The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
r3 ^ W H E fe d e r a l reserve F^g;QlffillrABIUTY ACT OF 1993 of S t. Louis J994 APR 1 2 " h e a k 'In g BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND llv URBjftj AFFAIRS HOUSE f REPRESENTATIVES 16 ' IA ONE HUNDRED THIRD CONGRESS FIRST SESSION OCTOBER 19, 1993 Printed for the use of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs Serial No. 103-78 U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 73-208 CC WASHINGTON : 1994 For sale by the U.S. Government Printing Office Superintendent of Documents, Congressional Sales Office, Washington, DC 20402 ISBN 0 - 1 6 -0 4 4 0 1 6 - 5 HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS HENRY B. GONZALEZ, Texas, Chairman JAMES A. LEACH, Iowa STEPHEN L. NEAL, North Carolina JOHN J. LaFALCE, New York BILL MCCOLLUM, Florida BRUCE F. VENTO, Minnesota MARGE ROUKEMA, New Jereey CHARLES E. SCHUMER, New York DOUG BEREUTER, Nebraska BARNEY FRANK, Massachusetts THOMAS J. RIDGE, Pennsylvania PAUL E. KANJORSKI, Pennsylvania TOBY ROTH, Wisconsin JOSEPH P. KENNEDY II, Massachusetts ALFRED A. (AL) McCANDLESS, California FLOYD H. FLAKE, New York RICHARD H. BAKER, Louisiana KWEISI MFUME, Maryland JIM NUSSLE, Iowa MAXINE WATERS, California CRAIG THOMAS, Wyoming LARRY LAROCCO, Idaho SAM JOHNSON, Texas BILL ORTON, Utah DEBORAH PRYCE, Ohio JIM BACCHUS, Florida JOHN LINDER, Georgia HERBERT C. KLEIN, New Jersey JOE KNOLLENBERG, Michigan RICK LAZIO, New York CAROLYN B. MALONEY, New York PETER DEUTSCH, Florida ROD GRAMS, Minnesota LUIS V. GUTIERREZ, Illinois SPENCER BACHUS, Alabama BOBBY L. RUSH, Illinois MIKE HUFFINGTON, California MICHAEL CASTLE, Delaware LUCILLE ROYBAL-ALLARD, California THOMAS M. BARRETT, Wisconsin PETER KING, New York ELIZABETH FURSE, Oregon BERNARD SANDERS, Vermont NYDIA M. VELAZQUEZ, New York ALBERT R. WYNN, Maryland CLEO FIELDS, Louisiana MELVIN WATT, North Carolina MAURICE HINCHEY, New York CALVIN M. DOOLEY, California RON KLINK, Pennsylvania ERIC FINGERHUT, Ohio (II) CONTENTS Page Hearing held on: October 19, 1993 ......................................................................................... Appendix: October 19, 1993 ......................................................................................... 1 63 WITNESSES Tuesday, October 19, 1993 Angell, Wayne, D., Governor, Federal Reserve Board ....................................... Boehne, Edward G., Jr., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia...... Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond .......... Craven, Robert, Fixed Income Management Group.......................................... Greenspan, Hon. Alan, Chairman oT the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Open Market Committee; accompanied by David W. Mullins, Jr., Governor, Federal Reserve Board; William J. McDonough, Federal Reserve Bank of New York; and Robert T. Parry, President, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco ....................................... Hoenig, Thomas M., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas C ity............ Jordan, Jerry L., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland ..................... Keehn, Silas, President, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago .............................. Kelley, Edward W., Jr., Governor, Federal Reserve Board............................... LaWare, John P., Governor, Federal Reserve Board ......................................... Lindsey, Lawrence B., Governor, Federal Reserve Board................ ................. McTeer, Robert D., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas ........................ Meigs, James, Senior Vice President and Chief Economist, First Interstate Bank Corp....................................................................................................... Melzer, Thomas C., President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis................... Parry, Robert T., President, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco .............. Phillips, Susan M., Governor, Federal Reserve Board ...................................... Schwartz, Anna, Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research . Stern, Gary H., President, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis .................... Syron, Richard F., Federal Reserve Bank of Boston ......................................... 12 19 20 54 8 22 23 24 13 15 16 25 50 27 28 18 47 29 31 APPENDIX Prepared statements: Gonzalez, Hon. Henry B............................................................................... Fingerhut, Hon. Eric D................................................................................ Johnson, Hon. Sam ..................................................................................... Leach, Hon. James A................................................................................... Roybal-Allard, Hon. Lucille ........................................................................ Angell, Wayne D.......................................................................................... Boehne, Edward G....................................................................................... Broaddus, J. Alfred, Jr................................................................................. Craven, Robert............................................................................................ Greenspan, Hon. Alan ................................................................................ Hoenig, Thomas M....................................................................................... Jordan, Jerry L............................................................................................ Keehn, Silas ................................................................................................ Kelley, Edward W., Jr.................................................................................. LaWare, John P............................................................................................ Lindsey, Lawrence S.................................................................................... McDonough, William J................................................................................. McTeer, Robert D......................................................................................... (HI) 64 70 73 68 75 138 162 167 222 76 173 176 179 143 147 152 127 183 IV Page Prepared statements—Continued Meigs, James............................................................................................... Melzer, Thomas C......................................................................................... Mullins, David W., Jr................................................................................... Pany, Robert T............................................................................................. Philfips, Susan M......................................................................................... Stem, Gary H............................................................................................... Schwartz, Anna J......................................................................................... Syron, Richard F.......................................................................................... 214 188 121 133 157 192 209 206 A d d it io n a l M a t e r ia l S u b m it t e d f o r t h e R e c o r d Neal, Hon. Stephen L.: ...................................................................................... Mr. Gary Stern’s response to questions submitted by the Congressman .... “Playing by The Rules, A Proposal for Federal Budget Reform,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1990 Annual Report ............................... 228 232 H.R. 28; FEDERAL RESERVE ACCOUNTABILITY ACT OF 1993 TUESDAY, OCTOBER 19, 1993 H ouse of R epresen tatives , C ommittee on Ban kin g , F inance and U rban A ffairs , Washington, DC. The committee met, pursuant to notice, at 10 a.m., in room 2128, Rayburn House Office Building, Hon. Henry B. Gonzalez [chairman of the committee] presiding. Present: Chairman Gonzalez, Representatives Neal, LaFalce, Roybal-Allard, Hinchey, Fingerhut, Leach, McCollum, Roukema, Ridge, Roth, McCandless, Nussle, Johnson, Pryce, Knollenberg, Lazio, and Huffington. The Chairm an. The committee will please come to order. Today, the Banking Committee begins the third day of hearings on issues involved in the Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993, otherwise known as H.R. 28. I certainly welcome and want to thank the Federal Reserve Chairman of the Board of Gov ernors, Mr. Greenspan, the Federal Reserve Governors, and the presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks. Chairman Greenspan testified at our last hearing last week that everything proposed in our H.R. 28 was a, quote, major mistake, end of quote. Today, we will hear additional testimony to see if our proposals are needed reforms or major mistakes. H.R. 28 requires that the Federal Open Market Committee: One, announce changes in its policy 1 week after its meetings and that it; two, make public a complete record of those meetings 60 days after each meeting. The central issue of today’s hearing is simple: Why is the Federal Reserve, among all Federal agencies, exempt from keeping com plete and accurate records? If the White House, the Supreme Court, the Defense Department, and every other government agen cy keep accurate records of what they are doing, why not the Fed eral Reserve? Are decisions by these parts of our government less sensitive than those made at the Federal Reserve? You distinguished gentlemen who serve as Federal Reserve presi dents did not have to present your credentials and your views to the American public to secure your seats on the FOMC. President Jordan has previously gone through the confirmation process for his seat on the Reagan Council of Economic Advisors. I hope to day’s hearing will allow the citizens of our country to learn a little bit more about you and how independent your views really are. (l) 2 I would like each of you to tell me if you think the following in formation is of sufficient national importance to require recording and publication of minutes of your FOMC meetings. Last week at these hearings I cited FOMC minutes of two meet ings prior to the reelection of President Richard Nixon. Those min utes were released 5 years after the FOMC meetings. Although he was warned that projections were for fast growth, Federal Reserve Chairman Arthur Bums had called for even faster money growth at these meetings. Why shouldn't the historical record reflect the truth that Burns was pursuing an inflationary policy? The importance of accurate minutes is reflected in the records of a Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank’s board of directors meeting. The minutes reveal a possible coverup by the Federal Reserve re lated to the Watergate burglary in 1972. Recall the Watergate scandal that began with the break-in of the Democratic National Committee offices in the Watergate office building on June 17, 1972. A dangerous political crisis rocked our country while Con gress sought to uncover the facts. As a matter of fact, this committee had original and first and pri mary responsibility in June 1972. I recall it vividly, as if it were today. And the committee chairman, the Honorable Wright Patman, was frustrated because we had to have subpoenas, and we had a solid block of the minority resisting, and all they had to do was pick up three of our fellow Democrats, which they did, and we were frustrated in that effort. Judge Sirica was very much involved in that. What would have happened if this committee had not been frustrated and we had from the very beginning unraveled—I think even President Nixon would have ended up better off. A dangerous political crisis did de velop, though, and I think we know the consequences today. I read now from page 77 of the June 22, 1972, minutes of the Philadelphia Bank’s board of directors meeting, and I am quoting: “Mr. X reported that $6,300 in $100 bills had been found on the persons arrested for breaking into the Democratic National Com mittee headquarters in Washington. The FBI came to this Bank and said that 10 new 3-C notes, that is, $100 bills, numbered in sequence were among those found. This Bank informed the FBI that they were part of a shipment sent to the Girard Bank on April 3. Mr. X also said that the Washington Post had called to verify a rumor that these bills were stolen from this Bank. The Post was informed of the CV&D thefts but was told they involved old bills that were ready for destruction. “Mr. X said that Chairman Burns doesn’t want the System to get involved and issued a directive to all Reserve banks on June 21 which said, in effect, that the System was cooperating with law en forcement agencies but should not disclose any information to others.” Three days earlier. Chairman Burns had written the following to the Joint Economic Committee about rumors regarding the sources of funds used to finance the Watergate burglars: “We at the Board have no knowledge of the Federal Reserve Bank which issued those particular notes or of the commercial bank to which they were transferred. Without this information, there is nothing that we can do to comply with your request.” 3 The apparent lie to the Washington Post reporter as a result of the directives issues by the Chairman of the Federal Reserve mav have been part of a coverup of important information by the Fed eral Reserve. Did the Federal Reserve ever inform the U.S. Con gress about these bills it had traced that were found on the Water gate burglars? If the answer is no, it appears that the Federal Re serve blocked the public and the Congress from a significant part of the investigation of the financing of the Watergate burglars. The Acting Director of the FBI, who may have been given the in formation, testified that he burned some Watergate files. The Nixon administration asked him to limit the FBI’s investigation of the burglars1 financing on the grounds that further inquiiy would “uncover CIA assets and sources.” Gosh, that sounds familiar. What was the Federal Reserve’s role in this coverup? Did the Fed eral Reserve deliberately obstruct the Congress and the public? If we only had a formal directive giving the extremely truncated version of these meetings, as the FOMC publishes today, there would not be a historical record of these events. The American pub lic and the Congress are not the barbarians at your gates. These are the people whom you are supposed to be serving. Our expert witnesses testifying today will tell you that, contrary to what Chairman Greenspan testified about at our last hearing, accurate information does not undermine markets. Partial informa tion and leaked information undermines market efficiency. I want to highlight the astounding claim in Dr. Anna Schwartz’ testimony, and I quote: “The Wall Street Journal has reported the contents of the directive within a week of each of 11 out of 34 FOMC meetings that were held between March, 1989, and May, 1993.” Since substantial information is already coming out in leaked form, why should we pretend that it is a closely guarded se cret? We need a straightforward record with complete and accurate information. Some claim we have all the information necessary in the formal directive that is issued 5 or 6 weeks after each FOMC meeting. That directive is sometimes called “minutes.” However, the FOMC directive is far from a complete record, and it is equivalent to the kind of information we would get if the Supreme Court only an nounced its decisions and not its opinions. Although the directive does contain the FOMC vote, those who understand the Federal Reserve know the objective in any FOMC meeting is to get a unan imous final vote regardless of any underlying disagreement. Publishing only the final vote at FOMC meetings is little more information than could be obtained from the Congress if we issued only the vote on adjournment and none of the discussion. In order to obtain a record that establishes individual accountability, there must be a more detailed record. Most of the so-called minutes the Federal Reserve now issues are boilerplate reports on the economy that anyone could copy out of government and newspaper reports. In 1976, the FOMC members arbitrarily announced that they had stopped taking minutes of their meetings. In response to his inquiries, Congressman Steve Neal, our ranking majority Member, investigated and reported that among the 55 individuals who op posed the FOMC’s decision to stop taking minutes were 4 former 4 Federal Reserve Governors and 2 former presidents of Federal Re serve Banks. One of the strongest letters was from Jerry L. Jordan, formerly an official at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, here today as president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. His letter of October 21, 1976, said, and I quote from him: “As an economist in the Federal Reserve for over 8 years, I found the memoranda of discussion”—that is the name of the minutes—“to be extremely useful. Even when I attended FOMC meetings I always reviewed the memoranda of previous meetings as part of the preparation for the next meeting.” The President of the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank was defi nitely influenced in a very positive way by the existence of a per manent record that would eventually be made public. It helped him and his staff to maintain intellectual honesty, sometimes in the face of great pressure to bend. He knew that even when his views fell on deaf ears in a meeting, consistent analysis of the problem and the recommendation of solutions would be in the record to be viewed with historical perspective. I want to know why minutes which were clearly helpful up until 1976 suddenly became harmful after 1976. I think it is a reason able question. I understand the peculiar position of the distinguished presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks who are testifying today. I under stand that, and I am extremely grateful for your presence. I think that goodwill—and, obviously, certainly there is no political advan tage—should reflect the seriousness of the intent and motivation and a clear attempt to discharge a prime responsibility that lays upon us who want to be and claim to be representatives of the peo ple in that area that most affects their livelihoods. I had thought that last week Chairman Greenspan would have emphasized tnat you serve as independent coequals on the FOMC. However, he contends that the ultimate defense against a bank president is the power by the Board of Governors to remove that person from office. I think this says a great deal about your inde pendence. Nevertheless, be that as it may, I hope our distinguished witnesses will give their honest views today, as I am sure they will, and that they will be perfectly frank while their comments are being recorded. And I certainly look forward to your testimony. [The prepared statement of Chairman Gonzalez can be found in the appendix.] The C hairm an. With that, I recognize Mr. Leach. Mr. L each , I thank the distinguished chairman. Today we hear from 10 presidents of the district banks and 5 Governors of the Federal Reserve Board. Given that these individ uals influence the allocation and expansion of credit through the regulation of the banking industry, it is important to note in the context of a hearing on reforming the Federal Reserve System that the American public is served by individuals represented here of distinctive quality and integrity. We welcome them in a spirit of appreciation and trust. And I personally would like to say, Mr. Chairman, I appreciate your sense of history that you iust expounded. It should be clear in the record that Watergate didn’t tar the reputation of any of the 5 individuals that we have before us, and that everybody is here vol untarily without any hint of misdoing or misdeeds. In fact, given the brain trust we have before us, it makes me think it would be very appropriate perhaps at some other time to invite all or part of this group before the committee again. Given the regional eco nomic perspective that is here, it might be very helpful to the Con gress itself. At the first two hearings, this committee gave deserved attention to the fact that particular presidents are assigned public respon sibility on boards comprised of individuals not only from the pri vate sector but one element of it. In defense of this selection meth odology, the Federal Reserve System can properly point to a tradi tion of independence, quality, and political insulation. Neverthe less, there is an element of unseemliness inherent in a system in which sectors of the public view their interest as distinct from the banking sector and in particular when individuals are asked to reg ulate the industry while being accountable to boards of directors controlled by members of that industry. While I have a high regard for the current leadership of the Fed and the direction it is currently moving on the regulatory front, it is useful to point out three areas where the Federal Reserve Sys tem in the past has instituted discriminatory regulatory policies. First, in the late 1970’s, early 1980’s, the Fed went along in be lieving that sovereign guarantees were ironclad because govern ments never go broke and imposed lesser regulation on LDC debt. Second, the Fed has continued to assume that large banks need less capital than smaller banks. Third, it has not required bad loans of large banks to be written off to the same extent required of small banks. My view is that discriminatory regulation skews the financial landscape and amounts to credit allocation. The irony in regulation being too accommodating, if not cozy, with individual banks is that management becomes misserved. For instance, New York money center banks for decades have been on the cutting edge of wanting to see liberalization of the Douglas amendment and McFadden Act so they could branch interstate. When interstate barriers started to fall, without congressional modification of these laws, many of these banks were in no position to take advantage of it because their capital had been so dramatically depleted. This was due, in part, to lending mistakes which were in effect sanctioned by regu lators. If regulators, on a timely basis, had insisted on stronger capital ratios for international lending, domestic as well as foreign, these institutions would be larger ana stronger today. It is instructive to note that Federal regulators, albeit a bit late, forced the Bank of America to restructure and recapitalize approxi mately 5 years before they served comparable notice on the east coast. Bank of America later credited regulator sternness with its turnaround and the ability to launch an expansionary drive. One of the lessons of the S&L debacle is that capital moves to ward industries which have the weakest regulation. The problem of regulator-driven deposit skewing was most evi dent in the 1980’s in the thrift industiy when institutions were al lowed to leverage minimal and in some cases nonexistent capital bases. It is a not inconsequential problem today. The more atten- 6 tion given to risk weighting assets, the less reliance Federal bank regulators are putting on the leverage ratio. Overreliance on riskbased capital standards without use of an adequate ratio leads to competitive inequities in deposit seeking and de facto credit alloca tion of those deposits. The fact that State bank regulators rely more on leverage ratios means that deposits will flow to national banks rather than State banks, to money center institutions rather than community banks, to bond buying instead of entrepreneurial lending. Regulatory agencies have a vested interest in the competitive vi tality of the institutions they regulate. Hence, if the Fed wants to keep, which I support, a major regulatory function, it must be care ful to ensure that conflicts, perceived or otherwise, do not exist, that regional inequities are not allowed to develop, and advantages are not provided one kind of institution over another. As mentioned earlier, one of the lessons of the S&L crisis was that disparity in regulations skews capital flows. Another was the conclusion by Congress that it had been a mistake to allow the 12 district banks in the Federal Home Loan Bank System, with boards comprised of representatives from regulated institutions, a prin cipal role in the regulatory process. As part of the cleanup, Con gress abolished the regulatory function of the Federal Home Loan Bank System and transferred them to an office which has its direc tor publicly appointed. As we consider regulatory consolidation, there is a case for and against providing continuation of regulatory responsibility for the Federal Reserve System. But if it is to be preserved—and I would stress again I support that prospect—an institutional arrangement must be established which gives no hint of self-regulation, of the fox guarding the foxes. In a country in which process is our most important product, it simply is unacceptable for regulators to be ac countable to boards which, in turn, are controlled by the regulated. I look forward today to the testimony of the witnesses. [The prepared statement of Mr. Leach can be found in the appen dix.] The C hairm an. The Chair will recognize Mr. Neal. He is our ranking Member on the majority side and also chairman of the fun damental Subcommittee on Financial Institutions. Thank you. Mr. N e a l . Thank you, sir, very much. I would like to say briefly, first of all, it is entirely appropriate for the Banking Committee to hold hearings looking into any and every area of its jurisdiction. It is entirely appropriate for us to continue to examine the underpinnings of our system, eveiy aspect of the underpinnings of our system, to constantly try to find ways to do better what it is we try to do. So I certainly have no objection to our examining the Fed’s regu latory structure, the open market operations, every aspect of it. In fact, I think it is very healthy. I think that certainly nothing should be set in stone forever, and that it is very healthy to con tinue to look at the way we do things. Having said that, I must say it is also a little strange to me that we are devoting a lot of time to the Fed, especially the Fed’s open market operations, at this time because it seems to me that those 7 operations have been very successful, and there has not been a hint of scandal ever. The Fed’s—the most important role, of course, is controlling in flation in the Open Market Committee, which has that responsibil ity, has done that job very well over recent years, in fact, extraor dinarily well under the most difficult circumstances. And every citi zen of this country really should be thankful to this group for the current situation. I am talking especially about the fact that young couples now can borrow at the lowest mortgage rates in memory, that banks are lowering the prime rates to the lowest rates in many years, that really the whole banking structure has been strengthened, in fact, saved, by low inflation, low interest rates. The stock market is strong because of low inflation, low interest rates. So the healthiest aspect of our economy is directly attributable to the fact that this institution has worked well, that it has done its job very, very well. Every American, most importantly the work ing people of America, the people who must borrow, not the rich people who can handle their finances under all circumstances but the average guy out trying to make it from paycheck to paycheck, is the main beneficiary of this policy that has lowered interest rates and lowered inflation. So I do find it a little strange that we are examining the Fed. But, in any case, it is an important subject, and if there is any problem, we ought to uncover it and deal with it. Just one more point I would like to make. I hope you all, in your testimony this morning, will try to relate the policies that we are examining, the idea of revealing minutes and auditing the Open Market Committee and the other suggestions that are contained in this legislation and in other legislation to your policy. Somehow, so far, it seems these hearings have considered process divorced from policy. And, frankly, if we were to look at sort of a good government model and that were all we were looking at, we might say, yes, it would be nice to know every word that was spo ken and know it that day and maybe show it on the evening news and so on, audit the Open Market Committee and so on. But the fact is that those considerations are not divorced firom policy. And the only reason we want an independent Fed is so the Fed can work for the long-term benefit of this country, even in light of the short-term political pressures that would be there were there not the independence. So I think that point hasn't quite been made when we have talked about how it would be a good idea for every comment made by every person when discussing monetary policy to be made pub lic. It is not a good idea because we want be free, open discussion devoid of political pressure. Because that can help lead to a policy that is best for our people. When we talk about auditing the Open Market Committee, the reason we don't want to audit the Open Market Committee is we don’t want to second-guess and impose a short-term political pres sure on the committee that is trying to take a long-term view in the interest of our people. So, anyway, Mr. Chairman, I appreciate the opportunity to say a few words. I am glad you are holding the hearing. I hope we will 8 just introduce the policy consideration here as it affects these poli cies that these so-called reforms are talking about. I think it will become clearer why we wouldn’t want to pass this bill. I thank the distinguished chairman. The C h a ir m a n . I ask unanimous consent that all members have an opportunity to place in the record in writing any preliminaiy statement they wisn to have appear in the transcript of the pro ceedings. And being that we have such numerous witnesses, we will try to hurry on expeditiously. [The prepared statements referred to can be found in the appendix.] We will recognize Chairman Greenspan, of course, first. The Chairman has asked for at least 15 minutes. We will be prepared to place in the record all of the written testi mony that has been submitted to us by the diverse presidents and directors and then ask that your oral presentation be as brief as possible following Chairman Greenspan. Mr. Chairman. STATEMENT OF HON. ALAN GREENSPAN, CHAIRMAN OF THE BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD AND THE FEDERAL OPEN MARKET COMMITTEE; ACCOM PANIED BY DAVID W. MULLINS, JR., GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD; WILLIAM J. McDONOUGH, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK; AND ROBERT T. PARRY, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO Mr. G r een spa n . Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I appre ciate the opportunity to appear before this committee and to pro vide my particular views on the appropriate degree of disclosure by the Federal Open Market Committee. In a democratic society, public policy decisions-----The C ha ir m an . Will you please yield to me for a moment? Gentlemen, I hate to bother you, but Congressman Johnson has reported that his view is obstructed. Is there any possible way you can take a shot without obstructing his view? Congressman, why don’t you sit up here? Thank you, sir. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. G r een spa n . Just to repeat, Mr. Chairman, it is important that we recognize that in a democratic society public policy deci sions should be in the open, except where exposure impedes the primary function assigned to an institution by law. Accordingly, the Federal Reserve makes its decisions public immediately, except when doing so could undercut the efficacy of policy or compromise the integrity of the policy process. What we do not disclose immediately are the implementing deci sions with respect to our open market operations. However, any changes in our objectives in reserve markets are quickly and pub licly signaled by our open market operations. And we publish min utes of the policy deliberations and decisions from each FOMC meeting shortly after the next regular meeting has taken place. These minutes, a copy of which for the meeting of February 1993, I have attached to the statement, can run from 15 to more than 30 pages, presenting a comprehensive record of the economic fac- 9 tors and analysis and alternative policy approaches considered in reaching our decisions. Nevertheless, the Federal Reserve, like other central banks, has a reputation of being secretive. I suspect this is largely a result of the nature of a central bank’s mission. The operations of central banks have a direct impact on financial and foreign exchange mar kets; therefore, these institutions often find themselves in the posi tion where complete openness and disclosure could regrettably in hibit or even thwart the implementation of their public purpose. It is often the case that the FOMC expresses a predisposition to ward a policy change in its directive to the Open Market Desk. Such a predisposition, for example, toward easing, implies that the FOMC is more concerned about developments that would dictate an easing of policy rather than a tightening, and therefore wants to respond relatively promptly to information suggesting the need for such action. We often express this predisposition without any change in in strument settings in fact resulting. In such circumstances, the re lease of those directives during the period they are in force would only add to fluctuations in financial markets, moving rates when no immediate change was intended. As a consequence, a disclosure requirement would impair the usefulness of the directives, as committee members, concerned about the announcement effect of a directive biased either toward ease or tightening, would tend to shy away from anything but a vote of immediate change or of no change at the meeting. An im portant element of flexibility in the current procedures would be lost, which can scarcely serve the public interest. Immediate disclo sure of the directive would change the nature of monetary policy making, and it would not be a change for the better. Holding open meetings of the FOMC or releasing a videotape, audio tape, or transcript of them would so seriously constrain the process of formulating policy as to render those meetings nearly unproductive. A number of important items currently discussed at FOMC meet ings simply could not be mentioned in open forum. We would no longer have the benefit of sensitive information from foreign central banks and other official institutions or of proprietary infor mation from private sector sources, as we could not risk the publi cation of information given us in confidence. Moreover, to avoid creating unnecessary volatility in financial and foreign exchange markets, the FOMC might have to forego ex plorations of the full range of policy options. Even a lag in releas ing a verbatim record of the meetings would not eliminate this problem but only attenuate it. Mr. Chairman, let me take a moment to describe more fully the process followed at FOMC meetings to reach decisions on monetary policy. After staff presentations of recent developments and emerg ing economic trends, a roundtable discussion of all 19 participants begins. The Reserve bank presidents describe conditions and devel opments within their districts, and both they and the members of the Board of Governors go on to evaluate the outlook for the U.S. economy as a whole. 10 All members bring in, where relevant, international economic and financial considerations. In light of this discussion, we then consider whether the stance of monetary policy needs to be ad justed, either immediately, or possibly in the fixture under particu lar circumstances. A considerable amount of free discussion and probing Questioning by the participants of each other and of key FOMC staff members takes place. In the wide-ranging debate, new ideas are often tested, many of which are rejected. Ideas initiated by one participant are frequently built upon by others. The prevailing views of many participants change as evidence and insights emerge. This process has proven to be a very effective procedure for gaining a consensus around which a directive to the Open Market Desk can be crafted. It could not function effectively if participants had to be concerned that their half-thought-through, but nonetheless potentially valuable, notions would soon be made public. I fear in such a situation the public record would be a sterile set of bland pronouncements scarcely capturing the necessary debates which are required of monetary policymaking. A tendency would arise for one-on-one premeeting discussions, with public meetings merely announcing already agreed-upon positions or for each par ticipant to enter the meeting with a final position not subject to the views of others. Such a record would be far less informative than the minutes we currently publish. In both the Freedom of Information Act and the Government in the Sunshine Act, Congress explicitly recognized that there were types of information ana kinds of meetings that should be protected from dissemination to the public. Certain exemptions have been provided in FOIA for information that, for example, is of a con fidential financial nature and in the Sunshine Act for meetings that would prompt speculation in financial markets. In the various exempted areas it was determined that release of information would not be in the public interest. For similar rea sons, I believe that the consequences of requiring prompt release of a verbatim record of FOMC meetings would most certainly not be in the Nation’s best interest. Mr. Chairman, in your letter of invitation to this hearing, you also posed several specific questions related to the maintenance of notes or records of FOMC meetings and to the premature release of FOMC information. I would like to turn now to the answers to those three questions. At FOMC meetings, I take very brief, rough notes on the views expressed by participants. These notes assist me in keeping track of committee sentiment as the meeting progresses and thus in judging where a consensus may be reached with respect to mone tary policy. After the meeting, the notes are kept in a locked file cabinet along with other FOMC materials. Others attending the FOMC meetings may also be taking notes, and I am sure they will tell you about them in their own responses. I have suggested to the Reserve bank presidents that they respond to your questions regarding whatever records may be kept at their own banks; I will cover records made by the Board staff and, in particular, by the FOMC secretariat. 11 Some individual members of the Board staff take handwritten notes and retain them to help them in discharging their respon sibilities. The meetings are reported electronically by the FOMC secretariat. These audio tapes are used to assist in the preparation of the minutes that are released to the public following the subse quent meeting. Thereafter, the tapes are recorded over. In the process of putting together the minutes, an unedited tran script is prepared from the tapes, as are detailed notes on selected topics discussed in the course of the meeting. These materials gen erally are seen only by the staff involved in preparing the minutes, and the documents are kept under lock and key by the FOMC secretariat. With regard to your final query on the release of information about FOMC meetings, I would again state my strong view that any unauthorized release of FOMC decisions is a very serious mat ter. Leaks of FOMC proceedings are clearly unfair to the public, po tentially disruptive of the policymaking process, and undoubtedly destructive of public confidence in the Federal Reserve. Any leaks tnat may have occurred were most assuredly not or chestrated or directed by the FOMC. A deliberate premature leak of information is repugnant. Our current policies that call for de layed release of information are in place for good reasons, as I indi cated previously. They are grounded on the assumption of confiden tiality; leaks undermine these policies. I suspect that, to an extent, what appear to be deliberate leaks may instead represent something quite different. In some cases, FOMC participants who speak to the press may believe they have revealed nothing about recent monetary policy decisions, but they may in fact have inadvertently provided enough of a sense of the policy considerations to allow conclusions to be drawn, especially for experienced reporters speaking to several sources. This puts us in a difficult situation. We should not reveal confidential informa tion about our decisions. At the same time, we cannot and should not wall ourselves off entirely from the media; it is our obligation to explain the broad considerations that motivate monetary policy, to correct certain misimpressions, and to convey as much informa tion as possible, without unsettling markets, creating inequities, or violating the trust of our colleagues. The FOMC has discussed this issue extensively, and we have taken several steps that we believe will curb any further unauthor ized release of information. We have reemphasized the necessity of avoiding contact with the press during the periods surrounding FOMC meetings and of caution at other times. Moreover, it has been made clear that any future leak from an FOMC meeting will be followed up very aggressively—by a full investigation that will include gathering sworn statements from all attendees. In response to your request as to whether I personally played a part in past leaks of FOMC information, I can assure you, Mr. Chairman, that I have never knowingly released to the press or to other members of the public any information about the results of an FOMC meeting prior to the formal, scheduled release. I would include one footnote to this statement, however: From time to time, I have briefed members of various administrations about the outcomes of FOMC meetings, because that knowledge 12 could assist them in the formulation of government policies for which they have responsibility. This qualification has not, however, been a relevant one over the past year or so, as the Federal Re serve has not altered its instrument settings. I trust the problem of leaks is behind us. If I am wrong about this, the FOMC’s policy on delayed disclosure of decisions will have to be reevaluated. Should we have to change our policy as a result, it would be unfortunate, for I firmly believe that a shift to prompt er disclosure of the substance of our deliberations will adversely af fect our discussions and decisions and therefore monetary policy it self. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Mr. Greenspan can be found in the appendix.] The Chairm an. We will recognize Governor Angell first. I under stand he has a time problem, and we have listed him here as first to be recognized. Governor Angell. STATEMENT OF WAYNE D. ANGELL, GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Mr. A n g e ll . Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I ap preciate this opportunity to give you my views on the accountabil ity of monetary policy. My perspective is of one who throughout his career as an elected ana appointed official has been in favor of opening government proceedings to the public and the press. Our democracy demands that the actions of its government be con ducted “in the sunshine” to the greatest extent possible. It also de mands that government agencies adopt the very best policies. In some cases, there is a tradeoff between these two objectives. Monetaiy policy is best formulated within a framework that pro vides an appropriate degree of insulation from day-to-day political pressures while requiring full accountability. The Board of Governors is required to report to the Congress on its monetaiy policy plans and objectives twice each year. Federal Reserve policymakers also testify as requested before this and other congressional committees about monetary policy and other matters of interest, including a detailed accounting of our expendi tures. Beyond the statutory requirements, the Federal Reserve provides significant additional information to the public about the conduct of monetary policy. The Federal Open Market Committee publishes minutes of its meetings. These minutes summarize fully the discus sion. Significant decisions taken by the FOMC should always be made on the basis of recorded votes—in accord with an important principle of accountability. Each member of the committee is af forded an opportunity to participate in the preparation of the min utes so that no individual or shared views are omitted. In my view, the minutes present an accurate account of each FOMC meeting. With regard to timeliness of the release of such minutes; as you know they are published shortly after the following committee meeting. It seems to me that sucn a lag is appropriate. The imme diate release of information on the committee’s plans for contin gencies could increase market volatility, particularly in cir 13 cumstances when the contingencies do not eventuate. Such vola tility is unnecessary and could be especially counterproductive if concerns about possible volatility deterred some members of the Federal Open Market Committee from discussing such contin gencies or drove them to relying on implicit or behind-the-scenes understandings. On balance, the market and the public are better served by more detail and more openness with delayed publication as compared with the realistic alternative of less specificity that would likely accompany earlier publication. Similarly, I believe that the provisions in H.R. 28 that would re quire release of videotapes or transcripts of committee meetings would have deleterious consequences. In the context of monetary policy, such provisions likely would cause policymakers to be less willing to conjecture about future economic and financial develop ments, to explore alternate policies, or to challenge others’ views. Under those conditions, discussions during FOMC meetings are less likely to lead to appropriate policy decisions. The willingness of individual members to explore verbally what may seem to be low probability events may be the beginning of a new perspective that elicits more careful watching and continued debate. The process of developing a consensus view through an open contrarian forum is essential if monetary policy is to lead toward monetary stability. For these reasons, I believe that the relevant provisions of H.R. 28 would do little to make the monetary policy process more trans parent and, unfortunately, would do much to make the conduct of monetary policy less effective. In my view, our current procedures regarding disclosure are on the right track. They permit a careful review of alternative policies while allowing the Congress and the public to analyze both the process by which our decisions are reached and their results. My answers to your specific questions are included in my written statement. The Chairman. Thank you very much. As I said before, your full prepared text will be in the record. [The prepared statement of Mr. Angell can be found in the appendix.] Our next witness is Governor Kelley. STATEMENT OF EDWARD W. KELLEY, JR., GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Mr. K e lle y . Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and thank you for the opportunity to present my views on H.R. 28. Pursuant to the request in your letter of invitation, I shall first answer, in order, the three specific questions posed therein and then offer my perspectives on the bill in the area of maintaining a record of the Federal Open Market Committee meetings. First, I have generated rough pencil notes of my own thoughts and summaries of the views of other members, as I understand them, at most meetings. These notes reside in a locked file in my office. Second, I would assume various persons present at the meetings prepare and keep notes and records of their own, certainly includ ing the FOMC secretariat, but I am unaware of specifically who 14 does what in that regard. Doubtless, others will report on their own activities. Finally, I have no information whatsoever about unauthorized or premature release of FOMC information. Let me move on to comment on H.R. 28 which would require, among other things, complete release of FOMC meeting proceed ings within 60 days. I must respectfully oppose this proposal. It seems to me that the issue here is the reconciliation of two basic principles for conducting public business in a democracy. The first is the obvious requirement that public policy be generated to further the public interest in the soundest possible way. The second is that the public has the right to know what its leaders are doing in the conduct of its business, including how and why they are doing it. While these two principles can often be fully accommodated, there are clear cases wherein the second, fully implemented, can potentially degrade the first. In such cases, the overriding require ment is that public policy must be of the highest possible quality. The meetings of the FOMC are such a case. In these meetings, 12 voting members, augmented by the 7 additional Reserve Bank presidents, debate and decide important public matters of mone tary policy. To work well, such an arrangement must proceed in private, where the participants may freely and easily exchange per spectives and confidential information, dispute, alter viewpoints, and work toward the discovery of common ground. In this manner, responsible public policy is created. To expose this process to public scrutiny would, in my view, very clearly introduce an atmosphere that would be detrimental to the final result. The quality of the final result, sound monetary policy to undergird and support our economy, is the most important of the interests in question. I believe H.R. 28 would be counterproductive in this respect. The requirement remains that the public be as informed as pos sible in these matters and that those involved in the process be ac countable. I believe that the existing procedures for release of FOMC decisions are responsive to the public’s right to be informed. Concerning accountability, FOMC decisions are the result of the votes of the participating members, and each participant's vote is recorded and made public. Affirmative votes are explained in the minutes as released, and dissenting votes are accompanied by indi vidual explanations. Thus, there is complete accountability for results. In summary, I feel that the public’s interest in this matter is best served by maintaining a system wherein the process is confidential and the policy results are made public in appropriate ways, with personal and group accountability for such results. Thank you, sir. The Chairm an. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Kelley can be found in the ap pendix.] The C hairm an. Our next witness is our long-time friend, a man who has spent a considerable number of minutes, maybe hours, be fore this committee, and we are grateful. Governor LaWare. 15 STATEMENT OF JOHN P. LAWARE, GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Mr. LaW are. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am here with my Federal Open Market Committee colleagues to comment on the proposed requirements in H.R. 28 for full and timely accounting of each FOMC meeting. I would strongly urge the committee to continue, as in the past, to concentrate its oversight efforts on the substance of monetary policy rather than on the procedures by which it is determined. The Humphrey-Hawkins testimony provides a full description of policy moves, historic economic performance, and future objectives for pol icy. It is the fullest public accounting of monetary policy provided by any central bank in the world. I see no purpose in the publication of a verbatim transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee’s deliberations and less purpose in a videotape record of the proceedings. A verbatim transcript or a videotape recording of the meetings of the Open Market Commit tee might significantly inhibit the members from the free exchange of ideas which presently characterizes our meetings. We all have a certain amount of self-consciousness about being on stage, as we would certainly be under the suggested protocol, and the problem would be aggravated by the knowledge that the matters under dis cussion are Highly sensitive for financial markets. Consultation in camera, rather than on camera, gives the mem bers of the Open Market Committee the same privileges of open communication and free exchange enioyed by juries. Importantly, it also gives the committee members the same right to change their minds as jurors enjoy. I am sure the quality of jury decisions would be significantly changed if their deliberations were published. I am equally sure the process of developing monetary policy would suffer under a regime of public performance. I am less concerned that the quality of policy decisions would be adversely affected by a memorandum of discussion carefully edited to delete market-sensitive information provided on a confidential basis and released on some delayed schedule, perhaps 1 year after the meeting it described. The issue of the timely release of the directive for open market operations is a difficult one. On the one hand, the market knows at 11:30 or so the morning after the FOMC meetings whether there has been a policy shift. Tnat is discernible from the way the Desk at the New York Reserve Bank enters the market. From that per spective, there is little to be gained or lost from the publication of FOMC decisions within a week, as proposed in H.R. 28. On the other hand, immediate release would discourage the use of asymmetric language because asymmetiy reflects the tilt of the committee either toward ease or tightening. Markets might react impulsively on such news, to no one’s best interest except specu lators. And, internally, such a stricture against asymmetric lan guage would inhibit quick intermeeting response to changing mar ket conditions. As to the three specific questions raised: Number one, I make no notes at FOMC meetings other than brief bullet points to outline my own comments to assure coherence. These, together with all the analytical materials supplied by the staff prior to the meeting, are 16 given by me to my executive assistant for destruction as soon as the FOMC meeting adjourns. Two, I have no knowledge of what notes or records are made by or retained by other members of the committee. Three, I have no knowledge of the source of the notorious leaks of FOMC information. Such leaks are irresponsible and reprehen sible. If they are unintentional, they reflect a naivete which should not be allowed to lurk anywhere near the FOMC. If they are inten tional, they should be punished to the full extent of whatever rem edies are available, no matter whom the culprit may be. I appreciate the opportunity to participate in this hearing and look forward to answering any further questions the committee may have, Mr. Chairman. The Chairm an. Thank you very much, Governor. Again, we thank you for your prepared text that we had an opportunity to re view before the meeting. [The prepared statement of Mr. LaWare can be found in the appendix.] The next witness is also our friend, Governor Lindsey, whom I happen to have had the pleasure of meeting in San Antonio. It wasn’t quite in my district. The hotel wasn’t in my district, Gov ernor, but it was close enough. STATEMENT OF LAWRENCE B. LINDSEY, GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Mr. L in dsey. Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the committee. I appreciate this opportunity to comment on provisions of the Federal Reserve System Accountability Act that pertain to the release of information on monetary policy. I point out that the Federal Reserve currently provides a great deal of information to the public about the monetary policymaking process both formally and informally. We report to the Congress in a formal sense semiannually on our objectives and plans for mone tary policy, and we provide additional testimony on request. We publish a considerable volume of timely data on our monetary pol icy actions. In addition, we publish minutes of each FOMC meeting shortly after the following meeting. These minutes are often many pages in length and fully summarize the discussion at the committee meetings, and I think are provided in a timely fashion. Federal Re serve officials frequently discuss the economic situation and mone tary policy in informal contacts with Members of the Congress, members of the administration and their staffs. I would also point out, Mr. Chairman, and you mentioned my trip to San Antonio, that part of our responsibility is to explain to the public what our positions are, and we, therefore, often speak out through speeches and other forums, not just on monetary policy but on economic policy more generally. We go into communities across the Nation, partly to understand the economic circumstances and concerns of all Americans, but also to articulate the Federal Reserve’s position on the economy. And I have had the pleasure of going to San Antonio twice as a Governor during the last 23 months. I have met with citizens from all walks of life there to listen to their needs and explain our mis- 17 sion. In fact, in virtually every city to which I have traveled, over 30 since becoming a Governor, I have met with local business peo ple, bankers, and citizens to discuss the economy and its direct im pact on their businesses and daily lives. I consider the process of carrying on a public dialog to be central to my responsibilities. There are no mysteries regarding my position or thinking. And I believe the same is true of my colleagues. In my view, the provisions of the proposed legislation directed at increasing the availability of monetary policy information probably would suffer from the law of unintended consequences. Videotaping FOMC meetings would likely reduce the usefulness of these meet ings considerably. Participants would hesitate to use hypothetical or speculative examples to explain points, because these examples could be easily misinterpreted and cause unnecessary volatility in financial markets. Information learned from meetings and travels is often proprietary or private in nature and thus could not be shared if the meetings were taped. More generally, the give and take in the discussion among policymakers would be sharply reduced. I think Governor LaWare’s analog/ to a jury is quite apt. Policy discussions, I believe, would then tend to take place out side of committee meetings, and members of the Board and Reserve bank presidents would come to the FOMC with preconceived no tions. The ideas that arise in the current process of open, candid discussion would no longer be produced in committee meetings and thus would not be reported in the FOMC minutes. Their loss would limit the flexibility and give and take of the policy process and, in so doing, produce the unintended consequence of actually reducing the net amount of publicly available, informed debate on monetary policy. I am also skeptical that, on balance, immediate release of the di rective would be useful. While there may be some advantages, there are also costs. Under current procedures, market participants and others are able to recognize an actual shift in the Federal Re serve’s policy stance on the morning that the change is imple mented. Thus, an immediate verbal statement on policy changes would provide no additional information to the market. A requirement to publish information could be damaging in cases where policy contingencies are part of the FOMC directive. In fact, increased market volatility could potentially result due to market speculation. Moreover, such a requirement could diminish the com mittee’s ability to provide instructions to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to respond to such contingencies, potentially hobbling the Federal Reserve’s ability to resolve financial crises. Let me turn next to the three specific questions that you posed in your letter. First, I do take very sketchy—and I would emphasize the words very sketchy—notes during FOMC meetings to help organize my own comments. I discard tnese notes at the end of each meeting. Second, I believe others will be describing their own note taking, and the Chairman will describe the note-taking process of the FOMC secretariat. Finally, I have no information for the committee on any pre mature release of FOMC confidential material. 18 In summary, Mr. Chairman, I believe there will always be a ten sion between the benefits of an open and ongoing public debate on economic policy and the benefits of confidentiality. Although the current system is imperfect, it is probably better than resolving the current tension in favor of either fuller openness or greater confidentiality. Thank you. The Chairm an. Thank you, sir. [The prepared statement of Mr. Lindsey can be found in the appendix.] The C hairm an. Governor Phillips. STATEMENT OF SUSAN M. PHILLIPS, GOVERNOR, FEDERAL RESERVE BOARD Ms. P h illip s . Thank you very much. Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased to have the opportunity to appear before this committee to present my views on the reporting of Federal Open Market Committee actions. I am the newest member of the Federal Reserve Board. Since joining the Board, I have been impressed by the care and the attention given throughout the System to seeking a broad range of viewpoints as monetary policy is formulated and con ducted. This comes about through various advisory committees, studies, reports, meetings, and certainly also through the boards of the individual Reserve banks. I believe that the System receives considerable cooperation in this enormous task of economic monitoring, precisely because of the serious and confidential manner in which business and economic information is treated by members of the FOMC. Releasing a lit eral transcription or videotape of FOMC meetings would likely in hibit members’ abilities to obtain and relate confidential informa tion because of its potential market sensitivity. In addition, a literal transcript or videotape of FOMC meetings may make many members feel constrained to speak only from pre pared statements. We will likely lose the analytical approach now used in building upon each other’s observations in a truly delibera tive process. There may also be reduced capability to reach a con sensus, since many members’ initial statements may limit their flexibility to adjust their positions. We all have an opportunity to edit the minutes before the next meeting to assure our views are adequately reflected in the min utes. To assist in this process I take sporadic, personal notes dur ing some parts of the FOMC meetings. Those handwritten notes are retained in my personal confidential files, shared with no one. I also know of no one who shares any of the FOMC materials with the public or the press prior to its official release. With respect to the question of earlier release of the minutes or very rapid release of the committee’s decisions or directives, such a change in procedure would, I believe, curtail the committee’s flexibility and perhaps even its market effectiveness. Those direc tives frequently contain longer range strategies the committee wishes to adopt. No major market participant, public or private, could announce its future strategy without that having an impact on the market itself. Such announcements, I believe, would be self- 19 defeating and limit the Federal Reserve’s ability to affect the mar ket as intended. I hope these comments are helpful to the committee in its delib erations. I have confined my comments to the issues that were raised in your letter. Nevertheless, I would be pleased to respond to additional questions along with my colleagues. Thank you. The Chairm an. Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Ms. Phillips can be found in the appendix.] President Boehne. STATEMENT OF EDWARD G* BOEHNE, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF PHILADELPHIA Mr. B oeh n e. Thank you very much for inviting me here. I spend a great deal of time speaking with citizens all across my district, which is the Philadelphia district, and it is especially nice to be meeting with you this morning. Let me begin by saying that I take very seriously my role in FOMC proceedings ana have a natural bias toward public disclo sure and personal accountability. I also take seriously the collective responsibility of the FOMC to formulate the best possible monetary policy. An essential ingredient in formulating the best possible mone tary policy is an effective deliberative process—one that fosters the free flow of information, the ability to speculate about the effects of alternative policies, the general give and take among members and the ability to reach a consensus. I believe the FOMC’s existing procedures generally provide a workable balance between the need for effective policy deliberations and the need for public disclosure and accountability. You have my full comments, but let me comment very briefly on some of the specific provisions of the bill. I believe the FOMC al ready complies with the provision of H.R. 28 that requires that a written copy of the minutes of each FOMC meeting be made avail able to the public within 60 days of it. For those who read the minutes completely and regularly, the minutes are typically available within 60 days and are indeed com prehensive. The minutes include information about current and prospective economic and financial conditions, the pros and cons of alternative policy actions, the reasons the majority favored a par ticular action, plus comments, by name, of those members dissent ing. The minutes the committee now releases are not as detailed as the memorandum of discussion that was released prior to 1976. But, in my view, the old memorandum had some disadvantages that hindered the deliberative process. I attended FOMC meetings during some of the years when the memorandum was still being prepared. At those meetings, as I re call, members of the committee tended to stick more to their pre pared statements, and there was less give and take about alter native views of the economy and policy actions. The current arrangement of releasing comprehensive minutes of FOMC meetings more promptly than the old memorandum in my judgment better serves both the need for disclosure that is of prac 20 tical use to the public and the need for an effective, deliberative process. Mr. Chairman, you also requested my comments specifically on three areas. First, during my tenure as president of the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, which began in 1981, I have not taken notes during FOMC meetings. My economic adviser usually takes handwritten notes, which are then kept in a locked file cabinet with other materials prepared for each FOMC meeting. He uses these notes to identify issues that should be explored in future pre-FOMC briefings. Finally, I am aware, of course, of news stories that have dis cussed the premature release of information about FOMC meet ings. I deplore such leaks in the strongest possible terms. Security of FOMC information is taken very seriously at the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, and I do not have any direct knowledge about how such leaks occurred. Thank you. The Chairm an. Thank you, sir. [The prepared statement of Mr. Boehne can be found in the ap pendix.] President Broaddus. STATEMENT OF J. ALFRED BROADDUS, JR., PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF RICHMOND Mr. B ro a d d u s. Thank you. I am pleased to be here today to dis cuss the procedures FOMC follows in recording policy information and releasing it to the public. My views in these areas are based on two principles. First, these procedures should enable us to make the best possible policy deci sions. Second, in general, we should release as much information to the public on our policy decision as promptly as possible, provided such release does not impair our ability to make sound decisions. Currently, the directive for a particular FOMC meeting is re leased immediately following the next meeting, along with a record of poli<y actions. I think it is worth emphasizing here today what that record of policy actions is and is not. It is not a brief summary. Instead, it is a lengthy and, in my view, very thorough description of the dis cussion leading up to the committee’s policy decisions. It indicates in considerable detail the views of those supporting the decision and contains a full explanation of any dissenting votes. As a long-time attendee at FOMC meetings, I can attest that the record of policy actions always conveys the content and flavor of the committee’s deliberations as well as its specific decisions com pletely and accurately. In my view, the record fully satisfies the need for the committee to be accountable to the public. H.R. 28 would change these procedures in two ways. First, it would require that videotapes of FOMC meetings be made and re leased along with a verbatim transcript within 60 days. My views on releasing videotapes and verbatim transcripts of FOMC meetings have not changed, Mr. Chairman, since I re sponded to your letter on this issue earlier this year. I believe the prospect of a literal record in any form, even if released after a long 21 period of time, would restrain committee members in debate and very seriously inhibit the flow and restrict the flow of information ana ideas. This, in turn, would undermine the deliberative process and therefore risk lowering the quality of monetary policy deci sions. While I cannot support release of a videotape or other verbatim transcript of the FOMC meetings, I believe there might be benefits from releasing a nonliteral but relatively complete record of FOMC proceedings similar to the old memorandum of discussion that we prepared until 1976, if and only if there were a long and enforce able delay of release, such as the 5-year period in the case of the memorandum of discussion. Early release of even a nonliteral record could inhibit FOMC discussion and reduce the quality of monetary policy decisions. Consequently, I think it is essential that any reinstitution of something like the memorandum be accom panied by a legislative guarantee that it would not be released pre maturely. The second change proposed in H.R. 28 is to release the directive 1 week after an FOMC meeting. Arguments can be made both for and against this proposal. An early release would be consistent with the general principle that we should inform the public of pol icy decisions as soon as possible. At the same time, I believe early release could well have announcement effects that could create un necessary volatility in interest rates in some situations for reasons I indicate in my written statement. Let me respond now to the specific questions raised in Chairman Gonzalez’ letter regarding my knowledge of notes made at FOMC meetings. As I indicated earlier, I have attended FOMC meetings for a number of years, mostly as the adviser to my predecessor as president of the Richmond Reserve Bank. While in this advisory position I took notes in order to serve my predecessor effectively. The notes were handwritten, were never transcribed to type written, or any other form, and were not distributed to anyone. I have always kept these notes in locked confidential files. I should add I have taken only partial notes since assuming my current position at the beginning of the year. I now rely on notes taken by my adviser who follows the same exact procedures I did. I have only limited knowledge of records made by other FOMC participants, and I have not read or used any such notes. Finally, I personally do not know of any information that has been released by anyone at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or elsewhere in the Federal Reserve System to persons outside the Federal Reserve prior to its official release. I would like to add one additional comment not in my written statement, but it probably should be. I certainly agree that the FOMC should be accountable for its actions. Basically, I think we already are. However, full and effective accountability for any insti tution requires that everyone understand clearly exactly what the institution is accountable for. With this in mind, I would respectfully suggest that one of the most positive things Congress could do to raise our already high level of accountability even higher would be to pass Congressman Neal’s amendment which would mandate that we achieve and maintain a stable price level over time. 22 Thank you, sir. The Chairm an. