View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

POSTWAR ECONOMIC STUDIES
No. 7, September 1947

INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY POLICIES

LLOYD A. METZLER
ROBERT TRIFFIN
GOTTFRIED HABERLER

BOARD OF GOVERNORS
OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
WASHINGTON




Published October 1947

CONTENTS
PAGE

PREFACE

Inside Front Cover

EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY
FUND
LLOYD A. METZLER
Methods of Setting Exchange Rates
Exchange Rates after the First World War
Exchange Rates after the Second World W7ar
Movements of Currency Values since 1937
General Survey
The Countries Occupied by Germany
The Prewar Sterling Area
The Latin American Countries
Summary of Exchange Rate Movements
Exchange Rates and Prices
The Purchasing Power Parity Theory
Criticisms of Purchasing Power Parity
Parity Rates in Peace and in War
Parity Rates Based upon Wholesale and Retail Prices
Multilateral and Bilateral Comparisons
The Policy of the International Monetary Fund
Alternatives Which Faced the Fund
Reasons for Accepting Current Rates
Dangers of Postponing Action
The "Undervalued'' Currencies
Conclusions
Appendix Tables

1
1
1
3
5
5
7
9
11
14
16
16
18
22
24
28
30
30
31
36
38
42
44

NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL
ECONOMY

ROBERT TRIPFIN

Central Banking and the Gold Standard
The Correction of International Disequilibria
Cyclical vs. Fundamental Maladjustments
Gold Standard or Sterling Exchange Standard?
A Positive Policy for the International Monetary Fund
Anti-cyclical Monetary Policies
Fundamental Readjustments
Conclusion




iii

46

48
55
55
58
63
63
75
79

CONTENTS
PAGE

COMMENTS ON "NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY"
GOTTFRIED HABERLER

82

Pure and Mixed Gold Standards
Bank Rate and the British Balance of Payments
Cyclical and Fundamental Maladjustments in the Balance of
Payments
How to Deal with Balance of Payments Maladjustments in Depressions
"Exchange Control"
Fundamental Disequilibrium
A Tentative Reformulation

82
87




iv

88
90
92
97
99

EXCHANGE RATES AND T H E INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY FUND
by
LLOYD A. METZLER1

Formerly of Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
The International Monetary Fund, conceived at Bretton Woods in
1944, commenced operations on March 1, 1947, after having negotiated
with member countries an initial pattern of international exchange rates.
These negotiations, which proceeded within an agreed framework laid
down in the Fund's Articles of Agreement, represented a marked advance
over previous attempts at securing coordinated action in the international
monetary field. It is the purpose of this paper to assess the results of this
new procedure in the highly important and complex field of exchange
relations.
METHODS OF SETTING EXCHANGE RATES

Exchange Rates after the First World War. A major factor in the international economic disturbances and frictions which followed the First
World War was the unbalanced condition of exchange rates. During the
war years and in the period immediately following the war, most currencies were divorced from gold, and since exchange controls had to a considerable extent been abandoned at the close of the war, exchange rates
were subject to substantial fluctuations. These exchange fluctuations created opportunities for speculative capital movements which frequently
tended further to upset the balance. As a result, in many countries the
actual exchange rates differed widely from those which would have provided a balanced condition between the supply and demand for foreign
exchange. When the important trading nations finally stabilized their
exchange rates by returning to the gold standard, no systematic attempt
was made to remove the discrepancies which had developed. Instead, each
individual country simply resumed the purchase and sale of gold at a price
1

A number of people assisted in preparing this paper. Miss Florence Jaffy of the Division
of Research and Statistics of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System compiled
the parity estimates. Miss Leila N. Small of the Institute for International Studies at Yale
University lent helpful assistance throughout the preparation of the paper. The final manuscript was read and criticized by Mr. Walter R. Gardner of the International Monetary Fund
and Mr. J. Burke Knapp, Assistant Director of the Division of Research and Statistics of
the Board of Governors. The author wishes to thank all of these people without implicating
any of them.




1

2

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

which was determined, for the most part, by unilateral action. Too much
attention was paid in this process to the superficial aspects of the gold
standard, such as the commitment of each country to redeem its currency
in gold, and too little attention was paid to the more fundamental fact
that the gold standard is a means of establishing or stabilizing the relative
values of different currencies in international trade.
The results of the unilateral and haphazard return to the gold standard
after the first war are well known and need not be repeated in detail
here. 2 I t is now generally recognized that the relative values at which a
number of currencies were stabilized failed to reflect the movements of
prices and other economic disturbances which had been brought about by
war. Perhaps the most conspicuous of these discrepancies was the overvaluation of the pound sterling. When the United Kingdom made the
pound sterling convertible in 1925, the prewar rate of exchange between
the pound and the dollar— approximately $4.87—was re-established. Since
prices and costs had increased more in the United Kingdom than in the
United States, and since a number of the most important British export
trades, such as coal and textiles, were meeting increased competition from
other sources, the prewar value of the pound was no longer appropriate.
A lower price for the pound, in other words, would have contributed to
equalizing Britain's supply of foreign exchange with her demand. In the
long run the effects of overvaluation of the pound might have been offset
by a vigorous attack upon the cost structure through rationalization and
modernization of British industries. But this is a time-consuming process
which could not solve the immediate problems confronting the British
exporters at the time Britain returned to the gold standard. In any
event, the rationalizing and modernizing of industry did not proceed
rapidly enough to avoid a serious depression during the twenties in the
British export trades.
The difficulties confronting the United Kingdom as a result of the
initial stabilization of the pound were subsequently aggravated by the
stabilization of the French franc at a price which, from some points of
view, appeared to be too low. In the case of the French franc, the problem
of returning to the gold standard was complicated by speculative capital
movements. Prices and costs had increased so much both during the war
and in the postwar years that a return to the old parities between the
2
See League of Nations, International Currency Experience: Lessons of the Interwar Period
(1944), Chap. I.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

3

franc and other currencies was clearly out of the question. The external
value of the franc of course declined as prices increased within the country. Moreover, since the period of postwar inflation in France was also a
period in which large holdings of money assets were being transferred from
Paris to London and other financial centers, the depreciation of the franc
was considerably greater than the relative decline in its purchasing power.
Between November 1918 and July 1926 the price of the franc in American
currency declined from 18.37 cents to 2.47 cents. Later, when internal
financial conditions in France had improved, a repatriation of French
capital occurred, and the franc accordingly increased in value. When the
French currency was finally stabilized in 1926 and 1927, however, the
price of the franc in terms of either dollars or pounds sterling was somewhat low relative to its purchasing power in France. Thus France became
a cheap market in which to buy, while the United Kindom became a
relatively expensive market.
Similar mistakes were made in other countries, but their effects upon
world trade and finance were less important than the effects of the return
to the gold standard in France and the United Kingdom. All of this is well
known and would not need to be repeated here except for the bearing
which it has on the problem of exchange rates in the present period of
readjustment. As a result of the planless manner in which exchange rates
were stabilized after the First World War, the balances of payments of
many countries were subjected to continuous stresses and strains throughout most of the decade of the twenties and in the early thirties. While some
of these disturbances were an inevitable consequence of the war, many of
them could have been avoided by a more systematic approach to the
problem of postwar exchange rates.
Exchange Rates after the Second World War. The plan evolved at
Bretton Woods for setting initial exchange rates, and for subsequent
adjustments in exchange rates through the International Monetary Fund,
offers a striking contrast to the stabilization of currencies after the First
World War. Whether the contrast in final results will be as striking as the
contrast in method of approach, however, depends almost entirely upon
how the new international monetary organization is administered, and
upon the cooperation which the Fund receives from member countries.
Unlike the unilateral and uncoordinated stabilization of currencies during the twenties, the plan set out in the Articles of Agreement of the Fund
created an opportunity for establishing relative exchange rates by mutual




4

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

agreement among the members of the Fund. The Fund Agreement provided that unless either the Fund or the member country concerned objected, the initial exchange rate at which the Fund commenced operations
in a particular currency should be the rate prevailing 60 days before the
Agreement went into effect. If either the member country concerned or
the Fund regarded the rate prevailing on that date as unsatisfactory,
however, a different rate was to be established by agreement between the
member and the Fund. The feature of this procedure which distinguishes
it from the stabilizing procedure adopted after the First World War is
the explicit recognition of the fact that exchange rates, or gold parities,
are a matter of international interest and cannot be determined satisfactorily by unilateral action.
In September 1946, Mr. Camille Gutt, the Managing Director of the
Fund, issued a call to all member countries for information concerning
their exchange rates, and after an extended period of study and discussion,
announcement was made in December 1946 of the initial exchange rates
at which the Fund would begin operations. The purpose of the present
paper is to discuss some of the problems which were involved in this
setting of exchange rates, and to describe the approach of the Fund to
solving these problems.
The rates finally agreed upon were, in every case, the rates existing at
the time the Fund made its call for information. In other words, no
changes were made in the existing pattern of exchange rates when the
Fund commenced operations. This does not mean, however, that the Fund
regards all of the present exchange rates as long-run rates, or that it does
not contemplate changes in some of these rates in the future. In their first
report, published in September 1946 before the initial rates were agreed
upon, the Executive Directors of the Fund made a statement on this
question which is so important that it is worth quoting at some length.3
We recognize that in some cases the initial par values that are established may later
be found incompatible with the maintenance of a balanced international payments
position at a high level of domestic economic activity. Because the entire world is in
need of goods, some countries may maintain foreign exchange values for their currencies which are not for the time being a great handicap to the sale of their exports,
but which prove to be too high when production is revived all over the world and the
immediate shortage of import goods is in large part met. Such countries may later
find difficulty in selling sufficient exports to pay for their needed imports. When this
* First Annual Report of the Executive Directors of the International Monetary Fund (Washington, D. C , September 1946), p. 12. Italics added.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

5

occurs, the Fund will be faced with new problems of adjustment and will have to
recognize the unusual circumstances under which the initial par values were determined....

Parts of this statement of policy were later repeated in the Fund's announcement of initial exchange rates. It is evident from the statement
that the Fund has foreseen from the outset that it might be desirable or
necessary to postpone the downward adjustment of some exchange rates.
Reasons for this postponement will be discussed in a later section of
this paper.
MOVEMENTS OF CURRENCY VALUES SINCE 1937
General Survey. How do the initial exchange rates announced by the
Fund compare with rates existing before the war? To give a partial answer
to this question, initial rates for 20 of the member countries are presented
in the table on page 6. Average exchange rates during a prewar "base"
period are also shown in the table. For most countries, the period selected as a prewar base was the nine-month period October 1936 to June
1937. This period was selected because it was relatively close to the war
years but at the same time reasonably free of war influences. If an earlier
period had been used, difficulties would have arisen from the wave of
currency devaluations which occurred in the early thirties and midthirties. If a later period had been used, on the other hand, complications
would have been introduced both by the American depression of 1937-38
and by the effects which the imminence of war had upon foreign exchange
markets. The base period is one of relative exchange stability which followed the Tri-Partite Agreement between the United States, the United
Kingdom, and France. The exchange rates prevailing in this base period
are assumed, in later sections of the present paper, to be more or less
normal prewar rates, but it is probable that in the unstable international
economic situation which prevailed before the war no single period can
be regarded as a completely normal or balanced period. The base period
exchange rates must therefore be accepted with reservations.
With the exceptions of Canada, Cuba, Colombia, Costa Rica, and
Venezuela, the exchange rates at which the Fund commenced operations,
when expressed in American currency, are all lower than the rates in the
prewar base period. The extent of depreciation varies from 71 per cent
in the case of the French franc to only 5 per cent in the case of the Danish
krone. What were the causes of these changes in currency values and how
were they related to war and postwar economic conditions? In order to




6

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

answer these questions, it will be necessary to consider not only the exchange rates which have been announced by the Fund, but also the
present exchange rates of certain member countries for which no rates
have yet been determined, as well as the rates of a number of nonmember
INITIAL EXCHANGE RATES ANNOUNCED BY THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND COMPARED
WITH PREWAR EXCHANGE RATES FOR SELECTED COUNTRIES

(In cents per unit of foreign currency)
Initial rate
announced by Fund

Rate in base period
October 1936-June 19371

2.28
100.00
3.23
57.14
17.81

3.37
100.04
5.17
57.06
2
16.26

Cuba
Czechoslovakia
Denmark
• Egypt
France

100.00
2.00
20.84
413.30
0.84

399 92
3.51
21.91
503.23
4
2.88

India
Iran
Mexico
Netherlands
Norway

30.23
3.10
20.60
37.70
20.15

37.07
6.07
27.75
54.55
24.66

Country

Belgium
Canada
Chile
Colombia
Costa Rica

Peru...
Turkey....
Union of South Africa
United Kingdom. .. .
Venezuela

15.38
35.71
403.00
403.00
29.85

5

25.07
80.00
485.70
490.81
5
26.53

1
Unless otherwise indicated.
2 1936 annual average.
* July-December 1937 average.
* 1938 average.
6 1936-37 average.
SOURCES: Federal Reserve Bulletin, Foreign Commerce Weekly, and Schedule of Exchange Rates issued by the
International Monetary Fund.

countries. Information concerning such rates in both the base period and
the month of December 1946 is presented in the table on page 7.
In comparing the present pattern of exchange rates with the pattern
prevailing in the base period, it is convenient to divide all countries into
three groups: (1) the countries occupied by the German army; (2) the




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

7

countries in the British Commonwealth of Nations, and other countries
such as Sweden and Argentina which followed a policy before the war of
stabilizing the values of their currencies in terms of the pound sterling;
(3) the Latin American countries, exclusive of Argentina. Although this
classification is not exhaustive, a consideration of these three broad groups
will nevertheless serve to indicate the main developments in the movement of exchange rates since 1937.
EXCHANGE RATES OF SELECTED NONMEMBER COUNTRIES AND or MEMBER COUNTRIES FOR
WHICH N O OFFICIAL FUND RATES HAVE BEEN ANNOUNCED

(In cents per unit of foreign currency)
Country

Nonmember countries:
Argentina
Australia*
New Zealand
Sweden
Switzerland
Member countries for which rates have not been
announced:
Brazil
Greece
Italy
Poland
Uruguay

Rate in December
19461

Rate in base period
October 1936-June 1937*

29.77
321.07
322.36
27.82
23.36

32.72
391.08
394.01
25.30
22.90

5.41
0.02
2
0.26
1.00
56.27

6.13
0.90
3
5.26
18.90
4
79.47

1

Unless otherwise indicated.
2 February 1947.
1937 average.
< 1936-37 average.
* Admitted to membership on Aug. 5, 1947, after this analysis had been completed.
SOURCES: Federal Reserve Bulletin and Foreign Commerce Weekly.

1

The Countries Occupied by Germany. Among other countries included
in the tables, Belgium, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, France, the Netherlands, and Norway were occupied by the Germans and their currencies
were cut off from the dollar and sterling markets during most of the war
years. In several instances, the postwar exchange rates of these countries
therefore represented a more or less complete break with the past. When
the period of occupation came to an end, there were no customary or
accepted rates which could be used as a guide to the new dollar and sterling rates for these currencies. Each country had to decide for itself,
perhaps in consultation with other members of the United Nations, what




8

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

its exchange rate would be. As a result of German expenditures in the
occupied countries, prices and costs in most of them had risen during the
war more than they rose in the United States or the United Kingdom, and
largely for this reason the rates at which the former occupied countries
began doing business in dollars and pounds sterling were usually well
below prewar rates.
The movement of dollar exchange rates in these countries since 1937 is
shown in the accompanying chart. The chart reveals a sharp contrast
DOLLAR PRICES OF CURRENCIES
OF FORMERLY OCCUPIED COUNTRIES
PER
CENT
120

PER
CENT
120

AS PER CENT OF AVERAGE PRICES, OCTOBER 1936-JUNE 1937

-\
100

|

X

100

(

i

80

60

{

40

20

/
—

—
••
-—
—
oo

FRANCE
NORWAY
BELGIUM
NETHERLANDS
DENMARK
CZECHOSLOVAKIA

80

y

60

40

20

j
1938

1939

1946

between postwar and prewar rates both with respect to the level of such
rates and with respect to exchange movements. In the period from 1938
to the time of invasion, the dollar rates in most of these countries were
subject to moderate fluctuations, the general tendency being downward.
In the period since the occupation came to an end, on the other hand,
fluctuations in exchange rates have been confined within narrow limits
by means of general exchange controls. The pre-invasion depreciation in
Norway, Denmark, the Netherlands, and France is attributable partly to
capital flights and a general fear psychology, and partly to the depreciation of the pound sterling, which will be discussed later.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

9

The Prewar Sterling Area. Index numbers of dollar exchange rates
for the United Kingdom and Canada, and for two non-British countries
formerly in the sterling area, are shown in the accompanying chart. The
chart covers the period 1938 through 1946. As in the case of the occupied
countries, the inflexible exchange rates of the early postwar period are in
sharp contrast with the exchange fluctuations of the years prior to 1940.
DOLLAR PRICES OF SELECTED CURRENCIES
IN PREWAR STERLING AREA AND CANADA

PER
CENT

110

100

PER
CENT

AS PER CENT OF AVERAGE PRICES, OCTOBER 1936 - JUNE 1937

r

k

^

90

1
li T '

SW EDEN

i

IV]

»/CANADA

"-Hl no
100

V-

y
'

ARGENTINA ^

90

y

\
UNITED Kl NGDOM

80

,

80

y

70

70

60

60
^UV

1938

1940

1
No rates were certified between June 14, 1941, and Feb. 5, 1946. During this period the official Stockholm
selling rate was 4.20 kronor to the dollar (23.8095 cents per krona), as indicated by the thin broken line.
2
Official rate.
3
Beginning March 1940, official rate.
4
From March 1940 through June 1945, official rate.

The most striking feature of exchange movements in the prewar sterling area is the general depreciation which occurred between June 1938
and September 1939. Since the other members of the sterling area had
stabilized their currencies relative to the pound sterling in the period
prior to 1938, the depreciation in the sterling area during the immediate
prewar period may be considered largely in terms of the British currency.
Many reasons have been given for the depreciation of the pound. As with
the countries occupied by Germany, the flight of capital was undoubtedly




10

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

a contributing factor. It seems probable, also, that in the face of this
capital movement the British authorities may have decided to relax the
efforts at stabilization which they had been making through their Exchange Equalization Account. No doubt the depression in the United
States was also partly responsible for the depreciation of sterling. In any
event, the pound sterling depreciated steadily in terms of dollars throughout the second half of 1938. With the outbreak of war in September 1939,
extensive exchange controls were introduced and the pound sterling was
sharply depreciated by the control authorities from more than $4.60 to
$4.03. During the early period of exchange control, a free market in
pounds sterling developed at rates considerably below the official rate,
but by the end of 1940 the free rate was approximately the same as the
official rate, and both the free rate and the official remained stabilized
throughout the war years. After the war, the single rate of $4.03 was
maintained and was accepted as the initial rate for the United Kingdom by
the International Monetary Fund.
The prewar changes in the value of the currencies of other British countries were almost identical with the changes in the pound sterling. With
the exception of Canada, these countries continued to maintain stability
of their currencies relative to the pound sterling, and the dollar prices of
their currencies therefore declined with the fall in the price of sterling.
The Canadian dollar, however, remained close to parity with the U. S.
dollar until the United Kingdom depreciated its currency sharply at the
outbreak of war. Canada then followed part way by depreciating its
currency about 10 per cent relative to the American dollar. Between June
1938 and March 1940, the decline in dollar prices of the currencies of
Australia, India, New Zealand, the Union of South Africa, and the United
Kingdom was approximately 18.5 per cent, whereas the decline in the
price of the Canadian currency in the same period (based upon the official
rate in 1940) was less than lOpercent. Asinthecaseof the pound sterling,
the depreciated rates were subsequently maintained throughout the war
years by means of exchange controls. Except for the Canadian dollar,
which was appreciated to its former parity with the American dollar
during 1946, the fixed rates established during the war were also maintained after the end of the war, and for India and South Africa they are
the official rates of the Monetary Fund.
The non-British members of the sterling area, including Argentina and
the Scandinavian countries, also permitted their currencies to depreciate
during 1938, in conformance with the price of the pound sterling, but when




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY EUND

11

war began and the pound sterling was rapidly depreciated, these countries
followed only to a limited extent and the over-all depreciation of their
currencies between June 1938 and 1940 was therefore somewhat smaller
than the depreciation of the pound. The exchange rates of two of these
countries, Denmark and Norway, have been discussed above in connection with the occupied countries. The other two countries, as the chart
indicates, both had dollar rates at the end of the war which were substantially the same as the rates prevailing in 1940. In the case of Argentina, a slight appreciation occurred in the special export rate in 1944, but
the official rate remained unchanged, and since the end of the war no
alterations have been made in the dollar price of the Argentine peso. In
the case of Sweden, the dollar price of the krona was adjusted upward
in 1946 by more than 15 per cent, and this adjusted rate is the one which
is currently being used.
The Latin American Countries. Movements of Latin American exchange rates are extremely difficult to describe because of the multiple
currency systems which prevail in many of these countries. When the
Argentine rate was discussed above in connection with the sterling area,
movements of the official rate alone were analyzed and the multiplicity
of rates was disregarded. This is a somewhat dangerous procedure, for
Argentina, like many other countries of South and Central America, has
a number of different rates, the particular rate in any given instance
depending upon the use to which the foreign exchange is to be put or on
the source from which it is derived.
There is no need, at this point, to give a detailed description of the
multiple exchange system. Its origin, for the most part, was in the Great
Depression of the thirties, when the rapid and pronounced decline in raw
material and agricultural prices created serious balance of payments problems for the Latin American exporters of such products. For a number of
reasons, many of these countries felt that outright exchange depreciation
would not improve their balances of payments. Depreciation would have
made it possible to reduce the foreign exchange prices of their exports
while maintaining the domestic prices received by producers, but since
their exports consisted largely of products for which the demand was
relatively unresponsive to changes in prices, it was widely believed that
price concessions would reduce rather than increase the amount of foreign
exchange accruing to the Latin American countries. If a 10 per cent reduction in the price of coffee, for example, would have resulted in an in-




12

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

crease of Brazilian exports of only 5 per cent, the amount of foreign exchange derived from coffee sales would obviously have been smaller
after the price reduction than before. This situation was regarded as typical of many Latin American exports, and a reduction in foreign prices,
made possible by currency depreciation, was therefore not considered to
be a solution to the shortage of foreign exchange.
The situation was further complicated, in many countries, by the fact
that substantial amounts of foreign exchange were required by governments to make payments on foreign debts denominated in foreign currencies. Currency depreciation, in such cases, would not have reduced the
demand for foreign exchange but would merely have increased the price
which the Latin American countries had to pay in their own currencies
to service their foreign obligations. While this budgetary problem was
essentially an internal one, there is nevertheless considerable evidence
that it played an important part in the decision of some countries
to adopt measures other than currency depreciation when confronted
with deficits in their balances of payments.
In the end, the balance of payments problems during the depression
were temporarily solved, or postponed, by a widespread adoption of
exchange controls. Foreign exchange acquired by exporters had to be sold
to a central authority, at fixed prices, and importers, in turn, purchased
their needed exchange at rates prescribed by the central authority. Having
become monopolists in their foreign exchange markets, the governments
of many of the Latin American countries found it profitable or desirable
to set up schedules of varying rates for the purchase and sale of foreign
currencies. Although the details of these multiple exchange systems differed considerably from one country to another, certain features were
nevertheless common to almost all of them. Preferential treatment was
accorded, in the first place, to governmental agencies which needed exchange to service their foreign obligations. Dollar or sterling exchange
was usually made available or acquired for this purpose, at the lowest
price in the schedule of rates. Favorable prices were also provided for
importers of commodities which were regarded as necessities, with correspondingly more expensive rates established for luxury imports. A similar
schedule of rates usually prevailed in the purchase of foreign exchange
from exporters. High prices were paid for foreign exchange arising from
the export of products which the government wished to encourage, and
somewhat lower prices were paid for exchange arising from other exports.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

13

Thus, in effect, the Latin American governments frequently depreciated
their currencies for some purposes such as luxury imports and certain
classes of exports, but left the rates at the old levels for other purposes,
such as government debt service and the import of certain necessary
items.
In all this maze of rates it is not feasible to give a brief description of
what happened to the external value of a country's currency in the period
between 1938 and 1946. The best that can be done, in many instances,
DOLLAR PRICES OF SELECTED CURRENCIES IN LATIN AMERICA
PER
CENT

PER
CENT

AS PER CENT OF AVERAGE PRICES, OCTOBER 1936-JUNE 1937

|
100

90

80

|
100

COLOMBIA

90

hK

BRAZIL^
^

H M t M t W

i\

£3 '!

70

Ssaaafifissa*"^

J~'

'""'"'" URUGUAY

—

•

•

_/1
» > < M » M I

&

80

MEXICO

70

60

60

50

50
1938

BeiiimLig April 1939, free rate.
Beginning January 1939, controlled rate. No quotations Sept. 1 through Nov. 28, 1939.

