View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

JOINT TREASURY-^FEOERALMSERVE

STUDY OP THE U.S. GOVERNMENT
SECIJRITIES

MARKE?

STAFF STUDIES-PART

3

J-6.6

7

-r

JOINT TREASURY-FEDERAL RESERVE

GOVERNMENT
MARKET
SECURITIES

STUDY OF THE
Staff

U.S.

Studies— Part 3

December 1973

NOTE TO READERS
The papers

in this pamphlet were prepared as
background material for a joint TreasuryFederal Reserve study of the U.S. Government
securities market initiated in early 1966 to
evaluate how that market was functioning in
light of the institutional and public policy
changes that had taken place in the first half

of the 1960's. The final Report of the Joint
Treasury-Federal Reserve Study of the

Government

U.S.

Securities

Market was

published in April 1969.

For the most part the individual papers do
not include data or

comments concerning the

period after mid-1967.

^

Library of Congress Catalog Card

this pamphlet may be obtained from Pubh'cations Services, Division of Administrative Services,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Copies of

D.C. 20551. The price is $1.00 per
copy; in quantities of 10 or more sent to one ad-

Washington,

Number 76-606840

85 cents each. Remittances
payable to the order of the Board
the Federal Reserve System in a
at par in U.S. currency. (Stamps
dress,

accepted.)

should be

made

of Governors of

form collectible
and coupons not

CONTENTS

NEW TECHNIQUES
IN DEBT MANAGEMENT
FROM THE LATE
THROUGH 1966

1

1950's

Lawrence Banyas

DEALER PROFITS AND

11

CAPITAL AVAILABILITY IN THE
GOVERNMENT SECURITIES INDUSTRY,
1955-65

U.S.

William G. Colby,

Jr.

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS
IN THE

117

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES MARKET
Felix T. Davis

and Matthew

J.

Hoey

Lawrence Banyas
Deputy Assistant to the Secretary
U.S. Treasury Department

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

CONTENTS

I.

II.

INTRODUCTION
HISTORICAL
Innovations

in

5

SUMMARY
Treasury

5
5

Bills

Issuance of Coupon Securities
Cash Refunding
Advance Refunding
Bond Auctions

at a

Discount

Participation Certificates

Innov.'^ons
III.

in

Nonmarketabie Issues

MARKET IMPACT AND ANALYSIS OF MAJOR NEW TECHNIQUES

22

Innovations

Participation Certificates

22
27
30
47

APPENDIX

53

Treasury
Cash Refunding
Advance Refunding

IV.

7
8
10
14
15
18

in

Bills

NEW TECHNIQUES

I.

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

INTRODUCTION

As

in

new techniques and innomanagement were demeet specific needs. Some of these

other

veloped to

needs were already well established by the late
1950's while others evolved
related

later,

but

all

management

The

objectives.

basic functions of

Of equal imdebt management in

refinance maturing obligations.

portance

is

the role of

—

major national policy goals promotion and maintenance of sound noninflationachieving

ary growth in the U.S.

economy and progress

of subsidiary objectives

may

also

To

and maintain a well-balanced

achieve

debt structure;

To

provide debt instruments that are de-

signed to meet market and nonmarket require-

ments;

To minimize the interference of
management actions with

Treasury debt management are to borrow for
expenditures not covered by revenues and to

number

be cited:

are

fundamental and continuing debt

to

A

fields,

vations in Treasury debt

ury's debt

tion of Federal Reserve

To

the execu-

monetary policy; and

minimum

hold interest costs to a

a framework consistent with

A

the Treas-

later addition to these

all

within

other goals.

aims has been the

coordination of the financings of Federal agen-

toward balancing our country's international

cies

accounts.

context of broad economic policy objectives.

II.

IN

TREASURY BILLS

Toward the fall of 1958 the Treasury became increasingly concerned over the lack of
receptivity in the market, even to short-term
offerings.

Faced with the huge increase

deficit in

fiscal

that

much

of

bills.

At

money market

area of

that time, only 91 -day bills

were being issued except for the seasonal taxanticipation

fered each

bills.

week

amount oftotal volume

In expanding the
to increase the

of the 91 -day bills outstanding, the Treasury

would have run the

the

Treasury within the

6-month bill in December
bill was not intended as
13-week bill. While the
shorter bills were reduced,

risk of not

having the of-

by subscriptions. Inby lengthening the maturity of the bills,
the same amount offered each week would be

fering adequately covered
stead,

able to support a proportional increase in the

The 26-week

1958.

a substitute for the

weekly offerings of
they were continued

most liquid

for those investors preferring the

Treasury borrowing instrument.

Developing a

out of necessity, would have

to be financed in the

Treasury

in the

1959, the Treasury felt

year

it,

those of

SUMMARY

HISTORICAL

INNOVATIONS

with

cycle

full

of

6-month

bills

while cutting back on 3-month offerings was a

slow process in a period of pressing

relatively

and

immediate

1-year
in

bill

Thus,

needs.

cycle involving

the

quarterly

amounts of $2

billion

each issuance was introduced in the spring

of

1959 to

as

little

offered

fill

that gap. In order to interfere

as possible with certificates generally
in

the

quarterly

refinancings

at

the

midpoints of February, May, August, and No-

vember,

mature

the
at

1-year

midmonth

bills

were

designed

in January,

to

April, July,

and October.
During the period through 1959, the currencies of most industrialized countries of the free
world had become convertible or fixed in terms

volume outstanding. For example, $1 billion of
13-week bills offered each week would keep
$13 billion outstanding and $1 billion of 26week bills could maintain $26 billion outstanding, and so forth. Conversely, it would need
only $1/2 billion of 26-week bills to maintain
$13 biUion outstanding. Accordingly, these

lost

considerations led to the introduction of the

excess of outgo over income resulted mainly

of gold

and/or

dollars.

Due

to increases in the

U.S. balance of payments deficit the Treasury

gold steadily and increasingly.

The

rising

from U.S. military commitments, foreign aid,
tourism, export of capital, and more particularly, from the lure of higher interest rates
abroad following currency convertibility. To
discourage the

flight of

short-term funds seek-

ing higher rates overseas after the onset of the

1960-61 recession, bill rates were prevented
from declining to the low levels that had been
reached during earlier postwar recessions.
In 1961 the procedure familiarly called "op-

was undertaken jointly by the
Federal Reserve System and the Treasury. The
System's role was to divert part of its open
market operations for monetary expansion into
the coupon issue area, including maturities
over 1 year. By so doing, the System would be
eration twist"

helping to hold long-term interest rates

down

economy, while refraining
from putting downward pressure on short-term
rates. Debt management's part in the process
was to increase the supply of bills: first, in the
conventional way by increasing offerings of
regular bills; and second, by offering bill strips
from time to time. These strips consisted of a

to spur the domestic

simultaneous addition to a number of consecutive weekly maturities of existing bills. The announcements stipulated that tenders had to include, in one bid, equal amounts of each
maturity offered in the strip. The comphcated

nature of the bidding for the strips tended to

discourage
ders.

As

rapidly

but the most sophisticated bid-

all

a result,

than

rates probably rose more
would have through the

bill

they

more gradual system
cycle of regular

of increments to a whole

amount

crease in the

In the meantime the quarterly 1-year bill
had not been enthusiastically received by the
market, and its performance during the next
several years was relatively spotty. To diminish
the impact of such bills on the market, the
Treasury reached the decision in 1963 to reduce substantially the amounts in each offering,

but to increase the frequency of the offerings.
1-year

of 1-year bills outstand-

ing on the completion of the cycle.

The initiation of the month-end annual bill
had an important effect on Treasury debt management choices and decisions in the shortterm coupon issue area. These bills virtually
replaced the 1-year certificate, which had been
the basic "anchor" issue in the quarterly refi-

nancings.

except for one offering of
August 1966 the Treasury has

Instead,
in

certificates

15 to 21 months'

issued short-term notes of

In

maturity.

addition,

the

pricing

of

these

short-term notes has been strongly influenced

by the

results of the 1-year bill auctions

imme-

diately preceding a financing.

In early September 1966, following announcements that Federal borrowing from the
public, including agency borrowing, would be
cut back and that sales of participation certificates (PC's) would be postponed until the
credit markets improved, the Treasury embarked upon a new month-end cycle of 9-

month

to raise part of

bills

its

current cash

At the same time the 1-year segment of
the monthly cycle was reduced slightly. Including the strip of three 9-month bills offered in
November 1966, only two monthly issues remained by the end of the year, to complete the
9-month cycle.
Chart 1 shows the composition of outstanding bills by original term to maturity. In early
needs.

December 1958,
the

6-month

bill,

just before

the inception of

regularly issued

totaled $23.4 billion.

bill offerings.

Accordingly, the quarterly cycle of

version permitted an appreciable over-all in-

By

the

end

3-month bills
of 1966 the

regular weekly and monthly bills outstanding

amounted
$34.4

to

bfllion.

billion or

$57.8

billion

—an

Of the $57.8 bUlion

29 per cent were

increase
total,

of

$16.9

originafly issued as

45 per cent were
and the combined 9-month and
1-year bills were $14.8 billion or 26 per cent.
By and large the 21/2 -fold expansion of reg-

3-month
6-month

bills,

$26.0

billion or

bills,

ularly issued bflls

occurred without straining

the absorptive capacity of the market,

and the

was converted into a monthly cycle beginning in August 1963. Although the amounts
offered were cut back by about 60 per cent,

added choices of maturities played a

significant

role in the orderly distribution of the

expanded

the greater frequency of offerings in the con-

volume.

bills

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

GROWTH OF REGULARLY ISSUED TREASURY

BILLS,

I

November 1958

^

December

1966

31,

I

BY ORIGINAL TERM TO MATURITY

*

Includfs SI. 2 billion strip of 4-. 5-. and 6-monlh bills issued m Novcr
dated Dec. 31. 1966, delivered Jan. 3, 1967.
in 1958 a figure for No

t Includes $0.4 billion

—

Note. Data are for end of year except that
shown. Based on data from U.S. Treasury Dept.

ISSUANCE OF COUPON SECURITIES
AT A DISCOUNT
actively

explored the

question of issuing coupon securities at a discount. At that time the General Counsel of the

Treasury held that public debt legislation enacted soon after U.S. entry into World

had overridden an

War

II

1958

the Attorney General rendered an opinion in

concurrence with the Treasury General Coun-

which stated that

it

was

over the years. In practice, however,

to

One advantage
sues below par

to the investor of offering is-

that the discount can usually
if

Accordingly, the Treasury began
coupon issues at a discount late in
1958. Although reasonably certain that it had
legal sanction for such issuances, stemming
from the wartime legislation, the Treasury did

the issue

gain (or loss)

This

if

is

of

investors

and

is

tage

taxable

the issue

sold before matu-

is

no advantage

nontaxable

to

not a very important advan-

to

holders

ordinarily,

to offer

cause

it

was

that

felt

below-par

would not be favorably received by

The
pon

offerings

the market.

principal advantage of discounting cou-

issues

is

that

it

"fine tune" the yields

them more

enables the Treasury to

on

attractive.

its

offerings to

Equally

close

make

pricing

held

be treated as the cost basis for determining a

obligations.

not exercise the option until 1958, mainly be-

is

Moreover, the discount price can

to maturity.

the issuance of U.S.

flexibility in

is

be treated as a capital gain

rity.

ury greater

had

pay above par for a closely priced offering
a somewhat cautious market environment.

clearly the intent

of Congress to give the Secretary of the Treas-

it

been found that investors were generally loath
in

earlier provision against of-

fering a security at less than par. Also in

sel

higher coupon rate at a premium.

next

the

This had been done on a number of occasions

1958 the Treasury

In

could, of course, be accomplished by providing

are

there

definite

limits

amount of discount
would be permitted
Section

Code

the

original

capital

because
allowable

issue,

gain

which

treatment.

1232 of the 1954 Internal Revenue

spells out this limitation, as follows:

"If the original

'4 of

at

to

1

%

issue discount

is

less

than

of the redemption price at maturity,

multiplied by the

number

of complete years to

maturity, then the issue discount shall be con-

sidered to be zero."

However,

if

the discount at original issue

is

V4 per cent or

each

full

year

more
to

of the maturity value for

treated as ordinary income.

discount

the

maturity,

For example,

2-year note held to maturity

if

a

issued at a

is

would be

of 99.50, the 0.50 discount

price

is

because the market had softened. The 0.30
discount in this case, however, was original-

and therefore the additional

issue-discount,

issue

of 3y8"s could not be regarded as truly identical

the February issue in the market.

to

In

treated as ordinary income for tax purposes,

order to differentiate between the two, the ad-

99.51, the 0.49 discount

but at a price

of, say,

discount

issue

(that

—up

to

of the discount based

on
be

original-issue-discount treatment for tax pur-

is,

the

how

amount

original-

99.50 example

long the issue has been held

—would

considered ordinary income. Suppose that in
the

first

example above, where a 2-year note

was issued

at 99.50, the original investor sells

the note for 99.75 at the

end

of

year.

1

The

pro rata part of the discount for the time he
has held the note

is

0.25, or one-half of the

issue discount. Since his gain
is

ordinary income.

it

would

still

If

is

0.25,

the gain were

all

of

less, all

be ordinary income, but

if it

poses,
at

was found desirable

it

many

a discount on

to issue securities

Since the

occasions.

was introduced in 1958, discount issuances through 1966 totaled about $97 billion
of coupon obligations for cash or in exchange
practice

for maturing securities.

of

CASH REFUNDING

were

second buyer then holds the note

and redeems it at 100 (face
value), the pro rata share of the discount for
the second year would also be 0.25, and the
second investor's gain would also be all ordito

to be stamped,

it

more, the excess over 0.25 would be a capital
gain. If the

ditional issue

the remaining term to maturity the

above), any gain on subsequent sale
the pro rata

had

and during
market had
to provide separate quotations for each part.
However, the right to issue certificates,
notes, and bonds at a discount has served the
Treasury well. Within the limitation precluding

would be treated as capital gain.
According to the tax code, under

In

the

fall

of

1958 and throughout 1959 the

Treasury also experienced a substantial

rise in

the proportion of maturing issues that

pubHc

maturity

holders turned in for cash, instead of accepting
attractively

course,

is

exchange

priced

terest-rate environment, in

nary income.

The problems stemming from an
issue-discount obligation

relate

to

of holdings
this

and

at

munerative

varying pur-

could create numerous prob-

lems.

In this connection, an anomalous situation

developed with an issue of Treasury notes in
1964.

In the regular quarterly

refunding in

February of that year, the anchor issue ofEered
by the Treasury was an 18-month, 3% per
cent note at a discount price of
the discount

was

less

99%.

the

that

offered

issues

re-

may

it

market.

was faced with

In either case, the Treasury

an increasing volume of

when,

in

addition

to

attrition

massive

quirements, large amounts of

needed.

To meet

ury announced in

succeeding

have

the

this

preemptive

Instead,

a time

new funds were

development, the Treas-

March 1960

maturities

at

refunding re-

that holders of

would not necessarily
right

the Treasury

to
at

an

exchange

its

discretion

Since

was not

considered original-issue-discount for tax pur-

During the following April, the Treasury reopened the 3% per cent note to raise
needed cash, but this time the price was 99.70
poses.

or

subsequently be obtained at lower cost in the

offer.

than Va per cent of the

par redemption price at maturity,

more

original-

trading in

ration of the discount must be continued. For

chase prices,

of

which investors be-

lieve that alternative instruments are

the secondary market, in which case the pro-

odd periods

This,

offers.

a natural consequence of a rising in-

would pay
tained

amount

One

off

maturing issues with funds ob-

by offering an approximately similar
of

new

securities for cash subscription.

of the problems that arose

of the cash refunding technique

from the use

was

related to

the rollover of maturing issues held by official

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

when

coupon

Beginning with the November 1963 cash re-

Reserve and the

funding, the Treasury announced that subscrib-

accounts. In a rights refunding,
issue matures,

Government
roll

the Federal

Accounts

Investment

over their holdings into the

a

generally

new

securities

offered, while other investors subscribe for as

many

new
new cash

of the

case of

In

while the Gov-

all

allotted a

$100

generally

full,

except

allotment

to small subscribers

those

allotment

full

the

that

their holdings of eligible securities

million or less. All other investors are subject

tions) allotted in

to

certify

prior to the announcement.

predetermined amount in

amounts

to

financings the Federal Re-

ernment Accounts have usually been

percentage

entitled

issues as they wish. In the

serve does not participate at

to

would be reamounts of their
subscriptions do not exceed the amounts of
ers

quired

for

minor

from buying up the eligible issues after the announcement to acquire a larger amount of an
attractively priced offering, possibly for speculative purposes.

As

in offerings for

in cash refundings

instances

involve

that

fundings the Treasury had to find a

cash

way

re-

to ac-

cord the same treatment to the holdings of the

is

intended to prevent any of the listed holders

(small subscrip-

full.

immediately

The stipuladon

subscriptions,

new

such as

cash, other factors

maximum

allowable

cash deposits, allotment ratios,

and minimum allotments have been varied to
suit particular conditions.

The cash

Federal Reserve and Treasury Accounts as in

num-

refinancing procedure has a

rights refundings; otherwise their subscriptions

ber of advantages over rights refundings. In a

would be subject to percentage allotment as
would those of all other subscribers. In that

cash operation the Treasury determines

and Treasury (for
Government Investment Accounts) would

much

more

of one or

issues

event, the Federal Reserve

Thus, the technique offers

the

ditional cash can be raised

it

wants to

flexibility in that

than the total amount maturing, or

or else these olBcial investors would acquire

is

either

more or

less of the

new

maturing

securities than

issues. In either

desired, the exact extent of

termined.
tion,

By

the

it

if

attrition

can be prede-

same token, unwanted

which may occur

in

ad-

by offering more

have to guess the correct percentage allotment,

their holdings of the

how
offer.

attri-

a rights refunding,

case, but mainly with respect to the Federal

can be avoided. In addition, with more

would be an unwanted effect on the money market of unpredictable extent: toward ease if more were acquired than held, or toward restraint if less
were acquired.
The problem was resolved by allowing all

control over subscriptions and allotments, ex-

Reserve's

allotment,

there

cessive speculative activity can be

flexible

more

easily

held within bounds.

However, there are two principal advantages
of rights over cash refundings. First, an investor

knows exactly how much of

a

new

issue

investors to turn in their maturing securities to

he will be allotted in a rights operation. This

pay for the new
one category all

preferred by the relatively smaller, less sophis-

issues,

and by including

official-type

holders or

in

ac-

counts whose subscriptions would be allotted

These accounts,

in full.

as

listed in

the

first

ticated investor

who would have

is

to guess the

allotment ratio in a cash refunding and pad his
subscription accordingly. If the guesses

on

al-

cash refinancing announcement of the August

lotment ratios

1960

have to accept more of the new securities
than they had wanted. Hence, smaller banks
and other institutional investors are ordinarily

litical

and their poand the instrumentalities
pension and retirement and

maturities, include: States

subdivisions

thereof,

public

funds. Government Investment
Accounts, the Federal Reserve Banks, interna-

other

public

tional organizations in

more

are

too

small,

investors

may

inclined to participate in rights refund-

ings than in cash operations.

which the United States

The second

basic advantage of using rights
market rather than the Treasury de-

holds membership, foreign central banks, and

is

foreign states.

termines the amount taken of each issue

that the

when

two or more options are provided. When the
sets the amounts of each issue of-

some tend-

amounts of debt extension, with a minimum
prevailing longer-term rates, was
advance refunding. In an advance refunding

option for

the Treasury offers holders of existing issues,

Treasury

fered in a cash refunding, there

ency to Hmit the
fear that

it

will not

be adequately covered. For

that reason longer options

may be

or

small,

trarily

is

size of the longer

may be made

arbi-

eliminated entirely.

Thus, rights refundings tend to maximize debt

The Treasury made

use of the

extensive

cash refunding technique from

its

inception in

August 1960 through November 1966. During
that period there were 26 quarterly refinanc-

Of

which are not due to mature for some time,
the opportunity to exchange their holdings for

longer issues.

these, 10

were cash operations.

for

many

when

when

the rapid

of debt extension to bring about a better balin the

maturity structure of the market-

able debt would have to be explored. Strenuous

had been made to
the period between Sep-

fairly successful efforts

lengthen the debt in

tember 1957 and January 1959, but the inexorable passage of time

temporary.

In

rendered the success

the

ensuing

period

of

rapid upturn in market rates of interest, the

normal

methods

extension

debt

of

cash offerings or refundings
strongly

felt to

at

through

maturity were

be inadequate and costly

deed, they were possible at

if,

in-

all.

In the normal
term issues shortened, they gravitated into the
hands of intermediate- and short-term holders,
mainly commercial banks and corporations.

when

the issues matured, holders of

short-term issues were not inclined to accept

long-term bonds

—
time —

refundings
that

in

The

otherwise be

legislation

provided

Accordingly,

issues

most

cases

for exchange to the

eligible

offered.

issues

in

could carry over the cost basis of
Generally,

Federal

new

and State

supervisory authorities followed the Treasury's
lead

in

allowing such

accounting treatment,

and under the provision many
vestors,

including

could take

institutional in-

not subject

those

tax,

to

advantage of the exchange offer

without having to show a substantial book loss

on the old

issues being replaced. In essence,

the nontaxable exchange provision postponed
the recognition of any gain (or loss) until the

new

were subsequently sold or

securities

re-

deemed.

The new

legislation

impediment

removed another

advance refunding

provided that the issue price

operations.

It

of the

security

old

also

successful

to

would become the issue
which precluded treating the
having been offered at an original-

price of the new,

course of events, as longer-

Finally,

in-

so stipulated by the Secretary of

Treasury.

their

quite

was

for nontaxable exchanges in advance refund-

investors

economic expansion that had started in the spring of 1958
was in full swing, the Treasury became increasingly convinced that alternative methods
In early 1959,

who would

investors

unwilling to exchange.

ings,

ADVANCE REFUNDING

and

of 1959, legislation

ease and simplify advance refunding operations

the

ance

summer

In the

troduced to modify the tax code sufficiently to

extension.

ings.

impact on

exchange; thus in rights

the usual type of operation up to

a reverse transfer of maturing issues

new

issue as

issue discount for tax purposes. In

without
profit

the

on the

new

provision

sale of the

new

any

many

cases,

subsequent

securities

would

have been converted from a capital gain into
ordinary income.

After the groundwork had been completed,
the Treasury tried a pilot advance refunding in

necessary. Ex-

June 1960. The operation was considered a
success, and it led to the full-scale advance re-

cept in a period of falling interest rates, there

funding of October 1960. In September 1960

chance for substantial amounts of

the Treasury issued a white paper. Debt Management and Advance Rejnnding, in which
basic concepts were discussed. The paper indi-

to long-term investors

was

little

became

long-term offerings to be taken. The method

decided

upon

as

promising truly

significant

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

cated that "senior" advance refundings, such
as the

October 1960 operation, should involve

outstanding issues maturing between 5 and 12
years whose holders

would be offered long-

term bonds with terms of 15 years or more.
"Junior" advance refundings, such as the June

1960 operation, would involve outstanding is1
and 5 years whose
.holders would be offered medium-term issues
sues maturing between

in the 5- to 10-year maturity range.

Thus, the

sues were included with junior advance refund-

Third, outstanding issues maturing in 5

ings.

years or less were

made

advance

refundings

eligible for

And

into long-term issues.

exchange

fourth, the scope of

was greatly enlarged

in

terms of the number of eligible issues in one
operation and the amounts of these issues in
public hands.

Advance refunding into long-term
was effectively prohibited when market

issues
yields

longer outstanding issues in a senior refunding

rose above the 4V<i per cent interest limitation

would be replaced by the new

on bonds

issues offered in

a junior refunding, leaving the

1-

to

5-year

area open to regular refundings of maturing
sues and cash offerings.

It

was

felt

is-

that in this

leapfrog process the ownership pattern of the

outstanding issues would remain relatively undisturbed, market churning

would be reduced,

and the upward pressure on longer-term interest rates would be much smaller than with
similar-term

conventional

refundings

at

ma-

in

the

fall

of

1965.

In 1966 the

technique was combined with regular refund-

and limited to the advance refunding of
maturing within, 6 months into notes
coming due within 5 years.
ings

issues

Even a brief history of advance refunding
would be incomplete without including a description

debt

of

its

evolution

restructuring

changes

tool

into

a formidable

through

conceptual

and the development of subsidiary

techniques.

turity.

In addition,

since

advance refundings are

not subject to any predetermined schedule, the

Treasury can choose the most opportune time
for such operations in relation to the

market

environment and to other debt management
objectives.

Moreover, unlike refunding

no expectation

at

ma-

no problem because there

turity, attrition is

that nearly

all

is

of the publicly

held portion of an eligible issue will be ex-

changed and no cash payoff of the remainder
involved. Thus, the Treasury runs little risk,
and any appreciable amount extended not only

is

improves the debt structure but also reduces
the refunding burden

when

the issue finally

matures.

While the precepts regarding the leapfrog
principle generally continued to be

observed,

the role of advance refunding

At

and ofby and large, to those
that could be accommodated on a straight
par-for-par basis. It was held by some that any
adjustment payments to, or by, the subscriber
would complicate the operation beyond the
chance of success. However, such adjustment
(or "boot") payments were successfully introduced in the third advance refunding. Thereafter, boot payments made possible a much
wider choice of eligible and offered issues and,
in fact, led to advance refundings in which as
many as nine eligible issues were exchangeable
for any of three offered issues.
By the time of the March 1962 advance refunding, congressional questions and criticisms
first

the choice of outstanding

fered issues

was

against the

new technique

limited,

led to hearings be-

Committee on March
14 and 16. Criticism centered particularly on
the senior refundings in which World War II
tap 2'/2's had been replaced by the Treasury

was gradually
expanded beginning in 1962. First, junior- and
senior-type offerings were included within one
operation. Second, the mechanics of advance
refunding were applied to outstanding issues

fore the Senate Finance

maturing within

parent increase in cost to the maturity date of

1

year, with the objective of

reducing large concentrations of early maturities to facilitate

finally

regular refinancing

came due, and

later

when they

such short-term

is-

with long-term 3Vi

The

ap-

was considered too great to be
by the subsequent likely saving in interOn the other hand, there seemed little or

the old issues
offset
est.

per cent bonds.

12

debt maturing within

year.

As

no opposition to junior refundings since the elwere due to be refunded relatively
soon anyway. Thus, no truly senior advance

in short-term

igible issues

shown

refunding has been attempted since 1962.

from 1958 through 1965 to an increase of $21
billion. The volume of coupon issues declined
from $43 billion to $33V2 billion in that time,

in

Another development resulted from the advance refunding of issues maturing within 1

some

year. In

cases

making the offered

bills.

Chart

2, this

1

procedure was effective

holding the under- 1-year marketable debt

bills grew by about $30 bilhon.
However, the sharp curtailment of advance refunding following the January 1965 operation
was chiefly responsible for the rapid build-up

while regular

issues

produced substantial "rights" values for the eligible issues. Holders unwilhng to
exchange "rights" were thus encouraged to sell
in the market and to invest the proceeds temattractive

porarily in

in

of within- 1 -year debt during 1966.

addition to

In

This had the effect of depress-

making room

for

bills,

ad-

actively

vance refunding greatly reduced amounts of

seeking to increase such yields for balance of

short-term issues in public hands by breaking

such experi-

up large concentrations of early maturities.
This is clearly illustrated by Chart 3. From the
second half of 1961 through 1966 advance
refundings reduced maturing issues held by the
public by between $1 billion and $9 bilhon, or
an average of $5Vi billion for each semiannual

ing

yields

bill

when

the Treasury

payments reasons. After the
ence the sale of additional

announcement

the

was
bill

effectively

first

bills at

was

the time or

of the intention to sell bills

used to prevent any substantial

rate declines.

The

and
had other important
By removing large blocks of early maroom was made for expanding the volregular bills without an undue increase

pre-refunding of near maturities

By 1963,

following the inception of

junior advance refundings

period.

aspects.

pre-refunding, whereby issues maturing within

turities,

ume

2

of

1

year were

ing,

made

eligible for

the regular refunding

COMPOSITION OF THE UNDER 1-YEAR MARKETABLE DEBT, 1958-66

COUPON ISSUES

DECEMBER

Includes $2,7 billion of spt-cial bills nKiliinn;; M.iv
$(1,4 billion
of 4-month bills dated be
t Includes
Note. Based on data from U.S. Treasury Dept.

31

-

*

—

31,

1966,

delivered

Jan.

3,

1967.

advance refund-

burden was sharply

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

PUBLICLY HELD TREASURY-ISSUE MATURITIES
Effect of Advance Refundings in Reducing Actual Maturities
Semiannually, July 1960 December 1966

By

—
—had

doing a good job of

advance refunding

in

held amounts to be rolled over each half year

debt extension

in effect already provided

had declined to between $5 billion and $7
billion. These smaller maturities greatly facilitated the quarterly refunding operations and

additional longer options.

reduced.

the second half of 1964, publicly

The

part played by advance refunding in re-

structuring the over- 1 -year marketable debt

is

Moreover, the actual amounts by which early

amply demonstrated in Chart 4. By the end of
1959 the most vulnerable segment of intermediate- and long-term debt, the 1- to 5-year maturities, had increased to $611^ billion. This

were reduced understate consider-

portion of the debt poses the constant threat of

ably the true contribution of advance refunding

dropping into the under- 1 -year category. When
the Treasury is foreclosed by the 4V4 per cent

indeed, in
easily

some

successful

have been
maturities

risky,

cases,

made

when otherwise
if

they

might

not impossible altogether.

to easier regular refunding.

ductions,

cash refundings

Without such

re-

most of the much larger original
would have been rolled

limitation

on bonds from extending beyond 5

maturities, of necessity,

years, this sensitive area of the maturity struc-

over into short-term issues requiring refunding

ture

again after a year or two.

to 5-year debt

In some cases so much of an eligible issue
was extended through advance refunding that

from $40 billion 5 years earlier. The $9 billion
growth in 1960 occurred partly as a result of
the pilot advance refunding in June that year,
while the big senior refunding in October had

the publicly held portion appeared too small
for

more than one option in the regular reat maturity. It was felt in such cases

funding
that

if

the resulting longer issue were too tiny,

market characteristics would be impaired.
While this, of course, was true, it is clear that

its

no

is

likely to

effect in that

Thereafter,

grow.

By December

had grown

to nearly

1960, 1-

$71 billion

maturity area.

however,

advance

refunding

played a very significant role in increasing the

volume of

issues

with

loneer

maturities.

As

14

4

STRUCTURE OF THE OVER 1-YEAR MARKETABLE DEBT, 1959-66
1-TO 5-YEAR MATURITIES

ISSUED

5-

TO 20-YEAR MATURITIES

IN

ADVANCE REFUNDINGSISSUED

IN

REGULAR FINANCING: —

20 YEARS AND OVER

late as

December 1966, advance refunding had

accounted for 72 per cent of the $17 bilhon

in

20-year-or-longer bonds outstanding, and for

53 per cent of the diminished 5- to 20-year
maturities. Even in the 1- to 5-year area 39
per cent of the outstanding issues had origi-

nated in advance refundings.
In summary, the importance of advance re-

funding

in

improving the structure of the mar-

debt

ketable

can

scarcely

be

exaggerated.

From June 1960 through January 1965
$68

billion

nearly

of securities were extended into

longer-term issues in 11 operations

—an

aver-

age of $6.2 bilhon per operation, of which

$5.7 billion was publicly held.

The scope

of

advance refundings gradually increased during
the period.
billion

By combining

and $22

issues in the July
ations,

the

extension of
curities.

as

much

as

$26'/i

billion of publicly held eligible

1964 and January 1965 operbrought about the

Treasury

more than $18 bilhon

of those se-

Yet, despite these massive doses of

debt extension and the upward pressure of the

continuing economic

expansion beginning

in

1961, the impact on long-term interest rates

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

well as other dealers, brokers,

and banks

the group.

The

tion of these

will-

members

ing to be affiliated with the major

sitive

economic and

to

news of

political

basic idea behind the organiza-

marketing groups was to

Second, obtaining advance commitments from

large

kinds,

spread the risk of handling a large issue and to

prospective investors was likely to be

ensure as wide a distribution as possible of the

particularly in a cautious

bonds

Third,

to the investing public.

—

The first auction for bonds amounting
$250 milhon was held in January 1963.

—

invitation to bid

its

all

both domestic and foreign. Thus, the
underwriters could not stand much exposure.

of

the Treasury

that the issue could carry either a

Government bond market

the

broad, and one long-term Treasury issue

In

much

like another, that

market

new

maturity area of the

so

is

to

announced

4 or

difficult,

market environment.
is

so

stability in the

issue could not

be

per

successfully maintained by the winning syndi-

it would mature in
30 years, but would become callable after 25
years. The winning bid at a'price of 99.85111
per $100 for the bonds as 4's of 1988-93

cate. Attempts by the syndicate to stabiUze the
market would be very difficult, especially if the
other market professionals were to sell the

provided an interest cost to the Treasury of

Federal Reserve in maintaining an "even keel"

4.008 per cent, and the bonds were reoffered

during the auction and early reoffering period

The un-

could not be expected to continue indefinitely.