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Broaddus can be found in the appendix.] The C hairm an. President Hoenig. STATEMENT OF THOMAS M. HOENIG, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF KANSAS CITY Mr. H o e n ig . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Good morning. I am very pleased to have this opportunity on be half of Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City to express my views on the disclosure of information of the FOMC meetings. I will tell you that our district is composed of agriculture, energy, and a lot of small manufacturing and, therefore, is diverse. I do spend a fair amount of time within the region listening to and speaking out on economic policy matters. As to your purpose of this hearing, let me begin by saying that I, like others, feel strongly that the Federal Reserve must be ac countable for its actions and has an obligation to disclose as much information as possible about its deliberations and decisions sub ject, in terms of balance, to maintaining the highest possible level of policy effectiveness. It is my belief that the Federal Reserve’s current disclosure policies achieve these ends and this balance. These policies provide a detailed accounting of FOMC delibera tions and decisions. The minutes of FOMC meetings I think are comprehensive. They are detailed. They document the information considered during the meeting and the decisions of each voting member. Moreover, the minutes provide the rationale for the ma jority's decisions and include statements filed by members who dis sent from the majority. In addition, the Federal Reserve reports regularly and frequently to Congress, ensuring further that we are accountable for our mon etary policy actions, that they are explained. Current procedures foster an environment of open and candid discussion among the members of the FOMC. Valuable information from a variety of sources is brought to the discussion, some of it is provided with the understanding that it be kept confidential. The give and take among members provides an opportunity to clarify issues, allows the FOMC to synthesize a range of views. Any proposals that would impair this deliberative process, given current procedures that I believe ensure accountability, I think would com promise the quality and effectiveness of policy without a significant offsetting benefit. Current procedures, in my opinion, also strike—and importantly strike—an effective balance between timely disclosure and the need for flexibility in the conduct of policy. These procedures, which pro vide release of the minutes shortly after the subsequent meeting, about 6 weeks usually, allow the FOMC to respond flexibly to var ious contingencies over the intermeeting period. Earlier release of the minutes, I think, would restrict this flexibility and could have the unintended effect of contributing to market volatility. With regard to the questions posed in your September 24 letter: One, I make brief notes for my personal use during FOMC meet- 23 ings, and our bank’s research director also occasionally takes notes. These notes are kept in locked files, as is other FOMC material. Two, I have observed other participants taking notes during the FOMC meetings, but I have no knowledge of their content or disposition. And, three, I have no information about the release of informa tion by anyone employed at the Federal Reserve about FOMC meetings prior to the official release of that information by the Fed eral Reserve. In closing, let me reiterate that I believe the FOMC must be ac countable for its actions. At the same time, it must be permitted to pursue effective policy and allow for dialog among its members. Current procedures provide, I think, the best balance toward achieving these ends. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairm an. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Hoenig can be found in the appendix.] President Jordan. STATEMENT OF JERRY L. JORDAN, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND Mr. J o rd a n . Thank you, Mr. Chairman, members of the commit tee. It seems to me this series of hearings and various proposals for legislation, various ideas, center on two questions. One is, what in formation should be released and when? And the second is, who should participate in the deliberations and the formulation of mon etary policy actions? I think that those two questions ought to be addressed in the context of three main issues. One is the objectives of monetary pol icy. I think that can only be the highest standard of living that we can achieve with our resources, with our labor force, ana so on. I know that fiscal policies and regulatory policies have other objec tives at times, including redistribution, but I think that monetary policy can only be used to try to maintain the highest growth of in come and the lowest sustainable rate of unemployment. Second, the strategy to do that, I am convinced, is maintaining price stability. I think that the Congress intended—what really the Constitution intended in maintaining the purchasing power of the currency, so that the dollar is a stable standard of value over time. And the third issue is whether or not independence furthers that strategy to achieve the ultimate objective. If these questions of what information we release and when, and who participates can be addressed in that context, I think we can clarify the issues involved. I believe that currently we are releasing the information that is necessary to make it clear to people what it is we are trying to do, what our strategy is and that we have the right people participat ing in that deliberation. Regarding your specific questions about notes, I took some notes the first few meetings of Open Market Committee meetings start ing in March 1992 with regard to research topics I wanted to go 24 back and get my staff to work on. I don’t find it necessary to take those notes anymore, so I don’t take any at all. I don’t know what kind of notes are kept by other people. I am learning here today what notes are taken by my colleagues at the meeting and what they do with them. On the subject of leaks, I deplore it, as others have indicated. We are the central bank. Central banks don’t leak. The C hairm an. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Jordan can be found in the appendix.] President Keehn. STATEMENT OF SILAS KEEHN, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO Mr. K eeh n . Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the com mittee. As requested, let me briefly summarize my views on the question of the appropriate recordkeeping and public release of the delibera tions of the FOMC. As I stated in my letter of January 13 of this year to you, Mr. Chairman, I fully support Chairman Greenspan’s previously stated position on the various proposals for maintaining and releasing a more detailed record of the FOMC’s deliberations. In my view, the minutes of the FOMC, as they are currently written, provide the right level of reporting and detail necessary to communicate the current policy concerns and actions of the committee. The minutes explicitly document the full range of policy arguments made during the discussion, and when a member of the committee disagrees with the resulting consensus, that member’s dissent becomes an in tegral part of the public policy record. Based on my participation in FOMC deliberations, I believe that releasing more detailed minutes, most especially a verbatim tran script of the meeting, without a significant delay would be counter productive and would impede the development of sound monetary policy—first, by limiting the free flow of necessary information into the policy process and second, by hindering the consensus process so essential if policy is to adequately reflect economic conditions in all regions of the country. As president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, I have an important responsibility to convey to the FOMC the economic con ditions of the Seventh Federal Reserve District. To meet this re sponsibility, I and other senior members of our staff maintain ex tensive contacts with district businesses, both large and small, community groups, and State and local government officials. From these individuals we are able to gather a wide array of highly sig nificant information about the district that cannot be derived from public data sources—information not only about current economic conditions, but about changes in business practices, future produc tion, labor negotiations, investment and hiring plans, and a host of other issues that have important value to the policy process. This type of information is particularly important at the present time. The economy is going through a very different phase than any that we have experienced in the past. Many of the economic indicators that have been useful guideposts in developing policy in the past are now proving unreliable. In such an environment, I find the regional information derived from local contacts, both about the Seventh Federal Reserve District and elsewhere in the country, es sential to the policy process. In the context of these hearings, it is important to understand that much of the information that these contacts provide is highly proprietary and very confidential in na ture. I have absolutely assured these contacts that the source and nature of the data will not be divulged in a wav that they would find compromising. I have never had anyone decline to speak with me about their activities. If I could not provide such assurances, then much of this significant information would not be forthcoming and the development of monetary policy would be impeded. It is precisely this type of information about local businesses, communities, and financial institutions that demonstrates the value of the regional structure of the Federal Reserve System and district representation on the FOMC. The impact of releasing such information as part of the written record of the FOMC without a significant delay would only result in the exclusion of this vital in formation from the FOMC policy discussion. In my view, this would not be in the public interest, especially when the current system of disclosure is able to convey an accurate description of the key issues and arguments underlying the FOMC’s decisions, as well as record individual votes and dissenting positions. As to the specific questions that you asked me to address: I pre pare an outline of economic conditions in the district which forms the basis for my remarks at each meeting of the FOMC. After the meeting, these notes are kept secured in my office until the next meeting at which time I destroy them. I do not maintain notes on the discussion that takes place at the meeting itself, and Chairman Greenspan has described the records that are kept by the FOMC secretariat. As to the premature release of information from the FOMC meet ings, I have not talked to the press or other outside contacts, nor to other Federal Reserve officials who do not have authorized ac cess to FOMC information and my only direct knowledge of such premature releases arises from articles I have seen in various newspapers. I completely concur with Chairman Greenspan that premature releases of this type of information are highly inappro priate and totally unacceptable. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Keehn can be found in the appendixj The Chairm an. President McTeer. STATEMENT OF ROBERT D. McTEER, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS Mr. M cT e e r. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your invitation to testify on H.R. 28. I will limit my testimony to the issue of FOMC records, although I do have opinions on other parts of the H.R. 28, especially the part that puts me out of work. I became president of the Dallas Fed in February 1991, so I am a relative newcomer, both to the FOMC and to your great State of Texas, Mr. Chairman, and also Congressman Johnson’s. As the bumper sticker says, “I wasn't bom in Texas, but I got there as soon as I could.” Prior to moving to Texas 2 V2 years ago, I was with the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond for 23 years, the last 11 of which I served as manager of its Baltimore branch. I have participated in FOMC meetings since 1991, but did not vote until this year. In your letter you asked us to respond to three specific questions regarding note taking in FOMC meetings. Regarding my own prac tice, I don’t take notes of the type I assume you mean. I do a lot of reading and homework prior to the meeting and I go into the meeting with some tentative ideas in mind. I doodle during our dis cussions and occasionally write down a word or phrase for ref erence when I speak. I don’t write down decisions because they are simple and easy to remember, and normally come at the end of the meeting. My doodles and notes all mixed up would be of no use to traders or journalists. I destroy them after the meeting and rely only on official documents for future reference. Regarding your second question, notes kept by others, my im pression is that most other members and staff probably follow a pattern similar to my own since all who are present presumably have access to the official records and documents. At least, I have no knowledge to the contrary. In answer to your third question, I have no information about the premature release of FOMC information by anyone at the Fed eral Reserve. Let me add that, in my opinion, if someone wanted to leak valuable information about the committee’s decisions, such notes would not be necessary nor even very helpful. While the deci sion process may be difficult, while the debate may be difficult, the decisions themselves are very simple and easy to remember with out notes. Let me comment briefly on other aspects of meeting records. As a former economist, I have some sympathy for the idea of imme diate release of the directive or decision. Immediate release of the decision would eliminate any question of leaks or the appearance of leaks. The practical problem with immediate release of the directive is that not all decisions are clear-cut decisions to ease, tighten, or re main unchanged. On occasion, the committee votes to hold steady, pending further information or developments, and wishes to give the chairman extra leeway to act on his own prior to the next scheduled meeting. More often than not, I believe, these asymmet ric directives are not acted on, but occasionally they are. To announce a decision of no change without the proviso would be misleading to the public, and to announce it with the proviso would likely cause the markets to react in a way not necessarily warranted by subsequent information. Given this dilemma, I believe the current arrangement is best. Markets are able to discern the immediate decision by watching the Federal funds rate the following morning, and we retain maxi mum flexibility to react to incoming data and changing cir cumstances without misleading anyone. Then as soon as another meeting is behind us, we release the directive that includes the 27 prevailing circumstances, the rationale for the decision, and the identity of any dissenters and their reasons for dissenting. I personally have a greater problem with videotaping and ver batim transcripts of discussions than with the prompt release of de cisions. I believe that videotaping or verbatim transcripts, no mat ter how they are released to the public, would diminish the quality of our deliberations. My colleagues and I are willing to listen to each other and adjust our initial leanings in the interest of consen sus-building. We currently don’t posture for the record or for the camera. There is no winning or losing the debate. There is no playing to the gallery or to the folks back home. This, I am afraid, would all change with videotaping or its equivalent. I would much prefer present arrangements even with more detail added, as long as the detail involves the substance of the discus sions and the decisions rather than the language used. I would also have no objection to detailed minutes, not a verbatim transcript, being released after a lengthy period of several years, as long as the legal obstacles to such a delay could be overcome. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. McTeer can be found in the appendix.] The Chairm an. Thank you very much. President Melzer. STATEMENT OF THOMAS C. MELZER, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Mr. M e lz e r . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am pleased to appear before the committee today to testify on the prompt public disclo sure of Open Market Committee meetings. As a creation of Con gress, the Federal Reserve System is fully accountable to the public for its monetary policy actions. One way we ensure this account ability is by releasing information about our policy decisions. The Federal Open Market Committee provides a full accounting of its actions in its minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee. The minutes, as has been mentioned earlier, contain all impor tant information about FOMC decisions, including the policy direc tive agreed upon by the majority and the reasons underlying the policy decisions. Any significant differences among those voting with the majority, as well as the views of any dissenting members, are included in the document. The minutes are released upon their approval by committee members at the next FOMC meeting. The public record thus contains the outcome of FOMC deliberations and the policy views of each member of the committee. I am not in favor of producing a further detailed account of FOMC deliberations, either in the form of an edited transcript, such as the memorandum of discussion, verbatim minutes, or an audio or videotape. Such a release, in my judgment, would impede the deliberative process and thereby impair policymaking. Arriving at appropriate policy often involves considerable give and take, consensus-building and debate of alternative actions. Be cause of the possibility that a particular statement might be mis understood or taken out of context, FOMC members would be reti cent to engage in the kind of open discussion that leads to good pol icymaking if they knew that all of their statements would be in the 28 public record. Furthermore, the release of verbatim minutes or any other detailed record of deliberations would discourage other par ties from supplying the FOMC with confidential information that is useful in determining appropriate policy. Turning to the timing of the release of the FOMC policy direc tive, I believe that immediate release of the outcome of FOMC de liberations would interfere with the deliberative process and would lessen the flexibility with which the Federal Reserve can respond to changing economic conditions. If directives were released imme diately, the FOMC might be reluctant, even if economic conditions warranted, to take a timely subsequent action because of concern that such action would add to the uncertainty in financial markets. In addition, the FOMC would be less inclined to bias its direc tives toward ease or restraint, in effect limiting its policy options. Consequently, reaching a consensus among FOMC members would be difficult, which might delay policy actions and add uncertainty to financial markets. Finally, let me turn to the three specific questions raised in your letter, Mr. Chairman, of September 24. I have included answers in my statement submitted for the record. To sum up, then, the Federal Open Market Committee is com mitted to informing the public of its policies, which ultimately must be judged by their results. Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee convey fully the relevant information about FOMC deci sions and do so in a timely manner. Thus, in my view, there is lit tle to be gained by providing detailed minutes or mechanical repro ductions of FOMC deliberations, while the adverse consequences of doing so are potentially very great. In addition, the benefits of immediate release of the policy direc tive would not seem to outweigh the potential cost of doing so. By inhibiting the frank exchange of views and possibly reducing the willingness of the FOMC to take timely actions, public release of the details of committee deliberations or immediate release of the policy directive could harm the policymaking process. Although intending to increase the accountability of FOMC members, the proposed changes in H.R. 28 may thus impede monetary policy per formance. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Melzer can be found in the ap pendix.] The Chairm an. Thank you. President Parry. STATEMENT OF ROBERT T. PARRY, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO Mr. P a rry . Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the com mittee. As president of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, one of my jobs is to contribute to Federal monetary policy delibera tions with information and ideas from my district. The 12th Fed eral Reserve district is highly diverse. It is made up of the nine western States which at present include three of the more robust State economies in the country: Utah, Idaho, and Nevada, and one of the weakest, California. In fact, California has seen employment fall by 592,000 jobs since mid-1990. 29 With that introduction, I would like to express my appreciation for this opportunity to discuss the disclosure of information about Federal Open Market Committee meetings. As I stated in my letter of January 13, 1993, I believe that there should be a presumption that Fed deliberations should be fully disclosed unless there is a compelling reason not to do so. In the case of FOMC deliberations, such a compelling reason ex ists. As discussed in my written testimony, I am concerned that verbatim records or videotapes would inhibit the free flow of com ments at our meetings, and thus the process limit the effectiveness of our policy discussions. Now, I will turn to the specific questions raised in your letter to me dated September 24. I do not take notes of what is said at FOMC meetings. However, I do take into the meetings notes con cerning the comments I plan to make about the national and 12th district economies, about monetary policy, and occasionally about special topics that are on the agenda for a particular meeting. These talking points are stored in locked files at the Federal Re serve Bank of San Francisco, in accordance with FOMC security procedures. My actual statements often divert somewhat from my notes, and I also make impromptu comments at each meeting for which I have no notes. I also take into FOMC meetings a briefing book prepared by the research department at the bank. This book contains analyses and forecasts of developments in the U.S. economy, analysis of develop ments in the 12th district, occasionally discussions of special topics related to FOMC issues, and analysis of monetary policy issues and recommendations by my staff. The director of research at the bank, and occasionally his alter nate, take handwritten notes of comments made at FOMC meet ings when they attend as my adviser. These notes are for their own use in directing FOMC policy analysis within the research depart ment. They are stored in their locked files at the bank in accord ance with FOMC security procedures. Finally, with respect to your question about leaks of confidential FOMC information, I have never knowingly divulged any FOMC information to unauthorized persons prior to the official release date, and I have no information concerning anyone else doing so. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Mr. Parry can be found in the appendix.] The Chairm an. Thank you. President Stern. STATEMENT OF GARY H. STERN, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF MINNEAPOLIS Mr. S te r n . Thank you. Mr. Chairman and members of the com mittee, I appreciate this opportunity to discuss issues related to maintaining a record of Federal Open Market Committee meetings and procedures followed at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapo lis to handle confidential monetary policy material. These are in deed significant matters. As indicated in my January correspondence, I am convinced there is considerable value in our current report of FOMC proceed- 7 3 -2 0 8 0 - 9 4 - 2 30 ings. As you know, we release extensive minutes of each FOMC meeting shortly after the subsequent meeting. The minutes de scribe the discussion and the votes of individual members. More specifically, they include an assessment of business conditions here and abroad, price developments, and performance of financial mar kets and monetary aggregates. They report the committee’s views of prospects for the economy, frequently including information gleaned from personal contacts in individual Federal Reserve districts. The minutes also report the discussions of monetary policy options as well as the decision ulti mately reached by the committee, including dissents, if any, and the logic underpinning the dissents. This amounts to a good deal of information in my view, and I do not find merit in suggestions to prepare and release at any time a literal record of FOMC deliberations through videotaping or other vehicles. Three issues in particular concern me. First, given the gravity of our responsibilities, I believe it is im perative that the quality of our deliberations be maintained. Open discussion of ideas, of policy alternatives, and of significant poten tial risks to the economy are critical to sound policymaking. Second, some of the information we discuss is voluntarily pro vided on a confidential basis. We have an obligation to maintain that confidentiality. Third, I believe our procedures carefully balance the need to pro vide information to the public with the necessities of effective mon etary policy. Even small changes carry the considerable risk that they will disturb, perhaps unknowingly and unintentionally, this balance, with adverse consequences for financial markets and eco nomic performance. As indicated in my earlier correspondence, I believe there could be some merit to reintroduction of something like the memorandum of discussion, a very detailed, although edited, accounting of FOMC discussions, provided that the confidentiality of such material is as sured for several years. As I see it, such a document could be use ful to historians and students of monetary policy when they inves tigate the broad context of policy decisions and the evolution of the policymaking process. Finally, in response to your specific inquiries about confidential ity, I am unaware of any unauthorized release of monetary policy information ever emanating from the Federal Reserve Bank of Min neapolis. My economic adviser and I leave highly confidential mate rial at the Board of Governors and do not return with it to Min neapolis. I take limited notes during the meeting, as does my ad viser. All notes or other materials are handled according to strict guidelines, and I attached a copy of those guidelines with my pre pared statement. Thank you. [The prepared statement of Mr. Stern can be found in the appendix.] The Chairm an. Thank you, sir. President Syron. 31 STATEMENT OF RICHARD F. SYRON, PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF BOSTON Mr. S y ro n . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. In the interests of time, I will try to be very short. Being involved in making monetary pol icy is something that is a great responsibility and enormous honor. Thus, from a purely personal perspective, I would welcome my views being made more public. However, as others have said, the key issue to me is what will provide the best policy for the people of the United States, and in my case for the 1st district. In this regard I believe there are difficult tradeoffs between open ness and the effectiveness of the deliberations that lead to the de velopment of monetary policy. Because we work for you as crea tures of the Congress, these tradeoffs are a valid reason to have this discussion today. But we need to think a lot about what is involved. I am concerned that a highly detailed accounting of FOMC delib erations, unless its release were accompanied by a delay of several years, would impair the ability of the FOMC to obtain and discuss confidential information essential to developing monetary policy. It would impact what I do personally. I literally never go anywhere on a personal or professional basis without asking people about what is happening in the economy. As others have said, being able to assure people that information they give you is confidential is an important part to being able to get that information. I believe the value of this process is dem onstrated by New England's experience in the most recent recession. The recession began earlier in New England than it did in other parts of the country, and proportionately many more jobs were lost. As a consequence some of our banks developed serious problems. These difficulties contributed to a credit crunch. The credit crunch was the subject of hearings held by this committee. These problems were discussed extensively at FOMC meetings. It wouldn’t have been possible to convey the seriousness of this problem without discussing individual lenders and individual firms and how it affected their employment plans, investment plans, and other business decisions. But, if the people from whom we gathered this information knew it would become public, they certainly, in their own interest, wouldn’t have volunteered it, and our understanding of the prob lems would have been greatly constrained. Again, I think tradeoffs are involved. The more specific are the references in the record of FOMC deliberations, the longer would be the time lag required before disclosure if access to valuable, con fidential information is to be maintained. If confidentiality could be assured and there were sufficient lags, I would have some sympathy for resubmitting the memorandum of discussion mentioned by others today. However, a second tradeoff is that much of the discussion and economic information subse quently disclosed in FOMC meetings pertains to the valuation of assets, value changes that can have a substantial impact on world financial markets. Fluctuations in asset values can have significant impact on the jobs of workers, and the incomes of investors. Public disclosure of 32 preliminary and exploratory discussions could generate unintended value changes that could lead to adverse and unnecessary reactions in the economy. In summary, the ultimate objective of monetary policy is to pro mote the highest sustainable standard of living possible for Ameri cans. The policymaking process should be as open as it can be, con sistent with that objective, and that is what we are here to explore this morning. My formal answer to the three questions you asked, Mr. Chair man, are contained in my written statement. [The prepared statement of Mr. Syron can be found in the appen dix.] The Chairm an. Thank you very much. May I take this oppor tunity to thank you for the graciousness with which you met the committee in Boston when we were there for a hearing on CRA and with your good work with respect to CRA. Well, it looks like we don’t have a consensus on H.R. 28 yet, but we are working up to it and hope springs eternal. At least we made a dent on Chairman Greenspan’s total unacceptability. There are some indications there is a little glimmer there for some hopeful change. I have a couple of questions. In the questions that I had directed, I did ask and each one of you responded, as to their notes or records that you are aware of. But today’s testimony by Chairman Greenspan reveals to me, at least, that the FOMC meetings are tape-recorded. As far as I know, I had not been aware of that, or know of any body else that had been aware of that. I don’t think we had been previously informed that there were these tape-recordings. What I am going to ask is if any of you knew or know about these record ings being made when you submitted your written testimony for to day’s hearing, or are you unaware that tape-recordings of FOMC meetings are customarily being made. Can you tell me exactly of any tapes of FOMC meetings now in existence that you do know about? I would be glad to hear from any of you. Mr. G reen sp an . Mr. Chairman, may I clarify that? The Ch airm an . Certainly. Mr. G reen sp an . In my remarks, what I indicated was that the FOMC staff, in the preparation of the minutes, takes a recording for purposes of getting a rough transcript, but the tapes are taped over. In other words, we don’t keep the actual tapes themselves. We do not have electronic recordings of the meetings. The Chairm an. I am a little bit confused here. In other words, you have no tape-recordings of the actual proceedings. Mr. G reen sp an . We have them only—as far as I know, what the staff does is, in order to assist its presentation and preparation of the minutes, it takes recordings but then tapes over them so they are not available thereafter. The Chairm an. Well, I am glad my staff doesn’t. Of course, I don’t know that I would grant that much blanket authority. Any way, the second question, about the so-called leaks, in your testi mony, Chairman Greenspan, you say, and I quote, “From time to 33 time I have briefed members of various administrations about the outcomes of FOMC meetings.” Now, you also say that you have not done it in the last IV2 years. Now, what I am really wondering about, how do each of you decide who to approve for the Chairman’s disbursal of confidential FOMC information? Is it just a coincidence that the official leaks went to the Bush administration, but not to the Clinton administration? If monetary policy changes again, who will receive those? Mr. G reen sp a n . Mr. Chairman, let me just say, as I indicated in my prepared text, what I do is try to communicate as best I can to the administration, whomever it may be, what the underlying monetary policy of the Federal Reserve is, and most importantly, to try to convey to them, those relevant individuals, why we are doing what we are doing and why we may do something else. In other words, I try to convey the substance of our deliberations, because if is important for individuals within the administration to know what we are doing so that they can do what they are doing better. In other words, we in previous testimonies have discussed the question of the interaction of monetary and fiscal policy and the ne cessity of communicating, and that is precisely what I was refer ring to. The notation I made with respect to the last year did not have to do with an ending of communication. On the contrary, I communicate more now than I have ever done. I was merely suggesting that an occasion to stipulate to them that we actually changed policy has not been necessary. But as I have suggested to you previously, the contacts I have personally with the individual key policymakers of the administration is exceptionally extensive and works very well. The Chairm an. Thank you very much. Mr. Leach. Mr. L ea ch . I thank the chairman. It has been an extraordinary hearing, and I have the sense that all of us are learning from each other. Let me just ask, first of all, in the area that I am most inter ested in many ways is how the regional bank presidents are se lected. There are basically three ideas that have been discussed in Congress. One relates to whether the regional bank presidents ought to be designated by the President with the advice and consent of the Senate. The second is whether regional bank presidents should participate in the Federal Open Market Committee. The third is whether the regional bank presidents should be designated by the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board. All three relate to the po litical science dilemma regarding regional bank presidents being designated by boards, the majority of which are composed of people whom they regulate, which is an awkward circumstance; or have as one of their responsibilities regulation; as well as the political science dilemma of representing only one industrial sector in Open Market Committee meetings. And so what I would like to ask, first, of the regional bank presi dents, of these three approaches, if there were change, recognizing that perhaps no change is preferred, which of the three would you find most reasonable? Maybe I should start at this end. 34 Mr. S y ro n . Mr. Leach, I would like to make one comment about the regulatory concern. I understand the point that you are raising, in that there is an appearance of a problem. With regard to regula tion the Federal Reserve Act makes clear that at the district level the presidents act as agents of the Board. Thus I, and I am sure this is true of my colleagues, never discuss a regulatory matter on a specific institution at a Board of Directors meeting. We talk about banking conditions overall, but we absolutely never discuss specific cases that are pending. Mr. L each . But you are selected by the Board and you are ac countable to the Board. Mr. S y ron . That is right. In response to your specific question, as you might expect, I think the present system has worked quite well, and thus of the three choices you present, if I had to choose I would prefer the one that represents the least change, which is the suggestion to have the presidents designated by the Federal Reserve Board. Mr. L each . Sure. Mr. Stem, would you agree with that? Mr. S te r n . I think I would agree with that, but I would empha size that the selection of Reserve bank presidents, ultimately those appointments have to be approved by the Board of Governors, so they are not made simply in isolation in the Reserve districts. Mr. L ea ch . Fair enough. Mr. Pariy. Mr. P a rry . I think the Chairman already has—and the Gov ernors have tremendous influence on the selection of the presidents at the present time. Mr. L ea ch . But of those three changes, which would you prefer? Mr. P a rry . I would prefer the third. The Chairm an. Mr. Melzer. Mr. M e lz e r . I just wanted to add a little to what Dick Syron was saying, if I could. I think with respect to the composition of the boards, as you know there are only three bank directors, and they come from three different groups of banks within the district. In other words, banks are broken down by size according to capital, so that it is impossible, for example, for large banks to dominate a Reserve bank board. Second, with respect to the other three di rectors who they nominate and elect, it is my experience that those directors are anything but pawns of the bankers. They can’t be bank officers; they can’t be bank directors. There may be an ap pearance problem, but as a practical matter, from firsthand experi ence, I have not seen any of those individuals to be what could be described as pawns of the bankers. And, third, in connection with the appointment of presidents, again, based on the experience at our bank, the search committee for a president would be chaired by either the Chairman or Deputy Chairman, a Class C director, one of the three public directors. There may be one bank director on a search committee, but it would not be dominated by so-called banker directors. And, finally, as has been noted, the appointment of a Reserve bank president must be approved by the Board of Governors, so that there is a already a very important public role in connection with that. 35 Mr. L e a c h . W hich o f the three would you prefer? Mr. M e lz e r . It is difficult for me to say. I guess on the theory that your suggestion is the least change, perhaps that one. But I think, as Chairman Greenspan noted the other day, that would have a significant impact, in my judgment, in terms of the role of regional Reserve bank boards of directors and the great benefit that we get from their input. I think that is why the Federal Re serve operates as efficiently as it does, because in effect we are ap plying, and have been for many years, private sector management concepts to the operation of our activities. Mr. L ea ch . I appreciate that. My problem is my time has ex pired. Let me ask briefly, would anyone differ with what has been said? Mr. J o r d a n . I differ, because it would destroy the Federal Re serve Bank System. Mr. L ea ch . Would you prefer that, would you rather have the President appoint-----Mr. J o r d a n . I would not prefer any of those. Mr. L e a ch . Would you prefer to have the district Governors not on the Federal Market Committee? Mr. J o r d a n . These are not acceptable choices. Making the presi dents nonvoting members, appointment by the President and con firmation by the Senate, or appointment by the Board of Gov ernors, would alter the Federal Reserve substantially, and in a very harmful way. It would not be a job I would want—— Mr. L e a ch . Of those three which would you find most----Mr. J o r d a n . I would not be a part of the system if you made any one of those three decisions. Mr. L ea ch . That is intellectually irrational. Let me pin you down, Mr. Jordan. Recognizing you might prefer not to serve under any of them, which is the least appealing? Mr. J o r d a n . I think it wouldn’t come to that because you don’t have a regional diversified decentralized system of Reserve banks if you make any one of those changes. You have a system of branches across the country. That outcome was considered by Con gress in 1913 and rejected. It would destroy the system. Mr. L e a ch . President Hoenig. Mr. H oen ig . Obviously, the preference is with the current. But I would make a slight change in what you are saying. The three Class C directors are appointed by the Board of Governors, and rather then having it appointed by the Board, I would suggest you have the three Class C directors do that with input from the other directors with the same veto power that is with the Board of Gov ernors. That way you have it with those appointed by the Board of Governors, not from this elected group as such, but you have input from them, and yet you have those three that are not elected actually making the appointment, and you still have the Board of Governors who can veto that. That is, I think, a better option than perhaps your third. Mr. L ea ch . Does anyone else wish to comment? Mr. B ro a d d u s. If I were forced to choose, I would choose the third alternative, but very reluctantly. It would change what is now a Federal Reserve System to a central reserve system. I went 36 through this process last year and I can tell you the Board of Gov ernors played an important role in reviewing my appointment and also the search committee that selected me included two Class C directors. The C hairm an. Let me suggest that since the time has expired that any other comment be submitted in writing. Mr. Neal. Mr. N e a l. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. You said a minute ago you didn’t think we had a consensus on this bill. I want to point out I think we, frankly, did. I did not find any support for the idea of the bill at all among any of our witnesses. I read that as a pretty solid consensus. And I think that is important, because our wit nesses are the country’s premier experts on this subject. And so their opinion is important, and their opinion in regard to Congressman Leach’s ideas also is important. And again, I think there was consensus. They don’t think we ought to inhibit what is now a very broad-based system. I want to ask these witnesses’ opinion on another subject, be cause I think ultimately you and Mr. Leach, in fact all of us, want accountability. It just seems to me we are going about it in a little different way. I think there is a possible solution here, and I want to make a stab at it. It may work; it may not. But as President Broaddus mentioned, I want to say this to the witnesses. You already may know, I have introduced legislation which would in effect require 100 percent accountability, oecause it would say that the Fed should require, over time, over whatever time it takes to avoid recession, a particular policy, and that policy is zero inflation or price stability, as the economists like to say, we mean the same thing. I want us to achieve and maintain this as zero inflation, price stability, because I am convinced it is the es sential policy necessary for us to achieve everything else it is that we want for the economy. It will allow us to achieve and maintain the lowest sustainable long-term interest rates, the highest sustainable levels of economic growth, the highest sustainable levels of employment, the highest levels of savings, and therefore investment, productivity, growth, the highest levels of efficiency in our economy, everything we want, the highest level of prosperity for all of our people. So, since I think we do know what is the best possible policy for the Fed, I would just like to ask our witnesses if they agree that this is the best policy or not, and if not, what they would say about it, and if they agree it is the best policy, do they think they should be held accountable to it, which is to say, would they support pas sage of our legislation, which would in effect require the Fed to achieve and maintain over a period of time, not overnight, but over a period of time, price stability? So just briefly, if I could, ask each of you to comment. Let me start at the left. Mr. K e lle y . Mr. Neal, I fully support your suggestion and have done so over the years. The Federal Reserve is a creature of the Congress, and the Federal Reserve should endeavor to try to fulfill the will of Congress as its boss, if you will. In order to achieve what the boss wants, it is necessary for the organization to understand just what that is. Very frankly, now 37 there are various voices that come to us from the Congress. I know of no one who has advocated inflation per se, but on the other hand, there are suggestions that come forth that could very easily lead in that direction, and in short, our mandate is unclear. I think it would be very helpful if it were clear. As things are now, I think it is somewhat confusing to the markets. I think it is confusing to other central banks ana to other governments, as to just what our mandate is from the Congress. And I think we would appreciate very much having that much more clear. Mr. N e a l. I know I am going to run out of time, so if I may just ask each of you to comment as briefly as you can. I would love to hear in great detail from all of you, but I know we are going to run out of time. Mr. L aW are. I certainly agree that the primary focus of mone tary policy should be price stability tempered by the additional re sponsibilities for sustained economic growth and as full a level of employment as is consistent with those two conditions. Mr. Lindsey. I agree with your objective completely, Mr. Neal. I would just caution you that perhaps binding the Federal Reserve, the Congress might find, binds itself with regard to fiscal policy de cisions. For example, one could imagine a value-added tax being passed by the Congress. I am not recommending it, but you would want to think long and hard about binding the Federal Reserve in the face of maintaining price stability. Mr. P h illip s . I do agree with your objective in terms of that it should have as its goal the achievement of real sustainable eco nomic growth in an environment of stable prices. I think that is what we are trying to achieve. Granted, we may disagree at times as to how to get there, and that is one of the very constructive parts of this assembly in the give-and-take process. Mr. B o e h n e . I would state the goal somewhat more broadly. I think, Congressman, that the goal of the Fed and indeed all eco nomic policy is economic growth, producing jobs, and higher stand ards of living. I think over the longer pull, the most significant con tribution that a central bank can make is low inflation. But I think we always need to keep that in the context that that is a means to an end, and the end is growth, jobs, and higher standards of living. And I think clearly from experience we know we do a lot better with low inflation rates rather than high inflation rates in pursu ing those ultimate objectives. Mr. B roa d d u s. I strongly, vigorously support the amendment specifically because I think it would enable the Federal Reserve, the Open Market Committee to make its maximum contribution to sustained employment and growth. The C hairm an. I will suggest that any additional comments be submitted in writing, since the time has expired. In fact, we have gone over just about equal to the time we allowed Mr. Leach. Mr. Roth. Mr. R o th . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, I came here this morning asking myself, you know, what kind of a testi mony are we going to hear today? What is our chairman after today? But I must say I was a little shaken by the testimony today. 38 The reason I say that is, when I look at these hearings, I always ask myself, how is it perceived by the general public, because here in our country we are really facing a severe problem of public trust and confidence in our institutions. We, as Congressmen, when we go home, we find that all the time. That is a big issue when we are at our town hall meetings. So for the American people, the Federal Reserve is really sort of a big question mark. What kind of powers do they have, and it is like a hidden hand in our economy. I think you ladies and gentlemen are aware of that. When I hear testimony of leaks and tapes erased and notes hidden away in stor age boxes, the public perception is, there is something going on there that shouldn’t be going on there. So I think the question I would have is, why shouldn’t the public question what goes on at the Fed? Mr. B oe h n e . I think, indeed, the public does have more than a right. I think it has an obligation to question what goes on at the Fed. I think that comes through in a variety of ways when we meet directly with the public and through you as their representatives. Speaking for myself, I want to be as completely open, no secrets, as possible in the conduct of monetary policy. However, I think that we all realize that there is a tradeoff sometimes in public policy be tween openness and the quality of the product, the quality of mone tary policy. We are trying to find the right tradeoff. Mr. R o th . Let me phrase the question this way. All the testi mony I have heard this morning could be capsulized as: Videotaping and verbatim transcripts, no matter when they are re leased to the public, would decrease the quality of the delibera tions. I think that is basically what everybody has said. So you make monetary policy, but Congress makes fiscal policy. Your ar guments are the same arguments we heard before Congress was televised. But do you think that Congress, and we make the fiscal policy, do you think that Congress has been less well served be cause we have been televised? Mr. B oe h n e . I am reluctant to comment on the quality of fiscal policy. Mr. R o th . But seriously, I think that is the question, I think, that basically is what we are wrestling with. Mr. S y ro n . Congressman, I think that is a relevant point, but fiscal policy that is made in a more episodic sense. It is made not on a continuous basis, where monetary policy is. Monetary policy is reported to the Congress twice a year in Humphrey-Hawkins hearings. While I am not opposed to having the degree of openness that is necessary, monetary policy does require input from con fidential sources. It would be impossible to get confidential infor mation from financial markets, companies, and other parts of the private sector. Mr. R o th . Mr. Syron, what goes on at these meetings that is so confidential that is going to hurt the public or the Congress if 60 days after the meeting Congress or the public read the transcript? Mr. S y ro n . I think it depends on what is discussed at the meet ings. I will give you a specific example. I come to a FOMC meeting talking about the credit crunch issue and I mention a specific com pany in one of the States in the New England district. 39 I give the company’s name, and say I am concerned that it is going to go out of business, this is what the employment effect is going to be, depending upon its capital flow over the next 90 days and what its bank does. That company is not going to give me that information if it is going to be included in a publicly available tran script in 60 days. Mr. R o th . Mr. Syron, that happens to us all the time. We get all kinds of cases, where people write to us, and we use that on the floor of Congress without giving their names. Mr. S ybon . They give you that information because they want to make a specific point and they are writing to you of their volition. We are going out seeking the information from them. I am talking about a process where we are continuously and appropriately ask ing people in our districts for confidential information. I am afraid that in an open, or videotaped session, you would dramatically alter our potential of getting that information. Mr. Roth. I appreciate your comment. Mr. Chairman, I want to make this comment in closing. There is no one on this committee that is a better friend of yourselves than I am. But I just want to say this. In the climate we are living through today, wnere there is so much public distrust and a lack of confidence in our public trust, I think we are coming to the point where all these things are going to have to be brought out in the open whether we like it or not, because I think the public is going to demand that. Thank you very much. The Chairm an. Mr. Hinchey. Mr. H in ch ey . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First of all, you are a very impressive group of Americans and I very much appreciate your being here and the opportunity to be with you. I express my appreciation to you, Mr. Chairman, for providing these gentlemen here. First, with regard to the question that the chairman asked of Mr. Greenspan earlier, I just want to see if I understood the answer. As I understand it, there are tape-recordings taken of the meeting by staff. Those tape-recordings serve as the basis for the prepara tion of the minutes that are released a month or so later after the next meeting. And in the interim, those tapes are then taped over so that no permanent record exists in that way. Is that correct? Mr. G reen sp a n . There is no permanent electronic record, that is correct. We obviously have rough notes-----Mr. H in ch ey . You do make recordings, but the recording is taped over? Mr. G reen sp a n . That is correct. Mr. H in ch ey . After the staff then prepares the minutes in prepa ration for their release at a subsequent date, a month or so later, between that time, the time that the staff prepares the minutes and their release, do the members then have an opportunity to re view those minutes? Mr. G reen sp a n . Yes. The minutes are drafted by the staff in some detail, circulated to the individual members to make certain that they capture the substance of what went on. There are changes that are made, corrections that are made. There are a number of suggestions to clarify certain points. Then we have a 40 final set of minutes which are those minutes which are released to the public 6 weeks, generally, after the meeting itself. Mr. H inch ey . S o the members in attendance then have an oppor tunity to edit the minutes before they are released? Mr. G reen sp a n . That is correct. Mr. HlNCHEY. With regard to the memorandum of understanding or memorandum of discussion, rather, that was available prior to 1976 or 1977, precisely what did that memorandum contain? Was that a verbatim release of what took place? Was it rough minutes? How would you describe it? Mr. G reen sp a n . It was a fairly detailed memorandum. In fact, maybe it would be better if I asked President Boehne. who was ac tually present at those times, to describe exactly wnat they are, and lie could probably do it better from memoiy than I can from nonexperience. Mr. B oe h n e . It would be hard to top your ability to do that sort of thing, Mr. Chairman, but let me try. What those memoranda were, they are not verbatim, but they went through and described the individual positions in a sequential way, ana they were per haps—I am really guessing now, but I would guess they would run maybe 150 pages or something like that for a typical meeting and they were released with a 5-year lag, although there were a num ber of things that were taken out, particularly involving relation ships with foreign central banks and other kinds of information that might damage individual firms or companies or banks or that sort of thing. Mr. H inch ey . Even after 5 years there was a danger that that might occur? Mr. B oeh ne . In terms of some o f the ongoing relationships, par ticularly in the foreign area, I think that was the judgm ent at the time. Mr. G reen sp an . In my comment that—minutes are not made available by other central banks, and that the Bundesbank, for ex ample, makes its minutes available, I believe, 30 years after the ac tual event. So the amount of disclosure which occurs by the Federal Reserve is far above any disclosures made by other central banks amongst the industrial countries. Mr. H in ch ey . But it is less so than it was prior to 1976 and 1977? Mr. G reen sp an . In the sense that we make—I would suspect that our actual minutes now are more inclusive than they used to be, and far more representative of the substance of the discussion. But they are not as long and detailed as the memoranda of discus sion that existed 15 or 17 years ago and earlier. Frankly, I would suspect the person who wanted to find out what happened at an FOMC meeting would learn far more from the min utes we produce today than having to plow through one of those memoranda of discussion of an earlier period. It is probably useful for scholars who are very interested in the extreme detail of the deliberations, but I will tell you, if the pur pose is to find out what happened, that is not the best way to do it. Mr. H in ch ey . So, Mr. Chairman, is it true, then, that as a means perhaps in part to compensate for the elimination of the detailed 41 memorandum of discussion, the elimination of that in part, the ra tionale— since that was done—let me rephrase the question. Since that was done at some point in 1976 or 1977, in order to com pensate for that absence now, the minutes that are produced on a monthly basis are more detailed than they would have been prior to that? Mr. G reen sp an . I think that is true. Mr. B o eh n e. That is correct. What is now put out is more de tailed than was put out pre-1976, and also is released more promptly. And I think in a much more usable fashion. If one wants to go back and look at what happened at a particular policy meet ing, I, for one, would prefer to read the minutes that we now produce than to plow through those old memoranda of discussion, just in terms of practical-----Mr. H in ch ey. Might I ask just one more brief question? I notice that in the minutes you provided, as appended to your testimony, Mr. Chairman, there is some discussion about events that took place and various things that are said, but it doesn’t attribute the statements to any particular member. What is the reason for that? Mr. G reen sp an . There is a good reason for that. First of all, let me say there are two positions one takes at these meetings. You are either in favor of the final result, meaning you are part of the majority, or you are in the minority. We try to explain in some de tail the rationale that has been developed during the meeting by those who eventually voted for it. So in that sense, each member of the majority is essentially subscribing to the views that are in volved in that decision. Those who dissent, for whatever reason, write special dissents specifically. The reason why we emphasize the overall view of the committee is that this by statute is a committee, not a group of in dividuals, and that we have responsibilities as a committee and are held responsible to the Congress for what it is we do as a commit tee, not as individuals. Mr. H in ch ey. But isn’t it true the committee is influenced or may be by statements that are made by individual members of the committee? That is the purpose of the discussion, and although one sees the vote, those who voted for and against, those who voted for, particularly, for example, with regard to the discussion of M l, M2, and M3 that took place at the meeting that is reported in the Feb ruary meeting, certain people may have been influenced by state ments made by others at that meeting and they may have voted on the basis of those statements. Isn’t it instructive to know who is influencing people to vote a certain way? Mr. G reen sp a n . That is difficult to do even in the memorandum of discussion, because what it is that creates changes in points of view or why people come out in certain ways is not always that clear. Sometimes in the discussion somebody will say, I agree with that or I don’t agree with that, or I see what you mean or some thing of that nature. What we would actually need is a different type of set of minutes that would not express what the committee is doing, and in that regard we have discussed this and looked at it at great length and have concluded that it is important that we emphasize what the consensus of the committee is, because that is 42 where the action and the directive comes from, and for which we are held responsible as a group. And I think that if we endeavor to start to separate this group into individuals, we would lose the strain of the importance of being a committee as differentiated from the individual members themselves. Mr. H in ch ey . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Chairm an. May I just add one thing here, to clarify, with respect to the Bundesbank, they report to the press immediately after their meeting regarding their decisions. Mr. G reen sp a n . They report their decisions, but they do not re port their deliberations. The Chairm an. Well, no, we are not talking about the same thing, though. Unlike the case of the Open Market Committee, you are not saying their decisions are reported immediately. Mr. G reen sp an . I am basically saying you don’t know what the vote of the Bundesbank Council is for a very long period of time. They don’t say who voted for what. All you get is the final conclu sion. The Chairm an. I don't want to go into it, but there is a vast dif ference between the culture and the historical association of that class of banker in a country like Germany and ours. The bankers in a country like Germany look upon themselves as part of the offi cialdom of the administration. And I don’t think we have that tra dition in our country. But I don’t want to get into that. I want to thank you for giving me the opportunity to interject. Mr. Ridge. Mr. R idge. Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. Chairman Greenspan, obviously from the comments of some of my colleagues and some of the legislative initiatives, there is some concern about the mystique surrounding the environment with which the Open Market Committee operates. As my colleague at the left was con cerned about, an increasing interest in the body politic of more sun shine, greater disclosure, that is the political side of the discussion. The policy side of the discussion, I think, recognizes the legiti mate need to keep the different contingencies that you had dis cussed, some of the confidential information you glean from those involved in the economy within the region that helps you come to the conclusions or certainly enables you to draw on information in the marketplace to deliberate and then make some decisions. So we are trying to balance the public’s right to know with your need to make some fundamental monetary policy decisions. And I under stand that, but I am very interested from your perspective in learn ing whether or not the manner in which you deal with the question of public access to monetary policy decisions differs from other central banks. And to the extent that it differs, are there any lessons to be drawn from the experience of other central banks where they may have provided either by design or unintentionally earlier access to the information involving your deliberations or accidental access as it affects monetary policy or minimizing inflation? Can we look to the central banks in other industrialized democ racies and draw any conclusion if the manner of dealing with this differs from ours? 43 Mr. G reen sp a n . We are so far ahead in the issue of disclosure and indicating to the public what we do and why we do it and who votes what on various different directives, that there is almost no comparison. The general culture of central banking outside the United States has far, far less elements of openness than we have. It is part of their culture, as the chairman says. So I don’t nec essarily think that we should be endeavoring to view essentially what others do as a model for what we do. We nave a different type of culture. It is a far more open one. And that is reflected in our central bank as well. The trouble, un fortunately, is that central banking by its nature cannot be open, fully open, without undermining our capability to implement our role as described by the law. It is a terrible dilemma that we have, and I personally, in fact, all of my colleagues believe that we would like to have everything out in the open. The only trouble is were we to do that we wouldn’t be able to do our jobs. So it is a very delicate and difficult balance that we believe that we at the central bank in conjunction with the Congress over the years have accom plished—a fairly reasonable balance that I think balances our cul ture on the one hand, and the necessity of operating in markets on the other. I don’t think that tradeoff even remotely resembles that which exists in any other industrial countiy. Mr. R idge. Are there any examples of which you are aware where the public or the marketplace in any of the industrial coun tries may have gained access, not through appropriate public dis closure, but through leaks of the sort that had an adverse impact on the marketplace? Mr. G reen sp a n . I assume they go on from time to time. Any in stitution which has got large numbers of people will tend to do that. The difference, however, is that in many of those institutions there is a single Governor and a Deputy Governor and very few people who are involved in the process, and hence the probability of leaks are much lower than where you have a large number of people involved. Mr. R idge. I appreciate that, I guess, and I apologize for being late. As I gleaned through some o f your testimony and listened to the few witnesses that I had an opportunity to hear, the contin gencies, the economic contingencies that you discuss and the infor mation that you share and tne dialog with which you engage and challenge one another, it is your collective opinion that the public disclosure of those contingencies or that confidential information, and I suspect engaged dialog, in your judgment, would bring vola tility, far more volatility to the marketplace to outweigh the need for us to see immediately the entire course of your deliberations? Mr. G reen sp an . That is the judgment of this committee, and I believe it is unanimous, unless I hear those who wish to dissent from that, because we have discussed this issue at very consider able length. We have no vested interest in not disclosing what we are doing as quickly as we can and as broadly as we can. The sole reason why we choose not to is because we believe that the imple mentation of policy would be impaired. Mr. R idge. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Ch airm an . Thank you. 44 Mr. Fingerhut. Mr. F in g e r h u t. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Mr. Chairman, I do have an opening statement I would like to submit for the record, with your permission. The C h airm an . Certainly. [The prepared statement of Mr. Fingerhut can be found in the appendix.] Mr. F in g e r h u t. I would say that based on what I had heard at the beginning of these hearings, I would associate myself with some of Mr. Neal’s opening comments, both with respect to the sub ject of the hearing and also his other resolutions. I have enjoyed these hearings, Mr. Chairman, and I appreciate you calling them, because it is an extraordinary opportunity for someone new to this committee both to have an exchange with the Chairman of the Federal Reserve and now to do so with all the members of the Federal Open Market Committee. Last week, Chairman Greenspan, we talked about the coordina tion of fiscal and monetary policy, and you, on the record, and I ap preciate it, were very open about the extent to which you do meet with the relevant persons in the administration who are charged with developing fiscal policy. And I, in fact, commend you and the administration because we have seen a coordination between fiscal and monetary policy over the last period of months that is better than some of the times in our history. Having the rest of the members of the committee here today, though, prompts me to take the question a step further. While we tend to report our economic results on a nationwide basis, we know that we are, in fact, a very diverse nation, and that often the re sults that make the headlines in the Wall Street Journal are a compendium where, in fact, some areas are doing very well and some areas are not doing as well as they should be. I would be interested in any comments, and I will just turn my time over to the panel, as to how we do and how we can improve our coordination of technical fiscal and monetary policy, and indeed the broader range of actions we take here in the Congress on a re gional level, so the sustained growth we all are seeking is one that is spread equally throughout the country. Mr. S y ro n . May I try answering that question? I think your question is a very apt one particularly at this point in time, be cause we all collect data on what happens in our regions. Actually, if you look at this recession's recovery period, you’ll notice that the variance in regional economic performance is very, very dramatic. In some places you would hardly know there had been a reces sion. In some cases, which unfortunately, includes my district, you would hardly know there has been a recovery. This type of transi tional situation underscores one of the great values of the system, when published information is not adequate, we have the ability to gather information on an anecdotal basis and get a better feel for what is happening. While the most important determinant of what happens to any part of the country is the national economy as a whole, another value of the regional system that it is completely consistent with the Federal system of government we have, is the input of all parts 45 of the countiy in deciding what melded policy on a crudely average basis is best for the Nation as a whole. Other countries have had policies o f different kinds to deal with distressed versus nondistressed regions. The history o f success o f that approach is mixed at best. O ur approach o f establishing a com m on national policy, taking into consideration regional dif ferences, has really worked out quite well in an overall sense. Mr. M cT e e r. Can I just add a footnote to that? To tie together your comments about regional differences in the country, a district, and the question of release of information, we do what they call a beige book, which is the result of a very extensive set of interviews with various sources by each Federal Reserve Bank and we actu ally publish all of that material that goes into the beige book prior to the FOMC meeting so the public has that even before we get to gether, to me, just a footnote. Mr. HOENIG. I think bringing regions to the meetings is very, very important in terms of bringing the differences that occur around the country together and forming monetary policy. As far as the coordination with fiscal policy, though, you do not want 12 regions trying to coordinate fiscal policy with people. I think that is why you bring it to the Open Market Committee, and why it goes to the Chairman, who then has the best means of informing and so forth in the right context. So it is important we bring it together, but how we coordinate, I think, has to be done very, very carefully. Mr. F in g e rh u t. I appreciate all of the answers. The Chairm an. The time of the gentleman has expired. We have another panel following. Mr. K n o lle n b e r g . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I must be the last one, looking around. I appreciate the testimony of this panel, espe cially Chairman Greenspan. You have been here a number times and it is a pleasure to see you come back each time. There are proposals that are being tossed about regarding more closely tying the FOMC and the Fed to each administration, and we have heard some comment about you folks being the foxes that guard the chicken house, I don’t especially believe that. In fact, if you look, the chickens seem to be in pretty good shape, so I would say you are doing your job very adequately. As I have said before, you are probably the envy of the rest of the world. There is a lurking feeling out there, and it has been talked about by a couple of my colleagues, as to getting things out in the open, the sunshine. Congress seems to, of course, hear a lot about that of late. The 14-year terms are one thing I hear about from my con stituency. Is there anything magic about 14 years? This is ad dressed to you, Chairman Greenspan, in the time that remains, but is there anything magic about those 14 years? Could it be shortened to 4 years or 6 years? Would that, in fact, do anything to alter the process, and your success rate? Mr. G reen span . Well, let me say, Congressman, that the 14-year term was something that was compromised out in the original act in 1913 in an endeavor to insulate the members of the Federal Re serve Board from political—from short-term political pressures, and to effectively spread out the appointment process of each individual 46 President of the United States. So in that sense, is there a magic element involved? Obviously not. Clearly, it could be shorter or it could be longer. That is a judg ment that the Congress has to make. As a practical matter, few of us actually serve the 14 years. So it is not a practical issue. It is an issue more of statute than it is for implementation. I call on my other colleagues to make other statements they would like to make. Mr. K n o lle n b e r g . Before you get to that, would you have any— I assume, and I shouldn't assume, I guess, but I assume you would feel differently about appointing the Fed Chairman at the com mencement of a President’s term. Mr. G reen sp an . I must admit I go back and forth on this par ticular question, because there are pluses and minuses as to when the Chairman and the Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board are chosen. And it is very rare that I don’t have an opinion strongly on one side or another. But the weight of evidence on both sides of this argument are as balanced as I remember any particular public policy issue getting. Mr. K n o lle n b e r g . In the time remaining, anybody else want to chime in and offer a comment? I assume you speak for the group. Then in that case I will conclude my questioning and I thank you, Mr. Chairman, for bringing these folks in. Thank you very much. The C hairm an. Thank you. Mr. G reen sp a n . Mr. Chairman, one of my staff has informed me, and I would correct this for the record, the 14-year term goes back to the 1930’s, not to 1913. So I amend my statement accordingly. Mr. K nollen berg . Y ou stand corrected. The Chairm an. Gentlemen, thank you. Mr. Leach has requested 1 minute for, I guess, a summation. Mr. L ea ch . Not a summation, but in our booklets we have a statement from David Mullins, and I would like to ask unanimous consent that it be presented for the record as well. The C h airm an . W ithout objection. [The prepared statement of Mr. Mullins can be found in the appendix.] Mr. L ea ch . Second, I want to respond from a personal perspec tive on the Open Market Committee issue. There has been a very emotive response from one of the Federal Reserve Bank presidents, but let me as carefully as I can say that the policies of the Federal Reserve Board of the United States of America, when it comes to regulation, have had multi-billion-dollar implications for the fiscal policy of the United States; that is, the LDC lending circumstance which was partly regulatorv-oriented decisionmaking, has caused us to write off billions of dollars of public debt. I raise this because we have a circumstance in America today that for the first time in the last 50 years, Federal Reserve Board regulated institutions have lower—lower, I repeat—capital ratios required than State-regulated institutions. By historical perspec tive, I think it very important that the Congress of the United States note that the independence of the Federal Reserve System is the tradition and the history of 20th century America. The Fed eral Reserve Board has a marvelous record which this Congress 47 must honor. But not all aspects of this record have been or are per fect. The C ha ir m an . Thank you very much. Mr. Neal is recognized for unanimous consent request. Mr. N e a l . I just wanted to ask that the rest of you, if you would, comment to me and for the record on these two questions; whether or not you agree that price stability is the best policy for the Fed, and whether or not you think the Fed should be held accountable for achieving and maintaining that policy by legislation. The C h a ir m an . Mr. Neal, the Chair had indicated that when we recognized you, your time was up; and any additional participation by any Member be submitted in writing for the record. Also, every member of the committee, both present and absent, is given unani mous consent to submit written questions to the members of this panel, provided they do so by the time you receive the transcript of the proceedings. Gentlemen, tnank you very much, and lady. Thank you very, very much. We have another panel, and I must apologize for the time they have had to sit all morning long, but it is a very important panel, and one to which I want to offer my profound personal thanks for their constant cooperation with us. It consists of the famous and internationally known Anna Schwartz of the National Bureau of Economic Research; Mr. James Meigs, economist for the First Interstate Bank Corp., and Mr. Rob ert Craven, Fixed Income Management Group. Thank you very much. Dr. Schwartz, I particularly want to thank you for your constant help to the committee and some subcommittees. I understand you have a time problem, and I can appreciate that, given the length of time you have had to sit here this morning. STATEMENT OF ANNA SCHWARTZ, RESEARCH ASSOCIATE, NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH Dr. S chw artz . Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am here to comment on two provisions in section 4 of H.R. 28 relating to prompt public disclosure of Federal Open Market Committee meetings. One provi sion would require the Federal Reserve to videotape and transcribe FOMC meetings and to make the videotape and transcription pub lic within 60 days after a meeting. Another provision would require the Federal Reserve to make public within a week of an FOMC meeting the domestic policy directive voted upon and issued to the trading desk in New York after each FOMC meeting. Let me first discuss the provision regarding the maintenance of detailed records of Federal Open Market Committee deliberations and their public disclosure. To gain some perspective on this provision, it is helpful to trace historical developments on the availability to the public of informa tion on the Federal Reserve’s conduct of monetary policy through its purchases and sales of open market securities. Three subperiods may be distinguished on this matter in the Federal Reserve’s history. 48 The first period was before 1936. The second period was from 1936 through March 1975. And the final period is the one since March 1975. In the period before 1936, abbreviated minutes of Open Market Committee meetings beginning in 1922 were maintained, but re stricted to internal use. Information on the Federal Reserve’s ac tivities is, however, available in two sources; one, the Library of Congress for the diaries of Charles Hamlin, a member of the Fed eral Reserve Board from 1914 to 1936, and Columbia University for the papers of George Harrison, a Governor and then president of the New York Fed from 1928 to 1940. Charles Hamlin recorded his observations on the views of impor tant Federal Reserve personalities and on the pressure of events on the decisions reached by the Board. The Harrison papers contain a wealth of documentary evidence, including the minutes of Open Market Committee meetings, official correspondence, memoranda exchanged in connection with those meetings, minutes of the meet ings of the board of directors of the New York Fed at which system policy was analyzed, and a full record of Harrison’s conversations with leading figures in the system. In the second period, March 1936 through March 1976, detailed minutes or memoranda of discussion were prepared for each FOMC meeting. Before 1965 these records were held to be confidential documents. In 1964 the FOMC adopted a policy to release minutes of each meeting held through 1960 and for the release of minutes for subsequent meetings with a 5-year lag after the calendar year in which the minutes were taken. This action by the FOMC was a response to congressional re quests in the early 1960’s for FOMC minutes and the publication in 1963 of a monetary history of the United States, from 1867 to 1960, of which Milton Friedman and I were coauthors. While the book was in draft, we sought but were denied access to the minutes of the FOMC by the Federal Reserve at that time. We had to sub stitute the Hamlin diaries and the Harrison papers for the period they covered. By 1964, despite its refusal 2 years earlier to let us see minutes of meetings, the FOMC apparently decided that disclosure of the minutes after a 5-year lag posed no threat to the Fed. In May 1976, the FOMC announced that after the March 15-16 meeting, memoranda of discussion would be discontinued, and the views of individual participants expressed at FOMC meetings would no longer be documented. The announcement apparently was inspired by the adoption of the Freedom of Information Act and the Sunshine Act that made it difficult for the Federal Reserve to maintain confidential and secret information. The March 1975 meeting of the FOMC is the last one to date of which minutes have been made public. I favor reinstatement by the FOMC of its former practice of maintaining detailed minutes of its meetings and publication of the record after a fixed period of time to protect the Federal Reserve against premature disclosure of ongoing, unsettled issues. The record should be verbatim. A videotape is neither essential nor de sirable. The record should be verbatim subject to correction within a brief period by the participants for inadvertently misspeaking. 49 If the Federal Reserve regards 60 days as to short a delay for publication, I would not object to lengthening the delay to 1 year for a full record of the minutes of a meeting. Absence of the minutes of meetings since March 1975 has de prived scholars of information on the formation of monetary policy and limits research. I am familiar with a recent proposal by a wellknown scholar to study Federal Reserve performance in recent dec ades. That scholar intends to resort to interviews with former Fed eral Reserve officials as a substitute for the unavailable minutes since 1975. The better course would be for the Federal Reserve to publish whatever documentation it has maintained for each meet ing in the period since 1976. Let me now discuss the question of the appropriate length of delay of the release of the FOMC domestic policy directive. Current )ractice, which began in 1976, is for directives to be released after inancial markets close on the Friday after the subsequent FOMC meeting. This is a lag of approximately 45 days after the meeting at whicn the directive was adopted and after another directive has been adopted. The directive that is released is always an outdated one. The position of the Federal Reserve is that early release would harm its ability to conduct monetary policy and the government’s commercial interests. It has asserted that prompt release of the di rective would have an announcement effect on financial markets. Market participants would hasten to realize gains in anticipation of the Federal Open Market Committee’s purchases or sales of se curities that would lead to substantial additional costs for the gov ernment’s debt financing. The Federal Reserve argument boils down to the claim that prompt release would cause increased interest rate volatility that would raise the average level of interest rates. Is there evidence to support these claims? Although official release of the directive is delayed for approxi mately 45 days, the Wall Street Journal has reported the contents of the directive within a week of each of 11 FOMC meetings out of the 34 meetings that took place between March 1989 and May 1993. These are leaks that the newspaper attributes to, quote, “government officials,” or “people familiar with the Fed’s delibera tions.” The newspaper articles correspond closely with the FOMC directives that were later published. Prof. Michael T. Belongia of the University of Mississippi and his coauthor, Kevin Kliesen, have analyzed the 11 leaks as if they rep resented the immediate release of the directive. The authors exam ine changes in the Treasury bill rate on each of 5 days before and 5 days after the Wall Street Journal story appeared to see if the T-bill rate changes support the Federal Reserve’s argument that the early release of the content of the directive would be associated with increased volatility in short-term interest rates. The authors find that any such effect was negligible even when the directive contradicted expectations based on current market rates. Moreover, even if there were large responses of interest rates to each of the 34 directives since 1989 on the assumption that they contained news different from existing market expectations, the in crease in variance was numerically small. S 50 Belongia and Kliesen also raised doubts that increased volatility of the limited magnitude they find around the dates of leaks would raise the average level of interest rates on all other days. I reach two conclusions. One is that the Fed would be better ad vised to release the directive promptly instead of selectively leaking its content. Market participants scrutinize every scrap of informa tion on prospective Federal Reserve actions. The market will per form better if the scrutiny is based on the actual directive, however Delphic its content, rather than on rumors and conjectures about the directive. It is hard to accept the view that markets perform better the less information they have. My second conclusion is that the Fed is needlessly concerned about the supposed disturbing effects of prompt release of the di rective on volatility and the level of interest rates. If FOMC meetings were held on Thursday and Friday and par ticipants had an opportunity over the weekend to review the ver batim record to correct instances in which they misspoke, the Fed could then release the domestic policy record and this abbreviated information record on Monday morning when U.S. markets opened. Finally, let me say that these hearings are devoted to peripheral aspects of Federal Reserve operations. The hearings do not touch on the substantive questions: What are the Fed’s objectives? How effective are the operating procedures it follows to achieve its objec tives? So I applaud the legislation that Congressman Neal is proposing that price level stability should be the sole Fed objective. Thank you. The C hairm an. Mr. Meigs. STATEMENT OF JAMES MEIGS, SENIOR VICE PRESIDENT AND CHIEF ECONOMIST, FIRST INTERSTATE BANK CORP. Mr. M eigs, Mr. Chairman, members of the committee, it is an honor for me to appear before you to express my views on this im portant matter. I am familiar with the materials we have been dis cussing, the policy record, and the proceedings, because I used them for many years in three capacities: One, as an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank, where we were providing analytical sup port for the president of our bank in preparing for meetings of the Open Market Committee; second, as a researcher, writing and lec turing on money and banking, monetary policy, and world financial markets; and third, as an economist or consultant for banks, secu rities firms, savings and loan associations, and other institutions. I have had no experience in the oversight role implied by Con gress’ power to coin money and regulate tne value thereof, in arti cle 1, section 8, clause 5, of the U.S. Constitution. However, I think my recommendations may be helpful to you in that function. I have three recommendations. One, the Federal Reserve should publish the policy record of the Federal Open Market Committee within 1 or 2 days after each meeting of the committee. The policy record should clearly state any changes in policy and the reasons for the changes. Second, the FOMC should resume the practice discontinued in 1976 of having the committee secretary prepare a memorandum of 51 discussion for each meeting, the minutes. The memorandum of dis cussion should be released to the public after no more than 1 year. The third recommendation is that the Congress should provide a clear mandate for the Federal Reserve to pursue a stable price level for the U.S. economy, that is, to regulate the value of money. This Banking Committee then could concentrate on holding the Federal Reserve accountable for how it carries out that delegated responsibility. In the rest of the statement, I plan to state some of the reasons for these arguments. On the policy record, at the end of my state ment for hearings of this committee on September 11, 1973, I said, “My one additional suggestion is to eliminate the secrecy that now cloaks the processes and decisions of the Board of Governors and the Open Market Committee. I see no reason why policy directives of the Open Market Committee should not be publicly announced immediately after each meeting of the committee, preferably with a discussion of the reasons for policy decisions. Ending the secrecy would not only facilitate the monitoring of System actions by the President ana the Congress, but it would greatly reduce uncer tainty among the general public.” At the time I wrote that, I was advising clients at banks and other financial firms. My inability to provide them with more near ly current information on Federal Reserve policies was extremely frustrating. Now, 20 years later, I am even more firmly convinced that the policy record should be released immediately after each meeting. Participants in United States and world financial markets are as skittish as gazelles drinking from a river infested with crocodiles. Over the last 20 years, they have invested vast resources in equip ment and techniques designed to shorten the time they need to react to new information about economic policies and prospects. They especially would like to know what the FOMC decides about policy at each meeting and what circumstances might lead to a change at future meetings or in the period between meetings. The slightest hint of a change in U.S. monetary policies can affect secu rities prices and exchange rates around the world within minutes. These well-known facts about financial markets* sensitivity to changes in the Federal Reserve policy have been used in arguing for delay in releasing the policy record in order to avoid destabiliz ing financial markets. I believe to the contrary that the effects of reducing the delay in releasing the policy record would be in the other direction. Immediate or early release would exert a stabiliz ing influence on financial markets by reducing uncertainty. That does not necessarily mean the markets would not jump when a new issue of the policy record announces a policy change. People with their own or client's money at risk adjust quickly to any announced or suspected policy change. Market jumps in reaction to early policy record releases might embarrass the policymakers, especially when interest rates or ex change rates shift in an unpopular direction. But the markets would be more likely to jump in a direction that would be consist ent with Federal Reserve policy objectives than when the markets react to rumors, leaks, innuendo, or conjectures which later prove to be unfounded. It would be better to provide the markets with the 52 truth—whether potentially disturbing or not—and let them sort it out. Early release of the policy record would have the further virtue of leveling the playing field. Some market players now are believed to have better access to information on Federal Reserve policy than others do. This obviouslv causes hard feelings or worse at times when some institutions believe competitors receive valuable infor mation from Federal Reserve sources sooner than they do. The pol icy record should be thrown on the table for everybody at once as soon as the facts are in, like a crop report. The memoranda of discussion are the minutes we have talked about quite a bit this morning. The memoranda of discussion that were discontinued in 1976 provided fascinating insights into FOMC policymaking procedures, although with an intolerably long delay. A new series of minutes or memoranda of discussion released with less delay would be extremely useful to future policymakers, re searchers and market practitioners. Chairman Arthur Burns told the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy in 1977 that he thought a bill to require the FOMC to maintain detailed minutes and to publish them after 3 years was “clearly motivated by a concern for the interests of schol ars and others who may have occasion to do historical research in the area of monetary policy ” Numerous other researchers and I had written to the committee to express various degrees of anguish over losing the memoranda of discussion. So he thought he was replying to the scholars out there, of whom there were very few. Chairman Burns conceded that the newly revised and expanded policy record “does not pre serve a historical record as detailed as that contained in the earlier memoranda of discussion.” While expressing his regret over no longer producing FOMC minutes for scholars to mull over, Chair man Burns slighted a much more important group of readers. He hardly mentioned members and staff of the Open Market Committee and innumerable people throughout the system who have to interpret, explain, and carry out monetary policy. For ex ample, at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, we used the draft minutes of each meeting to help our president prepare for the next meeting. One reason was that the economist who accompanied the president to FOMC meetings seldom could take enough notes to tell the rest of us who said what and why in a meeting of 12 Reserve Bank presidents, 7 board members, and several staff advisers. The point of this anecdote is that Federal Reserve views on how monetary policy should be formulated and carried out, were evolv ing then at a rapid rate, as they still must be evolving now. There was no clear manual of procedure for dealing with policy problems. The FOMC was adapting to changing economic institutions, chang ing financial institutions, and changing doctrines in monetary eco nomics. Because the membership of the committee was continually changing, the FOMC needed an institutional memoiy to organize and to preserve this learning experience for future generations of policymakers inside the Fed itself. The memoranda of discussion provided a fine vehicle and repositoiy for the FOMC institutional memory. The memorandum for 53 each meeting recording the discussion was reviewed by the partici pants to guard against errors in transcription or wording and was locked up in final form for posterity at the next meeting, usually 1 month later. As Dr. Schwartz said, years of such records of expe rience are now lacking, never to be retrieved, and these are years of the most sweeping changes and conditions of monetary policy. Keeping and publishing detailed minutes of FOMC meetings would help answer three overriding questions. One, how do mem bers of the Federal Open Market Committee learn to exercise the awesome powers delegated to them? Two, how does a corporate body made up of ever-changing indi vidual members remember and employ what it learns from its mis takes and successes? Three, how can the government that delegated those powers oversee the performance of their stewards? Former Reserve Board member and Vice Chairman J.L. Robert son summed up these issues in a letter to the chairman of the Sub committee on Domestic Monetary Policy in 1976, Chairman Neal at that time. He said—and he was a veiy outstanding and articulate Governor—“In my view, the formulation of monetary policy by the Open Market Committee is one of the most important factors influ encing the economy. Hence, it should be mandatory that there be kept a detailed record, to be made available to Congress and the public, after a lapse of appropriate time.” He went on to say, “If minutes of the meetings are not kept and eventually made available, there would be no possible way for the Congress or members of the public to appraise the contribution of any member of the committee to the formulation of monetary pol icy. Such appraisals are essential to any study of how to improve the system.” Governor Robertson also answered the question which came up over and over and over and over again this morning, of whether knowing they were on public record would inhibit members willing ness to speak frankly in FOMC meetings. He said, and I quote, “Men competent to serve in these positions should be willing and anxious to stand on their records and be held responsible for the way in which they play their respective roles.” The men and women who serve on the FOMC today and those who will serve in the future should not be reluctant to go on record. Each will be backed up by some of the most competent economists in the world. Each one will already have won distinction as a responsible professional in some capacity before joining the committee. I would suggest that any committee member who is afraid his or her statements might not stand up to the tests of time or outside view should either put more thought into the statements or seek a less demanding line of work. Now we come to what I think is a crucial recommendation, which I would call a mandate for the Federal Reserve. When considering the use of the minutes and other information from the Federal Reserve for establishing accountability one must ask, accountability for what? Most treatises on responsibility and accountability in business, government, and the military stress the 54 need for a clear statement of the responsibility or mission for which an individual or an organization can be held accountable. Such a statement or mandate is lacking here. After 200 years of constitutional history, we still have not clearly decided what the mandate for control of the money power is or where it resides. The Federal Reserve System and most other central banks pur sue multiple objectives at the same time, economic growth, employ ment, price stability, interest rates, and exchange rates and others. Experience of many years and many countries demonstrates that it is impossible to achieve all of the objectives set by central banks and the governments simultaneously. In operating and in reporting to the governments and the public, it is agonizingly difficult for the central banks to decide which ob jective or objectives to stress. Consequently, there is an inflationary bias in monetary policies o f m any countries that is extremely difficult to counteract. Most important, there is no simple tradeoff that would permit central banks and governments to achieve higher real economic growth by tolerating more inflation. Instead, a stable price level would provide the best possible foundation for maximizing opportu nities for increasing employment and real incomes. Now, this Congress could cut the knot by instructing the Federal Reserve to maintain a stable price level—zero inflation—to regu late the value of the money. That is, the Congress could tell the Federal Reserve to do something it can do and that would have a tangible, measurable result. The Federal Reserve could then concentrate on learning how to do that and doing it. The Congress could hold the Federal Reserve accountable for carrying out that responsibility. The Congress could and should examine all information coming from the FOMC, including the memoranda of discussion, and the policy record, to assure itself and the public that the value of money is well regulated. The voters ultimately would hold both of these bodies accountable for the results. Thank you. Chairman G o n z a le z . Thank you very much. [The prepared statement of Mr. Meigs can be found in the appendix.] Mr. Craven. STATEMENT OF ROBERT CRAVEN, FIXED INCOME MANAGEMENT GROUP Mr. C ra ven . Chairman Gonzalez, members o f the committee, thank you for the opportunity to address you this morning. Congressman Neal, as you stated, the Fed clearly has done a good job and I would agree with you and I also would say it is easy to be critical and I would like my comments today to be taken in a constructive light It is a very, very tough job that the policymakers are harnessed to, I realize that, but it's a shame that they have chosen to cloak their communication in what I feel is unnecessary secrecy. Some times it seems almost designed to confuse and mislead the market place. 55 It is as if I were a heart surgeon and I was here before you, I could explain in two ways heart disease; one in medical terms, which none of us would understand; and the other is that the mus cle is weak and the veins are clogged, and you would get the point. When I look at the committee and I see few in attendance and I am told—believe me I am very naive in the v/ays of Washington— but I am told there are members who are intimidated by Fed lan guage, by the members of the Fed, and I understand that com pletely. I think that the Fed is guilty of using language to intimi date and that is something that I think needs serious attention. I would like to testify on the impact of leaks on the financial market as you asked me to do. I would like to expand also my com ments to include what I feel to be a general lack of central bank control over the members use of the media, a lack of discipline, and how that is detrimental to the marketplace and ultimately costly to the taxpayer. I am not here to solicit sympathy for the trading community be cause I don’t think they need it, but if we can draw the line to the taxpayer maybe it makes more sense. I would also like to suggest that procedure be improved as Dr. Schwartz and Jim Meigs have done, regarding dissemination of Fed policy. My presentation is in three parts. The first concerns leaks of the outcome of the deliberations, that is the vote, and the turmoil caused by those leaks, the extreme volatility. I use the term vio lence in fact in the marketplace. As a result of these leaks, a pre mium of uncertainty is built into the interest rates (meaning high er) and the burden is carried by the taxpayer because of higher Treasury borrowing costs when auctions take place near or around the leak. Two recent leaks will serve as examples and if I have time to plow through them, I would like to. Second, I would urge change in procedure surrounding the re lease of the minutes. My view is that the directive should be released immediately after deliberations; and second I would suggest that policy not be changed until the next meeting and I would just brush on this be cause it represents a major change in Fed operating procedure, but it dovetails with the discussion. Last, other than leaks, under the Greenspan Fed, some policy makers use the media to air their own viewpoints even if at odds with current Fed policy. This is my personal view. Some policy makers seem to be intent, at this particular time, on selling them selves through the media. Second, general commentary is often ill informed and reckless. Such commentary destabilizes the financial markets every bit as much as the “leak.” This loose cannon approach must be stopped. Although Green span pledged to stop the leaks after some urging by this committee, he needs to enforce a measure of discipline on policymakers general use of the media. Let’s first address the leaks and I will skip some of this given our time constraints. The leak of May 21, 1992, carried on pages A2 and C20 of the Wall Street Journal—by the way, on several oc 56 casions I have confronted the Journal and talked to the reporter involved and, of course, the response is the same, that we are doing our job. One wonders why Reuters and Dow Jones and KnightRidder are not doing their job? This leak was carried first in the Asia edition of the Wall Street Journal. This means that while U.S. traders were asleep, prices dropped overnight on Euro and U.S. Treasury debt and fixed in come products in general, which are traded on a 24-hour basis. Short-term rates jumped, and this will give you a very practical view of the effects of a leak. Short-term rates jumped 15 to 25 basis points, which means a quarter of 1 percent, early in the U.S. trad ing day, the first half hour or so. I will always remember because it is branded on my soul, unfortunately. Bond yields, which had closed at 7.77 percent the day before closed May 21 at 7.86. Now let’s take this one more step. One-year Treasury bill rates, that averaged 4.07 on May 20, a day before, were 4.24 on May 21. In the scheme of things in fixed income markets, a 4.07 to 4.24 in 1 day on Treasury bills is a very extreme jump. Had Eurobills been auctioned that day this would have cost the U.S. taxpayer an additional $24 million, which is 17 kicks or basis points on the average size of $14 billion, due to this leak-induced spike in rates. It was pure luck that the $10 million, 30-year issue which was auctioned on May 7, was not auctioned on May 21. We would have had then 30 years of additional cost. I mention David Jones in the next statement. He is a wellregarded Fed watcher, if you like, and he works for a Wall Street firm. His book, “Politics of Money, The Fed Under Alan Green span,” is a good one. When referring to the turmoil from the Thanksgiving Day fiasco in November 1989, he said that “The uncertainty almost certainly was reflected in higher average Treasury borrowing costs in the pe riod immediately following the Thanksgiving fiasco, than otherwise would have been the case.” This so-called fiasco was not a leak, but it was a cause of extreme volatility, because of a Fed miscue in open market operations. In addition the Wall Street Journal reporter or reporters didn’t bother to talk to the Fed before reporting the story that the Fed had eased. The Fed had not eased and through subsequent open market operations indicated that, and the market settled back. But the difference in these two is that the first was an honest mistake. Leaks are not honest mistakes. The end result is the same, however; extreme market volatility and ultimately higher costs to the taxpayer. Let’s examine one more leak. The infamous leak of May 24, 1993. That was a very effective leak because through this leak, the Fed told all of us that they are on the ball, they will snug at the first indication of inflation. It was in fact very effective. It put a cap on long-term rates by saying the second we see any indication of an inflation problem, we will snug. 57 The markets had taken a nosedive on May 21 just previous to this date when minutes of the March meeting were released. So there is an example of what might happen the day of release. At any rate, on that day, rates on short-term debt jumped 10 to 15 basis points and bonds, after fluctuating wildly, closed a half point lower in price. That was on the day of the leak. This story was first carried again in the Asia edition of the Wall Street Jour nal. So when U.S. markets came to work, they saw significant losses. Approximately 12 billion 6-month bills were auctioned at an av erage rate of 3.19 percent versus 3.10 on May 17, at the previous auction, for an additional cost of $11 million to the taxpayer. It could be argued that all of that cost was not necessarily due to that leak, but a good part of it was. The leak was followed by a May 27 CNBC story, placed by a Fed source, which gave an actual trigger for tightening; that is, if the CPI goes up 0.04, we will snug. There was more violence in the marketplace, higher rates. Rates recovered from the May 24 leak, and then fluctuated wild ly. All this due to uncertainty. The 39 recognized dealers on Wall Street, were extremely nervous. They are reluctant to inventory debt, and that drives up rates. Again pure luck that other scheduled U.S. Treasury debt did not come on these days. We intend to study the amount of private debt that is associated around the leak dates, and what additional costs were incurred. Had the 30-year bond issued on May 13 been auctioned May 31, it could have cost the taxpayer $4 million to $12 million annually for the next 30 years. My view is not an extreme one. Let’s look at another view. On July 6, speaking of this leak to Market News Service, a reputable news organization, David Resler, chief economist to Nomura Securities in New York stated, "To se lect particular news organizations to divulge the contents of the meeting is criminal ana absolutely immoral. The offending mem bers should be subject to incredibly severe penalties, including being expelled from the Federal Reserve System, at a minimum. In light of the Fed’s leak to the Wall Street Journal, <£They might as well own Dow Jones stock.” Now, President Jordan said that the Fed—I don’t want to mis quote him here—“central banks don’t leak.” Yet, Chairman Greenspan told us that he hopes the leaks are be hind us. So there is some problem there. Let’s go next to the minutes. As Anna Schwartz and Jim have pointed out, the so-called minutes of deliberations are not real min utes. They are summaries of deliberations. My view is different from Anna’s on release. I don’t really have a problem with the full minutes being released at a later date but I have a problem with the directive. The directive is the two- or three-page summary to the New York Fed which says “Tell us if the economy is hot, cold or in-between,” do this, this or this until the next meeting. That is what I think should be released imme diately, as does Milton Friedman. 58 For example, the minutes for the meeting of August 17 go on for 14 pages. They can be longer. They say at the conclusion of the meeting, ‘The Federal Reserve Bank of New York was authorized and directed, until instructed otherwise to execute transactions in the system account in accordance with the following directive,” and the directive is about two pages. That is what we want released immediately. It is brief, gives the reason for the consensus and the action and the vote. The release should be by way of a press statement. It is true that BBK can release information immediately after meeting, but it is at their own volition. They only do so at their own volition. But what I feel is that the Fed must be compelled to release after every meeting. Milton Friedman has been a proponent of immediate release, saying, “The whole thing is absurd and unnecessary.” In discussion with my firm on October 13, he said he supports our view. There is one change I might make to Anna Schwartz' view and that is release on a Sunday night or Friday. These minutes I feel must be released on a weekday and if released on a Sunday, again the Asians and the European Community have a shot at our U.S. rates. These are traded 24 hours. They are traded in FIMEX and Japan. This information must be released early in the U.S. trading day. At that time, the Asian community is still trading and the Euro pean Community is still trading, so this is fair. Chairman Greenspan's response to this argument as we have heard here and as originally given to Congressman Neal in 1989 and repeated many times since is that the immediate release will increase market volatility. The comment was spread through the entire discussion, every single policymaker, that the problem is the immediate release will increase volatility. But if anything, nothing could be further from the truth. Under the present system we have to live with leaks almost on a weekly or monthly basis. We would much rather take our medi cine in the middle of the week after the FOMC and be done with it. The argument that immediate release would compromise the market, it is, if anything, 180 degrees from the truth. There is another problem surrounding the deliberations I would like to address just for the record; that is, the intermeeting policy changes. I think the intermeeting policy changes should be elimi nated. I think that they should say, “Look, here it is. This is the nature of the economy. This is our feeling. Here is the directive to the Board and that is it.” The current system is that the Chairman within certain param eters is allowed to change policy intermeeting. This causes vola tility. Every time we have an economic number, we wonder wheth er this numbers will trigger a change. Over 30 percent of the last 2 V2 years of policy changes have been triggered right after a nonpayroll number. They [Fed] often hinge on one number even though they say they may not. The marketplace tries to second-guess the Fed around every housing number, ever retail sales number, ever payroll number. I suggest the changes be limited only to the meeting date. 59 Last, many of these reports around which policies in fact hinge are revised several times. That makes it even more confusing. The Greenspan Fed is clearly a more democratic institution than that under Paul Volcker. On its face, this is admirable, but as Mar tha Seeger said in referring to the Fed in the Wall Street Journal, “democracy is messier than dictatorship.” As a result, during the FOMC deliberations, we hear more than ever—it seems to me more than ever before—from individual pol icymakers. This is very unfortunate. Policymaker statements in the media are sometimes reckless, ill-advised, sometimes cheerleading, and sometimes are politically motivated. All this adds unnecessary volatility and confusion to the marketplace. This can be traced back, ultimately, to the U.S. taxpayer. In May 1992, as an example, at a Civil Rights Commission Con ference in Washington, the Commission suggested to Governor Lindsey that U.S. manufacturing was in decline and Governor Lindsey responded the manufacturing is “going like gangbusters.” When the marketplace here that, that is important, rates move on that type of comment. Governor Lindsey was quoted on May 13 as saying “The economy is moving along quite well.” Again the market hinges on every single word these gentlemen say. Just to add to the confusion, on that same day, Richard Syron, a voting member of the FOMC and president of the Boston Fed, was on the news saying that “the recovery could fall apart.” This is on the same day from two policymakers. The market sold off on May 13 as a result of what we feel was either cheerleading, which I tnink is an inappropriate use of the of fice; or a total lack of knowledge of the real sector. I list for the record the actual economic numbers which I won’t go through, but they were showing an economy with decreasing vigor, an economy clearly slowing down and particularly manufac turing employment was indicated to be off. This was just preceding the Governor s commentary. Then economic numbers showed an even slower economy in June. Direct Fed surveys, housing starts, manufacturing employ ment, again, all lower. Finally the payroll number of July 2 was so weak the Fed cut the discount rate and the Fed funds on the same date. So again, this is misleading commentary. This is not “going like gangbusters,” not an economy doing “quite well,” and yet we are not just speaking of one opinion of one policy maker, but a policymaker whose commentary is taken to reflect the view of the FOMC. That is my point, that such reckless com mentary leads to violence in the market, it leads to volatility in the market, it leads to higher rates. Shall I go on? Chairman G on za lez. Sir, we have notice of a recorded vote and, therefore, if you could summarize—we would be grateful to you. Mr. C raven . I will do so. Let me say that I feel like the policymakers, most of the policy makers have not been guilty of these offenses, and other situations mentioned in the presentation, and they have the wisdom to keep it zipped for lack of a better term, between the meetings. 60 Others have not. Let me quote again from the Jones book, that some ambitious, new breed Fed policymakers have, in competition with the Fed Chairman, begun to effectively use the media and public relations to sell themselves or their own ideas perhaps in seeking recognition for future administration appointments to the Fed the Chairman’s job itself or other key government positions, through background press, and the infamous Washington leak they can advance their own policy positions. I would say in conclusion, there must be a return to discipline at the Greenspan Fed. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. [The prepared statement of Mr. Craven can be found in the appendix.] Chairman G o n z a le z . Thank you very much. I thank each and every one of you. Members who have come in and walked out and those who have not been able to be here, will have questions that they will be submitting to you. Each has a copy of your testimony. I will have only one question since I believe I saw you all here during most of the testimony by the previous panel. In your opinion, and it is just your opinion, could all of the leaks revealed today be possible without the knowledge of anyone on that first panel? Ms. S c h w a r tz . I think from the way the stories were reported it was obvious that they came from some official source. I don’t know who the official was. Mr. M eigs. I don’t know how they did it but I agree with Anna, that somebody very high in the system who knew what was going on talked to a reporter, maybe the same one more than once, you know. That is a favorite—I don’t want to make any invidious com ments about Washington, but there are those living in the rest of the country who kina of think this is the way things are done a lot in Washington. The leak is the source. Now, I think it is valuable that we get the information however we get it. I am not so—so I am sorry for the dealers who were caugnt short, the people in Asia got the word before they did, but it is just important to get the information out on what is the policy. Without a mandate, a clear mandate on what the policy should be, that expands the dimensions of all the possibilities that they react to. If they were pursuing a stable price level, policy would be set for periods of years at a time, there wouldn’t be all this fancy maneu vering and changing and speculating and leaks; there wouldn’t be needed. Mr. C ra v en . I concur. The leaks clearly came from an official source. In the last four or five—the wording of the last four or five leaks clearly came from an official source. Chairman G o n z a le z . Thank you Mr. Craven. Mr. Neal. Mr. N e a l. Yes, sir. I know we don’t have much time. I just wanted to thank Dr. Schwartz for her endorsement of our bill. Mr. Meigs, actually you didn’t mention my bill but you said the same thing. So I thank you for the sentiments also. 61 Mr. M eigs. Yes. Mr. N e a l. I remember, Dr. Schwartz, you were executive director of the Gold Commission and I was one of our Banking Committee's representative to that. I just want to thank all three of you for your help this morning. We don’t have time to get into any substance here, but I thank you all very much. Chairman G o n z a le z . Thank you, Mr. Neal. You have been most patient. We have gone right through the lunch period and it's a quarter of 2 o'clock, but I do want you to know we are very grateful. Your help is a lot more valuable than you may think and the presence or absence here of members should not in any way detract from your impression that this com mittee is not interested. Let me say that even in the present form, we have better than a dozen cosponsors on this committee, on this bill. We have 21, Dr. Auerbach tells me. Incidentally, I wish to thank him for putting these meetings together. He is the main instrument and the com mittee is very fortunate to have him on leave from the university and he at one time worked for the committee before so I think you have met him. I just wanted to give him the credit that ought to be his. Thank you again very much. The committee will stand adjourned until further call of the Chair which will be our fourth meeting next week. [Whereupon, at 1:50 p.m., the hearing was adjourned, to recon vene subject to the call of the Chair.] 73-208 0 - 94-3 63 APPENDIX October 19, 1993 64 Opening Statement by Henry B. Gonzalez Chairman Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs October 19, 1993 Third Day of Hearings on the Issues Involved in the "Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993" HR 28 ft*************************)!***)!')!'***)!'))!**************’)** Today, the Banking Committee begins the third day of hearings on issues involved in the "Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993," HR 28. I welcome Federal Reserve Chairman of the Board of Governors, Alan Greenspan; Federal Reserve governors; and presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks. Chairman Greenspan testified at our last hearing that everything proposed in our legislation, HR 28, was a "major mistake." Today we are going to hear additional testimony to see if our proposals are needed reforms or major mistakes. HR 28 requires that the FOMC: 1) 2) announce changes in its policy one week after its meetings and that it make public a complete record of those meetings 60 days after each meeting. The central issue of today’s hearing is simple: Why is the Federal Reserve, among all Federal agencies, exempt from keeping complete and accurate records? If the White House, the Supreme Court, the Defense Department and every other government agency keep accurate records of what they are doing, why not the Federal Reserve? Are decisions by these parts of our government less sensitive than those made at the Federal Reserve? You distinguished gentlemen who serve as Federal Reserve presidents, did not have to present your credentials and your views to the American public to secure your seats on the FOMC. President Jordan has previously gone through the confirmation process for his seat on the Reagan Council of Economic Advisors. I hope today’s hearing will allow the citizens of our country to learn a little bit about you and how independent your views really are. I would like each of you to tell me if you think the following information is of sufficient national importance to require recording and publication of minutes of your FOMC meetings. Last week at these hearings I cited FOMC minutes of two meetings prior to the reelection of President Richard Nixon. Those minutes were released five years after the FOMC meetings. Although he was warned that projections were for fast money growth, Federal Reserve Chairman Arthur Burns had called for even faster money growth at these meetings. Why shouldn’t the historical record reflect the truth that Burns was pursuing an inflationary policy? 1 65 The importance of accurate minutes is reflected in the records of a Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank’s board of directors meeting. The minutes reveal a possible cover-up by the Federal Reserve related to the Watergate burglary in 1972. Recall the Watergate scandal that began with the break-in of the Democratic National Committee offices in the Watergate office building on June 17, 1972. A dangerous political crisis rocked our country while Congress sought to uncover the facts, including who financed the break-in. I read now from page 77 of the June 22, 1972 minutes of the Philadelphia Federal Reserve Bank’ s Board of Directors meeting: "Mr [X] reported that $6,300 in one hundred dollar bills had been found on the persons arrested for breaking into the Democratic National Committee headquarters in Washington. The FBI came to this Bank and said that ten new 3-C notes [$100 bills] numbered in sequence were among those found. This Bank informed the FBI that they were part of a shipment sent to the Girard Bank on April 3. Mr. [X] also said that the Washington Post had called to verify a rumor that these bills were stolen from this Bank. The Post was informed of the CV&D thefts but told they involved old bills that were ready for destruction. Mr. [X] said that Chairman Burns doesn’t want the System to get involved and issued a directive to all Reserve banks on June 21, which said, in effect, that the System was cooperating with law enforcement agencies but should not disclose any information to others." Three days earlier, Chairman Burns had written the following to the Joint Economic Committee about rumors regarding the sources of funds used to finance the Watergate burglars: "We at the Board have no knowledge of the Federal Reserve bank which issued those particular notes or of the commercial bank to which they were transferred. Without this information, there is nothing that we can do to comply with your request." The apparent lie to The Washington Post reporter, as a result of the directive issued by the Chairman of the Federal Reserve, may have been part of a cover-up of important information by the Federal Reserve. Did the Federal Reserve ever inform the U.S. Congress about these bills it had traced that were found on the Watergate burglars? If the answer is "No" it appears that the Federal Reserve blocked the public and the Congress from a significant part of the investigation of the financing of the Watergate burglars. The acting director of the FBI, who may have been given the information, testified that he burned some Watergate files. The Nixon administration asked him to limit the FBI’s investigation of the burglars’ financing on the grounds that further inquiry would "uncover CIA assets and sources." That sounds familiar. What was the Federal Reserve’s role in this coverup? Did the Federal Reserve deliberately obstruct the Congress and the public? 2 66 If we only had a formal directive giving the extremely truncated version of these meetings, as the FOMC publishes today, there would not be a historical record of these events. The American public and the Congress are not the barbarians at your gates. These are the people whom you must serve. Our expert witnesses testifying today will tell you that, contrary to what Chairman Greenspan testified about at our last hearing, accurate information does not undermine markets. Partial information and leaked information undermines market efficiency. I want to highlight the astounding claim in Dr. Anna Schwartz’ s testimony: "The Wall Street Journal has reported the contents of the directive within a week of each of 11 out of 34 FOMC meetings that were held between March 1989 and May 1993." Since substantial information is already coming out in leaked form, why should we pretend that it a closely guarded secret? We need a straight-forward record with complete and accurate information. Some claim we have all the information necessary in the formal directive that is issued five or six weeks after each FOMC meeting. That directive is sometimes called "minutes." However, the FOMC directive is far from a complete record and it is equivalent to the kind of information we would get if the Supreme Court only announced its decisions and not its opinions. Although the directive does contain the FOMC vote, those who understand the Federal Reserve know the objective in any FOMC meeting is to get a unanimous final vote regardless of any underlying disagreement. Publishing only the final vote at FOMC meetings is little more information than could be obtained from the Congress if we issued only the vote on adjournment and none of the discussion. In order to obtain a record that establishes individual accountability, there must be a more detailed record. Most of the socalled "minutes" the Federal Reserve now issues are boiler-plate reports on the economy that anyone could copy out of government and newspaper reports. In 1976, the FOMC members arbitrarily announced that they had stopped taking minutes of their meetings. In response to his inquiries, Congressman Steve Neal investigated and reported that among the 55 individuals who opposed the FOMC’s decision to stop taking minutes were four former Federal Reserve Governors and two former presidents of Federal Reserve Banks. One of the strongest letters was from Jerry L. Jordan, formerly an official at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and here today as president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. His letter of October 21, 1976 said: "As an economist in the Federal Reserve for over eight years, I found the "memoranda of discussion" [the name for the minutes] to be extremely useful. Even when I attended the FOMC meetings I always reviewed the memoranda of previous meetings as part of the preparation for the next meeting. 3 67 The President of the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank was definitely influenced in a very positive way by the existence of a permanent record that would eventually be made public. It helped him and his staff to maintain intellectual honesty, sometimes in the face of great pressure to bend. He knew that even when his views fell on deaf ears in a meeting, consistent analysis of the problem and the recommendation of solutions would be in the record to be viewed with historical perspective." I want to know why minutes which were clearly helpful up until 1976, suddenly became harmful after 1976. I understand the peculiar position of the distinguished presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks who are testifying today. I had thought that last week Chairman Greenspan would have emphasized that you serve as independent coequals on the FOMC. However, he contends that the "ultimate defense against a bank president ... is the power [by the Board of Governors] to remove that person from office." I think this says a great deal about your independence. Nevertheless, I hope that our distinguished witnesses will give their honest views today and that they will be perfectly frank while their comments are being recorded. I look forward to your testimony. 4 68 STATEMENT BY REPRESENTATIVE JAMES A. LEACH Before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs Hearing on Reforming the Federal Reserve System October 19, 1993 Today we hear from ten presidents o f the Federal Reserve District Banks and six Governors o f the Federal Reserve Board. Given that these individuals influence the allocation and expansion o f credit, not only through their member ship on the Federal Open Market Committee (F O M C ) but through their regula tion o f the banking industry, it is important to note in the context o f a hearing on reform ing the Federal Reserve System that the American public is served by individuals represented here o f distinctive quality and integrity. We w elcom e them in a spirit o f appreciation and trust. Here, I appreciate the sense o f history the Chairman brought in his opening comm ents, but it should be noted that no member o f this panel has in any sense been tarred by Watergate. All have agreed to appear voluntarily with no implica tion o f wrongdoing. Given the braintrust assembled, I am only sorry the subject matter isn't the state o f the econom y and at the risk o f presumption, I might sug gest the panel — or a representative grouping — be invited back, perhaps in a Humphrey-Hawkins context to discuss the economy. At the first two hearings, this Committee gave deserved attention to the political science predicament o f Reserve Bank presidents, who are assigned a particular public responsibility but are selected by boards comprised in the m ajor ity by individuals not only from the private sector but one element o f it. In de fense o f this selection m ethodology the Federal Reserve System can properly point to a tradition o f independence, quality, and political insulation. Neverthe less, there is an element o f unseemliness inherent in a system in which sectors o f the public may view their interest as distinct from that o f the banking sector, in particular when individuals are asked to regulate an industry while being ac countable to boards o f directors controlled by members o f that industry. While I have a high regard for current leadership o f the Fed and the direc tion it is currently m oving on the regulatory front, it may be useful to point out three areas where the Federal Reserve System in the past has instituted discrimi natory regulatory policies. First, in the late seventies and early eighties, the Fed went along with the large money center banks in believing that sovereign guaran tees were ironclad because governments never go broke and, accordingly, im posed lesser regulation on LDC debt. Second, the Fed has continued to assume that large banks, because o f their large deposit and lending bases, need less capi tal than smaller banks. And, third, it has not required bad loans at large banks to be written o f f as rapidly as regulators require comparably bad loans at smaller banks. M y view is that discriminatory regulation skews the financial landscape and amounts to credit allocation. The irony in regulation being too accom m odat ing, i f not cozy, with individual banks is that management becom es misserved. For instance, N ew York money center banks for decades have been on the cutting edge o f wanting to see liberalization o f the Douglas Amendment and McFadden Act so that they could branch interstate. When interstate barriers started to fall, 69 w ithout C ongressional m odification o f these law s, many o f the m oney center banks w ere in no position to take advantage o f the liberalization because their capital had been so dram atically depleted. T his w as due, in part, to lending m is takes w hich w ere in effect sanctioned by regulators. If regulators on a tim ely basis had insisted on stronger capital ratios for international lending or m oved promptly to force recapitalization w hen problem loans, dom estic as w ell as foreign, d ev el oped, these institutions w ould be larger and stronger today. It is instructive to note that federal regulators, albeit a little late, forced B ank o f A m erica to restructure and recapitalize approxim ately five years before they served com parable notice on the Hast coast. Bank o f A m erica later credited regulator sternness w ith its turnaround and w ith its ability by the end o f the decade o f the 1980's to launch an expansionary drive. O ne o f the lesso n s o f the S&L debacle is that capital m oves toward institu tion s or industries w hich have the w eakest regulation. The problem o f regulator driven deposit skew ing w as m ost evident in the 1980's in the thrift industry w hen institutions w ere allow ed to leverage minimal and in som e ca ses non -existen t capital bases. It is, how ever, a not inconsequential problem today w ithin the banking industry. For exam ple, one ram ification o f over reliance on the B a sle A ccord standards is that the more attention given to risk w eigh tin g assets, the less reliance national bank regulators are putting on the lever age ratio. O ver-reliance on risk-based capital standards w ithout use o f an adequate leverage ratio leads to com petitive inequities in deposit seek in g and de facto credit allocation o f those deposits. The fact that state bank regulators rely more on lever age ratios than federal regulators m eans that deposits w ill flow to national banks rather than state banks, to m oney center institutions rather than com m unity banks, to bond buying instead o f entrepreneurial lending. Here, the anom aly exits as in virtually all regulated circum stances that regu latory agencies have a vested interest in the com petitive vitality o f the institutions they regulate. H ence, i f the Fed w ants to keep, w hich I support, a major regulatory function, it m ust be careful to insure that con flicts, perceived or otherw ise, do not ex ist, that regional inequities are not allow ed to develop, and that advantages are not provided one kind o f institution over another. A s m entioned earlier, one o f the lesso n s o f the S&L crisis w as that disparity in regulation sk ew s capital flow s. A nother w as the conclusion by C ongress that it had been a mistake to allo w the 12 district banks o f the Federal H om e Loan Bank System w ith boards com prised in the majority o f representatives from member institutions a principal role in the regulatory process. A ccordingly, as part o f the S& L cleanup in FIR R EA , C ongress abolished the regulatory functions o f the FH LB system and transferred them to an o ffice w hich has its director publicly appointed. A s w e consider regulatory consolidation, there is a case for and against providing continuation o f regulatory responsibility for the Federal R eserve System, B ut if it is to be preserved, an institutional arrangement must be established w hich g iv e s no hint o f s e lf -regulation, o f the fo x guarding the foxes. In a country in w h ich process is our m ost important product it sim ply is unacceptable for regula tors, in any sen se, to be accountable to boards w hich in tum are controlled by the regulated. I look forward to the testim on y o f today’s w itn esses. - 30 - 70 OPENING STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ERIC D . FINGERHUT b e f o r e the COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS o f the U .S HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES on OCTOBER 1 9 , Thank you Mr. Chairman. 