2

is to select one or two rates which seem to be most representative and to
describe the movements of these rates. In following this course, however,
it is well to remember that for many of the Latin American countries no
single exchange rate can possibly represent a complete picture of exchange
developments. Movements of some of the more important exchange
rates for a selected group of Latin American countries are shown in the
accompanying chart. It is apparent from the chart that the prewar exchange movements for the Latin American countries were much less uniform than the movements of sterling area currencies. While the general




14

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

tendency in 1938 and 1939 was a downward adjustment relative to the
dollar, there were exceptions to the tendency, as the line for Colombia indicates. Some Latin American currencies, such as the Uruguayan and Argentine pesos, were clearly influenced by the depreciation of sterling, but the
timing of the downward movement in others is quite out of line with the
depreciation of the British currency. This suggests that other influences,
such as the American depression of 1937 and 1938, may have been responsible for some of the immediate prewar depreciation in the Latin American
currencies.
Like the European exchange rates, the Latin American rates have been
rigidly controlled both during the war years and in the postwar period.
This means, in general, that any depreciation of present dollar prices of
these currencies compared with the dollar rates in the base period October
1936-June 1937 is attributable to the depreciation which occurred prior
to 1941, and cannot be directly ascribed to changes in prices and costs
which occurred during the war.
Summary of Exchange Rate Movements. The description presented
above of exchange rate adjustments since 1937 naturally shows a considerable diversity among countries. Despite this diversity, however, certain more or less general tendencies stand out both in the countries which
are members of the Fund and in nonmember countries. Since these
general tendencies are important in the discussion of postwar exchange
rates, a brief summary may be given here.
For a period of slightly less than one year after the stabilization agreement was made between the United States, the United Kingdom, and
France in 1936, fluctuations in exchange rates remained within relatively
narrow limits. Except for certain Latin American countries and countries
in Eastern Europe, exchange controls were not widespread at this time,
and exchange rate fluctuations were controlled largely by indirect means
such as equalization accounts. Since equalization accounts or stabilization
funds are known to be relatively ineffective against a pronounced and
persistent discrepancy between the supply and demand for foreign exchange, it seems likely that the stability of exchange rates in this period
was indicative of a generally balanced condition in the foreign exchange
markets. This is one of the reasons why the period from October 1936 to
June 1937 was chosen as a base period for the comparison of prewar and
postwar exchange rates.
Beginning in the middle of 1937, the French franc slowly depreciated




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

15

in terms of dollars, and this movement was followed, in the middle of
1938, by a gradual but persistent depreciation of the pound sterling. The
threat of war and the resulting capital flights, as well as the depression in
the United States, were no doubt contributing factors in the depreciation
of both the franc and the pound. After the outbreak of war, the pound
sterling was sharply depreciated to $4.03 (official rate). In France, the
movement was similar; the franc depreciated at irregular intervals until
it had reached a level of approximately 2 cents at the time of the German
invasion. I t was pointed out above that the depreciation of the pound
sterling, and to a lesser extent the depreciation of the French franc, had
far-reaching effects on other exchange rates. Although not all of the currencies of South and Central America shared in the movement, there was
a general tendency for these currencies, like the European currencies, to
fall in value relative to the dollar during the period between 1938 and
1940. The period between 1938 and 1940 was thus a period of fluctuating
exchange rates, the general tendency being a reduction in currency values
relative to the dollar. In most countries, these currency fluctuations were
finally stopped after the outbreak of war by the introduction of exchange
controls, and thereafter the pattern of exchange rates was relatively
stable throughout the war years.
Stability of exchange rates did not end with the end of the war. For the
most part, the exchange controls which were devised in the early war
years have been continued in operation, and exchange fluctuations have
been confined within relatively narrow limits. Except for the Swedish
krona and the Canadian dollar, which were appreciated by official action
in 1946, the present pattern of exchange rates in the sterling countries is
substantially the same as the pattern prevailing in 1940. Similarly, among
the countries of Latin America, present dollar exchange rates are broadly
the same as the rates prevailing in 1940 or 1941, and the stability which
is characteristic of postwar rates in other countries also characterizes the
Latin American rates. This means that the rates announced by the
International Monetary Fund have made allowance for war-induced
changes in international economic conditions only to the extent that the
1940 rates anticipated wartime economic developments.
In the countries occupied by the German army, postwar exchange rates
are, in most instances, considerably different from the 1940 rates. A
different set of rates was inevitable,' since the wartime rise in prices was
considerably greater in these countries than in most other nations. I t




16

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

seems doubtful, however, that the rates established represented the
results of any careful and deliberate study of changes in economic conditions brought about by the war. The speed with which the new rates had
to be set up precluded such studies, and in any event there were so many
uncertainties regarding the economic future that political considerations
and considerations of expediency inevitably played a dominant part.
This, in brief, is the evolution of present exchange rates for a selected
group of countries. A general description of exchange rate movements has
been given because it was believed that such a background would be helpful in discussing the appropriateness of present rates. In any comparison
of present rates with prewar rates it is useful to know how the rates got
where they are from the prewrar level. This, indeed, is an essential part of
a judgment as to the appropriateness of existing rates. It would obviously
be impossible, within the limits of a paper such as this, to indicate how
each individual rate is likely to affect the future course of world trade.
An attempt is made below, however, to suggest certain probable consequences of the present exchange rate pattern as a whole.
EXCHANGE RATES AND PRICES

The Purchasing Power Parity Theory. One of the factors which must be
taken into account in any discussion of present currency values is the
general rise in prices and costs which was brought about by the war.
Even in countries where price controls were maintained throughout the
war years, the inflationary effects of large government purchases of goods
and services could not be entirely avoided. If these price increases had
been uniform throughout all countries, no particular difficulties would
have arisen as far as foreign trade is concerned. A casual glance at a few
statistics of prices, however, will convince the reader of the enormous
disparity which has developed between the price changes in one country
and those in another. In France, for example, wholesale prices have
increased about 700 per cent above the prewar level, compared with increases of 200 per cent in Czechoslovakia, 185 per cent in Mexico, and
45 per cent in Australia.4 In view of these discrepancies, it is obvious that
relative changes in the internal purchasing power of different currencies
will have substantial effects on the course of international trade unless
they are offset by corresponding changes in exchange rates.
4
These figures, taken from the appendix table on p. 45, represent a comparison of prewar
prices with prices prevailing at the end of 1946.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

17

After the First World War, the discrepancies between movements of
price levels in different countries were equally great, and since exchange
rates in many countries were uncontrolled, these changes in relative purchasing power exerted a considerable influence on exchange rates. Indeed
the changes in prices and costs were so striking by comparison with other
economic changes that there was a tendency to explain the observed
movement of exchange rates entirely in terms of changes in relative purchasing power. This was the doctrine of purchasing power parity which
enjoyed a considerable popularity among economists in the 1920's. The
theory of purchasing power parity, in its simplest form, may be illustrated by means of a numerical example.
Suppose that in some initial period, when international payments are
in a balanced condition, the exchange rate between the dollar and the
pound sterling is $4.50 = £ l . And suppose that as a result of a war, prices
and costs in the United States increase uniformly to a level just twice
their former level, while prices and costs in the United Kingdom rise to
three times their former level; in other words, the index of prices in the
United States increases to 200 while the index in the United Kingdom
increases to 300. According to the purchasing power parity doctrine the
internal purchasing power of the dollar at the close of the war is one-half
of its former level, and the internal purchasing power of the pound is onethird its former level. Hence, it is argued, in order to preserve balanced
trade relations between the two countries, the price of the pound, in terms
of dollars, must drop to two-thirds of the old price, or to $3 = £ l . More
generally, the so-called parity exchange rate is equal to the price of the
pound in the base year, in terms of dollars, multiplied by the ratio of the
price index in the United States to the price index in the United Kingdom.
The virtue of the parity rate is that it preserves the earlier real exchange ratio between the goods and services of one country and the goods
and services of another. To see why this is true, suppose in the above
example that an American product, X, before the war sold for $1.50,
while a British product, F, sold for £ l . At the old exchange rate, American purchasers of Y would have had to pay $4.50 per unit, and the price
per unit in the United States would thus have been three times the price
of a unit of the American product, X. We may assume, now, that as a
result of the war inflation the cost of production and the price of each
commodity, in the currency of the selling country, rises according to the
general price rise. In other words, the selling price of X, the American




18

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

product, is doubled while the price of F, the British product, is tripled;
the new price of X is $3.00, and the new price of Y is £3. At the parityexchange rate of $3 = £1, the American price of the British product is
thus $9. Once again, therefore, the unit price of the British product, in
dollars, is three times the unit price of the American product.
Since the relative price of British goods, compared with the price of
American goods, is the same after the inflation as before, the general rise
in prices will not affect the import of British goods; unless tastes or conditions of production and trade have changed, the physical volume of
British imports will be the same as in the prewar situation, and only the
monetary units in which these imports are measured will have changed.
Likewise, in the United Kingdom the sterling price of United States
goods, relative to the price of British goods, will remain the same as
before the inflation, and a presumption exists that the physical volume of
British imports will be unchanged.
Criticisms of Purchasing Power Parity. While adoption of the parity
rate is desirable in the solution of some problems, it may be quite undesirable in the solution of others, for in some circumstances it may be
necessary to change the real terms of trade between countries in order to
restore a balanced condition in international trade. If this is true, the socalled "equilibrium" rate of exchange will differ from the parity rate.
Suppose, for example, that the base period chosen for the calculation of a
parity rate in the numerical example above had been a period in which the
United States had a deficit in its balance of payments. Other things being
equal, the parity rate between the dollar and the pound, by perpetuating
the real terms of exchange between British and American goods, will likewise perpetuate the deficit. Only the money units in which the deficit is
measured will have changed. In order to restore a balanced condition,
exports of the United States must be encouraged, and imports reduced, by
means of a depreciation in the value of the dollar below the parity rate.
Thus, if the base period is one of disequilibrium, the parity rate, after the
price rise has taken place, will not be the same as the rate which will
establish equilibrium in a country's balance of payments.5
Other factors will also create a disparity between the parity rate and
the equilibrium rate. Consider, for example, the effects of capital movements. Suppose that in the prewar base period there were no capital move5
On all of these criticisms of parity calculations cf. Gottfried Haberler, "The Choice
of Exchange Rates after the War," American Economic Review, June 1945, pp. 311-15.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

19

ments, and that after the rise in prices has taken place the United States
expects to make extensive loans to the United Kingdom. Assuming that
the base period was one of balanced trade without capital movements, the
parity rate will also establish a balanced condition, in the absence of
capital movements, after the price rise has taken place. But if the United
States is to make large foreign loans an export surplus can and should be
allowed to develop in the United States balance of trade, and in order to
bring about such an export surplus, the exchange rate for the dollar must
be depreciated below the parity rate. Accordingly, we find once more a
difference between the parity rate and.the equilibrium rate. Changes in
tastes or in methods of production will create a similar difference between
the two rates. If, because of such changes, the American demand for
British goods has increased during the time interval between the base
period and the period of comparison, the parity rate, by re-establishing
the earlier ratio of exchange between British and American goods, will
lead to a deficit in the United States balance even though the initial
period was one of equilibrium. In order to make the supply of foreign
exchange equal to the demand, the value of the dollar in this case must
again be depreciated below the purchasing power parity rate.
Movements of output and employment are also important in judging
the validity of parity calculation, for these movements bring with them
substantial changes in the demand for imports. In times of comparative
economic stability, the effects of changes in employment upon the equilibrium level of exchange rates can perhaps be neglected, but in a period
such as the prewar decade of the thirties, when movements of output and
employment were the dominant feature of economic activity, large discrepancies may develop between the parity exchange rates and the rates
which would restore equilibrium in a country's balance of payments. To
see why this is true, suppose that international trade is initially in equilibrium, and that the level of output in a single country is increased while
output in other countries remains unchanged. As a result of the higher
output in the expanding country, the demand for imports rises; a greater
volume of imported materials is required to produce the higher level of
output and, at the same time, consumers with higher incomes increase
their purchases of foreign commodities. The expanding country is faced
with a deficit in its balance of payments which will normally lead to a
depreciation of its currency even if there are no changes in sellers' prices
either at home or abroad. In other words, a relative expansion of output




20

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

in one country alters the equilibrium exchange rate in a way which does
not correspond to the movement of prices; in extreme examples the equilibrium exchange rate can be altered with no changes in prices at all.
The foregoing criticisms of purchasing power parity have all considered
the most favorable case for the parity theory in which prices and costs
rise or fall uniformly within any given country. Although this implied
assumption may be justified, to a considerable extent, in periods of hyperinflation, the practical application of the parity doctrine is usually complicated by differences in the degree of price rise or fall within each country. When some prices or costs rise more rapidly than others within the
same country, no simple comparison between price movements in different countries can be made. The best that can be done is to use an average
or index number of price changes, and if the discrepancies in price movements as between different commodities in the same country are large,
such an index number, at best, is only a rough indication of the change in
the value of the monetary unit. Moreover, since several types of price
index numbers are usually available, the calculation of parity rates is not
a simple procedure, but involves a considerable element of judgment as to
what prices and costs are important for a country's balance of payments.
Considering this element of judgment, it is not surprising that the selection of an appropriate price index has been one of the most controversial
topics concerning purchasing power parity. Indeed, in some cases the
difficulty of selecting an index has been the most important single cause
for the disrepute into which the parity theory has fallen. It has been said,
on the one hand, that the prices of commodities which do not enter into
international trade are irrelevant, since these prices, at most, have only
an indirect influence on a country's balance of payments. And on the other
hand, it has been argued that international prices, or the prices of goods
which enter into international trade, cannot be used because these prices
necessarily adjust themselves to changes in exchange rates. In other
words, it has been argued that prices for commodities which have a world
market, such as many agricultural products and raw materials, necessarily adjust themselves, within a given country, to any change in that
country's exchange rate.
To clarify this point, suppose that Canada is an exporter of such a
product, Z, to the United Kingdom. If the exchange rate between Canada
and the United Kingdom is $4 = £ l , and if the British price of Z is onefourth pound per unit, the Canadian price will necessarily be $1.00, since
Canada is an exporter of Z and its price is governed by the world price.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

21

Now suppose the exchange rate is altered to $5 = £ l . If the British price
of Z were to remain unchanged, the price in Canadian currency would
rise to $1.25, and the relative change in the price of Z between the two
countries would conform exactly to the change in the exchange rate.
Since this type of behavior is characteristic of many commodities which
are sold in competitive international markets, it has been said that the
prices of internationally traded goods cannot be used in parity calculations. To include such prices, it is said, imparts a bias in the parity calculations which tends to justify the existing exchange rate, whatever it may
be. If prices of domestic goods cannot be used in the calculations because
they are irrelevant, and if prices of international goods cannot be used
because they always adjust themselves to movements of exchange rates,
it must seem, as it did to some economists, that the theory of parity has
little substance, and must be replaced by other methods of judging exchange rates.
One proposed solution of the price dilemma is a substitution of data on
unit costs of production for price data. In other words, it has been suggested that parity rates might be computed from indexes of costs rather
than price indexes. If adequate information concerning costs were available this would no doubt be a useful approach, for the cost figures would
be free, to a considerable extent, of some of the most glaring logical problems which beset the use of price indexes. Unlike some price comparisons,
it could hardly be said that parity calculations based upon costs of internationally traded goods would inevitably justify existing exchange rates,
for costs of production do not adjust themselves as quickly or as completely to a change in exchange rates as do the prices of some international goods.
Although cost comparisons would obviously be preferable to price comparisons in some respects, it is clear that the use of cost data in the parity
calculations could also present some new difficulties. If costs of production
for a given product vary as between different firms, for example, which
firms' costs are to be included in the index of general costs? And if the
costs for a particular firm vary according to the level of output, at what
level of output should the parity calculations be made? These questions
will be recognized as the same difficult questions as those which arose in
connection with the tariff to equalize costs of production at home and
abroad, and the answers are no less difficult to find now than they were
with regard to the tariff.
The selection of cost data for parity calculations, like the selection of




22

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

price index numbers, involves a more or less arbitrary judgment, and the
resulting parity rates are thus to be regarded as rough approximations to
the effects of monetary inflation or currency values, and not as final
answers to the problem of exchange rates.
Perhaps the principal advantage of cost comparisons over price comparisons is that costs are likely to represent more or less permanent
changes in monetary values whereas prices may reflect the transitory
effects of inflation. At the close of a period of general inflation, it is possible that prices may have increased considerably more than wage rates
and other costs. In this event a short recession may cause a significant
reduction in prices without a corresponding reduction in costs. In many
instances, the permanent effects of inflation on the value of a currency
will accordingly be measured more accurately by cost changes than by
price movements.
Despite the obvious advantage of cost comparisons, it has been impossible to make such comparisons in the present study. Accurate and
comprehensive data of unit costs of production are seldom published even
in countries with as much economic data as the United States and the
United Kingdom possess, and in other countries having less advanced
statistical services cost information is virtually nonexistent. Changes in
wage rates, the most important element of unit costs, might be substituted for the unavailable unit cost figures, but here again the investigation
is confronted with a lack of data, for general indexes of wages are much
less common than are general price indexes. In considering the effects of
war inflation on relative currency values it has therefore been necessary
to employ only price data, even though a comparison of wage changes or
changes in other costs of production would have been a useful supplement.
Parity Rates in Peace and in War. The arguments against purchasing
power parity appeared to be so overwhelming during the interwar period
that many economists abandoned the theory entirely. It is a curious fact,
nevertheless, that despite its abandonment in principle the theory continues to be widely used in practice as a means of judging the pattern of
postwar exchange rates. What are the reasons for this divergence between
theory and practice? Why is the purchasing power parity doctrine generally discredited and at the same time widely employed? The explanation
of this inconsistency, the writer believes, is in the fact that the parity
theory is not a general theory of exchange rates, and that it has been
applied, in the past, to conditions for which it was not intended. The




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

23

parity doctrine was used primarily for the purpose of explaining the movements of exchange rates after the First World War, and as a theory of
postwar exchange rates it retains much validity notwithstanding the arguments against it. The theory was discredited not because it was
unimportant or irrelevant in the explanation of exchange rates after the
war, but because attempts were later made to use it in the explanation
of exchange rates under more normal conditions for which it was not
appropriate.
The factors which should be taken into account in setting exchange
rates after a period of war-induced inflation are obviously quite different
from those which affect exchange rates under more normal conditions.
In particular, wartime movements in prices and costs are unusually large,
and the discrepancies in price movements between different countries
are likewise large. Examples of these discrepancies, taken from wholesale price statistics, were presented at the beginning of the present discussion of prices and exchange rates. Equally great discrepancies appeared during the war in retail prices. Although retail price movements
did not always agree with wholesale price movements in any particular
country, the order of magnitude of the two types of price change was in
most instances roughly comparable, and the changes in prices, whether
measured by one index or the other, were so large and so different as
between one country and another that they immediately impress the
observer as one of the most important influences on relative currency
values.
Perhaps even more important than the amplitude of the price and
cost movements is the fact that such movements, in times of war, tend
to be more or less independent of changes in output and employment.
Indeed, the really large price changes do not occur until output has approached the limits of a country's capacity. In contrast to these war
developments, price and cost changes in normal years of peace are smaller
and much more closely related to rising and falling output and employment. The disturbances in a country's balance of payments during nonwar periods are therefore largely attributable to factors other than price
change, and parity calculations have a correspondingly small significance.
This was particularly true during the thirties when international payments throughout the world were disrupted by large and divergent
movements of output and employment as well as by large and rapidly
changing capital movements. Under these circumstances, it is not sur-




24

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

prising that a method of estimating equilibrium exchange rates which
was reasonably satisfactory for conditions of war and postwar inflation
should have been quite inapplicable to the depressed and unstable conditions of the early thirties. I t is unfortunate, however, that the inappropriateness of the parity doctrine to the conditions of the thirties should have
led to a complete condemnation of purchasing power parity under all
conditions. Despite the limitations of parity calculations, it ought to be
recognized that a comparison of price movements in different countries,
in times of war inflation, provides much useful information regarding
exchange rates and international equilibrium. In other words, war-induced
movements of prices and costs should be recognized as an independent
influence on the flow of foreign payments and receipts.
Parity Rates Based upon Wholesale and Retail Prices. Without intending to deny the relevance of other forces, a table is presented here
which indicates roughly to what extent the exchange rates announced
by the International Monetary Fund have made allowance for war-induced changes in prices. For 19 of the member countries, purchasing
power parity rates have been computed by using the period from October
1936 through June 1937 as a base. The parity rate for a given country is
the rate which wrould make the present purchasing power of that country's
currency the same, relative to the purchasing power of the dollar, as it
was in the base period. Reasons for the choice of the base period used
here have been discussed earlier in connection with the prewar movement
of exchange rates. Most of the parity rates have been computed as of
November or December 1946, but in any event the date for which each
rate was computed is indicated in the table. Since prices seldom moved in
an entirely uniform manner within a single country, parity rates have
been computed for two types of average prices, a wholesale price index and
a cost of living or retail price index. The table shows a rather persistent
tendency for the rates announced by the Fund to exceed the parity rates.
Of the 19 countries whose rates are included, 9 countries—Belgium,
Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Egypt, France, India, Iran, and Mexico—
have official exchange rates which appear to be well above the parity
rates, regardless of whether such parity rates are measured in wholesale
or retail prices. In only three cases—Canada, the Union of South Africa,
and the United Kingdom—are the rates announced by the Fund substantially lower than the parity rates for the end of 1946.
The fact, shown by the table, that official rates announced by the




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

25

Fund exceed the parity rates for a considerable number of countries does
not mean, of course, that the currencies of the countries involved are
necessarily overvalued by the Fund. The question whether any particular
rate is too high or too low in terms of dollars is an extremely involved
question which could not possibly be answered in an over-all survey of
PARITY EXCHANGE RATES COMPARED WITH THE RATES ANNOUNCED BY THE INTERNATIONAL
MONETARY FUND 1

(In cents per units of foreign currency)
Parity rates
Cost of living parity

Rates
announced
by the Fund

13.28

(12/46)
1.52
(11/46) 118.45
(11/46)
2.35
(10/46) 39.39
(11/46) 11.38

2.28
100.00
3.23
57.14
17.81

Cuba
Czechoslovakia.
Denmark
Egypt
France

(11/46)
1.90
(11/46) 18.54
(7/46) 246.27
(11/46)
0.63

(10/46) 72.17
(11/46)
1.54
(9/46) 19.34
(7/46)251.93
(9/46)
0.53

100.00
2.00
20.84
413.30
0.84

India
Iran
Mexico
Netherlands.
Norway

(8/46) 16.69
(5/46) 1.54
(11/46) 15.89
(10/46) 34.16
(11/46) 22.80

(11/46)
(5/46)
(11/46)
(9/46)
(11/46)

21.21
1.07
11.63
42.11
21.59

30.23
3.10
20.60
37.70
20.15

Peru
Turkey
Union of South Africa.
United Kingdom

(11/46) 15.58
(9/46) 29.50
(9/46)425.24
(11/46)467.59

(11/46) 17.40
(9/46) 35.23
(9/46) 500.27
(11/46) 549.46

15.38
35.71
403.00
403.00

Member country
Wholesale price parity

Belgium
Canada....
Chile
Colombia...
Costa Rica.