4'/8

cent coupon rate, and that

at par.

The

reoffering

was a

success.

issue

derwriters were able to dispose of the securities,

terminate price restrictions, and dissolve

the selling group in 2 days.

And

short.

As a

the

fourth,

result of the

problems involved, syndi-

cate underwriting of long-term bonds has not

been used since April 1963. At the time, mar-

The Treasury held the second auction
April 1963 for $300 million of bonds. The

in
in-

bidding for an entire issue of long-

term bonds were too great even

1988-94. The winning bid was 100.55119 on
a 414 per cent coupon at an interest cost of

offered were limited to

4.093 per cent, and the bonds were reoffered

PARTICIPATION CERTIFICATES

100.75 to yield 4.082 per cent. However,

this issue
first

proved more

difficult to sell

auction offering and remained

syndicate restrictions for

some

time.

than the

bound by
It

so hap-

pened that the chances for the second offering
to achieve a quick sellout were substantially
dampened by the announcement of an impending large telephone company issue on the day
of the Treasury auction.

The

interest

cost to

the

Treasury on the

auction bonds was probably less than if they
had been sold in regular financings. The yield
spread on each of the auction issues was 8
basis points above prevailing Treasury market
rates as compared with an average spread of

about 12 basis points for regular Treasury of-

The new

$300

The sale of participation
management tool orginated

method of selling longterm bonds created a number of problems.
First, the underwriting risk was great because
the Government bond market is extremely senauction

as

issues
in

amounts

debt

a

1953 mainly as

program

part of a generalized

the

if

million or less.

to

hold

down

the Federal debt subject to statutory limit, but

the budgetary effect
first

PC's

—

the

was

also recognized.

Commodity

The

Credit Corporation

—

(CCC) certificates of interest were (and still
were through 1966) short-term instruments of
participation

in

a

pool of crop loans. They

have been taken mostly by commercial banks,
to redemption on demand,
and have been guaranteed by the CCC.
For a number of years the CCC certificates
of interest were the only PC's offered by the

have been subject

Federal Government, except for a small Reconstruction Finance Corporation

ferings.

com-

ket circles held strongly that the risks of
petitive

vitation to bid called for either 4's or 4'/8's of

at

of the

attitude

in

(RFC)

1954, which was liquidated 2 years

Ordinarily, PC's of the

CCC

result

issue
later.

when crop

loans are taken over by banks or other financial
institutions, instead of

being presented for pay-

ment by

Government. In that way the

the

CCC

PC's reduce expenditures for loans and

at the

same time do not add

to the debt.

PC

In fuller explanation, the proceeds of

have a twofold fiscal effect: When deposited in the general fund balance, the proceeds

sales

new

diminish the Treasury's refunding or

rowing needs. Thus, the public debt

is

PC's against a pool of selected foreign

to issue

loans in

its

originally

portfolio.

10-year

These

certificates

obligations

(later

were

7-year)

bor-

with semiannual level amortizations of princi-

reduced

pal to coincide roughly with the amortization

much

or prevented from increasing as

Even before the Federal Credit Programs
Committee report, the Export-Import Bank of
Washington (Eximbank) in 1962 had begun

as

it

The

schedules of the loans in the pool.

certifi-

would have without the PC's. The explanation
of the effect on budget expenditures is more
complicated. The money for most Federal
credit programs is drawn from revolving funds
set
up under congressional authorizations.
Drawings by the agencies represent borrowings
from the Treasury; as these agencies make
loans to the pubhc, the funds used become

cates were offered only to commercial banks,

budget expenditures. The process

made

subject to redemption in part or in full

at the

option of the holder or of the

when

is

reversed

loans are repaid by the public, or are

sold to private investors, or

As

sued.

when PC's

are

is-

the repayments or the proceeds of

mainly those with a substantial interest
eign loans.

By

in for-

the terms of the offerings, the

Eximbank PC's had

limited

negotiability,

in

banks originally subscribing could sell
only subparticipations to correspondent banks

that the

or other affiliated institutions.
this

To make up

for

lack of liquidity, the participations were

beginning 2Vi

years

from

Eximbank
As a

date.

issue

source of funds, additional issues of PC's were

Eximbank from time

outright sales or of PC's were deposited in the

sold by the

became negative
budget expenditures, and at the same time
agency indebtedness to the Treasury was re-

out appreciably changing the basic terms of

should also be stressed, however,

grams Committee recommendation on an en-

some replenishment

larged role for private credit, active considera-

duced.

It

PC

that

they

balance,

Treasury's

sales represented

of loanable funds for the credit programs.

To stem

to tune with-

the instrument.

pursuance of the Federal Credit Pro-

In

tion

began

to

be given to expanding the scope

the rising tide of private loans and

of participation offerings. After intensive study,

mortgages held by the Government, outright
sales of financial assets had been actively pur-

legislation was introduced and enacted in September 1964 empowering the Federal National

sued under some programs.

were

clearly

However, these

not large enough to affect the

growth of Federally financed
To study this and other
related problems, the President appointed a
Committee on Federal Credit Programs, with
over-all

rapid,

credit to the public.

Secretary of the Treasury

the

The Committee submitted
ary 1963, and

among

tions the

report

financing

should

credit

be
it

as

many recommendaurged that

substituted

was

Chairman.

report in Febru-

feasible to

for

do

private

Federal-agency-held

seemed

to

Committee's

(FNMA)

to

act

as

gages as the backing for a
fering.

new type

of

PC

of-

In effect, marketing of these PC's rep-

resented the sale of the interest and principal

payments on the mortgages. Accordingly, the
PC's were arranged to mature serially to correspond with the payments inflow. In the mortgage field, PC's have distinct advantages over
outright sales of mortgages: They remove the
risk of default; they eliminate servicing costs;

In

and they attract investors otherwise not interested in mortgages directly.
The mortgages involved in the first PC offerings were from FNMA's Management and
Liquidation and Special Assistance portfolios
and from the portfoho of the Veterans Admin-

and mortgages

promise the speediest approach for

implementing the
tion.

loans

Association

public
so.

regard the sale of participations in pools

this

of

whenever

its

strongly

its

Mortgage

trustee for pooling Federal-agency-held mort-

recommenda-

NEW TECHNIQUES
istration

fering in

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT-

17

(VA). FNMA sold the initial PC ofNovember 1964, as a $300 million,

expanded

for an

PC program

went forward,

culminating in the Participation Sales Act of

10-year serial issue with $30 million maturing

1966, passed in May. Under the statute the

each year.

potential coverage of credit

The marketing arrangement

as originally set

up remained essentially unchanged through
1966. Under this arrangement PC offerings
were awarded by FNMA to one very large
underwriting
fered

which

syndicate,

them

the

to

turn

in

public

investing

scribed interest rates and prices.
price for each of the maturities

reof-

at

pre-

The rate and
making up the

were determined by negotiation between
the syndicate and FNMA, with Treasury con-

issue

was a

currence. Also included

scale of under-

writing charges or commissions for each of the
serial maturities

paid by

FNMA.

FNMA

PC's posed a number
For example, some of the
serial maturities were unpopular and hard to
sell; the amount of each serial maturity was
small, making dealer operations in the secondary market difficult and risky; although negotiof market problems.

PC's were

the

able,

more time
ter

requiring

and handling; and the
though backed by a let-

for transfer

FNMA,

guarantee by
ing

registered,

all

Treasury
if

willingness

to

lend

funds

to

be

After the

first

few

offerings, the receptivity

FNMA

PC's declined in the

rapidly rising interest-rate environment follow-

ing the enlargement of the
Asia. During the
for

Eximbank

for

bank

war

in Southeast

same period the environment
weakened as demand

offerings

credit increased sharply. Despite at-

make

the Eximbank-type PC's more
by reducing the time to earliest redemption by holders and by making them
eligible for discounting by the Federal Reserve,
the Eximbank found it increasingly difficult to
attractive

PC's

In

addition,

ap-

the

PC

the

offerings with

management operations and

debt

its

authorizes

legislation

to

ap-

prove the direct sales of certain financial as-

The programs and agencies

sets.

Act

listed in the

are:

Home AdminisDepartment of Agriculture, relating to
farm operations, farm ownership, housing, and
soil and water;
Loans for academic facilities by the Office
of Education, Department of Health, Education, and Welfare;
Loans and mortgages held by the Department of Housing and Urban Development exrelated
to
secondary market
cept
those
Direct loans of the Farmers

operations of

FNMA;

Loans and mortgages held by the VA;
Loans held by the Eximbank;
Loans held by the Small Business Administration.

According

at

reasonable rates of interest.

increase

further

the

role

of

private

sales

to the

House Banking and Cur-

at

$33.3

direct Federal loans

billion,

assuming

all

PC

sales

contem-

document

had been completed. Of this amount, however,
only some $10 billion to $11 bilhon of financial assets were in programs listed in the act.
During the second quarter of 1966, yields
on Federal agency issues and PC's rose
sharply relative to Treasury market rates as
private and public credit demands soared. Federal agencies were faced with greatly increased
demands from those unable to borrow from
banks and other sources. In consequence, the
agencies

FNMA,

in

all

plated in the January 1966 budget

funds primarily as a result of the war, plans

and

the level of

bill,

outstanding on June 30, 1966, was estimated

view of the greater need for

credit,

provide for congressional

rency Committee report on the participation

of the market to

To

To

Act requires congressional

Treasury to coordinate the

fully bind-

ing legally.

tempts to

the

insufficiency of the pools to service the PC's.

to

necessary, for servicing the PC's,

was not considered by some

enlarged.

proval, through appropriations, to cover any

from the Secretary of the Treasury regard-

FNMA,

sell

tially

control,

tration,

Aside from rates and prices, the terms and
conditions of the

programs subject
was substan-

to inclusion in participation pools

—

particularly

and the

the

farm

home
credit

loan

banks,

agencies

—

in-

18

creased their market borrowing. Together with

PC program

expanded

by the
budget for fiscal year 1967, these demands
created a very depressed and unhealthy atmosphere in the credit markets. By late August the
markets had become so severely tightened that
interest rates rose to the highest levels in 40
the

called for

years or more.

In

this

situation

the

administration

acted

vigorously to dispel apprehension and to ease
pressures on the

money and

capital markets.

San Francisco; wire transfer facilities among
major money market centers; and an
opinion by the Attorney General that PC's are
full faith and credit instruments of the United
these

States.

from 1962
1966 totaled about $5% billion. Of
this amount about $4 billion remained outstanding on December 31, 1966, after redemptions, amortizations, and maturities. The shift
of these amounts from Federal to private
Sales of participation certificates

through

In addition to other measures, the President,

credit

on September 9, 1966, requested the curtailment of agency borrowing. The next day the
Secretary of the Treasury announced that
scheduled sales of PC's would be postponed
until the credit markets improved, and any
new money to meet Federal agency needs in
excess of maturities would be provided by the
Government Investment Accounts.
As a result of official measures to relieve
pressures, interest rates dropped quickly and
the tightness in the money and capital markets
gradually eased. Toward the end of the year,
the environment was considered appropriate
for FNMA to announce the first offering of
PC's following the early September postpone-

tion.

ment. Additional legislation providing congres-

meet insufficiencies of
from the loan pools to service PC interest payments was enacted in September.
In the meantime, while market receptivity to
the growing volume of PC's was reaching a
low ebb during the summer of 1966, meetings
were held among market participants, representatives of the Treasury, the Bureau of the
Budget, FNMA, and other interested agencies
to discuss measures for improving the market
sional authorization to

some degree

required

By and

to believe that

of experimenta-

however, there

large,

is

reason

through adequate coordination

with Treasury debt

management and Federal

agency borrowing operations, PC's could have
continued to play a useful and beneficial

fiscal

role.

INNOVATIONS

NONMARKETABLE

IN

ISSUES
The history of debt management innovations
would be incomplete without mentioning developments

area of nonmarketable
Although such issues do
not have a direct impact on the market, they
have important effects in changing the supply
of marketable issues and in carrying out broad
debt management and national economic pol-

Treasury

in

the

securities.

interest

characteristics

gestions

of

of
the

PC's.

market

Most

of

the

professionals

sug-

were

FNMA PC's announced in
December. These included: the concentration
of one offering into as few as two or three sepadopted for the

arate maturities, instead of small annual serial
maturities; optional bearer or registered forms

icy objectives.

Savings bonds. By the spring of 1959, the
bond program was faltering and in evident trouble. Sales of Series E and H bonds
had declined from $5.3 billion in fiscal year
savings

1956

to $4.5 billion in 1959; in the latter year

—
—reached more

the net cash drain

over sales

than $0.6

billion.

Twice before, in 1952 and again in 1957,
the Treasury had raised savings bond rates by
small fractions of 1 per cent: first, from 2.9 to
3 per cent to maturity in May 1952 and then
3Vi per cent in February 1957. As

from

3 to

rate

competition for

3'/4

savings

sharpened,

the

per cent became clearly inadequate. Ac-

of the certificates; denominational exchanges

cordingly,

the

coupon issues to be provided by the Federal
Reserve Banks of New York, Chicago, and

permitting

the

of

the excess of redemptions

Treasury requested legislation
rate

to

bonds to be increased to

maturity

3%

on savings

per cent begin-

NEW TECHNIQUES
June

ning in

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

The enacted

1959.

maximum

raised the

legislation

allowable savings

bond

4V4 per cent, provided the President

rate to

found that the increase would be

crease of $7Vi billion in the 7Vi years from

mid-1959

E

tional interest.

Additionally,

the

Treasury asked for and

December 1966, or an average
billion

per year.

Coincidentally, the average rate of growth in

the na-

in

to

growth rate of $1

H

and

bonds outstanding during the 20

years ending 1966, although anything but con-

was also $1 billion a year, or a total of
$20 billion. This is $20 billion the

was granted statutory permission to raise future earning rates on all outstanding E and H
bonds. Under this innovation yields for the
remaining period to the next maturity were

stant,

increased generally by Vz

other publicly held Federal debt during that

same increase
bonds

of

as provided

to maturity.

per cent, the

1

The higher

and H
on out-

E

on new

rates

about

Treasury did not have to raise

making possible an $8V2
period instead of an $1

market,

in the

billion decrease in all

billion increase.

1 '/i

Retirement Bonds. In January 1963 the

to

Treasury introduced United States Retirement

switch out of old bonds into

Plan Bonds to provide an alternative invest-

greatly reduced incentives to

new ones and
move out of sav-

ment medium under the Self-Employed Individuals Tax Retirement Act of 1962 (26
U.S.C. 401-05). As a parallel to retirement
and pension plans covering employees only,
the Act affords self-employed persons the opportunity to set up retirement plans subject to
approval by the Internal Revenue Service.
Under an approved plan, any qualified selfemployed person (for himself and his em-

standing

bonds

ehminated

any incentive

bonds altogether. In asking the Congress
for permission to raise earning rates on outstanding bonds, the Treasury also felt that it

ings

has something of a trusteeship function on behalf of millions

of individual

savers

who do

not follow interest-rate trends closely, and that

on the grounds of equity, these holders were
entitled to the increased earning rates.

The new

rates

worked

quite well in bringing

and between
June 1959 and June 1965 the volume of outstanding E and H bonds increased by more
than $6 billion. During this period, the relative
stability of long-term interest rates was a
strong factor in sustaining the performance of
a

turnaround

in

the

program,

the program.

In the
ings

fall

of 1965 as competition for sav-

intensified,

E

H

and

bond

sales

were

ployees)

is

entitled to deduct

$2,500, whichever

is

10 per cent or

from the net income

less,

of each person for retirement purposes.

retirement funds,

become

including earnings

taxable to the retiree as the

The

thereon,

money

is

disbursed upon retirement, or beginning at age

59 1/2, or earlier

disability,

Most

or at death.

approved self-employed retirement plans are
administered by bank and insurance company
trustees

or as custodial accounts, with fairly

again flagging and redemptions rising. In con-

wide latitude for the investment of the funds.

sequence, the Treasury asked the President to

These

raise the rate to maturity

on new bonds from

may be

various

types

of

public

and

private securities including equities. There are,

expenses for man-

3.75 to 4.15 per cent, and increased the earn-

of

ing rates on outstanding bonds to next matu-

aging or maintaining custody of the retirement

rity

by 0.4 per

sification

1966, the

of

cent. Despite the

the

competition

extreme intenfor

savings

in

E and H bond program performed

course,

administrative

fund investments.

United States Retirement Bonds were designed as an investment

medium wherein no

remarkably well after the announcement of the

administrative cost would be involved. Other

improvement

advantages of these bonds are: (1) safety regarding risk of default; (2) a guaranteed level

in savings

bond

rates in

Febru-

ary 1966. In the ensuing 10 months to the end
of the year, the amount of E and H savings
bonds outstanding grew by nearly $1.0 billion
to

$50.2

billion.

This represented a total

in-

rate

of return

until

they are redeemed;

ready availability throughout the country

banks and other financial

institutions,

(3)
at

or di-

20

from Federal Reserve Banks, or

the U.S.

States in exchange for dollars. Instead of using

Treasury; and (4) the fact that income from

those dollars to buy a large block of market-

rectly

these retirement plan

bonds

is

not subject to

The rate of earning on United States Retirement Bonds has generally been the same as
that on new Series E and H savings bonds.
Retirement bonds were not actively promoted
by the U.S. Treasury, but they do represent a
investment

significant

outlet

to

many

self-

employed persons. The fact is, however, that
by the end of calendar year 1966, only $18
million were outstanding.
Foreign-series securities. Nonmarketable
securities issued to foreign central banks and
governments, payable in dollars, were introduced in August 1961 under the authority of
the Second Liberty Bond Act. These issues include certificates, generally 3 months to maturity; 1- to 5-year notes; and bonds, which in
practice have had maturities between 1 and 7
years. Most foreign-series securities have been
general,

the

foreign-series

were made redeemable

in

whole or

certificates
in part at

the option of the holder on 2 days' notice,

longer issues were
into

3-month

usually

made

and

convertible

certificates. In special cases cer-

been redeemable at the option of the United States while
others, by prior agreement, have been made
subject to redemption before maturity. In all
cases payments on early redemption are at par.
tain over- 1 -year maturities have

The

principal purposes of the foreign-series

securities

The German marks

received in exchange by
would thus increase foreign
exchange reserves for payments purposes or

the United States

for protecting the position of the dollar.

The nonmarketable foreign bonds issued in
1964 to Canada in connection with the Columbia River project and treaty provide an example of the use of longer-term foreign-series
securities for bilateral financial

The agreement

have been: to insulate certain large

from having a major impact on
the U.S. Government securities markets; to
provide issues that are not subject to market
risk; to furnish longer-term investment media
transactions

arrangements.

called for project funds to be

raised in the United States and accordingly
$254 million was turned over to the Canadian
Government, which then transferred $204 million in Canadian dollars to the British Columbia Government to pay for construction costs.
Of the $254 million U.S. dollars, $50 million
was used to pay off U.S. commercial bank

loans

issued for special purposes.

In

German central bank might innonmarketable foreign-series, 3-month
certificates at the going rate on 3-month bills.
able issues, the

vest in

estate taxes.

to

Columbia.

British

The remaining

$204 million of such dollars was invested by
the Canadian Government in nonmarketable,
U.S.

foreign-series

bonds,

nonconvertible

to

prevent the transaction from having an imme-

payments impact. The bonds
mature serially in equal
amounts over a 7-year period, and as the
bonds are paid off, the U.S. dollars received
are added to Canadian foreign exchange rediate balance of

were

arranged

to

serves.

The outstanding amount
sues

grew

November
clined

to

to a

of foreign-series is-

peak of nearly $1.2

1965.

billion in

After that these issues de-

about $600 million by the end of

1966. Of this amount, nearly $330 million was
in over-1-year convertible issues,

which do not

for facilitating certain types of bilateral finan-

enter into U.S. international payments deficits

arrangements; to finance currency swap

on the "liquidity balance" basis.
Foreign-currency-series securities. In Oc-

cial

agreements; and to induce long-term capital

nonmar-

which improve the U.S. balance of
payments position.
Although not all of these purposes are com-

to official foreign entities.

mon

to all transactions, they are interrelated.

nonmarketable foreign issues payable in U.S.

For example, in a swap transaction. West German marks may be obtained by the United

dollars, the authority to provide these securi-

inflows,

tober 1961 the Treasury began to

sell

ketable securities payable in foreign currencies

ties

As

in the case of the

stems from the Second Liberty

Bond

Act.

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

The use of such issues
War I when Treasury
denominated

ness

in

originated during

World

certificates of indebted-

currency were

Spanish

given in payment for war materiel purchased
in that country.

Originally,

could

be

either

certificates

with maturities of
limited in any

1

way

year or

of

indebtedness

less,

or bonds not

as to the term to maturity.

Issuing foreign-currency bonds gave the Treas-

convertibility.

This greatly increased the potential for largescale flows of funds

from the United States to

foreign markets seeking higher rates of return.
In

foreign-currency-series securities

had moved to currency

tries

turn,

movements could

such

change-rate

difficulties

ex-

create

and produce an adverse

impact on the balance of payments.

As

the United States continued to sustain

balance of payments

deficits,

exchange

foreign

official

of comparable maturity, the statutory 4'/i per

produced a
flow of dollars into the hands of central banks
in countries with favorable payments balances.
Most of these dollars were invested at interest
in short-term marketable Treasury issues to
satisfy liquidity needs. Although these investments represented a reduction in potential

cent interest limit effectively foreclosed the

drain of U.S. gold, they did not fully meet

ury
of

full

leeway to provide maturities upwards

year as long as the interest rates paid re-

1

mained 414 per cent or

less.

Since the rates on

foreign-currency issues have generally been de-

termined by market yields on Treasury issues

is-

suance of bonds when market rates rose above

efforts to stabilize

other needs.

Although

that level. Accordingly, the Treasury requested
legislation,

which was passed

in

November

1966, to permit also the issuance of foreigncurrency-series notes having original maturities
of

1

to 5 years.

were redeemable, usually
holder. Others were
turity

at the option of the

made payable

before

ma-

according to prior agreement or were

callable

by the U.S. Treasury. In all cases of
payments are at par.

early redemption,

The

reduced

basic purposes of the

new

foreign-cur-

use has

their

since

the

currency-series

been substantially

mid-1960's,

securities

the

foreign-

do furnish another

investment alternative, thus helping to reduce

demand

the

Through 1966 most foreign-currency certificates had an original maturity of 3 months,
usually subject to redemption on 2 days' notice.
The longer issues generally had original maturities of 15 to 24 months and most were
made convertible into 3-month certificates, or

rates

for U.S. gold; they also directly

provide the United States with foreign currency

needed

to protect the dollar against speculation

and to meet day-to-day requirements arising
from trade, tourism, foreign aid, military commitments

and so

abroad,

forth.

Ordinarily

But in
payments
deficits, the purchase of foreign exchange with
dollars would only increase the amount of dolforeign currency

is

bought with

dollars.

a situation of sustained balance of

lars in foreign

hands.

The technique

of bor-

rowing foreign currency was used to avoid the
build-up of foreign dollar holdings.

rency issues were to provide a supply of for-

In addition to providing foreign exchange,

eign exchange for conducting operations to de-

foreign-currency

beyond

1

fend the U.S. dollar, to help cushion demands

year count as long-term investments. These

is-

on the U.S. gold stock by adding a new investment medium for foreign central banks and
governments, and to assist in meeting U.S. balance of payments deficits. In addition, the foreign-currency securities have proved to be a
useful device for temporarily augmenting international liquidity.

The more immediate developments

leading

to the introduction of foreign-currency issues

started in 1959, after a

number

of

major coun-

sues

bring

U.S.

issues

maturing

international

accounts

into

closer balance

on the generally accepted "liquidity balance of payments" basis, because
they are nonconvertible bonds or notes, which
cannot be optionally exchanged for certificates
or redeemed before 1 year.
Aside from being hquid earning assets to
central banks and governments, issues payable
in

foreign currencies are riskless in that they

protect the lender against exchange risk.

22

Through 1966 foreign-currency
denominated

Austrian

in

francs,

German marks,

francs.

The volume

ItaHan

were

issues

Belgian

schillings,

and Swiss

lire,

of foreign-currency series

outstanding rose to a peak of $1.3 billion in

III.

TREASURY BILLS

Treasury

larly offered

sonal

IN

of the calendar year 1966, regu-

end

the

tax- anticipation

nearly 2i/i

(excluding the sea-

had

series)

was by

risen

to

amount outstanding at
December 1958 from $23V'2

$57%

to

billion

bills

times the

the beginning of

rise

—

billion.

far the largest

This $34i/4

growth

in

billion

any cate-

gory of the public debt over the period, and it
represented more than 70 per cent of the increase in the total public debt.

The

increase in

volume of Treasury bills in the 8 years
after 1958 took place during two expansions
of the economy and one recession. By and
large it occurred without undue strains on
the money market except in early 1960 and
the

in

holder.

MARKET IMPACT AND ANALYSIS OF MAJOR NEW TECHNIQUES

INNOVATIONS
By

September 1965, but by the end of 1966 the
amount had declined to $860 million. Of this
total about $750 million was subject to redemption or conversion at the option of the

September 1966

To

rate cycle.

cussful expansion
careful use

at the crests of the interest-

a considerable degree the suc-

of the

program was

result

the

new techniques and

of

inno-

The 6-month

bill.

The 6-month

bill

did not

market acceptance immediately.
new bills were offered in
amounts of $400 million each week while offerings of 3 -month bills were reduced from
$1,800 million to $1,600 million. By June
full

the

Originally

1959,

when

6-month
3-month

and the economic recession was well under
way. (See Appendix Table 1 for 3- and 6month bill auction rates.)
The low point in Treasury short-term borrowing rates was reached in April 1961, at avauction

erage

the Treasury

bills
bill

to

$500

offerings

$1.0 billion and $1.2

upped

its

million

had declined
billion,

offerings of

while
to

the

between

average discount

on new 3- and 6-month bills had moved
up sharply and the spread between them had
climbed from an average of about 25 basis
points in the first few auctions to a high of 81
basis points. In consequence, the $500 million,
6-month bill cycle was not completed until the

rates

1 Background
tables and other material
found in the Appendix.

will

be

of

rates

2.18

per cent for 3

months and 2.30 per cent for 6 months. By
contrast, in the 1957-58 recession the low
point for 3-month bills was 0.64 per cent. In
the next economic expansion, starting in the
spring of 1961, short-term rates did not really

begin to

rise until after

the

first

offering of a

had been made in June of that
year and after the supply of 6-month bills had
been increased to $600 million per week.
By the late spring of 1961, the 6-month
strip of bills

Treasury

bill

was achieving

The coverage

ance.

subscriptions

vations.

achieve

second half of calendar year 1960. By that
time the peak of interest rates had been passed

to

ratio

—

full

that

allotments

market acceptis,

—was

the ratio of

averaging

220 per cent versus 185 per cent for the
3 -month bill. This occurred despite the increase in the weekly offerings of 6-month bills
to $500 million, while the 3-month offerings
had been gradually reduced from $1.8 billion
nearly

before

the

introduction of the longer

about $1.1 billion

in

bill

to

1961. During the period

from the cyclical high in rates in January 1960
to mid- 1961, the spread in average discount
rates between the two maturities had declined
to about 15 basis points, indicating a growing
awareness of the greater gain potential in the
longer bills. (See Appendix Table 3.)

Also during this period, bidding in the
6-month auctions became increasingly sophisticated. From 1959 to mid- 1961, the range in
an auction from the average of all successful
bid prices to the stop-out, the lowest accepted

NEW TECHNIQUES
bid,

narrowed

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

Expressed in terms
from the average bid rate
the stop-out rate declined from 4 basis
significantly.

the year, monthly average spreads did not rise

of yields, the range

above 20 basis points, and they were generally

to

considerably

points to

1

less.

Subscription coverage on the

longer of the two maturities had slipped a

basis point.

While the decline in average rate spreads
between the 3- and 6-month bills may well be
attributed to expectations of greater gains on
the longer bills in a falling-interest-rate envi-

ronment, the increased concentration of bids
demonstrates more clearly market acceptance

6-month bill.
By the end of 1963, following the Federal
Reserve discount rate increase from 3 to 3Vi
per cent, rates in the weekly auctions had also
of the

risen to 3V^ per cent or more.

The

increase in

but

tle,

was

it

still

lit-

close to 190 per cent during

1964

compared with
The bids on
6-month bills continued to be closely bunched
around the average rate, and the yield range
the fourth quarter of

175 per cent for 3-month

as

bills.

between the auction average and the stop-out
was usually less than 1 basis point. By this
time, also, dealer net positions in over-92-day

were running two to three times as large

bills

as in shorter

bills. It is quite likely that with an
upward-sloping yield curve continuing in the

rates reflected the enlarged

volume of weekly
amount of 3-month bills issued
each week had grown to $1.3 billion, and of
6-month bills to $0.8 billion. As a result of a

short-term area the market

offerings as the

a greater propensity for gain in the longer

$1.0 billion bill-strip-offering in October 1963,

the usual measures of market receptivity did

which added $100 million to 10 weekly maturities in the 26-week cycle, the total volume
of weekly bills outstanding had increased to

appreciably. During this period
on 3- and 6-month bills gradually rose,
and they were about 4V& and 414 per cent by
early December before the discount rate was
increased to 4V2 per cent.
Following the increase in the discount rate,

$38.5

billion, of

which

bills originally

accounted

maturity

to

for

$21.8

6 months
billion

or

about 57 per cent.
Despite the growth in the volume

of the

and the increases in short-term
interest rates that had taken place between
mid-1961 and December 1963, monthlylonger

bills

felt

there

was

still

bills.

Despite the escalation of the war in Viet-

nam

in July

1965, the situation with respect to

change

not

rates

bill

rates again rose rapidly

during the
the

first

and

after a

pause

jumped to
In the mean-

half of 1966, they

40

highest levels in

years.

time, dealer net positions in bills dwindled in

average rate spreads in the weekly auctions

response to expectations of higher rates in the

between the two maturities declined from about
25 basis points in December 1958 to 14 basis

short-term area, and by June 1966 they were

points in

December 1963. At times

the spreads

reached a low of 3 basis points,

and they

averaged 15 basis points during the period. In
corroboration
the

6-month

vironment,

of

the

market's

the

receptivity

of

a rising-interest-rate en-

in

bill

high

concentration

of

bids

the lowest points since such statistics be-

at

came

available in

3-month

the period of extreme tightness that developed

around the auction averages continued without

in the credit

significant change.

ing vigorous

During 1964, offerings of 6-month bills
were gradually increased to $1.0 billion per
week by the fall, while the 3 -month bill was
reduced from $1.3 biUion to $1.2 bilHon dur-

allay apprehensions

ing most of the period. Rates in the auctions

had moved close

to

count rate increase

4 per cent after the
in

dis-

November, but during

1960. Weekly offerings of

had again increased to $1.3 billion, but the spread between the two maturities
gradually widened and reached a high of 50
basis points in early September 1966, during
bills

markets.

Two weeks

and

average

follow-

relieve the pressure of

Federal agency borrowings and
the

later,

action by the administration to

PC

offerings,

reached
peaks of 5.59 per cent on the 3-month and
6.04 per cent on the 6-month bill.

The jump

the

levels

in

in

rates

bill

realization that part of the

auctions

was touched off by
burden of Govern-

ment financing and foregone PC sales would
have to be borne by the bill market. Market
hesitance in the auctions was demonstrated by
the widened range from the average rate to the
stop-out, which in the case of 6-month bills
fluctuated sharply from 1 to more than 6 basis
points in the third quarter. Oddly enough,
however, during

this

period the ratio of sub-

than the rates on comparable coupon issues.

And

that did not include the value of the tax-

and-loan-account credit created, which would

have added an estimated 31 basis points to the
It should be recalled, however, that

spread.