1993 Throughout my career, I have been a strong and outspoken advocate of government reform. A regular, in-depth examinationn of the operations of all branches of government, including this institution, of representative democracy. is in the best traditions For example, I believe instituting congressional reform will restore our credibility with the public and enable us to address the serious problems facing our country. Until the country believes in the process once again, our attempts to make difficult decisions will continue to be stalled by a wall of public cynicism. However, a re-examination of all levels of government does not mean we always need to take action. I do not believe in reform for reform's sake. It is from this perspective that I have approached these hearings. After listening to the witnesses and studying the testimony, particularly that of Chairman Greenspan, reached some conclusions. I have While there is always room for improvement in the procedures of the Federal Reserve, of one thing: the Federal Reserve is working. I am sure During the last 12 years, while the executive and legislative branches quadrupled our national debt, interest rates. the Fed whipped inflation and brought down In fact, the Fed has done their job so well, that when inflation crept over just 4% earlier this year, most of us 71 were startled. I am also convinced that this outcome is a result of the independent status of the Fed. The ability to focus on long term stability is compromised when political pressures interfere. The short-term economic benefits of decisions based on political expediency are far outweighed by the inflationary costs which inevitably occur after a lag. International comparisons confirm this relationship between Central Bank independence and low inflation rates. Fed, Before we change the decision process of the I want to be sure we are not risking the soundness of our monetary policy. This should not be interpreted as a blanket approval of all of the Fed's actions. It is not. Most of the reforms Chairman Gonzalez has proposed are modest and would not do irreparable harm to our monetary policy. For example, I believe publishing the minutes of the FOMC's meetings on a more timely basis would reduce information uncertainty and increase market efficiency. However, I am concerned that Congress has once again taken up a more glamorous and high profile issue at the expense of others which are more mundane, but more substantial. easing the credit crunch, instituting community banking, for business, I believe reducing burdensome bank regulations, and creating a secondary market commercial and community development loans would go a long way to stimulating our economy and building a base for long and sustainable growth. Reforming the Federal Reserve processes adds nothing to that fundamental responsibility of government and may indeed detract from it. 72 I thank Chairman Gonzalez for raising these issues. this issue is very important to the Chairman. I know I would only urge this Committee not to get sidetracked when the American economy deserves our full attention. 73 OPENING REMARKS FOR REP. SAM JOHNSON BANKING COMMITTEE HEARING ON FEDERAL RESERVE OVERSIGHT - OCTOBER 19, 1993 THANK YOU MR. CHAIRMAN: I LOOK FORWARD TO THIS HEARING TODAY TO HOPEFULLY GET A NEW PERSPECTIVE ON POSSIBLE CHANGES TO THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM. I WOULD LIKE TO THANK ALL OF THE WITNESSES FOR BEING HERE TODAY AND ESPECIALLY RECOGNIZE MR. BOB MCTEER, THE PRESIDENT OF THE DALLAS FEDERAL RESERVE BANK. AS WE CONSIDER LEGISLATION TO OPEN THIS SYSTEM , I FEEL THAT IT IS ESSENTIAL TO HAVE INPUT FROM ALL THOSE EFFECTED. FURTHERMORE, I FEEL THAT WE SHOULD NOT CHANGE THIS SYSTEM UNLESS IT IS ABSOLUTELY NECESSARY. 74 HOWEVER, I DO HAVE SOME CONCERNS WITH REGARD TO THE REGIONAL RESERVE BANKS. I AM CONCERNED THAT SOME BANKS, SPECIFICALLY NEW YORK, HAVE MORE SAY IN DOMESTIC MONETARY POLICY AND INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY POLICY THAN OTHER FED. BANKS. I AM ALSO CONCERNED THAT THE CURRENT GAO AUDITS ARE NOT REVEALING TO THE TAXPA YERS REAL AND UNNECESSARY SPENDING BY THE REGIONAL BANKS. FOR EXAMPLE, IS ANY GAO AUDIT GOING TO REVEAL THE $200,000 THE DALLAS FEDERAL RESERVE IS SPENDING TO RENOVATE THEIR GUN RANGE IN THE BASEMENT? I HOPE THE REGIONAL PRESIDENTS CAN GIVE ME SOME INSIGHT ON THESE CONCERNS. THANK YOU MR. CHAIRMAN. 75 Opening statement of Congresswoman Lucille R oybal-Allard Banking Com m ittee Hearing on the Federal Reserve, # 3 O ctober 19, 1993 Mr. Chairman, I want to com m end you for holding these hearings on H.R. 28, legislation which w ould establish accountability on behalf o f the Federal Reserve. This is a bill which merits serious attention and I look forward to hearing our expert testimony. Specifically, I am anxious to hear how the Federal Reserve intends to im prove its record o f minority and wom en hiring. Last week, Chairman Greenspan highlighted the sluggish pace at which wom en and minorities have m oved into the top echelons o f the federal reserve. I concur with the Chairman that this problem , which exists throughout our society, is very damaging. In order to rectify pervasive discrimination, we must make the necessary changes now-- and wherever possible, change must be applied equally to all areas o f the federal government, including the Federal Reserve. Mr. Chairman, for twenty-nine years the Federal Reserve has been exempted from com pliance o f Title VII o f the Civil Rights Act o f 1964. This exemption has effectively allowed the Fed to view the matter o f minority and wom en hiring as merely a goal, not a directive. T here is no good reason for this exemption to remain-- it must be repealed and the time for change is now. Mr. Chairman, I look forward to working with the com m ittee as we consider H .R. 28 and as we examine the Federal R eserve’s dismal perform ance with regard to the hiring and prom oting o f w om en and minorities. 76 For R e l e a s e on D e l i v e r y 10:00 A.M. EDT Octob er 19, 1993 T e s t i m o n y by Alan Greenspan Chai rman B o ard of G o v e r n o r s of the F e d er al R e s e r v e System b ef ore the Committee on Banking, U.S. H o use Finance and U r b a n A f f a i r s of R e p r e s e n t a t i v e s Oct o b e r 19, 1993 77 I ap p reciate t h is on t h e a p p r o p r i a t e Market Committee of fu lle r and d e c i s i o n s has b een a c o n t r o v e r s i a l In C o n g r e s s , academia, t o p i c has been d e b a t e d th is The FOMC i t s e l f procedures in th is the f i n a n c i a l m arkets, has r e v ie w e d area f r e q u e n t l y p ractices several balance: The a p p r o p r i a t e d e g r e e strik in g th e p r o v i d e my v ie w s by t h e F e d e r a l Open or more i m m e d ia te d i s c l o s u r e h isto ric a lly . years. to (FOMC). The i s s u e FOMC d i s c u s s i o n s opportunity d e gr ee o f d i s c l o s u r e tim e s. p o lic ie s and has At t h e h e a r t effectiv e one and r e p e a t e d ly over the its and r ev ise d of th is o f openness r i g h t b a l a n c e bet ween t h e know and th e need f o r of issu e is comes from p u b lic 's po licym a kin g its rig h t to and im p le m e n ta tion . In a d e m o c r a t i c s h o u l d be i n t h e open, so ciety , p u b lic ‘ p o licy e x c e p t where e x p o s u r e prim ary f u n c t i o n a s s i g n e d to an i n s t i t u t i o n A ccord in gly, th e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e makes i t s im m ediately, e x c e p t when d o i n g so effica cy of p o licy process. requ irem en ts, we e s t a b l i s h those discount d ecisio n s fo rth we p u b l i s h a o n e -d a y l a g , c on sid e rab le are pro m p tly in our b a l a n c e enablin g a n a ly s ts i m p le m e n tin g d e c i s i o n s w i t h operation s. rate our reports sheet to p o licy However, once. When g ro w th , those to Congress. e v e r y week w i t h j u s t r e v i e w our o p e r a t i o n s im m ediately are th e respect any c h an g es operation s. d e lib eration s a fter o f the p o li c y or r e s e r v e announced a t to our sig n a lle d And we p u b l i s h m i n u t e s and d e c i s i o n s the next open market in our o b j e c t i v e s r e s e r v e m arkets a r e q u i c k l y and p u b l i c l y s h ortly pu b lic d e ta il. What we do n o t d i s c l o s e open market d e c isio n s could undercut the new r an g es f o r money and c r e d i t ranges are s e t Moreover, im pedes t h e by la w. or compromise t h e i n t e g r i t y When we change t h e d e cisio n s in by our o f the fr om ea c h FOMC m e e t i n g r e g u l a r m e e t i n g has ta k e n p l a c e . in 78 - T h e se m i n u t e s , 1993, a copy o f which f o r I h av e a t t a c h e d more th an 30 p a g e s , e con om ic f a c t o r s approaches to in d irect The o p e r a t i o n s these p o s i t i o n where in h ib it c o m p le t e I o f c e n t r a l banks have a o ften openness or ev en t h w a r t t h e oth er o f the nature o f a c e n t r a l and f o r e i g n in stitu tio n s lik e o f being s e c r e t i v e . a resu lt i m p a ct on f i n a n c i a l th erefo re, o f the p o licy r e a c h i n g our d e c i s i o n s . the Federal Reserve, la rg e ly bank’ s m issio n . can run fr om 15 t o and a l t e r n a t i v e h as a r e p u t a t i o n is th e m e e tin g o f F e b r u a r y , statem ent, and a n a l y s i s N ev erth eless, th is th is p r e s e n t i n g a com prehensi ve r e c o r d considered c e n t r a l banks, suspect 2- exchange m a r k e t s ; fin d them selves and d i s c l o s u r e im p le m e n t a t io n in the could of th eir p u b lic purpose. Suppose, by t a r g e t i n g the be a p p r o p r i a t e the fu tu re. that the rate bank p h r a se d i t s p la n s--th a t the is, if certain a p a rticu la r changes e ffe c tiv e ly More b r o a d l y , bank t h a t operated it m ig h t a given p o in t clo ser t o home, i n ter m s economic in sa y of or f i n a n c i a l a c t i o n would be t a k e n . im m ediately, carried at p o lic ie s t h o s e d e c i s i o n s were made p u b l i c , fr o m b e i n g m arkets would ten d t o preven tin g the p o l i c i e s out as pla n n e d . im mediate d i s c l o s u r e of these types c o n t i n g e n c i e s would t en d t o pro duce i n c r e a s e d v o l a t i l i t y in f i n a n c i a l only to m arkets, actual as market p a r t i c i p a n t s action s. expresses a p re d isp o sitio n d irective to exam ple tow ard e a s i n g , rather It is o ft e n the toward a p o l i c y t h e Open Market D esk. concerned about p o lic y r e a c t e d n ot Fed eral Reserve a c t io n s but a ls o F ed eral Reserve fo r a central exchange r a t e d e c id e d t h a t change t h e t a r g e t prev ailed , in corporate of ex am p le, to b r in g the d is c u s s io n cen tral con d ition s If to O r, con tin gency fo r fo reig n im p lies p o ssible t h e FOMC change i n i t s Such a p r e d i s p o s i t i o n , t h a t t h e FOMC i s more d e v e lo p m e n t s t h a t would d i c t a t e than a t i g h t e n i n g , to c a se t h a t an e a s i n g and t h e r e f o r e wants t o of 79 -3respo n d rela tiv ely p r o m p tly t o need f o r such a c t i o n . w ithout in fo rm a tio n We o f t e n any change i n express instrum ent In such c i r c u m s t a n c e s , the settin g s re le a se s u g g e s tin g the th is p r e d isp o sitio n in o f those fa ct resu ltin g . directives d u r i n g t h e p e r i o d t h e y a r e i n f o r c e would o n l y add t o flu ctu a tio n s immediate in f i n a n c i a l m ark e ts, As a c o n s e q u e n c e , i m p a ir t h e u s e f u l n e s s members, a d isc lo su re r e q u ir e m e n t would o f the d i r e c t i v e s , a s Committee c on c e rn e d about t h e announcement e f f e c t d irective tend to moving r a t e s when no change was i n t e n d e d . b iased eith er toward e a s e shy away from a n y t h i n g b u t a v o t e change or o f no change a t t h e m e e t i n g . of fle x ib ilit y of would im mediate An i m p o r t a n t e l e m e n t i n t h e c u r r e n t p r o c e d u r e s would be l o s t , which can s c a r c e l y d isclo su re of a or t i g h t e n i n g , serve the p u b lic o f t h e d i r e c t i v e would mon eta ry p o l i c y m a k i n g , and i t in te re st. Immediate change t h e n a t u r e of would n ot be a change f o r the b etter. To r e p e a t , p u b lic in stitu tio n s as a g e n e r a l m a t t e r , to con d u ct t h e i r The F e d e r a l R e s e r v e e n d o r s e s it, th is it is b u sin e ss p rin c ip le d esira ble for i n t h e open . and a d h e r e s to e x c e p t when do in g so would p r e v e n t us fr o m f u l f i l l i n g our fu n d am en tal m i s s i o n o f p r o d u c i n g sound p u b l i c H o l d i n g open m e e t i n g s v id e o ta p e , a ud io t a p e , seriou sly con strain a irin g o f v iew s, te n tativ e o f th e FOMC or r e l e a s i n g or t r a n s c r i p t the pro cess render th ose m eetings the f o r t h r i g h t M on etary p o l i c y would s u f f e r , o f form ulating sim ply g i v e and t a k e , as t o and t h e and t h e economy w i t h c u rren tly c o u ld n o t be m en tio n ed i n We would no l o n g e r have th e b e n e f i t fr om f o r e i g n p o licy The c a n d id l i k e l y wo uld d i s a p p e a r . A number o f i m p o r t a n t i t e m s FOMC m e e t i n g s a o f them would so n early unprod uctive. p o s i n g o f new i d e a s p o licy . c e n t r a l banks and o t h e r at open forum . of sen sitive o fficia l it. discussed in form ation in stitu tio n s 80 - k - or o f p ro p rie ta ry as we c o u l d n o t in con fiden ce. in fin a n cia l in form ation risk Moreover, have t o o p tio n s. avoid prevent verbatim record problem , but econom ic g i v e n us c r e a t in g unnecessary v o l a t i l i t y o f th e f u l l w o u ld , the v o i c i n g in t h e FOMC m igh t range o f p o l i c y effe ct, become s e l f o f any v ie w s t h a t m igh t the m arkets. Even a l a g i n releasin g a o f t h e m e e t i n g s would n o t e l i m i n a t e t h i s only a tte n u a te p rescrip tion s su rfaced to sources, o f in form ation exchange m a r k e ts , Our d i s c u s s i o n s censored to be to exploration s p ro ve u n s e t t l i n g fo r the p u b lic a t io n and f o r e i g n fo rgo from p r i v a t e - s e c t o r it. and r u m i n a t i o n s U n c o n v e n ti o n a l p o l i c y about t h e l o n g e r - t e r m outlook and f i n a n c i a l market develo p m en ts m ight n e v e r at m eetin gs, fo r fear of ig n itin g a sp ecu lative r e a c t i o n when t h e d i s c u s s i o n was d i s c l o s e d . L e t me t a k e a moment t o process fo llo w ed at m on e ta ry p o l i c y . d e v e lo p m e n t s d iscu ssion tio n a l mon eta ry p o l i c y evalu ate we t h e n the in , c on sid e ratio n s. The R e s e r v e new i d e a s either amount o f f r e e are o ft e n in itiated t h e U. S . in tern a In l i g h t c o n s i d e r whether th e s t a n c e t h e f u t u r e unde r p a r t i c u l a r Ideas a roundtable begin s. outlook fo r q u e s t i o n i n g by t h e p a r t i c i p a n t s r e je c te d . on of recent where r e l e v a n t , key FOMC s t a f f members t a k e s p l a c e . debate, the and deve lo p m en ts w i t h i n n eeds t o be a d j u s t e d , A con sid e rab le probing trends, participants and f i n a n c i a l d iscu ssion , in presen tatio n s con d ition s members b r i n g econom ic reach d e c i s i o n s and b o t h t h e y and th e members o f t h e Board go on t o A ll p ossibly nineteen describe d istricts, economy. staff to and em erg ing economic o f Governors th is A fter of a ll Bank p r e s i d e n t s th eir d e s c r i b e more f u l l y FOMC m e e t i n g s tested, of of im m ediately, or circum stances. discu ssion and o f each o t h e r and o f In t h e w i d e - r a n g i n g many o f which a re by one p a r t i c i p a n t a r e f r e q u e n t l y 81 b u ilt upon by o t h e r s . in valu ab le in gred ie n t This typ e As I i n d i c a t e d b e f o r e p r e v a i l i n g v ie w s in sig h ts of discourse th is an Committee l a s t o f many p a r t i c i p a n t s emerge. is o f our p o l i c y m a k i n g p r o c e s s . change as week, th e evidence and T h i s p r o c e s s has proven t o be a v e r y effectiv e procedure f o r d irective to t h e Open Market Desk can be c r a f t e d . n ot f u n c t i o n that e ffe c tiv e ly g a i n i n g a c o n s e n s u s around which a if p articip an ts t h e i r h a l f - t h o u g h t -t h r o u g h , but n o n e th e le s s v a lu a b le, be a s t e r i l e in set such a s i t u a t i o n po licym a kin g. the p u b lic requ ired A te n d e n c y would a r i s e m eeting d i s c u s s i o n s , with p u b lic or f o r th e m e e ti n g w i t h a f i n a l p o sition v ie w s of oth ers. It because action s. t h a t v o te are a l s o This i s recorded, recorded. the t h e i r v ie w s and t h e r e a s o n s In t h e fo r In b o t h t h e Freedom o f m eetings that t h e m i n u t e s we v o i c e d which v ie w s escape contrary by name, to f a c t . and th e In t h e c a s e case record w i l l of a o f a vote is cast o f t h e m in u t e s accu rately r eflec t v o t in g as th ey d i d . Inform atio n Act t h e Government i n t h e S u n s h in e A c t , recognized th at the le ss p u b lish . t h e members r e v i e w d r a f t s a ssu r e th em selves t h a t the to to r e a s o n i n g b e h in d t h e v o t e explained s e p a r a t e l y . w ith the m a jo r i t y , to th eir from t h e m a j o r i t y , g en erally su b ject t h e FOMC members t h e m s e l v e s fo r o f each FOMC member i s reasons fo r not i n d i c a t e which i n d i v i d u a l s the m e e tin g s, dissent each p a r t i c i p a n t than t h e m in u t e s we c u r r e n t l y a c c o u n ta b ility o n e -o n -o n e p r e Such a r e c o r d would be f a r has been a v e r r e d t h a t , do not cap tu ring o f m on eta ry fo r enter in form ative r e c o r d would m e e t i n g s m e r e l y ann ou n cin g a l r e a d y a g r e e d -u p o n p o s i t i o n s , The v o t e p o ten tia lly o f b la n d pronouncem en ts s c a r c e l y th e n e c e s s a r y d e b a t e s which a r e at could n o t i o n s would soon be made p u b l i c . I fear rele a se It had t o be con ce rn e d t h e r e were t y p e s s h o u l d be p r o t e c t e d Congress (FOIA) and e x p lic itly o f in fo rm a tio n and k i n d s from d i s s e m i n a t i o n to of th e 82 p u b lic . Certain in form ation fin a n cia l wo uld e x e m p t i o n s have been p r o v id e d that, fo r ex am p le , n a t u r e and i n exem pted a r e a s , reasons, In th e i t was de te rm in ed t h a t rele a se re q u irin g the I b elie v e in terest. of For t h a t th e c on se q u e n ce s o f prompt r e l e a s e m e e t i n g s would most that i n f i n a n c i a l m a r k e ts . i n f o r m a t i o n would n o t be i n t h e p u b l i c sim ila r i n FOIA f o r of a con fid en tial t h e Sunsh ine A c t f o r m e e t i n g s prompt s p e c u l a t i o n variou s is o f a verbatim record certa in ly o f FOMC n o t be i n th e n a t i o n ' s best in te re st. Mr. h earin g, Chairman, you a l s o i n your l e t t e r posed s e v e r a l to t h e m a in t e n a n c e to the to t u r n now t o o f notes prem a tu re r e l e a s e or r e c o r d s in k eep in g track and t h u s reached w ith the n o te s respect are kept in th is and I would l i k e q u estio n s. I take very b r i e f , rough n o t e s These n o t e s a s s i s t o f Committee se n t i m e n t in to rela te d o f FOMC m e e t i n g s those three e x p r e s s e d by p a r t i c i p a n t s . progresses q u estion s o f FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n . t h e a nsw ers t o A t FOMC m e e t i n g s , the view s of in vitation sp e cific on me as th e m e e t i n g j u d g i n g where a con se n su s may be t o m on etary p o l i c y . a locked f i l e A fter cabinet th e m e e t i n g , a lo n g w i t h o t h e r FOMC m a t e r i a l s . O thers tak in g n o te s, th eir own r e s p o n s e s . presid en ts whatever cover a t t e n d i n g t h e FOMC m e e ti n g s may a l s o and I am s u r e t h e y w i l l that they te ll I have s u g g e s t e d be you a bout them i n t o th e R e s e r v e Bank respon d t o you r q u e s t i o n s r e g a r d i n g r e c o r d s may be k e p t a t t h e i r own Banks; r e c o r d s made by t h e Board s t a f f , and. I w ill in p a r t i c u l a r , by t h e FOMC s e c r e t a r i a t . Some i n d i v i d u a l members o f t h e Board s t a f f h an dw ritten n otes and r e t a i n d isch arg in g t h e ir resp o n sib ilitie s. recorded audio ele c tro n ic a lly tapes a r e u s ed t o take them t o h e l p them i n The m e e t i n g s a r e by th e FOMC s e c r e t a r i a t . These a ssist o f th e in the p rep ara tion 83 -7m inutes th a t a re r e l e a s e d subsequent m eeting; In t h e process tra n scrip t is on s e l e c t e d the p u b lic discussed are over. an u n e d i t e d as a r e d e t a i l e d in the course notes o f the m eeting. g e n e r a l l y a r e s e e n o n l y by t h e in p r e p a r i n g t h e m i n u t e s , the recorded the m in u tes, pr ep ar ed from t h e t a p e s , top ics fo llo w in g the tapes of p u ttin g to g eth er T h ese m a t e r i a l s in volved to thereafter, staff and t h e do cuments a re k e p t un der l o c k and ke y by t h e FOMC s e c r e t a r i a t . With r e g a r d t o your f i n a l in form ation about FOMC m e e t i n g s , s t r o n g v ie w t h a t any u n a u t h o r i z e d is a very seriou s m atter. c le a rly u n fair to Lea ks th e p u b l i c , policym aking p r o c e s s , query, on t h e I would a g a i n rele ase rele ase state of my o f FOMC d e c i s i o n s o f FOMC p r o c e e d i n g s p o ten tia lly d isru p tive and u n d o u b t e d ly d e s t r u c t i v e are o f the o f pu blic c o n f i d e n c e i n th e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e . Any l e a k s t h a t may have o c c u r r e d were most a s s u r e d l y not o r c h e s t r a t e d d elib erate current p o lic ie s in form ation that call fo r a re i n p l a c e f o r p rev iou sly . by t h e FOMC. d elayed to d iffe re n t. In some c a s e s . t h e p r e s s may b e l i e v e r e c e n t monetary p o l i c y c o n sid e ra tio n s to experienced c on fid en tial s o m e th i n g q u i t e FOMC p a r t i c i p a n t s who s p e a k t o d e cisio n s, b u t t h e y may i n a llo w c o n c lu s io n s several it is esp ecia lly sources. We s h o u l d n o t we cannot and sh o u ld n o t w a l l our o b l i g a t i o n o urselves to f a c t have p o licy t o be drawn, sp e ak in g to situ a tio n . o f the i n f o r m a t i o n a b o u t our d e c i s i o n s . fr om t h e m edia ; of t h e y have r e v e a l e d n o t h i n g a b o u t reporters p u t s us i n a d i f f i c u l t of I in d icated what a ppear t o be represent i n a d v e r t e n t l y p r o v i d e d enough o f a s e n s e tim e, as Our p o lic ie s. an e x t e n t , l e a k s may i n s t e a d A repugnant. release good r e a s o n s , l e a k s undermine t h e s e I suspect t h a t, fo r is They a r e grounded on an a s s u m p t i o n c o n fid e n tia lity ; d e lib era te or d i r e c t e d prem ature l e a k o f i n f o r m a t i o n This reveal A t t h e same o ff explain en tire ly t h e broad 84 - con sid e ratio n s t h a t m o t i v a t e monetary p o l i c y , c e r ta in m isim p re ssio n s. p o ssib le, w ithout v io la tin g 8- and t o r o i l i n g m arkets, the t r u s t of fu rth er unauthorized steps the n e c e s s i t y during the periods other tim e s . fu tu r e o f avoid ing a fu ll it and curb any We have r e has been made c l e a r I perso n ally o f FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n , p u b lic caution t h a t any in clu d e to about the can a s s u r e you t h a t th is in past I have or t o o t h e r members resu lts o f an FOMC s c h e d u le d release. statem ent, howev er: of I would From t im e I have b r i e f e d members o f v a r i o u s A d m i n i s t r a t i o n s outcom es a ssist o f FOMC m e e t i n g s , them i n f o r w hich t h e y have h ow ev er , as the to in clu de p lay ed a p a r t th e p r e s s the fo r m a l, one f o o t n o t e tim e , I to that w i l l attendees. any i n f o r m a t i o n about t h e m eeting p r i o r not, ex ten sively, con tact w ith the p ress in vestigation n e v e r k n o w i n g ly r e l e a s e d could issu e o f in fo rm a tio n . sworn s t a t e m e n t s from a l l As t o w h e th e r to as or l e a k fro m an FOMC m e e ti n g w i l l be f o l l o w e d up v e r y g ath erin g the th is s u r r o u n d i n g FOMC m e e ti n g s and o f M oreover, a g g re ssiv e ly --b y le a k s creatin g i n e q u itie s , t h a t we b e l i e v e w i l l rele a se em p ha sized at correct our c o l l e a g u e s . The FOMC h as d i s c u s s e d we have t a k e n s e v e r a l to convey as much i n f o r m a t i o n Federal the b ec a u s e t h a t kn owled ge fo rm u la tio n o f government p o l i c i e s re sp o n sib ility . been a r e l e v a n t This q u a lifica tio n has one over th e p a s t y e a r or s o , R e s e r v e h as not a l t e r e d its instrum ent se ttin g s. I tru st wrong a b o u t t h i s , d e c isio n s w i l l change I substance t h e FOMC’ s p o l i c y b elie v e as a r e s u l t , that a sh ift it and d e c i s i o n s itse lf. beh ind u s . If I am of Should we have t o would be u n f o r t u n a t e , t o prompter d i s c l o s u r e o f our d e l i b e r a t i o n s w i l l d iscu ssion s is on d e la y e d d i s c l o s u r e have t o b e r e e v a l u a t e d . our p o l i c y firm ly t h e pro blem o f l e a k s adversely a f f e c t fo r o f the our and t h e r e f o r e monetary p o l i c y FEDERAL RESERVE press release For Use at 4:30 p.m. March 26, 1993 The Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Open Market Committee today released the attached minutes of the Committee meeting held on February 2-3, 1993. The minutes for each meeting of the Committee are made available a few days after the next regularly scheduled meeting and subsequently are published in the Federal Reserve Bulletin. The summary description of economic and financial conditions contained in these minutes is based solely on the information that was available to the Committee at the time of the meeting. Attachment 86 Min u t e s of the Federal O p en Market Committee M e e t i n g of February 2-3.J.993 A m e e t i n g of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in t he offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Syst e m in W ash i n gton, D.C., on Tuesday. February 2. 1993, at 2:30 p.m. and was c o n t i n u e d on Wednesday. F e bruary 3. 1993. at 9:00 a.m. P RESENT: Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Mr. Ms. Mr. Greenspan, Chairman Corrigan, Vice Chairman Angell Boehne Keehn Ke l l e y LaWare L i n dsey McTeer Mullins Phillips Stern Messrs: B r o a d d u s . Jordan. Forrestal, and Parry, A lternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee Messrs. Hoenig. Melzer. and Syron, Reserve Banks of Kansas City. respectively Presidents St. Louis, of the Federal and Boston, Mr. K o h n . Secretary and Economist Mr. Bernard. Deputy Secretary Mr. Coyne, Assistant Secretary Mr. Gillum, Assistant Secretary Mr. M a t t i n g l y f General Counsel Mr. Patrikis. Deputy General Counsel Mr. Prell, Economist Mr. Truman, Economist Messrs. R. Davis, Lang, Lindsey. Promisel, Rosenblum. Scheld. Siegman. Simpson, and Slifman. Associate Economists Mr, Ms. Ms. McDonough. Manager of the System Open Market Account G r e e n e .^Deputy Manager for Foreign Ope r a t i o n s Lovett.* Deputy Manager for Domestic Operations Mr. Ettin. Deputy Director. Division of Research and Statistics. Board of Governors Mr. Stockton. Associate Director, Division of R e s e a r c h and Statistics. Board of Governors Mr. Madigan, Assistant Director, Division of M o n e t a r y Affairs. Board of Governors 1. 2. A t t e n d e d W e d n e s d a y session only. At t e n d e d T u e s d a y session only. 87 - 2- Mr. Brady, Section Chief, Di v i s i o n of M o n e t a r y Affairs. Board of Governors Mr. Rosine. Senior Economist, D i v i s i o n of R e s e a r c h and Statisjics, Board of Governors Mr. Wiles, Secretary of the Board, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors Mr. Winn, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members. Board of^Governors Ms- Werneke, Special Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors Mr. Siciliano, Special Assistant to the General Counsel. Legal Division, Board of Governors Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Assistant, D i v i s i o n of Monetary Affairs. Board of Governors Messrs. Beebe, T. Davis. Dewald. Goodfriend, and Ms. Tschinkel, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal R e s e r v e Banks of San Francisco. Kansa s City. St. Louis. Richmond, and Atlanta, respec t i v e l y Mr. McNees, Vice President, Federal R e serve B ank of Boston Mr. Gavin, Assistant Vice President. Federal R e s e r v e B a n k of Cleveland Mr. Weber, Senior R e s e a r c h Officer, Federal R e s e r v e B a n k of M inneapolis Ms. Meulendyke, Manager. Open Mark e t Operations, Federal Reserve Bank of New York The Secretary reported that advices of the e l e c t i o n of the R eserve Bank members and alternate members of the F e deral O p e n Market C o m m i t t e e for the period c o m m encing January 1. 1993, and e n d i n g D e c e m b e r 31, 1993, had been received and that these indivi d u a l s had executed their oaths of office. The elected m e m b e r s and a l t e rnate m e m b e r s were as f o l l o w s : E. G e r a l d Corrigan, President of the Federal R e serve Ban k of N ew York, w i t h James H. Oltman. First Vice President of the Fede r a l Reserve B a n k of New York, as alternate; E d w a r d G. Boehne, President of the Federal R e serve Bank of Philadelphia, with J. Alfred Broaddus. Jr.. President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, as alternate; Silas Keehn. President of the Federal Reserve Ban k of Chicago, w i t h J e r r y L. Jordan, President of the Federal R e serve B ank ofCleveland, as alternate: 3. 4. Attended portion of m e e t i n g relating to the C o m m i t t e e ’s discussion of the economic outlook and its l o n g e r - r u n objectives for monetary and debt aggregates. Attended portion of the m e e t i n g relating to the release of FOMC information to the public. 88 - 3 - Robert D. McTeer, Jr.. President of the Federal Reserve B a n k of Dallas, with Robert P. Forrestal, President of the Federal Reserve Ban k of Atlanta, as alternate; Gary H. Stern, P r esident of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, wit h Robert T. Parry, President of the Federal Reserve B a n k of San Francisco, as alternate. By u n animous vote, the Committee elected the f o l l o w i n g of f i c ers of the Federal Open Market Committee to serve until the el e c t i o n of their successors at the first meeting of t h e Committee after D e c e m b e r 31. 1993. wi t h the understanding that in the event the d i s c o n t i n u a n c e of their official connection with the Board of G o v e r nors or with a Federal Reserve Bank, o f f icial they would cea s e to have Chairman Vice Chairman D o nald L. K o h n N o rmand R. V. Bernard J o s e p h R. Coyne Gary P. G i l l u m J. V i rgil Mattingly, Jr. E r nest T. Patrikis M i chael J. Prell E d w i n M. T r u m a n Secretary and Economist Deput y S e c r e t a r y Assistant Secretary Assistant Secretary General Counsel Deputy G e n e r a l Counsel Economist Economist R i c h a r d G. Davis, Ric h a r d W. Lang, David E. Lindsey, Larry J. Promisel, A r t h u r J. Rolnick, H a rvey Rosenblum, K arl A. Scheld, Charles J. Siegman, Thomas D. Simpson, and Lawrence Slifman By u n animous vote, 31, of the Assoc i a t e Economists the Federal Reserve Bank of N e w Y ork was se l e c t e d to execute tran s a c t i o n s until the a d j o u rnment for the System Open Mar k e t Acc o u n t first meeting of the Committee after 1993. By u n animous vote, W i l l i a m J. McDonough, M a r garet L. Greene, and Joan E. Love t t were selected to serve at the pleasure of the C o m m i t t e e in the c a p acities A c c ount, any conn e c t i o n with the Federal Open Market Committee: Alan Greenspan E. G e rald Corrigan December of Deputy Manager of Manager of the System O p e n Market for Foreign Operations. System Open Market 89 - Account, 4 - and Deputy Manager for Domestic Operations, Market Account respectively, System Open on the underst a n d i n g that their selection was subject to their being satisfactory to the Federal Reserve B a n k of New York. S e c r e t a r y ’s note: Advice subsequentl y was received that the selections indicated above w e r e satisf a c t o r y to the board of directors of the Federal Res e r v e Ban k of New York. On January 15. authorizations, 1993, the continuing rules, regulations, and other instruments of the C o m m ittee listed b e low were distributed with the advice that, approved by the Committee, in accord a n c e with proced u r e s they were being called to the C o m m i t t e e ’s atten t i o n before the February 2-3 organization m e e t i n g to give members an o p p o rtunity to raise any questions they might h ave c o n c e r n i n g them. M e mbers were asked to indicate if they wished to hav e any of the instruments in question placed on the agenda for consid e r a t i o n meeting. No requests at this for substantive consider a t i o n were received. At the meeting, the Committee voted unani m o u s l y to update the references to the Management of the System Open M arket Account were contained in the following: securities (1) Procedur e s for a l l o c a t i o n of in the System Open Market Account and Security of FOMC Information. titles, that (2) Prog r a m for Apart from the i n d i cated u p d a t i n g of all of the instruments listed b e l o w remained in effect in their existing forms. 1. Procedures for allocation of securities in the System Open Market Account. 2. A u t h ority for the Chairman to appoint a Federal R e serve B a n k as agent to operate the System Account in case the N e w York B a n k is unable to function. 3. Reso l u t i o n of FOMC to provide for the cont i n u e d operation of the C o mmittee during an emergency; R e s o l u t i o n of FOM C a u t h o r i z i n g certain actions by Federal Reserve Banks d u r i n g an emergency. 4. Reso l u t i o n relating to examinations of the S y s t e m Open Market Account. 90 -5- 5. Guid e l i n e s issues. for the c o n duct of System operations in Fed e r a l agency 6. R e g u l a t i o n r e l ating to Op e n Market Operations of F e d e r a l Reserve Banks. 7. P r o g r a m for Security of FOMC Information. 8. F e d e r a l O p e n Market Commi t t e e Rules. B y u n a n i m o u s vote, the Authorization for D o m e s t i c Open Market Operations, as shown below, was reaffirmed: 1. The F e d eral Open Market Committee authorizes and d irects the Federal Res e r v e Bank of N e w York, to the extent n e c e s s a r y to carry out the most recent domestic policy d i r e c t i v e adopted at a meeting of the Committee: (a) To buy or sell U. S. Government securities, i n c l u d i n g securities of the Federal Financing Bank, and s e curities that are direct obligations of, or fully guar a n t e e d as to principal and interest by. any agen c y of the Uni t e d States in the open market, from or to s e curities dealers and foreign and international accounts m a i n t a i n e d at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, on a cash, regular, or d e ferred delivery basis, for the S y s t e m O pen M a r k e t Account at m a r k e t prices, and, for suc h Account, to exchange m a t u r i n g U. S. Government and Federal age n c y securities with the Treasury or -the i n dividual agencies or to allow them to mature with o u t replacement: provided that the aggregate amount of U. S-. Gove r n m e n t and Federal agency securities held in such Account (including forward commitments) at the close of b u s iness on the day of a meeting of the Committee at wh i c h a c t i o n is taken with respect to a domestic p o l i c y dir e c t i v e shall not be increased or decreased by m o r e than $8.0 billion d u r i n g the period commencing w i t h the ope n i n g of business on the day following such m e e t i n g and ending w i t h the close of business on the day of t h e next such meeting; (b) W h e n appropriate, to buy or sell in the open market, f r o m or to acceptance dealers and foreign accounts m a i n t a i n e d at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, on a cash, regular, or deferred delivery basis, for the a c c ount of the F e deral Reserve Bank of N e w Y o r k at m a rket d i s c o u n t rates, prime bankers acceptances w i t h m a t u r i t i e s of up to nine months at the time of a c c e p t a n c e that (1) a r ise out of the current shipment of-goods between co u n t r i e s or w i t h i n the United States; or (2) arise out of the storage within the United States of goods u n d e r contract of sale or expected to move into the ch a nnels of t r a d e w i t h i n a reasonable time and t h a t are secured t h r o u g h o u t t h e i r life by a warehouse receipt or similar docu m e n t c o n v e y i n g title to the u n de r l y i n g goods; 91 - 6- provided that the aggregate amount of b a n k e r s acceptances h eld at any one time shall not exceed $100 million; (c) To buy U. S . Government s e c u r i t i e s . o b ligations that are direct obligations of, or fully gua r a n t e e d as to principal and interest by, any agen c y of t h e Uni t e d States, and prime bankers a c c e p tances of t h e types authorized for purchase under 1(b) above, f r o m dealers for the account of the Federal Res e r v e B a n k - o f N e w Y o r k under agreements for repurchase of such securities, obligations, or acceptances in 15 cale n d a r days or less, at rates that, unless otherwise expre s s l y a u t h o r i z e d by the Committee, shall be determined by comp e t i t i v e bidding, after applying reasonable limita t i o n s on the volume of agreements with individual dealers; provided that in the event Government securities or agency issues covered by any such agreement are not rep u r c h a s e d by the dealer pursuant to the agreement or a r e n e w a l - t h e r e o f , they shall be sold in the market or t r a n s f e r r e d to the System Open Market Account: and provided f u r t h e r that in the event bankers acceptances covered by any such agreement are not repurchased by the seller, t h e y shall continue to be held by the Federal Re serve B a n k or shall be sold in the open m a r k e t . 2. In order to ensure the effective conduct of open market operations, the Federal Open M a r k e t C o m m ittee authorizes and directs the Federal Re s e r v e Banks to lend U. S. Government securities held in the S y s t e m Open Market Account to Government securities d e a l e r s and to banks participating in G o v ernment sec u r i t i e s clear i n g arrangements conducted through a Federal R e s e r v e Bank, under such instructions as the Commit t e e m a y s p ecify f r o m time to time. 3. In order to ensure the effective c o nduct of open market operations, while assisting in t he p r o v i s i o n of short-term investments for foreign and inte r n a t i o n a l accounts maintained at the Federal Re s e r v e B a n k of N e w York, the Federal Open Market Committee a u t horizes and directs the Federal Reserve Bank of New Y o r k (a) for Syst e m Open Market Account, to sell U. S. Gov e r n m e n t securities to such foreign and i n t ern a t i o n a l accounts on th e bases set forth in paragraph 1(a) u n d e r agreements providing for the resale by such accounts of those securities within 15 calendar days on terms c o m parable to th ose available on such transactions in t he market; and (b) for N e w York Bank account, when appropriate, to undertake with dealers, subject to the condit i o n s imposed on purchases and sales of securities in p a r a g r a p h 1 ( c ) , repurchase agreements in U. S. G o vern m e n t and agency securities, and to arrange corr e s p o n d i n g sale and repurchase agreements between its own a c c o u n t and for e i g n and international accounts m a i n t a i n e d at t h e Bank. Transa ctions undertaken with such acc o u n t s under the provisions of this paragraph may prov i d e f or a service fee when appropriate. 92 - By una n i m o u s vote, Ope r a t i ons was 7 - the Authorization for Foreign Currency amended to update the title of the Manager of the S ystem Open Mark e t Account. The Authorization, as amended, is shown below: 1. The Federal Open Market Committee authorizes__and directs the Feder al Reserve Bank of New York, for S y s t e m Open M a r k e t Account, to the extent necessary to carry out the C o m m i t t e e ’s foreign currency directive and express a u thoriz a t i o n s by the Committee pursuant thereto, and in c o n formity wi t h such procedural instructions as the C o mmittee may issue from time to time: A. To p u r chase and sell the following foreign c urrencies in the form of cable transfers through spot or forward transa c t i o n s on the open market at home and abroad, including transactions with the U. S. Treasury, with the U. S. Exchange Stabilization Fund established by Section 10 of the Gold Reserve Act of 1934. with f o r e i g n m o n e t a r y authorities, wi t h the Bank for International Settlements, and with other international financial institutions: A u s t r i a n schillings B e l gian francs C a nadian dollars Danish kroner Pounds sterling French francs German marks Italian lire J a panese yen M ex i c a n pesos N etherlands guilders N o r wegian kroner Swedish kronor Swiss francs B. To hold balances of. and to have outstanding forward c o ntracts to receive or to deliver, the foreign c urrencies listed in paragraph A above. C. To d r a w foreign currencies and to permit foreign banks to dr a w dollars under the reciprocal currency a r rangements listed in paragraph 2 below, provided that d rawings by either party to any such arrangement shall be fully liquid a t e d within 12 months after any amount o u t s t a n d i n g at that time was first drawn, unless the Committee, because of exceptional circumstances, s p e c i f i c a l l y authorizes a delay. D. To m a i n t a i n an overall open position in all f o r e i g n currencies not exceeding $25.0 billion. For this purpose, the overall open position in all foreign c u rrencies is defined as the sum (disregarding signs) of 93 - 8 - net positions in individual currencies. The net position in a single foreign currency is defined as holdings of balances in that currency, plus outstanding contracts for future receipt, minus outstanding contracts for future de livery of that currency, i.e.. as the sum of these elements with due regard to sign. 2. The Federal Open Market Committee directs, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to maintain reciprocal currency arrangements ("swap" arrangements) for the System Open Market Account for periods up to a m a x i m u m of 12 months with the following foreign banks, whic h are among those designated by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve S ystem under Section 214.5 of Regulation N, Relations with Foreign Banks and Bankers, and with the approval of the Committee to renew such arrangements on maturity: Foreign bank Amount of arrangement (millions of dollars _______ equivalent) A u st r i a n National Bank N ational Bank of Belgium Bank of Canada National Bank of Denmark Ban k of England Ban k of France German Federal Bank Ban k of Italy Bank of Japan Bank of Mexico Netherlands Bank Bank of Norway Ban k of Sweden Swiss National Bank Ban k for International Settlements: Dollars against Swiss francs Dollars against authorized European currencies other than Swiss francs 250 1 ,000 2 .000 250 3 ,000 2 .000 6 ,000 3 ,000 5 ,000 700 500 250 300 4,000 600 1 ,250 Any changes in the terms of existing swap arrangements, and the proposed terms of any new arrangements that may be authorized, shall be referred for review and approval to the Committee. 3. All transactions in foreign currencies undertaken under paragraph 1(A) above shall, unless otherwise expressly authorized by the Committee, be at prevailing market rates. For the purpose of providing an investment return on System holdings of foreign currencies, or for the purpose of adjusting interest rates paid or received in connection with swap drawings, transactions with foreign central banks may be undertaken at non-market exchange rates. 4. It shall be the normal practice to arrange with f oreign central banks for the coordination of foreign 7 3 -2 9 8 0 - 9 4 - 4 94 -9- currency transactions. In making operating arrangements with foreign central banks on System h oldings of foreign currencies, the Federal Reserve B ank of N e w Yo r k shall not commit itself to m a i n t a i n any specific balance, unless authorized by the Federal Open Market Committee. Any agreements or understandings concerning the administration o f the accounts m a intained by the Federal Reserve B a n k of N e w York with the foreign banks designated by the Board of Governors under Section 214.5 of Regulation N shall be referred for review and approval to the Committee. 5. Foreign currency holdings shall be invested insofar as practicable, considering needs for m i n i m u m work i n g balances. Such investments shall be in liquid form, and generally have no more than 12 mon t h s remaining to maturity. When appropriate in c o n nection wit h arrangements to provide investment facilities for foreign currency holdings, U. S. Government securities m ay be purchased from foreign central banks under a greements for repurchase of such securities w i t h i n 30 calendar d a y s . 6. All operations undertaken pursuant to the preceding paragraphs shall be reported p r o m p t l y to the Foreign Currency Subcommittee and the Committee. The F oreign Currency Subcommittee consists of the C h a irman and Vice Chairman of the Committee, the Vice C h a i r m a n of the Board of Governors, and such other memb e r of the Board as the Chairman may designate Cor in the absence of members of the Board serving on the Subcommittee, other Board Members designated by the Chairman as alternates, and in the absence of the Vice Chairman of the Committee, his alternate). Meetings of the S ubcommittee shall be called at the request of any member, or at the request of the Manager of t he S y stem Ope n Market Account, for the purposes of reviewing recent or contemplated operations and of consulting w i t h the Manager on other matters relating to his r e s p o n s i b i l i t i e s . At the request of any m e m b e r of the Subcommittee, questions arising from such reviews and c onsultations shall be referred for determ ination to the Federal Open Market Committee. 7. The Chairman is authorized: A. Wit h the approval of the Committee, to enter into any needed agreement or understanding wit h the S ecretary of the Treasury about the divisi o n of responsibility for foreign currency operations between the System and the Treasury: B. To keep the Secretary of the Treasury fully advised c o n c erning System foreign currency operations, and to consult with the Secretary on policy matters relating to foreign currency operations: 95 - 10- C. From time to time, to transmit appropriate reports and information to the National Ad v i s o r y Council on International Monetary and Financial Policies. 8. Staff officers of the Committee are authorized to transmit pertinent information on System foreign c urrency operations to appropriate officials of the Treasury Department. 9. All Federal Reserve Banks shall participate in the foreign currency operations for System Account in accordance with paragraph 3 G(l) of the Board of Governors* Statement of Procedure with Respect to Foreign Relationships of Federal Reserve Banks dated January 1, 1944. By unanimous vote, below, the Foreign Currency Directive, was reaffirmed: 1. System operations in foreign currencies shall generally be directed at countering disorderly market conditions, provided that market exchange rates for the U. S. dollar reflect actions and behavior consistent w ith the IMF Article IV, Section 1. 2. To achieve this end the System shall: A. Undertake spot and forward purchases and sales of foreign e x c h a n g e . B. M a i ntain reciprocal currency ("swap") arrangements with selected foreign central banks and with the Ba n k for International Settlements, C. Cooperate in other respects with central banks of other countries and with international m onetary institutions. 3. Transactions may also be undertaken: A. To adjust System balances in light of probable future needs for currencies. B. To provide means for meeting System and T r easury commitments in particular currencies, &nd to facilitate operations of the Exchange Stabilization Fund . C. For such other purposes as may be expressly authorized by the Committee. 4. System foreign currency operations shall be conducted: A. In close and continuous consultation and cooperation w i t h the United States Treasury; as shown 96 -ii- B. In cooperation, as appropriate, m o n e t a r y authorities; and with foreign C. In a manner consistent with the obli g a t i o n s of the United States in the International Mone t a r y Fund regarding exchange arrangements under the IMF Article IV. By unanimous vote, the Procedural Instructions w i t h respect to Foreign Currency Operations were amended to up date the title of the Manager of the System Open Market Account. Instructions, as amended, The Procedural are shown below: In conducting operations pursuant to the authorization and direction of the Federal Open Market Committee as set forth in the Authorization for Foreign Currency Operations and the Foreign Currency Directive, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, t h roug h the Manager of the System Open Market Account ("Manager"), shall be guided by the following procedural u n derstandings with respect to consultations and clearance wi t h the Committee, the Foreign Cu r rency Subcommittee, and the Chairman of the Committee. All operations undertaken pursuant to such clearances shall be reported promptly to the Committee. 1. The Manager shall clear with the Subcommittee (or wi t h the Chairman, if the Chairman believes that consultation with the Subcommittee is not feasible in the time a v a i l a b l e ) : A. Any operation that would result in a change in the S y s t e m ’s overall open position in foreign currencies exceeding $300 million on any day or $600 mil l i o n since the most recent regular mee t i n g of the C o m m i t t e e .‘ B. An y operation that would result in a change on any day in the S y s t e m ’s net position in a single foreign curre ncy exceeding $150 million, or $300 mil l i o n w h e n the operation is associated wit h repayment of swap drawings. C. A n y operation that might generate a substantial volume of trading in a particular c u r rency by the System, even though the change in the S y s t e m ’s net p o sition in that currency might be less t h a n the limits specified in IB. D. A n y swap drawing proposed by a foreign bank not exceeding the larger of (i) $200 m i l lion or (ii) 15 percent of the size of the swap arrangement. 2. The Manager shall clear with the Commit t e e (or wit h the Subcommittee, if the Subcommittee believes 97 - 12- that consultation with the full Committee is not feasible in the time available, or with the Chairman, if the Chairman believes that consultation w i t h the Subcommittee is not feasible in the time a v a i l a b l e ) : A. Any operation that would result in a change in the System's overall open position in foreign currencies exceeding $1.5 billion since the mos t recent regular m e e t i n g of the Committee. B. Any swap drawing proposed by a foreign bank exceeding the larger of Ti) $200 million or (ii) 15 percent of the size of the swap arrangement. 3. The Manager shall also consult with the Subcommittee or the Chairman about proposed swap drawings by the System, and about any operations that are not of a routine character. The Report of Examination of the System Open Market Account, conducted by the B o a r d ’s Division of Reserve Bank Operations and Payments Systems as of the close of business on July 31, 1992, was accepted. By unanimous vote, the minutes of actions taken at the m e eting of the Federal Open Market Committee held on December 22, 1992, were approved. The Deputy Manager for Foreign Operations reported on developments in foreign exchange markets during the period December 22, 1992. through February 2, 1993. There were no System open market transactions in foreign currencies during this period, and thus no vote was required of the Committee. The M a n ager of the System Open Market A c count reported on developments in domestic financial markets and on System open market transactions in government securities and federal agency obligations during the period December 22, 1992, through Febr u a r y 2. 1993. By unanimous vote, the Committee ratified these transactions. The Committee then turned to a discussion of the economic outlook, the ranges for the growth of money and debt in 1993, and the 98 - 13- i mplementation of monetary policy over the interm e e t i n g period ahead. A summary of the economic and financial information a v ailable at the time of the meeting and of the Committee's discus s i o n is provided below, followed by the domestic policy directive that was approved by the Committee and issued to the Federal Reserve B ank of N ew York. The information reviewed at this meeti n g indicated that economic activity rose appreciably further in the fourth quarter. Final demands were buoyed by strength in consumption, spending for durable equipment, and residential construction. M anufacturing activity also increased considerably, appeared to be on a modest upward trajectory, flow of announcements of layoffs by large corporations. on balance they registered a small increase for the fourth consecutive month. notably business and health services, nearly all of the rise in jobs. payrolls changed little, Service industries, and retail trade accounted for Manufacturing and construction, and government employment fell as temporary election workers were dropped from payrolls. ment Although inflation was trending gradually lower. Total nonfarm payroll employment in December and employment despite a continuing recent data on wages and prices had been mixed, suggested that business rate remained at 7.3 percent, almost The civilian u n e m p l o y 1/2 percentage point below its mid-year peak but slightly above its level at the b e ginning of the year . Industrial production advanced further in D ecember and was up considerably over the fourth quarter as a whole. assemblies rose sharply during the quarter; registered in business output of computers, equipment, Motor vehicle strong gains also were partly reflecting a further jump in and in nondurable consumer goods. By contrast, the production of durable consumer goods other than m o tor vehicles was 99 - 14- lower on balance after changing little over the third quarter, and the output of defense and space equipment remained on a downward trend. Total u t i l ization of industrial capacity increased significantly in the fourth quarter and for the year as a whole. Consumer spending was up substantially in the fourth quarter. Retail sales, November, after rising sharply in October and c hanging little in posted a further sizable increase in December. sales gains in the fourth quarter were reported at automotive dealers and at building m a terial and supply outlets, retail The largest stores also recorded higher sales. spending for services, expenditures, but most other types of By contrast, consumer as indicated by data on personal consumption rose more slowly. Housing starts surged in December, with single family starts reaching their highest level in nearly three years and m u l t i f a m i l y starts picking up slightly from the very low levels of October and November. Sales of new and existing homes remained on a strong upward trend in December. Real outlays for business fixed investment apparently registered a notable gain in the fourth quarter, producers' durable equipment. particularly for Shipments of nondefense capital goods rose in November and December after changing little in October: the quarter as a whole, shipments advanced substantially, increases w i d e s p r e a d by category. for with Business purchases of cars and trucks were up sharply in the fourth quarter, while nonresidential construction activity retraced a small part of a third-quarter decline. Business inventories expanded moderately in November as a sizable drop in ma n u f a c t u r i n g inventories was more than offset by increases in who l e s a l e and retail inventories. level, At the m a n ufacturing the d r a w d o w n of stocks was associated with strong shipments of 100 -15- durable goods, and inventory-to-shipments ratios in most industries were at or near the bottom of their recent ranges. sector, sizable inventory increases were In the wholesale reported in November for a second straight month; most of the buildup was limited to machinery, motor vehicles, and miscellaneous nondurable goods. Wit h stocks rising in line with sales since September, the stock-to-sales ratio in wholesaling remained at the low end of its range over the past year. Retail inventories increased moderately further in November; the inventory-to-sales ratio for the sector was slightly b e l o w its average for previous months of the year. The nominal U.S. merchandise trade deficit widened slightly in November. For October and November together, however, the deficit narrowed a little from its average rate in the third quarter, value of exports rose more than the value of imports. increase in exports was in capital goods, and in consumer goods. as the Most of the both m a c h i n e r y and aircraft, Passenger cars accounted for a considerable part of the rise in imports, while the inflow of consumer goods eased from the very strong pace of the third quarter. Recent indicators suggested that economic activity had remained w e a k in the major foreign industrial countries and that unemployment further in most of those countries. to be continuing, rates had increased The recovery in Canada appeared but the downturn in western G e r many and Japan evidently had persisted into the fourth quarter. A small November decline in producer prices of finished goods was reversed in December, with a rebound in prices of finished foods outweighing a further drop in energy prices. other than food and energy, advance followed six months of no change on balance: whole, For finished items producer prices rose in December, but the for 1992 as a this measure of prices increased by a co n s i derably smaller 101 -16- amount than in 1991* nonfood, At the consumer level, the index for prices of non-energy items edged higher in December after somewhat larger increases in the two preceding months. The rise in this index in 1992 was the smallest for any year since the early 1970s. when wage and price controls were in effect. Hourly compensation of private industry workers advanced a little more rapidly in the fourth quarter than in the two previous quarters, but the rise in total compensation over the year as a whole was considerably smaller than in 1991. The slowing of labor cost increases last year occurred in both the wages and benefits components. At its mee t i n g on December 22, the Committee adopted a directive that called for maintaining the existing degree of pressure on reserve positions and that did not include a presumption about the likely direction of any adjustments to policy during the intermeeting period. Accordingly, the directive indicated that in the context of the Committee's long-run objectives for price stability and sustainable economic growth, economic, reserve financial, and giving careful consideration to and monetary developments, slightly greater restraint or slightly lesser reserve restraint would be acceptable during the intermeeting period. The reserve conditions associated with this directive were expected to be consistent with expansion of M2 at an annual rate of about 1-1/2 percent and with M3 remaining about unchanged on balance over the four-month period from November through March. Open market operations during the intermeeting period were directed toward maintaining the existing degree of pressure on reserve positions. Adjustment plus seasonal borrowing was well above expected levels in the first two full reserve maintenance periods in the intermeeting interval; borrowing was sizable over the long N e w Y e a r ’s 102 -17- weekend and also later when unusually heavy Treasury t ax receipts drained reserves from the banking system. The federal funds rate averaged close to expected levels over the intermeeting period. However, the rate was somewhat volatile in late December as a result of sizable swings in market factors affecting reserves and of shifting market anticipations regarding year-end pressures. Most other short-term interest rates declined somewhat over the intermeeting period, pressures. Intermediate- fixed-rate mortgages, in part reflecting the passing of year-end and long-term rates, including those on also moved somewhat lower; the declines occurred in response to growing indications that any proposed n e ar-term fiscal stimulus would be quite moderate and that the new Administration intended to recommend steps, possibly including new taxes, to lower the trajectory of the fiscal deficit appreciably over time. Broad indexes of stock prices exhibited mixed results over the intermeeting period: little, Indexes giving heavy weight to large companies changed while those primarily reflecting smaller companies rose significantly. In foreign exchange markets, the trade-weighted value of the dollar in terms of the other G-10 currencies rose on balance over the intermeeting period. Through early January, against both the yen and the mark, the dollar appreciated especially the latter, in response to actual and expected further declines in interest rates in Japan and Germany. Subsequently, the d o l l a r ’s gains were partially erased as the prospects for near-term easing in Germany diminished somewhat and perceptions grew that fiscal initiatives in the United States would lower the deficit and reduce the chances that mon e t a r y policy might be tightened in the months ahead. 