View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Global Recovery Still at Risk
November 7, 2012
The global outlook remains uneven, with emerging economies outperforming advanced economies in terms of
growth while registering higher inflation rates (Chart 1A,
B).1 Overall, inflation continues to moderate as commodity prices retreat, although the weak recovery also may be
a restraining force.
Indicators of global economic activity—particularly in
manufacturing—are raising the prospect of a further slowdown. The Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas’ weighted purchasing managers index (PMI) measures show that manufacturing has staggered since the second half of 2011 in
both advanced and emerging economies (Chart 2A). Despite that, the global service sector PMI remains in expansion.
Financial conditions have returned to 2010–11 levels after
substantial monetary support and intervention, as evidenced by declining spreads between corporate and government bonds (Chart 2B). However, credit is not equally
accessible across countries due to the strained banking
systems of some advanced economies.

Chart 1
Global Economic Outlook
A.Two-Speed Pace of Real GDP Growth Continues
Percent, year/year
Q2:

10

7.0

5
3.3
1.6

0
Emerging economies
World
Advanced economies

-5
-10
1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

B. Headline Consumer Price Index Inflation Moderates
Percent, year/year
12
10
8

Q3:

6

5.6

4

3.9

2

1.5

0
-2
1999
2001
2003
NOTE: Shaded areas indicate global recession.
SOURCES: Haver Analytics; authors' calculations.

2005

2007

2009

2011

Chart 2
Real and Financial Indicators
A. Manufacturing PMIs Remain Weak, Services Still Resilient
Index < 50 = contraction
65
60
55

Delayed External Adjustments

50

Current accounts—like the two sides of a coin—describe
an economy’s trade balance, plus net income and transfers from abroad, and also its net external borrowing/
lending (domestic savings minus investment). If imports
exceed exports, external funds must be borrowed to cover the resulting deficit. The growing current-account deficits among advanced economies (the U.S. and a number
of European countries) prior to the global recession were
a counterpart to the large surpluses accumulated mainly
by emerging economies.

40

45

Growth in economies with large current-account deficits
was based on high domestic absorption stimulated by the
wealth illusion of a boom in real asset prices (particularly
real estate); domestic demand in the aftermath of the
2008–09 downturn was supported by large public
dissaving and expansionary, unconventional monetary
policy. In economies with large current-account surpluses,
domestic savings tends to be high and growth remains
largely dependent on foreign demand and policy support.
The policy response to the global recession has, in effect,
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

JP Morgan World: Services PMI
Emerging economies: Manufacturing PMI
World: Manufacturing PMI
Advanced economies: Manufacturing PMI

35
30
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

B. Spread Between Corporate and Government Funding Costs Narrows
Percentage points
5
Euro area
4
Emerging economies
U.S.
3

May 9, 2010:
EFSF/EFSM creation

Percentage points
12

July 15, 2011:
EU stress test results
announced

10
8
6

2

4

1

2

0

0
2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

NOTES: The emerging economies spread is the Corporate Emerging Market Bond Index by J.P. Morgan, which tracks dollar-denominated
long-term debt rated Baa2/BBB that is issued by emerging-market corporations. Spreads for the euro area and U.S. are calculated as the
difference between 10-year corporate bond yields, rated A, and 10-year government bond yields. EFSF and EFSM are European
temporary lending facilities.
SOURCES: Haver Analytics; Markit; Bloomberg; authors' calculations.

delayed the structural adjustment of current-account balances and, by extension, the rebalancing of growth toward
domestic demand in current-account-surplus countries and
foreign demand in deficit countries. As the external adjustment lags, global risks increase due to policy uncertainty
and the consequences of fiscal restraint—especially for
countries with severely strained public finances.
Exchange-rate realignments can help to unwind the current account and rebalance global growth. A real deprecia-

International Economic Update

1

tion—at least in the short run—increases the relative price Chart 3
International Monetary Developments
of tradables over nontradables (such as housing), encour- A. Real Value of U.S. Dollar Against Advanced and Emerging Economies Diverges
Index, October 2002 = 100
150
aging resources to relocate to the tradable sector. It
140
Emerging economies
World
makes imports more expensive, supporting a demand
130
Advanced economies
shift toward domestic products. Exchange rates can also
120
affect the domestic demand by altering the relative value 110
100
of national wealth and the external debt.
90
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

