View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

L (

Ju/Jllllll':!J mepol'l


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

rlt/2e ,:::J:°edeml [J/e,fel'()e fJJoaNI

/ft~(~

20, 2000

This Executive Summary provides highlights of the Board's
Monetary Policy Report to the Congress


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Contents
Section

Page

Testimony of Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Federal Reserve Board

1

Conclusion

6

Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook

8

Monetary Policy, Financial Markets,
and the Economy over the First Half of 2000

9

Economic Projections for 2000 and 2001


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

12

Testimony of Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Federal Reserve Board
Mr. Chairman and other
members of the Committee, I
appreciate this opportunity to
present the Federal Reserve's
report on monetary policy.
The Federal Reserve has been confronting a complex set of challenges in judging the stance of policy that will best
contribute to sustaining the strong
and long-running expansion of our
economy. The challenges will be no
less in coming months as we judge
whether ongoing adjustments in supply and demand will be sufficient to
prevent distortions that would undermine the economy's extraordinary
performance.
For some time· now, the growth of
aggregate demand has exceeded the
expansion of production potential.
Technological innovations have
boosted the growth rate of potential,
but as I noted in my testimony last
February, the effects of this process also
have spurred aggregate demand. It has
been clear to us that, w ith labor markets already quite tight, a continuing
disp arity between the growth of
demand and potential supply would
produce disruptive imbalances.
A key element in this disparity has
been the very rapid growth of consumption resulting from the effects on
spending of the remarkable rise in
household wealth. However, the
growth in household spending has

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

slowed noticeably this spring from the
unusually rapid pace observed late in
1999 and early this year. Some argue
that this slowing is a pause following
the surge in demand through the
warmer-than-normal winter months
and hence a reacceleration can be
expected later this year. Certainly, we
have seen slowdowns in spending during this near-decade-long expansion
that have proven temporary, with
aggregate demand growth subsequently rebounding to an unsustainable pace.
But other analysts point to a number
of factors that may be exerting more
persistent restraint on spending. One
they cite is the flattening in equity
prices, on net, this year. They attribute
much of the slowing of consumer
spending to this diminution of the
wealth effect through the spring and
early summer. This view looks to

equity markets as a key influence on
the trend in consumer spending over
the rest of this year and next.
Another factor said by some to
account for the spending slow down is
the rising debt burden of households.
Interest and amortization as a percent
of disposable income have risen materially during the past six years, as consumer and especially mortgage debt
has climbed and, more recently, as
interest rates have moved higher.
In addition, the past year's rise in the
price of oil has amounted to an annual
$75 billion levy by foreign producers
on domestic consumers of imported
oil, the equivalent of a tax of roughly
1 percent of disposable income. This

late. If that slowing were to persist,
some reduction in the rapid pace of
accumulation of household appliances
across our more than a hundred million
households would not come as a surprise, nor would a slowdown in vehicle
demand so often historically associated
with declines in housing demand.
Inventories of durable assets in
households are just as formidable a factor in new production as inventories at
manufacturing and trade establishments. The notion that consumer
spending and housing construction
may be slowing because the stock of
consumer durables and houses may be
running into upside resistance is a
credible addition to the possible explanations of current consumer trends.
This effect on spending would be reinforced by the waning effects of gains in
wealth.
Because the softness in outlay growth
is so recent, all of the aforementioned
hypotheses, of course, must be provisional. It is certainly premature to make
a definitive assessment of either the
recent trends in household spending or
what they mean. But it is clear that, for
the time being at least, the increase in
spending on consumer goods and
houses has come down several notches,
albeit from very high levels.
In one sense, the more important
question for the longer-term economic
outlook is the extent of any productivity slowdown that might accompany a
more subdued pace of production and
consumer spending, should it persist.
The behavior of productivity under
such circumstances will be a revealing

