View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

S. HRG. 107–503

FEDERAL RESERVE’S FIRST MONETARY POLICY
REPORT FOR 2002

HEARING
BEFORE THE

COMMITTEE ON
BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS
UNITED STATES SENATE
ONE HUNDRED SEVENTH CONGRESS
SECOND SESSION
ON
OVERSIGHT ON THE MONETARY POLICY REPORT TO CONGRESS PURSUANT TO THE FULL EMPLOYMENT AND BALANCED GROWTH ACT OF 1978

MARCH 7, 2002

Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs

(
U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON

80–301 PDF

:

2002

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512–1800; DC area (202) 512–1800
Fax: (202) 512–2250 Mail: Stop SSOP, Washington, DC 20402–0001

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00001

Fmt 5011

Sfmt 5011

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS
PAUL S. SARBANES,
CHRISTOPHER J. DODD, Connecticut
TIM JOHNSON, South Dakota
JACK REED, Rhode Island
CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York
EVAN BAYH, Indiana
ZELL MILLER, Georgia
THOMAS R. CARPER, Delaware
DEBBIE STABENOW, Michigan
JON S. CORZINE, New Jersey
DANIEL K. AKAKA, Hawaii

JOSEPH

Maryland, Chairman
PHIL GRAMM, Texas
RICHARD C. SHELBY, Alabama
ROBERT F. BENNETT, Utah
WAYNE ALLARD, Colorado
MICHAEL B. ENZI, Wyoming
CHUCK HAGEL, Nebraska
RICK SANTORUM, Pennsylvania
JIM BUNNING, Kentucky
MIKE CRAPO, Idaho
JOHN ENSIGN, Nevada

STEVEN B. HARRIS, Staff Director and Chief Counsel
WAYNE A. ABERNATHY, Republican Staff Director
MARTIN J. GRUENBERG, Senior Counsel
TOM LOO, Republican Senior Economist
R. KOLINSKI, Chief Clerk and Computer Systems Administrator
GEORGE E. WHITTLE, Editor
(II)

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00002

Fmt 0486

Sfmt 0486

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

C O N T E N T S
THURSDAY, MARCH 7, 2002
Page

Opening statement of Chairman Sarbanes ...........................................................
Prepared statement ..........................................................................................
Opening statements, comments, or prepared statements of:
Senator Gramm ................................................................................................
Senator Johnson ...............................................................................................
Prepared statement ...................................................................................
Senator Bennett ................................................................................................
Senator Bayh ....................................................................................................
Senator Hagel ...................................................................................................
Senator Carper .................................................................................................
Senator Bunning ...............................................................................................
Senator Stabenow .............................................................................................
Senator Crapo ...................................................................................................
Senator Corzine ................................................................................................
Senator Allard ...................................................................................................
Prepared statement ...................................................................................
Senator Dodd ....................................................................................................
Prepared statement ...................................................................................
Senator Ensign .................................................................................................
Senator Akaka ..................................................................................................
Prepared statement ...................................................................................
Senator Miller ...................................................................................................
Prepared statement ...................................................................................

1
39
2
3
40
3
3
4
4
5
6
6
7
7
40
11
41
11
11
41
30
42

WITNESS
Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington, DC ...........................................................................................
Prepared statement ..........................................................................................
ADDITIONAL MATERIAL SUPPLIED

FOR THE

7
42

RECORD

Monetary Policy Report to the Congress, February 27, 2002 ..............................

49

(III)

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00003

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00004

Fmt 5904

Sfmt 5904

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

FEDERAL RESERVE’S FIRST MONETARY
POLICY REPORT OF 2002
THURSDAY, MARCH 7, 2002

U.S. SENATE,
URBAN AFFAIRS,
Washington, DC.
The Committee met at 10:10 a.m., in room SD–106 of the Dirksen Senate Office Building, Senator Paul S. Sarbanes (Chairman of
the Committee) presiding.
COMMITTEE

ON

BANKING, HOUSING,

AND

OPENING STATMENT OF CHAIRMAN PAUL S. SARBANES

Chairman SARBANES. The Committee will come to order.
We are very pleased to welcome Chairman Greenspan back before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs this
morning, to give testimony on the Federal Reserve’s Semi-Annual
Monetary Policy Report to the Congress.
I just note, Mr. Chairman, that yesterday, as I understand, it
was your birthday. We want to wish you a belated happy birthday,
a day late, and many more of them to come.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Thank you very much.
Chairman SARBANES. I am sure I speak for all the Members of
the Committee when I say that. It is not like the board of directors
voted, you know, the chief officer was ill and they voted 5 to 4 for
a full recovery.
[Laughter.]
Chairman GREENSPAN. I am glad you did not take a vote, Mr.
Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Actually, legislation that we enacted in the
last Congress has set out a framework now for the Federal Reserve
to submit a report to Congress twice a year on the conduct of monetary policy and for the Chairman of the Fed to testify before the
Congress. Before that, it was a matter of custom. But Senator
Gramm and I worked together with the Chairman, who was supportive of the idea that at regular intervals, it would serve an important public purpose for the Fed to come before the Congress and
present testimony with respect to monetary policy in open session.
Now, we alternate back and forth between the House and the
Senate and the Fed testified last week before the House. So in a
sense, much of the Chairman’s initial readings of the economy have
already been publicly given, although we have had some interesting reports since that testimony.
Yesterday, the Fed issued the beige reports from the various regional banks around the country in terms of how they see economic
conditions, and we have also gotten some additional statistics.
(1)

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00005

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

2
Since you testified last Wednesday, the Commerce Department
released a report which revised upward U.S. economic growth in
the fourth quarter of last year. The Commerce Department report,
as I understand it, revised it upward from 2⁄10 of 1 percent growth
to 1.4 percent growth, for the fourth quarter of last year. Which
leads me to ask the question, what kind of economic statistics do
we have, if the margin of error is going to be of that magnitude?
In other words, when trying to frame public policy, we look at an
economic report and a statistic, it says, the growth in the fourth
quarter was 2⁄10 of 1 percent. So your thinking is geared to that.
It is an important figure, that growth figure.
Then they come in and they do the revision and now we are told
it was 1.4 percent. Well, that could lead to a different judgment,
so, I intend in the question period to explore with you this economic statistics issue. I also want to make a couple other observations.
I think everyone now perceives the economy as recovering, but
we expect unemployment to increase and that is, of course, the projection of the Fed. Over the last year, according to the Bureau of
Labor Statistics, the number of people unemployed for more than
14 weeks has nearly doubled. Those unemployed for more than 26
weeks, the current cutoff for unemployment insurance, also nearly
doubled. These figures, in my view, make a compelling case for the
extension of unemployment benefits above the 26 weeks. We have
consistently done that in every previous recession. We have not yet
done it in this one. And I very much hope that the Congress will
see its way clear to doing that in the very near future.
I just want to underscore again that we are pleased that the
Chairman is back with us. The New York Times has a story this
morning about our economic situation. It says: ‘‘The Recovery That
Defied the Forecasts of Economists.’’ And we look forward to exploring that with you.
Senator Gramm.
STATEMENT OF SENATOR PHIL GRAMM

Senator GRAMM. Mr. Chairman, thank you very much.
Chairman Greenspan, thank you for coming before the Committee. I would just like to make a few points.
First of all, I would like to thank you for the great job you have
done. I think in the wake of someone’s birthday, it is always a good
opportunity to say something good about them.
I have been somewhat dumbfounded by criticism, especially the
one that you did not take action to combat the overspeculation in
the high-tech area.
You have to wonder where the hell these critics were when you
appeared before this Committee and talked about irrational exuberance, and the whole world groaned and complained that you
were talking down the stock market.
I would just have to say that I have had the opportunity to work
in this town and be involved in Government for 24 years. And in
that 24 years, no person has done more to promote the economic
well-being of this country and the people that work here than Alan
Greenspan.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00006

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

3
I want to thank you for the great service you have rendered. As
I have said on other occasions, millions of people who will never
know your name have benefited from the service that you have provided.
On behalf of the 21 million of those people that I represent, I
want to thank you for the great job that you have done. Capitalism
grows in fits and starts. It is the very nature of a dynamic system
that is based on individual initiative and that is based on new
ideas, new vision, and new leadership in the corporate sector, and
good and bad leadership in Government.
The duty of the Fed Chairman is to try to set a monetary policy
that maximizes the economic growth that we can get and minimizes the variance about that mean.
I just want to conclude by saying that in the 24 years that I have
been involved in public policy, and in the years that you have been
Chairman of the Federal Reserve Bank, I do not think anybody
could have or ever has done a better job of achieving a combination
of those two objectives—to set the framework in which productivity
and the energies of a free people can promote economic growth, and
to provide a monetary policy that tries to minimize the variance
about the mean that is created by these basic forces in the most
dynamic free society in history. So, I appreciate the great job you
have done and it has been a privilege for me to work with you.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Senator.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Johnson.
COMMENTS OF SENATOR TIM JOHNSON

Senator JOHNSON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for holding this
hearing.
Welcome to Chairman Greenspan.
In order to expedite an opportunity to hear from Chairman
Greenspan, I have an opening statement relative to some questions
that I would like to present to Chairman Greenspan, as well as an
observation relative to future hearings on the capitalization needs
in Indian country, and I am going to submit that statement for the
record.
Chairman SARBANES. Without objection, the full statement will
be included in the record.
Senator Bennett.
COMMENT OF SENATOR ROBERT F. BENNETT

Senator BENNETT. I have no comment, Mr. Chairman. I will wait
to hear the witness.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Bayh.
COMMENT OF SENATOR EVAN BAYH

Senator BAYH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am looking forward
to hearing from Chairman Greenspan and I will save my comments
for the questions.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Hagel.
COMMENT OF SENATOR CHUCK HAGEL

Senator HAGEL. I have no statement, Mr. Chairman. I look forward to the comments.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00007

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

4
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Carper.
STATEMENT OF SENATOR THOMAS R. CARPER

Senator CARPER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, I was listening to Senator Gramm and
that was one of the nicest things I have ever heard him say about
anybody.
[Laughter.]
I have known him for 20 years.
[Laughter.]
Yesterday might have been your birthday, but that is a pretty
good present a day late. I think it reflects the views of a lot of us.
For about the last 8 years I was the Governor of Delaware. Near
the end of my tenure as Governor, and Evan Bayh can probably reflect on this in his time as Governor. But my the last year as Governor, somebody said to me, were you the Governor when we had
the ice storm of the century?
And I said, yes.
Were you the Governor when we had the blizzard of the century?
I said, yes.
He said, were you the Governor when we had the flood of the
century?
I said, yes.
He said, were you the Governor when we had the drought of the
century?
I said, yes.
He said to me, do you know what I think? I said, no. He said,
I think you are bad luck.
[Laughter.]
Compare my record to yours. You have been Chairman of the
Federal Reserve when we have had the longest running economic
expansion in the history of our country. And you have been the
Chairman of the Federal Reserve during what appears to have
been the shortest recession, at least as far as we can recall. That
is a pretty good record.
I am one who believes that we should go out on top. But I do
not believe that you should go out any time soon. So, I would just
suggest that to you.
You testified before us, almost 5 or 6 months ago. We were just
beginning at the time to debate what kind of economic recovery
package or economic stimulus package that we should consider.
And your advice to us at the time was something to the effect, it
is better to be right than fast. I do not know if those were your
exact words, but something to the effect, it is better to be right
than fast.
As it turns out, we were not fast. But in the end, I think we
came out all right. And when you look back at how short the recession was and how we seem to be coming out of it fairly nicely, I
am reminded of at least 3 factors that have been at play.
The first of those is the most aggressive monetary policy that I
have witnessed in my lifetime that you have led. The second is just
some good luck. Energy prices have dropped precipitously across
the country and around the world. And the third factor is, we are
doing a fair amount of deficit spending, fighting the war in Afghan-

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00008

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

5
istan, the war against terrorism, helping New York State and the
airline industries and others and pumping a fair amount of red ink
into the economy to help bolster it. All of which I think factor in
to shorten the recession that we have gone through.
We have before us today, this week, probably next week, comprehensive energy legislation. It is before the Senate. A number of
proposals that would help us to create more energy. A number of
proposals that would help us to conserve more energy.
When we get to the Q&A’s, I would hope to have an opportunity,
not just to talk about monetary policy, but to revisit with you the
need for us to move on that front in order to better ensure a longer
lasting economic recovery in the years ahead. Thank you very
much. And thank you again for your stewardship.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you very much, Senator Carper.
Senator Bunning.
STATEMENT OF SENATOR JIM BUNNING

Senator BUNNING. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to thank the Chairman of the Federal Reserve for
testifying today. It is once again time for the biannual monetary
policy report.
Generally, I agree with Senator Gramm on about 99 percent of
the things that he says. Today, I do not. Mr. Greenspan, once again
today, I will probably be the only skunk at the garden party. Sometimes I feel like the lone voice crying out in the wilderness about
our monetary policy. I just want to make sure you know, to quote
‘‘The Godfather,’’ it is business, not personal.
It looks like we are coming out of this recession and I am guardedly optimistic, but I am not sure that we are not in the middle
of a double-dip, where we start to come out and then go right back
down again. I hope that is not the case.
Mr. Chairman, one thing we have talked about before that I
would like to highlight again today is my belief that we did not
have to have a recession at all. I think that you unilaterally popped
the bubble in the stock markets and that helped precipitate the
economic downturn. And I do not think that is your job.
I also do not think it is your job to jawbone market gains and
to declare that gains were a product of irrational exuberance.
No one individual should be able to influence the market so
much and to be able to take trillions of dollars of market capital
out of this economy.
I know many of us have gotten lumps in our throats watching
our 401(k) plans go down recently. We talked about it before, how
the Fed’s duty is to focus on monetary policy and should not overlap into equities.
When I tried to talk to the people back home about these issues,
their eyes sometimes glaze over. But these are real issues and the
millions of workers who lost their job in the recession now have
real problems. These folks are not just statistics.
It may surprise you that I think you do a good job when you do
what you are supposed to do. I think we all acknowledge the Fed
has moved aggressively over the past year. Once the Fed got going,
it did respond. I also think that the Fed did a very good job after
September 11 to help shore up the confidence in our markets.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00009

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

6
You should be commended for that, and that might have helped
limit the damage. But there was damage even before September
11, damage that I do not think we should have had. The Fed came
to help, but it was too late in coming.
Mr. Chairman, thank you again for coming before this Committee and I look forward to digging into these issues a little bit
more during the question-and-answer period.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you very much, Senator Bunning.
Senator Stabenow.
COMMENTS OF SENATOR DEBBIE STABENOW

Senator STABENOW. Well, thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to associate myself with Senator Gramm and reiterate the fact that you did come before our Committee and talk
about irrational exuberance and did speak with caution about what
was occurring in the economy. I appreciate the fact that the Fed
has acted aggressively.
I would only say that, as a Member of the Budget Committee, as
we look to the long term, that while we are seeing some glimmers
of hope, and I certainly want to hear from you this morning about
your view the economy and where we are going, but we certainly
know that we have many challenges left in the long term as we
look at the budget and the economy.
And I would have to say that while academics were debating last
year whether or not we were technically in a recession, in my great
State of Michigan, you only had to look to the iron ore mines in
the upper peninsula or our cities in Detroit or Flint, or our farmers
trying to get a good price for their products, to understand that this
has been a challenging time for many families and many business
people in our country. I appreciate your being here again and I look
forward to your comments.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you very much, Senator Stabenow.
Senator Crapo.
COMMENTS OF SENATOR MIKE CRAPO

