that way, basically is probably consistent with
a measured inflation rate of the Consumer Price Index higher than
zero. For reasons we have discussed in the past, we tend to mismeasure the degree of inflation. In a certain sense, as the inflation
rate has come down, we are not now all that far from our ultimate
goal where we think price stability is; but, until we have a much
better sense of what it is that is happening in M2, and what it is
that is happening in the other aggregates, I dp not think that other
than technical changes at this particular point are called for. We
may find when all of the data work their way through that we are
pleased with the stance of credit policy. I do not know that to be
the case. I am saying that will require us to have a much better
sense of how M2 is evolving, whether its behavior is going to be a
real long-term problem, and the like.
Mr. NEAL OF NORTH CAROLINA. Thanks. I know we have had
these changes that we do not fully understand. I thank you.
The other question really has to do with what you think about
the strength of our economy now. I know, over the last several
years, there have been several of what appeared to be spurts,
maybe brief spurts in the economy that proved to be short lived. It
seems to me, and just looking at what other experts are saying and
so on, that now we might be on a course that is fairly sustainable—




25

a healthy recovery that, even though not booming, in fact, it is
probably good it is not booming—that we are on a course that
could be sustainable over a long period of time—of healthy growth,
job-creating growth. If that were the case, then that might be an
argument for not spending some of the money that has been considered to be necessary for stimulus. If that were possible, there
would be an opportunity to save a little money.
Now, the question obviously would be, are we on that kind of
path with the economy, in your opinion? We certainly would not
want to do something that is going to cost more in the long haul. I
think the argument of the administration here is that by giving a
little stimulus, that we ward off the possibility of a dip in the economy later that will end up costing us more—that this is a cost-benefit ratio—the stimulus now would be positive. What would you say
about that?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is clear that if you look at the last two quarters of 1992 the data show important improvements. The third
quarter, as I recall, was up 3.4 percent at an annual rate, and the
fourth quarter, I assume, will be revised up from its 3.8 percent
rate. The data will be available I believe at the end of this week. Is
that right? Yes.
The first quarter level is running at a somewhat slower pace, as
best we can judge, from the upward revised—I would say assumedly upward revised—fourth quarter number, but it is moving at a
reasonably good pace.
The problem, however, in saying that this is a sustainable recovery and all of the wheels are running correctly, is that it would require that the problems that the chairman raised at the beginning
have been resolved. So long as we have the process of balance sheet
restructuring continuing, so long as we have a continuation of the
problems that exist within the commercial banks, especially with
respect to small business loans, and so long as we have the continued downward adjustment of the defense industries, which has
very significant impact across the country, it is too soon to say that
we are, in a sense, moving forward in a self-perpetuating recovery.
Having said that, Congressman, there is no question that the improvement in productivity which has been quite extraordinary and
which I suspect is probably related to the low level of inflation we
are looking at, is very important to this outlook.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. LaFalce.
Mr. LAFALCE. Chairman Greenspan, I always find your testimony stimulating and insightful, and today certainly was no exception. I think it would also be instructive and insightful for us to
listen to another wise individual, Pogo, who has said "we have met
the enemy and it is us."
I think that so many of the problems that we are visiting today
have been self-induced. I am thinking of the credit crunch, for example. I remember when I started predicting the credit crunch in
1989, saying we were beginning to experience it in 1990. I had difficulty getting either the Federal Reserve or the administration to
recognize that reality. I go back to the 1989 law, FIRREA, which
was quite a spectacle in 1989, where you had an administration
and a Congress each trying to work with the media to prove which




26

was tougher. Reason was thrown out the window. There was one
purpose and mission in life, you know, prove that you are tough.
I remember when the administration came in with a 10-year amortization period for good will, despite the fact you might have had
an agreement for 20, 30, 40 years. I called representatives from the
administration in. I said that is too tough. That is too precipitous of
a change. They said, you know, we think you are right. We might
have to ease up on that a bit. Of course, then the administration
and the Congress chipped in to go down to a 5-year period. That
was just one small example. The application that we made of the
Basel accords, not just to commercial institutions, but to thrift institutions, when you had a decidedly different history of our institutions, the underemphasis in the early and mid-1980's on capital,
and then an appropriate emphasis, but not to the exclusion of all
other factors on capital precipitously in 1989, especially since we
were using risk-based capital, and the definition of risk-based capital, under the Basel standards, did not consider interest rate sensitivity, helped to create an incentive to go to government securities,
as opposed to commercial loans as a means of satisfying these requirements.
The hearings that we held where we excoriated regulators and
examiners, we indicted them, we tried them, we convicted, we sentenced them, and then we asked them to come in to testify, after
all that had taken place, the chilling effect that that had. Not only
the creation of the ETC to buy as many commercial assets that you
conceivably could, the largest financial institution in the world; but
the hearings we had, constantly asking the regulators how many
institutions have you closed today? That became the watchword—
the number of institutions you closed, as opposed to the number
that you were helping to resolve, to make better, to heal.
I hope we understand certain lessons, rather than just think that
there are a bunch of bad guys out there—that the Congress and
the administration itself, and the regulators may have contributed
to this.
I was very pleased—working for years—I was very pleased when
President Clinton at least put a sentence or two dealing with the
possibility of excessive regulation, how necessary it is to have regulation, and solid regulation; but it can go too far. too. We had 1 million applause lines. That was not an applause line. I think I was
about the only one applauding at that one. We need tough regulations, but not too tough, not too tough. We can frighten the examiners, frighten the financial institutions, the loan officers, and so
forth. We have to have safety and soundness of institutions, but we
have to also spur the economy. We have to strike a balance. We
could have the safest and soundest banks in the world, we just will
not make any loans. We would make a lot of money to put it into
government securities.
I am curious too. This is an argument. Are they putting too
much into government securities? I tend to think they are. They
come back and they say, oh no, they are not, if you look at it historically 20 years ago; but 20 years ago, all of the money was in
banks, it was not in the Merrill Lynches, and the Dean Whitters of
this world, and so forth. That is one question I have for you.




27

Another question I have is on the Basel accords. Do we need
some change in the standards we use for determining risk-based
capital? How do we take into consideration interest rate sensitivity? Is there a problem in getting from here to there, because of the
extent to which we rely upon this high percentage of monies in
government securities as a means of financing our deficit? Is there
a transition period that will be needed if we are going to make any
change in those standards?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, let me say, first, I generally agree with
most of what you said, as I am sure you know.
Mr. LAFALCE. OK.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I will stipulate that.
Mr. LAFALCE. OK.
Mr. GREENSPAN. I think, perhaps, I should have mentioned it
with respect to Chairman Kanjorski's question earlier. There is a
problem of regulatory cost that is involved in this process which is
inhibiting small business loans, very specifically what we used to
call character loans, where you could basically make a loan to an
individual of a modest amount on your knowledge of the individual, with full expectation of it being repaid, without going through
a number of formal documents, without collateral,
without appraisals, without various different things which nowr make a number of
those loans prohibitively costly. As a consequence, we do not see
them anymore. This is the direction of the excess that you are
mentioning.
We have looked into the question of the securities holdings of
commercial banks in some considerable detail to see if we can infer
what the various motives are. While there is a small amount of evidence to suggest that the Basel accord differences do make some
slight difference, the overwhelming reason that we can infer as to
why they are holding these securities is basically that they have no
loans that they feel they can make in a manner which is profitable
to them, for reasons which I mentioned earlier. In that regard, I
would suspect that the availability of this extraordinary amount of
liquidity which exists in the system is reason to believe that when
finally the dam is broken, and they no longer are concerned about
the losses and they are more worried about competitive positions as
bankers, that they have more than adequate liquidity to essentially
service the loan community. I hope, under those conditions, we will
see this psychological problem unwinding.
Mr. LAFALCE. You mentioned tremendous liquidity, and yet you
also posited, at the beginning of your testimony, a real credit
crunch, a slight easing, but, still, a real credit crunch despite this
liquidity. So, obviously, you have a quarrel with the simple explanation that there are good loans out there, otherwise you would
not posit a credit crunch. Reconciling those two competing arguments is sometimes difficult.
My last question. Go to the secondary market. I have introduced
legislation for 10 years now, to help facilitate the development of a
secondary market, first, as chairman of this subcommittee, and
then as chairman of the Small Business Committee. There is a
debate on a number of issues I should say. Can we do it simply by
changing laws to facilitate securitization of small business loans, or
will the needed homogenization of small business loans, a very dif-




28

ficult thing, require some government jump-start, through either
the creation of a new government-sponsored enterprise, or, as I
have introduced, or as I know Paul is thinking, the amendment of
the charter of an existing governmental-sponsored enterprise, to
enable them to do not only residential mortgages, but small business loans?
I tend to think some jump-start is necessary—that you cannot do
it, given the tremendous disparity that exists amongst commercial
loans, without that governmental involvement.
I am also curious though too—I do not think it is going to bring
additional liquidity. We do not seem to need additional liquidity. I
mean, that will bring it, but that is not our big need. One of the
biggest values of the small business community is that it will avail
him of long-term loans, something that is not now available to the
small business community; but it also has some downsides too. The
standardization of the loans might make character loans when this
dam does break a little more difficult, too. I would want to develop
a secondary market, but I do not want to develop a secondary
market that is going to have a perverse, unintended consequence.
That is a trick, if it can be accomplished. I would seek your insights on these issues that I have raised.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, we want to be a little careful
about extending the federally sponsored credit agency type of organization because there is this never-never land as to whether or not
they are federally insured or not federally insured. That is a problem which we ought to be backing away from. As a consequence,
when and if you look at solutions, increasing the contingent liabilities of the Federal Government is something I think we have to be
very careful to avoid.
There are lots of problems in the construction of securitization of
small business loans, which I suspect appropriate legislative vehicles can possibly eliminate. I do not know enough about some of
the detailed legal aspects at this particular stage, but I am aware
that we did facilitate the secondary markets in mortgages by certain legal changes which inhibited the form in which these securities could be issued. So, as a minimum, we want to make certain
that the legal playing field, if I may put it that way, is clearly in
this direction.
When you get to the other issues, then we have to get to the far
more detailed question of how small business is financed, where
the bottlenecks are, and whether those bottlenecks are temporary
or of a more permanent nature. If they are temporary, which is
what I suspect they are, if we could get the character loan back
into the mix, then I do not suspect we will need to go for any longterm solution. But, if we have essentially eliminated a significant
part of small business lending through the regulatory area, which I
think in part we have done, then some additional avenues will
have to be explored.
Mr. LAFALCE. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mrs. Roukema.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I welcome you here
today.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.




29

Mrs. ROUKEMA. I want to associate myself with the remarks
made earlier by our colleague, Mr. Schumer, when he pointed out
that he was opposed to any attempts to politicize or compromise
the positions, or restrict the position of the Fed, vis-a-vis either political parties or the Congress, and I stand with him on that.
However, without compromising your position, I do want to press
you a little bit further, not to the point of writing a headline, but I
do want to press you a little further here on this subject of the
package that we are facing, this so-called deficit reduction share of
pain, share of the sacrifice program. I am pressing you because I
think it is the obligation of people in your position, and certainly
the business community, and other economists to give us an assessment in the best possible way, because we are going to have extraordinary decisions to make here. It is not a question of whether
you reduce spending, or increase taxes, it is the package that we
have put together. Another element that I find that has not been
really focused upon is the relative position of what I call capital
investment incentives in this package, which I think are woefully
lacking.
I would like to ask you, if you would, please give us a relative
value scale here as to the position of the tax increases; evaluate the
capital investment, whether it be the ITC or the capital gains approach, because I think it is woefully lacking, and maybe I am
wrong. I would just like to know your opinion on that. Most specifically, I find it very disturbing that the President would be leading
off with new spending programs when we have not gotten the ability to pay for what we have, and when you are even speaking about
reining in medical costs. I mean, that would be the most extraordinary thing that we would be able to do without being accused of
balancing the budget on the backs of the sick elderly.
There are human capital and social spending proposals here that
I think should be put on hold, unless and until we get some evidence of structural deficit reduction. I am not talking about the infrastructure, or the waste water treatment programs, that part of
the stimulus, I am talking about what are clearly new social entitlement programs that are being recommended, and the human
capital investment which I think, proportionately speaking, is
much too great in this package.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congresswoman, the only response I can give is
that, if I were a private economist, a private citizen, I would unquestionably be giving you the answers that you request, as indeed
I did when I was a private citizen and appeared before this subcommittee.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. Yes, you certainly did. We did not listen to you,
did we, Mr. Chairman, unfortunately?
Mr. GREENSPAN. All I can say to you is that I do not think it is
appropriate for the central bank to be involved in this particular
set of decisions. I would regrettably request that you seek responses
from private economists who can be of considerable assistance. As I
have said in the past to the Ways and Means Committee, and other
committees of the Congress, I personally think that the capital
gains tax ought to be lowered, but that is not relevant to this.
Indeed, I went even further. I said I do not think the capital gains
tax is a desirable tax instrument to raise revenue, because I do not

64-740 0 - 9 3



30

think the negative effects that it has is something that I would consider to be—in a cost-benefit analysis—something that should be on
the table.
This is something which really is not quite related to this whole
package. That is independent of the budget deficit reduction question which is a much broader and much more complex issue, as far
as I see it.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. Mr. Chairman, are you suggesting that, as part
of this—well, let me put it this way. I believe that one of our goals,
our primary goal in reducing the deficit was to develop more facility for capital investment—make capital more available. You are
suggesting that we should do that, absent a package that has a corollary to it, which is tax programs that would develop capital investment as a corollary to deficit reduction?
Mr. GREENSPAN. What I am basically saying is I do not want to
comment on the specific elements of the package that I am very
hopeful this Congress develops to finally confront an issue which
has been simmering for a very long period of time. There are a
number of other elements involved in tax policy which do not
relate to the budget deficit question.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. Well, all right. If you do not want to go further
than that, would you be free to give a relative value to the concept
of no new spending programs, unless and until there is progress on
the structural deficit demonstrated?
Mr. GREENSPAN. That is getting involved in this detail, and I personally regret I cannot be responsible—I would love to be involved
in this debate, but I just do not think it is appropriate for the Federal Reserve to be involved in it.
Mrs. ROUKEMA. Well, I am sorry for that, because I am fearful,
and I hope I am wrong. I have been here 12 years, and I have
never yet seen a deficit package proposal, including the well-intended Gramm-Rudman enforcement mechanism ever yet result in
reductions here. I am fearful that Congress is going to work itself
into a lather over this, maybe come up with the same gridlock, or a
simplistic or a symbolic deficit reduction that we find in a few
years is not doing the job. Unless we have strong leadership from
some independent sources, particularly the business community
and the economics community, and since you were willing to talk
about reining in medical costs, I thought you might be willing to go
out a little further on some of the other areas. I respect your decision, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Klein.
Mr. KLEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First of all, Chairman
Greenspan, I wanted to tell you that I share with you your feeling
that it is absolutely critical that we make real, meaningful, serious
cuts in the budget deficit. To you, my colleague from New Jersey,
on the other side of the aisle, you have been here 12 years, I have
only been here 6 or 7 weeks, but I can tell you there are 65 new
Members on this side of the aisle who really mean business, and
are going to do something in a very serious way about structural
budget deficit reduction.
I would like to turn to the question of credit—the credit crunch.
I think that your efforts, Chairman Greenspan, with respect to




31

monetary policy, have been commendable, and indeed have been
extremely helpful. It does seem to me that the monetary policy
alone does not ease completely the credit crunch. I was wondering
if you have any thoughts as to whether incentives to the banking
community are an appropriate way of stimulating lending? I hear
so often from members of the banking community that one of the
big reasons that they are not lending is because they can make a
very handsome profit simply by investing in government securities
and, therefore, there is not a great deal of incentive for them to go
out and make loans that are of a marginal nature, or the character
loans that you have talked about. Can we provide them with some
incentives so that they will once again get into this market?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Klein, we at the Federal Reserve are in discussions with our colleagues at the Treasury Department in trying
to confront precisely this question, and to review the experience we
have had in recent years. Remember, we have tried a number of
different vehicles which have not been very successful. We want to
see whether we now are in a position to find newer ways to break
the back of this credit crunch which I certainly agree with you is a
crucial element. I hope that we will have something useful forthcoming reasonably soon.
Mr. KLEIN. Second, you commented about the regulatory problems affecting the credit crunch. Do you have any specific suggestions as to how we might ease the regulatory situation so as to
make it easier to make the kind of character loans that you have
talked about?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes. That is the type of thing we are discussing
with the Treasury. It obviously would require, in certain instances,
changed statutes as well as changed regulations. We have not decided which is which at this particular stage. There is no question
that the costs of making a loan have risen very dramatically. That,
to a large extent, is partly the regulatory burden which has increased so substantially in recent years. Nonetheless, we do recognize that there is a need to maintain a degree of supervision and
regulation to maintain the safety and soundness of the institutions.
I believe it was Congressman LaFalce who talked about the issue of
appropriate balance—and it is in that context that we are coming
at this issue.
Mr. KLEIN. Thank you very much.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. King.
Mr. KING. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, just to put it on the record, I want to associate myself with the remarks of Mr. Schumer and Mrs. Roukema;
regarding any attempt to politicize the Fed, I am totally opposed to
any attempt of that nature.
Second, I also want to endorse your remarks about the need for
deregulation in the banking industry. I think it is very important.
Now, having said that, in your statement, you say that it would
be fanciful to say that we could grow our way out of a deficit. On
the other hand, I believe, to achieve real long-term deficit reduction, we have to ensure some element of long-term solid growth.
Now, if I could just make this point which may seem somewhat
parochial, but hopefully, is pertinent to the Nation. My district on
Long Island is in Nassau County. Nassau and Suffolk Counties




32

comprise almost 3 million people. Over the past 5 years, both of
those counties, under both democratic and republican administrations, have been devastated by the economy. One reason was the
loss of jobs due to the cutback at Grumman; second, a tremendous
loss of jobs because of the 1987 Wall Street crash. As a result of
that, both counties went literally to the verge of bankruptcy,
almost reaching junk bond status by Moody's and Standard and
Poors. I should emphasize, that was not so much because of government spending at the local level, it is because sales tax revenues
were just not coming in because of the tremendous business reverses on Long Island.
Now, from talking to the county executives, from talking to the
banking industry, from speaking to the business community, it appears that businesses on Long Island are very much the way you
describe the national economy on page 20 of your testimony. There
has been a recent momentum in spending. Christmas sales were
almost at record heights, inventories are at very low levels. Consumer confidence is recovering. They are anticipating a steady
growth over the next 2 to 3 years.
I am asking what impact are these new taxes going to have on
these businesses that are just on the verge or recovering? Specifically, we are talking about increasing the marginal rates drastically. We are talking about increasing corporate rates. Also, the
energy tax is going to be particularly damaging on Long Island. I
understand the estimates are it is going to cost families more than
$300 a year. That has to affect sales. That has to affect consumer
spending. It has to have an effect on business.
So, I would just really ask you a series of questions with that as
the backdrop. One, Chairman Greenspan, has there ever been an
instance in our history where tax increases have brought us put of
business downturn, or out of a faltering economy? Specifically,
whether it is Hoover in 1931 or Bush in 1990, it appears raising
taxes at critical stages has just caused a further downturn.
Second, in your testimony, you referred to—that tax increases at
a certain level could bring about considerable damage. I am asking,
are we at a stage now where we can afford any damage to the business cycle? Would any damage, no matter how small, also be considerable? I would just ask you that, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. What the Congress is confronted with, Congressman, is the extraordinary dilemma, as I indicated in my comments,
that how the budget deficit is brought down matters a good deal,
but that it be brought down is crucial.
The problem that one confronts in this sort of environment of
trying to come to a political decision is that, if no conclusions are
reached that can achieve a majority in both Houses, and we fall
back on not solving this problem, that is the worst of all possible
outcomes. If you are asking me, in the process of trying to solve
this, whether taxes can be put on with impunity, the answer is, I
do not know of any economist who would say that. Clearly, taxes,
by their very nature, do restrain. The issue, however, is a more
general one as to how does one sort out this whole question? How
does one put it all together in a manner in which we can get the
budget deficit down in a way which does not undercut the underlying efficacy of the incentive structure of our economy and the basic