103 -18- After expanding at a moderate pace over the course of earlier months, M2 contracted in December and January. Some of the weakness reflected a slowdown in Ml growth associated with lower mortgage refinancing activity. Within M 2 ' s nontransaction component, the expansion of savings and money market deposit accounts slowed abruptly, perhaps owing in part to the wider spread that had developed during the fall between market rates and those paid on these accounts, as well as to the use of monies’ in these accounts to fund a step-up in consumer purchases and nonwithheld tax payments. In addition, the continued attractiveness to investors of bond and stock mutual funds might have contributed to a quickening of the runoff of holdings of money market mutual funds and to the persisting weakness in other M2 accounts. Appreciable declines in M3 in December and January reflected both the contraction in M2 and reduced needs by banks for managed liabilities at a time of weak overall credit demand. From the fourth quarter of 1991 to the fourth quarter of 1992. both M2 and M3 grew at rates somewhat below the lower ends of the C o m m i t t e e ’s annual ranges. Total domestic nonfinancial debt appeared to have expanded at the lower end of the Committee's monitoring range for 1992. The staff projection prepared for this meeting suggested that economic activity would expand over the year ahead at a pace that w ould be sufficient to reduce gradually margins of unemployed labor and capital. Recent declines in long-term interest rates and more optimistic attitudes on the part of businesses and households were e xpected to support further solid gains in business fixed investment and in homebuying. Continuing progress in reducing debt service burdens and a gradual lessening of concerns regarding job security were projected to foster an expansion of consumer spending a shade faster than the growth in incomes. Export demand would be damped for 104 - 19- some period of time by the appreciation of the dollar since m i d - 1992, but an anticipated pickup in growth abroad later this year would begin to counteract the effects of the higher dollar. Against the background of considerable uncertainties associated wit h still unannounced fiscal policy initiatives, the staff retained for this forecast the assumption contained in several previous forecasts that fiscal policy would remain mildly restrictive, declining defense outlays. largely because of The persisting slack in resource utilization over the forecast horizon was expected to be associated with some additional progress in reducing inflation. In the Com m i t t e e ’s discussion of current and prospective economic developments, the members were encouraged by the mounting evidence of appreciable m o mentum in the economic expansion. whole, On the recent developments tended to reinforce their forecasts of continuing growth at a moderate pace over the year ahead, in light of the improvement impact of some retarding influences on the expansion, balance sheet adjustment activities, addition, while some major The notably various appeared to be waning. In sectors of the economy such as defense spending and commercial construction remained weak, the economy was b e nefitting from considerable growth in consumer spending, business expenditures for producer equipment, outlays for housing. especially in business and consumer confidence. In one view, from rising and from increasing the recent behavior of commodity prices also tended to indicate some strengthening in the e c o n o m y ’s expansion. expansion, Despite various indications of a more firmly established however, the members felt that the outl o o k remained subject to a good deal of uncertainty, and some commented that substantial de viations--in either direction--from their current forecasts could not be ruled out. It was noted in this connection that the specifics 105 - 20- of the President's fiscal policy proposals were still unknown, and their reception by the public and the Congress would have a major influence on confidence, economy. interest rates, and the performance of the Other sources of uncertainty related to the outlook for further restructuring activities that involved cutbacks in operations and employment by many firms, banking institutions. and the prospective lending policies of With regard to the outlook for inflation, most of the members believed that some further progress toward stable prices was likely over the year ahead, given an economic outcome about in line with their forecasts of continued, albeit reduced, margins of unutilized or underutilized productive resources. Some members also referred to the extended period of relatively sluggish growth in the broad measures of money as a favorable indicator in the outlook for inflation. In keeping with the practice at meetings whe n the Committee establishes its long-run ranges for growth of the mon e y and debt aggregates, the Committee members and the Federal Reserve B a n k presidents not currently serving as members had prepared projections of economic activity, 1993. the rate of unemployment, and inflation for The central tendencies of the forecasts pointed to slightly faster economic growth this year than currently seemed to have occurred in 1992. The anticipated rate of economic expansion would be at a pace that was rapid enough to reduce the rate of unemployment a little further. persisting, Nonetheless, with some slack in productive resources price and cost pressures would remain subdued and modest additional moderation in inflation was expected by most members. Measured from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter of 1993. the forecasts for growth of real GDP had a central tendency of 3 106 - 21- to 3-1/4 percent within a full range of 2-1/2 to 4 percent. Projec tions of the civilian rate of unemployment in the f ourth quarter of 1993 were concentrated in the upper half of a 6-1/2 to 7 percent range. For the CPI, the central tendency of the forecasts for the period from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth q u arter of 1993 was centered on increases in a range of 2-1/2 to 2-3/4 percent, and for nominal GDP the forecasts were clustered in a range of 5-1/2 to 6 percent for the year. In the course of the C o m m i t t e e ’s discussion of various factors underlying the outlook for economic activity, the m e mbers observed that* on the whole the effects of a number of structural impediments to the expansion seemed to be diminishing as the financial condition of households, business firms, continued to improve. eased substantially, and financial institutions Household and business debt-service burdens had but it remained difficult to predict t o what extent and for how long the ongoing balance sheet adjust m e n t s would continue to divert an unusual proportion of cash flows from spending to balance sheet repair. Improved profitability and n e w c a p i t a l - market issuance had strengthened the capital positions of banking institutions, and in genexal they were now in a m u c h b etter position to augment their len d i n g activities. However, there w e r e few indications thus far of any easing in terms or standards on business loans, and the depressed and uncertain values of c ommercial mortgages and real estate held in bank portfolios might continue to exert an inhibiting effect on the willingness of banks to lend. Another negative factor was the persistence of downsizing and other restructuring activities by numerous firms, notably large businesses. Such restructuring activities had not fully run their cou r s e as m a n y firms continued to pare excess production capacity and to m o d e r n i z e 107 - pro d u c t i o n facilities to meet fo r e i g n markets. 22 - strong competition in domestic and The resulting layoffs had damped overall job growth. Despite tepid job growth, retail sales had strengthened m a r k e d l y during the closing mo n t h s of 1992. and several members commented that such sales had continued to di splay surprising vigor in some parts of the country during the early weeks of 1993. the improvement in consumer sentiment, Apart from other favorable factors cited wit h regard to thte butlook'for consumer spending included lower debtservice burdens and the capital gains or enhanced cash flows n o w being realized as sales of hom e s picked up and mortgage refinancings again strengthened. Some members nonetheless expressed a degree of concern about the sustainability of the gains in consumer spending unless t h ere were faster growth in employment and income to support such spending. Announcements by prominent firms of cutbacks in their work f o r c e s had continued into the new year, other firms, and while job gains at especially smaller ones, were contributing to modest net g rowth in overall employment, the publicity surrounding the persisting job cutbacks and a tendency for many new jobs to be lower-paying, added an element of caution to the outlook for consumer expenditures. balance, wit h the measured saving rate already at a low level, an argument On though could be made that the actual rate was somewhat higher t h a n indicated by the currently published data, consumer spending s eemed likely to expand about in line w i t h the growth in consumer i ncomes over the coming year. The growth in consumer incomes in turn was likely to depend i m p o r t a n t l y on the expansion in business investment spending, and m e m b e r s cited a number of factors that were expected to provide a f avor a b l e setting for sustained mome n t u m in such spending over the year ahead. These included the strengthening of final demands, the 108 - recent declines in intermediate- 23- and long-term interest rates, the greater leeway for financial intermediaries to increase their lending to businesses, and a continuing desire by business firms to improve their operating efficiencies. however, Commercial construction activity, was likely t o ‘remain quite sluggish. There wer e indications that commercial real estate values had stabilized in a number of areas, but at low levels, and given the persistence of mar k e d imbalances in numerous real estate markets that were t he result of several years of overbuilding, a significant rebound in commercial building activity for the nation as a whole might well be several years away. promising. The outlook for housing construction was m u c h more Against the background of a general upswing in consumer confidence and the improved balance sheets of man y households, the declines that had occurred in mortgage interest rates had fostered a m arked strengthening in the demand for single-family h o u s i n g as evidenced by reports from many parts of the country as well as the overall statistics on housing. On the basis of these developments, the members anticipated a continuing impetus to the e conomic expansion from housing construction and from related industries over the year ahead. In addition, business inventories, the current indications of generally lean associated in part with strong final demands over the past several months, suggested that the prospects for further gains in overall spending were likely to stimulate efforts by business firms to build up inventories over the quarters ahead. The increasing signs of slow growth or recession in a number of foreign nations represented a greater downside r isk to t he demand for U.S. exports than had been apparent earlier. example, that firms engaged in business activities abroad were It w as noted, reporting substantial deterioration in markets for U.S. for goods in many 109 -24- foreign countries. the year ahead, U.S. Growth in U.S. exports might remain positive over but against the background of a relatively expansive economy and the d o l l a r ’s recent appreciation, the value of exports might well fall increasingly short of that of imports with adverse effects on the growth of U.S. economic activity. Turning to the outlook for fiscal policy, members were encouraged by the prospect that the President would soon propose a program that would produce substantial reductions in the federal deficit over the years ahead. deemed credible, Such a deficit -reduction program, could result in lower intermediate- if and long-term interest rates than would otherwise pr e v a i l - - even before the program was enacted --with very positive implications for interest-sensitive expenditures. For the nearer term, the President was expected to announce some modest fiscal stimulus relative to what was currently in train. However, the specifics of the President's proposals were not yet known and there was little current basis on w h i c h to judge prospective public and Congressional reactions. the critical need for long-term deficit Members emphasized reduction, and some expressed concern about the adverse effects on financial markets if fiscal stimulus measures were to be enacted for the short run without the assurance of further legislation to cut federal deficits over time. With regard to the outlook for inflation, most of the members anticipated that the trend toward lower price and wage inflation would be sustained over the year ahead, and one member observed that the disinflationary mo m e n t u m in the economy might well be underestimated. Favorable developments relating to the outlook for inflation included evidence of slowing increases in labor costs and continued aggressive efforts by many business firms to improve productivity and reduce costs in the face of intense competition from domestic and foreign 110 -25- producers. Indeed, anecdotal reports from around the country continued to suggest little or no upward pressure on prices in m a n y regions. In addition, the behavior of interest rates in l o n g er-term debt markets was consistent with spreading expectations of gradually d i minishing inflation. Some members believed, however, that little or no further progress in reducing inflation was a more likely outcome in the year ahead, though none anticipated higher inflation. commodity price indexes had edged higher recently, Some apparently in response to growing demands related to strengthening activity in several sectors of the economy. Lumber prices in particular had risen co nsiderably in conjunction with the uptrend in single-family housing c onstruction and various constraints on lumber supplies. Some business contacts reported for the first time in a long while that they were experiencing or anticipated some upward pressure on their raw materials prices. Further, while most business contacts saw or anticipated little or no upward pressure on prices in their own industries, m a n y continued to expect rising inflation more generally. The still relatively steep slope of the yield curve and its i mplications with regard to expectations of future increases in interest rates also suggested that investors remained concerned about the possibility of higher inflation over the longer run, even t hough such concerns m i ght have abated somewhat recently and did not appear to extend to the next year or two. In general, however, the members viewed the inflation outlook with considerable optimism on the p r esumption of favorable fiscal and monetary policy developments. In k e eping with the requirements of the Full Employment and B alanced G r owth Act of 1978 (the Humphrey-Hawkins Act), the Committee at this m e e t i n g reviewed the ranges for growth of the m o n e t a r y and debt aggregates in 1993 that it had established on a tentative basis I ll -26- at its meeting on June 30-July 1. 1992. The tentative ranges included expansion of 2-1/2 to 6-1/2 percent for M2 and 1 to 5 percent for M3, measured from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter 1993. of The monitoring range for grovth of total domestic nonfinancial debt had been set provisionally at 4-1/2 to 8*1/2 percent for 1993. All of these ranges were unchanged from those that the Committee had set for 1992 at its meeting in February of last year and had r e a f firmed at mid-year. When the provisional ranges for m o n e y grovth were established, the Committee had noted that they were especially tentative and subject to revision in the latter part of 1992 or early 1993 owing to the considerable uncertainty about the evolving relationship of money to income. In the event, the velocities of M2 and M3 had increased appreciably in the second half of 1992 and analysis of the factors behind this development suggested further increases in the year ahead. Consequently, M2, in the C o m m i t t e e ’s discussion, which tended to focus on all the members indicated that they could support a proposal to lower the tentative ranges for grovth of the broad m o n etary aggregates by one-half percentage point members for 1993. At the same time, a number of indicated that they preferred somewhat different ranges including the retention of the tentative ranges, by more than the proposal, l owering the ranges and widening or na r r o w i n g them. All the members were in firm agreement that the purpose of the proposed reductions was not to signal or implement any change in mone t a r y policy or to convey any intention to move away from the Committee's commitment to m a x i m u m sustainable economic expansion. Rather, the reductions were motivated by the persistence of m arked shortfalls in the growth of M2 and M3 from their historical relationships w i t h various measures of aggregate economic performance: those shortfalls 112 -27- appeared to be the technical result of forces that are altering the relationship between m o n e y and income. Members of the Committee urged that the B o a r d ’s report to Congress and the Chairman's accompanying testimony make clear the reasons for the unusual behavior of money and its consequences for the C o m m i t t e e ’s choice of ranges. - The deviations in monetary growth from historical norms reflected a number of developments whose relative importance and intensity had shifted to some extent over the course of recent years, but in general they had served to rechannel funds away from depository institutions, and the associated weakness in deposit v elocity--the ratio of nominal GDP to money. growth had raised The result was the need for lower m o ney growth than in the past to support a given rate of income growth. Among the developments that had tended to retard the relative growth of M2 and M3 was the unprecedented steepness of the yield curve that had prompted large shifts of funds by savers from M2 accounts to higher-yielding intermediatethe same time, and long-term assets. At credit growth at bank and thrift depository institutions had been weak, partly as a result of efforts by these institutions to improve capital and liquidity positions, owing to weak demand. As a consequence, and partly they also had maintained relatively l c * offering rates on deposits that had provided consumers with an incentive to reduce or hold down their deposit holdings in order to pay down relatively high cost mortgages and other debts. 1992, In sluggish growth of M2 and M3 had been associated with a c onsiderable acceleration in nominal spending. Indeed, of both M2 and M3 at rates below the Commi t t e e ’s ranges, despite growth the expansion of the economy had exceeded most forecasts. The members generally anticipated that the intensity of these forces might diminish in 1993 as borrowers and lending institutions 113 -28- achieved more comfortable balance sheet positions. Nonetheless, the relative weakness in money growth was seen as likely to persist to a marked extent. The yield curve, while it had flattened a bit recently, was still expected to provide a considerable incentive for many savers to shift funds out of M2 assets, especially as relatively high-yielding time deposits continued to mature. In addition, banks were likely to remain generally unaggressive in bidding for deposits, in part because their substantial earlier acquisitions of securities would permit them to accommodate some of the anticipated growth in loan demand by selling securities or limiting purchases. circumstances, In these restrained money growth seemed likely to remain consistent with relative strength in the economic expansion. The members recognized that the strength of the factors that were expected to continue to depress broad mon e y growth in relation to income in 1993 was still subject to considerable uncertainty, and this implied the need for flexibility in assessing the i m p lications of money growth relative to the Committee's ranges. Should the factors influencing the behavior of the broad aggregates persist in hol d i n g down money growth to the extent seen in 1992. expansion of M2 and M3 in the lower portion of their reduced ranges would be consistent with considerable further growth in nominal spending. from the reduced ranges could not be ruled out. Indeed, a shortfall and one m e m b e r felt that the potential for such a development warranted c o n sideration of a somewhat larger reduction in the M2 range; such a reduction also would signal more clearly the C o m m i t t e e ’s commitment to price stability. On the other hand, the upper portions of the reduced ranges would still accommodate an ample provision of liquidity to support further economic expansion even if the growth of mone y and of income were to move toward an historically more normal alignment and Velo c i t y w ere to 114 •29- slow from its high rate of increase* In one view, w i d e n i n g the t entative M2 range by reducing its lower limit while retaining its upper limit would help the Committee to convey its views regarding the potential for a continuing but acceptable sluggishness in M2 growth while leaving room for the possibility of faster M2 exp a n s i o n should changing circumstances foster diminishing strength in velocity. Another member expressed a preference for narrowing the tentative range by lowering only its upper limit as a means of signaling the Committee's intent to resist both inflationary and recessionary developments. In light of the uncertainties that were involved, the informational content of the aggregates probably had d i m inished and in any event the Ccimnittee would need to continue to evaluate mone t a r y growth developments in the context of a careful assessment of a wide variety of other financial, connection, m agnitude that, of different appropriate ranges economic, and price developments. In this one member observed that the uncertainties were of such a while plausible arguments could be made for a number ranges, retention of the tentative ranges would be in light of the C o m m i t t e e ’s willingness to review the in the event that unanticipated developments wer e to unfold. All of the m e m bers agreed that it would be desir a b l e to retain the m o n i ' o r i n g range of 4-1/2 to 8*1/2 percent that the Committee had established on a provisional basis for t h e growth of total domestic nonfinancial debt in 1993. The expansion in such debt had not been damped by special forces to the same extent as the broad m onetary aggregates in 1992. Over the year ahead, g rowth in the federal debt was likely to remain substantial, debt in the nonfederal and the expansion of sectors was projected to accelerate somewhat given the continued improvement in borrower balance sheets and an a nticipated increase in the willingness of financial institutions to 115 -30- l«>ni as the economy continued to expand. Nonetheless, in the context of still cautious attitudes on the part of bo t h borrowers and lenders, the growth of nonfederal debt probably would remain bel o w that of nominal GDP in the year ahead. At the conclusion ot the Committee's discussion, members all of the indicated that they favored or could accept a t e chnical downward adjustment of one-half percentage point in the tentative ranges for the broader monetary aggregates for 1993 to rates of 2 to 6 percent for M2 and 1/2 to 4-1/2 percent for M3. It was agreed that there should be no change from the tentative range for total domestic nonfinancial debt. In keeping with the Committee's usual procedures under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act. midyear, the ranges would be or sooner if deemed necessary, reviewed at in light of the growth and velocity behavior of the aggregates and ongoing economic and financial developments. Accordingly, by unanimous vote, the f o llowing longer- run policy for 1993 was approved by the Committee for i n c l u s i o n in the domestic policy directive: The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monet a r y and financial conditions that will foster price s t a bility and promote sustainable growth in output. In furtherance of these objectives, the Committee at this meeting established ranges for growth of M2 and M3 of 2 to 6 percent and 1/2 to 4-1/2 percent respectively, measured from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter of 1993. The Committee expects that d e v e l o p ments contributing to unusual velocity increases are likely to persist during the year. The. monito r i n g range for growth of total domestic nonfinancial debt was set at 4-1/2 to 8-1/2 percent for the year. The behavior of the monetary aggregates will continue to be evaluated in the light of progress toward price level stability, movements in their velocities, and developments in the economy and financial markets. Turning to policy for the intermeeting period ahead, all of the members endorsed a proposal to m a intain unchanged conditions in reserve markets, and all indicated that they could ac3ept a d irective 116 - SI - that did not incorporate any presumption with regard to the likely direction of possible intermeeting adjustments to policy. While there was concern about the weakness in the monetary aggregates, the members generally agreed that recent economic developments t e nded to reinforce the view that mon etary policy was on an appropriate course. The economy seemed to be on a stronger growth track than earlier in the expansion, and inflation remained quite subdued--only a bit above some estimates of price stability--and likely to moderate further in coming quarters in the view of most members. Some commented that a further easing move at this juncture might well have adverse effects on inflation sentiment and on interest rates in intermediate* term debt markets. and l o n g A few referred to the recent firming in some commodity prices and the consensus among private forecasters that inflation could drift higher over the next few years. one member, In the v iew of these developments might argue for a tilt in the directive toward possible restraint, but they did not call for an immediate tightening in reserve conditions. A staff analysis prepared for this meeting suggested a resumption of some growth in the broad measures of money later in the first quarter but a decline in both M2 and M3 for the quarter as a whole. W hile part of the declines appeared to reflect reflect difficulties with seasonal adjustments and the ebbing of special factors that previously had boosted growth, the uncertainties surrounding the behavior of these aggregates tended to reduce their role in current monetary policy. N e v e r t h e -l e s s . there was concern about the p ersisting weakness in the broad aggregates, that they would fall well first part of the year. including the likelihood short of the Committee's n e w ranges over the Some members also noted that the growth of # Ml, while still fairly robust in December and January, was m arkedly 117 - b e l o w its pace over most of 1992. 32- On the other hand, bank loans had increased in recent months, and the weakness in the m o n etary aggregates did not appear to reflect underlying softness in the economy. In these circumstances, a number of mem b e r s believed that any effort to stimulate monetary growth under immediately prevai l i n g economic conditions and market expectations might well prove to be counterproductive. An easing at this time could accelerate outflows from interest-sensitive M2 assets if the easing were seen as signaling a weake n i n g of the S y s t e m ’s anti-inflationary resolve and were to result in higher rates on intermediate- and l o n g -term debt securities. At the conclusion of the Committee's discussion, all of the m e m b e r s indicated that they favored a directive that called for ma i n t a i n i n g the existing degree of pressure on reserve positions. They also noted their preference for. or acceptance of, a dir e c t i v e that did not include a presumption about the likely dir e c t i o n of any adjustment to policy over the intermeeting period. Accordingly, in the context of the C o m m i t t e e ’s long-run objectives for price stability and sustainable economic growth, economic, that financial, and giving careful c o n s i d eration to and monetary developments, the Committee decided slightly greater or slightly lesser reserve restraint w o uld be acceptable during the intermeeting period. The reserve conditions contemplated at this meeting were expected to be consistent w ith l i ttle change in the levels of M2 and M3 over the two-month period from January through March. By unanimous vote, authorized and directed, the Federal Reserve Bank of N ew Y o r k was until otherwise directed by the Committee, e x ecute transactions in the System Account in accordance w i t h the follo w i n g domestic policy directive: The information reviewed at this m e e t i n g indicates that economic activity rose appreciably further in the to 118 -33- fourth quarter. Total nonfarm payroll employment registered another small increase in December, and the civilian unemployment rate remained at 7.3 percent. Industrial production posted solid gains over the closing mont h s of the year. Retail sales were up substantially in the fourth quarterr and residential c o n struction activity increased sharply. Indicators of business fixed investment suggest a notable gain in recent months, particularly for producers’ durable equipment. The nominal U.S. merchandise trade deficit narrowed slightly in October-November from its average rate in the third quarter. Recent data on wages and prices have been mixed but they continue to suggest on balance a trend toward lover inflation. Interest rates have declined somewhat since the Committee m e eting on December 22. In foreign exchange markets, the trade-weighted value of the dollar in terms of the other G-10 currencies rose on balance over the intermeeting period. M2 appears to have contracted in December and January, after expanding at a moderate pace over the course of previous months; M3 is estimated to have declined appreciably in both months. From the fourth quarter of 1991 to the fourth quarter of 1992, b o t h M2 and M3 grew at rates somewhat below the lower ends of the C o m m i t t e e ’s annual ranges for 1992. Total domestic no n financial debt appears to have expanded at the lower end of the Committee's monitoring range for the year. The Federal Open Market Committee seeks m onetary and financial conditions that will foster price s t a bility and promote sustainable growth in output. In furtherance of these objectives, the Committee at this m e e t i n g established ranges for growth of M2 and M3 of 2 to 6 percent and 1/2 to 4-1/2 percent respectively, measured from the fourth quarter of 1992 to the fourth quarter of 1993. The Committee expects that d e v e l o p ments contributing to unusual velocity increases are likely to persist during the year. The monitoring range for growth of total domestic nonfinancial debt was set at 4-1/2 to 8-1/2 percent for the year. The behavior of the mone t a r y aggregates will continue to be evaluated in the light of progress toward price level stability, movements in their velocities, and de v e l opments in the economy and financial markets. In the implementation of policy for the immediate future, the Committee seeks to maintain the existing degree of pressure on reserve positions. In the context of the C o m m i t t e e ’s long-run objectives for price stability and sustainable economic growth, and giving careful consideration to economic, financial, and m o n e t a r y developments, slightly greater reserve restraint or slightly lesser reserve restraint w o u l d be acceptable in the intermeeting period. The c o n t e m plated reserve conditions are expected to be consistent 119 -3 4 - wit h little change in M2 and M3 over the period from J anuary to March. At this meeting the Committee discussed a preliminary report of a subcommittee that had been established to examine various issues relating to the release of information about Committee meetings and decisions. All of the members agreed that the Committee should keep the public as fully informed as possible about its monetary policy decisions and their rationale. Such information could reduce uncertainty about the stance of policy and about the factors the Committee takes into account in reaching its decisions. However, release of information should not be allowed to compromise the overriding objective of making and implementing the best possible decisions. process In that regard, the Committee noted that its deliberative requires a free flow of ideas, advance or question hypotheses, including the ability to to speculate on alternative outcomes, and to change opinions in response to the views expressed by other members. The members also needed to feel at liberty during meetings to use a wide array of information that is obtained on a confidential basis; at least some of that information would no longer be provided to the Committee if there were a risk of public disclosure. Moreover, the Committee wanted to give further consideration to the risk that the adoption of a different schedule for releasing information about policy decisions might have the effect, in difficult circumstances, of reducing its willingness to make needed policy adjustments promptly. No decisions were made at this meeting concer n i n g various options for apprising the public more fully or promptly of the Committee's actions, and it was understood that the subcommittee would continue to study the matter. 120 -35- It was agreed that the next meeting of the Committee would be held on Tuesday, March 2 3 . 1993. The m e e t i n g adjourned. Secretary 121 F o r u s e a t 10 a . m . , EDT T u e s d a y , O c t o b e r 1 9 , 1993 S ta te m e n t o f D a v id W. M u l l i n s , J r . V i c e C h a irm a n B o a r d o f G o v e r n o r s o f t h e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s te m W a s h in g to n , D. C . H e a r in g o n I s s u e s R a i s e d b y HR 28 " F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y ste m A c c o u n t a b i l i t y A c t o f 1993” C o m m itte e o n B a n k in g , F i n a n c e a n d U r b a n A f f a i r s U .S . H o u se o f R e p r e s e n t a t i v e s O cto b e r 19, 19 93 122 C h a irm a n G o n z a l e z , C o m m it te e . I a p p r e c ia te y ou r in v it a t io n th a t p o r tio n o f H .R . 28, A c c o u n ta b ility A c t ," o ffe r both C on gressm an L e a c h , th is d e a l i n g w it h d i s c l o s u r e . an d o u t s i d e B e fo r e I a r r iv e d i n W a s h in g t o n , fin a n c ia l e c o n o m ic s f o r p r o fe s s io n a l w r itin g s m arket p a r t i c i p a n t s r e fle c t t o r e p o r t my v i e v s W a s h in g t o n , s e r v in g I t a u g h t an d c o n d u c t e d ov e r a d eca d e. a b s o r b an d i n t e r p r e t F ederal R eserv e, in t e llig e n c e in a v a r ie ty on t h e c o n d i t i o n o f p o lic y array o f c o n c e iv a b le an d t h e o p e r a t i o n s fo r e ig n o ffe r w hat o f t e n t h e m em bers o f t h i s cu rren t r o le , p rocess and th e n a t t h e T r e a s u r y an d t h e of c o n fid e n tia l in s titu tio n s , fo r th e a w id e t h e v ie w s o f o t h e r a g e n c i e s , o ffic ia l th e C on gress, r e g u la to r s , I w o u ld r e s p e c t f u l l y fin a n c ia l in s tit u t io n s . I have i n m e e tin g s w it h o t h e r o f f i c i a l s th e T rea su ry , an d s t a f f an d b a n k in g as w e ll as r e p r e s e n ta tiv e s o f g o v e rn m e n ts and i n t e r n a t i o n a l d e lib e r a tiv e jo b s of in fo r m a tio n c o n t in g e n c y p la n s e m e r g e n c ie s , of o f th e F ed era l R eserv e, F ir s t, of o f fin a n c ia l in s tr u m e n ts , p a r tic ip a te d an d s e c u r i t i e s Many o f my As a p o lic y m a k e r in I have been exposed t o th e flo w s e ttin g s to fr o m my c a r e e r e x p lo r e d th e e s tim a b le a b i l i t y to on t h e B e ltw a y . t h a t k n o w le d g e in m a rk et p r i c e s . r o u tin e ly I w o u ld l i k e C o m m it te e a p e r s p e c t i v e t h a t w as g a i n e d in th e " T h e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s te m in s id e research an d m em bers o f in s titu tio n s . From t h i s fo r e ig n e x p e r ie n c e th ree p o in ts . m ak es new s i s n o t a lw a y s i n f o r m a t i v e . p a n e l a r e w e ll a w a re, p a r t o f t h e is a c t u a lly th in k in g o u t lo u d . I n my w h e t h e r i n m e e t i n g s o f t h e B o a r d o r t h e FOMC o r As in 123 2 le s s fo r m a l s e t t i n g s , I r o u tin e ly en g a ge in who a r e c o n c e r n e d a b o u t t h e n a t i o n ' s on p o s s i b l e p o lic y o p tio n s , d ia lo g u e s w ith o t h e r s in te r e s t, p la n n in g f o r e x c h a n g in g v ie w s c o n t in g e n c ie s t h a t none o f u s h o p e w i l l happen b u t t h a t m ust n o t c a t c h u s u n p r e p a r e d , c o n t e m p l a t i n g t h e m a r k e t 's r e a c t i o n t o w h a t we m ig h t d o . and H u ch o f th e jo b o f a c e n t r a l ban k er in v o lv e s w o r r y in g a b o u t e v e n ts t h a t h a ve a s m a ll p r o b a b i l i t y co sts o f occu rren ce, b u t w o u ld im p o s e l a r g e o n t h e f i n a n c i a l s y s t e m an d t h e e c o n o m y w e r e t h e y t o U n fo r tu n a te ly , th e p u b lic r e le a s e o f serve to fo c u s a t te n tio n o p in io n , th e fe a r s abou t in d iv id u a l s u c h d i s c u s s i o n s w o u ld o n l y on th e s e n s a t io n a l— th e d i f f e r e n c e s co n ce rn s ab ou t w o r s t-c a s e in s titu tio n s , in an d t h e s c e n a r i o s — t h a t n o r m a lly h a v e l i t t l e co n se q u e n ce on n e t t o th e s e t t i n g d i s t r a c t p e o p le occu r. o f p o lic y a n d t h a t w o u ld fr o m m ore fu n d a m e n t a l i s s u e s , a lm o s t c e r t a i n l y h e ig h t e n in g m arket v o l a t i l i t y . S e c o n d ly , lik e ly an d t h i s g e n e r a liz in g s h a r e w i t h a n y o n e who h a s s a t p ro s p e c t o f d e ta ile d o n som e p r o c e e d i n g s . w ord, is fr o m a f r u s t r a t i o n i n many p u b l i c m e e t i n g s , and c o m p l e t e e x p o s u r e t e n d s t o A s p e a k e r h a s t o w e ig h t h e g u a rd in g a g a in s t t h e p o s s i b i l i t y th a t in o p in io n o r c o n d itio n a l s p e c u la tio n s w i l l n ew spapers. One p o s s i b l e h e a d lin e s th a t th e c r i t i c a l th e is s id e lin e s , ou tcom e o f con cern is th is s u b tle th a t th e q u a lit y th e cast a c h ill e ffe c ts of every d is tin c tio n s be s p la s h e d a b o u t th e fe a r o f u n fo r tu n a te con d u ct o f p o lic y g e t s push ed o n to w h ere fe w e r p e o p le c a n p a r t i c i p a t e . c o u ld b e le s s p u b lic d is c lo s u r e th a t I o f th e p o lic y The r e s u l t p rocess. My c h i e f o f p o l i c y m a k i n g w o u ld s u f f e r , w ith 124 3 a d v erse con se q u en ces a d e lib e r a tiv e oth er, fo r th e n a tio n . I f t o o m any p a r t i c i p a n t s g r o u p s p e a k t o t h e r e c o r d r a t h e r th a n t o in each in n o v a tiv e id e a s d o n o t g e t t h e i r due and t h e s e a r c h f o r con sen su s s e t t l e s t o o q u ic k ly on th e s t a t u s qu o o r th e e a s i e s t , th ou g h n o t t h e b e s t , T h ir d , It is th o se cou n ts. our a c tio n s a c tio n s c o n d itio n s t h e m on eta ry p o l i c y Our a c t i o n s m a t t e r , th a t a ffe c t a r e m ade p u b l i c fo r is n o t our d e lib e r a t io n s . i n t e r e s t r a t e s and t h e econ om y, im m e d ia t e ly . an d C hanges in r e s e r v e t h e o p e n fo r u m o f t h e f i n a n c i a l m a r k e t . th e a c t io n th a t a re r e le a s e d an d d i s s e n t s an n ou n ced. ju s t are la id s ix w eeks l a t e r , e x p la in e d . To p r o v id e C h a irm a n o f t h e m em bers o f t h e are t a llie d D is c o u n t r a t e ch a n g es a re a l s o p u b l i c l y to C on gress, th e a s e m ia n n u a l r e v i e w d e c is io n s , fo r c o m m itte e s o f p o lic y . M e a n w h ile , p o lic y th e a summary o f t h e f o r t h e c o m in g y e a r . m em bers o f t h e B o a r d , an d o f f i c i a l s C on gress t o S y s te m On a m o re R e s e r v e B ank o f t h e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s te m o f t e n d i s c u s s a s p e c t s o f m on eta ry s t a f f p ro d u ce a s te a d y strea m t h e e c o n o m y an d c r i t i q u e s in to o f m em bers o f t h e B o a r d an d R e s e r v e B ank an d p l a n s b e fo re a n a ly s e s o f v o te s B a n k in g C o m m itte e an d t h e i r c o u n t e r p a r t s s c h e d u le , p r e s id e n t s , an d a l l a b r o a d e r o v e r v ie w F ed era l R eserve o ff e r s e c o n o m ic f o r e c a s t s p r e s id e n ts , T he o u t i n t h e m in u t e s o f t h e m e e t in g S e n a te e n c o m p a s s in g r e c e n t p o l i c y ir r e g u la r p rocess a r e t r a n s p a r e n t t o t h e m a r k e t b y 1 1 :3 0 am o n t h e d a y o f th e ch an g e in reason s s o lu tio n s . fr o m my e x p e r i e n c e , op en w h ere i t a o f p o lic y th a t are of s it 125 4 p u b lis h e d and t h e in th e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B u l l e t i n , R e s e r v e B ank R e v i e w s , a c a d e m ic p r e s s . T o sum u p my v i e w s o n t h e con cern is th e q u a lity d epen ds upon th e e f f e c t i v e n e s s I b e lie v e is s u e o f d is c lo s u r e , o f m on eta ry p o l i c y of a s u b s ta n tia l d egree o f th e c e n tr a l d e c is io n -m a k in g , t h e FOMC d e l i b e r a t i v e c o n fid e n t ia lity p rocess. n ecessa ry to en su re th e e ffe c tiv e n e s s o f th is v ie w t h a t , on t h e w h o le , t h e c u r r e n t p r o c e s s w o r k s w e l l an d p rop osed s u b s ta n tia l w o u ld t h r e a t e n th e r e fo r e p u b lic th e q u a lity su ch p r o p o s e d of c o n fid e n tia l t im e . have o b serv ed engaged in p la n s t o It is my FOMC d e l i b e r a t i o n s d e c is io n s , i n my v i e w , th e in fo r m a tio n in an d serve th e of I a fte r of as w e ll. or a p p r o x im a t e ly som e o f my p e r s o n a l i n my l o c k e d file s . I o c c a s io n a lly As I b e lie v e C h a irm a n G r e e n s p a n d o r e ta in n o t e s and ro u g h t r a n s c r i p t s som e fo r use in FOMC m i n u t e s . in t e n t io n a l q u e s tio n , le a k in g th e p u b lic , 7 3 -2 0 8 0 - 9 4 - 5 n otes n ote s u b s e q u e n t l y k e p t i n my am a w a r e t h a t FOMC s t a f f you r th ir d th e p re s s keep e d ite d in y ou r I d o o c c a s io n a lly an d a r e d e s t r o y e d t h e FOMC m e e t i n g s th ou g h e d i t e d , As f o r re q u e s te d d u r i n g FOMC m e e t i n g s file s n o te -ta k in g p r e p a r a tio n or oth er o t h e r s p r e s e n t a t FOMC m e e t i n g s d is c u s s , d e ta ile d , to c h a n g e s w o u ld n o t , I a ls o in te r v e n tio n s w illfu l of o f m o n e ta ry p o l i c y sum m ary o b s e r v a t i o n s w h ic h a r e o n e y e a r 's oral to in v it a t io n , v e ry rou gh lo c k e d d is c lo s u r e p rocess. in t e r e s t. W it h r e s p e c t le t te r ch an ges in d e lib e r a tiv e is w h ic h I d o n o t k now o f a n y c a s e o f o f c o n fid e n tia l a lth o u g h I FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n am a w a r e t h a t t h e r e h a s 126 5 b e e n c o n f i d e n t i a l c o m m u n ic a tio n w it h a p p r o p r i a t e s e n i o r a d m in is t r a t io n a v o id r e l e a s e o ffic ia ls . of le a k e d s t o r i e s in fe r e n c e s . c o n fid e n tia l of it is in v o lv e d a r e v e r y c a r e fu l t o in fo r m a tio n , may h a v e r e s u l t e d I n my v i e w , c o n fid e n tia lity W h ile a l l fr o m is p o s s ib le in a d v e r te n c e o r th a t s k illfu l im p e r a t iv e t h a t we e n s u r e t h e FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n , and I can a s s u r e th e C o m m it te e t h a t w e a r e m a k in g e v e r y e f f o r t it to do so. 127 STATEMENT PREPARED FOR THE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES HEARINGS OF OCTOBER 19, 1993 WILLIAM J. MCDONOUGH PRESIDENT, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK 128 Mr. Chairman, you invited me to appear before the Committee to present my independent views regarding the accounting of FOMC meetings. As you know, it is not possible for me to appear at the hearings, but I submit herewith my views, as well as the answers to three questions to me in your letter of September 20. I believe that the primary responsibility of the Federal Open Market Committee is to develop and carry out a monetary policy which contributes to sustained economic growth with price stability. Therefore, I address myself to the question before us guided essentially by whether the present accounting of the FOMC meetings is more or less supportive of that responsibility than would be the case under the provisions proposed in the legislation being considered, H.R. 28. In addition to serving as President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Vice Chairman of the FOMC, I also bring to this consideration a period as Manager of the Federal Reserve System Open Market Account with responsibility for the day-to-day execution of FOMC decisions. In the hope of adding some specialized value to the Committee’s consideration, I will direct my consideration to the market effect of one 129 2 aspect of H.R. 28, release of the policy decision of the FOMC within seven days as compared with the release of the directive the Friday after the subsequent meeting, i.e., with a delay of about seven weeks. We all may have differing views either in general or from time to time regarding the right direction of monetary policy. But whatever these views, the actual carrying out of monetary policy in the best interest of the American people must involve flexibility. Why? It is frequently the case that the right monetary policy conclusion is not an immediate change in policy. On occasion, the FOMC decides that there should be a "tilt” between meetings towards a shift in monetary policy; that "tilt" may or may not result in an actual policy change, depending on how circumstances in the economy and in financial markets play out. The present policy of releasing the minutes and the directive after the following meeting permits this flexibility, since by the time of release under the present policy it is a clear fact whether policy has been changed or not. A person who has not spent much of his or her life in these markets may say that nothing would be lost by immediate disclosure. That is simply not so. I can assure the Committee, based on over two decades of private sector experience in financial markets, that the disclosure of an FOMC 130 3 policy tilt would be translated by the financial markets in moments after the release to an execution of the policy shift. A policy change which the FOMC thought might make sense only if certain economic circumstances evolve would become an executed policy as market participants acted instantly to either profit or avoid loss. In other words, market participants would immediately assume that the policy tilt would become reality and protect themselves by immediately moving market rates accordingly. With that being the case, the FOMC would be deprived of the inter-meeting flexibility which I believe is essential for carrying out the optimum monetary policy. The Committee would be convinced that it could not choose a tilt, even if it thought a tilt was the right decision. The FOMC would be left with only the binary choice of maintaining present policy or changing it immediately. Monetary policy is simply too important to the good of the American people to force it into that kind of arbitrary and inappropriate straightjacket. The greater good of the best monetary policy which the FOMC can devise and carry out must be given priority over a great, but lesser, good of immediately informing the public. Mr. Chairman, you asked that I also respond to three specific questions included in your letter to me of September 20. I provide these 131 4 answers as follows: First, I have made no notes or records of the FOMC meetings I have attended. Second, an officer of the Open Market Function at the New York Fed attends the FOMC meetings to provide backup for the Manager for Domestic Operations, That officer prepares informal written notes during the meeting which are not intended to be a record of events, but rather a guide to the Open Market officers in the day-to-day management of the account between meetings. These notes are given very limited distribution within the New York Fed: to the President, the First Vice President, the General Counsel and the other system account officers, a total of about seven people. Recipients return the notes to the officer who has prepared them and they are immediately destroyed. No file is maintained. The Research Director of the New York Fed is my principal advisor on monetary policy matters. He attends the FOMC meetings and keeps handwritten notes; these notes are not transcribed and are kept in the Research Director’s own files, not those of the Research Group. I have no personal knowledge of any other notes or records that others may have made at FOMC meetings or the release of FOMC meeting 132 5 information prior to the official release of that information. As President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, I appreciate this opportunity to address myself to the Committee. The Federal Reserve was created by the Congress and we are accountable to the American people through the Congress as the people’s elected representatives. I hope that these comments are helpful to you in your deliberations. ###### 133 F o r U se a t 1 0 :0 0 T u esday, O c t o b e r 1 9 , 19 93 a .m . EDT T e s tim o n y by R ob ert T. P re s id e n t P arry an d C h i e f E x e c u t i v e O f f i c e r F e d e r a l R e s e r v e Bank o f b e fo re C o m m it te e o n B a n k in g , U .S . S an F r a n c i s c o th e F i n a n c e a n d U rb a n A f f a i r s H o u se o f R e p r e s e n t a t i v e s . O cto b e r 19, 1993 134 As P r e s id e n t o f th e one o f my j o b s d e lib e r a tio n s T w e lfth up o f is to w it h F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B ank o f c o n tr ib u te in fo r m a tio n to and id e a s F ed era l R eserve D is t r ic t th e n in e w e s te r n t h e m ore r o b u s t sta te sta tes, e c o n o m ie s is fr o m my D i s t r i c t . h ig h ly d iv e r s e : w h ic h a t p r e s e n t in S an F r a n c i s c o , F ederal R eserve p o lic y th e co u n try is in c lu d e (U t a h , N e v a d a ), and on e o f t h e w e a k e s t— C a l i f o r n i a . In h a s s e e n e m p lo y m e n t f a l l (4 .7 b y 592 t h o u s a n d j o b s it The m ade th ree of I d a h o an d fa c t, C a lifo r n ia p ercen t) s in c e m id -1 9 9 0 . W it h t h a t a p p r e c ia tio n d is c lo s u r e (FOMC) in tr o d u c tio n , fo r of t h is th is in th ere v ie w th e in case e x is ts . is I b e lie v e th a t th e re to not to im p o r ta n c e o f t h e d e c i s i o n s to en su re th e e ffe c t iv e n e s s p rocess. In order to is id e a s do s o . of (I be a fr e e expressed 1 9 9 3 .) H ow ever, reason b e in g m ade, it flo w of p o lic y d e c is io n s , in fo r m a tio n and a t e a c h m e e tin g . Some o f th e in fo r m a tio n in h e r e n tly c o n fid e n tia l in d iv id u a l fir m s c o n fid e n tia lity , — d is c u s s e d fo r e x a m p le , at FOMC m e e t i n g s becau se it is p e r ta in s t o an d w as o b t a i n e d u n d e r a p r o m i s e o f or in som e i n s t a n c e s , 1 is th e d e c is io n -m a k in g re a ch th e b e s t p o s s ib le im p o r ta n t t h a t t h e r e d is c lo s e d , su ch a c o m p e llin g e s s e n tia l it b e a p r e s u m p t io n you d a te d J a n u a ry 1 3 , FOMC d e l i b e r a t i o n s , G iv e n t h e s h o u ld s h o u ld b e f u l l y a c o m p e llin g r e a so n my l e t t e r of e x p r e s s my a b o u t F e d e r a l O pen M a r k e t C o m m it te e th a t F ed era l R eserve d e lib e r a tio n s u n le s s to o p p o r t u n i t y t o d i s c u s s my v i e w s o n t h e in fo r m a t io n m e e tin g s . I w o u ld l i k e becau se it p e r ta in s to 135 c o n f i d e n t i a l m a tte rs record s of w o u ld b e It brou gh t is th e ir d is c u s s io n . som e i d e a s ta k en in to id e a s in th e co n te x t o f v e r y n a tu re o f th e m e e tin g s o r t h a t v e r b a tim fr e e of of co n te x t, c o lle c tiv e record s our p o lic y I have c o n s id e r e d m in u t e s w it h w as d o n e u n t i l FOMC f e e l in th e fiv e years— a fte r o b je c t io n s w o u ld b e a s s u a g e d . s tu d y in g th a t su ch be g u a ra n teed . U .S . If tr a n s c r ip t c o u ld I m ig h t a l s o it a m is in te r p r e te d d is c u s s io n s I am in h ib it th e p rocess, lim it to d e t a ile d non a fte r a lo n g d e la y , w ere p o s s i b l e fo r to as en su re th a t an e x t e n d e d p e r io d of m any o f my S u c h r e c o r d s m ig h t h a v e v a l u e t o in th e r e le a s e H ow ever, of I am in fo r m a tio n o f an e a r l y ham per t h e d e l i b e r a t i v e w o u ld r e a c h in g th e a m e e tin g w ere h e l d , r e le a s e c o u ld of a p rocess at FOMC add t h a t t h e p r e p a r a t io n of su ch d e t a ile d m in u t e s w o u ld b e v e r y b u r d e n s o m e , b e n e fits r e tu r n in g r e v e a le d E v en t h e p o s s i b i l i t y m e e tin g s . of d is c u s s io n s . m o n eta ry p o l i c y . a d e la y d is c u s s io n , p rocess an d i n to flo w in g o r v i d e o t a p e s w o u ld a ttr ib u tio n t h e m id -1 9 7 0 s . fr e e i n s t i t u t i o n a l m e m o r ie s . th e m e r its o f t im e — s a y , research ers o r v e r b a tim in fo r m a tio n th a t w h ic h may i n c l u d e s u c h m i n u t e s w o u ld n o t b e m ade p u b l i c s o c ia l a fr e e ly co m m e n ts a t o u r m e e t i n g s , e ffe c tiv e n e s s s k e p tic a l th e any p r o d u c t i v e o r m o d ifie d fu ll con cern ed v e r b a tim lim it Y e t s u c h co m m e n ts c o u l d b e s e r i o u s l y a t p r e v io u s th e V id e o t a p e s th e d e cis io n -m a k in g p r o c e s s . a re d is c a r d e d out o f flo w c o u n tr ie s . i m p o r t a n t t h a t m em bers o f t h e By t h e con sen su s. if o th er o u r m e e t i n g s w o u ld s e v e r e l y a ls o ad van ce in ju s t ify an d I am n o t th e c o s t s . 2 c o n v in c e d t h a t th e 136 A ls o , c u r r e n t ly I b e lie v e t h a t t h e M in u t e s o f a r e m ade a v a i l a b l e d is tilla tio n of a ll p r o v id e FOMC m e e t i n g s t h a t an a c c u r a t e and th o r o u g h t h e co m m e n ts m ade b y me an d my FOMC c o lle a g u e s , w h il e a v o id in g t h e p r o b le m s a s s o c i a t e d a ttr ib u tio n or a c c u r a te ly d e c is io n s w e ll as a v e r b a tim r e fle c ts by c l e a r l y con tra ry t h e ir M in u t e s . p e r io d th e In y o u r fo r m ade i n in d e c is io n id e n tifie d e x p e c ta tio n s s u b s e q u e n t m e e tin g , le tte r c o n n e c t io n w ith I have o f I do ta k e co m m e n ts I p l a n R eserve D is t r ic t o c c a s io n a lly p a r tic u la r file s w it h th e as C o m m it te e b y nam e i n o f p o lic y FOMC m e e t i n g s is th e over th e r e le a s e d a s e s s io n , or record s th a t I have a tte n d e d , you I have and an y n o t e s t h a t o t h e r s h a v e m ad e. in to s a id a t FOMC m e e t i n g s . t h e m e e tin g s n o t e s e c o n o m ie s , c o n c e r n in g a b o u t m o n eta ry p o l i c y , T h ese t h a t a r e on t h e " t a l k i n g p o i n t s 1' a r e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e Bank o f p roced u res. s o m e w h a t fr o m my n o t e s , a tten d t h is n otes abou t s p e c ia l t o p ic s FOMC s e c u r i t y d iv e r g e of p o lic y M oreover, t o m ake a b o u t t h e n a t i o n a l a n d T w e l f t h m e e tin g . a t th e th e m a jo r it y , and n o r m a lly r e q u e s t i n g me t o I d o n o t t a k e n o t e s o f w hat i s H ow ever, to t h a t s u b s e q u e n t m e e tin g . in fo r m a t io n c o n c e r n in g k n o w le d g e le a d in g th e d is c u s s io n . fin a l T he d ocu m en t c o v e r s u n til t h e v ie w s o f an d a r e d ir e c t The c u r r e n t d o cu m e n t an d d i s c u s s i o n s r a is e d fr o m t h e r e a s o n in g , fe w d a y s a f t e r ask ed is s u e s d e s c r ib in g p o in ts m em bers w h o d i s s e n t e x p la in th e record . w it h F ederal and agen da f o r stored S an F r a n c i s c o th e in in lo c k e d a ccord an ce My a c t u a l s t a t e m e n t s o f t e n a n d I a l s o m ake im p r o m p tu 3 a 137 co m m e n ts a t in to e a ch m e e tin g , FOMC m e e t i n g s of in o c c a s io n a lly d is c u s s io n s in th e T w e lfth and a n a l y s i s of of I have no n o t e s . book p rep ared T h is b o o k d e v e lo p m e n ts d e v e lo p m e n ts is s u e s , w h ic h a b r ie fin g D e p a rtm e n t a t t h e B an k. fo r e c a s ts fo r by th e c o n ta in s t h e U .S . ta k e R esearch a n a ly s is econ om y, I a ls o an d a n a ly s is of F ed eral R eserve D is t r ic t , s p e c ia l t o p ic s m on eta ry p o l i c y r e la te d is s u e s to FOMC and r e c o m m e n d a t io n s b y my s t a f f . The D i r e c t o r of R esearch a t th e an d o c c a s i o n a l l y h is co m m e n ts m ade a t FOMC m e e t i n g s w hen t h e y T hese n o te s a n a ly s is th e ir in are w ith in lo c k e d fo r a c c o r d a n c e w ith c o n fid e n tia l in fo r m a tio n d a te, and th e ir w ith a t th e d ir e c tin g FOMC s e c u r i t y resp ect to u n a u th o r iz e d n otes Bank, of a s my a d v i s o r . FOMC p o l i c y T hey a r e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B ank o f stored in S an F r a n c i s c o p roced u res. y o u r q u e s tio n about "le a k s ” I have n ev er d iv u lg e d p erson s p r io r I h ave no in fo r m a tio n in a tte n d D e p a rtm e n t. FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n , to ta k e h a n d -w r itte n own u s e th e R esearch file s F in a lly , a lte r n a te , S an F r a n c i s c o R e s e r v e c o n c e r n in g to th e of a n y FOMC o ffic ia l anyone e ls e r e le a s e d o in g so. 138 FOR R E LEASE ON DELI V E R Y 10:00 A.M. EDT OCTOBER 19, 1993 Statement by- Wayne D. An g e l l Member. Board of Governors of the Federal R e s e r v e S y s t e m before the Committee on Banking, U.S. Finance and U r b a n A f f airs Hou s e of R e p r e s e n t a t i v e s October 19, 1993 139 Mr. Chairman and m e mbers o p portunity to give y o u m y views policy. As perspective I have indicated of the Committee, I a p p r e c i a t e this on the a c c o u n t a b i l i t y of m o n e t a r y p r e viously in co r r e s p o n d e n c e w i t h you, is of one who throug h o u t his career as an elected appointed official has bee n in favor of openi n g g o v ernment to the public and the press. extent possible to ensure that the process f o rmulation is app r o p r i a t e and equitable: to the of publ i c adopt the ve r y best policies. I b e l i e v e the current greatest policy it also d e m a n d s that In some cases, there is a t r a d e - o f f b e t w e e n these two objectives. will explain, procee d i n g s Our democracy demands that the actions of its government be c o n d u c t e d "in the sunshine" government agencies my and As m y stat e m e n t legislati v e r e q u i r e m e n t s for m o n e t a r y policy a c c o u n t a b i l i t y and the Federa l R e s e r v e ' s current policies regarding the provi s i o n of m o n e t a r y p o l i c y i n f o r m a t i o n strike a reasonable b a l ance b e t w e e n these objectives. M o n e t a r y po l i c y is best formulated w i t h i n a f r a m e w o r k that p rovides an app ro p r i a t e de g r e e of i n s ulation f r o m d a y - t o - d a y political pressures whi l e r e q uiring full accountability. Federal R e s erve some insulation, terms for m e m b e r s for example, of the B o ard of Governors budget of the F ederal R e s e r v e T he C ongress gave the by e s t a b l i s h i n g long and b y e x e m p t i n g the System f r o m Co n g r e s s i o n a l appr o p r i a t i o n s of f u n d s . But at the same time, the Congress has p r o v i d e d for full a c c o u n t a b i l i t y of m o n e t a r y policy. As yo u know, t h e B o a r d of Governors is required to report to the Congress on its m o n e t a r y pol i c y plans and obj e c t i v e s t w i c e each year. In hea r i n g s b e f o r e this Committee and the c o r r e s p o n d i n g bod y in the Senate, the C h a i r m a n of the B o ard presents t e s t i m o n y on the m o n e t a r y p o l i c y report and responds fully to your questions on m o n e t a r y policy. Federal Reserve 140 - 2- p o l i c y m a k e r s also t e s t i f y as requested before this and other C o n gressional Committees interest, about m o n e t a r y p o licy and other m a t t e r s of inc l u d i n g a detailed B e yond the s t a tutory provides conduct significant ac c o u n t i n g of our expenditures. requirements, the Federal R e s e r v e additional i n f o r m a t i o n to t he public about the of m o n e t a r y policy. In particular, the Federal Open M a r k e t C o m mittee p u blishe s m i n u t e s of each of its meetings. These m i n u t e s summarize fully the di s c u s s i o n and indi c a t e the a t t e n d a n c e at the meetings. They show the results of all recorded votes, s t atements that by the FOMC explain d i s s e n t i n g votes. Signi f i c a n t including d e c i sions t a k e n should always be made on the basis of r e c orded v o t e s * - i n a ccord wit h an important pri n c i p l e of accountabi l i t y . Each m e m b e r of the Com m i t t e e is a f forded an oppor t u n i t y to part i c i p a t e in the p r e p a r a t i o n of the m i n u t e s omitted. In m y view, so that no individual or shared v iews the minu t e s pres e n t an acc u r a t e account are of each FOMC meeting. W i t h regard to th e ti m e l i n e s s of the release of such minutes, as yo u k n o w the y are pub l i s h e d s h ortly after the f o l l o w i n g Com m i t t e e meeting. It seems to me that such a lag is appropriate. i m m ediate r e l ease of in f o r m a t i o n on the Committe e ' s c on tingencies could increase mark e t volatility, plans for p a r t i c u l a r l y in c i rcumstances whe n the conti n g e n c i e s do not eventuate. v o l a t i l i t y is unnecessary, if concerns The Such and could be e s p e c i a l l y c o u n t e r p r o d u c t i v e about p o ssible v o l a t i l i t y dete r r e d some m e m b e r s of the Federal O p e n M a r k e t Commi t t e e from d i s c u s s i n g suc h c o n t i n g e n c i e s or drove t h e m to r e l ying on implicit or b e h i n d - t h e - s c e n e s unders t a n d i n g s . On balance, the ma r k e t and the public are better s e rved by m o r e d e t a i l and m o r e openness w i t h d e layed p u b l i c a t i o n as co m p a r e d w i t h the 141 -3- realistic alternative of less s p e c i f i c i t y that w o u l d l i k e l y a c c o m p a n y e a r lier publication. Similarly, I believe that p r ovisio n s in the F e d e r a l Reserve System Accountability Act (H.R. videot a p e s or transcripts of Commi t t e e m e e t i n g s w o u l d hav e delete r i o u s consequences. In any setting, 28) that wo u l d require release of t h e recog n i t i o n that o n e ’s remarks will be reported verb a t i m will dampen p a r t i c i p a t i o n of m o s t m e m b e r s discussion. In the context of m o n e t a r y policy, in the such p r o v i s i o n s likely would cause man y policymakers to be m u c h less w i l l i n g to c o n j e c t u r e about future economic and financial developm e n t s , a lternative policies, conditions, or to c h allenge discussions during FOMC m e e t i n g s to appropriate policy decisions. to e x p l o r e o t h e r s ’ views. Under those are less l i k e l y to lead The w i l l i n g n e s s of i n d i v i d u a l m e m b e r s to explore verbally what m a y seem to be l o w p r o b a b i l i t y events m a y be the b e ginning of a ne w pe r s p e c t i v e that elic i t s m ore c a reful w a t c h i n g and continued debate. The process of d e v e l o p i n g a consensus vie w through an open contrarian f o r u m is e s s e n t i a l if m o n e t a r y policy is to lead toward monetary stability. For these H.R. reasons, I b e l i e v e that t h e relevant p r o v i s i o n s of 28 would do little to make the m o n e t a r y p o l i c y process m o r e transparent and, unfortunately, m o n e t a r y policy less effective. w o u l d do m u c h to m a k e the con d u c t In m y view, r egar d i n g disclosure are on the right track: r evi e w of alternative policies w h i l e of our current p r o c e d u r e s T h e y permit a c a reful a l l o w i n g the C ongress and the public to analyze both the p r o cess by w h i c h our deci s i o n s a re reached and their results. In addition to soli c i t i n g m y comme n t s of mone t a r y policy, you also asked about notes on the a c c o u n t a b i l i t y or records r e g a r d i n g FOMC meetings and about p r e mature release of i n f o r m a t i o n p e r t a i n i n g to 142 -4 - the discus s i o n at such meetings. It has been my p r a ctice to take sketchy notes du r i n g the course of FOMC meetings; the n otes solely for my own use, Federal Reserve. are kept, in a locked file cabinet in m y o f f i c e at the Others m a y also take notes, but I h a v e no i n f ormation regarding the location and disposition, others will answer your question themselves. aware of the e x istence and Some yea r s I assume the ago I became of rough transcripts of the m e e t i n g s w h e n I was w r i t i n g a d i s s e n t i n g statement. ava ilable to me a t r a n s c r i p t fro m the previous meeting. The secretary of the FOM C m a d e of m y statements, and only my statements, With regard to premature d i s c l o s u r e of c o n fidential FOMC information, over the years I have bee n t r o u b l e d by t he appearance in the press of information that serves to give c redence to c o n jecture and t h e r e b y damages Federal R e s e r v e credibility, I have no kn o w l e d g e as to the source of such information. Thank y o u again for the opportunity to t e s t i f y on this i m portant subject. 143 For Release On Delivery 10:00 A.M., EDT October 19, 1993 Statement by Edvard W. Kelley, Jr. Member Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Before The Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives Washington, D .C . October 19, 1993 144 Thank you for an opportunity to present my views on HR 28, the "Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993". Pursuant to the request in the Chairman’s letter of invitation, I shall first answer, in order, the three specific questions posed therein and then offer my perspectives on the bill in the area of maintaining a record of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings. Question 1: I have generated rough pencil notes of my own thoughts, and summaries of the views of other members as I under stood them, at most meetings. These notes reside in a locked file in my office. Question 2: I would assume that various persons present at the meetings prepare and keep notes and records of their own, including the FOMC secretariat, but I am unaware of specifically who does what in this regard. Doubtless others will report on their own activities. Question 3: I have no information whatsoever about unauthorized or premature release of FOMC information. Let me move on to comment on HR 28 which would require, among other things, complete release of FOMC meeting proceedings within sixty days. I must oppose this proposal. 145 - 2- It seems to me that the issue here is the reconciliation of two basic principles for conducting public business in a democracy. The first is the obvious requirement that public policy be generated to further the public interest in the soundest possible way. The second is that the public has the right to know what its leaders are doing in the conduct of its business, including how and why they are doing it. While these two principles can often be fully accommodated, there are clearly cases wherein the second, fully implemented, can potentially degrade the first. In such cases, the overriding requirement is that public policy must be of the highest possible quality. The meetings of the FOMC are such a case. In these meetings twelve voting members augmented by the seven additional Reserve Bank Presidents debate and decide important public matters of monetary policy. To work well such an arrangement must proceed in private, where the participants may freely and easily exchange perspectives and confidential information, dispute, alter viewpoints, and work toward discovery of common ground. In this manner, responsible public policy is created. To expose this process to public scrutiny would, in my view, very clearly introduce 146 -3 - an atmosphere that would be detrimental to the final result. The quality of the final result, sound monetary policy to undergird and support our economy, is the most important of the interests in question. I believe HR 28 would be counterproductive in this respect. The requirement remains that the public be as informed as possible in these matters and that those involved in the process be accountable. I believe that the existing procedures for release of FOMC decisions are responsive to the public’s right to be informed. Concerning accountability, FOMC decisions are the result of the votes of the participating members and each participant’s vote is recorded and made public. Affirmative votes are explained in the minutes as released, and dissenting votes are accompanied by individual explanations. Thus, there is complete accountability for results. In summary, I feel that the public’s interest in this matter is best served by maintaining a system wherein the process is confidential and the policy results are made public in appropriate ways, with personal and group accountability for such results. 