1959 was a year of rapidly

rising interest rates,

an environment not very conducive

new

cessful introduction of a

on annual

to the suc-

instrument. (For

Appendix Table

on both the 3- and
remained remarkably constant,
hovering around 170 per cent for the former

details

and around 200 per cent for the

cut back to $1.5 billion. Despite the reduction

allotments

scriptions

to

6-month

bills

In the

fall

latter.

of 1966, as tightness in the credit

began
to decline, and with that the spreads between
average rates on 3- and 6-month bills in the
weekly auctions dropped to less than 10 basis
markets was gradually eased,

bill

rates

by the year-end. In further evidence of
return to more normal conditions, the

points
the

On
in

the

bills see

4.)

rollover of the 1-year bill cycle

first

January 1960 the amount of the issue was
January 15, 1960,

in offerings, the cost of the

1-year

(average discount rate) was 5.07

bill

per cent. This was equivalent to a coupon yield

was the highest rate
by the Treasury for any issue

of 5.36 per cent and

of

interest paid

in

1958—61

the

The

interest-rate cycle.

next

1-year

auction

bill

range of bids from the average to the stop-out

1960, with $2.0 billion offered

was reduced to less than a basis point in November and December. At the same time,
dealer positions in bills maturing beyond 92

which

coupon-equivalent

of

yield

—

—

April

in

resulted in a

4.84

per

cent,

days rose sharply, indicating again the greater

But the
spread of 1.03 per cent above the comparable
1 -year-coupon-issue rate was the largest in the

gain potential on longer

quarterly cycle,

bills.

was 23

basis

points

lower.

the value of tax-and-loan-ac-

if

In summary, the market adjusted extremely

count credit

in the fixst four auctions in

6-month
Treasury bills. In the process, the amount of
weekly bills outstanding grew from $23 Vi billion in December 1958 at the start of the
6-month bill cycle to nearly $43 billion at the
end of 1966. Of that total, $26 billion, or 60
per cent, originated in 6-month bills. During
the same period the weekly offerings increased

disregarded.

The

well

to

the

increased

volume

of

The 1-year

bill.

A

was originated

bills that

quarterly cycle of 1-year
in

the

is

is

easily seen in the

range of bids from

average to the stop-out, a high for the
cycle of 13 basis points in terms of

1-year

bill

yield.

Thereafter,

the

amounts

in

the

next

three offerings were cut back to $1.5 bilHon;
after that they

were restored to $2.0 bilUon

through July 1962. During

this

period the cov-

erage ratio picked up from an average of 148

only from $1.8 bilUon to $2.3 billion.

bills

tion

1959

apathetic bidding in this auc-

1959. Issues of such

year averaged $2.0 billion per quarter

first two auctions of 1960 to
209 per cent in the next three, but ranged
from 173 to 208 per cent when offerings were

per cent in the

and about 330 days to maturity. Each offering
was adequately covered by the subscriptions,
with an average coverage ratio of 176 per cent.
This is not surprising because payment through
tax-and-loan-account credit was permitted. The
new bill cycle was expensive by comparison
with coupon-issue yields in the market. The
4.20 per cent average bank discount rate in the

increased to $2.0 biUion. Following the cut-

auctions adjusted to a coupon-equivalent yield

$2.0

basis of 4.41 per cent

was 38

basis points

more

backs to $1.5 bilHon, the concentration of bids

around the average returned to more normal
ranges.

For the

remaining

year

of

the

quarterly

amount offered in
four quarters was raised to $2.5

cycle through July 1963, the

three of the
billion

cycle

whereas in the other quarter

billion.

it

stayed at

Thus, by the time the monthly

was introduced, the

total

amount

of

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT
had

outstanding

annual

bUls

billion.

During

risen

to

$9.5

period the coverage ratio

this

did not change significantly on the average, but

other

measures

market

improving

indicated

acceptance.

For the quarterly cycle

nonbank

as a whole,

dealer awards ranged from 19 to 35 per cent
of total public allotments

—excluding

the offer-

ings paid through tax-and-loan-account credit,

which were awarded almost
mercial banks.

The average

entirely to

com-

of 25 per cent for

nonbank dealer awards to total allotments for
the quarterly bills compares with 21 per cent
on 3- and 6-month bills during the same period.

This indicates a greater participation of
bill

auction.

During the period from July 1960

to July

sophisticated bidders in the 1-year

a high of 44 basis points in August and re-

mained

high for the next three issues,

fairly

following the introduction of the 9-month

prove.

1963 the range of bids in the quarterly auctions from the midpoint to the stop-out declined to about Vi of 1 basis point. However,

bill

the spreads of coupon-equivalent rates above

any standard of measurement. Because

coupon-issue yields fluctuated sharply, ranging

auction instrument,

from 4 basis points less than 1 -year-couponissue yields to 52 basis points more. The higher

come

spreads

coincided

generally

raise short-term rates to

with

efforts

to

be more competitive

began

in

per month

cycle,

which

market reception than the quarterly cycle. The
subscription coverage averaged about 225 per
fall

1964. While this
the smaller

of 1963 through the end of
is

amounts

not significant in view of
offered, other

measures of

market acceptance clearly showed the preference for the monthly cycle. Spreads above
coupon-issue rates narrowed significantly, averaging about 12 basis points through the middle
of

as a

1966 as compared with more than twice

that average spread for

all

of the issues in the

nonbank

monthly

performed quite well

going

structure

of

developed

in the

summer

of 1966, the spread

above comparable coupon-issue yields rose to

to be-

tight

money
in the

been

has

rates

shaken.

9-month

bill,

The

bill.

which began

brief history of the
in

September 1966,

provides only a short-run opportunity for anal-

Coverage ratios on the four $500 million
monthly offerings in 1966 averaged 217 per
cent. However, only 83 per cent, or $1.7 bilysis.

$2.0 billion

lion of the

public holders.

Of

total,

was

allotted to

the $1.7 billion in public al-

lotments, 41 per cent was awarded to
dealers.

year

bill

nonbank

comparison, the simultaneous

In

1-

auctions produced an average cover-

age ratio of 210 per cent for the four $900
million

offerings.

those

In

cent, or $2.8 billion,

was

(See Appendix Table 5.)

25 per cent for the quarterly offerings.
Under the extreme monetary tightness that

tends

a

interest

of which the dealers were

Moreover,

it

in

market environment or when confidence

dealer

cycle.

market by
it is an

the

however,

awards as a percentage of total public allotments in the monthly cycle through mid- 1966
increased to an average of 43 per cent from

quarterly

cycle, the 1-year

in

expensive

relatively

The 9-month

billion

August 1963, met with a much better

cent from the

summary,

In

with rates abroad.

The $1.0

bill.

However, the range of bids from the average
to the stop-out rose to 10 basis points in June
1966, but the range in other monthly auctions
did not exceed 4 basis points. In December
the spread above coupon-issue yields declined
to normal levels once again as market expectations improved in an environment clearly reflecting moves toward further monetary ease.
In the second half of 1966, public allotments
dropped to 75 per cent of total offerings; during this period, the percentage of nonbank
dealer awards to public allotments fell to 23
per cent in the August auction, but picked up
again when the credit markets began to im-

auctions

79 per

allotted to the public,

awarded 44 per

In the four 9-month auctions of

cent.

1966 the

range of successful bids from the average to
the

3

somewhat greater than for
The average range was nearly

stop-out was

the annual
basis

1-year

bills.

points

bills,

as

against 2

but the difference

basis

may

points for

easily

be

at-

)

26

tributed to the newness of the

9-month

instru-

ment

tax-and-loan-account

through

credit,

the market, the four 9-month bills averaged

which was estimated to be worth 50 basis
points. Taking that into account, the spread
above the average of going rates on compara-

5.72 per cent (coupon-equivalent) for a spread

ble

ment.
In comparison with coupon-issue yields in

26 basis points above comparable coupon
issues, while the annual bills auctioned at the
same time averaged 5.74 per cent, about 27
basis points

above

1

-year-coupon-issue yields.

Thus, the early performance of the 9-month
bill was about on a par with the annual bill by
of these standards of comparison,

any

which

implies that the relative sizes of the amounts
offered

— $500

9-month

—

bill

million

per

month

of

the

versus $900 million of the 1-year

represented

a

good balance between the

two.
Bill strips.

offerings

From June

1961,

when

were made, through 1966,

the

first

six strips

of bills totaling $6.8 billion were issued.

That

amount included a $1.2 billion strip of three
month-end maturing bills issued in November
1966 as part of the 9-month cycle. (For details on strips of bills see Appendix Table 6.

The first bill strip covered 18 maturities of
$100 million each, with terms ranging from 8
to 25 weeks. The strip was sold at an average
bank discount

P-

3

j

i

rate of 2.31 per cent with pay-

bill

maturities

In June

of

1961,

was 35

when

basis points.

the

first

strip of bills

was offered, short-term rates were dechning
and the strip had no significant effect in turning rates upward. However, each subsequent
strip of weekly bills had a substantial impact
on the market. For example, in November
1961 the 3-month bill rate rose 14 basis points
between the announcement date for the strip of
bills and the day of the auction, and it rose
another 17 basis points between the auction
the payment date.
The degree of market impact
assess in each case because some

and

is

difficult to

of the effects

were anticipated by the
an aftermath of pre- or junior ad-

of the strip offering

market

as

vance refundings, which tended to put downward pressure on bill rates as rights were liquidated by holders not interested in the advance
refunding
All

offer.

of the

subscriptions

strips

were well covered, with
190 to 259 per

ranging from

cent of allotments. Official accounts did not

take part in the strip offerings;

INCREASES IN REGULAR BILLS OUTSTANDING,
November 1958 December 1966

all

of the offer-

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT
about 6 per cent. In the next 4 years,

were publicly allotted. Awards to nonbank dealers averaged 55 per cent of total allotments for the four strips for which payment
through tax and loan accounts was not
permitted. In the last two of these, nonbank
dealers accounted for 67 per cent of total al-

billion, or

lotments, indicating that sophisticated bidders

for details see

ings

were getting an increasing share of awards of

Summary
prior

innovations

of

regularly

of

issued

in

The

bills.

outstanding

bills

6-month

advent of the

the

to

grew by $12.5

regular bills outstanding

biflion.

in

bill

But of

amount pub-

that

holders acquired only $2.7 billion or 22

lic

per cent while the

accounts absorbed

official

(See Chart 5;

$9.8 billion, or 78 per cent.

Appendix Table

During the
big

the

rise

when

1959,
largely

—

—November

a substantial part of

occurred in

holdings

public

in

7.)

4-year period

first

1958-December 1962

bill strips.

amount

December 1966,

to

the brunt of deficit financing

borne by the

bill

market

in

was

a tight

December 1958 increased by 2Vi times by the
end of 1966. By and large, this substantial
increase was smoothly absorbed by the market.

monetary environment. But a greater part took
place in 1961 and 1962, when official action
was directed toward increasing the amount of

For the most part, the increase occurred during an 8-year period of widely fluctuating

liquidity in the

From

short-term rates.

the start of the eco-

nomic expansion, beginning in 1961, through
1966 average discount rates in the 3- and
6-month bill auctions ranged from 2.2 and 2.3
per cent, respectively, at the 1961 low points to
5.6 and 6.0 per cent at the peak in September
1966, and the range on annual bills was almost

3%

About one-half

as great.

percentage-point

in

rise

of the S'/i
bill

rates

to

took

place in the 9 months after the increase in the

Reserve discount rate

Federal

Even

1965.

strain

little

so,

in

December

market operated with
the period of sharp market

the bill

until

tension in the late

summer

of 1966. After ad-

ministration action to dispel fears and to relieve

and

some

PC

of the pressure of agency borrowing

sales, the

normal flow of

bifls into

and

economy

the expansion then

in the early years of

under way.

During the second 4 years, through Decem1966, the Federal Reserve System again
began to increase its bill holdings as the need

ber

"operation

for

this period,

twist"

waned.

Also

during

business corporations increasingly

found other short-term investments such as
commercial bank CD's more profitable than

—

Treasury bills, and later in the period ^from
mid-1965 through most of 1966 the banks
found it desirable to reduce their bill holdings
to meet the insatiable private demand for bank
credit. From 1964 on, the Federal Reserve increasingly acquired bills in open market operations to replace gold losses and rebuild the reserves needed for the continuation of economic

—

expansion.

However, even during the period

of rapid

out of the market was quickly restored. This

increase

occurred despite some apparent increase in the

counts, commercial banks and dealers contin-

impending burden on the bill market resulting
from the reduced pressures of Government
financing elsewhere on the credit markets.

bills.

An
crease

important
in

aspect

regularly

of

issued

the
bills

IVi-iold in-

should

be

pointed out. In the 4 years or so from the end
of

in

the

holdings

bill

of

official

ac-

major "underwriters" for new
Reserve found
it expedient to buy more bills than coupon issues in its open market operations did not
detract from the bill market's ability to undertake the distribution of the added supply.
ued

to act as the

The

fact that the Federal

November 1958 through December 1962,

by
amount public investors
absorbed $20.5 billion or 94 per cent, while
holdings of the Federal Reserve and Government Investment Accounts increased by $1.3

regularly issued bills outstanding increased

$21.8

billion.

Of

CASH REFUNDING

that

When

the

Treasury began

in

1960

to

refi-

nance through cash subscriptions instead of
rights

exchanges in

its

quarterly refinancings,

28

the change in technique gave rise to a

of questions.

After some 6Vi

quarterly cash refundings in

worth of new

lion

swers to a
ably clear.

securities

number

and 10
which STlVi bilwere issued, anyears

number of the questions are reasonSome of the questions are:

cash refinancing a complete substitute

Is

for rights refundings?

Which does a

better job of restructur-

ing the debt?

Which

more

is

expensive

for

the

Treasury?

How

do they compare with regard to
and activity of the dealer

the participation

market?

The following information provides some
the

bilhon

$71^/6

issued

in

quarterly

cash refinancings through 1966, $35Vi billion

was awarded

of the

to public subscribers (other than

Government Investment Accounts). During the same period $141
of

new

securities

rights refundings.-

Of

were issued

in

16

these, public holders re-

ceived $75 billion for an average exchange of

$4.7

billion. In the

cash refinancings the aver-

age amount allotted to public subscribers was
$3.5

billion,

indicating

the

that

Treasury

tended to use the exchange approach for the

some $7% billion were allotted in
The average length of these
longer issues in rights refundings was slightly
less than 60 months, or nearly 5 years, and in
terms of debt extension was equal to $42%
billion times 5 years or $212 bilhon bondyears. The average length in cash operations
was 70 months, but the effective debt extension was only $45 billion bond-years. Moreover, of these longer issues the pubhc allotment in
rights
was $35Vi
biUion
in
cash subscriptions.

comparison with

of

the

10 cash operations only a

billion in cash

opera-

effective in extending the length of those hold-

roUed over at

ings that are not automatically

maturity.

One

attribute of cash financings that has

counterpart in rights refundings
ury's control over the

amounts

is

$3.1 bilhon of

new money was

offered, includ-

new

About

raised in seven

of the 10 cash refundings, while in the
eration, instead of raising

no

the Treas-

ing additional cash or planned attrition.

first

cash, there

op-

was

about $660 million of planned payoff. In the
other two cases, offerings just about replaced

amounts without

attrition or ad-

ditional cash.

The

shorter-term anchor issue was offered. In three

two options were offered; and in one
operation there were three options. The Treas-

$6%

Thus, rights refundings were far more

the maturing
six

other than

ings, while

larger operations.

In

of offerings to debt extension.

billion in securities

anchor options were issued in rights refund-

the Federal Reserve and

billion

two types

About $42%

tions.

relevant comparisons:

Of

understates the difference in the contribution

variation in the allotment ratios illus-

one of the chief disadvantages of cash

trates

others,

ury provided more options to extend maturities

Of the 16 exchange
two were limited to one option. In each of these cases pubhc holdings of
the maturing issues were about $2Vi billion,
which was considered too small to warrant
more than a single option. Of the 14 remaining rights operations, 10 provided two options
and four had three options.
The average length of the issues offered in
rights exchanges was 28 months as against 22
months in the cash operations. But this greatly
in the rights refundings.

operations, only

refinancings.

ments to

The

ratio

For

details see

Appendix Table

8.

pubhc

allot-

15

individual issues offered in the cash refundings

ranged from 12 to 100 per cent. The 100 per

—

$365 million
bonds in August 1962, of
which $315 million was subscribed for and alcent allotment was on a small

—

issue of long-term

lotted to the public. In

November 1965,

a very

cautious market environment produced an al-

lotment ratio of 48 per cent on a single-option

18-month
received
total

note. In this case

much more than

in

many

subscribers

they wanted of the

$3.2 billion awarded to the public, which

weak secondary market
Even without those two

contributed to a very
-

of total

total public subscriptions for the

the

new

issue.

—

1

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

cases, however, the variation in allotment ratios to public investors

from 12

was

still

—with

about 35 per cent

to

an aver-

age ratio of 21 per cent.

The

cost

terms

in

of

on
cash offerings than on rights refundings. These
spreads are the differences between the offering rates and market yields on comparable
outstanding

needed

was

than existing

slightly

Such

maturities.

less

spreads

are

new issues more attractive
issues. The average spread was

make

to

lowing a financing. Expressing the exposure in

each financing as a percentage of allotments,

Treasury

the

to

"underwriting spreads"

These data indicate the dealers' degree of exposure to market risk in or immediately fol-

quite large

the

22 per cent of

1

basis points in the rights ex-

V4

changes. This was not due to the greater proportion

longer-term issues

of

There

refundings.

rights

offered

the

in

been no

has

dis-

cernible pattern in the spreads with respect to

However, on both kinds of

maturity.
the

offerings

spreads declined substantially from early

1963

to late 1966.

The

per cent, with an 11 Vi per cent average. Here
the difference in the

and

market

in

activity of the dealer

cash as compared with rights re-

fundings showed no clear-cut differences, ac-

cording to

statistics

on dealer

activity

by the Federal Reserve Bank of

These

statistics,

which begin

in

compiled

New

York.

1961, included

nine of the 10 cash refinancings and 13 of 16

through 1966. In these financ-

rights operations

two averages

is

negligible,

indicating that the dealers were about equally
willing to take risks in either type of financing.

A
ume

third index of dealer activity

immediately

or

is

the vol-

of trading in when-issued securities during

available

through

after

nearly

for

seventh

the

a

Data are

financing.

refundings

the

of

all

day following the

nouncement of terms. Although trading

an-

in cash

operations did not start until after the sub-

books closed, while trading

scription

began

refundings

participation

total issues to the

an average of 1 1 per cent, and on the rights
approach the range was from about 7 to 20Vi

about lOV^ basis points in the cash operations
as against

was 5
pubUc for

the range in the case of cash refundings
to

nouncements,

immediately
difference

this

in rights

an-

the

after

procedure

in

is

not considered significant due to the high concentration

Trading

of

in

trading

rights,

the

in

mainly

dealers prior to exchange,

first

few days.

by
was excluded since
accumulations

can be considered equivalent to dealer

that

awards

cash refinancings.

in

The volume

of

trading in each financing has been related to

amount

ings dealer activity varied widely within each

the

to

the

type of offering, but the averages were not far

public, to allow for differences in the size

and

(See Appendix Tables 9 and 10.)
For example, awards to reporting dealers
through cash subscriptions ran from about 6V2
to more than 20 per cent of total allotments to
apart.

the public for an average of roughly 12'/i per
cent.

Issues

dealers

to

rights

in

refundings

ranged from approximately 9 to 26'/2 per cent

and averaged 14'/i per
The small difference between the two av-

total

in the

number

in

one type of opera-

Another

comparison
net

long

refi-

which data were available,

trading ranged from 21 to 32 V2 per cent, for

an average of 26 per
31

cent.

cent. In rights operations

—from

was somewhat broader

per cent

—

for an average of

13'/i

19Vi per

However, the difference between the two

averages

is

not large.

One

possible explanation

stems from the circumstance that unsophisti-

tion as in the other.

maximum

two types of

trading volume in cash

six of the eight for

to

much

of refundings in the

The average

cent.

about as

issued

nancings ran from liVi to 43 per cent, but in

the range

ticipate

securities

operations.

of issues to the public

erages reflects the dealers' willingness to par-

of

of

position

activity

of

when-issued securities in a cash

the

is

dealers

in

cated

ample

investors

—

—

the

smaller

banks,

for

ordinarily prefer rights refundings

exto

refinancing

cash refinancings. Guessing the probable per-

plus

centage allotment in a cash operation requires

when-issued securities in a rights operation.

a high degree of market sophistication. Even

and

the

maximum

position

in

rights

30

expert appraisal
guess

more or

much

possibly

new

of the

less

than they wish to hold,

curities

may

often wrong. Rather than
and receive possibly much

is

incorrectly

many

se-

investors

amount

prefer to acquire the exact desired

secondary market.

in the

the fact that the

average of the marketable

coupon debt outstanding

each midyear durwas about $154 bilof which about $117 bilUon was publicly
at

ing the 6'/4-year period

held. Thus, the

advance refundings during the

period represented offers to

marketable

the

roll

debt

over some
the

in

1%

public's

hands, with the turn-ins amounting to about
cent.

multiplicity

of

offerings

and maturities of the

rates

with

eligible

verita-

respect

to

and offered

more than 65 outstanding issues
and about 25 newly offered issues were involved, with several of these eligible and ofissues. In all,

fered issues used again in succeeding operations.

The

maturities of

new

issues offered in

exchange ran from a little less than 4 years to
more than 38 years, while those of outstanding
eligible issues ranged from less than a month

more than 10%

to

holdings

public

years.

of

The percentages

eligible

issues

All

groups

necessary

is

for

of

these

the

advance refundings occurred

peak-to-peak

interest-rate

August 1966. The offering

advance

refunding

in

the

released

prior to the full-scale advance refunding operation of
pre-,

October 1960. The three categories are

junior,

and senior advance refundings,

based on the terms to maturity of the

eligible

issues involved. Pre-refunding refers to the ex-

change of

with remaining terms

eligible issues

than

to maturity of less

1

year; junior advance

refunding refers to those maturing between

1

and 5 years; and senior advance refunding to
those 5 years or longer. These are arbitrary
distinctions, particularly when it is found that
seven of the 18 junior refunding issues had
remaining terms of

IVz years, while the

to

1

32 pre-refunding issues had remaining terms
of a month to 9% months.
ranging from
For the purposes of this paper, the measure

yields

performance

of

been

based

cycle,

on the

advance

in

refundings

has

on the percentage of

primarily

publicly held issues exchanged. In this regard,

performance

number

of

is

complicated by the fact that a

the

pre-refunding and junior re-

funding issues were

made

more than

eligible in

one advance refunding. Moreover, some
ble

issues

standing

—

eligi-

were reopened that is, the outamounts were added to between

—

advance refundings.

Over

all,

about 34 per cent of the issues

publicly held that were
in

made

eligible for ad-

1960-66 were exchanged,

the eligible issues are all regarded as not

if

having been previously included in an earlier

advance refunding.

If

such double counting

is

eliminated, the average proportion exchanged
cent.*

For purposes of

Appendix Table
provides detailed informa1
on each advance refunding and the totals for

1960-66.

coupon

analytical

two of which were described
paper on

white

would be about 46 per
2

tion

issues

refundings have been grouped into three categories,

vance refunding

spanning a period from early January 1960 to
late

eligible

Performance factors. With such wide variand terms, some degree of segregation of these operations into more compa-

of

exchanged

covered a range of 8.6 to 72.2 per cent.
within

while

%

These advance refundings included a
ble

ranged from IVa to 5 per cent.

rable

Between June 1960 and August
1966 the Treasury conducted 13 advance refunding operations. In magnitude a total of
about $286 billion in outstanding issues was
made eligible for exchange offers, and of these
about $204 biUion was in public hands.
Slightly over $69 billion, or more than onethird of public holdings, was exchanged.^ The
scope of these operations can be judged from

60 per

1966,

rates

purposes. Thus, for most analyses the advance

Scope.

times

on

gust

ations in rates

ADVANCE REFUNDING

lion,

new issues ran from a low of 3.63 per cent in
March 1961 to a high of 5.24 per cent in Au-

1

-

Based on figures

in

Appendix Table

11.

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

however, and with the extensive
ownership as maturities shorten, in

simplicity,

changes

IN

in

the analyses that follow, allowance

is

made

for

This

strongly

implies

that

the

shorter

the

length of the eligible issue, the larger the per-

centage that will be exchanged.

As

a

broad

double counting only within category groups.

generalization that

For example, an

However, other factors also had a bearing
on performance in advance refundings. One
such factor was the coupon rate of the eligible
issue. In making this comparison, the total
amount exchanged of all issues of a certain
coupon rate was divided by the amounts of

eligible issue in a junior re-

funding category (1- to 5-year maturity) that

was involved twice in an advance refunding
without having been added to in the meantime
is treated as one eligible issue merely having
been offered additional options; or for some
purposes

second

the

involvement

is

disre-

ings,

became

of each

gory

(

within- 1 -year maturity)

is

regarded as

one not subject to a previous advance refunding.

Account
case

eligible

issues

involved

made

As shown

of

additions

to

senior

of

IVi's) was

taken

between advance refundings. In
refundings none of the

eligible issues

the

also

is

in

Chart

World War
more than once.

(the

eligible
6,

II

producing a weighted-average percentage

initial

coupon

size

exchanged.

First,

use of each individual issue

only the

was consid-

when an issue was made eligimore than once it was closer to maturity,
hence more apt to have a higher turn-in rate
based on the amount remaining in public
ered. Generally,

ble

Moreover,

hands.
investors

pre-refundings with

the case.

those issues in public hands before the refund-

garded. However, a junior refunding issue that
eligible again in the pre-rcfunding cate-

is

in

pre-refundings

assumed that when the

many

issues reached

maturity, the refunding offer might include a

nearly 45 per cent of eligible public holdings

short-term option only, or that the operation

exchanged were the most successful category if
account is taken of the same issue having been
involved in more than one advance refunding.

might be a cash refinancing with no right to

Junior refundings were the next most successful

pon

size

top

tier of

category with 37Vi

per cent exchanged, and

senior refundings are last with 32 Vi per cent.

exchange.

Chart 7 shows the relationship between cou-

and the percentage exchanged. The
bars gives only a hint of any signifi-

cant relationship

if all

EXCHANGES OF PUBLICLY HELD ISSUES
REFUNDINGS, 1960-66
AMOUNTS INVOLVED

_

of the ehgible issues in-

IN

ADVANCE

PERCENTAGE EXCHANGED

AMOUNT

SfEXCHANGED

OVCR
5 VRS.

-TERM TOMATURH or EllGieLC ISSUES-

SIZE OF ELIGIBLE-ISSUE COUPON RATES IN ADVANCE
REFUNDINGS RELATED TO PERCENTAGE OF PUBLIC HOLDINGS
EXCHANGED: First Offerings Only

from U.S. Tre

volved in the advance refundings are lumped

no tendency because only one coupon

But when they are distributed according to the type of operation in which they

made

together.

—

pre-, junior, or senior refund-

fairly

apparent that a rough inverse

were involved
ings

—

it is

On

size

was

eligible.

the basis of prehminary studies, the cor-

relations in the pre-

and junior refundings are

not precise enough for truly predictive pur-

correlation exists between the size of the ehgible-issue

coupon

rate

and the percentage ex-

changed. The tendency

is

more evident

in the

case of pre-refundings than in junior advance
refundings,'' while the senior refundings

show

• The one issue clearly out of line in the junior refunding was the V/a per cent note of Feb. 15,
1965, with 67 per cent exchanged in the January

1965 advance refunding. It was barely over 1 year to
maturity at the time and was held largely by banks
and corporations willing to turn in their holdings for
the rights value involved. In addition, dealers were
more satisfied to position the notes until maturity
since that eligible issue carried the second highest
coupon rate in the refunding, thus reducing their
carrying cost. The issue bearing the highest coupon
rate, 4 per cent, was not so readily available, and
relatively fewer rights were turned in to the market.

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

poses. Such studies of the resuhs in advance

servations to permit any meaningful conclu-

refundings through July 1964 indicate a coeffi-

sions.

(r) of .565

cient of correlation squared

the case of pre-refundings

and only about .243

the case of junior operations.

in

possible that as the

in

number

is

It

quite

of advance refund-

tors

It

is

—such

issue, its length,

ble
also

coupon size of the offered
and the shortness of the eligi-

remaining term

issue's

significant.

And

ings of all types grows and additional refinements are used, the statistics will yield more

policy

favorable results.

time of a refunding

In those cases where

made

same

the

issue

no pattern emerges with respect to size of
coupon, mainly because there are too few ob-

ing,

and

of

to

the

interest-rate

maturity

course,

general

are

only

monetary

environment

become

—

with

at

the

overriding.

Another apparently important factor
As shown in Chart

length of extension.

is

the

8,

the

greater the extension, the smaller the percent-

age that

is

likely to

be taken

in pre-

and junior

PERCENTAGE OF ELIGIBLE ISSUES EXCHANGED RELATED TO
THE LENGTH OF EXTENSION IN ADVANCE REFUNDINGS

8

First Offerings

p
2

observations,

limited

was

advance refund-

eligible again in a later

however, that other fac-

evident,
as the

3

H

5

6

Only

—
34

refundings. In senior operations no truly significant pattern

formance

emerges except that the per-

the

in

better than in

first

the

senior

refunding

was

second, and better in the

(The terms to maturity of the eligible issues in each of the last
two senior refundings were longer than those
in the preceding one. Moreover, each succeeding refunding occurred later, and the ofi:ered
issues were the same in each case. Therefore,
second than

the

first

in the

third.

senior refunding provided the longest

extensions of the three, the second produced
the next longest extensions, and the last pro-

duced the shortest extensions. The lengths of
the extensions are shown in Appendix Table
11.) Here again the correlation between years
of extension and percentages exchanged even
in the pre- and junior operations is imprecise
and cannot be used with any appreciable deanother

factor

that

should

logically

attempt to find useful relationships for

multiple

number

sufficient

may be

of

degrees

freedom.

fundings grows, the data will provide

It

more

precisely useful statistical conclusions.

Investor participation. The following anal-

advance refundings through
two in 1966 were combinations
of regular refundings at maturity and precover

yses

The

1965.

the

last

refundings, thus precluding the investor classifi-

cation of the offered issues originating from
the regular as against the pre-refunding issues.

This

leaves over

still

exchanges for

$62Vi

billion of public

analysis.''

The ownership

pattern in those exchanges

between the three

senior refundings and the pre- and junior re-

The

senior operations included as el-

IVi's of September 1967-72,

pay-

of

that as experience with advance re-

from

(boot)

a

amount of

cant results primarily because the

fundings.

course, has to take adjustment

in

signifi-

data then available was too small to provide a

have had a substantial bearing on the percentage exchanged is the increase in coupon rate
the eligible to the offered issue. This, of

1964

study yielded no

correlation

closely follows the division

gree of confidence for predictive purposes.
Still

An

the advance refundings through July

igible issues the

World War

ing terms of over 5 years.

included

II 21/2

The

all

's

and the

with remain-

pre- and junior

ments into account. As with the other factors
mentioned, a very rough relationship appears
to exist, but again it is imprecise and does not

refundings

stand the test of correlation significance.

panies and mutual savings banks together ac-

Prehminary studies

failed

to

up any

turn

conclusive evidence that the attractiveness of
the offerings in terms of the yield spread

on

the offered issues above the prevaihng market
pattern of rates

had any appreciable

effect

on

When measured

against another variable

the size of the offered-issue

coupon

However,

this is

—

not too surprising. With an

upward-sloping yield curve, although gradually
diminishing in slope, the longer options carried
the higher coupons during most of the active

advance refunding period of June 1960 to January 1965, and apparently the length of the extension

was

As

a stronger factor than the

in

Table

1,

insurance com-

quired 50 per cent of the $7.6 billion in
3'/2

new

per cent bonds in the senior refundings.

In the

first

two senior operations these investor

accounted for more than 58 per cent of
the BVi's taken; but in the third, they could
classes

more

fully

because their hold-

ings of the 2Vi's ehgible in that refunding

had

been largely depleted by conversion into nonmarketable

2%

per cent bonds in 1951 and

1952.

Pension funds of State and local governments exchanged over $800 million of the
wartime IVi's, picking up the next largest part
of the offered long-term 3'/2's. Other State and
local funds

coupon
''

size of offered issues.

indicated

the per-

centage taken showed an inverse relationship.

other eUgible issues.

(See Appendix Table 13.)

not participate

the proportion exchanged.

all

accounted for nearly $650 million,

Exchanges

in the

1960-65 advance refundings, by
Appendix Table 12.

investor classes, are covered in

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

TABLE 1: PUBLIC PARTICIPATION
OF INVESTOR

Investor class

35

IN

ADVANCE REFUNDINGS,

1960-65,

BY CLASS

36

TABLE

2:

PUBLIC

IN

MATURITY DISTRIBUTION OF ISSUES ACQUIRED BY THE
1960-65, BY CLASS OF INVESTOR

ADVANCE REFUNDINGS,

In billions of dollars

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

5-year maturities declined by nearly $13
lion over the period. This

37

bil-

the maturity area

is

which a large part of commercial bank ac-

into

quisitions

advance

the

in

would

refundings

have shortened with the passage of time. Since
they acquired almost $30 billion of issues in
the 4- to 10-year maturity area,

it

follows that

the banks, like the dealers, were generally act-

ing in an underwriting capacity in these operations. In addition, the

ing

these

securities

mechanism for distributwas through the dealer

market. Thus, in large measure, the success of
the advance refunding technique was due to
the underwriting and distributing functions of

these two groups.

