View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

MONEY, CREDIT, AND
BANKING LECTURE

From Obscurity to Notoriety: A Biography
of the Exchange Stabilization Fund
ANNA J. SCHWARTZ
The U.S. Treasury's $12 billion loan to Mexico in January 1995 from the Exchange
Stabilization Fund (ESF) brought to public notice the fund that had functioned in obscurity since its authorization by the Gold Reserve Act of January 31, 1934. The design of the ESF, as set forth in the statute, contributed to its obscurity. Its stated
mission was to stabilize the exchange value of the dollar, but it has also assumed a
role that had no mandate, that of lender to favored countries. ESFs intervention activities and the Federal Reserve's warehousing of ESF foreign currency assets are questionable. A statistical profile of the ESF accounts for the growth of its working
balance from $200 million in 1934 to $42.6 billion in assets in 1995.

THE EXCHANGE STABILIZATION FUND (ESF), an institution
that has been in operation since shortly after it was established by the Gold Reserve
Act of January 31, 1934, was remarkably little known before January 1995, when
the U.S. Treasury loaned Mexico $12 billion from the ESF as part of a rescue package. What made the loan notorious was that it did not require Congressional authorization but could be made at the discretion of the Secretary of the Treasury, with the
approval of the President. In February 1996, the Treasury Department announced
that it was suspending payment of interest on government securities in the ESF's
portfolio in order to create additional borrowing power for the government under the
debt ceiling that Congress was refusing to raise. These actions brought the fund to
public notice after it had remained so long in obscurity.
The fund began operations as of April 27, 1934, financed by $2 billion of the
$2.8 billion paper profit that the government realized from devaluation, that is, from
raising the price of gold to $35 an ounce from $20.67. This sum was deposited to
its account with the Treasurer of the United States (Treasury AR 1935, Exhibit 40,
p. 265). The fund was authorized to deal in gold and foreign exchange in order to
stabilize the exchange value of the dollar, to invest any portion of the fund not currently required for stabilization purposes in direct obligations of the United States,




136

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

and to add any earnings from sales and interest on its investments to the sum available for its use. 1
Of the $2 billion set aside for ESF capital, only $200 million was made available
for its working fund. The $1.8 billion was shown in the gold asset and liability statement of the Treasurer of the United States as gold credited to the ESF. The residual
$200 million was presumably initially deposited in a special account at the New
York Federal Reserve Bank, but by June 1934 the ESF had reduced the deposit by
investing $38 million in U.S. Treasury bonds, $20 million in gold (the bulk held at
the U.S. Assay Office), and $30 million in silver.
The ESF was established at a time when the dollar was pegged to the price of gold
but not to the exchange value of other currencies. It was expected to function in just
such an international monetary system. The expectation, however, proved false, and
the ESF had to adapt to the changing international monetary system over the six
decades that followed.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 1 I examine the design of
the ESF as set forth in the statute, in particular, the provisions that contributed to its
obscurity. In section 2 I describe the mission of the ESF as defined in the statute and
as the mission developed in the unexpected circumstances in which it operated. I
conclude the section with a statistical profile of the ESF that reflects the missions it
serves. In section 3 I assess the influence of the ESF in a broader context than its
role in the 1995 Mexican bailout.
1. DESIGN OF THE ESF

The act creating the ESF excluded it from the congressional appropriation process
once its initial capitalization was in place. It was intended to be self-financing, and
was not required to seek annual congressional funding for its operations.2 The selffinancing arrangement contributed to the secrecy of ESF actions, since the fund did
not have to justify its expenditures during annual appeals to Congress for appropriations. The ESF has increased the $200 million working balance it started with in
1. Harry Dexter White (Treasury Director of Monetary Research, 1938-45; Assistant Secretary of the
Treasury, 1945-46) was appointed on December 15, 1941, to manage the operation of the ESF and to act
as liaison between the Treasury and the State Department on all matters having a bearing on foreign
relations (Treasury AR 1942, Order No. 43, 335). In an unpublished, undated, memorandum on stabilization funds and international trade, he described stabilization funds as "a convenient instrument to countries" to insulate their economies from changes in "international balances, which immediately reflect
foreign disturbances and developments," and, more important, to influence day-to-day, week-to-week,
and seasonal fluctuations of exchange rates, "especially those arising from the operations of speculators,"
to facilitate "the transition from one level of exchange rates to another," and "within certain limits to set
the level of exchange rates . . . . The determination and maintenance of the external value of its currency is the main task of a Stabilization Fund" (see the Harry Dexter White Papers in the Seeley G. Mudd
Manuscript Library, Princeton University, box 2, item 6.e).
2. The suggestion that Congress might be requested to appropriate additional funds to be used by the
ESF, to my knowledge, was made on only one occasion. On January 14, 1948, in testimony before the
Senate Foreign Relations Committee on financing the European Recovery Program, Treasury Secretary
John W. Snyder proposed extending stabilization loans to European countries, adding, "At the appropriate time, Congress may then be requested to appropriate additional funds to be used by the United States
Stabilization Fund to make those loans" (Treasury A.R. 1948, p. 300).




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

:

137

1934 to $42 billion in June 1995.3 The statistical profile that I present at a later point
shows how the ESF achieved this increase.
The fund was conceived to operate in secrecy under the exclusive control of the
Secretary of the Treasury, with the approval of the President, "whose decisions shall
be final and not subject to review by any other officer of the United States" (PL
87-73, sec. 10(b)). The intention was to cloak foreign exchange market intervention. However, the Secretary of the Treasury was willing to reveal information on
stabilization loans to favored countries that the ESF negotiated—loans that had no
mandate in the statute yet essentially created a foreign affairs role for the Treasury.
The secrecy promoted two objectives. One was to conceal from the public and
Congress the exchange rates at which foreign currencies were bought and sold, particularly if they involved losses. A second objective was to permit the Treasury, if it
so desired, to conceal information about any other operations the ESF might undertake.4 The ESF in any event could base the secrecy of its operations on the British
Exchange Equalisation Account (EEA), formally initiated July 1, 1932. It was described as "an anonymous and secret body whose actions are not open to continuous
scrutiny and criticism" (Hall 1935, p. 81). The House of Commons did not know
and could not be told what the EEA was doing (Drummond 1981, p. 188). One
feature of the model was not, however, copied. To operate the EEA, Parliament
appropriated 175 million pounds in Treasury bills, an amount that in later years was
sizably increased (Sayers 1976, II, p. 427, pp. 487-88). 5
Suspicion of the purpose of the EEA was a motive for the establishment of the
ESF. U.S. officials believed that the EEA was used to depreciate the pound, not
to smooth fluctuations in its exchange rates, its official purpose (Drummond 1981,
p. 195). Each fund would have liked to know what the other's intentions and actions
were.
The secrecy in which both the ESF and the EEA were designed to operate was
subsequently modified. A 1977 amendment to the Gold Reserve Act (31 U.S.C.§
5302(b)) provided that an ESF loan or credit to a foreign entity or government for
more than six months in any twelve-month period required the President to give
Congress "a written statement that unique or emergency circumstances require the
loan or credit for more than six months." A 1978 amendment (31 U.S.C.§ 5302 (c)
(1)) provided for a monthly statement to the House and Senate Banking Committees
3. Unlike the Federal Reserve, the ESF is not required to transfer any of its earnings to the Treasury
General Fund.
4. One example of a use of the ESF other than for foreign exchange market intervention or stabilization loans is that, before fiscal 1980, "the administrative expenses for international programs, formerly
funded by the Exchange Stabilization Fund, became a separate international affairs appropriation" (Treasury AR 1980, p. 105).
Until 1980 ESF annual and quarterly reports show gross income, expenses to operate the ESF, and net
income. Thereafter, only ESF net income has been shown in its reports, as its expenses were shifted to
the general government budget.
5. In Britain lagged publication of EEA figures began in 1937. In June 1937, the Chancellor disclosed
total holdings of gold in the EEA and Issue Department on March 3 1 , and subsequently made similar
announcements every six months (Sayers 1976, II, p. 490). Foreign exchange balances on March 3 1 ,
1937, were stated as "not more than a trifling amount." They were actually about £7m.




138

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

by the Treasury "on all agreements made or renewed, all transactions occurring during the month, and all projected liabilities" of the ESF.
No change has occurred in the status of the Secretary's decisions as final, and not
subject to review. In testimony before the House Banking Committee in 1990, however, a Treasury official indicated that the department would be amenable to review
by Congress of this "veil of the greatest secrecy" (Mulford, Hearings 1990, p. 62).
The ESF's administrative expenses have been subject to the budget process since
1979. In addition, the ESF is audited annually, with the report originally submitted
to the President, not to Congress. Later, Section §5302 (c) provided that Congress
should also receive reports of the ESF's operations.
The response of the Republican Congress to the President's authorization of the
ESF offer of $20 billion in medium-term loans to Mexico in January 1995 less any
outstanding short-term loans and securities guarantees was to pass the Mexican Debt
Disclosure Act of April 5, 1995. It directed the administration to provide a broad
range of documents, some of them classified, about the bailout, before Mexico
could obtain more money from the ESF.
Although Congress has required the President to give it information about ESF
transactions, the constitutionality of the ESF has not been challenged. The ESF in
its original design as a creature of the Executive Branch, immune to legislative oversight, breaches the separation of powers. It is hard to believe that a fund with similar
powers would win legislative approval currently. In 1934, of course, New Deal legislation by and large was initiated by the administration, Congress rubber-stamping
what was put before it. Ordinary citizens have no standing to mount a challenge to
the constitutionality of the ESF, and sixty years after its creation, it is unlikely to
happen.

2. MISSION OF THE ESF

A. Foreign Exchange Market Intervention
The statute authorized the ESF to deal in gold6 and foreign exchange. To a limited
extent it was involved in such transactions during the 1930s, but it was not until
1961 that it became active in the foreign exchange market. The reason was that,
except during its initial years, the international monetary system in which the ESF
existed did not conform to the expectations of the designers of the agency.
The record of ESF foreign exchange market intervention thus falls into two periods: the period before 1962, when little opportunity for intervention arose, and the
period that followed, when the ESF enlisted the Federal Reserve to join it in inter6. Gold was held as an ESF asset only until 1975. See the discussion in section 2C. below. Note,
however, that at IMF gold auctions in 1977, the Treasury purchased gold which it sold to the ESF (Treasury AR 1977, p. 158). The official source does not explain why the ESF acquired this gold and how it
disposed of it. An entry for gold appears on the ESF balance sheet at the end of the first three quarters of
1977 and not thereafter.




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

:

139

vening in the foreign exchange market. I begin by summarizing the few highlights
of the first period.
Pre-1962 Intervention. The ESF dealt in foreign exchange only prior to World
War II. A statement by Treasury Secretary Morgenthau on February 11, 1935, apparently alluded to the ESF's first and only foreign exchange purchase until 1936—
sterling amounting to $21,000: "When we saw that the external value of the dollar
was rapidly going out of control, we put the stabilization fund to work on a moment's notice, with the result that for the past four weeks we have successfully managed the value of the dollar in terms of foreign currencies. The country can go about
its business with assurance that we are prepared to manage the external value of the
dollar as long as it may be necessary" (Treasury AR 1935, Exhibit 40, p. 235).
The decline in buying rates for the pound from November 1934 through March
1935 apparently led Morgenthau to believe that the British were deliberately depreciating the pound. Why he concluded that he had "successfully managed the value
of the dollar" is not obvious since the pound did not strengthen for six weeks following his self-congratulatory statement. Another example of Morgenthau's readiness
to believe that exchange rate movements were designed to be destabilizing when in
fact they were routine occurred in September 1936. The Russians then offered to sell
one million pounds which the ESF bought on the Treasury's off-hand assumption
that the sale was intended to drive down the pound, a result that its purchase
thwarted. That very day the Treasury changed its mind about the Russian motive
(Paris 1938, p. 31).
The secrecy of ESF operations was breached in June 1935, when the franc was
under attack and the president of the French central bank publicly thanked Morgenthau for the ESF purchase of francs, much to Morgenthau's embarrassment
(Paris 1938, p. 31).
Tripartite Agreement of 1936. In September 1936 the United States, United Kingdom, and French governments simultaneously issued declarations accepting a devaluation of the French franc and agreeing to use appropriate available resources to
avoid disturbance of international exchanges resulting from the readjustment. The
appropriate available resources were those of their exchange equalization funds, the
French having used more than half of the devaluation capital gain to establish a newly created stabilization fund. The three governments agreed to guarantee exchange
rates for twenty-four hours at a time, authorities of the stabilization funds announcing each morning the price at which they would convert into gold at the end of the
day on a reciprocal basis the foreign currency balances the others had acquired. The
United States, which had previously sold gold at $35 an ounce, plus handling
charges, only to gold-standard countries, announced it would sell gold to stabilization funds. The arrangement eliminated exchange risk for the authorities while preserving exchange-rate flexibility. Belgium, the Netherlands, and Switzerland were
soon added to the nations complying with the Tripartite Agreement and eligible to
buy gold from the United States.
By World War II the ESF had sold off modest amounts of sterling, francs, and