burden is another likely source of the
slowed growth in real consumption
outlays in recent months, though one
that may prove to be largely transitory.
Mentioned less prominently have
been the effects of the faster increase in
the stock of consumer durable assetsboth household durable goods and
houses-in the last several years, a rate
of increase that history tells us is usually followed by a pause. Stocks of
household durable goods, including
motor vehicles, are estimated to have
increased at nearly a 6 percent annual
rate over the past three years, a marked
acceleration from the growth rate of the
previous ten years. The number of cars
and light trucks owned or leased by
households, for example, apparently
has continued to rise in recent years
despite having reached nearly 1¾
vehicles per household by the mid1990s. Notwithstanding their recent
slowing, sales of new homes continue
at extraordinarily high levels relative to
new household formations. While we
will not know for sure until the 2000
census is tabulated, the surge in new
home sales is strong evidence that the
growth of owner-occupied homes has
accelerated during the past five years.
Those who focus on the high and rising stocks of durable assets point out
that even without the rise in interest
rates, an eventual leveling out or some
tapering off of purchases of durable
goods and construction of singlefamily housing would be expected.
Reflecting both higher interest rates
and higher stocks of housing, starts of
new housing units have fallen off of

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

test of just how much of the rapid
growth of productivity in recent years
has represented structural change as
distinct from cyclical aberrations and,
hence, how truly different the developments of the past five years have been.
At issue is how much of the current
downshift in our overall economic
growth rate can be accounted for by
reduced growth in output per hour and
how much by slowed increases in
hours.
So far there is little evidence to
undermine the notion that most of the
productivity increase of recent years
has been structural and that structural
productivity may still be accelerating.
New orders for capital equipment continue quite strong-so strong that the
rise in unfilled orders has actually
steepened in recent months. Capitaldeepening investment in a broad range
of equipment embodying the newer
productivity-enhancing technologies
remains brisk.
To be sure, if current personal consumption outlays slow significantly
further than the pattern now in train
suggests, profit and sales expectations
might be scaled back, possibly inducing some hesitancy in moving forward
even with capital projects that appear
quite profitable over the longer run. In
addition, the direct negative effects of
the sharp recent run-up in energy
prices on profits as well as on sales
expectations may temporarily damp
capital spending. Despite the marked
decline over the past decades in the
energy requirements per dollar of GDP,
energy inputs are still a significant ele
https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ment in the cost structure of many
American businesses.
For the moment, the drop-off in overall economic growth to date appears
about matched by reduced growth in
hours, suggesting continued strength
in growth in output per hour. The
increase of production worker hours
from March through June, for example,
was at an annual rate of ½ percent
compared with 3¼ percent the previous
three months. Of course, we do not
have comprehensive measures of output on a monthly basis, but available
data suggest a roughly comparable
deceleration.
A lower overall rate of economic
growth that did not carry with it a significant deterioration in productivity
growth obviously would be a desirable
outcome. It could conceivably slow or
even bring to a halt the deterioration in
the balance of overall demand and
potential supply in our economy.
As I testified before this committee in
February, domestic demand growth,
influenced importantly by the wealth
effect on consumer spending, has been
running 1½ to 2 percentage points at an
annual rate in excess of even the higher,
productivity-driven, growth in potential supply since late 1997. That gap has
been filled both by a marked rise in
imports as a percent of GDP and by a
marked increase in domestic production resulting both from significant
immigration and from the employment
of previously unutilized labor
resources.
I also pointed out in February
that there are limits to how far net
3

imports-or the broader measure, our
current account deficit-can rise, or
our pool of unemployed labor
resources can fall. As a consequence,
the excess of the growth of domestic
demand over potential supply must be
closed before the resulting strains and
imbalances undermine the economic
expansion that now has reached 112
months, a record for peace or war.
The current account deficit is a proxy
for the increase in net claims against
U.S. residents held by foreigners,
mainly as debt, but increasingly as
equities. So long as foreigners continue
to seek to hold ever-increasing quantities of dollar investments in their portfolios, as they obviously have been,
the exchange rate for the dollar will
remain firm. Indeed, the same sharp
rise in potential rates of return on new
American investments that has been
driving capital accumulation and
accelerating productivity in the United
States has also been inducing foreigners to expand their portfolios of American securities and direct investment.
The latest data published by the
Department of Commerce indicate that
the annual pace of direct plus portfolio
investment by foreigners in the U.S.
economy during the first quarter was
more than two and one-half times its
rate in 1995.
There has to be a limit as to how
much of the world's savings our residents can borrow at close to prevailing
interest and exchange rates. And a narrowing of disparities among global
growth rates could induce a narrowing
of rates of return here relative to those