147 FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY 1 0 : 0 0 A .M . EDT OCTOBER 1 9 , 1 9 9 3 S ta te m e n t by John P . M em b er, L aW are B oard o f G o v ern ors o f b e fo re C o m m it te e o n B a n k in g , U .S . th e F ed era l R eserve S y ste m th e F in a n c e an d U rban A f f a i r s H o u se o f O cto b e r R e p r e s e n ta tiv e s 19, 1993 148 M r. C h a ir m a n a n d M e m b e rs o f t h e C o m m it te e — I to am h e r e w i t h my F e d e r a l O pen M a r k e t C o m m it te e c o l l e a g u e s com m ent o n t h e d e s ig n e d to im p r o v e t h e C o m m it t e e f o r I p a st, of it p resen ted fo r its tw ic e m oves, expressed p erh a p s th e fu lle s t by any c e n t r a l I bank p r o v id e s d e lib e r a tio n s s c r u tin iz e d a ra th er term s p r e s c r ib e d p u b lic a c c o u n tin g in w o r ld . th e of and e v e n see by th e I d o n 't A v e r b a tim m e e tin g s of th e t h e m e m b e rs fr o m o f m on eta ry p o l i c y no p u rpose t o le s s pu rpose c h a r a c te r iz e s b e lie v e b e g a in e d or in a v id e o ta p e is by p u b lic a t io n record on t h e have p a r t i c u l a r l y h ig h a v id e o ta p e r e c o r d in g exch an ge o f o u r m e e tin g s . It p ro v id e d We a r e , of th e fo r flo o r o f th e r a tin g s . of th e O p en M a r k e t C o m m it te e m i g h t s i g n i f i c a n t l y fr e e of o b je c t iv e s t h e F e d e r a l O pen M a r k e t C o m m i t t e e 's tr a n s c r ip t th e by sta tu te. w h ic h m ig h t p r o v i d e p r im e -t im e c o m p e t i t i o n w h ic h th e on t h e f u l l d e s c r ip tio n C o n g r e s s i o n a l C o m m it t e e h e a r i n g s an d s p e e c h e s H ou se, in and a n a ly z e d by e c o n o m i c p e r f o r m a n c e an d f u t u r e in tr a n s c r ip t p r o c e e d in g s , fo r T h e m a n d a te d H u m p h re y -H a w k in s t e s t i m o n y , can h o n e s t ly a v e r b a tim as r a t h e r th a n on th e p r o c e d u r e s a y e a r and in t e n s e ly h is to r ic c o n tin u e , a p p r o p r ia te o v e r s ig h t e f f o r t s d e te r m in e d . p o lic y , you have ask ed a f u l l anc^, t i m e l y u r g e t h e C o m m itte e t o C o n g r e s s an d t h e m e d ia , p o lic y S p e c ific a lly , O pen M a r k e t e a c h FOMC m e e t i n g . co n ce n tra te is o f th e r e q u ir e m e n t f o r s u b s ta n c e o f m on eta ry p o l i c y w h ic h 28 w h ic h a r e p u r p o r t e d l y a c c o u n ta b ility p rop osed w o u ld s t r o n g l y to i n H .R . m on eta ry p o l i c y . com m e n t o n t h e a c c o u n tin g in it ia t iv e s in h ib it i d e a s w h ic h p r e s e n t l y a fte r a ll, hu m an, a n d we a l l of 149 2 have a c e r ta in am ou n t o f s e lf-c o n s c io u s n e s s s t a g e , * 1 a s w e w o u ld c e r t a i n l y be under th e a b o u t b e in g su g g ested "on p r o to c o l. T h i s p r o b l e m w o u ld b e h e i g h t e n e d b y t h e k n o w l e d g e t h a t t h e m a tte rs u n der d is c u s s io n a re h ig h ly m a rk e ts h e r e and a rou n d t h e w o r ld . g iv e s t h e m em b ers o f p r iv ile g e s ju r ie s . s e n s itiv e C o n s u lta tio n Im p o r ta n tly , it a ls o g iv e s th e m ig h t d e l i b e r a t e or o r a v id e o cam era . ju r y d e c is io n s in w o u ld b e s i g n i f i c a n t l y I ch an ged. p u b lic p e rfo rm a n ce . d e c is io n s w o u ld b e a d v e r s e l y d is c u s s io n in fo r m a t io n d e la y e d c a r e fu lly p r o v id e d s c h e d u le , d e s c r ib e d . e d ite d a ffe c te d to d e le te it F in a lly , fo r to is s u e o f th e op en m arket o p e r a t io n s m a rk e t know s a t 1 1 :3 0 or th e q u a lity am e q u a l l y of of su re u n der su ch p o lic y m a r k e t-s e n s itiv e b a s is and r e l e a s e d t h e m e e tin g is be ex p ected , a lte r tim e ly a tr ic k y th e o n som e it fr o m s h ift. r e le a s e one. T h is b u t I w o u ld n o t in h ib it cou rse s o t h e m o r n in g a f t e r w h e th e r t h e r e h a s b een a p o l i c y im m e d ia t e ly d i s c e r n i b l e a s c r ib e w o u ld s u f f e r s ig n ific a n t ly o f t h e C o m m it te e o r th e c a n 't so m e b e h a v i o r a l c h a n g e o n t h e p a r t o f w o u ld b e s u f f i c i e n t d e lib e r a tio n s by b y a m em orandum o f p erh a p s on e y e a r a f t e r O pen M a r k e t C o m m it te e m e m b e rs c o u l d t h in k I I th a t th e q u a lity on a c o n f i d e n t i a l E v en t h e r e , e n jo y . am s u r e a r e g im e o f con cern ed sam e th e p re se n ce o f o f d e v e lo p in g m on eta ry p o l i c y am m uch l e s s c a m e r a 11 C o m m it t e e m em b ers t h e th e p ro c e s s I "in e x c h a n g e e n jo y e d c h a n g e t h e i r m in d s a s j u r o r s i m a g i n e h ow j u r i e s a ta p e re co rd e r fin a n c ia l t h e O p en M a r k e t C o m m it t e e t h e o f o p e n c o m m u n ic a tio n a n d f r e e sam e r i g h t t o fo r of of p o lic y . th e D ir e c tiv e On t h e th e is th e one hand, th e FOMC m e e t i n g s a lm o s t t h e w ay t h e D e s k a t t h e New Y o r k 150 3 F e d e r a l R e s e r v e B an k e n t e r s p e r s p e c tiv e , p u b lic a tio n H .R . 28. th ere of little to FOMC d e c i s i o n s On t h e o t h e r h a n d , w o u ld p r o b a b l y d ir e c tiv e , e ith e r is t h e m a rk e t. d is c o u r a g e So, fr o m th is b e g a in e d o r lo s t fr o m w it h in a w eek, im p u ls iv e ly on su ch s p e c u la to r s . a s y m m e tr ic And, tig h te n in g . n ew s, to l a n g u a g e w o u ld th e t i l t th e d ir e c t iv e of in th e t h e C o m m it te e M a r k e t s m i g h t i^ e a c t n o o n e 's in te r n a lly , of a s y m m e t r ic l a n g u a g e b e c a u s e asy m m etry r e f l e c t s tow a rd e a s e o r a s p rop osed under im m e d ia t e r e l e a s e th e use o f th e best in te r e s t su ch a s t r i c t u r e i n h i b i t q u ic k except a g a in s t in te r -m e e tin g resp on se to c h a n g in g m a rk et c o n d i t i o n s . As to th e th r e e s p e c ific q u e s tio n s in y ou r le tte r of in v ita tio n : 1. I m ake n o n o t e s b u lle t p o in ts coh eren ce. my own co m m e n ts t o t o g e t h e r w ith a l l s u p p lie d by th e s t a f f p r i o r t o a r e g iv e n b y me t o my e x e c u t i v e as soon as th e FOMC m e e t i n g of sou rce FOMC i n f o r m a t i o n . ir r e s p o n s ib le a d jo u r n s . m ade o r r e fle c t lu r k a n y w h e r e n e a r t h e FOMC. of If a n a i v e t e w h ic h s h o u l d b e p u n is h e d to th e fu ll th e n o to r io u s S u ch " l e a k s " and r e p r e h e n s ib le . th ey fo r b y o t h e r m em bers o f t h e C o m m it t e e . I h a v e n o k n o w le d g e o f t h e s h o u ld th e m e e tin g , a s s is ta n t I h a v e n o k n o w le d g e o f n o t e s o r r e c o r d s "le a k s ” assu re a n a ly tic a l m a te r ia ls r e ta in e d 3. o u tlin e T hese, d e s tr u c tio n 2. a t FOMC m e e t i n g s o t h e r t h a n b r i e f to If are u n in te n t io n a l, n o t be a llo w e d in te n tio n a l, th ey e x t e n t o f w h a te v e r to 151 4 r e m e d ie s a r e a v a i l a b l e , n o m a t t e r who t h e c u lp r it may be. I a p p r e c ia te and lo o k th e o p p o r tu n ity t o fo r w a r d t o in a n s w e r in g a n y f u r t h e r q u e s t i o n s m ay h a v e . p a r tic ip a te # th is th e h e a r in g C o m m it t e e 152 F or r e le a s e on d e liv e r y 1 0 : 0 0 am, EDT O c t o b e r 19 f 1 9 9 3 S ta te m e n t b y L a w ren ce B . L in d s e y M em b er, B oard o f G o v ern ors o f th e b e fo re th e C o m m it t e e o n B a n k i n g , U .S . H ou se o f F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y ste m F i n a n c e a n d U rb a n A f f a i r s R e p r e s e n ta tiv e s O cto b e r 19, 1993 153 Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee, I appreciate this opportunity to comment on provisions of the Federal Reserve System Accountability Act (H.R. 28) that pertain to the release of information on monetary policy. The Federal Reserve currently provides a great deal of information to the public about the monetary policymaking process both formally and informally. We report to the Congress semiannually on our objectives and plans for monetary policy, and we provide additional testimony on request. We publish a considerable volume of timely data on our monetary policy actions. In addition, we publish minutes of each FOMC meeting shortly after the following meeting. These minutes fully summarize the discussion at Committee meetings and are reasonably timely. Federal Reserve officials frequently discuss the economic situation and monetary policy in informal contacts with members of the Congress, members of the Administration and their staffs. We publish numerous articles relating to monetary policy in System publications. Members of the Board and Presidents of Federal Reserve Banks have an obligation to the public to explain their policy positions, and we therefore often speak out through speeches and other forums, not just on monetary policy but on economic policy more generally. We go out into communities across the nation, partly to understand the economic circumstances and concerns of all Americans, but also to articulate the Federal Reserve's position on the economy. For example, Mr. Chairman, I have visited the fine city of San Antonio twice during my 23 months as 154 a Governor and have met with citizens from all walks of life to listen to their needs and to explain our mission. In fact, in virtually every city to which I have travelled, over 30 in all since becoming a Governor, I have met with local businesspeople, bankers and citizens to discuss the economy and its direct impact on their businesses and daily lives. X consider the process of carrying on a public dialogue to be central to my responsibilities. or thinking. There are no mysteries regarding my position And I believe the same is true of my colleagues. In my view, the provisions of the proposed legislation directed at increasing the availability of monetary policy information probably would suffer from the law of unintended consequences. Videotaping FOMC meetings would likely reduce the usefulness of these meetings considerably. Participants would hesitate to use hypothetical or speculative examples to explain points, because these examples could be misinterpreted and cause unnecessary volatility in the financial markets. Information learned from meetings and travels is often proprietary in nature, and thus could not be shared if the meetings were taped. More generally, the give and take in the discussion among policymakers would be sharply reduced. Policy discussions would tend to take place outside of Committee meetings, and members of the Board and Reserve Bank Presidents would come into meetings with preconceived views to a much greater degree than is the case currently. Videotapes of these meetings might, in fact, consist of nothing more than prepared speeches by the Board members and 2 155 Reserve Bank Presidents. The ideas that arise in the current process of open, candid discussion would no longer be produced at Committee meetings, and thus would not be reported in FOMC minutes. Their loss would limit the flexibility and give and take of the policy process and in so doing produce the unintended consequence of actually reducing the net amount of publicly available informed debate on monetary policy. I am also skeptical that, on balance, immediate release of the directive would be useful. While there may be some advantages, there are also costs. Under current procedures, market participants and others are able to recognize an actual shift in the Federal Reserve's policy stance on the morning that the change is implemented. Thus, an immediate verbal statement on policy changes would provide no additional information to the market. A requirement to publish information could be damaging in cases where policy contingencies are part of the FOMC directive. In fact, increased market volatility could potentially result due to market speculation. Moreover, such a requirement could diminish the Committee's ability to provide instructions to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to respond to contingencies, potentially hobbling the Federal Reserve's ability to resolve financial crises. Let me turn next to the three specific questions that you posed in your letter of invitation to this hearing. First, I do take very sketchy notes during FOMC meetings to help organize my 3 156 own comments. meeting. These notes are discarded by me after each Second, I believe that others will be describing their own note taking practices and that the Chairman will describe the note taking process of the FOMC Secretariat. Finally, I have no information for the Committee on any premature release of FOMC confidential material. In summary, Mr. Chairman, I believe that there will always be a tension between the benefits of an open and ongoing public debate on economic policy and benefits of confidentiality. Although the current system is imperfect, it is probably better than resolving the current tension in favor of either fuller openness or greater confidentiality. 157 F or r e le a s e on d e l i v e r y 1 0 :0 0 A .M . EDT O c t o b e r 1 9 , 1993 T e s tim o n y b y S u sa n M. M em ber, B oard o f G ov ern ors of th e b e fo re th e C o m m it te e o n B a n k in g , U .S . P h illip s H o u se o f F i n a n c e a n d U rb a n A f f a i r s R e p r e s e n ta tiv e s O cto b e r 19, 7 3 -2 0 8 0 - 9 4 - 6 F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s te m 19 9 3 158 I am p l e a s e d C o m m itte e to to have p resen t th e o p p o r tu n ity my v i e w s on th e to appear r e p o r tin g of b e fo re t h is F ederal O pen M a rk e t C o m m it te e a c t i o n s , w i t h s p e c i f i c r e f e r e n c e t o s e c t i o n s o f HR 28, " F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y s te m A c c o u n t a b i l i t y A c t o f on m a in t a in in g m em ber o f th e m em ber o f th e S in c e a record B oard of of th e 1993" th a t fo c u s FOMC m e e t i n g s . G overnors I am t h e a n d am t h e r e f o r e a ls o n ew est a v o tin g FOMC. jo in in g th e F ederal R eserve B oard, I have been d e e p ly im p r e s s e d b y t h e c a r e a n d a t t e n t i o n g i v e n t h r o u g h o u t t h e S y s te m t o th e i n c o r p o r a t i o n o f a b r o a d r a n g e o f v i e w p o in t s i n t h e d e v e lo p m e n t an d con d u ct of m on eta ry e c o n o m ic m o n i t o r in g i s an d c o n s u lta tiv e B a n k s, s tu d ie s p o lic y . T h is in fo r m a t io n g a th e r in g d o n e t h r o u g h a v a r i e t y o f m ea n s - - c o m m itte e s r e q u ir in g to th e B oard s p e c ia liz e d and su rveys a d v is o r y in d iv id u a l or d a ta or R eserve g a th e r in g , f i n a n c i a l r e p o r t s s u b m it t e d t o t h e B oa rd a s p a r t o f t h e r e g u l a t o r y o v e r s ig h t p rocess, R eserve B ank r e p o r t s and an d s t u d i e s u n d e r t a k e n a s b a c k g r o u n d f o r FOMC d o c u m e n t s . S y s te m in th is a ttr ib u ta b le T he c o o p e r a t i o n en orm ou s to th e c o n fid e n tia lity , tre a te d by th e in ta sk of s e r io u s w h ic h B oard and v a r io u s by e c o n o m ic m o n ito r in g m a n n e r, and R eserve a n a ly s e s th e B e ig e B ook and s t a f f r e c e iv e d b u s in e s s th e th e and th e F ederal in som e e c o n o m ic B an ks. is R eserve no doubt cases in fo r m a t io n T h is th e is c o o p e r a tio n d e m o n s t r a t e s c o n s i d e r a b l e c o n f i d e n c e i n t h e FOM C's p r o c e s s e s an d i s lik e ly b o ls t e r e d stru ctu re of th e by th e u n iq u e q u a s i-p u b lic F e d e r a l R e s e r v e S y ste m , c a r e fu lly o r g a n iz a tio n a l c ra fte d 159 2 - by th e C on gress b a la n c e s , w ith to The m anner i n t h e m a rk e ts c o n ta in th e p r iv a t e w h ic h and th e in m em bers o f FOMC i n th e th e v a r io u s econ om y. th e tren d s in The a b i l i t y fin a n c ia l U .S . th e nu m ber B oard and th e is c r u c ia l n a t i o n a l 's g a t h e r in g b oth of checks an d th e not cen tra l FOMC c o m m u n ic a te w i t h o n ly m a i n t a in bank b u t s u ffic ie n t real to a ls o to in fo r m a tio n and f i n a n c i a l tru st a s s is t to assess secto rs of th e t o r e c e i v e a n d r e l a y t o t h e FOMC c o n f i d e n t i a l in fo r m a tio n c o m p le x in h e re n t s e c t o r a n i n t e g r a l p a r t o f t h e S y s te m . p u b lic and c o n fid e n c e an - is v ita l econ om y. I to a b e lie v e fu ll u n d e r s t a n d in g th at r e le a s in g of a th e lite r a l t r a n s c r i p t i o n o r v i d e o t a p e o f t h e m e e t i n g s w o u ld s e r i o u s l y i n h i b i t m em bers' a b i l i t i e s t o o b t a in and r e l a t e s u ch in f o r m a t io n b e c a u s e o f its p o t e n t i a l m ark et s e n s i t i v i t y . A v id e o ta p e e ffe c ts on stru ctu re th e of or t r a n s c r ip t n a tu re th ose of a ls o c o u ld d is c u s s io n s m e e tin g s a llo w s at a ll have FOMC B oard oth er h a r m fu l m e e tin g s . m em bers p r e s id e n t s an o p p o r t u n it y t o p r e s e n t t h e i r v ie w s . T he and B ank T h e se v o t i n g and n o n - v o t i n g m em bers com e f r o m v e r y d i v e r s e b a c k g r o u n d s , r e p r e s e n t i n g d iffe r e n t p a rts of th e co u n try , and v a r y in g p e r s p e c tiv e s on th e m a c r o e c o n o m y an d t h e o p e r a t i o n o f m o n e t a r y p o l i c y . T he p r o c e s s o f e x p la in in g d iffe r e n t them r e q u ir e s s ig n ific a n t e x p la n a t io n s and c o n s id e r a b le and ta k e . E ffo r ts are m ade r e g io n a l r e n d e rin g by or m em bers e c o n o m ic th e d iffic u lt. v ie w p o in t s If use to com pare and and o b s e r v a tio n s of a lite r a l c o m p le te r e c o n c ilin g g iv e con tra st w ith th ose p rep ared tra n s c r ip t th e ir of oth er sta te m e n ts o r v id e o ta p e o f p a r tic u la r m em b ers, e x tr e m e ly FOMC m e e t in g s 160 - 3 w ere t o b e r e l e a s e d , to speak o n ly a n a ly tic a l in it ia l in a red u ced p o s itio n s . now t r u ly may sta te m e n ts, used in to lim it reach th e ir The c u r r e n t a p p ro a ch t o w h ic h d is c u s s e d and c o n tr ib u te s a llo w s v ie w s to th is r e fle c te d e d it th e d r a ft in th e a p p r o p r ia te . r e c o r d a tio n w it h o u t t h e m in u t e s b e f o r e m in u t e s , an d i n my p e r s o n a l s u b je c t s a ttr ib u tio n , A l l m em bers th e n e x t m e e tin g . make e d ito r ia l I ta k e s u g g e s t io n s as s p o r a d ic p e rs o n a l to r e m in d m y s e l f o f , T h ose h a n d w r itte n n o t e s a r e r e t a in e d c o n fid e n tia l o t h e r m em bers w i l l file s , c ir c u la tio n b u t in any c a s e i s one s h a r e d w ith n o o n e . com m ent o n t h e i r The p r e p a r a t i o n , who th e p r e s s E a r lie r th e e c o n o m i c c o n d i t i o n s n o t e d b y o t h e r m em bers a n d my own on v a r io u s i s s u e s . no t h e ir t o a s s u r e t h a t my own v i e w s a r e a d e q u a t e l y t h e FOMC m e e t i n g s of of p rocess. th is p ro ce s s , know m e m b e rs' a d ju s t s p e c ific in p u b lic o r to th ere c o n s t r u c t i n g and r e l e a s i n g th e of som e t i m e , s in c e th e o t h e r 's M oreover, fle x ib ility To a s s i s t p o s itio n s lo s in g each a con sen su s, n o t e s d u r i n g som e p a r t s f o r e x a m p le , upon p rocess. a n a ly tic a l d e lib e r a tiv e h a v e an o p p o r t u n i t y t o I r e v ie w c o m p le te p resen ted c o n s t r a in e d th ereb y b u ild in g d e lib e r a tiv e c a p a b ility s ta te m e n ts m in u t e s , p rep ared ap p roa ch o b s e r v a tio n s w o u ld b e I b e l i e v e m any m em bers w o u ld f e e l fr o m r e le a s e sh ares p r io r of th e ir its s t a f f 's n otes. an d e d i t i n g o f t h e m i n u t e s t a k e s c o m p le te b e f o r e th is to own o r I p re s u m e in fo r m a tio n o ffic ia l th e m in u te s , th e n e x t m e e tin g . w ith I m em bers of th e r e le a s e of th e r e le a s e . or very r a p id C o m m i t t e e 's d e c i s i o n s a n d d i r e c t i v e s , w o u ld c u r t a i l t h e f l e x i b i l i t y o f t h e C o m m i t t e e 's d e c i s i o n s . T hose d i r e c t i v e s fr e q u e n t ly c o n t a in 161 - 4 or r e fe r e n c e th o u g h th e lo n g e r -r u n p r e c is e s tr a te g ie s fo r m th ose its e lf. th e w o u ld ta k e t o a d o p t, depends on No m a jo r m a r k e t p a r t i c i p a n t c a n f u t u r e s t r a t e g y w i t h o u t h a v in g a n i m p a c t on t h e m a r k e t S u c h a n n o u n c e m e n ts w o u ld b e F ederal R e s e r v e 's fle x ib ilitie s w hen i t w is h e s do s o . X hope C o m m itte e w is h e s s tr a te g ie s s u b s e q u e n t e c o n o m ic d e v e lo p m e n t s . an n ou n ce i t s - to th ese d e lib e r a tio n s . q u e s tio n s . com m en ts I w o u ld are be s e lf d e fe a tin g an d a b i l i t y h e lp fu l p le a s e d to to to th e an d l i m i t a ffe c t th e C o m m itte e resp on d to th e m arket in its a d d itio n a l 162 For release on delivery 10:00 a.m., EDT October 19, 1993 Statement by Edward G . Boehne President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 163 I am pleased to testify on the provisions of Section 4 of H.R. 28, the "Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993," that involve public disclosure of FOMC meetings. Let me begin by saying that I take very seriously my role in FOMC proceedings and have a natural bias toward public disclosure and personal accountability. I also take seriously the collective responsibility of the FOMC to formulate the best possible monetary policy. An essential ingredient in formulating the best possible monetary policy is an effective deliberative process — one that fosters the free flow of information, the ability to speculate about the effects of alternative policies, the general give and take among members, and the ability to reach a consensus. The challenge is how to maintain an effective deliberative process and still achieve meaningful disclosure and accountability. I believe the FOMC's existing procedures provide a workable balance between the need for a process that allows for the formulation of an effective monetary policy and the need for public disclosure and accountability. Let me comment briefly on the specific provisions of the bill. I believe the FOMC already complies with the provision of H.R. 28 that requires that a written copy of 164 2 the minutes of each FOMC meeting be made available to the public within 60 days of the meeting. The FOMC currently releases minutes of its meetings six to eight weeks after each meeting, proposed which consistent period. They current who bill!s regularly, these minutes are quite comprehensive. about those the them information For with read include 60-day is and prospective economic and financial conditions, the pros and cons of alternative policy actions, the reasons a majority favored a particular action, plus comments, by name, of those members dissenting. The minutes the Committee now releases are not as detailed as released prior Memorandum the had Memorandum to some 1976. of But Discussion in disadvantages FOMC's deliberative process. my that that was the old hindered the view I attended FOMC meetings in the early 1970s when the Memorandum was still being prepared. At those meetings, as I recall, members of the Committee tended to stick to their prepared statements and there was less give and take about alternative views of the economy and policy options. This occurred even though the Memorandum was released only with a long lag of five years. I believe the current arrangement of releasing the minutes of the FOMC meeting in summary form but much more promptly than the Memorandum — has 165 3 served the deliberative process well, while at the same time providing relatively prompt public disclosure. For the same reasons, I believe the bill's provisions to require a verbatim transcript or videotape of each meeting would impede the FOMC's deliberative process. They would tend to lock members into prepared statements and reduce the give and take of discussion. Innovative proposals could easily be stifled. would be proposing less willing policy to play alternatives, devil's and the Members advocate in quality of monetary policy decision-making would suffer accordingly. With regard to the bill's proposal for public release of the directive or other FOMC decisions within one week, I believe such a provision would not be very helpful to the public. The directive is best read along with the minutes of the meeting. currently meeting. released together Indeed, the two are within 60 days of each To release the directive earlier is likely to confuse, rather than clarify, people's perceptions of the stance of monetary policy because they will not have the full context in which the directive was prepared. Consequently, I do not favor this provision of the bill. Mr. Chairman, in your letter of invitation to appear today, you also requested my comments on three other areas. Let me now turn to those. First, during my 166 4 tenure as President of the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, which began in 1981, I have not taken notes during FOMC meetings. My economic advisor usually takes handwritten notes during meetings, which are then kept in a locked file cabinet with other materials prepared for each FOMC meeting. should He uses these notes to identify issues that be briefings. investigated for future pre-FOMC economic And finally, I am aware, of course, of news stories that have discussed the premature release of information about FOMC meetings. I deplore such leaks. Security of FOMC information is taken very seriously at the Philadelphia Reserve Bank, and X do not have any direct knowledge about how such leaks occurred. 167 For use at 10:00 a.m. EST Tuesday October 19, 1993 Testimony by J. Alfred Broaddus, Jr. President Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs U. S. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 168 l I am pleased to be here today to discuss the procedures the Federal Open Market Committee follows in recording policy information and releasing it to the public. My views in this area are based on two principles. First, these procedures should enable us to make the best possible monetary policy decisions. Second, in general we should release as much information to the public on our policy decisions as promptly as possible, provided such release does not compromise our ability to make sound decisions. reflect substantial experience with the Committee. My views also Although I have been in my present position only since the beginning of the year, I previously attended committee meetings as an advisor over a period of approximately 20 years. At each FOMC meeting, the Committee reviews current and prospective economic conditions, discusses current policy issues, and then decides on an appropriate policy direction. This decision is communicated to the Trading Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York in a "directive" that instructs the Desk to take actions in the money market that are consistent with the desired policy direction. document. The directive is the Committee's primary policy It contains the Committee's decision on whether to ease or tighten reserve conditions or leave them unchanged immediately following the meeting. It also signals, through the symmetry or asymmetry of some of its language, the most likely direction of any prospective changes in policy during the period up to the next meeting. Currently, the directive for a particular FOMC meeting is released immediately following the next meeting along with a "record of policy actions.” This record provides a lengthy and thorough summary of the discussion leading up to the Committee's policy decision. It indicates in considerable detail the views of those supporting the decision and contains a 169 2 full explanation of any dissenting votes. It also lists by name the Committee members voting for or against the policy decision. As a long-time attendee at FOMC meetings, I can attest that the record of policy actions always conveys the content and flavor of the Committee's deliberations as well as its specific decisions fully and accurately. In my view, the record fully satisfies the need for the Committee to be accountable to the public. HR 28 would change these procedures in two ways. First, it would require that videotapes of FOMC meetings be made and released along with verbatim transcripts within 60 days. Second, it would require that Committee decisions (i.e. the directive) be released within one week. Let me comment on each of these changes. FOMC Policy Discussions. My views on releasing videotapes and verbatim transcripts of FOMC meetings have not changed since I responded to Chairman Gonzalez on this issue earlier this year. I believe that the prospect of a literal record, even if it were released after a long period of time, inevitably would introduce a self-consciousness into Committee proceedings that would seriously inhibit the flow of information and ideas. Members would almost certainly be reluctant to speak and argue as freely and frankly as they do now if they knew that their statements would be recorded and released publicly. In sum, I believe that releasing a literal record of Committee meetings in any form would restrain Committee members in debate, undermine the deliberative process, and therefore risk lowering the quality of policy decisions. While I cannot support release of a videotape or any other verbatim transcript of the FOMC meetings, I do believe that there might be benefits from releasing a nonliteral but relatively complete record of FOMC proceedings 170 3 similar to the "memorandum of discussion" that we prepared until 1976, i f there were a long and enforceable delay of the release. As I said in my earlier letter, such a record would assist researchers interested in monetary policy by helping them focus more clearly on the issues that most concerned the Committee at a particular meeting and by strengthening their appreciation of some of the more practical aspects of formulating policy. Over a long period of time it might also provide a clearer picture of the evolution of the positions of various members of the FOMC than is currently available, which some researchers might find useful. I believe strongly that such a nonliteral record should only be released after a delay of several years, such as the five-year period in the case of the memorandum of discussion. Early release of even a nonliteral record like the memorandum could inhibit FOMC discussion and reduce the quality of monetary policy decisions. Consequently, I think it is essential that any reinstitution of something like the memorandum of discussion be accompanied by a legislative guarantee that it would not be released prematurely. FOMC Policy Decisions. The second change proposed in HR 28 is to release the directive one week after an FOMC meeting. both for and against this proposal. Arguments can be made Earlier release would be consistent with the general principle that we should inform the public of policy decisions as soon as possible. At the same time, I believe that early release of the directive could well have announcement effects that could create unnecessary volatility in interest rates. The FOMC's policy decision at a particular meeting is often conditional on economic data that become available in the period after the meeting, and the language of the directive frequently reflects this conditional element. If the directive were released soon after 171 4 the meeting, interest rates typically would react immediately to any policy action contemplated in the directive even though the actual policy action had not yet been taken. If the action subsequently did not take place, then the initial reaction of rates would be reversed. One can distinguish, of course, between the part of the directive that announces the Committee's decision regarding any immediate policy actions and the part that may predispose the Committee to undertake a particular future action. It is the latter, conditional part of the current directive that causes my concern regarding financial volatility because it suggests a direction in future policy that may or may not be implemented subsequently. This problem could be dealt with by removing the conditional language from the directive. Doing so, however, could well reduce the usefulness of the directive, both as a policy instruction to the Trading Desk and as a focal point for the Committee's deliberations. The Committee would need to consider very carefully the potential loss from changing the form of the directive before making any such change. Notes on FOMC Meetings. Let me respond now to the specific questions raised in Chairman Gonzalez's letter regarding my knowledge of notes made at FOMC meetings. As I indicated earlier, I have attended FOMC meetings for a number of years, mostly as the advisor to the president of the Richmond Reserve Bank. While in this advisory position I took notes in order to serve the president more effectively. Monetary policy is a continuous process in which particular issues, such as how to interpret the behavior of the monetary aggregates, frequently recur at subsequent meetings. Consequently, it is sometimes helpful, in preparing for a meeting, to be able to review the discussion of a particular issue at an earlier meeting. I used my notes for 172 5 this purpose during my years as an advisor. The notes were handwritten, were never transcribed to typewritten or any other form, and were not distributed to anyone. I have always kept these notes in locked, confidential files. I should add that I have taken only very partial notes since assuming my current position at the beginning of the year. I now rely on the notes taken by my advisor, who follows exactly the same procedures I did. I have only limited knowledge of notes or records made by other FOMC participants and have not read or used any such notes. Finally, I do not personally know of any information that has been released by anyone at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or elsewhere in the Federal Reserve to persons outside the Federal Reserve prior to its official release. 173 ORAL TESTIMONY presented to House Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban A ffairs by Thom as M. H oenig President Federal Reserve Bank o f Kansas City Kansas City, M issouri October 19, 1993 W ashington, D.C. 174 G o o d morning, Mr. Chairman and members o f the Committee. M y name is Thom as M. H oenig, and I am president o f the Federal Reserve Bank o f Kansas City. This bank serves the Tenth Federal Reserve District, which includes C olorado, Kansas, Nebraska, Oklahoma, W yom in g, the northern half o f New M exico, and the western third o f M issouri. I am pleased to have the opportunity to express m y views on the disclosure o f inform ation from Federal Open Market Committee (F O M C ) meetings. The Federal Reserve must be accountable for its actions and has an obligation to disclose as much inform ation as possible about its deliberations and decisions subject to maintaining the highest possible level o f p olicy effectiveness. It is m y b elief that the Federal R eserve’ s current disclosure policies achieve these ends. The current policies provide a detailed accounting o f F O M C deliberations and decisions. The minutes o f F O M C meetings are comprehensive. They docum ent the inform ation considered during a meeting and the decision o f each voting m ember. M oreover, the minutes provide the rationale fo r the m ajority’ s decision and include statements filed by m embers w h o dissent from the majority. In addition, the Federal Reserve reports regularly and frequently to Congress, ensuring further that we are accountable for our monetary p olicy actions. Current procedures foster an environm ent o f open and candid discussion am ong the m em bers o f the F O M C . V aluable information from a variety o f sources is brought to the discussion, som e o f it provided with the understanding that it be kept confidential. The give and take am ong members provides an opportunity to clarify issues and allow s the F O M C to synthesize a range o f views. A ny proposals that w ould impair this deliberative process, given current procedures that ensure accountability, 175 w ould com prom ise the quality and effectiveness o f Federal Reserve monetary p olicy. Current procedures, in my opinion, also strike an effective balance between timely disclosure and the need for flexibility in the con d u ct o f monetary policy. These procedures, which provide for the release o f the minutes shortly after the subsequent meeting, allow the FO M C to respond flexibly to various contingencies over the intermeeting period. Earlier release o f the minutes w ould restrict this flexibility and could have the unintended effect o f contributing to market volatility. With regard to the three specific questions posed to me in Chairman G on za lez’ s letter o f September 24, 1993, m y answers are as fo llow s. One, I make brief notes for my personal use during F O M C meetings. Our bank’ s Research D irector also occasionally takes notes. These notes are kept in locked files, as is other confidential F O M C material. T w o, I have observed other participants taking notes during F O M C meetings, but I have no know ledge o f their content or disposition. Three, I have no information about the release o f information by anyone em ployed at the Federal Reserve about FO M C meetings prior to the official release o f that inform ation by the Federal Reserve. In closing, let me reiterate that I believe the F O M C must be accountable for its actions, and I believe that its current disclosure p olicies are appropriate and effective in achieving this end. They provide the public with com prehensive information about the F O M C ’ s decisions and deliberative process and they enhance the Federal R eserve’ s ability to pursue the nation’ s objectives o f e c o n o m ic growth and price stability. That concludes my statement, Mr. Chairman. Thank you. 176 FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY 10:00 A.M. EDT OCTOBER 19, 1993 Testimony by Jerry L. Jordan President Federal Reserve of Cleveland before the Committee on Banking, Housing, Finance and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 177 M r Chairman and Members of the Committee, I welcome the opportunity to appear before you this morning to discuss the release of information about the meetings of the Federal Open Market Committee. Before I respond to the three specific questions raised in your letter of September 24, 1993, I would like to address a general issue that I believe is highly relevant. The questions of what information to release and when to release it must be answered in the context of accountability for achieving clear, unambiguous objectives for monetary policy. If the FOMC is charged with conflicting or unattainable objectives, discussions about the appropriate timing and content of disclosure could easily reflect misplaced priorities. Congress could best contribute to a clarification of the FOMC's policy direction by enacting the Neal Resolution, which specifies an ultimate goal of achieving the highest sustainable rate of real economic growth through the maintenance of purchasing power stability. The timing and content of disclosure become less contentious issues in the presence of a credible framework for monetary policy. Markets operate more efficiently with knowledge of the collective thought process that generates Committee decisions. Such information allows people to deal with uncertainties about how policy actions might respond to unknowable future developments. It takes some time to ensure members' agreement on an accurate portrayal of a meeting, and to remove sensitive material. Thus, the minutes of a meeting, describing the climate and substance of Federal Open Market Committee decisionmaking, are released only after their formal acceptance, at the next regularly scheduled meeting. Meeting minutes are released through an orderly process that guarantees equal access for everyone who wants to receive them, simultaneously, at 178 numerous sites nationwide. In the interim, prior to release, actions in the open market are taken in accordance with a publicly understood procedure. Within seconds of any market action, electronic information services communicate the facts nationwide. As a member of the Committee, I find it objectionable to see news stories that are not written on the basis of the Committee's well-defined, orderly procedures for information security and release. I do not condone the actions of individuals who unilaterally release such information, even through inadvertence. Chairman Greenspan indicated last week that measures have been taken to ensure that the procedures adopted by the Committee are followed. You have asked me to respond to three specific questions. First, I do not take notes at an FOMC meeting. At the first few meetings I attended in 1992, I took a few notes during Committee meetings to remind me later of issues raised in the course of discussion, but soon decided that I did not need notes to remind me of the important issues. If I want staff analyses of theoretical or empirical issues in preparation for subsequent meetings, I discuss the issues with senior policy advisers. All this is done in accordance with the Committee's standard rules for maintaining confidential FOMC information. We adhere to a "need to know" policy when relating information to research economists conducting studies on policy issues. Second, I have not questioned any other participants in FOMC meetings about the procedures they follow, and consequently am not aware of whether they keep notes or records of the meetings. Finally, I have no information about the premature disclosure of FOMC meeting materials by anyone employed at the Federal Reserve. - 2 - 179 For release on delivery 10:00 a.m. EDT October 19, 1993 Remarks of Silas Keehn, President Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago before the United States House of Representatives Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs Washington, D.C. October 19,1993 1 80 Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: As requested, let me briefly summarize my views on the question of the appropriate record keeping and public release of the deliberations of the Federal Open Market Committee. As I stated in my letter of January 13 of this year to the Chairman of this Committee, I fully support Chairman Greenspan’s previously stated position on the various proposals for maintaining and releasing a more detailed record of the FOMC’s deliberations. In my view, the minutes of the FOMC, as they are currently written, provide the right level of reporting and detail necessary to communicate the current policy concerns and actions of the Committee. The minutes explicitly document the full range of policy arguments made during the discussion and when a member of the Committee disagrees with the resulting consensus, that member’s dissent becomes an integral part of the public policy record. Based on my participation in FOMC deliberations, I believe that releasing more detailed minutes, most especially a verbatim transcript of the meeting, without a significant delay would be counterproductive and would impede the development of sound monetary policy — first, by limiting the free flow of necessary information into the policy process and second, by hindering the consensus process so essential if policy is to adequately reflect economic conditions in all regions of the country. As President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, I have an important responsibility to convey to the FOMC the economic conditions of the Seventh Federal Reserve District. To meet this responsibility, I and other senior members of our staff maintain extensive contacts with District businesses (large and small), community groups, and state and local government officials. From 181 these individuals we are able to gather a wide array of highly significant information about the District that cannot be derived from the public data sources — information not only about current economic conditions, but about changes in business practices, future production, labor negotiations, investment and hiring plans and a host of other issues that have important value to the policy process. This type of information is particularly important at the present time. The economy is going through a very different phase than any that we have experienced in the past. Many of the economic indicators that have been useful guideposts in developing policy in the past are now proving unreliable. In such an environment, I find the regional information derived from local contacts, both about the Seventh District and elsewhere in the country, essential to the policy process. In the context of these hearings, it is important to understand that much of the information that these contacts provide is highly proprietary and very confidential in nature. I have absolutely assured these contacts that the source and nature of the data will not be divulged in a way that they would find compromising. I have never had anyone decline to speak with me about their activities. If I could not provide such assurances, then much of this significant information would not be forthcoming and the development of monetary policy would be impeded. It is precisely this type of information about local businesses, communities and financial institutions that demonstrates the value of the regional structure of the Federal Reserve System and District representation on the Federal Open Market Committee. The impact of releasing such information as part of the written record of the FOMC without a significant delay would only -2- 182 result in the exclusion of this vital information from the FOMC policy discussion. In my view, this would not be in the public interest, especially when the current system of disclosure is able to convey an accurate description of the key issues and arguments underlying the FOMC decisions, as well as record individual votes and dissenting positions. If it became necessary to prepare more detailed minutes, then they should only be released after a period of five years and with alt confidential information about individual corporations excised, as well as confidential information about foreign countries, foreign central banks and international institutions. As to the specific questions you asked us to address: I prepare an outline of economic conditions in the District which forms the basis for my remarks at each meeting of the FOMC. After the meeting, these notes are kept secured in my office until the next meeting at which time I destroy them. I do not maintain notes on the discussion that takes place at the meeting itself and Chairman Greenspan is in a better position to describe the records that are kept by the FOMC Secretariat. As to the premature release of information from the FOMC meetings, I have not talked to the press or other outside contacts, nor to other Federal Reserve officials who do not have authorized access to FOMC information and my only direct knowledge of such premature releases arises from articles that I have seen in various newspapers. I completely concur with Chairman Greenspan that premature releases of this type are highly inappropriate and totally unacceptable. Thank you. - 3 - 183 For release on delivery 10 a.m. E.D.T. Tuesday, October 19, 1993 Statement by Robert D. McTeer, Jr. President Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives Washington, D.C. October 19, 1993 184 Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for your invitation to te stify on HR 28. As requested, I w ill limit my testimony to the issue of FOMC records, although I do have opinions on other parts of HR 28, especially the part that puts me out of work. I became President of the Dallas Fed in February 1991, so I'm a relative newcomer both to the FOMC and to your great state of Texas, Mr. Chairman. As the bumper sticker says, " I w asn't born in Texas, but I got there as soon as I could. " Prior to moving to Texas tw o and a half years ago, I was w ith the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond for 23 years, the last 11 of which I served as manager of its Baltimore Branch. I have participated in FOMC meetings since 1991, but did not vote until this year. You asked us to respond to three specific questions regarding note-taking in FOMC meetings. Regarding my own practice, I don't take notes of the type I assume you mean. I do a lot of reading and homework prior to the meeting, and I go into the meeting w ith some tentative ideas in mind. I doodle during our discussion and occasionally w rite down a word or phrase for reference when I speak. I don’t w rite down decisions because they are simple and easy to remember and 1 185 come at the end of the meeting. My doodles and notes would be of no use to traders or journalists. I destroy them after the meeting and rely only on official documents for future reference. Regarding your second question, notes kept by others, my impression is that most other members and sta ff probably follow a pattern similar to my own since all who are present presumably have access to the official records and documents. A t least, I have no knowledge to the contrary. In answer to your third question, I have no information about the premature release of FOMC information by anyone at the Federal Reserve. Let me add that, in my opinion, if someone wanted to leak valuable information about the Com m ittee's decisions, such notes would not be necessary nor even very helpful. While the decision process may be difficult, the decisions themselves are simple and easy to remember. Let me comment briefly on other aspects of meeting records. As a former economist, I have some sympathy for the idea of immediate release of the directive. Immediate release of the decision would eliminate any question of leaks or the appearance of leaks. The practical problem w ith immediate release of the directive is 2 186 that not all decisions are clear-cut decisions to ease, tighten, or remain unchanged. On occasion, the Committee votes to hold steady, pending further information or developments, and wishes to give the Chairman extra leeway to act on his own prior to the next scheduled meeting. More often that not, I believe, these "asymmetric directives" are not acted on, but occasionally they are. To announce a decision of "no change" w ithout the proviso would be misleading, and to announce it w ith the proviso would likely cause the markets to react in a way not necessarily warranted by subsequent information. Given this dilemma, I believe the current arrangement is best. Markets are able to discern the immediate decision by watching the federal funds rate the following morning, and we retain maximum flexibility to react to incoming data and changing circumstances w ithout misleading anyone. Then as soon as another meeting is behind us, we release the directive that includes the prevailing circumstances, the rationale for the decision, and the identity of any dissenters and their reasons for dissenting. 1, personally, have a greater problem w ith videotaping and verbatim transcripts of discussions than w ith prompt release of 3 187 decisions. I believe that videotaping or verbatim transcripts, no matter when they are released to the public, would diminish the quality of our deliberations. My colleagues and I are willing to listen to each other and adjust our initial leanings in the interest of consensus-building. We currently don’t posture for the record or for the camera. There is no winning or losing the debate. There is no playing to the gallery or to the folks back home. This, i'm afraid, would all change w ith videotaping or its equivalent. I would much prefer present arrangements even w ith more detail added, so long as the detail involves the substance of the discussions and decisions rather than the language used. I would also have no objection to detailed minutes (not a verbatim transcript) being released after a lengthy period, so long as the legal obstacles to a decent delay could be overcome. 4 For release on delivery 10 a.m. EDT October 19, 1993 Statement by Thomas C. Melzer President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs United States House of Representatives October 19, 1993 189 I am pleased to appear before the Committee today to testify on Section 4 of the Federal Reserve System Accountability Act of 1993, entitled "Prompt Public Disclosure of Open Market Committee Meetings." As a creation of Congress, the Federal Reserve System is fully accountable to the public for its monetary policy actions. One way the Federal Reserve ensures this accountability is by releasing information about its policy decisions. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) provides a full accounting of its actions in its "Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee" (Minutes). The Minutes contain all important information about FOMC decisions, including the policy directive agreed upon by the majority and the reasons underlying policy decisions. Any significant differences among those voting with the majority, as well as the views of any dissenting members, are included in the document. The Minutes are released upon their approval by Committee members at the next FOMC meeting. The public record thus contains the outcome of FOMC deliberations and the policy views of each member of the committee. I am not in favor of producing a further detailed account of FOMC deliberations, either in the form of an edited transcript, such as the "memorandum of discussion," verbatim minutes, or an audio or videotape. Such a release would impede the deliberative process and thereby impair policymaking. Arriving at appropriate policy often involves considerable give and take, consensus-building and debate of alternative actions. Because of the possibility that a particular statement might be misunderstood or taken out of context, FOMC members would be reticent to engage in the kind of open discussion that leads to good policymaking if they knew that all of their statements would be in the public record. Furthermore, the release of verbatim minutes or any other detailed record of deliberations would discourage other parties from supplying the FOMC with confidential information that is useful in determining appropriate policy. 190 Turning to the timing of the release of the FOMC policy directive, I believe that immediate release of the outcome of FOMC deliberations would interfere with the deliberative process and would lessen the flexibility with which the Federal Reserve can respond to changing economic conditions. If directives were released immediately, the FOMC might be reluctant, even if economic conditions warranted, to take a timely subsequent action because of concern that such action would add to the uncertainty in financial markets. In addition, the FOMC would be less inclined to bias its directives toward ease or restraint, in effect limiting its policy options. Consequently, reaching a consensus among FOMC members would be difficult, which might delay policy actions and add uncertainty to financial markets. Finally, let me turn to the specific questions that I was asked to address in my statement. • In response to your inquiry about my own notes or records, I usually take some notes at FOMC meetings for my personal use. They are not typed, copied or shared with anyone else and are maintained in a locked file cabinet in my office. • Your second question concerns my knowledge of notes or records that others have made at FOMC meetings. Though others who attend FOMC meetings sometimes appear to take notes, I am unaware of their content, disposition or location. • In response to your third query, I have no knowledge about the release of information on FOMC meetings prior to its official release by the Federal Reserve. To sum up, the Federal Open Market Committee is committed to informing the public of its policies, which ultimately must be judged by their results. The "Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee" convey fully the relevant information about FOMC decisions and do so in a timely way. Thus, in my view, there is little to be gained by providing detailed minutes or mechanical reproduction of FOMC deliberations, while the adverse 191 consequences of doing so are potentially very great. In addition, the benefits of immediate release of the policy directive would not seem to outweigh the potential costs of doing so. By inhibiting the frank exchange of views and possibly reducing the willingness of the FOMC to take timely actions, public release of the details of committee deliberations or immediate release of the policy directive could harm the policymaking process. Though intending to increase the accountability of FOMC members, the proposed changes specified in HR 28 may thus impede monetary policy performance. Thank you. 192 For Release at 10:00 a.m. E.S.T. October 19, 1993 TESTIMONY by Gary H. Stern President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 193 SUMMARY Mr. Chairma n and members of the Committee, to discuss Committee I a p p r e c i a t e this o p p o r t u n i t y issues re l a t e d to mainta i n i n g a rec o r d of Fe d e r a l O p e n M a r k e t (FOMC) meetings and procedures fol l o w e d at the Federal R e s e r v e Bank of Minneapolis to handle confidential m o n e t a r y p o l i c y material. indeed, significant matters. I will try to keep m y comments Th e s e are, direct and succinct this m o r n i n g and ask that my complete s t a t e m e n t be inc l u d e d in the record. As indicate d in my Ja n u a r y correspondence, considerable value I am c o n v i n c e d there is in our current report of FOMC p r oceedings. As y o u know, we release extensive minutes of each FOMC m e e t i n g s h o r t l y after the subse q u e n t meeting. The minutes describe the dis c u s s i o n and the votes of individual members. More specifically, here and abroad, price developments, and monet a r y aggregates. the economy, they include an a s s e s s m e n t of bus i n e s s conditions and the p e r f o r m a n c e of f i n ancial mark e t s They report the Commit t e e ' s vi e w s of prosp e c t s for frequently including info r m a t i o n g l e a n e d from per s o n a l contacts in individual Federal Reserve Districts. The m i n u t e s also report d i s c u s s i o n of m onetary poli c y options as well as the d e c i s i o n u l t i m a t e l y re a c h e d b y the Committee, including dissents, if any, a n d the logic u n d e r p i n n i n g the dissents. This amounts to a g ood deal of i n formation in m y view, merit in suggestions FOMC deliberatio n s to p repare and release, a literal re c o r d of -- t hrough videot a p i n g or other vehicles. partic u l a r concern me. at any time, First, and I do not find Three issues in given the g ravity of our r e s p onsibilities, I 194 b elieve it imperative that the quality of our deliberations be maintained. O pe n discussion of ideas, of p o l i c y alternatives, and of s i g n i f i c a n t p o tential risks to the econ o m y are c r itical to sound policymaking. the information we discuss Secondly, some of is v o l u n t a r i l y provi d e d on a c o n f i d e n t i a l basis. We have an obliga t i o n to m a i n t a i n that confidentiality. Thirdly, I believe our procedures caref u l l y b a l a n c e the n e e d to p rovide i n f o r m a t i o n to the p u b l i c w i t h the ne c e s s i t i e s of effective monet a r y policy. Even small changes ca r r y the considerable risk that they will disturb, perhaps u n k n o w i n g l y an d u nintentionally, this balance, w i t h adverse consequences for f i nancial mark e t s and economic performance. As i n d icated in my e arlier correspondence, I believe there could be some m e rit to r e i n t r o d u c t i o n of something like the "memorandum of d i s c u s s i o n , " a ver y detailed, altho u g h edited, accounting of FOMC discussions, p r o v i d e d that the c o n f i d e ntiality of such material is assured for several years. it, such a document coul d be useful to historians and students policy whe n they investigate As I see of m o n e t a r y the br o a d context of p o l i c y decis i o n s and the evolution of the p o l i c ym a k i n g process. Finally, in response to yo u r specific inquiries about c o n f i d e n t i a l i t y , I am unaware of any unau t h o r i z e d release of monetary policy i n f o r m a t i o n ever e manating from the Federal R e s erve Bank of Minneapolis. My ec o n o m i c advisor and I leave h i g h l y confid e n t i a l material at the B o ard of G o v e r n o r s and do no t return wit h it to Minneapolis. does my advisor. strict guidelines, I take limited notes during the meeting, as A ll notes and other materials are h a n d l e d a c c o r d i n g to the essence of which is to limit their d i s t r i b u t i o n and 2 195 access and assure proper disposal. appended to m y complete testimony.) (A c opy of our B a nk's pro c e d u r e s T h a n k you. 3 is 196 TESTIMONY Mr. Cha i r m a n and members of the Committee, to discuss Committee (FOMC) meeti n g s of Mi n n e a p o l i s indeed, As I appreciate this o p p o rtunity issues rela t e d to mainta i n i n g a record of Federal Open Mark e t and procedures followed at the Federal Reserve B ank to hand l e confidential monetary policy material. These are, significant matters. i ndicated in my J a n u a r y correspondence, considerable value I am convinced there is in our current report of FOMC proceedings. As y o u know, we release extensive minutes of each FOMC meeting shortly after the s ubsequent meeting. The minutes describe the discussion and the votes of individual members. M o r e specifically, her e and abroad, price developments, and m o n e t a r y aggregates. the economy, they include an assessment of b usiness conditions frequentl y and the p erformance of financial markets They report the Committee's views of prospects for i n cluding information g leaned from p e rsonal contacts in individual Federal R eserve Districts. The minutes also report dis c u s s i o n of mon e t a r y poli c y options as we l l as the d e cision ultimately r eached by the Committee, including dissents, if any, and the logic underp i n n i n g the dissents. In light of these m i n u t e s , I believe that the views of the Committee members are known. o ther ways. meetings, In addition, Certainly, FOMC members I take full r e s p onsibility for my p o sitions and I have p r e s e n t e d m y policy views M i n n e apolis publications, and one from 1993, reveal their po l i c y po s i t i o n s among other places. at FOMC in Federal Re s e r v e Ba n k of (Two examples, are app e n d e d to this document). in one from 1990 In addition, Congress can 197 at any time ask us about our views, as the Senate Banking Committee did last March. Thus, a good deal of information is available in my view, and I do not find merit in suggestions to prepare and release, at any time, a literal record of FOMC deliberations * - through videotaping or other vehicles. issues in particular concern me. Three First, given the gravity of our responsibilities, I believe it imperative that the quality of our deliberations be maintained. Open discussion of ideas, of policy alternatives, and of significant potential risks to the economy are critical to sound policymaking. Secondly, some of the information we discuss is voluntarily provided on a confidential basis. Much of this information would be lost if we were unable to insure the integrity of confidential treatment. Moreover, we have an obligation to respect anonymity and confidentiality. Thirdly, I believe our procedures carefully balance the need to provide information to the public with the necessities of effective monetary policy. Even small changes carry the considerable risk that they will disturb, perhaps unknowingly and unintentionally, this balance, with adverse consequences for financial markets and economic performance. As indicated in my earlier correspondence, I believe there could be some merit to reintroduction of something like the "memorandum of discussion,11 a very detailed, although edited, accounting of FOMC discussions, provided that the confidentiality of such material is assured for several years. As I see it, such a document could be useful to historians and students of monetary 2 7 3 -2 0 8 0 - 9 4 - 8 198 policy when they investigate the broad context of policy decisions and the evolution of the policymaking process. Finally, in response to your specific inquiries about confidentiality, I am unaware of any unauthorized release of monetary policy information ever emanating from the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis. My economic advisor and I leave highly confidential material at the Board of Governors and do not return with it to Minneapolis. does my advisor. I take limited notes during the meeting, as All notes and other materials are handled according to strict guidelines, the essence of which is to limit their distribution and access and assure proper disposal, appended to this testimony.) (A copy of our Bank's procedures is Thank you. 3 199 C o n . .tv ,• i. i s !» \ (i i > S i , r n . 1' < ■ The Goal of Price Stability O ver the past year or two, there has been consider able discussion o f price stability as the preeminent goal o f Federal Reserve monetary policy. This discus sion has generated support for the goal but has also touched off a variety o f concerns, including the compatibility o f this objective with other policy goals, the potentially high cost o f achieving price stability, and the means o f conducting policy to achieve this objective. These concerns are worthy o f serious consideration but, on balance, price stability should remain the overarching goal o f monetary policy. In two pieces o f legislation— the Employment Act over which Federal Reserve policies have no influ ence or effect. o f 1946 and the Full Employment and Balanced Equally important, in the long run no funda Growth Act o f 1978— Congress has specified objec tives for monetary policy. T o paraphrase a bit, these mental incom patibility exists am ong these multiple objectives. T he principal contribution monetary pol objectives include achievement of high employment, icy can make to achieve sustainable growth and high econom ic stability and growth, price stability and employment is to establish an environm ent o f overall balance in our international transactions. Clearly, price-level stability. Beyond dem ographic factors, these objectives represent a highly desirable state o f growth depends on the capital stock with which the econom ic conditions, but I sense concern that if labor force works. Capital investment is likely to prominence, or preeminence, is given to one, es pecially price stability, others may be compromised. do well in a non-inflationary environment. In sum, price stability is com patible with the other ob jec That is, these objectives may conflict in a funda tives specified by Congress and is the principal mental and lasting way, which implies that the policy contribution the Federal Reserve can make toward challenge is to somehow strike a reasonable balance attainment o f those objectives and continuing eco am ong these objectives. I don’ t find the vision o f fundamental conflict nom ic prosperity. Perhaps a more serious concern about dedicating persuasive for several reasons. There is a plethora o f evidence indicating that monetary policy signifi monetary policy so exclusively to achievement o f cantly influences price performance, implying that, if in the abstract, many fear that it would impose properly designed and substantial costs on the econom y in practice. administered, policy can price stability is that, while this objective is embraced reasonably be expected to achieve price stability in the long run. O n the other hand, the influence o f Those who hold this view im plicitly, if not explic itly, accept the Phillips Curve notion o f a trade-off monetary policy on the other objectives is limited and between inflation and unem ploym ent or lost output. indirect at best. For example, econom ic growth depends in part on demographics such as labor force If this notion is accepted, there is little doubt that growth, and on the quality o f the labor force, matters achieving price stability could prove very costly indeed. 