(11/46) 120.33
(11/46)
3.19
(11/46)

1
Sources of price data are given in the appendix table on p. 45; sources of exchange rates in preceding tables.
The base period used in calculating these parity rates is the same as the base period for which prewar exchange
rates are given in the earlier tables. Figures in parentheses indicate the month and year for which the parity rate
was computed.

postwar exchange rates such as the present paper. In order to make an
exact estimate of the exchange rates which would be consistent with a
balanced position in international trade, it would be necessary to consider
all of the changes in tastes, techniques, real income, and capital movements mentioned above, in addition to the changes in prices. In other
words, the parity calculations are only a first approximation which




26

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

indicates to what extent present exchange rates have made allowance for
the war-induced changes in the domestic purchasing power of various
currencies. Nevertheless the fact that the parity rates tend to fall short
of the rates announced by the Fund is, in the author's opinion, a general
indication that present exchange rates of a number of countries are somewhat higher than the rates which will ultimately be consistent with a
balanced state of international payments.
The tendency for present exchange rates to exceed parity rates is also
apparent in countries which are not members of the Fund, as well as in
member countries for which no exchange rates have been announced.
The accompanying table presents parity rates and actual rates as of
December 1946 for five nonmember countries and for five member
countries whose official rates have not been agreed upon. Since the general
picture presented by this table is much the same as that for the member
countries which have agreed rates, it will not be necessary to comment
in detail. I t may be useful, however, in concluding the presentation of
parity rates, to make a few remarks concerning the general pattern of
rates in both member and nonmember countries. So far as possible,
rates will be considered within broad economic or geographic groups of
countries.
The only group of countries for which parity rates are consistently
higher than actual rates are the United Kingdom and the British
dominions of Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa. In all
of these countries, price controls were effective during the war and to a
considerable extent have subsequently been maintained. Up to the present
time, war and postwar inflation have thus been largely avoided, and at
present exchange rates the purchasing power of the currencies of these
countries has increased, relative to the purchasing power of the dollar.
The position of these countries is discussed further in a later section.
Parity rates for the Western European countries, except for the Netherlands, are to a greater or smaller extent below the actual dollar exchange
rates. Among the Scandinavian countries, the parity rates for Denmark
and Sweden are below present rates, while the parity rate for Norway is
slightly above the actual rate. In any event, the discrepancies between
parity rates and actual rates for the Scandinavian countries are not large.
Egypt, India, and Iran all have parity rates which are well below the
actual rates. The parity rate of the Egyptian pound, for example, is approximately $2.50, compared with an actual rate of $4.13. Likewise, with




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

27

respect to India, the parity rate for the rupee is between 17 and 21 cents,
compared with an actual rate of approximately 30 cents. Although these
figures indicate a substantial change in comparative purchasing power,
the reader is warned against placing too much reliance upon any particular figure. The price index numbers for these countries are at best rough
approximations, and more comprehensive indexes might deviate considerably from the ones used in the parity calculations. Moreover, in nonindustrial countries such as these the cost structure is much more flexible
PARITY EXCHANGE RATES COMPARED WITH RATES IN DECEMBER, 1946, FOR NONMEMBER
COUNTRIES AND FOR MEMBER COUNTRIES FOR WHICH RATES HAVE
N O T B E E N ANNOUNCED 1

(In cents per unit of foreign currency)
Parity rates
Country
Wholesale price parity

Nonmember countries:
Argentina
Australia*
New Zealand
Sweden
Switzerland
Member countries for which ratesj
have not been announced:
Brazil
Greece
Italy
Poland
Uruguay

(11/46) 24.66
(11/46)440.51
(10/46)395.27
(11/46) 24.66
(11/46) 18.77

(11/46)

0.14

Cost of living parity

(9/46) 424.97
(9/46)
(11/46)

24.11
21.86

(11/46) 3.87
(10/46) 0.0083
(9/46) 0.26
(10/46) 0.23
(9/46) 74.94

Rates in
December
1946

29.77
321.07
322.36
27.82
23.36

5.41
0.02
0.26
1.00
56.27

1
Sources are the same as in preceding tables. The base period is the same as in the tables of exchange ratesFigures in parentheses indicate the month and year for which the parity rate was computed.
* Admitted to membership on Aug. 5, 1947, after this analysis had been completed.

than in countries like the United States and the United Kingdom. If a
decline in prices eventually sets in, price indexes for these countries may
therefore decline quite rapidly. It would accordingly be a mistake to
assume that the war-induced inflation of prices and costs is as permanent
in countries such as Egypt and India as it will probably be in the United
States and the United Kingdom. The same consideration applies, to a
considerable extent, to prices and costs in Latin America. As the two
tables show, the Latin American parity rates are, with a few exceptions,
somewhat below the actual rates. This does not necessarily mean, how-




28

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

ever, that the Latin American countries will experience difficulties in
exporting at existing rates, for the cost structure is relatively flexible in
many of these countries, and may adjust itself rather rapidly in a period
of general deflation.
Multilateral and Bilateral Comparisons. The foregoing description of
exchange rates and of the relation of such rates to parity rates has been
devoted exclusively to a comparison of individual currencies with the
U. S. dollar. Nothing has been said about such additional problems as the
relation of the French franc to the pound sterling, or the relation of the
Scandinavian currencies to those of France, Belgium, and the Netherlands. A bilateral comparison of individual currencies with the dollar,
such as the comparison above, is obviously important, since the foreign
trade and foreign financial transactions between the United States and
other countries will continue to be a substantial part of world trade and
finance, particularly in the immediate future. A complete description of
exchange rates and prices, on the other hand, must consider not only
such bilateral relations but also the multilateral character of all currency
values and prices.
In Belgium, for example, the relation of the French franc to the Belgium franc is normally more important than the relation of these two
currencies to the dollar. Similarly in Denmark, the sterling-krone ratio
is more significant than the dollar-krone ratio. These "cross rates" should
therefore be considered as well as the dollar rates.
Unfortunately, a completely multilateral assessment of exchange rates
is confronted, at the outset, with tremendous technical difficulties. It is
possible to consider the balance of payments of a particular country with
the rest of the world, and to say that with the existing cross rates of
exchange in the rest of the world the present value of the particular
currency appears to be too high or too low. But what if these cross rates
are altered by a change in the value of some other country's currency?
How will this affect the judgment that the particular country's currency
is overvalued or undervalued relative to the rest of the world? To the
professional reader it will be apparent that the problem posed here is
really a problem of simultaneous equations, and a complete solution cannot be obtained in any other way. For present purposes, therefore, the
multilateral comparison must necessarily be limited to a few rather
general observations.
It may be noted at the outset that so far as price effects are concerned




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

29

there is no need to make a multilateral comparison in addition to the
bilateral study of parity rates, for the parity rates of all currencies in relation to a particular currency will establish cross rates which are also
parity rates for the currencies concerned. To clarify this point, consider a
numerical example. Suppose that in a base period the price of the pound
sterling in dollars is $4.50 while the price of the French franc is $0.05.
The cross rate between the franc and the pound will then be 90 francs to
the pound. Suppose now, that at the end of a period of inflation, representative price index numbers in the three countries, with the base period
as 100, are as follows: United States, 150; United Kingdom, 300; France,
600. The parity rates for the pound and the franc, relative to the dollar,
are then $2.25 and $0.0125 respectively. This implies a cross rate between
the pound and the franc of 180 francs to the pound, which is also the
parity rate of the franc relative to the pound. Thus, as far as price comparisons are concerned, parity calculations and multilateral comparisons
come to the same thing. Multilateral comparisons must be made only
when we are considering the complications introduced by capital movements, changes in methods of production, and other nonprice influences
on a country's balance of payments, or when we wish to study the effects
of maintaining exchange rates which in some instances do not agree with
the parity rates.
The significance of multilateral comparisons is readily apparent in
some of the regional problems which were suggested above. We have seen
that, as far as prices alone are concerned, the present value of the pound
sterling relative to the dollar appears to be somewhat low while the prices
of the Scandinavian currencies are not far from the dollar parity rates.
As3uming that no change is made in the value of the pound relative to
the dollar, this means that the Scandinavian currencies will be expensive
relative to sterling. Unless Danish exports of agricultural products are
subsidized, these exports to the United Kingdom may accordingly be
expensive compared with other prices in the United Kingdom. Thus, if
the dollar price of the pound remains unchanged it may be necessary at
some point to change the dollar prices of the Scandinavian currencies
even though they are at present not far from the dollar parities.
Similar arguments apply to other cross rates such as that between
France and Belgium. Although both the French franc and the Belgian
franc appear to be expensive in terms of dollars, the degree of overvaluation is about the same in both cases; the Belgian dollar parity rate,




30

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

based on retail prices, is 67 per cent of the actual rate, while the French
parity is 63 per cent of the actual rate. In export markets where the two
countries are in competition, overvaluation relative to the dollar is
thus less significant than it would have been had the degree of overvaluation differed as between the two countries, and Belgium's decision
concerning any future adjustment of the external value of its currency
will be greatly influenced by the policy adopted concerning the French
franc.
Other examples of cross relationships could be given, but for present
purposes the ones above should suffice to indicate the complicated character of the multilateral system of exchange rates. Every rate is related to
every other rate, and changes in one will inevitably have repercussions
upon many others.
THE POLICY OF THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

Alternatives Which Faced the Fund. When initial exchange rates were
under discussion during the last quarter of 1946, the Fund and the
member countries were faced with two alternative courses of action.
First, they could have attempted to determine the pattern of exchange
rates which would be consistent with a long-run balance in international
payments and receipts, and these rates could then have been adopted as
the initial rates with which the Fund began operations. This course of
action would probably have required substantial changes in some exchange rates, but if the original calculations were carefully done there
might have been a reasonable expectation that subsequent changes
in rates would be relatively small. The second alternative was to accept
more or less the existing pattern of exchange rates with the expectation
that adjustments would be made later when more normal conditions
returned. In other words, the adjustment of exchange rates to the new
economic conditions brought about by the war could be postponed until
a later date.
In fact, the Fund adopted the second alternative. Although Mr. Gutt,
in requesting information from the member countries relative to their
exchange rates, had announced that the Fund must solve its most
difficult problem—the agreement on initial exchange rates—before it
commenced operations, in the end a decision was made, in effect, to
postpone the solution of the problem by accepting the present pattern
of exchange rates. The member countries requested that the rates at
which they had stabilized their currencies after the war be used as official




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

31

rates by the Fund, and after considerable discussion this was agreed to
in the case of all the countries for which rates were announced. As noted
earlier, however, it was frankly recognized at the time the initial rates
were announced that adjustments would probably be necessary later.
The foregoing discussion of parity rates lends support to this view, for it
indicates that unless unforeseen changes in prices and costs occur, the
currencies of a considerable number of countries will probably prove to be
too high, when normal conditions have returned, to preserve a balance
between foreign payments and receipts.
Reasons for Accepting Current Rates. Why were the existing rates accepted as initial rates by the Fund despite the fact that some of them
were known to be out of line with current prices and costs? And what will
be the consequences of this action on the flow of international trade?
Perhaps the most important reason for beginning operations with existing
rates is that the member countries themselves were anxious to keep their
present rates, and that most of them had good economic reasons for
wanting to do so. It is an interesting fact that many countries today
want to keep the value of their currencies as high as possible, despite
wartime increases in prices and costs, whereas in the prewar decade these
same countries, in many instances, were rivals in a general move to
depreciate their currencies. Although this reversal in attitude may seem
strange at first sight, it is easily explained in terms of the difference between the primary economic problems of the thirties and those of the
present day. In the thirties, the over-riding economic problem in almost
all countries was deflation, inadequate demand, and unemployment.
Most countries were extremely anxious to increase the demand for their
products, including the foreign demand, and one means of increasing
foreign demand was to depreciate the currency. Once this process was
started, it led to depreciation of other currencies in retaliation or selfprotection, and thus we witnessed a wave of competitive currency depreciation.
The situation today offers a sharp contrast with conditions in the thirties, and the currency policies followed by individual countries are accordingly different. The problem today is how to avoid a rise in prices
rather than how to avoid a price decline. A considerable part of the
world's productive capacity has been destroyed or worn out and at the
same time the demand for goods in general has reached an unprecedented
height as the combined result of accumulated war shortages and accumulated purchasing power. Thus the primary problem today is how to




32

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

produce enough to satisfy the present demand, whereas the problem of
the thirties was how to find markets for the goods which could be produced. In view of this contrast in economic conditions, it is not surprising that the foreign financial policies of many countries are strikingly
different from their policies during the thirties. Although many countries
recognize that their current exchange rates in terms of dollars and pounds
sterling are probably too high, relative to present prices and costs, most
of these countries are extremely reluctant to depreciate at the present
time.
This reluctance to depreciate is in part attributable to a fear that depreciation would aggravate inflationary developments. Just as currency
depreciation in the thirties helped individual countries to avoid a fall in
domestic prices and incomes by creating a foreign demand for their goods,
so today, the maintenance of high currency values helps many of these
same countries to retard inflation by keeping down the domestic prices of
their imports. Despite present inflationary pressures, many countries
have finally succeeded in achieving a precarious price stability and an
equally precarious balance between prices and costs by means of price
controls, wage controls, and rationing. Although these controls in many
instances are neither as comprehensive nor as strictly enforced as war
controls, they have frequently accomplished the purpose of preventing
or retarding a further spiral of increased prices and increased costs. The
distaste for currency depreciation is in many instances attributable to a
fear that depreciation, by increasing the domestic prices of imports, will
disturb the precarious balance and lead to additional increases in both
prices and wages. If a country's domestic prices for imported goods rise
as a result of depreciation, this means in many cases a substantial increase
in the cost of living, and an increase in living costs may easily lead to
demands for wage increases which will start the entire inflationary process
anew. Considering this possibility, it is easy to understand why many
countries, and particularly those countries whose economies were badly
damaged by war, are reluctant to depreciate their currencies at the
present time.
Apart from its effect on the cost of living, currency depreciation in the
near future might have serious inflationary consequences simply as a
result of its psychological effects. This is particularly true of the European
countries in which inflation after the First World War was accompanied
by a rapid currency depreciation. The people in many of these countries
have an exaggerated idea of the relation between depreciation and the




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

33

internal value of a currency and tend in some cases to regard depreciation
and inflation as synonymous. Depreciation in these countries, under
present circumstances, might therefore lead to a wave of spending which
would further aggravate the tendency of prices to rise. It would be assuming a considerable responsibility to insist, in the face of these conditions,
that an immediate adjustment should be made in the exchange rates of
the countries whose currencies seem from a long-run point of view to be
overvalued.
Apart from the dangers of further inflation, there are a number of
other convincing arguments against making an immediate adjustment
in exchange rates. Most countries whose currencies appear to be too
expensive in relation to their domestic prices are also countries which will
be borrowing heavily from the dollar area during the next three or four
years. In other words, the normal condition for these countries during
the transition years will be an import surplus, the excess of imports to
be paid for out of dollar loans from such agencies as the Export-Import
Bank and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
Thus even if such countries had no import controls and their exchange
rates were immediately adjusted to a level where their foreign receipts,
including loans, were equal to their foreign payments, the presence of the
import surplus financed by loans would mean that the currency values
of the borrowing countries could be somewhat higher during the borrowing period, relative to prices, than the prewar equilibrium rates. To put
the matter another way, the equilibrium rates for the borrowing countries
during the transition period will be above the parity rates. How much
significance should be attached to this point is difficult to estimate. For
some countries exchange rates are probably so high, relative to prices,
that the present rates are above equilibrium rates even if allowance is
made for borrowing from abroad. In cases where the parity rate indicates
only a slight overvaluation relative to prices, on the other hand, the
present exchange rates may not be far out of line.
Another reason for maintaining present exchange rates during the
transition years is the condition of the export industries. In many countries whose currencies appear to be overvalued exports are limited not by
market conditions but by inability to produce. As long as this is the case,
a depreciation of the currency will not enable the depreciating country
to increase its receipts of foreign exchange. It is true, of course, that depreciation will enable a country to reduce its export prices, in terms of
foreign currency, while maintaining or even increasing the prices which




34

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

domestic producers receive in their own currency, but if the physical
volume of exports cannot be increased because of limits to productive
capacity the reduction in foreign prices will not increase the foreign exchange available to the exporting country. On the contrary, depreciation
in this case will reduce the amount of foreign exchange received in the
depreciating country and thereby worsen the country's balance of payments.
In addition to the reasons mentioned above, it seems likely that the
decision of the Fund to begin operations with existing exchange rates was
influenced to a considerable extent by the great uncertainty concerning
the future course of world trade. Although comparisons of price changes
with changes in exchange rates establish a presumption that many currencies today are too expensive relative to the dollar for a long-run
balanced world economy, it would be a mistake to assume that the parity
rates themselves are necessarily the proper rates. Many changes in basic
economic conditions have occurred during the war and these changes will
inevitably affect the terms on which goods will be exchanged in the future.
For this reason, it is not sufficient simply to adjust exchange rates to the
observed price movements. In addition, an allowance must be made for
the increased or decreased ability of some countries to export, and for
changes in the demand for imports.
Unfortunately, adjustments of this type are extremely difficult to make.
How, for example, will the decline of Germany and Japan in world trade
affect the trade balances of other countries? What effect will the rebuilding
of the devastated countries have on their ability to produce and to
export? At the present time it is obviously impossible to give precise
quantitative answers to questions such as these. The network of world
trade is so complex that it is extremely difficult to trace the consequence
of Germany's decline or the rebuilding of the French and British economies through all of their ramifications. This uncertainty adds weight to
the decision of the Fund to postpone exchange adjustments, for only
actual experience can tell us which countries are likely to have deficits
and which to have surpluses as a result of the war-induced changes in
conditions of production and consumption.
With regard to the course of prices in different countries, uncertainties are almost equally great. I t has been said, on the one hand, that
prices and costs in countries which now have overvalued currencies will
probably fall as normal production is resumed and the accumulated war
losses are replaced. On the other hand, however, the continuing infla-




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

35

Probably even more important so far as price comparisons are concerned
is the fact that the index numbers upon which these comparisons are
based are limited, for the most part, to official prices and make only slight
allowance for the higher black market prices. As output is increased and
accumulated demands are satisfied, some of these black market prices will
clearly tend to fall. At the same time, however, it seems highly probable
that official prices will tend to rise, since the current cost structure almost
certainly reflects, in part, the high level of black market prices. Taking all
of these possibilities into account, it seems doubtful, to the present writer,
whether a significant part of the disparities between current prices and
exchange rates will be corrected by a fall in prices in the countries with
overvalued currencies.
Several of the reasons discussed above for postponing action on exchange
adjustments were explicitly recognized by the Fund. The announcement
of initial rates which was made on December 18, 1946, contained the
following statement:
The Fund realizes that at the present exchange rates there are substantial disparities in price and wage levels among a number of countries. In present circumstances, however, such disparities do not have the same significance as in normal
times. For practically all countries, exports are being limited mainly by difficulties of
production or transport, and the wide gaps which exist in some countries between
the cost of needed imports and the proceeds of exports would not be appreciably
narrowed by changes in their currency parities. In addition, many countries have
just begun to recover from the disruption of war, and efforts to restore the productivity
of their economies may be expected gradually to bring their cost structures into line
with those of other countries. Furthermore, for many countries now concerned with
combating inflation there is a danger that a change in the exchange rate would aggravate internal tendencies toward inflation.

From this statement it is apparent that the Fund placed considerable
weight on the numerous reasons for postponing adjustments. Even if the
Fund had wanted to change some of the present rates, however, there is
some doubt as to whether it would have been able to establish its authority to require such changes under the present abnormal conditions.
Article X X of the Articles of Agreement of the Fund stipulates that the
par value of a currency communicated to the Fund by a member shall be
the initial value for the purpose of the Fund's operations unless, "(i) the
member notifies the Fund that it regards the par value as unsatisfactory,
or (ii) the Fund notifies the member that in its opinion the par value
cannot be maintained without causing recourse to the Fund on the part




36

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

of that member or others on a scale prejudicial to the Fund and to members"*
From this part of the Agreement, it appears that the Fund has only
rather limited authority in the setting of initial rates. The member
country itself can apparently object to the communicated par value for
any reason whatsoever, whereas the Fund can object only if it feels that
the communicated par value would cause undue recourse to the Fund.
The difficulty about this criterion is that a number of war-ravaged
countries, whatever exchange rate they adopt, may be expected to have a
deficit in their balance of payments over the next year or so of a size
necessitating their making full use of their annual drawing rights on the
Fund and yet of such an apparently transitory character as to justify
use of the Fund's resources. In the case of such countries, the scale of
recourse to the Fund will not be dependent, in the initial period, upon
the level of the exchange rate. Of course the Fund might fear that if the
existing rate were maintained over a period of years, these drafts upon
the Fund might become chronic. But in view of the uncertainties concerning long-range predictions of balance of payment developments, the
Fund would find it difficult to offer convincing substantiation for such
fears. Even if it could, the country concerned might well respond that the
time for adjustment would arrive only later when the scale of its recourse
to the Fund actually came to depend upon its exchange rate policy. It
is not known to what extent this limitation on the Fund influenced the
decision concerning initial rates, but it may have played some part.
Dangers of Postponing Action. Unless radical readjustments of prices
occur in some countries, it seems apparent from the preceding discussion
that the initial exchange rates at which the Fund has commenced operations are in a substantial number of cases too high for a long-run balanced
state of trade. This is not necessarily an indication that an immediate
adjustment should be made, for we have seen that there are strong arguments for postponing the adjustment and continuing during the transition period with existing rates. At the same time, however, it is well to
recognize that maintaining exchange rates which are too high in relation
to prices may involve certain dangers for the future of a liberal foreign
economic program.7
6

Article XX, Sec. 4(b). Italics added.
A substantial number of the advantages and disadvantages of an immediate adjustment
of exchange rates were listed by Haberler in the article previously cited. In contrast to the
present paper, however, Professor Haberler concluded that undervaluation of European
currencies was preferable to the present rather general overvaluation.
7




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

37

The principal danger is that once a country has adjusted its trade controls to an overvalued currency the country may later be reluctant to
relax these controls and depreciate its currency to a level compatible with
balanced international payments. Apart from the question of national
prestige, an overvalued currency may be tempting to some countries even
after the period of reconstruction has ended and the threat of inflation
has subsided. Rightly or wrongly, there is a tendency to associate a highpriced currency with low prices for imports relative to the prices received
for exports. In other words, it is widely believed that an appreciated
currency means favorable terms of trade. Whether this is always true or
not is beside the point. For present purposes, it is sufficient that many
people believe it is true, and that some countries may therefore desire
to maintain overvalued currencies more of less permanently, and to
preserve balance in their international payments by means of trade controls or other barriers to trade. In other words, if exchange rates are set,
for a considerable period of time, in a pattern which is not consistent
with balanced international payments, there is a danger that balance will
nevertheless be achieved by means of various direct controls, and that
the pressure for a readjustment of rates arising from loss of external reserves will accordingly be negligible.
A second danger of the present exchange pattern is that it may freeze
a system of export subsidies more or less permanently into many economic
systems. In some countries, exchange rates are so high relative to prices
that it seems doubtful whether many industries in these countries will be
able to resume their prewar normal export trade without substantial
subsidies. Like import controls, these export subsidies may come to be
regarded as a permanent feature of international trade. If so, the cost
of postponing adjustments of exchange rates will be a permanent distortion of the price system.
Whether the dangers of postponing action are real or only apparent
depends to some extent upon the success or failure of current efforts to
establish an International Trade Organization. Under the draft charter
of this proposed organization, the member countries would agree to a
code of trade practices calling for a general reduction of trade barriers
and export subsidies. The charter recognizes that quantitative import
controls may be needed, in some instances, to preserve equilibrium in a
country's balance of payments, but if equilibrium continues to require
import restrictions it is anticipated that other measures, such as an ad-




38

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

justment of exchange rates or of prices and costs, will be undertaken.
Tariffs and export subsidies are presumably not to be considered, under
the organization's charter, as means of adjusting the balance of payments
either temporarily or in the long run. Thus if the charter is accepted by a
large number of countries there will be less danger that the present pattern of rather abnormal exchange rates will become permanent than
would otherwise be the case. Although these rates might be compensated
or offset for a considerable period of time by export subsidies and direct
import controls, the International Trade Organization would presumably
exert strong influence on the member countries to reduce their controls
and subsidies, and to adjust their exchange rates to a level which is compatible with balanced international payments and receipts. Whether
the International Trade Organization comes into existence or not, however, it seems doubtful to the present writer that the arguments in favor
of an immediate adjustment of exchange rates are sufficiently convincing
to offset the serious disadvantages of such action.
The "Undervalued" Currencies. In discussing the probable consequences
of the acceptance by the Fund of existing exchange rates, we have considered thus far only the countries whose currencies appear to be too
expensive relative to the dollar. This, indeed, is the problem which has
received most attention in current discussions, and it is no doubt the
most important problem from a practical point of view. Nevertheless, as
noted earlier, the table of parity rates for members of the Fund shows
that a few of the present rates are below the parity rates, relative to the
dollar. In other words, for a few countries depreciation of the currency
in terms of dollars, relative to the prewar situation, was greater than the
relative rise in prices. In order to complete the description of present
exchange rates, we ought to consider briefly the position of these undervalued currencies.
The countries whose currencies seem to be undervalued in terms of
dollars are the United Kingdom and the following members of the British
Commonwealth of Nations: Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the
Union of South Africa. Although Australia* and New Zealand are not
yet members of the Fund, their present exchange rates will nevertheless
be considered along with the other British currencies. Whether measured
in wholesale or in retail prices, the parity rates for all of these countries
are above the actual rates. For convenient reference, the ratio of parity
* Australia was admitted to membership on Aug. 5, 1947, after this analysis had been
completed.