140

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

belgas it had acquired by participating in the Tripartite Agreement. During the war
the ESF held Swiss francs and balances in foreign currencies at depositories abroad.
It made the Swiss francs "available for governmental and humanitarian purposes,"
according to the Treasury's statement (Treasury AR 1945, p. 95).
Post-Bretton Woods Change in ESF. As early as 1943 the Treasury Department
tentatively proposed the establishment of an international stabilization fund postwar
to which all United Nations members would belong—the original model of the
IMF, of which Harry Dexter White was the designer (Treasury AR 1943, p. 116;
1944, pp. 96-97; 1945, pp. 95-96). 7
The U.S. Bretton Woods Agreement Act (PL 171-79) of July 31, 1945, made a
change with long-term effects on ESF operations. That change was the provision in
Sec. 7 that amended the Gold Reserve Act.8 The amendment directed the Secretary
of the Treasury to use $1.8 billion of the ESF capital (shown on the balance sheet as
cash in the form of gold held by the Treasurer of the United States) to pay part of the
$2,750 million U.S. subscription to the IMF.
By June 1946, the United States had paid $275,000 of its subscription (Treasury
AR 1946, p. 83). It completed payment of its subscription on February 26, 1947, in
the form of $687.5 million in gold, $280.5 million in cash, the remaining $1,782
million in nonnegotiable noninterest-bearing notes, payable on demand in dollars
when needed by the IMF (Treasury AR 1947, p. 48).
From 1946 until 1961 the ESF held no foreign exchange of the industrialized
countries. A role for an exchange stabilization fund would seem to have been obviated once the IMF was in place to manage exchange rates, but the ESF regarded the
IMF as needing its support.
Balance-of-Payments Concerns. A deterioration in the U.S. balance of payments,
as measured by outflows of gold and dollars to countries in surplus, aroused the
7. In 1941 Morgenthau instructed the Treasury staff to begin work on postwar international monetary
problems (Treasury AR 1945, Exhibit 51, p. 415). Harry Dexter White was the author of the U.S. Treasury draft of the Bretton Woods Agreement.
8. A second change made by the Bretton Woods Agreement Act was the creation by Section 4(a) of a
National Advisory Council "to coordinate the policies and operations of the representatives of the United
States on the Fund and the Bank and of all agencies of the Government which make or participate in
making foreign loans or which engage in foreign financial, exchange or monetary transactions." The
Secretary of the Treasury was chairman of the Council, and the Secretaries of State and Commerce, the
Chairman of the Board of Governors and of the Board of Trustees of the Export-Import Bank were members. The agencies covered by the act were to inform the Council of their activities. (As an aside, one
may question the appropriateness of including the Chairman of the Federal Reserve System in this roster
of Executive Branch representatives.)
According to the Council, "The International Monetary Fund was projected to help achieve stability of
exchange rates" (Treasury AR 1946, 302), hence might have been expected to preempt the ESF role. In
fact, the ESF role before 1962 was hardly diminished. Despite its exchange-rate implications, the AngloAmerican Loan Agreement dated December 6, 1945 (approved July 15, 1946, by joint resolution of
Congress), that authorized the Secretary of the Treasury to make $3,750 million available as a line of
credit to the United Kingdom, did not involve the ESF, presumably because the size of the loan was
clearly in excess of the capacity of the ESF (Treasury AR 1947, 51).
In May 1976, however, the ESF had the capacity to lend the Bank of England $1 billion. The Federal
Reserve lent a like amount (Treasury AR 1976, p. 86). Since the Federal Reserve had a $3 billion swap
line with the Bank of England, it could itself have provided the $2 billion. However, then Chairman
Arthur F. Burns insisted on ESF participation as the price for his agreement with a Treasury plan to
enforce Britishfinancialdiscipline (Burk and Cairncross 1992, p. 42).




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

: 141

concern of the Kennedy administration when it took office in January 1961. The loss
of gold to foreigners in that month was seen as an expression of a lack of confidence
in the administration's commitment to a dollar convertible into gold at a fixed price.
The twin goals became to eliminate the balance-of-payments deficit and to check
speculation against the dollar. To achieve the second goal the Treasury wanted to be
in the same position as other countries that influenced the exchange value of their
currencies. That required resources to buy and sell other currencies or, in official
parlance, sales and purchases of dollars.
To that end the ESF began to operate directly in the foreign exchange market. By
June 1961 it had bought spot $25.4 million sterling, $20.1 million D-marks, and
$65 million Swiss francs to counter threats against the dollar.
In March 1961, after revaluations of the D-mark and the Dutch guilder, the ESF
made forward sales of D-marks to drive down the forward premium on the mark
(discount on the dollar). The Treasury's forward mark commitments were liquidated
by early December; it used marks it had acquired in April 1961 from a German debt
repayment to the United States to settle in part forward contracts that were maturing
in the fall of 1961.
There were similar forward operations by the Treasury in Swiss francs and Dutch
guilders to bring down the premium on these currencies. As a response to the rise in
the exchange value of the Italian lira in 1961 to its upper limit against the dollar, the
Treasury took over forward lire contracts from the Italian foreign exchange office
and drew on a $150 million line of credit in lire it obtained by issuing three-month
certificates of indebtedness to support spot and forward operations in lire. As a result dollar accumulations in Italy were lessened.
Even these limited operations strained the resources of the ESF. In June 1961 it
had $200 million capital plus $136 million in net earnings accumulated over its
twenty-seven-year life. Average annual net earnings approximated $5 million, from
income on gold bullion sales, gold and exchange transactions, and interest on its
government securities portfolio. To finance its foreign exchange purchases of roughly $100 million in 1961, the ESF had reduced its account at the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York by $91 million and sold U.S. government securities.
The Treasury's immediate aim was to find ways to supplement ESF foreign currency balances.9 It did so first by persuading the G-10 countries to create a facility
that would expand the IMF's ability to lend. The IMF held only about $1.5 billion in
currencies other than dollars. The new facility, established in December 1961, was
the General Arrangements to Borrow (GAB), which provided the IMF with a
$6 billion line of credit from central banks in surplus to assist countries in deficit, in
particular, the United States. The U.S. quota in the IMF was nearly $6 billion, so it
could not draw enough to meet its reserve needs; the GAB was intended to serve as
a supplementary source of liquidity for the United States. The IMF would sell to the
United States for dollars foreign convertible currencies borrowed from other coun9. ESF balances of foreign currencies are to be distinguished from foreign currency balances held in
Treasury and in agency accounts that were acquired without purchase with dollars.