Senator CRAPO. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
I too want to thank you, Chairman Greenspan, for coming here
for your annual report on monetary policy. And I look forward, as
has been indicated by a number of the others here, to discussing
a number of the issues relating to our monetary policy with you.
Just to kind of get a heads-up for where I may be headed in my
questioning, as I am sure you are already aware, there is a proposal now coming up before Congress dealing with derivatives and
whether we are currently governing them in the right way, and basically whether the Commodities Futures Modernization Act that
we passed a few years ago has approached the issue properly.
I am very concerned that we may be addressing this issue in
Congress without any hearings, without any analysis, and simply
having an amendment coming up on the floor which has not had
the kind of evaluation that is going to be necessary for us to make
the right decision here. And I am going to be asking for your input
on that issue.
With that, Mr. Chairman, I thank you for holding this hearing.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you very much.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00010

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

7
Senator Corzine.
COMMENTS OF SENATOR JON S. CORZINE

Senator CORZINE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to join with those who speak about appreciation for
your thoughtful and balanced leadership with regard to economic
issues in this country and your remarkable tenure. Thank you.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Allard.
COMMENTS OF SENATOR WAYNE ALLARD

Senator ALLARD. Mr. Chairman, I just want to join my colleagues
to welcome Chairman Greenspan and look forward to his comments. I have some comments that I would just like to submit for
the record.
Chairman SARBANES. Very good. Mr. Chairman, we would be
happy to hear from you.
STATEMENT OF ALAN GREENSPAN
CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE
FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM

Chairman GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman,
and Members of the Committee.
Since July, when I last reported to the Committee on the conduct
of monetary policy, the U.S. economy has undergone a period of
considerable strain, with economic output contracting for a time
and unemployment rising.
Chairman SARBANES. Mr. Chairman, I think if you pulled the
microphone a little closer, it would be helpful.
Chairman GREENSPAN. We in the Federal Reserve System acted
vigorously to adjust monetary policy in an endeavor both to limit
the extent of the downturn and to hasten its completion. Despite
the disruptions engendered by the terrorist attacks of September
11, the typical dynamics of the business cycle have reemerged and
are prompting a firming in economic activity. The recent evidence
increasingly suggests that an economic expansion is already well
under way, although an array of influences unique to this business
cycle seems likely to moderate its speed.
One key consideration in the assessment that the economy is
moving through a turning point is the behavior of inventories.
Stocks in many industries have been drawn down to levels at
which firms will soon need to taper off their rate of liquidation, if
they have not already done so. Any slowing in the rate of inventory
liquidation will induce a rise in industrial production if demand for
those products is stable or is falling only moderately. That rise in
production will, other things being equal, increase household income and spending.
But that impetus to the growth of activity will be short-lived unless sustained increases in final demand kick in before the positive
effects of the swing from inventory liquidation dissipate. We have
seen encouraging signs in recent days that underlying trends in
final demand are strengthening, although the dimensions of the
pickup remain uncertain.
Through much of last year’s slowdown, however, spending by the
household sector held up well and proved to be a major stabilizing

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00011

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

8
force. As a consequence, although household spending should continue to trend up, the potential for significant acceleration in activity in this sector is likely to be more limited than in past cycles.
While consumer demand will have important consequences for
the economic outlook in coming months, the broad contours of the
present cycle have been, and will continue to be, driven by the evolution of corporate profits and capital investment.
The retrenchment in capital spending over the past year and a
half was central to the sharp slowing we experienced in overall activity. These cutbacks in capital spending interacted with, and
were reinforced by, falling profits and equity prices. Indeed, a striking feature of the current cyclical episode relative to many earlier
ones has been the virtual absence of pricing power across much of
American business, as increasing globalization and deregulation
have enhanced competition.
Part of the reduction in pricing power observed in this cycle
should be reversed as firming demand enables firms to take back
large price discounts. Though such an adjustment would tend to
elevate price levels, underlying inflationary cost pressures should
remain contained.
Improved profit margins and more assured prospects for rising
final demand would likely be accompanied by a decline in risk premiums from their current elevated levels toward a more normal
range. With real rates of return on high-tech equipment still attractive, that should provide an additional spur to new investment.
However, the recovery and overall spending on business fixed investment is likely to be only gradual.
Even a subdued recovery would constitute a truly remarkable
performance for the American economy in the face of so severe a
decline in equity asset values and an unprecedented blow from terrorists to the foundations of our market systems. For, if the tentative indications that the contraction phase of this business cycle
has drawn to a close are ultimately confirmed, we will have experienced a significantly milder downturn than the long history of business cycles would have led us to expect.
The imbalances that triggered the downturn and that could have
prolonged this difficult period did not fester. The obvious questions
are what has changed in our economy in recent decades to provide
resilience and whether such changes will persist into the future.
Doubtless, the substantial improvement in the access of business
decisionmakers to real-time information has played a key role. The
large quantities of data available virtually in real time allow businesses to address and resolve economic imbalances far more rapidly than in the past.
The apparent increased flexibility of the American economy arguably also reflects the extent of deregulation over the past quarter
century.
Both deregulation and innovation in the financial sector have
been especially important in enhancing overall economic resilience.
New financial products, including derivatives, have enabled risk to
be dispersed more effectively to those willing to, and presumably
capable of, bearing it. Shocks to the overall economic system are
accordingly less likely to create cascading credit failure. Despite
the concerns that these complex instruments have induced—and

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00012

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

9
that is an issue that I will address shortly—the record of their performance, especially over the past couple of stressful years, suggests that on balance they have contributed to the development of
a far more flexible and efficient financial system—both domestically and internationally—than we had just 20 or 30 years ago.
As a consequence of increased access to real-time information
and, more arguably, extensive deregulation in financial and product markets and the unbundling of risk, imbalances are more likely
to be readily contained, and cyclical episodes overall should be less
severe than would be the case otherwise.
However, the very technologies that appear to be the main cause
of our apparent increased flexibility and resiliency may also be imparting different forms of vulnerability that could intensify or be
intensified by a business cycle.
From one perspective, the ever-increasing proportion of our GDP
that represents conceptual as distinct from physical value added,
may actually have lessened cyclical volatility. In particular, the fact
that concepts cannot be held as inventories means a great share of
GDP is not subject to the type of dynamics that amplifies cyclical
swings. But an economy in which concepts form an important share
of valuation has its own vulnerabilities.
As the recent events surrounding Enron have highlighted, a firm
is inherently fragile if its value added emanates more from conceptual as distinct from physical assets. A physical asset, whether an
office building or an automotive assembly plant, has the capability
of producing goods or services even if the reputation of the managers of such facilities falls under a cloud. The rapidity of Enron’s
decline is an effective illustration of the vulnerability of a firm
whose market value largely rests on capitalized reputation. The
physical assets of such a firm comprise a small proportion of its
asset base. Trust and reputation can vanish overnight, whereas, a
factory cannot.
The implications of such a loss of confidence for the macroeconomy depend importantly on how freely the conceptual capital
of the fading firm can be replaced by a competitor or a new entrant
into the industry. Even if entry is relatively free, macroeconomic
risks can emerge if problems at one particular firm tend to make
investors and counterparties uncertain about other firms that they
see as potentially similarly situated. The difficulty of valuing firms
that deal primarily with concepts and the growing size and importance of these firms may make our economy more susceptible to
this type of contagion.
Another, more conventional determinant of stability will be the
economy’s degree of leverage, the extent to which debt rather than
equity is financing the level of capital. A sophisticated financial
system, with its substantial array of instruments to unbundle
risks, will tend toward a higher degree of leverage at any given
level of underlying economic risk. But, the greater the degree of leverage in any economy, the greater its vulnerability to unexpected
shortfalls in demand and mistakes.
Although the fears of business leverage have been mostly confined to specific sectors in recent years, concerns over potential systemic problems resulting from the vast expansion of derivatives
have emerged with the difficulties of Enron. To be sure, firms like

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00013

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

10
Enron and Long-Term Capital Management before it, were major
players in the derivatives markets. But their problems were readily
traceable to an old-fashioned excess of debt, however acquired, as
well as to opaque accounting of that leverage and lax counterparty
scrutiny.
Swaps and other derivatives throughout their short history, including over the past 18 months, have been remarkably free of default. Of course, there can be latent problems in any market that
expands as rapidly as these markets have. Regulators and supervisors are particularly sensitive to this possibility.
Derivatives have provided greater flexibility to our financial system. But their very complexity could leave counterparties vulnerable to significant risk that they do not currently recognize, and
hence these instruments potentially expose the overall system if
mistakes are large. In that regard, the market’s reaction to the revelations about Enron provides encouragement that the force of
market discipline can be counted on over time to foster much greater transparency and increased clarity and completeness in the accounting treatment of derivatives.
How these countervailing forces for stability evolve will surely be
a major determinant of the volatility that our economy will experience in the future. Monetary policy will have to be particularly sensitive to the possibility that the resiliency that our economy has
exhibited during the past 2 years signals subtle changes in the way
our system functions.
Although there are ample reasons to be cautious about the economic outlook, the recuperative powers of the American economy,
as I have tried to emphasize in my presentation, have been remarkable. When I presented our report on monetary policy to this
Committee last summer, few if any of us could have anticipated
events such as those to which our Nation has subsequently been
subjected.
The economic consequences of those events and their aftermath
are an integral part of the many challenges that we now collectively face. The U.S. economy has experienced a substantial shock,
and, no doubt, we continue to face risks in the period ahead. But
the response thus far of our citizens to these new economic challenges provides reason for encouragement.
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I would appreciate if my
full remarks were included for the record.
Chairman SARBANES. The full statement will be included in the
record, without objection. And thank you for your testimony.
Since the opening statements, we have been joined by Senators
Dodd, Ensign, and Akaka. I will yield to them now for any opening
statement they may have before we go to questions for Chairman
Greenspan.
Senator Dodd.
COMMENT OF SENATOR CHRISTOPHER J. DODD

Senator DODD. Mr. Chairman, I just ask unanimous consent that
my statement be included in the record and I look forward to the
questions.
Chairman SARBANES. Very good.
Senator Ensign.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00014

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

11
COMMENTS OF SENATOR JOHN ENSIGN

Senator ENSIGN. No opening statement, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Akaka.
COMMENT OF SENATOR DANIEL K. AKAKA

Senator AKAKA. Mr. Chairman, I have a statement and I will
submit it for the record.
Chairman SARBANES. It will be included in full in the record.
Mr. Chairman, I would like to come back to this two-tenths of
1 percent growth figure that the Commerce Department gave us as
the initial figure on fourth-quarter growth, revised to 1.4 percent.
Now, I take it that is a revision of sufficient magnitude and consequence that we ought to have some concern about the accuracy
of our economic statistics.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, the cause of that, Mr. Chairman is
that the Commerce Department, the Bureau of Economic Analysis,
chooses to make an early estimate of the gross domestic product for
a quarter just passed before it has all of the important information.
In this particular case and, indeed, in all of these advanced reports,
two major items of exclusion which are never available at the point
at which they make the earliest estimate, are, one, inventory
change for the last month of a quarter and, two, the trade figures
for the last month.
Both of those numbers can be really quite difficult to judge. And
what happens in the early data is that technicians at the Department of Commerce endeavor to make their best judgments as to
what those numbers are likely to be.
They publish their judgments, so it is not a black box which people who are trying to evaluate the numbers are unable to understand. And since those of us who endeavor to follow the GDP as
it moves from one month to the next in its quarterly format are
able to judge as the new monthly data comes in, whether in fact
the numbers published—the last published set of numbers by the
Department of Commerce—are going to be revised.
Most people can reasonably judge what the nature of the revisions is going to be because they know what plugged numbers the
Department of Commerce put in for data they did not have.
Now, to be sure, that does create significant changes, as you just
cited a particularly large one. The question would be, would we be
better off if we did not have the advanced report? And I suggest
the answer to that is no, it does help. But I do think it is important
to point out that these numbers are subject to significant revision.
Rarely do they give an impression of the economy which is false.
Chairman SARBANES. Presumably, they might have some impact
on consumer outlooks and consumer confidence because I want to
move now to consumers in this economic situation.
Generally speaking, consumer demand has held up pretty well,
as I understand it. It is in fact what has cushioned the downturn.
The question then becomes whether it is been used up, in a sense.
In previous sessions, when consumer demand slackens, it then
picks up as we move into a recovery period and provides a boost
for the economic recovery. That may not be there this time. What
is your view on that question?

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00015

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

12
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, I think that is an important point
to make, Mr. Chairman.
In past periods of significant contraction, when inventory liquidation was a major factor pushing the economy down, consumer durable demand and homebuilding also tended to be much lower. And
that was largely because interest rates at the top of the cycle were
usually relatively high and that suppressed demand for housing
and durables.
When we got to the bottom of the cycle, as inventory liquidation
started to slow and turn the economy around, there was an unmet
demand for a number of motor vehicles and other consumer durable goods and new homes. And they tended to come back together
and as a consequence of that, my recollection is that the average
rate of increase in the first year after a recession ended has been
something like 7 percent.
This is almost certainly not going to be the case this time. And
one of the reasons, as you point out, is we never went down and,
consequently, the ability to go back up is limited because no matter
how one looks at it, both motor vehicles have been doing really
quite extraordinarily well, as well as homebuilding.
So that there is very little upside potential to carry through. And
that is the reason why I made my remarks in my formal text about
the need for final demands to kick in prior to when the obvious significant increase in economic activity that is occurring now as a
consequence of inventory liquidation slowing down finally dissipates.
Chairman SARBANES. Yes. Well, my time is expired.
Senator Gramm.
Senator GRAMM. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Alan, I have three short questions and then a longer question.
Let me try and give them to you briefly, and if you could just give
me a short statement on them.
As you know, there is an effort afoot in both the House and the
Senate to raise the level of deposit insurance. Could you tell me
where you stand on that?
Chairman GREENSPAN. We just recently had letters from both
Chairman Bachus and Congressman LaFalce with respect to where
the Federal Reserve Board is. What we have done is essentially indicated that for most of the bill which is being considered in the
House, we find ourselves as a Board in agreement.
We do not, however, subscribe to any change in the level of coverage of deposit insurance because all of our analysis has indicated
the need for it is clearly not evident in the data that we have.
And obviously, because there is some indication coming from the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation that losses will be rising
and, indeed, the so-called ratio of reserves to deposits that is relevant, as I recall came down to 1.27 at the end of the fourth quarter, and there is a statutory requirement to do things at 1.25.
So it strikes me that if we move to any significant expansion of
coverage, we are going to have to start boosting premiums. And I
am not sure that that in total is a particularly useful activity.
But most importantly, I think that we have to be very careful
about the extent to which we create the levels of subsidy within
our system to make certain that they are contained so that the

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00016

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

13
probabilities of systemic risk which come as a consequence of them,
are also contained.
Senator GRAMM. Okay. Let me go to the next two questions.
We passed a security litigation reform bill, I believe in 1995. We
had a series of lawsuits where one big law firm had about 80 percent of the business and they literally had a boilerplate complaint.
And if a company put out a prospectus on what it expected to do
in the future, and they did better, it took that boilerplate thing and
filed a lawsuit. If it did not do as well, it filed a lawsuit.
What we tried to do is tighten up on the process, bring all those
lawsuits to Federal court since the securities market is a national
market.
There is an effort underway to try to repeal that provision or
substantially cut back on it. I would like to get you to comment on
that. And also, the effort that might be underway to regulate energy derivatives and energy swaps.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, as I recall, when the original
discussions of that legislation a number of years ago developed, we
did not, I think, have a position on it as such, but I personally
thought it struck me as a sensible idea because we have to be very
careful in the functioning of our financial markets that we do not
get swamped with lawsuits or challenges to the form of corporate
governance and the whole structure of security issuances, beyond
what is necessary to maintain the soundness and stability of the
system.
I have not been familiar with how successful, or lack thereof,
that has been, so I cannot really comment on what has occurred.
But certainly, the original principle strikes me as the correct one.
And unless the evidence to date has indicated that that is wrong,
I would presume that, at least from my own personal view, I would
not change.
With the issue of energy derivatives, as you may recall, in the
Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, we went over that
issue in very considerable detail. The main issue involved was to
recognize the extraordinary importance to improving our financial
system of the whole derivatives market. And we were concerned
about a numbers of things which included the uncertainties with
respect to whether or not they were legally binding.
And we came up with a bill which, I think in retrospect, was an
exceptionally good bill. What it did with respect to energy derivatives—or I should be more exact—over-the-counter energy derivatives, was to recognize that public policy essentially focuses on
three issues in this respect. First is consumer protection. The second is anti-manipulation. And the third is pricing systems which
are not opaque so that we can understand what is going on.
In the second two, the CFTC still has authorities to act against
manipulation and act against systems in which it appears that
pricing is not being appropriately indicated to the marketplace.
The issue of consumer protection does not, or did not, in our
view, apply—I am talking about the President’s Working Group, as
you may remember. The President’s Working Group said it did not
apply to transactions amongst professionals.
Now, it was crucially important that we allow those types of
markets to evolve amongst professionals who are most capable of