33

recovery that is underway? That is a very difficult problem that if
we continue to procrastinate and not confront is only going to get
worse.
So, my major focus in this morning's testimony is to try to emphasize how crucially important it is, and how significant it is to
the long-term outlook of this economy that this deficit issue be confronted very quickly. We no longer have the luxury to stretch out
the discussions and various different policy initiatives. We have to
come to grips with this issue because the arithmetic is just overwhelming—with the inexorable turn of the calendar, we are going
to be confronted with some very serious financial difficulties, as a
consequence of a budget deficit which begins to accelerate.
Mr. KING. Can I have just one followup question, Mr. Chairman?
Chairman KANJORSKI. We have a vote on.
Mr. KING. OK.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I wanted to get Mr. Fingerhut though.
Mr. KING. OK. That is fine. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Fingerhut.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I will try and be
brief. I, being the first one to speak after your last answer, Chairman Greenspan, I just have to say how much I agree with you that
the principal objective here has got to be to do something, and that
the worst thing that we could do about the budget deficit is to do
nothing. One cannot help but sit here and listen, and think what
the public is thinking back home when they listen to the back and
forth between the opposite sides of the aisle that there is a growing
fear and a growing sense that we may indeed gridlock and do nothing.
We have a President who has put his plan out. He has been duly
elected by the American people. Clearly, his preferences are
known. That sets the terms of the debate. I just feel very strongly
that your statement is right, that we must do something.
Let me ask a couple of brief questions to follow up on some earlier points you made, if I can. A couple of times, in response to the
subject of the credit crunch, which you have said has impacts on
small business disproportionately, you referenced the subject of
character loans. One of the things I am concerned about is that the
ability to give character loans is not only related to the regulatory
structure of the banking system, but also to the ability of a banker
to know the individuals on a personal basis. What we are increasingly seeing is the decline in local banks, and small communitybased banks, and the increase in these decisions being made at centralized locations, hundreds of miles away from our communities.
Would you care to comment on what we could do, not only through
the regulatory structure, but through other ways to make sure that
our bankers know my small businessmen in my community?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, if we change the regulatory structure so that character loans can again be made, it then gives an
incentive to those individuals who know the people in the business
community to either form smaller banks, or to take branches of
other banks and literally make them profitable. In other words,
what we have done by removing the character loan is we have removed the economic franchise of the small bank which had a very
strong competitive advantage over the larger banks and over those




34

from other areas who did not know the people in the particular
community. So that, if we are interested in community banking,
which I certainly am, the way to make sure that the appropriate
incentives are there is to ensure that the people who are bankers
in the small community and have the assets of knowing all of the
various players in this community, be allowed to function as banks
in a profitable way. If we require somebody who knows everybody
in the community to sit and write out a long series of loan documents and various different forms of appraisal requirements, the
cost of doing that is more than the profit that the loan could conceivably engender. As a consequence of that, I would say that what
we are doing is undercutting our small community banks by essentially taking their franchise away from them in that respect.
Mr. FINGERHUT. It is your opinion, Mr. Chairman, that undoing
that regulatory element alone is sufficient to overcome the other
dynamics in the regulatory and financial structures that have been
leading to the banking consolidations and the decline in community banking?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No. I do not think so. There is more to this in
the sense that there is still a fear on the part of bankers, there is
still a concern with respect to commercial real estate markets and
their liquidity, and there are a number of other general aspects to
this problem which will keep it festering for a while. Having said
that, there is no question that moving in the character loan area
would be a major factor contributing to easing this problem.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Mr. Chairman, if I could ask one other quick
question? I know we have to go vote very quickly. In my opening
remarks, I asked you about the subject of the impact of spending
cuts on the economy. We have had any number of questions about
taxes, and I think we all understand the parameters of that debate.
Just as a perfect example, my colleague, Mr. Schumer, to my right,
in his aggressive remarks about the subject of spending cuts, said
he is against the space station. Well, that decision alone takes 2,000
jobs out of my district overnight.
What you have said is—and that does not mean I am not willing
to consider that—what you have said in your prepared testimony is
that you cannot comment specifically on the actions that the Federal Reserve could take, but, in general, you felt that you could
take ameliorative actions to make up for whatever we would do to
the deficit, because reducing the deficit is so important. Can you
comment specifically on the spending cuts side, and whether
indeed you think you can take ameliorative actions? I am sure the
chairman would appreciate it if you did that in 30 seconds or less,
so we could go vote.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I suggest maybe we hold that answer. I
think it is a great question. Can we take a break now, Mr. Greenspan? We will be right back as soon as we vote, and we will take
your answer.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Certainly.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Thank you.
[Recess.]
Chairman KANJORSKI. We have a question pending I understand.
Mr. FINGERHUT. I assume that we all remember the question.




35

Chairman KANJORSKI. In detail? I was just wondering if it would
help Mr. Greenspan if we had the stenographer reread the question?
Mr. FINGERHUT. Mr. Chairman, I could save time. I will just
maybe rephrase it very quickly. The question was that we have
had a lot of discussion about the subject of the impact of potential
tax increases on the economy. We all know that subject very well.
In my opening remarks, and again in my question, I posed to you
the question of the impact on spending cuts, particularly program
cuts that resulted in unemployment. I cited the example of the
space station which would, if cut, take a couple of thousand jobs
out of my district. In your testimony you said, well, you could not
be specific, which I understand—that you did feel that we should
not be afraid of deficit reduction through either mechanism because of the ability of the Fed to take ameliorative measures. I
wanted to ask you specifically your feeling about the impact of cuts
that result in job losses on the economy and what, in general
terms, measures you think will be taken to help areas that will be
hard hit by the cuts.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Congressman, let me say that, to the extent that
expenditure cuts change the long-term expected direction of the
structural Federal budget, then one could expect long-term interest
rates, and intermediate-term interest rates, and, most specifically,
mortgage interest rates to fall. What that will do is engender a
degree of economic activity, unassociated obviously with the expenditure cuts, but, nonetheless, of an order of magnitude which
will probably either closely offset or maybe somewhat fall short.
One can expect a significant impact from declining real long-term
interest rates, as a consequence of expenditure cuts.
What I was indicating in my prepared remarks is that monetary
policy obviously is focusing on the economy as a whole. While we
would not respond to anything specific because we do not know
what the consequences are, to the extent that various different
fiscal policies have an impact upon the overall economy, on the
structure of the economy, obviously we respond to that, but to say
in advance how we might or might not respond would require us to
have a judgment and knowledge about a huge number of individual
events that may or may not transpire. So, all I can say is that the
basic purpose of monetary policy is long-term stability, and to
foster the elements in the financial system which would contribute
to long-term sustainable economic growth. To the extent that various elements of fiscal policy impact the environment in which that
was occurring, obviously we would respond to that.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Is there—Mr. Chairman, if I could just follow
up—I know that, by virtue of this break, I have gotten more than
my share of time—but, is there an issue of timing? You indicated,
in your response just now, Mr. Greenspan, that we would expect, as
we cut spending, even if it has an impact on jobs that were previously government-sponsored jobs, that the reduction in interest
rates, the private sector would make up the slack. You also indicated that it may not be a one for one
Mr. GREENSPAN. It may not be one for one.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Or a direct relationship. One of the real concerns, frankly, is not that it would be a one-to-one relationship na-




36

tionwide, but that it will be far from a one-to-one relationship in
certain regions. In other words, we will have regionally impacted
development.
I guess the question is, do you have a sense on the timing of this?
Should we be phasing in things at a certain rate, such that the private sector would be able to pick that up at a certain rate, or are
you not at all concerned about that question?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I am frankly not concerned. I am not concerned
in the sense that if we give reasons not to do something—if we give
reasons not to cut expenditures—we will procrastinate. That would
be most unfortunate. My judgment is that the amount of cutting
that is likely to be done to be effective is extremely unlikely to go
to the extreme where it will cause great economic hardship. I do
not believe that there is a consensus within the Congress, for example, to actually do that. Even if it was the inclination of a number
of the Members, it would not happen that way. I am saying, even
were it to happen, there are vehicles that one could expect to occur
as countervailing forces which would very significantly ameliorate
the problem.
I suspect that on the interest rate issue, more specifically the
mortgage rate, the one thing that every community in this economy has is residential building. In that respect, the one thing we are
certain of is that when mortgage rates come down, building goes
up. That is true everywhere in the country.
Mr. FINGERHUT. Thank you. Thank you for waiting for 15 minutes to answer the question. I appreciate it.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Bachus.
Mr. BACHUS. Chairman Greenspan, as a member of the ETC
Board, what advice
Mr. GREENSPAN. Oversight Board. We are not actually members
of the Board, per se, but we are the members of the Board which
oversees
Mr. BACHUS. I see.
Mr. GREENSPAN. The ETC, itself.
Mr. BACHUS. Well, in your capacity as—on that Board of Oversight, what would you suggest to this subcommittee on how we get
a handle on the ETC? Now, I will give you the backdrop, which you
know, but which concerns us about the fact that this agency may
be losing $6 million a day, by their own testimony. They have been
making procurement decisions, including the 67-cent-a-page cost of
copying. We are very disturbed about that.
We just received an estimate that the costs of resolving the remaining failed institutions may be less than we expected because
of the return we are getting from asset sales. I will say this specifically, just two questions within that general question. Are you concerned that ETC funding has not been included in the President's
package, number one; and what has been the effect of Congress in
withholding the ETC bill?
Mr. GREENSPAN. The answer to your first question is yes, I am. I
think that it is something which is not a question of funding the
ETC, it is a question of the obligation of the Federal Government
to support the deposits that are being insured. To the extent we are
not doing that, we are, in effect, losing, as you point out, $6 million
a month.




37

Mr. BACKUS. A month?
Mr. GREENSPAN. A day.
Mr. BACKUS. A day.
Mr. GREENSPAN. The reasons for the losses, obviously, is we are
keeping institutions open which shouldn't be kept open. The sooner
that that issue gets resolved, the sooner the job is completed the
cheaper it is going to be for the American taxpayer. It has been a
horrendous amount of money. It has been a horrendous problem,
but I do think we are getting close to where we can see the end of
the tunnel. I hope, in using that term, I do not create a jinx on the
system. There is no question that very significant progress has
been made. We are fairly close to getting this very unpleasant incident behind us.
Mr. BACKUS. Well, I appreciate your straightforward advice, and
I think that is basically to fund ETC, and let them resolve
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes.
Mr. BACKUS. The remaining
Mr. GREENSPAN. Remember, it is not the ETC that is getting the
money
Mr. BACKUS. Right.
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is basically the depositor who has been insured.
Mr. BACKUS. Thank you very much.
Chairman KANJORSKI. We have finally rescued our friend from
Pennsylvania whose plane just arrived. I reached him on the floor
and advised him that we had not concluded. It is my pleasure to
recognize Mr. Ridge, my distinguished ranking Member.
Mr. RIDGE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman, and thank you,
Chairman Greenspan. I apologize to both of you for being late.
Transportation got a little messed up this morning. I am happy to
be here with you. I am sorry I did not get the opportunity to listen
to your entire testimony. I do have a few questions for you, if I
might.
I thought that President Clinton made a very succinct and probably the best statement concerning the deficit and its impact on
the American taxpayer in his State of the Union, or his economic
address, which I thought was long overdue. I thought it, as I said
before, was a good, succinct, and appropriate statement.
Having said that, when I take a look at some of the projections
for—within the administration with regard to new taxes, and compared with spending reductions, there is an analysis that we have
seen that says in the first year taxes will go up $36 billion, and we
are going to cut government about $3.6 billion. That is a 10 to 1
ratio. We in the Congress are supposed to anticipate that the
spending cuts will come later. In my 11 years here, normally, when
this entity has had access to more revenue, expenditures just seem
to grow, and we never seem to get around to cutting that deficit.
One of the advantages that the President pointed out, and you
have talked about a long, long time with reducing the deficit, is the
impact on interest rates. I am just wondering, if we fail to do our
share of reducing the deficit by spending cuts, will the interest rate
reduction that the President has suggested we could anticipate, and
that you have suggested we might, if we do the right thing, antici-




38

pate, will it ever really materialize if we do not actually reduce the
size of government?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Mr. Ridge, as I said in my prepared remarks, or
more exactly in the supplementary remarks, we are dealing with a
current services expenditure path which, when projected indefinitely out into the future, creates an increasing growth in the deficit
which becomes destabilizing at the end of the day, if I may put it
that way. It is clear that one cannot resolve that longer term deficit solely from the tax side, because what that would imply is everincreasing tax rates and, at some point, that becomes debilitating
to economic growth, and hence revenues fall and the deficit starts
back up.
So, you are led to the conclusion, inexorably, that a necessary
condition for resolving the long-term budget deficit problem is to
restrain the growth in spending to a point which is not in excess of
the tax base that we would project indefinitely into the future, and
be related to some level of economic growth. Obviously, the greater
the economic growth, the more that the current services level of
expenditures could be tolerated. As I also indicated in my testimony, I do not find it credible that growth, per se, is going to resolve
that issue, and I, therefore, concluded that expenditure growth had
to be suppressed over the long run, if the structural deficit is to be
brought down and if, as a consequence, long-term and intermediate
interest rates are to come down.
Mr. RIDGE. When you look at that though—let's assume the bestcase scenario, with the government trying to tighten
its belt, at the
same time we are trying to lighten taxpayers' wrallets. It remains
to be seen whether or not we are going to do that. What would you
anticipate would be the response, in terms of interest rate reduction, and how do you think, given the fact that we had short-term
interest rates down fairly low, even during 2-3 years ago, the small
business community still seemed to lack the credit opportunities
that many of them felt continued—exacerbated the recession and
retarded their growth? What is it about this package of spending
cuts, if we do our job on the Hill, tax revenue that will reduce the
rates even less than they have been in the past couple of years, and
will make capital accessible to smaller business, which seems to be
the engine of growth down the road for the entire country?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Yes. As I have discussed in previous testimonies
and here this morning, interest rates as such are not the major inhibitor in small business lending. It has basically been an extraordinary concern, on the part of lending officers and bank officers
generally, following on their very unhappy experiences of the
1980's when lax underwriting standards led to very significant increases in nonperforming loans which threatened a number of institutions, and essentially traumatized a big segment of the commercial banking industry which, as a consequence, have been extraordinarily restrained, slightly less so recently, but still extraordinarily restrained in lending. When you say that, what we really
mean is lending to small business because, to a large extent, it is
they who are feeling the brunt of this because their alternate
sources of credit are extraordinarily limited and, as a consequence
of that, expansion in the small business area has clearly been suppressed.




39

So, it is more an issue of several things. One, as I indicated earlier, improving liquidity in commercial real estate assets would enhance the ability to liquidate collateral, and assure the degree of
capital that one actually really has in your bank, except other than
an accounting judgment as to what might happen under certain
hypothetical values for commercial real estate. Then there is the
question of the regulatory issues, which we discussed at length, and
I very specifically argued that we have eliminated the character
loan in small business lending and, in my judgment, that probably
has been a really strong force undercutting the availability of
credit for a lot of businesses.
Mr. RIDGE. Should it be restored?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I think we should, most certainly.
Mr. RIDGE. I appreciate that. I have just seen, over the past
couple of years, the relationships between small business and their
credit market—their lending institution with whom they had dealt
for 10, 15, and 20 years, with whom they had a mutually profitable
relationship, with whom they worked, and never had—businesses
that had never had a default payment, were always on time, and
did historically what businesses had done, got a line of credit, continued to pay on the interest for a long period of time, and either
refinanced it, paid it off, or went back again. Yet, sadly, for a lot of
reasons in the past 3 or 4 years, this avenue has been cut off, and
there has been no alternative to them. So, your recommendation
that we restore those character loans is
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would say, Congressman, at a minimum, allowing well capitalized banks to get back into the business of character
loans strikes me as no threat to the safety and soundness of the
banking system.
Mr. RIDGE. Good. Thank you.
One final question with regard to small business. I know my time
has elapsed. There are those who have taken a look, and you perhaps have answered this question before, but there are those who
have taken a look at President Clinton's tax package. At the top
end, although the suggestion is that these are the affluent and the
wealthy, as a matter of fact, the burden will fall heavily upon individuals who file as subchapter S, who are in the business of creating wealth and opportunity through their small businesses. If you
increase the tax on small business, we still have an unfriendly regulatory environment, or at least unfriendly credit environment, the
two do not seem to provide the kind of incentive that I would think
that this administration or all of us, Republicans and Democrats,
would like for a small business. Have I misstated the impact of the
tax burden on small business? Will it be a deterrent to growth?
Mr. GREENSPAN. In my earlier testimony this morning, I had indicated that I did not think it was appropriate for the Federal Reserve to be involved in the programmatic detail of the discussions
Mr. RIDGE. Right.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Which are involved here. So, I would like to just
remain mute on that subject if I may.
Mr. RIDGE. All right.
I very much appreciate the fact that whenever you are before
this subcommittee or others, that it is rare that you remain mute. I




40

certainly appreciate your thought on that regard. Thank you for
testifying.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you.
Chairman KANJORSKI. One quick question, Mr. Greenspan. What
do you think is the window of opportunity for the Congress and the
President to cooperate on this deficit reduction package?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would certainly think that it is obviously
within this year. The problem is that the longer we procrastinate
in resolving this issue, the more difficult it is going to become to
really come to grips with it. While it is not something where one
can say, as of August 31 or what have you, the window comes
down, and all problems are unsolvable—I certainly would not want
to say that and clearly, no one should—the time element here is
not what it used to be.
When we discussed these issues 3 or 4 years ago, as indeed I
recall I am repeating myself almost verbatim in what I have said
this morning, the difference was that we looked at the deficit problem as a slow, corrosive deterioration in the system which did not
really create a major concern that a crisis was on the other side of
the horizon. What is happening, however, is the data are becoming
increasingly persuasive that this problem is beginning to move
closer and closer to a destabilizing type of environment, and I
should think we should not be taking the risks that are implicit in
waiting indefinitely to get this issue resolved. Time is no longer on
our side.
Chairman KANJORSKI. You have indicated that, if we are successful, we can anticipate the long-term interest rates falling. Have
your economists or you yourself come up with where you see that
eventual leveling out—what is the most optimum level?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It depends, in large respect, on those issues I
raised in my prepared testimony, when I discussed the attitudes
that existed in the 1960's, and most of the 1970's, about this country being essentially inflation-resistant and in that environment
long-term interest rates never got particularly high, I mean, higher
than 4 or 5 percent. When the dam broke, as I put it, and all of a
sudden the inflationary potentials of this economy became evident,
of course, we got interest rates rising very sharply.
The key question is, can we put the genie back in the box, so to
speak? Can we go back to the judgments and values, and institutional insights that occurred say in the 1960's? My suspicion is
probably not—not fully. It will take a very long while before people
really have a serious view that inflation is no longer a crucial force
in this economy. Nonetheless, if we resolve the long-term structural budget deficit, and put into place hard-wired budgetary actions,
which, instead of having the long-term budget go down through
1996 and 1997 and start back up, if we have programmatic changes,
which are in the law that bring it down, and credibly bring it
down, then we have still further to go on the downside for longterm interest rates and mortgage rates. Indeed, it is the expectation that the resolution of this debate, which is now in the process
of emerging within the Congress, will be successful that has already lowered long-term rates not insignificantly. We have essentially pierced the 7-percent long-term 30-year bond rate which no
one really expected would occur at this particular stage. That is es-




41

sentially attributable, as best I can judge, to the expectation that
by the end of this debate major progress will be made and longterm budget issues will be resolved. If that occurs, I think that is a
very important event in American economic history.
Chairman KANJORSKI. If the long-term interest rate falls by 1
percentage point, that would alleviate the Federal Government of
about $40 billion in interest on the debt, assuming we had longterm funding of the debt. You give a figure that there would be an
injection into the system of, I think, for every point, $50 billion or
$100 billion, I am not sure into the private
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is a very tricky calculation; but it is between
the two numbers. It is fairly apparent that in this particular environment the sensitivity of economic activity to the intermediate interest rate, mainly the mortgage rate, is very high, and that, as we
have observed in recent quarters, whenever the mortgage rate goes
down, there is an acceleration of economic activity. It is the far
most potent stimulus that I can imagine that we can get.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Mr. Greenspan, you have heard the political bickering that has occurred today. Actually, that surprises me,
although I am aware that this is a very political institution.
I see this as a once-a-lifetime opportunity. If we do not do something about the deficit now, we will never get another opportunity
quite like this. To see the contentious political activity that has
even appeared here at the subcommittee today is a little bit disappointing for me, so that I am moving now to the next phase. If we
cannot get a singular comprehensive program approved, if the minority and the majority talk ourselves to death, and refuse to cut,
as we have to cut across the board, or increase taxes, if we have to
increase taxes, is this problem so severe, in your estimation, that it
would warrant us passing extraordinary emergency powers constitutionally to provide what the President—with extraordinary
powers to cut the budget at will, or line item at will?
Mr. GREENSPAN. No, Mr. Chairman. I am very conscious of the
constitutional structure that we have imposed on this country, and
I just cannot imagine that this issue cannot be resolved through
constitutional means. If we cannot do that, then I think we will
find some very significant debilitating forces affecting our economy
and our society. I have enough confidence in this country in watching the way our political system functions to remember that when
we do confront crises, we eventually come out OK. The presumption that there should be extra constitutional powers is, in my
judgment, wholly misplaced.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Finally—and I will give my fellow members an opportunity to ask final questions—is there some point
where we will cut too much? I think, when we finally get used to
cutting things around here, we will find a stampede of who can
outdo each other. I think one of the fellow members talked about a
similar stampede when we set capital standards in FIRREA. We
amazed ourselves that we went so far we destroyed ourselves in a
way. I think we may do the same thing in cutting. Is there some
point where we could cut too fast and injure the economy?
Mr. GREENSPAN. I find that politically noncredible, meaning it
just




