View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

1990 MONETARY POLICY OBJECTIVES


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Summary Report of the Federal Reserve Board

February 20, 1990

1990 MONETARY POLICY OBJECTIVES


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Testimony of Alan Greenspan, Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

February 20, 1990

Testimony of Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Federal Reserve Board
About a year ago, Federal Reserve policy was in
the final phase of a period of gradual tightening,
designed to inhibit a buildup of inflation pressures.
Interest rates moved higher through the winter, but
started down when signs of more restrained
aggregate demand and of reduced potential for
higher inflation began to appear. As midyear
approached, a marked strengthening of the dollar on
foreign exchange markets further diminished the
threat of accelerating inflation. New economic data
suggested that the balance of risks had shifted
toward the possibility of an undue weakening in
economic activity. With M2 and M3 below the lower
bounds of their annual ranges in the spring, the
Federal Reserve in June embarked on a series of
measured easing steps that continued through late
last year. Across the maturity spectrum, interest
rates declined further, to levels about 1 ½ percentage
points below March peaks. Reductions in inflation
expectations and reports of a softer economy
evidently contributed to the drop in rates in
longer-term markets.
The decrease in short-term rates lifted M2 to
around the middle of its annual range in the latter
part of the year. Efforts under the Financial
Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement
Act of 1989 (FIRREA) to close insolvent thrift
institutions and strengthen undercapitalized thrifts
led to a cutback of the industry's assets and funding
needs . This behavior held down M3 growth in the
second half of the year, and that aggregate ended the
year around the lower end of its annual range. The
restructuring of the thrift industry did not, however,
seem to appreciably affect the overall cost and
availability of residential mortgage credit, as other
suppliers of this credit stepped into the breach. In
the aggregate, the debt of nonfinancial sectors
slowed somewhat, along with spending, to a rate just
below the midpoint of its annual range.

Mr. Chairman and Members of the
Committee) I appreciate the
opportunity to testify today on the
Federal Reserve)s semiannual
Monetary Policy Report to the
Congress. My prepared remarks
discuss our monetary policy actions
and plans in the context not only of
the current and projected state of the
economy) but also against the
background of our longer-term
objectives and strategy for achieving
them. The final section of the
testimony addresses some issues for
monetary policy raised by the
increasingly international character
offinancial markets.

Economic and Monetary Policy
Developments in 1989
Last year marked the seventh year of the longest
peacetime expansion of the U.S . economy on
record. Some 2 ½ million jobs were created, and
the civilian unemployment rate held steady at
5 ¼ percent. Inflation was held to a rate no faster
than that in recent years, but unfortunately no
progress was made in 1989 toward price stability.
Thus, while we can look back with satisfaction at
the economic progress made last year, there is still
important work to be done.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1

So far this year, the federal funds rate has
remained around 8 ¼ percent, but rates on Treasury
securities and longer-term private instruments have
reversed some of their earlier declines. Investors
have reacted to stronger-than-expected economic
data, a runup in energy prices, and increasingly
attractive investment opportunities abroad,
especially in Europe.

inflation and inflation expectations, while avoiding a
recession. Approaching price stability may involve a
period of expansion in activity at a rate below the
growth in the economy's potential, thereby relieving
pressures on resources. Once some slack develops,
real output growth can pick up to around its
potential growth rate, even as inflation continues to
trend down. Later, as price stability is approached,
real output growth can move still higher, until full
resource utilization is restored.
While these are the general principles, no one can
be certain what path for the economy would, in
practice, accompany the gradual approach to price
stability. One key element that would minimize the
costs associated with the transition would be a
conviction of participants in the economy that the
anti-inflation policy is credible, that is, likely to be
effective and unlikely to be reversed.
Stability of the general price level will yield
important long-run benefits. Nominal interest rates
will be reduced with the disappearance of expectations of inflation, and real interest rates likely will be
lower as well, as less uncertainty about the future
behavior of overall prices induces a greater willingness to save. Higher saving and capital accumulation will enhance productivity, and the trend growth
in real GNP will be greater than would be possible if
the recent inflation rate continued.
If past patterns of monetary behavior persist,
maintaining price stability will require an average
rate of M2 growth over time approximately equal to
the trend growth in output. During the transition,
the decline of market interest rates in response to the
moderation in inflation would boost the public's
demand for M2 relative to nominal spending,
lowering M2 velocity. M2 growth over several years
accordingly may show little deceleration, and it
could actually speed up from time to time, as
interest rates decline in fits and starts. Hence, the
FOMC would not expect to lower its M2 range
mechanically each and every year in the transition to
price stability.

The Ultimate Objectives and Medium-Term
Strategy of Monetary Policy
Monetary policy was conducted again last year with
an eye on long-run policy goals, and economic
developments in 1989 were consistent with the
Federal Reserve's medium-term strategy for
reaching them. The ultimate objective of economic
policy is to foster the maximum sustainable rate of
economic growth. This outcome depends on market
mechanisms that provide incentives for economic
progress by encouraging creativity, innovation,
saving, and investment. Markets perform these
tasks most effectively when individuals can reasonably believe that by forgoing consumption or leisure
in the present they can reap adequate rewards in the
future. Inflation insidiously undermines such
confidence. It raises doubts in people's minds about
the future real value of their nominal savings and
earnings, and it distorts decision-making. Faced
with inflation, investors are more likely to divert
their attention to protecting the near-term purchasing power of their wealth. Modern-day examples of
economies stunted by rapid inflation are instructive.
In countries with high rates of inflation, people tend
to put their savings in foreign currencies and
commodities rather than in the financial investments
and claims on productive assets that can best foster
domestic growth. By ensuring stable prices,
monetary policy can play its most important role in
promoting economic progress.
The strategy of the Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC) for moving toward this goal
remains the same-to restrain growth in money and
aggregate demand in coming years enough to
establish a clear downward tilt to the trend of


