View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

106 CONGRESS
2nd Session

SENATE
I

f REPORT
106-255

THE 2000 JOINT ECONOMIC REPORT

REPORT
OF THE

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
ON THE

2000 ECONOMIC REPORT
OF THE PRESIDENT
together with
MINORITY VIEWS

April 5, 2000. - Ordered to be printed

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON: 2000

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
[Created pursuant to Sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Congress]

SENATE

HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES

CONNIE MACK, Florida, Chairman
WILLIAM V. ROTH, JR., Delaware
ROBERT F. BENNETT, Utah
ROD GRAMS, Minnesota
SAM BROWNBACK, Kansas
JEFF SESSIONS, Alabama
CHARLES S. RoBB, Virginia
PAUL-S. SARBANES, Maryland
EDWARD M. KENNEDY, Massachusetts
JEFF BINGAMAN, New Mexico

JIM SAXTON, NEW JERSEY, Vice Chairman
MARK SANFORD, South Carolina
JOHN DOOLITTLE, California
TOM CAMPBELL, California
JOSEPH S. PITTS, Pennsylvania
PAUL RYAN, Wisconsin
PETE STARK, California
CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York
DAVID MINGE, Minnesota
MELVtN L. WATT, North Carolina

Shelley S. Hymes, Executive Director
James D. Gwartney, ChiefEconomist
Howard Rosen, Minority Staff Director

ii

LETTER OF TRANSMITTAL

April 5, 2000
HON. TRENT LoTr
Majority Leader, U.S. Senate
Washington, DC
DEAR MR. LEADER:
Pursuant to the requirements of the Employment Act of 1946, as
amended, I hereby transmit the 2000 Joint Economic Report. The
analyses and conclusions of this Report are to assist the several
Committees of the Congress and its Members as they deal with
economic issues and legislation pertaining thereto.
Sincerely,

CONNIE MACK
Chairman

ii

CONTENTS
OVERVIEW OF THE ECONOMY ............................................ 1

I

MAJORITY STAFF REPORT

5
Introduction ...............................................
6
1. The Great Expansion ...............................................
I. The Great Change in Policy, 1979-81 ....................................... 6
II. Factors Underlying the Great Expansion ................................ 8
III. Why Has the Budget Shifted from Deficit to Surplus? ........ 18
IV. Can the Great Expansion Continue? .................................... 20
2. Improving Social Security, Health Care, and Education ........ 22
22
I. Social Security ..............................................
27
II. Health Care ..............................................
31
III. Education ..............................................
34
3. Promoting a More Open Economy ...........................................
I. The Trade Record of the Clinton Administration ................... 36
II. The Future Direction of Trade Policy .................................... 38
4. Promoting Sound Monetary Policy at Home and Abroad ...... 40
5. Making the International Monetary Fund More Effective ..... 43
43
I. Problems with IMF Lending ..............................................
44
II. Reforming the IMF ..............................................
6. Reducing the Burden of Federal Taxes .................................... 46
I. The Size of the Federal Tax Burden ....................................... 46
46
II. Who Pays Federal Taxes? .................................
III. Problems Created by the High Tax Burden ......................... 49
IV. First Steps to a Simpler and More Efficient Tax System ..... 51
7. Economics, Trade Deficits, and Paying Off
55
the National Debt ..............................................
I. Is the Trade Deficit a Problem? .............................................. 55
II. Should the Federal Debt Be Fully Paid Off9 ......................... 58
60
8. Conclusion ..............................................
63
Appendix ..............................................
Table 1. Real Federal Spending per Person ............................... 64
66
Table 2. Civilian Labor Force ..............................................
Table 3. National Health Care Expenditures .............................. 67
Table 4. Health Care Price Indexes ............................................ 68
Table 5. Real Education Spending and Student Performance ....69
70
Table 6. Trade Openness Index ..............................................
Table 7. Individual Income Tax Shares ..................................... 71
Table 8. Trade Deficit and Net Foreign Investment ................... 72

V

RANKING MINORITY MEMBER'S VIEWS

AND MINORITY STAFF REPORT ..............................................
73
Finishing the Job ..............................................
75
I. The Longest Expansion in U.S. History .................................... 77
What is fueling the expansion? .............................................. 81
What should be done to maintain the current expansion? ...... 85
II. The Widening Income Gap ..............................................
88
Before-Tax Family Income ..............................................
88
After-Tax Household Income .............................................. 89
What should be done to close the income gap? ...................... 93
III. The Erosion of the Minimum Wage ....................................... 94
What should be done to restore the value
of the Minimum Wage? ..............................................
96
IV. Living Wages ..............................................
98
What should be done to expand Living Wage ordinances?.. 101
V. The Aftermath of Welfare Reform ......................................... 102
What should be done to assist welfare leavers? .................... 106
VI. Children's Health Insurance Program ................................. 108
What should be done to expand CHIP participation? ........... 110
VII. The Growing Number of Adults
Without Health Insurance ..............................................
111
What should be done to improve health care
coverage for adults? ..............................................
112
VIII. Prescription Drug Coverage and the
High Cost of Medication ..............................................
114
What should be done to help people afford
prescription drugs? ..............................................
116
IX. The Social Consequences of Globalization ........................... 117
What should be done to protect workers
and the environment? ..............................................
118
X. Digital Divide ..............................................
120
What should be done to increase access to
computers and the Internet? ..............................................
122
XI. Vulnerabilities ..............................................
123
The Stock Market ..............................................
123
Oil Prices ..............................................
124
Cyclical Factors ..............................................
125
International Economic Environment ................................... 127
The Current Account Deficit .............................................. 128
XII. Conclusion ..............................................
130

Vi

106T'ICONGRESS

2nd Session

S

f

SENATE

REPORT

106-255

THE 2000 JOINT ECONOMIC REPORT

Mr. MACK, from the Joint Economic Committee,
submitted the following

REPORT
together with

MINORITYVIEWS

OVERVIEW OF THE ECONOMY
The United States continues to enjoy the effects of the Great
Expansion, a period of economic growth since December 1982 that has
been interrupted only by a shallow recession from August 1990 to
March 1991. The U.S.. economy has spent less time in recession since
December 1982 than in any comparable period in history. As of March
2000, economic indicators continue to show favorable conditions. Real
(inflation-adjusted) economic growth is approximately 4 percent,
above average for the expansion as a whole; unemployment is around 4
percent, its lowest level since the late 1960s; and inflation remains
subdued, at 2 to 3 percent a year. Healthy economic growth has
contributed to continuing surpluses in the federal budget.
The international economy is improving. Most of our trading
partners have better prospects for growth today than during the period
of currency crises that affected many developing countries from July
1997 to January 1999. This means that demand for U.S. exports should
strengthen. The only cloud in the sky is the big jump in the price of oil,
which threatens to reduce economic growth worldwide. However,
because of changes in the U.S. economy, we are now in a better
position to weather adverse consequences than we were in the 1970s.
The current segment of the Great Expansion, since April 1991,
has lasted so long in part because, unlike in most previous expansions,
growth in productivity has not fallen; rather, it has accelerated in recent
years. This is good news because growth in productivity is vital to
long-term improvement in the standard of living. The enormous
investment that American businesses and workers have made in new

technology, particularly computer technology, is bearing fruit and from
all indications will continue to do so for years to come.
Unlike the expansions of the 1960s and 1970s, the Great
Expansion is not the result of policies aimed at stimulating demand. In
the 1960s and 1970s, policies to stimulate demand often led to
inflation, provoking policy makers to depress demand to bring inflation
back under control. This stop-go strategy was discarded during the
early 1980s. Since then, monetary policy has focused on price stability
and fiscal policy has focused on long-run growth.
Expansions do not die of old age. Sometimes they are ended by
dramatic change beyond the control of policy-makers such as a natural
disaster or financial crisis abroad. In other cases, they end as a result of
domestic policy errors such as a monetary shock. For 20 years, the
Federal Reserve has avoided sudden changes in inflation and has
gradually reduced the rate of inflation to low single digits. The
resulting stability has enabled Americans to plan for the near term and
the long term with confidence that their efforts would not be derailed
by sharp fluctuations in prices and interest rates like those of the 1970s.
Another error is to have tax rates so high that they strongly
discourage productive effort. In the early 1980s the United States
slashed top rates on income taxes and capital gains taxes to spur
economic growth. Since then, tax rates have gradually crept up, though
not to their former levels. By avoiding increases that are too large and
too sudden, the federal government has generated higher tax revenues
without stifling economic growth. Still, the federal government today
takes about as much of the nation's income in taxes as it did during the
height of World War II. It is appropriate to ask what can be done to
reduce the burden of taxes so as to help prolong the current expansion.
The majority report examines the roots of the Great Expansion
and makes suggestions to help it continue. Through its hearings and
staff reports, the Joint Economic Committee addresses important
economic issues facing the United States. Additional information is
available on our Web sites (for the office of the chairman,
<http://wwwjec.senate.gov>; for the office of the vice chairman,
<http://www.house.gov/jec>). We hope this report adds to the public's
understanding of the U.S. economy.
SENATOR CONNIE MACK
Chairman
REPRESENTATIVE JIM SAXTON
Vice Chairman

2

MAJORITY STAFF
REPORT

INTRODUCTION
There are competing visions for the future direction of the U.S.
government. One prominent vision claims we are best served by an
activist government, another that we are best served by controlling and
reducing the size of the federal government.
The activist vision proposes more government involvement for the
problems facing our country. President Clinton's February 2000 State
of the Union message, advocating more than 60 new federal spending
initiatives, is an example of the activist vision. If it is followed,
government spending will soon begin to rise as a share of the economy.
The limited-government vision focuses on controlling and
reducing the size of government by offering people greater choice and
more options for addressing the nation's problems. It stresses that the
keys to economic progress are price stability, secure property rights,
freedom of exchange in international markets, a small federal
government and low taxes.
Which vision we follow will greatly influence how prosperous
America's future will be. As the experience of Europe indicates, slow
growth and stagnating living standards will result if government is too
big. No country has been able to achieve and sustain high rates of
economic growth when government spending has risen to 40 percent or
more of the economy. (In the United States, total spending by all levels
of government in 1999 was 28 percent of GDP, down from the plateau
of 30 to 32 percent that existed for most years from 1975 to 1995.
Total government receipts were 29.9 percent of gross domestic product
[GDP], the highest level ever.')
In contrast, countries following policies consistent with price
stability and free trade while restraining the size of government have
persistently achieved solid growth. This mix of policies has been the
key to the strong economic performance of the United States during the
1980s and 1990s. It has also been the prescription for the economic
success of Ireland, Australia, Hong Kong, Singapore and several other
countries in recent years.

'These and some other statistics in this report reflect the recent revisions to
U.S. national income statistics.
5

1. THE GREAT EXPANSION
In terms of economic performance, government policy, and effect on
the thinking of professional economists, the, 1980s and 1990s form a
continuous era radicallydifferentfrom what preceded it.
Former Federal Reserve governor
Lawrence B. Lindsey
I. The-Great Change in Policy, 1979-81
During the 1970s, the U.S. economy was plagued with inflation
and economic instability. It performed poorly mainly because policy
makers, influenced by incorrect economic theories, sought to achieve
goals beyond their means. At the time, many economists and policy
makers believed government could smooth business cycles by "finetuning" fiscal and monetary policy. The result was ill-conceived
policies that caused stop-go cycles of economic growth. Many
economists and policy makers also believed government could
stimulate economic demand to reduce unemployment. The result was
double-digit inflation.
Chastened by the combination of high unemployment and doubledigit inflation that conventional economic models claimed should not
occur, policy makers began to change their goals. In October 1979,
President Jimmy Carter appointed Paul Volcker chairman of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The emphasis of
monetary policy shifted toward constraining inflation and achieving
price stability. In 1981, newly elected President Ronald Reagan
refocused fiscal policy on the long run. He proposed, and Congress
passed, sharp cuts in marginal tax rates. The cuts increased incentives
to work and stimulated growth. These were fundamental policy
changes that provided the foundation for the Great Expansion that
began in December 1982.
As Exhibit I shows, the economic record of the last 17 years is
remarkable, particularly when viewed against the backdrop of the
1970s. The United States has experienced two of the longest and
strongest expansions in our history back-to-back. They have been
interrupted only by a shallow eight-month downturn in 1990-91. The
years from 1983 are best viewed as a single expansion, with its roots in
the policy changes of the late 1970s and early 1980s. There has never

6

Exhibit 1: The Great Expansion, 1983-Present
Both segments of the Great Expansion have delivered growth
in consumption, production, jobs, and stock market valuation.
1983-90*
expansion

expansion

Entire
period

35.7%
4.1%

33.0%
3.3%

80.9%
3.6%

26.7%
3.2%

22.4%
2.3%

54.2%
2.6%

26.8%
3.2%

24.1%
2.5%

56.9%
2.7%

Total growth

28.9%

38.7%

78.9%

Total growth

19.9 mil.

16.4 mil.

35.0 mil.

14.5%

16.1%

15.0%

1991-99*

-

Real GDP
Total growth
Average annual growth

Real GDPperperson
Total growth
Average annual growth

Real consumption
perperson
Total growth
Average annual growth

Industrialproduction

Employment

Dow Jones
IndustrialAverage
Average annual growth

Sources: Industrial production data are annual figures from Economic Report of the
President. 2000. DJIA data are quarterly averages from Economagic.com.
Changes in real GDP and consumption are based on figures for 4-quarter
moving averages, derived from data extracted from Haver Analytics.
Note: *The 1983-90 expansion is measured from 1983:qI - 1990:q2. The 1991-99
expansion is measured from 1991:q2 - 1999:q4.

7

been a period of comparable length with so much growth and so little
contraction in the history of the United States. 2
During the last 17 years:
*
*
*
*
*

Real GDP expanded 81 percent (3.6 percent a year).
Real GDP per person rose 54.2 percent; real consumption per
person rose 56.9 percent.
Employers created more than 35 million new jobs.
Industrial production jumped 78.9 percent.
The Dow Jones Industrial Average ballooned 11-fold (15 percent a
year).

II. Factors Underlying the Great Expansion
Economic growth is no accident: it is influenced by the policies
and organization of an economy. Countries must establish an
appropriate economic environment if they want to achieve and sustain
rapid growth. 3 The key elements of this environment are monetary
stability, secure property rights, a legal structure that enforces
contracts, free trade, limited government, and low taxes. The Great
Expansion has occurred within this framework.
Price stability. Price stability enhances the efficiency of an
economy. Low and steady rates of inflation reduce uncertainty in
making long-term decisions, such as buying a house or business
machinery. When inflation is low, people can spend more time
producing and less time trying to protect themselves from inflation. In
addition, low inflation avoids imposing the extra tax that in effect falls
on earnings if taxes are not indexed for inflation.
Under the chairmanships of Paul Volcker and Alan Greenspan,
the Federal Reserve has successfully focused on price stability. As
Exhibit 2 shows, the year-to-year change in the rate of inflation has
never exceeded 1.2 percentage points since 1983. Low inflation during
the 1980s contributed to the strength of that decade's expansion. With
the passage of time, confidence increased that the Federal Reserve

2To

put the period in perspective, consider that the U.S. economy was in
recession approximately 33 percent of the time from 1910 to 1959 and 23
percent of the time from 1960 to 1982, but only 4 percent of the time since
1982. This is by far the lowest percentage of any comparable period in
American history.
3See Joint Economic Committee, Office of the Chairman,
"Economic Growth
and the Future Prospects of the U.S. Economy," October 1999, available
online at <http://www.senate.gov/-jec/gp 1.htm>.
8

Exhibit 2: Inflation Volatility
Inflation has been far less variable during the Great
Expansion than it was in the 1970s.
Year-to-year
change
(percentage points)

32-

\4 Aj
10
-1°

-

I

-2.

-3

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Source: Economic Report of the President,2000, table B-3.
Note: Based on implicit GDP price deflator.

would continue striving for price stability, contributing substantially to
the growth of the economy during the 1990s.
When the monetary authorities achieve price stability, they have
done their part to enhance growth and prosperity. In this regard, the
performance of the Federal Reserve during the last two decades has
been outstanding.
Increases in the size of the trade sector. Both parties in a trade
gain. Buyers, whether consumers or businesses, gain because trade
enables them to buy things more cheaply. Sellers gain because trade
enables them to sell more goods at better prices. Each party to a trade
can focus more on producing those things it does most efficiently.
Together, trading partners produce more and achieve higher standards
of living than they could do separately. Trade also increases the
competitiveness of markets and generates additional gains from
economies of scale, the introduction of new products, innovative

9

Exhibit 3: Growth of Trade
Duringthe GreatExpansion, internationaltrade has grown
faster than GDP, helping to propel economic growth.
Average
annual
growth

9.2%
9.2%

8.4%

7.7%
7.0%

4.3%
3.0%

1990-99

1983-89
*

Real GDP

Real exports

* Real imports

Source: Economic Report of the President,2000, table B-2.

methods of production, and the spread of technology. All this enhances
efficiency and promotes growth.4
Trade liberalization and reductions in the cost of transportation
and communications have helped boost U.S. and international trade
during the last 15 years. Some countries have reduced their trade
barriers unilaterally, while others have done so as an outgrowth of the
"Uruguay round" negotiated by the United States and other members
of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). The United
States has particularly reduced trade barriers with Canada and Mexico,
concluding the U.S.-Canadian Free Trade Agreement in 1988 and the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994.
During the Great Expansion, the size of the U.S. trade sector has
increased dramatically. Adjusted for inflation, exports more than
4 For

more on the impact of trade on the economy, see Joint Economic
Committee, Office of the Chairman, "12 Myths of International Trade," July
1999, available online at <http:/Hwww.senate.gov/-jec/tradel.html>.
10

Exhibit 4: U.S. Trade with Canada, Mexico,
and the Rest of the World

U.S. trade with Canadaand Mexico has grown rapidly
under NAFTA. So has trade with the rest of the world.
Trade as
a Share
of GDP

92/IQ1

15.9%

n7
I

20/.

7 In0/,

1.1%
1991
1998
Canada

_

1991
1998
Mexico

1991 1998
Rest of world

-I

Sources: Economic Report of the President, 2000, table B-I; Department of
Commerce, International Trade Administration Web site,
http.//www.ita.doc.gov.
Note: Trade share represents (imports + exports) / GDP.

tripled from 1983 to 1999; imports expanded even more rapidly. As
Exhibit 3 shows, imports and exports alike rose roughly twice as fast as
GDP in the 1980s and the 1990s. Exhibit 4 illustrates the growth of
U.S. trade in goods and services with Canada, Mexico, and other
countries. From 1991 to 1998, trade with Canada rose from 2.9 percent
to 3.8 percent of U.S. GDP, while trade with Mexico jumped from 1.1
percent to 2.0 percent. U.S. trade with other countries also expanded,
indicating that NAFTA not only expanded U.S. trade with Canada and
Mexico, but contributed to an expansion in the overall size of the trade
sector.
11

Economists of almost all persuasions accept that economies open
produce more value from their resources and achieve higher
trade
to
levels of income than closed economies. 5 In contrast, protectionists
argue that increased openness and expansion in trade creates
unemployment, capital flight to low-wage economies, and economic
stagnation. The facts support the free trade position. As the U.S.
economy has become more open, employment has increased by 35
million and the rate of unemployment has fallen to its lowest level in
30 years. From 1983 to 1998, foreigners invested $1.5 trillion more in
the United States than Americans invested abroad. From 1983 to 1999,
real GDP per person in the United States rose from $21,102 to
$32,439, an increase of 54 percent. Both Congress and the Clinton
Administration have generally supported open markets and rejected
protectionist calls for trade restraints. Their actions have contributed to
the growth and strength of the U.S. economy.
Lower marginal tax rates. When Ronald Reagan became
president in 1981, the top marginal rate on federal income taxes stood
at 70 percent. At Reagan's urging, Congress cut rates across the board
by about 30 percent and indexed taxes for inflation. In 1986, it cut
marginal tax rates again and the top rate fell to 28 percent. In just a few
years, after-tax returns for the top earners jumped from 30 cents to 72
cents per dollar of additional earnings, a 140 percent increase in the
incentive to earn. The effects of lower tax rates were smaller but still
substantial in other brackets. Although Congress raised marginal rates
in the early 1990s, marginal rates in almost all tax brackets are still
well below the levels of the 1970S.6 These lower rates continue to
enhance the growth of the U.S. economy.
5 The

positive impact of trade on growth is also stressed by the Economic

Report of the President 2000, which states:

The freedom of firms to choose from a wider range of inputs, and of
consumers to choose from a wider range of products, improves
efficiency, promotes innovation in technology and management,
encourages the transfer of technology, and otherwise enhances
productivity growth. These benefits in turn lead to higher real
incomes and wages. (Economic Report of the President Transmitted
to the Congress February 2000, Washington: Government Printing
Office, 2000, p. 282).
6For a detailed analysis of how reductions in marginal tax rates during the
1980s helped strengthen the U.S. economy, see Joint Economic Committee,
Office of the Chairman, "The Supply-Side Revolution: 20 Years Later,"
March 2000, available online at <http://www.senate.gov/bjec/ssreportl.htrn>.
Some claim the Reagan tax cuts were a mistake. But to return to the steeply
progressive rate structure that Reagan inherited, with a confiscatory top rate of
70 percent and no adjustments for inflation, would be a severe blow to the
American economy. According to estimates by the Joint Committee on
12

Reductions in the size of government. Governments contribute
to economic growth when they provide an environment conducive to
peaceful interaction among citizens and the smooth operation of
markets. As we discussed in a prior report,7 the following factors are
particularly important:
*
*
*
*

National defense and police services that protect people and
property from aggression.
Monetary arrangements that provide citizens with access to sound
money.
A legal system that enforces contracts and provides a forum for
settling disputes.
Provision of a limited set of goods that are difficult to provide
through markets.

When governments handle these core activities well, they enhance
economic growth. However, if they move beyond these functions and
become producers of goods and redistributors of income, they
generally do more harm than good. Economies with high government
spending usually have sluggish economic growth. For example, in the
last four decades, among countries that belong to the Organisation for
Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), a 10 percentage
point increase in government spending has been associated with a 1
percent reduction in the long-term rate of annual economic growth. 8
Federal government spending in the United States persistently
rose as a share of GDP between the mid-1960s and the early 1980s.
After leveling off during the 1980s, the relative size of government
declined during the 1990s. Federal spending has fallen approximately 4
percentage points as a share of GDP in the last seven years. The
relationship mentioned in the previous paragraph suggests that the
shrinkage of government during the 1990s enhanced growth by

Taxation of the U.S. Congress, under static analysis this would increase the
tax burden by $871 billion in 2000 alone, nearly doubling individual income
taxes and raising overall taxes 54.7 percent. A middle-class family earning
$30,000 would see its taxes increase 45 percent. Because of the economic
distortions resulting from such an increase, actual revenue collected would be
less than this amount, perhaps even less than under current law.
7Joint Economic Committee, "Economic Growth and the Future Prospects of
the U.S. Economy," pp. 22-7.
8
James Gwartney, Robert Lawson, and Randall Holcombe, "The Size and
Functions of Government and Economic Growth," Joint Economic
Committee, April 1998; the full text is available online at
<http://www.house.gov/jec/growth/function/function.htm>.
13

Exhibit 5: Government Spending
as a Share of GDP
Measuredas a share of GDP, government spending rose
during the 1960s and 1970s, leveled off during the 1980s,
andfell during the 1990s.
Percent
of GDP

28.3%

Total*

3025-

22.7% "

2019%

15-

16.3%
10

1960

-

1970

1980

I

-

1990

I

2000

Source: Economic Report of the President, 2000, table B-80.
Note: * Total government spending includes federal, state, and local.

approximately one-tenth this amount, or 0.4 percent a year. The decline
in government spending as a share of GDP is shown in Exhibit 5.
Exhibit 6 presents data on real federal spending per person,
measured in 1999 dollars. This figure rose from $2,379 in 1960 to
$6,169 in 1992. Real spending per person on programs other than
defense more than quadrupled, from $1,137 in 1960 to $4,837 in 1992.
During the 1990s, the growth of real federal spending per person
slowed substantially, mainly as a result of lower defense spending.
From 1992 to 1999, total real federal spending per person was nearly
unchanged, rising from $6,169 to $6,236, an increase of $67. During
the same period, defense spending fell $326 per person. Both changes
reflect the priorities of the Clinton Administration, which has been
keener to cut defense spending and less interested in restraining nondefense spending than the Republican Congress.
Demographics. The changing demographics of the workforce has
been an overlooked factor facilitating faster economic growth in the
Great Expansion. Most people spend their twenties and early
14

Exhibit 6: Real Federal Spending per Person
Non-defense spending has driven the growth of thefederal
government. Defense reductions after the Cold War victory
have slowed realfederalspendingperperson in the 1990s.
Federal spending
per person
(1999 $)
6000-