B. Emerging Economies' Monetary Policy Stance Tightens Relative to U.S.
A policy of managed exchange rates to protect exporters
Percentage-point deviation from target rate
12
(de facto or de jure) that interferes with the current10
8
account adjustment has had some notable adherents in
6
4
Relatively tighter
Latin America and Asia. However, this policy appears nei2
monetary policy
0
ther as broad-based nor as sustained as feared during the -2
Relatively easier
-4
monetary policy
2008–09 global downturn (Chart 3A). Emerging econo-6
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
mies in particular are increasingly less willing or less able NOTE: Shaded areas indicate global recession. An increase in the consumer price index-based real exchange rate means a
real depreciation.
to import U.S. monetary policy to maintain their exchange SOURCES: Haver Analytics; authors' calculations.
rates. After an initial appreciation in 2008, the real value
of the dollar largely continues to depreciate against a bas- Chart 4
European Financial Developments
ket of emerging currencies while it moves sideways with
A. Current Account Balances Adjusting in Peripheral Euro Area
U.S. dollars (billions)
U.S. dollars (billions)
the advanced currencies.
100
EFSF/EFSM 450

Exchange rates partly reflect differences in monetary policy between advanced and emerging economies. Chart 3B
illustrates the relative stance of international monetary
policy using the U.S. as a benchmark. A stance is deemed
accommodative if the U.S. would have employed tighter
policy in the same situation, while aiming to keep inflation
under control and output close to potential. By this metric, emerging economies’ monetary policy has followed
closely that of the advanced economies since 2003. By
2008, central banks (mainly in advanced economies) with
policy rates near the zero bound started to use the size
and composition of their balance sheets to reverse involuntary tightening. Emerging economies began to slowly
adjust for the overly accommodative monetary policy in
the middle of 2011. Now, only advanced economies display signs of accommodative monetary policy. It’s uncertain how this divergence in monetary policy stance will
affect exchange rates and the speed of adjustment.
Euro-Area Crisis
The ongoing euro crisis is reminiscent of the 1992–93
crisis of the European Monetary System, but back then,
the crisis’ resolution was facilitated by the U.K. withdrawal
from the peg and the devaluation of the currencies of Italy, Spain, Portugal and Ireland. Nonetheless, European
policymakers came to reaffirm their commitment to give
up the exchange rate as a stabilization policy tool—
judging from the 1992–93 experience that semifixed exchange rates were vulnerable because they were neither
truly binding nor fully credible. The limited economic integration and real convergence attained during the 1990s
did not constitute a major impediment to the creation of
the euro in 1999.
The convergence of borrowing rates was deemed key in
the perceived success of the first decade of the euro, in
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

creation

Euro
adoption

European
Monetary System
crisis

60

300
150

CA balances of world
countries in surplus

20

0

CA balances of world
countries in deficit

-20

-150

Peripheral euro-area economies
Core euro-area economies

-60

-300

-100

-450
1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

B. Ten-Year Government Bond Yield Divergence Reemerges
16
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0

Euro
adoption

Peripheral euro-area economies
Core euro-area economies
U.S.

EFSF/EFSM
creation

European Monetary System crisis

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

NOTES: Shaded areas indicate global recession. Peripheral euro-area economies are Ireland, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy and
Slovenia. Data for Malta and Cyprus are excluded. Current account (CA) balances for world countries in surplus and deficit (represented
with green blocks) based on annual International Monetary Fund (IMF) data, divided by 4. EFSF and EFSM are European temporary
lending facilities.
SOURCES: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development; IMF; Haver Analytics; authors' calculations.

spite of the buildup of current account deficits and surpluses in peripheral and core euro-area economies, respectively—a significant fraction of the world’s total for
both deficits and surpluses (Chart 4A). Low interest rates
and access to external borrowed funds spurred a large
increase in private (and public) indebtedness and also
fueled asset price booms in many peripheral euro-area
economies (Chart 4B). In the aftermath of the global recession, current-account balances have declined significantly for the peripheral euro-area economies, and the
divergence in long-term yields has reemerged, revealing a
significant disparity in fundamentals within the euro area.
The response to the global downturn was based on expansionary fiscal policies at the country level and accommodative monetary policy. This supported domestic demand
to some extent but also crowded out private investment
and delayed the external adjustment.
When an external devaluation (through the exchange rate)
is not possible and fiscal policy runs its course, putting at
risk the sustainability of public finances, countries with

International Economic Update

2

Chart 5
Banking System Conditions
A. Bank CDS Spreads Remain Elevated in Peripheral Euro Area...
Basis points
800
July 15, 2011:
EU stress test
results

May 9, 2010:
EFSF/EFSM
creation

Peripheral euro-area economies
Core euro-area economies
U.S.