142

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

tries. These currencies would enable the United States to buy up dollars offered in
the market and to redeem dollars foreign central banks did not want to hold, thus
maintaining U.S. monetary gold reserves.
The Treasury next persuaded the Federal Reserve to serve as its partner in exchange market intervention. So begins the second period of ESF intervention
operations.
The Federal Reserve as ESF Partner. The Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) authorized open market transactions in foreign currencies for the account
of the Federal Reserve System on February 13, 1962. Before that date the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York served as the agent only of the ESF in executing its
limited foreign currency transactions. Since that date it has served both the ESF and
the Federal Reserve System. In support of its decision to engage in intervention operations, the FOMC cited "the need to supplement the relatively small resources
which the Treasury Stabilization Fund had available and had been using to defend
the dollar from speculative attack in the foreign exchange markets since 1961"
(Board AR 1962, p. 11).
Since this paper is a study of the ESF, 1 shall refer to the Federal Reserve's operations only in relation to the conduct of the ESF. The first imperative for the Federal
Reserve, once it determined that it had the legal authority to intervene, was to acquire foreign currencies for its future operations. It did so by purchasing from the
ESF in 1962 dollar equivalents of $32 million in D-marks, and of one-half million
dollars each in Swiss francs, Dutch guilders, and Italian lire to open accounts at the
central banks that issued these currencies.
This initial Federal Reserve purchase of currencies owned by the ESF has been
cited as the origin of "warehousing," the euphemism that later came into use to describe the provision of funds to the ESF outside the Congressional appropriations
process (Todd 1992, pp. 132-33). 10 It was not until 1977, however, that warehousing of foreign currencies for the ESF was formally authorized by the Federal Reserve. I shall discuss warehousing in a moment as one of the ways that ESF funds its
currency acquisitions.
During the Bretton Woods period, except for forward purchases and sales of foreign currencies, the ESF rarely participated in interventions, which were for the
most part financed by drawings on Federal Reserve swap lines.11 It was only beginning in 1978, after the formal authorization of warehousing that the ESF jointly intervened with the Federal Reserve. The prearranged share of the ESF varied from a

10. Two official statements support this interpretation. In Section VI on "Methods of Acquiring and
Selling Foreign Currencies" (see the document, "Authorization Regarding Open Market Transactions in
Foreign Currencies"), the FOMC included transactions with the ESF. In Section 4, "Transactions in Forward Exchange" (see the document, "Guidelines for System Foreign Currency Operations") referred to
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, where authorized, taking over from the ESF "outstanding contracts for forward sales or purchases of authorized currencies" (Board AR, 1962, pp. 59, 63).
11. These were lines of credit the Federal Reserve established with the central banks of the leading
European countries providing for the right of the United States to draw on a foreign currency up to a
specified ceiling for a specified term, and the reciprocal right of the foreign central bank to draw on U.S.
dollars at the current exchange rate for a matching sum and term.




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

: 143

little more than 10 percent of the foreign currency purchase or sale to half (more
than half in the case of marks, since the ESF had a swap line with the Bundesbank),
and the Federal Reserve took the remaining share. Shares tended to be equal during
the limited interventions of 1981-85. Since 1987, shares have varied from equal
percentages to three-quarters for the ESF, one-quarter for the Federal Reserve. In
addition to its swap line with the Bundesbank, the ESF also had a line with the
central bank of the Netherlands, 1962-69.
The ESF as Principal. There are nuances in the relation of the ESF as principal to
its agent, the Federal Reserve. Paul Volcker emphasizes that the Treasury does not
have authority to instruct the Federal Reserve to spend its own money on intervention and to take the attendant risks, and that the Treasury would be reluctant to intervene over strong objections of the Federal Reserve (Volcker and Gyohten 1992,
p. 234). The FOMC, at its March 27, 1990, meeting, argued in favor of continuing
to intervene, despite misgivings about the effectiveness of intervention, as a means
of moderating Treasury initiatives (Federal Open Market Committee, 1990).
At the start in 1962 of Federal Reserve participation for its own account, it was an
eager agent, ready to support the principal and enthusiastic about defending the dollar under the Bretton Woods system. Even as disillusion with the results emerged
when foreign currency balances ballooned in the late 1980s, there was no consensus
in the FOMC to end its supporting role. It clearly did not want to challenge the
Treasury's role as its superior.
Sources of ESF Funds. Since the ESF sought to expand its operations after 1961,
despite limited resources, it developed a range of means to do so. The Treasury in
addition to the establishment of the GAB relied for the most part on other forms of
borrowing that of course had to be repaid.
One means was a U.S. drawing on its IMF quota, by which it purchased foreign
currencies for dollars, payable over a three- to five-year period. These drawings that
were turned over to the ESF occurred during 1964-66 ($1.6 billion), 1968 ($0.2
billion), 1970-72 ($1.7 billion), and 1978 ($3 billion).
Warehousing by the Federal Reserve of ESF foreign currencies was formally authorized on January 17, 1977, for up to $1.5 billion, increased in 1978 first to $1.75
and then to $5 billion, limited to twelve months, with no limit on the term in 1980.
The ceiling was raised to $10 billion in 1989, and to $15 billion in 1990. The
amounts held in the warehouse tended to rise with the authorized amounts. In 1991
the ceiling was lowered to $10 billion and in February 1992 to $5 billion. The ESF
repurchased amounts in the warehouse in 1990-92 when it was emptied. The ceiling was raised to $20 billion in January 1995 at the time of the Mexican bailout. No
use has, however, been made of the warehouse since 1992.
Another source of ESF funds was the sale of Treasury securities denominated in
foreign currencies. These issued in 1962-74 were known as Roosa bonds and in
1978-79 as Carter bonds, in the former years to official institutions in half a dozen
countries (Austria, Belgium, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, and Switzerland) and the
Bank of International Settlements, in the later years to German and Swiss private
investors. Net amounts issued in different foreign currencies in the former period