Market impact.

In

its

white paper called

Debt Management and Advance Refunding the

long-term investors would be given

thought,

the opportunity to extend their intermediate-

term

holdings

before

those

largely gravitated into the

had

securities

hands of short-term

inducement to extend
would be provided by higher coupon rates of
interest, based on the higher investment yields
resulting from an upward-sloping, market-pattern-of-rates curve. Moreover, in such an exinvestors. In general, the

change the injection of new long-term funds

would be substantially smaller than in a regular maturity refunding, hence the upward pressure on long-term rates would be minimized.
These tenets remained generally in effect
through the March 1962 combination juniorsenior refunding. Thereafter, however, senior
advance refunding was discontinued. First, be-

Treasury maintained that the impact of ad-

cause of congressional criticism, and second,

vance

because after

refunding

on

long-term

interest

would be much smaller than that

rates

of ordinary

all

the holders of the wartime

2l4's had been given an opportunity to ex-

cash financing or of maturity refunding, given

change, few alternative low coupon issues re-

equal volumes of long-term debt extension in

mained

The

either case.

discussion in the white paper

of exchanging intermediate-term

bonds
on the one hand, and finding new long-term
funds or issuing long-term bonds for cash or in
refundings at maturity, on the other.
It was thought, in the latter case, that new
cash borrowing would absorb long-term funds
otherwise available for private or State and
local needs and that the added supply of long
Treasury bonds would exert upward pressure
on interest rates generally. It was also felt that
this would occur in regular refundings at maissues for long-terra (senior refundings)

By

turity.

the time issues that

long-term

reached

maturity,

were
they

originally

would be

held mostly by short-term investors or as liquid-

by other

and neither of
these investor groups would want long-term
bonds in exchange. In that case, new longterm investment funds would be required for
the purchase of the "rights" or the "whenity reserves

issued"

new

maturity,

investors,

a

re-

the

publicly

fall

of 1960 to

1962, $8.0 billion of existing

spring of

held issues had been extended into

new long-term bonds maturing beyond

15

volume of debt
extension, yields on mortgages and on longterm corporate and municipal bonds continued
years. Despite this substantial

to decline.

During the

period

that

through

followed

January 1965, the Treasury revised

its

position

on the circumstances under which long-term
bonds might be issued in advance refundings.
In most of the combination junior and pre-

March 1962, the existing issues
made eligible for exchange into

refundings after

involved were

long-term bonds. Consequently, a substantial

expansion

in the role of the dealer

market was

required in the transfer of rights, in helping to

underwrite the refundings, and in distributing
the

new

issues to firm holders.

tively little net

Although

new money was needed,

rela-

the re-

securities in "rights" refundings at

vised procedure induced a considerable degree

new

and a substantial amount
overhang of the new securities in the after
market. Nevertheless, it was felt that these pre-

thus

paralleling

the

effect

of

long-term issues sold for cash.

In

for senior advance

In the meantime, from the

centered primarily on the contrast between the
relative ease

as candidates

fundings.

senior

advance

refunding,

of market churning
of

it

was

38

[yields on public

9

and private long-term

issues, 1960-66

—

Note. Montlily averages of daily ligurLs, except for FHA mortgages, which are secondary
market yields as ot the hrst of the month, as reported by the Federal Housing AdministraBonds New Aa corporate; Treasury estimates of reoffcring rates; new municipals:
Bond Buyer's index of 20 issues

—

tion.

and junior refundings would act

as catalysts to

reduce market hesitance and to increase activinterest in the long-term securities in

and

ity

general. Thus,

it

was expected

upward

that the

either leveled off or declined in five of the eight

refundings

in

which

bonds

long-term

issued. Also, in five of the eight cases,

were
by the

time the subscription books had been closed,

impact on long-term rates would continue to

long-term rates were approximately back to or

be small.

were under

Expectations based on the newer concepts

During the March
1962 to January 1965 period, yields on longterm Treasury issues rose 13 basis points from
4.01 to 4.14 per cent, but rates on private and
were

fairly

municipal

shown

Aa

in

well

realized.

long-term

Chart

9.

obligations

declined,

The monthly average

corporate reoffering rates declined

of

as

new

basis

1

point; mortgage rates in the secondary market

new

declined 25 basis points; and yields on

municipal bonds

Appendix Table

fell

about 9 basis points. (See

14.)

During

this

period an

additional $6.3 billion of publicly held Treas-

ury issues were extended beyond 15 years.

While the more prolonged

effect of

is

not

readily discernible in a period of slowly rising

bond

yields, the

immediate rate impact of such

operations was clearly minimal. This
trated in Chart 10. After the initial

lowing

the

announcement,

is

illus-

jump

long-term

fol-

yields

to

be

flat

announcement,
or to dechne

thereafter.

In the three refundings wherein long-term
rates

were

slightly higher 15

market days

the announcement, the rates were

up

after

less

than

from the level before the announcement. In most cases, yields remained
level for some time thereafter. Obviously, mar5 basis points

ket trend comparisons cannot be carried
further

in

this

connection,

as

other

would increasingly influence the

much

factors

interest-rate

environment soon after a refunding.

One
that

advance

refundings on long-term Treasury yields

their levels at the

and they continued

shown in Chart 10 is
remained remarkably stable

interesting point

market

yields

most part from one refunding operation
Except for the October 1960 and
the March 1963 operations, yields on longterm U.S. Treasury issues were within an 11for the

to another.

basis-point

range

immediately following

the

announcements.

The experience with long-term bonds

issued

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

39

advance refundings through 1965 amply

in the

demonstrates that debt extension can be ac-

complished

with

long-term rates.

relatively little impact on
Between October 1960 and

January 1965 about $14.3

billion in publicly

held eligible issues were extended into maturities

ranging from nearly 17 to more than 38

economic
expansion. In fact, average market rates on
mortgages and yields on corporate and municipal bonds were generally lower at the end of
years, during a period of substantial

this

period than at the beginning, while Treas-

ury long-term rates were

less

than one-quarter

of a percentage point higher. Only after the

enlargement of the war in Vietnam in July
1965, followed by the increase in the Federal

Reserve discount rate
est rates

The

begin to

in

December, did

inter-

economy was not
in

accelerated rise in interest rates pro-

fully reflected in the in-

long-term Treasury yields because

the 414 per cent interest ceiling brought to an

abrupt halt the chance of any increase in the
supply of long-term bonds. The upward pressure
fully

on Treasury
in

the

yields

was

re-

on a 4-year, 9-month note
combined maturity and
pre-refunding operation of August 1966. During the extreme credit squeeze that followed
the refunding announcement in late July, the
market yield on the new SVa's rose to a high
of 5% per cent on August 29.
Dealer participation and activity. Availin

the

able statistics on dealer activities compiled

Bank

of

New York

by

give

the clear impression (Table 3) that dealer participation in the first five

BOOKS CLOSING DATE*
JAN. 22, 1964

V_
or inlerest-adjustment, date.

**In the refundings ot September 1961, March 1962, and March 1963, books were
about one week earlier.
Note. Based on data from U.S. Treasury Dept.

—

In

a 5V4 per cent rate

was required

ANNOUNCEMENT DATE

* Issue,

area.

sponse to the sharp increase in market yields,

advance refundings

LONG-TERM TREASURY YIELDS DURING RELEVANT ADVANCE REFUNDINGS

I

more

reflected

intermediate-term

the Federal Reserve

rise sharply.

duced by the war and by the overheating of

10

the

crease

40

TABLE 3: ALLOTMENTS, MAXIMUM NET POSITION,
AND TRADING VOLUME OF REPORTING
DEALERS IN ADVANCE REFUNDINGS, 1960-65
Percentages of total publi

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

On

advance refundings.

the

in

IN

the

average,

they acquired 21 per cent of total issues to the

gree of debt extension in another way. But
is

difficult to

escape the conclusion that the

it

is-

public in the advance operations through Janu-

suance of long-term bonds in cash financings

compared with 14V2 per cent in
the quarterly rights refundings from August

or through regular refundings at maturity, in

ary 1965, as

1961 through

One index

May

1966.

same volume as through advance refundwould either have been impossible under

the

ings,

per cent interest ceiling, or without

maxiwhen-

the ceiling

would have been considerably more

issued securities, which measures the degree of

expensive.

The experience with

mum

of dealer activity

net long position in

their exposure to

market

risk.

As

of total public allotments, this

same

in

is

rights

their

plus

a percentage

was about the

both types of operations. In the quar-

terly rights refundings

tioned, dealers'

during the period men-

maximum

net positions per re-

the

4'/i

regular financ-

comparison with advance refundings

ings in

in

the 1960's clearly points to that conclusion.

As indicated in Table 5, the total amount of
bonds of over-1 0-year maturities issued in the
3-year period from April 1960 through April
cash financings or regular maturity re-

funding averaged 11.3 per cent of total public

1963

allotments, as against 10.7 per cent in the ad-

fundings was $1.9 billion. During this period

vance refundings. But excluding the

the Treasury

first

five

advance refundings, their maximum net positions in the other six averaged 13.4 per cent.

Another measure of dealer activity is the
volume of trading in when-issued securities
during or immediately after a financing.

Com-

parable data indicate that dealers traded the

new

issues

more

actively in the

advance

re-

funding operations than in the regular quarrefundings.

terly

Available figures on trading

through the seventh day following the announcements of terms show that the accumulated volume of trading in the advance refundings was 24.8 per cent of total issues to the
public as compared with 19.4 per cent in the
quarterly rights operations. Excluding the
five
rises

by

first

advance refundings, the trading volume
to 27.8 per cent of the new issues taken

all

public holders.-'

Cost of advance refunding.

It is

virtually

impossible to quantify the "true" net extra cost

from advance refunding.

or saving

resulting

Once such

a refunding has been

consummated

no one can know, or even guess with confidence, what would have happened without it
or by attempting to accomplish the same de-

in

the last strenuous attempts

issue long-term

then abandoned as an impractical means of

producing
scale.

debt

on

extension

substantial

a

In these financings the Treasury issued

long-term bonds on five separate occasions in

amounts averaging about $380 million per of(For details see Appendix Table 17.)
During a closely similar period the Treasury
conducted five advance refundings in which
bonds longer than 10 years were offered. The
total amount extended was $13.6 billion, and

fering.

about

averaged

$2.7

billion

per

operation.

bonds
was nearly 2% years longer, and their interest
yield was about 3 basis points (0.03 per cent)
less, than on the bonds issued for cash or in
regular refundings. Thus, although the two
methods achieved roughly comparable degrees

The average term

of

to maturity of these

debt extension

costs,

closely

at

similar

interest

average amount extended per ad-

the

vance refunding was more than seven times as
great.

In

(For
the

Treasury
For a discussion of the longer-run effect of
advance refunding on dealer trading volume in the
intermediate- and long-term areas of the market, see
Louise Ahearn and Janice Peskin, Market Pcrfonii-

made

bonds without resorting to
advance refunding. It was also the period during which the bond auction was introduced and

to

details see

remaining

found

over- 10-year

it

debt

Appendix Table 17.)
advance refundings the

possible

by

to

another

increase

$4.2

the

billion

^

ance as Reflected
this series, pp.

in

Aggregative Indicators, Part 2 of

Ill and 112.

without

offering

an

than 4.25 per cent. In

investment

yield

higher

about

$17%

billion

all,

of long-term debt was advance refunded between October 1960 and January 1965 before

,

TABLE

5:

ISSUES OF OVER-10-YEAR TREASURY BONDS, 1960-65
Average

Amount
of dollars)

n

offering
yield

offering
yield
(in per cent)

issued
(in millions

spread '
per cent)

(in

cash financings and regular refundings al
maturity, Apr. 1960-Apr. 1963

In advance refundings:
Oct. 1960-Sept. 1963 .
Jan. 1964-Jan. 1965 =.

1

2

sues of comparable maturity.
cash financings or regular refundings at maturity

Spreads above market yields o
No bonds longer than 10 year;

i

this period.

the rise in interest rates during the last

mer

sum-

of the period effectively foreclosed the of-

claims from time to time that Treasury

the

little impact on economic
management could not comforta-

debt operations have

fering of issues longer than 5 years because of

cycles, debt

the 4V^ per cent interest limitation on bonds.

bly ignore even the marginal procyclical effect

In terms of spreads above existing market
yields on comparable maturities, long-term

of a large-scale absorption of long-term funds

bonds issued for cash and in regular refundings appeared to be about as attractive as
those in advance refundings. The average of
offering yield spreads was 12 basis points in
the cash and maturity refundings and 11 basis
points in the first five advance refunciings.
In view of these statistics, it seems probable
that regular operations on the scale of advance
refundings could not have succeeded. Long-

ings during a recession.

two of the regular refundings during the 1960-63 period were for

compare favorably. For

cash subscription. In both of these cases the

through cash subscription or in regular refund-

allotment ratio was 100 per cent, indicating a
considerable degree of unwillingness on the

ings

term bonds offered

in

part of investors to subscribe for long-term

It seems reasonable to infer that massive
amounts of debt cannot be extended at long
term through regular means, except possibly
during a fairly protracted recession. Despite

ISSUED

6:

n cash financings and regular refundings
maturity. May 1960-Nov. 1966

'

Gov-

ernments, would also be a strong procyclical
influence.

As was

true of long-term issues, the relative

costs of advance refunding offerings in the in-

termediate maturity area and of similar maturissued

ities

issues

regular

in

maturing

in 3

appear to
comparison new

financings
this

through 10 years offered

were matched against similar issues of-

fered in advance refundings.

As shown

in

Table

6,

from

May 1960

through November 1966, about $45 billion of
3- to 10-year securities were issued at an average offering rate of 4.15 per cent with an average term of 5.6 years in regular financings. In

comparison, issues of a similar term offered in

TREASURY SECURITIES MATURING BETWEEN

3

AND

Amount

Average

issued

of dollars)

offering
yield
(in per cent)

44.9

4.15

56.5

4.11

;

In advance refundings, June 1960-Aug. 1966.

interest rates,

including long-term rates other than on

YEARS

10

IN 1960-66

(in billions

Moreover, as indicated

any upward pressure on

earlier,

is-

sues.

TABLE

cash financings or regular maturity refund-

in

Spreads above market yields on outstanding issues of comparable maturity.

Average
offering
yield

spread ^
per cent)

(in

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

advance refundings, totaled $56.5

43

billion,

at

refunding

is

not mandatory as

an average investment yield of 4.11 per cent

of a

maturing

(For

may

logically

with an average maturity of 6.4 years.
details see

Appendix Table

funding

comparable maturity was slightly more in the
advance refundings than in cash financings and
regular refundings. In practice, however, such
spreads have not been an important factor in

turity

exchange percentage

in

ad-

value

the

of

new cash do

not reflect the

tax-and-loan-account credit in-

volved.
It

case

be

regular financings

the

noted,

tended was for the
not

however, that

should
of

all

full

the

in

the

debt ex-

term of 5.6 years while

of the 6.4 years in advance refunding

represents debt extension. In advance refund-

reduced by the

ing the debt extension

is

maining terms of the

eligible

issues.

re-

In the

in the first place

structure

of

to

is

improve the ma-

marketable

the

same point

at

debt,

it

maturity

would have been extended to

the eligible issues
the

effect

be measured on the basis of

seems appropriate to assume that

of time as in the actual ad-

vance refundings.

More

vance refundings. Moreover, the yield spreads
in financings for

the refunding

the reason for offering an advance re-

since

fered yields above market rates on issues of

determining the

is

Thus, the budget

an issue reaches maturity. But

waiting until

18.)

In this case, the average spread of the of-

issue.

the

explicitly,

additional

cost

(per

$100) is the difference between the interest
rate on the outstanding eligible issue and the
rate on the new issue offered in exchange, acting over the remaining term of the old issue.

The saving (per $100)

is the difference between the interest rate on the new issue offered
in the exchange and the rate that would be required to reopen the same new issue when the
remainder of the old issue reaches maturity.

This difference

applied to the period from

is

case of junior advance refunding into interme-

the maturity of the old issue to the maturity of

diate issues this can reduce the debt extension

the new.

The following

considerably. But even with full allowance for

analysis includes only those

on 3- to 10-year issues in the advance refundings was 5.3 years.
Thus the bond-years of extension (amounts

eligible

times years) in the regular financings totaled

to guess the interest

$250

the remainder of the eligible issues maturing in

the average extension

this,

billion years;

and

in the

advance refund-

issues

of

exchanges but also precludes any need

all

the future.

into the intermediate area at an interest rate

on the

It

that

was comparable

to

and

in fact slighdy less

It

is

abundantly clear that by advance

This

is

true

maturing through 1966.
whether or not the 414 per cent

interest

taken into account.

cost

is

the cost

the budget- or dollar-

concept as shown in the report of the

Senate

Finance

Committee hearings on ad-

vance refunding, March

approach

it

is

implicitly

1962.'"

re-

eligible issues

than that in issuance for cash or in maturity

One approach toward determining

rates required to refund

funding the Treasury saved very substantially

refunding.

of advance refunding

matured before December

1966. This not only covers about 80 per cent

$299 billion years.
would seem, therefore, that advance refunding was also successful in extending debt
ings,

that

ceiling

on

over-5-year

offerings

is

Under assumption "A" in Table 7, if the
Treasury had waited and could have refunded
the maturing issues into the
in the

advance refundings

new

issues offered

at rates

above 414

In this

per cent, the over-all net saving would have

assumed that advance

more than $700 million. This is the
amount saved by having refunded
earlier.
Through 1963 the Treasury would
have incurred a net loss. But as rates rose dur-

14,

totaled

theoretical

1° U.S.,

Congress, Senate, Committee on Finance.

Hearings of Mar. 14 and 16, 1962, Advance Refundin!' and Debt Management,
87th Cong., 2d Sess.,
1962, pp. 14 and 15.

ing the course of the interest-rate cycle, the net

TABLE 7: ESTIMATED INTEREST COST OR SAVINGS IN ADVANCE
REFUNDING OF ELIGIBLE ISSUES THAT MATURED BEFORE

DECEMBER

31, 1966

In millions of dollars
nterest cost

between the

eligible

and

the otTered

Assumption A on interest saving: Saving based on difference between rate on the new
security ottered
olTered in the advance refunding and the mark
market rate required to reopen the
offered issue when the eligible issue reached maturity.^

Eligible
issues

maturing

in—

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

to the dates of the advance

added

refundings,

the

would be discounted more than the

savings

costs because the savings are further in

the future. Nevertheless, the discounted values

produce a net over-all savings of more

the advance refundings would have been far
more expensive and would have had a much

greater repercussion in the capital market,

indeed

it

would have been possible

at

all.

if

It

than $200 million on the amounts exchanged

also appears certain that, through 1966, advance refunding produced interest savings for

which would have matured by the end of
1966. Thus, even under the more realistic assumption regarding the 4V^ per cent interest

the Treasury, even if the early benefits of an
improved debt structure are ignored. Moreover, any reasonable assumption on the inter-

still

Treasury undoubtedly saved on

ceiling, the

terest cost as a result of

in-

having previously ex-

tended debt through advance refunding.

From

this,

may be

it

Treasury over the long run
only

is

interest rates

if

But that

trend.

is

inferred
is

bound

that the figures in assumption

the

that

upward
The fact

"B" tend

to

understate the benefits of advance refunding.

Not only were the amounts extended placed
well beyond the need to refund them at the
historically high rate levels that followed, but

was

also there

the probability that

much

of the

$59 billion maturing through 1966 or later
would have been refunded and most likely rerefunded one or more times. This most certainly would have added to the upward pressure on the rates for refunding the issues that
did actually mature.

From

a budget-cost point of view, approxi-

came to maturity and was refunded in the regway during the SVi years from mid- 1961
through 1966. About $99 bilUon of that
amount was publicly held, of which over $50

ular

was

in eligible

advance refunding issues

maturing through 1966. It seems reasonable to
suppose that the net effect of reducing the
publicly

held

short-dated

having reduced publicly

coupon debt

—wherein

fre-

at escalating rates of interest

would have been required

— would have added

considerably to the interest saved directly as a
result of

advance refunding.

Tax consequences

of advance refundThere have been two types of tax treatment of exchanges in advance refunding: nontaxable exchanges with the tax effect on gains
ing.

or losses generally postponed; and taxable ex-

changes with an immediate tax

effect

on gains

or losses.

Beginning with the July 1964 advance refunding, taxable exchange treatment has been

accorded to the pre-refunding

maturing

in 6

months or

the passage of the

until

less.

eligible

From

issues

that time

Tax Reform Act

of

1969, the Treasury decided that issues as close

mately $185 billion of marketable coupon debt

billion

held

quent refinancing

to benefit

are in an ever

a superficial view.

est saving involved in

refunding

load

one-third should have produced

by more than

some lowering

to maturity as 6 months should be regarded as
maturing issues for tax purposes. Under such

tax treatment any gain or loss

was recognized

immediately for tax purposes and was reportable for the year in which the exchange took
place.

Advance refunding exchanges
ble

if

are nontaxa-

so designated by the Secretary of the

Treasury under the authority of Section 1037
of the Internal

Revenue Code

as

amended

in

of interest rates required for the regular re-

September 1959. As defined in the code, any
gain or loss in such an exchange is not recog-

fundings.

nized for tax purposes at the time of the ex-

If

assumed

that lessening of the rate required

have averaged as

massive debt extension through cash financing

is postponed until the new
by the taxpayer are sold, redeemed, or otherwise disposed of, whichever
comes first. As originally prescribed, the designation of an exchange as nontaxable was not
permissive; it had to be treated as such by all

or refunding at maturity on a scale matching

taxpayers.

is

to

points, the budget savings
turities

little

based on

as 5 basis
total

ma-

would have been over $90 million a

year.

In

summary,

it

seems almost certain that

change but instead
securities received

46

In a nontaxable exchange, any subsequent
gain

or

upon the

loss

new

other disposal of the
gain

redemption,

sale,

issues

a capital

is

a taxpayer unless the securities

to

stock in trade, as in the case of dealers.

capital gain

short or long term

is

are

The

determines whether the

period that

holding

or

measured

is

from the purchase date of the eligible issue
turned in by the taxpayer to the disposal date

new

of the

issue offered in the exchange. If the

period of holding

any gain (or

is

loss)

is

also to

mutual

whether acquired

issues,

in

advance

refundings or otherwise, were considered to be

ordinary losses for tax purposes, while gains in
excess of losses were capital gains. (Gains on

less

is

is

than the

determined

sum

cost basis of the old issue. If the

of the

boot plus the new-issue value exceeds the oldis recognized immedino case can the amount recognized be greater than the amount of the boot
received by the taxpayer. (For examples of the

But

the excess

in

tax treatment of boot see p. 74.)

The

losses in excess of gains in a given year

on coupon

pro-

this

by comparing the sum of the boot received by
the investor and the fair market value of the
new issue at the time of exchange with the

ately.

—and

to deter-

the total value received by

cost basis of his old issue. This

issue basis,

To commercial banks

if

the investor in the exchange

a long-term capital gain

savings banks and savings and loan associa-

—

cedure holds only

greater than 6 months,

(or loss).

tions

from the cost basis of the old issue
mine the basis of the new issue. But

in

advance

One

generali-

tax consequences of boot

refunding can be quite complex.

that may be made, however, is that
boot paid to a taxpayer by the Treasury improves his yield after tax as compared with

zation

by

providing the same investment yield on the of-

banks and savings and loan associations are
treated as ordinary income in symmetry with
losses or ordinary losses.) Thus, until the pas-

fered issue before tax, but without boot. Boot

securities

acquired

sage of the
cial

July

after

Tax Reform Act

banks tended

to

of 1969,

advantage

of

in

order to take

unsymmetrical tax

the

treatment of gains and losses on coupon se-

This practice was confined mostly to

curities.

their holdings of

paid by a taxpayer to the Treasury has the opposite effect.

As

commer-

segregate gains in one

year and losses in another
greater

1969,

11,

Governments (and municipal

a fairly simple illustration, let us

that a 5-year,

rently priced in the
price, yield

market

at

96.20 (decimal

about 3.84 per cent)

ble for exchange into

bond without

assume

3 per cent existing issue cur-

boot.

is

made

eligi-

a 25-year, 4 per cent

Based on the price

eligible issue, the offering

of the

investment yield be-

on the 25-year 4's would be 4.25 per
Given these assumptions, the "minimum

bonds). Advance refunding allowed considerable latitude in this regard during the term to

fore tax

maturity of the offered issues.

reinvestment rate" before tax for the 20-year

The September 1959 Act covering nonrecognition of gains or losses in advance refundings also

amended

the code with respect to the

cost basis of the eligible and offered issues. In

par-for-par

a

without

exchange,

adjustment

cent.

extension would be 4.41 per cent. This

tures, in

offer.

to

added

the

Treasury,

the

boot

is

invariably

it

ma-

had

he

accepted

the

exchange

^-

Table 8 shows the
ing investment yield
if

when

order to equal the return on the 4 per

bond,

cent

becomes the cost basis of the new
issue received by the investor. However, when
an adjustment payment is made by the investor

the

rate at

proceeds of his 3 per cent issue

(boot) payments, the cost basis of the eligible
(old) issue

is

which an investor who elects
not to exchange would have to reinvest the

minimum

boot

is

effect of tax on the offerand the reinvestment rate

used to equate the terms of the ex-

to the cost basis of the old issue to de-

termine the basis of the

When

new

issue.
1-

boot

investor, the

is

paid by the Treasury to the

payment

is

ordinarily subtracted

For a

fuller

Feb. 20,

explanation

of

the

reinvestment
offer of

from the advance refunding
1963, which is shown on p. 75.

rate see excerpt

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT
TABLE
YIELD

47

8: TAX EFFECT OF BOOT PAYMENTS ON INVESTMENT
AND REINVESTMENT RATE

Assumptions: The tax rate is 48 per cent {the corporate marginal rate) on the coupon income and 25
per cent on long-term capital gain. The taxpayer is a nonbank corporation. The cost basis of the 5year. 3 percent issue outstanding is 98 per $!00; and its current market price is 96.20. The exchange
is nontaxable.

Coupon

rale
(per cenl)

the problem helped to trigger a major study of
budget concepts and practice, while the politi-

problems and implications sharply divided

cal

the Congress on the subject.

At

the time of the controversy proponents

principal

and

income of an

interest

ir-

revocably pledged pool of loans, the practice

They claimed

represents the sale of assets.

credit

programs

more

are

PC

under the

that

procedures

the

of

costs

Federal Government

the

to

also

truly reflected than

if

the

Moreover, they said that PC's provide a

costs.

means

attracting

for

was

less

even

into

the

by the pool of loans

at less cost than afi'orded

They pointed out

funds

private

credit areas represented

by other alternatives.

that the cost of selling PC's

than the cost of selling assets directly,

which the Federal Govservicing responsibility and

in those cases in

ernment

retains full

provides a

full

to act as trustee for pooling

market yields on Treasury and Federal

agency

major impact of issuing
1966 after the escalation of the
Vietnam in mid- 1965, and after the insecurities, the

PC's came

war

in

in

crease in the discount rate in

December

of that

year. Increased sales of

PC's had been forecast

budget for

year 1966, with a sub-

in the

fiscal

year 1967.

stantially larger increase in fiscal

During the December 1964-June 1966 pe-

programs

were financed through Treasury advances to
agencies at rates below Treasury borrowing

FNMA

offerings started during a period of slowly ris-

ing

of the sale of PC's believed that, as shares in

the

powering

Federal-agency-held mortgages. Although these

PC's

riod,

by

held

the

public

more than

doubled, from $2.0 billion to nearly $4.4

bil-

same period, public borrowing by
Federal credit agencies also expanded sharply.
In fact, during the I'/i years from December
1964 through June 1966, Federal agency debt
held by the public increased from $12.1 biUion
In the

lion.

$17.6

to

billion, at

roughly

3'/^

times the an-

nual rate of increase in the preceding 4 years.

To

a considerable extent, the expansion of

agency borrowing resulted from a
growing demand for credit generally. CommerFederal

guarantee.

Those on the other side felt strongly that a
PC is a somewhat thinly disguised device for

banks and other lending

cial

institutions, fac-

new

ing heavy borrowing requirements in a tighten-

funds into fully guaranteed PC's free of servic-

ing money and credit market environment,
began to ration credit and choose among borrowers. Unsatisfied borrowers, including farm-

selling another debt instrument. Attracting

ing costs merely proves that the attraction

indeed a Government security. Moreover,

is

all

of the improvements in their terms and conditions since early
ity

1967

to

enhance marketabil-

made the PC's resemble direct debt obligamore and more and to resemble sales of

tions

assets less

As

and

a matter of fact, that aspect of PC's did

not become a significant problem until after

FNMA-type

vember 1964. Before
had been sold by the

eral

and small businessmen, turned to the Fedagencies to meet credit needs ordinarily

supplied by the private institutions. In addition, the tightening situation

offerings in

such

that

CCC

for

No-

The

savings and loan associations experienced

particularly

instruments

ketable instruments.

many

tions increased their

years

home

eral

bank PC's, which date back to May 1962,
had also been distributed without fanfare,

FNMA

it

should be noted they were sold to

a rather select group

of

Other PC's had been sold
liquidating the

in

commercial banks.
in

heavy withdrawals of funds, for

reinvestment at higher rates of return in mar-

without repercussions, while the early Exim-

although

produced a sharp

reduction in the supply of mortgage money.

less.

the advent of the

ers

the process

of

RFC.

The FNMA offerings of PC's, which began
November 1964, followed legislation em-

an attempt

to

a result, the associa-

borrowing from the Fedbanks. At the same time

loan

increased

As

its

purchases of mortgages in

support the secondary market.

Faced with expanded

credit

demands, these

Federal agencies sharply increased their market borrowing. Also during this period the increased

demand

for

bank

credit for business

loans and other private needs, plus the bur-

geoning

corporate

and municipal

long-term

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

PUBLIC HOLDINGS OF MARKETABLE TREASURY
FEDERAL AGENCY OBLIGATIONS

11 AND

50

TABLE

9:

1962-66

'

EXPORT-IMPORT BANK PC OFFERINGS, RATES, AND SPREADS,

NEW TECHNIQUES

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

was 10 years on the
duced

first

was

PC's, but this

re-

to 7 years thereafter.

About $2.1

in

Eximbank PC's

billion of these

were issued but by December 1966 about $1.0

had been

billion

mostly through the

retired,

over, in the belief of

The Exim-

exercise of the redemption option.

bank-type PC's were relatively expensive
struments as indicated in Table

in-

bond counseling,

some lawyers specializing
was a definite need

there

from the Attorney General that
if required, would be guaranteed to meet interest and principal payments.
As indicated in Table 10, the interests costs
on the first three PC's averaged between 7 and
for an opinion

Treasury funds,

9 basis points above

spread

comparable agency issue
and between 14 and
per cent above
Treasury yields. These spreads seemed to be

above market rates on Federal agency issues

quite reasonable in view of the newness of the

and even above the commercial bank rate. In
later offerings, the spreads above agency issue

ings in the

first

somewhat

much more

expensive in the rapidly rising in-

As

9.

Eximbank

a new, untried instrument the

PC's started with a

fairly

high

yield

rates declined, partly as a result of a

improved customer reception, but mainly due

mounting upward rate pressures in the
agency market. Comparisons with the prime
rate do not indicate a close relationship,
mainly because the prime rate was held at artificial levels, with compensating balances providing the
finer
tuning needed for rate

offered instruments.

terest-rate

to

flexibihty.

Attempts

to

raise

target

amounts through

Eximbank offerings in 1966 proved unsuccessful. As a result, beginning in 1967 the terms
and conditions of Eximbank PC's were
changed

to

conform with

the newest

FNMA-

type PC's.

three offerings of

Eximbank PC's

FNMA

PC's were

the

first

fairly well

received at rates generally in line with yields
existing

agency

issues.

This occurred de-

spite the underwriters' dislike of

such as small
10- to

It

However, the two offer1966 were relatively

half of

environment

at the time.

should be mentioned that the comparison

PC

costs with yields on outstanding agency
depended on the validity of dealers' quotations in the agency market. If it can be
argued that dealers' quotations were not much
further ou of line with '"true" market values
at any one time than at another, the changes

of

issues

in the
tive

spreads are a reasonable index of rela-

additional costs needed to ensure market

acceptance.

In

1965-66

the

above

spreads

Treasury rates on the parts of

PC

offerings

maturing after 5 years reiected the lack of any
possible increase in the supply of over-5-year

In contrast to the

on

%

yields

serial maturities

some

features

extending over a

15-year period and the availability of

the obligations only in registered form.

TABLE

10:

More-

Treasury issues

in the

immediate future.