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

abroad that could adversely affect the
propensity of foreigners to invest in
the United States. But obviously, so
long as our rates of return appear to be
unusually high, if not rising, balance of
payments trends are less likely to pose
a threat to our prosperity. In addition,
our burgeoning budget surpluses have
clearly contributed to a fending off, if
only temporarily, of some of the pressures on our balance of payments. The
stresses on the global savings pool
resulting from the excess of domestic
private investment demands over
domestic private saving have been
mitigated by the large federal budget
surplm,es that have developed of late.
In addition, by substantially augmenting national saving, these budget
surpluses have kept real interest rates
at levels lower than they would have
been otherwise. This development has
helped foster the investment boom that
in recent years has contributed greatly
to the strengthening of U.S. productivity and economic growth. The Congress and the Administration have
wisely avoided steps that would materially reduce these budget surpluses.
Continued fiscal discipline will contribute to maintaining robust expansion of the American economy in the
future.
Just as there is a limit to our reliance
on foreign saving, so is there a limit to
the continuing drain on our unused
labor resources. Despite the ever-tightening labor market, as yet, gains in
compensation per hour are not significantly outstripping gains in productivity. But as I have argued previously,
4

should labor markets continue to
tighten, short of a repeal of the law of
supply and demand, labor costs eventually would have to accelerate to levels threatening price stability and our
continuing economic expansion.
The more modest pace of increase in
domestic final spending in recent
months suggests that aggregate
demand may be moving closer into
line with the rate of advance in the
economy's potential, given our continued impressive productivity growth.
Should these trends toward supply and
demand balance persist, the ongoing
need for ever-rising imports and for a
further draining of our limited labor
resources should ease or perhaps even
end. Should this favorable outcome
prevail, the immediate threat to our
prosperity from growing imbalances in
our economy would abate.
But as I indicated earlier, it is much
too soon to conclude that these concerns are behind us. We cannot yet
be sure that the slower expansion of
domestic final demand, at a pace more
in line with potential supply, will
persist. Even if the growth rates of
demand and potential supply move
into better balance, there is still uncertainty about whether the current level
of labor resource utilization can be
maintained without generating
increased cost and price pressures.
As I have already noted, to date costs
have been held in check by productivity gains. But at the same time, inflation
has picked up-even the core measures
that do not include energy prices
directly. Higher rates of core inflation

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

may mostly reflect the indirect effects
of energy prices, but the Federal
Reserve will need to be alert to the
risks that high levels of resource utilization may put upward pressure on
inflation.
Moreover, energy prices may pose
a challenge to containing inflation.
Energy price changes represent a onetime shift in a set of important prices,
but by themselves generally cannot
drive an ongoing inflation process. The
key to whether such a process could get
under way is inflation expectations. To
date, survey evidence, as well as readings from the Treasury's inflationindexed securities, suggests that households and investors do not view the
current energy price surge as affecting
longer-term inflation. But any deterioration in such expectations would pose
a risk to the economic outlook.
As the financing requirements for our
ever-rising capital investment needs
mounted in recent years-beyond
forthcoming domestic saving-real
long-term interest rates rose to address
this gap. We at the Federal Reserve,
responding to the same economic
forces, have moved the overnight federal funds rate up 1¾ percentage points
over the past year. To have held to the
federal funds rate of June 1999 would
have required a massive increase in
liquidity that would presumably have
underwritten an acceleration of prices
and, hence, an eventual curbing of economic growth.
By our meeting this June, the
appraisal of all the foregoing issues
led the Federal Open Market Commit5

tee to conclude that, while some signs
of slower growth were evident and justified standing pat at least for the time
being, they were not sufficiently compelling to alter our view that the risks
remained more on the side of higher
inflation.
As indicated in their forecasts, FOMC
members and nonvoting presidents
expect that the long period of continuous economic expansion will be
extended over the next year and onehalf, but with growth at a somewhat
slower pace than over the past several
years. For the current year, the central
tendency of Board members' and
Reserve Bank presidents' forecasts is
for real GDP to increase 4 percent to
4½ percent, suggesting a noticeable
deceleration over the second half of
2000 from its likely pace over the first
half. The unemployment rate is projected to remain close to 4 percent. This
outlook is a little stronger than anticipated last February, no doubt owing
primarily to the unexpectedly strong
jump in output in the first quarter.
Mainly reflecting higher prices of
energy products than had been foreseen, the central tendency for inflation
this year in prices for personal consumption expenditures also has been
revised up somewhat, to the vicinity of
2½ percent to 2¾ percent.
Given the firmer financial conditions
that have developed over the past
eighteen months, the Committee
expects economic growth to moderate
somewhat next year. Real output is
anticipated to expand 3¼ percent to
3¾ percent, somewhat less rapidly than

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

in recent years. The unemployment rate
is likely to remain close to its recent
very low levels. Energy prices could
ease somewhat, helping to trim PCE
inflation next year to around 2 percent
to 2½ percent, somewhat above the
average of recent years.