600
400
200
0

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

B. ...While Deposits Flow Out of Peripheral Euro Area
Euros (billions)
800
May 9, 2010:
EFSF/EFSM
creation

600
400

July 15,
2011:
EU stress
test results

200
0
-200
-400
1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

NOTE: Shaded areas indicate global recessions. Peripheral euro-area economies are Ireland, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy, Slovenia
and Cyprus. Bank CDS (credit default swap) spreads are weighted by 2005 bank assets. Twelve-month cumulated deposit flows are
from households and private nonfinancial corporations. EFSF and EFSM are European temporary lending facilities.
SOURCES: Bloomberg; The Banker; ECB; authors' calculations.

Chart 6
Euro-Area Fiscal Policy Challenges
A. Sovereign Debt Repayment Schedules Face Difficult Climb
Euros (billions)
700

Peripheral economies Core economies

600
500

ESM maximum lending capacity

Interest
Principal

400

Interest
Principal

300
200
100
0
2012

2017

2022

2027

2032

2037

2042

2045–62
2045-2062

B. Primary Balance Surplus Expected by 2013
2012-13
European
Commission
forecasts

Euros (billions)
160
80
0
-80
-160
-240

Peripheral economies Core economies
Primary balance
Interest expenditure

Primary balance
Interest expenditure

-320
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
2012
NOTES: Peripheral euro-area economies are Ireland, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy, Slovenia and Cyprus. ESM is the
European Stability Mechanism.
SOURCES: Bloomberg; Haver Analytics; authors' calculations.

large current-account deficits resort to some combination
of structural reforms and internal devaluation to restore
their competitiveness. Labor market reform, wage cuts and
cuts in taxes on labor (partly offset by the increase of other taxes) have been implemented with that aim. Without
growth resumption, debt restructuring for financially distressed countries such as Greece and even the abandonment of the euro currency have become part of the policy
debate as well.
The ailing banking system and worsening public finances in
the peripheral euro-area economies are presently the most
pressing challenges. Problems of chronic low productivity
in the peripheral economies were partly masked by strong
domestic demand sustained by borrowing. This borrowing
funded large increases in government expenditures and
high public debt and, in other cases, increases in private
sector debt and large run-ups in real estate and land prices. Domestic banks intermediated much of the debt
buildup by borrowing cheaply from abroad, thereby facilitating the accumulation of current-account deficits.
As the external funds that once flowed freely toward these
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