$6236
Total
federal

4000

~~~ N~~~on-defense

2000-

$1570

Defense
1960

1970

1980

$1006/
1990

2000

Sources: Economic Report of the President, 2000, tables B- I, B-3, B-82;
population data from Haver Analytics.
Note: Federal spending data are for fiscal years. For underlying data, see
Appendix, table 1.

thirties developing skills through higher education, training, and job
experience. During these years, their productivity and earnings are
below average. At the other end of their careers, as they approach
retirement their productivity often declines because their health
declines and because their job skills may not be as up-to-date as before.
Thus, the productivity and earnings of people in their late fifties and
over are also below average. People 35 to 54 generally have the
combination of education, experience, and health that results in the
highest levels of productivity. Therefore, an increase in the share of the
population 35 to 54 years old tends to push average productivity and
earnings upward.

15

Exhibit 7: Prime-Age Earners as a
Share of the Labor Force
Prime-age earners(35-54) fell as a share of the laborforce
during the 1960s and 1970s but rose during the 1980s and
1990s, enhancinggrowth during the Great Expansion.
Share of
labor force
48.3%

44.7%
41.6%

I
1960

1970

1980

1990

1999

Source: Haver Analytics.
Note: For underlying data, see Appendix, table 2.

In the 1980s, the "baby boom" generation began moving into their
prime earning years. The share of the labor force in the prime years
rose sharply during the 1990s. We estimate that the expansion in
prime-age workers increased the total productivity of the labor force by
about 0.5 percent a year from 1991 to 1998. Since World War II, labor
productivity has grown an average of about 2 percent a year, so an
increase of 0.5 percent is substantial. The changing share of the labor
force made up by prime-age workers is shown in Exhibit 7.
High technology. The high-technology sector has played a
starring role in the dynamic economic climate of the 1980s and 1990s.
High-tech industries now account for over 8 percent of U.S. GDP, up
from 4.5 percent in 1980. U.S. software, semiconductor,
16

biotechnology, pharmaceutical, and Internet-related companies
dominate world markets.
Coincident with the rapid growth in high-tech industries has been
an explosion of entrepreneurship. Entrepreneurs have created
thousands of fast-growing technology firms such as America Online,
Cisco Systems, Compaq Computer, Dell Computer, and Microsoft,
which were nonexistent two decades ago. While many pundits believed
that "strategic" federal action was needed to shore up America's hightech sector a decade ago, it is now clear that it was the energetic and
forward-looking actions of many individual entrepreneurs that put the
U.S. economy back on top.
Technology has given new entrepreneurial businesses the tools
needed to compete against the largest corporations. The growth in
personal computers, sophisticated software applications, and the
Internet has allowed new businesses to shake up many formerly stable
industries. To respond to the new competitive realities, big businesses
have invested billions in information technology equipment. Real
business equipment and software investment have grown over 11
percent a year since 1991.
At the same time, revolutions in the nation's capital markets,
spurred by financial deregulation and technology, have channeled huge
investment flows to new, entrepreneurial businesses. High-yield debt
securities provided needed capital to fast-growing businesses and
helped fund the corporate restructuring boom during the past two
decades. Big corporations were forced to become more entrepreneurial
to respond to intensified competition at home and in foreign markets.
Deregulation and capital gains tax cuts helped the venture capital
market take off in the early 1980s. Venture capital investment in fastgrowing companies in Silicon Valley and other hot spots has exploded
from $3 billion in 1990 to $48 billion in 1999. Venture capital is
flowing into new companies in fast-growing industries such as
computers, telecommunications, and biotechnology. Complementing
the growth in venture capital is the great success of the NASDAQ
stock market, which has allowed thousands of young technology
companies access to the funds they need to grow and compete. The
NASDAQ now hosts hundreds of initial public offerings each year.
The value of initial public offerings rose from $2 billion in 1990 to $50
billion in 1999.
The success of the U.S. high-tech sector illustrates the mutually
reinforcing strengths of entrepreneurship and dynamic capital markets.
Entrepreneurs have flooded into competitive high-tech industries
because of the huge opportunities and rewards available to successful
innovators. America's diverse sources of financial and human capital
17

have ensured that good ideas are not overlooked, and that many paths
to innovation and economic growth are pursued.
Welfare reform. The federal government enacted sweeping
welfare reforms in 1996. It ended the "entitlement" status of welfare,
whereby anyone with children who had a sufficiently low income
automatically qualified for federal benefits. States were -given much
greater latitude in setting eligibility requirements and time limits for
those receiving benefits. Since then, the share of the U.S. population on
welfare has fallen dramatically--substantially more than can be
attributed to the general strength of the economy.
Before welfare reform, the unemployment rate had been hovering
around 5.5 percent for about 18 months. This was a higher rate than
near the end of the 1983-90 expansion. Not until welfare reform was
enacted did the unemployment rate drop below the low of the previous
expansion toward the 30-year low we enjoy today.
For the economy as a whole, the cost of hiring workers includes
not only compensation directly paid to workers and the taxes on their
earnings, but transfer payments to potential workers who are not
working. By making work less attractive for those entering the labor
force in low-paying jobs, transfer payments to the able-bodied
unemployed tend to increase the unemployment rate. By reducing
transfer payments to the able-bodied unemployed, welfare reform
reduces the cost of hiring, thereby increasing employment in the
private sector and stimulating economic growth. Once in the labor
force, workers in low-paying jobs acquire skills that help them stay
employed and move into higher-paying jobs, whereas if they had
remained unemployed they never would have acquired the skills.
III. Why Has the Budget Shifted from Deficit to Surplus?
From 1987-89, the federal budget deficit was approximately $150
billion each fiscal year. The deficit rose during the contraction of 199091 and fell as the economy began to recover. The Clinton
Administration claims that its 1993 tax increase reduced the budget
deficit and led to lower interest rates that propelled the expansion of
the 1990s. 9 The facts are inconsistent with this view. Interest rates,
which had fallen steadily throughout 1992 and the first half of 1993,
began rising almost immediately following the Clinton tax increase and
passage of the 1993 budget. By July of 1994, the interest rate on 309In

1999, for example, President Clinton stated, "Our new economic strategy
was rooted first and foremost in fiscal discipline... .The market responded by
lowering long-term interest rates." Economic Report of the President
Transmitted to the Congress February 1999 (Washington: Government
Printing Office, 1999), p. 3.
18

year Treasury bonds had risen to 7.6 percent, up from 5.9 percent in
October of 1993. Other rates followed a similar path. President
Clinton's scenario that his 1993 tax and budgetary policies lowered
interest rates and unleashed the current expansion is simply
mythology.' 0
If the Clinton tax and budgetary policy had little to do with the
transformation of the federal budget, what accounts for the turn
around? Aside from the cyclical effects of the expansion, a variety of
other factors caused the federal budget to turn from deficits to
projections of large and growing surpluses.
Higher defense spending in the 1980s enabled spending to be
lower in the 1990s. Higher real defense spending in the 1980s proved
to be an excellent investment. It led to victory in the Cold War.
Following the collapse of the Soviet Union, however, real defense
spending declined as the American people asked for a "peace
dividend." As the Clinton Administration often highlights, the
unemployment rate remained high in 1991 and 1992, the last years of
President George Bush's administration, even though the economy was
expanding. The transitional movement of resources out of defense and
into non-defense industries was a major factor underlying the
unusually high unemployment of the period. The United States was
able to shift more than 2 million jobs out of defense-related industries
between 1989 and 1993. In the short run, this was a major contraction
of an important sector, resulting in sluggish growth and upward
pressure on the unemployment rate. However, our free market
economy created new jobs to use the talents of the displaced defense
workers. This exerted a positive impact on the long-run health of the
economy.
Favorable demographics. During the 1990s, prime-age workers
grew rapidly as a share of the work force, while the elderly population
grew much more slowly. The rapid growth of the prime-age workers
propelled federal revenues, while the slow growth of the elderly
population restrained spending.
Flow of funds into and out of tax-favored savings accounts.
Tax legislation during the 1980s encouraged individuals and families
to channel funds into tax-free Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs)
and 401(k) accounts. As funds flowed into these accounts in the 1980s,
federal revenues were reduced. Funds began to flow out of these
accounts in the late 1990s because federal law requires people to start
withdrawing from them by age 70-1/2 or face penalties. The
'0For additional details on this topic, see Joint Economic Committee, Office of
the Vice Chairman, "Assessing the Current Expansion," January 2000,
available online at <http://www.house.gov/jec/growth/assess/assess.pdfs.
19

withdrawals are taxable. In early 1999, the Congressional Budget
Office estimated that withdrawals from taxable IRAs would rise from
$93 billion in 1999 to $195 billion by 2008. Currently, 401(k) assets
are about 60 percent as large as IRA assets, indicating that withdrawals
from them will also generate significant tax revenue in the coming
years.
IV. Can the Great Expansion Continue?
When analyzing the factors underlying the Great Expansion, one
thing is clear: a major paradigm shift occurred between the 1970s and
1980s. In the 1970s, economists and policy makers alike believed that
inflationary policies would reduce unemployment. The policy makers
of the 1980s rejected this view and redirected economic policy toward
price stability and long-term goals regarding taxation and spending. In
the 1970s, it was widely believed that stop-go monetary and fiscal
policy could smooth the ups and downs of the business cycle. Only the
demand-side effects of fiscal policy were recognized; the supply-side
incentive effects were ignored until the 1980s. These were fundamental
changes in economic thought that shifted economic policy toward an
environment more conducive to economic growth.
Can the Great Expansion continue? It is unlikely that the business
cycle has been repealed. Surprise shocks will no doubt occur in the
future and they will exert a destabilizing influence on the economy. In
this regard, the recent dramatic rise in the price of crude oil is a source
of concern. When oil prices rise, oil importing nations like the U.S.
have to give up more of other things for each barrel of oil imported.
This adversely affects their potential output and short-term growth.
Energy consumption, however, is now a smaller portion of the U.S.
economy than was true two decades ago. In 1981, energy expenditures
comprised 14 percent of GDP; today the comparable figure is 7
percent. Petroleum expenditures were over 8 percent of GDP in 1980;
today they are just 3 percent. Sustained high oil prices may cause the
U.S. economy to slow, but given its current strength, they are unlikely
to throw it into a recession.
The most important lesson of the Great Expansion is a positive
one: monetary and price stability, free trade, small government, and
low taxes provide the prescription for stability and prosperity. The
Federal Reserve has kept its focus on achieving price stability during
the Great Expansion. This should continue to be its focus in the future.
Lower trade barriers will enhance the growth of an economy for years
to come. The U.S. economy can expect to reap gains from NAFTA for
at least another decade, and additional gains can be achieved from
further reducing trade barriers. Favorable demographics--the large
20

share of the work force in the prime-age category--will continue for
another decade. However, around 2010 the demographic trend will
become less favorable. This will not only slow growth; it will also tend
to expand the size of government unless Social Security and Medicare
are reformed.
The lesson of the last two decades is clear: a continuation of the
strong and steady growth experienced during the last 18 years is
achievable if we follow sound policies. Now we turn to the steps that
need to be taken to provide prosperity for the next generation of
Americans.

21

2. IMPROVING SOCIAL SECURITY,
AND EDUCATION

HEALTH CARE,

Social Security, health care, and education now account for more
than half of combined federal, state, and local government spending.
As Exhibit 8 shows, spending in these three areas rose from 10.8
percent of GDP in 1970 to 15.5 percent in 1996. Despite the increase in
spending, all three areas continue to suffer from poor performance. In
each case, the problem is the same: too much uniformity and too little
personal choice. Central planning and regulation have replaced
personal choice and market competition. As the experience of centrally
planned economies illustrates, a "one size fits all" approach is
ultimately a recipe for disaster. Good intentions are no substitute for
sound policies. The problems of Social Security, health care, and
education are structural, and will not be solved by spending more
money in the same old way.
I. Social Security
The pay-as-you-go Social Security system was initiated in 1935 in
favorable demographic circumstances. The population was growing
rapidly, life expectancy past the retirement age of 65 was low, and the
number of workers per retiree was consequently high in the system's
early years (16 workers per retiree in 1950). The system was designed
for this environment and for many years it was adequate. Today the
world is vastly different. The population is growing more slowly,
people live longer, and there are only 3.4 workers per retiree. By 2034,
the aging of the baby boom generation will reduce the ratio to two
workers per retiree.
The retirement of the baby boom generation will make the Social
Security system unsustainable in its present form. According to
projections by the system's trustees, by 2037 the trust fund will be
exhausted and the current payroll tax rate will be unable to fund
promised retirement benefits. Under reasonable population projections,
promised benefits will exceed projected revenues by $5 trillion to $11
trillion. The retirement payroll tax already absorbs 10.4 percent of the
take-home pay of each worker. Without reform, an even higher rate
will be required to keep Social Security solvent.
Life expectancy is difficult to predict. During the last century, the
life expectancy of Americans has increased from 47 to 77 years, or
approximately 65 percent. As we move into the 21 st century,
developments in drugs and biogenetics may greatly increase the
number of Americans over age 70 and substantially improve their
22

Exhibit 8: Spending on Major Domestic
Programs as a Share of GDP
Federal, state, and local spending on education, Social
Security, and health care is now 15.5% of GDP -- more
than halfof all government spending. Since 1970, spending
on Social Security and health care has risen sharply.
Share
of GDP
15.5%
14.0%
12.7%
10.8%

*

62

3.0%

4.3

4.4%

4.5%

1970

1980

1990

1996

Education

i Social

Security

Health care

Sources: Digest of Education Statistics, various issues; Budget of the United States
Government, FY2001, Historical Tables; Health Care Financing
Administration Web site, http://www.hcfa.gov.
Note: Due to rounding, column totals may not equal the sum of their represented parts.

health. Like the retirement of the baby boomers, this will erode the
solvency of the current Social Security system.
Under the current system, the link between taxes paid and benefits
received is weak. This undermines the property rights of workers to
their earnings and reduces their incentive to earn. It also results in
complex redistributive effects, many of which are unintended.

The Lottery-Like Nature of the System
Social Security has become a complex redistribution program that
treats several groups unfairly. Reflecting the labor force participation at
the time the program was initiated, individuals can draw benefits based
23

on their own earnings or 50 percent of their spouse's earnings,
whichever is greater. For many women, benefits based on their
husband's earnings exceed benefits based on their own earnings, so
many working women derive little or no additional benefits from the
Social Security taxes they pay.
Although the system is financed with a flat tax, benefits are highly
skewed toward those with lower incomes. Retirement benefits are set
at 90 percent of the first $6,372 per year of base earnings, but
additional benefits fall to only 32 percent of earnings between $6,372
and $38,424 and just 15 percent of earnings above $38,424. Thus,
those with earnings above $38,424 a year gain very little from the
additional taxes they pay into the system. On its face, this appears to
favor the poor. Before jumping to this conclusion, however, it is
important to consider that people who earn more generally live longer.
High-income beneficiaries generally draw benefits longer than lowincome beneficiaries. People with low incomes are more likely to pay
taxes for years and then die before collecting a penny in benefits. They
may pay tens of thousands of dollars to Social Security that benefit
neither themselves nor their heirs. Taking this into consideration,
Social Security may actually increase economic inequality.
Differences in life expectancy also redistribute income across
ethnic groups. For example, the life expectancy of blacks is lower than
that of whites, so blacks are more likely to pay Social Security taxes
for years and draw few or no retirement benefits. As a result, the Social
Security system tends to redistribute income from blacks to whites.
This is not the intent of the system, but it is a consequence of its
current structure."
The current system is highly unfair to those with diabetes, heart
disease, AIDS, and other life-shortening diseases. On top of the burden
imposed by their health condition, Social Security forces them to hand
over approximately 10 percent of their earnings even though they have
little or no hope of ever deriving retirement benefits.
The design of the system is also biased against families with
children. Consider two families with the same income, one with four
children and the other with none. Both families will one day depend on
the children to generate Social Security taxes to pay for their retirement
benefits. Viewed across generations, Social Security transfers income
from those with children to those without. Again, this is not necessarily
the intent of the system, but it is a consequence of its current structure.
"See Gareth Davis, "Ethnic and Racial Differentials in the Return from Social
Security Old Age and Survivors' Insurance," unpublished paper, Heritage
Foundation Center for Data Analysis and George Mason University, presented
at Westem Economic Association meetings, San Diego, July 8, 1999.
24

The bottom line is this: the current Social Security system
redistributes income in complex, opaque ways. Much of the
redistribution is unintended and would be considered perverse if more
people were aware of it. The complexity of the system makes it
difficult for policy makers and citizens to figure out what is going on.
Furthermore, the lottery-like nature of the program weakens the
property rights of workers over their own earnings and thereby reduces
their incentive to earn.
The Savings-Investment Approach to Retirement
Given the nature of the Social Security system and the difficulties
that are sure to arise with the retirement of the baby boomers, this is an
excellent time to consider modifications appropriate for the
environment of the 21st century. Meaningful reform of the system
involves shifting from a pay-as-you-go arrangement to a savingsinvestment approach. Under a savings-investment approach, each
generation of retirees would fund its own retirement benefits through
savings during its working years.
There are several advantages of a retirement system financed by
personal savings rather than taxes. First, a savings-investment system
will lead to higher capital formation. Under a savings-investment
system, current savings finance real assets that will generate income in
the future for retirement benefits. In contrast, there is no additional
capital formation under a pay-as-you-go system. Only the promise to
levy the required future taxes underlies the benefits promised to
workers. Because of the additional capital formation accompanying a
savings-investment system, the productivity of workers will grow
faster, producing higher economic growth than would occur with a
pay-as-you-go system.
Second, the incentive effects of a retirement system financed by
personal savings accounts (PSAs) differ sharply from those of a taxfinanced system. Taxes reduce the take-home pay of workers and
reduce their incentive to earn. In contrast, PSAs provide workers with
property rights to the funds paid into their accounts. Additional
payments into PSAs result in higher retirement benefits or, in the case
of death before retirement, larger bequests to heirs. There is a direct
link between payment into the system and the benefits derived from it.
The disincentive effects of the current system would be removed.
Third, PSAs would give retirees more independence by giving
them clearly defined rights to the assets producing their income.
Payments by Social Security are not a right; they can be reduced from
their promised levels, and there is a strong possibility they will be in
future decades, when according to projections the Social Security
system will run large deficits.
25

A wide range of proposals for PSAs has been introduced in
Congress, by Democrats and Republicans alike. Generally, these plans
would allow individuals to channel a portion of their payroll taxes into
PSAs in exchange for accepting lower Social Security retirement
benefits. The PSA funds would be invested and eventually used to
provide annuities during retirement. Most proposed PSA plans would
be voluntary, but some would be mandatory for young workers or
those initially entering the work force. In some cases, the PSA funds
would be administered centrally, as in the Thrift Savings Plan to which
federal employees belong. In other cases, the proposals would contract
out the management of funds to private investment firms. Most
proposals would provide individuals with some choice over allocating
funds between stocks and bonds.' 2
The Transitionto PersonalSavings Accounts
Moving to a system based on PSAs would solve the primary
problems of the current system. However, many people are worried
about the transition from a pay-as-you-go system to a savingsinvestment system. Some argue that the current generation of workers
would pay twice: once for the benefits of current retirees and again for
their own retirement benefits.
If action is taken quickly, this potential problem can be overcome.
During the next decade, the Social Security system will need only
about 80 percent of its projected revenues to fund the benefits of
current retirees. The remaining 20 percent will be available to fund
PSAs without having to raise the payroll tax. Moreover, the average
real rate of return on private investment has been substantially greater
than the 2 percent that future retirees can expect from Social Security.
For example, the U.S. stock market has yielded an average long-run
real return of 7 percent, and the long-run real return of a portfolio
comprised 60 percent of bonds and 40 percent of stocks has averaged
approximately 5.5 percent a year. Because of the substantially higher
real return that can be expected from private investment compared to
Social Security, only a portion of the current retirement payroll tax will
be required to fund retirement benefits equal to those of Social
Security.
* Benefits promised under the current system can be maintained
while still allowing current workers the option to channel 60 or 70
'2For a summary of current reform proposals that would establish personal
savings accounts, see "Personal Account Options for Social Security Reform:
A Side-by-Side Comparison," Joint Economic Committee, Office of the
Chairman, January 2000; the full text is available online at
<http://www.senate.gov/-jec/ss22000.htm>. The Joint Economic Committee
will publish a further report on reforming Social Security later this year.
26

percent of their payroll tax into PSAs. In turn, contributions of 6 or 7
percentage points of earnings to PSAs can be expected to produce
retirement benefits higher than those of Social Security. In contrast, if
the current system is not reformed, the retirement payroll tax will have
to increase from the current 10.4 percent to approximately 15 percent
to fund promised benefits to the baby boom and subsequent
generations.
Compared to the current pay-as-you-go system, the savingsinvestment approach will increase the rate of capital formation and
largely eliminate the disincentive effects of the payroll tax. It will place
the United States at a competitive advantage in international markets.
All of these factors will enhance economic growth and the future
prosperity of Americans.
II. Health Care
The Rising Cost of Health Care
There is considerable dissatisfaction with the cost of health care
in the United States. Total spending on health care rose from 5.7
percent of GDP in 1966 to 13.3 percent in 1998. Government spending
on health care soared from 1.7 percent of GDP in 1966 to 6.2 percent
in 1998. The worst is yet to come: there will be a huge increase in the
cost of Medicare, the largest government health care program, when
the baby boomers retire. Like Social Security, Medicare transfers
wealth from workers to retirees. The funds derived from the 2.9
percent payroll tax for Medicare are immediately paid out to current
beneficiaries. Presently, Medicare spending accounts for 2.6 percent of
GDP and 13 percent of the federal budget. Under current law, these
figures are projected to double by 2045.
The rapid growth of health care spending to a large extent reflects
the nature of the government's involvement. Since 1965, Medicare and
Medicaid have subsidized health care for the elderly and the poor. One
reason these programs have pushed up prices and spending on health
care is that they have increased demand for medical care. The supply
of key health care services is highly inelastic, that is, higher prices do
not lead to much increase in output. This is perhaps most evident in the
case of the services of doctors. Training for doctors is long and
rigorous, so an increase in doctors' fees will not quickly increase the
number of practicing doctors. Rather, fees will tend to stay high for
quite a while.

63-597 00 - 2

Exhibit 9: Third-Party Payments and
Health Care Inflation
Since 1960, third-partypayments for health care have
soared while out-of-pocket spending hasfallen. The cost of
medical services has increasedfasterthan prices in general.
Shar,e
(%)
80
Out-ofpocket
60

Cumulative
third-party*
78.9% -,k
Private insurance

I _._. . . .

'__financed

40
20 J

|Govern ment |00
fianced

U

i gi}0

S

A:-:- I..:it. .:

-: :-.... :-C

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995
Health care
prices relative
to CPI
(CPI = 100)

175
160
145
130 115
100
85
70

55
1966

............................

1
1971

1 7
1976

1
1981

1986

1991

1996

Source: Health Care Financing Administration Web site, http://www.hcfa.gov.