42

Chairman KANJORSKI. Would not be beyond the political boundary?
Mr. GREENSPAN. It is hard to believe that there could be sufficient agreement. I am arguing that there should be adequate
agreement to cut the budget, but that it should be far greater than
that, I just find difficulty contemplating.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I am just suggesting there may be schizophrenia at work here. I am not sure—once we tend to start in a
direction, the correction may exceed even our best expectations.
You mean, you do not see that some of our friends may say well,
the space station—we will raise you one with the super collider,
and then somebody comes back and says, well, we will do a real job
on defense and do away with the B-2, and raise you on the tanks,
or whatever? You do not see that type of bidding war occurring?
You just see that it is a hard knock, if we can get anything out of
the system, we are going to
Mr. GREENSPAN. I would appreciate observing that phenomenon,
Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. I think, from an outside observer, maybe I
have been here too long, Mr. Greenspan.
Mr. Bachus. Did you have any further questions?
Mr. BACHUS. No.
Chairman KANJORSKI. No. OK.
Mr. Ridge.
Mr. RIDGE. Just one. I agree, Mr. Chairman, sometimes it is
better to be a spectator than a participant. It remains to be seen
whether or not we will have a comity that I think—and not
comedy—comity that I think the Chairman is talking about.
I guess when I take a look at, not only the actual day-to-day
working of the marketplace, but also the psychological impact of
what we do on the marketplace, which is very real, it is troubling
to me to see that the ratio between spending cuts, and revenue increases—let's not just talk necessarily this administration, but the
discussion has always started at a fair level that we were going to
be $2 or $3 of spending cuts for $1 of increased expenditure. As the
process worked, as administrations assessed and reassessed what
they were able to do on the Hill, it would go from three to one, to
two to one, to one to one. Now I guess, what is it? Fifty-nine cents?
Depending on the analyst.
The bottom line is that it seemed to me that the most significant
factor in the degree to which this entire scheme will affect shortand long-term interest rates and affect the economy is the degree
to which we not only increase revenues, but we also downsize government in projected years. I just do not get a sense, from some of
the initial discussions that we are going to get that. Without getting you into commenting about specific programmatic changes,
and those kind of political decisions that we have to make, could
you say that the positive impact on the market, on financial institutions, on interest rates, on the economy generally would be
better or worse, the higher the ratio was between spending cuts
and increased revenue?
Mr. GREENSPAN. Well, Mr. Ridge, I have said many times before
this subcommittee in years past, and indeed I repeated it this
morning, if one's purpose is to get the budget deficit down, it is




43

more efficiently done from the expenditure side than from the tax
side. If that is true then, clearly, the market's anticipation of the
decline in the budget deficit is likely to give more credence to the
expenditure cuts, which are perceived to be permanent, than the
tax increases. It is also clear that the markets will react as they
indeed have to expectations that the deficit is coming down. It is
only an issue of the relative weighting of what they think the probabilities are of effectively achieving that on expenditures on one
side, or taxes on the other.
It is essentially a question of what is the probability of long-term
success for equal amounts of a dollar of taxes and a dollar of expenditures? I would say, as best I can judge the evidence, that
there is a higher probability on the expenditures side. Clearly, the
tax side is not zero. Ultimately, the judgment that has to be made
by the Congress is a political one, and, as I said, political in the
best sense of the word. It is the way our Constitution functions and
the way our elected representatives bring to bear the various value
judgments of the electorate hopefully to a solution to this problem
which, as I indicated to the chairman, is one for which time is not
infinitely available.
Mr. RIDGE. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman KANJORSKI. Well, thank you very much, Mr. Greenspan. We certainly do appreciate it. I know some subcommittee
members have not had an opportunity to ask questions, and they
would like to do so in writing. So, if we could have your cooperation, we would appreciate it. Further, we have asked your assistance on resolving this question of whether there is in fact a use of
the open window to acquire funds for purchasing securities or some
other abuses out there by banks. Ahead of time, I would like to
thank you for the indicated cooperation of the Federal Reserve
with the Congress on that issue. We look forward to further conversations.
Thank you very much for your statement. I congratulate you for
taking the position that you will not allow the Federal Reserve to
become politicized in the highly political question of what we do on
the deficit reduction issue.
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. GREENSPAN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
[Whereupon, at 1:09 p.m., the hearing was recessed, to reconvene
at the call of the Chair.]










APPENDIX

February 23, 1993

(45)

46

Opening Statement
The Honorable Paul E. Kanjorski, Chairman
Subcommittee on Economic Growth & Credit Formation
Semi-Annual Hearing on the Conduct of Monetary Policy
February 23,1993

The Subcommittee meets today to receive the semi-annual report of the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System on economic and monetary policy as mandated under the Full
Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, popularly known as the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.
Under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act, the Federal Reserve is required to set forth:
1. A review and analysis of recent developments affecting economic trends in the Nation,
including changes in the exchange rate;
2. The objectives and plans of the Board of Governors and the Federal Open Market
Committee with respect to the ranges of growth or diminution of the money supply, taking into
account past and prospective developments in employment, unemployment, production, investment,
real income, productivity, international trade, and prices; and
3. The relationship between the Federal Reserve's plans and the short-term goals set forth in
the most recent Economic Report of the President, and any goals set by the Congress.
As the new chairman of this subcommittee, I want to welcome Chairman Greenspan. I look
forward to working with the Chairman, his colleagues at the Federal Reserve, and my colleagues on
both sides of the aisle, to achieve the overall goals of the Humphrey-Hawkins Act - full employment
and balanced growth.
As we sit here today, the single most significant development in economic policy since the
last time the Chairman testified before the House Banking Committee, comes not as a result of any
action taken by the Federal Reserve, the Federal Open Market Committee, or this Committee. The
single most significant development is that the American people have delivered a mandate for
change.
In the election of 1992 the American people told the Executive Branch, the Legislative
Branch, and independent agencies like the Federal Reserve, that this is not a time for politics as
usual, that the time for gridlock and divided government is over.
I am extremely encouraged by Chairman Greenspan's statements that President Clinton's
deficit reduction proposal is both "serious" and "credible." The Chairman's statements indicate that




47

not only is the President heading in the right direction, but also that cooperation is possible between
a president from one party and a Board of Governors appointed by presidents from the other party.
For my own part, I can only hope that this bipartisan spirit of cooperation will spill over to the
Legislative Branch. I will certainly do my best to encourage it in this subcommittee.
The Chairman's appearance today comes at a time when short-term interest rates are at
relatively historical lows. Few Americans today are complaining about the price of money. Low
interest rates usually mean an ample supply of money - "easy money."
The anomaly we find ourselves in today is that while interest rates are low, many Americans
still cannot find access to it at any price. This continuing "credit crunch" is particularly acute for the
small and medium-sized businesses which are the lifeblood of our economy and which have
historically created the majority of new jobs in our economy. It is the inability of small and mediumsized businesses to obtain access to credit which has undoubtedly caused unemployment to remain
unacceptably high. Our inner cities, our second and third tier cities, and our minority communities
have been particularly hard hit by the inability to obtain access to credit. Small communities in
Northeastern Pennsylvania, and the riot-torn sections of Los Angeles may be thousands of miles
apart and have vastly different social and cultural backgrounds, but they share one important thing in
common: both feel that their economic recovery has been blocked by inadequate access to capital
for business expansion and job creation.
In our economy today, big businesses have avenues other than commercial banks through
which they can obtain credit. They can go directly to the capital markets. They can obtain loans
from pension funds and insurance companies. Individuals who seek home loans and credit for
consumer loans benefit from the secondary markets which have been created to increase the flow of
funds for these purposes.
Virtually alone among borrowers, small and medium-sized businesses have little or no
alternatives than borrowing from commercial banks. Yet banks are all too often reluctant to make
loans, claiming they are strangling under the weight of increased capital requirements and regulation.
Where are these businesses to turn at a time when short-term interest rates are low, and capital
requirements and regulators who make it easier and more profitable for a bank to invest in
government securities than in small and medium-sized commercial loans?
I hope the Chairman will address the question of how we ensure that "small and medium sized
businesses obtain access to the credit they need to make our economic recovery complete and to
ensure that we meet the goal of full employment which is an integral part of the Humphrey-Hawkins
Act. If artificial restrictions imposed by either the regulators or the Congress are impeding bank
lending to small and medium-sized businesses, please tell us how we can remove those impediments.
If new incentives or a secondary market for commercial loans need to be created, tell us the most
effective way to create them. If nothing we can do will convince banks to make commercial loans
then who can we find or create who will make them, and why are we in the business of chartering
and insuring commercial banks?
Mr. Chairman, I welcome you to today's hearing and I look forward to hearing your
testimony and to working with you in the months and years ahead to revitalize our economy.




48
Testimony by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Subcommittee on Economic Growth and Credit Formation
of the

Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs




J.S. House of Representatives

February 23, 1993

49
Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee.

I appreciate this

opportunity to discuss with you developments in the economy and the
conduct of monetary policy.

Nineteen ninety-two saw an improved

performance of our economy.

The expansion firmed, and inflation

moderated.
diminish.

Some of the structural impediments to growth seemed to
In particular, the financial condition of households,

firms, and financial institutions improved.

In addition, confidence

rebounded late in the year.
Nevertheless, the expansion seemed to exhibit

little

momentum through much of 1992, unemployment remained high, and money
and credit growth was sluggish.

In response, the Federal Reserve took

steps to increase the availability of bank reserves on several
occasions.

These actions brought short-term interest rates to their

lowest levels in thirty years.

Long-term interest rates also fell in

1992 and early 1993 as inflation expectations gradually moderated and
optimism developed about a potential for genuine progress in reducing
federal budget deficits.
Mr. Chairman, in the last few years our economy has been held
back by a variety of structural factors that have not been typical of
post-World War II business cycles--certainly not occurring all at
once.

These factors have included record debt burdens, overbuilding

in commercial real estate, and a substantial cutback in defense
spending.

In this we have not been alone:

Other major industrial

countries also have been experiencing unusual impediments to growth,
and by comparison the recent performance of the U.S. economy has been
relatively good.

Our monetary policy actions have been directed at

facilitating adjustments to these developments and have in the process
improved our economy's prospects for long-run sustainable growth.




50

Significant hurdles, of course, still remain to be overcome in the
short run.

Nonetheless, in the view of the vast majority of business

analysts, prospects appear reasonable for continued economic expansion
and further declines in the unemployment

rate.

The tasks of the

monetary and fiscal authorities alike will be not only to support this
prospective growth but also to set policies to enhance the capacity of
our economy to produce rising living standards over time.

Before

discussing the outlook in more detail, I would like to reflect on how
monetary policy has interacted with the forces that have shaped
developments over recent years.
Recent Economic Developments and Monetary Policy in Perspective
I have often noted before this Committee the distinctly
different nature of the current business cycle.

A number of

extraordinary factors contributed to the earlier weakening in the
economy and have worked against a brisk and normal rebound from the
recession.
Balance sheet restructuring has been, perhaps, the most
important of these factors.

In the 1980s, debt growth, hand in hand

with rising asset prices, considerably exceeded that of income, and
debt burdens rose to record levels.

Debt-financed construction in the

commercial real estate market was an extreme manifestation of this
development, but it was apparent as well in other sectors of the
economy.
That these imbalances developed should not be entirely
surprising.

The economy grew continuously for nearly eight years--

from late 1982 through mid-1990. the longest peacetime expansion on
record.

In this unusual period of uninterrupted growth, unrealistic

expectations of what the economy could deliver seem to have developed.
In addition, households and businesses apparently were skeptical that




51

inflation would continue to decline and. based on their experience
during the 1970s, may even have expected it to rebound.

As a

consequence, many may have shaped their investment decisions
importantly on expectations of inflation-induced appreciation of asset
prices, rather than on more fundamental economic considerations.

In

the commercial real estate sector, assessments of profit potential
formed during the first half of the 1980s simply went too far, leading
to an unavoidable period of retrenchment.
The difficulties faced by borrowers in servicing their debts
as the expansion slowed and the levelling out or decline in asset
prices prompted many to cut back expenditures and divert abnormal
proportions of their cash flows to debt repayment.
back into slower economic growth.

This in turn fed

In addition, financial institutions

were faced with impaired equity positions owing to sizable loan losses
as well as more stringent supervision and regulation and demands by
investors and regulators for better capital ratios'.

In response, they

limited the availability of credit, with particular effects on smaller
businesses.

Over the last year or so, however, considerable progress

has been made in strengthening balance sheets in both the nonfinancial
and financial sectors.

Moreover, by some measures the rate of

deterioration of the commercial real-estate industry might be slowing
and prices in this sector may soon begin to stabilize.

Such

developments should contribute to the sustainability of the expansion
in the period ahead.
Intensive business restructuring has been another important
characteristic of the evolving economic situation.

In an environment

of weak demand and intense competition here and abroad, many firms
have found it necessary to take aggressive measures to reduce costs.
These actions have included selling or closing down unprofitable units




52

and reducing their workforce.

The process of restructuring has been

given added momentum by the availability of new computing and
communication technologies.

Although these changes involve difficult

adjustments in the short run. they are producing important gains in
productivity, which will boost real wages and living standards over
time.
The contraction in defense spending has been a third
development restraining the expansion.

Real federal defense

expenditures dropped about 6 percent in 1992, and are down 9 percent
from their 1987 peak.

Those regions of the country with substantial

defense-related activity have been among the areas whose economies
have performed especially poorly.

Although this development is having

a contractionary influence on the economy in the short run, over a
longer period the productive resources freed in this process will find
employment in the private sector, contributing to capital formation
and the growth potential of the economy.
Another, less-discussed factor that contributed to the
formulation of our recent monetary policy dates not from the 1980s but
rather from the 1970s--inflation and inflation expectations.

Over the

past decade or so, the importance of the interactions of monetary
policy with these expectations has become increasingly apparent.

The

effects of policy on the economy depend critically on how market
participants react to actions taken by the Federal Reserve, as well as
on expectations of our future actions.

These expectations — and thus

the credibility of monetary policy--are influenced not only by the
statements and behavior of the Federal Reserve, but by those of the
Congress and the Administration as well.
Through the first two decades of the post World War II
period, this interaction was patently less important.




Savers and

53

investors, firms and households made economic and financial decisions
based on an implicit assumption that inflation over the long run would
remain low enough to be inconsequential.

There was a sense that our

institutional structure and culture, unlike those of many other
nations of the world, were alien to inflation.

As a consequence,

inflation premiums embodied in long-term interest rates were low and
effectively capped.

Inflation expectations were reasonably

to unexpected shifts in aggregate demand or supply.

impervious

In those

circumstances, monetary policy had far more room to maneuver; monetary
policy, for example, could ease aggressively without igniting
inflation expectations.
Even during the rise in inflation of the late 1960s and 1970s
there was a clear reluctance to believe that the inflation being
experienced was other than transitory; it was presumed that inflation
would eventually retreat to the 1 to 2 percent area that prevailed
during the 1950s and the first half of the 1960s.

Consequently, long-

term interest rates remained contained.
But the dam eventually broke, and the huge losses suffered by
bondholders during the 1970s and early 1980s sensitized them to the
slightest sign, real or imagined, of rising inflation.

At the first

indication of an inflationary policy--monetary or fiscal--investors
dump bonds, driving up long-term interest rates.

To guard against

unexpected losses, investors now demand a considerable premium in bond
yields--a premium that seems out of proportion to the likely future
path of inflation, but one that nevertheless conditions the
environment of monetary policy today.

The steep slope of the yield

curve and the expectations about future interest rates that it implies
suggest that investors remain quite concerned about the possibility of




54

higher inflation over the longer run, even as they appear less
concerned about that possibility for the next year or two.
This heightened sensitivity
interacts with the economy.

affects the way monetary policy

An overly expansionary monetary policy,

or even its anticipation, is embedded fairly soon in higher inflation
expectations and nominal bond yields.

Producers incorporate expected

cost increases quickly into their own prices, and eventually any
increase in output disappears as inflation rises and any initial
decline in long-term nominal interest rates is more than retraced.

To

be sure, a stimulative monetary policy can prompt a short-run
acceleration of economic activity.

But the experience of the 1970s

provided convincing evidence that there is no lasting tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment; in the long run, higher inflation buys no
increase in employment.
This view of the capabilities of monetary policy is entirely
consistent with the Humphrey-Hawkins Act.

As you know, the Act

requires the Federal Reserve to "maintain long-run growth of the
monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy's longrun potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the
goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term
interest rates."
The goal of moderate long-term interest rates is particularly
relevant in the current circumstances, in which balance sheet
constraints have been a major--if not the major--drag on the
expansion.

The halting, but substantial, declines in intermediate-

and long-term interest rates that have occurred over the past few
years have been the single most important factor encouraging balancesheet restructuring by households and firms and fostering the very
significant reductions in debt service burdens.




And monetary policy

55

has played a crucial role in facilitating balance sheet adjustments-and thus enhancing the sustainability of the expansion — by easing in
measured steps, gradually convincing investors that inflation was
likely to remain subdued and fostering the decline in longer-term
interest rates.
That is the background against which we have conducted
monetary policy for the last several years.

Through this period.

Federal Reserve policy was directed at fostering sustainable growth in
the economy.

Recognizing tendencies for the economy to slow, the

Federal Reserve began to ease monetary policy in the spring of 1989.
In response to the downturn that began in August 1990, we accelerated
the reduction in short-term interest rates.

Last year, we extended

our earlier reductions in interest rates by lowering the federal funds
rate another percentage point through another cut in the discount rate
and injections of a large volume of reserves.

In addition to reducing

interest rates, the Federal Reserve lowered reserve requirements last
year for the second time in eighteen months to help reduce depository
institutions' costs and encourage lending.
Although the easing actions over the past few years have been
purposely gradual, cumulatively they have been quite large.

Short-

term interest rates have been reduced since their 1989 peak by nearly
7 percentage points; looked at differently, short rates have been
lowered by two-thirds.

Some have argued that monetary policy has been

too cautious, that rates should have been lowered more sharply or in
larger increments.
In my view, these arguments miss the crucial features of our
current experience: the sensitivity of inflation expectations and the
necessity to work through structural imbalances in order establish a
basis for sustained growth.




In these circumstances, monetary policy

56

clearly has a role to play in helping the economy to grow; the process
by which monetary policy can contribute, however, has been different
in some respects than in past business cycles.

Lower intermediate-

and long-term interest rates and inflation are essential to the
structural adjustments in our economy, and monetary policy thus has
given considerable weight to helping such rates move lower.
Some have suggested that the decline in inflation permitted
more aggressive moves and. had the downward trajectory of short-term
interest rates been a bit steeper, that aggregate demand would have
been appreciably stronger.

I question that as well.

Basing this

argument on the lower inflation that has occurred is a non sequitur;
the disinflation very likely would not have occurred in the context of
an appreciably more stimulative policy, and such a policy could have
led to higher inflation in the next few years..

Moreover, such a

policy would not have dealt fundamentally with the very real
imbalances in our economy that needed to be resolved before
sustainable growth could resume.

And it would have run the risk of

aborting the process of balance sheet adjustment before it was
completed.

The credibility of noninflationary policies would have

been strained, and longer-term interest rates likely would be higher,
inhibiting the restructuring of balance sheets and reducing the odds
on sustainable growth.
Recent evidence suggests that our approach to monetary policy
in recent years has been appropriate and productive.

Even by last

July, when I presented our midyear report to the Congress, some straws
in the wind suggested that the easing of monetary policy to that date
and the various financial adjustments underway in the economy were
proving successful in paving the way for better economic performance.
Households and businesses appeared to have made significant progress




57

in shoring up their balance sheets; considerable reductions in debt
servicing requirements had been achieved, equity had risen, and
liquidity was higher.

In the financial sector, bank profitability had

improved, and a brisker flow of bank earnings as well as issuance of
new equity shares and subordinated debt had bolstered capital ratios,
helping to arrest the tightening of lending terms and standards.

The

lower level of interest rates, both short- and long-term, helped to
limit the decline in real estate values and boost the profitability of
thrift institutions, as a byproduct reducing the losses that would
have been borne by the Resolution Trust Corporation and. ultimately,
the taxpayer.
It is now apparent that our July expectation of a firmer
trajectory of output has been borne out.

GDP growth is estimated to

have picked up to a 3-1/2 percent rate during the second half of 1992,
following a more modest increase in the first half.

Beginning in the

late summer, some quickening in the pace of auto sales could be
detected, and spending on other consumer durables strengthened as
well.

Single-family housing starts rebounded.

production, and shipments all rose.

Industrial orders,

In association with this stronger

trend, payroll employment growth has picked up and the unemployment
rate has dropped back to 7.1 percent by early this year--certainly too
high, but well below the level at mid-year. For 1992 as a whole, real
gross domestic product is currently estimated to have increased at
about a 3 percent rate.