peripheral euro-area economies dried up, their banks became increasingly stressed (Chart 5A) and dependent
upon European Central Bank (ECB) support. Adding to
worries due to the strained interbank lending, the peripheral economies were hit by a sizeable decline in deposits,
which were partly relocated to stronger euro-area economies (Chart 5B). The decline did not start in earnest until
after the deterioration of public finances and the extent of
bank exposures became more apparent to the public in
2011.
Euro-area governments responded to the distress of peripheral euro-area sovereigns with the creation of the
European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF) and the European Financial Stabilisation Mechanism (EFSM). The European Stability Mechanism (ESM) was established on Sept.
27, 2012, to replace the temporary lending facilities of
the EFSF/EFSM. The pledges to nations so far include
€198 billion to Greece, €52 billion to Ireland and €45 billion to Portugal, plus €100 billion to Spanish banks. The
ESM’s maximum lending capacity of €500 billion covers
only a fraction of the gross funding needs of the peripheral economies through 2013 (Chart 6A) and does not necessarily guarantee the sustainability of their debt obligations.
Whenever the nominal GDP growth of an economy is below its government’s funding costs, a surplus on the primary balance (the difference between government revenues and expenses, excluding interest on debt) is required to stabilize the debt as a fraction of GDP. So, unless sustained growth, lower funding costs or both can be
attained, the primary-balance surplus that is expected by
2013 will be important to take back control over public
finances (Chart 6B). Economies that default do so primarily as a result of high interest expenditures, and those
remain a heavy burden for peripheral euro-area economies. However, debt restructuring does not avoid the
need for a significant fiscal consolidation because a defaulting country is likely shut out of borrowing and therefore needs to run a primary-balance surplus to service its
restructured debt (and any debt not affected by restructuring).
After borrowing and lending dried up in the interbank
market in 2009, peripheral euro-area banks’ funding
needs were increasingly supported through the Eurosystem (Chart 7A). Banks in core euro-area economies that
would have loaned funds to peripheral banks directly four
years ago now prefer to park those funds at their central
banks, which assume the risks. The Securities Markets
Program (SMP) initiated by the central banks of the Eurosystem on May 10, 2010, allowed the ECB to purchase
distressed government bonds. Spain and Italy have seen
a decline in the share of government debt owned by foreigners and an increase in their borrowing costs, partly
offset by SMP purchases since August 2011 (Chart 7B).

International Economic Update

3

At its meeting on Sept. 6, the ECB upped its support further
with the Outright Monetary Transactions program. Governments must agree to strict ESM conditions before ECB bondbuying operations in the secondary market are triggered.
Enforcement rests on the threat that bond purchases will be
suspended if conditions imposed under the terms of the
bailout are not met.
Even if the sovereign and banking crises can be contained in
the near term, any resolution to the European problems that
preserves the integrity of the common currency must confront a number of long-term structural issues. A currency
area must rely on a policy framework and policy tools that
minimize the emergence of imbalances and foster their adjustment when they occur, but progress has been slow and
the global downturn has tended to magnify preexisting policy
disagreements. Europe also has to deal with other long-term
issues. Aside from demographic factors stemming from a low
fertility rate and an aging population, those concerns notably
include the productivity gap between the peripheral and core
economies. The gap has been rising since the adoption of the
euro, and even core European economies have had a hard
time catching up to U.S. productivity.

Chart 7
Euro-Area Monetary Policy Support
A. Net Balances with Eurosystem Show Strains of European Banking System
Euros (billions)
1200

May 9, 2010:
EFSF/EFSM
creation

Core euro-area economies

800

Peripheral euro-area economies

400
0
-400

July 15,
2011:
EU stress
test

-800
-1200
1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

B. Foreign Ownership of Peripheral Debt Declines in Italy and Spain
Percent of debt outstanding
60
Italy
Italy: includes ECB purchases
Spain
50
Spain: includes ECB purchases

May 10, 2010:
ECB establishes
SMP

Aug. 12,
2011: SMP
expansion

40
30
20
1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

NOTES: Shaded areas indicate global recessions. SMP stands for the Securities Markets Program established by the European Central
Bank (ECB), which was extended to include Spanish and Italian bonds in August 2011. Purchases are assumed to be one-third of
Spanish bonds and two-thirds of Italian bonds. EFSF and EFSM are European temporary lending facilities. Peripheral euro-area
economies are Ireland, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy, Slovenia and Cyprus.
SOURCES: University of Osnabrück; Bank of Italy; Bank of Spain; Bloomberg; authors' calculations.

—Valerie Grossman, Adrienne Mack and Enrique MartínezGarcía
Note
1.

Advanced economies include all countries whose gross
domestic product (GDP) per capita in purchasing power
parity (PPP) was—on average in 2003–07—at least three
times higher than the median of all countries in the
world, excluding oil producers. Emerging economies include all other countries. Each aggregate uses all available data according to this classification, with annual purchasing power parity-adjusted GDP weights from the
International Monetary Fund (IMF), except real exchange
rates, where trade weights are computed with IMF data
on imports plus exports in U.S. dollars. Turning points of
the global cycle are determined by the size of the economies’ simultaneously contracting industrial production
reaching 60 percent of global output.

………………………………………………………………………………………………..
About the Authors
Grossman is a research assistant, Mack is a research analyst
and Martínez-García is a senior research economist in the
Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas.

Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas

International Economic Update

4