Note: *There remains a small portion of third-party financing (not included
above) composed principally of charitable contributions. For underlying data, see Appendix, tables 3 and 4.

28

An even more important reason why government health care
programs drive prices upward is they virtually eliminate incentives for
consumers and suppliers to economize. In a normal market, consumers
have a strong incentive to shop around in search of value for money.
Because consumers bear the cost of unwise purchases, they seek to
avoid high-cost, inefficient suppliers. At the same time, suppliers have
a strong incentive to produce efficiently and provide goods at
economical prices. Failure to do so will lead to the loss of customers to
rivals. Third-party payment of medical bills--the dominant practice in
the United States--erodes incentives to keep costs low. When someone
else is paying the bill, consumers have little incentive to economize or
seek out low-cost suppliers. That reduces incentives for suppliers to
produce economically and keep costs low.
As the top panel of Exhibit 9 shows, in 1960 consumers paid
directly for about half of all health care spending, while insurance
companies and government financed less than a quarter each. The
shares changed rapidly after the Medicare and Medicaid programs
were established. By the late 1970s, government financed more than 40
percent of all health care spending, and today it finances almost half.
Private insurance covers another 31.9 percent, and consumers pay only
17.2 percent directly.
As government subsidies have expanded and direct spending by
consumers has fallen, health care prices have risen sharply. The bottom
panel of Exhibit 9 details how much faster the prices of medical
services have grown than the general level of prices during the last four
decades. There is no evidence that the trend is about to subside.
The Future of Health Care
Public policy is the main culprit behind rapidly rising medical
costs. Neither suppliers nor consumers have much incentive to
economize. The incentive to patronize low-cost, low-price suppliers is
weak. Because lower prices will not attract many additional
consumers, health-care suppliers have little incentive to keep prices
low. As the price of health care continues to rise rapidly, policy makers
impose additional mandates and regulations; some even want price
controls. The experience of other countries indicates where this will
lead. The health care industry is too large, complex, and diverse to
centrally plan and regulate. Efforts at central planning will waste
resources and produce disappointing results.
Health care costs so much because consumers directly pay for so
little of it. When consumers spend their own money, they try to choose
wisely and this provides suppliers with a strong incentive to control
costs and offer quality service. If health care is to become more
29

efficient and cost-effective, consumers must have both freedom of
choice and incentives to consider costs.
There are two ways to make consumers more aware of costs and
give them more freedom of choice than many now have. One way is to
encourage increased use of personal Medical Savings Accounts
(MSAs). MSAs could be particularly effective combined with medical
insurance that carries a high deductible. Retirement MSAs could be
used to establish a nest egg for medical expenses during retirement.
Under this approach, individuals would pay into MSAs during their
working years and the funds would be invested. During retirement, the
funds would be used to finance health care and lifetime insurance
policies with high deductibles covering catastrophic medical expenses.
Like personal savings accounts, MSAs would be the property of
individuals. Funds in MSAs could be rolled over from year to year and
the unused portion could be passed on to heirs.
Retirement MSAs would induce consumers and suppliers to
economize, while stimulating capital formation and economic growth.
Research indicates that a payroll contribution of approximately 1.3
percent (rather than the current 2.9 percent) during the working years
would be sufficient to cover the cost of medical service during
retirement. Equally important, the percentage would not be affected
by demographic changes because each generation would finance its
own costs of health care in retirement.
A second way to make consumers more aware of costs would be
to shift Medicare at least partly from a reimbursement service to a
defined-benefit plan. Under this approach, Medicare recipients would
receive a specific amount each year for paying medical bills directly
and purchasing private insurance. All Medicare recipients would be
required to purchase at least a catastrophic insurance plan. The funds
not used in one year could be rolled over for use in subsequent years.
This approach would increase the freedom of Medicare recipients to
choose the combination of medical services that best fits their personal
situation.
One thing is certain: current policy places too much emphasis on
the demand side (paying bills) and not enough on the supply side
(expanding supply and encouraging economical decisions). Current
policy is inefficient because what works for an individual does not
necessarily work for a group. One person can spend more on health
care and thereby obtain more care. However, when members of a large
group simultaneously spend more on health care, prices go up, and
13Andrew J. Rettenmaier and Thomas R. Saving, The Economics of Medicare
Reform (Kalamazoo, Michigan: W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment

Research, forthcoming), chapter 6. Calculations are based on data from the
Continuous Medicare History Sample File, 1974-97.
30

4
because of rigidities in supply, prices can stay up for a long time.'
This highlights the need for a more balanced approach to health care
policy. Rather than merely increasing demand, it should also focus on
the need to expand the supply of medical resources (more doctors and
nurses, for example).

m. Education
Increasingly, brains rather than brawn or resources are the basis of
economic development and individual wealth. A good education is
more important than ever to economic success. For several decades,
high-level officials have been telling us that additional funds would
improve the quality of public education. This promise is beginning to
have a hollow ring. Spending on elementary and secondary education
in the United States is high. In 1996, the latest year for which
international data are available, public spending on education was 5.4
percent of GDP for the United States versus 5.3 percent for all highincome countries.15 Public spending per pupil is among the very
highest in the world. Moreover, this omits private spending, which is
more extensive in the United States than in many other countries.
Despite spending that compares well to other nations by almost
any measure, the performance of public elementary and secondary
schools in the United States is widely perceived to be mediocre. This
reflects too little choice. Empowerment comes from the freedom to
choose. With choice, consumers, including students and their parents,
shop for and choose the most attractive options. This induces suppliers
to cater to their needs and produce efficiently. If consumers do not like
the products or prices of a supplier, they seldom complain or organize
protests. They have a much stronger weapon: shifting their business
elsewhere.
When choice is absent, consumers are unable to weed out
inefficient suppliers and those that fail to provide desired products.
This is precisely the problem in education. In most states, primary and
secondary education is a monopoly. Students are assigned to a
particular public school, and it is virtually impossible to escape the
grasp of a failing school, particularly for children of parents with low
incomes.
resulting from Medicare also drive up the health care costs and
insurance rates of younger people. As health care insurance becomes more
expensive, more households decide that it is unaffordable. Thus, the increase
in the number of persons without health care insurance accompanying the
expansion in Medicare spending is precisely what one would expect.
"World Bank data. The figure here for the United States differs slightly from
that of Exhibit 8 because of recent revisions to U.S. national income accounts.
31
14Higher prices

Exhibit 10: Real Educational Spending
and Student Performance
Real spendingperpupil on public elementary and secondary
education doubledfrom 1970 to 1996, yet SATscores fell.
Spending on
education

Avg. SAT
scores
(students entering
college)

(totalgovernment per

pupil in 1982-84 S)

./-

3000
2600

2200
1800
900 j-L
1970

1400
1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

Sources: Digest of Education Statistics, various issues; College Board Web site,
http://www.collegeboard.org;Haver Analytics.
Note: For underlying data, see Appendix, table 5.

As Exhibit 10 illustrates, since 1970 real spending per pupil on
elementary and secondary education has approximately doubled.
Despite this increase, achievement scores fell in the 1970s, held steady
in the 1980s, and crept up only a little during the 1990s. Cross-country
comparisons of achievement scores also illustrate the weak
performance of U.S. schools. The Third International Mathematics and
Science Study, which compared achievement in 41 countries, found
that even though U.S. fourth-graders scored above the international
average in math and science, the scores of twelfth-graders were well
below average. The achievement scores of older U.S. elementary
students and secondary students lag well behind those of most
developed countries.

32

The situation is quite different at the college and university level.
In higher education, students choose the schools they attend and
financial aid is more readily available, increasing the effective
competition between private and public schools. The United States
leads the world in the variety of programs offered, eminence of
researchers, quality of facilities, and percentage of high school
graduates who participate.
In its proposed budget for 2001, the Clinton Administration seeks
to boost federal spending on primary and secondary education from
$17.2 billion to $26.8 billion. Unfortunately, its approach is to continue
federal direction of resources. The federal government is ill suited for
assessing the diverse needs of the more than 50 million students in
America's primary and secondary schools. State and local governments
are much closer to the students and better able to assess how best to
spend money on education. It is desirable to give state and local
governments flexibility over the use of federal funds given to them for
education, because the needs of students vary from place to place.
It is also desirable to encourage more choice in primary and
secondary education. Several promising choice initiatives are already
underway at the state and local level. These include Florida's A-Plus
Education Plan, which sets clear standards for public schools and pays
for students in poorly performing schools who wish to transfer to other
public schools or participating private schools; state and locally funded
school voucher programs in Milwaukee, Cleveland, and elsewhere; and
privately funded efforts to offer scholarships to low-income families in
some of the country's worst-performing school districts.
Choice is essential for the improvement of elementary and
secondary education. Without choice, experience indicates that more
money will yield only further disappointing results. The federal
government should encourage the initiation and expansion of choice
programs. Voucher programs that pay some or all of the tuition at
private primary and secondary schools already exist in other countries,
including Chile, Colombia, the Netherlands, Sweden, and even postcommunist Russia. If the United States is to keep up and excel in this
crucial area, Americans, including those with low incomes, must have
greater opportunity to choose the schools that best meet the educational
needs of their children.'6

16For an international perspective on choice in education, see Harry Anthony
Patrinos, "Market Forces in Education," World Bank paper, July 1999,
available online at <http://www.worldbank.org/edinvest/MarketHP.html>.
33

3. PROMOTING A MORE OPEN ECONOMY
Openness to trade plays a crucial part in improving living
standards. Imagine how wasteful it would be if each of the 50 states
had to grow all its own oranges, produce all its own oil, or make all the
movies shown within its borders. It is far more efficient for Florida to
grow oranges, Texas to produce oil, California to make movies, and so
on, then trade those things for the goods other states make best. In
essence, the United States is a large free trade zone. This is an
important factor that has contributed to our growth and long-term
success. Just as domestic trade makes it possible for Americans in each
of the 50 states to achieve higher income levels, international trade
makes it possible for citizens in different countries to achieve higher
living standards.
Economics indicates that residents of a country will be more
prosperous when they are permitted to buy from suppliers offering the
best deal and sell to purchasers willing to pay the most attractive
prices. To test this proposition, the staff of the Joint Economic
Committee developed a Trade Openness Index. This index measures
the degree to which citizens in various countries are free to exchange
goods, services, and capital assets with residents of other countries.
The index is based on four factors: (1) tariff rates, (2) presence or
absence of a black market for foreign currency, (3) size of the trade
sector as a share of the economy, and (4) restrictions on capital
movements. High ratings are given to countries with low tariffs, no
black market for foreign exchange, a large trade sector (given the
country's size and locational characteristics), and few restrictions on
the inflow or outflow of capital.' 7
It was possible to derive the index for 97 countries and four time
periods during the last two decades (1980-82, 1985-87, 1990-92, and
1995-97). Exhibit 11 illustrates the relationship between openness and
economic growth for the countries with the 12 highest and 12 lowest
'7 The four components of the index were weighted equally. The country data
on tariffs, black market exchange rate premiums, the actual size of the trade
sector relative to the expected size, and a categorical rating indicative of
capital market restrictions were all placed on a 0 to 10 scale. For details, see
James Gwartney and Robert Lawson, Economic Freedom of the World: 2000
Annual Report (Vancouver: Fraser Institute, 2000). The expected size of the
trade sector is influenced by both country size and location. Thus, the model
used to estimate the expected size of the trade sector is adjusted for size of
country (population and geographic area) and locational characteristics (length
of coastline and distance from concentrations of demand). The Joint Economic
Committee will publish a more comprehensive report on international trade
and economic growth later this year.
34

Exhibit 11: Trade Openness, Income, and Growth

Most open econ onmies

Trade
Openness
Real GDP
Index (avg) per person
1997
1980-97

Avg annual
growth of real
GDP per person
1980-97

Hong Kong

9.9

$26,150

4.7%

Singapore

9.8

5.8%

Belgium

9.0

$30,756
$23,763

Panama

8.8

$7,521

Luxembourg

8.5

$36,190

Germany

8.5

United Kingdo m

8.4

$22,693
$21,825

United States

8.4

$30,610

1.6%

Netherlands

8.4

$22,717

1.6%

Switzerland

8.1

$27,985

0.8%

Malaysia

7.9

4.2%

7.7

$11,274
$23,272

8.6

$23, 730

2.3%

3.0
3.0
2.9
2.8
2.8
2.4
2.4
2.0
1.4
1.4
0.6
0.2

$4,887
$971
$935
$10,600
$1,913
$3,182
$1,117
$6,206
$646
$538
$1,117
$1,287

-0.9%
-2.2%
-0.9%
0.4%
-0.1%
1.0%
2.2%

2.1

$2,783

-0.3%

Canada
Average
Least open econiomies
Algeria
Madagascar
Nigeria
Argentina
Ghana
Syria
Uganda
Iran
Burundi
Sierra Leone
Bangladesh
Myanmar
Average

1.7%
0.7%
3.7%
1.6% *
1.8%

1.2%

*

-0.2%
-1.2%
-3.9%
2.4%
1.7%

Sources: Trade openness (0- 10 scale) derived by JEC staff. Data are from CIA,
Handbook of InternationalFinancialStatistics; World Bank, World
Development Indicators,1999; IMF, InternationalFinancialStatistics
Yearbook, 1999. GDP per person is in 1998 dollars, derived by purchasing
power parity method. Growth rates derived from real local currency units.
Note: *Data for Germany are for West Germnany only prior to unification. Due
to data restrictions, Uganda's average annual growth is based upon
growth only since 1982. For entire series, see Appendix, table 6.
35

average ratings for openness during these four periods. The 12 most
open economies had low tariffs, liberal currency conversion policies,
large trade sectors, and few restraints on the inflow and outflow of
capital. Hong Kong, Singapore, Belgium, Panama, Luxembourg, and
Germany head the list; the United States ranks seventh, tied with the
United Kingdom and the Netherlands. In contrast, the least open
economies--Myanmar, Bangladesh, Sierra Leone, Burundi, Iran,
Uganda, and Syria--persistently followed policies that restricted trade.
If trade makes a difference, countries that are open over a long
time should both achieve higher levels of income and grow faster.' As
Exhibit 11 shows, this has indeed been the case. The GDP per person
of the 12 most open economies in 1997 averaged $23,730-more than
eight times the average of $2,783 for the 12 least open economies. The
12 most open economies grew on average 2.3 percent a year during
1980-97, compared to minus 0.3 percent a year for the 12 least open
economies. The striking differences in both the income levels and
growth rates illustrate the importance of international trade as a source
of growth and prosperity.'9
I. The Trade Record of the Clinton Administration
The Clinton Administration has generally supported economic
openness and the President's Council of Economic Advisers has
consistently presented the case for free trade.2 0 President Clinton
deserves high marks for lobbying reluctant members of his own party
on behalf of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA).
Without these efforts, the agreement could not have been passed.
Recently, however, Administration leadership on behalf of free trade
has been lacking. The Administration's insistence on bringing labor
and environmental regulations into the World Trade Organization
'8For an excellent technical analysis of the relationship between international
trade in economic growth, see Jeffrey A. Frankel and David Romer, "Does

Trade Cause Growth?," American Economic Review, June 1999.

'9 The high incomes of the open economies reflect factors other than the direct
impact of international trade. The more open economies have also followed
monetary, fiscal, and regulatory policies more consistent with high rates of
investment and rapid economic growth. This highlights another important
point: openness gives policy makers strong incentives to establish an
environment that is attractive for investment in physical capital, education,
and technology. Failure to do so will result in low investment rates, capital
flight, and a "brain drain." Thus, in addition to its direct effects, openness
indirectly promotes growth by encouraging the adoption of sound policies in
other areas.
20See Economic
Report of the President2000, chapter 6.
36

(WTO) has, at least for now, undermined the WTO's effectiveness as a
force for trade liberalization.
The focus of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
(GATT), the predecessor of the WTO, was on the reduction of tariffs
and the elimination of quotas and other regulatory barriers that restrict
trade. GATT was effective precisely because it focused on
deregulation. If the WTO is going to be effective, it must follow the
same course. It would be a major mistake to burden the WTO with new
regulatory responsibilities. Other organizations, notably the
International Labor Organization and the United Nations
Environmental Program, already exist as forums for handling labor and
environmental issues, and they are more likely to achieve progress by
keeping their affairs separate from those of the WTO.
Low-income countries resent the imposition of labor and
environmental regulations by the United States and other high-income
countries.2 ' They argue that such regulations are nothing more than a
disguised form of protectionism. They have a strong case. Their labor
and environmental standards are much like those the United States
itself had a century ago, when it had a comparable income level. In
1900, most Americans began their working lives by the time they
finished eighth grade. The air in American cities was thick with coal
dust from thousands of stoves and furnaces, and drinking water was
often infested with disease-causing organisms from raw sewage
dumped by cities upstream. In those days, Americans wanted education
for their children and a clean environment just as much as they do now;
the problem was how to afford them.
The United States now has universal education through twelfth
grade and better pollution control mainly because we are far wealthier
than our great-grandparents were, not because we have better
regulations or more noble intentions. Pressuring developing countries
to adopt our labor and environmental standards prematurely may
actually impede their advance toward the standards by slowing their
economic growth. Most already have met or are striving to meet
minimum standards governing such areas as prohibition of forced labor
and cross-border pollution. As they grow richer, their own citizens will
want them to have standards more like ours. Moreover, the United
States remains free to set standards so that imported goods meet our
norms for health and safety.
and environmental standards were part of NAFTA. NAFTA, however,
was an agreement among just three countries in the same region that had
considerable experience in negotiating a wide range of issues related to their
common borders. WTO agreements are far different. They involve 135
countries scattered across the globe. It is difficult to get a substantial majority
of 135 countries to agree on anything.
37
2'Labor

If the Clinton Administration is really interested in improving
labor standards and environmental regulations around the world, the
most constructive thing it could do would be to push for free trade. As
both economic theory and historical experience illustrate, open markets
will promote growth and prosperity. As the income levels of countries
improve, so too will working conditions, educational levels, and the
demand for stricter environmental controls. Free trade and
improvements in working conditions and environmental quality are
friends, not enemies.
II. The Future Direction of Trade Policy
What specifically should the United States be doing to promote
more open markets and freer trade across national borders? The House
and Senate have approved legislation that would reduce tariffs and
liberalize trade with Caribbean and African countries. The legislation,
now in conference committee, should be enacted into law.
Steps need to be taken to repair the recent damage imposed on the
WTO and restore it as an effective organization for trade liberalization.
In the short term, however, a more promising course may be to expand
NAFTA, and thereby create an even larger free trade zone. Several
Latin American and Pacific Rim countries--including Argentina, Chile,
Australia, New Zealand, and Singapore--are leading candidates for
NAFTA expansion. These countries already have labor standards and,
to a lesser extent, environmental standards similar to those embodied in
the NAFTA treaty.2 2
Finally, it may be time for the United States to consider seriously
unilaterally phasing out its tariffs and quotas. If they were phased out
over 10 or 15 years, domestic industries would have ample opportunity
to adjust to the more competitive environment. All trade barriers,
whether imposed domestically or by one's trading partners, reduce the
volume of trade and deter the achievement of maximum sustainable
output. In addition, quotas also result in wasteful use of resources in an
effort to circumvent trade barriers. The United States could both help
contrast with President Clinton's praise for the demonstrators in Seattle,
Mexican president Emesto Zedillo denounced them as self-appointed
representatives out to "save the people of developing countries from
development." Despite the setback in Seattle, Mexico continues to move
toward trade liberalization. Most recently, it signed a far-reaching free trade
agreement with the European Union. Previously, Mexico had reached free
trade agreements with Bolivia, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Israel,
Nicaragua, and Venezuela. The United States should follow a similar path and
continue to expand the area in which Americans are permitted to enjoy the
benefits of free exchange.
38
22In

itself and set an example for the rest of the world to emulate by
following this course of action.2 3

2 3Currently,

the United States imposes more than 1,000 import allotments that
set the quantities of various products that a country can supply to the U.S.
market. Quotas are particularly attractive to the foreign suppliers that possess
them because they can sell to U.S. consumers at prices above the world
market level. Politically powerful foreigners often control quotas, which they
trade openly like stock options. Foreign producers use circuitous shipping
routes. fraudulent labeling, political contributions, and outright bribes in order
to sell their goods in the U.S. market. In an effort to stifle the process, the U.S.
government employs additional customs officials. All of this results in waste,
corruption, higher taxes, and higher prices for U.S. consumers.
39

4. PROMOTING SOUND MONETARY POLICY
AT HOME AND ABROAD
A sound currency facilitates trade by providing a reliable means
of making payments, whereas a bad currency hinders trade by creating
doubt that it is worthwhile to accept the currency. An unsound
currency is a type of trade barrier, because a sudden depreciation of the
currency--such as occurs during a currency crisis--can temporarily
boost exports and choke imports much as a tariff would. For
liberalization of trade to achieve its full potential, it needs to occur in a
context of sound currencies. The implication for economic growth is
that the United States should promote sound monetary policy both at
home and abroad.
In the 1980s and 1990s, the Federal Reserve System painstakingly
rebuilt the credibility it had lost in the 1970s. It had support from
succeeding administrations to do so, including the Clinton
Administration under Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin. Today, people
around the world have confidence that inflation will remain low in the
United States. This benefits lenders and borrowers alike: lenders are
reassured that inflation will not rob them of their savings, while
borrowers pay lower rates of interest than they would in most other
currencies. It is highly desirable that the dollar continue to have high
credibility. A good way to ensure that is to reform the legislative
mandate of the Federal Reserve System. Agreement is spreading
among economists that central banks in countries with floating
exchange rates should focus on price stability as their main long-term
goal. The Humphrey-Hawkins Act gives the Federal Reserve multiple,
contradictory goals. The act should be revised to conform to the policy
the Federal Reserve is already following in fact. That would strengthen
the ability of the Federal Reserve to resist pressure for inflation. 2 4
The high credibility the dollar enjoys is rare. Among the world's
150 or so currencies, only the dollar, the euro, the Japanese yen, and a
few others such as the Swiss franc and British pound are trusted
enough to be internationally acceptable. Most other countries have
currencies that are unsound and suffer periodic currency crises as a
result. In 1997, East Asian countries were affected; in 1998, Russia;
and in 1999, Brazil and Ecuador. The frequency of currency crises in
the 1990s has resulted in calls for a "new international financial
architecture." The Group of Seven (G-7) nations and other official and
unofficial groups have held numerous meetings and issued many
Connie Mack's Economic Growth and Price Stability Act (S. 1492)
would make price stability the main long-term goal for the Federal Reserve.
40
24Senator

papers on various aspects of the subject. So far, proposals for reform
have produced few concrete results.