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

2

This qualitative description of our medium-term
strategy is easy to state, but actually implementing it
will be difficult. Unexpected developments no doubt
will require flexible policy responses. Any such
adjustments will not imply a retreat from the
medium-term strategy or from ultimate policy goals.
Rather, they will be mid-course corrections that
attempt to keep the economy and prices on track.
The easing of reserve pressures starting last June is a
case in point. Successive FOMC decisions to ease
operating policy were intended to forestall an
economic downturn, the chances of which seemed to
be increasing as the balance of risks shifted away
from greater inflation. The FOMC was in no way
abandoning its long-run goal of price stability.
Instead, it sought financial conditions that would
support the moderate economic expansion judged to
be consistent with progress toward stable prices. In
the event, output growth was sustained last year,
although in the fourth quarter a major strike at
Boeing combined with the first round of production
cuts in the auto industry accentuated the underlying
slowdown. On the inflation side, price increases in
the second half were appreciably lower than those in
the first. Although the CPI for January, as expected,
showed a sizable jump in energy and food prices in
the wake of December's cold snap, a reversal is
apparently underway.

money and debt. With the economic situation not
materially different from what was anticipated
at that time, the FOMC reaffirmed the tentative
3 to 7 percent growth range for M2 in 1990 that it set
last July. This range, which is the same as that used
in 1989, is expected by most FOMC members to
produce somewhat slower growth in nominal GNP
this year. The declines in short-term interest rates
through late last year can be expected to continue to
boost the public's demands for liquid balances in
M2, at least for a while longer. M2 growth over 1990
thus may be faster than in recent years, and M2
velocity could well decline over the four quarters of
the year, absent a pronounced firming in short-term
market interest rates.
In contrast with M2, the range for M3 has been
reduced from its tentative range set last July. The
new M3 range of 2 ½ to 6 ½ percent is intended to
embody the same degree of restraint as the M2
range, but it was lowered to reflect the continued
decline in thrift assets and funding needs now
anticipated to accompany the ongoing restructuring
of the thrift industry. This asset runoff began in
earnest in the second half oflast year, so its magnitude was not incorporated into the tentative M3
range for 1990 set lastjuly. The bulk of the mortgage and real estate assets that thrifts will shed are
expected to be acquired by the Resolution Trust
Corporation and diversified investors other than
depository institutions. Such assets thus will no
longer be financed by monetary instruments
included in M3. In addition, commercial banks are
likely to be more cautious in their lending activities,
reducing their need to issue wholesale managed
liabilities included in M3. These influences should
retard the growth of M3 relative to M2 again this
year.
The debt of domestic nonfinancial sectors is
expected to decelerate along with nominal GNP for
a fourth straight year, and the Committee chose to
lower the monitoring range for this aggregate to
5 to 9 percent for 1990. Merger and acquisition
activity has retreated from the feverish pace of
recent years, reflecting some well-publicized

Monetary Policy and the Economic
Outlook for 1990
Against this background, the Federal Reserve
Governors and the Presidents of Reserve Banks
foresee continued moderate economic expansion
over 1990, consistent with conditions that will foster
progress toward price stability over time. At its
meeting earlier this month, the FOMC selected
ranges for growth in money and debt it believes will
promote this outcome.
My testimony last July indicated the very
preliminary nature of the tentative ranges chosen for
1990, given the uncertain outlook for the economy,
financial conditions, and appropriate growth of


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

3

Risks to the Economic Outlook

difficulties of restructured firms and more caution
on the part of creditors. All other things equal, less
restructuring activity and greater use of equity
finance imply reduced corporate borrowing. An
ebbing of growth in household debt also seems
probable.
Over the last decade, money and debt aggregates
have become less reliable guides for the Federal
Reserve in conducting policy. The velocities of the
aggregates have ranged widely from one quarter or
one year to the next, in response to interest rate
movements and special factors. In the coming year,
the effects of the contraction of the thrift industry on
the velocity of M3, and to a lesser extent on that of
M2, are especially difficult to predict. While
recognizing that the growth rates of the broader
monetary aggregates over long periods are still good
indicators of trends in inflation, the FOMC will
continue to take an array of factors into account in
guiding operating policy. Information about .
emerging patterns of inflationary pressure, business
activity, and conditions in domestic and international financial markets again will need to supplement monetary data in providing the background
for decisions about the appropriate operating stance.
The Committee's best judgment is that money
and debt growth within these annual ranges will be
compatible with a moderation in the expansion of
nominal GNP. Most FOMC members and other
Reserve Bank presidents foresee real GNP growing
1 ¾ to 2 percent over the year as a whole. Such a
rate would be around last year's moderate pace,
excluding the rebound in agricultural output from
the 1988 drought. A slight easing of pressures on
resources probably is in store. Inflation pressures
should remain contained, even though the decline in
the dollar's value over the past half-year likely will
reverse some of the beneficial effects on domestic
inflation stemming from the dollar's earlier appreciation. The CPI this year is projected to increase
4 to 4 ½ percent, as compared with last year's
4½ percent.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Experience has shown such macroeco~omic
.
forecasts to be subject to a variety of risks. Assessing
the balance of risks between production shortfalls
and inflation pressures in the current outlook is
complicated by several cross-currents in the
domestic and international economic and financial
situation.
One risk is that the weakness in economic activity
evident around year-end may tend to cumulate,
causing members' forecasts about production and
employment this year to be overly optimistic.
However, available indicators of near-term economic performance suggest that the weakest point
may have passed. The inventory correction in the
auto industry-a rapid one involving a sharp
reduction in motor vehicle assemblies injanuary
coupled with better motor vehicle sales-seems to be
largely behind us. Industrial activity outside of
motor vehicles appears to be holding up. Production
of business equipment, where evidence has accumulated of some stability-if not an increase-in orders
for capital goods, is likely to support manufacturing
output in coming months. Housing starts were .
depressed in December by severely cold weather in
much of the country. But starts bounced back
strongly in January, in line with the large gain in
construction employment last month. From these
and similar data, one can infer the beginnings of a
modest firming in economic activity. While we
cannot be certain that we are as yet out of the
recessionary woods, such evidence warrants at least
guarded optimism.
There are, however, other undercurrents that
continue to signal caution. One that could disturb
the sustainability of the current economic expansion
has been the recent substantial deterioration in
profit margins. A continuation of this trend could
seriously undercut the still expanding capital goods
market. However, if current signs of an upturn in
economic activity broaden, profit margins can be
expected to stabilize.