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00017

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

14
protecting themselves far better than either we, the Fed, the
CFTC, or the SEC could conceivably do.
The important issue is that there is a significant downside if we
regulate where we do not have to in this area because one of the
major and, indeed, the primary, area for regulation and protection
of the system is counterparty surveillance; that is, the individual
private parties looking at the economic events, looking at the status of the people with whom they are doing business, with whom
they have this derivative transaction. We have to allow that system
to work because if we step in as Government regulators, we will
remove a considerable amount of the caution that is necessary to
allow those markets to evolve.
And while it may appear to be sensible to go in and regulate, all
of our experience is that there is a significant downside when you
do not allow counterparty surveillance to function in an appropriate matter.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Bayh.
Senator BAYH. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman, and Chairman Greenspan.
I would like to begin by asking two questions regarding productivity growth, which, as you know, is so critically important to our
economic and fiscal estimates.
There was an excellent paper prepared by Dale Jorgensen of
Harvard, Monhoe and Kevin Sterow—I hope I pronounced that correctly—regarding the methodology of productivity growth forecasts.
Their conclusions, if I could just summarize them, were that the
productivity revival of the 1995 to 2000 period remains largely intact, that information technology investments were critical to that
revival, and that going forward over the next decade, they project
only some slightening of that productivity growth.
This is an important analysis. I was wondering if, and you and
I have chatted about this, there has been some work at the Fed.
Any update on their thesis that, to my understanding, the difference between state-of-the-art technology, the competitive advantage that it affords, and mean technology is expanding, giving
added impetus for investing in technology, which will keep this productivity growth advancing.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, that is a crucial issue which a
number of people are beginning to look at. There have been certain
papers which suggest, indeed, that there has been an opening up
of the difference between what you might say are the ultimate cutting-edge technologies and the average application that exists in
the economy.
It is too soon to conclude that. Indeed, if the conclusion is accurate, obviously, it says a great deal about the potential for the future. But I do not think we have gotten to the point at this stage
where we can confirm that that is the case.
The general notion, however, that something fundamentally important happened in the last 4 or 5 years is continuously being reaffirmed quarter by quarter and in the most recent period because,
even as I indicated at the peak of the acceleration in economic activity and of productivity growth, we did not at that point have a
real test of how the structure of productivity would respond when
the economy weakened.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00018

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

15
Now, we have been through a period like that and the result is,
if anything, somewhat suspiciously too strong, in the sense that, as
you may know, this morning, the Department of Labor issued an
estimate of productivity growth for the nonfarm business sector in
the fourth quarter of last year and they revised the number up to
5.2 percent at an annual rate.
Senator BAYH. Remarkably robust under the circumstances.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Not only remarkably robust, but also very
unlikely, if I may put it that way.
Senator BAYH. That gets to your questions, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman GREENSPAN. But what it does suggest is that, if you
smooth through the noise in the data, we are getting increasing
confirmation that something fundamentally important did happen
in the latter part of the 1990’s and it does give us some confidence
projecting forward into the future.
Senator BAYH. Certainly very good news going forward.
Mr. Chairman, I would like to ask if you have an opinion on an
accounting issue that may indirectly, have some impact on productivity in the longer term, specifically with regard to the treatment
of stock options.
We had some leaders in the high-tech community on Capitol Hill
yesterday. This is a matter of great concern to them. Their argument is that the change in the treatment of stock options will limit
their ability to attract and retain high-quality people and that requiring these to be expensed will affect their income statements,
their ability to attract capital, that even in the event that the options turn out to not be worth what they originally were calculated
at being worth.
So there is a great deal of concern. Innovation is so important
to the new economy, growing productivity growth rates. Do you
have an opinion about the treatment of these options?
Chairman GREENSPAN. I can speak for myself, but I cannot speak
for the Federal Reserve Board because I have not discussed it with
them.
The question basically is that stock options are a replacement for
cash compensation. And if they are not that, what are they, as I
think my good friend Warren Buffet once said.
The truth of the matter is that if you do not expense the granting
of stock options or their realization in the income statement, as indeed, we are required in our tax forms, then you will get a pre-tax
income which is higher than one can argue you really had and the
estimates by the Federal Reserve suggest that somewhere in excess
of 21⁄2 percent of the growth rate per year in earnings of major corporations is the result of this nonexpensing of stock options.
I do not deny that earnings would be lower if you expensed them.
I do not deny that there may be greater difficulty in attracting capital with presumed lower earnings than you would otherwise have.
I do not disagree with the fact that if the company has lower earnings, that people may not be attracted to come to the firm. But
there is no reason why you cannot issue stock options if you wish
to attract people. It does not affect them. If the stock price goes up,
they get the rewards.
The only thing that is involved is the issue of, the question, is
income being properly recorded? And I would submit to you that

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00019

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

16
the answer is no. I do not understand why there is an issue here
of great moment. The data does show that when you have a significant amount of stock options which are not expensed, and the higher the proportion that that affects pre-tax income, the greater the
volatility of the return from the stock.
So the answer is yes. People argue that they are likely to get less
capital, but that is only if the people who are lending to them just
do not know how to count because these data are reported in footnotes. It does not require very much to figure out what part of the
pre-tax income of any corporation which is issuing stock options is
the result of stock options in lieu of compensation of employees.
So the only issue here is, if you gain something, you are gaining
something because people who are giving you something just did
not quite understand what in fact they were reading.
It is their fault. They should be doing the calculations. But nothing happens in the real world with respect to this question because
for tax purposes, you have to expense it. If you issue options and
the stock prices goes up, the effect of what the individual employee
gets is there, wholly independent of what the company did with respect to the issue of earnings.
Now if the stock market does not know what is going on and it
overprices the stock because the earnings numbers are bigger, that
is just because securities analysts are lazy.
Senator BAYH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Bennett.
Senator BENNETT. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, I assume, given all of the other things
that you read, you have been familiar with the three columns now
that have run in The Wall Street Journal by Robert Bartley, addressing the issue of whether or not spending stimulates the economy, deficits stimulate the economy, surpluses stimulate the economy, and for his final effort, marginal tax rates stimulate the economy.
I find this series very interesting, not only because I know Mr.
Bartley and have respected his opinion over the years, but also because these are the fundamental questions that we as policymakers
have to face as we address fiscal policy.
Should we encourage surpluses at the expense of everything else?
Should we encourage deficits in the name of stimulating the economy? Should we say that as long as they are within various ranges,
deficits and surpluses do not really matter?
And the most important thing to focus on is the tax level.
Right now, as a percentage of GDP, the tax burden is the highest
it has been probably in history. And as you look ahead into the future, with your crystal ball, admittedly, clouded, but probably a little less clouded than ours, would you comment on this controversy
about the impact of the size of a deficit, the impact of the size of
a surplus, and the impact of the overall tax burden on the prospect
for future economic growth?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, first, Senator, let me just comment
that the ratio of total Federal taxes over GDP is indeed at a record
high, or at least it was up until very recently. We have to be a little
careful because the GDP, the denominator of the ratio, does not include capital gains, as you know.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00020

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

17
Senator BENNETT. Yes.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Yet a significant part of the tax receipts
in recent years has reflected either the capital gains tax, which has
been quite substantial, or the issue I was just mentioning with
Senator Bayh, namely, a very substantial amount of tax receipts
that occur as a consequence of the exercise of stock options.
And both of those items have been particularly large parts of the
numerator of that ratio. I have forgotten what happens if you take
them out, but it does look a good deal less burdensome.
Nonetheless, the issue of taxes rising because, as real incomes
rise, they gradually get up into ever-increasing tax brackets, so, indeed, one has to be very careful about that. And I must say I find
myself in substantial agreement with Mr. Bartley on the question
of marginal tax rates and I think it is important. If economic
growth is a particular purpose, which it should be, of economic policy, then I think that is an obviously critical issue.
The questions of when you have surpluses or deficits and the
like, is a far more controversial issue because I suspect that it varies depending on the circumstances.
I also come out pretty much where he does on most of those
issues. But in certain places, I do not. On the issue of surpluses
in the most recent period, I think they have created some value,
especially in reducing long-term real interest rates, and I think
that has been an effective factor in the last several years.
But there is no question that it is important that in approaching
various different forms of economic policy in Government, that we
have answers to those questions.
As you know, Senator, most economists would agree that, in
evaluating the effects of various different fiscal policies, it would be
far better to use what we call dynamic scoring, that is, the ability
to get the interaction of the effect, as well as the initial impact.
The only problem is that the interaction is a function of the particular model you are using, and no one can quite agree on what
the appropriate model is. So that we have fallen back to a static
analysis, which we can all somehow agree on as the first stage of
the effect. But the questions that Bob Bartley is raising get into all
of these questions. And while we do not choose to address them,
that does not mean that we are not in fact making judgments
about them.
In certain instances, we are making very specific adjustments. In
our budgetary analysis, we are saying that the secondary impacts
of tax and spending programs are zero. Now, we know that to be
false. But we are making those judgments because we have no alternative.
So, I think it is an issue which is not going to get resolved easily,
and probably requires continuous evaluation. But I think that Mr.
Bartley is raising some of the crucial issues which essentially are
closely involved with the type of decisionmaking which this body
must make.
Senator BENNETT. Thank you.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you, Senator Bennett.
Senator Stabenow.
Senator STABENOW. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Again, Chairman Sarbanes, we appreciate your comments.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00021

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

18
I was particularly interested in your raising the issues of conceptual capital versus physical assets. I have had concern for some
time particularly, again, coming from Michigan, where we turn
those concepts into physical assets.
We are seeing more and more relationship between Silicon Valley
and Automation Alley, which is a high-tech manufacturing corridor
in Michigan.
I am concerned that we keep that balance. I appreciate what you
have raised, not only the positives of concepts, but also the negatives that occur from that. I think that is an important issue for
us long-term in the economy, as we move forward, and particularly,
coming from a State that brings iron ore out of the ground and
makes steel and all the implications that relate to having physical
assets, which I think are a foundation for us in the economy. Many
of those involved in those industries have raised a concern about
credit standards that I wondered if you might speak to.
I understand that lenders are tightening their terms and I am
concerned about the negative impact, particularly for our smaller
businesses, as we come out of the recession.
I am wondering if you think that the higher credit standards are
justified or if they are an overreaction or a misperception of the
current economic risks.
Chairman GREENSPAN. You are quite correct. Our surveys do
pick up on that evidence of tightening. And it is clearly appropriate
in many respects, if not most respects, because the balance sheets
of borrowers have deteriorated over the last 18 to 24 months. Profit
margins are down quite significantly. So the actual creditworthiness of borrowers has come down.
There has, however, been no evidence of anything remotely resembling the credit crunch that we had a decade ago, where you
just could not get a loan out of a commercial bank no matter what
your creditworthiness was, at least in some cases.
The data that we have do not suggest that there is a credit
crunch in small business, but undoubtedly numerous small businesses are having difficulty. One hopeful sign is that the economy
appears to be turning and credit tends to come in with a lag. So
that to the extent that numbers of firms, especially small firms, are
finding difficulty in getting the credits they need at the prices they
can afford to pay, that is likely to change to the better.
Our commercial banking system has come through this period
really quite effectively. It bodes well to the future of the system as
a whole.
Senator STABENOW. I wonder if you might also address another
issue of concern to our U.S. manufacturing sector. Glenn Hubbard,
the Chairman of the President’s Council of Economic Advisers,
noted in a speech that U.S. manufacturing jobs and our manufacturing exports have been badly hurt by a strong dollar.
I know we are particularly concerned about the excessively weak
yen. And I wonder if you would comment if you believe that that
is in fact a serious issue and what you would comment about that.
Chairman GREENSPAN. When your dollar strengthens, as ours
has, clearly, it creates lesser competitive capability for exporting.
And to the extent that that impacts on the job market it is a negative in that respect.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00022

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

19
But manufacturing jobs have been falling for quite a long period
of time, not because manufacturing is disappearing, but because
productivity, output per hour in manufacturing plants, has really
accelerated and they are doing an exceptional job. So as a percent
of the GDP, there has not been all that much change in manufacturing. As a percent of the total workforce, manufacturing jobs
have been falling fairly appreciably for a while.
One can hardly argue—I should say, argue against—gains in productivity. The vast majority of those people who have left manufacturing jobs obviously have gone into other parts of the economy
because, as you know, up until fairly recently, the unemployment
rate had gotten to 4 percent and less, which has been really quite
a remarkable performance indicating a major improvement in labor
market flexibility.
Senator STABENOW. I wonder if I might just quickly ask one more
question. That is, regarding the Treasury rule to allow banks into
the real estate, brokerage, and managing business. I am wondering
when you see a rule or what is happening in terms of the process
of considering that regulation?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, as I am sure you know
better than anyone, we have had a flurry—I should say a deluge—
of letters, comments and the like, on this issue of the question of
real estate brokerage.
We are in the process of processing the data, all of the information, as we are required to do, and at some point, hopefully sooner
rather than later, we will be able to address the issue and in working with the Treasury—as you know, the statute requires a joint
decision on this—we will be coming forth with some conclusion.
Senator STABENOW. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you very much, Senator Stabenow.
Senator Bunning.
Senator BUNNING. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Last year, Chairman Greenspan we were in a recession. I think
that it started early in the fall of 2000. I let you know my thoughts
then, that we should start loosening our monetary policy. I continued to argue that we should have loosened it all the way through
the fall.
The Fed finally did start seriously loosening it in January. But
by then, the damage had been done. I have been highly critical of
the Fed on the recession for two reasons.
First, I think your attempts to pop the Nasdaq bubble greatly
contributed to the recession. And I think the word you used about
a year and a half ago was something about a wealth effect. I do
not think it is the place of you or the Federal Reserve to pop these
so-called bubbles.
Second, I believe the Fed acted entirely too slowly in responding
to the signs of an economic slowdown. I believe that this past recession could have been lessened, if not avoided, and a lot of people
would not have lost their jobs.
I also think that part of the problem is you need to have more
independent voices at the Fed who will stand up and say when
they think you are wrong on issues. Nobody needs the people
around them to simply agree with everything they say.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00023