International agreement on a new international financial
architecture is likely to be slow and move in small steps. However, the
United States can do much on its own to make the international
monetary system more stable. Most important, it can offer countries
that have unsound currencies an incentive to replace them fully with
the dollar. The International Monetary Stability Act (S. 2101 and H.R.
3493), introduced by Senators Connie Mack (R-Florida) and Robert
Bennett (R-Utah) and Representative Paul Ryan (R-Wisconsin), would
allow the Secretary of the Treasury to share with countries that become
officially dollarized some of the extra revenue the United States would
earn. This would reduce the loss of revenue dollarized countries would
experience from ceasing to issue their own currencies, which at present
constitutes an important political obstacle to dollarization.
Until this year, Panama, which has fewer than 3 million people,
was the largest independent dollarized country, and no country had
become officially dollarized for decades. However, in January
Ecuador, whose population exceeds 12 million people, announced its
intention to become officially dollarized. Despite intervening political
difficulties that included a change of government, in March Ecuador
began replacing its domestic currency, the sucre, with dollar notes.
Dollarization is expected to be complete within six months. East
Timor, which recently became independent again after a quartercentury of Indonesian occupation, announced in January that it would
replace the Indonesian rupiah with the dollar as its official currency.
Currently East Timor is under United Nations administration, and it is
undetermined how long dollarization will persist after East Timor
becomes fully self-governing.
Official dollarization has also been much discussed in a number of
other Latin American countries, particularly El Salvador and
Argentina. The Clinton Administration has been timid about
dollarization, stressing the potential risks other countries incur when
they give up the right to issue their own currency. It is in the interest of
the United States to note the benefits of dollarization as well and to
make a positive case for dollarization. Spreading a sound currency to
more countries would benefit them by promoting higher economic
growth and benefit us by reducing the cost of international transactions
and expanding the number of foreign consumers able to buy American
goods.
Dollarization should be completely voluntary: the United States
should not exert pressure on any country to dollarize. However, it is
perfectly appropriate for the United States to point out that many
countries have been unable to provide sound currencies for their
41

citizens despite experimenting with a wide range of monetary policies.
Dollarization works well, whereas most other policies have not.
Dollarization works because it denies a government the ability to
finance budget deficits by creating inflation. That eliminates one of the
main obstacles to higher economic growth in many countries.
Dollarization has no preconditions; rather, by establishing a sound
currency, it tends to create and enforce a framework for sound
economic policies. Dollarization cannot by itself cure all of a country's
economic problems, but by bringing greater stability to monetary
policy and promoting transparency in government finance, it improves
the chance of addressing many problems effectively. 2 5

25See

Joint Economic Committee, Office of the Chairman, "Basics of
Dollarization," staff report, January 2000. This and other materials on
dollarization are available at <http://www.senate.gov/-jec/dollamews.htm>.
On the benefits of a common currency for international trade, see Andrew K.
Rose, "One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effect of Common
Currencies on Trade," working paper, Haas School of Business, University of
California-Berkeley, 17 February 2000; the full text is available online at
<http://haas.berkeley.edu/-arose/Grav.pdfP.
42

5. MAKING THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
MORE EFFECTIVE
If steps are taken to establish a new international financial
architecture through multinational action, they are likely to involve the
International Monetary Fund (IMF). The United States has a leading
role in the IMF because it is the organization's largest contributor. The
IMF was established in 1945 to finance temporary balance of payments
problems under the system of pegged exchange rates that existed from
1945 to 1973. Under the flexible exchange rates that have existed
among the major currencies since 1973, the IMF's focus has become
less clear.
I. Problems with IMF Lending
Loans by the IMF are potentially (though not always) stabilizing
in the short run, but create some long-term problems.
Moral hazard. Loans may encourage reckless behavior, which
economists call "moral hazard." Borrowers and lenders recognize that
their national governments, backed by the IMF, will likely rescue them
if they behave imprudently on a sufficiently large scale.
Inappropriate conditions attached to loans. The IMF typically
imposes certain conditions on the loans it makes. Too often, one of the
conditions is that recipient countries increase tax rates. That hampers
economic growth by penalizing effort. Moreover, in a number of recent
loans the IMF has required recipient countries to restructure entire
sectors of their economies. Neither the IMF nor any other international
organization has the knowledge and personnel to design such
restructurings well. At the same time, the IMF has paid insufficient
attention to promoting durable stabilization of currencies. The most
noteworthy example is Indonesia, where the IMF in 1998 discouraged
the government from using a currency board despite the success of
currency boards elsewhere. 2 6 A collapse of the currency, economic
depression, riots, and resignation of the president followed.
Cost to U.S. taxpayers. The Clinton Administration has claimed
there is no cost associated with U.S. contributions to the IMF. The
IMF's base rate for loans, currently less than 5 percent, is comparable
to or even below the rates the United States and other highly
creditworthy governments pay in open markets. But almost all IMF
Blustein, "Suharto Reconsidering Currency Policy; IMF Opposed
Indonesian Leader's Plans to Peg Rupiah to Dollar," Washington Post,
February 22, 1998, p. A24; Steve H. Hanke, "How I Spent My Spring
Vacation," The InternationalEconomy, July-August 1998.
43
26Paul

loans are made to less creditworthy governments who would pay much
higher rates in open markets. The rates the IMF charges them do not
adequately reflect their potential risk, and thereby exacerbate the moral
hazard problem discussed above. Subsidized loans are not necessary to
assist illiquid borrowers and are counterproductive for insolvent
entities.
Lack of transparency. In response to pressure from the U.S.
Congress and governments of other countries, the IMF now releases
more information about its activities on its Web site and in print. This
is a welcome development, but the IMF's policies (and the policies of
the U.S. Treasury when it supports IMF loans) are still too ill-defined
and secretive.
II. Reforming the IMF
The IMF has drifted into areas unrelated to its core mission of
financing temporary balance of payments problems. Its far-flung
economic development and structural lending projects duplicate the
activities of its sister organization, the World Bank. To address these
problems, the Congress established a bipartisan International Financial
Institution Advisory Commission, which completed its work and
presented a report in March 2000.27 The report contains many
suggestions for improving the performance of the IMF and other
international financial institutions. Among its findings are these:
The IMF and other international financial institutions should
write off their debt to certain very poor countries that simply
cannot repay it. Congressional impetus for this idea, known as the
HIPC (Highly Indebted Poor Countries) initiative, was bipartisan and
incorporated into law (Public Law 106-113). The IMF is making de
facto writeoffs for some countries through complex accounting
transactions that revalue to more realistic levels the gold it holds. In
return for the writeoffs, countries agree to structural reforms to
promote economic growth and prevent them from making the same
mistakes again. Unlike the structural reforms agreed to in IMF loans

2 7The

full text of the report of the commission is available online at
<http://phantom-x.gsia.cmu.edu/IFIAC/USMRPTDV.html>. The Treasury has
made some highly inaccurate criticisms of the report; see the testimony of
Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers to the House of Representatives
Committee on Banking, March 23, 2000, available online at
<http://www.house.gov/banking/32300sum.htm>. Representative Jim Saxton
(R-New Jersey) introduced the IMF Reform Act of 2000 in February (H.R.
3750) to address some of the same issues covered by the commission. The text
of the bill is available online at <http://www.house.gov/jec/imf/2-29-leg.pdf>.
44

that have more of an emergency character, these reforms are the result
of more deliberation and more initiative from indebted countries.
The IMF should restrict its lending to providing temporary
liquidity, and cease making long-term loans for other purposes.
This would return the IMF to its core mission. The report of the
commission suggests the IMF charge rates of interest above recent
market rates so that countries borrow from it only when they are really
in trouble. The report also proposes allowing countries to qualify
automatically for loans if they meet certain international standards.
Countries that do not qualify would still be eligible to borrow, but on
less favorable terms and with more supervision by the IMF. The IMF
should not be involved in restructuring entire sectors of national
economies, such as automobiles or food distribution.
The IMF should improve its transparency further. It should
disseminate its so-called Article IV reports and other country
information that, at the request of some member countries, is now
confidential. Also, it should publish minutes of the meetings of its
executive board, with a suitable lag, and should reformat its balance
sheet to be more understandable. At present, the balance sheet contains
no direct information on how much the IMF has lent or how liquid its
various assets and liabilities are.
The IMF has sufficient assets to borrow from international
capital markets should it need to expand its capacity to lend in the
near future. It is not necessary for U.S. taxpayers to put more money
into the IMF through an increase in the U.S. contribution.
Countries should choose either firmly fixed exchange rates
(dollarization or currency boards) or fluctuating rates. As officials
of the U.S. Treasury have also said, mixed systems such as pegged
exchange rates have proved to work poorly. The IMF should not force
countries to give up pegged exchange rates, but it should not lend to
support them and should tell countries that its best advice is to avoid
pegged rates. The commission was silent about the choice between
fixed and fluctuating rates, but experience indicates that fluctuating
rates work better in developed countries than in developing countries.
The Commission's recommendations are sound and they should
be implemented. The report of the commission proposes a phase-in
period of three to five years to implement these and other
recommendations. That is ample time to allow countries to adjust to the
new rules under which the commission recommends the IMF operate.

45

6. REDUCING THE BURDEN OF FEDERAL TAXES
I. The Size of the Federal Tax Burden
Just eleven years after breaching the $1 trillion revenue barrier in
1990, the federal government is expected to top $2 trillion in revenue
in the coming fiscal year. The strong economy has fueled record tax
collections from the income, payroll, and excise tax systems. Since
1992, federal revenues have risen 79 percent, compared to a 54 percent
rise in nominal GDP.2 8
In earlier times, the federal government could rely on a few
simple tax mechanisms to collect the resources that it needed. In 1900,
federal taxes represented just 2.4 percent of GDP, which was collected
without the need for payroll taxes or individual and corporate income
taxes. Customs dues and excise taxes generated 91 percent of federal
taxes back then. It cost the Treasury about $12 million to collect taxes
and customs dues in 1900, and required roughly 10,000 workers. 2 9
Today, federal revenues are 20 percent of GDP, meaning that onefifth of the value of everything produced is channeled though
Washington, D.C. Numerous and complex tax collection systems are
needed to tap into different pools of income in the economy. The IRS
now employs 100,000 workers with an $8.2 billion budget.
It is useful to occasionally step back and ask: who really pays the
$2 trillion in taxes, and how does its collection affect the performance
of the economy?
II. Who Pays Federal Taxes?
Personal income taxes account for 49 percent of federal revenues;
Social Security and Medicare payroll taxes account for 33 percent;
corporate income taxes account for 10 percent; and other taxes account
for 8 percent. Each source of federal tax revenue imposes a distinct
cost on American families in their roles as workers, consumers, savers,
and entrepreneurs. The actual burden of a tax may be distinct from the
source of collection. Following is a brief description of the burden of
each major tax.

28Data

from the Office of Management and Budget for fiscal years; figure for
2001 is estimated.
29

StatisticalAbstract of the United States, 1902; U.S. Treasury, Annual Report
of the Secretary of Treasury, Fiscal Year 1900; and Joint Economic

Committee estimates.
46

Exhibit 12: Individual Income Tax Shares
Over the last two decades, high-income taxpayers
have paid an increasingshare offederalpersonal
income taxes.

Income group
Top 1%
Top 5%
Top 10%
Next 40%
Bottom 50%

Share of total federal
personal income tax paid
1980
1990
1997
19.1%
25.1%
33.2%
36.8%
43.6%
51.9%
49.3%
55.4%
63.2%
43.7%
38.8%
32.5%
7.0%
5.8%
4.3%

Source:1nternal Revenue Service.
Note: For entire series, see Appendix, table 8.

*

*

Personal income taxes. The personal income tax burden is highly
skewed towards upper-income individuals. As the IRS data of
Exhibit 12 show, the top 5 percent of tax-filing families paid 51.9
percent of the federal personal income taxes in 1997, up from 43.6
percent in 1990 and 36.8 percent in 1980.30 The top 10 percent of
earners paid 63.2 percent of the 1997 federal income tax. While the
revenue collected from the top group has risen, the share paid by
the bottom 90 percent of taxpayers has fallen. Interestingly, this
was true during both the 1980s, when marginal rates were reduced,
and during the 1990s, when except for the capital gains rate, the
top marginal rates were increased. The standard deduction and
other provisions exempt millions of lower-income families from
taxation, so that just 64 percent of U.S. families are expected to
pay income tax in 1999.31'
Payroll taxes. The combined Social Security and Medicare payroll
tax of 15.3 percent imposes a heavy burden on all employed and
self-employed families, since it applies to wages from the first

301ntemal

Revenue Service, SO! Bulletin, Spring 1999, and electronic data
from the IRS for 1997. See Appendix, table 8, for annual data on the shares of
personal income taxes paid by various income groups since 1980.
31
U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, "Estimates of Federal Tax
Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2000-2004," JCS-13-99, December 22, 1999.
47

Exhibit 13: Total Federal Taxes
as a Share of Income
The higherthe income, the greater the shareof earnings a
family pays infederal tax.
Federal
taxes as %
of income*

24.6%

20.1%
17.4%

11.7%

5.9%

Lowest
------

Second

Third

Fourth

Highest

Family income groups (quintiles)

Source: Treasury Department. Income is "Family Economic Income."
Note: * Total federal taxes include income, excise, payroll, and estate taxes.

dollar earned. About 80 percent of working families pay more
payroll taxes than they do income taxes. 32
Corporate income taxes. The corporate income tax is passed
through businesses to shareholders, debt holders, workers,
consumers, or some combination. The tax is highly complex and

32 Congressional

Budget Office, "Estimates of Federal Tax Liabilities for

Individuals and Families by Income Category and Family Type for 1995 and
1999," May 1998.
48

*

creates a hidden burden of taxation that many Americans are
unaware that they pay.
Other taxes. Consumers pay federal excise taxes on a variety of
products including cigarettes, gasoline, alcohol, telephone service,
and other items. The federal estate and gift tax, also known as the
death tax, can be thought of as falling on either deceased people or
their heirs. It is considered unjust by many, and can impede the
transfer of family businesses such as farms and shops.

All in all, the federal tax system is highly progressive, meaning
that lower-income families pay a smaller share of income in taxes than
higher-income families. Exhibit 13 shows Treasury Department
estimates of average tax burdens for U.S. families grouped into five
income groups for 2000. Families in the highest fifth will pay 24.6
percent of income in federal taxes this year, on average, while families
in the lowest fifth will pay 5.9 percent.
III. Problems Created by the High Tax Burden
While the $2 trillion of federal taxes collected each year do fund
many useful and desirable programs, they also create an array of
damaging side effects on the nation's economy. The most obvious
impact, of course, is that individuals lose control of earnings sent to
Washington, and as a result may be short of funds needed to finance
their own family's food, housing, or health care needs.
The actual transfer of resources from individuals to the
government through taxation is far from frictionless. A tax dollar
extracted from an individual or a business ends up costing the private
economy much more than just one dollar. This is the case for two main
reasons.
First, tax design, collection, and enforcement is costly and
requires many highly skilled experts who would otherwise be
producing useful goods and services for consumption. In addition to
the IRS's 100,000 employees, every business in America must employ
tax accountants, bookkeepers, and lawyers to tabulate and collect the
required taxes. In turn, they hire tens of thousands of outside
accountants and lawyers to figure out how much is owed, devise plans
to minimize next year's tax bill, and do battle in the tax courts. For
example, U.S. businesses spend roughly $5 billion each year in tax
consulting fees to the Big Five accounting firms, let alone fees paid to
smaller accounting firms, law firms, and other consultants. One

49

estimate placed the total cost of tax compliance for U.S. businesses at
$150 billion. 3 3
The Office of Management and Budget estimates that individuals
and businesses will spend over 6 billion hours (3 million person-years)
filling out tax forms this year, including hours spent record-keeping
and learning the tax rules.3 4 The tax code has gotten so complicated
that more than half of U.S. families now use tax preparation firms to
make sure they comply with the complex rules. These firms, such as
H&R Block and Jackson Hewitt, have seen their businesses soar. H&R
Block's 1999 revenues from tax operations of $1.3 billion are up 30
percent in the past two years.
A second, larger burden to the economy than the actual tax
collection costs are the incentive and disincentive effects created by the
tax code on individual and business behavior. High marginal tax rates
in the personal income tax code dissuade individuals from extra work
effort, saving for retirement, or taking risks to start and grow
businesses.
The highly complex corporate income tax system has a wideranging impact on how American businesses structure themselves and
conduct their operations. Business decisions such as how much new
machinery should be purchased, where new facilities should be
located, how employees should be compensated, how many workers
should be hired, and what type of pension plan to offer, are all affected
by tax rules. The result is that billions of dollars of economic resources
are being moved around in response to tax rules, and not being
allocated to uses that maximize economic growth.
In summary, larger tax burdens mean that more skilled people are
engaged in zero-sum work, and that more economic decisions are made
with regard to tax considerations, rather than individual choice and
maximum efficiency. While taxes are required to fund the necessary
functions of government, a simplified tax system can minimize these
negative side effects. At the heart of tax reform ideas, such as the flat
tax and the national retail sales tax, is the goal of minimizing
distortions and waste in the current system.
But before the country moves towards a major tax reform, the
federal tax system can be updated and improved with some smaller
reforms. The next section briefly summarizes some first steps towards
a new tax system for the 21 st century.

33Tax Foundation Special Briefby Arthur Hall, March 1996.
34Office of Management and Budget, Information Collection

United States Government, fiscal year 1999.
50

Budget of the

IV. First Steps to a Simpler and More Efficient Tax System
Reduce income taxes on savings and investment. America's
income tax system is widely recognized to create a bias against savings
and investment. Because savings and investment are crucial to
sustaining strong economic growth, reforms should be enacted to
reduce this distortion.
A main source of the problem is that earnings from corporate
investments are taxed at both the corporate level and the individual
level. Corporate profits generated by investments in machines and
equipment first incur a 35 percent corporate income tax.3 5 Then a
portion of earnings are distributed to individual shareholders in the
form of dividends, which are subject to ordinary income tax rates of up
to 39.6 percent (plus state and local income taxes). If corporations
retain after-tax profits, company valuation will increase as share prices
rise. Ultimately shareholders will pay tax on the rising share prices
when they realize capital gains, or may pay the estate tax on the fair
market value of their shares when they die, at a top rate of 55 percent.
Consider a corporation that earns $1 per share, pays 35 cents in
corporate income tax and distributes the remaining 65 cents. Individual
shareholders in the 39.6 percent tax bracket will end up with just 39
cents from the original $1 in earnings. In this case, the effective
marginal tax rate on the $1 of earnings is 61 percent. Even taxpayers in
the 15 percent bracket confront an effective tax rate of 45 percent on
their corporate earnings, leaving them with only 55 cents of each dollar
earned by their corporate assets. The effect is to reduce the return on
equity investment, which may reduce the pool of capital available for
business investment, and may bias businesses toward debt financing,
since interest is a deductible expense at the corporate level.
While many other industrial countries have a higher overall level
of taxes than the United States, most nonetheless have income tax
systems that contain provisions to reduce the double-tax burden on
corporate equity. The double layer of tax may be reduced by lowering
the tax on dividends and capital gains at the individual level, or
allowing businesses to deduct dividends at the corporate level.
Other aspects of the income tax system are also investmentunfriendly for U.S. businesses seeking to compete in the global
economy. For example, the rapid obsolescence of new technologies is
not fully reflected in tax depreciation rules. Semiconductor and printed
circuit board manufacturing equipment must be written off over five
35 Moreover,

to the extent that depreciation schedules do not allow the
equipment to be fully expensed, the initial investment is also subject to
additional tax.
51

years, but often becomes obsolete in three. A number of other
industrial countries have more competitive depreciation treatment for
technology equipment. 3 6
hi summary, through multiple tax layers, high marginal rates, and
uncompetitive depreciation rules, the income tax system creates
disincentives to savings and investment. The benefits of reducing these
burdens would include greater efficiency, reduced business debt levels,
greater capital formation, and faster economic growth.
Reduce the marriage penalty. Substantial concern has been
expressed in recent years regarding features of the income tax code
which create "marriage penalties." These occur because the tax code
does not treat a married couple as equal partners in earning the
couple's total income.
Marriage penalties are mainly caused by the breakpoints between
tax brackets for married taxpayers (which are not twice the breakpoints
for single taxpayers), and the standard deduction for married taxpayers
(which is not twice that for single taxpayers). In 2000, the standard
deduction is $4,400 for singles, but only $7,350 for married couples.
Similarly, the 28 percent tax rate bracket begins at $26,250 for singles,
but only $43,850 for married couples. At the top end of the income
spectrum, marriage penalties become severe. This is because the
income breakpoint for the 39.6 percent rate is the same for singles as
for married couples. A straightforward way to reduce marriage
penalties is to make the standard deduction and the tax breakpoints for
married couples twice the amounts for singles. 3 7
Make health insurance deductible for individuals. Health care
insurance is an important component of employee compensation for
most workers. There are two main reasons why employers and
employees benefit from inclusion of health insurance in compensation
packages: lower costs as the result of economies of group purchase,
and employer tax advantages. As a result, about two-thirds of nonelderly adults receive health insurance through group plans offered by
their employers.
When employees receive health insurance benefits as part of their
compensation package, the benefits are generally not taxed at the
employer or employee level. By contrast, families and individuals
purchasing health insurance directly must generally do so with after36Testimony by the American Council for Capital Formation before the Senate
Budget Committee, January 20, 1999. The Treasury Department is conducting
an extensive study of depreciation periods and methods, which will be
completed later this year.
37This has been proposed in the Marriage Tax Relief Act of 2000, which has
been passed by the Senate Finance Committee and awaits action by the full
Senate.
52

* 38
tax earnings.
This difference in tax treatment makes the direct
purchase of health insurance more costly, creating an unfair bias
against families not receiving benefits through work.
This unequal treatment is a historical relic dating back to World
War II. At the time, employers provided health insurance as a means to
escape wage controls. Because health insurance was not counted as a
wage increase, it enabled employers to raise total compensation and
attract additional workers. The rule distorts personal decision making
and reduces the competitiveness of the health insurance industry. In
today's world, the rule is indefensible. Legislation making the direct
purchase of health insurance frilly deductible for all families should be
adopted. Provisions in the Taxpayer Refund and Relief Act of 1999
would have accomplished this, but President Clinton vetoed the act.
Repeal the Alternative Minimum Tax. Congress adopted the
Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) to ensure that high-income
taxpayers would pay their fair share of taxes. Unfortunately, this goal
was accomplished at a very high cost in terms of tax complexity
because the AMT essentially requires taxpayers to perform additional
calculations under a second tax system parallel to the regular income
tax.
Today, tax statistics show the AMT is unneeded because higherincome families pay a very high average tax burden even before AMT
is considered. IRS figures show that in 1997 families with incomes
over $200,000 (who represent just 1.5 percent of tax filing families)
paid 37.1 percent of all income taxes before AMT. The AMT only very
slightly increased the tax share of these families to 37.3 percent. But
this slight increase in burden creates high complexity costs for