The first FNMA PC's following the postponement of scheduled offerings by the SecreSeptember 1966 carand conditions strongly
recommended by market professionals during
the summer. In the improved market environment at the end of the year, the average intertary of the Treasury in
ried

revised

terms

FNMA PC OFFERINGS, RATES AND SPREADS

1964-66

'

Average
Average

Federal

lerni
{in years}

(in per

agency
market
yields

Nov. 1964.
July 1965..

Dec. 1965

I

reasury

market
yields

4.37
4.54
4.76

Apr. 1966..
June 1966..
Jan. 1967

•

"

'.

Including the January 1967 offering announced on Dec. 19. 1966.
Public portion of offering; in addition, S500 rrtillion was taken by Government Investment Accounts.

est-cost spread

above Federal agency rates on

new PC's was

In summary, the

FNMA-type

PC's, particu-

models following the September 1966
postponement, appeared to have earned a place

conformance with the
pre- 1966 levels. However, the average spreads
above Treasury yields remained large, reflect-

larly the

ing the continuing substantial yield differentials

extent,

the nature of PC's as viewed

between Treasury and agency

market

at the

the

in

issues.

in the roster of regular

agency

time was resolved.

issues.

To

that

by the

NEW TECHNIQUES

IV.

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

APPENDIX

TABLES
1.

Monthly average

rates

on 91- and 182-day Treasury

bills in

the weekly auctions

November 1958-December 1966
2.
3.

4.
5.

91-day Treasury

55

—
—

1958-66
182-day Treasury bills
quarterly averages of auction results, 1958-66
Auction results on 1-year Treasury bills, quarterly or monthly, 1959-66
Auction results on 9-month Treasury bills, monthly, 1966
bills

quarterly averages of auction results,

6.

Trcasury-bill-strip auction results

7.

Regularly issued

8.

Treasury coupon securities issued

bills

56
57
58
59
59
59

outstanding, selected dates
in rights

and

in

cash quarterly refinancings,

August 1960-December 1966
9.

60

Dealer activity in quarterly rights refundings, 1961-66

61

cash refinancings, 1961-66

61

10.

Dealer activity

11.

Advance

12.
13.

Exchanges
Exchanges
1960-65

14.

Yields on long-term Treasury, municipal, and private securities, 1960-66

15.

Dealer activity

16.

18.

New issues ofTered, terms to maturity, and allotments to
and dealers
69
Treasury bonds with over 10 years to maturity issued in cash financings and regular
refundings at maturity and in advance refundings. 1960-65
70
Treasury securities maturing in 3 through 10 years issued in cash financings and regular

19.

Estimated cost or savings

Advance

in quarterly

refundings,
in

1960-66

advance refundings by investor

in senior

in

and

in pre-

classes,

62
66

1960-65

and junior advance refundings by investor

classes.

advance refundings, 1960-65

66
67
68

refundings, 1960-65:

total public

17.

refundings at maturity and in advance refundings, 1960-66
in

advance refundings

—

Eligible issues

71

maturing before

December

20.
21.

31, 1966
Types of exchange and adjustment (boot) payments in advance refundings, 1960-66
Market yields on Federal agency and Treasury issues at constant maturities, and
reoffering rates

on new corporate bonds

—

Selected dates,

1963-66

72
73
74

EXAMPLES OF TAX TREATMENT OF ADJUSTMENT (BOOT) PAYMENTS

74

EXCERPT FROM ADVANCE REFUNDING OFFER OF

75

FEB. 20, 1963

NEW TECHNIQUES
APPENDIX TABLE

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

1

MONTHLY AVERAGE RATES ON 91- AND 182-DAY TREASURY BILLS
WEEKLY AUCTIONS, NOVEMBER 1958-DECEMBER 1966
'

Nov.
Dec.

Jan..

2.914

Feb.

Mar.

2.420
2.327
2.288
2.359

Apr.

May
June
July.

Aug.
Sept.
Oct..

Nov.
Dec.

4.436
3.954
3.439
3.244
3.392

4.840

2.641

4.321
3.693
3.548
3.684
2.909

.396

.826

.735
.694
.719

2.838
2.789
2.804

Sept..

.945
.837
.792

Oct..

.751

3.085
3.005
2.947
2.859

July.

Aug..

'Bank discount nu
3-week average.

•

IN

THE

APPENDIX TABLE

2

91-DAY TREASURY BILLS— QUARTERLY AVERAGES OF AUCTION RESULTS, 1958-66

NEW TECHNIQUES
APPENDIX TABLE

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

3

182-DAY TREASURY BILLS— QUARTERLY

AVERAGES OF AUCTION RESULTS, 1958-66
nl r;ues

Acccpled

Received

Nonkink

deale

Received Accepted

Ri

und spreads

APPENDIX TABLE 4
AUCTION RESULTS ON 1-YEAR TREASURY BILLS, QUARTERLY OR MONTHLY, 1959-66

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

APPENDIX TABLE 5
AUCTION RESULTS ON 9-MONTH TREASURY BILLS, MONTHLY, 1966

APPENDIX TABLE 8
TREASURY COUPON SECURITIES ISSUED IN RIGHTS AND IN CASH
QUARTERLY REFINANCINGS, AUGUST 1960-DECEMBER 1966

NEW TECHNIQUES
APPENDIX TABLE
DEALER ACTIVITY

DEBT MANAGEMENT

IN

9
IN

QUARTERLY RIGHTS REFUNDINGS, 1961-66
Cumulative volume of trading

Dealers
as per cent
of public

To

the
public,

Amount
(in

issues to

millions
of dollars)

(in

public

6,387
8,593
6,683

2/15/62...
5/15/62..
11/15/62.

Amount

Per cent of

millions

of dollars)

tolal

7.2
8.9
9.7

2/15/63...
5/15/63...
8/15/63...

15.4
12.8
10.3

21 .4

13.6
17.9

5/15/66
Total, or average ....

Excluding 8/1/61
E.xcluding 2/15/62
•

13,590

Excluding combination maturity and pre-refundings in Februai

and August 1966.

^

'

- Includes position in outstanding reopened issues except in
1961 refunding.

APPENDIX TABLE
DEALER ACTIVITY

10
IN

Augu

^

Dealers reporting to the Federal Re

n.a.

Not

available.

QUARTERLY CASH REFINANCINGS, 1961-66

Dealers a
per cent
of public

8/15/62..

5,107

11/15/63.

3,972

1,516
11.2

928

22.0

936
867

Total, or average ....

Excluding 2/15/61

284
397

16.1

571

12.5

454

14.3

735

20.9

738

20.9

3,504

12.3

32,118
.

28,398

Dealers reporting to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
" In tolal new issues {where more
than one). Includes positions in outstanding issues
'Trading through seventh day after announcement. Includes trading in outstandir
reopened.
'

I

n.a.

Not

available.

23

While books were open.
Through seventh day afte

Bank of

New

York.

O

62

C c u

£

300QOQQQOO
1111111177

SOOO^ON —

•lOf^CN

£s

6?

— Mrno, — O—

^

£?

B?

5?

(3

00 u.

<UJ
HOC
XlU
UJ<
Q.>

Q.Q
<<

f
a

6*
:.^

6?
s;

6*

£*

6^

:sj

:s?

:>?

s?

NEW TECHNIQUES

i

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

M

1

"'9??^???

£?£?

656§

6§&?

t"^^

^

£^

fe§

£?

171 1171

-7

?T-?=!

^

6*

6*^

St

S*

^

6*

;^

SS

g;

I

I

I

I

I

I

7

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

I

II

171

I

7?7?=r7?=r t1'7T=7"i"ri'777?T=i-'

sss?

sSsS

?

?

sss?

sS6n

sSb?

ssss

sSfeS

fiSS?

SS6^

NEW TECHNIQUES

II

??-

IN

Mill

DEBT MANAGEMENT

II

r??f??-

2I

II

II

,

APPENDIX TABLE

EXCHANGES

IN

12

ADVANCE REFUNDINGS BY INVESTOR CLASSES,

1960-65

Dealer:

and
broker-

Pension

1,090
328
1,337

1962— Mar,
Sept

1963— Mar,
Sepl.

1964— Jan.
July

1965— Jan

,

.

1,877
4,731

4,403
3,365
1,442
5,501

5,650

348
1,194
1,567
1,539

658
1,086
1,426

Other
300
254
508
156

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

67

3 2 S

§

a?

?:r;i§

iijU

-IZ

mo

So
^u:S<S^ ^<;;iOZQ

4li.S<S-?

^<J:oza

..

APPENDIX TABLE
DEALER ACTIVITY

15

To

the

IN

ADVANCE REFUNDINGS,

Amounts
P"''"'^-

6/23/60.

4,077

10/3/60.

3,396

3/30/61

.';,443

9/29/61

2,827

3/9/62.

4,178

9/20/62.

3/15/63.

9/18/63.

1/29/64.

7/24/64.

Total, or av

Excluding:
3/9/62.

(in

deiile

mil-

lions of
dollars)

Per cent
of issues
to public

—

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

APPENDIX TABLE 16
ADVANCE REFUNDINGS, 1960-65: NEW ISSUES OFFERED,
TERMS TO MATURITY, AND ALLOTMENTS TO TOTAL PUBLIC AND DEALERS
Advance
refunding of

69

APPENDIX TABLE 17

TREASURY BONDS WITH OVER 10 YEARS TO MATURITY ISSUED
FINANCINGS AND REGULAR REFUNDINGS AT MATURITY
AND IN ADVANCE REFUNDINGS, 1960-65

above outstanding-

of dollars)

Cash

11/15/61

3H%

Bd.

8/15/62

41^%

Bd.

8/15/87-92

30-0

1/17/63

4%

Bd.

2/15/88-93

30-1

4/18/63

4H%

Bd.

5/15/89-94

Total, or average

5/15/75-85

11/15/74

issue yields

financings and regular rcfundings

Bd.

25-1'

13^

31-1

24-4

{in

per cent)

issued

414%

CASH

Spread

Amount
{in millions

4/5/60

IN

New

cash

.
.

NEW TECHNIQUES
APPENDIX TABLE

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

18

TREASURY SECURITIES MATURING IN 3 THROUGH 10 YEARS ISSUED
FINANCINGS AND REGULAR REFUNDINGS AT MATURITY AND IN
ADVANCE REFUNDINGS, 1960-66
Amount

Offering

issued

yield (in

(in millions

per cenl)

of dollars)

Cash

4HTo
VA^r

5/15/60.
8/15/60.
11/15/60.

Nt.
Bd.
3^'"; Bd.

5/15/65
5/15/68
5/15/66

3M%Nl.
VA%Bd.

8/15/64
5/15/68
5/15/66

3Ji%Bd.

11/15/61.

A%
A%

1/24/62.
2/15/62.
4/18/62.
5/15/62.
5/15/62.
8/15/62.
11/15/62.

Bd.

10/1/69

Nl.
^7,. Bd.
3$/8% Nl.
Bd.

8/1 5/66

VA%
4%
4%

1

,

1

.213

8/15/68
2/15/66
2/15/69
2/15/72

4K''; Bd.

5/15/74

Rights

Cash

rl'dg.

4.625
3.875

Rights

3.75

Rights
Rights
Rights

3.75
3.98
3.81

3.68

Rights
Rights

11/15/71

Bd.
Bd.

Cash

3.94
4.00
4.00

rl

Rights

10-0
9 A)

5%Nl.

2/15/66.
8/15/66.
11/15/66.

5K%Nt.
5=8%

Total, or average.

6/23/60.

3/30/61

.

.

May

Nt.

11/15/70
5/15/71
11/15/71

2,839
2,578
1,734

Rights
Rights

Cash

rfdg.

5.00
5.25
5.375

1960-Nov. 1966

.

.

3/9/62.
9/20/62...
.

Nl.

8/15/71
8/15/67

Bd.

8/15/72

4rr Bd.
3Ji

%

4%

2/15/67
11/15/71
11/15/68
9/15/73

3/15/63...

9/18/63...

1/29/64...
7/24/64.
,

4%
4%
Vs'y,

1/19/65...

Bd.
Bd.
Bd.

8/15/70
10/1/69
11/15/73
2/15/70
2/15/74

4.104

.

3.809

4.06
3.645
3.965
4.02
4.147

4,287
1,515
1,591

9-11

3,894

6-63i

2,223
3,726
4,357

5-2K
9-3J-i

and
and
and

Jr
Jr
Jr

4.155
4.07
4.229
4.175
4.238

4.976

2/15/66...
8/15/66...
Total, or average.

9-5'
4-11
9-11

1960-.\ug. 1966

CASH

Spread (in
per cenO
above oulstandingissue yields

financings and regular refundings

2.113
070

IN

O

E

a;

~

o

.....

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

73

APPENDIX TABLE 20
TYPES OF EXCHANGE AND ADJUSTMENT (BOOT) PAYMENTS
Types

IN

ADVANCE REFUNDINGS,

1960-66

exchange: Nontaxable, recognition of gains or losses postponed;
Taxable, immediate recognition

of

Excliangcs by

Total exchanges

Boot

Boot

Boot

Boot

Boot

paid to
investor

paid by
investor

paid by
investor

paid to
investor

paid by
investor

tlie

public

Amounts exchanged
1960— June..
Oct..

3,979

.

1961— Mar..

4,864
1,519

Sept..

1962— Mar..
7,519

Sept.

1963— Mar..

7,3.^1

6,548

Sept.

1964— Jan.

.

1

.

July.

.

1965— Jan...

,999

9. 284

9 258

9,765

9,063

,

1966— Feb...
Aug.
Total

.

.

.

.

(Net
vestor)

1960—June..
Oct...

1961— Mar..
33.1

Sept.

1962— Mar..

50.9
34. S

Sept.

1963— Mar..
Sept.

.

38.6

.

,

1964— Jan...
July..

2.5

1965— Jan...

9.7

1966— Feb...
Aug.
Total
1

.

I,3U7

2,908

.

.

Boot paid

,

74

APPENDIX TABLE

21

MARKET YIELDS ON FEDERAL AGENCY AND TREASURY ISSUES AT CONSTANT
MATURITIES, AND REOFFERING RATES ON NEW CORPORATE BONDS

—

SELECTED DATES, 1963-66
In per cent per

annum

NEW TECHNIQUES

IN

DEBT MANAGEMENT

EXCERPT FROM ADVANCE REFUNDING OFFER OF
12.

Explanation of

minimum reinvestment

A holder of the oulslanding eligible securities Iwd llie option of
accepting the Treasury's exchange offer or of holding thent to
maturity. Consetiuently, he can compare the interest plus (or
minus) any payment, other than the adjustment of accrued
interest, he will receive resulting from exchanging now with the
total of the interest on the eligible issues and what he inight
obtain by reinvesting the proceeds of the eligible securities at
maturity.
The income before tax for making the extension now through
exchange will be the coupon rates plus (or minus) any payment
on the new issues. If a holder of the eligible securities does noi
make the exchange he would receive the coupon rates on the
eligible issues to their maturity and would have to reinvest at
that time at a rate eiiual to that indiciited in paragraph 13 below
lor the remaining terms of the issues now offered, in order to
efunding

Paragraph 12 of Treasury
nnounced Feb. 20, 1963.
1

Investment rates on the
the eligible securities

Eligible securities

>

FEB.

20,

rate for the extension of maturity in

1963
advance refunding

equal the return (including any payjitent) he would receive by
accepting the exchange offer. For example, if the 3'; bonds of
2/15/64 arc exchanged for 3-ls'^ bonds of 11/15/71 the investor receives 2-Vs'"c: interest for the entire eight years and
eight months plus $.70 (per $100 face value) immediately. If
the exchange is not made, a i'i rale will be received until February 15. 1964, requiring reinvestment of the proceeds of the
3's of 1964 at that time at a rale of at least 4.11 '";, for the remaining seven years and nine months, all at compound interest,
to average out to a 3-J^';f, rate for eight years and eight months
plus the S.70 immediate payment. This minimum reinvestment
rale of the extension period is shown in the table under paragraph 13. The minimum reinvestment rates for the other issues
included in the exchange are tilso shown in the table under
p.iragraph 13.

oft'e

new notes and bonds

offered in

exchange

to

holders of

William G. Colby,

Jr.

Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of

New York

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

CONTENTS

I.

II.

III.

INTRODUCTION

81

SUMMARY

82

Profits

Capital

82
83

DEALER PROFIT PERFORMANCE

84

The Income Equation

85
87
93
96
97
99

Trading Profits
Net Carry
Trends in Trading Profits plus Carry, by Type and Size of Dealer
Operating Expenses
Regression Results
IV.

DEALER CAPITAL: CAPACITY

IN

THE INDUSTRY

Invested Capital

Margins Required
Capital
V.
VI.

Adequacy

102
103
106
109

RATE OF RETURN ON CAPITAL

110

APPENDIX

112

Summary

112
113
115

of Dealer Income and Expenses, 1964 and 1965
Regression Equations
Measurement of Dealer Capital

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

INTRODUCTION

I.

5 years 1961-65, average annual
from dealer operations in U.S. Government securities fell substantially below the

For

the

profits

5-year period.^

level attained in the previous

This decline culminated in a net loss of more

when only

20

tude and direction of certain measurable aspects of dealer profits and related variables.

The

limitations of the data are

avoid excessive

detail,

numerous; to

only the more impor-

tant qualifications are described.

the entrance of additional dealers over the past

Data on dealer income have been gathered
from three sources. Differing in their construction and coverage, these disparate series present the most serious constraint to meaningful
interperiod income analysis. One source is the
study of the Government securities market
made by Meltzer and von der Linde, which

few years as well as from recent innovations

records various annual income and expense

than $14 million in 1965,
dealers reported a profit

3 of

from these operations.

This deterioration has caused some concern
about the maintenance of a strong dealer industry and has brought into question the effects

of increased competition

official policies

The

resulting

from
in

and operations.

task of this study

is

twofold:

(1)

to

and evaluate the factors bearing on
dealer profitability, such as changing economic
circumstances, industry structure, and operating techniques utilized by the Federal Reserve
specify

and the Treasury; and (2) to ascertain the
under current market conditions, with a view to judging whether
sufficiency of dealer capital

the industry will have sufficient capital so that
it

can continue to "make markets" and to ab-

sorb large

The

official

operations.

discussion in this paper

based largely
to

the less complicated nature of their activities

and the existence of more reliable profit data
for them; any known or suspected variations in
bank dealer operations or behavior are noted.
Both the description and the evaluation of
dealer profit performance are severely constrained by the fragmentation and inadequacies
of the data and by the absence of clear and
consistent definitions underlying the data

meant

Many

to give

com-

of the dealer data presented are

some

indication of the magni-

In this paper, virtually all references to dealer
operations in U.S. Government securities include
operations in Federal agency securities and, commencing in 1961, certificates of deposit. Where data
include operations in bankers' acceptances and municipal and corporate securities, which are undertaken by many dealer firms, specific note is made.
'

dealers" (bank and

nonbank)

for the 11 years

1948-58.- This series covers earnings and expenses on

all

types of securities operations for

nonbank dealers but covers only
Government securities operations of
banks. Details on reporting procedures and
methods of allocating income and expenses are
absent. The series includes the 5 bank dealers
and the 12 nonbank dealers trading with the
Federal Reserve Open Market Account in
1958; however, that was not the exact group
the diversified
the U.S.

'

is

on the operations of nonbank dealers owing

pilation.

fig-

including net profits, for "all reporting

ures,

of "authorized" dealers in each of the
as

noted

is

A

study

market

-

U.S.

by

years,

is an unpubGovernment securities
George Benston, conducted

second source of

lished

1 1

in the discussion of dealer capital.

of

Dr.

Congress,

profits data

the

Joint

Economic Committee,

/(

of the Dealer Market for Federal Govenuncnt
report written by Allan H. Meltzer and
Gert von der Linde. Joint Committee Print (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1960).

Sillily

Securities;

17 dealers were: Bankers Trust Company,
York; Chemical Bank New York Trust Company, Continental Illinois National Bank and Trust
Company of Chicago; The First National Bank of
Chicago; Morgan Guaranty Trust Company of New
York; Bartow Leeds & Co.; Briggs, Schaedle & Co.,
Inc.; C. F. Childs & Co., Inc.; C. J. Devine & Co.;
Discount Corporation of New York; The First Boston
Corporation; Aubrey G. Lanston & Co., Inc.; New
York Hanseatic Corporation; Wm. E. Pollock & Co.,
Inc.: Chas. E. Quincey & Co.; D. W. Rich & Company, Inc.; and Salomon Bros. & Hutzler.

'The

New

:

under the auspices of the Banking and Cur-

bined profit concept, and the absence of trad-

rency Committee of the House of Representa-

ing profit (or carry) data for bills as contrasted

In this study, data for the

tives.

Government

securities

operations of individual firms were

collected

on a monthly

from 1958

coupon

with

securities,

may

seriously bias the

statistical analysis.

to

Finally, partially disaggregated data for indi-

1963; here, too, procedural and allocative de-

vidual dealers are available for operations in

was the only one

U.S. Government securities from the reporting
program initiated for nonbank dealers in 1964
and for bank dealers in 1965 by the Market

basis

are missing. This series

tails

with sufficient observations to permit

statistical

which was undertaken despite known

analysis,

shortcomings in the data. Because of the ina-

most dealers to separate trading proffrom interest income on Treasury bills, and

bility of
its

the differences

number

of

among

dealers in classifying a

income and expense components,

the series used for measuring profits
ing profits plus carry." ("Carry"

is

"trad-

is

defined as

the diflierence between interest earned on securities held in position

and the

interest cost of

Federal Reserve Bank
York. Although these figures cannot

Statistics Division of the

New

of

be directly related to the earlier
are a

more

reliable

series,

actual profit performance.

A

short analysis of

aggregate income statements for these 2 years
is

presented in the Appendix. Again, the inabil-

ity

trading profits

to segregate

bills

from

on Treasury

interest accruals, plus diverse alloca-

financing them. This difference, or "net carry,"

tive practices, precludes exact inter-firm

may be

parisons of trading or carry.

positive or negative.

Use of

)

this

com-

they

and detailed statement of

com-

SUMMARY

II.

PROFITS

rupted interval of economic expansion, which

The sharply deteriorating trend in earnings
of U.S. Government securities dealers from

was accompanied by generally rising and, perhaps more importantly, nonvolatile interest
rates.

1961

through

1966,

late

after

several

ex-

tremely successful years, has been offered as

evidence that public and private innovations in
financial

markets have been detrimental to the

profitability of the industry.

This deterioration

some concern about the future effectiveness of the industry in accommodating public

led to

(official)

and private

activity in

the market.

This study examined the effects of such innovations, as well as the impact of the

and
ade,

institutional

economic

2. The sharp reduction in dealer profits for
1961-65 inclusive can be attributed in great
measure to the negative effects of cyclically declining securities prices on dealer positions as
monetary conditions tightened. Treasury bill
yields rose in each year of this period, and
long-term bond yields moved higher in every
year but 1962. (In that year, there was some
improvement in dealer earnings.) Furthermore,

with trading activity in long-term securities ob-

environment of the past dec-

on aggregate

profits

of

dealers,

and

served to
ness,

1.

A

longer view of dealer profit perform-

ance, from the late

1940's, reveals

move

inversely with monetary tight-

it

reached the following conclusions
a strong

cyclical pattern of earnings. This suggests that

recent low levels were not abnormally
below those of other periods at the same stage

the

a

coupon

declining
issues

volume

after

of

portunities for profits

on turnover.

the differential between longinterest rates

the

transactions

Finally, as

and short-term

narrowed with higher

rate levels,

tendency for profitable carry was mini-

in the business cycle.

mized and eventually eliminated. At

the early 1960's

ing, sufficient data are not available for a

The principal feature of
was the extended and uninter-

in

1963 led to reduced op-

this writ-

com-

—
DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
plete analysis, although early reports indicate

1966, with the abrupt drop in security

that

yields late in the year,

was a very profitable

period for dealers;

fact lends support to

this

hypothesis that cyclical monetary condi-

the

have dominated the

tions

profit

performance of

when

Still,

a major rate reversal oc-

accurately.
5.

Developments

private

the

in

sector

tended to affect dealer profits adversely. The
greater mobility

and

sensitivity

of investible

funds, inherent in the growth of Federal funds

dealers.

long-term

assessing

In

3.

1950's.

curred in late 1966, dealers reacted swiftly and

of

profitability

activity

and

in the

expanded use of

certificates

dealers, the effects of innovations in financial

of deposit (CD's), contributed to a flattening

markets by public and private sectors become
increasingly important. Both sectors may have

of yield curves

contributed

most

the

to

change

notable

namely, the nature of the business cycle

The

structure

for

competed

itself.

and

to a relatively higher rate

financing
for

directly

Both uses

positions.

funds

that

otherwise

might have been available more cheaply to

well-defined and relatively short cycle of

finance dealer positions. Furthermore, the in-

been supplanted by a new pat-

creased competition of these instruments for

the 1950's has
tern, as yet

perhaps not entirely visible or iden-

short-term funds undoubtedly aggravated the

will represent

pressure on dealers to reduce quoted spreads

tifiable. If this

pattern persists,

it

a changed environment for dealer operations

Government

for short-maturity U.S.

and one to which dealers must attempt to adjust. Such a pattern may mean, for example,
that a longer period of meager returns will be

parent increase in competition

followed by a relatively short but highly profita-

ers

ble interval, with

becoming imperative

it

for

securities.

During the early 1960's, there was an aparising

from the entry

of three

among dealers
new bank deal-

and the "net" entry of one sizable nonbank
numbers may have

dealer. This expansion in

dealers to be able to identify promptly the turn-

contributed

ing point.

spreads and reduced the existing dealers' shares

One
ment

aspect of the changed cyclical environ-

was apparently harmful

that

to

broader grounds, was the

—

from

intracyclical

price

fluctuations

(through appropriate, well-timed position adjustments)
4.

It

is

may

decline.

difficult

to

measure the extent

to

which public innovation, in the broad sense of
new and evolving fiscal and monetary action
and debt management, guided the prolonged
expansion

—and

in

doing

so,

how

it

affected

and their perception of
Whether these essentially exogen-

capital

deterioration

would

Available

evidence suggests that dealers were less successful in adjusting positions in anticipation of

price changes in the

1960's than in the late

in

Insufficient

profits.

capital

to
in

is,

A

circumstance of

presumably detrimental
efficient and effective market performance
accommodating public and private opera-

insufficient

capital

is

This study found that the amount of

capital

unclear.

accommodate

to

act as a constraint

ciated with large positions.

tions.

about rate movements and thus hindered

available

on the desired expansion of positions and on the concomitant
willingness of dealers to assume the risks asso-

risks.

ous decisions reduced or increased uncertain-

would be

future market operations, in light of the past

expectations

is

of transactions.

CAPITAL

market

or helped dealer profits

on

This study also investigated whether adequate

dealer

ties

volume

of the rising

pressure

increased

stability of interest

Not only do bid-asked spreads tend to
narrow with diminished volatility of rates
making transactions less profitable but also

rates.

gains

the

dealer

though unquestionably valuable on

earnings,

to

possessed

capital

by nonbank dealers

sufficiently liquid

to satisfy

(that

margin

requirements) plus the amount of funds potentially

available to

bank dealers

is

far in excess

of any possible needs in the foreseeable future.

Estimated

minimum

capital

requirements

(for positioning daily-average gross long posi-

tions of $4.6 billion in

Of

million.

1965) were about $42

nonbank dealer

this total,

positions

"required" $29 million. These dealers reported
aggregate invested capital of $261 million in

1965 and had allocated $86 million of the
support their positions.

total to

reasonable

It is

nonbank dealers'
capital that could conceivably be employed as
margins is, at the least, considerably more than
$100 million.
Bank dealers, who accounted for approxiassume that the amount

to

of

minimum mar-

mately one-third of estimated
gin

requirements, in fact are not subject to

such capital

with

financed

are

In fact, three new banks and
two nonbank firms entered the industry. The
departures by two nonbank dealers were for
reasons unrelated to market performance. The
willingness of both old and new dealers to
commit their available capital to expand positions,

dealers.

however,

profitable

is

not a

realistic

amount

of

for the industry as a

constraint

on the ex-

trend in earnings in the early

1960's certainly had no perceptible effect on

investment except to the extent that

capital

III.

If

expected profits in U.S. Gov-

securities operations are

exceeded by

potential gains in other activities, or

if

they are

not sufficient to compensate for the risks of

making markets, dealers are unlikely

to

com-

mit capital to positioning Government securi-

pansion of positions.

The adverse

shifted readily to ac-

used to expand positions under unfavorable

capital potentially available for margining se-

whole

the

own

circumstances.

enormous and

to

employment.

ernment

is

unrelated

that provide greater opportunities for

and by
curities

largely

and mobile and may be
tivities

through borrowing in the Federal funds market
issuing CD's. In short, the

is

amount available. For both nonbank dealers
and bank dealers, such funds tend to be liquid

readily

their

may be augmented

funds. These funds

slowed the growth in capital of ex-

profits

Even if alternative uses did not exist, "dormant" capital may be less costly than capital

requirements since the bulk of

positions

their

low

isting

ties.

Nevertheless, there

is

no doubt that ample

capital will be forthcoming
justify

its

expected profits

if

utilization.

DEALER PROFIT PERFORMANCE
income on

This section describes the elements of deal-

eral dealers reported their

income and expenses and then explores
the impact of postulated relationships between
selected exogenous variables and observed

trading profits while others included

ers'

performance. The testing of these rela-

profit

tionships

and regression

both visual

utihzes

analyses.

The behavior
and

of net income and of

components

derlying

The

also in

Table

cessive

series

trading

expenses

operating

briefly.

—

—may

data, presented
1,

in

nonbank

be

un-

carry,

reviewed

Chart

1

and

are linked for the three suc-

despite

several

The Meltzer-von der Linde data
viously noted,

its

profits,

all

terest earned. In

any event,

to obtain valid estimates of

cause

of

the

by individual
to

dealers, particularly with regard

operating expenses, necessitated interpola-

tion of data for subgroups of dealers in order to

income and expense levels.
bank dealer data were
not collected at all. The industry figures shown
in Table 1 include estimates for income and

cover, as pre-

In 1964, as noted earlier,

two

series

was impossible

annual net carry

the

arrive at aggregate

operations of participating

with

with in-

entire 1948-65 interval beproblem of separating trading
profits from interest earned on bills.
For both the Meltzer—von der Linde and
Benston series, gaps in the figures submitted

throughout

discrepancies.

dealers whereas the other

it

bills

it

only the Government securities opera-

expenses of bank dealers; these estimates are

Net carry, in the Benston figures, had to
be combined with trading profits because sev-

based on nonbank dealer figures and on data
obtained informally from several dealer banks.

reflect

tions.

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

1

INCOME AND EXPENSES OF
I

I

U.S.

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES DEALERS, 1948-65

MELTZER-VON DER LINDE DATA

19571
I

I

Despite these shortcomings, certain conclu-

may be drawn from

sions

the

linked series.

First, it is evident that trading profits have
been the primary determinant of net income
and that their extreme volatility has led to
wide fluctuations in the level of net income.'

Trading

appear to move

in turn,

profits,

versely with the business cycle. Years in

in-

which

trading profits were high were generally associ-

and

with

rates,

and years of low returns with expansion

and

declining

from 1956

And

to 1965.
it

would seem

one

to

view average earnings

as

abnormally swollen as to characterize those

in

the

1961—65 period

in the earlier 5 years

as unusually poor.

THE INCOME EQUATION
Broadly

speaking,

net

the

income,

before

accruing to dealers from Government

interest

Furthermore, in years when
were low the industry as a

if

as valid

operations

securities

and

represents

sum

the

of

minus

operating

expenses.'' In order to identify the

exogenous

trading

profits

carry

rising rates.

trading

profits

whole often sustained net losses, as in 1950,
1955, 1965, and perhaps in 1948 and 1956 if
profits

for

Government

securities

operations

alone are considered.

Second, profits in the peak years
1958, and

1960

—appear

as a

— 1957,

hump

in

the

earnings picture rather than as the culmination

and subsequently reversed
misleading to compare
and contrast profits in only the two halves of
of

1

;

uses the 5-year periods,

taxes,

ated

recessions

the 10 years

!9591

a

trend.

well-defined

Thus

it

may be

• Data
on the relative contributions of capital
gains or losses and spreads ("turnaround" prices) to
these swings in trading profits are not available.

However, the behavior of these two components
be examined later.

will

variables that influence dealer earnings

and

to

diagnose their effect on earnings over the past
decade, the elements of income and expense

can be viewed as the products of independent,
or possibly interdependent, components.

Trading

profits, the

primary element of net

income, are the sum of differences between the
purchase and sale price of each security sold.