Conclusion
The last decade has been a remarkable
period of expansion for our economy.
Federal Reserve policy through this
period has been required to react to a
constantly evolving set of economic
forces, often at variance with historical
relationships, changing federal funds
rates when events appeared to threaten
our prosperity, and refraining from
action when that appeared warranted.
Early in the expansion, for example,
we kept rates unusually low for an
extended period, when financial sector
fragility held back the economy. Most
recently we have needed to raise rates
to relatively high levels in real terms
in response to the side effects of accelerating growth and related demandsupply imbalances. Variations in the
stance of policy-or keeping it the
same-in response to evolving forces
are made in the framework of an
unchanging objective-to foster as best
we can those financial conditions most
likely to promote sustained economic
expansion at the highest rate possible.
Maximum sustainable growth, as history so amply demonstrates, requires
price stability. Irrespective of the complexities of economic change, our primary goal is to find those policies that
6

best contribute to a non-inflationary
environment and hence to growth. The
Federal Reserve, I trust, will always
remain vigilant in pursuit of that goal.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary Policy and the Economic
Outlook
The impressive performance of the
U.S. economy persisted in the first half
of 2000 with economic activity expanding at a rapid pace. Overall rates of
inflation were noticeably higher,
largely as a result of steep increases in
energy prices. The remarkable wave of
new technologies and the associated
surge in capital investment have continued to boost potential s_u pply and to
help contain price pressures at high
levels of labor resource use. At the
same time, rising productivity
growth-working through its effects
on wealth and consumption, as well
as on investment spending-has been
one of the important factors contributing to rapid increases in aggregate
demand that have exceeded even the
stepped-up increases in potential supply. Under such circumstances, and

with the pool of available labor already
at an unusually low level, the continued expansion of aggregate demand in
excess of the growth in potential supply increasingly threatened to set off
greater price pressures. Because price
stability is essential to achieving maximum sustainable economic growth,
heading off these pressures has been
critical to extending the extraordinary
performance of the U.S. economy.
To promote balance between aggregate demand and potential supply and
to contain inflation pressures, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
took additional firming actions this
year, raising the benchmark federal
funds rate 1 percentage point between
February and May. The tighter stance
of monetary policy, along with the
ongoing strength of credit demands,
has led to less accommodative financial conditions: On balance, since the
beginning of the year, real interest rates
have increased, equity prices have
changed little after a sizable run-up in
1999, and lenders have become more
cautious about extending credit, especially to marginal borrowers. Still,
households and businesses have continued to borrow at a rapid pace, and
the growth of M2 remained relatively
robust, despite the rise in market interest rates. The favorable outlook for the
U.S. economy has contributed to a
further strengthening of the dollar,
despite tighter monetary policy and
rising interest rates in most other
industrial countries.
Perhaps partly reflecting firmer
financial conditions, the incoming eco-

Change in Real GDP
Percent, annual rate

----------------

Ql

6

4

2

I
1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000
Note. Changes are measured to the final
quarter of the period indicated, from the final
quarter of the previous period.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

8

nomic data since May have suggested
some moderation in the growth of
aggregate demand. Nonetheless, labor
markets remained tight at the time of
the FOMC meeting in June, and it
was unclear whether the slowdown
represented a decisive shift to more
sustainable growth or just a pause.
The Committee left the stance of policy
unchanged but saw the balance of
risks to the economic outlook as still
weighted toward rising inflation.

Change in PCE Chain-Type Price
Index

Measures of Labor Utilization

2000
1994
1996
1998
Note. Changes are m easured to the final
quarter of the period indicated, from the final
quarter of the previous period.