taxpayers, and high administrative expenses for the IRS. The IRS
National Taxpayer Advocate and other tax experts recommend that this
unnecessary tax be repealed, or at least reformed. 3 9
While the tax was originally aimed only at high-income
Americans, flaws in its design mean that rising numbers of middleincome taxpayers must also deal with the AMT. In particular, AMT
exemption amounts, phase-out thresholds, and the top tax rate
threshold are not indexed for inflation, so as incomes grow more
families become subject to this tax. Even if they do not owe AMT,
more and more taxpayers must perform calculations to see if they are

38 However,

taxpayers who itemize can deduct some medical expenses, but
only to the extent that their total medical expenses exceed 7.5 percent of
adjusted gross income. Self-employed individuals can currently deduct 60
percent of their family's expenses for health insurance; this will rise to 100

pIercent in 2003.

Internal Revenue Service, National Taxpayer Advocate, Annual Report to
Congress FY 1999.
53

liable for it, above and beyond their regular tax amount. Taxpayers hit
by this add-on tax are projected to jump from about 1 million today to
about 9 million by 2009.40
Repeal the Social Security earnings test. Americans in their
sixties are increasingly healthy and energetic and not ready for
retirement. Unfortunately, current Social Security rules discourage
them from continuing to work. The minimum age to begin receiving
Social Security retirement benefits is 62. The Social Security "earnings
test" reduces benefits for retirees age 62 to 69 who have earnings from
work above fairly low earnings thresholds. While these rules are not
part of the tax system, they effectively act like a high marginal tax rate
on work effort for retirees. The earnings test should be repealed to
eliminate this perverse incentive which discriminates against the
industrious elderly.
In 2000, individuals age 62 to 64 lose $1 of benefits for every $2
they earn above $10,080 a year. Those age 65 to 69 lose $1 of benefits
for every $3 they earn above $17,000 a year. Like other workers, older
workers are also subject to payroll and income taxes on earnings.
The combined effect of lost Social Security benefits plus payroll
and income taxes means that, above the threshold, persons age 65 to 69
keep only $41 for every $100 they earn if they have decided to take
Social Security benefits during those years. This effectively creates a
marginal tax rate of 59 percent.4 ' Such high marginal tax rates are hard
to justify. The economy suffers because it is deprived of the knowledge
and skills of productive workers. The elderly are harmed because the
law discourages them from providing for themselves and, as a result
they become more dependent on government.
Today, most Social Security recipients do not work. But many
would like to, and this policy discourages them from doing so. As the
health of older Americans continues to improve, the harmful side
effects of the current Social Security earnings test will worsen. As we
write this, a bill to remove the earnings test for persons 65 and older
(H.R. 5) has passed the House of Representatives and the Senate.
However, the bill would not remove the earnings test for persons under
age 65.

'*U.S. Congress, Joint Committee on Taxation, report JCX-39-99, June 22,
1999.
4'Suppose that a Social Security recipient age 65 to 69 earns an additional
$107.65 in pre-tax wages above the earnings threshold. Payroll taxes take
$15.30, income taxes are $15 in the 15 percent bracket, and Social Security
benefits are reduced $33.33. The effective, combined marginal rate is
$63.33 $107.65 = 0.59, or 59 percent.
54

7. ECONOMICS, TRADE DEFICITS, AND
PAYING OFF THE NATIONAL DEBT
Sound economic policy requires sound thinking. Two issues that
are currently attracting considerable attention are trade deficits and the
possible elimination of the federal government's public debt.
Economic analysis provides considerable insight into both issues.
I. Is the Trade Deficit a Problem?
During the last 25 years, the United States has persistently run
large trade deficits. There is a natural tendency to believe that a trade
deficit is bad for an economy. This is understandable: the word
"deficit" suggests things like excessive spending relative to income,
bank overdrafts, indebtedness, and a future day of reckoning. A trade
deficit, however, is not like this. A trade deficit occurs when a nation's
imports exceed its exports. Many times, this occurs because a nation is
growing more rapidly than its trading partners. Rapid domestic growth
stimulates imports, while slow growth abroad weakens demand for a
nation's exports. This combination often causes a trade deficit.
Trade deficits may also occur when investment opportunities at
home are attractive relative to those available abroad. Trade deficits are
the flip side of net inflows of capital. With floating exchange rates,
market forces will bring American purchases of goods, services, and
assets from foreigners into balance with sales of these items to
foreigners. This means that
Exports + Net Foreign Investment = Imports4 2
Therefore, when foreigners invest heavily in a country--when there is
the net inflow of capital--a trade deficit (current-account deficit) will
occur.
During the last two decades, the United States has grown faster
than many of its trading partners. At the same time, investment
opportunities have been highly attractive in the United States. This
combination has undergirded the trade deficits of the last two decades.
Why do many people think the trade deficits are bad? Would we have
been better off if the U.S. had grown more slowly or if the environment
for investment in the United States had been less attractive? These
4 2This

formula omits investment income and unilateral transfers, which are
small in the case of the United States.
55

Exhibit 14: Relationship Between the Trade
Deficit and Net Foreign Investment
Netforeign investment (NFI) and the trade deficit are
closely linked. When NFI changes, so does the trade deficit.
% of

GDP
Net foreign
investment

3

2
1
0

-1

-2

deficit

-3
1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Sources: Economic Report of the President, 2000, table b-22; Haver Analytics.
Note: For underlying data, see Appendix, table 7.

questions answer themselves. Recent trade deficits reflect the strength
of the U.S. economy, not its weakness.
Exhibit 14 illustrates that net foreign investment (net inflow of
capital) and the trade deficit are almost mirror images. When net
foreign investment increases, the demand for the dollar rises in the
foreign exchange market, causing it to appreciate. In turn, the
appreciation of the dollar stimulates imports relative to exports,
causing a trade deficit. Just the opposite happens. when there is an
outflow of capital: the dollar depreciates, exports are stimulated
relative to imports, and the trade balance shifts toward a surplus.
Doesn't a trade deficit mean greater indebtedness to foreigners?
Not necessarily. Much of the foreign investment involves the purchase
of stocks and physical assets like buildings and business assets.
56

Americans benefit because they are able to sell these assets to
foreigners at more attractive prices than would otherwise be possible.
Foreign investments of this type do not increase American
indebtedness to foreigners. Some foreign investments are in the form
of loans or the purchase of bonds, which mean lower interest rates for
Americans. If the investments are sound, they will generate a future
income stream that is more than sufficient to repay the loans. Even in
this case, the loans are helpful to the U.S. economy.
Critics of trade often argue that trade deficits mean loss of jobs.
Once the link between the inflow of capital and trade deficits is
recognized, the error of this view is obvious. The inflow of capital that
must accompany a trade deficit will lead to lower interest rates and a
higher level of investment. Any loss of jobs accompanying the excess
of the imports relative to exports will be offset by higher employment
due to the lower interest rates and more investment. The U.S.
experience during the Great Expansion illustrates this. Even though
imports grew more rapidly than exports and trade deficits were sizeable
throughout much of the period, total employment increased by 35
million from 1983 to 1999 and the unemployment rate fell to a 30-year
low (see Exhibits I and 3 above). Simply put, the protectionist view
that trade deficits reduce employment is fallacious. Neither economic
theory nor empirical evidence provide support for this position.
Can a country continue to run trade deficits? Perhaps surprisingly,
the answer is "yes." Remember that trade deficits reflect the net inflow
of capital. The inflow can and will continue as long as investors find
the U.S. economy more attractive than other economies. Put another
way, foreigners will be happy to supply investment capital to the U.S.
economy as long as they can earn competitive returns. In the case of
debt financing, as long as the net income generated by the investment
is large enough to cover the borrowing costs, there is no reason why
the process cannot continue indefinitely. The historical evidence is
consistent with this view. The U.S. experienced trade deficits and
capital inflows year after year from 1820 to 1870. During that period,
investment opportunities in the New World were more attractive than
those in Europe, so Europeans were quite willing to continue financing
undertakings in the New World.
A trade deficit is quite different from a business loss or even the
budget deficit of a government. No legal entity is responsible for the
trade deficit. 4 3 It is not something that one party owes to another; it is
In his typical satirical manner, the late Herbert Stein put it this way: "The
trade deficit does not belong to any individual or institution. It is a pure
statistical aggregate, like the number of eggs laid in the U.S. or the number of
bald-headed men living here." Herbert Stein, "Leave the Trade Deficit
43

Alone," Wall Street Journal, March II, 1987.
57

merely the sum of the buying and selling decisions of millions of
people. Suppose an American retailer purchases $500,000 of shoes
from a British manufacturer. In turn, the British firm uses the funds to
buy stocks or bonds issued by an American corporation. These
transactions will increase the size of the trade deficit. But why is there
any reason for concern? They reflect the voluntary choices of
individuals that will both reap the benefits and bear the costs. This is
also true for a nation's trade deficit.
II. Should the Federal Debt Be Fully Paid Off?
At the end of 1999, the federal debt was $5.7 trillion. Of this
amount, $2.2 trillion was held by federal agencies and trust funds
(primarily the Social Security Administration) and another $500 billion
was held by Federal Reserve Banks. Thus, the amount of debt that the
federal government owes to someone other than itself is only $3
trillion.
Eliminating or at least greatly reducing the federal debt has
become a generally accepted goal across the political spectrum. The
attractiveness of paying off the national debt is certainly
understandable. However, there are also reasons to exercise caution.
There is an "optimal amount of debt" for both businesses and
governments. Just as the optimal amount is often positive for a strong
healthy business, it may also be positive for the federal government.
There are several reasons why the optimal federal debt is unlikely to be
zero. First, U.S. Treasury securities play an important role in our
financial markets. Treasury securities, particularly those that are
indexed for inflation, provide households, businesses, pension funds,
and financial institutions with a secure, highly liquid asset that makes it
easier for them to deal with an uncertain future. The interest rate on
these securities also provides a benchmark for the evaluation of other,
riskier assets. Furthermore, if the federal government repays the debt
by levying higher taxes than would otherwise exist, private households
and businesses will have to borrow more than would otherwise be the
case. In essence, this substitutes riskier, high-interest debt for more
secure, low-interest debt. On balance, it is not obvious that the
substitution will reduce overall interest costs.
Second, the Federal Reserve manages the money supply through
the purchase and sale of U.S. securities in the open market. If Treasury
securities were unavailable, the Fed would have to buy and sell a large
amount of securities issued by private firms, which would give the Fed
an opportunity to play favorites and subject the Fed to political
pressure regarding the companies whose securities it purchases.
58

Third, the U.S. dollar is a "reserve currency." Central banks and
other monetary authorities around the globe currently hold more than
$600 billion of U.S. Treasury securities as reserve assets. If the
national debt were paid off and the securities were unavailable to
foreigners, the dollar would be less attractive as a worldwide currency.
With time, the reduction in the worldwide demand for the dollar could
erode its position as the world's leading currency and make financial
markets in dollars less extensive. That might make it more costly for
Americans to engage in international transactions.
Finally, we must not forget that the national debt is a relatively
small portion of the federal government's unfunded liabilities.
Currently, the unfunded liabilities of the Social Security system are
estimated to be between $5 trillion and $11 trillion; those of the
Medicare program are projected at almost $10 trillion. These liabilities
are far greater than the outstanding federal debt. Thus, restructuring
these two programs in a manner that will both improve their
performance and solvency is far more important to the future of
American taxpayers than paying off the debt.

59

63-597 00 -3

8. CONCLUSION
During the last two decades, the United States has been
prosperous because we have had relatively open markets, monetary
policy has focused on price stability, and federal government spending
has fallen modestly as a share of GDP. This prescription has worked
around the world. If the United States continues to adopt sound policies
consistent with strong growth, the Great Expansion can continue. In
this regard, the following are important.
Social Security, health care, and education
* Adopt Social Security reforms that would allow individuals to
channel a portion of their payroll tax into Personal Savings
Accounts. Begin moving the system from the pay-as-you-go
approach to a personal savings and investment approach.
* Reform Medicare by placing greater reliance on Medical Savings
Accounts and less reliance on third-party payments. This would
increase incentives for consumers and suppliers to economize.
* Expand choice in education and make it possible for parents,
particularly those with low incomes, to escape failing schools and
choose the schools most suitable for their children.
Trade
* Avoid giving the World Trade Organization (WTO) responsibility
for environmental and labor standards, which are already handled
by other organizations and would dilute the WTO's focus.
* Expand the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and
other initiatives designed to promote open markets and free trade.
* Consider a unilateral phase-out of U.S. quotas and tariffs over 10
to 15 years.
Domestic and international monetary policy
* Continue to focus the Federal Reserve on price stability. Establish
price stability by law as the main long-term goal of the Federal
Reserve.
* Encourage official dollarization in interested countries.
* Encourage countries to adopt fixed exchange rates (as dollarization
would provide) or fluctuating rates, and avoid pegged rates, which
have been at the center of many currency crises.
* Reform the International Monetary Fund, using as a basis some of
the recommendations of the International Financial Advisory
Commission appointed by the Congress.
60

Taxes
* Reduce or eliminate the marriage penalty.
* Make health insurance fully deductible for individuals so that
direct purchase of health insurance is on an equal footing with
purchase through an employer.
* Repeal the Alternative Minimum Tax, which imposes a high
burden of paperwork and generates little additional revenue.
* Repeal the Social Security earnings test, as Congress has recently
done for persons age 65 to 69, but not persons age 62 to 64.
* End multiple taxation that discourages savings and investment,
such as the double taxation of corporate profits.
* Shorten depreciation periods to reflect the rapid pace of
technological change in an increasing number of industries.
* Resist big new spending initiatives that will obligate taxpayers for
large sums in the future.

This staff report was prepared by James Gwartney, Chief
Economist to the Chairman, and James Carter, Chris Edwards,
Angela Ritzert, Kurt Schuler, Charles D. Skipton, Robert Stein,
Lawrence Whitman, and Victor Wolski. Contact James Gwartney
(202-224-2989) with questions or comments.
This staff report reflects the views of the authors only. These
views do not necessarily reflect those of the Joint Economic
Committee, its Chairman, Vice Chairman, or any of its Members.

61

APPENDIX

Table 1: Real Federal Spending per Person
Federal government spending (FY)
Year

Total

Defense

Non-defense

GDP
deflator
1999=100

1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998

92.2
97.7
106.8
111.3
118.5
118.2
134.5
157.5
178.1
183.6
195.6
210.2
230.7
245.7
269.4
332.3
371.8
409.2
458.7
504.0
590.9
678.2
745.8
808.4
851.9
946.4
990.5
1,004.1
1,064.5
1,143.7
1,253.2
1,324.4
1,381.7
1,409.4
1,461.7
1,515.7
1,560.5
1,601.2
1,652.6
1,703.0

48.1
49.6
52.3
53.4
54.8
50.6
58.1
71.4
81.9
82.5
81.7
78.9
79.2
76.7
79.3
86.5
89.6
97.2
104.5
116.3
134.0
157.5
185.3
209.9
227.4
252.7
273.4
282.0
290.4
303.6
299.3
273.3
298.4
291.1
281.6
272.1
265.8
270.5
268.5
274.9

44.1
48.1
54.5
57.9
63.8
67.6
76.4
86.0
96.2
101.1
114.0
131.3
151.5
169.0
190.0
245.8
282.2
312.0
354.3
387.7
457.0
520.7
560.4
598.5
624.5
693.7
717.1
722.1
774.1
840.1
953.8
1,051.1
1,083.3
1,118.3
1,180.1
1,243.7
1,294.8
1,330.7
1,384.1
1,428.2

21.5
21.7
22.0
22.2
22.6
23.0
23.5
24.3
25.2
26.4
27.8
29.3
30.6
32.2
34.7
38.1
40.6
43.1
46.1
49.7
54.0
59.1
63.2
66.0
68.5
70.7
72.4
74.3
76.7
79.7
82.7
85.8
87.7
90.0
92.0
94.0
95.8
97.4
98.7
100.0

--

1999

Billions of currentdollars -

Current
population
millions
180.6
183.6
186.5
189.2
191.8
194.2
196.5
198.7
200.7
202.6
205.0
207.6
209.8
211.9
213.8
215.9
218.0
220.2
222.5
225.0
227.6
229.9
232.1
234.2
236.3
238.4
240.6
242.8
245.0
247.3
249.9
252.6
255.3
258.0
260.5
263.0
265.4
267.9
270.5
273.1

Sources: Haver Analytics; Economic Report of the President, 2000, tables b-I, b-3, b-80,
and b-82.
Note: FY= fiscal year.

64

Real Federal Spending per Person

Year
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999

(continued)

Federal government spending (FY)
Per person in 1999 dollarsBillions of 1999 dollarsDefense Non-defense
Total
Total Defense Non-defense
429.7

224.4

450.3
485.7
500.7
525.4
515.1
571.7
648.8
705.7
694.9
703.0
717.2
753.4
763.6
776.0
871.5
916.0
948.5
995.8
1014.8
1095.2
1147.0
1180.1
1224.8
1244.1
1338.5
1368.2
1351.4
1387.9
1435.5
1515.3
1544.3
1574.8
1566.6
1588.4
1613.0
1629.2
1643.8
1674.9
1703.0

228.5
238.0
240.2
242.7
220.5
247.0
294.2
324.6
312.2
293.5
269.2
258.6
238.3
228.6
226.9
220.8
225.4
226.8
234.2
248.3
266.4
293.2
318.0
332.1
357.5
377.6
379.5
378.6
381.0
361.9
318.7
340.1
323.5
306.0
289.5
277.4
277.7
272.1
274.9

205.4
221.7
247.7
260.5
282.7
294.5
324.8
354.5
381.1
382.7
409.5
448.1
494.8
525.3
547.4
644.6
695.2
723.1
768.9
780.6
846.9
880.6
886.9
906.7
912.0
981.1
990.6
971.8
1009.3
1054.5
1153.3
1225.6
1234.8
1243.1
1282.4
1323.5
1351.7
1366.1
1402.9
1428.2

65

2,379
2,452
2,605
2,647
2,739
2,652
2,909
3,266
3,517
3,429
3,430
3,455
3,590
3,604
3,630
4,037
4,202
4,307
4,475
4,510
4,811
4,989
5,084
5,229
5,265
5,614
5,687
5,567
5,665
5,805
6,064
6,114
6,169
6,072
6,097
6,134
6,138
6,135
6,192
6,236

1,242
1,245
1,276
1,270
1,265
1,135
1,257
1,481
1,617
1,540
1,432
1,297
1,232
1,125
1,069
1,051
1,013
1,024
1,019
1,041
1,091
1,159
1,263
1,358
1,405
1,499
1,570
1,563
1,545
1,541
1,449
1,262
1,332
1,254
1,175
1,101
1,045
1,036
1,006
1,006

1,137
1,208
1,328
1,377
1,474
1,516
1,653
1,785
1,899
1,889
1,998
2,159
2,358
2,479
2,560
2,986
3,189
3,284
3,456
3,469
3,720
3,830
3,821
3,871
3,859
4,115
4,117
4,003
4,120
4,264
4,616
4,853
4,837
4,818
4,922
5,033
5,093
5,098
5,186
5,229

Table 2: Civilian Labor Force
Year

age 16-34

millions
age 35-54

Total

1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999

25.9
26.2
26.0
26.7
27.4
28.4
29.4
30.6
31.6
33.2
34.9
36.5
39.1
41.7
43.8
45.5
47.5
49.7
51.7
53.3
54.5
55.5
55.8
56.1
56.7
57.2
58.0
58.2
58.0
58.0
58.4
57.3
57.0
56.3
56.0
55.7
55.0
54.8
54.7
54.4

31.1
31.5
31.7
32.1
32.4
32.6
32.7
32.9
33.0
33.2
33.4
33.3
33.4
33.5
33.9
34.0
34.3
34.8
35.7
36.6
37.4
38.2
39.3
40.5
41.9
43.4
45.0
46.7
48.5
50.5
52.4
54.1
56.1
57.9
59.5
61.0
63.0
64.9
65.9
67.3

69.6
70.5
70.6
71.8
73.1
74.5
75.8
77.3
78.7
80.7
82.8
84.4
87.0
89.4
92.0
93.8
96.2
99.0
102.3
105.0
106.9
108.7
110.2
111.6
113.5
115.5
117.8
119.9
121.7
123.8
125.8
126.3
128.1
129.2
131.1
132.3
133.9
136.3
137.7
139.4

Source: Haver Analytics.

66

share of total age 16-34 age 35-54
37.2%
37.2%
36.8%
37.1%
37.5%
38.1%
38.8%
39.5%
40.2%
41.1%
42.1%
43.3%
45.0%
46.7%
47.7%
48.5%
49.4%
50.2%
50.6%
50.8%
51.0%
51.1%
50.6%
50.3%
49.9%
49.5%
49.2%
48.6%
47.7%
46.8%
46.4%
45.4%
44.5%
43.6%
42.7%
42.1%
41.1%
40.2%
39.7%
39.0%

44.7%
44.7%
44.9%
44.7%
44.3%
43.8%
43.2%
42.5%
41.9%
41.1%
40.3%
39.5%
38.3%
37.4%
36.9%
36.2%
35.7%
35.2%
34.9%
34.9%
34.9%
35.1%
35.7%
36.3%
36.9%
37.6%
38.2%
38.9%
39.9%
40.8%
41.6%
42.9%
43.8%
44.8%
45.4%
46.1%
47.0%
47.6%
47.9%
48.3%

Table 3: National Health Care Expenditures (NHE)
-I--

Year

Total
NHE

1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997

26.9
28.8
31.3
34.1
37.6
41.1
45.3
51.0
57.7
64.8
73.2
81.0
90.9
100.8
114.3
130.7
149.9
170.4
190.6
215.2
247.3
286.9
323.0
355.3
390.1
428.7
461.2
500.5
560.4
623.5
699.4
766.8
836.5
898.5
947.7
993.7
1,042.5
1,092.4

Billions of dollars----Out-ofPrivate
pocket
health
Public
payments insurance funds
13.1
13.4
14.2
15.5
17.3
18.5
18.8
18.8
20.8
22.7
24.9
26.4
29.0
32.0
34.8
38.1
41.9
46.4
49.7
54.3
60.3
68.5
75.4
82.3
90.9

100.7
108.1
116.1
127.5
133.2
145.0
153.3
161.8
167.1
168.5
171.0
178.1
187.6

5.9
6.6
7.4
8.0
8.9
10.0
10.3
10.7
12.2
13.8
16.3
18.6
21.3
23.9
26.8
31.3
37.9
45.9
52.5
60.9
69.8
82.2
95.4
106.2
119.2
132.8
140.6
152.4
178.1
208.5
239.6
261.7
285.5
306.8
315.1
324.3
337.1
348.0

6.6
7.3
8.0
8.7
9.4
10.3
13.7
19.0
21.8
24.5
27.7
31.2
35.1
39.3
46.6
55.0
62.4
70.2
79.6
90.1
104.8
121.2
134.6
147.5
160.1
174.2
189.8
207.2
226.1
252.1
283.2
317.9
353.0
385.3
422.8
455.2
481.4
507.1

Share of NHE -Out-ofPrivate
pocket
health
Public
payments insurance funds
48.7%
46.5%
45.5%
45.6%
45.8%
45.1%
41.6%
36.9%
36.0%
35.1%
34.0%
32.6%
31.9%
31.7%
30.5%
29.1%
28.0%
27.2%
26.1%
25.2%
24.4%
23.9%
23.4%
23.2%
23.3%
23.5%
23.4%
23.2%
22.7%
21.4%
20.7%
20.0%
19.3%
18.6%
17.8%
17.2%
17.1%
17.2%

21.9%
23.1%
23.6%
23.5%
23.8%
24.4%
22.9%
20.9%
21.1%
21.4%
22.2%
22.9%
23.4%
23.7%
23.5%
23.9%
25.3%
26.9%
27.6%
28.3%
28.2%
28.6%
29.5%
29.9%
30.6%
31.0%
30.5%
30.5%
31.8%
33.4%
34.3%
34.1%
34.1%
34.1%
33.2%
32.6%
32.3%
31.9%

24.8%
25.4%
25.5%
25.6%
24.9%
25.0%
30.2%
37.3%
37.8%
37.9%
37.8%
38.5%
38.6%
39.0%
40.8%
42.1%
41.7%
41.2%
41.7%
41.9%
42.4%
42.2%
41.7%
41.5%
41.1%
40.6%
41.2%
41.4%
40.4%
40.4%
40.5%
41.5%
42.2%
42.9%
44.6%
45.8%
46.2%
46.4%

Source: Health Care Financing Administration Web site,http.//www.hcfa.gov.
.Note: There remains a small portion of third-party financing, comprised principally of
charitable contributions.

67

Table 4: Health Care Price Indexes
CPI
Year (1966=100)
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997

100.0
103.1
107.4
113.3
119.8
125.0
129.0
137.0
152.2
166.0
175.6
187.0
201.2
224.1
254.3
280.6
297.8
307.4
320.7
332.1
338.3
350.6
365.1
382.7
403.4
420.4
433.0
446.0
457.4
470.4
484.3
495.4

--- Raw index --Medical
Drugs and
care
supplies
100.0
107.2
113.7
121.3
129.3
137.3
141.8
147.5
161.2
180.6
197.7
216.7
235.0
256.7
284.8
315.2
351.7
382.5
406.1
431.6
463.9
494.7
527.0
567.7
619.0
673.0
722.8
765.8
802.3
838.4
867.7
892.0

100.0
98.1
96.4
97.7
99.4
99.4
99.0
98.7
101.0
107.3
113.0
119.9
129.1
139.2
152.0
169.4
189.1
209.9
230.0
251.8
273.4
295.2
318.7
346.3
380.9
418.7
450.1
467.5
483.4
492.7
509.2
522.6

Source: Haver Analytics.

68

-- Index relative to CPI-Medical
Drugs and
care
supplies
100.0
104.0
105.8
107.1
108.0
109.8
109.9
107.7
106.0
108.8
112.6
115.9
116.8
114.5
112.0
112.4
118.1
124.4
126.6
129.9
137.1
141.1
144.3
148.3
153.5
160.1
166.9
171.7
175.4
178.2
179.2
180.1

100.0
95.2
89.8
86.2
83.0
79.5
76.7
72.1
66.4
64.6
64.3
64.1
64.2
62.1
59.8
60.4
63.5
68.3
71.7
75.8
80.8
84.2
87.3
90.5
94.4
99.6
103.9
104.8
105.7
104.7
105.2
105.5

Table 5: Real Education Spending
and Student Performance

End of

Public
school
K-12

school
year

students
(millions)

1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975
*1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
' 1986
*1987
1988
1989
1990
-1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996

51.3
51.3
50.7
50.4
50.1
49.8
49.5
48.7
47.6
46.7
46.2
45.5
45.2
45.0
44.9
45.0
45.2
45.5
45.4
45.9

46.4
47.2
48.2
48.9
49.7
50.5
51.4

Total government
expenditures for elementary
and secondary education
Billions of
current $ 1999 $
28.4
33.1
35.4
40.9
44.6
48.2
52.0
57.1
61.7
70.4
.72.8
81.0
86.8
95.7
103.2
112.1
118.1
127.2
136.7
148.1
160.4
172.2
192.5
207.4
223.6
234.7
246.0

122.0
136.2
141.2
153.6
150.8
149.3
152.3
157.1
157.8
161.6
147.3
148.5
149.9
160.2
165.6
173.7
179.6
186.7
192.6
199.1
204.6
210.8
228.7
239.3
251.5
256.7
261.4

1999 S
per pupil

Avg SAT
of
students
entering
college

$2,381
$2,657
$2,783
$3,044
$3,012
$2,998
$3,079
$3,224
$3,312
$3,464
$3,187
$3,262
$3,320
$3,562
$3,687
$3,861
$3,974
$4,103
$4,240
$4,338
$4,405
*$4,461
$4,745
$4,889
$5,060
$5,080
$5,087

1049
1045
1039
1029
1026
1010
1006
1003
1001
998
994
994
997
997
1001
1009
1009
1008
1006
1006
1001
999
1001
1003
1003
1010
1013

Sources: Dept. of Education, National Center for Education Statisitics,Digest of Education
-Statistics, 1998 and earlier editions; College Board Web site,
http://www.collegeboard.org; Haver Analytics.

69

Table 6: Trade Openness Index (average 1980-97)
Country
I
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49

Hong Kong
Singapore
Belgium
Panama
Luxembourg
Germany
United Kingdom
United States
Netherlands
Switzerland
Malaysia
Canada
Sweden
Ireland
Norway
New Zealand
Italy
Taiwan
Spain
Australia
Denmark
Uruguay
Austria
Portugal
Finland
Venezuela
Thailand
Japan
South Korea
France
Chile
South Africa
Jordan
Israel
Indonesia
Botswana
Philippines
Fiji
Rep of the Congo
Bolivia
Greece
Jamaica
Malta
Mali
Iceland
Mexico
Morocco
Costa Rica
Mauritius

Index

Country

9.9
9.8
9.0
8.8
8.5
8.5
8.4
8.4
8.4
8.1
7.9
7.7
7.7
7.5
7.4
7.4
7.3
7.1
7.1
7.1
7.1
6.9
6.9
6.7
6.5
6.5
6.4
6.4
6.4
6.3
6.2
6.2
6.2
6.1
6.0
6.0
6.0
5.9
5.7
5.5
5.5
5.5
5.4
5.4
5.3
5.3
5.3
5.1
5.0

50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97

Kenya
Tunisia
Cote d'lvoire
Gabon
Paraguay
China
Sri Lanka
Dem Rep of the Congo
Ecuador
Zambia
Turkey
Cyprus
Cameroon
Hungary
Colombia
Honduras
Belize
Zimbabwe
Guatemala
Senegal
Barbados
Malawi
Niger
Peru
Dominican Republic
Central African Republic
Trinidad & Tobago
Bahamas
El Salvador
Pakistan
Egypt
Nepal
Nicaragua
India
Brazil
Tanzania
Algeria
Madagascar
Nigeria
Argentina
Ghana
Syria
Uganda
Iran
Burundi
Sierra Leone
Bangladesh
Myanmar

Source: Constructed by the staff of the Joint Economic Committee.
70

Index
5.0
5.0
5.0
4.9
4.9
4.8
4.8
4.8
4.7
4.6
4.6
4.6
4.6
4.5
4.5
4.4
4.4
4.4
4.3
4.3
4.2
4.2
4.2
4.2
4.1
4.0
4.0
3.8
3.7
3.7
3.7
3.6
3.4
3.3
3.3
3.1
3.0
3.0
2.9
2.8
2.8
2.4
2.4
2.0
1.4
1.4
0.6
0.2

Table 7: Individual Income Tax Shares
Federalincome tax share by percentiles
Year

Top 1%

Top 5%

Top 10%

Next 40%

Bottom 50%

1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997

19.1%
17.6%
19.0%
20.3%
21.1%
21.8%
25.7%
24.8%
27.6%
25.2%
25.1%
24.8%
27.5%
29.0%
28.9%
30.3%
32.3%
33.2%

36.8%
35.1%
36.1%
37.3%
38.0%
38.8%
42.6%
43.3%
45.6%
43.9%
43.6%
43.4%
45.9%
47.4%
47.5%
48.9%
51.0%
51.9%

49.3%
48.0%
48.6%
49.7%
50.6%
51.5%
54.7%
55.6%
57.3%
55.8%
55.4%
55.8%
58.0%
59.2%
59.4%
60.7%
62.5%
63.2%

43.7%
44.6%
44.1%
43.1%
42.1%
41.4%
38.9%
38.3%
37.0%
38.4%
38.8%
38.7%
36.9%
36.0%
35.8%
34.6%
33.2%
32.5%