4

A more deep-seated concern with respect to the
longer-run viability of the expansion is the increase
in debt leverage. Although the trends of income and
cash flow may have turned the corner, the structure
of the economy's financial balance sheet weighs
increasingly heavily on the dynamics of economic
expansion. In recent years , business debt burdens
have been enlarged through corporate restructurings, and as a consequence interest costs as a percent
of cash flow have risen markedly. Responding to
certain well-publicized debt-servicing problems,
creditors have become more selective in committing
funds for these purposes. Within the banking
industry, credit standards have been tightened for
merger and LBO loans, as well as for some other
business customers. Credit for construction projects
reportedly has become less available because of
FIRREA-imposed limits and heightened concerns
about overbuilding in a number of real estate
markets.
Among households, too, debt-servicing burdens
have risen to historic highs relative to income, and
delinquency rates have moved up oflate. Suppliers
of consumer and mortgage credit appear to have
tightened lending terms a little. Real estate values
have softened in some locales, although prices have
maintained an uptrend in terms of the national
averages, especially for single-family residences.
These and other financial forces merit careful
monitoring. While welcome from a supervisory
perspective, more cautious lending does have the
potential for damping aggregate demand.
It is difficult to assess how serious a threat
increased leverage is to the current levels of economic activity. Clearly, should the economy fall into
a recession, excess debt service costs would intensify
the problems of adjustment. But it is unlikely that in
current circumstances strains coming from the
economy's financial balance sheet can themselves
precipitate a downturn. As I indicated earlier, we
expect nonfinancial debt growth to continue to slow
from its frenetic pace of the mid-1980s. This should
lessen the strain and hopefully the threat to the
economy.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

International Financial Markets and
Monetary Policy
Among other concerns, recent events have highlighted the complex interactions between developments in the U.S. economy and financial markets
and those in the other major industrial countries.
Specifically, the parallel movements in long-term
interest rates here and abroad over the early weeks
of 1990 have raised questions: To what extent is the
U.S. economy subject to influences from abroad? To
what extent, as a consequence, have we lost control
over our economic destiny? The simple answer to
these questions is that the U.S. economy is influenced from abroad to a substantially greater degree
than, say, two or three decades ago, but U.S.
monetary policy is, nonetheless, able to carry out its
responsibilities effectively.
The post-war period has seen markedly closer ties
among the world's economies. Markets for goods
have become increasingly, and irreversibly,
integrated as a result of the downsizing of economic
output and the consequent expansion of international trade. The past decade, in particular, also has
witnessed the growing integration of financial
markets around the world. Advancing technology
has fostered the unbundling and transfer of risk and
engendered a proliferation of new financial products. Cross border financial flows have accordingly
accelerated at a pace in excess of global trade gains.
This globalization of financial markets has meant
that events in one market or in one country can
affect within minutes developments in markets
throughout the world.
More integrated and open financial markets have
enabled all countries to reap the benefits of
enhanced competition and improved allocation of
capital. Our businesses can raise funds almost
anywhere in the world. Our savers can choose from
a lengthening menu of investments as they seek the
highest possible return on their funds. Our financial
institutions enjoy wider opportunities to compete.

5

In such an environment, a change in the expected
rate of return on financial assets abroad naturally
can affect the actions of borrowers or lenders in the
United States. In response, exchange rates, asset
prices, and rates of return all may adjust to new
values.
Strengthened linkages among world financial
markets affect all markets and all investors. Just as
U.S. markets are influenced by developments in
markets abroad, foreign markets are influenced by
events here. These channels of influence do not
depend on whether a country is experiencing a
deficit or a surplus in its current account. In today's
financial markets, the net flows associated with
current account surpluses and deficits are only the
tip of the iceberg. What are more important are
the huge stocks of financial claims-more than
$1.5 trillion held in the United States by foreigners
and more than $26 trillion of dollar-denominated
claims on U.S. borrowers held by U.S . residents.
This is in addition to the vast quantities of assets
held in foreign currencies abroad. It is these
holdings that can respond to changes in actual and
expected rates of return.
In recent years we have seen several instances in
which rates of return have changed essentially
simultaneously around the world. For example,
stock prices moved together in October 1987 and

