View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Search

MACROBLOG

April 13, 2016

Putting the MetLife Decision into an Economic Context

In a recently released decision, a U.S. district court has ruled that the Financial Stability Oversight Council's (FSOC's) decision to
designate MetLife as a potential threat to financial stability was "arbitrary and capricious" and rescinded that designation. This
decision raises many questions, among them:
• Why did MetLife sue to end its status as a too-big-to-fail (TBTF) firm?
• How will this decision affect the Federal Reserve's regulation of nonbank financial firms?
• What else can be done to reduce the risk of crisis arising from nonbank financial firms?
Why does MetLife want to end its TBTF status?
An often-expressed concern is that market participants will consider FSOC-designated firms too big to fail, and investors will accord
these firms lower risk premiums (see, for example, Peter J. Wallison). The result is that FSOC-designated firms will gain a
competitive advantage. If so, why did MetLife sue to have the designation rescinded? And why did the announcement of the court's
determination result in an immediate 5 percent increase in the MetLife's stock price?
One possible explanation is that the FSOC's designation guarantees the firm will be subject to higher regulatory costs, but it only
marginally changes the likelihood it would receive a government bailout. The Dodd-Frank Act (DFA) requires that FSOC-designated
firms be subject to consolidated prudential supervision by the Federal Reserve using standards that are more stringent than the
requirements for other nonbank financial firms.
Moreover, the argument that such designation automatically conveys a competitive advantage has at least two weaknesses. First,
although Title II of the DFA authorizes the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) to resolve a failing nonbank firm in certain
circumstances, DFA does not provide FDIC insurance for any of the nonbank firm's liabilities, nor does it provide the FDIC with funds
to undertake a bailout. The FDIC is supposed to recover its costs from the failed firm's assets. Admittedly, DFA does allow for the
possibility that the FDIC would need to assess other designated firms for part of the cost of a resolution. However, MetLife could as
easily have been assessed to pay for another firm as it could have been the beneficiary of assessments on other systemically
important firms.
A second potential weakness in the competitive advantage argument is that the U.S. Treasury Secretary decides to invoke FDIC
resolution only after receiving a recommendation from the Federal Reserve Board and one other federal financial regulatory agency
(depending upon the type of failing firm). Invocation of resolution is not automatic. Moreover, a part of any decision authorizing FDIC
resolution are findings that at the time of authorization:
• the firm is in default or in danger of default,
• resolution under other applicable law (bankruptcy statutes) would have "serious adverse consequences" on financial stability,
and
• those adverse effects could be avoided or mitigated by FDIC resolution.
Although it would seem logical that FSOC-designated firms are more likely to satisfy these criteria than other financial firms, the Title
II criteria for FDIC resolution are the same for both types of firms.
How does this affect the Fed's regulation of nonbank firms?
Secretary of the Treasury Jack Lew has indicated his strong disagreement with the district court's decision, and the U.S. Treasury
has said it will appeal. Suppose, however, that FSOC designation ultimately does become far more difficult. How significantly would
that affect the Federal Reserve's regulatory power over nonbank financial firms?
Although the obvious answer would be that it would greatly reduce the Fed's regulatory power, recent experience casts some doubt
on this view. Nonbank financial firms appear to regard FSOC designation as imposing costly burdens that substantially exceed any
benefits they receive. Indeed, GE Capital viewed the costs as so significant that it had been selling large parts of its operations and
recently petitioned the FSOC to rescind its designation. Unless systemically important activities are a core part of the firm's business
model, nonbank financial firms may decide to avoid undertaking activities that would risk FSOC designation.
Thus, a plausible set of future scenarios is that the Federal Reserve would be supervising few, if any, nonbank financial firms
regardless of the result of the MetLife case. Rather, ultimate resolution of the case may have more of an impact on whether large
nonbank financial firms conduct systemically important activities (if designation becomes much harder) or the activities are
conducted by some combination of smaller nonbank financial firms and by banks that are already subject to Fed regulation (if the
ruling does not prevent future designations).
Lessons learned?
Regardless of how the courts and the FSOC respond to this recent judicial decision, the financial crisis should have taught us
valuable lessons about the importance of the nonbank financial sector to financial stability. However, those lessons should go

A

A

A

beyond merely the need to impose prudential supervision on any firms that are systemically important.
The cause of the financial crisis was not the failure of one or two large nonbank financial firms. Rather, the cause was that almost the
entire financial system stood on the brink of collapse because almost all the major participants were heavily exposed to the weak
credit standards that were pervasive in the residential real estate business. Yet if the real problem was the risk of multiple failures as
a result of correlated exposures to a single large market, perhaps we ought to invest more effort in evaluating the riskiness of
markets that could have systemic consequences.
In an article in Notes from the Vault and other forums, I have called for systematic end-to-end reviews of major financial markets
starting with the origination of the risks and ending with the ultimate holder(s) of the risks. This analysis would involve both
quantitative analysis of risk measures and qualitative analysis of the safeguards designed to reduce risk.
The primary goal would be to identify and try to correct weaknesses in the markets. A secondary goal would be to give the
authorities a better sense of where problems are likely to arise if a market does encounter problems.

Photo of By Larry D. Wall, executive director of the Atlanta Fed's Center for Financial Innovation and Stability
Larry D.
Wall
April 13, 2016 in Banking, Regulation | Permalink