View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Search

MACROBLOG

March 19, 2013

Being Ahead of the Curve: Not Always a Good Thing

Our friends at the New York Fed have a nifty interactive graphic that compares the unemployment rate, labor force participation rate,
and employment-to-population ratio over the last five business cycles. You can even break these indicators down by gender, by age,
or by a particular business cycle. (For a deeper dive, check out this post at Liberty Street Economics by Jonathan McCarthy and
Simon Potter.) And though it’s not exactly late-breaking news, no matter which of the three indicators you look at, you can’t help but
conclude that the most recent recession is an outlier.
The Beveridge curve is a fourth and particularly useful graphical representation of a steady-state economy showing how, in theory,
one might expect the vacancy rate to change, given an unemployment rate. It depicts the relationship between job openings and the
unemployment rate. (The Atlanta Fed’s magazine, EconSouth, discussed the Beveridge curve.) It, too, has been standing out over
the course of the most recent recovery, so much so that we think it warrants at least a second glance. There are a number of ways to
estimate a Beveridge curve (see, for example, methods described by Gadi Barlevy of the Chicago Fed here and by the Richmond
Fed’s Thomas Lubik here).
We use the method described by Barnichon et al. (2012) to estimate the solid curve used in the first chart below. The square plots
represent actual vacancy rate (y-axis) and unemployment rate (x-axis) combinations by month from December 2000, when the Job
Openings and Labor Turnover Statistics (JOLTS) data series from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) series begins, to
January 2013, the most recent month of data available for both series.

(enlarge)

Blue squares represent data from December 2000 to December 2009, when the “errors” between actual plots and the curve
estimation were below 2 percentage points, and red squares represent data since January 2010, where data suddenly seem to jump
higher than the predicted Beveridge curve to the tune of 2 percentage points or greater (see the chart below).

A

A

A

(enlarge)

But why?
In June 2012, Regis Barnichon and his coauthors concluded that the unemployment rate’s lackluster performance so far in the
recovery was attributable to a shortfall in hires per vacancy. Since then, the vacancy rate has climbed its way back to its June 2008
level of 2.7 percent. However, the unemployment rate has clearly not returned to either its June 2008 level (5.6 percent) or where the
Beveridge curve says it should be given this vacancy rate, which one might predict to be 5.5 percent using the methodology of
Barnichon et al.
This “ahead of the curve” phenomenon has not gone unnoticed and has prompted some explanations. In a March 6, 2013, article in
The New York Times (which also has some cool charts), Catherine Rampell posits that available positions are staying unfilled longer,
while interview processes have become lengthier.
The next day, Rampell went into more detail about why we’re going “off the curve” in a New York Times Economix post. She cites
skills mismatch and a skills atrophy effect of the long-term unemployed affecting the ability of employers to fill positions (which she
explains aren’t full explanations, yet we would expect to see wages for highly coveted positions rise significantly).
Rampell goes back to the explanation many of us continue to hear from business contacts: employers are unwilling to fill vacant
positions because of economic and fiscal policy uncertainty. She quotes Stephen Davis of Chicago’s Booth School: “They’re taking
longer to fill vacancies because they just feel less need to fill jobs now,” Davis said. “They recognize that in a slack labor market,
there is an abundance of viable candidates. If something happens, and if they need to hire quickly, they know they can do that.
That’s harder in a tight labor market.”
So maybe as labor markets “tighten up,” or perhaps if the speed by which they tighten up quickens, we’ll get back on the Beveridge
curve. Only time, and several BLS releases, will tell.
By Patrick Higgins, an economist at the Atlanta Fed, and

Mark Carter, a senior economic analyst at the Atlanta Fed
March 19, 2013 in Economics, Employment, Labor Markets | Permalink