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

39

rates to actual rates in all five countries is given in the following table for
the end of 1946.
RATIO OF PARITY RATES TO ACTUAL RATES FOR SELECTED BRITISH CURRENCIES

(Ratios computed with reference to U. S. dollar)
Country

Australia
Canada
New Zealand
Union of South Africa.
United Kingdom

In wholesale prices

In retail prices

1.37
1.20
1.23
1.06
1.16

1.32
1.18

—
1.24
1.36

The extent of undervaluation, measured by prices, varies from 6 percent
to 37 per cent, with an average of perhaps 20 per cent. The actual numbers are not as important, however, as the general direction, for we have
seen that it is impossible to give a precise interpretation to the parity
calculations.
The undervaluation of British currencies shown by these figures is to
a large extent attributable to the price inflation which has taken place
in the United States since price controls were abandoned in the middle
of 1946. In August 1946, parity calculations comparable to those included
in the present paper were made, and at that time the currency rates for
the British countries, except for India and Egypt, appeared to correspond
roughly with parity rates. Subsequently, however, both retail and wholesale prices increased much more rapidly in the United States than in the
British countries. A few examples will indicate the disparity in price
movements. Between June and December 1946, the index of wholesale
prices in the United States increased 25 per cent, whereas the British
wholesale price index increased by only 4 per cent. During the same
period, retail prices in the United States increased by 15 per cent, compared with an increase of 2.4 per cent in Canada and virtually no change
in the United Kingdom. As a result of these changes, the British currencies, including the Canadian dollar, now appear to be low-priced in relation to the movement of prices in general.
If this is true, why did the countries of the British Commonwealth
not request an appreciation of their currencies, relative to the dollar,
when initial exchange rates for the Fund were being considered? A complete answer to this question would be beyond the scope of the present
paper, since it would require a detailed investigation of economic conditions in each of the countries concerned. It will suffice, at this point, to
indicate a number of broad considerations bearing on the question.




40

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

Unlike many other countries, the British countries whose currencies appear to be undervalued do not have an acute problem of inflation. It is
true, of course, that most of them have a substantial amount of accumulated demand and a corresponding amount of liquid purchasing power,
but this development, which would otherwise be inflationary, has not
been permitted to have any appreciable effect upon prices, since wartime
controls have been carried over into the period of reconstruction. The
situation is accordingly less precarious in these countries than in many
others, and there is less danger that a price rise in a particular group of
commodities such as imports will set off an inflationary spiral of prices
and costs. This means that countries such as the United .Kingdom and
Australia do not have to rely on low prices of imports as a means of preventing inflation at home. In other words, their domestic controls are so
strong that it is not necessary, or at least not imperative, to use their
exchange rates as instruments of domestic policy. It may be presumed
that this is one reason why the British countries did not insist upon more
expensive currencies, relative to the dollar.
Another factor in the decision, no doubt, was the feeling that the price
situation in the United States is only temporary, and that prices here will
eventually fall. Also, price indexes used for the United Kingdom probably
overstated somewhat the degree of undervaluation of the pound sterling,
since the cost of living index, at any rate, was known to be relatively
insensitive to the war-induced rise of prices. The complaint was frequently heard in the United Kingdom that the British authorities had
stabilized the cost of living index but not the cost of living. This fact,
together with the belief that prices in the United States may fall to some
extent from their present high level, means that the price comparison is
not as valid an indication of the equilibrium rate for the pound sterling
as would otherwise be the case. The British apparently do not wish to
appreciate now and be confronted later with the necessity of reducing the
price of their currency as the result of a decline in American prices.
Apart from the price factors, additional reasons for not appreciating
the pound may be found in the state of Britain's balance of payments.
The British international position is well known and it will not be
necessary to review it in detail here. Liquidation of British overseas assets
as well as the great increase in her overseas liabilities which occurred
during the war will make it necessary for the United Kingdom to export
a larger volume of goods in order to pay for a given volume of imports
than was the case in the prewar years. Adjustment to this new situation
will nf rnnrcp K^ nnQtnnnprl h v flip InnriQ w h i r h thp TTnifpH l^incrHnm ha*




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

41

received from the United States and Canada, but eventually it is highly
probable that a rate of exchange for the pound lower than the parity
rate will be needed in order to increase Britain's exports relative to her
imports. In the present state of general world shortage of goods, the
British could no doubt sell as much abroad as they are now selling even
if they increased their foreign prices. This means that appreciation of the
pound might, in the immediate future, increase Britain's receipts from
exports. At a later date, however, when world markets become more
competitive, it is almost certain that British exports would be affected
adversely if the pound had been appreciated. In its current export drive,
the United Kingdom is apparently taking the long view, being willing to
forego some temporary gains for the benefit of a more lasting position in
the world's export markets. Moreover, in view of the key importance of
the sterling-dollar rate in the world rate structure, the British may have
been very hesitant to upset their existing relationship; they may also
have had some feeling that the American, public would find it difficult
to reconcile an upward revaluation in the pound sterling with continued
British requests for American financial support.
The Canadian situation is somewhat different from that of the United
Kingdom. In the United Kingdom, as we have seen, there might be a
short-run advantage to an appreciation of the pound, but over a longer
period, when borrowing from other countries has ceased, it is doubtful
whether a value of the pound as high as the parity rate could be maintained. In Canada, on the other hand, an upward adjustment of the
currency value might be appropriate as a long-run measure but in the
immediate future there are pressing reasons for retaining the present
rate, even though it is low relative to the war-induced movement of
prices. The Canadians have committed themselves to make postwar loans
of approximately 2 billion dollars, and Canadian exports must therefore
be considerably greater than imports, in the near future, in order to
preserve a balanced state of international payments. Canada is already
beginning to feel the effects of this situation in a deficit with the United
States, and there is accordingly little prospect that the Canadian authorities will want to raise the value of their currency.
With regard to the other countries—Australia, New Zealand, and
South Africa—little need be added. As in the past, they will probably
wish to maintain a stable relation between their currencies and the
pound sterling. As far as relative prices are concerned, there is no reason
why this should not be possible. In the long run, however, the fact that
they have reduced their indebtedness to the United Kingdom will mean




42

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

that their exports will be smaller relative to imports than in the past. In
other words, they will no longer need an export surplus to make service
payments on their foreign debts, and on this account a long-run appreciation of their currencies, relative to the pound and the dollar, might reasonably be expected.
CONCLUSIONS
A contrast was drawn at the beginning of this paper between the
manner of setting exchange rates after the First World War and the
procedure provided through the International Monetary Fund for establishing such rates after the Second World War. The uncoordinated,
almost anarchistic establishment of relative currency values through
unilateral return to the gold standard after the First World War was
compared with the deliberations contemplated under the Articles of
Agreement of the Fund. From the discussion of present exchange rates,
however, and from the action of the Fund in announcing these rates as
initial rates for the Fund's operations, it should be apparent that the
contrast, at the present time, is more in the mechanism for setting rates
than in the actual results. It was a considerable achievement, even though
a belated one, to have recognized in the Fund Agreement that gold parities of different currencies are important primarily because they govern
relative currency values in international trade. It was an achievement,
also, to have obtained an explicit statement of the importance of multilateral negotiations in establishing gold parities and relative currency
values. It can hardly be said, however, that progress in exchange rate
policy has gone much beyond these statements of principle, for we have
seen that the exchange rates announced by the Fund involve, to some extent, discrepancies similar to those which disturbed world trade after the
First World War. Many currencies appear to be too expensive, relative
to prices, while a few are too cheap.
This is not to say that the Fund made a mistake in deciding to begin
operations with the rates at which the member countries had pegged their
exchanges. There are many convincing reasons, as noted above, for
postponing action in the adjustment of exchange rates, particularly in
the adjustment of rates which at the present time appear to be too high.
Inflationary pressures are still strong and persistent in many of the
countries having currencies which are expensive relative to prices, and
depreciation at this time would intensify these inflationary tendencies by




EXCHANGE RATES AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

43

increasing the domestic prices of imports. Depreciation, moreover, would
not increase the foreign exchange available to such countries from the
sale of exports, for under present market conditions the limitation on
exports is usually inability of export industries to produce rather than
inability to sell, and depreciation would do little, in the short run at least,
to increase a country's capacity to produce for export. Another reason for
maintaining rates which in some cases appear to be too high is that the
countries with apparent overvaluation in their currencies are, generally
speaking, countries which will be borrowing heavily in the next few years.
Such borrowing countries will not expect to secure an even balance of
payments on current account in the near future. They will expect, instead, to have an excess of imports of goods and services over exports,
and the exchange rate appropriate to this situation, even if no direct
controls were maintained, would be a rate somewhat above the parity
rate. For the borrowing countries, apparent overvaluation relative to
prices is thus not necessarily an indication that a downward adjustment
is desirable.
In addition to all of these considerations, a probable further factor
in the Fund's decision to accept existing exchange rates as initial rates is
the large amount of uncertainty regarding the future development of
world trade. The future is uncertain both with respect to the pattern of
trade and the pattern of prices. The Second World War was much more
destructive than the first, and as a result it is almost impossible to say,
at this time, which countries will have a comparative advantage in
particular commodities when the period of reconstruction has ended.
Two countries, Germany and Japan, have been almost completely eliminated from world markets and it is not known to what extent their trade
will revive or what effect their diminished importance will have on the
trade of other countries. In any event, many uncertainties remain both
with respect to changes in the pattern of trade and with respect to future
price movements, and these uncertainties make it almost impossible to
establish a pattern of long-run exchange rates immediately even if it
were desirable on other grounds to do so.
It was probably for all of the reasons given above that the Fund decided
to postpone the adjustment of exchange rates. The real test of the new
mechanism for setting exchange rates will thus not come until more normal conditions return. In the meantime, the fact that some exchange
rates are out of line will not necessarily have serious financial conse-




44

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

quences since both trade and payments will be rather strictly controlled
during the reconstruction years. Eventually, however, when inflationary
pressures have subsided, when individual economies have been restored
to a high productive capacity, and when the ability to export has been
increased, many countries will be in a position to remove import controls
and exchange controls, to reduce export subsidies, and to adjust the
values of their currencies downward, in consultation with the Fund.
When this time comes, and not before, the value of the Fund arrangements for adjusting exchange rates will be given a genuine trial.
A P P E N D I X TABLES
TABLE I
U. S. WHOLESALE PRICE AND COST OF LIVING INDEXES

(October 1936 to June 1937 = 100)
Date

1946:
March
April
May
June
July
August....
September.
October—
November.
December..

Wholesale price index

Cost of living index

127.2
128.7
129.7
131.9
145.2
150.8
144.9
156.7
163.1
164.6

128.7
129.3
130.1
131.7
139.3
142.0
144.2
146.6
149.9
151.9

SOURCES: Converted to given base from Bureau of Labor Statistics index.




TABLE I I
PRICE INDEXES USED IN PARITY CALCULATIONS

(October 1936 to June 1937 is base period unless otherwise indicated)
Wholesale price index
Country

Cost of living index

Value of
index

Date for
which computed

Argentina.
Australia..
Belgium...
Brazil
Canada

November 1946
November 1946

216.4
144.8

November 1946

135.6

Chile
Colombia
Costa Rica
Cuba
Czechoslovakia.

November 1946

264.5
2

November 1946

211.5

November 1946

302.0

Denmark.
Egypt....
France...
Greece—
India

November 1946
July 1946
November 1946

192.7
296.7
4
808.3

August 1946

335.0

Iran
Italy
Mexico
Netherlands..
New Zealand.

May 1946
November 1946
November 1946
October 1946
October 1946

Norway....
Peru
Poland
Sweden
Switzerland..
Turkey
Union of South Africa.
United Kingdom
Uruguay
Venezuela
1

Date for
which computed

September 1946
December 1946
November 1946
November 1946

132.7
336.7
237.3
126.6

November 1946
October 1946
November 1946
October 1946
November 1946

330.1
*212.8
2
210.5
*235.8
340.8

September 1946
July 1946
September 1946
October 1946
November 1946

163.4
278.3
4
787.0
15,834.2
262.0

512.3
5,884.5
284.8
250.2
156.2

May 1946
November 1946
November 1946
September 1946

November 1946
November 1946

176.4
262.5

November 1946
November 1946

167.3
199.0

November 1946
November 1946
October 1946
September 1946
November 1946

September 1946
September 1946
November 1946

392.9
165.5
171.2

August 1946

155.6

6

Value of
index

September
September
November
September

1946
1946
1946
1946

7

*753.7
3,344.0
357.8
186.8

171.2
216.0
11,900.0
151.3
157.0
4

329.0
140.0
133.9
8
157.9

February 1937 base period.
1936 base period.
* July to December 1937 base period; food prices only.
4
1938 base period.
6
March 1936 to March 1937 base period.
• 1937 base period Index includes black market prices on rationed goods.
7
1937 base period; food prices only.
8
1936-37 base period.
SOURCES: United Nations statistical bulletins, government publications of Cuba, Poland, France, and China;
consular reports. Recent cost of living figures for Belgium, Greece, France, and Poland were obtained from consular reports or government publications, and converted to the 1936-37 base period by the use of earlier indexes as
given by the League of Nations. In other cases, continuous series were available.
2




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING A N D T H E
I N T E R N A T I O N A L ECONOMY
by
ROBERT T R I F F I N

Formerly of Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
The growth of nationalistic policies in a world of growingly interdependent nations is one of the apparent paradoxes of our age. Interdependence has proved to have disadvantages as well as advantages,
and its disadvantages have at times resulted in a resurgence of extreme
nationalism. Countries have become engulfed in wars which in the
past would never have concerned them, and they have suffered from
economic depressions having their origin in far distant lands. Nationalism persists in part as an effort to preserve or rebuild the crumbling
natural boundaries which once protected countries from the political
conflicts and economic maladjustments of other parts of the world.
The many cases in which international crises have been intensified by
nationalistic measures of defense by one country and retaliatory action
by others have tended to overshadow the real and challenging problem
responsible for these measures. Nothing can be gained by denying or
ignoring its existence.
Our internationalism is often short-sighted in this respect. In the
monetary field, for example, we are prone to stigmatize exchange control
or exchange devaluation, but slow to suggest workable alternatives to
meet or prevent the exchange shortages which bring about such measures
of defense. Perhaps this is one reason why so little progress has been
made in practice toward the elimination of exchange control and competitive devaluation, notwithstanding their condemnation by economists
and statesmen alike.
A more constructive approach toward the problem is now in the process
of effective realization. The recently created International Monetary
Fund is specifically designed to promote international monetary stability
through the concerted action of all member countries. The legal powers
of the Fund may be grouped into two broad categories. First, the Fund
has the financial machinery to help the members to maintain free and
stable exchanges by supplementing their gold and foreign exchange
resources in case of need. Thus at least one cause of monetary insta-




46

NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 47

bility will be removed or considerably weakened. There is now an
alternative to unilateral resort to currency depreciation or exchange
restrictions during a period of severe even though temporary exchange
shortages. Secondly, the Fund will wield a degree of influence over
policy decisions of member countries. In some cases the Fund has only
the power to make recommendations, or the right to be consulted. In
others, such as parity changes or the establishment of exchange control,
action by a member is subject to the Fund's authorization or approval.
In actual practice, however, the effective power and influence of the
Fund may be far greater, or it may be far smaller, than its legal authority.
Although the Fund has no right to impose specific domestic monetary
or credit policies, it may develop a leadership and moral influence far
beyond the scope of formal official recommendations. On the other hand,
although in theory the Fund can forbid a country to engage in either
currency devaluation or exchange control, such prohibition may prove
to be unenforceable in the face of severe exchange shortages. Currency
devaluation and exchange control are often the outcome of basic disequilibria in a country's international position and, in such a case, cannot
be eliminated by mere legal provisions as long as the root causes remain,
even with the best of will on the part of the country affected.
The ultimate success or failure of the Fund will depend in no small
part on its ability to devise, in collaboration with member countries,
workable and realistic standards of domestic as well as international
monetary policy. This will require a bold revision of the traditional
concepts and dogmas associated with the gold standard theory. The
orthodox gold standard mechanism implied a more or less passive acceptance by each country of the automatic monetary adjustments necessitated by fluctuations in its balance of payments. This view was
reaffirmed in the twenties by the Cunliffe Committee and played a major
part in the studies and recommendations of the League of Nations in
the monetary field. It is in direct contradiction to the increasing trend,
both in theory and practice, toward independent monetary management
by individual countries.
The events of the thirties, the increasing influence of Keynesian economics, and finally the financial impact of World War II have destroyed
the institutional and ideological framework of the automatic gold standard. Tomorrow's currencies will be managed currencies. The only question
at issue—and it is a fundamental one—is the direction toward which
management will work, and the extent to which national objectives can




48

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

be reconciled with international balance. Any attempt to enforce rigid
solutions patterned after orthodox gold standard doctrines would be
even more futile in the postwar period than it has proved to be in the
interwar period.
The purpose of this paper is to review briefly the interaction between
the evolution of national central banking and that of the -international
gold standard, to raise some questions with relation to the actual working
of the gold standard in prewar years, and to outline tentative suggestions
with respect to the problem of international monetary stabilization.
CENTRAL BANKING AND THE GOLD STANDARD
The main problem considered in this paper is the reconciliation of
domestic monetary policies with the prerequisites of international balance.
In its purest form, the gold standard solved the problem automatically
by eliminating one of its terms: the domestic volume of money escaped
the control of national authorities and was determined automatically
by international market forces. Monetary circulation was made up of
gold and subsidiary coin; it expanded or contracted, not as a result of
conscious monetary policy, but in accordance with the net movements
of the international balance of payments. A favorable balance of payments brought gold into a country and expanded the circulating medium.
An unfavorable balance produced the opposite effect.
These movements were regarded as self-adjusting through their influence on national price and cost levels and on interest rates. International balance, if disturbed, would be restored because of the effects
of the ensuing domestic contraction or expansion on relative cost and
interest levels at home and abroad and the resulting shifts in trade and
capital movements. The automatic monetary contraction produced by
gold exports would raise interest rates and attract capital from abroad.
I t would at the same time exert a downward pressure on domestic prices
and costs, thus stimulating exports and discouraging imports. Both of
these movements—capital and trade—would tend to correct the balance
of payments deficit in which they originated. 1 A surplus in the balance
of payments would also be self-corrective. Gold imports would expand
monetary circulation, lower interest rates, increase prices and costs,
and stimulate capital exports and merchandise imports while discouraging
1
Modern theories of international trade and capital movements would incorporate two
further major elements in this analysis. One is the elasticity of supply and demand for imports and exports, the other the direct income effects associated with balance of payments
disequilibria.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 49
exports. These processes would continue until foreign payments and
receipts were again brought into balance,
This type of analysis contemplates a particularly rigid form of the
gold standard in which there is no room for national sovereignty over
currency or money. The only circulating medium is gold itself, i.e., an
international standard largely impervious to national manipulation or
management. In actual practice, the gold standard never existed in such
pure and unadulterated form. The value of the theoretical model discussed
so far does not lie in its descriptive realism, but in the fact that it inspired
so much of the academic thinking and legislative controversies regarding
national and international monetary mechanisms during the nineteenth
and even the twentieth century.
The coexistence of national means of payment, side by side with gold
itself, deeply modified the practical functioning of the gold standard by
freeing the domestic money supply from rigid dependence on balance of
payments fluctuations. Little attention is usually paid, in this respect,
to the latent antinomy between central banking and the classical gold
standard. And yet the automatic monetary mechanism of the pure gold
standard would obviously leave little room for what is today conceived
as one of the primary functions of central banking action; namely, monetary management by the central banking authorities. An element in the
confusion of thought on the subject is the lack of adaptability of our
language, which reflects and tends to perpetuate outmoded habits of
thought. Unchanging terminology has obscured fundamental institutional changes. Just as the gold standard of the twenties was basically
different from the gold standard of earlier days, the central banks of
today bear little resemblance to the central banks of the nineteenth
century.
Indeed the original pattern of central banking had little or nothing
to do with monetary management, which was left to the automatic
regulation of the pure gold standard. The functions of central banks were
purely ancillary ones, and even their power of issue was not designed to
interfere with or supplant the controlling role of gold over the money
supply. The shift from monetary automatism to monetary management
was slow and gradual. The evolution of the Bank of England is most
revealing in this respect.
The Bank Act of 1844 had as its objective the restoration of an unmanaged gold standard, ruled exclusively by fluctuations in the balance of




50

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

payments. Variations in the total note issue of the Bank of England would
correspond exactly to the movements of gold itself in the reserves of the
Issue Department. Any inflow or outflow of gold would produce a corresponding increase or decrease in the volume of money, just as would
have occurred if the circulation had consisted exclusively of gold coin.
The Issue Department of the Bank of England therefore played a purely
passive role and could not exert the slightest influence on the volume
of money.2
Whatever central banking functions this system left to the Bank of
England pertained, not to the Issue, but to the Banking Department.
No such functions, however, were originally intended by the authors
of the Act. In the years immediately following the Bank Act, the Banking
Department was regarded merely as a commercial bank "to be managed
in the same way as any other private bank."3 It was only gradually,
and at the initiative of the Government rather than of the Bank itself,
that the special position and responsibilities of the Banking Department
came to be clearly recognized and accepted by the Bank authorities.
Even then, these responsibilities did not extend to the broad and modern
concept of monetary management, but merely to the function of "lender
of last resort." This function, moreover, did not imply the issue power
since, in principle at least, fluctuations in the note issue continued to
correspond exactly to fluctuations in the gold assets of the Issue Department.
As "lender of last resort," however, the Banking Department, through
its credit and investment operations, would relieve temporary shortages
of cash in the commercial banks. In doing so it would interfere with the
process of readjustment contemplated in the gold standard theory,
since it would offset the deflationary internal effect of a deficit in the
balance of payments and thus prevent its ultimate correction. The drain
on the limited note reserves of the Department would continue until
their exhaustion made it impossible for the Bank to continue its assistance
to the market unless the limitation on its fiduciary issue was raised or
2
The only channel for interference with market forces lay in changes in the amount of
the "fiduciary" issue, which was not covered by gold. Outside of one brief and minor exception, no such change occurred prior to the First World War.
3
"Evidence of the Governor and Deputy Governor of the Bank of England before the
Secret Committee of the House of Commons on the Commercial Distress" (Mar. 7, 1848),
in T. E. Gregory, Select Statutes, Documents and Reports relating to British Banking, 18321928 (London, 1929), Vol. II, p. 28.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 51
suspended. 4 Thus the "lender of last resort" operations were conceived
as a mere temporary palliative, to be accompanied by other measures
tending toward a fundamental readjustment similar to the one which
would have taken place automatically under the pure gold standard.
The most important instrument used toward that end was the management of the discount rate. Credit was made available in times of crisis,
but at higher rates which led to a general rise of interest costs and contraction of credit. In the words of the Cunliffe Committee, this would
result in "a decline in general prices in the home market which, by checking imports and stimulating exports, corrected the adverse trade balance
which was the primary cause of the difficulty."5 In this way, central
banks could perform their mission of lender of last resort—could provide
credit institutions, in times of need, with the liquid funds necessary to
tide them over temporary panics and difficulties—while still transmitting
to the economy the external pressures arising from balance of payments
disequilibria under the pure gold standard system. They could expand
credit in times of favorable balances and contract it, except for temporary
assistance to the banks, in times of unfavorable balances. The general
effect of this policy would be similar to the automatic results of gold
inflows or outflows under a purely metallic monetary standard, at least
as far as the direction of the movements was concerned.
The hiatus between gold and total monetary circulation introduced by
deposit banking, however, could greatly increase monetary fluctuations
and affect their incidence. Under a fractional reserve system of commercial banking, given the fairly stable ratio maintained by British banks
between cash and deposits, the deposit component of monetary circulation would increase or decrease by several times the amount of the increase
or decrease in the cash reserves of the banks. Banking expansion and
contraction would also affect the cash balances of some individuals and
firms which, under the pure gold standard, might not otherwise have been
touched, at least directly, by the monetary fluctuations resulting from
disequilibria in the country's balance of payments. Finally, because of the
narrow gold base which it maintained, the Bank of England, in order to
4
In the first crisis following the Bank Act, the Bank refused full support to the market
until authorized by the Government to exceed its legal fiduciary issue. Similar authorizations were granted, but not used, in 1857, 1866, and 1914. In the more recent period, further
expansions have been made possible under the Currency and Bank Notes Acts of 1928 and
1939.
6
"First Interim Report of the Committee on Currency and Foreign Exchanges after the
War," in T. E. Gregory, op. cit.y Vol. II, p. 337.