7.0%
7.5%
7.3%
7.2%
7.4%
7.2%
6.5%
6.1%
5.7%
5.8%
5.8%
5.5%
5.1%
4.8%
4.8%
4.6%
4.3%
4.3%

Source: Internal Revenue Service.

71

Table 8: Trade Deficit and Net Foreign Investment
GDP
Year
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998

2795.6
3131.4
3259.2
3535.0
3932.8
4213.0
4452.9
4742.5
5108.3
5489.1
5803.3
5986.2
6319.0
6642.3
7054.3
7400.6
7813.2
8300.7
8760.0

Net foreign
Trade
investment
deficit
billions of dollars
-14.9
-15.0
-20.6
-51.7
-102.0
-114.2
-131.9
-142.3
-106.3
-80.7
-71.5
-20.7
-27.8
-60.5
-87.1
-84.3
-89.0
-88.3
-149.55

11.4
6.3
-0.2
-32.0
-87.0
-110.9
-140.6
-152.0
-113.2
-86.7
-69.2
14.9
-38.7
-72.9
-108.3
-98.0
-110.7
-123.7
-201.5

Trade
deficit
-as

-0.5%
-0.5%
-0.6%
-1.5%
-2.6%
-2.7%
-3.0%
-3.0%
-2.1%
-1.5%
-1.2%
-0.3%
-0.4%
-0.9%
-1.2%
-1.1%
-1.1%
-1.1%
-1.7%

Net foreign
investment
a share of GDP0.4%
0.2%
0.0%
-0.9%
-2.2%
-2.6%
-3.2%
-3.2%
-2.2%
-1.6%
-1.2%
0.2%
-0.6%
-1.1%
-1.5%
-1.3%
-1.4%
-1.5%
-2.3%

Source: Haver Analytics; Economic Report of the President, 2000, table b-22.

72

RANKING MINORITY
MEMBER'S VIEWS
AND
MINORITY STAFF
REPORT

Finishing the Job
For the first time in over a generation, an increasing number of
Americans are enjoying economic prosperity. Wages for most
workers are up, unemployment and inflation are at historic lows. The
United States is currently experiencing the longest economic
expansion in its history. A lot has been accomplished, but there is still
more to achieve.

Accomplishments
*

After 20 years of stagnation, real average weekly earnings
are rising once again.

*

At 4.2 percent, unemployment is at its lowest rate since
1970. The unemployment rate has been at or below 5
percent for the last 3 years.

*

The economy created more than 20 million jobs between
1992 and 1999, an average of 2% million jobs per year. By
contrast, between 1980 and 1992, employment grew by
only an average of less that 1IA million jobs per year.

*

Core inflation has fallen to its lowest rate since 1965despite continued declines in the unemployment rate.

*

Economic growth has been above 4 percent during each of
the last 3 years, well Into the current expansion.

For the first time since the Full Employment and Balanced
Growth Act was passed in 1978, the US economy has met the goals set
out by Senator Hubert Humphrey and Congressman Gus Hawkins:
*

The unemployment rate for individuals over 20 years old is
just 1/2 percentage point above the goal of 3 percent.

*

The unemployment rate for individuals over 16 years old has
met the stated goal of 4 percent.

75

*

Inflation has remained below the goal of 3 percent since the
beginning of the Clinton Administration, 7 years ago.

*

All of the above was achieved while balancing the federal
budget, for the first time in over 40 years.

The great irony is that Senator Humphrey and Congressman
Hawkins saw these goals as part of the path toward achieving full
employment and balanced economic growth. Today, 20 years later,
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan views them as dangerous
signs of an overheating economy. On the contrary, low unemployment, low inflation, and rising wages are always good for an economy.
There is much to celebrate in the current economic expansion.
At the same time, there remains a lot more to do. The benefits of the
expanding economy have not yet been experienced by all Americans.
The current economic prosperity provides a good opportunity to finish
the work which has begun on the following agenda, thereby restoring
some of the economic losses experienced over the last 2 decades.

Unfinished Agenda
*

Raise the minimum wage by $1 over the next two years.

*

Encourage more localities to implement Living Wage
ordinances, which include a higher minimum wage and
pension and health care benefits.

*

Move toward universal health care.

*

Enroll all uninsured children in the Children's Health
Insurance Program.

*

Establish an outpatient prescription drug benefit for all
seniors on Medicare.

*

Ensure that all students have access to computers and to
the Internet, and educate children on how to use them to
enhance their skills.

76

-

I. The Longest Economic Expansion in US History
The new century begins with the US economy characterized
by robust growth, low and stable inflation and low unemployment. By
February 2000, the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) had grown for 107
consecutive months, making the current economic expansion the
longest on record. Between 1992 and 1999, average real GDP growth
was approximately 3 1/2 percent a year. During the fourth quarter of
1999, well into the expansion, real GDP growth was almost 7 percent
on an annual basis, the highest quarterly growth rate in 3 /2 years.
Growth in Real GDP

5%

2%

~

-1%
88

87 88 89

90 91

92 93 94

95 98

97 98 99

Source: Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis

After falling and stagnating for over 20 years, real average
weekly earnings have been rising since 1993. Over the last 6 years,
real average weekly wages have grown by more than 6 percent. Yetj
despite this growth, real average weekly wages have only just returned
to levels achieved in 1986 and are still 14 percent below their 1973
high. Although the stagnation of real average wages has been halted,
there is a lot more to do to reverse the decline experienced since the
mid-1970s. Assuming wages continue to rise as fast as they have over
the last 6 years, it would take another 14 years before they would
reach their 1973 value.

77

Real Average Weekly Earnings
320 -

300-

4

280

co/
260-

l

240-

70

65

-75

95

90

85

80

2000

Source: Department of Labor (BLS).

The average monthly unemployment rate in 1999 was 4.2
percent, its lowest rate in 30 years. The-economy created more than
20-million jobs between 1992 and -1999. Most of the new jobs created
(18 million) were in the service sector; 1.8 million new jobs were in
construction. Manufacturing employment grew by-almost 330,000
jobs since 1992, despite a significant loss of jobs over the last two
years due to the loss of export markets and the surge in imports
resulting from the Asian financial crisis.
Unemployment Rates

210
15
5.

.'

Af-an Anvncan
. .. . Total
O

1

1 1 1 1 1 1 I II I

-- I

I

I

I

94
89
84
79
74
69
Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics

78

99

Tight labor market conditions have lifted the job prospects for
minority workers after years of difficulty. The unemployment rate for
African-Americans was 8 percent in 1999, down from a high of more
than 14 percent in 1992. Hispanics have also seen their unemployment rate drop from about 1I Y percent in 1992 to approximately 6Y2
percent in 1999. These are the lowest minority unemployment rates
since the government began tracking them in 1973.
This performance also extends to other labor market measures.
The number of discouraged workers - those who are not actively
seeking employment due to pessimism about their job prospects - fell
from 7 million in 1994 to 4.3 million in January 2000. Discouraged
workers as a percent of all those not in the workforce fell from 10
percent in 1994 to 6 percent in January 2000.
Despite the tight labor market, inflation has remained in check
throughout this entire economic expansion. In 1999, core inflation the change in prices of goods excluding food and energy - was at its
lowest rate since 1965. There is little evidence that the strong
economy has led to increases in broader price levels during 1999 and
early 2000, despite recent increases in energy prices. Energy prices
rose at an annual rate of 34 percent for the 3 months ending February
2000, and the core inflation index increased at an annual rate of only
1.8 percent over the same period. For all of 1999, inflation remained
low, at less than 3 percent, while consumer spending grew by 5Y2
percent. To date, there is no evidence that low unemployment, recent
wage gains and higher consumer spending have put upward pressure
on inflation.
Changes in Consumer Prices
6
5

J3
2
1
86

88

90

92

94

96

98

Source: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Core rate of inflation,
calculated year to year.

79

In recent years, wages have grown faster than the prices of
goods and services. This represents a real improvement in living
standards. In addition, with all the recent advancements in
technology, the quality of most goods has improved. For example, a
19-inch TV cost $439 in 1973. An average person would have had to
work about 2Y/2 weeks in order to afford the TV. Today, a substantially
better quality 19-inch TV costs only $270 and an average person only
has to work a little less that 2 days in order to afford it. The price of
televisions has fallen while their quality has improved, and wage
increases have made televisions even more affordable.
There have also been improvements in the affordability of
food and other basic commodities. For example, a family of four who
lived in San Jose, California paid $100.83 a month in 1983 for a
basket of selected goods and commodities., This was equivalent to a
little over a day's wages. By contrast, this same basket of goods cost
$124.12 in 1997, but because wages grew faster than prices, it took
only a little over half a day's work to afford these goods.
Most of the improvement in consumer purchasing power
occurred in the 1990s. The current expansion has increased job
opportunities for all workers and has halted the slow deterioration in
middle class living standards that occurred in the 1970s and 1980s.
Probably the most important economic development of the
1990s has been the elimination of the federal budget deficit. A
combination of fiscal discipline and robust economic growth has
created two consecutive years of federal budget surpluses after 40
years of continuous deficits. The surplus in 1998 was proof that
policies implemented over the previous 6 years were successful in
reversing the large budget deficits which resulted from Reaganomics.
In the early 1980s, large tax breaks for corporations and
wealthy Americans, coupled with an increase in defense outlays,
resulted in large budget deficits throughout the rest of the 1980s and
into the early 1990s. The deficit reached its post-World War II peak
in 1983, when it accounted for 6 percent of total output. From the late
' The basket includes 4 loaves of bread (one for each week), 4-4 pound
roasts, 4-4 pound chickens, 4 dozen eggs (one dozen per week), 16 pounds of
apples (4 pounds a week), I pound of coffee and 24 gallons of gas (12 gallons
twice a month).

80

1980s until 1992, the economy struggled to overcome the burden of
deficits in an economically stagnant environment. Presidential
leadership and Democratic efforts on the Omnibus Budget
Reconciliation Act of 1993, which no Republicans supported, together
with sound economic growth during the 1990s, resulted in reducing
and finally eliminating the budget deficit by 1998.
Federal Budget Deficits/Surpluses
200
E

0

100 -

0
-00

_

-200
-300
-400
1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000
Source: Office of Management and Budget.

Since 1981, Americans have paid more than $2 trillion in
interest payments accrued on the additional debt incurred between
1981 and 1992. This translates into approximately $500 per man,
woman, and child each year for the last 19 years. The run-up of the
budget deficit during the 1980s placed a heavy burden on Americans,
at a time when their wages were stagnant. The challenge for the future
is not to repeat the mistakes of the early 1980s, but to maintain fiscal
discipline and promote greater investment and economic growth.
What is fueling the expansion?
The most important factor in understanding recent
improvements in wages and salaries is the increase in productivity
growth rates. Higher productivity growth makes it possible for wages
to grow while maintaining low rates of unemployment with little or no
inflation. In order to be most beneficial to workers, productivity
growth should reflect real improvements in output and wages, not just
firms laying off workers. Thus, the challenge is to achieve both high
81

rates of productivity growth and low rates of unemployment
simultaneously. This is currently the case in the US economy.
Between 1973 and 1995, the average annual rate of
productivity growth was an anemic 1.4 percent per year. At the same
time, real average weekly wages declined by 1percent a year. In
contrast, since 1995, average annual productivity growth has doubled,
while the unemployment rate has fallen, and real average wages have
grown by more than I1'Apercent per year.
This impressive growth in productivity raises several
questions. Most importantly, are we experiencing a long-term shift in

Labor Productivity

120O 1100

04 100
0)

1.4 percetaveragegrawth

1973-1995

90
'

2.9perce averagegrowth
1995-1999

80 -

70
1973

1989

1981

1997

Sources: Department of Commerce (Bureau of Economic Analysis) and Department of
Labor (BLS).

productivity growth rates or is it just a one-time phenomenon? How
much of the improvement in productivity is attributable to recent
advances in technology? How much of the improvement is due to
cyclical factors?
In its recent Annual Report to the President, the Council of
Economic Advisors highlights the fact that current productivity
growth rates are unusually strong this far into an economic expansion.
Historically, productivity tends to surge during an economic
slowdown, as firms lay off workers and cut costs, and tends to remain
high during the early stages of a recovery, before declining. The
continued surge in productivity growth this far into the economic
82

expansion suggests that the recent improvement is not all due to
cyclical factors. At the Joint Economic Committee's High-Tech
Summit held last summer, Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan, as well as
CEOs of IBM, Intel, Microsoft, the President of MIT, and the
President of the Communications Workers of America, all testified
that recent advancements in technology have contributed to this
improvement in productivity. These experts also suggested that we
are at the beginning of these technological advances, and that further
improvements can be expected for many years to come.
Recent improvements in productivity growth have followed an
unprecedented increase in investment in new technologies, especially
computers and information technology. Between 1981 and 1993, nonresidential fixed investment fell from 13 percent of GDP to less than
10 percent. The last time the rate of investment was that low was in
1964. The fall in investment throughout the 1980s and the early 1990s
helps explain the low productivity growth during that period. Between
1993 and 1999, non-residential fixed investment rose from less than
10 percent to almost 14 percent of GDP. Between 1991 and 1998,
total investment grew more than 3 times faster than GDP, and more
than twice as much as in the 1980s. The steep growth in investment
over such a short period of time is unprecedented and is fueling the
current economic expansion.
In addition to a significant increase in the amount of
productive investment, there has been a shift in the composition of
investment. In 1960, investment in structures - such as the bricks and
mortar of factories - accounted for 60 percent of non-residential fixed
investment, while equipment - such as machinery and computer
software - accounted for the remaining 40 percent. The rapid growth
of investment in equipment - especially computer software - over

the last 40 years has resulted in a reversal of that relationship. Since
1993, investment in information processing equipment and software
has grown at an average annual rate of 19 percent. By 1999,
equipment and software comprised 80 percent and structures
comprised only 20 percent of non-residential fixed investment.
Improvements in the quantity and quality of investment are
critical to expanding the productive capacity - or the supply-side - of

the economy. This pick-up in investment can be traced to efforts by
President Clinton and Democrats in Congress over the last few years
to reduce the budget deficit, thereby freeing up capital and making it

83
63-597 00 -4

Investment

I4-

1210.-:--.-.-.
...E-.:
.

8 L-

]~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
.. .....:...I

&Sfwr
Je~~~~~~....... Equment
..
::

~.

-:.
...:-----. :-.
E: :E
...
...
:.

.-:--.-,-:.

ii
... .. . ...iR|

22

....

-

1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Source: Department of Conunerce, Bureau of Econonic Analysis.

available for productivity-enhancing investments in the economy. The
economic expansion of the 1990s has been primarily fueled by
increases in investment, rather than by increases in government
spending, as in the 1980s. In fact, government spending as a percent
of GDP has declined during the current expansion, and currently
stands at less than 18 percent of GDP, its lowest rate since 1967.
Reducing the budget deficit enabled monetary policy to be
more accommodating, allowing interest rates to fall. This helped
contribute to a positive environment for investment, particularly in
information technology (IT) equipment and software. Developmentsin the IT sector were at a stage where massive inflows of capital could
be absorbed. This increase in investment led to major advances in
technology, which in turn contributed to a significant improvement in
productivity growth. As a consequence, wages and salaries rose after
20 years of decline and stagnation without igniting inflation. This
chain of events, which occurred during the 1990s, represents a true
expansion of the supply-side of the economy.
There is much to celebrate in the current economic expansion.
Today, more people are working at higher wages than anytime in the
past 20 years. Low inflation and high productivity growth have
contributed to real improvements in living standards for most
Americans. But the benefits of this prosperity have not yet been
shared equally by everyone. In fact, some Americans have yet to see
significant change in their economic situation.
84

What should be done to maintain the current expansion?
If anything has been learned over the last 7 years in terms of
economic policy, it is how important eliminating the budget deficit has
been for stimulating private investment, raising wages for American
workers and keeping inflation low. Looking forward, it is crucial to
maintain the fiscal discipline practiced by the Clinton Administration
and the Democrats in Congress since 1993.
The last 20 years provide sufficient evidence to analyze the
consequences of economic policies. The key is to learn from our
experiences and avoid making the same mistakes we made in the past.
The simple fact is that the Reagan "supply-side revolution"
was a complete disaster. While a few got rich, the vast majority of
Americans suffered as the country was saddled with an enormous
debt, which working families are still paying off.
As a consequence of the 1981 tax cut, tax receipts not only did
not rise, as the advocates promised, but rather they fell from 19
percent of GDP in 1980 to approximately 17Y/2 percent between 1983
and 1986. Government outlays, which included draconian cuts in
social programs in order to pay for the large build up in defense
spending, stood at approximately 22Y/2 percent of GDP throughout the
period. The results were budget deficits for "as far as the eye could
see."
These ballooning budget deficits placed, and continue to
place, a burden on American workers and caused the federal debt to
triple between 1981 and 1992. Since 1981, American workers have
paid approximately $2 trillion in interest on the additional debt, to
finance the so-called "supply-side experiment" of the 1980s.
The great irony is that the Reagan Administration's so-called
"supply-side experiment" was nothing more than a Keynesian expansion of consumer demand, without any improvement in investment. In
fact, the "supply-side" policies of the 1980s actually hurt the exact
investment they were intended to encourage. Despite these tax cuts, or
may be because of them, investment in plant and equipment remained
flat, at less than 10 percent of GDP, from 1980 to 1992.
The only difference between the Keynesian expansion in the
1980s and others, was that this one was accompanied by a real decline
85

in living standards of American workers. Workers watched the
purchasing power of their paychecks fall 7 percent between 1980 and
1992. In addition, the 1981 tax cuts - which favored the wealthy contributed to a considerable worsening in income inequality.
The last 7 years have been an excellent example of how to
expand the supply-side of the economy. Consider the record: Since
1992, investment in plant and equipment has grown from less than 9
percent of GDP to almost 14 percent of GDP last year. Productivity
growth rates, which averaged 1/2 percent annually between 1973 and
1995, have been closer to 3 percent annually since 1995. Recently, the
Commerce Department revised upward its estimate of productivity
growth in the non-farm sector to 6.4 percent in the fourth quarter of
1999. The size of the revision alone was greater than average
productivity growth rates during most of the 1970s and 1980s.
Higher productivity growth enables wages to rise without
igniting inflation. As productivity grew over the last 7 years, real
average weekly wages rose by 6 percent. The unemployment rate fell
and now stands at 4.2 percent. There are no signs of renewed inflation
due to the wage gains. There is much to celebrate in this economy, but
there is still a lot which needs to be done to make up for the declines
in living standards due to the supply-side experiment of the 1980s.
One of the most important lessons of the last 20 years is that
the best way to increase tax revenues is simply to grow the supply-side
of the economy - as the nation has been doing since 1993, not by
drastically cutting tax rates, which was done in the 1980s.
The Republicans in Congress seemed not to have learned that
lesson. Their proposed budget for FY 2001 includes a "Bush-lite" tax
cut. It only goes half as far as Governor Bush's proposal, but costs
more than the bloated Republican tax cut proposal for FY 2000, which
the American people clearly rejected.
There are two fundamental things wrong with the
Republican's latest tax proposal. First, it benefits the rich and does
not help the vast majority of Americans. Second, the tax cuts, together
with the rest of the proposed budget package, are certain to take the
economy back down the path it took during the 1980s, which caused
real economic hardship on workers and their families.

86

In addition to the large tax cuts, the Republican budget calls
for increases in defense spending, and drastic reductions to nondefense discretionary spending. This precise mix of policies brought
us the record budget deficits of the 1980s, which contributed to a
decline in living standards for the vast majority of Americans.
The Republican budget calls for increasing defense spending
by $17 2billion above the caps, which is even more than the
Administration's request. According to the Children's Defense Fund,
just this additional spending alone would be enough to:
*

Provide Head Start to 1.7 million additional children; and

*

Provide child care to more than 8 million additional children;
and

*

Provide 21' Century After-School programs for close to 35
million additional children.

The Republican budget cuts non-defense discretionary
spending by 6 percent or $114 billion over 5 years. If this budget is
enacted, it will mean, among other program cuts:
*

Dropping 310,000 low-income women off of the Women,
Infant and Children program (WIC), just next year;

*

Denying child care to over 12,000 children in 2001;

*

Eliminating Head Start services for more than 40,000 children
and their families by 2005; and

*

Cutting off energy assistance to 164,000 low-income families
next year, precisely at the same time rising oil prices are
hurting families.

The nation should not return to the failed policies of the past,
which would certainly jeopardize the recent unprecedented prosperity.
Instead, Congress and the President should maintain fiscal discipline,
and focus on addressing some of the major economic problems
affecting American workers and their families which have been put off
for at least 20 years. Now is the time to begin solving these problems.

87

II. The Widening Income Gap
Although it has taken some time to achieve, average beforetax income is now beginning to grow for Americans in all income
groups, not just for the wealthy. Yet after-tax incomes have not
performed as well. Overall, the income gap between the wealthy and
the rest of Americans continues to widen.
Before-Tax Family Income
Over the past 20 years, real average income for the wealthiest
20 percent of families (the top quintile) grew, while real average
income for the poorest 20 percent of families (the lowest quintile)
remained fairly flat. Real average income for those in the lowest
quintile began rising in 1993 and by 1998 returned to its 1978 level.
Real Average Income by Quintile
$140

-

$120

-

$100

-

$127.529
$108,671

M~s~

E

$91211

0o ;
U l
D a

aA
o*
0
V

$80 +'
$80

-,

-

_

4,aS

$40 -4
$20 -4
So -,

l$92i

$8973

1980

1990
Year

Source: US Census Bureau, Income Statistics Branch, from Detailed Historical Income
and Poverty Tables, Table H-3, revised May 24, 1999.

Although it is heartening to see that the current economic
expansion has finally begun to raise the incomes of those people in the
lowest quintile, they are still trailing the rest of the country in sharing
the benefits of the current prosperity. In 1980, the average income of
the wealthiest 20 percent of families was 10 times higher than that of
88

the poorest 20 percent. By 1998, the wealthiest families earned 14
times as much as the poorest. The primary reason for this widening
gap is the incredible growth in the average income of the wealthy.
Although average income in each quintile has improved since 1993,
the average income of the wealthiest families has grown much faster.
In other words, the income gap continues to widen despite income
improvements in each quintile.
Income Ratio of Wealthiest to Poorest
Families
1980 to 1998
16

14 0
'I

12

10

8
1980

1985

1990

1995

Years
Source: US Census Bureau, Income and Statistics Branch, from Detailed Historical
Income and Poverty Tables, Table H-3, revised May 23, 1999.

After-Tax Household Income
A recent study, based on data from the Congressional Budget
Office (CBO), analyzes trends in after-tax income.2 After adjusting for
taxes (and the Earned Income Tax Credit), the top 20 percent of US
households experienced a 43 percent increase in average income from
1977 to 1999, while the average income of the lowest 20 percent
experienced a 9 percent decline. Recent improvements in income,

"The Widening Income Gulf," The Center on Budget and Policy Priorities,
Washington, DC: 1999. The CBO data begin in 1977 and end with
projections for 1999.
2

89

although welcomed, have been too limited to have much impact on
narrowing the income gap thus far.
The study also reports that:
*

The increase in income of the top one percent of families from
1977 to 1999 equaled the total income of the lowest 20
percent in 1999.

*

The richest one percent of Americans - 2.7 million people
took home as much after-tax income as the lowest 38
percent - or 100 million people - combined.

*

In 1977, the top one percent of Americans received a little
more than 7 percent of all national after-tax income. By 1999
this concentration had almost doubled, as the top one percent
of Americans received almost 13 percent of total national
after-tax income.

*

On average, the richest one percent of households are
expected to pay a smaller percentage of their 1999 income in
taxes than they would have under 1977 tax rates. This
amounts to an average saving of $40,000 per household.

The foundations for this disparity were laid in the 1980s.
Most of the large income growth for the top quintile occurred from
1977 to 1989, when their average after-tax income increased by 33
percent, compared to a 7 percent increase from 1989 to 1999.
Comparing the increase in income before taxes to the increase
after taxes for the wealthiest Americans illustrates the perverse impact
of federal tax policy over the last 20 years. For the top one percent of
households, average after-tax income grew by 20 percentage points
more than average before-tax income between 1977 and 1999. Yet,
meanwhile, average after-tax income for the poorest fifth of
households declined over this same period. In contrast to
conventional wisdom, the US tax system is redistributing income from
the poor to the rich.