Percent, annual rate
Ql

2

+
0

Percent
-----------------

Augmented
unemp loyment rate

Monetary Policy, Financial
Markets, and the Economy over
the First Half of 2000

12

When the FOMC convened for its first
two meetings of the year, in February
and March, economic conditions in the
United States were pointing toward an
increasingly taut labor market as a consequence of a persistent imbalance
between the growth rates of aggregate
demand and potential aggregate supply. Reflecting the underlying strength
in spending and expectations of tighter
monetary policy, market interest rates
were rising, especially after the century
date change passed without incident.
But, at the same time, equity prices
were still posting appreciable gains on
net. Knowing that the two safety

6

'70
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Note. The augmented unemployment rate is
the number of unemployed plus those who are
not in the labor force and want a job, divided by
the civilian labor force plus those who are not in
the labor force and want a job. The break in data
at January 1994 marks the introduction of a
redesigned survey; data from that point on are
not directly comparable with those of earlier
periods. The data extend through June 2000.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

9

Selected Interest Rates

i

1scowr-t
4

fel eral funds rate

I
2/4

3/31

5/19

7/1

I

8/18 9/29 11/17 12/22 2/3
10/15

I
3/30

1998

I
5/18 6/30

1999

"

8/24 10 /5 11 /1612/21 2/3

3/ 21

5/ 16 6/ 28

2000

Note. The d ata are d aily. Vertical lines indicate
the days on w hich the Federal Reserve announced
a change in the intended funds rate. The dates on
the horizontal axis are those on which either the

FOMC held a scheduled m eeting or a policy
action was announced . Last observations are for
July 17, 2000.

valves that had been keeping underlying inflation from picking up until
then-the economy's ability to draw
on the pool of available workers and to
expand its trade deficit on reasonable
terms-could not be counted on indefinitely, the FOMC voted for a further
tightening in monetary policy at both
its February and its March meetings,
raising the target for the overnight federal funds rate 25 basis points on each
occasion. In related actions, the Board
of Governors also approved quarterpoint increases in the discount rate in
both February and March.
The FOMC considered larger policy
moves at its first two meetings of 2000
but concluded that significant uncertainty about the outlook for the expan-

sion of aggregate demand in relation to
that of aggregate supply, including the
timing and strength of the economy's
response to earlier monetary policy
tightenings, warranted a more limited
policy action. Still, noting that there
had been few signs that the rise in
interest rates over recent quarters had
begun to bring demand in line with
potential supply, the Committee
decided in both instances that the balance of risks going forward was
weighted mainly in the direction of
rising inflation pressures. In particular,
it was becoming increasingly clear that
the Committee would need to move
more aggressively at a later meeting
if imbalances continued to build and
inflation and inflation expectations,


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

which had remained relatively subdued until then, began to pick up. 1
Some readings between the March
and May meetings of the FOMC on
labor costs and prices suggested a possible increase of inflation pressures.
Moreover, aggregate demand had continued to grow at a fast clip, and markets for labor and other resources were
showing signs of further tightening.
Financial market conditions had
firmed in response to these developments; the substantial rise in private
borrowing rates between March and
l. At its March and May meetings, the FOMC
took a number of actions that were aimed at
adjusting the implementation of monetary policy
to actual and prospective reductions in the stock
of Treasury debt securities.

May had been influenced by the
buildup in expectations of more policy
tightening as market participants recognized the need for higher short-term
interest rates. Given all these circumstances, the FOMC decided in May to
raise the target for the overnight federal funds rate 50 basis points, to 6½
percent. The Committee saw little risk
in the more forceful action given the
strong momentum of the economic
expansion and widespread market
expectations of such an action. Even
after taking into account its latest
action, however, the FOMC saw the
strength in spending and pressures in
labor markets as indicating that the
balance of risks remained tilted toward
rising inflation.

Growth of Domestic Nonfinancial Debt
Percent, annual rate

-

-

--

.___

- -

■

..__

I I

Total
D Federal
■ Nonfederal

1990

1991

Hl

.___ ,....