And indications are that the expansion is

continuing in the early months of 1993, though perhaps at a slightly
reduced rate.
The news on inflation in 1992 likewise was quite encouraging.
The consumer price index rose just 3 percent in 1992, at the lower end
of the central tendency of our July projections.




Excluding volatile

58

food and energy prices, inflation last year was the lowest in two
decades.

Although the January CPI was surprisingly high, judging from

survey evidence and the behavior of long-term interest rates,
inflation expectations appear to be gradually diminishing, as market
participants gain more confidence that inflation is being contained.
Money and Credit in 1992
These favorable outcomes occurred despite slow growth of the
money and credit aggregates.

The Federal Open Market Committee had

established ranges of 2-1/2 to 6-1/2 percent for M2. 1 to 5 percent
for M3, and 4-1/2 to 8-1/2 percent for domestic nonfinancial sector
debt.

Over the year, M2 actually rose 2 percent, M3 1/2 percent, and

debt 4-1/2 percent.

Thus, both of the monetary aggregates finished

the year about 1/2 percentage point below their ranges, and debt just
at its lower bound.
Interpreting this slow growth was one of the major challenges
faced by the Federal Reserve last year.

You may recall that, in

establishing the ranges in February and reviewing them in July, the
Committee took note of the substantial uncertainties regarding the
relationships between income and money in 1992.

Although the velocity

of the broad monetary aggregates--the ratio of nominal GDP to the
quantity of money--had not changed much in 1991, that result itself
was surprising.

In the past, when market interest rates declined, as

they had in 1991, savers shifted funds into M2, since deposit rates
usually did not fall as much as market rates, and this produced a
decline in velocity, in contrast to what occurred in 1991.

As we

moved into 1992, there appeared to be an appreciable likelihood that
unusual weakness in M2 growth relative to spending would continue.
But, in the absence of convincing evidence for increases in velocity,
the FOMC elected to leave the ranges unchanged from the previous year.




59

noting that it would need to be flexible in assessing the implications
of monetary growth relative to the ranges.
In the event, nominal GDP was even stronger relative to the
broad aggregates in 1992 than seemed likely when their ranges were
established.

Income increased 3-1/2 percent faster than M2 over the

year and 4-3/4 percent faster than M3.

The unusual nature of these

increases in velocity can be illustrated by noting that, prior to
1992. the velocity of M3 had risen more than 3 percent in a year only
once: the historical increases in M2 velocity comparable to last
year's occurred solely in the context of sizable increases in market
interest rates, in contrast to last year's declines.
What accounts for this unusual behavior?

Why is it that our

financial system was able to support 5-1/2 percent growth in nominal
GDP with only 2 percent growth in M2 and 1/2 percent growth in M3?

We

can't be entirely certain we have all the answers, but certain
elements of our evolving financial picture clearly have played a major
role.

The most important, perhaps, was that savers believed they

could earn considerably more on their funds if they were invested in
something other than the deposits and money market mutual funds that
make up M2.

The unprecedented steepness of the yield curve was one

factor contributing to the apparent rate disadvantage of M2 assets.
The high level of long-term yields relative to shorter-term rates-rates on deposits, in particular--has attracted funds from bank and
thrift deposits into alternative, longer-term investments.

For

example, bond and stock mutual funds, which are not included in our
standard monetary measures, flourished in 1992.

Assets in those

funds, excluding institutional holdings and IRA and Keogh accounts,
increased $125 billion.

In the absence of such growth, a sizable

proportion of the additional shares doubtless would have resided in




60

deposits.

Shifts from deposits to mutual funds have been abetted by

the spread of facilities in banks and thrifts to sell mutual funds
directly to their

customers.

In addition, the high relative cost of consumer debt, which
has resulted partly from the elimination of the tax deductibility of
consumer interest expenses, no doubt has prompted households to use
funds that otherwise would be held in M2 to pay off, or avoid taking
on, consumer debt.

Mortgage interest rates also are high compared

with interest rates on deposits, reflecting the steep yield curve.
This relationship has led some households to repay mortgage debt with
funds that might otherwise be held in deposits.
Of course, if banks and thrifts had been expanding their loan
portfolios, they would have had to bid more vigorously for deposits.
But a number of developments damped growth of bank and thrift credit,
and depositories consequently have been prompt to reduce rates on
deposits.

In the business sector, the higher levels of stock and bond

prices have encouraged many corporations to pay down bank debt with
the proceeds of a large volume of bond and stock offerings.

More

generally, the attitudes of households and firms toward debt and
leverage appear to have changed considerably in recent years, perhaps
in part mirroring revised expectations about prospects for inflation
to ease debt burdens or reward leverage.
The supplies of credit by depositories also have been
constrained.

Incentives to lend have been damped by market and

regulatory pressures for depository institutions to increase capital
ratios, as well as by other factors raising their costs of
intermediating credit, such as higher deposit insurance premiums,
rising regulatory costs, and more stringent supervisory oversight.




As

61

a result, banking and thrift institutions have sought to limit
balance-sheet growth or actually to shrink.
Together, these supply and demand factors have accelerated a
long-standing process of rechannelling
depository institutions.

credit flows outside of

With reduced needs to fund asset growth,

banks and thrifts have bid less vigorously for deposits, as can be
observed in the very low returns on such instruments.

These low

yields, as I have noted, provide incentives for depositors to redirect
cash toward alternative investments and repayment of debt.

In

addition, the proceeds of banking firms' offerings of equity shares
and subordinated debt have substituted for banks' deposit funding and
have thus reduced monetary growth.
The adjustments

in our depository sector have significant

implications for the overall operation of the financial system and the
performance of the economy.

Historically, banking institutions have

played a critical role in financing small and medium-sized
businesses--firms that in the past have bean a key source of growth in
the economy.

Some of the factors leading to the relative shrinkage of

our banking industry, by limiting the availability of credit to
smaller firms, have restrained aggregate demand and thus have
significantly hindered the economic expansion.
Nevertheless, the financial markets have shown a remarkable
capacity to adjust to the contraction of the depository sector in a
way that mutes the impact on the overall economy.

For instance,

despite a massive contraction in the thrift industry since 1988,
housing credit has remained readily available and, in fact, relatively
inexpensive as a result of the further explo^ ±r»tion of financial
innovations such as mortgage- telattdd securities.

Similarly, cpsn

market sources of funds have flourished in recent years, allowing many




62

firms to tap the stock or bond markets to restructure their balance
sheets.
As a result of such adaptations, the relationship
money and the economy may be undergoing a significant

between

transformation.

In contrast to earlier work that suggested a stable long-run
relationship between M2 growth and inflation, recent developments may
indicate that the velocities of the broader monetary aggregates are
moving toward higher trend levels.

It may be that the opening of

securities markets to increasing numbers of borrowers and lenders--in
part through securitization of loans by depositories as well as their
offerings of mutual funds to deposit customers--is permanently
shunting financing around depository institutions.

If this is true,

the liabilities of these institutions will not be as good a gauge of
financial conditions as they once were.
This is not to argue that money growth can be ignored in
formulating monetary policy.

The Federal Reserve in 1992 paid

substantial attention to developments in the money supply, and we will
continue to do so in 1993 and beyond.

Selecting ranges for monetary

growth over the coming year consistent with desired economic
performance, however, is especially difficult when the relationship
between money and income has become uncertain.

Recent experience

suggests that, at least for a time, measuring money against such
ranges may lead to erroneous conclusions regarding the stance of
monetary policy.
The shortfall of the aggregates from their ranges and
suggestions that the Federal Reserve should have been more vigorous in
preventing the shortfall have raised the general question of the role
of the ranges in conducting monetary policy.

The annual ranges for

money and credit growth can be useful in communicating to the Congress




63

and the public the Federal Reserve's plans for monetary policy and
their relationship

to the country's broader economic

objectives.

Lowering the ranges during the 1980s, for instance, served as an
important signal of the anti-inflationary commitment of the Federal
Reserve.
In some circumstances, the monetary aggregates can also be of
value by serving as indicators of the thrust of monetary policy.
Deviations of money growth from expectations may well signal that
policy is not having its intended effect, and that adjustments should
be considered.

Over much of our nation's financial history a number

of measures of the money supply had reasonably
relationships with aggregate income.

predictable

The period of rapid financial

change had not yet begun, and measuring money was more
straightforward.

Recognition of these predictable money-income

relationships was the basis for the Federal Reserve's

increased

emphasis on money in the 1970s and the subsequent Humphrey-Hawkins
legislation.

And at the beginning of the 1980s, the Congress passed

the Monetary Control Act and the Federal Reserve adopted procedures to
provide greater assurance that targets for Ml could be achieved.
But, even by the mid-1970s, the relationship of the monetary
aggregates to the economy was becoming more complex.

Financial

Innovation and deregulation significantly altered the spectrum of
available transaction and saving instruments.

In the mid-1970s,

advances in corporate cash management techniques, such as sweep
accounts, reduced the need for business demand deposit balances for
any given level of transactions.

And in the early 1980s, the

widespread availability of NOW accounts --transactions accounts that
pay interest--led households to treat their checking accounts to some
degree as savings instruments and to shift funds in and out of such




64

accounts mainly on the basis of interest rate relationships.
developments primarily affected Ml.

Such

The FOMC made repeated

adjustments to its Ml range to take account of changing velocity and
soon after the mid-1980s had eliminated its target for this aggregate.
Many of the shifts were captured within the broader aggregates, but
adjustments to their ranges also had to be made from time to time.
In the last few years, the broader aggregates in turn have
become much less reliable guides for the conduct of policy.
Eventually, these measures may resume a more stable relationship with
the economy, or experience may suggest useful new definitions for the
aggregates.

We are currently investigating several possible

alternative measures.

But, in the meanwhile, the FOMC necessarily has

given less weight to monetary aggregates in the conduct of policy and
has relied on a broad range of indicators of future financial and
economic developments and price pressures.

And, in particular, the

FOMC judged in 1992 that more determined efforts to push the
aggregates into their ranges would not have been consistent with
achieving the nation's longer-term objective of maximum
sustainable economic growth.

Indeed, had there been an attempt to

force M2 and M3 toward the middle of their ranges, intermediate- and
long-term rates by now might have been significantly higher than they
are currently, threatening the durability of the expansion.
This use of a broad range of indicators is appropriate
because achievement of the ranges for growth of particular measures of
money and credit is not, and should not be, the objective of monetary
policy.

Rather, the ranges are a means to an end.

The Humphrey-

Hawkins Act, incorporating this view, does not require that the ranges
be attained in circumstances in which doing so would not be consistent
with achieving the more fundamental economic objectives.




65

Ranges for Money and Credit for 1993
In establishing ranges for the monetary and credit aggregates
in the current year, the FOMC took into account the likelihood that
many of the factors that have acted in recent years to restrain money
and credit growth relative to income would continue, though perhaps
with somewhat diminishing intensity.

The yield curve could well

remain steep, absent very marked progress in deficit reduction or a
distinct break in long-term inflation expectations, which would tend
to lower long-term interest rates.

Banking and thrift

institutions

are unlikely to step up the pace of balance-sheet expansion sharply,
and the large volume of securities they have accumulated in recent
years will allow them to fund a pickup in loan growth without as
marked an acceleration of deposit growth.

And households and firms

are expected to continue to be relatively cautious in their use of
credit.

Other factors may add to tendencies for money to expand more

slowly than income.

For example, a resumption of resolutions by the

Resolution Trust Corporation, which has been inactive for nearly a
year, by shifting assets from thrifts onto government balance sheets,
would tend to substitute federal liabilities for those of thrift
institutions, reducing monetary growth.
Reflecting the expectation that sluggish monetary growth will
be associated with sustainable expansion in the economy, the Federal
Open Market Committee has elected to reduce the ranges for M2 and M3
for 1993 by one-half percentage point.

For M2, a range of 2 to 6

percent, measured as usual on a fourth-quarter-to-fourth-quarter
basis, was established.

A range of 1/2 to 4-1/2 percent was. specified

for M3.

As I have indicated in correspondence with.members of the
Congress, the FOMC does not view the reductions in the monetary ranges




66

as signalling a change in the stance of monetary policy.

And most

emphatically, these reductions do not indicate a desire en the part of
the Federal Reserve to thwart the expansion.

The Federal Reserve, to

the contrary, is endeavoring to conduct monetary policy in a way that
promotes sustainable economic expansion.

The lowering of these ranges

does not imply any change in our fundamental objectives.

The

necessity for a reduction in the monetary ranges at this time is
wholly technical in nature, and is a result of the forces that are
altering the money-income relationship.

Consistent with this view,

the FOMC decided to maintain a range of 4-1/2 to 8-1/2 percent for
domestic nonfinancial sector debt, an aggregate whose relationship
with nominal GDP has been less distorted in the last few years than
that of the monetary aggregates.
Significant uncertainties regarding the appropriate ranges
for monetary growth remain.

While we have made some progress in

understanding the behavior of the money and credit aggregates over the
past year, to a degree this increased understanding has reinforced our
appreciation of the complexity--and limited predictability--of the
economic and financial relationships that affect money growth and its
linkages with the economy.
These uncertainties imply that the relationship between money
and GDP growth could turn out significantly different from what
currently seems likely.

Accordingly, the Federal Reserve again will

interpret the growth of money and credit relative to their ranges in
the context of other indicators of the financial system, the
performance of the economy, and prices.

Should recent trends

affecting the money-income relationship continue, growth of the
monetary aggregates in the lower portions of their ranges might be
expected.




On the other hand, the upper ends of the ranges provide

67

ample room for adequate monetary growth should demands for money
relative to income come more into line with historical patterns.

In

any event, until the relationship between the monetary aggregates and
spending returns to a more reliable basis, flexibility in the
interpretation of the aggregates relative to their new ranges is
required.
Economic Outlook for 1993
Several of the forces affecting relationships between money
and income also complicate the task of assessing the economic outlook
itself.

For example, the prospects for an easing of supply

restrictions on credit from banks and other intermediaries are
difficult to assess, but any major change in this situation could have
important implications for the economy.

While banking institutions

have become much more healthy and are well-positioned to meet an
increase in loan demand, very few signals of any easing of terms or
standards on business loans have been apparent to date.
In addition, other factors that hobbled the economy in the
last several years are likely to persist in 1993, though perhaps with
diminished intensity.

Households and business are likely to remain

cautious in using credit--a healthy development for sustained growth,
but potentially continuing to constrain spending in the short run.
Sizable imbalances in commercial real estate remain, and a significant
rebound in this sector is doubtless several years off.

Government

spending at the federal, state, and local levels is likely to remain
constrained.

A number of foreign nations are confronting

slow

economic growth or recession, which is likely to hold back demand for
our exports.

And it is apparent from recent announcements by several

large firms that corporate restructuring, involving significant
cutbacks in operations and employment, is continuing.




68

Another very considerable uncertainty in the economic outlook
is fiscal policy.

The Congress and the Administration are considering

both short-run fiscal stimulus and steps to reduce the deficit in the
long run.

Obviously, government spending and taxes could be affected

by such measures in such a way as to influence directly the overall
economy this year, although the bulk of any effect likely would occur
in succeeding years.

In addition, depending on the timing,

dimensions, and credibility of any fiscal measures, market interest
rates and stock prices could be affected appreciably, with
implications for private expenditures.
While uncertainties thus remain, the economy appears to have
entered the year with noticeable momentum to spending.

In addition,

inventories are at relatively low levels, and factory orders have been
rising.

Consumer confidence has recovered, and spending on durables

and homes appears to be moving at a brisker pace.

Recent surveys

suggest an appreciable increase in business investment this year.
Against this background, members of the Board and Federal
Reserve Bank presidents project a further gain in economic activity in
1993.

The central tendency of our projections is for real GDP to

increase at a 3 to 3-1/4 percent rate this year.

Such an increase

should result in a decline in the unemployment rate, which would be
expected to finish 1993 at a level of 6-3/4 to 7 percent.

Inflation

is expected to remain low this year.
Containing, and over time eliminating, inflation is a key
element in a strategy to foster maximum sustainable long-run growth of
the economy.

As I have often emphasized, monetary policy, by

achieving and maintaining price stability, can foster a stable
economic and financial environment that is conducive to private
economic planning, savings, investment, and economic growth.




It is no

69

accident that the periods in our nation's history of low inflation
were the times when the economy experienced high rates of private
saving, investment, and hence productivity and economic growth.

When

inflation is low, endeavors to boost profit margins necessarily
involve reductions in cost rather than increasing prices: thus, low
rates of inflation tend to be associated with relatively high
productivity growth.

Conversely, periods of high and rising inflation

here and abroad have been characterized by financial instability, an
excessive amount of resources devoted to protecting financial wealth
rather than production of goods and services, and substandard economic
growth.
Over the past decade or so. our nation has made very
substantial progress toward the achievement of price stability,
reversing a dangerous upward trend of inflation and inflationary
expectations.

Last year's 3-1/4 percent increase in the core CPI was

the lowest in twenty years and far lower than the debilitating doubledigit rates at the close of the 1970s.

As I have indicated to this

Committee on numerous occasions, price stability does not require that
measured inflation literally be zero, but rather is achieved when
inflation is low enough that changes in the general price level are
insignificant for economic and financial planning.

At current

inflation rates, we are thus quite close to attaining this goal.
Going forward, the strategy of monetary policy will be to
provide sufficient liquidity to support the economic expansion while
containing inflationary pressures.

The existing slack implies that

the economy can grow more rapidly than potential GDP for a time,
permitting further reductions in the unemployment rate even while
inflation is contained.




70

Implementing this strategy, however, will be challenging.
Judging the level of potential output and its rate of growth is
difficult.

Recent increases in productivity have been unusually

strong, given the moderate pace of economic growth during much of the
expansion, and it is unclear whether these rates of productivity gain
can be continued.

In addition, the monetary aggregates do not appear

to be giving reliable indications of economic developments and price
pressures, and numerous other uncertainties cloud the particular
features of the outlook.

Monetary policy will have to adjust to

unexpected developments as they occur, taking into account a variety
of economic and financial indicators.
The contributions that monetary policy can make to maximum
sustainable economic growth would be complemented by a fiscal policy
focused on long-term deficit reduction.

In the current environment,

reducing the federal government's drain on scarce savings would take
pressure off long-term interest rates, facilitating the readjustment
of balance sheets and helping to promote capital formation and more
robust economic growth over the longer term.
The Federal Reserve, in formulating monetary policy.
certainly needs to take into account fiscal policy developments.

Of

course, it is not possible for the Federal Reserve to specify in
advance what actions might be taken in the presence of particular
fiscal policy strategies.

Clearly, the course of interest rates and

financial market conditions more generally will depend importantly on
a host of forces — in addition to fiscal policy--affecting the economy
and prices.

And the effects of fiscal policy on the economy in turn

will depend importantly on the credibility of long-run deficit
reduction and the market reaction to any package.

The lower long-term

interest rates that resulted from a credible deficit-reduction plan




71

would themselves have an immediate positive effect on the economy.

In

any event. I can assure you of our shared goal for the American
economy--the greatest possible increase in living standards for our
citizens over time.
The last several years have been difficult, and the economy
is still adjusting to structural imbalances that have built up over
recent decades.
uncertain.

The near-term outlook, as always, is somewhat

But I believe that in many respects the inevitable painful

adjustments have laid the foundation for better performance of our
economy over the longer term.

Financial positions have been

strengthened; inflation is low and should remain subdued: labor
productivity is increasing; resources are being shifted from national
defense to investment and consumption.

Nevertheless, the challenges

ahead for policymakers will be considerable.

While continuing to be

supportive of the expansion of our economy over coming quarters, the
monetary and fiscal authorities alike need to structure our policies
to enable our economy to reach its full potential over time.




72
Supplemental statement of Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal
Reserve Board:
The President is to be commended for placing on the table
for active debate the issue of our burgeoning structural budget
deficit, which will increasingly threaten the stability of our
economic system if we continue to fail to address it.

Leaving

aside the specific details, it is- a serious proposal, its
baseline economic assumptions are plausible, and it is a detailed
program-by-program set of recommendations as distinct from
general goals.
It is obviously very difficult to get a consensus on deficit
cutting.

If it were easy it would have been done long ago.

The

debate among the nation's elected representatives will be
profoundly political, in the best sense of the word.

As the

nation's central bankers, our primary and professional concern is
having the structural deficit sharply reduced and soon.
Time is no longer on our side.

After declining through

1996, the current services deficit starts on an inexorable upward
path again.

The deficit and the mounting federal debt as a

percent of gross domestic product are corrosive forces slowly
undermining the vitality of our free market system.
If we fail to resolve our structural deficit at this time,
the next opportunity will doubtless confront us with still more
difficult choices.