90

State income data reveal that the widening income gap is
prevalent across the entire country. One recent study shows that the
income gap has widened in almost every state since the 1970s.'
Specifically:
Over the last decade, the gap between the wealthiest 20
percent and the poorest 20 percent of Americans widened in
34 states, and was reduced in only 3 states - Alaska,
Louisiana, and Tennessee.
Changes in the Income Gap* by State
from 1988-90 to 1996-98

EIco-

Gap Inirovad (shra*)

(3)

QNoSigniffca tChange
(13)
* bkcom Gap Worsened (-88860ed(34)
'Defbied as the differnebetwenthe average ,comeof thepooes endrchust

20 pecn of families.
Source: "Pulling Apart," Center on Budget and Policy Priorities.

The real income of the poorest 20 percent of families declined
in 18 states between the late 1970s and the late 1990s. In 6 of
those states, the decline was over $2,000 per family (in 1997
dollars).

"Pulling Apart: A State by State Analysis of Income Trends", Center on
Budget and Policy Priorities and the Economic Policy Institute, Washington,
DC: 2000.
3

91

By the late 1990s, the wealthiest 20 percent of families in
every state had a larger share of the state's total income than
they had in the late 1970s. Meanwhile, in 47 states, the share
of total income held by the poorest 20 percent of families
declinedby the late 1990s.
Change In Average Income of the
Poorest Families

Increased

/
_

2 States

20 States

I

Declined

No
Significant
Change
Source: "Pulling Apart," Center on Budget and Policy Priorities.

*

In 24 states, the wealthiest 20 percent of families had more
than 91/2 times as much income as the poorest 20 percent of
families. In the late 1970s, not a single state had such a high
"top-to-bottom" ratio.

*

The gap between the average income of all middle-income
families and the top 20 percent grew in 45 of the 50 states
from the late 1970s to the late 1990s.
Between 1991 and 1993

-

the "Bush Recovery" - average

real income for those families in the 4 out of 5 income groups
declined. By contrast, between 1993 and 1996 - the "Clinton
Recovery" - average real income for all families, regardless of income
group, improved.4

Klein, Bruce, "The 1990s Economic Expansion: Who Gained the Most,"
Report Prepared for the Democratic Members of the Joint Economic
Committee, Washington, DC: 1998.
4

92

The widening gap can be explained by strong growth in the
upper income group and a weakening in the safety net for the lower
income group. Even as the income gap has widened, there has been an
erosion in the mechanisms originally designed to help lower income
people, particularly as real value of the minimum wage has declined
and limitations on assistance resulting from welfare reform have
increased.
What should be done to close the income gap?
On the basis of national averages, the US economy is robust.
But national averages camouflage how individuals are fairing. It is
ironic that the income gap continues to widen as the economy
prospers. Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan has raised the
widening income gap as one of the most serious problems currently
facing the nation, yet the Federal Reserve's recent decisions to raise
interest rates are likely to worsen the situation. Economic policy
should be aimed at redistributing income from the wealthy to the less
fortunate. These policies should be specifically targeted at raising
incomes for the vast majority of Americans, not just for the wealthy.
At a minimum, the policies should stem any further erosion in
incomes of those at the lower end of the income scale. Policies such
as raising the minimum wage, establishing living wages, increasing
health insur-ance coverage, providing prescription drug coverage for
seniors, and improving education can all contribute to narrowing the
income gap.

93

III. The Erosion of the Minimum Wage
One of the most important public policy tools aimed at raising
living standards for low-income Americans is the federal minimum
wage. Instituted in 1938, the minimum wage was established to help
ensure "maintenance of the minimum standard of living necessary for
health, efficiency, and general well-being of workers." In 1999, 7.2
million people, or 5Y2 percent of workers - two-thirds of whom were
25 years and older - worked at the minimum wage, which is currently
set at $5.15 an hour.
Most employees receiving the federal minimum wage work in
fast food restaurants, retail establishments, and lower-skilled service
jobs (such as commercial housekeeping). More than half of those
workers earning the minimum wage are employed in retail trade.
Another 25 percent of minimum wage workers are employed in
agriculture and 6 percent work in the public sector. Women comprise
almost two-thirds of minimum wage workers and minorities are
disproportionately more likely to earn the minimum wage than others.
Over the last 20 years, the real value of the federal minimum
wage has been falling, despite moderate increases in overall wages and
salaries. Over the last 20 years, the real value of the minimum wage
has fallen by 22 percent and is currently below its real value in the
1960s and 1970s. By contrast, the real average wage for all hourly
workers has declined by 10 percent, or less than half that amount. As
Real Value of the MInimum Wage
7.00

6.50

_

6.00

aX

5.50

q

5.00

1 978: S 6.62

5.5

$5.1 5

\1998:

4.504.00

1978

1982

1986

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

94

1990

1994

1998

a consequence, workers earning the minimum wage have been
experiencing a real decline in their living standards - earning less and
less for the same amount of work, and falling further and further
behind.
Part of the continuous erosion in the minimum wage can be
explained by its legislatively-mandated structure. As currently
structured, the minimum wage can only be adjusted by an act of
Congress. Thus, the minimum wage, by its very nature, is reactive and
is always trying to "catch up" to changes in prices and other wages.
In contrast to earlier times, the minimum wage, at its current
level, does not guarantee a family income above the poverty level.
Despite two increases since 1980, the minimum wage remains below
the level required for a single parent to earn enough to provide the
necessities for themselves and a child.
Working full-time at the minimum wage, an individual would
earn an after-tax income of $10,912.' This figure does not include the
cost of health care, pension and other benefits. This annual income is
below the national poverty rate for a family of one adult and one child
($11,483), one adult and two children ($13,423) and two adults and
two children ($16,895). In order for an adult working full-time to earn
enough to meet the federal poverty guideline for a family of two, the
minimum wage would need to be set at $5.52. For a single parent with
two children, the minimum wage would need to be at least $6.45.
Poverty Income Threshold
1999
Annual

Hourly Wage

Two people: one parent (under
65) and one child

$11,483

$5.52

Three people: one parent and
two children

$13,423

$6.45

Four people: two parents and
two children

$16,895
I_

$8.12
I

5After-tax income is obtained by subtracting the payroll tax and adding back

the Earned Income Tax Credit

95

Critics argue that raising the minimum wage will result in
higher unemployment as employers will have to pay more for their
workers. This fear has proven to be unfounded. Despite the 19961997 increase in the minimum wage, unemployment rates for workers
of all ages and demographic groups fell.
Following the 1996 and 1997 increases in the minimum wage,
the unemployment rates for teenagers and minorities - those groups
most likely affected by the minimum wage - continued to decline.
Between 1996 and 1999, the unemployment rate for teenagers fell
from nearly 17 to 14 percent, the Africa-American unemployment rate
fell from IO/2 to 8 percent and the unemployment rate for all

minorities fell from approximately 9 to 7 percent. Similar patterns
have also occurred in states which have recently raised their minimum
wage above the federal level.
Raising the minimum wage during periods of economic
expansion is likely to erase any potential adverse effects. Stronger
economic growth makes it easier for firms to afford the wage increase.
In addition, the number of workers earning the minimum wage should
be expected to decline as the labor market tightens.
Raising the minimum wage during a period of tight labor
market, which is currently the case, can actually result in higher
employment over the long run. Firms may be more willing to train
their workers, including those receiving the minimum wage, which
will increase their productivity and expand the economy. With this in
mind, President Clinton and the Democrats in Congress strongly
support an increase in the minimum wage.
What should be done to restore the value of the Minimum Wage?
Senator Kennedy and 26 co-sponsors have introduced the Fair
Minimum Wage Act (S 192) which would raise the minimum wage by
$1 over 2 years (from $5.15 to $5.65 and then to $6.15). A companion
bill was introduced in the House of Representatives by Congressman
Bonior and 151 co-sponsors. This increase would bring the real value
of the minimum wage back to its 1979-1980 level. Republicans are
conditioning approval of the increase on tax breaks for the wealthy.
Although raising the minimum wage will not fix all the problems
faced by many lower-income Americans, it does serve as a safety-net.

96

At the very least, the minimum wage should be tied to, and
move with, the federal poverty rate for a family of four. It should also
be linked to inflation. This would eliminate the necessity for
continuous legislative adjustment to maintain its value.

97

IV. Living Wages
States and localities are free to set their "minimum wages"
above the federal minimum wage. Frustrated by the continued erosion
in the real value of the federal minimum wage and the difficulties
associated with raising it, a diverse collection of cities and
municipalities are spearheading local efforts to guarantee workers a
"livable wage" - not an arbitrary wage by one that is calculated to
enable workers to afford basic needs. Full-time workers should be
paid enough to meet basic needs and government should not subsidize,
encourage, or provide incentives to firms to pay below-poverty wages.
The minimum wage, even with the increase currently being
considered, does not provide workers with enough income to keep a
family above the poverty line. Combined with the arduous manner in
which the minimum wage is increased, even to just keep pace with
inflation, it no longer fulfills its original purpose and needs to be
changed.
Cities and Counties With Living Wage Ordinances
and Year Introduced
*Buffalo
Cambridge
Corvallis
Dane County
Hartford
Hayward
Hudson County
Kankakee County
Los Angles County
Madison
Miami-Dade County
Somerville
Tucson
Ypsilanti
Chicago
Cook County
Detroit
Durham
Multnomah County

-A__._f........

NY
MA
OR

1999
1999
1999

WI

1999

CT
CA
NJ

1999
1999
1999

IL

1999

CA
WI
FL
MA
AZ
Ml
IL
IL
Ml
NC
OR

1999
1999

1999
1999
1999
1999
1998
1998
1998
1998
1998

Oakland
Pasadena
San Antonio
San Jose
Boston
Duluth
Los Angles (city)
Minneapolis
New Haven
St. Paul
Jersey City
New York City
Portland
Milwaukee
Santa Clara County
Baltimore
Oakland
Des Moines

CA
CA
TX
CA
MA
MN
CA
MN
CT
MN
NJ
NY
OR
WI
CA
MD
IN
IA

1998
1998
1998
1998
1997
1997
1997
1997
1997
1997
1996
1996
1996
1995
1995
1994
1991
1988

The Living Wage ordinance which fueled much of the current
movement was instituted in Baltimore in 1994. It set a base wage
higher than the minimum wage at the time ($6.60 an hour, increased in
98

two stages to $7.70 in 1999) for workers employed under city service
contracts. By January 2000, Living Wage ordinances had been
enacted in 41 cities or counties nationwide, nearly a third of which (16
cities and 7 counties) had been introduced within the last 2 years.
Most Living Wage ordinances apply to employees working
under municipal contracts (similar to the original Baltimore
ordinance), though several new ones have been expanded to include
businesses that receive subsidies or tax abatements. Each ordinance is
unique to each locality, but all variations cluster around 3 themes: (1)
who is covered/affected; (2) what is the wage/benefit; and (3) how it is
implemented in order to maintain purchasing power. Many ordinances
have exemptions, such as for non-profit organizations and summer
youth programs. Wages range from $6.25 per hour (Des Moines) to
$11.42 per hour in Kankakee County, Illinois (passed in September
1999). Wages under most ordinances are indexed either to a poverty
rate, the inflation rate, or another appropriate index.
Distribution of Basic Wage of Living Wage
Ordinances
1999
E 10

8
e

E

6

IL

172
11

$6.00 -$6.99

$7.00 - $7.99

88.00 - $8.99

$9.00 - $9.99

810.00 +

Hourly Wage Without Benefits
Source: "Living Wage Ordinances as of May 1999," Economic Policy Institute.

Nearly half of the Living Wage ordinances require employers
to provide some sort of health benefit or premium. Eleven Living
Wage laws require an additional $0.75 to $1.50 an hour if health
benefits are not offered (most require an additional $1.25). One
(Jersey City) requires $2,000 a year to pay for benefits, and two
require that the wage be calculated on a higher percent of the federal
99
63-597 00 -5

poverty rate than if benefits were offered. One (Santa Clara County,
California) simply mandates that health benefits be offered.
In addition to instituting a higher wage, policymakers are
debating other mechanisms for assisting low-wage workers to
purchase health coverage as part of Living Wage legislation. These
include a local tax credit for health care similar to the Earned Income
Tax Credit; mandating that the employer contribute funds into a local
or regional health care purchasing entity on behalf of workers; or
contributing additional money directly into a medical insurance and/or
health care expense account.
Essentially, Living Wage ordinances differ from the minimum
wage in that they cover fewer people, mandate wages above the
minimum wage, and include some kind of mechanism for automatic
increases. Research on ordinances already enacted and analysis of
business surveys indicate little adverse affect on employment as a
result of living wage programs.,
Three comprehensive studies analyzed the impact of a Living
Wage ordinance after implementation in Baltimore and Los Angeles.
One study found that no company with a Baltimore city service
contract reduced its staffing in response to the new law. At the same
time, the real cost of city contracts decreasedafter the Living Wage
went into effect, and although the number of bids on each contract
decreased, the decline was statistically insignificant. Another study
examining the law's impact after 2 years, found that it helped a small
number of workers at little additional cost to Baltimore.' Unfortunately, the study also found that many companies did not comply with
the ordinance and that many employees did not see a very noticeable
increase in income, since their work was part-time or seasonal.

In 1999, the Jerome Levy Economics Institute surveyed small businesses to
gauge their response to various levels of a minimum wage. More than threequarters of the respondents replied that their employment practices would not
be affected by a minimum wage increase of up to a total of $6.00 per hour.
Levin-Waldman, Oren, 'The Minimum Wage Can Be Raised: Lessons from
the 1999 Levy Institute Survey of Small Business," PolicyNote Number 6,
6

1999.

"TheEffects of the Living Wage In Baltimore," Economic Policy Institute,
1999.
100

The cost of Living Wage ordinances is relatively small to
business. According to Dr. Robert Pollin, author of Living Wage and
studies of several ordinances, Los Angeles' living wage ($8.64) raised
total costs by up to I1YApercent for the average covered business.
The erosion of the real value of the minimum wage, and the
difficulties in raising it, coupled with the increase in the number of
workers who do not have health insurance and other basic benefits,
make Living Wage ordinances very attractive. These ordinances are a
creative way to address a real problem.
What should be done to expand Living Wage ordinances?
Individual cities and counties should be encouraged to adopt
Living Wage ordinances. Laws already exist which require firms with
federal contracts to pay their employees a wage at least as high as the
prevailing wage for that job (as established by the Department of
Labor). A better option would be to insist that any employee working
on any federal contract be paid at least the minimum required for a
family of three to remain above poverty, or the prevailing wage for
that position, which ever is higher. The Department of Health and
Human Services could also develop a program to facilitate and
partially fund regional and local programs for local health
cooperatives and other experiments in providing health coverage tied
to Living Wage ordinances. Another option is to require employers to
devote $1 an hour for health insurance. Best practices learned from
these experiments should be communicated to other interested cities.

101

V. The Aftermath of Welfare Reform
Welfare reform is another factor adversely affecting the
average income of the poorest families. A key goal of the Personal
Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996 was
to "end the dependence of needy parents on government benefits." In
January 1993, 14.1 million people were on welfare. By March 1999
that figure had fallen to 7.3 million - a 48 percent drop. An August
1999 report by the Council of Economic Advisors attributes nearly 36
percent of that decline to the unusually strong labor market, and 10
percent to the increase in the minimum wage in 1997. This only
explains half of the decline in the welfare rolls. What happened to the
others?
A significant minority of those leaving welfare have
essentially "disappeared" from the official statistics. The 1999 GAO
review of all the broad state studies on former welfare recipients (17
states) found that significant numbers of families could not be located.
Even those studies that used 'administrative data' (matching families
to other records including employment and other public assistance)
missed 8 to 18 percent of families in its count. Researchers are
currently not able to comfortably explain this troubling phenomenon.
Overall, the evidence suggests that many of those people
leaving welfare are working. The Urban Institute found that 61
percent of former welfare recipients were working in 1997, a rate that
was higher than that for similar low-income mothers who were not on
welfare.'
Yet claims of success may be premature. One of the most
troubling early findings is that even among the early group of welfare
leavers - whom many researchers felt would be the easiest to employ
- staying off public assistance has proven to be difficult. The Urban
Institute's survey of those who left welfare during 1995 and 1997
found that 29 percent returned to the welfare rolls. Meanwhile, a
significant portion of those who managed to stay off welfare were
receiving other benefits, such as food stamps and housing assistance.

Loprest, Pamela, "Families Who Left Welfare: Who Are They and How Are
They Doing?" Number 99-01, Urban Institute, Washington, DC: 1999.
8

102

Many researchers have cautioned that the most difficult-toassist welfare recipients remain on welfare rolls and that a notable
slow-down in the decline of welfare recipients should be expected
over the coming years. A 1997 Urban Institute study found that more
than half of welfare recipients in 1991 "experienced a serious form of
at least one potential barrier [to employment]." Although the law does
allow for 20 percent of a state's welfare population to be exempt from
the five year time limit on benefits, this figure can not cover all former
welfare recipients with disabilities, low basic skills, substance abuse,
and domestic violence.
Additional data show that across the nation, the income of the
poorest of the poor is declining again after gains in the mid-i 990s - at
least partially due to the huge drop in the number of welfare recipients.
A recent Center on Budget and Policy Priorities study found that the
average income of the poorest 20 percent of single mothers with
children improved by almost 14 percent between 1993 and 1995, but
declined by almost 7 percent from 1995 to 1997, during which time
welfare reform was being filly implemented.
Many former welfare recipients with jobs earn the minimum
wage or slightly more - not enough for a family of four or even three
to live above the poverty rate. More than half (57 percent) of the
former welfare women surveyed in the Urban Institute study had
family incomes below the federal poverty line. Indeed, 66 percent of
children who had been on welfare lived in families with incomes
below the poverty line.
Another significant problem facing this group is that many
former welfare recipients still can not afford health coverage. The
Urban Institute found that 41 percent of adults and 25 percent of
children who used to be on welfare did not have public or private
health insurance. Understandably, given the high cost of medical care,
families without health coverage are unlikely to be able to remain off
welfare assistance.
Lack of affordable and accessible health coverage is one of the
most significant problems for welfare leavers and low income
families. Another analysis by the Urban Institute found that a year or
9Primus, Wendell, et. al., "The Initial Impacts of Welfare Reform on the
Economic Well-Being of Single Mother Families," Center on Budget and
Policy Priorities, Washington, DC: 1999.
103

more after having left welfare, nearly half of the women (49 percent)
and a third of the children (30 percent) were without health insurance
coverage, despite the fact that the majority of the women were
working.
The longer women were off welfare, the more likely they were
not to have any health insurance. This was partly due to the fact that
transitional health insurance programs for those leaving welfare had
expired. The Family Support Act of 1998 required states to provide
Transitional Medicaid Assistance for six months to all families who
leave welfare because of increased earnings, and another six months of
coverage to those whose family income is 185 percent of the federal
poverty rate or less (after child care expenses). Surprisingly, of those
who left welfare in the preceding six months, 34 percent were
uninsured - even though all should have been offered government
health coverage. The percent of uninsured rises to 49 percent, after
being off welfare for more than a year.
Welfare reform was supposed to encourage economic
independence, but an Urban Institute study found that having a job
does not alone guarantee adequate health coverage. Although more
than half of those who left welfare had a job, one third of these
Health Insurance Coverage for Employed
Former Welfare Recipients
Private
Insurance

32 percent

35 percent

Medicaid
Source: Loprest, Urban Institute.

to Health Affairs, January/February 2000.

104

No
Insurance

working parents remained dependent on Medicaid and another third
had no health insurance at all. In fact, according to another recent
Urban Institute study, only 23 percent of all employed former welfare
recipients received their health coverage from their employer in 1997.
The others, who had some sort of private insurance, were covered by
their spouses' health plan."
Of those children whose custodial parent was employed, 45
percent were dependent on Medicaid or state assistance and 23 percent
had no health coverage at all. Although this compares favorably with
health care coverage for adults, more than 1 in 5 children - whose
parent worked - did not have any health coverage. Despite the
existence of special health care programs for children formerly on
welfare, 41 percent of these children did not have health coverage."2
A significant minority of former welfare recipients had more
difficulty getting enough food and paying utilities than other families
at the same income level. The Urban Institute study of mothers who
left welfare during 1995 to 1997 found that one third had to cut the
Measures of Economic Struggle for Former
Welfare Recipients
50
38.7

.9

5. 40
X

r,

40-

~33.4i,.

30

0

u.

20

7 17

-°>10-

cut or skip meal

difficulty paying
mortgage, rent or
utilities

Source: Urban Institute, Famliks Who Left Welfare, 1999.

Loprest, Pamela, 1999.
12 See

further discussion of CHIP below.
105

had to move In w ith
others

size of a meal or skip a meal because they could not afford food,
compared to only 25 percent of other mothers with similar income
levels. Even more, 39 percent, had difficulty paying mortgage, rent, or
utility bills, versus only 29 percent of other mothers with similar
income levels.
The "success" of welfare reform should not just be measured
by the number of people receiving welfare. Although the number of
welfare recipients may have fallen, many former welfare mothers and
their children are worse off now than when they were on welfare.
Getting people off welfare should not be our sole objective. Welfareleavers must be able to earn enough to provide a basic standard of
living for their families. The apparent loss of health insurance among
those leaving welfare is placing an additional heavy burden on those
people who are already facing severe economic difficulty and on the
hospitals that serve them.
What should be done to assist welfare leavers?
Lack of adequate health coverage is a major problem among
the poor and the working-poor, as it is for all middle-income families.
Instituting universal health care coverage would be the most effective
way to expand coverage to those currently without health insurance.
Universal coverage would eliminate the need to worry about such
things as welfare leavers and their children. It would also address one
of the major factors pushing families into poverty.
In the absence of universal health coverage, other steps should
be taken to ensure adequate coverage for poor families. Enrollment in
Medicaid for at least 6 months should be automatic for families
leaving welfare, without requiring any additional steps, as is currently
the case. Vice-President Gore has proposed extending Medicaid
coverage to parents of children enrolled in the Children's Health
Insurance Program (CHIP).
Additional assistance needs to be provided to those families
who have left welfare, found jobs and are still experiencing economic
hardship. A variety of existing programs can help, along with some
changes in the way welfare is administered. For example, expand the
Earned Income Tax Credit; do not count time spent in training
programs toward the 6 month time limit; increase funds available for
subsidized child care and transportation to work programs; increase
the income limits on welfare enrollment; and expand vocational
106

training opportunities. Other options include, encouraging states to be
more effective in increasing the actual economic well-being of welfare
and former welfare recipients; and expanding the High Performance
Bonus. The Bonus should also include a measure of the rate of Food
Stamp and Medicaid participation as a percent of all those who were
eligible, to ensure that states do not continue to underutilize other
support programs.
For the currently unemployed and former welfare recipients,
programs to improve their employment prospects need to be expanded
to include health care, food stamps, and housing assistance. Programs
should be extended to address the significant barriers to employment
faced by many poor adults, such as alcoholism, domestic violence,
poor education and work skills. Adequate funds should be provided
for outreach. The Children's Defense Fund calls for all parents who
are unable to find a job after the expiration of their welfare benefits, to
be provided with a public job (subject to verification of the
unavailability of private employment).

107

VI. Children's Health Insurance Program
The proportion of children without any health coverage has
been rising since 1992, with the exception of a small decline in 1995.
In 1992, more than 13 percent of all children under 19 had no health
coverage and by 1996 - the year welfare reform was enacted - the
uninsured rate had risen to more than 15 percent. At the same time,
the proportion of children covered by private plans steadily declined
from 71 /2 percent in 1990 to approximately 67 percent in 1995.

Children with No Health Insurance
1990 to 1998
17
Welfar Reform

i

a
C

16

2

15
.C *3
C 14