The purchase-sale
split

conceptually

price
into

differential

two

facets:

can
(1)

be
the

spread, which represents the bid-offer quotations at

which a dealer would simultaneously

Hereinafter, the terms "dealer" and "dealer function" refer only to the Government securities opera"'

tions of participating firms.

86

TABLE

1:

INCOME AND EXPENSES OF

SECURITIES DEALERS, 1948-65

U.S.

GOVERNMENT

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

= number of bonds sold
= p.t - p., -I
= price at end of period

Si,
i^Pit

Pi,

bond
coupon on

=
= number

Ci,

Pit-i

period

/

in period

ined
/,

in dollars

per

=

F=
V =

net of gross long and

borrowed

on

rate

funds borrowed during period

constant

ex-

1960's the

number

bill

of dealers

as short-term investment instruments

was

U.S.

supply

Government

elasticities in

securities,

the market for

thereby narrowing

spreads.

of

risks

making

markets.

Quoted

1950 are presented in Table 2. It is
bill spreads narrowed throughout
the late 1950's and continued to decline in the
early 1960's while spreads on coupon securities exhibited mixed behavior. It should be
since

noted that the spreads recorded here are an-

nounced quotations,

which

may

vary

to

a

greater or lesser degree from the actual or inside spreads at

which trades are effected. The
between announced

possibility of a discrepancy

inside spreads increases as spreads widen,

do

in the case of longer-term issues.

and carry

rates were prephenomena, the
long-term profitability of Government securities dealers would depend in great measure on
the behavior of spreads. Although much de-

price changes

to be primarily cyclical

tailed empirical analysis
is

dealers for

of these

evident that

sumed

CD's

mand and
variable

representing

spreads for several maturity categories of secu-

If

among

developments should have increased the de-

/

fixed expenses

diary broker service and a reward for assum-

and

both to the

vastly expanded. Theoretically, both of these

/

Spread. The bid-asked spread encompasses

as they

refers

increased and the use of Federal funds and

funds

both compensation for performing the interme-

rities

case,

spreads in the

1,

TRADING PROFITS

the

this

of alternative instruments and

—

components can now be investigated separately in measuring the impact
of changing exogenous variables.

ing

Competition, in

is examon operating expenses.

of variable costs

to the degree of competition

/th issue, in dollars

penses

Each

section

business. Coincident with the narrowing of

interest

total

the

of bonds held at the end of

during period
Bit

in

substitutability

short positions in the /th issue

=

b,

The behavior

costs.

/

remains to be done,

it

possible to suggest several factors that influ-

ence the width of security spreads.
Intuitively

component

one

would

expect

the

service

of spread to vary inversely with the

degree of competition and the level of variable

2: SPREAD BETWEEN DEALERS' QUOTED
AND ASKED PRICES ON U.S. GOVERNMENT

TABLE
BID

SECURITIES, 1950-65

2

CHANGES

IN

TREASURY

BILL RATES, 1948-66

I

'58

—Changes

Federal Reserve

derived

I

I

rages

f

I

I

of

daily

volume

undertaken

for each category; this exercise

is

spread quotations

is

making

and

markets

influencing the width of

the

associated with

risk

maintaining

positions

under conditions of potential price decline and
capital loss. Although risk cannot be measured
it

should be reflected

in the volatility

of the short-run rate or in price changes over
time.

Chart 2 shows the pattern of rate

3-month bills.
dropped considerably
ity for

with the late

1950's.

It

in

is

volatil-

clear that volatility

1961-65 compared

The primary

reduced price fluctuation should be

effect

to

of

lower

the risks inherent in positioning securities and
therefore

I

as

I

to

spread. This

contract the risk

would depress

daily-average rates on 3-month

component

profitability,

of

even

from 1948 to 1950 when the Federal Reserve
was pegging interest rates. Indeed, bill spreads
were widest in the years immediately following
removal of the pegs. (Reduced volatility in the
1960"s is also evident in Appendix Tables 6
and 7 of the Ahearn-Peskin study; these tables
record the frequency of large and small daily
price changes.)

In examining the financial environment of
the 1960's, Ettin concludes that

stability

to
in

the

dealers, the reason for

early

1960's

movements by

tion

with "operation twist."

It

is

As

.

.

more

the Treasury and Federal

contributed
'

".

ag-

response to short-run rate

to

a

greater

stability

Reof

evidence, he notes the increased

Reserve

in the 1960's

—which had

the effect of

was the

greater control of interest rates exerted by the

Open Market Committee

flexible

use of repurchase agreements by the Federal

might be zero.

many

and

gressive

yields."

According

in

declined

when the program was iniand that they remained relatively stable
through most of 1965. The only period of commensurate stability shown on the chart was

the actual net price change for periods of either
stability or instability

bills

tiated,

serve

Federal

the

in

Chart 2 that month-to-month fluctuations

though the expected value of price changes or

rate

|

published

sharply in 1961,

in the next section.

The second element

directly,

I

figures

Biilleiin.

evaluated only in the context of the trend in
sales

'64

'62

'60

I

Note.

in conjunc-

evident in

Edward C.
vii-onment

of

Government
p. 22.

Ettin,

the

"Financial and Economic Enin Relation to the U.S.

1960's

Securities Market," Part 2 of this series,

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
eliminating

sharp

short-term

pressures

89

stem-

—

ming from outright purchases and sales and
the greater care taken by the Treasury in the
pattern and timing of its actions.
At the same time, Ettin attributes a good
portion of the stability

short-term rates dur-

in

ing the period to events and innovations in the
private sector.

Most important was

and balanced growth

in

the steady

output with relatively

constant prices and costs, which led to expec-

would be stable. In
expanded use of Federal

the risks associated with short-term rate

move-

ments. The circumstance of balanced growth

and of expectations that

rates

would be steady

could well have dominated rate changes in the
1960's. Needless to say, this situation

be permanent.

If

not,

the

may

reduction in

which implies lower spreads and

profits,

not

risk,

would

be only transitory.

Transactions." Linked to spread in the inis the volume of sales. Ceteris

come equation

tations that interest rates

paribus, profits should be positively related to

addition, substantially

sales

funds and of CD's as short-term instruments
raised the elasticities of supply

Treasury

securities,

tending

and demand for
smooth out

to

short-run imbalances between the two.

Whether behavior
tributed

more

in the public sector

to

be

seen.

—assuming

short-term stability to be a continuing goal of

—and

policy

the

increase

in

mobility

the

of

funds and the substitutability of instruments in
the

private sector should permanently lower

3

however,

the

of

interplay

spreads and of sales in various ma-

turity categories complicates the

measurement

of each component. Spreads were observed to
bills

but widened for some

longer-term coupon issues; on the other hand,
sales

climbed steeply for

bills

but behaved er-

The

increased sensitivity of the Treasury and the

Federal Reserve to rate volatility

in

have declined for
con-

to rate stability than behavior in

the private sector remains

volume;

changes

^ The data on dealer transactions and positions are
those utilized in other papers prepared for this study,

and they are subject to the same qualifications. Of
particular importance are the revisions of reporting
procedures and coverage in 1960, which essentially
preclude detailed interperiod ( 1950's versus 1960's)
comparisons of transactions and position effects on
profits.

SPREAD PROFITS ON

GOVERNMENT

U.S.

SECURITIES, 1955-65

I

MATURITY CATEGORY (YEARS)

TREASURY

BILLS

1959

i5i:.;

.

1965

1

I

Note.

—Spread

pi

Dealer
bid
iked qu
actions (Table 3), inflated to a gr

iroduct

were computed
annual basis.

lies
>

and

.'I

kule-half

iht-

of

dilkiLtiee between
d.ulN-average trans-

go

TABLE

DEALERS' DAILY-AVERAGE GROSS TRANSACTIONS
GOVERNMENT SECURITIES BY MATURITY CATEGORY,

3:

IN U.S.

1955-65
In millions of dollars

Year

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

From 1963

1963.

1965, total sales of cou-

to

pon issues fell 20 per cent.
The decline in spread profits after 1962
clearly depressed dealer income in 1964 and
1965. At the same time, one can hardly con-

growth

contingent not only on

is

but also on debt
lion

the

rise

management

Treasury

in

1955-65 period

bills

fiscal

policy.

policy

$1

bil-

outstanding during

$20 million

led to a

in daily-average transactions in bills,

coupon

A

rise

whereas a

clude from the foregoing analysis that gross

$1 billion rise in

spread profits contributed significantly to the

an expansion of only $3 million to $4 million

reduced

level of net

income

the preceding 5

to

tive

1961-65 relaNot only did

in

years.

spread profits reach a peak

in

1962, but also

1961-65

the average level of spread profits for

was $4

million, or nearly 5 per cent,

above the

earlier 5-year period.

Furthermore,

spread

profits

on

Federal

agency securities were undoubtedly higher

in

owing to expanded sales.
Dealer sales of agency securities generally paralleled the trend in issues outstanding, which
grew from $2.9 billion in 1955 to $7.9 billion
the

in

later

period

1960 and $13.8

billion

in

1965.

Dealer

doubled in the
Although narrower
spreads did offset much of the 150 per cent
expansion in bill volume from 1955 to 1965,
spread profits on bills were a minor component of the total. Had spreads been the same
in 1965 as in 1960 (the peak year for net income), spread profits on bills would have been
of

agency

securities

1960-65

period

alone.

sales

increased by only $7 million, a small incre-

ment

in total

spread

profits.

Future growth in spread

profits will

depend,

on the trends in spreads and in sales
of U.S. Government securities. Increased competition from other money market instruments
and from additional dealers is likely to remain.
On the other hand, rate volatility, which has
been somewhat greater since late 1965, is difof course,

ficult

to

predict.

The

stability

so evident in

in trading in

coupon

securities stimulated

issues.

Nevertheless, before concluding that growth

volume of short-term issues outstanding
more than a similar growth
in coupon issues, differences in the profitability
of sales in various maturity classes must be
in the

will benefit dealers

considered, along with the effect of debt increases in each class on spreads themselves. In

1962, for example, a sharp increase in outstanding 5- to 10-year issues
in

enhanced spread

profits.

ever, this expansion

is

initially resulted

Subsequently, how-

believed to have led to

narrower spreads due to the greater availability
or liquidity of these securities.
Sales volume, particularly in longer-term securities,

also varies inversely with the degree

monetary tightness. In the early 1960's,
coupon sales turned down in all maturity categories except issues with maturities of over 20

of

^''

years;

from

1963 to

when

1965,

interest

coupon issues
declined almost 20 per cent. In late 1966 and
early 1967, when interest rates turned down,
sales of such issues expanded appreciably
rates

were

total sales of

rising,

above the average

level of the

preceding 2V^

years.

Price (rate) changes; positions. The sec-

ond and by

far

trading profits

is

more

component

volatile

the gain

of

or loss associated

with price changes of securities held in position.

These changes are a function of ecoactivity and monetary policy and are

was based on a peculiar combination of public and private factors,
any or all of which may change considerably.
Sales volume is a function primarily of the
level and maturity composition of outstanding

nomic

marketable debt.^' Since the turnover of secu-

dealer positions, and the success of dealers in

rates in the early 1960's

rities

(dealers sales/debt outstanding)

dimin-

ishes as the time to maturity lengthens, sales

See Ahearn-Peskin, Part 2 of

this series.

accepted as part of the dealers' environment.

Trading

profits

vary

directly

changes and depend on the
such

changes,

the

anticipating price

The

size

size

with

price

and rapidity of

and composition of

movements.

close relationship between rate changes

1^ Sales of Federal agency securities rose in every
year from 1960 to 1965.

92

TRADING PROFITS PLUS NET CARRY,

y,

I

T-

AND CHANGE

BILL RATE, 1948-65

TREASURY

IN

CHANGE

IN BILL

RAT

llnverted scale)

Note —For
bill

rate

drsc
average

is

lining

Decemlie

midyear for compa

and dealer revenues is apparent in Chart 4,
which presents annual changes in the 3-month
(plotted inversely) and the annual
bill rate
level

trading profits plus carry.

of

when movements

—

the

in

bill

rate

In years

reversed

by a moveminus or vice versa the
level of gross profits changed in accordance
with the rate movements as plotted. For all
other years (except 1958), when the bill rate
continued to change in the same direction as
in the prior year (as for example in 1954), the
"wrong" movement in gross profits can be attributed largely to a rebound effect, since capital gains and losses were not cumulative from
direction

as indicated in the chart

ment from

—

plus to

The

tions.
tal

and extent of price movements and
ing positions appropriately.
the market,

als in

and flow of

rates in

some years modified
In

relationship.

profits

undoubtedly derived

long-term

the observed rate/

1962 the

profits

in

rise in gross

in part

from

falling

long-term rates over the year.

The
tions

size

and the composition of dealer posi-

determine the impact of a given price

change on trading
ticularly in

profits.

Large positions, par-

long-term coupon securities, will

naturally affect profits

more than small

posi-

in fact the

mechanism

may be

ex-

prices.

The year 1958

how

dealers

offers

a clear example of

were able to

profit

by making

timely adjustments in their positions during a

sharp intraycar change in securities prices. In
that year trading profits soared despite a sharp
rise in

bond

positions

movements

in adjust-

the profession-

pected to do better than break even in the ebb

change was usually diminished. Of course, the
of

and

As

for effecting price changes, dealers

in

and direction

on positions depends on the

success of dealers in anticipating the direction

year to year and the magnitude of the rate

size

net contribution to profits of capi-

gains or losses

bill

rates.

and a very small net decline
Table 4 presents average daily

rates

for all dealers in each quarter of
1958 along with changes in bill and long-term
bond rates; it also shows trading profits plus

nonbank dealers. In the first half
nonbank dealers had trading profits plus carry of $36.1 milhon, compared with
$6.4 million in the second half. With estimated
operating expenses of about $17 million for

carry for

all

of the year,

the year as a whole,

it

is

apparent that non-

bank dealers as a group suffered net losses in
the third and fourth quarters. Yet, they were

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
able to post the second highest annual net in-

come in the entire 1948-65 period.
The emergence of an apparently new pattern of economic expansion
one that is much

—

longer than the pattern of the 1950's and that
is

followed by short, sharp retrenchments in in-

terest rates

dealers.

—has

altered the flow of profits to

The implied

indeterminate.

Less

would tend

facie,

effect

on earnings

frequent

to indicate a

cycles,

drop

is

still

prima

in long-

same time magnify the importance of catching the peaks and
troughs in rate movements. Greater control of
economic growth should also imply decreased
amplitude in rate movements; this in turn, determ profitability and

spite

at the

the abihty of dealers to adjust relative

positions correctly at alternate

business cycle, would
opportunities.^''

factors

and

is

stages

of the

mean diminished

earning

Potentially

the extent to

contract

positions,

these

offsetting

which dealers expand
particularly

in

the

longer-maturity categories, and the timing of
these changes.

TABLE

4:

NET POSITIONS

GOVERNMENT
AND TRADING

IN U.S.

SECURITIES, RATE CHANGES,

PROFITS PLUS NET CARRY, QUARTERLY 1958

94

YIELDS ON

U.S.

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES COMPARED WITH

DEALER BORROWING COSTS, 1960-65

REPURCHASE AGREEMENTS

H^HL'^^^
Note.

— Borrowing

were selected from special reports

rates

submitted by several nonbank dealers and are believed to be
representative of all borrowing costs of nonbank dealers. Rates
on repurchase agreements represent the cost of short-term
borrowing from sources other than New York City banks.
"All borrowing" is the over-all cost of financing reported by

should
these

be

with rates on
bank dealers have

associated

closely

Indeed,

substitutes.

one dealer; over-all financing costs of other dealers may vary
slightly, depending on the particular mix of borrowing from
New York City banks and other sources. Treasury bill rates
are monthly averages of daily rates on the outstanding bill
closest
to a 3-month maturity; rate on U.S. Government
long-term bonds, from Federal Reserve Bulletin.

and longer-term bond
suitable

typically applied the Federal funds or the 3-

ability

month

in

computing the cost of

bill rate in

inter-

rates should provide

proxy for tracing relative carry

a

profit-

over time. Such differences are plotted

Chart

6.

In general, the carry differential

ent types of dealer financing, as reported by

and
widened
during
recessions
(1958,
1960-61) when interest rate levels were low,
and narrowed as rates rose." (During boom
periods the 3- to 5-year rate had a tendency to
rise above the long-term rate, making interme-

3-

diate-term issues relatively less costly to posi-

funds used.

nal
part,

Nonbank

have also financed securities

costs approximate to these
as

shown

in

Chart

month bill rate and
Government bonds.

at interest

money market

5. Interest

selected dealers, are

their

for

dealers,

rates,

costs for differ-

shown along with the

the rate on long-term U.S.

net

In the absence of actual data on net carry,
the difference between the

tion.)

3-month

bill

rate

Thus,

carry

" Most
flected

it

is

evident that the behavior of

over the past decade has usually
of the fluctuation in the differentials re-

changes

in rates

on 3-month

bills.

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

compounded
profits.-"

declined,

In
it is

the impact of changing prices

1961,

when

prices

of

on

securities

estimated that a large part of net

—

economic expansion the
tened. On the assumption
occurred in

yield curve

period,

this

had

flat-

that a similar pattern
is

it

impossible

to

income perhaps $3 million out of total net
income of $6 million represented profits on
carry. In most other boom years, however,
such as 1956, 1957, and 1965, it is likely that

help or hinder earnings depends on whether

aggravated already di-

financing costs are higher or lower than se-

negative carry profits

—

minished levels of trading profits and net

in-

in supplies of bills versus longer-term issues.

Whether

position

curity yields.

potential for profitable carry declined

from 1961 to 1965 as the Treasury
and the Federal Reserve worked jointly to in-

steadily

crease the relative supply of
to induce higher yields,

bills, in

and

to

an attempt

decrease the

relative supply of longer-term securities, with

an attendant lowering of
should be noted that

in

yields.

However,

it

previous periods of

-"In 1961, when the difference between short- and
long-term rates was quite large, net profits from
carry were estimated to have been about $3 million.
This estimate was based on average annual interest
rates and on net dealer positions for several maturity
categories of securities, with the assumption that
carrying costs were equal to the 6-month bill rate.

to

turities

and

size

composition

Although there may have been

some tendency

come.

The

assess accurately the relative impact of changes

for positions

vary

yield differential,

with

the

in

sign

different

of

the

macost-

Ahearn-Peskin found neither

strong nor consistent relationships of the type
to

be expected.

tory

It

is

probable that the inven-

and expectations about prices
outweighed considerations with regard

motive

largely

to carry.

The

fact that significant relationships

were found between short positions and carry
suggests that dealers may have preferred to use
short sales to

meet customer needs rather than

to hold securities with negative carry.-'

-^ This
observed relationship may be spurious,
however, since short sales may be more directly related to the behavior of interest rates.

ESTIMATES OF CARRY PROFITS ON SELECTED MATURITIES OF
U.S. GOVERNMENT BONDS, 1955-65

Note.— Rates on U.S. Government ^rcuntius
Federal Reserve BiiUeim. The J-monih bill rale
financing dealers' positions.

pru.\y tor the rate charged for

'

Dealer profits (or losses) from carry also depend on the type and source of borrowed
funds. Referring again to Chart 5, the cost of

repurchase agreements, such as those made
with corporations, was noticeably lower than

bank

the rate paid for
loans,

Among bank

loans.

charged by "out-of-town" banks

rates

during most of the late 1950's were Vt. point
New York City banks.

or more below those of

These

differentials,

narrowed sub-

however,

stantially during the early 1960's;

much

of the

shrinkage has been attributed to the broader
use of competing instruments, notably Federal

funds and CD's. Greater mobility of bank reserves has meant that rates on out-of-town

bank funds have become more sensitive to,
and thus have moved closer to, rates prevailing
at New York banks. Likewise, the development of CD's, which can be tailored to meet
needs and which have rates
above those on short-term bills, has vireliminated the advantageous position

nonbank dealers, and five small nonbank dealers are shown in Table 5.
From 1958 to 1963, the operations of the
large nonbank dealers were generally the most
profitable of the three groups, and this group

five large

had the greatest consistency in performance.
Not until 1965 did a large dealer incur a loss
in its Government securities operations. Small
nonbank dealers, nevertheless, were not far behind in 1960-61, and in 1962, 1964, and
1965

not more so, but that at the same time

firms,

if

small

dealers

have been more vulnerable to

changing conditions. One important source of
enhanced profitability has presumably
the

been

agency

had been held by dealer repurchase agreements as an outlet for short-term funds.

From an

dealers.

been as profitable per unit of sales as large

slightly

that

nonbank

examination of individual dealer performance,
1960 small dealers have
it appears that since

specific corporate

tually

earnings per unit exceeded

gross

their

those of the larger

increasing

the

activity

in

proportion

total

of

Federal
of

transactions

the

smaller firms.
Per-unit

gross

earnings

of

bank

behind those of nonbank

lagged

every year.

This

result,

dealers

dealers

in

and differences be-

TRENDS

IN TRADING PROFITS PLUS
CARRY, BY TYPE AND SIZE

tween the large and small nonbank dealers,
does not necessarily imply varying levels of ef-

OF DEALER

ficiency

order to evaluate differences in performance among dealers, figures for trading profits
In

plus carry were deflated

by gross annual

sales

for three dealer groups in each of the years

1958-65. The

results

for

five

bank

dealers.

:

.

,

Range: Higli

nonbank dealers:
Weighted average
Unweighted average
Range High

ive large

:

Low
'ive

small nonbank dealers:

Weighted average
Unweighted average
Range: High.

Low
1

Interest expense based

i

;

on Federal funds.

expertise.

Bank

their

rather,

dealers,

activity

in

the

bill

market, where profits per unit of sales are lowest.

However, because

correspondingly
tions,

TABLE 5: TRADING PROFITS PLUS CARRY PER MILLION
DOLLARS OF SALES, 1958-65, BY DEALER GROUPS

Five bank dealers
Weighted average.
Unweigiited average.

or

concentrated

have

it

is

bill

less capital

impossible

to

positions

require

than coupon posi-

determine

which

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
TABLE 6: RATIOS OF SELECTED INCOME AND
EXPENSE ITEMS TO GROSS SALES, BY
DEALER GROUPS, 1964-65
In dollars per million dollars of gross

s;ilcs

97

may be

misleading. In

in transactions
bills

—

entirely

tlie

first

place, growth

term operating expenses

has been mainly in Treasury
so

since

1960

—where

gate

sales.

—

Of

derive

increases in salary expenses pre-

course,

it

is

related

petitively sustainable;

TABLE
U.S.

7:

if

from certain operating economies

in-

bank

activities.

fivg

large

-' Data for individual dealers are not shown. In
1964 and 1965, 7 and 9 of 12 nonbank dealers, respectively, had operating expenses between $73 and
$105 per million dollars of sales.

com-

OPERATING EXPENSES PER MILLION DOLLARS OF SALES,
1948-65

for

nonbank dealers averaged $90 and $95 in
1964 and 1965, respectively, whereas corre-

not, the trend in long-

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES DEALERS,

nonbank dealers

Unit operating expenses of the

a matter of conjecture
levels are

of

herent in sharing overhead expenses with other

sumably derived from profit-oriented bonuses.
Were this the case, the relatively low level of
costs per unit of sales in the 1960's may have
been achieved largely at the expense of bowhether these salary and wage

been

of unit expenses reported

expenses are closely related to net income. In

nuses.

aggre-

years.-"'

indicates that per-unit operating

most years when profits rose
1949, 1953,
1957, 1958, and 1960
operating expenses
(per unit) advanced also, paced primarily by

The

the

—has

The lower (weighted) average level
by bank dealers for
their Government securities operations in 1965
($77 versus $96 for nonbank dealers) may

Second, a comparison of figures in Table 7

salaries.

in

sales

1964 and 1965 showed virtually no year-to-year
change (Table 6). Moreover, the expense
variations among dealers were small in both

portion of over-all spread profits per unit of

—

—both

of

unit

The expense data

spread profits are lowest. In this sense, per-

1

per

understated.

gross

unit fixed expenses have increased as a pro-

and Table

and

'

:

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
spending costs for the

were $166 and

five

99

small nonbank deal-

The

$165.-''

forth earlier in that:

large differ-

rather

ences in both years between the two groups of

profits

ers

nonbank
bank

may

dealers

economies of

be explained in part by

diversification,

suggested for

as

on balance the large dealers were considerably more diversified. Such a
finding would have important implications for
dealer profitability over the long term, as would
dealers, since

economies of scale with
volume of transactions.
Rank correlation analysis was employed
signs of

definite

re-

to

terms of both

and changes (from 1964 to 1965) in
transactions and unit operating expenses, but
no significant relationships were found. This
result casts considerable doubt on the meanlevels

may have

these differences

from the
sales

large part of

in effect

stemmed

"denominator," wherein varying

mixes produced dissimilar unit expenses.

The two
in

sales

A

dealers with the highest unit expenses

1965, for example, also had the highest ra-

tios of

agency transactions to

and both were small

total transactions

dealers.

REGRESSION RESULTS

deals with gross

it

before

taxes,

(2)

from trading and carry are lumped together as the dependent variable, and (3)
gross earnings are deflated by sales.-"

A

gross earnings concept was substituted for
income because of the unreliability and incompleteness of monthly data on operating expenses. In view of the problems that dealers
net

encountered in preparing the annual reports
Statistics Division for

1964 and 1965, it is doubtful that the dealers
were able to allocate to their Government seoperations

curities

fittle

more than

clearing

charges on a monthly basis. In addition, two

nonbank dealers submitted no expense data
at

all.

The dependent

ingfulness of the described cost differences be-

tween large and small dealers.

(1)

earnings

net

submitted to the Market

spect to the

test for the latter relationship, in

than

ported

trading

some dealers

—

variable

carry,

since

—reported

noted earlier

as

income) from

gregate

both re-

includes

and net

profits

bills

whereas others included

it

as

ag-

trading profits

with interest earned.

Total trading profits plus carry was deflated by

monthly

nonbank

sales of all

dealers to elimi-

nate the effects of market growth and bring out

more
ment

securities operations.

able

(A'li)

specifically

is

the

profitability

of

Govern-

The dependent

vari-

expressed as dollars of trading

Multiple regression analysis was employed to

profits plus carry per million dollars of sales.

estimate the relative importance of the con-

The

tributing
tion.

It

components

in the net

income equa-

should be noted that the observed reare

lationships

although
positions

with

—

it

is

in

terms

certain

of

realized

variables

—

Xi

particularly

the dealers' adjustments to ex-

and the resultant discrepancy between expected and realized profits that should
be of major concern.
Equations were estimated by using the
monthly data on dealer earnings furnished for
the Benston study. These data encompass the
6 years 1958-63 and thus were conveniently
divisible into two subintervals, which more or
less coincided with the two broad periods
under investigation. The general model tested
here differs basically from the equation set
Unweighted averages were used

to lessen the bias of

extreme values.

in this

instance

variables

were

tested

as

Spread

1.

profits,

— Quoted

bid-asked spread on 3-month

bills

Transactions

2.

pectations

-''

independent

follows

X-,

— Sales,

all securities,

nonbank dealers

— transactions, dealers
dealers
Xi — Coupon transactions,

X3

Bill

all

all

Rates and rate changes

3.

A's

— Change

end-of-month. 3-month

in

bill

rate
Xr,

— Change

in

long-term

bond

rate

(Federal Reserve series)

X:

— Change

in

preceding

Xs

-

— 3-month

bill

rate,

last

3

days of

month

bill

rate

Only nonbank dealer data were used since bank
dealers submitted no figures on interest expense.

100

— positions, dealers
dealers
Xio — Coupon positions,
dealers
Xn— Total positions,
X^

Bill

the preceding

cluded.

Others
1960 data

variable for

re-

— Dummy

all,

same

of the

independent variables. Differences in specificaentailed

mainly alternative

transactions,

and rate differential or level variaowing to substantial multicollinearity

positions,

variables. Five representative equations

are presented

Appendix Table

in

earlier subperiod, observations

3.

In

the

were used only

through April 1960 because of the discontinuity

data created by reporting revisions

in the

in the following

month.

Rate changes. Interest-rate-change

—

varia-

proxy for realized changes in the
proved to have the greatest
value of positions
impact on monthly trading profits plus carry.
Two such variables were employed in every
bles

the

—

equation

change

—

in

month-end
month-end
to
the 3-month Treasury bill rate (Z,,)
the

and the change

in the

monthly-average level of

long-term U.S. Government bond rates

(A",;),

using the Federal Reserve series on Govern-

ment bond
highly

These two series were not
and each contributed

yields.

intercorrelated

substantially to the total explained variation.

Experimentation
variables

with

indicated

various

that

this

rate-change

particular

pair

yielded the best results.

A

the 1958-April

1960 period and for the

full

6

ently larger than the bill coefficient (Zn), often

— 1958-63,

same dependent variable and many

bles,

therefore in-

proved to be highly significant for

1958-April

months when

for

1960, and 1961-63. The equations used the

among

rate over the last 3 days of

17 equations were estimated for each

of three time periods

tion

It

bill

month {X-) was

Several tentative observations may be drawn
from the examination of the rate-change coefficients. The bond coefficient {X,0 was consist-

variable

there were advance refundings

In

month-end would
The change

years 1958-63.

vision
X\-i

3-month

in the

all

Xn — Dummy

at

lead to unrealized gains or losses.

all

all

5.

changes that occur

rate

Positions

4.

third rate-change variable

was used con-

currently, but for a slightly different purpose.

Dealers, in calculating monthly income figures
for the Benston series,

may

not have included

the unrealized appreciation or depreciation on

month-end positions. Such gains or losses
would usually be realized in the succeeding
month. On the assumption that dealers turn
over their positions every few days, only those

by a factor of two or more. Changes in bond
were undoubtedly more representative of
broad changes in security yields than were variations in the bill rate, and given changes in
long-term yields have a greater effect on prices.
Second, the rate-change coefficients were al-

rates

ways larger

in the early 1960"s than in the late

1950's. This suggests that dealers carried larger
positions

relative

to

transactions in the later

period.

Spread.'^

The spread on Treasury

bills

{Xi) was positively related to gross earnings
in all periods tested, although the coefficients

were significant only for regressions covering
the full 6 years

and were much smaller than

the rate-change coefficients. Despite the impor-

tance over the long run of spread profits to
dealer income, there are several reasons

why

two results might be expected. First, the
spread on bills may not have been a valid
proxy for all spreads; for example, whereas
bill spreads narrowed throughout much of the
these

-^

The

variable serving as a measure of spread
bid-asked differential on the new 3-month
bill, as reported by the Securities Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York in its "Composite Closing Quotations" for the Thursday following

was

the

each new auction. Spreads on bills were typically
smaller during the week of auction than in succeeding weeks. The new 91-day bill, for example, might
have had a 3-basis-point spread on Thursday while
the 84-day bill (issued the previous week) had a
quoted 6-point spread, reflecting in part the greater
dispersion and scarcity of the latter issue. The Thursday quoted spread on the new 3-month bill was
considered

more

more

sensitive to

representative

of

actual

changing competitive and

spreads,
risk

con-

and less a function of scarcity than bills that
had been fully digested in the market. The monthly
spread figure is an arithmetic average of Thursday
ditions,

figures.

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
1955-65
issues

Because

selecting a meaningful

the

of

coupon

difficulty

in

for the

—

—

underestimation of spread influence relative to

spread

in interest rates.-''

between

itself.'' Our hypothesis was that tradvolume is inversely related to spread, since
higher volume enhances liquidity in the market
and therefore reduces the risk element in the

variable

spread.

The
riods,
initial

the

runs,

significantly

(X..)

is

more

sions, the bill rate

(X^) was substituted for the

rate differential, representing not only carry but

general monetary conditions as well. Occasionally the results

were

significant,

and they had

the expected sign; however, the variable contributed very

little

to the explanatory

power

of

the set of independent variables.

Transactions. To estimate the effect of
trading volume on profitability, trading profits
plus

carry per

unit

of sales

were regressed

pe-

so for the 6-year and the

bill

likely

stemmed from
The dependent

types.

rate, the rate-spread variable was found
be highly correlated with the 3-month bill
rate itself. Hence, in the final set of regres-

transactions

in all three

The

coefficients for total

transactions

difficult to assess the validity of the

bond
to

and

coupon

for

be positive

3-year intervals.

composition

Federal

the

yields of long-term

to

(X,) were
found to be negative and significant in the
same periods. With these mixed results, it is
sales

It

pilot regression

coefficient

(X,) was found

Reserve series
bonds and the 3-month
bill rate was tested as a proxy for net carry.
The variable coefficients were never significant
and occasionally had the wrong sign. Furthermore, because of the relative stability of the

on

With gross

ing

monthly data as opposed to,
annual data
has undoubtedly led to an

Carry rates. In

dealers.'"'

ables might be expected to reflect changes in

The second reason may be the lack of
month-to-month variation of bill spreads,
particularly in the 1961-63 period. (Quoted
coupon spreads varied even less.) As a result,
much of the importance of spread contributions to income may have shown up in the
constant terms, which were typically similar in
magnitude to the rate-change coefficients. In

changes

nonbank

of

bid-asked spreads not picked up by the spread

were not segregated, a variable
coupon spread was not introduced.

say,

sales

earnings already deflated by sales, these vari-

and for coupon

bills

issues

addition, use of

total

proxy and of the fact

trading profits for

that

some

on

spreads

period,

widened.