144

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

totaled $4.67 billion, $6.44 billion in the later period. By 1983 all issues had been
redeemed, with losses on Swiss francs in 1972-73, 1978-79, and 1981. The ESF's
net losses in 1972-73 were $165 million; in 1978-79, $1 billion; and in 1981, $573
million.
The one new source of funding that created a net addition to the ESF's resources
was the issue of Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) by the IMF. Allocations to the
Treasury in 1970-72 amounted to $2.29 billion, in 1977 to $0.87 billion, and in
1980-81 to $1.73 billion. The Federal Reserve monetized SDRs for ESF use, crediting dollar amounts of the SDRs to ESF deposit balances at the Federal Reserve,
and these dollar amounts appear as SDR assets on ESF balance sheets. Table 1
shows the importance of the SDR contribution to the growth of ESF resources.
Record of Intervention. During the Bretton Woods era intervention was directed
to protect the value of dollars held by foreign central banks in order to deter their
exchange for U.S. gold. Rather than sell gold, the United States borrowed foreign
currencies to buy dollars held abroad. To repay the borrowed foreign currencies, the
proceeds of the sale of Treasury bonds denominated in foreign currencies were
used. As the decade of the 1960s progressed, the authorities intervened massively in
every major currency. The defense of the dollar during the Bretton Woods period,
however, failed, since the policies to correct the U.S. balance of payments and dollar overvaluation were inadequate. When the United States closed the gold window

TABLE 1
PRINCIPAL NONCASH ASSETS OF THE ESF AT FIVE-YEAR INTERVALS, 1935-95
Principal Noncash Assets
Total
Assetsa

U.S. Government
and Foreign
Securities

End of
June

(1)

(2)

1934
1935
1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995

200.0
205.8
244.4
290.4
301.5
314.7
330.2
517.4
2,560.8
4,038.8
11,354.0
12,878.1
26,346.9
42,572.9

Foreign
Exchange

Gold

Special
Drawing
Rights

(4)

(5)

($ Millions)

38.2
26.8
10.4
20.4
20.0
25.0
60.0
317.6
45.2
1,451.4
4,036.1
3,332.3
1,021.0
410.9

(3)

0
0.02
19.12
24.09 b
27.60
0
25.00 c
80.67
409.29
0.27
3,251.71
3,228.48
13,060.12
28,997.18e

50.6 d
0
86.0
80.0
99.9
52.2
40.4
115.2
522.0
0
0
0
0
0

0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
957.2
2,417.7
3,781.7
6,196.1
10,490.5
11,868.6

NOTES:

a. Excludes $1.8 billion in gold account at Treasurer of U.S., 1934-45, used in 1947 to pay for part of U.S. subscription to IMF.
b. Includes $5 million due from Government of Cuba.
c. Due from Argentine central bank.
d. Includes $30 million in silver.
e. Includes Mexican pesos valued at $9 billion, and foreign securities.
Source: Cols. 1-5, Treasury Bulletin, for 1940-1995: AR Treasury, 1940, p. 789, for 1934-35.




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

: 145

on August 15, 1971, it turned from defense of the dollar valued in gold at $35 an
ounce to dollar devaluation.
With the demise of Bretton Woods and the coming of floating exchange rates, the
ESF and the Federal Reserve have nevertheless persisted in efforts to manage exchange rates, despite the interval from 1981 to early 1985 when intervention lost
political favor. The record since then suggests that large and reversible transitory
movements of some exchange rates and widening of bid-ask spreads may be temporarily reduced by intervention. There is no indication, however, that the frequent
action of the U.S. authorities to quell disorderly markets has had any permanent
effect.
Whether the dollar is deemed strong or weak, intervention does not deal with the
fundamental economic conditions that underlie medium-term changes in the exchange value of the dollar. The feared changes of medium-term variations in the
dollar's exchange value have not materialized. The supposedly grossly overvalued
dollar in 1981-85 did not deindustrialize the U.S. economy and usher in a service
economy of low-income occupations. Similarly, concern that a weak dollar would
induce domestic inflation has not been substantiated. In general, the costs of floating
exchange rates should be compared to the costs of the alternative, which is fixed or
pegged exchange rates, vulnerable to speculative attacks and bigger adjustments.
Why Warehousing? Two aspects of intervention merit comment. One is the practice of warehousing by the Federal Reserve and the Treasury. It seems to contravene
the statutory prohibition of the direct financing of the Treasury by the Federal Reserve (Todd 1992, pp. 140-41). The transcript of the FOMC's March 27, 1990,
meeting reveals members' doubts about the legality of warehousing, despite the
claim that the Federal Reserve General Counsel in 1962 had issued an opinion that
justified warehousing as an open market purchase of foreign exchange from the
Treasury. The concern was that warehousing removed from Congress the appropriation power, eliminating the necessity for the Treasury to turn to Congress to obtain
funds it did not have to acquire foreign currencies. Nevertheless, at that meeting the
FOMC increased the limit on warehousing from $10 billion to $15 billion.12
As mentioned earlier, the ceiling in 1992 was reduced to $5 billion when the ESF
repurchased its foreign currencies in the warehouse. However, the role of warehousing remains very much in question, since the FOMC raised the upper limit to $20
12. Chairman Greenspan was eloquent in 1991 in opposing the Treasury's proposal that would authorize the Federal Reserve Banks to lend up to $25 billion to the FDIC to absorb losses sustained by the
Bank Insurance Fund in resolving failed banks. He stated: "Not only would use of the Reserve Banks for
funding the BIF serve no economic purpose, it could create potential problems of precedent and perception of the Federal Reserve. In particular, the proposal involves the Federal Reserve directly funding the
government. The Congress has always severely limited and, more recently, has forbidden the direct
placement of Treasury debt with the Federal Reserve, apparently out of concern that such a practice could
compromise the independent conduct of monetary policy and would allow the Treasury to escape the
discipline of selling its debt directly to the market. . . . In addition, if implementation of the proposal
created a precedent for further loans to the BIF or to other entities, the liquidity of the Federal Reserve's
portfolio could be reduced sufficiently to create concerns about the ability of the Federal Reserve to control the supply of reserves and, thereby, to achieve its monetary policy objectives" (FRB June 1991,
pp. 4 3 5 - 3 6 ) .
Chairman Greenspan has not been equally opposed to Federal Reserve loans to the ESF. In what respect does warehousing differ from lending to the BIF?