~~~

_

~~~~ClP Endced

I-1

2

13

0! 0

z

12
11
1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

Year
Source: Smith, "Health Insurance Coverage of Children," CRS, January 12, 2000.

In 1998, almost 12 million children had no health insurance.
Teenagers now make up a disproportionately high percentage of all
uninsured children. Seventeen percent of teenagers under the age of
19 are uninsured, and 15 percent of children between the age of I and
12 are uninsured. About 80 percent of those uninsured kids had a
parent that worked at least part-time. Fifty-eight percent had a parent
that worked full-time year-round but were still without health
coverage.' 3

" Smith, Madeleine, "Health Insurance Coverage of Children,"
Congressional Research Service, January 12, 2000.

108

Uninsured Children by Age Group
1998
20 _5

15

M

10

1-5

6-12

1-18

Age
Source: Kaiser Commission, 1998 Health Insurance Coverage.

One of the main criticisms of welfare reform concerns its
potential negative impact on children in low-income families. Since
income assistance and Medicaid enrollment often occur togther, many
members of Congress were concerned that millions of children would
be without health insurance due to welfare reform. To address this
problem, Congress enacted the State Children's Health Insurance
Program in 1997, referred to as CHIP or S-CHIP.
CHIP is a combined federal-state program, with the federal
government contributing at a higher rate in each state than it does for
Medicaid. CHIP does not guarantee coverage, but encourages states to
expand their Medicaid coverage to include uninsured children. The
program was originally funded for only 5years, with the goal of
enrolling 5 million kids by FY 2002. By June 1999 only about a
million children had enrolled in the program.
CHIP is considerably short of meeting its five-year goal; only
one-fourth of flnds allocated for the program were spent in 1999.
Outreach has been hampered by the fact that only 10 percent of
disbursed funds can be used for administrative costs, which could be
used to promote the program and increase enrollment. There is still a
significant lack of awareness of the program among individuals
109

moving off welfare to a job with no health insurance. Nonetheless,
more must also be done to get individuals discouraged from going on
welfare rolls to enroll their kids in CHIP.
What should be done to expand CHIP participation?
There are a variety of things which should be done to expand
health care coverage of children. First, further improvements are
necessary for CHIP to meet its objectives. Increased administrative
funds need to be allocated so that all states can begin significant
outreach and improved training for providers. Congress should
appropriate additional funds specifically for outreach and staff
training. Alternatively, Congress should expand the portion of state
grants that can be used for this function. States should also continue
to be tracked on their success rates in ensuring that all children are
covered 6 months after leaving welfare. In addition, states should be
encouraged to increase their program coverage. This will likely
require additional federal funds. In February, the Administration
proposed several actions aimed at improving CHIP's implementation,
including allowing school lunch programs to share information with
Medicaid so that a higher proportion of eligible children are enrolled
in both Medicaid and CHIP; expanding the sites authorized to enroll
children; and requiring states to simplify enrollment procedures.
The Medikids program, initially proposed by Representative
Sabo, would address the needs of middle income families who do not
have health coverage for their children. The program would cover
children in families living at up to 3 times the federal poverty level.
With a federal matching grant (75 percent federal share/25 percent
state share) these children would be eligible for an expanded statesponsored Medicaid package or would receive assistance in
purchasing private insurance (most likely at a sliding-scale).

110

VII. The Growing Number of Adults Without
Health Insurances
Forty-four million non-elderly Americans lacked health
insurance in 1998, 6 million more than in 1992, when the current
economic expansion began. Health care coverage continues to
decline, despite economic prosperity.
The US system of health insurance is one of the few in the
world that is structured around the workplace. In recent years, small
businesses have accounted for more than three-quarters of the job
expansion. Yet, between 1996 and 1998, the percentage of small
business employees with employer-sponsored health coverage dropped
from 52 percent to 47 percent. In 1998, only 54 percent of small firms
offered health coverage, down from 59 percent in 1996.
Currently, 70 percent of the uninsured are full-time workers or
dependents of full-time workers.

Access to Employer-Sponsored Health Care
By Wage. 1996
0
-

1000
80

67.00 or Le"

$7.01410.00

610.01-415.00 $15.01 or More

Source: Cooper and Schone, 'More Offers, Fewer Takers for Employment
Based Health Insurance: 1987-1996", Health Affairs (Nov/Dec, 1997)

14 This section relies heavily on three sources: Hewitt Associates for The
Henry J. Kaiser Foundation, "Retiree Health Coverage: Recent Trends and
Employer Perspectives on Future Benefits," October, 1999; The Kaiser
Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured, "Uninsured in America, A Chart
Book," June 1998; The Kaiser Commission on Medicaid and the Uninsured,
"Health Insurance Coverage of Low Wage Workers, " June 1998.

111

A deterioration in health care coverage of low income workers
has further widened the gap between the rich and the poor. Between
1987 and 1996, health insurance coverage rates for low-wage workers
fell from 54 percent to 42 percent while coverage for the highest paid
workers increased from 87 percent to 90 percent. Most recent data
(1996) suggest that only 55 percent of low-wage workers ($7 per hour
or less) have access to job-based coverage, compared to 95 percent of
high-wage workers (earning more than $15 an hour).
In addition, many who have stopped working are dependent on
health coverage received under previous jobs. Employer-provided
health benefits are the leading source of supplemental coverage for
Medicare beneficiaries and the largest source for supplemental
prescription drug coverage. However, employer-based coverage for
retirees is on the decline, with many large companies dropping
coverage and fewer new companies adding it. A number of trends
have surfaced in recent years: fewer large companies offer postretirement health benefits; financial caps are being placed on
employers' contributions; eligibility requirements are being tightened;
and more employers are offering managed care Medicare plans. A
recent study shows that between 1991 and 1998, health coverage
provided by large employers for retirees above the age of 65 declined
by 13 percentage points. For those retirees younger than 65, coverage
declined by 12 percentage points. In addition, the percent of
companies that require retiree contributions rose from 73 percent in
1991 to 92 percent in 1998."
What should be done to improve health care coverage for adults?
The United States is the only advanced industrial society that
does not provide some sort of universal healthcare. In the last year a

number of legislative bills have been introduced in Congress to move
the United States more towards such a system. One bill (HR 2227)

extends COBRA coverage until the age of Medicare eligibility for
individuals who are age 55 or older. Another bill (HR 2228) would
allow middle-income workers aged 55 to 60 to buy into Medicare. If
enacted, this legislation would reduce the number of uninsured by
400,000 Americans. Both of these approaches improve Americans'

15 Hewitt Associates for The Henry J. Kaiser Foundation, "Retiree Health
Coverage: Recent Trends and Employer Perspectives on Future Benefits,"
October, 1999.

112

access to healthcare by either extending government-sponsored plans,
like Medicare, or expanding employer-sponsored plans. Both types of
coverage should be expanded to give all Americans the peace of mind
of knowing that they would be covered should they fall ill.

113

VIII. Prescription Drug Coverage and the High
Cost of Medication
The decline in health care coverage is only part of the problem
facing Americans. Another part of the problem is rising health care
costs. Prescription drug costs are the single largest out-of-pocket
medical expense for seniors, many of whom have moderate incomes.
In 1994 and 1995, 76 percent of seniors had incomes below $30,000
and the average senior paid $558 for prescriptions. This compared to
an average of $355 spent by 55 to 64 year-olds during the same period.
By 1999, spending on outpatient pharmaceuticals had ballooned to
roughly $1,000 per Medicare beneficiary.6
Medicare provides health insurance for 34 million seniors and
5 million disabled persons - virtually everyone 65 and older is insured
by Medicare. Although Medicare provides a broad range of basic
health care services, it does not include coverage of outpatient
prescription drugs. Only one-third of all Medicare beneficiaries in
2000 are estimated to have a consistent prescription drug benefit
through a supplemental plan. Over 13 million of Medicare
beneficiaries do not have prescription drug coverage at all."
Medicare beneficiaries with no supplemental drug coverage
are the hardest hit. They fill one fourth fewer prescriptions than those
with full-time coverage, yet face higher total out-of pocket costs
during the year. In fact, seniors without prescription drug coverage
pay higher prices for medications than any other group. A 1993
survey found that I in 8 seniors reported having to choose between
medicine and food at some point during the year.,

16 Gluck, Michael, "A Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit," The National
Academy of Social Insurance, April 1999.
17 Actuarial Research Corporation for the US Department of Health and
Human Services.

American Pharmacy, October, 1992; HCFA Office of Strategic Planning,
Data from the Current Beneficiary Survey, cited in staff documents, Medicare
Commission; Department of Health and Human Services, unpublished data;
Committee on Government Reform and Oversight, US House of
Representatives, Minority Staff Report, "Prescription Drug Pricing in the
United States: Drug Companies Profit at the Expense of Older Americans,"
October 20, 1998.

114

Since 1980, drug expenditures have grown by double digits,
far more than total health care expenditures. In 1998, drug expenditures grew by more than 15 percent, almost three times the growth of
total national health care expenditures. Most of the growth in drug
expenditures can be traced to a significant increase in volume, mix and
availability. However, as prescription drugs have become more
important to overall health care and new, effective medicines have
become available, people who rely most on prescription drugs - the
elderly and the disabled - have found their access increasingly denied.
The proportion of firms offering retiree health coverage
declined by 25 percent from 1994 to 1998. Medigap premiums for
drugs remain high and increase with age; the value of Medicare
managed care benefits keeps declining; and participation of Medicaid
eligible populations remains low.
At the same time that prescription drug costs are rising and
less people are covered by any kind of insurance, profit rates calculated after expenditures for R&D are removed - for the drug
industry have reached close to 20 percent, four times larger than the
average profit rates for other industries. According to Fortune, the
pharmaceutical industry was the most profitable industry in 1998. The
stock prices of the top pharmaceuticals achieved average annual gains
of 24 percent since 1984, versus almost 15 percent for the S&P 500 as
a whole.
Concerns about rising prescription drug costs, the desire to
enable more seniors to take advantage of new, effective medications,
and arguments that proper use of medications can decrease the
reliance on other, more expensive treatments have led to various
Congressional proposals to incorporate a universal prescription drug
benefit into Medicare. It is difficult to precisely predict all the
potential impacts of the various prescription drug proposals. However,
studies have shown that drugs can be used as effective substitutes for
other kinds of treatment, potentially reducing total health care costs.9
For example, proper use of medications can be expected to decrease
hospital and nursing home costs.> Also, a Medicare drug benefit
provides a means for tracking drug use, thereby reducing adverse drug
interactions. According to the General Accounting Office, Medicaid's
19See

for example, the Employee Benefit Research Institute.

See New EnglandJournalof Medicine, March 4, 1999.
115

automated drug utilization system reduced adverse drug reactions and
saved more than $30 million in 5 states.
What should be done to help people afford prescription drugs?
Twenty-five million Medicare beneficiaries do not have
dependable and affordable outpatient prescription drug coverage.
Americans of all ages look to Medicare for guaranteed coverage as
part of the foundation of their retirement planning.
Accordingly, Representative Stark introduced the "Access to
Prescription Medications in Medicare Act." This legislation meets the
needs of present and future Medicare beneficiaries by offering a
comprehensive drug benefit that restrains ballooning prescription drug
prices. By giving beneficiaries the same marketplace power as others
already insured, the bill tackles the glaring price discrimination that
seniors now are forced to face. It provides a universal Medicare drug
benefit with a $200 deductible and 20 percent coinsurance for seniors
and disabled persons up to $1,700 per year. Medicare beneficiaries
with very high drug expenses will get all of their drug costs paid by
Medicare after $3,000 in annual out-of-pocket spending. This plan
merges cost containment with a voluntary benefit that is universal,
affordable, and also covers catastrophic care.
It appears that the Republicans do not intend to go forward
with meaningful prescription drug legislation this year. On February

16, 2000, Representatives Stark and Shows filed discharge petitions on
the "Access to Prescription Medications in Medicare Act" (HR 1495S
and the "Prescription Drug Fairness for Seniors Act" (HR 664). These
petitions were the only means of forcing the House to address the
crucial issue of affordable access to prescription drugs for seniors and
the disabled. Both petitions call for bringing each of these bills to the
House floor for consideration as soon as possible, without conditions.
Both the Republicans and the pharmaceutical industry are
stalling due to their concern for industry profits. However, a number
of Wall Street analysts have stated that a Medicare drug benefit could
be positive for the pharmaceutical industry, with incremental volume
gains more than offsetting any price pressures. Studies have suggested
that drug utilization increases dramatically when coverage is provide
to the uninsured. In the end, a prescription drug benefit will result in
healthier seniors, higher quality care, a curb in overall medical costs,
and a more profitable pharmaceutical industry.
116

IX. The Social Consequences of Globalization
The US economy has become much more integrated into the
world economy over the last 20 years. Once it was rare for a US firm
to have operations in other countries. Now, these same firms are
probably owned by a group of US and international investors. It is
difficult to determine what constitutes an "American company."
The flow of all goods and services traded between the United
States and the rest of the world currently amounts to more than $2
trillion, double what it was just 10 years ago. More firms are trading
in more countries than ever before. Although there are benefits to this
increased trade, there are also significant social consequences. The
challenge facing the nation is how to participate in this process of
globalization, without hurting workers and the environment, here at
home and abroad.
International trade accents the differences in domestic policies
and practices. One nation's labor and environmental standards can be
considered excessive by some of its trading partners and inadequate by
others. Except for the major industrialized countries, very few other
countries adhere to universally-accepted basic standards on labor
practices, like the prohibition against slave and child labor. Even
fewer countries provide workers the right to organize for independent
trade unions. This raises many questions when two countries, with
different labor standards begin trading with one another.
People and firms in countries with high labor standards may
find it cheaper to import goods from countries with lower labor
standards, rather than produce them at home. In addition, consumers
may not know the labor and environmental conditions under which the
products they buy were made. The net result is that the country with
the higher labor standards loses production and jobs, and there is an
implicit endorsement of the lower labor standards of the other country.
Policies should be pursued which have the opposite outcome increase production and employment here at home and encourage
higher labor standards around the world.
Much of the recent increases in trade, primarily imports into
the United States, come from countries that have low labor standards,
and in fact do not even provide their workers with basic fundamental
rights. As the major promoter of democracy and individual freedom
around the world, the United States should do all that it can to
117

encourage the adoption of higher labor standards abroad, and certainly
should not be engaged in trade that endorses low standards abroad and
displaces good paying jobs in the United States. Trade with low
income countries should not merely exploit their lower wages.
A similar, but more intractable challenge exists concerning the
environment. The production of goods and services depletes resources
- everything from non-renewable resources like oil and coal to
renewable resources like trees. As in the case of labor standards, all
countries have different environmental laws and protections. The
challenge is for the United States to protect its environment, without
jeopardizing the environment in other parts of the world. Currently,
the United States avoids domestic production in order to save its
environment, only to import goods from abroad, thereby harming
another country's environment. The United States should not be
encouraging the abuse of the environment either at home or abroad.
Instead, it should encourage all nations to adhere to high standards to
protect the environment.
What should be done to protect workers and the environment?
As a first step, all countries should be encouraged to adopt the
four intemationally-recognized "core" labor standards developed by
the International Labor Organization (ILO) - freedom from forced
labor, freedom of association and the right to organize and bargain
collectively, the effective abolition of child labor, and
nondiscrimination in employment. Fair and decent labor standards do
not inhibit trade or global economic growth. The growth of the
industrialized economies over the last 50 years is testament to that.
The gains from trade must be better shared with the workers
the goods and services which are traded. All firms should
make
who
pay their workers fair compensation. A firm's success should be
shared with its workers, thereby encouraging them to be more
productive. Trade should not be a "race toward the bottom" that
forces countries to compete on the basis of low wages, poor working
conditions, and disregard for the environment. Work should raise
people out of poverty and provide them with a standard of living
which enables them to provide for the health and welfare of their
families.
It will be more difficult to achieve high and internationally
agreed-upon environmental standards. First, there is no international
118

organization, similar to the ILO, as in the case of labor, to provide a.
forum for countries to develop environmental standards and to help
countries meet those standards. Although there are a lot of
commonalities in terms of environmental protection, each country also
has its unique environmental concerns.
The first thing that needs to be done is to improve
international awareness of the impact of trade on the environment, and
the spill-over of environmental impact in one country on others. The
only way to avoid exploitation of the environment is to develop some
form of internationally-agreed upon standards. It is very important
that these international standards not be the lowest common
denominator. It should be the responsibility of the industrialized
countries - those with the highest standards - to ensure that the

internationally-accepted standards be meaningful in protecting the
environment from further exploitation. In both cases of labor and the
environment, technical assistance should be provided to countries in
need and there needs to be strict monitoring of adherence to the
internationally agreed-upon standards.
International trade should benefit everyone involved and
should not be just a means toward avoiding laws and practices put in
place to protect workers and the environment. In order to meet this
objective, further efforts toward trade liberalization should be
conditioned on the adoption of internationally-recognized labor
standards and environmental protections.

119

X. Digital Divide
Technological advances, which are at the core of the current
economic expansion, have the potential of further widening the gap
between the haves and the have-nots. Most jobs already require that
workers be comfortable using computers and the Internet. As with the
development of other skills, the sooner a person begins learning them,
the higher the probability that he or she will succeed in the workplace.
Recent studies find that computer use and Internet access
correlate very strongly with income and education. According to the
Department of Education, in 1998, 80 percent of households with
incomes above $75,000 had a computer, versus 26 percent for
households earning between $20,000 and $25,000. At the same time,
59 percent of those households with incomes above $75,000 used the
Internet compared to only 20 percent of those households earning
between $20,000 and $25,000.21

Households with a Computer
1998
90

79.9

70

502

o

50

35.2

40
r-

30

*
20 15.9

15.9

25.7
~~~~~~21.2

10~~12

Under
$5,000

5,0009.999

10,00014.999

15.000- 20.00019,999 24.999

25,000- 35,000- 50.000- 75.000+
34,999 49.999 74.999

Household Income
Source: National Telecommunications and Information Administration: 1999.

21

National Telecommunications and Information Administration, Falling

Through the Net: Definine the Digital Divide. Washington, DC: 1999.

120

Computer and Internet use are significantly lower for
minorities, even after controlling for income and education." African
Americans, Native Americans, Pacific Islanders, and Hispanics are all
more likely to access the Internet outside their home, if at all.
The digital divide closes for minorities as their incomes rise over time.
Between 1984 and 1998, African Americans at the highest income
level measured (above $75,000) narrowed the difference between
them and whites in home computer ownership by three-fourths.=
Although nearly all (over 90 percent) schools have some
Internet access with little difference by income and geography, there
are still substantial differences in the quality of Internet accessibility
for students. Schools with a higher proportion of low-income students
have significantlyfewer proportion of classrooms with Internet access.
Classrooms with Internet Access
80

1.1

70

E

60
50
40

0
30
20
0
IL

10
0

111_..~IN
_yo

1994

1996

1998

1999

Years
71 %or more on school lunch

*Ml %or los on school lunch

Source: US Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics, Internet Access in US
Public Schools and Classrooms: 1994-199," Washington, DC: 2000.

According to the Department of Education's survey, schools
with higher concentrations of poverty are more dependent on state and

National Telecommunications and Information Administration (NTIA)
"Factsheet: Racial Divide Continues to Growth," 1999.

22

23

"Factsheet," NTIA.
121

federal support for Internet access than private resources. Forty-eight
percent of schools with the highest concentration of students below
poverty list the state or federal government as primary support instead
of the local school district, compared to 14 percent of the schools with
the lowest poverty rates.
What should be done to increase access to computers and the
Internet?
In addition to improving computer access and learning at
it
school, is vital that all adults have improved access to computers
and the Internet. The Commerce Department finds that Community
Access Centers (CACs), which are schools, community centers and
other places with broad public access, are vitally important to those
who do not have home access to computers. 24 CACs have been
particularly valuable in rural areas and inner city neighborhoods. The
Department also finds that those people with lower incomes and
education, and many unemployed are using the Internet to search for
jobs and take courses. Public access to technology for these groups
may be vital to helping them advance economically, which may also
help narrow the broader income gap.

-

24

1998 Census Bureau data.
122

XI. Vulnerabilities
The current prosperity is not free of potential complications.
The economy faces a number of external and internal factors which
might make it vulnerable to economic slowdown or inflation in the
future. The following section discusses some of those vulnerabilities.
The Stock Market
US financial markets have experienced a considerable run-up
over the last 20 years. In addition, there has been a shift in the kinds
of stocks attracting capital in the private market. The Dow Jones
Industrial index grew by 334 percent between 1980 and 1989, and by
418 percent between 1989 and 1999. The NASDAQ index grew threefold between 1980 and 1989 and nine-fold between 1989 and 1999.
The sustained growth in both markets is unprecedented. There has
also been a shift in investor preference from the traditional companies
listed on the New York Stock Exchange to the young, technology
companies listed on the NASDAQ.
At the same time that stock prices have been soaring, margin
debt has been growing. Margin debt grew by 60 percent -- or almost
$90 billion in 1999. Between September 1999 and February 2000
alone, it jumped by an average of $20 billion per month. Until
recently, the growth of margin debt remained proportional to market
capitalization, but this is no longer the case. Margin debt is running
well ahead of gains in the stock market - a sign that speculation is
Margin Debt Soaring
250 208-

8 166
as_124
82-

40-

Jan. '98

Jan. 99

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

123

Jan. 00

picking up. Heavily-indebted investors are more vulnerable to a
market downturn because they may be forced by margin calls to
unload portions of their portfolio. This, in turn, could further fuel a
downturn, setting off a self-feeding downward spiral. The Federal
Reserve has not responded to these early signs of excess speculation,
but could consider raising margin requirements in order to stem a
further build-up in debt.
Oil Prices
In recent months, there has been a significant increase in oil
prices. An improving worldwide economy and output cuts by
members of the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC) in 1999 have sent prices soaring. Oil prices have almost
tripled in the last year, fueling fears of inflation for the overall
economy. Heating bills have escalated, especially in the northeastern
part of the United States, and average gas prices have increased 40
percent in the last year around the country.
The current oil price, although high, remains considerably
Oil Prices

30 -

25 -d

s

<

~20
115

io
51992

1996

2000

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

lower than its price of $38 a barrel in 1980. However, oil inventories
are extremely low. As oil inventories have decreased, the world
market has become more vulnerable to supply shocks, such as a break
in oil exports from Iraq. In addition, world demand for oil is projected
to increase in 2000, since the world economy is expected to begin
growing once again. This will make it difficult for OPEC to gauge the
124

fine line between maintaining oil inventories and starving the world
economy. The International Energy Agency estimates that OPEC
would need to increase output by nearly 10 percent in order to keep
pace with world demand.
Fortunately, the US economy is no longer as dependent on oil
as it was during the oil shocks of the 1970s. Overall, oil comprised 3
percent of GNP in 1998, down considerably from nearly 9 percent in
1980. However, oil can still be a powerful drag on the industrialized
economies. The Organization of Economic Cooperation and
Development estimates that every $10 rise in the price of a barrel of
oil lifts inflation by half a percentage point and reduces economic
growth by a quarter percentage point. Although a return to the 1970s
era of stagflation is unlikely, any unanticipated supply shock could
fuel inflationary pressures and simultaneously act as a drag on the
economy. In the final analysis, low and stable oil prices are best for
the long-run prospects of the economy.
Cyclical Factors
It has long been understood that economies follow a business
cycle, based on firm profitability. As firms' expectations of the
economy improve, they tend to invest more. The economy
consequently grows, unemployment falls, and wages increase,
squeezing firms' profits. This "profit squeeze" compels firms to cut
back their investments because of lower expected future profits. Less
investment drags down economic growth and chokes off the amount of
capital available to develop new technologies. The economy then
enters a period of economic stagnation.
The US economy has followed this business cycle pretty
closely over the last century. More recently, however, people have
argued that changes in the structure of the US economy have made it
less susceptible to the traditional business cycle. For example, recent
advances in technology have made it possible for firms to maintain
"just-in-time" inventories, thereby avoiding any serious build-up of
inventories, one of the main consequences of the business cycle.
In addition, after 9 years of expanding, the US economy does
not exhibit many of the trends which might indicate a pending slowdown. Productivity growth rates have accelerated during the last
several years, rather than stagnate as in other mature expansions.
Inflation has been falling, not rising, as expected given the long period
125

of low unemployment. While these trends suggest that an economic
down-turn is not imminent, they do not necessarily signal the demise
of the business cycle.
Technological advances, particularly in the area of
information technology, have been at the center of the current
economic expansion. The revolution in information technology has
been compared to the invention of electricity more than 100 years ago.
It remains unclear how long the current technology-induced
investment will continue. In the case of electricity, the subsequent
investment wave began to level off, bringing about an economic
slowdown. It remains too early to know if investment in information
technology will follow that course, or set out a course of its own.
Monetary policy also plays an important role in understanding
the path an economy takes. In the past, as unemployment rates fell,
wages began to rise, igniting fears of inflation. To address these fears,
the Federal Reserve has typically raised interest rates, thereby
tightening the supply of money. Although a restrictive monetary
policy might contain inflation, it can also pull the economy into
recession. Once that occurs, the Federal Reserve might ease monetary
policy in order to get the economy moving again.
The economic expansion of the last 9 years has been
challenging to Chairman Alan Greenspan and his colleagues at the
Federal Reserve. In contrast to previous expansions, there has been no
evidence that wages have grown as a consequence of the historic low
rates of unemployment. This has caused Mr. Greenspan, always
vigilant of inflation lurking around the corner, to call for pre-emptive
increases in interest rates in order to cut-off even the prospect of
inflation. These pre-emptive moves, in and of themselves, risk
causing the economy to slow down even though there are no signs of
inflation.
There are many reasons why the economy might experience a
downturn and, there is no evidence that the current expansion is
immune from some of the internal dynamics that have characterized
similar expansions in the past. Speculation about the death of the
business cycle may be greatly exaggerated. The real risk to continued
prosperity may be the overzealous implementation of monetary policy.

126

International Economic Environment
The strength of the US economy over the last several years has
not been matched in the other industrialized countries. At above 4
percent, the US economy in 1999 grew almost 3 times faster than the
average growth rates in France, Germany, Italy, Japan and the United
Kingdom. Economic growth in Canada was a little less than 4 percent.
Japan, once thought to be the "model economy" grew at less than I /2z
percent in 1999, as it continued to recover from the East Asian
financial crisis of 1997-1998.
Comparing growth rates is not just a contest of economic
superiority. As the US economy becomes more open to the
international economy, growth rates abroad take on increased
significance at home. Exports and imports combined currently
account for about a quarter of the US economy, and are a key factor in
contributing to US economic growth. As foreign economies grow
faster, they tend to buy more imports, providing US exporters with an
opportunity to expand sales in those markets. Conversely, the US
economy has been growing faster than the economies of our major
trading partners, causing US imports from abroad to grow faster than
US exports to foreign markets. This has contributed to the growing
US trade deficit.
The East Asian financial crisis hurt the prospects of US
exports and placed additional pressure on import-competing industries
in the United States. In 1996, prior to the outbreak of the crisis, Japan,
Korea, Singapore and Taiwan together accounted for approximately
one-fifth of all US exports and imports. As a result of the financial
crisis - which caused these economies to slow down and their
currencies to depreciate - US exports to these four countries stagnated
and US imports from them jumped considerably. Between 1996 and
1999, US exports to the four countries fell by 4 percent and US
imports from them grew by 17 percent.
Differential growth rates and the East Asian financial crisis
are just two examples of how important developments in the world
economy are to the strength of the US economy. Over the next several
years, growth rates in Europe and East Asia are expected to recover,
thereby expanding markets for US goods and services. But as these
major economies grow, so too might their exports to the United States.
Thus although international economic conditions may improve, if US

127

imports continue to grow faster than exports, the trade deficit will
continue to worsen.
The ideal is for the international economy to grow at a healthy
but steady pace. In order to achieve this goal, it is important to avoid
economic shocks, such as increases in oil prices mentioned above, or
minimize their impact on the international economy as soon as
possible. Although countries have agreed in principle to meeting this
objective, action has proven more difficult than words.
The Current Account Deficit
In 1999, the US current account deficit, the broadest measure
of US trade in good and services, grew by 54 percent from the
previous year, and reached $339 billion or almost 4 percent of GDP.
The booming US economy, a strong dollar and weak overseas
economies have contributed to a surge in imports and only a moderate
increase in exports. These developments have placed pressure on the
US manufacturing sector in particular. As a result, net manufacturing
employment has fallen by close to a half million jobs since 1997, even
though output has remained stable.

4-

Current Account Deficit As a Share of GDP

3 .2

0-1 I

1980

1990

1999

Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

The Current Account reflects the gap between domestic saving
and investment. In recent years, US investment has been booming and
128

domestic saving has been relatively flat. Despite the elimination of
the federal budget deficit, national saving - traditionally low in the
United States - has not improved, primarily because private saving has
continued to fall. The United States needs to make up this "saving
gap" by borrowing from abroad. Over the last decade foreign
governments, firms and individuals have invested hundreds of billions
of dollars a year in US securities to finance this gap.
During the 1980s, when the federal budget deficit began
ballooning, the United States went from being the world's largest
creditor to the world's largest debtor. Such a dependency on foreign
borrowing makes US financial markets vulnerable to changes in
foreign investor preferences. If foreign investors decide not to
continue to buy dollar-denominated assets, the value of the dollar
could depreciate significantly, making US imports more expensive,
pushing up inflation, and possibly contracting the domestic economy.
In the long-run, the large current account deficit makes the US
economy more vulnerable to external shocks. In the short-run, the
deficit reflects real economic hardship for US workers and their
families. Increased imports and slow export growth have contributed
to further shifts in employment out of high-paying manufacturing jobs
and into service jobs which may be lower-paying and frequently do
not provide benefits. Although the expanding economy makes it
somewhat easier for workers to find new jobs, the adjustment process
still places severe burdens on individuals and their families.
Dislocated workers are sometimes forced to accept permanent income
losses in order to get re-employed. This transition may also entail the
need to move, retrain, lose health care, and pension coverage. Policies
should be implemented to ease the adjustment burden being felt by
these workers, who, by no fault of their own, find themselves under
severe economic pressure.

129

XII. Conclusion
The economy is in its best shape in years, yet some Americans
are still not sharing in the prosperity. There remains quite a lot of
unfinished business to attend to in order to raise living standards of all
Americans, not just for the lucky few.
Despite recent improvements in all income groups, the gap
between the rich and the poor continues to widen. Stemming any
further widening in the income gap, let alone reducing it, does not
necessarily have to mean taking wealth away from the rich. It can be
done by devoting more of the recent economic gains to those people
whose incomes have not been growing as much.
One immediate way to narrow this gap is to strengthen the
safety net for those in lower income groups. First and foremost, the
minimum wage should be raised in order to correct for the 20 year
erosion in its value. The next step is to encourage the adoption of
Living Wage ordinances throughout the country.
Losing or not having health care coverage can be very costly,
and can throw families into poverty. Health care coverage should be
extended to all those who need it, and the delivery of health care
services should be improved. In particular, more needs to be done to
insure that all children are covered by health care insurance.
Prescription medication is becoming one of the most
expensive elements of health care, and its cost is expected to continue
rising in the future. Congress should expand Medicare to include
prescription drug coverage for all seniors and disabled people, those
who face the heaviest burden of rising medication costs.
The United States is experiencing an unprecedented period of
economic prosperity. Unemployment is at a historic low and there are
no signs of a resurgence of inflation. But as good as this story is, it is
not complete. Economic prosperity has not yet come to millions in
our society, and for most it has come following a period of prolonged
economic stagnation. The challenge before the nation is to both ensure
the continuation of this economic prosperity and to aim at sharing its
benefits more widely with all Americans.

130
0