101

that

the

hypothesis.

observed

effect

the nature of the data involved.

variable incorporates profits on,

and transactions in, both bills and coupon securities. Because transactions are considerably
more profitable for coupon issues than for bills,
the

dependent variable should vary with the
of total sales between the two

The differential effect of composition
changes on the numerator and denominator of
the dependent variable, therefore, may well
have produced the particular regression
at hand.

A dummy
months

variable

(A',,,)

results

was introduced for

which advance refundings occurred in the 1958-63 period. The coefficient
was consistently positive and significant for rethe 8

in

gressions covering the 6-year period but neither consistently positive nor significant for the

1961-63 interval in which six refundings were
conducted. Inasmuch as activity in coupon is-

against three variables for transactions

(pur-

sues

increased

chases plus sales):

deal-

when

there were refundings, higher profits per

ers,

bill

transactions of

coupon transactions

of

all

all

dealers,

and

substantially

unit of total sales might be expected
basis of the foregoing argument.

On

a monthly basis, interest rates fluctuated
more widely than did quoted spreads. Were annual
data used, the relative magnitude of spread changes
would increase while the gains and losses associated
with monthly rate changes would cancel out to some
degree. The annual "net" of monthly changes in
trading profits plus carry would therefore be more
-'-'

sensitive to variations in spread.

months

during

the coefficients for the

The

on the

fact that

1961-63 period were

"' It

was necessary to use total sales for the latter
group because no breakdowns between bills and coupon issues were readily available for either transactions or sales.
•" Shortcomings
in the spread variable
cussed under "Spread" beginning on p. 100.

are

dis-

were positive

not significantly different from zero suggests,

ever, both coefficients

assuming that the number of refunding obser-

1950's (1958-April 1960) and negative in the

vations

coupon

was not inadequate, that spreads on
issues were lower during refunding

(1961-63).

1960's

early

spreads between

(New York

months.

in the late

Examination of
at banks

dealer loan rates

and out-of-town) suggests

City

were
inserted alternately with the bill rate (X^) as
proxies for net carry profits, on the assumption

that the average excess of these over the 3-

that all capital gain or loss effects associated

at that time. In light of these results, there is

with position levels had been removed by the

strong likelihood that coefficients in the two

Positions.

Dealer-position

variables

month
riod,

variables.''The results were
mixed and generally insignificant. The bill coefficient (X.,) was negative and the coupon
coefficient (Xio) was positive for the 6-year

rate-change

bill

rate

was greater

in the earlier pe-

implying a higher negative carry on

subintervals

may have
and

a

been influenced

in fact

by factors other than relative
capital gains

bills

rates,

such as

losses associated with posi-

tion levels.^'

period, as might be expected, with a positively

At the same

sloping yield curve. ^^

time,

how-

ss Although the 3-month bill rate was
used as a
proxy for financing costs in the discussion of net
carry, financing costs have typically exceeded that
rate. See footnote 20.
'* Revisions
in data coverage and reporting procedures may also have aff'ected the results.

s'

Position data were for all dealers since nonbank
were not readily available for
1958-60.
33 This note appears in opposite column.

dealer figures alone

IV.

DEALER CAPITAL: CAPACITY

IN

THE INDUSTRY

study refers

The only

to shareholder or partnership equity in a firm

bank dealer

The term

—

that

is,

"capital"

used

net worth.

in

this

Net worth

ployed as a base for calculating
is

also

assumed

is

measure

to function as a

and constraint on, a

em-

often

profitability. It

firm's ability to

of,

borrow.

historical data available for

non-

capital are those for aggregate net

worth; therefore, in the subsequent analysis of
trends in invested capital over the past two
it
has been necessary to use this
broad concept. At the same time, alternative

decades,

diffi-

concepts of capital more appropriate to the

render net worth a poor measure for

assessing either profitability or the potential for

measurement of borrowing capacity and profitability have been developed to give some per-

borrowing by Government

spective to the analysis.

Unfortunately, conceptual and statistical
culties

nonbank

In the case of

in segregating capital

as

Government

securities dealers.

used for their operations

securities dealers arise

both be-

cause of the intermingling of activities in an
operational

sense

and because

capital

often

flows from one activity to another depending

on the

relative

profitability

of

each

at

any

point in time. There could be similar complications for
dealers

bank

regard

dealers, but as

capital

as

A

dealers, difficulties

neither

a rule such

a

relevant

constraint on the expansion of positions nor a

discussion of measures of capital for non-

bank dealers and

of

the

arguments against

applying such measures to bank dealers

is

pre-

sented in the Appendix. In brief, two concepts
are developed for
capital available,

of

nonbank

is

nonbank dealers

dealers:

The

used to estimate the
to

expand

the second, capital in use,

is

first,

ability

their positions;

used to derive a

meaningful rate of return on equity. Capital
available

is

essentially the

maximum amount

of net worth available to cover margin require-

The portion of net worth representing
book value of furniture or stock exchange

suitable standard for assessing the profitability

ments.

of the dealer function.

the

—

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY
memberships, for example,
in use

ital

eligible.

Cap-

simply that portion of net worth

is

meet margin requirements

actually used to
effect, the

not

is

103

—

in

excess of the purchase price of posi-

Government and agency securiand CD's over the amount of funds bor-

tions in U.S.
ties

rowed.

rity of collateral;
rities

risk

The primary

defect in using total net worth

to detect secular shifts

of

the

no way
among competing func-

is

that there

Insofar

firm.

is

of

shifts

as

that

type represent permanent or semi-permanent

commitments

that could inhibit flexibility, the

trends in capacity growth will be misstated.

On

margins on longer-term secu-

are higher because of the greater price

incurred by the lender. In sum, the ex-

pandability of dealer positions depends on the

amount
size

to gauge industry size

tions

quirements vary according to type and matu-

of capital available for margins;

of required margins;

with the

latter,

and types

—

and

in

on the

conjunction

on the maturity composition

of securities held by dealers.

change. Changes in the level
nonbank dealer firms over the
past two decades have resulted from varying
profit performance,
the entry and exit of
firms, and decisions about the retention or dis-

Sources

of capital

of

of

the other hand, the available net worth data

bursement of earnings.

may be

a reasonably accurate measure of capi-

clude the addition or withdrawal of capital by

For ex-

individual officers or partners, the issuance of

to

long-term debt, and unrealized appreciation or

available in certain circumstances.

tal

ample,

for

nonbank dealers

active

prior

1960, the dealer function constituted an important

—

if

not the most important

—

part of

Thus observed trends in
amount of
U.S. Government securities

the firm's activities.

net worth should validly reflect the
capital available to

dealers for their operations.

Marginal factors

in-

shows the year-end level
nonbank dealers for
1948-65, based on two overlapping series.
The first series, 1948-58, was compiled by
Meltzer and von der Linde largely on the basis
of annual financial statements; it includes what

depreciation. Table 8

of aggregate net worth of

appears to be net worth plus recognizable re-

INVESTED CAPITAL
The expansion
is

of

a function of the

through borrowing

amount

of capital available

and of the nature of the

assets that

as financing collateral. Dealers in

may

serve

Government

an extreme in the utilizaborrowed funds or leverage, for they

securities represent

tion of

The second

1955-65, was comfrom both financial statements and supplementary data available on a
confidential basis to the Credit Department of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Much
of the discrepancy between the two series in
the 1955-58 period stems from the inclusion
serves.

assets

series,

piled by the author

typically maintain a capital/asset ratio of less

than 5 per cent. Their ability to operate with
this

exaggerated leverage

on the

is

based, of course,

and risk characteristics of their
namely U.S. Government seExpansion is limited, however, since

liquidity

TABLE 8: TOTAL NET WORTH OF NONBANK
DEALERS IN U.S. GOVERNMENT SECURITIES,
1948-65

collateral assets,
curities.

nonbank dealers are required to provide some
margin to the lender as protection against potential price declines on securities used as
collateral.^^

These

^^

capital

—

or

margin

—

re-

Collateral securities are necessary for long posiFor short positions the margin provides protection against price increases in the
loaned securities. Bank dealers also have expansion
constraints, but these constraints are not of the same

tions or short positions.

nature. See Appendix.

Year

—

more permanent-type reserves in the second series. Some of the variation may also result from diiferences in treatment of unreaHzed

One bank dealer that began trading with the
System Open Market Account in 1954 ceased

gains or losses.

small nonbank dealer in mid- 1955, the industry

of

The

figures

worth

on net

generated

by

Meltzer and von der Linde cover the 12 non-

bank

dealers "designated for handling transac-

tions in U.S. securities (with the

Market Account)"

in

System Open

1958. In the 1948-52

period, however, only 5 of these dealers were

more than 12

actually so designated, whereas

were trading with the Federal Reserve at one
time or another in 1953-58; thus, net worth
for the group, as

we have

defined

it,

was over-

stated in the Meltzer-von der Linde series for

1948-52 and perhaps slightly understated for
1953-58. The discrepancy would probably be
on the order of 10 per cent or less, however.
For the two periods examined more thoroughly, 1955-60 and 1960-65, the net worth
figures (from the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York) are those for all authorized nonbank dealers.
period
the
For
1948-55.
Change,
1948-52,-"' there were 10 recognized dealers
5 nonbank firms and 5 dealer departments of
commercial banks. The five nonbank dealers
had an estimated net worth of $45 million at
the end of 1952, and in each of these firms a
considerable portion of activity was devoted to
operations in Government securities. Based on
their participations in sales and on their positions at that time, the five bank dealers probably "contributed" an additional $10 million
to

$15 million

of capital."

In 1953 capital and other requirements for
trading with the System

Open Market Account

were eased, and nine additional nonbank dealers received such authorization. These firms

added an estimated $10 million of capital.
Although three of them, each with net worth of
less

than $500,000, ceased operations within 3

years, the other six
'•"

The end of

remained

the calendar year

in the
is

industry.

used as the

1955. With the addition of a

the end of

at year-end consisted of 5 bank and 12 nonbank dealers with aggregate capital of perhaps
$85 million to $90 million, including an estimated $15 million to $18 million for bank

dealers.

Change, 1955-60. From 1955 to 1960, the
membership of authorized firms remained unchanged. Total net worth of nonbank dealers
rose from $72 million to almost $96 million, a
gain of 33 per cent. During the period about
$1.3 million of new capital was invested in
dealer firms and perhaps $6 million or $7 million
als

was withdrawn; the bulk

of the withdraw-

occurred because of the death or retirement

of participating partners

and

officers.

With a

decline of about $2 million in long-term debt

—from $3.3

million to $1.4 million

—

ap-

it is

parent that between $25 million and $30 million of earnings

Dividend
differed

or

were retained in the industry.
disbursement

among nonbank

policies

clearly

dealers. First

Boston

Corporation earned $20 milfion in 1955-60

and paid out 88 per cent of
dividends.

Similarly,

paid out 80 per cent of
profits.

this

Discount
its

amount

in

Corporation

$6.4 million of net

Largely as a result of

this policy, the

net worth of these two firms grew only 7

and

8 per cent, respectively. Other firms, however,

expanded

their net

worth considerably,

six

by

50 per cent or more. It is perhaps significant
that First Boston and Discount are the only
publicly

owned

firms.

Only four firms had long-term debt outstanding during the period, and all of them
were medium-sized or small. At three of these
firms, such debt declined between 1955 and
1960, leaving a total of only $1.4 million for
the industry in the latter year.

Change,

1960-65.

Between

1960

and

1965, the dealer industry experienced several
ref-

erence for inckision or exckision of authorized firms.
''
This and subsequent estimates of capital of
bank dealers are in effect capital available approximately the amount that would have been necessary
to conduct the operation on an independent basis.

—

at

membership changes. Three bank and two
nonbank dealers joined the industry, one nonbank dealer merged with a large brokerage
firm, and two nonbank dealers withdrew. Both

—

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

105

withdrawals from the industry were for reasons
unrelated to firm performance in the Govern-

ment securities market. By 1965, the number
of bank dealers had risen from 5 to 8, and
there were still 12 nonbank dealers.
Total net worth of all recognized nonbank
dealers jumped from $96 million in 1960 to
$261 million in 1965. Of the net increase of
$165 million, $148 million represented the
entry of two dealers plus the merging broker-

age firm, $25 million came from the increase

worth of these three firms over the 5

in net

and $12 million represented

years,

cumulation

the

at

nine

capital ac-

previously

existing

was a drop
$20 million in net worth because of the two
departures and the withdrawal of some capital
from the merged dealer.
For the nine previously active dealers alone,
net worth advanced $11.9 million to $83.6
million from 1960 to 1965, an increase of
16.6 per cent. This growth compares with a
rise of $17.5 million
32 per cent during the
earlier period. Three of the nine firms experienced a decline in net worth from 1960 to
1965, however, and $10.4 million of the $11.9
million increase was concentrated at two
firms. Partially offsetting this rise

of

mary

dealers from 1955 to 1960; between
1961 and 1965, three additional banks became

primary dealers and were authorized to trade
with the System

Open Market Account. When

gross transactions are used as a measure of

they show that the five older bank dealers
grew approximately 23 per cent from 1955 to
1960 and 34 per cent from 1960 to 1965.
Since most of this growth in transactions was
in the bill sector where margin requirements
size,

are

minimal,

the

of

rate

could easily have been

less

capital

expansion

than the growth in

bank dealer capital availat $15 million to
1955, may not have exceeded
1960 and, for the same prefive bank dealers, $25 million

transactions; thus,
able,

which was estimated

$18 million
$20 million

in
in

viously existing

the period; at the very least, earnings perform-

$27 mOlion in 1965. ,ln 1965, the three new
bank dealers accounted for 27 per cent of total
transactions by bank dealers, a figure that
would imply an additional $8 million of employed capital. Such a figure added to the estimate for the five dealers indicates that bank
dealers had a capital investment of $33 million
to $35 million, a figure that is close to the $35
million estimated by the banks themselves in
1965 as necessary for their operations.
In summary, the total net worth of the active
nonbank dealers plus the assumed capital investment of the bank dealers rose from a range
of $85 million to $90 million in 1955 to about
$115 million in 1960. Based on figures of capital available for the entering nonbank dealers,
the 1965 figure for capital funds employed in
Government securities operations by bank and
nonbank dealers was about $140 milUon. This
represents an approximate increase of 60 per
cent over the decade. For perspective, over the
same interval net positions and gross transactions for all dealers
after some adjustment
for reporting revisions
are estimated to have
expanded on the order of 67 per cent and 100
per cent, respectively. The two increases
stemmed largely from changes in Treasury

ance provided

bills.

—

—

dealers.

Capital could presumably have grown faster
had dealers retained a greater share of income
earned. At the same time, fragmentary evi-

dence suggests that

in the

1960's the propor-

tion of the total earnings of

nonbank dealers

accruing from operations in Government securities

years.

was substantially smaller than in earlier
For 1964 and 1965 combined, for ex-

ample, the Government securities operations of
these

dealers

resulted

in

a net loss of $6.8

million whereas aggregate

income before taxes
from all sources amounted to $128 million
($100 million of which was earned by one
large brokerage house).
capital

available

expand the
ties

could

little

It is

thus possible that

have declined during

incentive

capital used in

for

dealers

Government

to

securi-

operations.

As

previously noted, five banks were pri-

to

—
—

Capital growth in the industry in

came about almost

1955-60

entirely through the reten-

tion of earnings. After that, the

major share

106

perhaps two-thirds

—

of

new

capital

devolved

from new entrants, as growth in the older firms
slowed because of declining earnings. Whereas
net worth appears to have risen in line with
expanding market activity, as measured by
positions

and transactions,

tain that capital

is

it

not so cer-

expanded at a
during 1960-65.

available has

comparable pace, particularly

on position

levels.

tions held at

However, the

any particular time

level of posiis

of expected profits as determined

a function

by transac-

tion volume, spreads, expected price changes,

and other

factors. Unless expected returns are

may not be induced to expand positions to what might be
considered, on other criteria, the most efficient
high and/or risks low, dealers

level. In this investigation

we

are limited to an

estimate of the degree to which positions could

MARGINS REQUIRED

be expanded, given favorable conditions, be-

The adequacy

of

dealer

capital

depends on

the relationship between available capital

and

The latter is a function of the
and composition of dealer positions as

fore

encountering

straint.

required capital.

is

size

of criteria

well as the margins required per dollar of securities held.

How

large can positions

grow be-

fore margin requirements exhaust the available

assuming a desire on the part of dealexpand inventories to that point?
The assumption of dealers' desire to expand
positions is crucial. As evidenced by the
strong, positive relationship between the size of
an individual dealer's capital and his position,
capital available operates as a broad constraint

valid

the

absolute

capital

con-

As noted in the Appendix, this exercise
for nonbank dealers, but a different set
must be developed for judging the

expandability of positions of bank dealers.

Margin

rates.

The most

striking

feature

about quoted margin rates for Government sedealers

the diversity of quotations

capital,

curities

ers to

for each of the various maturity categories, to-

TABLE

9:

is

gether with the apparent flexibility in applying

such

quotations.

Schedules

of

approximate

and by
and by two clearing banks in 1966,
are presented in Table 9. The rates are ap-

rates,

as

reported

in

earlier

studies

dealers

MARGINS REQUIRED ON COLLATERAL LOANS AND REPURCHASE AGREEMENTS

In basis points unless otherwise noted

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

als

many

margins are

set

value of the

bills,

in

ments. Tlie consensus of persons interviewed

was tiiat margin requirements had, if anytliing,
narrowed over the past decade. Several noted
requirements were,

current

that

below the
years

In

narrow or

be

of

to

number

a

less strictly

stable

of

should be

it

some tendency

relatively

practice,

in

set

connection

this
is

periods

margins

"officiar"

ago.

noted that there
to

for margins

enforced during

rates,

as

in

the

early 1960's.

The maturity
ernment
the

in

(U.S. Govwas the overriding factor

of the collateral

securities)

determination

of

margins

required,

and despite variations among lenders, advertised margins seemed to be granted to all Government securities dealers without discrimination.
At the same time, discussions with
dealers and clearing banks indicated that preferential treatment
in the form of waiving
minimum requirements was extended by
some lenders on the basis of business received
or of the size of the borrower in terms of capital. Size was a factor in that lenders were typically more careful in checking, on a day-to-

—

—

adequacy of margins provided
by small dealers. Large dealers might be undermargined one day, and simply be asked to
day

basis, the

provide more coverage the next. Nevertheless,
it

by taking the current market

instances individu-

were quite vague about minimum require-

proximate because

is

doubtful that large dealers were able to

operate

on

continuously

margins

narrower

than small dealers over any extended period of
time.

In order to estimate

minimum

requirements for past position

total

levels,

it

capital
is

nec-

essary to assign margin rates to each maturity

category or type of position activity. Margin

in

terms of their bid price,

and rounding down to the nearest convenient
number.'-' The margin on CD's is computed
similarly,

although the requirement

with the source of the

CD,

that

is,

may

bank. For coupon securities maturing in
or

accrued interest

less,

margin, since

it is

vary

the issuing
1

year

effect serves as

in

a

rarely counted as part of the

collateral value. In order to reflect the

conven-

and CD's and the
addition of accrued interest on within- 1 -year
coupon securities, Va of 1 per cent was applied to bills and CD's and V2 of 1 per cent to
the coupon securities.
For coupon securities maturing after 1 year,
financing is again handled on a flat basis, that
is, excluding accrued interest. For issues maturing in 1 to 5 years, margins ranged from V2
point to 2 points, with the more frequent quoience factor in financing

tation nearer to

1

point.

accrued

for

sion

bills

To make some

interest,

Wi

selected for our computations.

turing

from 2

in

lower

5

to

10

years,

provi-

per cent was

For

issues

quotations

ma-

ranged

to 5 points

but were generally on the

Again,

allowing for convenience

side.

per cent was applied to
For issues with maturities of
over 10 years, margin rates quoted were from
3 to 5 points. In this case, 4 per cent was used
for 10- to 20-year issues and 5 per cent for issues maturing after 20 years.
Federal agency securities, having become
much more actively traded and widely held,
appear to have experienced declining margin

and accrued

this

interest, 3

category.

requirements

over

the

past

decade.

In

the

Meltzer-von der Linde study, 5 per cent was
used to compute dollar margin requirements
were reported on the basis of par value. Because bill
positions were reported at par value, however, aggregate margin requirements for bills may be slightly

totals

rates for
rities

Treasury

maturing

zero to as

in

much

bills,
1

as

CD's, and other secu-

year or
1

less

point.'''

ranged from

Typically,

bill

overstated. In congressional hearings in 1958, a survey

indicated that initial margins for loans at commercial

Zero margin generally means that the loan is
covered by an equivalent dollar amount of collateral
securities valued at the hid price. Although a computational distinction between points ($10,000 per million par value) and per cent of market value exists,
the overriding convenience factor has rendered the
•'^

distinction

virtually

irrelevant;

in

this

study,

there

need be no computational distinction because position

banks against collateral (U.S. Government securities)
maturing in 1 year or less were as follows: of $1.95
billion of financing, 47 per cent was financed initially
at zero margin, 23 per cent at W point or less, 14
per cent at 1 point. 10 per cent at 2 points, and 6
per cent at 3 points or more.
••''For example, a 180-day bill bid at 98.321 might
be valued at 98.250 for collateral purposes.

—

108

applied uniformly to

all

types and maturities.

As

of 1967, several sources said agency securi-

ties

were accorded the same margins as com-

parable maturities for U.S. Government securities. For agency securities maturing in 1 year

per cent margin was used; for
those maturing after 1 year, a 3 per cent mar-

or

less,

a

positions; the second, used as a comparative

check,

was applied.
Margin rates for borrowed

summary

A

on the maturity of the
margins are
rity sectors

collateral,

lower

slightly

in the

depend

movements

positions

loans

covering

borrowed,

securities

because

move

prices of these securities

direction as those that are put

involved in

up

the

same

in the

as collateral.

borrowed
margins required on

then, are a

securities,

largely

because of the inconvenience entailed in calcu-

direct

Aggregate

the gross long positions,

of dealer capital needed to support the

amount

observed

level

—and

composition

—

posi-

of

without regard for the relative size of

tions,

period, in the

borrowed

either

against

securities."

approximation of the minimum

first

the total collection of securities submitted as

against

esti-

of capital used

to the fullest extent pos-

collateral

as

the

collateral

borrow

or

(The dollar value of a loan, of course, does
change with security prices.) Margins
range from virtually zero on bills to 3 points
for securities maturing in over 10 years. However, as a rule of thumb, 2 points is applied to
not

concerning

This entails using the entire gross long

although the

is

second method.

assumption

minimum amount

that dealers

sible.

longer-matu-

than they are for direct loans. Less

risk of adverse price

method

results of the first

figures for the

necessary

mates of the
is

securities

The

are presented in detail in Table 10, as are the

1

gin

based on the gross short plus net

is

long positions.

short

method,
from more
more than $40

on

Based

position.

this

capital requirements rose

dealers'

than $23 million in 1960 to

by 74 per

million in 1965, or

When

cent.

net

long positions were at their peak during this

week ended August 21, 1964,

requirements were $57 million.

The second approximation
needed takes the

of

dealers'

minimum

cap-

short positions

margin allowances for individual issues.
A total of two points was therefore applied
when estimating total margins on dealers' short

ital

positions.

can be used to repay outstanding loans and,
concomitantly, the released collateral can be

lating

Minimum

capital requirements. Applying

the margin rates selected in the foregoing discussion,

minimum

capital

requirements were

estimated for dealers' average positions from
1960 to 1965, and for the week of highest
daily-average positions, that

is,

August 17-21,

1964.'" Position data are given for all dealers,
even though bank dealers financed the bulk of
their positions themselves and hence were not
subject to margin requirements; the importance
of

this

procedure

will

be noted

later.

Two

methods of calculation were employed. The
is based on dealers' gross long

primary one

into account.

When

dealers

to sell short, the proceeds

shifted

noted

to

borrow

when long-term

collateral

borrowed securities
Moreover, bills sold short are
often financed by "due bills," which are unsecured borrowings requiring no margins. Potentially offsetting these margin advantages, howplied to

to direct loans.

ever,

is

the

fact

that

institutions

bills

lend

required with direct loans.

By

applying the straight 2-point margin

and the previously selected margins

sues are typically taken into position several days (or
more) prior to actual issue and payment. This
practice occurs largely in bills, however, where the
impact on capital is relatively small.

that

margins on Treasury
when used as collateral than are normally

securities require larger

ment basis, the position data lead to some overstatement of capital requirements because new security is-

to

is

when apthan when applied

being used, margin rates are lower

frequently used as a rule of

prior

As

cover the borrowed securities.

earlier,

1960 were available
only on a net basis, precluding meaningful analysis
or interperiod comparisons. Reported on a commit-

'"Data for years

securities

of the short sales

of securities

—

thumb by

lenders

to dealers' gross short positions
to net long

Minimization of capital used does not necesimply the least-cost combination of capital and
borrowing.
'1

sarily

...

..

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

109

TABLE 10: WIlNriVIUIVI AGGREGATE CAPITAL REQUIREMENTS FOR
FINANCING DEALER POSITIONS, SELECTED PERIODS,
BY MATURITY CATEGORY

5.09

Coupon

1

7.02

6.31

year

1-5 years.

.

.

5-10 years.
10-20 years..
After 20 years
.

Agency

6.50

7.17

securilu

Within

1.48

1.31

8.20
7.15
1.24
3.14

7.52
8.39

5.29
8.30

26.52

31.59

35.12

40.63

29.24

33.48

36.88

44.99

10.04
3.14
1.15

7.72
2.66

6.24
4.73

1.29
1.16

1.45
1.94

1.19

1.04

1.72

:

Within 1 year
After 1 year.
lificates of deposit.

Total
tross short plus net lonj

Gross short position
Net long position.
.

.

25.11

Total.

24.69

58.94

Includes long-term repurchase agreements.
Includes long-term repurchase agreements.
margin of 2 points was applied to the entire short
position; then selected margins were applied to net long positions in eitch category.
1

A

-

Note.

— Figures based on daily-average positions.

positions in each maturity category, aggregate

another way. The results, shown in Table 10,

near-term requirements of public and private
market participants. The foregoing analysis of
invested capital and of minimum requirements

were consistently above the totals computed
from gross long positions but not by very large

available

minimum

capital requirements

were estimated

amounts; the differences ranged from 5 to 11
per cent. The higher margins imposed on short
positions in bills weighed

more

heavily than

reduced margins on long-term collateral securities,
is

is

an important deter-

minant of capital requirements. '-

this

pected
'-

rate

availability

for

and

to

under cur-

judge

its

accommodating
to

exthe

similar types of

errors, not only with regard to the validity of

margin

rates applied hut also in terms of the practical prob-

lems of daily financing activities. In the latter sense,
both methods probably underestimate needed capital
by implicitly assuming a degree of fle.xibility and efficiency in the distribution of collateral

rates

However,

may

offset

among

lend-

under current clearing arthe generous estimates of

ers not practically feasible

rangements.

some

for

amounts of

capital

positioning

were

securities.
at

a faster

1960's than did the proxies

for capital available, the absolute

gap between

the two widened.

Far from seeing a withdrawal of invested

most firms grew in size
and six firms entered the
Furthermore, since bank dealers

capital in dealer firms,

from 1960

own
study was to ascer-

Both techniques are subject

margin

during the

industry.

tain the sufficiency of dealer capital

rent market conditions

1965

to 1965,

finance the bulk of their positions with their

CAPITAL ADEQUACY
primary task of

in

While capital requirements grew

but the variation between the two methods

not sufficient to indicate that the relative size

of the short positions

A

indicates that adequate

of this bias.

funds, the potential capacity of the indus-

grew substantially with the addition of
three new bank dealers. Indeed, of the $18
million increase in required capital from 1960
to 1965, bank dealers accounted for $9 million. In 1965, the actual amount of capital required
that is, the requirements of nonbank
dealers
was just under $29 million. This can
be compared roughly with total nonbank
dealer capital of $261 million and capital of
$86 million allocated to operations in Government securities. With the> mobility of funds
try

—
—

among

firms' various functions,

there

is

little

doubt that there

is

sufficient capital

meet any foreseeable needs

to

in the

securities, dealers

near fu-

their positions to

ture.

The

mentioned

crucial factor, as

may be unwilling to expand
accommodate official or private operations and may divert resources to
other, more profitable uses.

available

earlier, in

Nothing

determining whether public and private operations will be

accommodated

efficiently

is

the

expected profitability of such accommodation.

When

profit

expectations

sources can be shifted to

are

favorable,

Government

re-

securi-

operations by dealers, even to the point

ties

where bank dealers may raise additional funds
CD and Federal funds markets. Alterna-

in the

tively, when prices are expected
when bid-asked spreads narrow

where they do not cover the

V.

to decline or

to

the point

risks of holding

early

in

the

analysis

of

profits

in

the

however, indicated that dealer

1960's,

—

—

income and return on capital would remain permanently at low levels. Therefore it is

net

likely that dealers will continue to

respond to

profit opportunities as they arise. Nevertheless,
efforts to

prevent deterioration in market per-

formance, however defined, can succeed only
if

there

profits.

is

reasonable assurance of adequate

Capital will be

more than

sufficient

if

this occurs.

RATE OF RETURN ON CAPITAL
When

combined operations

Computing a meaningful rate of return for
employed by dealers in their U.S. Government securities operations is severely ham-

before taxes.

capital

each nonbank dealer were examined, however,

pered by the problems inherent in specifying

per cent (1964) and 27 per cent (1965). In

and measuring the appropriate capital base
and in making the proper allocations of income and expenses to this and closely related

rates of return

functions. Furthermore,

the

it is

almost impossible

may accrue to the dimake markets in U.S.

to assess the returns that
versified

dealers

Government

that

securities. Nevertheless, the rates

by Meltzer-von der Linde
for 1948-58 are presented in Table 11. These
data refer to income from all operations of
nonbank dealers.
The Benston study did not provide suffi-

the rates of return

the

of

on net worth averaged 26

both years, as might be expected, the highest

were achieved primarily by the

larger, diversified firms. In

1965,

when 10

of

nonbank dealers reported losses in
Government securities operations, 5 had overall profits and 4 of these were the large diver12

sified dealers.

of return reported

ciently

detailed figures

to

permit meaningful

on capital for 1959-63.
nonbank dealers only
whereas income data were for all dealers.
Clearly, the return was very high in 1960 and
quite low in 1963.
calculations of return

Capital data werel for

For 1964 and 1965, nonbank dealers

mated

that they

and $85.5
their

million, respectively, of capital to

Government

on these

esti-

had allocated $82.2 million
securities operations.

figures, the rates of return

per cent in 1964 and

-

Based

were 3.7

12.3 per cent in 1965

TABLE 11: RATIO OF AGGREGATE NET INCOME
TO NET WORTH, NONBANK DEALERS, 1948-58

Year

—

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

Some comparison
lar

fields

such

of rates of return in simi-

as

among

investment firms has been

brokerage

or

predictable clue about potential capital

Any

undertaken.

The second, and perhaps more important,

comparison of this nature, however, suffers
from difficulties that are more extensive than
simply allocating capital and income. Foremost

constraint on interindustry comparisons

are the problems of average versus marginal

various types of enterprise.

measurement, and the specification of a risk
differential. Currently available data on income

ble to

and

capital allow

computation only of average

rates of return for

The crux
ever,

is

extended periods of time.

of efficient capital allocation,

the marginal rate of return, that

howis,

the

move-

ments.

problem of assigning a

risk

component

is

the

to rates

of return in order to reflect the riskiness of

ers

assume

that

It

may be

Government

reasona-

securities deal-

should receive greater risk-compensation per

unit of invested capital

—

given the risks associ-

ated with highly leveraged positions and volatile

prices

minimal

—

than,

capital

say,
risk

brokerage firms with

how much

exposure;

income per marginal change in capiIn a diversified dealer firm, where consid-

greater this compensation should be, however,

erable portions of capital are mobile, average

very wide cyclical swings in earnings and the

change
tal.

in

rates of return to various functions

may

differ

although marginal rates are equal. Similarly,

is

a matter of conjecture.

difficulties in

Federal

Indeed, given the

quantifying nonmarket factors

Reserve

support

of

rates

—

just

after

average rates

World War

marginal

may differ among firms and yet
rates may be equal. Thus, differences

to generate a reliable long-run rate of return

observed average rates of return provide no

for the U.S.

in

II,

for

example

Government

it

is

impossible

securities industry.