1992

8

r
1993

-

1994

0----

-

4

-

1995

1996

1997

+

-

1998

0

1999

4

2000

Note. Total debt consists of the outstanding fourth quarter of year indicated. Growth in the first
credit market debt of the U.S. government, state half of 2000 is computed from average for fourth
and local governments, households and nonprofit quarter of 1999 to average for the second quarter of
organizations, nonfinancial businesses, and farms. 2000 and expressed at an annual rate. The growth
Annual growth rates are computed from average rate for 2000:Hl is currently based on partially
for fourth quarter of preceding year to average for estimated data.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
11
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

By the June FOMC meeting, the
incoming data were suggesting that
the expansion of aggregate demand
might be moderating toward a more
sustainable pace: Consumers had
increased their outlays for goods modestly during the spring; home purchases and starts appeared to have
softened; and readings on the labor
market suggested that the pace of hiring might be cooling off. Moreover,
much of the effects on demand of previous policy firmings, including the 50
basis point tightening in May, had not
yet been fully realized. Financial market participants interpreted signs of
economic slowing as suggesting that

the Federal Reserve probably would
be able to hold inflation in check without much additional policy firming.
However, whether aggregate demand
had moved decisively onto a more
moderate expansion track was not yet
clear, and labor resource utilization
remained unusually elevated. Thus,
although the FOMC decided to defer
any policy action in June, it indicated
that the balance of risks was still on the
side of rising inflation in the foreseeable future. 2

Economic Projections for
2000 and 2001
The members of the Board of Governors and the Federal Reserve Bank
presidents expect the current economic
expansion to continue through next
year, but at a more moderate pace than
the average over recent quarters. For
2000 as a whole, the central tendency
of their forecasts for the rate of increase
in real gross domestic product (GDP) is
4 percent to 4½ percent, measured as
the change between the fourth quarter
of 1999 and the fourth quarter of 2000.
Over the four quarters of 2001, the central tendency forecasts of real GDP are

M2 Growth Rate
Percent, annual rate

8

Hl
6

4

2

2. At its June meeting, the FOMC did not
establish ranges for growth of money and debt
in 2000 and 2001. The legal requirement to
establish and to announce such ranges had
expired, and owing to uncertainties about the
behavior of the velocities of debt and money,
these ranges for many years have not provided
useful benchmarks for the conduct of monetary
policy. Nevertheless, the FOMC believes that the
behavior of money and credit will continue to
have value for gauging economic and financial
conditions.

1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
Note. M2 consists of currency, travelers checks,
demand deposits, other checkable deposits,
savings deposits (including money market
deposit accounts), small-denomination time
deposits, and balances in retail money market
funds. See footnote under the domestic nonfinancial debt chart for details on the computation of
growth rates.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

12

2001 than in 1999, and the Committee
will need to be alert to the possibility
that financial conditions may need to
be adjusted further to balance aggregate demand and potential supply and
to keep inflation low.
Considerable uncertainties attend
estimates of potential supply-both

in the 3¼ percent to 3¾ percent range.
With this pace of expansion, the civilian unemployment rate should remain
near its recent level of 4 percent. Even
with the moderation in the pace of economic activity, the Committee members and nonvoting Bank presidents
expect that inflation may be higher in

Economic Projections for 2000 and 2001
Percent
Federal Reserve governors and
Reserve Bank presidents

2000

Change,
fourth quarter
to fourth
quarter:1

Average
level,
fourth
quarter:

Nominal GDP
Real GDP2

Average
level,
fourth
quarter:

Range

Central
tendency

6-7¼

6¼-6¾

6.0

4-4½

3.9

3¾-5

PCE prices

2-2¾

2½-2¾

3.23

Civilian unemployment rate

4-4¼

About 4

4.1

Range

Central
Tendency

2001

Change,
four th quarter
to fourth
quarter: 1

Administration

Nominal GDP

5-6¼

5½-6

5.3
3.2

Real GDP 2

2½-4

31/4-3¾

PCE prices

1¾-3

2-2½

2.53

4-4¼

4.2

Civilian unemployment rate

4-4½

2. Chain-weighted.
3. Projection for the consumer price index.

1. Change from average for fourth quarter of
previous year to average for fourth quarter of
year indicated.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

13

the rate of growth and the level of the
economy's ability to produce on a sustained non-inflationary basis. Business
investment in new equipment and
software has been exceptionally high,
and given the rapid pace of technological change, firms will continue to
exploit opportunities to implement
more-efficient processes and to speed
the flow of information across markets.
In such an environment, a further
pickup in productivity growth is a distinct possibility. However, a portion of
the very rapid rise in measured productivity in recent quarters may be a
result of the cyclical characteristics of
this expansion rather than an indication of structural rates of increase
consistent with holding the level of
resource utilization unchanged. Current levels of labor resource utilization