How the deficit is reduced is very important,

that it be done, is crucial.
In this regard, there are certain issues that I have
discussed with this and other committees of the Congress over the




73
- 2 years, which are worth repeating.
First, with current services outlays from 1997 and beyond
rising faster than the tax base, stabilizing the deficit as a
percent of nominal gross domestic product, not to mention a
reduction, would require ever increasing tax rates.

Hence, there

is no alternative to achieving much slower growth of outlays.
This implies not only the need to make cuts now, but to control
future spending impulses.

I trust the President's endeavor to

reign in medical costs will contribute importantly to this goal.
Second, the hope that we can possibly inflate or grow our
way out of the structural deficit is fanciful.

Certainly greater

inflation is not the answer; aside from its serious debilitating
effects on our economic system, higher inflation, given the
explicit and implicit indexing of receipts and expenditures,
would not reduce the deficit.

As I indicated in testimony last

month to the Joint Economic Committee, there is a possibility
that productivity growth may be moving into a faster long-term
channel, boosting real growth over time.

But even^if that turns

out to be the case, it wouldn't by itself resolve the basic longterm imbalance in our budgetary accounts.
Finally, fear that the deficit reduction can be overdone and
create a degree of "fiscal drag" that would significantly harm
the economy, I find misplaced.

In our current political

environment, to presume that the Congress and the President would
jointly cut too much from the deficit too soon is in the words of
my predecessor "nothing I would lose sleep over."




74
- 3 -

The Federal Reserve recognizes that it has an important role
to play in this regard.

In formulating monetary policy, we

certainly need to take into account fiscal policy developments.
But it is not possible for the Federal Reserve to specify in
advance what actions might be taken in the presence of particular
fiscal policy strategies.

Clearly, the course of interest rates

and financial market conditions more generally will depend .,
importantly on a host of forces—in addition to fiscal policy—
affecting the economy and prices.

In any event, I can assure you

of our shared goal for the American economy—the greatest
possible increase in living standards for our citizens over time.




February 19, 1993

75
For use at 9:45 a.m., E.S.T.
Friday
February 19,1993

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Monetary Policy Report to the Congress
Pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978
February 19, 1993




76

Letter of Transmittal

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Washington, D.C., February 19, 1993
THE PRESIDENT OF THE SENATE
THE SPEAKER OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
The Board of Governors is pleased to submit its Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, pursuant to the
Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978.
Sincerely,

Alan Greenspan, Chairman




77
Table of Contents
Page
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook for 1993

1

Section 2:

The Performance of the Economy in 1992

6

Section 3:

Monetary and Financial Developments in 1992

64-740 O - 93 - 4



19

78
Section 1: Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook for 1993
Last July, when the Federal Reserve Board presented its semiannual monetary policy report to the
Congress, there was considerable uncertainty about
the prospects for the economy in the second half of
1992. After a promising start at the beginning of the
year, growth of the economy had slowed once again
in the spring, and various structural adjustments that
had been impeding the pace of the expansion retained considerable force. However, with drag from
the structural adjustments expected to diminish gradually over time and with the economy continuing to
benefit from the substantial easing of money market
conditions that the System had implemented over the
years, the most likely prospect for the economy was
thought to be one of moderate growth in the second
half of the year.
In the event, economic growth did indeed proceed
at an improved pace in the second half of 1992,
although the pickup did not start to become evident in
the incoming economic data until well into the autumn. Fueled by strong increases in household and
business spending, real gross domestic product rose at
an annual rate of 3.6 percent in the second half of the
year. The increase over the four quarters of the year
amounted to 2.9 percent. This was the largest gain in
output since 1988, and, while far from robust by the
standards of past cyclical upswings in activity, it was
a much stronger performance than many analysts—
inside and outside of government—had thought likely,
given the extraordinary headwinds with which the
economy had to contend. Indeed, the performance
of the U.S. economy stands in sharp contrast to that
of a number of major foreign industrial economies
that appear still to be laboring to regain forward
momentum.
Employment has grown since the middle of last
year, but at only a gradual pace. Hiring has been
damped by the ability of firms to meet their output
objectives through hefty increases in productivity.
The unemployment rate, which had risen in the first
half of 1992 in conjunction with a surge in the share
of the working-age population in the lator force.
turned down thereafter as labor force participation fell
back. The unemployment rate in January of this year
was 7.1 percent, more than half a percentage point
below the peak rate of last summer.
Price developments remained favorable in the second half of 1992, and the rise in the consumer price
index over the four quarters of the year amounted to




3 percent, matching the low rate achieved in the
previous year. Consumer energy prices turned back
up in 1992, but the prices of other goods and services
that enter into the CPI generally rose less rapidly than
they had in 1991. Although the CPI spurted '/2 percent
this past month, the underlying trends in labor costs
and prices remain encouraging. The success to date in
keeping inflation in check, while restoring growth,
has had highly salutary effects on financial markets
and on the process of financial reconstruction, the
continuing progress of which is essential to the
achievement of renewed and sustainable prosperity.
The hesitant pace of the economy evident in incoming information throughout much of last year, along
with notable weakness in the monetary and credit
aggregates and steady gains against inflation,
prompted the Federal Reserve to ease monetary conditions three times, bringing short-term rates down by
another full percentage point over the year. The discount rate was reduced to three percent and shortterm rates generally are now at their lowest levels
since the early 1960s.
Long-term rates also fell, on balance. Declines
were limited at times, however, by concerns about
prospective federal budget deficits and about the possibility that inflation might begin to move higher as
the expansion proceeded. Notable decreases in long
rates were registered in late 1992 and early 1993, as
inflation remained subdued and as statements by
Administration officials suggested that they would
seek only limited near-term fiscal stimulus and that
proposals to make substantial cuts in the federal budget deficit over time were under serious consideration.
The trade-weighted foreign exchange value of the
dollar in terms of the other Group-of-Ten currencies
appreciated on balance over the course of 1992 and
rose further during the first weeks of 1993. The dollar
benefited from the improved performance of the U.S.
economy relative to conditions in other industrial
countries.
Growth of the monetary aggregates slowed last
year despite an acceleration in nominal spending and
income. For the year, M2 advanced 1.9 percent, below
the 2'/2 percent lower end of its target range. M3 also
came in under its 1 to 5 percent target range, growing
only .5 percent. The Federal Reserve did not make
greater efforts to boost growth to within these ranges

79
because, as the year went on, it became increasingly
clear that slow growth of the broad money aggregates
did not indicate that financial market conditions were
impeding the expansion of spending and income. In
fact, growth of nominal GDP exceeded that of M2 by
31/2 percentage points last year and that of M3 by
43/4 percentage points. Not only did data on spending
itself show a firming trend over the year, but narrow
money (Ml) and reserves were expanding rapidly—
suggesting to some that liquidity was quite ample—
and the growth of debt, while restrained, was considerably in excess of that of the broader monetary
aggregates.
Nominal GDP growth last year, which picked up to
5.4 percent from 3.5 percent in 1991, was fueled by
spending that was financed largely outside of banks
and other depositories, whose liabilities constitute the
lion's share of the monetary aggregates. Spurred in
part by advances in equity prices and by declines in
longer-term interest rates, businesses and households
strengthened their balance sheets by raising funds in
bond, mortgage, and equity markets, and repaying
bank loans and other short-term debt. This shift in the
focus of financing efforts toward the capital markets,
a process which has been in progress for the last
couple of years, has helped to redress financial distortions that accompanied the buildup of debt and the
rapid rise in some asset prices in the 1980s.
The low level of credit demanded from depositories has meant that these institutions have not needed
to seek large volumes of deposits. As a consequence,
rates paid on deposits have been adjusted downward
rapidly as short-term market rates have declined. Savers, reacting to the lower deposit rates and to attractive returns on bonds and equity, have shifted funds
from M2 deposits into the capital markets. One
method savers have used to capture these higher
capital market yields has been through purchases of
bond and stock mutual funds, which are not included
in the monetary aggregates, and which together experienced record inflows in 1992. Moreover, consumer
loan rates have fallen by less than deposit rates, and
households appear to be using M2 assets to repay
consumer debt or restrain its growth. The combination of rate incentives, desires to strengthen balance
sheets, and the greater availability at low transaction
cost of a broadened array of savings vehicles beyond
traditional deposits appear to have distorted, at least
for a time, the traditional relationship between levels
of M2 and M3 assets and given levels of spending.
Although growth of M2 and M3 was very weak last
year, Ml accelerated to 14.3 percent, the second fast-




est annual increase recorded in the official series,
which begins in 1959. In part, this pickup owed to the
expansion of spending, but it mainly reflected the
tendency for rates on liquid deposits to adjust downward less rapidly than those on time deposits. In
response, savers shifted substantial volumes of funds
from maturing time deposits to NOW accounts. In
addition, businesses boosted their demand deposits
substantially. To support this growth in transactions
deposits, the Federal Reserve added substantial volumes of reserves in 1992. Total reserves increased
20 percent last year, and the monetary base, which
includes currency outstanding as well as reserves,
increased 10.5 percent, the highest rate ever registered in the official series.
Decisions to strengthen balance sheets had a
smaller but significant effect on debt growth. The debt
of nonfinancial sectors is estimated to have expanded
4.6 percent, only slightly faster than in 1991 and just
above the lower end of its monitoring range. With
debt growing less rapidly than income and with
declines in market interest rates allowing higher cost
debt to be rolled over at lower rates, households and
businesses made substantial further progress in reducing debt service burdens.

Monetary Objectives for 1993
The aim of the Federal Open Market Committee
in 1993 is to promote financial conditions that will
help to maintain the greater momentum that the economy developed in 1992 and to consolidate the trend
toward lower inflation. The objectives for the monetary aggregates in 1993 were set with that aim in
mind.
At its July 1992 meeting, the Committee had provisionally chosen the same ranges for 1993 as it was
confirming for 1992—2'/2 to 6'/2 percent for M2 and
1 to 5 percent for M3, with a monitoring range for the
nonfinancial debt aggregate of 4!/2 to 8'/2 percent. At
that time, the Committee noted that the extent and
duration of deviations of money growth from historical relationships remained highly uncertain and that
the actual setting, in February, of 1993 ranges consistent with the basic policy objectives would need to be
made in light of additional experience and analysis.
At its February meeting, in reviewing the ranges
provisionally chosen for 1993, the Committee noted
that nominal spending had accelerated considerably
in 1992 despite the quite sluggish growth of M2
and M3 throughout the year. The Committee viewed
this development as underscoring the importance that

80
Ranges for Growth of Monetary and Credit Aggregates
1991

1992

1993

Percentage change,
fourth quarter to fourth quarter
1

1

M2

2 /2 to 6 /2

2V2 to 61/2

2 to 6

M3

1 to 5

1 to 5

1

Debt

4 /2 to 8 /2

1

1

special, and historically anomalous, forces have had
in restraining the growth of broad money relative to
spending. While the intensity of some of these forces
might diminish in 1993, as borrowers and lenders
achieve more comfortable balance sheet positions,
they are unlikely to end. For example, the substantial
volume of liquid securities on banks' balance sheets
suggested that they will not become vigorous bidders
for deposits in 1993 even if, as expected, lending
picks up. In addition, the yield curve, although it had
begun to flatten a bit early in the new year, is likely to
continue to provide savers an incentive to shift funds
out of monetary assets and into capital markets—
a process facilitated by the growing availability of
mutual funds at banks and thrifts.
Given that these forces, and others, tending to
channel funds around depository institutions and
hence to raise velocity—the ratio of nominal GDP to
money—seem likely to persist in 1993, a downward
adjustment to the money ranges is appropriate to take
account of the expected atypical behavior of velocity:
Lower money growth than normally expected would
be sufficient to support substantial growth in income.
With this in mind, the Committee made a technical
downward adjustment in the target growth ranges for
M2 and M3, reducing the upper and lower ends of
each range by '/2 percentage point.
The strength of the influences depressing money
growth relative to income remains somewhat uncertain, however. If they persist in 1993 to the same
extent as in 1992, growth of M2 and M3 in the lower
portions of their reduced target ranges would be consistent with substantial further growth of nominal
spending. Alternatively, the upper ends of the target
ranges would accommodate ample provision of
liquidity to support further economic expansion even
if the growth of money and income were to begin
coming into more normal alignment, and the recent




1

4 /2

tO 81/2

/2 tO 41/2

41/2 to 81/2

high rate of increase in velocity were to slow. The
Committee will continue to examine money growth
as the year unfolds for evidence on developing economic and financial conditions. As in the past, the
Federal Reserve will be guided also by a careful
assessment of a wide variety of other financial and
economic indicators. The Committee's primary concern, as in 1992, will remain that of fostering financial
conditions conducive to sustained economic expansion and a noninflationary environment.
For debt growth, which has been less damped by
special forces than has the expansion of the broader
monetary aggregates, last year's range was retained
for 1993. Federal debt growth again is likely to be
substantial. Growth of the debt of nonfederal sectors
is expected to accelerate somewhat as borrowers'
balance sheets continue to improve, as intermediaries
become more willing to lend, and as the economy
expands. Nevertheless, the growth of nonfederal debt
is expected to remain below that of nominal GDP, a
development the Committee sees as contributing to
building the sound financial foundation crucial to a
sustained economic expansion.

Economic Projections for 1993
Although the economy and the financial markets
continue to face difficult adjustments, the governors
and Bank presidents think that the most likely prospect for 1993 is that economic growth will proceed at
a moderate pace. The growth of output probably will
be supported by further gains in productivity, the
ultimate source of increased real income and
improved living standards over the long run. In addition, increases in employment are expected to be
large enough to bring further gradual declines in the
unemployment rate over the course of 1993. Inflation is expected to remain subdued, boding well for
sustained expansion in 1993 and beyond.

81
Economic Projections for 1993
Measure

Memo:
1992 Actual

FOMC Members and
Other FRB Presidents
Central
Tendency

Range
Percentage change,
fourth quarter to fourth quarter
Nominal GDP
Real GDP
Consumer price index1

5.4
2.9
3.1

5 /4 to 6 /4

Average level in the
fourth quarter, percent2
Unemployment rate

7.3

6 /2 to 7

1

1

1

2 /2 to 4

2V2 to 3

1

5V2 to 6
3 to 31/4
1
2 /2 to 2%

6% to 7

1. CPI for all urban consumers.
2. Percentage of the civilian labor force.

The governors' and Bank presidents' forecasts of
real GDP growth over the four quarters of 1993 span
a range of 2'/2 percent to 4 percent, with the central
tendency of the forecasts in a range of 3 to 31/4 percent. In considering the possible outcomes for 1993,
the governors and Bank presidents cited the degree of
momentum that appears to have developed in the
economy in the latter part of 1992 and early 1993.
The various balance sheet problems that apparently
retarded growth of the economy during the early
phases of the current expansion, while by no means
fully resolved, seem to be receding. In addition, sectors such as residential construction, business investment, and consumer durables clearly are benefiting
from the declines that have occurred in interest rates.
However, impediments to more rapid expansion
still are present. Government spending for defense
appears likely to continue to decline for some time to
come. More broadly, balance sheet repair and business restructuring, which have exerted major restraint
on economic activity in recent years, still are in
process, despite the apparent improvement in business finances in 1992. Indeed, the new year has
brought additional announcements of business restructurings in a variety of industries, both defense-related
and other. These changes are leading to an economy
that is more productive and competitive, but at the
cost of some dislocation and disruption in the short
run. The magnitude of structural changes like these is
a special uncertainty in the economic outlook for the
remainder of the year. With regard to the external
sector, many foreign industrial countries are experi-




encing prolonged economic weakness. Under the circumstances, the growth of U.S. exports, while remaining positive, may well fall short of the growth of
imports again in 1993, exerting a drag on real GDP in
contrast with the substantial impetus in the period up
to early 1991.
Despite the job cutbacks at some large companies,
other firms, especially smaller ones, are adding to
payrolls, albeit cautiously, and total employment has
been rising modestly. The governors and Bank presidents expect this pattern to persist, with net gains in
employment during 1993 likely to be sufficient to
bring the unemployment rate down somewhat further
over the course of the year. The central tendency of
the unemployment rate forecasts for the fourth quarter
of 1993 extends from 63A percent to 7 percent; the
remaining forecasts of the System officials range
down to about 61/2 percent.
The governors' and Bank presidents' forecasts of
the rise in the consumer price index over the four
quarters of 1993 extend from a low of 21/2 percent to a
high of 3 percent. Within that range, a large majority
of the forecasts are clustered in the span of 2'/2 to
23/4 percent. The considerable progress that has been
made in bringing down inflation during the past
decade is providing one of the essential underpinnings for the sustained growth of real living standards
over the long run.
However, achieving a satisfactory economic performance in 1993—and in the years thereafter—will
depend on initiatives in many types of policy other

82
than monetary policy. In coming months, Congress
and the new Administration will be grappling with a
host of issues, including those related to fiscal policy,
regulatory policy and foreign trade policy. Far-sighted
approaches are needed in all those areas, if the economy is to perform at its full potential over the long
haul. In framing regulatory policy and foreign trade
policy, Congress and the Administration will need to
keep an eye on potential costs and rigidities that could




sap the vigor of a market economy. With regard to
fiscal policy, credible action to reduce the prospective
size of future federal budget deficits could yield a
very direct and meaningful payoff in the form of
lower long-term interest rates than otherwise would
prevail. Such action would encourage capital investment and would go far toward relieving anxieties that
many of the nation's citizens still have about longerrun economic prospects.

83
Section 2: The Performance of the Economy in 1992
The economy began to exhibit renewed firmness in
1992, overcoming a host of impediments that have
been working to retard the growth of activity. With
the strengthening of growth in the second half, to a
3.6 percent rate, the rise in real GDP over the year
cumulated to 2.9 percent, the strongest gain since
1988. Employment also picked up in 1992, but rather
slowly; the unemployment rate continued to move up
in the first half of the year, but thereafter followed a
course of gradual decline. Inflation continued to trend
lower in 1992, with most broad price indexes showing increases that were among the smallest since the
mid-1960s.
Real GDP
Percent change, annual rate

HnH
3

6

The growth of household and business expenditures picked up appreciably in 1992. Households, for
their part, began to spend more freely on motor vehicles and other goods, and their purchases of homes
also strengthened, spurring additional gains in residential construction. Businesses began investing more
heavily in new equipment; much of that gain went for
computers and other electronic equipment embodying
new technologies. Business outlays for nonresidential
construction declined, on net, over the year, but by a
much smaller amount than in 1991. In total, the final
purchases of households and businesses rose about
4'/4 percent in real terms in 1992, after declining in
each of the two previous years; the 1992 gain matched
that of 1988 and otherwise was the largest in eight
years. By contrast, governments at all levels continued to be burdened by huge budget deficits in 1992,
and, for a second year, their combined purchases of




goods and services changed little in real terms. In
addition, export growth was slowed by weakness of
activity in several foreign industrial economies;
despite improvement in the second half, the rise in
real exports of goods and services over the year,
3'/2 percent, was only about half as large as the annual
gains in 1990 and 1991. Meanwhile, the faster growth
of domestic spending pushed up the growth in imports
of goods and services to 9'/4 percent in 1992.
Further progress was made in reducing inflation
last year. The consumer price index excluding food
and energy—a measure widely used in gauging the
underlying trend of inflation—increased about
3!/2 percent over the four quarters of 1992; this was a
full percentage point less than the increase during
1991. The total CPI rose about 3 percent over the four
quarters of 1992, the same as in the previous year;
energy prices, which had fallen sharply in 1991,
turned up slightly this past year, while increases in
food prices were quite small for the second year in a
row. Except for 1986, when the CPI was pulled down
by a collapse of world oil prices, the increases of the
past two years are the smallest in a quarter century.

The Household Sector
The financial condition of households improved in
1992. Income growth picked up a little in the aggregate, the strains on household balance sheets eased a
bit, and the spirits of consumers brightened markedly toward year-end. Growth in consumer spending
followed a stop-and-go pattern through midsummer, but the gains thereafter were steadier and
fairly sizable overall. Spending for residential investment also advanced over the year, by a considerable
amount in total.
The aggregate wealth of households appears to
have increased further during 1992. With stock prices
increasing, the value of households' financial assets
rose moderately, and the value of residential real
estate also moved up, on average. On the liability
side, households remained cautious in taking on new
debt in 1992, and the burden of carrying debt continued to ease, owing both to slow growth in the volume
of debt outstanding and to the further reductions in
interest rates, which facilitated the ongoing substitution of new, lower-cost debt for old, higher-cost obligations. The incidence of households experiencing
loan repayment difficulties diminished over the year.