Moreover, despite globalization, financial
markets do not necessarily move together-they also
respond to more localized influences. Over 1989, for
example, bond yields in West Germany and Japan
rose about a pe_rcentage point, while those in the
United States fell by a similar amount. The contrast
between 1989 and 1990 illustrates the complexity of
relationships among financial markets. Interactions
can show through in movements in exchange rates
as well as interest rates, and changes in the relative
prices of assets depend on a variety of factors,
including economic developments and inflation
expectations in various countries as well as monetary and fiscal policies here and abroad.
The importance of foreign economic policies for
domestic economic conditions has given rise in
recent years to a formalized process of policy
coordination among the major industrial countries.
The purpose of such coordination is to help policymakers achieve better performance in their national
economies. It begins with improved communication
among authorities about economic developments
within each country. It includes systematic analysis
of the likely impact of these developments on the
economies of the partner countries and on variables
such as exchange rates that are inherently jointly
determined in international markets. Within such a
framework, it is possible to consider alternative

1989, and in 1990 bond yields have risen markedly

choices for economic policies and to account

in many industrial countries.
However, we must be cautious in interpreting
such events, and in drawing implications for the
United States. Frequently, such movements occur in
response to a common worldwide influence.
Currently, the world economy is adjusting to the
implications of changes in Eastern Europe, where
there are tremendous new opportunities to invest
and promote reconstruction and growth. Those
opportunities, while contributing to the increase in
interest rates in the United States, also open up new
markets for our exports.

explicitly for the impacts of likely policy measures in
one country on the other economies.
The influence of economic policies abroad and
other foreign developments on the U.S. economy is
profound, and the Federal Reserve must carefully
take them into account when considering its
monetary policy. But these influences do not
fundamentally constrain our ability to meet our
most important monetary policy objectives.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

6

Developments within U.S. financial markets remain
the strongest influence on the asset prices and
interest rates determined by those markets and,
through them, on the U.S. economy. Exchange
rates absorb much of the impact of developments in
foreign asset markets, permitting U.S. interest rates
to reflect primarily domestic economic conditions.
Exchange rates influence the prices of products that
do, or can, enter into international trade. Such
factors can bring about changes in the composition
of production between purely domestic goods and
services and those entering international trade, and
they can affect aggregate price movements for a
time.
However, the overall pace of spending and output
in the United States depends on the demands upon
all sectors of the U.S. economy taken together. And
our inflation rate, over time, depends on the
strength of those demands relative to our ability to
supply them out of domestic production. Because
the Federal Reserve is able to affect short-term
interest rates in U.S. financial markets, it is able to
influence the pace of economic activity in the
short-run and inflationary pressures longer-term. To
be sure, monetary policy must currently balance
more factors than in previous decades. But our goals
are still achievable.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary policy is only one tool, however, and it
cannot be used successfully to meet multiple
objectives. The Federal Reserve, for example, can
address itself to either domestic prices or exchange
rates but cannot be expected to achieve objectives
for both simultaneously. Monetary policy alone is
not readily capable of addressing today's large
current account deficit, which is symptomatic of
underlying imbalances among saving, spending,
and production within the U.S. economy. Continued progress in reducing the federal deficit is a more
appropriate instrument to raise domestic saving and
free additional resources for productive investment.
The long-term health of our economy requires the
balanced use of monetary and fiscal policy in order
to reach all of the nation's policy objectives.

7

1990 MONETARY POLICY OBJECTIVES


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

This Executive Summary provides highlights of the Board's
Review to the Congress on the Full Employment and
Balanced Growth Act of 1978.

February 20, 1990

Contents

Section

Page

Monetary Policy and the Economic Outlook for 1990

3

Monetary Policy for 1990

4

Economic Projections for 1990

5

The Performance of the Economy 1n 1989

6

The Household Sector

6

The Business Sector

7

The Government Sector

7

The External Sector

7

Labor Markets

8

Price Developments

9

Monetary Policy and Financial Developments during 1989

10

Implementation of Monetary Policy

10

Behavior of Money and Credit

11


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Monetary Policy and the Economic
Outlook for 1990
M3

The U.S. economy recorded its seventh consecutive
year of expansion in 1989. Although growth was
slower than in the preceding two years, it was sufficient to support the creation of 2 ½ million jobs and
to hold the unemployment rate steady at 5 ¼ percent, the lowest reading since the early 1970s. On
the external front, the trade and current account
deficits shrank further in 1989. And while inflation
remained undesirably high, the pace was less than
many analysts-and, indeed, most members of the
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)-had
predicted, owing in part to the continuing diminution in longer-range inflation expectations.
In 1989, monetary policy was tailored to the
changing contours of the economic expansion and
the potential for inflation. Early in the year, as for
most of 1988, the Federal Reserve tightened money
market conditions in order to prevent pressures on
wages and prices from building. Market rates of
interest rose relative to those on deposit accounts,
and unexpectedly large tax payments in April and
May drained liquid balances, restraining the growth
of the monetary aggregates in the first half of the
year. By May, M2 and M3 lay below the lower
bounds of the annual target ranges established by
the FOMC.

M2

4150
4050
3950
3850
3750

0

3150

3050

2950

F M A M J J A S O N D


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

F M A M J

J A S O N D

1989

Around midyear, risks of an acceleration in inflation were perceived to have diminished as pressures
on industrial capacity had moderated, commmodity
prices had leveled out, and the dollar had strengthened on exchange markets, reinforcing the signals
conveyed by the weakness in the monetary
aggregates. In June, the FOMC began a series of
steps, undertaken with care to avoid excessive inflationary stimulus, that trimmed 1 ½ percentage
points from short-term interest rates by year-end.
Longer-term interest rates moved down by a like
amount, influenced by both the System's easing and
a reduction in inflation expectations.
Growth of M2 rebounded to end the year at
about the midpoint of the 1989 target range. Growth
of M3, however, remained around the lower end of
its range, as a contraction of the thrift industry,
encouraged by the Financial Institutions Reform,
Recovery, and Enforcement Act of 1989 (FIRREA),
reduced needs to tap M3 sources of funds. The primary effect of the shrinkage of the thrift industry's
assets was a rechanneling of funds in mortgage markets, rather than a reduction in overall credit availability; growth of the nonfinancial ,s ector debt
aggregate monitored by the FOMC was just a bit
slower in the second half than in the first, and this
measure ended the year only a little below the midpoint of its range.