52

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

defend its reserve position, was led to follow credit policies which not
only permitted but also reinforced the automatic contraction resulting
from the retirement of its notes in exchange for gold. The net effect of
the banking superstructure erected upon the gold standard basis was
monetary fluctuations of far greater amplitude than they would have
been under a pure gold standard.
The departure from the pure gold standard mechanism, implicit in the
operations of deposit banks, was carried even further under the "rules
of the game" so much publicized in the twenties by central bank and
League of Nations experts. "Whenever gold flowed in, the central bank
was expected to increase the national currency supply not only through
the purchase of that gold but also through the acquisition of additional
domestic assets; similarly, when gold flowed out, the central bank was
supposed to contract its domestic assets also. In this way the influence
of gold movements on the domestic credit base was to be magnified,
and magnified in accordance with the central bank's reserve ratio. With
a ratio of 33 per cent, for instance, any net increase or decrease in the
gold reserve was supposed to create a threefold expansion or contraction
in the total credit base." 6
The "rules of the game" were presented as synonymous with the rules
of the gold standard itself. Their effects, however, were vastly different
from those envisaged by the theory. Under the pure gold standard,
balance of payments disequilibria produced only an equivalent amount
of expansion or contraction in the monetary circulation, while under the
"rules of the game" they fostered in addition a secondary expansion or
contraction many times the original one. This multiple expansion or
contraction was defended as a way to speed up international readjustments and to conserve the country's international reserves, but the result
was achieved only at the cost of much greater domestic instability. 7
No wonder the "rules of the game" encountered increasing resistance,
and that their breach became more characteristic of monetary policy
than their observance.
The breakdown of the gold standard in the interwar period has often
been ascribed in part to the unwillingness or inability of central banks
6

League of Nations, International Currency Experience, 1944, pp. 66-67.
This instability, moreover, had a very different incidence than that attaching to the
primary contraction or expansion associated with gold flows under the pure gold standard.
I t bore especially heavily on bank borrowers and investment activities. See F. A. von
Hayek, Monetary Nationalism and International Stability (London, 1937), pp. 25-32.
7




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

S3

to play the gold standard game in accordance with its supposed rules.8
It should again be emphasized, however, that these rules did not fit
the pure gold standard theory and that consequently their observance
would have impeded rather than advanced the objectives of the classical
mechanism of international adjustments. Thus, the monetary policy
of the United States in the twenties has often been interpreted as a "sterilization" or "neutralization" policy, and criticized as contrary to gold
standard rules. In fact, however, the total money supply (deposits and
currency outside banks) increased from June 1920 to December 1924
by 7.2 billion dollars, or about 4.5 times the increase in gold reserves
during the same period. In 1925-29, the money supply rose by 7.6 billion
in the face of a decrease in gold reserves. For the period as a whole, therefore, monetary circulation increased by 14.8 billion dollars, while the
increase under a pure gold standard would have been less than 1.5 billion.
Mr. Nurkse's discussion of neutralization policies in the United States
and other countries demonstrates his point that, contrary to the "rules
of the game," "central banks' international and domestic assets . . .
moved far more often in the opposite than in the same direction."9 This
does not mean, however, that the primary impact of the gold flows was
fully offset or neutralized, or even that their influence on monetary
circulation was not multiplied several times by commercial banking
expansion. Thus, in spite of neutralization policies, gold flows may well
have exerted at least as much influence on the money market as they
would have under classical gold standard assumptions.
The most significant development of the period, however, was the
growing importance of domestic factors as the final determinant of monetary policies. While international gold flows continued to stimulate
domestic monetary expansion or contraction, the total volume of money
was no longer controlled by them. Factors of a purely domestic nature
also tended to shape monetary developments in a manner totally alien
both to the classical gold standard mechanism and to its "rules of the
game" interpretation, or rather misinterpretation. Central bank powers
were no longer used to transmit automatically to the domestic economy
the upward or downward pressures of surpluses or deficits in the balance
of payments, regardless of national policy objectives. On the contrary,
central banking policies came to be defined less and less with reference
8
9

See especially Lionel Robbins, The Great Depression (London, 1934).
International Currency Experience, pp. 68-88 and 237-40.




54

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

to the state of the gold reserves or the prerequisites of international
balance, and more and more in terms of domestic price stability, the
promotion of fuller employment, etc. This tendency was greatly reinforced
in the thirties through the general adoption of national recovery programs based on domestic monetary and credit expansion and supported
by exchange control and currency devaluation. Thus the latent contradiction between the international and automatic monetary regulation characteristic of the pure gold standard on the one hand, and the evolution
toward autonomous and discretionary monetary management by national
central banks on the other, was accentuated by practical policies even
though it was not readily incorporated into theoretical analysis.
The swing of the pendulum may now have reversed its direction. The
experience of the thirties has demonstrated the pitfalls of monetary
isolation along purely national lines and the difficulties of reconciling
domestic stability and prosperity with international disequilibrium.
The Bretton Woods Agreements, without returning to the full subordination of national monetary policies to the single goal of exchange stability,
have sought to re-establish some mechanism designed to protect the
international economy against autarchic excesses in the monetary field.
Member countries agree to cede to the Fund a considerable measure of
control over modifications in their exchange rates or the imposition of
exchange restrictions. To make possible this partial renunciation of
national monetary sovereignty, the International Monetary Fund undertakes to make available to member countries, in times of need, additional
exchange reserves necessary to finance temporary deficits in their balance
of payments. The Fund, however, does not attempt to restore an automatic international monetary standard. Central banks and other national
monetary authorities are left free to determine domestic monetary policies as long as they do not use the resources of the Fund "in a manner
contrary to the purposes of the Fund." The success of the new institution will thus depend largely on the soundness of the national monetary
policies followed by its members, and on the successful solution by each
member country of the basic conflict between domestic goals of action
and the preservation of international balance. Fundamental disequilibria, if not corrected by domestic measures of readjustment, would
perpetuate the need for new borrowings from the Fund or would force
recourse to currency devaluation or exchange control. The assistance
provided by the Fund is a limited right of borrowing, equivalent to a mere




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

55

increase in the members' international reserves, together with some
protection against arbitrary and damaging monetary action by other
members.
No attempt is made, however, to lay down detailed "rules of the game"
for the new international standard which would prevent or correct fundamental international disequilibria. And yet, it is well recognized that
persistent deficits in a country's balance of payments would ultimately
lead to the exhaustion of its limited drawing rights on the Fund, as well
as of its gold and foreign exchange reserves. Once such a situation is
reached, the whole Fund machinery becomes ineffective,10 and no paper
commitments can maintain free and stable exchange rates. Correction
of international disequilibria is thus crucial to the successful functioning
of the new international monetary standard.
THE CORRECTION OF INTERNATIONAL DISEQUILIBRIA

Notwithstanding the important divergencies between the classical
gold standard theory and its modern "rules of the game" version, both
types of analyses coincide in some important respects. Balance of payments disequilibria are ascribed to international cost and price disparities,
and their correction is made to depend on the elimination of such disparities through automatic, or induced, domestic monetary expansion
or contraction.
These views of the mechanism of international adjustment under gold
standard assumptions are open to grave question. First, they fail to
distinguish between a fundamental disequilibrium in one country's
international position and world-wide disturbances in balances of payments associated with cyclical fluctuations. Secondly, the explanation
of the readjustment of a country's balance of payments is vitiated by the
underlying and totally unrealistic assumption of near-perfect competition
between nations of roughly equal strength and importance in world trade.
Cyclical vs. Fundamental Maladjustments. The classical explanation
of balance of payments maladjustments runs in terms of price and
cost disparities between one country and the rest of the world. While
applicable to many important instances of disequilibria, this analysis
does not exhaust all possible causes of deficits in a country's international
transactions. The most cursory examination of statistical data clearly
shows that many of the most spectacular disequilibria in balances of
10
The day of reckoning could, of course, be postponed as long as the Fund was willing
and able to grant, under Art. V, Sec. 4, additional drawing rights to meet the deficit.




56

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

payments are world-wide in scope, and must be traced to cyclical fluctuations of an international character rather than to national price and cost
maladj ustment s.
In the decade prior to the war, for instance, the dollar value of world
trade fell by more than 60 per cent between 1929 and 1932, increased by
by 23.5 per cent from 1936 to 1937, and fell again by 12.5 per cent during
1938. If the major cause of these fluctuations had resided in international
price and cost disparities, it would be expected that high-cost countries
would have shown a decrease in exports and an increase in imports, while
low-cost countries would have shown movements in the opposite direction. The striking fact, however, is that, in spite of differences in amplitude, both exports and imports moved in the same direction for practically
all trading countries. Clearly, the major force impinging upon their trade
was international in character, and associated with a world cycle rather
than with maladjustments in individual countries.
To take a concrete illustration, in the short space of three years (1929—
31), Colombia lost 80 per cent of its central bank gold and foreign exchange reserves. Total exports fell from 122 million dollars in 1929 to 67
million in 1932, a decline of 46 per cent. Coffee, the major export item
(about 60 per cent of total export values), suffered a reduction of 45 per
cent. If this contraction in coffee exports had been due to disparities in
production costs between Colombia and other major coffee exporting
countries in competition with her, we would expect these other countries
to have expanded their exports at the expense of Colombian producers.
The fact is, however, that during the same period total exports and coffee
exports of all other competing coffee countries were also falling in similar,
or even larger, proportions. This coincidence in time of export fluctuations
in these countries was also characteristic of the recovery period 193337, the 1937-40 decline, and the record levels of exports reached during
the more recent war years. It might of course be argued that, even though
no price disparity was evident as between the various coffee exporting
countries, all of them were suffering simultaneously from the consequences of excessive price and cost levels as compared with the rest of the
world, and that the classical prescription for readjustment still remained
applicable to the group as a whole. This position, however, would be hard
to defend in view of the fact that the export prices for typical coffee
grades had fallen to nearly one-half of their 1928 level by 1930 and to not
far from one-third by 1931, without resulting in any substantial recovery
of quantities exported.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

57

Indeed, for most agricultural countries, large export receipts and favorable balances of payments usually coincide with high and not with low
levels of domestic and export prices. The reason for this is that their export volume and export prices fluctuate as much with demand as with
supply conditions, if not more. That is, they are largely determined by
international rather than domestic factors. Major fluctuations in export
values result primarily from cyclical movements in economic activity and
income in the buying countries, and not from changes in the relationship
of domestic price or cost levels to prices and costs in other competing or
buying countries. Thus, for many agricultural and raw material countries,
the international cycle is mainly an imported product. Such is also the
conclusion of the League of Nations' Delegation on Economic Depressions. "General depressions would seem to result mainly from fluctuations
in investment and employment in industrial countries." 11
Whenever this is true, the classical prescription for remedial policy
becomes as misleading as the diagnosis on which it is based. Deflationary
efforts at readjustment by individual countries are largely self-defeating
because they aggravate the depression rather than cure the disequilibrium. Any initial success that they may have in curbing imports or
expanding exports aggravates the difficulties in their supply and export
markets as well as in competing countries, and leads to similar and mutually offsetting measures of defense or retaliation. I t should be noted
that the argument applies equally to remedial action through currency
devaluation and through internal price changes. Under the conditions
described, both price deflation and currency devaluation spread from
country to country and accentuate the international deflation. While
some categories of exports may expand under the stimulus of price reductions, the expansion will often be insufficient to compensate for the
decline in unit prices, especially in the case of agricultural or raw material
exports faced with an inelastic world demand. The burden of readjustment
then falls upon imports, the reduction of which further aggravates income
contraction abroad and the effective demand for each country's exports.
The situation described presents a strong analogy with that of oligopoly, where efforts by one seller to cut into his competitors' markets are
"League of Nations, Economic Stability in the Post-War World (1945), p. 291. The clearest case is provided by the brief depression of 1938 in which world exports to the United
States fell by over 35 per cent in a single year, while United States exports decreased by only
7 per cent. It is not denied, of course, that other factors—including price disparities—may
be simultaneously operating in bringing about or accentuating a major depression.




58

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

thwarted by the competitors' retaliation and the ensuing price war. The
expansionary effect of a decline in one country's prices upon its exports is
largely offset by simultaneous, or retaliatory, price decreases by competing countries. Thus the effective elasticity of demand for one country's
exports becomes merged with the much lower elasticity of world demand
for products of the types the country exports.12 Sales can be expanded on
a stable basis only in so far as lower prices stimulate world consumption,
a result that is not achieved through inroads into other nations' markets.
It should be noted that this analysis does not conflict in any way with
the classical theory of balance of payments maladjustments. It merely
applies to an entirely different set of circumstances. Cyclical disturbances
of the kind assumed here played little or no part in classical analysis.
The error made by later economists—and especially by the "rules of the
game" school—was to extend to world-wide, cyclical disturbances an
analysis aimed at fundamental maladjustments between one economy
and the rest of the world. In the latter case, moderate price changes by
the deficit country may restore its normal export-import balance and
share of world trade without depressing world prices to any significant
extent. This is especially true if, as contemplated also in classical theory,
its exports are broadly diversified rather than concentrated on one or a
few major items. During a global depression, however, simultaneous
efforts by many nations at maintaining or increasing their exports in the
face of a shrinking world demand merely result in an accelerated fall of
prices and reduction of export proceeds.
Gold Standard or Sterling Exchange Standard? A second assumption
underlying the classical theory of the gold standard is that of near-perfect
competition between many trading nations, more or less coequal in importance. The assumption is obviously unrealistic, and in recent years
many writers have emphasized the central position occupied by Great
Britain in the nineteenth century functioning of the gold standard.13 It
has been suggested that that position "made the prewar gold standard
essentially a sterling exchange standard system,"14 but the concrete implications of that assertion have not been fully drawn. If examined, they
12
In the case of competing oligopolists, the effective demand elasticity is similarly determined by the demand curve for the industry as a whole, rather than by the demand curve
which would face any one seller if his competitors' prices remained constant.
13
See, especially, William Adams Brown, Jr., The International Gold Standard Reinterpreted (New York,' 1940).
14
Idem, p. xiii.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

59

may suggest one possible explanation both for the relative success of the
gold standard in Britain and for its failure to operate satisfactorily in the
least industrialized nations. In many of the latter countries it was adhered
to only sporadically, and abandoned in times of crisis. When actually
enforced, it may well have retarded rather than accelerated the rate of
their economic development. In Great Britain itself the mechanism of
balance of payments readjustments seems to have operated, in important
respects, in a manner directly opposite to that described by gold standard
theory. To a very large extent, increases in the London discount rates
brought about a readjustment in the British balances of payments, not
through their effects on the British economy, but through their effects
on the outside world and especially on the agricultural and raw material
countries.
One of the reasons for this has long been recognized. As early as 1840
it was pointed out by Tooke before a Select Committee of the House of
Commons on banks of issue, that: "The effect upon the exchange of a
rise in the rate of interest would be that of inducing foreign capitalists to
abstain from calling for their funds from this country to the same extent
as they otherwise might do, and it would operate at the same time in
diminishing the inducements to capitalists in this country to invest in
foreign securities or to hold foreign securities, and it might induce them
to part with foreign securities in order to invest in British stocks and
shares. It would likewise operate in restraining credits from the merchants
in tliis country by advances on shipments outwards, and it would have the
effect of causing a larger proportion of the importations into this country
to be carried on upon foreign capital."15
This shift in international capital movements contributed powerfully
to a rapid restoration of equilibrium in the exchange market. However,
it tended to relieve rather than accentuate domestic deflationary pressures
on the economy, and to that extent to delay or prevent the basic readjustment of fundamental price and cost disparities contemplated by gold
standard theorists. It constituted, in a sense, the equivalent of the compensatory monetary policies so strongly condemned by many gold standard theorists.
Similarly, the outflow of capital in periods of favorable balances tended
to check surpluses and thus to reduce external expansionary impacts
upon the British economy. This again was contrary to the "rules of the
18

Quoted by R. G. Hawtrey, The Art of Central Banking (London, 1932), p. 141.




60

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

game" and tantamount to the opposite policy of sterilization or neutralization of gold movements.
Debtor countries, however, did not have a similar mechanism at their
disposal. Capital tended to flow toward them in times of prosperity and
away from them in times of depression, irrespective of their discount
policy. The effect of such fluctuations in capital movements was to smooth
down cyclical monetary and credit fluctuations in the creditor countries,
but to accentuate them in the debtor countries. To that extent the financial centers could shift part of the burden of readjustment upon the weaker
countries in the world economy. Their only mechanism of defense was the
policy consistently followed by the Central Bank of Argentina in the
recent past with such remarkable success: to offset external drains from or
accretions to its reserves through domestic policies of expansion or contraction. This was contrary to classical orthodoxy, but in fact equivalent
to the effects of the British discount rate on capital movements to and
from Great Britain.
The readjustment of fundamental price disequilibria which changes in
the British discount rate were designed to stimulate was thus thwarted
and delayed by the effects of such changes on capital movements. I t is
still contended, however, that those basic readjustments would obtain
in the end, capital movements notwithstanding, through the domestic
effects of discount changes on British prices. The discount rate would be
raised and credit would be contracted in order to force down excessive
British prices to levels more competitive with the level of foreign prices.
On the other hand, the discount rate would be lowered and credit would
expand when British prices were low relative to foreign prices and tended
to disequilibrate the balance of payments in Britain's favor.
I t should be noted that, according to this theory, the British deficit
would be corrected through a deterioration of the British terms of trade
(i.e., a decrease in British prices relative to foreign prices), such deterioration being considered necessary to restore the international competitive
position of British producers. Logically speaking, however, the opposite
assumption is just as plausible. That is to say, the elimination of the
deficit might also result from an improvement in the British terms of trade,
decreasing the unit cost of imports and increasing the returns on exports. 16
16
Reconstruction and statistical verification of balance of payments readjustments would
have to distinguish between: (1) the relationship of Britain's prices and costs to competing
countries' prices and costs for similar goods; and (2) the relative price movements of noncompeting import goods (raw materials and foodstuffs) and export goods (manufactures).
Such a discussion, however, would exceed the scope and purpose of this paper.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 61
Statistical evidence may be used to support either theory. During the
interwar period, the British terms of trade consistently improved in depression and deteriorated during the upswing of the cycle.17 Before the
First World War available data are more difficult to interpret and they
reveal, if anything, sharper rises in export prices than in import prices
during the crest of the boom. Indexes of export prices for that period,
however, give relatively little weight to manufactured products and do
not appear to be truly representative of British exports in general.
As far as the discount rate is concerned, the interwar period is of minor
interest for the elucidation of the problem under consideration. The
discount policy had ceased by then to be a major instrument of monetary
control and, moreover, Britain was no longer the dominant financial
center of the world. In the 30 years prior to the First World War, however, the statistical series fail to confirm the traditional view that an
increase in discount rates contributed directly to a lowering of British
prices relative to foreign prices. On the contrary, all major rises in the
discount rate are associated with an improvement of the British terms of
trade, i.e., with an increase in export prices relative to import prices. 18
The declines in the terms of trade followed the increases in the discount
rate only after a considerable lag, and actually coincided with decreases
in the rate. Their most obvious explanation would seem to lie in depressed
business conditions in Britain, associated with the spread of the international cycle, rather than in any direct influence of the discount rate over
domestic prices.
This improvement in the British terms of trade in periods of rising
discount rates should not be surprising, in view of the special position of
Britain as a financial center for world trade. On purely a priori grounds,
it would appear at least as probable as the opposite pattern contemplated
by the classicists. What was really discussed by them was the case of
price disparities between one country and a large number of other countries, equal to the first in importance. Under that assumption, deflation
17
The ratio of export to import prices, calculated from Board of Trade indexes, declined
from 104 in 1923 to 98 in 1929, rose during the ensuing depression to a peak of 122 in 1933,
fell to 107 in the relatively prosperous year 1937, and improved again to 116 during the 1938
recession.
18
Thus the yearly average of discount rates rose gradually from 2.9 per cent in 1885 to
4.5 per cent in 1890, while the ratio of export to import prices improved from 91 to 106.
The next sustained rise in the rate, from 2 per cent in 1895 to 3.9 in 1900, was accompanied
by an increase in the ratio from 97 to 114. The same positive correlation between rising rates
and better terms of trade continued until the outbreak of war.




62

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

by the first country would force down domestic prices and costs without
affecting to any significant extent the level of prices in the rest of the
world. The position of Britain in the nineteenth century was, however, a
very different one. Britain was the major center of world trade and
finance, and British deflationary efforts immediately affected, not only
the British economy and prices, but also the economy and prices of other
countries, transmitting to them the cyclical fluctuations experienced by
Great Britain. Thus, the problem became essentially one, not of disparities between one country and the others, but of a simultaneous upward or downward movement engulfing most other nations along with
Great Britain.
We have already seen that the most immediate effect of a rise in the
British discount rates was to reverse the normal direction of international
capital movements. The outflow of funds from the other countries toward
Great Britain exerted an immediate downward pressure on prices and
income in those countries. In fact, since the great bulk of foreign exports
was financed through London, and since foreign bills far outweighed inland bills in the London discount market, a tightening in discount rates
could be expected to affect the prices of foreign goods more drastically
and directly than domestic prices in Britain. The reverse would be true
in the case of a credit relaxation or expansion in London. These movements would be further magnified by the banking contraction or expansion thus induced in the foreign countries themselves, especially as
higher discount rates in those markets would tighten domestic credit
without attracting, as they did in London, compensatory capital movements from abroad.
These considerations are reinforced by the fact that a large part of
Britain's exports consisted of manufactured industrial products, while
the bulk of her imports was composed of foodstuffs and raw materials.
Less flexibility of demand and supply conditions could be expected to
make the prices of the second category of goods especially sensitive to
credit contraction and expansion, as well as to general cyclical fluctuations.
The failure of British discount policy to effect the type of readjustments contemplated in classical theory is thus easily understandable.
I t was due primarily to the international character of the London discount
market, whose expansion and contraction affected foreign prices as much
as or more than British prices. I t is also explainable by the fact that




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

63

producers of agricultural and raw materials are more vulnerable to cyclical and credit fluctuations than is the British economy.19
A POSITIVE POLICY FOR THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
One main conclusion emerges from the foregoing analysis. The "rules
of the game" of the twentieth century gold standard, no matter how valid
they may be in the case of isolated fundamental disequilibria in one
country's or a few countries' international accounts, are totally inappropriate for dealing with world-wide cyclical fluctuations. The main
result of "orthodox" gold standard policies under such circumstances was
to spread throughout the world at large any cyclical disturbance arising
in major industrialized nations. Balance of payments deficits would be
corrected in the end, but mostly through a general contraction in income
and economic activity, rather than through direct price readjustments.
Furthermore, the accompanying price changes would leave in their wake
a basically unbalanced structure of international prices wThen the cyclical
depression subsided and more normal conditions were restored.
The success of the International Monetary Fund will largely depend on
the progressive development and general acceptance of new canons of
international monetary behavior, to replace the previous "rules of the
game" code. These new standards of policy should be less crude in their
application, and more acceptable to the national monetary authorities of
member countries. They should recognize the primacy of domestic goals
of stability and high levels of economic performance, and distinguish
strongly between cyclical and fundamental disequilibria in the balances
of payments.
Anti-cyclical Monetary Policies. The International Monetary Fund has
proclaimed that one of its main purposes is "to facilitate the expansion
and balanced growth of international trade, and to contribute thereby to '
the promotion and maintenance of high levels of employment and real
income and to the development of the productive resources of all members
as primary objectives of monetary policy."20 This formulation recognizes
the basic agreement and interdependence of national and international
monetary objectives. A large volume of world trade obviously contributes
to domestic prosperity. Conversely, domestic prosperity in one country
19
A somewhat similar observation is made by R. G. Hawtrey in A Century of Bank Rate
(London, 1938), p. 44, but is not systematically related to the general theory of balance of
payments readjustments, which it so clearly contradicts.
20
Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund, Art. I (ii).




64

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

redounds to the benefit of other members by maintaining effective demand for imports and thus encouraging exports and production in other
areas. The responsibility of the largest and more industrialized countries
is especially heavy in this respect. Major depressions usually originate
with them, rather than with smaller, agricultural nations, and are especially contagious internationally because of the weight these countries
have in world trade and finance. The only satisfactory corrective of
cyclical disequilibria in the balance of payments which are not due to
fundamental maladjustments in international price levels thus lies for
most nations, not in internal deflation according to the "rules of the
game" recipe, but in the restoration of economic activity and purchasing
power in the centers of the cyclical disturbance.
Balance of payments disequilibria, however, will continue to occur and
to threaten domestic stability, especially in countries with undiversified
economies, heavily dependent on international trade and especially on
one or a few export products for which demand is inelastic. Variations in
weather and crop yields as well as cyclical fluctuations in the major world
markets will result in alternate phases of favorable and unfavorable
balances, reflected in inflationary and deflationary pressures on incomes,
cash balances, prices, and costs. Such disequilibria will be of a temporary
character, and the country should attempt to offset them to the largest
possible extent by domestic compensatory policies. In doing so, it will
contribute to international stabilization as well as to the maintenance of
domestic levels of income and activity. In the absence of compensatory
action—and even worse, if the automatic upward or downward pressures
are reinforced in accordance with the "rules of the game" by secondary
domestic expansion or contraction—not only national but also international balance will be needlessly sacrificed, since domestic "adjustments" to temporary disturbances of equilibrium will result in basic
maladjustments, once the temporary factors cease to operate and more
normal conditions are restored.
Anti-cyclical compensatory policies would thus in general help to
moderate both national and international depressions and to preserve
fundamental international balance. Their generalized adoption, however, would tend to amplify the instability of national reserves of gold
and foreign exchange. As long as the temporary factors of disequilibrium
are present, reserves will move from the deficit to the surplus countries,
unchecked by counteracting movements in prices, exchange rates, or




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY 65
national incomes. This redistribution of reserves, even though temporary,
creates a serious problem. The receiving countries accumulate funds
which will help them to meet later deficits, but for which they have no
immediate use or need. On the other hand, the drain on the reserves of
the deficit countries may be such as to make a continuation of compensatory policies incompatible with the preservation of free and stable
exchanges. I t is precisely this situation which the International Fund is so
well organized to meet. The drain of reserves is arrested, or moderated,
by an indirect extension of credit by the surplus countries to the deficit
countries, through their accounts with the Fund. In this manner
the deficit countries are enabled to avoid recourse to internal deflation,
currency devaluation, exchange control, or other restrictive policies,
while the lending of unneeded accretions to reserves by the surplus countries protects them against the contractionary effects which such measures
of defense would exert on their exports and domestic economic activity.
One of the main dangers of the system is the abuse of the Fund's credit
for the financing of fundamental, as opposed to cyclical or fortuitous,
disequilibria in a country's international account. In that case, the borrowings would assume a continuous character, and indebtedness to the
Fund would pile up rapidly until the country's quota was exhausted.
Adequate safeguards must be provided against such abuse of the Fund's
machinery, and toward the application of effective remedial action.21
In the first place, a deficit country should be required to make the
fullest possible use of its own international reserves. In the Fund's Charter
this problem is approached in an indirect and incomplete manner through
the application of the so-called "repurchase provisions." 22 Further progress in this direction appears highly desirable in the long run, through
amendment, interpretation, administration of the Fund's statutes, or
through the Fund's powers of moral suasion. Such action, however,
will meet considerable resistance, based on the still prevalent misinterpretation of the role of monetary reserves. In many countries monetary
legislation as well as public opinion still regards the central bank's gold and
foreign exchange reserves as the "backing" of the currency. Reserve
ratios between gold and foreign exchange holdings and the central bank's
note issue or total sight obligations are viewed by the public as an indication of the currency's soundness, and are generally subject by law to
minimum requirements. This deep-rooted tradition bars the effective
21
22

See below, pp. 75-78.
Articles of Agreement, Art. V, Sec. 7.