84
Income growth picked up moderately in 1992.
Wages and salaries rose about 4'/4 percent in nominal
terms, after a gain of only 21A percent in 1991. In
addition, proprietors' incomes benefited from the
strengthening of economic activity, and, with corporate profits on the rise, the dividends paid to shareholders more than reversed their decline of the previous year. Transfer payments, which had soared as the
economy softened in 1990 and 1991, continued to
grow rapidly in 1992. By contrast, interest income
trended sharply lower, as the rates of return on household deposits and other financial assets fell further.
Total after-tax income got a temporary boost in 1992
from an adjustment of federal tax withholdings that
took effect at the start of March. With inflation low,
real disposable personal income increased nearly
21/2 percent over the year—not a large gain by past
cyclical standards, but nonetheless the biggest since
1988.
Income and Consumption
Percent change, annual rate

[] Real Disposable Personal Income
H Real Personal Consumption Expenditures

r-n

LO

Real personal consumption expenditures rose about
3'/4 percent over the four quarters of 1992, after
essentially no gain over the two previous years. For a
considerable part of 1992, the increases in spending
were interspersed with stretches of sluggishness. A
surge in consumer expenditures early in the year was
followed by listlessness during the spring, and a second jump in spending around mid-year was followed
by still another bout of slow growth during the summer. However, the last few months of the year brought
fairly sizable advances, boosting the growth of consumption expenditures to a rate of more than 4 percent in the fourth quarter.
Consumer expenditures for motor vehicles increased about 9 percent over the four quarters of
1992. More than half of that gain came in the fourth




quarter, when sales of new vehicles were boosted
by special promotional incentives and, apparently, by
a growing perception among consumers that better
economic conditions lay ahead. At the start of 1993,
after some of the more highly-publicized promotional
programs had ended, sales of cars and light trucks
fell sharply for a brief time, but they since appear to
have regained strength. More than likely, some fundamental support for sales is coming from the replacement needs of persons who had put off buying new
vehicles during the recession and the early phases of
the recovery.
Spending picked up during the second half of 1992
for many items other than motor vehicles, with notable gains in categories in which an element of discretion typically enters into households' purchasing decisions. Real outlays for furniture and household
equipment rose at an annual rate of nearly 15 percent
in the second half of 1992, and real expenditures for
apparel climbed at nearly a 10 percent rate. In total,
spending for consumer durables other than motor
vehicles grew about 9 percent in real terms over the
four quarters of 1992, after declining in each of the
two previous years. Real outlays for nondurables,
which also had fallen in both 1990 and 1991, rose
almost 3 percent in the latest year. Real expenditures
for services increased about 2 percent during 1992,
slightly faster than in other recent years.
The personal saving rate—the share of disposable
income not used for consumption or other outlays—
rose moderately in the first half of the year, when
concerns of households about the prospects for the
economy apparently led them to adopt more cautious
attitudes toward spending. The rate then turned down
in the second half of the year, as consumers began to
spend more freely. The fourth-quarter rate was
slightly below the average for 1992, but it was well
within the range of quarterly observations seen over
the past several years.
Real outlays for residential investment rose 15 percent during 1992, climbing to a fourth-quarter level
nearly 25 percent above their recession low of early
1991. Most of the 1992 rise in residential investment
came in the form of increased construction of singlefamily housing units, which benefited from the further
net reduction in mortgage interest rates over the
course of the year. Outlays for home improvements,
which make up about one-fifth of total residential
investment, also increased in 1992, after declining in
each of the three previous years; repair of the damage
caused by Hurricane Andrew accounted for part of
that gain. By contrast, multifamily housing remained
depressed; high vacancy rates and unfavorable demo-

85
Private Housing Starts
Annual rate, millions of units
Quarterly average

0.4

no doubt have deterred some buyers from taking
advantage of the lower rates on home mortgages.
More broadly, recent demographic trends have been
less favorable to growth in the demand for singlefamily housing than were the trends of the mid-1980s.
The declines in house prices that have occurred in a
number of regions in recent years—and the more
general lack of any real price appreciation to speak
of—also may have affected demand to some extent;
certainly, housing is no longer viewed by potential
buyers as the sure-fire, high-yield investment that it
was once thought to be.
Builders, for their part, have remained a little cautious, as have the lenders who finance new construction. In many cases, houses are being started only
when a buyer actually is lined up; eagerness to build
in anticipation of future sales is not widely apparent.

graphic trends continued to be big obstacles to new
construction activity in that portion of the market.
As with consumer spending, the gains in singlefamily housing activity tended to come in intermittent
bursts through much of 1992. Sales of new homes
surged early in the year, weakened in the spring,
surged again during the summer, and then fell back
just a touch in the fourth quarter; on net, the increase
over the year amounted to 12 percent. Mortgage interest rates, while lower than in 1QQ1. exhibited some
mild swings during 1992, and these swings appear to
have contributed to the fluctuations in home sales. In
addition, proposals early in the year for a tax credit
for first-time homebuyers may have affected the timing of purchases to some degree.
Construction activity in the single-family sector
also had its ups and downs in 1992, influenced by
unusual weather patterns as well as by the fluctuations
in sales. Nonetheless, the trend over the year as a
whole was decidedly upward, and the average level of
starts in the fourth quarter was about 20 percent above
that of a year earlier. In January, single-family starts
fell back somewhat; volatility in the monthly data on
starts is not unusual at this time of year, however.
Despite the large gains seen in 1992, starts in the
single-family sector have retraced only part of the
decline that took place in the late 1980s and early
1990s. Strong impetus for recovery has come from
declines in mortgage interest rates, which have been
considerably lower this past year than they were in
1986, when single-family starts were at their most
recent annual peak. However, a number of other
developments have continued to retard the recovery
of housing activity. Uncertainties about job prospects




In the multifamily sector, the number of units
started in 1992 was about 75 percent below the peak
rates of the mid-1980s; the sector accounted for only
6 percent of total residential investment this past year.
The overbuilding that occurred in the multifamily
sector in the mid-1980s led to high vacancy rates that
have stymied activity ever since. In that regard, little
progress was made in reducing vacancy rates for
multifamily rental units in 1992, despite the greatly
diminished level of new construction. The speed at
which the excess supply of space can be worked off is
being limited by declines in the population of young
adults, as well as by the slow rate of depreciation of
these long-lived structures.

The Business Sector
The past year brought moderate increases in activity in the business sector of the economy. Production, sales, and orders rose, on net, over the year, and
business profits continued to swing back up from the
recession lows of 1991. Many businesses continued
to undertake major structural changes designed to cut
costs and enhance efficiency. Those changes were
manifest both through reorganization of existing
operations and through investment in new technologies. Businesses also continued to shore up their
finances, trimming away debt and building equity.
Financial pressures persisted in the business sector in
1992, but, in general, they seemed to become less
acute as the year progressed.
Industrial output rose nearly 3 percent from December of 1991 to December of 1992. Production fell in
the first month of 1992, but then picked up, rising
about '/2 percent per month from February through

86
Industrial Production

Changes in Real Nonfarm Business Inventories
Index 1987 = 100

Annual rate, billions of 1987 dollars

110

n n n»

nlln

1989

1990

1991

1992

1989

May. During the summer, the expansion of activity
seemed to be losing momentum; orders and shipments fell slightly, on net, from May to August,
factory inventories backed up a little, and industrial
production essentially flattened out over a four-month
stretch. However, orders and shipments began moving up once again in September, and they increased
considerably in the fourth quarter. Industrial production also picked up once again in the fourth quarter,
and a further gain, amounting to 0.4 percent, was
recorded in January of this year.
Business profits, which had taken a turn for the
better late in 1991, improved further during 1992. The
operating profits earned by nonfinancial corporations
from their domestic operations rose 18 percent from
the final quarter of 1991 to the third quarter of 1992,
Before-tax Profit Share of
Gross Domestic Product*

1988

1990

1992

'Profits from domestic operations with inventory valuation and
capital consumption adjustments divided by gross domestic
product of nonfinancial corporate sector.




1991

1992

and a further gain seems implicit in the available data
for the fourth quarter. (An actual estimate of fourthquarter profits will not be published by the Commerce
Department until late March.) Profits of these firms
have been lifted, in part, by increases in the volume of
output since the end of the recession. In addition, tight
control over costs has led to increases in profits per
unit of output. Unit labor costs of nonfinancial corporations have risen only slightly since the start of the
current economic expansion, and their net interest
costs have declined sharply, owing to lower interest
rates and restraint in the use of debt. The domestic
profits of financial corporations were strong in the
first half of 1992, but were severely depressed in the
third quarter by the unprecedented losses that insurance companies suffered in the wake of Hurricane
Andrew; in the absence of the hurricane, profits in the
financial sector would have increased in the third
quarter.
The economic condition of smaller companies also
seemed to improve somewhat in 1992. The past year's
estimated rise in the profits of nonfarm proprietors
was the largest annual gain since the mid-1980s;
increases had been relatively small over the three
previous years.

Nonfinancial Corporations

1986

1990

The net income of farm proprietors turned back up
in 1992, after a moderate decline in 1991. Farm
output rose to a record high in 1992, with strong gains
for both crops and livestock. Prices, meanwhile,
lagged year-earlier levels through much of 1992, but
most of that slippage in farm prices already had taken
place by the start of the year; the average level of
farm prices in December of 1992 actually was about
the same as that of a year earlier. Farm production
expenses edged down for a second year, as farm

87
Real Business Fixed Investment
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

[] Structures

15

H Producers' Durable Equipment

JL
operators, like their nonfarm counterparts, continued
to maintain tight control over costs.
Business investment in fixed capital rose about
8 percent in real terms during 1992, more than reversing the decline of the previous year. Spending for
equipment increased in each quarter of 1992, and the
gains cumulated to nearly 12 percent by the fourth
quarter; with spare capacity still extensive in most
industries in 1992, much of the gain in equipment
spending over the year probably was a result of the
desire of businesses to modernize their operations.
Meanwhile, nonresidential construction spending,
which had plunged 14 percent in 1991, fell by a much
smaller amount in 1992—1'/2 percent according to
the estimate in the most recent GDP report.
Spending for computers was at the forefront of the
rise in equipment outlays in 1992. In terms of annual
averages, the nominal outlays for office and computing equipment rose about 17 percent; the gains in
real terms were much greater still, as technological
advances and competitive market conditions combined to continue driving down the price of real,
effective computing power. Businesses also boosted
their outlays for telecommunications equipment, especially in the second half of 1992. Spending for motor
vehicles strengthened in 1992, and investment in
industrial equipment edged up after three years of
decline. Spending for aircraft traced out a volatile
pattern during 1992 and, for the year as a whole, was
down only moderately from the high level of 1991;
however, these outlays closed out the year on a weak
note, and prospects for 1993 are not encouraging,
given the losses that have been experienced by airline
companies and the related cancellations and stretchouts of orders.




The small decline in nonresidential construction
outlays during 1992 reflected some widely divergent
trends across the various types of construction activity. Spending for new office buildings fell sharply
further during the year, to a fourth-quarter level that
was about 60 percent below the peak of the mid1980s. In addition, the real outlays for industrial
structures declined in 1992 for the second year in a
row, influenced, no doubt, by the current high levels
of unused industrial capacity and by the ongoing
trend toward tighter control of inventories and concomitant reductions in needed storage space. Annual
outlays for oil and gas drilling also fell further in
1992; a rise in drilling in the year's final quarter
probably was prompted mainly by a year-end phaseout of certain tax incentives, although some drillers
may also have been responding to an upturn in natural
gas prices over the year.
Other types of construction activity fared better in
1992. Spending for commercial structures other than
office buildings moved up over the year, after sharp
declines in both 1990 and 1991, and the outlays of
utilities rose appreciably, boosted by environmental
requirements as well as by further moderate additions
to capacity. Increases in construction spending also
were reported for various types of institutional structures, such as religious facilities and hospitals.
The Government Sector
Government purchases of goods and services, the
portion of government spending that is included in
GDP, increased slightly in real terms over the course
of 1992, after declining slightly during 1991. Federal purchases fell '/2 percent in real terms over the
Real Federal Purchases
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

U
•J-1 6

1986

1988

1990

1992

88
Real State and Local Purchases
Percent change. Q4 to Q4

1986

1988

1990

1992

year, as a further decline in real defense purchases
more than offset another year of increase in real nondefense purchases. State and local purchases of goods
and services increased about 1 l/i percent during 1992,
a slightly larger rise than in 1991, but still well below
the rates of increase seen through much of the 1980s.
Governments at all levels continued to be plagued
by severe budgetary imbalances in 1992. At the federal level, the unified budget deficit rose about
$20 billion in fiscal year 1992, to a level of $290 billion. With the economy gradually strengthening, the
rate of increase in federal receipts picked up a little, to
3'/2 percent, from only 2!A percent in fiscal 1991.
However, spending once again rose faster than
receipts; total federal outlays were up 4V2 percent in
fiscal 1992, after a rise of nearly 53/4 percent in the
previous fiscal year.
Federal Unified Budget Deficit




Billions of dollars

The rates of growth in total spending in 1991 and
1992 may well understate the degree of upward
momentum in federal outlays in those years. In 1991,
total spending was held down considerably by a convention used in the federal budget to account for the
flow of contributions to the United States from its
allies in the Gulf War. Those contributions were
counted as negative defense outlays, rather than as
additions to receipts. Additional contributions from
the allied countries were received in fiscal year 1992,
but were much smaller than those of 1991. Another
important factor at work in 1992, however, was a
delay in funding the activities of the Resolution Trust
Corporation (RTC), which kept the 1992 outlays for
deposit insurance programs much lower than they
otherwise would have been.
Excluding the outlays for deposit insurance and the
effect of the allied contributions on reported levels of
defense spending, federal expenditures rose about
6'/2 percent in nominal terms in fiscal year 1992, after
an increase of nearly 9 percent in fiscal year 1991.
Spending for entitlements, especially those related to
health care and income support, continued to grow
very rapidly in 1992. In the health area, federal outlays for Medicaid increased nearly 30 percent, and
spending for Medicare rose 14 percent. Spending for
income security was boosted in 1992 by further large
increases in unemployment benefits and food stamp
disbursements. In dollar terms, the combined rise in
outlays for health care and income security amounted
to about $60 billion. Increased expenditures for social
security added almost another $20 billion.
Combined spending for all other programs rose
only slightly in fiscal year 1992. Within that broad
and diverse grouping, defense outlays fell sharply in
nominal terms, once adjustment is made for the allied
contributions, but some nondefense functions posted
large increases in outlays.
State and local governments saw no relief from
budgetary pressures in 1992. The combined deficit in
their operating and capital accounts, net of social
insurance funds, widened a bit over the first three
quarters of the year, reversing the small improvement
that had been achieved in the latter part of 1991. As is
true at the federal level, a rapidly rising level of
mandated transfer payments to individuals for health
and income support is at the core of the budget
difficulties of many states and localities; in nominal
terms, transfer payments in the fourth quarter were
about 16 percent above the level of a year earlier.

1990

Construction spending by state and local governments picked up in 1992. According to preliminary

89
data, the real gain in these outlays amounted to about
3Vi percent over the four quarters of the year. Spending for highways increased considerably in 1992, and
outlays for buildings other than schools were strong
in the first half of the year. Construction of educational facilities, which has been boosted by increases
in the school-age population in recent years, rose
further in 1992, but the increase was small, both in
absolute terms and relative to the gains in most other
recent years.
Growth in other major categories of state and
local expenditures was restrained. Compensation of
employees, which accounts for more than half of total
state and local expenditures, increased about 1 '/2 percent in real terms over the four quarters of 1992; in
nominal terms, the rise over the year amounted to
about 4'/2 percent, similar to that of 1991 but much
less than the nominal increases seen in the years
before 1991. Restraint on wage growth was widespread in the state and local sector in 1992, and
although total employment in the sector grew a little
faster than in 1991, hiring freezes, furloughs, and
layoffs continued to be reported in some hard-pressed
jurisdictions. State and local purchases of durable and
nondurable goods—such things as equipment and
supplies—apparently grew little in real terms over the
course of 1992. Real purchases of services from outside suppliers apparently edged down for the third
year in a row.
Many states and localities have implemented tax
increases in recent years in an effort to bolster
receipts. In addition, grants-in-aid from the federal
government have been rising rapidly, and, in 1992,
improvement in the economy helped boost receipts to
some degree. In total, state and local receipts rose
7'/2 percent in annual average terms in 1992, outpacing the growth of nominal GDP by a considerable
amount. However, for the third year in a row, the
increase in receipts fell short of the annual rise in
nominal expenditures, which amounted to 8 percent
in 1992.

The External Sector
The trade-weighted foreign exchange value of the
U.S. dollar, measured in terms of the other G-10
currencies, rose nearly 6 percent on balance from
December 1991 to December 1992. The dollar
increased over the first three months of 1992 amid
expectations of strengthening economic recovery in
the United States and slowing economic growth
abroad. Over the summer, however, the dollar
declined to a point below the previous year's low as




Foreign Exchange Value of the U.S. Dollar *
Index, March 1973 = 100

100

75

j
1986

I
1988

I

I
1990

I

50
1992

•Index of weighted average foreign exchange value of U.S. dollar
in terms of currencies of other G-10 countries. Weights are based
on 1972-76 global trade of each of the 10 countries.

growth of the U.S. economy was perceived to be
more sluggish than expected and as the Federal
Reserve eased short-term interest rates further. The
dollar reversed direction again in the fall, strengthening sharply in the wake of turmoil in the European
Monetary System and, more importantly, on evidence of increased momentum in the U.S. economic
expansion and sluggish conditions in foreign industrial economies. The dollar's rise continued into the
early weeks of 1993.
On a bilateral basis, the net rise in the weightedaverage dollar over 1992 primarily reflected sharp
increases in the dollar's value against several European currencies and against the Canadian dollar. Denmark's rejection of the Maastricht Treaty in early
June called into question the future of European monetary and political union and led to pressures on the
exchange rate mechanism (ERM) of the European
Monetary System. In September, those pressures
intensified enough to force Italy and the United Kingdom to withdraw from the ERM, and their currencies
depreciated sharply. For the year as a whole, the
dollar appreciated against those two currencies by
19 percent and 18 percent, respectively. Several other
European currencies, including those of Spain, Portugal, and the Scandinavian countries, also depreciated
sharply against the dollar in the autumn. The parity of
the French franc with the German mark was maintained within the ERM, but at the cost of relatively
high French short-term interest rates in the face of a
sluggish French economy and rising unemployment.
The dollar fell more than 7 percent against the
German mark from December 1991 to August 1992,

90
as German monetary policy, responding to relatively
high German money growth and inflation, remained
tight longer than market participants had expected.
That decline of the dollar was more than reversed
during the fall and winter, however, as it became clear
that German economic activity had turned significantly downward and as German monetary policy
was eased somewhat. By mid-February 1993, the
dollar was about 5 percent higher against the mark
than it had been in December 1991.
The dollar depreciated about 6 percent on balance
against the Japanese yen during 1992 and early 1993,
despite a noticeable decline in Japanese GDP during
the second and third quarters and a significant reduction in Japanese interest rates. The net strengthening
of the yen probably can be attributed, at least in part,
to market reactions to a substantial widening of
Japan's external surplus.
The U.S. merchandise trade deficit widened to
about $84 billion in 1992, compared with $65 billion
in 1991 (Census basis). Imports grew about twice as
fast as exports as the U.S. economic recovery gained
some momentum while economic growth in U.S. markets abroad was sluggish on average. Early in the
year, the deficit narrowed somewhat when a drop in
oil prices lowered the value of imports. The deficit
widened sharply in the second quarter, however,
when imports surged and exports remained about
unchanged. During the second half of 1992, imports
continued to expand somewhat more rapidly than
exports, and the deficit increased further.

one-time cash transfers associated with the Gulf War
accounted for most of the difference; these transfers
had reduced the current account deficit by $42 billion
in 1991, but they reduced it by only about $2 billion
at an annual rate during the first three quarters of
1992. Excluding these transfers, the current account
deficit weakened somewhat less than the trade deficit,
owing to a strengthening of net service receipts.
U.S. merchandise exports grew 41/2 percent in real
terms over the four quarters of 1992. Most of the
increase occurred in the second half of the year and
consisted largely of stronger shipments of agricultural
goods, computers, other machinery, and automotive
products. Excluding agricultural products and computers, the quantity of exports grew only 1 percent in
1992 compared with a rise of 6J/2 percent in 1991; this
slowdown was mainly a reflection of sluggish demand
in key industrial countries. By region of the world,
most of the increase in exports during 1992 went to
areas that continued to register moderate to fairly
strong rates of economic growth—primarily developing countries in Asia and Latin America. Exports to
Japan and to European countries, whose growth rates
probably averaged less than 1 percent when weighted
by the shares of those countries in U.S. exports,
actually declined in 1992.