146

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

billion on January 31, 1995 (FRB May 1995, p. 447). The expansion of the warehouse was intended to help the ESF participate in the Mexican rescue program but,
in the event, it has not availed itself of this provision. Just as the courts have not
tested the constitutionality of the ESF, there has been no test of the legality of
warehousing.
Why Intervention? Empirical evidence offers no support for intervention operations. No theoretical model is able to predict exchange rate movements at short horizons, let alone explain exchange rate movements ex post. What justifies the hubris
of monetary authorities that they know the secret of the foreign exchange market?
In a recent essay the president and senior vice president of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond argue the case for separating the Federal Reserve completely
from foreign exchange operations on the ground that they imperil the credibility of
monetary policy (Broaddus and Goodfriend 1996). They do not, however, recommend that the nation should forsake foreign exchange operations. In my view, intervention has proved to be a pointless activity, so I see no purpose in a continued role
for either the Federal Reserve or the ESF in this connection.

B. ESF as Lender
The ESF early on discovered a purpose for its existence other than exchange market intervention—stabilizing not the value of the dollar in exchange for the currencies of the major industrialized countries, but lending dollars to LDCs to stabilize
their currencies, initially to compensate for the damaging effects of the U.S. 1934
Silver Purchase Act. Before 1961 the only foreign currencies in the post-World War
II ESF portfolio were currencies of LDCs with which it negotiated intermittent stabilization loan programs, a form of foreign aid.
What was the genesis of the idea of stabilization loans? The prototype may have
been the stabilization credits extended to central banks during 1924-31 to facilitate
their return to the gold standard. Benjamin Strong and Montagu Norman actively
promoted the stabilization of the newly restored European exchange rate structure
post-World War I by means of credits from the Federal Reserve and other central
banks (Clarke 1967).
The selection of countries to which the ESF extended loans was obviously a political decision made by the Treasury. Harry Dexter White's memoranda, written between 1936 and 1944, found among his unpublished papers, supporting loans to
various countries, attest to his influence on which ones the ESF selected during this
period. The countries included China, Mexico, other Latin American countries, and
Russia (Harry Dexter White Papers in the Seeley G. Mudd Manuscript Library,
Princeton University, box 1, items 3a, 3b; box 6, items 14a, 14b, 14L, 19a; box 11,
item 28a).
Stabilization Loans. Ten Latin American countries at one time or another during
the period 1936-61 had exchange stabilization agreements, often with renewals.
The countries in this group were Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Cuba, Ecuador,
Mexico, Nicaragua, Paraguay, and Peru. Mexico had the longest record of agree-




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

:

147

ments, the initial ones motivated by the disturbing effects of the U.S. Silver Purchase Act of June 19, 1934, which led to a trebling of the market price of silver
between 1933 and 1935.
During World War II the mission of the ESF was expanded to include provision of
dollars to countries deemed worthy of such assistance for their importance in the
war effort. In Europe only Iceland had an exchange stabilization agreement, but the
ESF provided the USSR with dollars during World War II in exchange for gold. In
Asia there were agreements with China with respect to silver, gold, and yuan from
1936 to 1943. The ESF had wartime agreements with India, Iran, and Egypt to sell
gold in exchange for local currencies for use by U.S. personnel stationed there. It
provided Liberia with U.S. currency when it converted its monetary system from
British coins.
During the postwar years ESF stabilization loan programs were combined with
IMF standby arrangements, Export-Import Bank (EXIM bank) foreign currency
credits, and assistance from the International Cooperation Administration and the
Agency for International Development that was established in 1961. These overlapping authorities represented different executive departments including Commerce
and State. The ESF contribution to these credit packages was small. One advantage
of combining the ESF loan with others was that the latter often provided the LDC
recipient with the means to repay the ESF.
In the period since 1962 stabilization agreements for the first time provided for
reciprocal swap facilities. Previously, when the ESF gave dollars to LDC countries,
a provision of the agreement required the country to repurchase in dollars any of its
currency that the ESF might have acquired. Many of the same countries that had
stabilization agreements with the ESF before 1962 were again represented in the
later period. There were also some newcomers in Europe, Asia, and Africa, but
Latin American countries predominated. As was characteristic of the earlier Bretton
Woods years, ESF agreements were usually combined with loans from international
or other U.S. agencies.
Latin American countries with stabilization agreements during part or all of the
period included Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guyana, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua,
Panama, Peru, and Venezuela. European countries included Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Yugoslavia. Jamaica was the sole West Indies country, the Philippine
Republic the sole Asian country, Nigeria the sole African country with a stabilization agreement.
An appendix, available on request from the author, presents the published information in official sources about the stabilization and other agreements the ESF
signed with foreign countries before and after 1962. A notable omission is any reference to the interest rate that these countries were required to pay for dollar loans.
The country with the longest and most continuous record of ESF agreements, as
in the period before 1962, is Mexico. A knowledgeable observer has noted: "Since
1976 [in fact, much earlier, as shown in the appendix], the international financial
community, led by the U.S. authorities, has come to the financial assistance of Mex-




148

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

ico on numerous occasions. The size and novelty of these operations may have suggested to investors that Mexico was a different, if not unique, sovereign borrower"
(Truman 1996, p. 202). In the case of Mexico, since 1967, the Federal Reserve as
well as the ESF have duplicate short-term loan programs.
Examination of the list of countries that have been granted loans over the years,
as detailed in the appendix leads me to doubt that they have resulted in stabilization.
What evidence is there that repeated extensions of loans helps these countries to
advance their economies? The message of the loan package seems to be that mismanaged countries have a friend at the ESF, which will arrange a rescue. Servicing
and amortizing the loans seem to add to the borrowers' problems. Loans may be a
fruitless policy for countries that have yet to develop institutions that observe the
eternal financial verities of sound fiscal and monetary management.