Billions of Dollars

1988

N D J
1988

3250

0 N D J

Billions of Dollars

1989

3

The Committee reduced the M3 range to 2 ½ to
6 ½ percent to take account of the effects of the
restructuring of the thrift industry, which is expected
to continue in 1990. A smaller proportion of mortgages is likely to be held at depository institutions
and financed by elements in M3; thrift institution
assets should continue to decline, as some solvent
thrifts will be under pressure to meet capital standards and insolvent thrifts will continue to be
shrunk and closed, with a portion of their assets
carried, temporarily, by the government. An
increase in lender-and borrower-caution more
generally points to some slowing in the pace at
which nonfinancial sectors take on debt relative to
their income in 1990. In particular, recent developments suggest that leveraged buyouts and other
transactions that substitute debt for equity in corporate capital structures will be noticeably less
important in 1990 than in recent years. Moreover,
a further decline in the federal sector's deficit is
expected to reduce credit growth this year. In light
of these considerations, the Committee reduced the
monitoring range for debt of the nonfinancial sectors
to 5 to 9 percent.
The setting of targets for money growth in 1990 is
made more difficult by uncertainty about developments affecting thrift institutions. The behavior of
M3 and, to a more limited extent, M2 is likely to
be affected by such developments, but there is only
limited basis in experience to gauge the impact.

Thus far this year, the overnight rate on federal
funds has held at 8 ¼ percent, but other market
rates have risen. Increases of as much as 1/2 percentage point have been recorded at the longer end
of the maturity spectrum. The bond markets
responded to indicators suggesting a somewhat
greater-than-anticipated buoyancy in economic
activity-which may have both raised expected real
returns on investment and renewed some apprehensions about the outlook for inflation. The rise in
yields occurred in the context of a general ~imup in
international capital market yields, which appears to
have been in part a response to emerging opportunities associated with the opening of Eastern Europe;
this development had particularly notable effects on
the exchange value of the West German mark,
which rose considerably relative to the dollar, the
yen, and other non-EMS currencies.

Monetary Policy for 1990
The Federal Open Market Committee is committed
to the achievement, over time, of price stability. The
importance of this objective derives from the fact
that the prospects for long-run growth in the economy are brightest when inflation need no longer be
a material consideration in the decisions of households and firms. The members recognize that certain
short-term factors-notably a sharp increase in food
and energy prices-are likely to boost inflation early
this year, but anticipate that these factors will not
persist. Under these circumstances, policy can support further economic expansion without abandoning
the goal of price stability.
To foster the achievement of those objectives, the
Committee has selected a target range of 3 to 7 percent for M2 growth in 1990. Growth in M2 may be
more rapid in 1990 than in recent years, and yet be
consistent with some moderation in the rate of
increase in nominal income and restraint on prices;
in particular, M2 may grow more rapidly than
nominal GNP in the first part of this year in lagged
response to last year's interest rate movements.
Eventually, however, slower M2 growth will be
required to achieve and maintain price stability.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Ranges of Growth for Monetary and
Credit Aggregates 1
(Percent Change, Fourth Quarter to Fourth Quarter)

4

1988

1989

1990

M2

4 to 8

3 to 7

3 to 7

M3

4 to 8

3 ½ to 7 ½

2 ½ to 6½

Debt

7 to 11

6½ to 10½

5 to 9

Economic Projections for 1990

The recent depreciation of the dollar likely will
constitute another impetus to near-term price
increases reversing the restraining influence exerted
by a stro~g dollar throug~ mos~ o~ last year: Prices
of imported goods, excluding 011, increased in the
fourth quarter after declining through the first three
quarters of 1989. The full eff~ct o~ this upturn_ likely
will not be felt on the domestic pnce level until
some additional time has passed.
Despite these adverse elements in the near-term
picture, the Committee believes that _progr~ss toward
price stability can be achieved over time, given the
apparently moderate pace of activity. In terms of the
consumer price index, most_ members expect an
increase of between 4 and 4 ½ percent, compared
with the 4. 5 percent advance recorded in 1989.
Relative to the Committee, the Administration
currently is forecasting more rapid growth in real
and nominal GNP. At the same time, the Administration's projection for consumer price inflation is at
the low end of the Committee's central tendency
range.
Most Committee members believe that growth in
nominal GNP will be between 5 ½ and 6 ½ percent,
but a more rapid expansion in nominal income .
would be welcome if it promised to be accompamed
by a declining path for inflation in 1990 and beyond.

The Committee members, and other Reserve Bank
presidents, expect that growth in the rea! economy
will be moderate during 1990. Most project real
GNP growth over the four quarters of the year to be
between 1 ¾ and 2 percent-essentially the same
increase as in 1989, excluding the bounce back in
farm output after the 1988 drought. It is expected
that this pace of expansion will be reflected in some
easing of pressures on domestic resources; the central tendency of forecasts is for an unemployment
rate of 5 ½ to 5 ¾ percent in the fourth quarter.
Given their importance in determining the trend
of overall costs, a deceleration in the cost of labor
inputs is an integral part of any solid progress
toward price stability. Unfortunately, the near-term
prospects for a moderation in labor cost pressures
are not favorable. Compensation growth is being
boosted in the first half of 1990 by an increase in
social security taxes and a hike in the minimum
wage. The anticipated easing of pressures in the
labor market should help produce some moderation
in the pace of wage increases in the second hal_f of
1990 but the Committee will continue to momtor
closeiy the growth of labor costs for signs of progress
in this area.