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

20
I think the last two nominees to the Board—Mark Olson and
Susan Schmidt Bies—will be independent voices who will stand up
and not be afraid to tell you when they think you are wrong. I can
tell you this, I would not be as effective as I am as a Senator if
I were surrounded by yes men and women.
I am hopeful that the President nominates more independent
voices for the two current vacancies on the Board. And I think that
we should fill those vacancies as quickly as we can so that the
Board has a full complement of members.
I am not privy to the actual discussions of the meetings of the
Board, so I might be wrong about the independence of the Board
members. But I doubt it. Now to the question. Do you think the
stock market gains this week and last Friday are products of irrational exuberance, or are they normal market fluctuations?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, I do not comment on stock market fluctuations in the short term. The issues that I raise really
relate to long-term questions. If I may, can I comment on your various different points?
Senator BUNNING. Absolutely.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Because I think I will endeavor to get to
your conclusion as best I can.
As I think I indicated to you previously, I do not think we did
pop the bubble, as you may put it. We did raise interest rates in
1999, and the reason we did is real long-term rates were beginning
to rise because the economy was beginning to accelerate. Had we
not raised the Federal funds rate during that particular period, we
could have held it in check only by expanding the money supply at
an inordinately rapid rate. In other words, suppress the demand,
or I should say, hold interest rates down by flooding the market.
We did not have an alternative to do that.
Senator BUNNING. But you squeezed the money out of the market
and therefore, you forced all those Nasdaq companies, because they
could not go to the market, where they got their money, to look
somewhere else.
Chairman GREENSPAN. I do not think that is factually accurate,
Senator.
Senator BUNNING. Well, we will disagree on that.
Chairman GREENSPAN. The wealth effect is basically an analytical issue which refers to the fact that asset price changes do affect
economic activity. Since it is the function of monetary policy to try
to maintain long-term, sustainable, economic growth, by not evaluating factors as important as the so-called wealth effect on economic activity would be a dereliction of our duty, in my judgment.
Senator BUNNING. Is it your duty, then, to drive the wealth effect
and make sure that there is no wealth effect?
Chairman GREENSPAN. No, on the contrary. I have said innumerable times in years past that when I raised the question in 1996
as to whether monetary policy ought to address asset price
changes, I subsequently concluded, and I think reported to this
Committee, that it would be inappropriate for the central bank to
be overriding the decisions of millions of investors in making their
value judgments. I do not think, one, we ought to do that. I do not
think that we did do that.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00024

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

21
Senator BUNNING. But, sir, when you say something that is contrary or detrimental to the market in a public statement, the market immediately reacts. If you are positive in your statements
about what is going to happen in the future, the market reacts.
Should one person have that power?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, the reason I did not answer the question as you put it is it probably could have an effect
on the market in addressing the question about the recent stock
price change.
Senator BUNNING. Are you telling me what you have said today
is exactly—I read your statement twice that you gave the House.
It is almost the exact same statement that you gave the House.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Correct. What I am trying to say, basically, is that we should not be, and do not, as best I can judge, endeavor to address asset valuations and try to change them.
What we do is take those changes into consideration as they impact on the economy and review monetary policy as essentially a
vehicle to try to alter the liquidity of the system in a manner to
maximize economic growth.
And we do not address the issue of trying to change the wealth
effect. We respond to the wealth effect. We do not try, nor do I
think we would ever succeed, in changing the wealth effect, or I
should say, asset prices, because human nature being what it is,
people will valuate things one way or the other. And I do not think
monetary policy in the long run actually could be effective even if
we chose to do it.
Senator BUNNING. Well, we have a major disagreement on that.
Chairman GREENSPAN. I agree. That I do agree with, Senator.
[Laughter.]
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Corzine.
Senator CORZINE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
I would like to turn a little bit to the current economic circumstance. If I read the papers right and hear from my colleagues,
there is an additional stimulus bill making its way through the
House tied to the extension of unemployment insurance benefits,
$43 billion or so of additional tax cuts. Is the economy in need of
additional stimulus, in your view?
Then there is a second concern that I hear—actually, I think it
is reflective of maybe a difference in what we hear from corporate
executives out in the world about the state of the economy relative
to the reported statistics, which is somewhat in dissonance.
But it has to do with the issue of terrorist insurance and whether
that is having significant impact in our real estate and construction
markets, and whether it is having impact in our lending markets,
and whether you think there is need for us to act in that area. I
would love to hear your comments on that, and come back to
counterparty surveillance issues, if we have time.
Chairman GREENSPAN. On the issue of stimulus, as I have stated
before the House and, indeed, before the Senate Budget Committee
at an earlier time, as you may recall, if we are dealing with an outlook which seems to be reasonably positive, as the rate of inventory
liquidation gradually goes to zero, then the key question is: will
final demand kick in to keep the economy recovering after the inventory stimulus, so to speak, dissipates?

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00025

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

22
If the conclusion is that it might not, then one can argue a stimulus program is a credible type of thing to try to do, largely because it rarely is anything useful in the short run because we can
never implement it in time. But what we are talking about is 4 to
6 months from now, to be effective.
As I indicated before the House, I doubt very much whether the
economy, if it did not get a stimulus, would sag. And I think the
crucial issue that the Congress has to make a judgment on is
whether the cost to the budget and to the level of debt that is created as a consequence is a useful fiscal initiative.
We do of course have the problem that the one fact we know with
almost reasonable certainty is the huge demographic bulge of retirees that is going to occur at the end of this decade. And that is
going to require that we have higher savings rates, higher capital
investment, higher productivity, to make certain that the retirees
can maintain a standard of living at the same time that the workers at that time continue to enjoy an increase in their standards
of living.
So as the years go on in this decade, we are going to become increasingly aware of the oncoming big bulge in retirees and the fiscal policies that that is going to require on the part of this country.
Senator CORZINE. Do I hear you saying that we are getting late
in the game?
Chairman GREENSPAN. The clock is ticking. And in any fiscal
stimulus program that is started, you have to get that into the policy mix.
With respect to the question of corporate executives being, as I
think you put it, more subdued than the forecasters, I think they
are just looking at a very low level of corporate profits, and that
is creating a significantly less buoyant view of the outlook than
that which most economists, even those who work for the corporate
executives, have.
On the issue of terrorist insurance, as I said at the House Committee last week, I do not think that it is possible to get any realistic view of what a probability distribution of the costs of a
terrorist act will be.
We know roughly what earthquakes can do. We know that it is
extraordinarily unlikely that you get much above 8, 81⁄2 on the
Richter Scale and you can sort of figure out what the costs are. We
do not have that ability on a terrorist act. And I am of the opinion
that we probably ought to endeavor to reinsure such risks with
some deductibles, that it may well be, as I said in the House last
week, that if the Congress merely indicates that it perceives that
terrorist acts will be essentially reinsured by the American taxpayer, how that is done can be left to after the fact because it is
a very tricky issue.
The question is, has it had an effect on real estate? Some. It is
too soon to get a sense of any large numbers. Whatever the effect
has been to date clearly is not yet showing up as a significant negative in the economy. But clearly, nonresidential building is being
affected and certainly large projects are essentially going forward
self-insured, which is a risky issue.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00026

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

23
It means that the insurance premium essentially, as you well
know, ends up in the interest rate premium that these projects are
required to pay to get funded.
Senator CORZINE. Have you seen that factor show up in rates
and/or spreads in any of the marketplaces?
Chairman GREENSPAN. I do not really think we see it as yet, and
it would really have to be an analysis of individual projects because, obviously, the probability of a terrorist attack in the vast
proportion of the area of the United States is very low. And one
would presume that the premium in those areas would not show
up significantly.
Unless you took a look at the self-insurance of individual projects
in areas where the risks of terrorist acts are much higher, I do not
think you get a good sense of what the cost of self-insurance is.
Chairman SARBANES. Good. Senator Crapo.
Senator CRAPO. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Mr. Greenspan, you have already answered my question in a
general sense in response to Senator Gramm’s inquiry about the
derivatives issue.
I take it from your answer that you do not believe that it was
a mistake to exclude certain derivatives transactions from regulations under the Commodities Futures Modernization Act?
Chairman GREENSPAN. I do not. I think that Act, in retrospect,
was a very sound program passed by the Congress. I do not see any
particular need to revisit many of the issues which were discussed
at length at that time.
Senator CRAPO. Some have said, or at least have tried to establish some kind of a link between the failure to regulate these types
of derivatives transactions and the Enron collapse.
Do you have an opinion on whether the failure to regulate these
specific types of derivatives transactions in energy is linked in
some way to the Enron circumstance?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, obviously, a lot of people
are looking at this and it is quite conceivable that things will be
unearthed at some subsequent date which will draw linkages.
At the moment, I have not seen any. Clearly, what essentially
undercut Enron were the special purpose vehicles which were offbalance sheet constructs which happened in certain respects to use
derivatives as a means for trying to create, which was what the
program was, namely, to obscure some of the underlying debt and
potential losses in the firm. They could have used anything else to
do the same thing.
Derivatives are a very effective financial instrument for good or
ill. They in and of themselves are not anything that is potentially
any more dangerous than the underlying assets which they are derived from.
Remember that the derivatives were used in the Enron case as
an end-user, not as a dealer, and that Enron Online, which is the
derivatives dealer, has apparently not had any particular problems,
except, obviously, that they have lost a lot of people. But, as you
know, that particular part of Enron was sold and had value.
So, you have to distinguish where the nature of the problem that
created the collapse and what I call capitalized reputation in Enron
came from.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00027

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

24
And at least to date, it does not appear to be—I will put it this
way: derivatives do not appear to be a smoking gun. It is conceivable to me that we will find that the statement I just made is false
on later evaluation of information we as yet do not have. But on
the basis of what I have seen, I have seen none that suggests that
that is a problem.
Senator CRAPO. And on sort of the flip side of that question, has
the utilization of derivatives generally in the marketplace been a
positive force in financial markets?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, as I indicated in my prepared remarks, it is very difficult to make judgments as to what
the effect of individual instruments are on the economy overall, but
having observed this phenomenon now for a number of years, it
does strike me as being a major contributor to the flexibility and
resiliency of our financial system. Because remember what derivatives do. They shift risk from those who are undesirous or incapable of absorbing it, to those who are.
Now that as an economic phenomenon is something which is always unequivocally positive. The issue is rarely, if ever, whether
that instrument is a useful instrument. Obviously, if it were not
you would not have the vast demand that has occurred for this
type of hedging procedure, whose basic purpose is to lower risk, not
increase it.
And I think it has been a major factor in the resiliency of our
economy and maybe a major player in why the contraction that we
have just been through was so mild, why the financial system did
not breach under the pressures of, one, the sharp decline in asset
prices, and two, the events of September 11.
I also indicated in my prepared remarks that, clearly, when you
are dealing with very sophisticated instruments such as this, there
are risks of things going wrong. But I cannot argue that you can
therefore say it is the derivative that did it. It is the fact that they
were misused or something about them did not work very well. But
there is nothing inherently negative about them because, were that
the case, the extraordinary small default record of these instruments, which is very low, would not be the case. And two, the demand for them year after year expanding at a dramatic rate, would
not have occurred.
Senator CRAPO. Thank you very much for these good insights.
Chairman SARBANES. Thank you, Senator Crapo.
To complete the first round, just so Members know where they
are, I have on this side, Senator Dodd, Senator Akaka, and then
Senator Miller. And Senator Allard, you are next on this side.
Senator ALLARD. Yes, Mr. Chairman. Do you want me to go now?
Chairman SARBANES. No, because we just went from here.
Senator ALLARD. Right.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Dodd.
Senator DODD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Welcome, Chairman Greespan. It gets said often enough, but it
deserves repeating—you have done a terrific job and we are all
very grateful for your leadership.
The fact that we are coming out of this recession, as brief as it
is, I think you and your staff at the Federal Reserve can take a

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00028

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

25
great deal of credit for what you have done over the last year or
so, particularly the rate cuts.
Let me, if I can, I will try to lump my questions together, too.
It will give you more of a chance to respond than to listen to the
question.
I appreciate Senator Corzine raising the terrorism insurance
issue. We did a lot of work on that a number of months ago. But
I think your testimony helps this morning give us a better feel and
flavor for that issue. It is one we need to watch and there will be
an effort, I know, to try and probably revive that issue.
Senator Stabenow raised the question of international. We have
had either flat GDP rates, in Great Britain, zero, in Germany, I
think, Japan, Argentina have problems.
I would like to know if you could take the long-term rate issue,
given the gap that exists between short- and long-term rates, and
then tieing in the question of what is going on internationally economically, add to it, if you will, some of the projections that we are
getting. The CBO’s numbers indicate a budget deficit substantially
different from what the President indicated only a few weeks ago.
They are talking now about $121 billion versus $80. And a cumulative deficit over the next 10 years, excluding Social Security, of
$1.8 trillion. I wonder if you might shed some light on to what extent that ought to be a concern in terms of those of us here as policy-setters. That is number one.
And then jumping to the issue—and I am not going to ask you
to comment on specific bills because that is not a fair question for
you. But pension reform, obviously in light of Enron, is going to be
a major subject of debate. Another committee on which I serve may
markup a bill as early as next week. Senator Corzine and Senator
Boxer have offered ideas in this area.
We are going to do some things in this area and I think you have
raised the issue of unintended consequences of some actions. I wonder if you might comment here. I do not know if you are familiar
with the bill that Senator Kennedy has proposed dealing with employer contributions, defined contribution, defined benefit plans,
and so forth.
But rather than getting it out in the details of a bill, I would like
to hear you comment on pension issues, the numbers have come
back down now, but they reached a high I think of 44 percent of
all stock was being held by employees in the firms in which they
worked. That number seems to have dropped back to around 34
percent, the latest numbers.
Give us some flavor and feel for that issue, if you will, because
all of us want to do the right thing up here. We realize that this
is a critically important issue. I, for one, have supported over the
years the employee stock option plans not just because of its ability
to generate wealth among those who work for companies, but also
because of the productivity issues associated with these stocks, the
kind of value.
So, I want to be careful as I vote up here on these questions. I
want to avoid the kind of Enron situation where people were absolutely taken to the cleaners by what happened.
But simultaneously, I do not want to do something up here that
has the unintended consequences of hurting people who legiti-

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00029

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

26
mately are using these vehicles as a way of increasing their wealth
and having other economic benefits. So those two questions.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, it is my impression that if the
stock of Enron had not collapsed effectively to zero, this issue
would not be on the table.
Senator DODD. I suspect it might not have been, certainly.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Yes. If Dynergy, for example, had successfully merged with Enron, my impression is that the story of
Enron would have been really quite different, not that there would
not have been very significant losses, but the starkness of the evaporation would not have been evident in that respect.
I agree with you. I think that the employee stock options plans
have been a very positive force in this country in the sense of ownership and, indeed, because there is a positive equity premium in
our economy, meaning that the rate of return on stocks is chronically in excess over a rolling 20 year period of say, bonds or debt
instruments, that it is useful for pensions, which have at least 20
years to run, to make sure that they have adequate common stock
coverage.
I think the problem that may be an unintended consequence here
is that corporations have been fairly generous in stock matching.
And what I am concerned about is that you may reduce the share
of the particular company stock within a 401(k), but it may be because that number went down and the rest did not go up. In other
words, you can very readily create disincentives for corporate management in giving stock under ESOP plans because the incentive
for them to do so has effectively been removed. It is not clear to
me that that is offset by increased compensation and, hence, it is
not clear to me that the employee necessarily benefits.
So all I am really suggesting is that, whatever the bills of Senator Kennedy and Senator Corzine provide—and you had an earlier
version and then you backed, as I recall, Senator Kennedy’s position—I just merely request that you try to evaluate as closely as
you can what the impact of ESOP issuance would be under these
various different provisions that would appear in any bill that
would reform the pension system.
Senator DODD. Can you comment on the long-term rate issue, the
gap, and the questions of the intervention on domestic fiscal policy?
Chairman GREENSPAN. There is always a tendency for the socalled term structure of interest rates to be positive, meaning
short-term rates are lower than long-term.
Senator DODD. Yes.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Not all the time. Obviously, under inflationary speculative periods, you will often get short-term rates
going higher than long-term rates.
But, in general, I do not think there is something terribly significant here in the sense that a very dramatic decline in long-term
interest rates occurred in the second half of the year 2000, and that
a goodly part of the expected decline in rates that occurred then
was in anticipation of an easing of monetary policy.
And so, it is certainly the case, as many have argued, that shortterm rates went down appreciably in the year 2001, but long-term
rates did not. They went down some, but not a great deal.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00030