200 However, conventional Phillips Curve analysis in part to swings in energy or agricultural prices that ignores the potentially crucial role o f credibility in d on ’ t relate well in every period to m acroeconom ic achieving policy objectives. If the Federal Reserve conditions. Similarly, we would continue to recog adopts and implements an anti-inflation policy that is nize that current price performance results from past widely believed and accepted by the public— that is policies, so we would not necessarily react to every credible— the costs associated with reducing the rate new statistic on inflation. And there would be o f inflation may be modest. nothing in our strategy' to preclude a response to In a recent publication, the Federal Reserve Bank f ‘shocks,” such as a sharp break in stock prices, if that o f San Francisco made this point very well. “ C redi were appropriate. Stated more positively, we would bility means that the public quickly adjusts its continue to bear in mind our responsibility for the expectations concerning future policy in response to safety and soundness o f the financial system, as well as the announcement o f a change in policy, or to policy the linkages between financial problem s and business actions that suggest a new policy stance. Thus, a activity. Setting course for price stability need, not central bank with ‘credibility’ can announce a new constrain our ability to deal with these situations. disinflationary monetary policy and quickly achieve a lower inflation rate without a prolonged econom ic Indeed, to the extent that speculative excesses con tributed in the past to such problems, achievement of downturn because the public expects it to follow price stability may make such episodes less likely. through with its new policy long enough to be successful. Consequently, wage and price increases moderate quickly.” H ow m uch credibility does the Federal Reserve have at present? I can’ t provide a quantitative an swer, but probably not as much as I would wish. Thus, there are likely to be some costs, in terms o f foregone output, in achieving price stability. But if an anti-inflation strategy is consistently pursued, credi bility can be earned and costs held to reasonable levels. Assuming that price stability is, in fact, the para mount goal o f policy, what should the Federal Reserve do to achieve this objective? In my judgm ent, policy formulation and implementation would probably have to change little from current procedures. Growth in the monetary aggregates, especially M 2, would be used to help assess and guide policy, and M 2 growth would have to be reduced over a series o f years to a pace consistent with stable prices. In terms o f M 2 growth ranges, the upper end would have to be lowered steadily to assure that there is no backsliding in this process. W e in the Federal Reserve would continue to recognize, as we do today, that price measures themselves may bounce around in the short run, due 201 T o p o f t h e Comments N by i n t h Gary Stern. President Views on the Economy, Monetary Policy Follanving is a summary of Gary Stern’s March 10, Im portant in the district are the natural resource 1993, testimony before the Senate Committee on Bank industries o f agriculture, forest products and ing, Housing and Urban Affairs. Stem, along with m ining; diverse m anufacturing industries includ the other 11 Federal Reserve bank presidents, was ing m odern computer, electronic and medical called to testify on the state o f the district economy and technologies; and tourism. to share his views on monetary policy. In the m iddle and late 1980s the district econ om y was a bitweaker than the national economy. Mr. Chairman and m em bers o f the Com m ittee, T h e district did not benefit as much as others I appreciate this opportunity to discuss with you from the defense build-up, the com m ercial con- econ om ic conditions in the Ninth Federal strucdon spree, or the real estate price run-up. Reserve District and my views on m onetary poli Consequently, though, w hen these areas turned cy. My task is somewhat easier today than it would dow n, the district econ om y was affected relatively have been eight years ago, right after I first took less than the national econom y. office. O ver this period econ om ic conditions In addition, the district has been fortunate to generally have im proved in the Ninth District, have som e growth industries within its borders. and over this period I have had the opportunity T h e district econom y has been supported by to refine my views on the role and cond uct o f growth in exports, m edical instrument manufac m onetary policy. Let m e briefly address these two turing, residential construction, medical serrices topics in turn. and tourism. And, notably, agriculture has for the T he Ninth District econom y is doin g well rela tive to the national econom y today, in large part because it did not participate as fully as some o f the regions o f the nation in the expansion and most part recovered appreciably from the serious problem s o f the mid-1980s. However, I d o not want to give the impression that all is well in the Ninth District. Not all indus excesses o f the m iddle and late 1980s. While the tries and not all regions are prospering. In partic rest o f the nation was affected by unsustainable ular, som e natural resource industries, com m er expansions and subsequent sharp contractions in cial construction, com puter manufacturing and some sectors the Ninth District was m ore steady- small-town retail stores all have been slumping to as-you-go. Moreover, inflation appears to have som e degree. Nevertheless, I think it is fair to say diminished in the district in recent years. that as a whole the district econom y has T he Ninth District has a relatively small p op u lation, but it is large geographically and contains a diverse industrial base. T he Ninth District im proved. T he fortunes o f the district’s banks largely have reflected the ups and downs o f the district’s includes the states o f Montana, North Dakota, econom y. In 1986 the district’s banking system South Dakota, and Minnesota, as well as western was far from healthy. The lagging effects o f the Wisconsin and the U pper Peninsula o f Michigan. 1981-82 recession, difficulties in the agricultural 2 THE REGION, JUNE 1993 202 standards for our citizens over time. In ord er to give this goal operational meaning, the Federal Reserve in my view should seek to achieve over time m axim um sustainable growth o f real output. My reading o f the accum ulated evidence on sector and problem s with loans to less developed econ om ic perform ance both here and abroad is countries had com bined to weaken banks’ finan that in the long run the most significant contri cial con d id on . But since then, banking con d i bution m onetary policy can make to achieving tions have im proved. Asset quality, earnings and m axim um sustainable growth in real output is to capital all have im proved. In the first three quar foster price stability. T hat is, I am convinced that ters o f 1992 only 2 percent o f the district’s banks in the lon g run, price stability goes hand-in-hand reported losses, dow n from 20 percent in 1986. with sustained econ om ic prosperity. T he two M uch o f the inform ation I get on the district goals are not antithetical and, indeed, price sta econ om y com es first-hand from District Dia bility is best thought o f as a means to the end o f logues with com m unity and business leaders and sustained prosperity. from meetings with the bank’s directors and advi In the short run, we in the Federal Reserve sory coun cil on small business, agriculture and may in deed find it appropriate to respond to labor. O ur involvement in district econ om ic in com ing financial and econ om ic inform ation in affairs has served both the com m unity and Feder order to keep the econ om y on, or to return it to, al Reserve policymaking well, I believe. its potential growth path. But, it seems to m e, our T h e state of, and prospects for, the regional short-run response should in general be cautious econ om y are important elem ents in my prepara because o f uncertainty both about the state o f the tion for an approaching Federal O pen Market e con om y and about the effects o f policy on the Com m ittee m eeting. But, o f course, regional con econom y. Moreover, we need to avoid the p rob siderations must be balanced and integrated with lem o f turning long-run policy into a sequence o f inform ation about the national and international short-run decisions. I f follow ed, such an econom y, for ultimately the effects o f monetary approach runs the risk o f adopting a strategy that policy transcend regional boundaries. Thus, a is persistently inflationary or contracuonary, wide range o f factors, com b in in g regional eco dep en din g on conditions prevailing when it is nom ic and financial inform ation with additional adopted. perspectives, helps to shape my view o f the appro priate course o f policy. In the broadest sense, and taking a long-run perspective, the object o f m onetary policy is, it seems to me, to attain the highest possible living I Th«R«gton ] 203 Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Memorandum Dale: PACS: 2000.2 To: (Relevant Individuals) From: Gary Stem Subject: Safeguarding FOMC Class I, Class II, and Class III Confidential Material To assure the necessary confidentiality, it is important that all staff mem bers exercise special care in handling FOMC materials. Please read the following guidelines, sign attached sheet, and return to Vicki Reupke by Friday, (Date): 1. In addition to ensuring that the documents themselves are made available only to staff members who have been authorized access to them, the information they contain should be discussed with such persons only. 2. FOMC documents should not be left unattended on desk or table tops. 3. All FOMC documents should be out of sight when outside visitors are in the office. 4. FOMC documents may be carried by hand from one office to another. If sent by messenger, they should be placed in envelopes with a gummed-label seal bearing the initials of the person sending them. 5. When no longer needed, FOMC documents should not be disposed of by dropping in wastebaskets but by shredding or incineration. 6. All FOMC documents should be kept under lock and key at night and over weekends. 204 2 7. Double-sealed envelopes should be used for mailing all Class I and Class II FOMC materials from the Board and the Reserve Banks. The inside envelope for Class I material should be marked “Personal and Confidential” and delivered unopened to addressees. 8. No Class I or II documents should be reproduced by recipients. 9. The distribution of all FOMC documents, apart from the Managers’ reports, should be handled through the Secretary who will attach the appropriate security classification before sending the documents to the Committee. 10. To facilitate the identification of FOMC documents that require safekeeping, distinctive covers should be placed on all such documents that are to be circu lated System-wide. The Bluebook and the Greenbook are already distinctive in appearance and are exempt from this requirement. Documents of especially great sensitivity, e.g., copies of recently issued directives that are intended for the “eyes only” of specified recipients, should be so identified with appropriate further markings such as a special stamp or special cover sheet. 205 I have read the attached FOMC guidelines memo dated ( ). Signature and Date 206 For release on delivery 10:00 a.m. EDT October 19, 1993 Testimony by Richard F. Syron Federal Reserve Bank of Boston before the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 207 Thank you, Mr. Chairman and members of the Committee for this opportunity to share my views on maintaining a more extensive record of Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meetings. Being involved in the making of monetary policy is a great honor and something in which I take deep personal pride. Thus, from a purely personal perspective, I might welcome my views and positions being made more public. However, the key issue to me is what will provide the best policy for the people of the United States and of the First District. I believe there are difficult trade-offs between openness and the effectiveness of the deliberations that lead to monetary policy. I would like to mention two specific reasons that contribute to this trade-off. First, I am concerned that a highly detailed accounting of FOMC deliberations, unless its release were delayed several years, would impair the ability of the FOMC to obtain and discuss confidential information on individual companies and foreign central banks -- information that is essential to conducting monetary policy. New England's experience in the recent recession is a relevant case in point. The recession began earlier in New England and proportionately many more jobs were lost in the region than in the rest of the country. A s a consequence, some problems surfaced in New England before they emerged elsewhere. For example, the difficulties experienced by New England banks contributed to a "credit crunch" for small and medium-sized businesses. These problems were discussed at FOMC meetings and helped shape policy. It would not have been possible to convey the seriousness of the banking problems in New England, the potential for reduced credit availability and its impact on the economy as a whole without reference to individual borrowers and lenders. Yet to make such information public would have violated confidences; indeed, much information would never have been volunteered and our understanding of the problems would have suffered greatly. 208 - 2- Again, trade-offs are involved: the more specific are the references in the record of FOMC deliberations, the longer would be the time lag required before disclosure, if access to valuable but confidential information on individual companies is to be maintained and used. Second, much of the discussion and economic information disclosed in FOMC meetings pertains to the valuation of assets priced continuously in world financial markets. Fluctuations in asset values can have a significant impact on the jobs of workers and on the incomes of investors. Public disclosure of preliminary and exploratory FOMC discussions could generate unintended value changes that could lead to harmful reactions and unnecessary volatility in the economy. In summary, the ultimate objective of monetary policy is to promote the highest standard of living possible for Americans. The policymaking process should be as open as it can be, without diminishing our ability to achieve that objective. In regard to the three specific questions you posed, I generally take rough, handwritten notes at FOMC meetings; these are subsequently kept in a locked drawer. Any notes taken by the senior economist accompanying me are also kept securely or disposed of according to procedures governing confidential documents. Except for the Secretary's maintenance of Committee records, I have no direct information about how others may keep notes. I have no information about individuals imparting information about FOMC meetings before official release. 209 STATEMENT OF ANNA J. SCHWARTZ ON OCTOBER 19, 1993 AT HOUSE BANKING COMMITTEE HEARINGS ON THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM ACCOUNTABILITY ACT OF 1993 HR28 I am here to comment on two provisions in section 4 of HR 28 relating to prompt public disclosure of Federal Open Market Committee {FOMC) meetings. One provision would require the Federal Reserve to videotape and transcribe FOMC meetings and to make the videotape and transcription public within 60 days after a meeting. Another provision would require the Federal Reserve to make public within a week of an FOMC meeting the Domestic Policy Directive voted upon and issued to the Trading Desk after each FOMC meeting. Provision on Minutes and Their Disclosure Let me first discuss the provision regarding the maintenance of detailed records of Federal Open Market Committee deliberations and their public disclosure. To gain some perspective on this provision it is helpful to trace historical developments on the availability to the public of information on the Federal Reserve's conduct of monetary policy through its purchases and sales of open market securities. Three subperiods may be distinguished on this matter in the Federal Reserve's history: period from 1936 through March 1975; (1) (1) the period before 1936; (2) the (3) the period since March 197 5. In the period before 1936, abbreviated minutes of open market committee meetings beginning 1922 were maintained but restricted to internal use. Information on the Federal Reserve's activities is, however, available in two sources: the Library of Congress for the diaries of Charles Hamlin, a member of the Federal Reserve Board from 1914 to 1936, and Columbia University for the papers of George Harrison, YorK Fed from 1928 to 1940. a governor and then president of the New 210 Hamlin recorded his observations on the views of important Federal Reserve personalities and the pressure of events on the decisions reached by the Board. The Harrison Papers contain a wealth of documentary evidence including the minutes of open market committee meetings, official correspondence, memoranda exchanged in connection with those meetings, minutes of meetings of the board of directors of the New York Fed at which System policy was analyzed, and a full record of Harrison's conversations with leading figures in the System. (2) In the period from March 1936 through March 1976 detailed minutes or memoranda of discussion were prepared for each FOMC meeting. Before 1965 these records were held to be confidential documents. In 1964 the FOMC adopted a policy to release minutes of each meeting held through 1960 and for the release of minutes for subsequent meetings with a five-year lag after the calendar year in which minutes were taken. This action by the FOMC was a response to Congressional requests in the early 1960s for FOMC minutes and the publication in 1963 of A Monetary History of the United States. 1867-1960 of which Milton Friedman and I are co-authors. While the book was in draft, we sought but were denied access to the minutes of the FOMC by the Federal Reserve at that time. We had to substitute the Hamlin diaries and Harrison Papers for the period they covered. By 1964, despite its refusal two years earlier to let us see minutes of meetings, the FOMC apparently decided that disclosure of the minutes after a five-year lag posed no threat to the Fed. (3) In May 1976 the FOMC announced that after the March 15-16 meeting, memoranda of discussion would be discontinued, and the views of individual participants expressed at FOMC meetings would no longer be documented. The announcement apparently was inspired by the adoption of the Freedom of 211 3 Information Act and the Sunshine Act that made it difficult for the Federal Reserve to maintain confidential and secret information. The March 1975 meeting of the FOMC is the last one to date of which minutes have been made public, I favor reinstatement by the FOMC of its former practice of maintaining detailed minutes of its meetings and publication of the record after a fixed period of time to protect the Federal Reserve against premature disclosure of ongoing unsettled issues. The record should be verbatim. A videotape is neither essential or desirable. The record should be verbatim subject to correction within a brief period by the participants for inadvertently misspeaking. If the Federal Reserve regards 60 days as too short a delay for publication, I would not object to lengthening the delay to one year. Absence of the minutes of meetings since March 1975 has deprived scholars of information on the formation of monetary policy and limits research. I am familiar with a recent proposal by a well-known scholar to study Federal Reserve performance in recent decades. That scholar intends to resort to interviews with former Federal Reserve officials as a substitute for the unavailable minutes since 1975. The better course would be for the Federal Reserve to publish whatever documentation it has maintained for each meeting in the period since 1976. Provision on the Directive and Its Disclosure Let me now discuss the question of the appropriate length of delay of the release of the FOMC Domestic Policy Directive. Current practice, which began in 1976, is for directives to be released after financial markets close on the Friday after the subsequent FOMC meeting. This is a lag of approximately 45 days after the meeting at which the directive was adopted and 212 after another directive has been adopted. The directive that is released is always an outdated one. The position of the Federal Reserve is that early release would harm its ability to conduct monetary policy and the government's commercial interests. It has asserted that prompt release of the directive would have an announcement effect on financial markets. Market participants would hasten to realize gains in anticipation of the FOMC's purchases or sales of securities that would lead to substantial additional costs for the government's debt financing. The Federal Reserve argument boils down to the claim that prompt release would cause increased interest rate volatility that would raise the average level of interest rates. Is there evidence to support these claims? Although official release of the directive is delayed for approximately 4 5 days, the Wall Street Journal has reported the contents of the directive within a week of each of 11 FOMC meetings out of the 34 meetings that took place between March 1989 and May 1993. These are leaks that the newspaper attributes to "government officials" or "people familiar with the Fed's deliberations." The newspaper stories correspond closely with the FOMC directives that were later published. Professor Michael T. Belongia of the University of Mississippi and his co-author Kevin Kliesen have analyzed the 11 leaks as if they represented immediate release of the directive. The authors examine changes in the Treasury bill rate on each of five days before and five days after the Wall Street Journal story appeared to see if the T-bill rate changes support the Federal Reserve's argument that the early release of the content of the directive would be associated with increased volatility in short-term interest rates. They find that any such effect was negligible even when the directive 213 5 contradicted expectations based on current market rates. Moreover, even if there were large responses of interest rates to each of the 34 directives since 1989 on the assumption that they contained news different from existing market expectations, the increase in variance was numerically small. Belongia and Kliesen also raise doubts that increased volatility of the limited magnitude they find around the dates of leaks would raise the average level of interest rates on all other days. I reach two conclusions. One is that the Fed would be better advised to release the directive promptly instead of selectively leaking its content. Market participants scrutinize every scrap of information on prospective Federal Reserve actions. The market will perform better if the scrutiny is based on the actual directive, however delphic its content, rumors and conjectures about the directive. rather than on It is hard to accept the view that markets perform better the less information they have. My second conclusion is that the Fed is needlessly concerned about the supposed disturbing effects of prompt release of the directive on volatility and the level of interest rates. If FOMC meetings were held on Thursday and Friday and participants had an opportunity over the weekend to review the verbatim record to correct instances in which they misspoke, the Fed could then release the domestic policy directive on Sunday night. Finally, let me say that these hearings are devoted to peripheral aspects of Federal Reserve operations. The hearings do not touch on the substantive questions: What are the Fed's objectives? How effective are the operating procedures it follows to achieve its objectives? 214 1 Statement Prepared by A. James Meigs for Hearings before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, U. 5. House of Representatives October 19, 1993 Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: It is an honor for me to appear before you to express my view s on producing, maintaining, and publishing records of the proceedings and policy decisions of the Federal Open Market Committee. I am fam iliar with these materials because I used them for many years as crucial sources of information for my work in three major capacities: 1. As an economist with the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 19531961, where ! helped to provide analytical support for the President of the Bank in preparing for his meetings with the Federal Open Market Committee and in interpreting the discussions and policy decisions afterwards. 2. A s a researcher, w riting and lecturing on money and banking, monetary policy, and world financial markets. 3. As an economist or consultant for banks, securities firms, savings and loan associations, and other institutions. One of my main problems always was, and still is, how to figure out what the Federal Reserve did in the past, is doing right now, and might do in the future. 1 have had no experience in the oversight role implied by the Congress's power "to coin Money, [and] regulate the Value thereof/1 in Article I, Section 8, Clause 5, of the U. S. Constitution. However, 1 plan to make some recommendations concerning the Federal Open Market Committee Policy Record, the Memoranda of Discussion, and the Federal Reserve’s policy mandate that i believe would be useful to this Committee and the Congress in providing oversight. Recommendations 1. The Federal Reserve should publish the Policy Record of the Federal Open Market Committee within one or two days after each meeting of the Committee. The Policy Record should clearly state any changes in policy and the reasons for the changes. 215 2 2. The FOMC should resume the practice discontinued in 1976 of having the Committee Secretary prepare a Memorandum of Discusston for each meeting (the minutes). The Memorandum should summarize the statements of each member of the Committee, each non-voting Reserve Bank President (or alternate) attending the meeting, and each member of the Committee Staff or Board Staff who presents information or recommendations during the Committee discussion. The Memorandum of Discussion should be released to the public after one year. 3. The Congress should provide a clear mandate for the Federal Reserve to pursue a stable price level for the U. S. economy; i.e. to regulate the value of money. This Banking Committee then could concentrate on holding the Federal Reserve accountable for how it carries out that delegated responsibility. . in the rest of this statement I plan to explain some of the reasons for the recommendations and to try to meet objections that you and the Federal Reserve might raise. I believe that adopting these recommendations would benefit all the classes of information users I mentioned above, including the Federal Reserve itself and the Congress. The Policy Record At the end of my statement for hearings of this Committee on September 11, 1973,1said: My one additional suggestion is to eliminate the secrecy that now cloaks the processes and decisions of the Board of Governors and the Open Market Committee. I see no reason why Policy Directives of the Open Market Committee should not be publicly announced immediately after each meeting of the Committee, preferably with a discussion of the reasons for policy decisions. Ending the secrecy would not only facilitate the monitoring of System actions by the President and the Congress, but it would greatly reduce uncertainty among the general public.1 At the time I wrote that, I was advising clients in securities firms and commercial banks. My Inability to provide them with more nearly current information on Federal Reserve policies was extremely frustrating. Now, twenty years later, I am even more firmly convinced that the Policy Record should be released immediately after each meeting. 216 3 Participants in U. 5. and world financial markets are as skittish as gazelles drinking from a river infested with crocodiles. Over the last twenty years they have invested vast resources in equipment and techniques designed to shorten the time they need to react to new information about economic policies and prospects. Securities firm s and banks hire experts, some of whom are former Federal Reserve officers, to analyze every scrap of information they can pry out of Federal Reserve reports or the remarks of Federal Reserve officials. They especially would like to know what the FOMC decides about policy at each meeting and what circumstances might lead to a change at a future meeting or in the period between meetings. The slightest hint of a change in U. 5. monetary policy can affect securities prices and exchange rates around the world within minutes. These well known facts about financial markets’ sensitivity to changes in Federal Reserve policy have been used in arguing for delay in releasing the Policy Record in order to avoid destabilizing financial markets, i believe to the contrary that the effects of reducing the delay in releasing the Policy Record would be in the other direction. Immediate or early release would exert a stabilizing influence on financial markets by reducing uncertainty. That does not necessarily mean the markets would not jump when a new issue of the Policy Record announces a policy change. People with their own or clients’ money at risk adjust quickly to any announced or suspected policy change. Market jumps in reaction to early Policy Record releases might embarrass policy makers, especially when interest rates or exchange rates shift in an unpopular direction. But the markets would be more likely to jump in a direction that would be consistent with Federal Reserve policy objectives than when the markets react to rumors, leaks, innuendo, or conjectures which later prove to be unfounded. It would be better to provide the markets with the truth — whether potentially disturbing or not - - and let them sort it out. Early release of the Policy Record would have the further virtue of leveling the playing field. Some market players now are believed to have better access to information on Federal Reserve policy than others do. This perceived inequality of access obviously can lead to hard feelings or worse when some institutions believe competitors receive valuable information from Federal Reserve sources sooner than they do. The Policy Record should be thrown on the table for everybody at once as soon as the facts are in, like a crop report. 217 4 The Memoranda of Discussion The Policy Record is useful as a way to keep financial markets and the general public informed on current Federal Reserve policy and changes in policy. It would be even more useful if it were released immediately after each meeting. But it does not now provide enough detail on the discussions preceding policy decisions to enable analysts to determine how decisions are made and how the FOMC members react to various kinds of Information. Contributions of non-voting members are not identified. Recording votes at the end of a meeting does not reveal how the committee members d istill their technical advice and masses of information into decisions for action. The Memoranda of Discussion that were discontinued in 1976 provided fascinating insights into FOMC policy making procedures, although with an intolerably long delay. A new series of minutes or Memoranda of Discussion, released with less delay, would be extremely useful to future policy makers, researchers, and market practitioners. Chairman Arthur Burns told the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy in 1977 that he thought a bill to require the FOMC to maintain detailed minutes and to publish them after three years was "clearly motivated by a concern for the interests of scholars and others who may have occasion to do historical research in the area of monetary policy."2 Numerous other researchers and I had written to the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy to express various degrees of anguish over losing the Memoranda of Discussion.3 Chairman Burns conceded that the newly revised and expanded Policy Record "does not preserve a historical record as detailed as that contained in the earlier Memoranda of Discussion." However, Chairman Burns said, "In the absence of express statutory protection against premature disclosure of the memorandum, we would feel compelled to object to a proposal for returning to the practice of keeping extensively detailed minutes of FOMC meetings.’* Monetary scholars evidently were not an effective interest group in those days; H. R. 9465, which would have required keeping and publishing FOMC minutes, never found its way to the President's desk for signature. While expressing his regret over no longer producing FOMC minutes for scholars to mull over, Chairman Burns slighted a much more important group of readers. He hardly mentioned members and staff of the Open Market Committee and innumerable people throughout the System who have to 218 5 interpret, explain, and carry out monetary policy. For example, at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louts, we were not limited by the five-year delay in releasing the minutes to the public. We used the draft minutes of each meeting to help our President prepare for the next meeting. The economist who accompanied the President to FOMC meetings seldom could take enough notes to tell the rest of us who said what and why In a meeting of 12 Reserve Bank Presidents, 7 Board Members, and several staff advisors. We searched back issues of the minutes for references to points of view that might not have seemed important at the time but became more significant later. Hearings of the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy in 1977 reported that several former FOMC members said they found the minutes useful.4 The point of this anecdote is that Federal Reserve views on how monetary policy should be formulated and carried out were evolving then at a rapid rate, as they must still be evolving now. There was no clear manual of procedure for dealing with a menu of policy problems. The FOMC was adapting to changing economic conditions, changing financial institutions, and changing doctrines in monetary economics. Because the membership of the Committee was continually changing, the FOMC needed an Institutional memory to organize and to preserve this learning experience for future generations of policy makers. The Memoranda of Discussion provided a fine vehicle and repository for the FOMC Institutional memory. The Memorandum for each meeting recorded the discussion, was reviewed by the participants to guard against errors in transcription or wording, and was locked up in final form for posterity at the next meeting, usually one month later. Years of such a record of experience are now lacking, never to be retrieved. The significance of keeping a consistent, comprehensive set of minutes of the meetings was brought home to me when I tried to write about an episode in FOMC history about 15 years after It had occurred.51 thought the Infra-committee policy discussions of 1959 and 1960 were engraved on my brain, because they had provided an unusually clear contrast between opposing views of how the Committee should tell the Open Market Manager what to do. They seemed almost a laboratory demonstration of how imprecisely framed instructions could produce results the Committee had not intended. But when I checked the minutes I found I was off by months in my chronology. I had forgotten some significant contributions from people in addition to those I remembered as playing the leading roles. This experience convinced me that an inside observer's memory of such complex discussions can not be be trusted fully. Not even my own. 219 6 Keeping and publishing detailed minutes of FOMC meetings would help to answer three overriding questions: 1. How do members of the Federal Open Market Committee learn to exercise the awesome powers delegated to them? 2. How does a corporate body made up of ever-changing individual members remember and employ what it learns from its mistakes and successes? 3. How can the government that delegated those powers oversee the performance of their stewards? Former Reserve Board Member and Vice Chairman J. L. Robertson summed up these issues in a letter to the Chairman of the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy in 1976: In my view, the formulation of monetary policy by the Open Market Committee is one of the most important factors influencing the economy. Hence it should be mandatory that there be kept a detailed record (to be made available to Congress and the public after a lapse of appropriate tim e)... If minutes of the meetings are not kept and eventually made available, there would be no possible way for the Congress or members of the public to appraise the contribution of any member of the Committee to the formulation of monetary policy. Such appraisals are essential to any study of how to improve the system ... 6 Governor Robertson also answered the question of whether knowing they were on public record would inhibit members' willingness to speak frankly in FOMC meetings. He said, "Men competent to serve in these positions should be willing and anxious to stand on their records and be held responsible for the way in which they play their respective roles." The men and women who serve on the FOMC today and those who w ill serve in the future should not be reluctant to go on record. Each w ill be backed up by some of the most competent economists in the world. Each one w ill already have won distinction as a responsible professional in some capacity before joining the Committee. I would suggest that any committee member who is afraid his or her statements might not stand up to the tests of time or outside view should either put more thought into the statements or seek a less demanding line of work. 220 7 A Mandate for the Federal Reserve When considering the use of the minutes and other information from the Federal Reserve for establishing accountability, one must ask: Accountability for w hat? Most treatises on responsibility and accountability in business, government, and the m ilitary stre ss the need for a clear statement of the responsibility or m ission for which an individual or an organization can be held accountable. Such a statement or mandate is lacking here. After 200 years of constitutional history we still have not clearly decided what the mandate for control of the money power is or where it resides. The Federal Reserve System and most other central banks pursue multiple objectives at the same time — economic growth, employment, price stability, interest rates, and exchange rates. Experience of many years and many countries demonstrates that it is impossible to achieve all of the objectives set by central banks and governments simultaneously. In operating and in reporting to their governments and the public, It is agonizingly difficult for the central banks to decide which objective or objectives to stress. Consequently, there is an inflationary bias in monetary policies of many countries that is extremely difficult to counteract Most important, there is no simple tradeoff that would permit central banks and governments to achieve higher real economic growth by tolerating more inflation. Instead, a stable price level would provide the best possible foundation for maximizing opportunities for increasing employment and real incomes. This Congress could cut the knot by instructing the Federal Reserve to maintain a stable price level — zero inflation — to regulate the value of money. That is, the Congress could tell the Federal Reserve to do something it can do and that would have a tangible, measurable result. The Federal Reserve could then concentrate on learning how to do that, and doing it. The Congress could hold the Federal Reserve accountable for carrying out that responsibility. The Congress could and should examine all information coming from the FOMC, including the Memoranda of Discussion and the Policy Record, to assure itself and the public that the value of money is well regulated. The voters ultimately would hold both of these bodies accountable for the results. 221 8 1A. James Meigs, Statement prepared for Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency, House of Representatives, Ninety-Third Congress, Part 1, September 10, 11, 12, 13, and 14, 1973, p 261. Statem ent of Arthur F. Burns, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, in Hearings before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, Ninety-Fifth Congress, First Session, on H.R. 9465 and H.R. 9589, October 27, 28; November 17, 1977, p. 56. 3These letters were published in Appendix 111. Compilation of Opinions Received From Prominent Business Leaders and Economic Professors on H.R. 9465 and H.R. 9589, in Hearings before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, House of Representatives, Ninety-Fifth Congress, First Session on H.R. 9465 and H.R. 8589, October 27, 28; November 17, 1977, pp. 187-312. 4Among former members of the FOMC who cited the usefulness of the minutes were Jeffrey M. Bucher, J. Dewey Daane, Sherman J. Maisel, and J. L. Robertson. See Appendix III. Compilation of Opinions, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy, October 27,28; November 17, 1977, pp. 187-312. 5 a . James Meigs, "Campaigning for Monetary Reform: The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis in 1959 and 1960, Journal of Monetary Economics 2 (1976), 439-453. 6J. L. Robertson, letter to Stephen L. Neal, October 1, 1976. Published In Appendix III. Compilation of Opinions, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy, October 27, 28; November 17, 1977, p. 245. 222 Fixed income Management Group inc. T u e sd a y , O c t o b e r 1 9 , 1993 . S ta te m e n t o f R o b e r t C raven t o t h e C om m ittee o n B an king F in a n c e and U rban A f f a i r s . U .S . H ouse o f R e p r e s e n t a t i v e s . H e a r in g s on HR28. I h a v e b e e n i n v i t e d by Chairm an G o n za le z t o t e s t i f y on t h e im p a c t o f F e d e r a l R e s e r v e l e a k s on t h e f i n a n c i a l m a r k e ts . I w o u ld l i k e t o ex p a n d my com m ents t o i n c l u d e what I f e e l t o b e a g e n e r a l l a c k o f C e n t r a l Bank c o n t r o l o v e r m em bers' u s e o f t h e m ed ia . I w o u ld a l s o s u g g e s t t h a t p r o c e d u r e b e im p rov ed on d i s s e m in a t i o n o f Fed p o l i c y . 1) L eak s o f t h e o u tco m e o f FOMC d e l i b e r a t i o n s c a u s e t u r m o i l and e x tr e m e v o l a t i l i t y i n t h e f i n a n c i a l m a r k e ts. As a r e s u l t , a prem ium o f u n c e r t a i n t y i s b u i l t i n t o i n t e r e s t r a t e s . The im m ed iate b u rd e n i s c a r r i e d b y t h e U n ite d S t a t e s t a x p a y e r b e c a u s e o f h ig h e r a v e r a g e T r e a s u r y b o r r o w in g c o s t s . H ig h e r c o s t s a r e a l s o a s s o c i a t e d w it h p r i v a t e d e b t o f f e r i n g s . Two r e c e n t le a k s w i l l s e r v e as e x a m p le s . 2) Change i s n e e d e d i n p r o c e d u r e s u r r o u n d in g t h e r e l e a s e o f t h e FOMC v o t e . R e l e a s e s h o u ld im m e d ia te ly f o l l o w d e l i b e r a t i o n s . I w o u ld s u g g e s t t h a t p o l i c y n o t b e chan ged u n t i l t h e n e x t s c h e d u le d m e e tin g . 3) U nder t h e G re e n sp a n F ed , some p o l i c y m akers u s e t h e m ed ia t o a i r t h e i r own v i e w p o i n t s , e v e n i f a t o d d s w it h c u r r e n t Fed p o l i c y (FOMC v o t e ) . Some p o l i c y m akers seem t o b e i n t e n t on s e l l i n g t h e m s e lv e s t h r o u g h t h e m e d ia . S e c o n d ly , g e n e r a l com m entary i s o f t e n i l l - i n f o r m e d and r e c k l e s s . Such com m entary d e - s t a b i l i z e s t h e f i n a n c i a l m a r k e ts j u s t a s much a s " l e a k s " . T h is l o o s e ca n on a p p r o a c h m ust b e s t o p p e d . A lth o u g h Chairman G reensp an p l e d g e d t o s t o p l e a k s r e l a t i n g t o FOMC d e l i b e r a t i o n s ( a f t e r some u r g in g by t h i s C om m ittee) h e a l s o must e n f o r c e a m easure o f d i s c i p l i n e on p o l i c y m a k e r s ' g e n e r a l u s e o f t h e m edia. 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 223 Fixed Income Management Group Inc. 1) The l e a k o f 5 /2 1 /9 2 , c a r r i e d on p a g e s A2 and C20 o f t h e WSJ, b e g a n , " F e d e r a l R e s e r v e p o l i c y m ak ers d e c i d e d t h i s w eek ( 5 /1 9 ) a g a i n s t an y im m ed iate c u t i n s h o r t - t e r m r a t e s , p e o p l e f a m i l i a r w it h t h e F e d 's d e l i b e r a t i o n s s a i d 1*. The A s ia e d i t i o n o f t h i s p a p e r c a r r i e d t h e s t o r y w h il e t h e U .S . was s l e e p i n g and p r i c e s d r o p p e d o v e r n i g h t ( i n t e r e s t r a t e s up) on E uro and U .S . T r e a s u r y d e b t , w h ich i s t r a d e d on a 24 h o u r s b a s i s . S h o r t r a t e s jum ped a n o t h e r 15 t o 25 b a s i s p o i n t s ( 1 /4 o f 1%) e a r l y i n t h e U .S . t r a d i n g d a y . Bond y i e l d s , w h ich had c l o s e d on 5 /2 0 a t 7 .7 7 % , c l o s e d 5 /2 1 a t 7 .8 6 % . One y e a r t r e a s u r y b i l l r a t e s , w h ic h a v e r a g e d 4.07% o n 5 /2 0 , a v e r a g e d 4.24% on 5 /2 1 . Had y e a r b i l l s b e e n a u c t i o n e d on 5 /2 1 t h e h i g h e r d i s c o u n t w ou ld h a v e c o s t t h e U .S . t a x p a y e r an a d d i t i o n a l $ 2 4 ,0 0 0 ,0 0 0 (I 7 b p on an a v e r a g e s i z e o f 1 4 B ln ) d u e t o t h i s le a k in d u c e d s p i k e in r a t e s . I t was p u r e l u c k t h a t t h e $10 b ln 30 y e a r i s s u e a u c t io n e d 5 /7 was n o t a u c t i o n e d on 5 /2 1 . As D a v id J o n e s s t a t e d in h is b ook , P o l i t i c s o f M oney, The Fed U nder A la n G r e e n sp a n . when r e f e r r i n g t o t h e t u r m o i l fr o m w hat i s known a s t h e T h a n k s g iv in g Day fia s c o , 1 1 /2 2 /8 9 : "T h e u n c e r ta in ty a lm o s t c e r t a i n l y was r e f l e c t e d i n h i g h e r a v e r a g e T r e a s u r y b o r r o w in g c o s t s i n t h e p e r i o d im m e d ia te ly f o l l o w i n g t h e T h a n k s g iv in g f i a s c o , th a n o t h e r w is e w ou ld h a v e b e e n t h e c a s e ” . The T h a n k s g iv in g f i a s c o was n o t a le a k b u t a c a s e o f a Fed m is c u e (a c o m m u n ica tio n p ro b le m ) i n t h e i r o p e n m arket o p e r a t i o n s , and i r r e s p o n s i b l e WSJ r e p o r t i n g , t h a t l e d t h e m ark et t o b e l i e v e t h e Fed had e a s e d . The d i f f e r e n c e i s t h a t t h e T h a n k s g iv in g Day f i a s c o was an h o n e s t Fed m is t a k e ; l e a k s a r e n o t . The end r e s u l t , w h e th e r l e a k , o r Fed m is c u e , i s t h e sam e: e x tr e m e and u n n e c e s s a r y m a rk et v o l a t i l i t y and u l t i m a t e l y h ig h e r c o s t s t o th e ta x p a yer. The l e a k o f 5 /2 4 /9 3 , was f i r s t c a r r i e d on p a g e A2 on t h e WSJ. I t b e g a n , " F e d e r a l R e s e r v e o f f i c i a l s v o t e d t o le a n t o w a r d h i g h e r s h o r t - t e r m r a t e s a t t h e i r c l o s e d - d o o r m e e tin g l a s t week ( 5 /1 8 ) p e o p l e f a m i l i a r w it h t h e F e d 's d e l i b e r a t i o n s s a i d " . The m a rk e ts had a l r e a d y ta k e n a n o s e d i v e on 5 /2 1 when t h e m in u te s o f t h e M arch m e e tin g w ere r e l e a s e d . On t h a t d a y r a t e s on s h o r t te rm d e b t jum ped 10 t o 15 b a s i s p o i n t s , and b o n d s , a f t e r f l u c t u a t i n g w i l d l y , c l o s e d 1 /2 p o i n t l o w e r . The 5 /2 4 s t o r y was c a r r i e d f i r s t i n t h e A s ia e d i t i o n o f t h e WSJ s o t h a t U .S . m a rk e ts f a c e d l o s s e s on i n v e n t o r i e s o f US d e b t f i r s t t h i n g Monday m o rn in g . A p p r o x im a t e ly 12 b l n s i x month b i l l s w ere a u c t i o n e d on 5 /2 4 a t an a v e r a g e r a t e o f 3 .1 9 % , v s 3.10% on 5 /1 7 , f o r an ad d ed a n n u a l c o s t o f some $11 m i l l i o n . T h is l e a k was f o l l o w e d b y a 5 /2 7 CNBC s t o r y , p l a c e d b y a Fed s o u r c e , w h ich g a v e an a c t u a l t r i g g e r f o r t i g h t e n i n g . M ore v i o l e n c e i n t h e m arket p l a c e . R a t e s , w h ich had r e c o v e r e d som ewhat fr o m t h e 5 /2 4 le a k , flu c t u a t e d w ild ly . A g a in , p u r e lu c k t h a t o t h e r s c h e d u le d U .S . T r e a s u r y d e b t d i d n o t com e o n t h e s e d a y s , y e t p r i v a t e d e b t u n d o u b t e d ly d i d . Had t h e 30 y e a r U .S . bon d i s s u e w h ic h was a u c t i o n e d on 5 /1 3 b e e n a u c t i o n e d on 5 /2 1 o r 5 / 2 4 , t h e l e a k c o u l d h a v e c o s t t h e t a x p a y e r an yw here fr o m .0 5 t o .1 5 o f 1% on t h e i s s u e s i z e o f $ 8 .2 6 b l n , o r from $4 t o $12 m i l l i o n a n n u a lly f o r 30 y e a r s . 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 224 Fixed Income Management Group Inc. The F ed l i k e l y n e v e r e v e r in t e n d e d t o t i g h t e n , b u t i n s t e a d p l a n t e d t h e 5 /2 4 m e ssa g e i n t h e m edia a s a way o f co m m u n ica tin g t h e i r v ie w . T h is i s n o t a c c e p t a b l e b e h a v i o r . On 7 / 6 , s p e a k in g o f t h i s le a k t o M arket News S e r v i c e . D a v id R e s l e r , c h i e f e c o n o m is t t o Nomura S e c u r i t i e s i n NY, s t a t e d : "T o s e l e c t p a r t i c u l a r news o r g a n i z a t i o n s t o d i v u l g e t h e c o n t e n t s o f t h e m e e tin g , i s c r i m i n a l and a b s o l u t e l y im m o r a l" . "T h e o f f e n d i n g members s h o u ld b e s u b j e c t t o i n c r e d i b l y s e v e r e p e n a l t i e s , i n c l u d i n g b e i n g e x p e l l e d from t h e Fed R es s y s te m , a t a m inim u m ." I n l i g h t o f t h e F e d 's le a k t o t h e WSJ, " t h e y m ig h t a s w e l l own Dow J o n e s s t o c k " . 2) The s o - c a l l e d " m in u t e s " o f t h e d e l i b e r a t i o n s o f t h e FOMC a r e n o t a c t u a l l y a c o m p l e t e r e c o r d o f t h e m e e tin g . T h is p r a c t i c e was s t o p p e d b y A r th u r B u rn s. The " m in u te s " a r e a summary o f t h e d e l i b e r a t i o n s . The m in u te s s h o u ld b e is s u e d i n c o m p le t e fo r m , b u t i t i s n o t c r i t i c a l t h e y b e r e l e a s e d im m e d ia te ly i n t h e i r e n t i r e t y . I t i s t h e d i r e c t i v e t o t h e NY Fed w h ich s h o u ld b e r e l e a s e d im m e d ia t e ly , o r t h e n e x t w eekd ay, d u r in g U .S . m ark et h o u r s . F or e x a m p le , t h e " m in u t e s " f o r t h e m e e tin g o f 8 /1 7 g o on f o r som e 14 p a g e s and t h e n l e a d i n g i n t o t h e d i r e c t i v e : "A t t h e c o n c l u s i o n o f t h e m e e t in g , t h e F e d e r a l R e s e r v e Bank o f NY was a u t h o r i z e d and d i r e c t e d , u n t i l i n s t r u c t e d o t h e r w is e by t h e C om m ittee, t o e x e c u t e t r a n s a c t i o n s i n t h e S ystem a c c o u n t i n a c c o r d a n c e w it h t h e f o l l o w i n g d o m e s t i c p o l i c y d i r e c t i v e : " The d i r e c t i v e i s b r i e f , g i v i n g r e a s o n s f o r t h e c o n s e n s u s , a c t i o n t o b e t a k e n , and t h e v o t e . T he r e l e a s e s h o u ld b e b y t h e way o f a p r e s s s ta te m e n t f o l l o w i n g e v e r y m e e tin g . T h is w o u ld d o n o t h i n g t o im p in g e on Fed in d e p e n d e n c e . M ilt o n F ried m an h a s b e e n a f r e q u e n t p r o p o n e n t o f im m ed iate r e l e a s e . "The w h o le t h i n g ( d e l a y ) i s a b s u r d and u n n e c e s s a r y " , h e s a i d i n a r e c e n t in t e r v ie w . I n a d i s c u s s i o n w it h Dr. F riedm an 1 0 /1 3 he s u p p o r t s ou r v ie w and a l s o t h e n o t i o n o f a w eekday r e l e a s e . I n t h e w ord s o f a p a s t F ed P r e s i d e n t , " T e l l u s i f t h e econom y i s h o t , c o l d , o r in b e tw e e n and i f t h e d i r e c t i v e i s t o f i r m , e a s e o r d o n o t h in g , and t h a t ' s i t u n t i l th e n e x t m e e tin g ". C hairm an G r e e n s p a n 's r e s p o n s e t o t h i s a rg u m en t, a s g iv e n t o R e p r e s e n t a t i v e N e a l i n 1 9 8 9 , and r e p e a t e d many t im e s s i n c e , i s t h a t s u ch d i s c l o s u r e w o u ld i n c r e a s e m arket v o l a t i l i t y when d e c i s i o n s d i d n 't m atch m a rk e t e x p e c t a t i o n s . T h ere w ou ld in d e e d b e movement on r e l e a s e d a y , b u t t h i s i s p r e f e r a b l e t o t h e p r e s e n t sy ste m w h ic h , a s we h a v e s e e n b y p r e v i o u s ex a m p le , i n s t i l l s f e a r and v o l a t i l i t y i n t h e m a rk et on a week t o week b a s i s . T h e r e i s a n o t h e r p r o b le m s u r r o u n d in g t h e d e l i b e r a t i o n s and t h e d i r e c t i v e : in t e r -m e e t in g p o l i c y ch an ges. Such c h a n g e s s h o u ld b e e lim in a te d . The Fed o f t e n c h a n g e s p o l i c y j u s t a f t e r an e c o n o m ic r e l e a s e , o f t e n t h e n o n -fa r m p a y r o l l num ber. They d en y t h a t an y on e number ca n t r i g g e r a p o l i c y ch a n g e and h ave s a i d t h a t t h e y m o n it o r a w h o le r a n g e o f i n d i c a t o r s . The l a s t t h r e e y e a r s o f e v id e n c e s u g g e st o th e r w is e . T h is a g a in c r e a t e s u n n e c e s s a r y m ark et 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 225 Fixed Income Management Group Inc. v o l a t i l i t y s u r r o u n d in g i n d i v i d u a l r e p o r t s a s i n v e s t o r s t r y t o g a u ge t h e F e d 's r e s p o n s e . To add t o t h e c o n f u s i o n , many o f t h e r e p o r t s r e l e a s e d by Commerce o r BLS a r e r e v i s e d b y a l a r g e m a r g in , som e tim e s m ore th a n o n c e . F u r t h e r , i n t e r - m e e t i n g c h a n g e s l e a d t o c o n f u s i o n o v e r d a i l y Fed o p e r a t i o n s (T h a n k s g iv in g d a y f i a s c o ) . 3) The G reen sp an Fed i s a m ore d e m o c r a t ic i n s t i t u t i o n th a n t h a t u n d e r P a u l V o l k e r . On i t s f a c e t h i s i s a d m ir a b le . B ut a s M artha S e e g e r s a i d , in r e f e r r i n g t o t h e F ed , "D em ocra cy i s m e s s i e r th a n d ic ta to r s h ip ". As a r e s u l t , d u r in g t h e p e r i o d b e tw e e n FOMC d e l i b e r a t i o n s , we h e a r m ore th a n e v e r b e f o r e fro m i n d i v i d u a l p o l i c y m a k e rs. T h is i s u n f o r t u n a t e . P o l i c y m ak ers' s ta te m e n ts in th e m edia a r e so m etim es r e c k l e s s , so m e tim e s i l l - a d v i s e d , som etim e p u r e c h e e r l e a d i n g and som etim es l i k e l y p o l i t i c a l l y m o t iv a t e d . A ll o f t h i s a d d s u n n e c e s s a r y v o l a t i l i t y and c o n f u s i o n . I n e a r l y May o f 1 9 9 2 , a t a C i v i l R i g h t s C om m ission c o n f e r e n c e in W a sh in g to n , a c o m m is s io n e r s u g g e s t e d t o Gov L in d s e y t h a t US m a n u fa c tu r in g was i n d e c l i n e . G o v e r n o r L in d s e y r e s p o n d e d t h a t m a n u fa c tu r in g was " g o i n g l i k e g a n g b u s t e r s " . On 5 /1 3 G o v e r n o r L in d s e y was q u o te d b y a news s e r v i c e a s s a y in g t h a t " t h e econom y i s m ovin g a l o n g q u i t e w e l l " . ( J u s t t o add t o t h e c o n f u s i o n , on t h e same d a y , R ic h a r d S y ro n , a v o t i n g member o f t h e FOMC and P r e s id e n t o f t h e B o s to n F ed, was on t h e news s a y i n g t h a t t h e " r e c o v e r y c o u l d f a l l a p a r t , b u t t h e ch a n c e o f t h a t was d e c r e a s i n g " . ) The m a r k e ts s o l d o f f 5 /1 3 a s a r e s u l t o f w hat we f e e l was e i t h e r c h e e r l e a d i n g (a n i n a p p r o p r i a t e u s e o f t h e o f f i c e ) , o r a t o t a l l a c k o f k n o w le d g e o f t h e r e a l s e c t o r (F ed s t a f f ? ) . L e t ' s lo o k a t t h e e c o n o m ic f a c t s p r e c e d i n g t h i s s t a t e m e n t. 4 /1 4 /3 4 /1 4 4 /1 5 4 /1 7 4 /2 3 4 /2 9 4 /3 0 5 /1 5 /5 5 /7 - NAPM - S l i g h t l y h i g h e r ( 5 4 .1 v s 5 2 .4 ) - P a y r o l l - Up m o d e s t ly b u t m a n u fa c t u r in g p a y r o l l - down. A m a jo r s u r p r i s e . A v e r y weak num ber. R a t e s plum m eted. - R e t a i l s a l e s - down ( - . 4 v s + 1 .3 ) - I n d u s t r i a l p r o d u c t i o n - Up m o d e s t ly ( + .2 v s + .5 ) - B u ild in g p e r m it s - dow n. S t a r t s - h i g h e r . - D u ra b le o r d e r s - up m o d e s t ly - New homes s a l e s - Down 1 4 .8 % . - F a c t o r y o r d e r s - Up m o d e s t ly - NAPM - Down ( 5 1 .3 v s 5 4 .1 ) - A u to s a l e s - s lo w p a c e - P a y r o l l - m o d e st i n c r e a s e , w it h a v e r a g e h o u r s and e a r n in g s l o w e r . I n t e r e s t r a t e s d r o p p e d a g a in a s t h i s # i n d i c a t e d d i s t r e s s i n t h e l a b o r m a rk e t. 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 226 Fixed Income Management Group Inc. E con om ic num bers sh ow ed an ev en s lo w e r econom y i n J u n e . D is t r ic t Fed s u r v e y s , h o u s in g s t a r t s , NAPM, m a n u fa c tu r in g em ploym en t, d u r a b l e o r d e r s w e r e a l l lo w e r . F i n a l l y , t h e p a y r o l l number on 7 /2 was s h o c k i n g l y w eak , t r i g g e r i n g a n o th e r c u t in b o t h d i s c o u n t r a t e and F F 's r a t e on t h a t d a y . T h is i s " g o i n g l i k e g a n g b u s t e r s " ? T h is i s an econom y " d o i n g q u i t e w e l l " ? We a r e n o t s p e a k in g a b o u t j u s t on e p e r s o n * s o p i n i o n (n o m a tte r how i l l - i n f o r m e d ) b u t a p o l i c y m aker w h ose com m entary i s ta k e n t o r e f l e c t t h e v ie w o f t h e FOMC. I f t h a t ' s w h at h e was d o i n g , th e n we a r e a l l i n d e e p t r o u b l e . I f n o t , i t was c h e e r l e a d i n g and i s an i n a p p r o p r i a t e u s e o f t h e o f f i c e . G iv e n s u ch com m en tary , we m igh t assum e t h a t Fed s t a f f e r s a r e n o t up t o p a r . A c c o r d i n g t o L y le G ram ley, fo r m e r r e s e a r c h d i r e c t o r a t t h e Fed and fo r m e r F ed G o v e r n o r , t h e m a jo r p ro b le m a t t h e Fed h a s been p o o r s t a f f su p p o rt in r e c e n t y e a r s . "The F e d e r a l R e s e r v e s t a f f f o r e c a s t s h a v e b e e n a b o m in a b le " , he s a i d in an i n t e r v i e w t h e week o f 5 /1 8 /9 2 . "T h e y s a t a l l d u r in g t h e summer o f '9 1 and d i d n 't s e e t h e w e a k n e ss t h a t was c o m in g " . In d e e d , t h e y h a ve b e e n d e a d wrong on g r o w th f o r t h e l a s t t h r e e y e a r s . The WSJ le a k o f 5 /9 2 i n d i c a t e d t h a t s t a f f e r s f e l t t h e l a b o r s i t u a t i o n was im p r o v in g , t h a t r e t a i l s a l e s l o o k e d g o o d , t h a t h o u s in g s t a r t s w ou ld t r e n d up and t h a t le a n i n v e n t o r i e s w o u ld s o o n le a d t o an i n c r e a s e in p r o d u c t i o n . Wrong a g a in and t h e Fed was f o r c e d t o e a s e tw o m ore t im e s t h a t y e a r . T h e se f o l k s n e e d t o t u r n o f f t h e main fr a m e , s t e p o u t s i d e and s n i f f th e a ir . (My w i f e ' s e c o n o m ic m odel c o n s i s t s o f a c a r and a ta n k o f gas. Her p a r k in g l o t s u r v e y s p r o v e d s u p e r i o r t o t h e F e d 's m odel tim e and t im e a g a in i n n o t i n g consum er d i s t r e s s . ) E a r ly i n t h e d a y o f 5 / 1 4 / 9 2 , G o v ern or L in d s e y was c a r r i e d on on e o r m ore news s e r v i c e s a s s a y in g t h a t "g r o w th o f M2 w i l l r e b o u n d " , and w i l l "b ou n ce b a c k ". As i s Fed p r o c e d u r e , t h e a g g r e g a t e s a r e r e l e a s e d e v e r y T h u rsd a y (5 /1 4 ) a t 4:30PM EST. Fed o f f i c i a l s r e c e i v e t h e s e f i g u r e s b e f o r e r e l e a s e b u t t h e y a r e s u p p o s e d t o be u n d e r s t r i c t e m b a rg o. H ere we h ave a Fed G o v e rn o r s p i l l i n g t h e beans p re -th e s c h e d u le d an nouncem ent. T h is is a b s o lu te ly u n a c c e p t a b l e . I t j u s t s o happened t h a t t h e m arket was k e y e d t o t h e 5 /1 4 r e l e a s e b e c a u s e Chairm an G reenspan l e d t h e m a rk et t o b e l i e v e t h a t M2 w ea k n e ss was t h e r e a s o n f o r t h e e a s e o f 4 / 9 / 9 2 . In f a c t , M2 was up $ 9 .8 b l n , 5 /1 4 a s o p p o s e d t o a d ro p o f $ 9 .7 b l n , 5 / 7 . An a lm o s t p r e c i s e " b o u n c e b a c k " . T h is i s a n o th e r ex a m p le o f an in a p p r o p r ia t e u se o f th e o f f i c e . The L ondon F i n a n c i a l Tim es ra n a s t o r y 1 0 /9 /9 2 w h ic h q u o te d a " s e n i o r Fed o f f i c i a l " . T h is o f f i c i a l i n d i c a t e d t h a t t h e Fed was on h o l d , n o t b e i n g c o n c e r n e d w it h t h e p a c e o f g r o w th . T h is s o u r c e c i t e d " r e l a t i v e l y s t r o n g " c a r , t r u c k and g e n e r a l r e t a i l s a l e s . On t h i s o c c a s i o n C hairm an G reenspan a c t u a l l y c a l l e d a s p e c i a l news c o n f e r e n c e t o d i s t a n c e h i m s e l f (and p re su m a b ly Fed p o l i c y ) from t h i s a r t i c l e . T oo l a t e . The harm was a l r e a d y d o n e . A n o th e r l e a k o u t 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 227 Fixed Income Management Group inc. o f t h e ch e a p s e a t s . E u ros l o s t up t o 30 t i c k s in t h e m orn in g o f 1 0 /9 a s r a t e s jum ped h i g h e r . On 1 0 /8 , y e a r b i l l s a v e r a g e d 3 .0 6 % . On 1 0 /9 , 3.18% 1 L e t u s assum e t h a t 1 0 /9 was a u c t i o n d a y . T w elv e b a s i s p o i n t s ( .1 2 o f 1%) on an a v e r a g e s i z e o f $15 B ln i s $18MM e x t r a t o t h e t a x p a y e r ( i g n o r e t h e p r i v a t e b o r r o w e r who may h a ve b e e n u n fo r t u n a t e enough t o h a v e com e t o m ark et on 1 0 /9 ) th a n k s t o a l a c k o f d i s c i p l i n e a t t h e F ed . A s r e c e n t l y as 1 0 /4 o f t h i s y e a r J e r r y J o r d o n , P r e s i d e n t o f t h e C le v e la n d Fed and s p e a k in g b e f o r e t h e O h io B a n k ers A s s o c i a t i o n , s a i d t h a t i t i s tim e t o t r e a t s t a t e c h a r t e r e d member i n s t i t u t i o n s a s c l i e n t s r a t h e r th a n ,,c a p t i v e s " . L o c a l b a n k e r s w e re m y s t i f i e d . No o n e h a s a p ro b le m w it h an o v e r b e a r i n g F ed , a c c o r d i n g t o re sp on ses th a t day. O h io b a n k e r s w e re " c o n f u s e d and i r r i t a t e d " . A Fed s t a f f e r s a i d , " I h a v e n o i d e a w h at h e i s t a l k i n g a b o u t " . " J o r d o n o f t e n s a y s t h i n g s t h a t d o n 't r e f l e c t t h e o p in io n o f th e b o a r d " , s a i d Ken G u e n th e r, vp o f t h e In d e p e n d e n t B a n k ers a s s o c and a fo r m e r a s s i s t a n t t o M i l l e r , B urns and V o l k e r . " J o r d a n 's p u b l i c u t t e r a n c e s h a v e an noyed o t h e r c e n t r a l b a n k e r p o l i c y m akers and c o u l d b e c o n s t r u e d a s an i n a p p r o p r i a t e u s e o f h i s o f f i c e " . (J o rd a n h a s b e e n a s u s p e c t in p a s t FOMC l e a k s . ) On 1 0 /8 , D ept T re a s u r y S e c t R o g e r A ltm an c r i t i c i z e d t h e NY Fed f o r comm ents by a s e n i o r o f f i c i a l t h a t w e re s e e n a s c r i t i c a l o f a s t a t e m e n t by C l i n t o n a d m in i s t r a t i o n o f f i c i a l s on t h e Y e n /$ e x c h a n g e ra te. M a rg a re t G reen , a s e n i o r v i c e p r e s id e n t a t t h e NY Fed s u g g e s t e d t h a t t h e s e comm ents may h a v e b e e n made b e c a u s e o f "in e x p e r ie n c e ". " I t i s n o t u n u su a l f o r som eone t o move i n t o an e c o n o m ic p o l i c y j o b , h a v in g b e e n i n p u b l i c s e r v i c e f o r s o much o f t h e i r c a r e e r , and answ er a q u e s t i o n w it h o u t h a v in g f u l l y t h o u g h t th r o u g h t h e c o n s e q u e n c e s . When new p e o p l e g e t i n t o new p o s i t i o n s , t h e y may make su ch comm ents w it h o u t r e a l i z i n g t h a t t h e r e s t o f t h e w o r ld i s l o o k i n g a t t h e i r com m ents a s i n d i c a t i v e o f p o l i c y " . E x a c t ly o u r p o i n t ! I f e e l t h a t t h e m a jo r i t y o f p o l i c y m akers h a v e n o t b e e n g u i l t y o f t h e s e o f f e n s e s and h ave t h e w isdom t o k e e p i t z ip p e d betw een m e e t in g s . O th e r s d o n o t . T o q u o t e a g a in f o r t h e J o n e s b o o k , " ...s o m e a m b it io u s , n e w -b r e e d Fed p o lic y m akers have, in c o m p e t it i o n w it h t h e Fed C hairm an, begu n t o e f f e c t i v e l y u s e t h e m edia and p u b l i c r e l a t i o n s t o s e l l t h e m s e lv e s o r t h e i r own id e a s (p e r h a p s in s e e k in g r e c o g n itio n fo r fu tu r e A d m in i s t r a t io n a p p o in tm e n ts t o t h e Fed C h a irm an 1s j o b i t s e l f o r o t h e r key g ov ern m en t p o s i t i o n s ) " . "T h ro u g h b a ck g r o u n d p r e s s i n t e r v i e w s and t h e in fa m o u s W ash in g ton ' l e a k ' , t h e y c a n a d v a n c e t h e i r own p o l i c y p o s it io n s ." T h e re must b e a r e t u r n t o d i s c i p l i n e a t t h e G reen sp an F ed. 100 California Street, Suite 1245 . San Francisco, California 94111 . Phone (415) 956-3994 . Fax (415) 956-9151 228 F e d e ra l R eserve B an k o f M in n e a p o lis 2 5 0 M a rq u ette Avenue M in n e a p o lis , M in n e s o ta 55480 G a r y H. S t e h n P r e s id e n t November 8, 1993 The Honorable Stephen L. Neal Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs U.S. House of Representatives 2129 Rayburn House Office Building Washington, D.C. 20515-8050 Dear Congressman: I was pleased to appear before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs on October 19, 1993, and I appreciate the opportunity to respond to the two questions you posed during those hearings: 1. “[Do] you agree that price stability is the best policy for the Fed?” 2. “[Do] you think the Fed should be held accountable for achieving and maintaining that policy—via legislation?” My answer to both questions is yes—but with qualifications. I am on the record as favoring price stability as the objective of monetary policy. Nevertheless, I have two concerns about legislation that makes the Federal Reserve accountable for achieving this objective: 1. If the Federal Reserve’s period of accountability were made too short, monetary policy could become a destabilizing force. 229 2 2. If Federal budget policy were not changed to be consistent with a noninflationary environment, uncertainty about the direction of future policy would be introduced into the markets. My published remarks (The Conference Board’s Economic Times, September 1992) convey my support for making price stability the objective of monetary policy, and in them I conclude that price stability should be the paramount objective of monetary policy. That conclusion rests on three main propositions: First, that the goal of economic policy is to achieve sustained prosperity. Second, that the principal contribution monetary policy can make to that goal is to establish price stability, since our economy does not work well in an inflationary environ ment. And third, that inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon. I further indicate in those remarks that the debate about monetary policy centers on the second of the above propositions: Some maintain that the benefits of price stability are small and that most of them can be obtained by suitable indexing of taxes, compensation, and credit agreements. This position is seriously flawed, however, because comprehensive indexing is unlikely and at most would be a second-best substitute for price stability. A more serious intellectual challenge is posed by those who assert that the goal should be a stable inflation rate rather than price stability. The historical record argues against this position in two ways: First, for whatever reasons, countries that abandon price stability as a goal generally experience accelerating inflation, not a stable inflation. Second, comparisons across countries show that over the long term lower inflation rates are associated with stronger growth. Some worry that too rigid a commitment to price stability could prevent the Federal Reserve from responding appropriately to ‘shocks,’ such as a sharp break in stock prices or other threats to the financial system. Not so—even large injections of liquidity are compatible with price stability if they are temporary. A more substantial concern is the fear that the short-term pursuit of price stability will lead to losses of employment and output, as suggested by the Phillips curve. If, however, the credibility of the Federal Reserve’s commitment to price stability and its ability to attain the goal are high, expectations about wages, prices, and interest rates are likely to moderate 7 3 -2 0 8 0 - 9 4 - 9 230 3 quickly. . . . If the Federal Reserve’s policies are credible, price stability can be attained at acceptably low cost. With all this support for price stability as the objective for monetary policy, why, you might ask, do I have reservations about putting the objective explicitly into law and holding the Federal Reserve accountable for achieving it? A careful reading of my remarks suggests my two reservations. First, I am concerned about the length of the time period over which the Federal Reserve is held accountable for achieving the objective. I stated that “inflation is ultimately a monetary phenomenon. ” However, it is affected by many other factors in the short run: e.g., business cycle phase, oil price shock, and bad weather. Moreover, the best empirical research suggests changes in money affect prices after a considerable lag—upwards of two years. If the period of accountability were made too short, the Federal Reserve would be forced to move wildly within the period to offset shocks, and this could be destabilizing as the effects of the monetary policy moves amplify over time. If the period of accountability were made too long, in effect, there would be no accountability. So, I see this as a thorny issue. Second, I am concerned about the coordination of monetary and budget policies. This relates to my statement that “if the Federal Reserve’s policies are credible, price stability can be attained at an acceptably low cost.” If the Federal Reserve were to pursue price stability, budget policy would have to be made consistent with that pursuit. A persistent deficit policy is not consistent with a nonaccommodating monetary policy: interest on the debt and the total amount of debt would continue to rise as proportions of total income. Were the two policies not consistent, the public would have to guess how they would be changed to make them 231 4 consistent. Thus, if budget policy were not adapted to a noninflationary environment, more uncertainty would be introduced into the marketplace. It is unlikely that the Federal Reserve's credibility as an inflation-fighter could be maintained were budget policy not to follow suit. My second reservation is not so much a criticism as a recommendation, I believe price stability should be a goal of macroeconomic policy, but I also believe both monetary and budget policies must pursue this goal. I have enclosed our 1990 annual report, which describes one way this could be done. Sincerely, GHS:jf Enclosure 232 Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 1990 Annual Report Playing by The Rules A Proposal for Federal Budget Reform 233 Federal Reserve Bank o f Minneapolis 1990 Annual Report Playing by The Rules A Proposal for Federal Budget Reform By Preston J. Miller, Vice President and Deputy Director o f Research, and V.V. Chari, Research Officer Contents President’s Message 1 Playing by The Rules A Proposal for Federal Budget Reform 3 Statement o f Condition 22 Earnings and Expenses 23 D irectors 24 Officers 25 The views expressed m this annual report are solely those o f the authors; they are not intended to represent a formal position o f the Federal Reserve System. 