Economic Projections for 1990
1989 Actual

Percent change,
fourth quarter to
fourth quarter:

Average level in
the fourth quarter,
percent:

FOMC Members and other FRB Presidents

Central Tendency

Nominal GNP

6.4

4 to 7

5 ½ to 6½

7.0

Real GNP

2.4

1 to 2¼

1 ¾ to 2

2.6

Consumer price index

4.5

3½ to 5

4 to 4½

4.1

Unemployment rate

5.3

5 ½ to 6½

5 ½ to 5¾

5.4 2

1. CPI-W. FOMC forecasts are for CPI-U .
2. Percent of total labor force , including armed forces residing in the United States .


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Range

Administration

5

1

The Performance of the Economy

Real GNP grew 2 ½ percent over the four quarters
of 1989, 2 percent after adjustment for the recovery
in farm output from the drought losses of the prior
year. This constituted a significant downshifting in
the pace of expansion from the unsustainably rapid
rates of 198 7 and 1988, which had carried activity to
the point that inflationary strains were beginning to
become visible in the economy. As the year
progressed, clear signs emerged that pressures on
resource utilization were easing, particularly in the
industrial sector. Nonetheless, the overall unemployment rate remained at 5.3 percent, the lowest reading since 19 73, and inflation remained at 4 ½ percent despite the restraining influence of a dollar that
was strong for most of the year.

Real GNP

•

Ill

1989

The Household Sector
Household spending softened significantly in 1989,
with a marked weakening in the demand for motor
vehicles and housing. Real consumer spending on
goods and services increased 2 ¼ percent over the
four quarters of 1989, 1 ½ percentage points less
than in 1988. Growth in real disposable income
slowed last year, but continued to outstrip growth in
spending, and, as a result, the personal saving rate
increased to 5 ¾ percent in the fourth quarter of
1989.
Percent of
disposable income

Personal Saving

Percent change , Q4 to Q4

6
Drought-Adjusted

6

3

4

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

2

The slackening in consumer demand was concentrated in spending on goods. Real spending on
durable goods was about unchanged from the fourth
quarter of 1988 to the fourth quarter of 1989-after
jumping 8 percent in the prior year-chiefly reflecting a slump in purchases of motor vehicles.
Residential investment fell in real terms through
the first three quarters of 1989, and with only a
slight upturn in the fourth quarter, expenditures
decreased 6 percent on net over the year. Construction was weighed down throughout 1989 by the
overbuilding that occurred in some locales earlier in
the decade. Vacancy rates were especially high for
multifamily rental and condominium units. In the
single-family sector, affordability problems constained demand, dramatically so in those areas in
which home prices had soared relative to household
income.

+

1984

1985


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1986

1987

1988

1989

6

The Business Sector

The External Sector

Business fixed investment, adjusted for inflation,
increased only 1 percent at an annual rate during
the second half of 1989 after surging 7 ¾ percent
during the first half. Although competitive pressures
forced many firms to continue seeking efficiency
gains through capital investment, the deceleration in
overall economic growth made the need for capacity
expansion less urgent, and shrinking profits reduced
the availability of internal finance.
Nonfarm business inventory investment averaged
$21 billion in 1989. Although the average pace of
accumulation last year was slower than in 1988, the
pattern across sectors was somewhat uneven.
Nonetheless, most sectors of the economy have
adjusted fairly promptly to the deceleration in sales,
and appear to have succeeded in preventing serious
overhangs from developing.

The U.S. external deficits improved somewhat in
1989, but not by as much as in 1988. On a balanceof-payments basis, the deficit on merchandise trade
fell from an annual rate of $128 billion in the fourth
quarter of 1988 ( and $12 7 billion for the year as a
whole) to $114 billion in the first quarter of 1989.
Thereafter, there was no further net improvement.
The appreciation in the foreign exchange value of
the dollar between early 1988 and mid-1989 appears
to have played an important role in inhibiting further progress on the trade front. During the first
three quarters of 1989, the current account, excluding the influence of capital gains and losses that are
largely caused by currency fluctuations, showed a
deficit of $106 billion at an annual rate-somewhat
below the $124 billion deficit in the comparable
period of 1988.

The Government Sector

Foreign Exchange Value of the
U.S. Dollar*

Budgetary pressures continued to restrain the growth
of purchases at all levels of government. At the federal level, purchases fell 3 percent in real terms over
the four quarters of 1989, lower defense purchases
accounting for the bulk of the decline. Nondefense
purchases also declined in real terms from the fourth
quarter of 1988 to the fourth quarter of 1989;
increases in such areas as the space program and
drug interdiction were more than offset by general
budgetary restraint that imposed real declines on
most other discretionary programs.
Purchases of goods and services at the state and
local level increased 2 ½ percent in real terms over
the four quarters of 1989, down more than a percentage point from the average pace of the preceding five years. Nonetheless, there were some areas
of growth. Spending for educational buildings
increased, and employment in the state and local
sector rose 350,000 over the year, largely driven by
a pickup in hiring by schools. Despite the overall
slowdown in the growth of purchases, the budgetary
position of the state and local sector deteriorated
further over the year.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Index, March 1973 =100

150
130
110
90

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

*Index of weighted average foreign exchange value of U.S . dollar in terms of currencies of other G-10 countries plus Switzerland. Weights are 1972-76 global
trade of each of the 10 countries .

On a GNP basis, merchandise exports increased
about 11 percent in real terms over the four quarters
of 1989-roughly 4 percentage points less than in 1988.