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

27
I think the problem in part is the timeframe in which we were
looking at that process. If we extended it back into July of 2000,
it looks a good deal different. You do get a measurable decline in
long-term rates, as well as short-term rates.
Senator DODD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thank you.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Allard.
Senator ALLARD. Chairman Greenspan, you noted in your testimony the economic importance of deregulation over the past 25
years. You went on to further state as an example, where deregulation worked in a positive manner was in the area of energy, as well
as financial markets. Are there other areas out there where you
think deregulation had a positive impact on the economy?
Chairman GREENSPAN. I do, Senator. As I indicated in my prepared remarks, I think that despite the fact that it is not terribly
evident that deregulation has helped the profitability of airlines,
there is no question that it has created a very much broader market and created the capability of American citizens to travel far
more cheaply than they had in earlier periods. And the ability to
create a very significant cargo freight system has I think facilitated
the movement of goods of high economic value. Trucking, obviously,
has been, in my judgment, a significantly improved system with
the deregulation that has occurred there. There are all sorts of
other smaller areas where it is questionable how much impact
there has been.
I would suspect that in certain areas of deregulation, you are
going to find that it does not work, or it does not work as well. But,
overall, the net effect of the last 20 years has been, as best I can
see, a positive force.
Senator ALLARD. Considering what our economy is doing right
now, do you think it is an appropriate time now to consider reducing capital gains rates even further?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, I always have been in
favor of doing that, but on long-term structural grounds. I do not
think the capital gains tax, as I have indicated many times before
this Committee, is a particularly effective tool for capital accumulation and economic growth. It has other characteristics. I think,
clearly, many people argue it has positive social impact and that
is an argument which I think you have to put on the table because
not everything is economics.
But from an economic point of view, I would prefer that we displace the whole capital gains tax with some other form of revenue
which has a less negative impact on capital accumulation, which I
perceive to be a crucial issue in long-term economic growth.
Senator ALLARD. In my State of Colorado, with the international
trade agreements, particularly NAFTA and GATT, we have experienced a greater growth in exports of any State in the country.
So, we have a lot of people that watch the exports and the value
of the dollar. Our value of the dollar in comparison to other economies, there are two variables there about what is happening. Two
big variables—one is what is happening in the United States, and
also, what is happening worldwide in other countries and how we
are trading with them. Is there anything that could be done to
change that value of the dollar that would encourage further exports.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00031

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

28
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, remember that the cause of the
strength of the dollar is largely the presumed perception on the
part of foreign investors that the rate of return in the United
States is higher than in their home countries. And so, they are
moving capital increasingly into the United States and that is
pressing the exchange rate higher.
I guess we could dissuade foreigners from investing here. I am
not sure that that is to our advantage. We do have the obverse of
this huge flow of funds into the economy, which is our current account deficit, which increasingly widens, and the trade deficit,
which is the major part of that. And that implies that—which is,
of course, the other side of the capital flowing in—that there are
ever increasing claims on the American economy by foreign investors. And that cannot go on indefinitely without some difficulty,
history tells us.
So, I have argued many times in the past that the current account deficit, meaning the capital surplus, cannot continue to increase. But it is the capital surplus which is driving the exchange
rate at this particular point. This process will end at some point,
but I have been forecasting this for 5 years, and I guess I will be
forecasting it for another five.
[Laughter.]
Senator ALLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Akaka.
Senator AKAKA. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Sarbanes, on March 5, President Bush announced
temporary tariffs on selected steel imports. I would like to know
your comments on the economic consequences of this action.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, Senator, as I have indicated before
this Committee on numerous occasions, I am a very strong proponent of free trade because I believe a free international trading
system has been a major contributor to the economic wealth created in this country.
I believe we benefit more than anybody from an open trading
system and we have, indeed, created a significant level of living in
this country in large part because of our ability to expand and get
the division of labor on a worldwide basis.
I understand the obvious problems that are involved in the transition as you invariably move capital from less productive areas of
an economy into the cutting-edge technologies. And it is difficult to
maintain the process. There are lots of casualties, both in capital
and in people, that are a consequence of these types of transitions,
and that it is appropriate to try to meet them, to a certain extent.
I understand the difficulties that any President has in trying to
come to grips with our trade laws and conditions such as exist in
our steel industry. I happen not to agree with the particular judgment, but I recognize that it is a very tough judgment that the
President had to make, and I am glad that I was not in a position
where I had to make that judgment.
Senator AKAKA. Chairman Greenspan, the confidence that investors have in the equity markets, I think there is no question, has
been shaken because of the collapse of Enron and the accounting
irregularities that have been found in the financial statements of
other public companies.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00032

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

29
You mentioned about the earthquakes. And when I use the word
shaken, I wondered at what part of the scale are we at.
There is a concern about how badly confidence in our country has
been shaken, to the point that there are proposals before this Committee addressing investor protection and also ways to improve accounting systems. So my question to you is, what actions do you
recommend to restore investor confidence?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, I think one of the things about
the Enron episode is that it is probably improved corporate governance to quite a significant degree.
The one thing I think everybody became aware of immediately
subsequent to the collapse of Enron is that investors started to put
a price-earnings premium on those companies which they perceived
to be free of spin in the sense of trying to game their earnings
numbers to make it look as though they are doing better than they
actually are. And what that has done is removed a very considerable amount of incentives to do that because if you are going to be
penalized for doing it, you are going to do it less.
And indeed, I think a considerable amount of changes that need
to happen—and I do not deny that there are significant problems
in corporate governance—have probably already happened.
I do think that numbers of issues with respect to accounting and
the structure of accounting and the issue of independent directors
and a variety of issues that have come forth, they will be addressed
and I think we are going to find out at the end of the day that,
even though Enron was a great tragedy for a number of people, especially the employees who worked there, it probably has created
a positive set of forces to improve corporate governance.
I think at the end of the day, we are going to find that it was
a net plus to our economy, with the obvious caveat that that is not
the way those thousands of employees of Enron could conceivably
visualize this very tragic incident.
Senator AKAKA. This next question is more parochial for me. The
financial condition of Japan has significant influence on the economy of Hawaii. Some economists predict that the gross domestic
product of Japan will decline during fiscal year 2002. And if you
care to answer this, what is your economic forecast for Japan?
Chairman GREENSPAN. Well, the Federal Reserve’s forecast is not
significantly different from what conventional forecasts are, either
of the Ministry of Finance or the Bank of Japan or private forecasters. We are all struggling with the fact that Japan is in a deflationary environment, that prices continue to ease inexorably. And
projecting what has been going on, it continues to be just a continuous erosion.
I would suspect, however, that if we turn around, and I hope that
the early data that we are seeing now are suggestive of that, it is
quite likely to be helpful to Japan, and helpful to Southeast Asia,
especially Japan. But we have never really had to confront something of the type of problem which Japan has been struggling with
for the last 10 years. So that we are not quite confident about how
to forecast that.
Senator AKAKA. Thank you.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Miller.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00033

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

30
STATEMENT OF SENATOR ZELL MILLER

Senator MILLER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have an opening
statement that I would like to request be made part of the record.
Chairman SARBANES. It will be included in full in the record.
Senator MILLER. Mr. Chairman, thank you so much for being
with us. You are always very patient in answering our questions.
I will be brief. I have a couple of questions.
First, I would like to associate myself with Senators Gramm and
Crapo on the derivatives question. I know you have already spoken
at length about it, but one thing I would be interested in is if you
had any thoughts on the impact of derivatives on energy prices
during the California energy crisis.
My other question, if I may go ahead and just ask you both, has
to do with something that could affect my home State of Georgia
in a dramatic way. As you well know, agri-business is the backbone
of the Georgia economy. It is a $60 billion business. One out of six
jobs come from agri-business. Our farmers right now are facing a
very uncertain future. They have skyrocketing production costs.
They have low commodity prices. And as they get ready to get into
their spring planting, many banks, I am told, are balking at
issuing loans to these farmers until we have a new farm bill. It is
causing a lot of instability, I am told.
My question is this. All my information is just anecdotal. I am
wondering if you, Mr. Chairman, have seen any reticence out there
from banks about making agricultural loans.
Chairman GREENSPAN. The evidence that we have is that loans
coming from so-called agricultural banks, which are those with a
significant part of agricultural loans in their assets, have not been
basically holding back until, as you point out, possibly recently because of the seeming stalemate between the House and the Senate
on the farm bill.
But we do not see any material or significant unavailability of
credit, either through the commercial banks or the farm credit system. And one of the reasons obviously is that, not speaking about
Georgia but generally speaking, Government payments have been
at significantly higher levels and have basically supported levels of
net farm income, and the real estate values, farm values, the land
values, have been doing reasonably well.
The underlying income and collateral of the farm community has
been such as to, as best I can judge, maintain the flow of credit.
I am not aware of banks balking, but I can understand why it
could create some hesitancy on the part of some lenders. But we
do not see that.
Senator MILLER. Thank you.
Chairman GREENSPAN. With respect to the California electric energy issue, you do not need to advert to derivatives to get a judgment as to why prices did what they did.
My recollection is that, 10 years ago or so, the sort of capacity
buffer that the California electric power system had was the typical
15 percent for summer peak loads, which is what generally a regulated industry had because you effectively guaranteed a rate of return on capacity which was not being used. But that 15 percent
kept prices down.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00034

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

31
As the years went on and demand went up in California, especially from Silicon Valley, where electric power demands are very
high, but no new capacity, no new plants, as you know, came on
stream, that 15 percent gradually dissolved because there is no
way to have inventories of electricity. Our battery systems are just
inadequate for that. So, you get into a situation where the demand
load, if it is running up against a limited capacity—and the demand tends to be price inelastic, as economists like to say, can
produce some huge price spikes because there is no way to store
electric power. And indeed, that is exactly what happened.
Then the authorities in California raised the retail prices of
power and demand came off, as you might expect, fairly abruptly.
And then, the actual load factors fell further in California, in part,
remembering that one of the reasons was that the weather was favorable toward less electric power use through the summer of 2001.
But prices have come all the way down. Excess capacity exists.
There has been, in fact, some delays in some of the capital expansion projects that were there.
You do not need derivatives to explain what happened to prices.
It is conceivable that there may have been price manipulation.
There may have been a number of things. But I do not think that
you need to advert to that, as I said earlier, to explain what happened. It is a question of fact. The authorities, to inhibit price manipulation, are following the statutes that we currently have and
I do not see any particular need, as I indicated to Senator Crapo,
of any major change in the underlying Commodity Exchange Act.
Senator MILLER. Thank you.
Chairman SARBANES. Good. Mr. Chairman, I have one subject
that I want to cover very quickly, and we may do another round.
I see Senator Corzine is still with us. I want to discuss the unemployment insurance benefits for a moment.
In every recession over the past 30 years, we have extended unemployment insurance benefits. That has not yet been done in this
economic downturn, and it is in part because and I do not want to
draw you into this issue—but there is a very sharp conflict in the
Congress.
Our colleagues particularly on the other side of the aisle, on the
House side, are insistent that they will not extend unemployment
insurance benefits unless there is a large tax cut again for what
many of us regard as being for people who do not need a tax cut.
It looks like they may now be relenting on that, or we certainly
hope so. But in any event, I have regarded it as something of an
outrage that extending the unemployment insurance benefits would
be linked to a tax cut, rather than to get that to help the needy.
But leaving that to one side, I think you have testified previously, you are supportive of extending unemployment insurance
benefits. Is that correct?
Chairman GREENSPAN. That is correct, Mr. Chairman. I think
that our unemployment insurance system is actually a reasonably
well constructed one in recent years. The 26 week length of total
insurance, which is pretty much general throughout the 50 States,
is not a bad limit because you do not want, as other countries have,
to use the unemployment system to induce people to leave the
workforce.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00035

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

32
But the premise of that is that, after 26 weeks, you should be
able to get a job. When we are in a recession, that may not actually
be the case. And therefore, the logic of having 26 weeks as a discipline issue in a market system is lost.
So, I argued at the House hearing that extension, temporary extension of unemployment insurance during periods of significant
decline in labor demand, seems to be a most reasonable approach
to the pattern. And I think the way we have done it is a fairly sensible approach to the whole concept of unemployment insurance.
Chairman SARBANES. I might note that in the downturn in the
early 1990’s, actually when the previous President Bush was in office, that in the end, we extended it for an additional 33 weeks. We
really ran it up to 59 weeks because we had difficulty coming out
of that downturn. But as you point out, it then reverted back to 26
weeks as we moved into a more stable and growth economy.
I want to ask two questions on what you said on the construct
of it because I am beginning to think that maybe we need to examine that a little bit.
One is that, on average, only 46 percent of the unemployed qualify for unemployment insurance. So, we have a significant part of
the workers who lose jobs who do not qualify for unemployment insurance because we require them to have worked a certain length
of time and so forth. This gets complicated when you get more and
more people working part-time. That is a significant component.
And part-time often means 30 to 35 hours a week. They are relatively shy of full-time.
Also, you get workers coming into the workforce, like Welfare To
Work, where we are trying to move people into work, and then they
lose the job. And where does that leave us? Is it worth examining
the coverage of the unemployment insurance program? I do not
have an answer in mind. I am just beginning to think that we
probably need to look at that. Let me ask the other dimension of
that question.
Unemployment insurance benefits now average about $230 a
week. In Northern Virginia, for example, the maximum unemployment insurance benefit is $1,160 per month. The rent for a typical
two-bedroom apartment is $907 per month.
So, again, that raises the question whether we need to examine
the level of the payments in terms of accomplishing our purposes.
Now, I know both of these raise questions because you do not
want to turn it into some kind of semi-permanent way of life. But
are those two issues worth taking a look at?
Chairman GREENSPAN. It is very difficult for me to answer. And
the reason I say that is, it gets down to what the economic effects
in the labor market would be were you to introduce them.
I do not know the answer to that. All I can say is that it has
been my experience that the system has worked remarkably well.
But implicit in it is that unemployment insurance is not freely
available, and that it induces a flexibility in the workforce which
has us down to an unemployment rate of under 4 percent. And I
think that is a highly desirable issue.
It is always easy to find selected people within the pool of unemployed who are not getting benefits and find reasons why they
should be. If you do that, I think you end up with a much higher

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00036

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

33
level than you would like for purposes of macroeconomic stability
and that is a judgment which I think the Congress has to make.
I do not think economists can help materially in that.
Chairman SARBANES. I would just observe, the trend lines show
that the percent of unemployed having access to unemployment insurance has been trending down from where it used to be.
Chairman GREENSPAN. I think that is correct, yes.
Chairman SARBANES. I also think the amount of income replaced
by the unemployment insurance has also been trending down. So,
at an earlier time, the system was in effect more comprehensive.
Chairman GREENSPAN. I think that is correct, Mr. Chairman.
The system was significantly more comprehensive. But, in my judgment, less effective in its purpose to maintain as a safety valve
which does not undercut the basic viability of the labor market.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Corzine, did you want to wind this
up here?
Senator CORZINE. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I will be a
quick second.
Mr. Chairman, in no way does the question I am going to ask
change the view that I concurred with Senator Gramm and others
at the start on the job that you have done in the leadership of the
Federal Reserve. But I am really mystified a little bit about the response to the question with regard to the CFTC Act and the exemption of over-the-counter derivative activities and derivative entities outside regulatory oversight, if not regulatory regimes. It
seems inconsistent to me relative to the needs of consumer protection or antimanipulation or price transparency in a market that
has secondary implications, if not direct implications, on consumers.
There is a serious issue about whether price manipulation actually ends up backing into causes of consumer losses in California.
I think that is the question that Senator Miller was referencing.
It is for certain that it has had implications on investors, at least
the overall Enron issue, yet to be determined, as I think you outlined. Whether the derivatives were a driver or not certainly has
not been revealed by the information we have today. But that does
not necessarily mean that it is not a part of it.
I think back into relatively recent history on nonregulated entities having impact into financial markets that then have secondary
implications, whether it is long-term capital, go into some of the
commodity trading problems that came with Sumotomo Corp.
I go back into history, Lombard Wahl and Drysdale and a whole
series of things where no oversight ended up having significant impacts into other areas.
And I think I recall another time and another place that the Federal Reserve—I do not know your own position on this—thought
that the Government securities market might need some oversight
so that it does not have to be ham-handed regulation. And certainly believe in counterparty surveillance, so that people would
have a sense of responsibility about how they are operating. I think
we do that with banks and securities firms.
And this idea that there is no oversight of a potentially significant market does not seem to gibe with the kinds of initiatives that
I have seen out of the Federal Reserve Board or yourself in some