The current account balance worsened substantially more than the trade deficit, moving from near
balance in 1991 to a deficit of $51 billion at an annual
rate over the first three quarters of 1992. However,

Merchandise imports grew IOV2 percent in real
terms during 1992. Two categories—oil and computers, the latter of which includes peripherals and
parts—accounted for a significant portion of that rise.
Oil imports rose 13 percent over the four quarters of
1992 as U.S. consumption of petroleum products
recovered from depressed levels in 1991 and as
domestic oil production resumed its long-run downtrend. U.S. domestic sales of computers were very
strong beginning in the summer, fueled by price wars

U.S. Current Account

U.S. Real Merchandise Trade

Annual rate, billions of dollars

Annual rate, billions of 1987 dollars

Exports
120

J

I

I

1986




1988

1

1
1990

1

1
1992

U

180

225

J-1-1-1-1-11100
1986
1988
1990
1992

91
and by a push on the part of U.S. businesses to
upgrade PCs and workstations to take advantage of
improvements in software. Most of the sales were in
the lower end of the spectrum of computer products—
items that often are imported. Imports of products
other than oil and computers increased 51A percent in
1992 as domestic demand in the United States picked
up. The strongest increases were in a wide range of
consumer goods, especially from China and various
other developing countries in Asia. Imports of telecommunications equipment, electric machinery, and
other types of machinery also showed significant
increases in 1992, for the first time since 1988.
For the first three quarters of 1992, the substantial
current account deficit was more than matched by
recorded net capital inflows, both official and private.
Net official inflows amounted to more than $30 billion at an annual rate, despite substantial net outflows
associated with intervention sales of dollars by major
foreign industrial countries. Net private inflows were
almost as large, with banks accounting for a large part
of these inflows. The agencies and branches of
Japanese-based banks used funds from abroad to substitute for a run-off in CDs outstanding in the United
States while other foreign-based banks used funds
from abroad to help finance asset expansion in the
United States. A reduction in the holdings of Eurodeposits by U.S. residents also contributed to the net
private capital inflow during the first three quarters of
the year, but that reduction was partially reversed in
the fourth quarter.
Although securities transactions contributed little
to the net inflow of capital in the first three quarters of
1992, the continued impact of the globalization of
financial markets was apparent. U.S. net purchases of
foreign stocks and bonds were very strong, accompanied by a near record pace of foreign bond issues in
the United States. During the same period, foreigners
added substantially to their holdings of U.S. government and corporate bonds; however, they made net
sales of U.S. equities.
U.S. direct investment abroad was very strong in
the first three quarters of 1992. Outflows to Europe
remained high, while outflows to Latin America and
Asia grew. In contrast, foreign direct investment in
the United States fell further, producing a net outflow.
The rate of new foreign direct investment in the
United States has declined dramatically in recent
years from large inflows recorded during the latter
part of the 1980s, partly reflecting the sharp drop in
mergers and acquisitions in the U.S. business sector.
In addition, the very low rates of return reported by




foreign direct investors on their holdings in the United
States in recent years may have helped to discourage
new investment.

Labor Market Developments
The labor market remained relatively sluggish in
1992. Some large companies continued to undergo
major restructurings or reorganizations, and these
changes led in many cases to permanent workforce
reductions at those firms. More generally, businesses remained hesitant to take on new workers,
even as the recovery progressed. The still-sluggish
pace of output growth in the first half of the year
tended to limit labor requirements during that period.
Later on, when firms started to expand output more
rapidly, they were able to do so without making major
long-term hiring commitments. Needs for additional
workers were met, in many cases, through use of
temporary-help firms, rather than through permanent
additions to companies' own payrolls.
Payroll Employment
Net change, millions of jobs, annual rate
Total Private Nonfarm

n Hn u

-

„ O -B

U U
L
1

1989

1990

1991

1
1992

Nonetheless, the tilt of the overall employment
trend was positive, rather than negative as it had been
in 1990 and 1991. Payroll employment, a measure
that is derived from a monthly survey of business
establishments, was up about 600,000 during 1992
and an additional 100,000 in January. The number of
jobs in manufacturing fell further in 1992, but not as
much as in either of the two previous years; small
increases in the number of factory jobs were reported
toward year-end and in early 1993. In addition,
employment in construction changed little in 1992,
after two years of sharp decline.
About 900,000 new jobs were created in the
service-producing sector of the economy in 1992. The
number of jobs in retail trade turned up a little, on net,

92
after dropping about one-half million over the two
previous years. In addition, firms that provide services to other businesses recorded strong employment
growth in 1992; more than likely, these firms were the
ones that benefited most from the tendency of businesses to purchase labor and services from other
firms, rather than hiring additional workers of their
own. Employment in health services, which had
remained on a strong upward trend right through the
recession, continued to grow rapidly in 1992.
The employment measure that is derived from the
monthly survey of households was stronger than the
payroll measure in 1992; it showed an increase of
about 1 Vi million in the number of persons holding
jobs and, by year-end, had moved back close to the
previous cyclical peak of mid-1990. Reasons for the
stronger performance of the household series are not
entirely clear. Differences in coverage between the
household survey and the payroll survey accounted
for only a small part of the 1992 gap, and other
possible explanations are little more than conjecture
at this point. A portion of the gap between the two
series was eliminated in January, as the rise in jobs
reported in the payroll survey in that month was
accompanied by a decline in the household measure
of employment.
The number of unemployed persons increased in
the first half of 1992, to a peak in June of nearly
9.8 million. Job losses—many of them apparently
permanent—continued to mount in the first half of the
year, and new job opportunities did not open up fast
enough to fully absorb either those workers or others
entering the work force for the first time. As a result,
the unemployment rate rose more than l/2 of a percentage point in the first half of the year, to a June level of
7.7 percent.
The second-half outcome was more favorable. The
number of unemployed persons declined about !/2 million from June to December, and the unemployment
rate moved down over that period, to a level of
7.3 percent at year-end. Some of the workers who had
been laid off temporarily were recalled in the second
half of the year. In addition, the number of unemployed workers not expecting to be recalled—the
so-called permanent job losers—also declined; presumably, these workers either found new jobs elsewhere in the economy or dropped out of the labor
force altogether. A similar story also applied to
unemployed new entrants, a category of jobless workers whose ranks were a little thinner at the end of
1992 than they had been at mid-year. In January of
this year, the number of unemployed persons fell




Civilian Unemployment Rate

further, and the unemployment rate edged down to
7.1 percent.
In the aggregate, the civilian labor force—the sum
of those persons who are employed and those who are
looking for work—rose sharply in the first half of
1992, but changed relatively little thereafter. Its level
in January of 1993 was up about 1 million from that
of a year earlier. The labor force participation rate—
the proportion of the working-age population that is
in the labor force—fell over the second half of the
year and into January of 1993, leaving it about where
it had been at the end of 1991.
Against a backdrop of slack in labor markets and in
the context of reduced inflation, the rate of rise in
workers' hourly compensation continued to slow in
1992. The employment cost index for private
industry—a measure of labor cost that includes both
Employment Cost Index *
Percent change, Dec. to Dec.

Total Compensation

1986

1988

1990

1992

•Employment cost index for private industry, excluding farm
and household workers.

93
wages and benefits and that covers the entire nonfarm
business sector—increased 3]/2 percent from December of 1991 to December of 1992. The index had risen
nearly 4'/2 percent in the previous twelve-month
period, and, as recently as mid-1990, its twelvemonth rate of change had exceeded 5 percent. The
employment cost index for wages and salaries
increased only 2.6 percent during 1992; this was the
smallest annual rise ever reported in this measure,
which dates back to 1975. The rate of rise in the cost
of benefits provided by firms to their employees also
slowed in 1992, but the size of the increase—
5!/4 percent—was still relatively large. Many firms,
both large and small, continued to be pressured by the
rising cost of medical care for their employees and by
the increased cost of workers' compensation insurance; the difficulty of bringing these costs under control may well have been a serious deterrent to
increased hiring in 1992.

normal cyclical tendencies, longer-range improvement in productivity growth also may be in progress.
The jump in output per hour in 1992, combined with
the slowing of compensation gains, held the annual
increase in unit labor costs to just 0.7 percent.

Price Developments
The consumer price index rose 3 percent over the
four quarters of 1992, the same as in the previous
year. Energy prices, which had fallen in 1991, turned
up a little in 1992, but price increases elsewhere in
the economy were generally smaller than those of the
previous year. The limited rise in labor costs in 1992
was one important factor exerting restraint on the rate
of price increase. In addition, the cost of materials
used in production rose only moderately over the
year, as did the prices of goods imported from abroad.
Consumer Prices*
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Despite the further slowdown in nominal compensation per hour in 1992, the purchasing power of an
hour's labor would appear to have risen in real terms,
as the nominal increase in hourly wages and benefits,
as measured by the employment cost index, outpaced
the rise in consumer prices for the second year in a
row. Real compensation, computed in this manner,
had declined sharply in 1990, and the increase in
1989 had been barely positive.
Sustained increases in real living standards depend
ultimately on achieving advances in the productivity
of the workforce, and on that score, the economy
performed well in 1992. Output per hour worked in
the nonfarm business sector jumped 3 percent over
the year, the largest annual gain since 1975. While a
portion of this large rise is no doubt a reflection of
Output per Hour
Percent change, Q4 to Q4
Nonfarm Business Sector

n




JZL

1986

1988

1990

1992

'Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

Although inflation expectations, as reported in various surveys of consumers and business officials, have
remained a step or so above actual inflation rates,
they too appear to have moved lower over time. On
average, their recent levels are about in line
with—or, according to some surveys, less than—the
lower bound of the range of inflation expectations
reported during the 1980s. In view of these recent
trends in prices, labor costs, and inflation expectations, the January rise of 0.5 percent in the CPI would
appear to be something of an aberration.
The CPI for food increased a bit less than P/4 percent in 1992, the same as in 1991. Not since the 1960s
has there been a two-year period in which the cumulative increase in food prices was so small. This low
rate of food price inflation in 1991 and 1992 was, in
part, a reflection of the same factors that were

94
Consumer Food Prices*
Percent change, Q4 to Q4

1986

1988

1990

1992

'Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

working to pull inflation down in other parts of
the economy. In addition, food prices have been
restrained by favorable supply conditions in the farm
sector. Meat production rose further in 1992, and the
output of crops soared. Dryness in some regions imparted temporary volatility to crop prices in late
spring. Thereafter, growing conditions turned
exceptionally favorable and remained so through the
summer and into early autumn. Unusually wet conditions in some regions later on in the autumn apparently made only a small dent in the eventual size of
the harvest.
The rise in consumer energy prices over the four
quarters of 1992 amounted to about 2'/2 percent. The
previous year, energy prices had fallen 8 percent.
With no major supply or demand shocks springing up

in world oil markets in 1992, the price of West Texas
Intermediate stayed in the relatively narrow trading
range of about $18 to $23 per barrel; the price has
remained in that range in the early part of 1993. At
the retail level, price changes for petroleum products
were mixed in 1992; the price of gasoline rose about
3 percent, while fuel oil prices declined moderately.
The CPI for natural gas rose about 5 percent in 1992,
considerably more than in other recent years.
Although much of that rise in gas prices came in the
second half of the year in the wake of supply disruptions caused by Hurricane Andrew, prices of gas at
the wellhead had already moved up considerably
before the hurricane hit, in response to a somewhat
tighter supply-demand balance than had existed over
the previous year or so.
The CPI excluding food and energy rose 3.4 percent over the four quarters of 1992, a percentage point
less than it had risen in 1991. The slowdown was
widespread among the various categories of goods
and services that are included in this measure of core
inflation. The rate of rise in the cost of shelter—the
single most important category in the CPI, with a
weight equal to more than one-fourth of the total—
slowed further in 1992; rents for both apartments and
houses apparently were damped by the large amount
of vacant housing that was available in many parts of
the country. The prices of other services that are
included in the CPI—which collectively make up
another one-fourth of the total index—also slowed
appreciably in 1992. Nonetheless, their overall rate
of increase remained relatively high. The costs of
medical care services and tuition continued to rise
much faster than prices in general in 1992, and air
Consumer Prices Excluding Food and Energy*

Consumer Energy Prices*

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

-

- 20

_

r n n

10

+
^

D

~

Q

~ 10

20

i

I
1986

I
1988

I

I

I

1990

'Consumer price index for all urban consumers.




I

I

1986

1988

1990

'Consumer price index for all urban consumers.

1992

95
fares rebounded from their 1991 decline. The CPI for
commodities other than food and energy rose 2'/2 percent during 1992, after an increase of more than
4 percent over the four quarters of 1991. Price
increases for this broad category of goods were
restrained by the cost and price developments in
manufacturing: Unit labor costs in manufacturing
actually declined in 1992, and the producer price
index for finished goods rose less than 2 percent.
After falling sharply from mid-1990 to the end of
1991, the prices of industrial commodities generally
changed little, on balance, during 1992. By the end of
1992, however, prices had begun to tilt up for some
industrial metals, consistent with the pickup in the
pace of industrial expansion toward year-end, and
additional price increases have been reported in some
of these markets in early 1993. The prices of lumber
and plywood—following a path considerably different from that of most other commodities—rose substantially during 1992, and further steep increases
have been evident in early 1993. The surge in prices
of these products appears to be a reflection of the




uptrend in single-family housing construction,
weather-related supply disturbances in some timber
regions, and adjustment of the logging industry to
environmental restrictions that have been implemented in some areas of the country. Prices of some
other wood products, such as pulp, also rose sharply
at the producer level in 1992.
The recent increases in prices of these raw materials have shown through to some extent to broader
measures of producer prices. For example, the producer price index for intermediate materials excluding food and energy—a price index that encompasses
a wide range of production materials—rose 1 percent
during 1992, after declining about % of a percentage
point during 1991, and the past couple of months
have seen some further pickup in that measure of
price change. From an economy-wide perspective,
however, that pickup in materials prices has not been
sufficient to dominate the deceleration in labor costs,
which account for a far greater share of total production costs.

96
Section 3: Monetary and Financial Developments in 1992
Federal Reserve policy in 1992 was directed at promoting and extending the recovery from the 1990-91
recession, in the context of continued progress toward price stability. The difficulty of designing and
implementing constructive monetary policies has
been exceptional in this period. In 1992, as earlier,
economic activity was held back to an unusual degree
by the efforts of households, nonfinancial businesses, and some key providers of credit to the economy, including commercial banks, to strengthen their
balance sheets. These forces have tended to alter the
normal relations between financial flows—particularly those reflected in movements in M2 and M3—and
the behavior of the economy. Under the circumstances, the Federal Reserve has had to take a flexible approach to the use of money and credit aggregates as intermediate policy targets; specifically, in
light of evidence that expansion in economic activity was being financed to an unusual extent in capital markets rather than through banks and other
depositories, the System tolerated shortfalls of M2
and M3 from their target ranges.
The Federal Reserve judged it appropriate to
ease reserve conditions on three occasions in 1992,
when financial and economic data suggested that the
economy might be losing momentum. The extent of
the casings last year was considerably less than
in 1991, however, as the underlying trend of the
economy overall was more positive. Partly as a result
of the cumulative effect of the monetary casings of
recent years, economic activity accelerated in 1992 to
its fastest pace since 1988. This pickup was achieved
even as various measures of inflation evidenced
further slowing, with the "core" inflation rate falling
to levels last seen in the early 1970s. Thus, 1992
was a year not only of financial repair, but also of
improved aggregate economic performance in the
United States.

The Implementation of Monetary Policy
Nineteen ninety-two began with short-term interest rates at their lowest levels in over a quarter of a
century, following a series of actions by the Federal
Reserve in the latter part of 1991 that reduced the
discount rate and the level around which the federal
funds rate was expected to trade to 3l/2 and 4 percent respectively. Long-term rates were also at lower
levels, reflecting the policy actions and a weakening
of economic activity in the final quarter of 1991.




Short-Term Interest Rates
Monthly

10

Three-month Treasury bill
Coupon equivalent

I
1982

I

I
1984

I

I
1986

I

I
1988

I
1990

I

I
1992

Last observation is for first two weeks of February 1993.

Evidently in the expectation that these rate cuts
would revive the recovery, the stock market began the
year with strong upward momentum, and the dollar
appreciated. However, other evidence that the economy was picking up remained scanty in the initial part
of the year, despite the significant monetary stimulus
already in place and the positive developments in
equity and capital markets. Apart from rising housing
starts, a phenomenon in part related to special weather
and tax factors, the economy appeared sluggish and
confidence levels were low. Spending by households
and businesses seemed to be restrained by efforts to
strengthen financial positions, and banks had done
little to reverse the substantial tightening of lending
standards that occurred in 1990 and 1991. In view of
the still tentative nature of the recovery and the solid
progress that had been made to that point against
inflation, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) at its first meeting of the new year instructed
the Manager of the Open Market Account at the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York to remain especially alert to evidence that money market conditions
might need to be eased before the next scheduled
meeting of the Committee. Such a policy stance
biased toward ease had prevailed over much of 1991.
M2 and M3, which had posted moderate gains in
January, surged in February, owing partly to stronger
income and earlier sharp declines in short-term interest rates, and partly to special factors—above-average
tax refunds and a jump in mortgage refinancing,
which results in funds being held temporarily in
demand deposits. Underlying money growth remained
very weak, however, and well below that consistent

97
with expectations based on the historical relationship
of money with income, deposit rates and market interest rates. In March, as the influence of the special
factors abated, M2 was about flat and M3 contracted.
The economy seemed to be improving during much
of the first quarter: retail sales and housing starts were
strong, industrial production turned up, and confidence levels of the business and household sectors
were rising as was the quality of their balance sheets.
The signs of recovery and the market view that the
prospects for further near-term monetary ease had
faded caused long-term interest rates to increase, and
the dollar rose on foreign exchange markets as well.
Increases in private interest rates were less than those
on Treasuries, likely reflecting perceived reductions
in the riskiness of private debt as the economy
strengthened coupled with concerns about enlarged
Treasury demands on credit markets stemming from
discussions of possible fiscal stimulus. Areas of weakness in the economy remained, however—some
attributable to the substantially overbuilt commercial
real estate sector and some to the transition to a
smaller defense sector. In addition, the backup in
long-term interest rates threatened to slow the pace
of balance sheet adjustment and could damp housing and its related industries as well as business
investment spending, and the outlook for exports
clouded.
In early April, the System eased reserve conditions
again. This action was taken on indications that the
monetary aggregates, already at the bottom of their
target ranges following their flat performance in
March, were beginning to contract, that the balance of
evidence was beginning to suggest a slowing in the
economic expansion, and that inflation was continuing to recede. Short-term interest rates fell more than
the V4 point drop in the trading level of the federal
funds rate, as market participants judged the economy
sufficiently weak to make further near-term monetary
easing moves likely. The easing buoyed the stock
market, but long-term rates showed a limited response
and remained well above year-end levels.
In the weeks following the easing, the economy
appeared to improve a bit but the evidence continued
to be mixed. Single-family housing starts, which had
contracted in March, fell considerably further in April
and retail sales were little changed on balance
between February and April. On the other hand, nonfarm payroll employment and industrial production
continued to expand. Weakness in the monetary
aggregates persisted into April, but concerns on
this front were allayed to some degree by evidence
that this was importantly related to the ongoing




re-channeling of credit away from depository institutions and into capital markets, and by expectations
that this re-channeling and other financial restructuring would continue to damp money growth considerably more than economic activity. Moreover, what
restraint balance sheet restructuring was exerting on
spending was seen as likely to abate in view of the
considerable progress that by then had been made in
this area, both by the borrowing sectors and by depository institutions, as banks added rapidly to capital. At
its mid-May meeting, the Committee determined that
its bias towards ease in assessing possible intermeeting policy changes was no longer appropriate.
Data becoming available over subsequent weeks,
however, suggested that the forces restraining economic expansion continued to be quite strong. The
contraction of consumer credit accelerated, and bank
loans more generally began to run off. With the forces
that had been constraining money growth intensifying, all three monetary aggregates contracted in June.
Long-Term Interest Rates
Monthly

18
Home mortgage
Primary conventional

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

Last observation is for first two weeks of February 1993.