66

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

employment of reserves at the time when they are most needed and for
the only economic purpose which they can usefully serve.
This anachronistic conception of central bank reserves dates back to an
entirely different institutional environment, in which gold coin effectively
circulated as the ultimate legal tender, and central banks were under
strict legal obligation to convert their notes into gold, not only for balance
of payment purposes, but also for internal circulation within a country.
In practice, gold coin does not circulate today as money, and bank notes
have become the ultimate legal tender for domestic payments. The only
purpose of a gold or foreign exchange reserve is, therefore, to provide
available resources to meet, without undue pressure on the currency, a
deficit in the balance of payments. 23 All member countries should be
induced to accept this viewpoint and to liberate their reserves for effective use in case of need.
Recourse to foreign borrowings outside the Fund is a second possible
line of action in case reserves are not adequate to meet a drain. This
would be especially valuable to meet specific rehabilitation or developmental expenditures, the financing of which is outside the scope of the
Fund. Financing could be obtained through private investments or
through the help of such institutions as the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, the Export-Import Bank, etc.
The third practical device is the husbanding of reserves for the most
urgent needs, through a system of priorities in allocating available exchange. Unfortunately the very mention of "exchange control" raises
such emotional reactions with many people as to prevent any serious
discussion of the subject. The history of exchange control in the last two
decades is such as to justify fully the condemnation of most exchange
control systems used in the past. It does not, however, justify a blind
condemnation of exchange controls as such, irrespective of their concrete
forms and of the circumstances leading to their adoption. In some cases
exchange control has been deliberately used as a weapon of economic
blackmail and aggression. In other cases, however, it has been adopted
as the result of sheer necessity and as a lesser evil. The statesmen who
introduced exchange control in so many countries were not necessarily
blackguards or fools. Their motives should be understood and, while
every effort should be made to prevent abuses or unnecessary restrictions,
23
The "war chest" argument falls within the scope of this definition, although recent procedures of foreign funds controls weaken greatly the value of gold for purchases in enemy,
or even neutral, countries.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

67

the real purposes which nondiscriminatory controls can justifiably serve
should not be summarily dismissed. Constructive criticism may succeed
where dogmatic and purely negative opposition has failed and will
probably remain as sterile in the future as it has proved in the past.
Both a member country and the Fund may prefer self-denial through
exchange restrictions to excessive borrowings, internal deflation, or exchange depreciation. Provision is made for some such cases in the Fund
Agreement itself. First, the Fund gives the members full freedom "to
exercise such controls as are necessary to regulate international capital
movements" not connected with payments for current transactions or
settlement of commitments.24 Members are even prohibited, in principle,
from making net use of the Fund's resources "to meet a large and sustained outflow of capital, and the Fund may request a member to exercise
controls to prevent such use of the resources of the Fund. If, after receiving such a request, a member fails to exercise appropriate controls,
the Fund may declare the member ineligible to use the resources of the
Fund.25
Secondly, the demands made upon the Fund for a member's currency
may exceed the Fund's ability to supply it. In that case, the Fund may
ultimately be forced to declare such a currency scarce and to ration its
supply among the members applying for it. Such a declaration "shall
operate as an authorization to any member, after consultation with the
Fund, temporarily to impose limitations on the freedom of exchange
operations in the scarce currency."26
Finally, the Fund may authorize a member country to "impose restrictions on the making of payments and transfers [even] for current international transactions."27 The case would be especially likely to occur
when a country has exhausted its drawing rights, under Article V, Section
3 of the Agreement, and when, at the same time, the Fund is reluctant
to give, under Section 4, special approval for further borrowings. The
only alternative to such authorization would then be either the enforcement of strong deflationary policies—the results of which might, in any
case, prove too slow to solve the immediate exchange problem—or currency devaluation. Again, either of these alternatives would be highly
undesirable in the case of cyclical or temporary disequilibria.
24

Articles of Agreement, Art. VI, Sec. 3.
Ibid., Art. VI, Sec. 1.
Ibid., Art. VII, Sec. 3 ( b ) .
27
Ibid., Art. VIII.
25

26




68

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

Exchange control may possibly be preferred to excessive loss of reserves
and borrowings from the Fund, even before reserves and drawing rights
have been exhausted. A country may feel that borrowings should not be
resorted to on a very large scale for the sole purpose of financing imports
of a purely sumptuary character. The Fund might concur with this view
and authorize some exchange restrictions rather than force further and
unwanted loans upon the country. Such an attitude on the part of the
Fund's authorities would not be unlikely in view of the specific limitations
placed by the Fund Agreement upon the use of the Fund's resources to
finance capital outflows. While not identical, the two cases present some
broad similarities. The general tenor of the Chapultepec discussions on
the desirability of husbanding, for the purpose of economic development,
reserves acquired in wartime is in harmony with this view.
The creation of the International Monetary Fund, therefore, should not
be interpreted as definitely removing, even after the expiration of the
transition period, all justification for and possibility of exchange control
measures by member countries. The Fund will greatly reduce the need for
exchange control, and set up safeguards against unnecessary or discriminatory restrictions. It will not, and should not, blindly and flatly
prohibit all use of legitimate controls as an instrument of monetary
policy, when temporary exchange shortages make them the only alternative to drastic deflationary policies or to currency devaluation. As has
been indicated above, price or currency adjustments may often be wholly
inadequate to correct balance of payments deficits except through the
resulting contraction of national income and effective import demand.
This is especially true in the case of agricultural or raw material producing
countries faced with an inelastic demand for their exports. Moreover,
since only a fraction of a country's total income is spent abroad, the
balancing of foreign transactions by contraction of national income is
likely to require a decline in the income level several times as great as the
deficit to be resorbed.28 This is clearly undesirable on national grounds
and does not, in any way, lessen the unfavorable impact of import contraction on world trade. On the contrary, it aggravates the difficulties
of competing exporting countries. Finally, it corrects a temporary disequilibrium at the cost of creating a fundamental one, in the other direction, once the transient factors of disturbance have disappeared. Under
such circumstances, temporary and selective controls of expenditures
28
More strictly speaking, this will depend on the "marginal propensity" to import and on
the elasticity of export supply and demand.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

69

abroad are far preferable to indiscriminate and multiple income adjustments.
The efforts of the International Monetary Fund should thus be directed,
not toward indiscriminate abolition of all exchange controls, but toward
the elimination of the abuses which have often characterized them in the
past.
The most patent and most crucial defect of exchange control lies in
the discriminatory practices to which it lends itself. As long as exchange
is rationed on an individual basis, through arbitrary decisions of the
national agencies entrusted with the application of the controls, any
allocation will be open to the accusation of incompetence, favoritism, or
dishonesty in the distribution of the scarce exchange among importers as
well as among supplying countries or firms.29 Such a procedure, however,
is by no means inevitable.
A promising alternative would be to enforce exchange restrictions
through flexible and impersonal market forces, leaving the importers free
to buy whatever they please wherever they please (presumably from the
cheapest source of supply), subject only to such automatic restrictions as
would normally result from the free interplay of supply and demand.
More concretely, what is suggested is a well-organized plan whereby all
of the current exchange receipts available to the monetary authorities is
offered for sale in the manner described in the following paragraphs.
(1) The monetary authorities would make exchange freely available,
without previous permit or restrictions of any sort, at the normal exchange rates, for payment of all essential and urgent imports or services
and of contractual obligations, dividends, or reasonable amortization on
approved foreign investments.
(2) The remainder of available exchange would be sold by the monetary
authorities to provide means of payment for deferrable or nonessential
imports and services, again without quantitative restrictions or import
permits, through the functioning of one, or a few, auction markets. In
29
International acceptance of a "previous representative period" criterion as an objective
guide for allocation might help to some extent, but would be of limited value. First, it could
not serve as a pattern for commodity allocation, since any rationing of scarce exchange
should change the "representative" pattern of imports in favor of more essential and against
less essential imports. Secondly, the "previous representative period" criterion tends to freeze
the channels of trade in a very arbitrary and uneconomic manner, especially when it becomes
necessary to go far back into the past to discover a "representative" period. Structural
changes brought about by the war make it extremely difficult to accept prewar patterns
as representative. Difficulties are even greater in the case of the many countries in which
prewar trade was subject to import quotas and exchange control regulation.




70

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

other words, the limited supply would be distributed among the buyers,
not by administrative decision, but as a result of an impersonal pricing
mechanism.
In order to provide the central bank with sufficient exchange to assure
the functioning of these two markets—the normal and the auction—all
exchange proceeds from exports or other easily controllable sources would
have to be sold, at the normal exchange rates, to the monetary authorities.
On the other hand, exchange proceeds from unimportant or practically
uncontrollable transactions could be freely sold and bought in a free exchange market. This would avoid giving a premium to illegal transactions, where evasion cannot be effectively checked, and would also provide
an escape valve for the control system. Capital exports, beyond those
which have access to the official market, could be channelled here without
harmful repercussions on the rates applying to more essential exchange
requirements. The higher rates prevailing on the free market in times of
crises would, moreover, tend to discourage capital exports and encourage
capital imports.
The advantages of such a plan are clear. It would eliminate at the
root arbitrary and discriminatory allocation of exchange, drastically
simplify the administrative machinery, red tape, and delays, and reduce
the possibilities of graft or favoritism in the distribution of exchange
permits. From the international point of view, the main objection raised,
quite properly, against the traditional forms of exchange control would
also disappear. Nothing in the system would tend to destroy, or even
weaken, a multilateral system of world trade. No distinction need be
made between the various currencies bid for on any auction market; on
the contrary, all auction premiums should be uniform, in percentage
terms, for any one category of transactions, no matter what foreign currency is involved. The exact currency requested need not even be specified until the bidding is over and the exchange allocated. Indeed, as long
as interconvertibility of currencies is maintained, the central bank would
have no justifiable incentive to sell one currency in preference to another. 30
This method of procedure would enable the Fund to judge whether
exchange control is justified in the particular circumstances and also to
supervise exchange control. The plan would not be contrary to the expressed purposes of the Fund, although at first sight it might appear that
the differential rates implied in the functioning of the auctioning and
80

The case of inconvertibility will be discussed below, pp. 73-74.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

71

free exchange markets might be interpreted as a multiple currency
practice. I t must be recalled that the problem before both the Fund
and the country is the allocation of a limited quota of exchange
among various claimants and that some method of restriction is both
basic and inevitable. It should be noted that the Fund Agreement (Article
VIII, 3) specifically permits the adoption of multiple currency practices
provided approval has been obtained from the Fund. Indeed, the Fund's
approval is necessary, not only for this case, but for the more general one
of any system of controls on current transactions (except as applied to
scarce currencies, or under the transitional arrangements of Article XIV).
More than that, however, the exact meaning of the "multiple currency"
clause is open to question. The system here proposed does not constitute
a multiple currency practice at all, if the term is interpreted to imply the
setting up of different exchange premiums as between currencies. As
pointed out above, no distinction is allowed as between currencies, but
only as between different categories of transactions, irrespective of the
currencies involved.
Secondly, the auction and free market premiums are completely
flexible, and would not—as would rigid multiple rates—introduce any
effective restriction on exchange transactions independent from and
additional to the basic and inevitable restriction resulting from the
allocation among various claimants of a limited quota of exchange. Since
under the proposed system the monetary authorities would be forced to
sell fully that quota for whatever rate was offered in an open auction, the
rate itself would not in any way constitute an independent or additional
restriction. Foreign exports to the country would be limited only by the
application of the quota, and would be in no way influenced by the fact
that the exchange rate diverged from normal. The only significant effect
would be a purely domestic and entirely desirable one, i.e., the recapture
by the monetary authorities of the unjustified windfall profits that would
otherwise accrue to importers.
I t should be kept in mind that any scarcity of exchange which reduces
imports below the normal demand at the official exchange rates tends to
drive up domestic prices no matter what the exchange rate charged to
the importers to which exchange is allocated may be. In the absence of
price control and rationing, the importers would be led to charge what
the traffic would bear, or would distribute their short supplies in an
arbitrary and capricious manner. While price control and rationing might
reasonably be expected for essential goods of mass consumption, in most




72

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

countries they would not normally be extended to sales of luxuries and
semi-luxuries, or would not be effectively enforced. Under the auction
system, the importers would be forced to compete with one another for
the exchange offered for sale. Such competition would drive the rate to,
but not beyond, the point at which profits would be close to competitive
levels, under competitive pricing conditions. Special problems might, of
course, arise in the case of collusion or monopolistic practices by the
sellers, but these would arise as well under a system of administrative
allocation. They could be taken care of, as far as is administratively and
politically feasible, without modifying the basic mechanism of control
suggested above.
I t might be observed in passing that any system of tariff duties is
equivalent to very real and rigid multiple currency practices. The very
fact that objections to tariffs are so much milder than objections to
multiple exchange rates again suggests that we often tend to fight words
rather than realities. If the problem is viewed without dogmatic preconceptions, it will be realized that the allocation of scarce exchange through
a free auction system carries no restrictive element that is not implicit in
the limitation placed on the amount of exchange made available to the
market. On the other hand, it presents the tremendous advantage of
eliminating, or restricting considerably, the opportunity for favoritism or
discrimination on the part of the exchange authorities.
The supervision of exchange control by the International Monetary
Fund will not be limited to the avoidance of discriminatory administration of the controls. The Fund will also want to judge whether exchange
control as such is justified in the concrete circumstances under which a
member country requests permission to adopt it. As the Fund gets under
operation, it will have to develop certain general and objective criteria
for granting or denying such requests, in order to avoid arbitrary, discriminatory, or merely haphazard decisions which would soon breed illwill among the members and endanger their loyalty to the institution.
The problem is most acute for the smaller countries, whose vote in the
Fund's councils will necessarily have little weight in reaching a decision.
These countries should be guaranteed an impartial treatment based on as
objective rules and principles of policy as can be practically devised by
the Fund.
One of the first criteria to be taken into consideration is clearly the level
of international reserves of the country requesting the authorization for
the establishment of exchange restrictions. The appraisal of the adequacy




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

73

or inadequacy of these reserves, from the point of view of balance of
payments needs, cannot be gauged with reference to the traditional
reserve ratios relating gold and foreign exchange holdings to note circulation or sight obligations. What is here relevant is the ability of the country
to finance from its own reserves foreseeable deficits in its international
transactions. From this point of view, reserves should first be expressed
as a percentage of the normal requirements for payments abroad, i.e.,
of total annual sales of exchange by the banks. A reserve ratio of 30 per
cent, for instance, would mean that the central bank could maintain a
free and stable exchange market for one year in the face of a 30 per cent
deficit in the balance of payments, or for two years, in the case of a 15 per
cent deficit. Calculated in this way, the level of reserves would indicate
the extent of the breathing spell which the monetary authorities would
have while waiting for an automatic improvement in the balance of
payments in cases of temporary disequilibria, or for the readjusting effect
of any corrective policy which they think advisable to adopt when the
deficit is deemed to be of a persistent or fundamental nature. If the length
of such breathing spell were too short, the country might be given authorization for direct restrictions over exchange sales.
Whether a 15, a 30, or a 50 per cent reserve is deemed sufficiently
critical for the introduction of exchange control would, of course, depend
upon the previous balance of payments experience of the country in
question. A country subject to sudden and violent fluctuations in its
export trade should be recognized as needing a higher critical reserve
level than a country with more stable sources of foreign exchange receipts.
Maximum variations in exports or exchange receipts in the past might
serve as an objective indication in helping to determine the critical
reserve level.
A weaker but possibly valid claim for measures of control might be
made when gold and foreign exchange reserves experienced a violent
and sustained decline, even though they remained above the critical
level agreed upon between the Fund and the member country. The
argument in such a case would be based, as in the Chapultepec discussions,
upon the desirability of limiting the expenditure of reserves for luxury
imports, capital flight, etc. Milder controls would suffice in such a case,
while stronger controls might prove unavoidable if the introduction of
the controls had to wait until the critical level had been reached.
As long as currency interconvertibility is maintained, no distinction
need be made between the various currencies included in reserves, or




74

INTEENATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

between currencies and gold. On the other hand, a country should be
allowed to maintain exchange freedom in general, while restricting the
sales of a currency in short supply—in accordance with the criteria discussed above—provided that the currency in question could not be
procured through the Fund, or through the normal conversion into such
currency of other international reserves at the disposal of the country.
I t would, indeed, be absurd to enforce general restrictions against all
imports because of the unavailability of one, or a few, currencies, 31 and the
scarce currency clauses of the Fund Charter 32 make such a case an exception to the general principle of nondiscrimination and multilateralism.
The abuses and discriminations resulting from the blocking of some
currencies cannot be blamed on the country subject to the blocking.
Responsibility for the maintenance of interconvertibility and multilateralism properly belongs only to the International Monetary Fund and
to the blocking countries themselves.
The Fund will also want to guard against retention of exchange
restrictions beyond the period in which they are required by the balance of
payments situation. The system outlined above would solve this difficulty
without necessitating further action by the Fund. Indeed, the control
system would be self-liquidating, since the auction and free market premiums would automatically decrease and vanish as the exchange situation
improved. If such improvement did not take place within a reasonable
period, the disequilibrium of the balance of payments should be recognized as fundamental rather than temporary, and corrective measures
rather than exchange control should be regarded as the proper remedy to
adopt. The Fund might encourage this change by reviewing periodically,
say once a year, the authorization granted to resort to exchange control.
These proposals are not theoretical. They have been recently embodied
in the basic monetary legislation of Paraguay and Guatemala and are
currently under discussion in other countries. 33 The Guatemalan law,
especially, indicates in great detail the precise mechanism whereby the
suggestions made here can be embodied in a practical manner. Both
laws, however, express only the limitations to which these countries sub31
For a discussion of this point, see League of Nations, Economic Stability in the Post-War
World (1945), pp. 245-47.
32
Art. VII.
33
See Decreto-Ley No. 10043 que establece el regimen de cambios de la Republica del
Paraguay (Asuncion, Paraguay), Aug. 29, 1945; and Ley Monetaria (Guatemala City,
Guatemala), Dec. 10, 1945. A translation of the latter legislation was published in the Federal
Reserve Bulletin, March 1946, pp. 259-69.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

75

jected their freedom of action on their own initiative. Further safeguards
might of course be desirable on an international plane, through the administration of the Fund's own powers with respect to exchange control.
Fundamental Readjustments. The main emphasis of this paper
has been on the inappropriateness of traditional readjustment policies as a
remedy for temporary or cyclical disequilibria. The opposite danger—
i.e., the failure to adopt readjustment policies in the case of fundamental
disequilibria—also faces the Fund, but it has been so widely discussed
elsewhere that a few comments will suffice here.
In any case of persistent disequilibrium in one country's economy as
a result of inflated price or income levels, corrective measures should be
applied. Neither the use of the country's reserves, nor borrowings from
abroad, nor exchange control would have any remedial influence on the
disequilibrium. While this would also be true in the absence of any International Monetary Fund, there is a danger that financial assistance
available from the Fund would be used in order further to postpone indispensable readjustments. The country's indebtedness would then
grow without lasting domestic benefit, and the resources of the Fund
would be wasted in a manner directly contrary to the objectives of the
institution. 34 The Fund, however, can protect itself against such abuses,
not only through the ceilings placed on each country's presumptive
borrowing rights, but also through the application of Article V, Section 5
of the Fund's Charter.
The diagnosis of a fundamental disequilibrium, however, is not an easy
task. A deficit in a country's balance of payments is not necessarily
evidence of an excessive and untenable level of domestic, as compared with
international, prices. Contrary to the "rules of the game" concept, it
should not, therefore, be taken as a signal for deflationary policies.
Compensatory action should be preferred, and supported by the Fund,
whenever the deficit can be ascribed to accidental causes, such as a
crop failure, or to a cyclical world depression. Similary, a favorable
balance of payments, not associated with international cost and price
disparities, should not be viewed as requiring expansionary policies which
are disruptive of domestic stability and conducive to inflationary price
rises.
Before the existence of a durable disequilibrium calling for corrective
34

One of the purposes of the Fund stated in Art. I (vi) is "to shorten the duration and
lessen the degree of disequilibrium in the international balances of payments of members."




76

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

measures is assumed, additional evidence should be studied and weighed.
Any fundamental disequilibrium would manifest itself, not only in a
deficit in the balance of payments, but also in monetary and banking
statistics, price and production data, etc. Such series, as well as the course
of the balance of payments, should be compared with the experience of
other countries, and especially of those of similar economic structure but
subject to different domestic influences and policies. Only in this manner
can a proper diagnosis be arrived at and an adequate policy determined.
Where clear evidence is lacking, arbitrary decisions are unavoidable.
The deficit country should probably be given the benefit of the doubt and
be allowed to pursue compensatory policies for a time with the help of the
Fund, and possibly under the additional protection of exchange control
when needed. This interpretation would be confirmed by events if the
deficit did in fact disappear within a normal period of time. The decision
would have to be reversed and corrective policies would have to be
applied, however, if the deficit continued to pile up the country's indebtedness to the Fund, or if the need for exchange control persisted, with
sustained and substantial premiums on the auction and free exchange
markets.
Just as a mere balance of payments deficit is not conclusive evidence of
a fundamental disequilibrium, the absence of such a deficit is not conclusive proof of a fundamental equilibrium in a country's international
position. In the absence of compensatory action by the monetary authorities, a fundamental disequilibrium may fail to be reflected in any balance
of payments deficit, owing to the prompt transmission of external deflationary pressures to domestic prices and incomes. One of the clearest
cases of a fundamental disequilibrium owing to currency overvaluation is
the experience of Belgium following the devaluation of the British pound
in September 1931. And yet, both the balance of trade and the balance
of payments improved rather than deteriorated during most of the
overvaluation period. The average import surplus fell from 4.3 billion
francs a year in 1929-30 to 0.8 billion in 1932-34 and the official gold and
foreign exchange reserves of the country remained nearly unchanged at a
level of 15 to 16 billion francs until the end of 1933.35 The impact of the
disequilibrium was thus felt, not in a deficit in the balance of payments,
but in a drastic decline in economic activity and incomes, especially in
35
A decline to 12.5 billion francs in the latter part of 1934 is to be ascribed primarily to
capital flight, prompted by the approaching devaluation of the currency.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

77

the so-called "nonsheltered" industries which were in competition with
foreign firms in the national or international markets.36
It has been argued recently that a country subject to such pressures
should attempt to protect itself through domestic compensatory policies,
but should not be allowed to devalue its currency unless and until these
policies had led to an actual deficit in the balance of international payments.87 This attitude is open to serious objections. First, it would lead
to unnecessary disruptions, since labor and other economic factors would
have to be uprooted and transferred into temporary activities, such as
public works for instance, and then returned to their normal field of
employment when currency devaluation again made it profitable and
economic. Secondly, the scope of compensatory action might be relatively
limited, especially in undeveloped countries heavily dependent on the
exportation of primary products. For such countries, currency devaluation
would often be the most direct, or even the only effective, way of maintaining domestic levels of income.
It is true, however, that devaluation should not be regarded as a proper
and legitimate remedy for any domestic depression, whatever its origin;
but neither should it be regarded as legitimate and desirable merely
because a country is experiencing balance of payments difficulties. The
Belgian case showed clear evidence that external pressures resulting from
the undervaluation of the pound with respect to the franc were at the
root of a severe domestic depression, but this evidence did not emerge
from balance of payments data. On the other hand, balance of payments
deficits are often the result of cyclical rather than fundmental disequilibria, and devaluation in such cases would usually be a most undesirable
remedy from the national as well as the international viewpoint.
Thus, the relevance of the balance of payments to the definition of a
"fundamental disequilibrium'' is of a subtler kind than is often imagined.
There may exist a fundamental disequilibrium in a country's economy,
even in the absence of any actual balance of payments deficit. On the
other hand, a deficit in the balance of payments may be due to cyclical,
or accidental, rather than to fundamental maladjustments. We might
define tentatively a fundamental disequilibrium as "a maladjustment in
a country's economy so grave and persistent that the restoration or
36
See Robert Triffin, "La theorie de la sur£valuation mon6taire et la devaluation beige/'
Bulletin de VInstitut de Recherches Economiques (Louvain, Belgium), November 1937, pp.
19-52.
37
See Gottfried Haberler, "Currency Depreciation and the International Monetary
Fund," Review of Economic Statistics, Vol. XXVI (November 1944), pp. 178-81.