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00037

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

34
instances. I would love for you to comment on that because it is inconsistent, at least in my eyesight.
Chairman GREENSPAN. No. Fair question. First of all, the CFTC
clearly has supervision over regulated markets in energy and elsewhere. They also have authority under existing statute to act
against price manipulation in the over-the-counter markets. And
indeed, had Enron been involved in price manipulation, there is authority as of today for the CFTC to be looking at that.
Senator CORZINE. If there is not an ongoing oversight, though,
then it is only a response to an event.
Chairman GREENSPAN. No. What I am trying to say is that the
CFTC has legal authority. In other words, the question is, do you
need additional legislation?
Senator CORZINE. Right.
Chairman GREENSPAN. And the answer is, they already have it.
It is there.
What the only issue here really gets down to is the question of
consumer protection, per se, in which, as I recall, when we addressed this issue in the President’s Working Group, which led to
the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, that when we
discussed that issue at considerable length, the notion was essentially when you are dealing with small investors, do you want protection? The answer was yes. And that is what the statute does.
The question, however, of over-the-counter derivatives being
overseen by regulation runs into two problems, at least from the
discussions that we had at the Working Group. One, that the whole
derivatives area was and still is in the process of evolving. And as
you well know, when you stick a regulatory structure on top of an
evolving market, you freeze it. Two, the effective advantages that
one can get are particularly questionable.
The only issue that is involved here reflects the question as to
whether there is oversight on the nature of the contract itself.
I remember when I was on the J.P. Morgan board and you were
at Goldman Sachs, there was a huge amount of credit that moved
between J.P. Morgan and Goldman and there was not any Government official overlooking whether the creditworthiness of the institutions was there or not. I would venture to say, looking at it from
the point of view of what bank regulators can do, we do not have
the capacity to look at counterparties at the level that it is possible
for individual institutions such as Morgan or Goldman. And that,
in our judgment, it was not, as we said at the time, the most effective means of regulation that you can have in those markets.
Senator CORZINE. You would not suggest that the relationship
between
Morgan
and
Goldman
and
credit
extension
between the two is not supervised either by the Federal Reserve
System and/or by the SEC? There are limits.
Chairman GREENSPAN. What I am saying is that there is no way
that the Federal Reserve, which, as you know, supervises Morgan,
has better judgments on a loan to Goldman than the people at the
bank would have.
Senator CORZINE. I am certainly not suggesting that. But there
are supervisory oversights—
Chairman GREENSPAN. There are. And indeed, you have to ask
whether they are positive or negative to the system.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00038

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

35
I have no doubt that we could put every sort of regulation on derivatives and over-the-counter derivatives and force them into specific molds. I will tell you, as you would agree probably more so
than I, that you will dry up that market. And if, indeed, we had
seen significant problems in the over-the-counter market, I think
that that is where we would be at this stage.
But what is really quite remarkable about the evolution of that
market is that when problems of risk emerged, you know, we went
to collateralization of derivatives, and the default rates are unimaginably low. There is this large legal issue as to whether certain transactions with Enron were a debt or a derivative—so the
surety bonds are under dispute—but if you eliminate that, it is
very hard to find defaults. And it was our view that in the overthe-counter energy area, it was desirable to allow that market to
evolve.
We think it has. The collapse of Enron did not demonstrably impact on the prices of natural gas or electric power or any of the elements that they were significantly involved as the major player in.
Senator CORZINE. Well, though, it is not just the impacts that
occur in the market, the immediate market. It has other implications for other activities when there is a financial dislocation with
a particular market entity, Long-Term Capital or any other.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Let me just say this. Long-Term Capital,
as you may recall, was not taking hedging positions. They took
principled positions. They happened to use derivatives as the vehicle to make some of those bets. They turned out to be dubious, to
say the least. But I would scarcely argue that derivatives were a
factor. They could just as readily have done it by plain vanilla
stocks, bonds, leverage, any other thing they could have done.
It is the case that derivatives are a very powerful tool. And if
misused, they can create problems. LTCM was a problem. But I
think we have to distinguish between the instruments and the actions. What I think was involved in LTCM and in Enron was, as
I put in my prepared remarks, just plain, old-fashioned excess of
debt. The derivatives were a vehicle in enabling that debt to be accumulated. But they could have done it in 20 other different ways.
They would not have done it as efficiently or as quickly. I will
grant you that.
And if it does turn out, Senator, that these types of over-thecounter derivative activities which are not now regulated, do impinge on consumers, I think that would be appropriately revisited.
What we said was that it was inappropriate at that time, meaning the year 2000, to effectively be locking in regulation until we
saw a particular need for it. And at least those of us who were involved in it, did not see it then. I must say that I have not yet seen
evidence to suggest that that is the case now.
But I grant you, it may turn out that way. If it does, I think it
would be most appropriate to take legislative action to address that
subject. However, at the moment, I have not seen anything that
suggests the need for it.
Chairman SARBANES. Senator Carper.
Senator CARPER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman Greenspan, shortly after you completed your statement and the questioning began, I had to slip out to preside in the

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00039

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

36
Senate where we are debating today, again, the comprehensive energy bill that is before the Senate.
I telegraphed you earlier in my opening statement that I would
like to visit with you just briefly before we conclude, some energyrelated issues. If you could do that with me, I would be grateful.
As we debate the energy legislation before the Senate, we do so
at a time when our oil imports are approaching 60 percent of that
which we consume, where our trade deficit, I believe for last year,
reached $300 billion. And we know that not all of that is oil, but
a significant piece of that trade deficit is.
I learned this week that apparently, there is some talk of a cartel
being formed similar to OPEC that might deal with another commodity, and that is natural gas. There was some talk of that occurring around the world.
Against that backdrop, and the debate on energy, I wanted to
ask, if you could, just to share a word or two with the implications
for our economy going forward, on our failure to adopt a comprehensive energy policy that does two things. One, produces more
energy; and two, conserves more energy.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Senator, it is fairly apparent from all of
the data that we have seen over the decades that there is a fairly
close relationship between energy consumption and GDP. Indeed,
we must be certain that even though the ratio of energy per constant dollar GDP has been falling over the years as we have gone
to increasing efficiencies of various different forms, the longer-term
outlook for energy is a crucial element in any view of where this
economy is going over the next 10, 15, 20 years.
The problems that I see we have crucial difficulties with are
more natural gas than oil because oil we can import. And one must
presume that we have been able to do that to date and hopefully,
we will be able to do it in the future.
Natural gas is a much more difficult issue in the sense that we
have chosen natural gas as the preferred fuel for emissions reasons
and there is, as you know, on the drawing board, a very significant
number of gas-fired electric power plants to effectively meet the
problems that we saw, not only in California, but also in many
other areas of the country.
The difficulty is that natural gas is essentially a domestic and
Canadian source of supply. That is, my recollection is we import
about a sixth of our gas from Canada and we produce the rest of
it essentially here by drilling.
And what we have found is that as the technology improves, increasingly the reservoirs that we get from drilling dissipate far
more rapidly than they have in the past, which means that, if, for
example, which is relative to the case, that we lose 50 percent of
a new reservoir a year, then, clearly, you need gross additions to
gas production to just maintain a net growth.
We expended a huge amount of effort in drilling in the last couple of years and only increased net marketed gas by a very small
percent. And if you project out into the future, and if you take a
look at the potential demands for natural gas, it is going to create
a problem because we cannot drill fast enough to do it, which leads
to the conclusion that we either get it from Canada, which is al-

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00040

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

37
ready beginning to run into capacity problems itself, or liquefied
natural gas imports.
It is very likely that that is where an increasing proportion of
our gas is going to come from. But we have been hesitant to put
in the terminals that are required to import gas from Indonesia or
from Qatar. And the reason is that there are environmental concerns about the issue of liquefied natural gas, which is a very
tricky commodity to handle at cryogenic temperatures. So, we are
going to have to build a number of areas which can bring the gas
in and we have not really addressed that issue, and I think that
is where a long-term program is required.
Second, we obviously are going to need to take a real close look
at our electric grids, which are really deteriorating. And indeed, I
noticed the Supreme Court, was it yesterday or the day before,
unanimously voted to grant authority to FERC to require that individual utilities open up their electric power to feed into the grid,
at least as I read it. That is helpful, but you need a grid that is
not deteriorating to handle those particular qualities.
So, I think that if you start to look at all the various different
things, including coal, there is still a very big problem that we are
importing an ever-increasing proportion of our oil, which creates
some national security problems as well.
It is going to be important, as far as I can judge, that we indeed
take a very close look at the long-term outlook and the supply of
energy and then take a close look at what our alternate sources of
conservation are.
Fuel cells have a huge potential, but they are considerably far
out in the future. They are not something that is going to be a
major factor. And as somebody said the other day, every time we
seem to be getting a fusion breakthrough, it is commercially available 50 years out.
It reminds me of shale oil. As you may recall back in the 1970’s,
the cost of shale oil was always something like $6 a barrel more
than crude oil, no matter what the price of crude oil was, which
made no sense whatever. It just sort of indicated to you that we
tend to look at these newer forms of energy supply and they seem
to be less available than we would like.
I think the issue of conservation, the issue of sources of production, our import strategy, our environmental strategy, are all part
of an integrated strategy which the Congress has to address in
total.
Senator CARPER. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. Mr. Chairman, thank you very much for
appearing before the Committee. As always, we very much appreciate your testimony. And again, we wish you a happy birthday.
Chairman GREENSPAN. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
Chairman SARBANES. The hearing stands adjourned.
[Whereupon, at 12:35 p.m., the hearing was adjourned.]
[Prepared statements and additional material supplied for the
record follow:]

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00041

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6633

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

38
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR PAUL S. SARBANES
I am pleased to welcome Chairman Greenspan before the Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs this morning to testify on the Federal Reserve’s SemiAnnual Monetary Policy Report to Congress.
Legislation enacted in the last Congress requires the Federal Reserve not only to
submit a report to Congress twice a year on the conduct of monetary policy, but also
requires the Chairman of the Federal Reserve to testify before the Congress on the
report. Prior to the enactment of that legislation, the Fed Chairman testified before
Congress on the report as a matter of custom, but was not actually required to do
so by statute. Senator Phil Gramm and I worked together with the Fed on that legislation, which provides that the Fed Chairman testifies first before the House in
February in even numbered years and first before the Senate in odd numbered
years. The House thus had the benefit of Chairman Greenspan’s testimony last
week. The Senate has the benefit of a week to review the testimony presented before the House.
Chairman Greenspan’s testimony last week and this morning presents a positive,
but cautious outlook for the U.S. economy. He speaks about a ‘‘subdued recovery,’’
which he views as remarkable in light of the severe shock experienced by the economy as a result of the terrorist attack on September 11.
According to his testimony, the central tendency of the forecasts of the Federal
Open Market Committee prepared for the Monetary Policy Report to Congress was
for real GDP to rise 21⁄2 to 3 percent during 2002. Unemployment was expected to
rise to 6 to 61⁄4 percent, and inflation as measured by the price index for personal
consumption expenditures was expected to increase only 11⁄2 percent. Chairman
Greenspan pointed out that despite the forecast of a resumption of economic growth,
the FOMC at its meeting on January 30 saw the risks as continuing to be weighted
toward conditions that may generate economic weakness in the foreseeable future.
Since Chairman Greenspan testified last Wednesday, the Commerce Department
released a report which revised upward U.S. economic growth in the fourth quarter
of last year from 0.2 percent to 1.4 percent. In addition, the Institute for Supply
Management (ISM), formerly known as the National Association of Purchasing
Management, released its index of manufacturing activity which showed a larger
than expected rise and gave the first sign of growth in manufacturing in 18 months.
The Federal Government also reported that consumer spending and income growth
increased in January, and that construction activity expanded. These reports have
led to increased optimism that a recovery is taking hold. Chairman Greenspan
slightly modified his testimony from last week to reflect those reports. The Banking
Committee will be very interested to hear Chairman Greenspan’s views on them
this morning.
I would like to make just a few of observations. First, I believe the Federal Reserve’s caution about the outlook for U.S. economic recovery is well placed. Sustained consumer demand has been the foundation of the improved outlook for of the
economy. However, both the University of Michigan’s Consumer Sentiment Index
and the Conference Board’s Index of Consumer Confidence declined last month.
Consumers reported that they are increasingly worried about unemployment and future income prospects. Those worries are grounded in the current weakness of labor
markets, and they will only be exacerbated by the projected increases in unemployment.
In addition, most observers agree that the key to the strength of a recovery will
be significant growth in capital spending, and there is great uncertainty as to
whether that will occur. According to the Commerce Department, business fixed investment in the fourth quarter of last year declined at an 11 percent annual rate,
even as the overall economy grew at a 1.4 percent rate.
Finally, even as the economy recovers, unemployment is expected to continue to
rise, as the FOMC forecasts. Over the last year, according to the Bureau of Labor
Statistics, the number of people unemployed for more than 14 weeks has nearly
doubled (from 1,357,000 to 2,547,000). Those unemployed for more than 26 weeks,
the cutoff for unemployment insurance, has also nearly doubled (from 648,000 to
1,127,000). This affects consumer sentiment. In my view it also makes a compelling
case for the temporary 13 week extension of unemployment benefits, as passed by
the Senate, for those who are looking for work but cannot find it. The extension
should not be tied to the enactment of the extreme tax cut proposal put forward in
the House.
The Federal Reserve is prudent to emphasize the uncertainties still present in the
economic outlook. With inflation contained the Fed can afford to adopt a wait and
see attitude, and certainly not move precipitously to raise interest rates. I look forward to hearing Chairman Greenspan’s testimony this morning.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00042