Nonfinancial data confirmed that the economy
remained slack. Although nonfarm payroll employment and industrial production each increased in May
for the fourth straight month, the unemployment rate
rose sharply, owing to a rising labor force participation rate. Moreover, homebuying and retail sales,
other than for automobiles, slowed from the pace
earlier in the year, and demand for U.S. exports was
held down as growth in some foreign industrial countries slowed or turned negative while other countries
struggled to recover from their downturns in 1991 or
remained in recession.
With the tenor of incoming economic news having
become distinctly negative, long-term Treasury rates,

98
which had been little changed over most of May and
June, turned down around mid-year, although they
remained above year-end lows. In light of these developments, and with the downward trend in inflation
continuing, the System reinstated its bias towards
ease at its mid-year meeting. Immediately following
that meeting, on July 2, with evidence of a weakening
economy confirmed by a further rise in the unemployment rate, to 73/4 percent in June, the Federal Reserve
reduced the discount rate and the federal funds rate
each by l/2 percentage point, to 3 and 3!/4 percent,
respectively. Banks lowered their prime rate, also by
'/2 percentage point, to 6 percent, leaving its unusually wide spread over market rates intact.
Long-term interest rates fell in response to the
employment data and the monetary easing and moved
down further into early August as the incoming economic news continued to be poor. The drop in yields
brought long-term rates to the lowest levels since the
early 1970s, and the dollar continued to retreat from
its peak levels reached in April.
In early September, with another weak labor report
and in the context of contracting industrial production
and expansion in the monetary and credit aggregates
that, while now positive, was weaker than had been
expected, reserve conditions were eased further and
the federal funds rate fell to around 3 percent. Shorterterm market rates dropped on this action, bringing
them to the neighborhood of zero in real terms.
Despite the poor economic news and expectations
that further easing moves were in the offing, longterm rates, although they initially declined, drifted
back up on renewed concerns that the federal deficit
would be enlarged by fiscal actions taken to stimulate
the economy.
Throughout the late summer and early fall, policy
was conducted against a background of tension in
foreign exchange markets; a strong Deutschemark
had caused several European countries to raise interest rates sharply to preserve fixed exchange rate relationships with and within the exchange rate mechanism (ERM) of the European Monetary System at a
time when aggregate demand in these countries was
slowing or sluggish. The dollar continued to decline
into early September, but then began to firm. The rise
in long-term rates contributed to the reversal, as did
actions by several European countries to devalue their
currencies, in some cases dropping out of the ERM,
and to lower interest rates.
With short-term interest rates in the United States
lower, the monetary aggregates continued to expand
in September. The implications of the strength of M2




were difficult to assess, however, since it reflected to
an uncertain degree the impact of mortgage refinancing on demand deposits as well as strong foreign
demands for U.S. currency. Stronger income also
appeared to be contributing to money growth, as
private employment edged up and the unemployment
rate declined in September. Nevertheless, the outlook
for the economy remained uncertain. Final demand
seemed weak and was being met in part through
higher imports, holding down industrial production
and employment, and business and consumer sentiment remained relatively depressed.
In these circumstances, the FOMC established a
strong bias toward ease at its early October meeting.
In the event, however, an improvement in economic
indicators immediately following the meeting, along
with evidence of some strength in M2 and bank
credit, stayed any further easing actions. Since anticipation of further easing had been built into the structure of interest rates, short-term rates backed up following the meeting. Rates also rose at the long end,
responding to growing expectations that fiscal stimulus could follow the upcoming presidential election,
as well as to the indications of improved economic
performance.
Evidence of greater economic strength continued to
accumulate in a variety of indicators of production
and spending over the fourth quarter. Although this
news initially put further upward pressures on longerterm interest rates, these came to be muted and then
reversed as the better economic prospects, along with
statements and actions of the incoming Administration, began to be viewed as reducing the likelihood of
outsized fiscal stimulus. Also helping to lower longerterm rates was continuing good news on inflation.
These factors, buttressed by an increasing focus in
public discourse on reducing the federal deficit, continued to play an important role as long-term rates fell
further into the new year.
With the better economic news, the Federal
Reserve kept reserve conditions and short-term interest rates unchanged as the year ended, and the FOMC
at its December meeting decided to move back to a
symmetric policy stance. Reflecting the improved
economic outlook, a stock market rally developed that
rivaled in strength that which began the year, and the
dollar rose further.
Although the monetary aggregates strengthened a
bit in the fourth quarter, the depressing effects of
balance sheet restructuring continued to be important,
a fact that became became clearer once the hard-tomeasure temporary boost to deposits deriving from

99
higher mortgage refinancing abated after October.
The velocities of both M2 and M3 rose significantly
further in the final quarter of the year, contributing to
the exceptional velocity increases posted by both
measures for the year as a whole.

Monetary and Credit Flows
Credit flows again were quite damped in 1992, and
money growth was exceptionally weak. Despite an
appreciable pickup in nominal GDP growth last year,
the broad monetary aggregates decelerated further,
and expansion of the nonfinancial debt aggregate
edged up only a bit. As had been the case for the last
couple of years, considerable efforts by key sectors of
the economy to improve balance sheets had a significant restraining effect on credit and, especially, on
money growth—a much greater effect than they had
on spending itself. Growth of the debt of nonfinancial borrowers other than the federal government
edged up by only 1A percentage point from 1991, to
2!/2 percent, as businesses and households restrained
borrowing and financed spending out of cash flow
and equity issuance and by limiting accumulation of
financial assets. The expansion of federal debt slowed
slightly to a still rapid 103/4 percent, held down by the
lack of activity by the Resolution Trust Corporation
(RTC) after April, when it exhausted its legislative
authority to fund losses at savings and loans. Reflecting the slowdown in the activities of the RTC and the
improving health of depositories, federal outlays
attributable to deposit insurance activity fell from the
$50 billion area in 1991 to nil last year. The total nonfinancial debt aggregate expanded about 4'/2 percent
last year, at the lower end of its monitoring range.

Debt: Monitoring Range and Actual Growth
Billions of dollars

12100
11900
11700
11500
11300
11100

O N D J

F M A M J




J

1992

A S O N D

10900

The sluggishness in credit and money growth last
year appeared to represent mainly weak demand,
rather than any new tightening of credit supply terms.
At banks, loan flows were depressed, and, in the
absence of appreciable credit demands, bank asset
growth mainly took the form of security acquisitions.
Some have argued that the shift to government securities over recent years has been motivated by the Basle
risk-weighted capital standards, which require capital
against loans but not against many government securities. However, the effect of these standards appears
to be relatively minor. As in 1990 and 1991, banks
that had already achieved adequate capital positions
were the major purchasers of U.S. Treasury and
agency securities last year, and loan flows were depressed at these banks as well. Moreover, other regulatory factors may be contributing to a reduction in
willingness to take deposits and make loans, including rising deposit insurance premiums and the tighter
regulations and requirements of new laws governing
banks and thrifts in recent years. A similar pattern of
asset growth concentrated in government securities
occurred at credit unions, which are not subject to the
Basle capital standards. Although loan growth at
banks remained lackluster, it strengthened in the final
quarter of the year as the economy began to expand
more rapidly. At the same time, the growth of bank
holdings of government securities, which had been
very rapid all year, slowed.
To be sure, the pickup of bank lending toward
year-end seemed primarily related to stronger
demand—banks gave little indication in Federal
Reserve surveys that they had begun to ease the
tighter lending standards and terms that they had put
in place in 1990 and 1991, and the unusually wide
spread of the prime rate over market rates persisted.
Banks do seem better positioned to meet increases in
demand than they were a few years ago. Not only has
their liquidity improved with the acquisitions of government securities, but they have made substantial
progress in improving capital positions, including
leverage ratios—which are unaffected by asset
composition—as both profits and debt and equity
issuance reached record levels in 1992. Moreover, the
quality of their assets showed some scattered signs of
improvement last year; the delinquency rate for bank
loans, though still high, began to turn down, as did the
rate of charge-offs.
Other financial intermediaries also have taken steps
to strengthen balance sheets, and the availability of
credit from these lenders also remains somewhat
constrained—though probably not more so than in
1991. Life insurance companies, for example, have

100
Comr nercial Bank Loan Delinquency Rate
andCCapital Ratios
Delinq uency rate, percent

Capital ratio, percent

D Total Capital to Risk-Weighted Assets
6 -11 Equity Capital to Assets
5.75

r

5.5

5.25

-\

^

Delinquency /
Rate
/

5
4.75

45

",lm
1988

1989

T~-

1990

12

\
"

\
1991

- 10
\

8

6
i

A

1992

Note: 1992 through September.

suffered from an abundance of bad loans and remain
saddled with poor quality commercial real estate
loans. Such firms have been limiting acquisitions
primarily to high quality, easily marketable assets,
meaning that, as in 1991, some medium-sized, belowinvestment-grade companies found credit from life
insurance companies difficult to obtain in 1992.
Some business finance companies also have experienced high and rising levels of nonperforming loans,
many of which were secured by commercial real
estate, with effects on their willingness to make new
loans.
Downgradings of the manufacturing parents of
automobile sales finance companies have led to some
increases in their funding costs. To date, however,
there has been little or no effect on the cost or availability of consumer credit, as these finance companies
have increased the volume of loans they have securitized. The availability of credit at thrift institutions
likely improved a bit last year. Reflecting the declines
in interest rates, profits of private sector savings and
loans had reached a record level as of the third
quarter, sustained by a wide spread between interest
earned on assets and the cost of funds, as well as by a
decline in the industry's still high level of troubled
assets.
Weak credit demand and constraints on some
sources of supply have produced generally sluggish
borrowing in each major nonfinancial sector other
than the federal government. Overall household borrowing accelerated slightly but continued moderate,
as demand was depressed by insecurity about employment as well as by efforts to restructure balance




sheets. Declines in mortgage rates promoted only
about a »/2 percentage point boost to net home mortgage growth, but they spurred a substantial volume
of refinancing. Some of the proceeds of mortgage
refinancings likely were used to pay down higher-cost
consumer credit. Consumer credit also was held down
last year as households apparently used funds that
otherwise would have been held in low-yielding
deposits to reduce high-cost debt.
With the pace of debt accumulation by the household sector damped, and with rates on consumer debt
falling and mortgage debt being refinanced at lower
rates, the ratio of debt servicing payments to household income declined considerably further last year.
Another sign of improving household financial conditions has been recent trends in delinquency rates.
Consumer loan delinquency rates mostly fell last year,
although they remain at high levels. Home mortgage
delinquency rates were little changed on balance last
year and still somewhat above their pre-recession
levels, but well below those of the mid-1980s.
Household Sector Debt Service
Debt Service as a Percentage of
Disposable Personal Income*
' (Quarterly)

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

• Debt service is a staff estimate of scheduled payments of
principal and interest on home mortgage and consumer debt.

Business debt grew only slightly last year as internally generated funds exceeded investment spending.
Taking advantage of the strong stock and bond markets, nonfinancial corporations stepped up their equity
issuance and refinanced large volumes of longer-term
debt at more favorable rates. In part, the proceeds of
these issues were used to pay down short-term debt,
particularly bank loans, thereby lengthening liability
structures.
The hospitality of the capital markets extended
even to lower-graded business borrowers, which

101
Business Sector Net Interest Payments

economy advanced, corporate debt ratings began to
improve and quality spreads narrowed.

Net Interest Payments as a Percentage of
Cash Flow plus Net Interest Payments*
(Quarterly)

The state and local sector also benefited from the
rate declines last year, with large amounts of debt
being refinanced, including a large volume that
was called. Net debt growth continued to be moderate, however, as this sector's spending remained
constrained.

I

1980

I

I

30

I

1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992

* Cash flow is defined as depreciation (book value) plus
retained earnings (book value).

issued substantially more bonds than in recent years.
Overall public gross bond issuance by nonfinancial
corporations was well above the 1991 level. Likewise, gross equity issuance by nonfinancial corporations also rose from the already high pace of 1991 and
was four times that of the late 1980s and early 1990s.
As a result of debt refinancing and sales of equity,
corporate net interest payments as a percent of cash
flow fell for the second year. As declining interest
rates allowed firms to reduce debt burdens, and as the

Although balance sheet restructuring has damped
credit flows and spending, its greatest impact has
been on the monetary aggregates, as an unusually
high proportion of spending in recent years has been
financed outside the depository system, whose liabilities make up the bulk of the monetary aggregates.
Some of this spending has been supported through
sources other than borrowing, for example, issuing
equity or restraining the accumulation of liquid assets.
Depository credit expanded last year, following two
years of contraction, but it continued to shrink as
a share of nonfinancial debt as borrowers concentrated their credit demands in long-term securities
markets—bonds for corporations and fixed-rate mortgages for households.
The sluggish expansion of depository credit was
echoed in M3, which comprises most—though not
all—of the instruments depositories use to finance
their credit extensions. In fact, growth of M3 slowed
last year to Vi percent despite the pickup in depository
credit, as depositories relied much more on equity

Growth of Domestic Nonfinancial Debt and Depository Credit*
Quarterly

Domestic Nonfinancial Debt

V
1960

1965

* Four-quarter moving average.




1985

1990

102
M3: Target Range and Actual Growth
Billions of dollars
Rate of Growth
1991:4 to 1992:4
.5 percent

4400
4300
4200

4100

O

N

O

J

F

M

A

M

J

J

A

S

O

N

D

1992

issuance and sales of subordinated debt, which are not
in M3. Large time deposits at banks and thrifts fell
rapidly. The tendency for spending to be financed
outside of depositories, along with the latter's reliance
on non-M3 funds, produced a sizable increase in M3
velocity last year—at a rate far above that of recent
years. The rise in velocity of M3 would have been
even greater had it not been for strong inflows into
institution-only money funds over the first three quarters of the year. The attractiveness of these funds
increases when short-term interest rates are falling, a
phenomenon caused by the fact that the funds do not
mark to market, so that their yields tend to exceed
market rates when those rates are declining.

modest growth in the first and last quarters of the
year, but was about flat over the middle quarters. The
reasons for underlying weak money growth appeared
to stem from several important factors, many related
to the unattractiveness of holding funds in M2 assets
relative to other possible uses of savings.
Contributing to the relative attractiveness of nonmonetary assets was the rapidity with which banks
adjusted down offering rates on retail deposits as
market rates declined last year. Banks' unaggressive
pricing of deposits reflected substantial paydowns of
bank debt by households and businesses, which kept
loan demand low and banks' need for funds to finance
them quite limited. In addition, banks and thrifts have
been discouraged from going after deposits by the
rising cost of issuing deposits to make loans; among
the factors accounting for this increase have been
increases in deposit insurance rates and higher capital
ratios occasioned by market and regulatory forces.
M2 and Stock and Bond Mutual Fund Balances
Billions of dollars
D Net flows into M2
• Net flows into stock and bond mutual
fund balances

400

i Net flows into M2 plus stock
\and bond mutual fund balances

M2 increased 2 percent last year, below the 21/2 percent lower end of its target range. M2 registered
M2: Target Range and Actual Growth
Billions of dollars

O

N D

J




F M A M

J

J

1992

A

1986

1988

1990

1992

Note: Mutual fund data exclude IRA and Keogh balances and
institutional holdings. IRA and Keogh balances and
institutional holdings for 1992 are estimated.

The prompt declines and low level of deposit rates
have combined with several other factors to induce
savers to cut back on holdings of assets in M2. One
important influence was the unprecedented steepness
of the yield curve, which was puiiing deposit funds
into capita! markets. An important method for accomplishing this portfolio shift was mutual funds, which
experienced record inflows last year. Not only were
yields on these funds attractive, but they have become
increasingly available through banks and thrifts.
Assets in bond and equity mutual funds (apart from
those held by institutions and those in IRA and Keogh
accounts) increased $125 billion last year, up from
$117 billion in 1991 and an average of $30 billion

103
Spreads between Pre- and After-Tax Auto Loan
Rates and Rate Paid on Small Time Deposits
Percentage points

1975

1980

1985

1990

Auto loan rate is the 48-month rate. Small time deposit rate is
for maturities of two and a half years and over.
Marginal federal tax rates based on John Seater, "On the
Construction of Marginal Federal Personal and Social Security
Tax Rates in the U.S.," Journal of Monetary Economics 15 (1985)
pp. 121-35.

over the previous five years. In 1991 and 1992 for the
first time, increases in mutual fund assets exceeded
increases in M2.
Money growth has also weakened as consumer
loan rates have moved downward less rapidly than
deposit rates. As a consequence, households face a
considerable interest rate incentive, particularly after
taking account of changes in the tax deductibility of
consumer interest payments, to use funds in deposit
accounts to pay down, or limit the accumulation of,
debt. In fact, the rise in consumption has been accompanied by an unusually small increase in debt, implying that it has been financed to a large extent by
reducing or limiting holdings of financial assets.
The cuts in bank deposit rates were particularly
evident for larger (and presumably more interest sensitive) accounts and at longer maturities. Small time
deposits ran off throughout the year. Some of these
funds appeared to flow into more liquid deposit
accounts, as small time deposit rates fell faster than
those on savings and checkable deposits. General
purpose and broker-dealer money market mutual
funds (MMMFs) also contracted over the year, despite
the yield advantage these assets offered vis-a-vis other
money market rates in an environment of declining
yields. This appeared to be another example of the
attraction that bond and equity mutual funds and other
capital market instruments provided last year to investors. MMMFs grew in October and November, however, perhaps reflecting capital losses in bond funds




resulting from the rise in long-term rates in September and October.
The overall effect of the unusual forces that have
been influencing M2 is summed up by the behavior of
its velocity, which accelerated for the second year in a
row, to a 3!/2 percent rate, despite the sharp downward trend in short-term interest rates over this period. Over previous decades, the velocity of M2 and
short-term rates had moved together in a reasonably
predictable way. This occurred because deposit rates
lagged market rates. When, for example, short-term
rates fell, deposit rates dropped by less, providing an
incentive to shift assets from market instruments to
deposits and depressing velocity. However, because
of the unusual configuration of forces discussed
above, these incentives to hold M2 have not followed
their usual pattern in the current cycle. As noted,
despite the drop in short-term interest rates, a combination of the steep yield curve, sluggish adjustment
of loan rates, and other factors has decreased, not
increased, the incentives to hold M2 in the last year.
In other words, the opportunity cost—the earnings
given up—in holding M2 actually has widened, rather
than narrowed as has happened in the past when
market interest rates fell, and this helps to explain
why M2 velocity has risen atypically.
Another indication of the unusual behavior of
velocity of M2 is the recent performance of the Board
staff"s P* model in predicting inflation. This model is
premised on the existence of a reasonably stable
behavior of the velocity of M2 over time, and uses
this to predict the price level and inflation rates,
consistent with M2 growth. If the velocity of M2 is
rising atypically, slow growth of M2 would not be
associated with the degree of disinflationary pressures
that would be predicted by the P* model, which
assumes normal velocity behavior. In fact, consistent
with the notion that velocity is behaving abnormally,
this model, using actual M2 growth, has underpredicted inflation in 1992.
The growth of M2 over the year was entirely attributable to its currency and transactions deposit components, as Ml growth surged to 14'/4 percent in 1992.
This performance reflected the advance in income
growth, but mainly stemmed from declines in both
short- and long-term interest rates. Long-term rate
declines prompted large volumes of mortgage rate
refinancings, particularly in the first and last quarters.
Because a large portion of prepayments are held in
demand deposits until the mortgage servicer remits
the funds, the level of demand deposits is temporarily
boosted by mortgage refinancings. Falling short-term

104
rates boosted demand deposits by lowering the opportunity cost of holding them and by increasing the
amount of deposits businesses needed to hold under
compensating balance arrangements. In addition,
NOW accounts were boosted by funds shifted from

small time deposits, as rates on the latter fell faster
than those offered on the former. Growth in NOW
accounts last year accelerated from the already brisk
pace of 1991, and demand deposits posted the largest
increase since at least 1959.

M2 Velocity and Measures of Opportunity Cost

1.75

1.54
3-Month Treasury Bill Rate

1.47 I—1

1978

1980

1982

1988

1990

1992

Ratio scale

1.68
1.5

»/ Broad Measure of
M2 Opportunity Cost*

I
1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

Note: Opportunity costs are two-quarter moving averages.
•Estimated difference between a weighted average of competing rates (3-monthT-bill, 5-year T-note, after-tax auto loan rate)
and a weighted average of rates paid on M2 components.




105
To accommodate the growth in transactions deposits associated with the process of easing reserve conditions, the Federal Reserve supplied large volumes
of new reserves in 1992. Total reserves grew at
around 20 percent, more than twice the rate of
increase in 1991. Currency growth also was rapid, in
part owing to shipments abroad, and as a consequence
the monetary base increased 101/2 percent last year—
the highest growth rate in the Board's official series,
which begins in 1959.

M1: Actual Growth
Billions of dollars

- 960
920
- 880
840

Growth of Money and Debt (Percentage Change)

M1

M2

M3

Debt of
domestic
nonfinancial
sectors

8.9
9.3
9.1
12.2
8.1
8.7
9.3

9.5
12.3

9.5
10.0

9.9

9.9
10.8
7.6
8.9

9.3
11.4
14.3
13.8
14.0

5.8
6.4
3.7
1.8
1.1
0.5

10.1
9.2
8.1
6.9
4.3
4.6

2.0

4.3
5.4
4.2
4.2

Fourth quarter to fourth quarter

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986

7.4
5.4(2.5)*
8.8
10.4
5.5
12.0
15.5

1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992

6.3
4.3
0.6
4.3
8.0
14.3

4.3
5.3
4.7
4.0
2.8
1.9

15.5
10.6
11.6
16.8

3.3
0.6
0.8
2.9

Quarterly (annual rates)

1992

Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

'Figure in parentheses is adjusted for shifts to NOW accounts in 1981.




-0.3
0.1
0.2

106
Velocity of Money and Debt
Quarterly

M2

Ratio scale
2.2

2
1.8

1.6

1990

1960
Debt

Ratio scale
1.5
1.2

Private
0.9

1.2

I I I I I I I I
1960

1970

1980

Note: Debt for 1992:Q4 is partially estimated.

64-740 (112)




1990

0.8

0.3

1970







ISBN 0-16-040771-0

90000

9"780160"40771I