78

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

maintenance of satisfactory levels of domestic activity, employment, and
incomes would prove incompatible with equilibrium in the balance of
payments, if not accompanied by extraordinary measures of external
defense, such as a change in the exchange rates, increased tariff or exchange control protection, etc."
The latter part of this definition also suggests that devaluation is not
necessarily the only, or even the most appropriate, remedy for a fundamental disequilibrium. The language of the Fund Agreement is interesting
in this respect. Members agree not to propose a change in the par value of
their currency except to correct a fundamental disequilibrium. The Fund,
however, shall concur in the proposed change only if it is satisfied that
the change is necessary to correct the disequilibrium (Article IV, Section
5 (a) and (f)). Thus, a fundamental disequilibrium is considered by the
Fund as a necessary, but not as a sufficient condition for currency readjustment. In some cases, other methods of correction may be preferable,
from a national as well as from an international standpoint.
For instance, the difficulties of the Chilean nitrate industry following
the development of synthetic nitrates were of a fundamental character
and had a deep impact on the international balance of the country.
Devaluation, even though probably unavoidable under the circumstances,
could not by itself have been expected to rectify the Chilean economy.
Domestic monetary and fiscal policies, changes in the tariff structure,
diversification of production, and modernization of industrial and agricultural techniques (possibly with foreign help) might have been better
remedies than currency readjustments, or at least their indispensable
complements.
A specially interesting case is the one of colonial economies in which
income expansion may lead rapidly and direcftly to balance of payments
disequilibria through its effects on luxury imports, tourist expenditures
abroad, capital exports, and the like, rather than through any upward
pressure on domestic wage and cost levels. Devaluation is a blunt and
indiscriminate instrument and may often be less efficient than selective
policies designed to plug the main leaks in the balance of payments, with
a minimum impact on basic economic activities and on production and
living costs.
Devaluation is also of limited value as a remedy for pervasive maladjustments, whether cyclical or fundamental, affecting simultaneously a
large number of countries. Agricultural overproduction, for instance, may
simultaneously disrupt the international balance of all the competing




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

79

countries whose exports are largely concentrated on the overproduced
commodities. Concerted international action designed toward readjustment would be preferable in this case to cut-throat competition through
lower prices or currency devaluation. The lack of balance between supply
and demand should be gauged, moreover, not with relation to abnormally
low levels of demand associated with a world depression, but in terms of
normal requirements. The ever-normal granary concept should be extended beyond national borders through international commodity agreements. It is true that such agreements may lead to opposite abuses and
to artificial efforts to maintain prices permanently at higher than competitive levels. The dilemma, however, is an inescapable one. Unfettered
competition in a market dominated by a few large sellers cannot ensure
the maintenance of competitive prices. It may often lead either to cutthroat underselling, monopolistic pricing through formal or informal
cartel agreements, price leadership, or other restrictive practices. This
is true at the international as well as at the national level. International
commodity agreements should be so organized as to prevent domination
of policies by vested interests of the producers or their governments.
Broad representation of consuming countries, together with the adoption
of automatic or semi-automatic indicators, might help to avoid major
errors. In the long run, however, policy decisions can never be dissociated
from responsibility. The refusal to take action is no solution in the face
of the breakdown, or unavailability, of the impersonal, competitive
mechanisms which, in classical theory, justified noninterference with
market forces.
CONCLUSION

The classical theory of international balance and of readjustments to
balance of payments disequilibria focusses on disparities in a single
country's price and cost levels with relation to the rest of the world.
Under such conditions, domestic deflation—if costs are not too rigid—
or currency devaluation may be able to bring about readjustment through
the restoration of the country's competitive position in world markets.
This doctrine was mistakenly extended, especially by the "rules of
the game* adherents, to world-wide cyclical disequilibria, originating in
one or a few highly developed and industrialized countries. Efforts by
other countries to correct resulting balance of payments deficits, either
through price deflation or exchange devaluation, were then thwarted
because such action by any one country or group of countries aggravated




80

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

the difficulties in their supply and export markets, as well as in competing
countries, and led to similar and mutually self-defeating measures of
defense. Price deflation and devaluation spread from country to country
without increasing export receipts, espedally if world demand for a
nation's exports is relatively inelastic.38 The situation presents a strong
analogy with that of oligopoly, where each effort by one seller to cut into
the competitors' markets is thwarted by the competitors' price retaliation.
Thus, the actual elasticity of demand for one country's exports is merged
with the much lower elasticity of world demand for those products.
Sales can be expanded only in so far as lower prices stimulate consumption, and not through inroads into the competitors' sales.
The main result of such policies is therefore to spread throughout the
world any cyclical disturbance arising in a major economic area., Balance
of payments deficits may be corrected in the end, but mostly as the result
of a general decline in income and economic activity. Furthermore, the
accompanying price changes leave in their wake a basically unbalanced
structure of international prices when the cyclical depression subsides
and more normal conditions are restored.
Whenever balance of payments disequilibria are due, not to international price disparities, but to accidental factors or to cyclical fluctuations in foreign income and demand, compensatory policies should be
followed to the fullest possible extent. This requires a high level of international reserves, especially in raw material and food producing countries,
and the willingness to spend these reserves liberally in times of crisis
and to accumulate them during prosperous years. When reserves are
insufficient, foreign or international assistance—such as is contemplated
under the International Monetary Fund—will be necessary. Failing this,
exchange control should be used as a third line of defense, in order to
continue compensatory policies and avoid the greater evils inseparable
from deflation or currency devaluation. The disadvantage of the latter
policies, as compared to exchange control, is that their corrective effect
on the balance of payments is likely to depend on a contraction of income
several times as severe as the international deficit to be plugged.
Exchange control, however, should be restricted to periods of temporary exchange difficulties, and should not be used to avoid readjustments
38
Devaluation may, of course, be preferable because its domestic impact is more favorable.
For this reason in some cases it may also be less damaging internationally. From the point
of view of eliminating a balance of payments deficit, however, the initial impact of both
measures may be very much the same except for their reaction on capital movements.




NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND THE INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY

81

to fundamental disequilibria. Even more important, the system of controls to be adopted should preserve the multilateralism and flexibility of
international trade. It should not lend itself to administrative arbitrariness, rigid and uneconomic allocation of exchange, discrimination and
bilateralism. These historical evils, associated with exchange control as
used in the interwar period, should not lead to a blind and dogmatic
rejection of exchange control as such, but to specific efforts to dissociate
it from such abuses and to make it a proper instrument for the protection
of the economy and the currency against temporary pressures on the
exchange.




COMMENTS ON "NATIONAL CENTRAL BANKING AND
T H E INTERNATIONAL ECONOMY"
by
GOTTFRIED HABERLER

Consultant, Board of Governors
One of the most challenging tasks of rational economic policy and one
of the most intriguing and controversial problems to economic science is
how to avoid or eliminate conflicts between domestic prosperity and
maximum gain from international trade and international division of
labor. Maximization of national output and income depends on both, full
employment of resources at home and full utilization of the opportunities
of international trade.
Conflicts between the two conditions in the sphere of monetary and
fiscal policy are quite frequent, because measures appropriate for maintaining full employment are not always conducive to promoting stability
of foreign exchange and of international trade and vice versa. These
conflicts are rarely, if ever, irreconcilable, but there is no simple formula
or easy automatic device which would permit satisfactory conciliation in
every single case.
Innumerable proposals for simple, once-for-all solutions, as well as for
complicated specifications of policy under different circumstances, have
been made, and many different policies have been tried out. Theoretical
insight has steadily grown and a vast stock of practical experience has
been accumulated. Thus, whenever a new attempt is made at finding a
solution of this problem, as in connection with the setting up of the
International Monetary Fund, a strong effort is required in order to
utilize to the fullest extent the lessons of historical experience and the
latest improvements in theoretical analysis. Dr. Robert Triffin's paper
is a most notable and stimulating contribution in both directions.

PURE AND MIXED GOLD STANDARDS
J. H. Williams once spoke of "a fundamental conflict between the
principles of central banking and the principles of the gold standard."1
Similarly, Dr. Triffin (page 49) stresses "the latent antinomy between
central banking and the classical gold standard." He points out that in
1

"Monetary Stability and the Gold Standard," American Economic Review, Supplement,
March 1932, reprinted in The Postwar Monetary Plans (1944), p. 183.




COMMENTS

83

its purest form the gold standard eliminates this conflict by removing one
of its terms: there is not room for national central banking in a "purely
metallic" currency system. A purely metallic currency was recommended
by some of the early classical economists, but it was never completely
realized in practice. The existence and development of credit and banking
(not only central but also commercial banking) prevented the gold standard from being a purely metallic currency. It is true, attempts were made
to make the actual mixed system behave like a purely metallic currency.
The so-called "Palmer Rule" adopted by the Bank of England in 1827
and the famous Bank Act (Peel's Act) of 1844 were such attempts, but
they remained abortive and the gold standard of the nineteenth century
remained a "mixed system." That is to say, the circulating medium consisted of two parts, a comparatively small base of gold or gold-covered
bank notes (international money) and a large superstructure of credit and
fiduciary currency (domestic money).
Roughly speaking, we may say that the gold standard as it actually
existed was superior to a purely metallic currency as far as the maintenance of internal stability and progress was concerned, because it
provided a flexible money supply. But it placed difficulties in the way of
maintaining external stability which would not have existed or would
have been much less serious under a pure gold standard.
Only a few remarks can be made here about the first point, viz., the
superiority of theflexible,mixed system over the rigid pure gold standard.
It cannot be denied, of course, that an elastic supply of money and credit
has its dangers, that it can be and often has been abused for wholly undesirable inflationary experiments. But very few economists would assert
that change in the money supply is bad of itself and should be avoided.
According to these few economists, a purely metallic currency would be
superior in both respects, for the maintenance of external and internal
stability alike. According to them, depressions and the business cycle as
such are entirely due to periodic expansion of money and credit; if the
supply of money and credit were rigid as it would be under a pure gold
standard, there would be no cyclical depressions.2
The great majority of economic experts realize, however, that things
are not so simple; that the business cycle has deeper roots than expansibility of bank credit; that periods of expansion and contraction of
2
There are shades of opinion in this group. Some would allow for a slow secular rise in the
money supply in order to compensate for certain growth factors and to stabilize prices; others
think that prices should be allowed to fall slowly pari passu with the secular rise in output.




84

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

money expenditures *nd of output and employment could and would
occur even if the money and credit supply were rigid, for even if the
quantity of money were constant there could be fluctuations in hoarding
and dishoarding, decreases and increases in the velocity of circulation,
and decreases and increases in the demand for liquidity. There are again
many shades of opinion. Most writers would concede that expansibility
of credit contributes to the amplitude of cyclical fluctuations, but many
would insist, with varying emphasis, that over the long run such an increase in the amplitude of cyclical swings increases the rate of economic
progress. But this is not the place to go more deeply into these complicated
questions. Suffice it to say that there are very few economists who would
seriously recommend making the money supply as rigid as it would be
under purely metallic currency.
We come now to the other point, where the pure gold standard would
be superior to the mixed system. Dr. Trifhn follows Professor Hayek and
other writers in attributing a large share of the difficulties in dealing with
international disequilibria to the mixed character of our historical currency systems. The erection of a large superstructure of fiduciary and
credit money (bank deposits) upon a narrow gold base meant that,
whenever there was a serious deficit in the balance of payments (drain
on gold reserves), strong measures had to be taken to protect the gold
supply and to maintain the convertibility of the currency into gold and
foreign money. Under a pure gold standard the loss of gold (decrease in
the international reserve) would lead to a reduction of the circulating
medium by not more than the amount of the gold loss, but with a large
credit superstructure it became necessary to contract the circulating
medium by a multiple of the gold loss. Under the "rules of the gold
standard game" the central bank of a country that was losing gold was
required to liquidate domestic assets (withdraw loans or sell securities)
along with the loss of its international reserves, and the central bank of
the country that gained gold was supposed to acquire domestic assets
along with the accretion to its international reserves. This policy of
"secondary expansion and contraction" could not fail to accentuate price
reactions to gold flows and thus to increase economic instability.
Two remarks may be made about this conventional criticism of the
nineteenth century gold standard. First, it should be emphasized that
smallness of the gold reserve in the English monetary system was a subject of comment and criticism throughout the century. Professor Viner
says: "From the late 1820's on to the end of the century a continuous




COMMENTS

85

succession of writers called attention to the inadequacy of the gold
reserve."3 Even Peel himself was said to have been "aware that the
metallic base of the currency was extraordinarily narrow, but did not
think that either the Bank or the people would willingly bear the expense
of broadening it." 4 In the early period, "the practice of extreme economy
in the maintenance of bank reserves" (Viner) was undoubtedly largely
due to the fact that a low reserve meant large profits to the Bank. But
there was a gradual evolution of the Bank from a passive conversion
fund operating according to certain rules and still influenced by the profit
motive to a policy-making body fully conscious of its responsibility for
domestic prosperity and of the possible conflicts between internal and
international equilibrium. This transition was completed long ago, and
when the Bank wasfinallynationalized by the present Labor Government,
the nationalization was generally regarded as a pure formality. Politically
it would have been impossible at an earlier date. But as far as the policy
of the Bank was concerned, it would hardly have made any difference if
the nationalization had occurred many years ago.
The second remark concerning the smallness of the reserve and the
fractional reserve system is this: multiple expansion and contraction in
response to gold flows was undoubtedly a disturbing factor. But it is
easy to exaggerate its importance and very difficult to estimate its
magnitude correctly. It is a fact that as far as central bank money (notes
outside the Bank plus private deposits in the Bank) is concerned there
is no multiplication of gold flows visible in the statistical record. For the
interwar period (1919-39) Professor Ragnar Nurkse has shown that,
contrary to what was required by "the rules of the game," "central
banks' international and domestic assets . . . moved far more often in the
opposite than in the same direction."5 That is to say, central banks,
instead of magnifying, toned down expansions and contractions resulting
from gold flows. No such careful study has been made for prewar periods,
but an inspection of the relevant statistical series shows no trace of
magnification. The volume of central bank money (notes plus deposits)
and gold reserves move together, but the changes in the former are in
most cases smaller than the changes in the latter. This is true not only
of Great Britain but also of France and Germany. If there was a magnifi3

J. Viner, Studies in the Theory of International Trade, p. 265.
* Ibid., p. 267.
League of Nations, International Currency Experience (1944), pp. 68-69.

6




86

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

cation, it must have taken place entirely in the field of commercial bank
deposits.
In the case of Great Britain, the record definitely shows such a magnification in that sphere. But for statistical reasons the average rate of
magnification is not easy to determine.6 Moreover, the causal interpretation is a different matter altogether. That is to say, given a certain magnification, it remains still to decide to what extent it is due to (a) changes
in the supply of central bank money and gold or (b) to changes in demand
for credit. The criticism of "the rules of the game" implies that changes in
money supply are all important. But modern business cycle and monetary
theory definitely tends to lay more and more stress on demand factors.
This shift in emphasis from supply to demand factors is supported by
recent business cycle experiences, namely, the occurrence of sharp
fluctuations in output and employment as well as price and money values
without significant changes in supply conditions of credit. The slump of
1937 in the United States is an outstanding example.
Whatever the last word in these matters will be, it is important not to
exaggerate the consequences of the fractional reserve gold standard.
Such exaggerations may easily lead to the conclusion that the elimination
of that objectionable feature of the gold standard is all that is needed to
assure a smoothly running international money mechanism. Dr. Triffin
is, of course, far from committing that mistake. He makes it abundantly
clear than an increase in international reserves and liquidity as provided
by the International Monetary Fund, although useful and necessary, is
by no means a sufficient reform of the existing system.
8
The English banks usually did not separate current accounts from (savings) deposits in
their balance sheets. Moreover, only balance sheets pertaining to a certain day of the year
were published, with a certain amount of "window dressing" involved; the average amount
of demand deposits over a period of a year, or even of a quarter, is not known. Another statistical difficulty arises because many banks combined the two cash items "cash on hand
and at Bank of England" with "cash at call." A considerable amount of fluctuating "surplus"
money is in the latter category, and can be withdrawn from the brokers at a moment's notice.
Thus the first impact of a reduction in the money supply falls on call money, while "cash on
hand and at the Bank of England" is increased. The effect, during the money crisis of 1907,
on the banks which separate "cash in hand" from "cash at call" serves as an illustration:

Cash on hand
Cash at call

Dec. 31, 1906

Dec. 31, 1907

£ 80.4 million
£ 72.2 million

£ 85.5 million
£ 62.0 million

"Cash at call" was reduced by £ 10.2 million, "cash on hand" increased by 5.1 million during
the same period. Edgar JaffS, Das tnglische Bankwesen (Leipzig, 1910), p. 326n. See also G.
Clare, A Money Market Primer (London, 1907), pp. 143ff., for a description of the working
of the mechanism.




COMMENTS

87

BANK RATE AND THE BRITISH BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

In Great Britain the gold standard was operated largely by means of
changes in the discount rate of the Bank of England. When a gold drain
became serious, the bank rate was raised and vice versa. Dr. Triflin criticizes what he thinks is the traditional theory of that mechanism. Actually,
he says (page 59), the mechanism "seems to have operated, in important
respects, in a manner directly opposite to that described by gold standard
theory." According to the classical theory, Dr. Triflin says, a rise in bank
rate should have depressed British prices and so have influenced favorably
the British balance of trade. In reality the influence of bank rate changes
was more through capital movements and through their effects on the outside world, especially on agricultural and raw material producing countries.
It must be emphasized that these features of the mechanism were
generally known and commented upon throughout the nineteenth
century. That a rise in bank rate served to attract capital was known
and stressed not only by the Banking School, especially by William Tooke
(whom Dr. Triflin quotes) who was somewhat of a heretic, but also by
Tooke's chief opponent, Lord Overstone, and the Currency School.
Professor Viner, writing of the period 1825-65, says: "Most of the discussions of the role of the interest rate referred only to short-run disturbances, including periodic business fluctuations, or 'cycles/ and the changes
in interest rates were related to specie movements mainly in terms of
their influence on international movement of short-term funds, and their
influence on relative prices was commonly held to be too slow-working
to be an important factor in restoring international equilibrium. Most
emphasis was put on the international mobility of funds." 7
That higher interest rates in London may affect prices in foreign countries more quickly and powerfully than prices in Great Britain, and that
therefore a rise in the discount rate in London may tend to turn the trade
balance against England, has also been observed. R. G. Hawtrey, for
example, says: "If this deflationary process [started by a rise in bank
rate] went faster at home than abroad, it made the foreign exchanges
favorable [for Great Britain] and occasioned an inflow of gold. But it
7

Op. cit.y p. 278. See also Elmer Wood, English Theories of Central Banking Control, 181958 (Harvard University Press, 1939), pp. 150-51. As an example of a classical writer stressing
the influence of bank rate changes on capital flows, compare the following passage from J.
S. Mill, Principles of Political Economy (Ashley edition), p. 497: "It is a fact now beginning
to be recognized, that the passage of the precious metals from country to country is determined much more than formerly supposed by the state of the loan markets in different countries, and much less by the state of prices."




88

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

sometimes went faster in some foreign country (particularly in case of a
financial crisis there) and caused an outflow."8 But as Dr. Triffin observes,
this idea has not been systematically elaborated.
All this serves to show that more can be learned from the older literature
than Dr. Triffin would make us believe and that business cycle implications were by no means overlooked. This does not mean that the
nineteenth century gold standard practices are not open to criticism. It
is misleading, however, to speak of "the" nineteenth century gold standard, for the operation of the gold standard underwent a continuous
evolution. Slowly but surely the monetary authorities learned many
useful lessons. That in spite of all improvements in monetary management the business cycle did not show signs of disappearing or of becoming
noticeably milder should make us cautious not to expect too much from
purely monetary reforms.
CYCLICAL AND FUNDAMENTAL MALADJUSTMENTS IN THE
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS

Dr. Triffin draws a sharp distinction between "world-wide disturbances
in balances of payments associated with cyclical fluctuations" on the one
hand and "fundamental disequilibria in single countries' international
position." He is on firm ground when, following modern trade theory, he
emphasizes the great importance of cyclical fluctuations and income
changes for the functioning of the international money mechanism,
especially the terrific disrupting force of world-wide depressions. It is very
unlikely that international monetary agreements and institutions like
the International Monetary Fund and the International Bank or international commercial policy agreements like the proposed International
Trade Convention could weather the hurricane of a major world depression; nor is it likely that such agreements and institutions alone, without
appropriate domestic policies in the large industrial countries, could do
much to prevent such a storm. It is probably also true that a full realization of the importance of the international business cycle and of depressions in particular is of fairly recent origin, at least as far as systematic,
theoretical thinking is concerned. But we have seen that not only practical
men, but also theorists, when they dealt with current problems, were
always confronted with the reality of the cycle and did not overlook it
altogether.
It is questionable whether Dr. Triffin is right when he says that,
8

A Century of Bank Rate (London, 1938), p. 44.




COMMENTS

89

according to classical gold standard theory in its original form or according
to its modern "rules of the game" version, any disequilibrium, whatever
its origin, has to be corrected by automatic or induced price changes
brought about by domestic monetary expansion and contraction. I t is
even more questionable whether "fundamental disequilibrium" can be
identified with "noncyclical disequilibrium" (i.e., a disequilibrium not
caused by a world-wide depression), and whether changes in relative
price levels (through currency depreciation or domestic price adjustments)
have to be ruled out as treatment of those maladjustments that emerge
during world-wide depressions.
Concerning the first point, it may be sufficient to mention that J. S.
Mill and other writers drew a distinction between two kinds of external
gold drains (the term they used for balance of payments disequilibria):
(a) drains that could be corrected only by changes in relative prices,
"fundamental disequilibria" we now say, and (b) temporary drains that
did not require such a treatment. 9 Mill criticized the Act of 1844 on the
ground that it forced the Bank of England to apply the same treatment
to both kinds of drains. Later he admitted that even under this Act the
Bank could differentiate between different drains if it kept a sufficiently
large reserve in the banking department. 10 I t is interesting that Mill was
criticized by contemporary writers for exaggerating the ease with which
in practice the distinction between temporary and lasting disequilibria
can be made. I t is true he did not identify temporary maladjustments with
cyclical or depression-born maladjustments. In that he was not so wrong,
however unsatisfactory in other respects his analysis may appear to us
now!
Although it is of utmost importance to recognize cyclical fluctuations
in income and international demand, especially the depression phase of
the cycle, as breeders of maladjustments in the balances of payments, it
is impossible to regard cyclical and fundamental disequilibria as mutually
exclusive opposites. A brief reflection will show that the two concepts
overlap, especially that depressions frequently breed fundamental as well
as temporary (reversible) maladjustments.
The term "fundamental disequilibrium" was introduced by the Bretton
Woods Agreements, without giving any definition, leaving it to the
practice of the Fund to evolve suitable criteria. Whatever the precise
9

See Mill, Principles (Ashley ed.), p. 665, and Viner, loc. ciL, pp. 261-64, for other references.
10
See Viner, ibid.