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

39
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR TIM JOHNSON
Chairman Greenspan, thank you for coming to today’s hearing to discuss the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy and the state of the U.S. economy. I would also like
to recognize your staff for preparing such a comprehensive written report on these
issues.
I sense a cautious optimism in your written testimony that reflects well on the
resilience of the U.S. economy, especially in the wake of September 11. Further, I
want to thank you, Chairman Greenspan, for the Federal Reserve’s diligent management of U.S. monetary policy in helping to make the recent economic downturn,
I hope, relatively shallow and brief.
While most Americans can look forward to continued prosperity during 2002, I
would like to draw your attention to a segment of the population that will not share
in this prosperity: the approximately 2.7 million Native American and Native Hawaiian people living in the United States.
Consider the following statistics. According to U.S. Department of Commerce’s
census data, unemployment rates on Indian Lands in the continental United States
ranging up to 80 percent compared to 5.6 percent for the United States as a whole.
Census data also show that the poverty rate for Native Americans during the late
1990’s was 26 percent, compared to the national average of 12 percent. In fact, overall, Native American household income is only three-quarters of the national average.
This disparity is particularly evident in my home State of South Dakota where
Native Americans represent over 8 percent of the State’s population. While the overall State economy is relatively strong with a low 3.1 percent unemployment rate,
the Native American population continues to suffer. South Dakota counties with Indian Reservations are ranked by the U.S. Census Bureau as among the most impoverished in the United States.
This past Tuesday’s Wall Street Journal carried an article by Jonathan Eig that
focuses, in part, on the toll of poverty for the Oglala Sioux living on the Pine Ridge
Indian Reservation. The article notes that:
Nearly half the tribe’s population is destitute. The unemployment rate is
about 75 percent. There is no bank, no motel, no movie theater. Restaurants open and close down before anyone notices. . .. The community
has the shortest life expectancy of anywhere in the Western Hemisphere
outside Haiti: 48 years old for men and 52 for women.
In light of this unacceptable economic disparity, it is important to address this
issue in a comprehensive manner. Therefore, as I announced at the National Congress of American Indians 2 weeks ago, I am moving forward with a Financial Institutions Subcommittee hearing on developing capital resources for Native Americans.
At the hearing, we will consider issues such as:
• mechanisms for providing small business capital;
• means for fostering the growth of Native American-owned financial intermediaries;
• incentives for financial institutions to provide services on Indian Lands;
• ways to encourage personal savings; and
• vehicles for improving financial literacy.
The goal of these discussions will be to assess the state of affairs of Native American capital formation and to develop strategies for addressing the barriers that
keep the first Americans out of the financial mainstream.
I thank you, Chairman Greenspan, for your extensive and thoughtful written testimony, and for the Federal Reserve’s efforts to keep the U.S. economy on track.
However, in closing, I would encourage you to consider the economic problems facing
Native Americans. I believe we all, including the Federal Reserve Board and Federal Reserve Banks, have a responsibility to address these issues, and I look forward
to working with you on this matter.
—————
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR WAYNE ALLARD
Mr. Chairman, I would like to thank you for holding this hearing today and I
want to welcome Federal Reserve Board Chairman Greenspan. I always look forward to the opportunity to hear from you, Chairman Greenspan, regarding monetary policy and other economic issues.
The Federal Reserve’s quick and aggressive efforts to counteract the effects of our
Nation’s weakened economy during 2001 should be applauded. The resiliency of our
economy through the September 11 attacks was remarkable and it seems that the

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00043

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

40
economy today is slowly gaining strength, which we can attribute to prudent monetary and fiscal policy.
Consumer spending remained high in recent months, particularly in the Housing
and Automotive Sectors. This strong consumption, along with other factors, helped
bring about a more stable economy. Chairman Greenspan, I look forward to hearing
from you what else can be done to continue strengthening our economy.
Thank you, again, Mr. Chairman, for holding this hearing and Chairman Greenspan, I look forward to your report.
—————
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR CHRISTOPHER J. DODD
It is always a pleasure to see you, Chairman Greenspan. I appreciate your coming
before the Committee today to deliver the Monetary Policy Report to Congress.
The last time Chairman Greenspan reported on the Nation’s monetary policy before this Committee was last summer. During that time we were wondering if our
economy was heading toward a significant downturn. Soon after, the events of September 11 occurred, and it was announced that we were officially in a recession, and
actually have been since March 2001. Never would we have predicted that so much
would have occurred in the last 5 months. I would like to commend you for doing
a great job in taking aggressive action to counter the effects of the shock suffered
by the economy after September 11.
It has been a difficult year for our Nation. We have seen the unemployment rate
climb to rates higher than we have seen in almost a decade. In 2001, the real GDP
grew only 1.2 percent, inflation as measured by the Consumer Price Index rose 1.6
percent in 2001. Interesting enough, while unemployment rates climbed in 2001,
consumer spending remained steady throughout. During the last 2 months, we have
seen somewhat of a small rebound. The unemployment rate has decreased during
the last 2 months, and hopefully, we will continue to see a decline.
Just yesterday, the Fed’s Beige Book reported that a majority of Federal Reserve
districts reported some signs of improvement in economic conditions in January and
early February. The Beige Book also reported that the increase in retail sales during the last 2 months is an indication that the U.S. economy is recovering from the
recession, but that the recovery will be a slow and weaker one than the average
post-recession recovery. While a recovery is good news, there are many challenges
that loom ahead. Challenges that must be confronted if we are going to build a
strong economy that will afford every hard working American an opportunity to
build a sound and secure future.
I look forward to hearing from the Chairman and my colleagues this morning. I
especially look forward to hearing the Chairman’s thoughts on the diminished surplus, the duration of the recession, and his predictions on future unemployment
rates.
Again, thank you Mr. Chairman for your time before this Committee.
—————
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR DANIEL K. AKAKA
Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As we all know, in November 2001, the National Bureau of Economic Research declared that the U.S. economy has been in recession
since March 2001, ending the longest expansion in U.S. history and beginning the
first downturn in a decade.
Chairman Greenspan and the Federal Reserve Board of Governors have been confronted with a recession very different than those in the past. Previous recessions
were a result of a decline in consumer spending which led to a reduction in production and capital investment. The current recession has resulted from a decline in
production and capital investment while consumer spending has remained strong.
The Federal Reserve sharply reduced the Federal funds rate in 2001 to encourage
economic growth.
There have been some encouraging economic indicators that show the early signs
of a recovery. Examples of these include the growth of the gross domestic product
in the fourth quarter by 1.4 percent and the significant increases in the consumer
confidence index since November. In addition, durable goods orders rose in January
by 2.6 percent.
However, not all economic data has been positive. Unemployment remains much
higher than it was a year ago. Corporate profits remain weak and new home sales
reached an 18 month low in January.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00044

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

41
Chairman Greenspan, I thank you for appearing today. I look forward to hearing
your thoughts on the state of the economy.
—————
PREPARED STATEMENT OF SENATOR ZELL MILLER
Mr. Chairman, it is a pleasure to have you before the Committee today. My State
of Georgia has been through some troubled economic times over the past few
months, just as the rest of the United States has as well. In Georgia, manufacturing
activity has been weak and we have seen job cuts in several industries.
Tourism has been especially hard hit after September 11. Hotel occupancy is still
below normal and we are seeing continued price discounting for hotel rooms and
rental cars. Our Georgia travel industry is vigorously promoting travel and tourism
in our State both domestically and internationally.
Additionally, agriculture has been a big concern in Georgia. Our farmers are hurting and they are facing an uncertain future. They are struggling with skyrocketing
production costs and low-commodity prices. They are desperately seeking the stability a farm bill will offer them. However, because it is taking longer to get a farm
bill than anticipated, many bankers are balking at issuing loans to farmers. The
bankers want a guarantee that there will be a new farm bill this season, or at the
very least a disaster relief package. Our farmers cannot operate without loans.
Their livelihood depends on getting that bank loan each season, so we have left
them in limbo, anxiously awaiting our next move.
And finally, many of my small businesses are reporting fairly steep increases in
their property and liability and workman’s compensation insurance premiums. Ed
Northup with Burger King in Albany, Georgia, reports that his workman’s comp
premiums increased 50 percent from $28,400 in 2001 to $43,366 in 2002, and his
property and liability premiums increased 26 percent from $26,264 in 2001 to
$33,213 in 2002. These increases may reflect post September 11 needs for a terrorism re-insurance bill.
When my time comes for questions. I look forward to asking you about many of
these concerns.
—————
PREPARED STATEMENT OF ALAN GREENSPAN
CHAIRMAN, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
MARCH 7, 2002
Since July, when I last reported to the Committee on the conduct of monetary policy, the U.S. economy has gone through a period of considerable strain, with output
contracting for a time and unemployment rising. We in the Federal Reserve System
acted vigorously to adjust monetary policy in an endeavor both to limit the extent
of the downturn and to hasten its completion. Despite the disruptions engendered
by the terrorist attacks of September 11, the typical dynamics of the business cycle
have reemerged and are prompting a firming in economic activity. The recent evidence increasingly suggests that an economic expansion is already well under way,
although an array of influences unique to this business cycle seems likely to moderate its speed.
At the time of our last report, the economy was weakening. Many firms were responding to the realization that significant overcapacity had developed. The demand
for capital goods had dropped sharply, and inventories were uncomfortably high in
many industries. In response, businesses slashed production, and the resulting declines in incomes amplified the cyclical downturn. Real gross domestic product did
not grow in the second quarter and contracted in the third.
A coincident deceleration in activity among the world economies was evident over
the past year, owing, at least in part, to the retrenchment in the high-technology
sector and the global reach of the capital markets in which the firms in that sector
are valued and funded. However, before the terrorist attacks, it was far from obvious that this concurrent weakness was becoming self-reinforcing. Indeed, immediately prior to September 11, some sectors exhibited tentative signs of stabilization,
contributing to a hope that the worst of the previous cumulative weakness in world
economic activity was nearing an end.
That hope was decisively dashed by the tragic events of early September. Adding
to the intense forces weighing on asset prices and economic activity before September 11 were new sources of uncertainty that began to press down on global demand for goods and services. Economies almost everywhere weakened further, a

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00045

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

42
cause for increasing uneasiness. The simultaneous further slowing in activity raised
concerns that a self-reinforcing cycle of contraction, fed by perceptions of greater
economic risk, could develop. Such an event, though rare, would not be unprecedented in business-cycle history.
If ever a situation existed in which the fabric of business and consumer confidence, both here and abroad, was vulnerable to being torn, the shock of September
11 was surely it. In addition to the horrific loss of life, enormous uncertainties had
accompanied the unfolding events and their implications for the economy. Indeed,
for a period of weeks, U.S. economic activity did drop dramatically in response to
that shock.
In the immediate aftermath of the strikes, the Federal Reserve engaged in aggressive action to counter the effects of the shock on payment systems and financial
markets. We provided a huge volume of reserves through open market operations,
the discount window, and other means to facilitate the functioning of the financial
system. We worked closely with many market participants, industry groups, and
other Government officials on a broad range of financial infrastructure problems
that needed to be resolved quickly and in the common interest.
Still, market functioning was impaired for a time. The substantial damage to
trading, settlement, and communications facilities forced many market participants
to their backup sites. Owing in part to careful and thorough contingency planning,
many firms, markets, and exchanges were able to resume business within a few
hours or days of the attacks. Nonetheless, the episode did reveal threats to, and
vulnerabilities of, the operations of financial institutions that had not been previously considered and illustrated the significant interdependence of the modern financial infrastructure. Institutions will need to continue to work diligently toward
ensuring that their backup capabilities are adequate. We at the Federal Reserve
have been reexamining intensively our own contingency capabilities to ensure that
our central banking functions can be performed in the most pressing of emergency
circumstances.
In the weeks following the attacks, along with the drops in activity and confidence, equity prices fell markedly, and lenders became more cautious, boosting
risk premiums, especially on credits already considered to be weak. In response, the
Federal Reserve reduced short-term interest rates considerably further. Longer-term
yields, including mortgage rates, fell to extraordinarily low levels. The monetary
stimulus that we provided was visible not only in interest rates but also in a rapid
growth of liquidity over the final months of the year, as gauged by the broad monetary aggregates. As the fourth quarter progressed, business and consumer confidence recovered, no doubt buoyed by successes in the war on terrorism. The
improved sentiment seemed to buffer the decline in economic activity.
Indeed, in the past several months, increasing signs have emerged that some of
the forces that have been restraining the economy over the past year are starting
to diminish and that activity is beginning to firm. The appearance of these signs,
in circumstances in which the level of the real Federal funds rate was at a very
low level, led the Federal Open Market Committee to keep policy unchanged at its
meeting in late January, although it retained its assessment that risks were tilted
toward economic weakness.
One key consideration in the assessment that the economy is moving through a
turning point is the behavior of inventories. Stocks in many industries have been
drawn down to levels at which firms will soon need to taper off their rate of liquidation, if they have not already done so. Any slowing in the rate of inventory liquidation will induce a rise in industrial production if demand for those products is stable
or is falling only moderately. That rise in production will, other things being equal,
increase household income and spending. The runoff of inventories, even apart from
the large reduction in motor vehicle stocks, remained sizable in the fourth quarter.
Hence, with production running well below sales, the lift to income and spending
from the inevitable cessation of inventory liquidation could be significant.
But that impetus to the growth of activity will be short-lived unless sustained
increases in final demand kick in before the positive effects of the swing from inventory liquidation dissipate. We have seen encouraging signs in recent days that underlying trends in final demand are strengthening, although the dimensions of the
pickup remain uncertain.
Most recoveries in the post-World War II period received a boost from a rebound
in demand for consumer durables and housing from recession-depressed levels in addition to an abatement of inventory liquidation. Through much of last year’s slowdown, however, spending by the household sector held up well and proved to be a
major stabilizing force. As a consequence, although household spending should continue to trend up, the potential for significant acceleration in activity in this sector
is likely to be more limited than in past cycles.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00046

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

43
In fact, there are a number of cross currents in the outlook for household spending. In recent months, low mortgage interest rates and favorable weather have provided considerable support to homebuilding. Moreover, attractive mortgage rates
have bolstered the sales of existing homes and the extraction of capital gains embedded in home equity that those sales engender. Low rates have also encouraged
households to take on larger mortgages when refinancing their homes. Drawing on
home equity in this manner is a significant source of funding for consumption and
home modernization. The pace of such extractions likely dropped along with the decline in refinancing activity that followed the backup in mortgage rates that began
in early November. But mortgage rates remain at low levels and should continue
to underpin activity in this sector.
Consumer spending received a considerable lift from the sales of new motor vehicles, which were remarkably strong in October and November owing to major
financing incentives. Sales have receded somewhat, but they have remained surprisingly resilient. Other consumer spending appears to have advanced at a solid pace
in recent months.
The substantial declines in the prices of natural gas, fuel oil, and gasoline have
clearly provided some support to real disposable income and spending. To have a
more persistent effect on the ongoing growth of total personal consumption expenditures, energy prices would need to decline further. Futures prices do not suggest
that such an outcome is in the offing, though the forecast record of these markets
is less than impressive.
Changes in household financial positions in recent years are probably damping
consumer spending, at least to a degree. Overall household wealth relative to income has dropped from a peak multiple of about 6.3 at the end of 1999 to around
5.3 currently. Moreover, the aggregate household debt service burden, defined as the
ratio of households’ required debt payments to their disposable personal income,
rose considerably in recent years, returning last year to its previous cyclical peak
of the mid-1980’s.
However, neither wealth nor the burden of debt is distributed evenly across
households. Hence, the spending effects of changes in these influences also will not
be evenly distributed. For example, increased debt burdens appear disproportionately attributable to higher-income households. Calculations by staff at the Federal
Reserve suggest that the ratio of household liabilities to annual income for the top
fifth of all households ranked by income, who accounted for 44 percent of total aftertax household income last year, rose from about 1.10 at the end of 1998 to 1.20 at
the end of the third quarter of 2001. The increase for the lower four-fifths was only
about half as large. Although high-income households should not experience much
strain in meeting their obligations, others might. Indeed, repayment difficulties
have already increased, particularly in the subprime markets for consumer loans
and mortgages. Delinquency rates may well worsen as a delayed result of the
strains on household finances over the past 2 years. Large erosions, however, do not
seem likely, and the overall levels of debt and repayment delinquencies do not, as
of now, appear to pose a major impediment to a moderate expansion of consumption
spending going forward.
Although the macroeconomic effects of debt burdens may be limited, we have already seen significant spending restraint among the top fifth of income earners, presumably owing to the drop in equity prices. The effect of the stock market on other
households’ spending has been less evident. Moderate-income households have a
much larger proportion of their assets in homes, and the continuing rise in the
value of houses has provided greater support for their net worth. Reflecting these
differences in portfolio composition, the net worth of the top fifth of income earners
has dropped far more than it did for the bottom 80 percent.
As a consequence, excluding capital gains and losses from the calculation, as is
the convention in our national income accounts, personal saving for the upper fifth,
which had been negative during 1999 and 2000, turned positive in 2001. By contrast, the average saving rate for the lower four-fifths of households, by income, was
generally positive during the second half of the 1990’s and has fluctuated in a narrow range in the past 2 years. Accordingly, most of the change in consumption expenditures that resulted from the bull stock market, and its demise, reflected shifts
in spending by upper-income households. The restraining effects from the net decline in wealth during the past 2 years presumably have not, as yet, fully played
out and could exert some further damping effect on the overall growth of household
spending relative to that of income.
Perhaps most central to the outlook for consumer spending will be developments
in the labor market. The pace of layoffs quickened last fall, especially after September 11, and the unemployment rate rose sharply. However, layoffs diminished
noticeably in January, and the reported unemployment rate declined—though ad-