7

Labor Markets

Annual rate,
billions of 1982 dollars

U.S. Real Merchandise Trade

Employment growth slowed in the second half of
1989; nonetheless, nonfarm payrolls increased nearly
2 ½ million during the year. The bulk of this expansion occurred in the service-producing sector. By
contrast, the manufacturing sector shed 100,000
jobs. These job losses were more than accounted for
by declines in the durable goods industries, and
appeared to reflect the slump in auto sales, the
weakening in capital spending, and the effects of a
stronger dollar on exports and imports.
Despite the slowdown in new job creation, the
overall balance of supply and demand in the labor
market remained steady over the year. The civilian
unemployment rate, which had declined about
1/2 percentage point over the twelve months of
1988, finished 1989 at 5.3 percent-unchanged from
twelve months earlier.

500
Imports

400

-- -- -~

Exports

-1984

1985

1986

300

,,,, ,,,,

200

1987

1988

1989

Merchandise imports excluding oil expanded
about 7 percent in real terms during 1989, with
much of the rise accounted for by imports of computers. Imports of oil increased 6 percent from the
fourth quarter of 1988 to the fourth quarter of 1989,
to a rate of 8.3 million barrels per day. At the same
time, the average price per barrel increased almost
40 percent, and the nation's bill for foreign oil
jumped 45 percent.
The counterpart of the current account deficit of
$106 billion at an annual rate over the first three
quarters of 1989 was a recorded net capital inflow of
about $60 billion at an annual rate and an unusually
large statistical discrepancy, especially in the second
quarter.

Nonfarm Payroll
Employment
lilll Total

D

9

'-----...........,

Net change , millions
of persons , Q4 to Q4

1984

Manufacturing

+


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1986

1987

1988

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

A slowdown in the growth of productivity often
accompanies a softening in the general economy,
and productivity gains were lackluster in 1989. Output per hour in the private nonfarm business sector
increased only 1/2 percent over the four quarters of
the year-1 percentage point below the rate of
increase in 1988. In the manufacturing sector,
productivity gains during the first half of 1989 kept
pace with the 1988 average of 3 percent; in the second half, however, productivity growth slowed to an
annual rate of 2 ¼ percent.

3

1985

7

5

6

1984

Quarterly
average, percent

Civilian Unemployment Rate

1989

8

Consumer Food Prices*

Price Developments
Inflation in consumer prices remained in the neighborhood of 4 ½ percent for the third year in a row,
as the level of economic activity was strong and continued to exert pressures on available resources.
During the first half of the year, overall inflation
was boosted by a sharp runup in energy prices and
a carry-over from 1988 of drought-related increases
in food prices. However, inflation in food prices
slowed during the second half, and energy prices
retraced about a third of the earlier run-up.
Food prices increased 5 ½ percent at the retail
level, slightly more than in 1988 when a number of
crops were severely damaged by drought. Continued
supply problems in some agricultural markets in
1989-notably a poor wheat crop and a shortfall in
dairy production-likely prevented a deceleration
from the drought-_induced rate of increase in 1988.

Consumer Prices*

6

1984

1985

1986

1988

1989

•Consumer Price Index for all urban consumers .


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1986

1978

1988

1989

Consumer energy prices surged 17 percent at an
annual rate during the first six months of 1989,
before dropping back 6 percent in the second half.
Consumer price increases for items other than food
and energy remained at about 4 ½ percent in 1989 .
In contrast to goods prices, the prices of nonenergy
services-which make up half of the overall consumer price index-increased 5 ¼ percent in 1989,
1/4 percentage point more than in 1988. The pickup
in this category was led by rents, medical services,
and entertainment services.

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

1987

1985

•Consumer Price Index for all urban consumers.

6

1984

Percent change, Q4 to Q4

9

Monetary and Financial Developments
during 1989
Implementation of Monetary Policy

In 1989 the Federal Reserve continued to pursue a
policy aimed at containing and ultimately eli~inating inflation while providing suppo:t for contu~ued
economic expansion. In implementmg that policy,
the Federal Open Market Committee mai~tained_ a
flexible approach to monetary targeting , with policy
responding to emerging conditions in the economy
and financial markets. This flexibility has been
necessitated by the substantial variability in the
short-run relationship between the monetary
aggregates and economic performan:e; however,
when viewed over a longer perspective, those
aggregates are still useful in conveying information
about price developments.
.
As the year began, monetary policy was followmg
through on a set of measured steps begun a year
earlier to check inflationary pressures. By then, however, evidence of a slackening in aggregate demand,
along with sluggish growth of the moneta:y .
aggregates, suggested that the year-long nse 1~ .
short-term interest rates was noticeably restrammg
the potential for more inflation. But, after a 1/2 percentage point increase in the discount rate at the
end of February, the Federal Reserve took no further policy action until June. Over the balance ~f
1989 the Federal Reserve moved toward an easmg
of m~ney market conditions, as indications mounted
of a slack in demand and lessened inflation pressures. The easing in reserve availability induced
declines in short-term interest rates of 1 ½ percentage points; money growth strengthened appreciably,
and M2 was near the middle of its target range by
the end of 1989. The level of M3, on the other
; hand remained around the lower bound of its
rang~, with its weakness mostly reflecting the shi.fting pattern of financial intermediation as the :hnft
industry retrenched. The growth of nonfinanc1~l
debt was trimmed to 8 percent in 1989, about m
line with the slowing in the growth of nominal GNP,
and ended the year at the midpoint of its monitoring
range.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