90

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

meaning and criteria of a "disequilibrium/' there can hardly be a doubt
that by a "fundamental" disequilibrium must be meant a serious and
lasting one. How serious it must be and how long it must last in order to
be regarded as "fundamental'' cannot and need not be decided here.
The answer will largely have to depend, as Professor Nurkse has pointed
out, on the magnitude of the international reserves at the disposal of the
country concerned (including its credit line wTith the Fund). 11 Whatever
the precise answer in each particular case there can be no doubt, furthermore, that any serious depression can and is likely to create fundamental
disequilibria which outlast the depression and do not automatically
reverse themselves as soon as the depression is over. Depressions always
cause or reveal structural changes; some eminent students of the business
cycle would even say that depressions are the vehicles for the assimilation
of structural changes into the economic system. We need not go so far to
realize that the initial impact as well as the permanent incidence of the
changes revealed or brought about by depressions is not likely to be the
same in different countries. Moreover, reactions of different countries to
depressive forces cannot be assumed to be the same. Some countries may
yield to deflationary forces and let their prices drop while others may
institute vigorous anti-depression policies and maintain their price and
cost levels with varying success and in various degrees. These divergences
in the impacts of depressions and in the reactions of different countries
result in lasting maladjustments.
All this makes it impossible to follow Dr. Triffin when he says (page
64 and elsewhere) that disequilibria resulting from "cyclical fluctuations
in the major world markets" are "of a temporary character." We cannot
identify all depression-born maladjustments with temporary, "reversible," "nonfundamental" disequilibria. It is not generally or even as a
rule true that cyclical maladjustments are not fundamental; they cannot
as a rule be expected to reverse themselves completely or suflEiciently and
it would thus be quite unsafe to assume that they never require correction
by adjustment in relative price and cost levels (by means of either currency depreciation or internal expansion and contraction).
HOW TO DEAL WITH BALANCE OF PAYMENTS MALADJUSTMENTS
IN DEPRESSIONS

What policies should thus be recommended for balance of payments
troubles in depressions? Everybody will agree with Dr. Triffin's emphasis
11
See Ragnar Nurkse, Conditions of International Monetary Equilibrium (Princeton,
1945). This is the most thorough and convincing discussion of the subject I have seen.




COMMENTS

91

on the responsibility of the largest and most industrialized countries to
maintain their economies at high levels of employment and production.
Sharp reductions in output and employment, like the one which occurred
in the United States in 1937-38 (which fortunately did not last very long),
would be extremely disturbing for the rest of the world. But Dr. Trifl&n is
certainly realistic when he says that, in spite of all good intentions,
depressions and balance of payments disequilibria "will continue to occur
and to threaten domestic stability, especially in countries with undiversified economies." What should those countries do when they are confronted with a fall in their exports due to a depression abroad?
In general, he says, an effort should be made everywhere to offset the
drop in exports to the largest possible extent by domestic compensatory
policies. Such policies, if generally pursued, will "help to moderate both
national and international depressions and to preserve fundamental
international balance."
But such a policy requires large international reserves. There the International Monetary Fund will be of great help. I t provides in itself an
augmentation of international reserves through various devices and it can
induce deficit countries to make full use of their own reserves outside the
Fund. Dr. Triffin is certainly right in saying that the main danger is that
the Fund's credit may be abused by many countries, that the borrowing
may assume a continuous character and indebtedness to the Fund may
pile up rapidly until the countries' quotas are exhausted. But to speak,
as Dr. Triffin does, of such an abuse only if the Fund's credit is used "for
the financing of fundamental, as opposed to cyclical or fortuitous, disequilibria in a country's international account" is too narrow, if "cyclical
disequilibrium" includes any disequilibrium caused by depression abroad.
Dr. Triffin clearly realizes that with its present resources the Fund
could hardly hope to finance all deficits which would arise even in the
course of a mild cyclical depression without taking "remedial actions."
In other words, if the Fund treated every cyclical deficit as a temporary
affair, it would in all likelihood run out of important currencies (i.e.,
they would become "scarce") and many of the deficit countries would
exhaust their quotas before the storm had passed—if it would pass at
all, one should perhaps add, without remedial actions.
What should those "remedial actions" be? Dr. Triffin's remedy is
exchange control of a certain kind, but he rejects currency depreciation
(as well as the analytically closely related gold standard technique of




92

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

internal adjustments of costs and prices by means of monetary expansion
and contraction).
"EXCHANGE CONTROL"
Dr. Triffin proposes a kind of nondiscriminatory exchange control
which it would be better not to describe as exchange control at all but
as partial and, so he hopes, temporary currency depreciation. There
would be an official exchange rate and a free, auction price of foreign
currencies; the former would be stable, the latter would fluctuate according to fluctuations in demand and supply. The low official rate would
apply to "easily controllable exports'' (which the author thinks would be
the overwhelmingly larger part of all exports), to certain categories of
"necessary or essential" imports, and to approved capital exports; the
higher auction rate would apply to other imports, to uncontrollable
exports and other exchange proceeds of "unimportant or practically
uncontrollable transactions." (Dr. Triffin also thinks that capital exports
beyond those which can be admitted to the official market can be channelled, apparently without special permission, through the auction
market without any harmful repercussions. "The higher rates prevailing
in the free market in times of crises would tend to discourage capital
exports and encourage capital imports." I should like to say, in passing,
that this seems to me much too optimistic. It assumes a degree of confidence on the part of the prospective capital exporters in the success and
the self-liquidating character of the whole scheme which is hardly warranted, as the following analysis will show.)
This is certainly a most ingenious scheme that is well worthy of trial on
a large scale when need arises.12 It is undoubtedly far superior to anything
that goes nowadays under the label "exchange control"; therefore Dr.
Triffin would be well advised not to call it so. But it has certain weaknesses
and I think Dr. Triffin shows too much enthusiasm and optimism—a
likeable and understandable trait of every successful inventor—when he
expects that in most cases his system will be self-liquidating, the higher
auction rate falling back to the lower official rate when the storm has
blown itself out. I think the opposite or some intermediate outcome is
more likely, namely, that the official rate will have to be raised to the
12
A similar scheme has apparently been operated in Argentina. Its inventor there was the
former General Manager of the Central Bank of Argentina, Paul Prebisch. On a smaller
scale it has been in successful operation since the middle of 1945 in Paraguay, but not yet
during a severe world-wide depression.




COMMENTS

93

auction rate or the two be allowed to meet in the middle. If that is correct,
the system would prove to be not a partial and temporary depreciation,
but a first step towards a general and permanent depreciation.
The plan has the following weaknesses: (1) The administrative difficulties should not be underestimated, even though they are certainly smaller
than in the case of ordinary exchange control and quota systems. Exporters will have a strong incentive to sell their export proceeds in the
black market at the auction price or somewhat below. In the case of
undiversified countries with a few staple commodities as exports this consideration may not be very important, but for practically all European
countries it is a very serious matter.
(2) I t is an illusion to assume that the system can be operated in an
entirely automatic fashion in the sense that lists of "necessary" and
"urgent" imports can be drawn up according to objective criteria before
any emergency arises, and that then in case of need those prearranged
plans are simply put into operation without any further arbitrary decision.
In reality, it will be necessary to extend, restrict, and otherwise modify
the list of essential imports according to changing circumstances, and
according to the severity and length of the crisis. A study of the Monetary
Law of Guatemala, 13 which embodies Dr. Triffin's ideas, shows that there
is danger that in practice the degree of automatism of such a system will
prove smaller than the theoretical outline as presented in Dr. Triffin's
contribution to the present pamphlet suggests. For example, Article 57
empowers the Monetary Board "to amplify and to restrict the list of such
merchandise [i.e., "essential imports" to which the official exchange rate
applies] in accordance with the situation in the exchange market."
Moreover, the creation of more than two categories of commodities and
more than two rates (official and auction) is provided for. The Monetary
Board can create any number of groups of imports, "according to the
degree of essentiality and urgency of the operations and may distribute the offers of exchange among these groups, with the object of assuring an adequate distribution of available exchange in accordance
with the real needs of the economy." For each group there will be a
separate (auction?) rate with the proviso that "the distribution [of the
available foreign exchange among the different groups] must be made in
such a way as to avoid having the rates corresponding to more essential
and more urgent operations exceed those applicable to less essential or
18

For a translation of the text, see Federal Reserve Bulletin, March 1946, pp. 257-88.




94

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

less urgent operations" (Article 66). This is a far cry indeed from the
simplicity of the theoretical scheme and begins to resemble a full-fledged
exchange control system of the Schachtian type. Moreover there is real
danger that when an actual test comes and the restrictive measures
contemplated in the Guatemalan law are put into practice, we shall,
under the influence of pressures and temptations from interested parties,
experience further deviation from the theoretical ideal. Something like
that seems to have happened in Argentina.
The International Monetary Fund, if it decides to permit experiments
with the system under consideration—which it would be well advised to
do in my opinion—will have to exercise much vigilance to preserve in
practice the simplicity of the system and its semi-automatic character
which make it so attractive in theory and to prevent it from degenerating
into the ordinary complicated and arbitrary kind of exchange control.
(3) The Government or the Central Bank would make a handsome
profit by selling part of its foreign funds at the auction price while paying
only the official rate. So "vested fiscal interests" in the system would be
created. This may be less serious than the creation of vested interests of
private importers which grow up under ordinary exchange control and
quota systems. But the history of monetary policy is full of cases where
fiscal considerations have led to the indefinite postponement of desirable
reforms. Moreover, would it not be tempting to use the exchange profits
of the Government to subsidize exports? This brings us to the next
weakness of the system.
(4) Under Dr. Triffin's plan, exports would not be stimulated as under
a depreciation. If there is a depression in the big industrial countries and
the price level there falls, or even if prices there do not fall, but income
contracts and the demand of those countries for imports falls—would it
be advisable for the raw material and food producing countries to make
no price concessions at all by leaving the value of their currency, as far
as exports are concerned, unchanged? Would they not run the danger of
losing part of their market permanently by stimulating competitive
production in the industrial countries themselves and in third countries? 14
(5) Prices of privileged, "essential" imports would be kept low or
would fall (because foreign export prices fall in a depression) and com14
Gold standard theorists would answer that export prices and costs in the raw material
and food producing countries, in terms of local currency, will, or should be made to, fall;
this would provide all the stimulation needed even if the exchange rate is kept unchanged.
This may very well happen, but it would substitute deflation for depreciation, and deflation
is universally rejected nowadays.




COMMENTS

95

peting home industries would be penalized. On the other hand, prices of
nonprivileged imports—which may not all be in the luxury class, for if
the deficit is large it will be necessary to shift more and more commodities
from the privileged to the nonprivileged class—will be kept high and the
production of domestic luxuries will be stimulated and thus vested interests will be created.
All this, it seems to me, adds up to a strong case for using the proposed
plan only for a very limited period of time, say, for a year or two at the
most. If the situation does not correct itself within a year or two, and
the scheme has to be kept in force longer, it should be taken as an indication that the official rate has to be adjusted, that is to say, that a general
depreciation is necessary. It will be an important task of the International
Monetary Fund to elaborate proper safeguards. This may take the form
of periodic reviews of the situation, of special permission being required
for changes in the list of essential and nonessential commodities and
similar provisions.
Another conclusion to be drawn from this criticism is that currency
depreciation should not be ruled out categorically in a depression.
Of course, a wave of competitive depreciation, as in the early thirties
when one country after the other depreciated and each tried to undercut the other, must be avoided. Begger-my-neighbor depreciations,
i.e., depreciations not justified by a serious balance of payments
deficit, must not be permitted. Only deficit countries should be
allowed to depreciate, and they should be allowed to do so only after
they have made substantial use of their international reserves, including their quota in the Fund, and possibly after they have tried
out Dr. Triffin's "partial depreciation" or, as he calls it, "exchange
control'' scheme.
Dr. Triffin's specific arguments against the use of depreciation in
the case of "world-wide cyclical disequilibria" apply only to such
abuses and are not convincing when directed against selective depreciation by deficit countries only. Only of competitive depreciation by deficit and surplus countries alike can it be said that it would
"spread throughout the world any cyclical disturbance arising in a
major economic area" (page 80). The case of a selective depreciation
is different. In that case the "major economic areas" in which a
"cyclical disturbance" (depression) has arisen are the surplus countries.
If now the deficit countries (after the above-mentioned initial stages)
are allowed to depreciate, there can be no question of propagating the




96

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

depression from the major areas to the depreciating countries. Such
a selective depreciation is a protective measure of the deficit countries.
Dr. Triffin says that efforts to correct deficits by depreciation (or
deflation) are thwarted because such action by any one country aggravates difficulties in supply and export markets, as well as in competing countries, and leads to similar, and mutually self-defeating,
measures of defense (page 79). But does this argument not spring
from excessive pessimism and defeatism? Just consider what this
argument amounts t o : There are countries which have developed a
serious deficit, they have exhausted their reserves including their
quota with the Fund, they have perhaps taken Dr. Triffin's "exchange
control'' medicine; when their trade deficit persists and they receive
permission from the Fund to depreciate their currency, is it reasonable
to assume that the Fund will not be able to restrain the surplus countries from using "self-defeating measures of defense 7 '? Defense
against what? Not against an unprovoked incursion of their markets,
but defense of a balance of payments surplus created by depression,
i.e., defense of the illicit fruits of an outlawed beggar-my-neighbor
policy! Must we really assume that "devaluation will spread from
country to country"? If it were true that the Fund cannot be expected to be able to prevent competitive devaluations by deficit and
surplus countries alike, it would seem to me that we might just as well
give up altogether any hope and any attempt at international regulation of these matters!
We may, however, mention two arguments against the use of depreciation which Dr. Triffin does not emphasize (quite rightly in my
opinion), although one of them lurks in the background of his analysis
and is occasionally alluded to by him. The first is that expected depreciation and its frequent use will lead to disturbing speculative
capital movements and other speculative anticipations. This argument should not be taken too lightly, but it is mainly directed against
frequent use of the depreciation weapon, which is not here advocated.
(The question arises, however, whether fluctuations of the auction rate
in Dr. Triffin's exchange control scheme would not lead to disturbing
speculative capital and commodity movements. I t seems to me that
this danger cannot be lightly dismissed, especially because the selfliquidating and temporary character of the scheme is likely often to
prove illusory in practice.)
The second argument against depreciation is more complicated.




COMMENTS

97

I t is based on the now fashionable assumption that the elasticities of
international demand are often such that a depreciation cannot always be expected to improve the balance of payments. I do not think
that this is a realistic theory, barring perhaps short-run considerations
of a few exceptional cases, but it would take too much space to argue
the matter at this point. Dr. Triffin alludes to it, but does not make it
a corner stone of his case.
FUNDAMENTAL DISEQUILIBRIUM
Dr. Triffin adds some very interesting points to the much discussed
question of the criteria of a fundamental disequilibrium, the existence
of which entitles a country under the Bretton Woods Agreement to
receive permission for depreciation of its currency.
Dr. Triffin stresses, quite rightly in my opinion, that "a deficit in a
country's balance of payments is not necessarily" evidence of a fundamental disequilibrium justifying currency depreciation (page 75). But
he is reluctant to accept the rule that a serious and persistent deficit
(whether brought about by deflation and depression abroad or by inflationary policies at home or possibly by a sharp shift in international
demand) should be so regarded, although there are passages which seem
to suggest that this rule is implicitly applied. For example: I t is convincingly argued that the probability of the existence of "a durable
disequilibrium'' should be judged in the light not only of the actual
balance of payments but also with due consideration of monetary and
banking statistics, price and production data, etc. Suppose the conclusion is reached in a particular case that no fundamental disequilibrium
exists and that hence the country in question be allowed to pursue,
for a time, compensatory policies with the aid of the Fund. "This interpretation would be confirmed by events if the deficit did in fact disappear," but it would have to be regarded as disproved by the facts "if
the deficit continued" (page 76). This suggests that a persistent deficit
(the assumption of which always implies, it should be observed, a forecast
of future events) is, in fact, accepted as the criterion of a fundamental
disequilibrium.
But then Dr. Triffin cites the famous Belgian case of 1934 in which
a fundamental disequilibrium is said to have existed without a visible
deficit. The facts of the case are not quite easy to ascertain, because
accurate figures of short-term capital movements are not available.




98

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

Moreover, protectionist measures must have contributed (to an unknown extent) to avoidance of a deficit which otherwise would have
appeared. But it is clear that there was no visible deficit, that is to
say, that there were no gold losses, although there may have been an
invisible deficit compensated by an influx of short-term capital.
Dr. Trifnn then argues against a proposal of mine to the effect that
a country which suffers from a depression and thinks that it is entitled under the "fundamental disequilibrium clause" of the Articles
of Agreement to a depreciation should at first attempt to protect itself
through compensatory domestic policies and should be allowed to depreciate only after a deficit in its balance of payments has actually
appeared. Dr. Triffin has two arguments against this proposal.
The first is that this policy would lead to unnecessary disruptions,
"since labor and other economic factors would have to be uprooted
and temporarily transferred to other activities/'
But does that really follow? In an industrial country with highly
diversified exports, it would always be possible to choose compensatory policies that operate partly on the depressed export industries
themselves, and partly on domestic industries which are depressed
because of the depression in the export industries. In the Belgian
case that would certainly have been possible and it would not have
been necessary to "uproot'' anybody or to transfer labor temporarily
into other industries. A deficit in the balance of payments would have
appeared almost immediately after an offsetting domestic policy was
started and depreciation could then have been permitted according to
the proposed rule. (Since that could have been foreseen so easily in
the Belgian case, I personally would not have hesitated to give the
permission to depreciate in advance!) Furthermore, it should be
observed that the Belgian difficulties were caused by a world-wide
cyclical depression and should therefore, according to Dr. Triffin's
own rules, have been offset "to the largest possible extent by domestic
compensatory policies" (page 64), even if there had been a current
drain of the country's international reserves! The fact that there was
no visible deficit in the balance of payments would have made, one
should think, compensatory policies all the more easy and appropriate !
Dr. Triffin's second point, that in primary producing countries
the effectiveness of compensatory domestic action may be very




COMMENTS

99

limited, is well taken. I have called attention to these limitations
myself.15 But that even primary producing countries are not entirely helpless is shown by the "remarkable success/' to use Dr.
Triffin's own words (page 60), with which the Central Bank of Argentina offset external drains through policies of domestic expansion.
However, Argentina is in a more favorable position in that respect
than any other Latin American country.
A TENTATIVE REFORMULATION

I shall now try briefly to reformulate some implications of defining
"fundamental disequilibrium" in terms of balance of payments deficits and discuss a few apparent and genuine exceptions to this rule.
What is said in the following pages seems to me in substantial agreement with Dr. Triffin's tentative definition of fundamental disequilibrium as a "maladjustment in a country's economy so grave and
persistent that the restoration or maintenance of satisfactory levels of
domestic activity, employment, and incomes would prove incompatible with equilibrium in the balance of payments, if not accompanied by extraordinary measures of external defense, such as a change
in the exchange rates, increased tariff or exchange control protection,
etc." (page 77).
This seems to me a most ingenious formulation which contains, in
a nutshell, all important elements of the problem. The fact that the
following pages were written before I saw Dr. Triffin's definition is a
welcome indication that economists' thoughts on these matters are
veering in the same direction.16
We speak of a fundamental disequilibrium, if there is a serious and
persistent deficit in the balance of payments.17 It has been already
15
"Some Factors Affecting the Future of International Trade," in Economic Reconstruction, edited by S. E. Harris (1945), p. 330.
16
The definition was inserted in a later version of his paper and the references to it were
subsequently added to my comments.
17
Note that an actual or potential deficit in the balance of payments is one of the essential
characteristics of fundamental disequilibrium also in Dr. Trifiin's definition. I t is true that
in Dr. Trifiin's formulation the "gravity and persistency" of the maladjustment is not defined by the size and persistency of the deficit in the balance of payments. But I do not think
that this constitutes a serious difference between his views and mine. For suppose he defines
the "gravity and persistency" in terms of the volume of unemployment or the loss in national
income. That would necessitate vigorous anti-depression measures which would involve a
large balance of payments deficit. In any case, the actual and prospective balance of payments deficit in conjunction with the size of the international reserve constitutes the limiting




100

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

indicated that the question of how large and persistent a deficit must
be in order to be called fundamental should be answered mainly with
reference to the magnitude of the international reserve at the disposal
of a country. I t should be clearly realized that the judgment to the
effect that there exists a fundamental disequilibrium always implies
a forecast of future events. The fact that a deficit has existed in the
past or that it is visible at present, without expectation that it may
continue in the future, should not be regarded as a sufficient reason to
depreciate the currency.
From the fact that forecasts of future events are always implied, it
follows that other data than actual balance of payments statistics have
to be used in order to ascertain whether there is a fundamental disequilibrium, i.e., whether a serious deficit is to be expected in the
future. I t is only natural that price and cost comparisons between
different countries will figure prominently, although not exclusively,
in such a study. This is, however, not the same thing as the adoption
of a purchasing power parity or a cost parity criterion of the equilibrium exchange. A rigid theory of exchange parity whether in terms
of wholesale prices, cost of living, production costs, or wages would
necessarily break down whenever there is a substantial shift in international demand, which may be brought about by a variety of
factors such as changes in tariffs, other impediments to trade, transportation costs, technological changes, changes in consumer demand
and last, but not least, the business cycle. Only in conjunction with a
judgment about these things can price and cost comparisons serve as
a guide.
Now a few words about possible exceptions to the rule that a serious
and persistent deficit should be regarded as the criterion of fundamental disequilibrium. Such a deficit can be prevented from arising
or be eliminated once it has arisen by a contraction in income and
employment (depression) or by the imposition of new import restrictions such as tariffs, quotas, exchange control, etc. These are the
things we wish to avoid. Therefore, a deficit which is being avoided
or eliminated by ad hoc changes in import restrictions or by a drop in
factor upon anti-depression policies. It goes without saying that different countries having
different marginal propensities to import will lose international reserves at different rates
for a given increase in income and employment. This factor has to be kept in mind in estimating the prospective deficit.




COMMENTS

101

real income and employment should be regarded as actually existent.18
This rule must, however, be interpreted with great care. On the one
hand, it should not be taken to mean that the mere existence even of
a severe depression and of mass unemployment entitles a country to
receive permission to depreciate, even if it could be expected with
confidence that such a depreciation would alleviate the depression.
For such an alleviation must not be achieved at the expense of somebody else; it must not be achieved by creating a balance of payments
surplus which is a deficit of somebody else. Only if the managers of
the Fund are confident that a depreciation will benefit the depreciating country without creating a serious and persistent surplus,
should they give permission for depreciation. Now, if a deficit does
not exist when a depreciation is contemplated, the presumption is that
a surplus will appear after the currency has been depreciated; for it
is only in exceptional cases that there will not be a least a considerable
time lag between the rise in exports and imports. The Belgian case
cited above is said to have been such an exceptional case. Granted
that it was, it would not have been easy to diagnose it as such in
advance. For that reason, I suggested the rule that countries should
at first try domestic compensatory policies and ask for depreciation
only after a deficit has in fact arisen. (That in highly specialized
economies there may be little scope for compensatory domestic policies
has already been stated at an earlier point.) On the other hand if,
in the absence of a balance of payments deficit, depreciation is requested on the ground that the appearance of a deficit is prevented by
undesirable artificial restrictions on imports, the permission to depreciate should obviously be conditioned upon the prior or simultaneous removal of those restrictions on imports.
Real exceptions to the rule that depreciations should not be allowed, if they are expected to result in an export surplus of the depreciating country may, of course, be granted in exceptional cases:
small countries which are in a specially difficult situation may be
allowed to stimulate their economies by developing an export surplus,
even if it is done at the expense of somebody else. But it should be
clearly realized that such a policy, if pursued too often or by too many
18
This rule has been suggested by Nurkse, loc. cit. This rule again is contained in Dr»
Triffin's definition, for he speaks of maintenance of satisfactory levels of activity being incompatible with equilibrium in the balance of payments if not accompanied by protectionist
measures.




102

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY POLICIES

countries, is not only disturbing internationally and, if others retaliate,
self-defeating, but it is also open to objections from a purely national
point of view even when no retaliation is to be feared: for suppose a
country succeeds in stimulating its economy by creating an export
surplus (through the working of the so-called foreign trade multiplier);
it must not be forgotten that, by exporting more than it imports, it
gives away more goods to foreign countries than it receives from them.
A domestic policy which increases output and employment without
creating an export surplus would be clearly preferable even from a
purely national point of view, unless for some special reasons (for
example in an undiversified economy) such domestic anti-depression
policies cannot be undertaken in an efficient manner or the accumulation of gold or foreign assets (the offset to the export surplus) is
desired in itself.
There are also cases where the creation of an export surplus in one
country, with a view to alleviating a depression there, will not only be
condoned but even welcomed in the import-surplus countries; namely,
if the import countries are under inflationary pressure. In these
cases, depreciation will tend to alleviate at the same time deflation in
one country and inflation in the others.
One more factor, which affects and complicates all cases discussed
so far, should be mentioned. Until now we have assumed t h a t a
depreciation always tends to eliminate a deficit or create a surplus in
the balance of payments of the depreciating country. This need not
be true, however, in all cases. I would argue that in the long run
exceptions are very rare. But in the short run they may not be infrequent.
Although this brief outline does not, and is not intended to, do full
justice to the complexity of the problem, it is surely not simplicity in
itself. Moreover, a set of rules, even if it sounds convincing, should
not be allowed to obscure the fact that at every stage of its application,
beginning with the simple question as to the mere existence of a deficit
whether persistent or not, difficult problems of judgment are involved.
As Professor Howard S. Ellis once wisely remarked: " T o define the
equilibrium rate formally is one thing; to determine its height or
probable behavior in a given situation, another. Precisely the latter
and infinitely more complicated task must be performed by the monetary authorities who have to determine the extent of devaluation.''