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00047

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

44
justing for seasonal influences was difficult last month. Moreover, initial claims for
unemployment insurance have decreased markedly, on balance, providing further
evidence of an improvement in labor market conditions. Even if the economy is on
the road to recovery, the unemployment rate, in typical cyclical fashion, may resume
its increase for a time, and a soft labor market could put something of a damper
on consumer spending.
However, the extent of such restraint will depend on how much of any rise in unemployment is the result of weakened demand for goods and services and how much
reflects strengthened productivity. In the latter case, average real incomes of workers could rise, at least partially offsetting losses of purchasing power that stem from
diminished levels of employment. Indeed, preliminary data suggest that productivity
has held up very well of late, and history suggests that any depressing effect of
rapid productivity growth on employment is only temporary.
The dynamics of inventory investment and the balance of factors influencing consumer demand will have important consequences for the economic outlook in coming
months. But the broad contours of the present cycle have been, and will continue
to be, driven by the evolution of corporate profits and capital investment.
The retrenchment in capital spending over the past year and a half was central
to the sharp slowing we experienced in overall activity. The steep rise in high-tech
spending that occurred in the early post-Y2K months was clearly not sustainable.
The demand for many of the newer technologies was growing rapidly, but capacity
was expanding even faster, and that imbalance exerted significant downward pressure on prices and the profits of producers of high-tech goods and services. New orders for equipment and software hesitated in the middle of 2000 and then fell
abruptly as firms reevaluated their capital investment programs. Uncertainty about
economic prospects boosted risk premiums significantly, and this rise, in turn, propelled required, or hurdle, rates of return to markedly elevated levels. In most
cases, businesses required that new investments pay off much more rapidly than
they had previously. For much of last year, the resulting decline in investment outlays was fierce and unrelenting. Although the weakness was most pronounced in the
technology area, reductions in capital outlays were broad-based.
These cutbacks in capital spending interacted with, and were reinforced by, falling
profits and equity prices. Indeed, a striking feature of the current cyclical episode
relative to many earlier ones has been the virtual absence of pricing power across
much of American business, as increasing globalization and deregulation have enhanced competition. In this low-inflation environment, firms have perceived very little ability to pass cost increases on to customers. To be sure, growth in hourly labor
compensation has moderated in response to slowed inflation and deteriorating economic conditions. A significant falloff in stock-option realizations and in other forms
of compensation related to company performance has likely been a factor. But over
most of the past year, even those smaller hourly compensation increases outstripped
gains in output per hour, precipitating a marked decline in profit margins.
Business managers, with little opportunity to raise prices, have moved aggressively to stabilize cashflows by trimming workforces. These efforts have limited any
rise in unit costs, attenuated the pressure on profit margins, and ultimately helped
to preserve the vast majority of private-sector jobs. To the extent that businesses
are successful in stabilizing and eventually boosting profits and cashflow, capital
spending should begin to recover more noticeably.
Part of the reduction in pricing power observed in this cycle should be reversed
as firming demand enables firms to take back large price discounts. Though such
an adjustment would tend to elevate price levels, underlying inflationary cost pressures should remain contained. Output per hour is not likely to accelerate this year
as much as in a typical recovery because businesses have not delayed, as they have
in past recessions, shedding workers at the first indications of weakened demand.
But slack in labor markets and further increases in productivity should hold labor
costs in check and result in rising profit margins even with inflation remaining low.
Improved profit margins and more assured prospects for rising final demand
would likely be accompanied by a decline in risk premiums from their current elevated levels toward a more normal range. With real rates of return on high-tech
equipment still attractive, that should provide an additional spur to new investment. Reports from businesses around the country suggest that the exploitation of
available networking and other information technologies was only partially completed when the cyclical retrenchment of the past year began. Many business managers are still of the view, according to a recent survey of purchasing managers,
that less than half of currently available new, and presumably profitable, supply
chain technologies have been put into use.
Recent evidence suggests that a recovery in at least some forms of high-tech investment could already be under way. Production of semiconductors, which in the

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00048

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

45
past has been a leading indicator of computer production, turned up last fall. Expenditures on computers rose at a double-digit annual rate in real terms last quarter. But investment expenditures in the communications sector, where the amount
of overcapacity was substantial, as yet show few signs of turning up, and business
investment in some other sectors, such as aircraft, hit by the drop in air travel, will
presumably remain weak this year.
On balance, the recovery in overall spending on business fixed investment is likely
to be only gradual; in particular, its growth will doubtless be less frenetic than in
1999 and early 2000—a period during which outlays were boosted by the dislocations of Y2K and the extraordinarily low cost of equity capital available to many
firms. Nonetheless, if the recent more favorable economic developments gather momentum, uncertainties will diminish, risk premiums will fall, and the pace of capital
investment embodying new technologies will increase.
Even a subdued recovery would constitute a truly remarkable performance for the
American economy in the face of so severe a decline in equity asset values and an
unprecedented blow from terrorists to the foundations of our market systems. For,
if the tentative indications that the contraction phase of this business cycle has
drawn to a close are ultimately confirmed, we will have experienced a significantly
milder downturn than the long history of business cycles would have led us to expect. Crucially, the imbalances that triggered the downturn and that could have
prolonged this difficult period did not fester. The obvious questions are what has
changed in our economy in recent decades to provide such resilience and whether
such changes will persist into the future.
Doubtless, the substantial improvement in the access of business decisionmakers
to real-time information has played a key role. Thirty years ago, the timeliness of
available information varied across companies and industries, often resulting in
differences in the speed and magnitude of their responses to changing business conditions. In contrast to the situation that prevails today, businesses did not have
real-time data systems that enabled decisionmakers in different enterprises to work
from essentially the same set of information. In those earlier years, imbalances were
inadvertently allowed to build to such an extent that their inevitable correction engendered significant economic stress. That process of correction and the accompanying economic and financial disruptions led to deep and prolonged recessions.
Today, businesses have large quantities of data available virtually in real time. As
a consequence, they address and resolve economic imbalances far more rapidly than
in the past.
The apparent increased flexibility of the American economy arguably also reflects
the extent of deregulation over the past quarter century. Certainly, if the energy
sector were still in the tight regulatory fetters of the 1970’s, our flexibility today
would be markedly less. That the collapse of Enron barely registered in the relatively recently developed markets for natural gas and electric power was encouraging. Although the terrorist attacks hit air travel especially hard over the past few
months, deregulation of that industry has demonstrably increased the quantity and
flexibility, if not the profitability, of air travel over the past 20 years. Trucking and
rail deregulation has added flexibility to the movement of goods across our Nation.
Both deregulation and innovation in the financial sector have been especially important in enhancing overall economic resilience. New financial products—including
derivatives, assetbacked securities, collateralized loan obligations, and collateralized
mortgage obligations, among others—have enabled risk to be dispersed more effectively to those willing to, and presumably capable of, bearing it. Shocks to the overall economic system are accordingly less likely to create cascading credit failure.
Lenders have the opportunity to be considerably more diversified, and borrowers are
far less dependent on specific institutions for funds. Financial derivatives, particularly, have grown at a phenomenal pace over the past 15 years, evidently fulfilling
a need to hedge risks that were not readily deflected in earlier decades.
Despite the concerns that these complex instruments have induced (an issue I will
address shortly), the record of their performance, especially over the past couple of
stressful years, suggests that on balance they have contributed to the development
of a far more flexible and efficient financial system—both domestically and internationally—than we had just 20 or 30 years ago.
As a consequence of increased access to real-time information and, more arguably,
extensive deregulation in financial and product markets and the unbundling of risk,
imbalances are more likely to be readily contained, and cyclical episodes overall
should be less severe than would be the case otherwise. If this is indeed the case—
and it must be considered speculative until more evidence is gathered—the implied
reduction in volatility, other things equal, would lower risk and equity premiums.
Other things, however, may not be wholly equal. The very technologies that appear to be the main cause of our apparent increased flexibility and resiliency may

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00049

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

46
also be imparting different forms of vulnerability that could intensify or be intensified by a business cycle.
From one perspective, the ever-increasing proportion of our GDP that represents
conceptual as distinct from physical value added may actually have lessened cyclical
volatility. In particular, the fact that concepts cannot be held as inventories means
a greater share of GDP is not subject to a type of dynamics that amplifies cyclical
swings. But an economy in which concepts form an important share of valuation has
its own vulnerabilities.
As the recent events surrounding Enron have highlighted, a firm is inherently
fragile if its value added emanates more from conceptual as distinct from physical
assets. A physical asset, whether an office building or an automotive assembly
plant, has the capability of producing goods even if the reputation of the managers
of such facilities falls under a cloud. The rapidity of Enron’s decline is an effective
illustration of the vulnerability of a firm whose market value largely rests on capitalized reputation. The physical assets of such a firm comprise a small proportion
of its asset base. Trust and reputation can vanish overnight. A factory cannot.
The implications of such a loss of confidence for the macroeconomy depend importantly on how freely the conceptual capital of the fading firm can be replaced by
a competitor or a new entrant into the industry. Even if entry is relatively free,
macroeconomic risks can emerge if problems at one particular firm tend to make
investors and counterparties uncertain about other firms that they see as potentially similarly situated. The difficulty of valuing firms that deal primarily with concepts and the growing size and importance of these firms may make our economy
more susceptible to this type of contagion.
Another, more conventional determinant of stability will be the economy’s degree
of leverage—the extent to which debt rather than equity is financing the level of
capital. The proper degree of leverage in a firm, or in an economy as a whole, is
an inherently elusive figure that almost certainly changes from time to time. Clearly, firms find some leverage advantageous in enhancing returns on equity, and thus
moderate leverage undoubtedly boosts the capital stock and the level of output. A
sophisticated financial system, with its substantial array of instruments to
unbundle risks, will tend toward a higher degree of leverage at any given level of
underlying economic risk. But, the greater the degree of leverage in any economy,
the greater its vulnerability to unexpected shortfalls in demand and mistakes.
Indeed, on a historical cost basis, the ratio of debt to net worth for the nonfinancial corporate business sector did rise, from 71 percent at the end of 1997 to
about 81 percent at the end of the third quarter of last year, though it is still well
below its level at the beginning of the recession in 1990. The ratio of interest payments to cashflow, one indicator of the consequence of leverage, has slowly crept up
in recent years, reflecting growth in debt. Owing to lower interest rates, it remains
far below its levels of the early 1990’s.
Although the fears of business leverage have been mostly confined to specific sectors in recent years, concerns over potential systemic problems resulting from the
vast expansion of derivatives have reemerged with the difficulties of Enron. To be
sure, firms like Enron, and Long-Term Capital Management before it, were major
players in the derivatives markets. But their problems were readily traceable to an
old fashioned excess of debt, however acquired, as well as to opaque accounting of
that leverage and lax counterparty scrutiny. Swaps and other derivatives throughout their short history, including over the past 18 months, have been remarkably
free of default. Of course, there can be latent problems in any market that expands
as rapidly as these markets have. Regulators and supervisors are particularly sensitive to this possibility. Derivatives have provided greater flexibility to our financial
system. But their very complexity could leave counterparties vulnerable to significant risk that they do not currently recognize, and hence these instruments potentially expose the overall system if mistakes are large. In that regard, the market’s
reaction to the revelations about Enron provides encouragement that the force of
market discipline can be counted on over time to foster much greater transparency
and increased clarity and completeness in the accounting treatment of derivatives.
How these countervailing forces for stability evolve will surely be a major determinant of the volatility that our economy will experience in the years ahead. Monetary policy will have to be particularly sensitive to the possibility that the resiliency
our economy has exhibited during the past 2 years signals subtle changes in the
way our system functions.
Our most recent experiences underscore this possibility, along with the persistence of a long list of older, well-tested, economic verities. Inventories, especially
among producers and purchasers of high-tech products, did run to excess over the
past year, as sales forecasts went badly astray; alas, technology has not allowed us
to see into the future any more clearly than we could previously. But technology

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00050

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

47
did facilitate the quick recognition of the weakening in sales and backup of inventories. This enabled producers to respond, as evidenced by output adjustments that
resulted in the extraordinary rate of inventory liquidation that we experienced late
last year.
For the period just ahead, the central tendency of the forecasts of the members
of the Federal Open Market Committee prepared earlier for our monetary policy report to the Congress was for real GDP to rise 21⁄2 to 3 percent during 2002. Such
a pace for the growth of real output would be somewhat below the rates of growth
typically seen early in previous expansions. Certain factors, such as the lack of pentup demand in the consumer sector, significant levels of excess capacity in a number
of industries, weakness and financial fragility in some key international trading
partners, and persistent caution in financial markets at home, seem likely to restrain the near-term performance of the economy.
In line with past experience during the early stages of expansion, labor market
performance was expected initially to lag as firms rely primarily on overtime and
shifts from part-time to full-time work. The unemployment rate was anticipated to
rise somewhat further over 2002, to the area of 6 to 61⁄4 percent. FOMC members
evidently anticipated that slack in resource utilization, the lagged effects of past declines in energy prices, and productivity growth will keep inflation low this year,
with the price index for personal consumption expenditure increasing 11⁄2 percent.
Despite its forecast that economic growth is likely to resume at a moderate pace,
as I already noted, the Federal Open Market Committee at its meeting on January
30 saw the risks nonetheless as continuing to be weighted mainly toward conditions
that may generate economic weakness in the foreseeable future. In effect, the FOMC
indicated that until the dynamics of sustained expansion are more firmly in place,
it remained concerned about the possibility of weak growth for a time, despite the
very low level of the Federal funds rate.
Although there are ample reasons to be cautious about the economic outlook, the
recuperative powers of the U.S. economy, as I have tried to emphasize in my presentation, have been remarkable. When I presented our report on monetary policy to
this Committee last summer, few if any of us could have anticipated events such
as those to which our Nation has subsequently been subjected. The economic consequences of those events and their aftermath are an integral part of the challenges
that we now collectively face. The U.S. economy has experienced a substantial
shock, and, no doubt, we continue to face risks in the period ahead. But the response thus far of our citizens to these new economic challenges provides reason for
encouragement.

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00051

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

48

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00052

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

49

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00053

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

50

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00054

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

51

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00055

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

52

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00056

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

53

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00057

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

54

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00058

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

55

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00059

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

56

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00060

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

57

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00061

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

58

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00062

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

59

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00063

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

60

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00064

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

61

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00065

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

62

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00066

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

63

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00067

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

64

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00068

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

65

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00069

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

66

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00070

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

67

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00071

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

68

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00072

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

69

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00073

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

70

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00074

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

71

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00075

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

72

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00076

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

73

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00077

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

74

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00078

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

75

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00079

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

76

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00080

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

77

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00081

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

78

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00082

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

79

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00083

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

80

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00084

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

81

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00085

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2

82

VerDate 11-MAY-2000

12:24 Jul 09, 2002

Jkt 000000

PO 00000

Frm 00086

Fmt 6633

Sfmt 6621

80301.TXT

SBANK2

PsN: SBANK2