C. Conspectus on ESF Asset Holdings
As the preceding discussion has shown, the biography of the ESF falls into two
periods. That break is also reflected in its statistical profile (Table 1). It began operations in 1934 with $200 million. By 1960 it held $330 million in assets, the cumulative net income of $130 million over the twenty-five intervening years accounting
for the increase. The slow growth was indicative of the atrophy of a foreign exchange role for the ESF during its initial quarter century and the rise of stabilization
lending that it nurtured to fill the void.
The principal noncash asset of the ESF in the first period was its gold account,
acquired for transactions with foreign monetary authorities and with the market, as
the statute authorized. The ESF continued to hold gold in a special account of the
Secretary of the Treasury at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York until December
9, 1974 (Treasury AR 1975, Exhibit 54, p. 501). The Treasury on that date consolidated three different gold accounts, including ESF gold, in its general account in
anticipation of the gold auctions it conducted in 1975 and 1978-79. ESF gold was
sold to the Treasury at its par value. The gold category was then eliminated from
ESF assets.
U.S. government securities and foreign exchange assets were minor components
of ESF noncash assets in the first period. Foreign exchange included currencies of
LDCs at par, not market, values, and minimal amounts of currencies of industrialized countries.
It was in the second period, after 1960, that the main growth in ESF assets occurred. By 1995 ESF assets amounted to $42.6 billion. Of the increase of $42.3
billion post-1960, the main contributors to faster growth of ESF assets were an increase of $29 billion in foreign exchange assets and the addition of the new asset of
Special Drawing Rights (SDRs) amounting to $11.9 billion. Though listed as SDRs
on the ESF balance sheet, they are ordinary dollar amounts, available for any use
the ESF chooses.
In addition to the $4.9 billion IMF allocation to the United States, the ESF acquired $2.6 billion SDRs from other IMF participants (IMF 1995, p. 53). The differ-




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

:

149

ence between the 1995 dollar value of SDRs and the dollar value of the initial acquisitions represents the net increase in SDR valuation in dollar terms from parity in
1970 to $1.49 in 1995.
Accompanying growth of cumulative net income amounting to $26.6 billion in
the second period was an increase in foreign exchange asset growth, which was a
policy objective, presumably reflecting the influence of Treasury officials who negotiated the Plaza Agreement of September 1985 and the Louvre Agreement of February 1987. The increases in foreign exchange assets was concentrated in the period
after the late 1980s. The assets encompassed major country currencies as well as
those of LDCs.
Holdings of U.S. government and foreign securities rose relative to their representation in the portfolio in the earlier period, but at most accounted for a third of
total assets during the second period. Because ESF investments in foreign securities
were either combined with U.S. government securities or foreign exchange or, if
separately shown, assigned the label of other securities, it is not possible to present
them as a separate category.

D. Rate of Return on ESF Assets
Table 2 shows capital gains (losses) on gold before 1975 and amounts on foreign
exchange, minor before 1975, more substantial since. If the table were annual,
losses on foreign exchange, totaling $1.7 billion, would be shown for 1972-73,
1978-79, and 1981. These losses were incurred, as mentioned above, when the liability for U.S. Treasury securities denominated in foreign currencies was extinguished. Interest earnings on foreign exchange, and on U.S. government and
foreign securities are separate categories.
Finally, the table shows SDR valuation changes and interest earnings on SDRs.
The IMF currently uses a basket of five currencies for determining SDR valuation. The same basket is also used to determine the interest rate on SDRs. Before
1981 the basket included sixteen currencies. The valuation is a weighted average of
the exchange rates of the five currencies.
The ESF posts a liability item of SDR certificates that it owes the Federal Reserve
for its SDR holdings, and a liability item of SDR allocations, representing its obligation that would arise if the IMF were to cancel SDRs. To date no cancellation has
occurred. The sum of these liability items on June 30, 1995, was $15.7 billion.
Deducting that amount from reported assets of $42.6 billion establishes ESF net
worth as no more than $26.9 billion on that date.
Table 3 shows the rate of return of net income on total ESF assets, 1935-95, and
of total return on individual assets, summing capital gains (losses) and interest earnings of the asset categories. The data for the separate asset categories are available
only beginning 1940.
The rate of return on total ESF assets at the five-year intervals the table presents,
with three exceptions, varied between less than 1 and 4 percent. Exceptional years
are 1945 when there was a windfall on gold holdings, and 1990 and 1995, when




150 : MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

TABLE 2
CAPITAL GAINS (LOSSES) AND INTEREST EARNINGS ON ESF ASSETS AT FIVE-YEAR INTERVALS,

1940-95 ($ MILLIONS)
Interest Earnings on
Capital Gains (Losses) on
Year Ending
June 30

1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995

Gold

3.8
26.9
2.6
1.1
2.3
0.2
(22.8)

Foreign
Exchange

0.40
a
0.10
a
a
a
a
(0.50)
271.20
(125.90)
1020.20
2963.60

Change in
SDR
Valuation

32.8
(39.8)
(9.7)
202.9
295.5

SDRs

U.S. Government
and Foreign
Securities

Foreign
Exchange
Balances

0.1
(65.7)
(104.1)
75.5
308.8
153.8

0.2
0.5
0.5
0.6
3.0
19.8
0.5
162.1
553.2
244.3
73.9
313.8

0.3
a
0.5
a
0.5
4.4
56.6
(0.2)
11.4
165.4
826.0
799.6

NOTE: a. Less than one hundred thousand.

foreign exchange, securities investments, and SDRs all yielded 5-9 percent returns.
I have not seen an explanation in official sources of the gold windfall in 1945.
Although there were losses on foreign exchange and SDR revaluation in the first
quarter of 1990, for the year ending June 30, 1990, the results were highly favorable. Similarly, foreign exchange losses and losses on SDR revaluation were recorded in the last quarter of 1994, but for the year ending June 30, 1995, the results
were even more favorable than in 1990. In the quarter ending September 30, 1995,
the last one for which information has been released, the ESF sustained a $2 billion
realized loss on its foreign exchange portfolio and a $168 million loss for change in
valuation of its SDR holdings.
Foreign exchange assets in 1990 included besides marks and yen, small amounts
of sterling and Swiss francs, and an assortment of LDC currencies (Mexican pesos,
Hungarian forints, Guyana dollars, Hondurian lempuras). By 1995 the portfolio was
restricted to marks and yen and Mexican pesos. With a weak dollar, the value of
foreign currencies appreciated, and increases in SDR assets accompanied increases
in revaluations of the SDR against the dollar between 1990 and 1995.
The ESF does not pursue positive rate of return results. Negative results apparently are compatible with the missions it fulfills. It has not, however, consistently
lost money.
3. AN ASSESSMENT OF THE INFLUENCE OF THE ESF

The ESF was originally established for a two-year period and subsequently given
repeated two-year extensions until it was made permanent. It was not exposed to
scrutiny by either Congress or by Democratic and Republican Administrations until
the events of January 1995.