234 President’s Message This year’s essay proposes major changes in the federal budget process. But why should changes be considered now, when just last fall a major reform package was passed? V.V. Chari and Preston Miller argue that the fall reforms provide at best a transition to a more balanced budget; even if the reforms work, many problems will remain. The authors persuasively argue that addressing those problems requires a more fundamen tal reform of the budget process than the fall reforms provide. Some may question why the Federal Reserve, which has responsibility for mon etary policy, is addressing fiscal policy issues. My response is that the two policies are intertwined. Persistent budget deficits and a rapidly growing federal debt increase the pressures on the Federal Reserve to follow an inflationary policy I expect some will also argue that all this talk about the budget process is small potatoes when we know the real problem is policymakers’ inadequate attempts to deal with the hard choice of higher taxes or major cuts in spending. No one disputes this is a major part of the problem. This essay’s contribution is to show clearly that the process also matters. Under the rule changes proposed by Chari and Miller, problems would not be allowed to accumulate and be foisted on future generations; they would have to be resolved within a two-year balanced budget span. Not only do they offer a treatment for the problem, but Chari and Miller also provide an analysis of its roots, showing that a sound framework for budget policy decisions is currendy lacking. They go on to provide one, based on economic prin ciples, for their proposed set of reforms. I hope this essay stirs discussion on the nature of the budget policy problem and on economic principles that should be used to guide the process. President Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 1990 Annual Report Playing by The Rules A Proposalfor FederalBudgetReform By Preston J. Miller, Vice President and Deputy Director ofResearch, and V.V. Chari Research Officer The federal budget mess just won’t go away.Despite the discipline of GrammRudman-Hollings (GRH), the government is running ever larger budget deficits, Weproposethattlw making poor decisions and spending an inordinate" amount of time on the process. federal governmentchange In 1990 the budget deficit reached $220 billion. This year; after the torturous passage actowningpractices, of a package of expenditure cuts and tax increases, itfe projected to exceed $30Q bil tastftHtsralesondebtIssue lion. Yet the original GRH deficit tai^et for fiscal 1991 was zero. Vbters are coricemed; Congress is concerned; the admmistration is concerned. Although there is wide- * andImposeonfonoinent spread agreement that something* seriously wrong with the budget process, there mechanisms. Outproposal is less agreement about what should be done about it In response to this concern, will prodecebadgetsthat many proposals for reform have been suggested. Yfet they miss the marie they foil to art balancedovertimein address the problems inherent in the budget process and are not based on sound anappropriatefatherthan economic principles. ^ anarbitrarysense. We provide a conceptual framework for budget policy Based on this framework, we propose that the federal government change accounting practices, institute rules on debt issue and impose enforcement mechanisms. Our proposal will produce budgets that are balanced over time in an appropriate rather than an arbitrary sense. Our proposal also will help inform die decision makers and the public about their policy options and the financial consequences of those options. O f course, our pro* posal will not cure all the ills in the budget process. Hard choices will still have to be made. But first a bit of history Since the late 1960s, the federal government has con sistently run large deficits (Figure 1), These large deficits have led to a dramatic in crease in the federal debt as a percentage of GNP in the 1980s (Figure 2). Interest payments to service this debt have absorbed an increasing proportion of our national product (Figure 3). The debilitating consequences of a growing federal debt are well-known. Large interest payments leave us with less to pay for education, highways, national defense and a variety of useful causes. A growing federal debt tends to raise interest rates and to increase pressure on the Federal Reserve System to follow inflationary policies. This litany of ills may be familiar; nonetheless, it is alarming. To make things worse, even though total non-defense expenditures have been allowed to grow at double-digit rates, too little money has been allocated for capital 237 Components of the Federal Budget Figure i Figure 2 Net Deficit Net Financial Liabilities W HO A - 70 K f\ 60 A A An - JaVA/ Vl\ l A A/ v y v ^ V 1 V 40 ■ V / \ ,K) / 1945 V SO 20 V I 1950 J 1955 . I„ Figure 3 1960 1 1965 1 1970 1 1975 ,i 19S0 Net Interest Payments 1 1985 1. 1990 ol r 1945 j i 1950 1955 Figure 4 %of GNP in 1982 S Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and Department of the Treasury 4 j i i i 1965 1970 1975 i Construction Expenditures i n 238 projects, such as highways, airports and sewer systems. Federal capital spending in fiscal 1991 is projected to be roughly 2.2 percent of GNR down from 4.4 percent of GNP in the early 1960s. Construction expenditures, which are an important com ponent of capital spending, have declined over the postwar period (Figure 4). Surely we can do better than to leave our children decayed highways, crumbled bridges and antiquated sewer systems, with little or no ability to repair or replace any of them because of the enormous tax bills coming due for services consumed before they were even born. We are not the first to offer solutions: The Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Act (GRH) and the reforms of last fall were attempts to respond to these problems. While these attempts to reach a balanced budget are laudable, we think our proposal is better. Specifically, we propose that the federal government adopt the following: ■ Record transactions on an accrual basis and maintain separate operating and capital budgets, ■ Require that the combined operating budget in the current and subsequent fiscal years be balanced, and establish overall limits on capital spending, ■ Institute enforcement mechanisms based on performance to ensure that the rules are being followed, ■ Set up rainy day funds to meet contingencies. Whydoweneedthess or anyrulesatall?Whynot relyonpolicy-makersto mategooddetialona? TheproblemIsthattha policy-makingprocess Isfundamentallybiased againstthafuture. Without rulestoconstrainpolicy decisions, wewill continue tohavebadoutcomes. We would, of course, not be averse to an escape clause suspending the rules in the event of a war or national emergency But we think that such suspension should require a supermajority of votes in Congress and the assent of the president. Why do we need these or any rules at all? Why not rely on policy-makers to make good decisions? The problem is that the policy-making process is fundamen tally biased against the future. Without rules to constrain policy decisions, we will continue to have bad outcomes. So the question is not whether to have rules, it is which rules to have. The current rules do not address the bias, nor are they based on sound economic principles. In the rest of the essay, we explain the bias in policy making, show that the current set of rules is inadequate and argue that our rules will yield good outcomes. The Need for Policy Rules Our political system encourages elected officials to adopt policies that are biased against the future. They are biased, because they are not what voters ideally would like. Voters tend to have a long-term view on policy issues. They care about the outcomes of policy decisions not only over their own lifetimes but over the life times of their descendants. Elected officials, however, tend to adopt a short-term view on policy issues. But why should this be so? If voters could keep themselves fully informed, closely monitor decisions and understand the effects of alternative policies, surely they would force their elected officials to act in the public’s interest. Voters would boot out officials 5 239 RatherthancartingDm guvemmeirt’s biasto excessivelydiscountthe future, theGrammRudman-Hollingsprocess fedH. who acted badly or develop institutional arrangements that set up proper incentives. But voters have neither the ability nor the incentive to get the information necessary to do these things. It is especially difficult for voters to decide whether policy-makers are making wise choices on decisions that will yield benefits or costs several years into the future. So even though voters care about the future, they weight current results heavily They rationally reward policy-makers who make decisions yielding large current benefits even if some of those decisions impose future costs. In order to get reelected, policy-makers have incentives to make decisions that are systematically biased against the future. Thus, it is not especially helpful to argue that if incumbent policy-makers were replaced, wiser policies would be chosen. The problem is that the system en courages policy-makers to adopt the short-term view. This bias results in decisions weighted toward current rather than future con sumption. In particular, these decisions mean too much deficit financing, too little capital investment and a proclivity to put off until tomorrow projects which should be undertaken today. The immediate benefit to elected officials is easily seen. Deficit financing shifts the tax burden for current consumption into the future. This allows more consumption now but less in the future as the taxes are paid. Less capital investment frees up resources and allows more consumption now, but since fewer resources have been invested, there is a smaller supply of goods available for future consumption. Elected officials can also make more resources available for current consumption by putting off projects such as maintenance of the infrastructure or closure of insolvent thrifts. But the problem is that such actions leave fewer resources available in the future as the real costs of the necessary but delayed, expenditures escalate. This policy-making bias against the future is not unique to the government, how ever. Corporate stockholders face many of the same problems as voters in deciding whether corporate managers are acting wisely. Corporate managers act on behalf of stockholders yet they have different interests. Stockholders have incomplete knowl edge about the managers’ decisions and the consequences of the managers’ actions. These are features of the so-called agency problem. Furthermore, no single stockholder has much incentive to monitor management’s actions. Stockholdings are typically dispersed among many individuals. Each stock holder has an incentive to let other stockholders monitor the firm. As a result, typically there is less monitoring of firms’ actions than would occur if the stockholders could act jointly This is known as the free rider problem. Voters also face the agency and free rider problems. It is difficult to know the con sequences of policy-makers’ actions and each voter has an incentive to free ride on other voters. The agency and free rider problems can be mitigated but not entirely solved. If stockholders cannot entirely solve these problems, certainly voters cannot be expected to solve them completely either, since compared to corporate decisions, government policy decisions are aimed at more diverse objectives and the responsi bility for them is more diffuse. 240 How stockholders attempt to manage the agency and free rider problems sug gests ways voters might deal with them, though. Publicly traded corporations, for example, are required to adopt standard accounting practices (known as Generally Accepted Accounting Principles) to inhibit inaccurate presentation of information. Corporate charters also limit management’s discretion. We think these ideas can and should be used to design better policy procedures for the federal government. Corporations also adopt a variety of other practices to align managers’ and stock holders’ interests, including incentive contracts for managers, hostile takeovers and so on. It is not apparent how, or even whether, these other practices can be transferred to the government, so here we will stick to practices that seem readily transferable. The agency and free rider problems point to a need for rules to limit policy makers’ discretion. Tb understand why we arc proposing new rules it is important to understand what’s wrong with the old ones. The Problems With the Old Rules The Gramm-Rudmati-Mailings Process Prior to the fall 1990 reforms, the budget process was designed to work roughly as follows: Early in January the president would submit to Congress a budget for the fiscal year beginning October 1. By the time Congress would adjourn in the summer it would pass bills and a budget resolution specifying amounts to be appropriated to discretionary spending programs and changes to be made to rules for entitlement programs and taxes. In mid-August the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) would determine whether the projected deficit for the upcoming fiscal year exceeded the CRH target by more than $10 billion. If it did, automatic spending cuts would be made according to a statutory formula to ensure that the projected deficit met the target. Then at some point Congress would raise the debt ceiling so that there was authority to issue additional debt to finance the projected deficit. The GRH procedure was supposed to lead to balanced budgets and to eliminate the government’s deficit financing bias by the use of rules. The procedure did not come close to achieving its goal and the original GRH targets had to be revised several times (Figure 5). In addition, the process led to other problems. Rather than curbing the government’s bias to excessively discount the future, the GRH process fed it. By focusing on the projected budget deficit in the approaching fiscal year, the process encouraged deficit financing, discouraged capital spending and made it more attractive to delay necessary expenditures. Paradoxically, the GRH process made deficit financing easier by encouraging the substitution of gimmicks for real actions. The gimmicks included the exchanging of assets, time-shifting of payments, movement of expenditures off the budget and use of unrealistic economic and technical assumptions. Selling government assets, such as loans, for cash resulted in budget savings, even though all that occurred was the exchange of one asset for another one of comparable value. Time-shifting created one time fictitious savings by taking payments scheduled for the approaching fiscal year TheGramm-RudmanHollingsprocessmade deficitfinancingeasier byencouragingthe substitutionofgimmicks forreal actions. The gimmicksIncludedthe exchangingol assets, time-shiftingof payments, movementofexpenditures offthebudgetanduseof unrealisticeconomicand tachnicel assumptions. 241 Figure 5 Gramm-Rudman: Receding Targets (By fiscal year; in billions o f dollars) Actual Deficit Gramm-Rudman I (1985) Gramm-Rudman 11 (1987) 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 $221.2 $149.7 $155.1 171.9 144.0 108.0 72.0 36.0 0 144.0 136.0 100.0 64.0 1992 1993 1994 1995 $153.4 $220.4 28.0 H Gramm-Rudman IH (1990) 327.0 349.8 0 285.2 u n 157.5 s 117.3 Due to bookkeeping changes, the Gramm-Rudman III deficit targets are not direcdy comparable to those of the first two versions of the antideficit law. New accounting rules exclude the surplus in the Social Security trust funds from the deficit calculations; that has the effect of increasing the deficit by at least $60 billion a year. These latest targets are larger than those in the original 1990 budget deal because of pre-planned adjustments in the president’s 1992 budget. Source: Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report, February 9,1991, Vol. 49, No. 6, page 337 and moving them into the current fiscal year where they were simply spilt milk, or into the following fiscal year where they were not yet subject to a sequester For example, the government achieved savings in an approaching fiscal year by taking payments such as employees’ pay and farm subsidies due out in late September and delaying them until early October of the following fiscal year Then without retribu tion, the government was able to switch the payments back once the new fiscal year was entered. Movement of expenditures off-budget, such as was done for die US. Postal Service and the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC), produced budget savings by a stroke of the pen without doing anything real. Finally, projected deficits were reduced by use of optimistic economic and technical assumptions that overestimated tax revenue, underestimated interest expense and understated the costs of existing programs. Just how extensively were these gimmicks used? Robert Reischauer, director of the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), notes that the amount of permanent deficit reduction enacted in the GRH period averaged a bit less than in the pre-GRH period of same duration: “What is different about the two periods is the reliance on one time savings that became a feature of the GRH period. ...In the pre-GRH period, these gimmicks occurred so infiequendy that CBO did not lceep systematic track of them. In the GRH era, fully half of the apparent deficit reduction has been achieved 242 by such devices” {Reischauer, 1990), Reischauer also notes that under GRH the amount of budget savings in the president’s budget attributable to overly optimistic economic and technical assumptions more than tripled. The GRH process, combined with existing accounting practices, also made capital spending highly susceptible to the knife. Existing accounting practices treat spending on capital projects, such as bridges, no differently than spending on cur rent consumption, such as legal counseling. Yet the two are fundamentally different. A capital project provides services in the current year as well as in the future, while current consumption provides services only in the year in which they were pur chased. As a result of this difference, spending on a capital project can be preferable to spending on current consumption yet can return less in benefits in the current year since it also provides benefits in future years. When GRH forced budget cuts in an approaching year, the existing accounting practice led government officials to believe that a dollar cut from capital spending would cause less immediate loss in benefits than would a dollar cut from current consumption. To understand better why this is so, consider the following example. Suppose the government has decided to build a bridge at a cost of $30 million which is expected to provide services over 30 years worth $6.4 million per year. Suppose the interest rate is 10 percent so that the present-value of these services is $60 million. With the present value of the benefits at double the cost, the bridge obviously should be built. But under the government’s accounting system, dropping the project saves $30 million in costs and sacrifices only $6.4 million in benefits. In contrast, a $30 million cut in spending on a less attractive current consumption item, for which benefits only matched costs, would sacrifice $30 million in benefits. Given the short-term focus of GRH, accounting exercises such as these might well explain why capital spending was so susceptible to the knife. In addition to capital spending, GRH made it unattractive to spend money on other projects having short-term costs and long-term benefits. For example, the government avoided proper maintenance of nuclear armaments plants to save money in the short term. Because of that neglect, the cost of keeping these plants operating has escalated and the additional cost is now estimated by the CBO to be roughly $160 billion spread over the next 40 years. Another painful example is the savings and loan crisis. If the government had dealt with the problem when it surfaced in 1986, it would have meant closing some insolvent thrifts at an estimated cost of $10 billion to $15 billion. But the government balked, at least in part because it didn’t want to put more pressure on itself to abide by the GRH targets. So spending to remedy the problem was delayed, the problem mushroomed, and the cost to the government as estimated by the CBO and the General Accounting Office rose to over $150 billion in presentvalue terms. The GRH process not only generated poor results, it also contributed to delays and confusion. Without a conceptual framework, policy-makers were forced to debate each minor budget variation as if it were a new theme. TheGramm-RurfmanHollingsprom* notonly generatedpoorresults, it alsocontributedtodelays andconfusion. Withouta conceptualframework, policy-makerswereforced todebateeachminor budgetvariationas Hit wereanewtheme. 243 The hill I99<) Ri’forms The government was well aware that the budget process was in need o f repair and direction. The administration suggested numerous reforms, including instituting a line-item veto and changing the accounting procedures for loans and guarantees. The budget committees in both chanihers of Congress held hearings on reform, several bills proposing reforms were introduced and the budget package that finally was passed last fall contains important reforms of the process. It’s too early to judge whether the fall reforms will lead to improvements in the process, hut its not too early to argue they don’t go far enough.These reforms still fail to provide government officials with a conceptual framework tor making decisions, and the definition of budget deficits and the targets tor them remain arbitrary Main Features of the Fall 1990 Budget Process Reforms ■ Rve-fear Budgeting. Budget resolutions and necessary reconciliation hills must project spending, revenues and deficits for five years. * DUcrstiOlltry Spending bps. Appropriations bills must stay within separate caps for defense, foreign aid and domestic discretionary spending for fiscal 1991-93; for fiscal 1994-95, the law sets overall discretionary spending caps. ■ Enforcement A complicated set of sequesters ensures that spending stays within the caps in the bill. Essentially, these sequesters apply if the Office of Management and Budget determines that spending will exceed the caps. The sequesters also “look back” to offset spending increases or revenue cuts in the prior fiscal year. * Piy-As-foli-Go Entitlements md Revenues. Bills containing increases in entitlement or other mandatory spending or reducing revenues must be offset by entitlement cuts or revenue increases. ■ Social SecurityandDepositInsurance. Social Security receipts and expenditures will no longer be included in budget calculations. Increased spending for deposit insurance activities—chiefly the savings and loan salvage operation—will not be allowed to trigger sequesters. * Em ergencies. If requested to do so by the president, Congress could enact emergency appropriations, entidement increases or revenue cuts with out triggering sequesters. ■ Hhr Mid Recession. A declaration of war would still cancel the sequester process. Congress could still vote to cancel the sequester process in the event of a projected recession or measured economic growth below 1 percent for two consecutive quarters. ID 244 The reforms make it more difficult to exceed the deficit targets, hut they also make it easier to niise the targets (see box tor details on the reforms/. Under the new process, there are constraints placed not only on the size of the total budget deficit as before, but also separately on entitlements, revenues and three types o f discretionary spending. In addition, a series of three sequesters cm be prompted by spending overruns in the prior fiscal year. These reforms give Congress less maneuvering room to exceed budget deficit targets. But at the same time, the reforms allow the deficit targets to be raised for economic and technical reasons, emergencies and increased spending on deposit insurance activities. Since the targets .ire arbitrary; the govern ment is highly likely to use these loopholes to continue its deficit spending ways. The reforms also fail to resolve problems associated with the current accounting The fall reforms of the budget process provide a system. I Inder the tall reforms it is still possible to achieve budget "savings" by shifting transition to a more payments forward into future fiscal years, although the reforms remove much of the balanced federal budget. incentive to shift them back to the current fiscal year. That’s because past spending But even If they take us to overruns could prompt a sequester and thus are no longer treated as spilt milk. that destination, problems However, the reforms do nothing to address the bias against capital spending. Capital expenditures are still treated 110 differently from current expenditures. We have argued that rules are needed to address the policy bias problem, but we wilt remain. Without a logical basis for their have seen that had rules can create further problems. While the tall 1990 reforms targets, policy-makers will improve the origin.il CRH rules, a lot more should be done. That is why we offer our find ways to violate them. proposal. Without a sound accounting The t.ill reforms of the budget process provide a transition to a more balanced federal budget. But even if they take us to that destination, problems will remain. system, they will continue to bias their decisions. Without a logical basis for their targets, policy-makers will find ways to violate them. Without a sound accounting system, they will continue to bias their decisions. And without a conceptual framework, they will continue to debate ever}1budget nuance as if it were a new problem. The Case for Our Rules Basic Principles Our budget proposal is a set of reforms intended to reduce both the policy-making bias and the confusion associated with current procedures, and its guided by tour basic economic principles. First, the budget should be balanced in a present-value sense without use o f the inflation tax. This principle is based 011 an accounting identity and on a stated goal of macroeconomic policy. The identity says that what goes out from the government must come in, and it implies that the present value of government expenditures cannot exceed the present value of government receipts. Since it would be inefficient for the government to take in more than was needed, it follows that the present value ot government expenditures should equal the present value o f government receipts. In this equality receipts can include proceeds from the inflation tax, that is, the depreciation caused bv inflation in the value o f government nominal liabilities. However, based on statements in Humphrey-Hawkins legislation and congressional ii 245 testimony ot high officials in the Feder.il Reserve, we take price stability to he a goal of policy With zero inflation as a goal, the first principle follows. Second, benefits should outweigh costs. This follows from the theory of econom ic policy-making which requires that government officials weigh alternative programs in terms of their economic benefits and costs to society Since the services o f programs occur over time, the government must measure benefits and costs in expected, present-value terms. Those benefits and costs are dated to occur when resources are transferred in and out of the private sector.Thus, when the government hires workers, That beneficiaries of government programs should pay is partly a the economic cost occurs when the workers enter the public sector and not when the government gets around to mailing their checks. The third economic principle is that users pay. That beneficiaries o f government fairness argument. It also programs should pay is partly a fairness argument. It also has the virtue o f making it more likely that the benefits of public programs exceed their costs, since those costs has the virtue of making it cannot be pushed (iff on non-involved parties. This principle suggests that borrow'ing more likely that the to finance current consumption is unacceptable because that method o f financing benefits of public programs exceed their costs, since those costs cannot be pushed off on non-lnvolved parties. pushes the costs off to future generations who do not benefit from the consumption. In contrast, it also suggests that borrowing to finance capital spending is acceptable since future generations will benefit from the services of that capit.il. Obviously this principle cannot be applied across the board. By definition, income redistribution programs, such as wdtare, cannot be financed by recipients. But some other pro grams, such as the national parks and the highway system, would fall squarely under the user-pays principle. And most other programs would fall under this principle in a general way Current services should be paid for by the current generation, And transfers to the poor of one generation, which are designed to even the income distribution, should be paid for by the wealthy of the same generation. Our fourth economic principle, tax smoothing, is an implication ot studies of the tax structure. The implication follows as long as the deaduK’ight loss, the distortions caused by the tax anti the resources burned up in collecting it, rises disproportion ately with the tax rate. That is, the deadweight loss more than doubles when the tax rate doubles, lax smoothing means that when the government has commitments to spend in the future, it should begin taxing for them today This is true whether those commitments are contractual, such as underfunded pensions, or non-contractual but fairly certain to occur, such as wars or natural disasters. What this means in practice is that its more efficient to raise taxes a little bit now and keep them there than it is to wait ami raise them a lot when the spending takes place. We believe that these four simple principles suggest reforms o f the budget process which help deal with the policy bias problem. We also believe they can provide guidance on many current budgetary issues. Our Reforms in More Detail Our proposal for reform is hardly radical. It is com posed ot modest changes in accounting procedures, rules on debt issue and enforcement mechanisms. Most of the changes are either incorporated into budget practices of corporations mid state 12 246 and local governments or included in other proposals tor feder.il budget reform. The accounting changes we propose are that expenditures and receipts he recorded on .in accrual basis and that separate accounts be maintained for operating and capit.il items. I hese accounting changes follow directly from our cost-benefit timing and user-pays principles. Our cost-benefit tuning principle requires that expenditures and receipts be recorded when the activity giving rise to them occurs; that is, they should be recorded on an accrual basis. Our user-pays principle suggests that it is not appropriate to borrow tor operating expenses but it may be appropriate to borrow tor capital. Therefore, it follows that separate accounts should be main tained tor operating and capital items. These accounting changes aJlow the financial effects of alternative policy actions to be more accurately represented. This facilitates official decision making and also Our proposal for reform is hardly radical. It is composed of modest makes it easier tor voters to monitor officials’ actions. Our proposals tor accounting changes in accounting changes are not original. They have been proposed by the General Accounting Office procedures, rules on debt ;GAO; and they have been included in a bill introduced by Sen. Herbert Kohl of issue and enforcement Wisconsin. Most firms and state governments, as well as the Federal Reserve, mechanisms. Most of the maintain separate operating and capital accounts. The federal budget is reported on an accrual basis in the National Income Accounts, and the budget, calculated as the changes are either CiAC') and we recommend, is produced by the O M R in a timely manner. Thus, all that is new here is that we are proposing using this existing budget information as the basis practices of corporations tor policy deliberations and rules. and state and local The rule changes we propose limit the amount of debt the government can issue incorporated into budget governments or Included on its operating and capital accounts. The rules follow from our principles and from in other proposals for our attempts to reduce the policy bias. Although they involve only minor changes to federal budget reform. existing rules, they provide explicit policy targets. We propose to limit the debt that can be issued on the operating budget by requir ing that the combined estimated and projected budget balance be zero in the current and subsequent fiscal years. Since the accounts would be maintained on an accrual basis, the proposal allows operating debt to be issued temporarily when there is a mistiming of payments mid receipts. It also could be issued temporarily when unforeseen spending increases or revenue losses occur. However, by including the current year's deficit in the calculation, the government would have to implement policies to eliminate debt caused by mistakes in budget projections. This proposal is similar to current GRH procedures and suggested balance-the-budget amendments. What is new in our proposal is that the budget being balanced is the operating budget and that adherence to the rule leads straightforwardly to present-value balance of the entire budget, without inflation, as our first principle requires. But why a two-year rule rather than a five-year rule or a month-by-month rule? Given the nature of the policy bias against the future, a rule requiring a balanced budget over a fairly short time frame is desirable. Otherwise, policy-makers can continue to run deficits while claiming they will be offset by surpluses at some distant time. However, neither spending nor tax revenues can be forecasted very accurately, and unforeseen events do occur. Thus, if the time frame is too short, policy-makers 13 247 Weproposetolimitthe debtthatcanbeissued onthecapital budget by requiringCongresstopass abill annuallyauthorizing debtIssueuptoaspecified ceiling. Whilethisis much likecurrentprocedures, ourcellingappliesonlyto debt Issuedtofinance capitalspending. This meansthatthecelling wouldbeanindependent control oncapital spending. 14 will continually be forced to make changes to expenditure programs or tax rates. In our view, a two-year rule is a reasonable compromise. We propose to limit the debt that can be issued on the capital budget by requiring Congress to pass a bill annually authorizing debt issue up to a specified ceiling. While this is much like current procedures, our ceiling applies only to debt issued to finance capital spending. This means that the ceiling would be an independent control on capital spending. It would not be redundant, required as it is now, to accommodate the operating deficits Congress has planned. Since all capital spending would be financed by debt issue, setting a ceiling on debt would be equivalent to setting a ceiling on federal capital spending. This would let policy-makers better decide on a desirable mix of private and public capital. More capital spending would be desirable as long as the benefits of a project were at least as large as its costs. We view a ceiling on total capital spending as desirable so that Congress as a whole can effectively force constituencies for capital spending to compete with each other. This reduces the incentives to spend excessively on capital equipment. We propose to enforce the rules using approaches similar to current practices. The rule on operating debt would be enforced with a sequester. The sequester could be applied in a disaggregated way, as it is under current procedures. The sequester would be triggered whenever the combined operating deficit in the current and succeeding year exceeded some small amount—say $10 billion to match the trigger amount under GRH. The sequester would require cuts in spending or increases in revenue to achieve combined budget balance. Thus, if there were an unforeseen deficit of $20 billion in the current fiscal year, the government would have to adopt policies leading to a $20 billion surplus in the succeeding year. We would limit the amount of deficit reduction in a sequester to 0.5 percent of GNP, which is roughly the amount of reduction that experts testified could be implemented without causing major eco nomic disruptions. The rule on capital debt would be self-enforcing. The Treasury simply would not be authorized to issue debt above the legislated ceilings. Our proposals so far are derived from our economic principles of present-value balance, cost-benefit comparison and user-pays, but seem in conflict with our tax-smoothing principle. The reason is that government spending and revenues fluctuate due to causes that cannot be perfecdy anticipated. Wars and recessions are as likely to occur in the future as they have in the past, but it’s hard to know when. Therefore, meeting the two-year balanced budget rule would require sharp changes in tax rates when these contingencies occur. To avoid these kinds of changes in tax rates, we propose that rainy day funds be set up to meet contingencies. These rainy day funds would be set apart from the operating budget. Inflows of cash into these funds would be counted as oudays for the operating budget and outflows from these funds would be counted as receipts. By drawing down the funds in bad times and building them up in good times, tax rates would not have to be adjusted in conflict with our tax-smoothing principle. Since we recognize the temptation to raid these funds in good times, we suggest that a supermajority in Congress be required to use these funds. 248 What Our Reforms Will Accomplish Our reforms are intended to lessen the government’s bias to overly discount the future and to remove some of the confusion that surrounds current budgetary practices. We argue that they lessen the bias by making deficit financing more difficult, capital spending more attractive and procrastinating more costly. We argue that they reduce the confusion by providing a framework based on economic principles. How do we make deficit spending more difficult? Reporting the accounts on an accrual basis takes away the budget ‘'savings” options of selling off assets for cash and delaying payments to government employees or program beneficiaries. Accrual accounting records when activities take place and not when exchanges or payments are made. Including an explicit makeup for past errors in the enforcement mechanism reduces the incentive to use overly optimistic economic and technical assumptions. Mistakes require painful adjustments in the upcoming year. And, as we argue later, requiring present-value balance makes the movement of items to off-budget status less advantageous. However, the most important contribution the proposal makes to controlling deficits is that it provides a definition of budget deficit and specifications of targets which are guided by economic principles and, thus, have some logical basis. One problem with the GRH targets is that they were designed to lead to budget balance for an arbitrary definition of the budget. There is no economic principle that suggests the deficit should be zero when capital transactions are included in the definition of balance. Moreover, under the GRH deficit definition there are different targets depending on whether Social Security or the RTC are included. Our definition and targets are not as arbitrary as those of GRH, and that should make it harder to raise or disregard the deficit targets. They are guided by the present-value principle. The definition makes clear that capital transactions are excluded from the zero deficit target. Having a clearer idea of the reason for the targets should make it easier to stay the course. Our proposal also makes capital spending more attractive by putting it on a more equal footing with current spending. A dollar cut from capital spending would have a comparable effect in the current fiscal year to a dollar cut from current spending. That is because in our proposal the operating cost of a capital asset is spread out over the life of the asset. While the purchase price of the asset is reported in the capital budget, only the annual depreciation and interest financing expense are reported on the operating budget. Thus, a dollar cut from capital spending cuts current spending by the amount of depreciation and interest. Our method spreads the cost of capital equipment over the years it provides services, while the current method charges it all to the current year. Our yearly charge is essentially what it would cost the government if it rented the capital from a private party The main difference between our method and current practices is how it treats dollars saved on capital spending in the current year. If the government decided not to purchase capital equipment, our method would show that the savings in current expenses would be only depreciation and interest. According to current practices the savings would be the cost of the capital purchase, which is much larger. As a result, 15 249 current practices make cuts in capital spending look more attractive to policy-makers than they really are. As is usual under standard accounting principles, we would require that the government’s assets be carried on its books at the lesser of cost or market value. Some assets of the government have an ascertainable market value such as the assets acquired from failed savings and loans. Thus, for such assets the government would have an incentive to provide appropriate maintenance. If the government did not maintain such assets appropriately, their market value would fall, thereby resulting in a larger depreciation charge and adversely affecting the government’s operating budget. Even for assets without a readily ascertainable market value, such as nuclear arma ments plants, standard accounting practices provide better incentive for maintenance than current practices. Our method also requires quick action to balance the budget when circumstances change. In this sense, under our proposal the federal government would be forced to act like state and local governments now do. Under our proposal, difficult choices could not be simply passed on to future Congresses and administrations. To illustrate how our proposal and the economic principles on which it is based could work to reduce the confusion surrounding current budgetary issues, we examine the treatment of trust funds, the RTC, loans and guarantees and future commitments. The controversy over trust funds, such as Social Security, is whether they should be on-budget or off-budget. If on-budget, their balances would be included in deficit calculations and targets. If off-budget, they would not. Our present-value balance principle gives some guidance on this issue. To move a program off-budget means that the program should have an independent budget. It should neither rely on revenue from the general budget nor should its earmarked revenue be accessible to other programs in the budget. If it’s not independent, then it’s not truly a trust fund and it’s not truly off-budget. The question of whether Social Security should be off-budget is then a question of whether its budget should be independent of the general budget. If the answer is yes, then by the present-value principle the Social Security budget and the general budget should be balanced independently in a present-value sense. If the answer is no, then just the sum of the two budgets should be balanced in present value. Within this framework, policy makers must first decide whether they want Social Security to have an independent budget, and if they do, they will find their choices to be quite limited on the financing of committed Social Security benefits. For instance, experts believe that given current benefit schedules and tax rates the Social Security system is balanced in present-value terms. Thus, by the present-value and tax-smoothing principles, policy-makers would not be allowed to lower Social Security tax rates unless they also lowered the benefits. We should also point out that our analysis of the policy bias problem suggests that trust fund accounting can be a useful disciplinary device. Because voters lack the information required to monitor the actions of policy-makers, it’s hard to monitor whether policy-makers are following the cost-benefit principle. This monitoring 16 250 difficulty is particularly acute when expenditures are financed out of general tax revenues. Beneficiaries have every reason to argue that the benefits accruing to them are large, whether they value the services a lot or a little. Dedicated programs with independent revenue sources that have strong safeguards against raiding the treasury can be useful in solving the monitoring problem. From this perspective, trust funds are not merely an accounting device; rather, they serve an important economic function. We also recognize that trust funds can be abused. Given the bias in policy-making, policy-makers have an incentive to postpone costs and accelerate benefits. For example, policy-makers have an incentive to run a deficit or a smaller surplus than is desirable on the Social Security system. The result is that future benefits must be reduced or future taxes raised if the system is to be independently balanced. One crude way to limit abuses of this kind is to require that trust funds not run a deficit. The issue on RTC spending is how to split it up into on-budget and off-budget. The RTC handles the assets and liabilities of failed thrifts. Since RTC spending relies on general revenues, our reasoning on trust funds suggests all of it belongs on-budget. The drive to move some of it off-budget was mainly a result of the current procedure’s failure to distinguish capital spending from operating expenses. What typically occurs is that the RTC takes over a failed thrift with assets valued at, say, $700 million and insured deposits of, say, $1 billion. The $1 billion must be paid off immediately, while the $700 million in assets is sold gradually over a number of years. By current methods the $1 billion is treated as a current expenditure. Then, when the assets are sold over time, the sale receipts are treated as revenue. The pay-off to depositors is funded by debt issue and the debt is in effect reduced when the assets are sold. The interest is also treated as an expenditure. The current procedure clearly overstates the deficit in the current year, since it assigns no value to the assets the government acquires. The drive to move RTC spending off-budget was a clumsy attempt to correct this problem. Using our procedures, only the capital loss and interest expense would show up on the operating budget. That budget would not be affected by the timing of asset sales. When the RTC initially takes over the failed thrift, it would be considered a capital purchase of $1 billion financed by debt. However, since the assets were worth only $700 million, there would be an immediate write-off of $300 million charged to depreciation. As with other capital purchases, there also would be an associated interest expense. Future asset sales would affect the operating budget only to the extent that actual sale values differed from the capital budget’s assumed market values. Thus, using our procedures, RTC spending would be treated no differently from other capita] spending. Capital budgeting also would clarify the treatment of government loans and guarantees. These items involve subsidies that are realized when private parties fail to maintain payments on loans. Past budget practices have treated the government loss of loan revenue or payment on a loan guarantee as a budget deficit increase at the time they occur. Thus, it appears to policy-makers as a good way to give out subsidies now and pay for them much later. Under our proposal, loans and guarantees would be Our reforms are Intended to lessen the government’* bias to overly discount the future and to remove some of the confusion that surrounds currant budgetary practices. We argue that they lessen the bias by making deficit financing more difficult, capital spending more attractive end procrastinating more costly. 17 251 Themaindifference betweenourmethodand currentpracticesishowit treatsdollarssavedon capital spendinginthe currentyear. ...current practicesmakecatsin capitalspending lookmore attractivetopolicy-makers thantheyreallyare. included in the capital budget as assets and liabilities, respectively The subsidies on loans and guarantees would show up on the operating budget at the time the loans and guarantees were granted. Under our proposal policy-makers would be con fronted immediately with the costs of the subsidies. We should point out that the way loans and guarantees affect the operating budget under our proposal is similar to how they will affect the GRH budget following last year’s reforms. Finally; our tax-smoothing principle suggests that revenue should be collected today for future commitments. Currendy the money is not collected until after the event occurs. Some of the commitments are contractual or explicit, such as pensions, and for these the government might make advance payments into something like an escrow account. Other commitments are not explicit but are fairly certain to occur in the future, such as wars and natural disasters. For these we have proposed that the government make advance payments into a rainy day account. The purpose of the escrow and rainy day accounts is to provide present-value budget balance without having to change tax rates. Assuming that the government^ capital expenditures rise at the same rate as national income, the effect of the accounts is to lower the government’s debt-to-income ratio over time until the commitments are realized and then to allow them to rise at that time. Over long periods of time, the debt-to-income ratio would remain constant. The purpose of using our procedures to examine these issues is to show their practical value. We believe they can considerably reduce the confusion surrounding current budget practices. Objections to Our Reforms Since aspects of our proposal have been tossed around for some time, we can anticipate two important objections to it. One objection is that it does not accommo date countercyclical policy, and the other is that our proposal would encourage policy-makers to move everything over to the capital budget Although these objec tions have some validity, we believe they are not decisive. We believe the constraint on countercyclical policy is not very costly, and we believe safeguards can be put in place to limit misclassification of expenditures. Consider first the loss in flexibility to conduct fiscal policy. Our proposal allows some limited countercyclical policy, but it does not allow the government to suspend the rules in case of a recession. The availability of a rainy day fund would, in any case, allow for some countercyclical fiscal policy But when an unforeseen shortfall does occur, it could be accommodated in the current year, provided it is made up for in the succeeding year. The government would also be able to increase capital spending in a recession when interest rates were low, because such spending then would generate less interest expense. • Nonetheless, our proposal is more rigid on countercyclical policy-making than current procedures. We do not think this rigidity is very cosdy because we are unaware of any evidence that discretionary countercyclical budget policy works. Most studies show that lags in responding to recessions cause any stimulative effects 18 252 of fiscal policy to occur too late, well into the ensuing recovery. Furthermore, the rigidity could be beneficial. If the decline in the growth rate of real output goes on for a long period, perhaps there is a secular as well as a cyclical element. To the extent that an output decline signals a long-term reduction in output growth, the government should reduce spending. Consider next the objection that policy-makers will want to move everything to the capital budget. To a great extent that’s true, but we argue that now everything, in effect, is treated as a capital expense. The government can borrow to finance any expenditure. So by strictly defining what is a capital expenditure, as states have done and as the GAO proposes for the federal government, many expenditures can be kept off the capital budget. Even with strict definitions, though, there will be problems with misclassifications or understating of depreciation on capital items. Some expenditures that provide benefits in future years would be classified as current. In fact, we would favor including most human resource programs, such as those for education, crime control and health, on the operating budget. We do not deny that a better educated, better protected and healthier population will make people better off in the future. We also do not deny that requiring these expenditures to be paid in full in the current year could lead to underfunding. It is just our judgment that the underfunding bias would be no greater than the policy-makers’ bias to overspend on current consumption. Thus, we judge that by stricdy limiting the capital budget to long-lived physical and nominal assets, a small cost in terms of underfunding of some expenditures would be more than offset: there would be a smaller bias toward overspending on current consumption, which now is facilitated by abuse of the debt-issue option. The government would also try to understate depreciation, as states and corpor ations have been known to do. It could classify some current consumption items as capital items and assign them value, even though, in a sense, they are fully depreciated in the current year and have no value. Or it could just overstate the value of some of its physical or nominal assets. This is where watchdogs such as the CBO and GAO would have to be on the alert. The logic of our proposal requires that depreciation be accurately recorded on the operating budget. If it were not, the budget situation could be seriously misrepresented. Understatement of asset depreciation led to the unrec ognized deterioration in the financial condition of many state and local governments and various financial institutions. Since aspects of our proposal have been tossed around for some time, we can anticipate two Important objections to It. One objection Is that It does not accommodate countercyclical policy, and tha other Is that our proposal would encourage policy-makers to move everything over to tha capital budget. Although these objections have some validity, we believe they are not decisive. Transition How do we get from the current system to our proposed system? Some of our reforms—accrual accounting and separating the capital and operating budgets— could and should be adopted for fiscal 1992. All that is required is that policy-makers look at a different set of books. However, an immediate move to a balanced budget would require enormous and disruptive increases in taxes or reductions in spending. We believe the government should move to a balanced operating budget over a three-to-five-year period. Over this period, the goal of monetary policy should be to 19 253 We believe ttw government should move to a balanced operating budget over a thiee-tottve-year period. Over this period, the goal of monetary policy should be to reduce the Inflation rate gradually to zero. reduce the inflation rate gradually to zero. Such transition periods have been abused in the past, but we think our enforce ment mechanism provides a way to limit future abuses. Specifically, we propose imposing annual limits on the operating budget deficit during the transition period. These limits would be enforced with a sequester. If the limits are exceeded within a given year, then the sequester would require cuts in spending or increases in revenues in the following year. These proposals, combined with the tall 1990 reforms enacted by Congress, would go a long way to reducing the deficit to zero over roughly a five-year span. It’s also possible to frontload the pain of spending reductions and tax increases to a greater extent than is now mandated under the fall 1990 reforms. One major problem with the GRH process was that large deficit reductions were supposed to occur toward the end of the targets, and this problem persists though to a lesser extent with the fell 1990 reforms. When the real pain of deficit reduction is postponed, however, the temptation to revise the targets often becomes irresistible. The only credible way around this problem is to ensure that substantial deficit reduction occurs in the early years of the transition period. Our Rules Are No Panacea We would like to conclude by claiming it would be all smooth sailing if only our proposal were accepted. But of course we know that’s not true. No change in the process can make the difficult choices confronting policy-makers easy They still would have to decide whose ox to gore by cutting spending or increasing taxes. But we think policy-makers would make better decisions if they understood what they were up against and what the consequences of their actions would be. No change in budget process is going to solve the policy bias problem or keep the government out of financial difficulty. Better budget processes than the federal government now employs have not stopped these problems with corporations or state governments. We nevertheless strongly believe our proposal can lessen the magnitude of the problems. Will our proposal work, or is a more drastic measure such as a constitutional amendment necessary? We believe that the situation is not yet so dire as to warrant such an extreme action. Concern over the budget is widespread enough in the nation and among policy-makers that we feel the problems described here can be addressed legislatively. The budget mess will not be completely cleaned up even if all our reforms are adopted. Hard choices will still have to be made. But we will no longer have the choice of inflicting costs upon future generations for programs that benefit us. 20 254 Suggested Readings On Political Economy: A classic in the field is... Downs, Anthony. 1957. Economic theory o f democracy. New York: Harper Press. Other excellent readings are... Buchanan, James and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The calculus o f consent Ann A rbor University of Michigan Press. O lson, Mancur. 1971. The logic o f collective action. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. On Agency Theories of the Firm: Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold. 1972. Production, information costs, and eco nomic organization. American Economic Review 62, pp. 777-795. Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, William H. 1976. Theory o f the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal o f Financial Economics 3, pp. 305-360. On Recent Budget Policy: Miller, Preston. 1989. Gramm-Rudman-HoUings' hold on budget policy: Losing its grip? Federal Reserve Bank o f Minneapolis Quarterly Review 13, pp. 11-21. Reischauer, Robert. 1990. Taxes and spending under Gramm-Rudman-HoUings. National TaxJournal 4 3 , pp. 223-232. Schick, Allen. 1990. The capacity to budget. Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute Press. On Last Fall’s Reforms: Congressional Quarterly staff, 1990. Budget-reconciliation bill. Congressional Quarterly, December 1, pp. 4012-4036. On Proposed Reforms: Bowsher, Charles A. 1988. Budget reform for the federal government. Statement before the Committee on Governmental Affairs, US. Senate, June 7. Budget reform proposals. 1989. Joint hearings before the Committee on Governmental Affairs and the Committee on the Budget, US. Senate, October 18,26. Acknowledgements We wish to thank Rudolph tenner, Alice Rivlin, Mark Sniderman, Eugene Steuerle and John Sturrock for useful comments on an earlier draft. 21 255 Statement of Condition (in thousands) December 31, 199° December 31, 1989 $ 203,000 172,000 13,228 5,495 $ 198,000 153,000 12,281 8,450 101,300 3,755,330 109,844 3,817,846 Cash Items in Process o f Collection 364,686 434,312 Bank Premises and Equipm entLess Depreciation of $33,493 and $27,704 Foreign Currencies Other Assets Interdistrict Settlement Fund 44,079 978,960 96,005 (188,629) 35,311 1,002,624 77,371 (405,069) Assets Gold Certificate Account Special Drawing Rights Coin Loans to Depository Institutions Securities: Federal Agency Obligations US. Government Securities Total Assets ______ $5,545,454 $5,443,970 $3,928,662 $4,146,926 1,027,895 4,500 6,207 685,999 4,800 30,478 1,038,602 721,277 395,132 46,036 389,555 51,448 5,408,432 5,309,206 68,511 68,511 67,382 67,382 137,022 134,764 Liabilities Federal Reserve N otes1 Deposits: Depository Institutions Foreign, Official Accounts Other Deposits Total Deposits Deferred Credit Items Other Liabilities Total Liabilities Capital Accounts Capital Paid In Surplus Total Capital Accounts Total Liabilities and Capital Accounts 'Amount is net of notes held by the Bank of $ 769 million in 1990 and S856 million in 1989. 22 _____ _____ S 5,545,454 $5,443,970 256 Earnings and Expenses (in thousands) For the Year Ended December 31, 1990 1989 $322,275 78,441 5,596 40,886 451 $321,299 33,152 6,173 38,513 476 447,649 399,613 32,901 7,567 1,643 5,576 429 2,041 2,328 31,024 6,648 1,382 5,285 433 1,510 2,265 Current Earnings Interest on US. Government Securities and Federal Agency Obligations Interest on Foreign Currency Investments Interest on Loans to Depository Institutions Revenue torn Priced Services All Other Earnings Total Current Earnings Current Expenses Salaries and Other Personnel Expenses Retirement and Other Benefits Travel Postage and Shipping Communications Software Materials and Supplies Building Expenses: Real Estate Taxes Depreciation—Bank Premises Utilities Rent and Other Building Expenses Furniture and Operating Equipment: Rentals Depreciation and Miscellaneous Purchases Repairs and Maintenance Cost o f Earnings Credits Net Costs Distributed/Received from Other FR Banks Other Operating Expenses Total Reimbursed Expenses2 Net Expenses Current Net Earnings 1Reflects a Si,424 refund of 19H9 taxes and a reduction ui 1990 taxes. 2Reimburse merits due from the U.S. Treasury and o ther federal agencies; $3,893 was unrcimbursed in 1990 and $1,682 Net Additions3 Less: Assessment by Board of Governors: Board Expenditures Federal Reserve Currency Costs Dividends Raid ftayments to US. Treasury Transferred to Surplus (512)' 1,071 862 1,029 2,359 1,072 778 965 567 4,573 2,660 6,426 2,103 1,689 600 4,462 2,461 7,371 1,784 2,585 72,953 72,984 (811) (2,496) 72,142 70,488 375,507 65,190 329,125 41,303 3,094 3,311 4,061 429,102 2,823 3,131 4,026 359,912 1,129 536 67,382 1,129 66,846 536 $ 68,511 $ 67,382 in 1989. 'T his item consists mamly of unrealized net gains (losses) related to revaluation o f assets denom inated in breign cu rren cies to market rates. Surplus Account Surplus, January 1 Transferred to Surplus—as above Surplus, December 31 23 257 Directors Federal Reserve Bank o f Minneapolis Helena Branch Michael W. Wright Chairman and Federal Reserve Agent J. Frank Gardner Chairman Delbert W. Johnson Deputy Chairman James E. Jenks Vice Chairman December 31,1990 Class A Elected by Member Banks J. Frank Gardner President Montana Resources, Inc. Butte, Montana Joel S. Harris President Yellowstone Bank Billings, Montana James E. Jenks Hogeland, Montana James H. Hearon, HI Chairman of the Board and Chief Executive Officer National City Bank Minneapolis, Minnesota Class B Elected by Member Banks Bruce C. Adams Parmer Triple Adams Farms Minot, North Dakota Duane E. Dingmann President Trubilt Auto Body, Inc. Eau Claire, Wisconsin Earl R. St.John, Jn President St.John Forest Products, Inc. Spalding, Michigan Class C Appointed by the Board of Governors Delbert W. Johnson President and Chief Executive Officer Pioneer Metal Finishing Minneapolis, Minnesota Gerald A. Rauenhorst Chairman and Chief Executive Officer Opus Corporation Minneapolis, Minnesota Michael W. Wright Chairman, Chief Executive Officer and President SuperValu Stores, Inc. Minneapolis, Minnesota Federal Advisory Council Member Lloyd EJohnson Chairman and Chief Executive Officer Norwest Corporation Minneapolis, Minnesota 24 Appointed by the Board of Governors Rodney W. Fouberg Chairman Farmers & Merchants Bank & Trust Co. Aberdeen, South Dakota Appointed by the Board of Directors Federal Reserve Bank ofMinneapolis Beverly D. Harris President Empire Federal Savings & Loan Assoc. Livingston, Montana Noble E Vbsburg President and Chief Executive Officer Pacific Hide and Fur Corporation Great Falls, Montana Robert H. Waller President and Chief Executive Officer First Interstate Bank of Billings, N.A. Billings, Montana 258 Officers December 3 1 ,1 9 9 0 Federal Reserve Bank o f Minneapolis Gary H . Stem President R ichard L. Kuxhausen Vice President S. Rao Aiyagari Research Officer Thom as E. Kleinschmit Assistant Vice President Thom as E. Gainor First Vice President David Levy Vice President and Director of Public Affairs Kent G Austinson Supervision Officer M arvin L. Knoff Supervision Officer Robert C. Brandt Assistant Vice President Richard W Puttin Assistant Vice President Jam es U Brooks Assistant Vice President Susan K. Rossbach Assistant General Counsel Marilyn L. Brown Assistant General Auditor Thom as M . Supel Assistant Vice President Vkradarajan V. Chari Research Officer Claudia S. Swendseid Assistant Vice President Lawrence J. Christiano Research Officer Robert E. Teetshom Supervision Officer Scott H. Dake Assistant Vice President Kenneth C T h e ise n Assistant Vice President James T. Deusterhoff Assistant Vice President Thom as H . Turner Assistant Vice President Kathleen J. Balkman Vice President Richard K. Einan Assistant Vice President and Community Affairs Officer Carolyn A. Verret Assistant Vice President John H . Boyd Senior Research Officer Jean C. Garrick Assistant Vice President Phil C. G erber Vice President Peter J. Gavin Assistant Vice President Caryl W. Hayward Vice President Karen L. Grandstrand Assistant Vice President Bruce H . Johnson Vice President James H . Hammill Credit and Corporate Affairs Officer Melvin L. Burstein Senior Vice President and General Counsel Jam es M . Lyon Vice President Leonard W. Femelius Senior Vice President Susan J. M anchester Vice President Ronald E. Kaatz Senior Vice President Preston J. Miller Vice President and Deputy Director of Research A rthur J. Rolnick Senior Vice President and Director of Research C olleen K. Strand Senior Vice President and Chief Financial Officer Sheldon L. Azine Vice President and Deputy General Counsel Charles L. Shromoff General Auditor T heodore E. Umhoefei; Jc Vice President W arren E. W eber Senior Research Officer William B. Holm Assistant Vice President Helena Branch Ronald O . Hostad Assistant Vice President John D. Johnson Vice President and Branch Manager Samuel H . Gane Assistant Vice President O M ildred E Williams Assistant Vice President William G . W urster Assistant Vice President