Wealth and Saving
Ratio

12
10
8

6
4

1980

4

_.___._____ i
-

1997

1999

Note. The value for 2000:Ql is the percent
change from a year earlier.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1990

1995

0

2000

are already unusually high. To date,
this has not led to escalating unit labor
costs, but whether such a favorable
performance in the labor market can
be sustained is one of the important
uncertainties in the outlook.
O n the demand side, the adjustments in financial markets that have
accompanied expected and actual
tighter monetary conditions may be
beginning to moderate the rise in
domestic demand. As that process
evolves, the substantial impetus that
household spending has received in
recent years from rapid gains in equity
wealth should subside. The higher
cost of business borrowing and morerestrictive credit supply conditions
probably will not exert substantial
restraint on investment decisions, particularly as long as the costs and poten-

2

1995

1985

+

Note. The wealth-to-income ratio is the ratio
of net worth of households to disposable
personal income.

Percent, Q4 to Q4

1993

Personal saving rate

---.Ql

----------------

1991

2

4

Change in Output per Hour for the
N onfarm Business Sector

Ql

Percent

14

Major Stock Price Indexes

Nominal U.S. Dollar Exchange Rate

Index, June 30, 1999=100

First week 1999=100

160

120
100
80

JJASONDJFMAMJJASONDJFMAMJJ

1999
2000
Note. The data are weekly. Indexes are tradeweighted averages of the exchange value of the
dollar against major currencies and against the
currencies of a broad group of important U.S.
trading partners. Last observations are for the
week ending July 12, 2000.

1998
1999
2000
Note. The data are daily. Last observations are
for July 17, 2000.

tial productivity payoffs of new equipment and software remain attractive.
The slowing in domestic spending will
not be fully reflected in a more moderate expansion of domestic production.
Some of the slowing will be absorbed
in smaller increases in imports of
goods and services, and given continued recovery in economic activity
abroad, domestic firms are expected to
continue seeing a boost to demand and
to production from rising exports.
Regarding inflation, FOMC participants believe that the rise in consumer
prices will be noticeably larger this
year than in 1999 and that inflation will
then drop back somewhat in 2001. The
central tendency of their forecasts for
the increase in the chain-type index
for personal consumption expenditures
is 2½ percent to 2¾percent over the

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

four quarters of 2000 and 2 percent to
2½ percent during 2001. Shaping the
contour of this inflation forecast is the
expectation that the direct and indirect
effects of the boost to domestic inflation this year from the rise in the price
of world crude oil will be partly
reversed next year if, as futures markets suggest, crude oil prices retrace
this year's run-up by next year. Nonetheless, these forecasts show consumer
price inflation in 2001 to have moved
above the rates that prevailed over the
1997-98 period. Such a trend, were it
not to show signs of quickly stabilizing
or reversing, would pose a considerable risk to the continuation of the
extraordinary economic performance
of recent years.
15

Prices for Oil and Other Commodities
Index, January 1999=100

The economic forecasts of the FOMC
are similar to those recently released by
the Administration in its MidSession Review of the Budget. Compared with the forecasts available in
February, the Administration raised its
projections for the increase in real GDP
in 2000 and 2001 to rates that lie at the
low end of the current range of central
tendencies of Federal Reserve policymakers. The Administration also
expects that the unemployment rate
will remain close to 4 percent. Like the
FOMC, the Administration sees consumer price inflation rising this year
and falling back in 2001. After accounting for the differences in the construction of the alternative measures of consumer prices, the Administration's
projections of increases in the consumer
price index of 3.2 percent in 2000 and
2.5 percent in 2001 are broadly consistent with the Committee's expectations
for the chain-type price index for personal consumption expenditures.

Dollars per barrel

---------------Oil
~

Non-oil commodities
.__

-

30

-

20

-

10

2000
1999
Note. The oil price is the spot price of West
Texas intermediate crude oil. The price for nonoil commodities is a weighted average of thirtynine non-fuel primary-commodity prices from
the International Monetary Fund. The data are
monthly. The last observation for non-oil commodities is May; for oil, July average through
July 12, 2000.

FRBl-16000-0700-C


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

16