TABLE 3
RATE OF RETURN ON TOTAL ESF ASSETS AND PRINCIPAL NONCASH ASSETS
Gold and Foreign Exchange
Year
Ending
June 30

1935
1940
1945
1950
1955
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995

:s and Investments
Securities

Total a
Return

Asset
($M illions)

(1)
0.02
105.12
104.09
127.50
52.20
65.40
195.87
931.29
0.27
3,251.71
3,228.48
13,060.12
28,997.18d

Asset
Col. 2/
Col. 1

(2)
4.7
26.9
3.2
1.1
2.8
4.6
23.8
-0.7
282.6
37.5
1,846.2
3,763.l d

(3)
0.04
0.26
0.03
0.02
0.04
0.02
0.03
-2.59
0.09
0.01
0.14
0.13£1

Col. 5/
Col. 4

($ Millions )

(4)
26.8
10.4
20.4
20.0
25.0
60.0
317.6
45.2
1,451.4
4,036.1
3,332.3
1,071.0
410.9d

SDRs

Total b
Return

(5)
0.2
0.5
0.5
0.6
3.0
19.8
0.5
162.1
553.2
244.3
73.9
313.8d

(6)
0.02
0.02
0.03
0.02
0.05
0.06
0.01
0.11
0.14
0.07
0.07
0.76d

Totalc
Return

Asset
($ Millions)

(7)

957.2
2,417.7
3,781.7
6,196.1
10,490.5
11,868.6

Total
Assets
Col. 8/
Col. 7

(8)

0.1
-32.9
-143.9
65.8
511.7
449.3

NOTES:

a. Sum of capital gains (losses) and interest earnings on combined gold and foreign exchange assets (1940-70), thereafter foreign exchange only.
b. Interest earnings on combined U.S. and foreign government securities.
c. Sum of change in SDR valuation and SDR interest earnings.
d. Foreign exchange includes foreign securities, so col. 4 is understated.
If one combines cols. 1 and 4 and cols. 2 and 5, the rate of return is 0.12 (3,538.9/29,408.08).

(9)

0.00
-0.01
-0.04
0.01
0.05
0.04

Total Net
Income
Col. 11/
Col. 10

($ Millions)

(10)
205.8
244.4
290.4
301.5
314.7
330.2
517.4
2,560.8
4,038.8
11,354.0
12,898.1
26,346.9
42,572.9

(11)

5.6
5.7
26.8
2.4
0.3
4.6
20.6
27.9
114.7
479.0
349.7
2,431.8
4,526.3

(12)
0.03
0.02
0.09
0.01
0.00
0.01
0.04
0.01
0.03
0.04
0.03
0.09
0.11

152

: MONEY, CREDIT, AND BANKING

The belated attention paid to the ESF because of its role in the Mexican bailout
misses a broader measure of its influence. The true significance of the ESF lies not
in its domestic aspect—a small agency in the U.S. Treasury Department, engaged
in masterminding foreign exchange market intervention and acting as a benevolent
lender to small troubled countries. What is more noteworthy is the influence of ESF
practice on the way the postwar international monetary system, with the IMF at its
center, has operated.
The ESF appears to be the prototype of the IMF. "The germ of the idea of combining regulatory and financial provisions that is so prominent a feature of the IMF"
has been linked to the bilateral ESF agreement of November 1941 with Mexico.
Like the ESF agreement, "the basic transactions of the IMF to assist its member
countries also involve exchanges of currency" (Gold 1988, p. 1127). The IMF is
said to have adopted the ESF form of exchanges of the currencies of the two contracting parties and not loans by one party to the other, to avoid the "indignity that
might seem to attach to borrowing." This may be IMF decorum, but no one believes
that the exchange of pesos for dollars is a transaction other than a loan of dollars.
The legacy of the ESF is that lending programs dominate the operation of the
IMF. Support for weak currencies that the IMF provides raises problems of moral
hazard. Whether IMF lending has good or bad consequences is a question beyond
the scope of this paper.13
LITERATURE CITED
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Annual Report. 1934-94.
Broaddus, Jr., J. Alfred, and Marvin Goodfriend. "Foreign Exchange Operations and the
Federal Reserve." Annual Report of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, 1996.
Burk, Kathleen, and Alec Cairncross. 'Goodbye, Great Britain': The 1976 IMF Crisis. New
Haven: Yale University Press, 1992.
Calomiris, Charles W., and David C. Wheelock. "Was the Great Depression a Watershed for
American Monetary Policy?" NBER Pre-Conference version, 1996.
Clarke, Stephen V. O. Central Bank Cooperation, 1924-31. New York: Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, 1967.
Drummond, Ian M. The Floating Pound and the Sterling Area, 1931-1939. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1981.
Federal Open Market Committee Meeting. Transcript. Processed. March 27, 1990.
Federal Reserve Bulletin. 1980-96.
Gold, Joseph. "Mexico and the Development of the Practice of the International Monetary
Fund." World Development 16 (No. 10, 1988), 1127-42.
Hall, N. F. The Exchange Equalisation Account. London: Macmillan, 1935.
International Monetary Fund, Treasurer's Department. Users' Guide to the SDR: A Manual of
Transactions and Operations in SDRs. Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund,
1995.
13. To balance the suggestion made here of a greater ESF influence than is commonly assigned to it.
let me note an erroneous attribution of greater ESF influence than it actually had. A recent paper asserts
that the ESF played a domestic monetary role in the control of excess reserves in 1936-37 (Calomiris and
Wheelock 1996). Inactive gold was held in the Treasury's General Fund, not the ESF.




ANNA J. SCHWARTZ

: 153

Mulford, David. "Review of Treasury Department's Conduct of International and Foreign
Policy." Hearings before the House of Representatives Committee on Banking, Finance,
and Urban Affairs. Serial No. 101-63, 101st Cong. 2d Sess. August 14, 1990.
Paris, James D. Monetary Policies of the United States, 1932-1938. New York: Columbia
University Press, 1938.
Sayers, Richard S. The Bank of England, 1891-1944. 3 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1976.
Todd, Walker F. "Disorderly Markets: The Law, History, and Economics of the Exchange
Stabilization Fund and U.S. Foreign Exchange Market Intervention." Research in Financial Services Public and Private Policy, vol. 4, pp. 111—79. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press,
1992.
Treasury Bulletin. 1940-1996.
Truman, Edwin M. "The Mexican Peso Crisis: Implications for International Finance." Federal Reserve Bulletin 82 (March 1996), 199-209.
U.S. Secretary of the Treasury. Annual Report on the State of the Finances. 1934-1979.
Volcker, Paul, and Toyoo Gyohten. Changing Fortunes: The World's Money and the Threat to
American Leadership. New York: Times Books, 1992.