In the opening months of the year, the Federal
Open Market Committee extended the mo:e toward
restraint that had begun almost a year earlier, seeking to counter a disquieting intensification of inflationary pressures. Policy actions in January and
February, restraining reserve availability and raising
the discount rate, · prompted a further 3/4 percentage
point increase in short-term market i~te:est r_ates.
As evidence on prospective trends m mflat10n and
spending became more mixed in the se~ond quarter,
the Committee refrained from further t1ghtenmg and
in June began to ease pressures on reserve marke.ts.
As the information on the real economy, along with
the continued rise in the dollar, suggested that the
outlook for inflation was improving, most long-term
nominal interest rates fell as much as a percentage
point from their March peaks; the yield on the bellwether thirty-year Treasury bond moved down to
about 8 percent by the end of June.
In July, when the FOMC met for its semiann~al
review of the growth ranges for money and credit,
M2 and M3 lay at or a bit below the lower bounds
of their target cones. This weakness, reinforcing the
signals from prices and activity, c??tribute~ to the
Committee's decision to take add1t10nal easmg
action in reserve markets.
Late in the summer, longer-term interest rates
turned higher, as several economic data releas~s suggested reinvigorated inflationary pressures. ~1th
growth in the monetary aggregates reboundmg, the
Committee kept reserve conditions about unchanged
until the direction of the economy and prices
clarified.
Beginning in October, amid indi~ations of. added
risks of a weakening in the economic expans10n, the
FOMC reduced pressures on reserve markets in
three separate steps, which nudged the federal funds
rate down to around 8 ¼ percent by year-end, about
1 ½ percentage points below its level when incremental tightening ceased in February.

10

Behavior of Money and Credit

The Ml component of M2 was especially affected
by the swings in interest rates and opportunity costs
last year, and in addition was buffeted by the effects
of outsized tax payments in April. After its 4 ¼ percent rise in 1988, Ml grew only 1/2 percent in
1989 with much of the weakness in this transactions
aggr;gate occurring early in the. ye~r. . .
The shift of deposits from thrift mst1tut10ns to
commercial banks and money fund shares owed, in
part, to regulatory pressures that broug_ht down rates
paid by some excessively aggressive thrifts. On balance the weak growth of retail deposits at thrifts
appe~rs to have been about offset by the shift into

Growth in M2 was uneven over 1989, with marked
weakness in the first part of the year giving way to
robust growth thereafter. On balance over the year,
M2 expanded 4 ½ percent, down from 5 pe~cent
growth in 1988, placing it about at the m1dpomt of
its 1989 target range of 3 to 7 percent. The sl?we~
rate of increase in M2 reflected some moderat10n m
nominal income growth as well as the pattern of
interest rates and associated opportunity costs of
holding money, with the effects of increases in_ 1988
and 1989 outweighing the later, smaller, drop m
rates.

Y:

Growth of Money and Debt (Percent change)
M2

M1
Fourth quarter to
fourth quarter

M3

Debt of Domestic
N onfinancial Sectors

1980

7.4

8.9

9.5

9.5

1981

5.4 (2.5)*

9.3

12.3

10.2

1982

8.8

9.1

9.9

9.1

1983

10.4

12.2

9.8

11.1

1984

5.4

7.9

10.6

14.2

1985

12.0

8.9

7.8

13.1

1986

15.5

9.3

9.1

13.2

1987

6.3

4.3

5.8

9.9

1988

4.3

5.2

6.3

9.2

1989

0.6

4.6

3.3

8.1

Quarterly growth
rates 1989

Ql

-0.1

2.3

3.9

8.4

(annual rates)

Q2

-4.4

1.6

3.3

7.9

Q3

1.8

6.9

3.9

7.2

Q4

5.1

7. 1

2.0

8.0

* Figure in parentheses is adjusted for shifts to NOW accounts in 1981.

https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

11

Footnotes

commercial banks and money market mutual funds,
leaving M2 little affected overall by the realignment
of the thrift industry.
M3 was largely driven, as usual, by the funding
needs of banks and thrifts; under the special circum stances of the restructuring of the thrift industry, it
was a less reliable barometer of monetary policy
pressures than is normally the case. After expanding
6 ¼ percent in 1988, M3 hugged the lower bound of
its 3 ½ to 7 ½ percent target cone in 1989, closing
the year about 3 ¼ percent above its fourth
quarter-1988 base. In 1989, bank credit growth
about matched the previous year's 7 ½ percent
increase, but credit at thrift institutions is estimated
to have contracted a bit on balance over the year, in
contrast to its 6 ¼ percent growth in 1988.
Aggregate debt of the domestic nonfinancial sectors grew at a fairly steady pace over 1989, averaging 8 percent, which placed it near the midpoint of
its monitoring range of 6 ½ to 10 ½ percent.
Although the annual growth of debt slowed in 1989,
as it had during the preceding two years, it still
exceeded the 6 ½ percent growth of nominal GNP.
Federal sector debt grew 7 ½ percent, about 1/2 percentage point below the 1988 increase-and the
lowest rate of expansion in a decade-as the deficit
leveled off.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1. M1 is currency held by the public, plus travelers'
checks, plus demand deposits, plus other checkable
deposits [including negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW
and Super NOW) accounts, automatic transfer service
(ATS) accounts, and credit union share draft accounts].
M2 is M 1 plus savings and small denomination time
deposits, plus Mon~y Market Deposit Accounts, plus
shares in money market mutual funds ( other than those
restricted to institutional investors), plus overnight repurchase agreements and certain overnight Eurodollar
deposits.
M3 is M2 plus large time deposits, plus large denomination term repurchase agreements, plus shares in money
market mutual funds restricted to institutional investors
and certain term Eurodollar deposits.

A copy of the full report to Congress is available from
Publication Services, Federal Reserve Board,
Washington, D.C. 20551

FRB 17-48000-0290

12