APPENDIX

VI.

SUMMARY OF DEALER INCOME
AND EXPENSES,

A

statement

of

1964

AND

aggregate

1965

income

on

the

Government securities operations of the
12 nonbank dealers in 1964 and 1965 and the
8 bank dealers in 1965 is presented in Appendix Table 1. In 1965 nonbank dealers incurred

U.S.

an aggegate loss of $9.9 million, before allowance for income taxes, from these operations;
only 2 of the 12 dealers realized a

profit.

In

had shown a profit in 1964
and their combined pre-tax net income had
totaled $3.1 million. Bank dealers had similar

contrast, 9 firms

1965; as a group they lost $4.5
Only one bank reported a net gain.
The primary cause of net losses in 1965 was
the extremely low level of trading profits, particularly on coupon securities. Spread profits
for coupon issues, based on annual sales and
difficulties in

million.

APPENDIX TABLE 1
DEALER INCOME AND EXPENSES ON
GOVERNMENT SECURITIES OPERATIONS,
AND NONBANK DEALER NET INCOME
FROM ALL OTHER ACTIVITIES,
1964

AND

1965

In ihousands of dollars

Govcrnmenl
ope rations

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

REGRESSION EQUATIONS
APPENDIX TABLE 2
LIST OF INDEPENDENT VARIABLES FOR MULTIPLE REGRESSIONS
Symbol

Variable

Unit

Quoted bid-asked spread on the new 3-month Treasury
monthly averages of Thursday observations
Total sales, nonbank dealers, monthly averages of daily figures

Xz

Bill transactions, all dealers,

Xi

Coupon

transactions,

X,

Change

in

X,

Monthly change
Reserve

dealers,

in

series),

Change
3-month

X,

Bill positions, all dealers,

x,„

Coupon

X,i

Total positions,

X,o

Dummy
Dummy

Includes Federal agency

;

riiies

3-month

bill rate,

bill rate, last 3

dealers,

-|-I

days of preceding month

Percentage points

Percentage points
Percentage points

figures

Millions of dollars

figures

monthly averages of daily

figures

figures

'

months, January 1958-April 1960

for refunding

Millions of dollars

daily figures

monthly averages of daily

variable, 4-1 for all

and CD's.

'

Percentage points

monthly averages of daily

positions, all dealers,

variable,

figures

rate

monthly averages of daily

all

Millions of dollars

long-term U.S. Government bond rate (Federal

monthly averages of

X^

in

bill

Basis points

Millions of dollars

figures

monthly averages of daily

end-of-month, 3-month

X,

^13

'

all

monthly averages of daily

bill.

'

months

in

1960-63

'

Millions of dollars
Millions of dollars

0|-

|-|-

,^l

I

III

111

II

III

III

III

III

II

III

I

I

II

I

I

I

Qj'
S 3

ffiO
<I1J

HOC
XUJ

<

^
<S

I

^

s;

I

< s

2

I

<

I

I

I

I

"

I

III
III

DEALER PROFITS AND CAPITAL AVAILABILITY

115

MEASUREMENT OF DEALER CAPITAL

may be
Dealers. The broadest measure of
the accapital is net worth

Nonbank

—

nonbank dealer

counting residual of assets over

liabilities.

It

has the advantage of being easily calculated

and

it

does provide an indication of the

protection afforded creditors.

Moreover,

risk
it

is

of

1958-63 period.
A narrower measure of capital, and one
which more closely reflects a dealer's ability
to expand positions, is capital available. Capital available represents the amount of capital
that management is able or willing to commit
to the financing of Government securities. If
not formally allocated by management, it is essentially net worth minus all assets not servicecapital for the

able

loan

as

finance

positions.

for example,

would be

collateral

to

stock

and fixtures, good faith deposits,
exchange memberships, and the mini-

mum

capital

furniture

ships

requirements for such member-

and for other firm

Finally, there

is

For example, a lucrative cormay pre-empt capital normally committed to financing a Treasury reparticular time.

funding operation.
In selecting a meaningful base to

biases exist

tial

a third potential measure,

over the value of loans against

which such securities have been pledged.
There is considerable evidence that all three
concepts were used in the most recent figures
on allocated capital collected by the Market
Statistics Division of the Federal Reserve Bank
York. However, some dealers, lacking
guidelines,

presented

figures

unre-

lated to any of these concepts.

Capital available
priate

measure

less there

is

is

some

—

additional

—because

it

is

for position expandability, un-

a policy limit set by

to

Government

culation,

it

management

may

securities financing.

should not be

be devoted

As

difficult for

corporated

to

expandability,

in reserve for financ-

would not be

securities,

in-

in the base. In this case, profitability

would be overstated. Alternatively, a capital
figure for firms that deal in both U.S. Government and other securities would certainly
include funds that are normally used for operations in other securities; this

would lead

to

an

for

profitability.

for cal-

At nondiversified
would result in

course, both concepts

firms,

the

of

same

Dealers in other than U.S. Government se-

may

not necessarily squeeze borrow-

ings to the limit

—

that

is,

always borrow with

minimal margins, siphoning

off or

adding capi-

as the level of positions requires. In ques-

tal

how much

tioning whether or

minimum

of the

required

is

capital in excess

included in ob-

served capital in use by diversified dealers, a
feasible

normative

assumption

is

suggested:

namely, that dealers faced with alternative apginal

of limited capital

benefits

of

allocating

Under such

equate the marfunds

to

each

would be
committed to maintaining Government securities positions when it is profitable to do so.
When competing needs for capital are slack,
activity."

a plan capital

manage-

ment to provide a realistic estimate of the
amount of capital that is potentially available.
A serious drawback to the use of such a figure
as a guidehne

being held

Government

ing

plications

undoubtedly the appro-

on the amount of capital that

both the capital-available

employed in other activities that
amount of capital available

capital not
is,

curities

New

in

and the capital-in-use concepts. For example,
in assessing the capital-in-use concept, any

ket value of securities positions, including ac-

allocative

measure

one should remember that poten-

profitability,

capital figure.

of

relative

funds at any

porate underwriting

which is the amount of funds
actually committed as margins for financing
positions. In practice, it is the excess of marinterest,

and of the

particular situation

a

not be stable but

overstated base and to an understated figure

activities.

capital in use,

crued

may

a function of the perceived profitability

profitability of alternative uses of

the only available statistical measure of dealer

Specifically excluded,

available

that capital

however,

is

Dynamically, capital flows are created hy .shifts
marginal revenue functions of various activities arising from changing market conditions, expectations, and opportunities for capital use in each ac'

'

in

the

tivity.

presumably borrowings would be minimized,
but

this

would be a function

financing

of

charges.

Bank Dealers. A
for

bank dealers

measure criterion

capital

virtually meaningless, be-

is

to estimate profitabihty for this

It is difficult

group

of

dealers

may borrow more

eral funds
sitions,

In

dealers.

the

market purely

first

bank

place,

heavily in the Fed-

to support dealer

po-

on the theory that the larger borrow-

cause capital does not function as a constraint

ings

on position expansion, nor is it used for calculating profitability. In sum, the concepts of
capital available and capital in use have no
useful interpretation in the bank dealer situa-

positions.

are

offset

To

this

by

these

of

the

liquidity

extent,

no bank

capital

this case

is

committed; the margin in

is

simply

constrained

good name of the bank. Secondly, there is
problem of defining an appropriate opportunity cost for the amount of funds in use
be
it deposits
(and capital) or borrowings that
would have been allocated to other bank
activities.^' This is perhaps one reason why

limits set

bankers,

tion.

The expansion

of positions in

Government

banks is
by formal or informal position
by management, usually for several

securities in the dealer operations of

maturity categories. Under certain conditions,
these

maximum

discretion

of

levels

may

be exceeded

management;

pansion of dealer positions

by factors not
role.

directly

at the

alternatively,

may be

ex-

restrained

related to the

dealer

In particular, several bank dealers pro-

vide considerable assistance to their banks in
adjusting

the

banks'

reserves,

often

through

short sales or the placing of repurchase agree-

ments.

Even though

theoretically divorced

investment portfolio,
physically

the

dealer operation

is

from management of the
it is

often integrated both

and operationally with the money
centers. In short, no matter what

management

the formal maximums may
may be determined in large
quidity needs, which may run
ties

be,

expandability

part by bank

biUty of the latter

is

adequate.

the

—
—

who

only recently have experimented

with functional cost analysis, have not devel-

oped standards for judging dealer profitability.
To quote one banker, "... a black figure is
good; the bigger, the better."
Finally,

banks

differ

in

their

use

of

the

dealer operation for servicing customers and,
as previously noted, in their assistance in adjusting reserve positions.

Because many dealers

are operationally integrated with other

management

money

functions, the difficulties of allo-

cating expenses properly,

combined with the
from

tangible costs and the intangible returns

servicing customers

and

assisting reserve

ad-

justment, render any statement of profitability

tenuous at best.

li-

counter to securi-

market considerations even when

the

profita-

'

Differences

in

securities operations

between U.S. Government
and other uses of funds would
comparing re-

rislv

also have to be taken into account in

turns

on funds

in use.

Felix T. Davis

and Matthew

J.

Hoey

Government Bond and Safekeeping Department
Federal Reserve Bank of New York

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

CONTENTS

I.

II.

INTRODUCTION

121

SECURITIES CLEARING ARRANGEMENT

122

Clearing Telegraphic Transfers of Government Securities
Development of a Full-Scale Government Securities Clearing

122

Arrangement
Other Transactions Processable Through Clearings

123
126

III.

BOOK-ENTRY PROCEDURE

127

IV.

EFFECTING CLEARING SETTLEMENTS THROUGH BOOK-ENTRY

128

CLEARING AND BOOK-ENTRY APPLIED TO AGENCY SECURITIES

129

CONCLUSION

130

V.
VI.

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS

I.

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

IN

INTRODUCTION

The market
ernment

in

of

securities

known today

as

—

U.S.

the

Gov-

so important both

This

paper describes

that

clearing

ment, which includes 8 of the

1 1

arrange-

New York

of trading that

member banks whose operations in the
Government bond market, either directly or as
clearing agent for nonbank dealers, are suffi-

issuance of Liberty

ciently

and

to fiscal policy

economy

—had

to the well-being of our

beginnings in the expansion

its

was accomplished through the
Loan Bonds during World
War L With the exception of the Federal Re-

City

broad to warrant

the clearing concept

serve System's telegraphic facilities for trans-

tance,

ferring securities, introduced in 1921, the dec-

local transfers of

ades since World
in

War

I

have seen few changes

cumbersome

the

and

time-consuming

observed in issuing, receiving, and

practices

securities.
The purmade by the primary dealers
Government securities frequently num-

Government

delivering

chases and sales
in U.S.

ber in the thousands on a single day, and so
is

it

apparent that an enormous amount of un-

pleting

individual

securities;

an experimental clear-

was created

ble to transfers of securities

that

between two

York City member banks and banks
Federal Reserve

districts

originally designed.

A

which

it

tion of the various types of transfers of

ernment
clearing

through

was

brief illustrated descrip-

Gov-

securities eligible for inclusion in the

arrangement

appears

in

Charts

1

3.

ticipants that maintain securities accounts with

was made toward

reducing the need for individual deliveries of
ing arrangement

City, in addition

interdistrict transfers for

New

delivery of the securities concerned.

Government

to the

was applica-

is

In mid- 1965 a beginning

the participants

now encompasses
securities among

Government
in New York

At the same time that the securities clearing
was being developed in New
York, plans were also being formulated within
the Federal Reserve System for the establishment of a book-entry procedure in connection
with the issuance and custody of U.S. Government securities held by the Reserve Banks for
member banks and certain other market par-

expended in comtransactions by physical

necessary time and effort

their participation in

such an arrangement. Of even greater impor-

in

other

through the Federal

arrangement

the Reserve Banks.

book-entry

Among

other things, the

procedure will contribute to the

facilities.

further development of the securities clearing

and bookNote.
entry procedures have been improved and expanded
since this paper was prepared in June 1969. In addi-

the daily net clearing balances by the delivery

Reserve System's telegraphic transfer

—

Many

aspects of

the

clearing

tion, the clearing participants currently include all

member banks
Association.

of

the

New York

Clearing

12

House

arrangement by eliminating the need to
of definitive securities. This prospect

settle

and other

important implications of the book-entry concept are discussed in this paper.

SECURITIES CLEARING ARRANGEMENT

II.

CLEARING TELEGRAPHIC TRANSFERS
OF GOVERNMENT SECURITIES
From
Bank

time
of

to

New

time,

Yorlc

tlie

Federal

Reserve

has considered various

proposals to reduce the substantial volume of
Government securities that are delivered daily
to

as fiscal agent of the

and from the Bank,

United States, in connection with interdistrict
telegraphic transfers of such securities among
Federal Reserve cities. Early in 1965 the Bank
formulated a proposal designed to achieve this
objective.

contemplated a
between the Reserve
Bank and seven of the major New York City
member banks ' that would provide for the esIn

essence,

clearing

the

proposal

arrangement

tablishment of securities clearing accounts at
the Reserve

Bank

in the

name

of each partici-

pating bank; in lieu of the physical deliveries
of securities by or to the New York City mem-

ber banks in connection with each individual
telegraphic transfer, appropriate entries would

be made

in the clearing

closed-circuit teletype

accounts by means of

notification to or

from

bank concerned. Settlement of the securities
owing at the close of business each day, based
on the net balances in the securities clearing
accounts of each participant, would be made
by deliveries of securities at the Reserve Bank,
the

amounts indicated by such balances, at
or after the close of business. It was estimated
that, over all, this clearing process would result
in reducing by about 80 per cent the burden
in the

of physically handling the securities associated

with these transactions.

experience, Bankers Trust

test

Manufacturers Hanover Trust

Company and
Company were

invited to join the operation in mid- 1966, fol-

lowed successively by First National City
Bank, Chemical Bank New York Trust Company, Chase Manhattan Bank, and the Bank
of

New

York.

With these additional banks the clearing
arrangement had grown to include as active
~
participants 8 of the 1 1 New York City banks
bond
Government
whose operations in the
market, either directly or as clearing agent for
nonbank dealers, were on a scale broad enough
to

participation in a local clearing ar-

make

rangement

attractive

During the

and

efficient.

stages of the clearing ar-

initial

rangement, questions necessarily arose about
the limitations on participation that should be
established.

For example, although

contemplated

inally

would extend only
banks

City

— and

to the principal dealers in
ties

—

number

a

It

it

was

orig-

arrangement

member

through them

Government

securi-

of exploratory inquiries

received regarding direct
ticipation.

the

to the seven largest

New York

in

that

were

nonbank dealer par-

did not appear necessary or ap-

propriate for the

Bank

to enter into direct ar-

rangements with nonbank dealers so long as
their clearing needs were adequately served by
the

member banks in the clearing group. Simithe Bank believed that dealer banks lo-

larly,

cated in other districts could and should par-

Following discussion of this proposal with
the Treasury Department, the Bank received
Treasury approval early in 1965 to conduct a
pilot-test operation of

ment with Morgan Guaranty Trust Company.
The pilot test was begun in July of that year
and in August was extended to include Irving
Trust Company. On the basis of the successful

ticipate

in

the

clearing

the facilities offered

banks

in

New York

arrangement through

by participating member

City.

such a clearing arrange-

1 Bankers
Company, Chase
Trust
Bank, Chemical Bank New York Trust
First National City Bank. Irving Trust
Manufacturers Hanover Trust Company,
gan Guaranty Trust Company.

Manhattan

Company,
Company,
and Mor-

-

Frankhn National Bank became the ninth active
in June 1969. Marine Midland Grace

participant

Trust Company and United States Trust Company
have joined in signing the clearing agreement but
have no immediate plans for active participation.

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS

1

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

2

LOCAL NEW YORK CITY TRANSFER
I

PHYSICAL DELIVERY -1

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS

3

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

MULTIPLE TRANSFER, Involving

PHYSICAL DELIVERY

-

Tim

All

Participating Banks

data processing equipment can be

electronic

put into operation by the Bank. Such equip-

ment

have

will

transfer

the

same time

it

will

of

capability

instructions

purposes

—

at

be capable of capturing

the
all

and accountincluding the development of

net securities balances of the various partici-

—and
—
—
pants

for the entry of debits

payments

representing

transferred

to

member banks
equipment

the

reserve

and

the

credits

securities

accounts

concerned. Until
installed,

is

for

As another means

switching

automatically;

pertinent information for clearing

ing

denominated certificates until the net
ment of balances each day.

of

the

this electronic

messages must be

re-

mum

of encouraging the maxi-

use of the clearing arrangement, banks

and other
Treasury
delivery

new

institutions subscribing to

Government

of

settle-

offerings

bill

of

securities

those

—

—such

as the

are permitted to take

securities,

whole or in

in

part, as a credit to their clearing

the issue in question.

Inasmuch

ble portion of such

newly issued

destined for transfer

issues

weekly

by wire

account for

as a considera-

to

securities

is

other local

or to other Federal Reserve

clearing banks,

layed and settlement positions developed by

Banks and branches, on the

manual methods. Accordingly, the volume of
intracity transactions must be kept within manageable limits by establishing relatively high
(in
1969,
dollar amounts per transaction
$250,000) as the minimum eligible for han-

of the clearing arrangement can

the transactions involving the principal dealers

dling through the clearing arrangement.

in

issue date, this use

eliminate a

great deal of unnecessary physical handling for
all

concerned.

Looking forward

Government

to the time

securities

will

when most

of

be accommo-

dated by the clearing arrangement, the scope

OTHER TRANSACTIONS PROCESSABLE
THROUGH CLEARINGS

of the clearings could be broadened to include
securities

States

amount of daily traffic
between the Reserve Bank and the New York
City banks and dealers in connection with the
There

is

or

Government

securities.

making physical

issued

by agencies of the United

a possibility that

principle

of

is

discussed later.

clearing

and

valuables on a net balance basis

nor

is

the use of telegraphically

settling
is

for

not new,

communicated

of

information to effect the transfer of securities

The rapid completion

between a seller and a purchaser. However,
the combination of these two established con-

denominational

exchanges,

of such exchanges can often be a critical factor
in

The

a substantial

"splitting,"

—

deliveries

on

a timely basis.

cepts in the current clearing arrangement, sup-

In order to expedite these denominational ex-

ported by the high-speed switching and data

changes, the clearing arrangement was broad-

processing capabilities offered by today's elec-

ened, effective in January 1969, to allow the

tronic computers, can assist in coping with the

participants to request the "change" they re-

quired

over

the

clearing

teletype

facihties,

thereby deferring the inclusion of the larger-

rapidly growing physical burden that

is

already

taxing the resources of large-volume handlers
of

Government

securities.

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

BOOK-ENTRY PROCEDURE

I.

In June

1963 the Board of Governors of the

Federal

Reserve

System

suggested

the

that

Conference of Presidents of the Federal Re-

Banks consider adopting a book-entry

serve

arrangement for Government securities held

in

While not expressed
Conference

in the

Presidents,

of

approval of the

adoption

of

the

book-entry procedure for safekeeping accounts
effectively

brought to an end the longstanding

policy of the Reserve

Banks against the ac-

custody by Federal Reserve Banks for their

ceptance of safekeeping deposits from banks

member banks

located in the central financial districts of their

means

a

as

of

freeing

vault

—

space, reducing the burden of cutting coupons

respective

and

because of the limited vault

collecting interest,

and minimizing the

risk

of misplacing securities of high value. Follow-

ing a study of this

proposal by the Reserve

Banks, discussions were held with

officials

of

Department and performance
tests were conducted at selected Reserve Banks.
Meanwhile, counsel for the Reserve Banks
Treasury

the

in

association with counsel for the Treasury

cities

and because there is a considerable
amount of movement between member bank
holdings and securities held by city banks as
custodians for their correspondent banks, trust

and others, including pledged ac-

accounts,

proved by the Conference of Presidents, the

of the Internal

placement

tive securities for

counts

discontinue issuing definiin the

and instead may

affected

custody acrely

on

ties.

Originally, the book-entry procedure ap-

plied only to

member banks
its,

Government
as

( 1 )

securities

free safekeeping depos-

(2) collateral to Reserve

and (3)

collateral

to

held for

Bank advances,

Treasury tax and loan

accounts and other public deposits. Pursuant
to

regulations

specific

governing book-entry

accounts formulated by the Treasury Depart-

ment, the program was put into

effect at the

various Federal Reserve offices on January

1968, and
ties

at

all

such

holdings of

Government

1,

securi-

offices for the three types of ac-

counts were converted to a book-entry basis

by the end of

that year. In addition, a

number

of custody accounts maintained

Reserve Bank of

Department

New

by the Federal
York for the Treasury

and for various
organizations were converted.

international

member banks made little response to
offer of this new service. In addition,

the

banks have been reluctant to put any of these
under the book-entry system because

securities

Revenue Service (IRS)

rulings

regarding the identification of such book-entry
securities for tax purposes.

As

a

computer-based system of book-entry securi-

member

confined to the investment holdings of

counts,

may

facilities available

banks,

The proposal was approved in principle by the Conference of Presidents in December 1965.
By means of the book-entry procedure apReserve Banks

primarily

initiated

However, because the
first promulgated was

the Reserve Banks.

at

book-entry procedure as

continued to review the legal implications of
the proposed book-entry procedure.

a policy

a major step toward

overcoming some of

the obstacles impeding the full-scale use of the

procedure,

book-entry

ment

is

revising

the

Treasury Depart-

and broadening

its

applicable

regulations to permit the conversion of certain

accounts

third-party

to

a

book-entry

This revision, though applicable

basis.

at the outset

pledged accounts of the types currently in

to

effect

at

the

Federal

Reserve

Banks

and

branches, nevertheless opens the door to the
inclusion of additional categories of accounts

maintained by

member banks

subject to the

orders of others, such as correspondent banks,
trust

accounts, and

ernment
being

nonbank dealers

in

Gov-

securities. Coincidentally, attempts are

made

to bring about a modification of

IRS regulation on book-entry securities,
which if successful should simplify the carrying

the

out of transactions in these accounts.

Although large-scale adoption of the book-

—

—

entry procedure by banks in the central finan-

discussions

would present no difficulties in
terms of maintenance by the Reserve Bank of

banks with a view to converting their holdings
to a book-entry system also. The inclusion of

cial

districts

the required book-entry records,

could gen-

it

amount of daily traffic befrom depositors for physical

be held with foreign central

will

Open Market Account and

the

Reserve Bank's foreign accounts

cause of requests

entry

delivery

of securities

to

their

or to others for their account.

representatives

As

discussed in

the following section, however, the effects of
this

New

York,

will

be reduced

to the extent that the securities can be trans-

ferred

among

participating banks through the

existing securities clearing arrangement,

which

requires only teletype notification rather than

physical delivery.

Plans have been
ties in

the System

book-entry

IV.

movement
counts and

made to convert the securiOpen Market Account to a

procedure.

At some future date

sion

would greatly

facilitate

member

banks.

may be

book-entry arrangements

of

the

from the purtransactions between these ac-

further in the future

Still

book-

in the

of securities resulting

chase and sale

increased activity, at least at the Federal

Reserve Bank of

procedure

New York

the

erate a substantial

the exten-

one or

at

more Reserve Banks to accommodate virtually
all owners of Government securities
including nonbanking institutions and individuals
through member banks. Once the principle of
relatively unlimited computer storage capacity
is accepted, there would be no insurmountable

—

barriers to the furnishing of book-entry cus-

tody service to

all

types of holders.

EFFECTING CLEARING SETTLEMENTS THROUGH BOOK-ENTRY

As already

discussed,

book-entry proce-

the

As

to the intracity transfers.

a consequence, the

dure that was adopted by the Federal Reserve

local transfer activity will be increasingly ex-

Banks in January 1968 was restricted to Government securities owned by member banks
and deposited with their Reserve Banks to be

or

held either in free safekeeping, or as collateral

tions.

Reserve Bank advances. Treasury tax and
loan accounts, or public deposits. Within a

balances at the end of each day will involve a

to

short time,

however, the book-entry concept

could be extended to apply to

all

Government

panded

pledged

to include transfers involving

accounts,

third-party

collateral

to

dealer

loans and loans to others, and similar transac-

Thus

the net settlements of the clearing

broad cross section of the kinds of accounts
maintained by any one participating bank.

Under

the

book-entry procedure these

di-

by member banks for their own
or for other accounts, thereby encompassing a

verse

number

fore not possible to settle the clearing account

securities held

of additional categories of holdings

including pledge arrangements

—not

provided

for under the present system.

The development
ties

of the

Government securiaccompa-

clearing arrangement has been

types

among

of

accounts

not

those that are eligible, and

it

included
is

balances through book-entry accounts.
ever,

once steps are taken

unrestricted

Government

to

the

For example, while interdistrict transfers of securities between Federal
Reserve Banks and branches are restricted to
bona fide sale transactions or to the borrowing
or the return of securities by a primary securities dealer, no such fimitation has been applied

mated Government

there-

How-

permit relatively

securities custody serv-

member banks on a book-entry
way will be clear to permit a fully

ices to

nied by a gradual broadening of the types of
transactions covered.

are

basis,

auto-

securities clearing arrange-

ment. In lieu of physical settlements the Reserve

Bank would merely

credit or debit the

respective book-entry accounts of the clearing

banks with the par amounts of the Government
securities issues owing to or owing from each

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS
bank

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES
To

as a result of the netting process.

per-

of a

large

volume

mit accurate accounting to their depositors, the

amounting

member banks would be expected

lions of dollars,

maintain

to

adequate internal records indicating the exact

each of their dealer or custody ac-

interest of

counts in the net clearing settlements and
the

account

book-entry

resulting

in

balances.

Normally, the clearing settlements would

in

Government

of

securities,

the aggregate to hundreds of mil-

from the banks where the

se-

are lodged to the banks that are ex-

curities

tending the loans.
counting,

The

examining,

labor involved in the

and movement of

this

normally defer the

collateral causes delays that

in-

delivery of the pledged securities to the lending

volve only one debit or credit entry for each

until late in the afternoon. Under a
combined book-entry and clearing procedure,
these transfers could be effected simply by
making entries in the affected accounts at the
Reserve Bank and confirming them by appro-

affected securities issue in a bank's book-entry

account, but in certain cases a limited
of subaccounts

number

would be maintained for

indi-

vidual banks corresponding to the general categories

of account

forth)

on the books of the bank.

(investment,

trust,

and so

banks

teletype

priate

The proceeds

notification.

of

the use of book-entry procedures relates to the

would be debited to the reserve account of the lending bank and credited to the
borrowing dealer, through the reserve account
of its clearing bank, at the same time that the

movement

securities are transferred in the

One

the loan

area of expansion of the clearing ar-

rangement that should be greatly assisted by
of securities as collateral for over-

night loans

made by banks

Government

in

securities.

when

well after midday,
lied

up

curities

the dealers have tal-

their total receipts

and assessed

loans

these

nonbank dealers
Normally negotiated

call

to

and

their

for

the

deliveries of se-

cash requirements,
physical

movement

counts. All entries
the following day

book-entry ac-

would then be reversed on

when

the loan

is

liquidated.

Such an arrangement, in addition to saving
time, would also eliminate the risks inherent in

amounts of

the exposure of large dollar
ties in

securi-

the streets.

CLEARING AND BOOK-ENTRY APPLIED TO AGENCY SECURITIES

V.

There

has

been

a

rapid

growth during

re-

cent years in the volume of securities offered

purchasers located
try are

in

other parts of the coun-

obligated to lodge their holdings with

New York

by the various agencies of the U.S. Govern-

correspondents

ment. The attractive rates on agency securities,

substantial costs incident to shipment to their

which are virtually indistinguishable from Government securities from the standpoint of
safety, have generated considerable interest on
the part of all investor classes and have re-

own

sulted in a steadily rising trading pace for such
securities in the

major

financial markets.

With few exceptions,
through

the

Federal

and paid for

Reserve Bank of

York. Since most of these issues are not
facilities of the

number

of instances, however, arrange-

ments have been made whereby

New York

City subscribers to certain bearer issues of the

National

Federal

Mortgage

Association

and

Export-Import Bank of the United States
may transfer their allotments, through Federal

Reserve System telegraphic

facilities, to either

New

the

eligi-

serve Bank, which will complete delivery

Chicago or the San Francisco Federal Re-

from

a supply of unissued stock maintained for that

Federal Reserve System,'

purpose. In addition, telegraphic transfers re-

Telegraphic transfer between Reserve Banks and
branches is possible only where stocks of unissned
securities are maintained at such banks in connection
with the original issue and related fiscal services.
'

city.

In a

through the leased

ble for telegraphic transfer

wire

City or to incur

the

securities of agencies

of the United States are issued

in

sulting

from subsequent transactions

securities

may be

effected

among

in

these

these three

Reserve Banks by means of the same

facilities.

The

further development and expansion of

the securities clearing arrangement discussed in

paper must be extended,

this

clude

obligations

of

the

of

United

comcommunity. To
the extent that these non-Government securiStates

plete

ties

if

the

service

arrangement

to the

may become

to furnish

is

financial

eligible for telegraphic trans-

through Federal Reserve facilities, they
must be among the issues represented in the
clearings. In any event the anticipated expansion of the clearing arrangement may necessifer

mechanism

tate the use of this

local delivery of

not these issues
transfer

noted
eral

agency

become

securities

later to securities

owned by
owned by

and customers of these banks,
no doubt ultimately lead to the inclusion
of securities of Government agencies as well.
The resulting expansion of the clearing arrangement and the book-entry procedure to
the depositors
will

roughly twice the number of individual issues

view of the immense recordkeeping capability

As

cities.

New York

in providing

—whether

securities
in

Govwould

for

—

such an ar-

of the sophisticated data processing

now

available. Since the

equipment

Reserve Banks have

long been accepting the deposit for custody of
types of securities

all

rities

—from

—

including agency secu-

member

their

banks, no question

of policy should arise in this connection.

CONCLUSION

The years that have elapsed since the start of
World War I have seen remarkable changes
affecting almost every aspect of the

The myriad

benefits

of

a

economy.

computer-oriented

society appear on

all sides, and sophisticated
and time-saving devices have become

labor-

commonplace
and

streets of

in practically all areas of finan-

industrial

activity.

Nevertheless,

Manhattan and other

throughout the country are

the

financial censtill

filled

with

hundreds of messengers making thousands of
trips

Government

eligible for telegraphic

be absorbed by the participants

ters

custody

involved in each category at the present time

ernment or non-Government

cial

to

member banks and

book-entry

of

Reserve Banks, applicable

should present no administrative problem in

an intracity clearing service

VI.

initially

at the

whether or

securities,

any costs incurred by the Fed-

Reserve Bank of

arrangements

to simplify the

among Federal Reserve

earlier,

The establishment

time, to in-

in

agencies

rangement rather than by the Treasury Department.

each day

—

delivering

individual

lots

of

back and forth among the banks and
dealers that comprise the Government bond
securities

market

—

exactly

they did when the
Loan Bonds was made

as

offering of Liberty

first

five

decades ago. The failure to complete any one
delivery by the appointed time can cause the

cancellation of security transactions involving
millions of dollars, can result in unanticipated

and unnecessary

interest costs,

and can create

operational problems that
of participants

in

may

affect a

number

these transactions.

change these cumbersome
methods and to allow the traders in
Government securities to function free of the
limitations imposed by antiquated physical deIt

essential to

is

delivery

livery

can

methods. Since transactions

now be

means

finally

of teletype,

consummated

in securities

seconds by
and painfully slow individual

deliveries can be replaced

in

by end-of-day

settle-

ment on a book-entry basis, the means are
at hand for radically improving the market
mechanism. The savings in time and labor resulting from the elimination of most physical
securities-handling tasks will also result in more
economical operations on the part of all Government bond dealers, their clearing banks,
the Treasury Department, and the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.

The combination
niques,

clearing

of teletype delivery tech-

procedures,

and book-entry

AUTOMATING OPERATIONS
arrangements

IN

GOVERNMENT SECURITIES

—conducted with
computer-switching and
—can broaden scope

the aid of rela-

data-

tively unlimited

the

storage capability

Government

trading

never before thought

completion

of

activities

possible.

transactions,

to

a

of

degree

Instantaneous

with

immediate

payment in Federal funds, will become commonplace and markets throughout the country
will

be as accessible as those across the

street.

proportion to the increase

in

the

number

of

banks and other participants covered by the

new arrangements.

In a period

when extreme

time pressures, heavy workloads, and shortages
of skilled

they

will

operations,

manpower
continue

are crucial factors
to

problems that
ers,

and others

store physical securities will diminish in direct

ties

operations.

—

in

all

— and

securities

new techniques offer the
many of the growing
are now faced by banks, dealinvolved in Government securi-

these

promise of solutions to

Further, the need to issue, receive, deliver, or

be

12G7