View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

92d Congress 1
2d Session /

JOINT COMMITTEE PRINT

GOLD, SDR’S, AND CENTRAL BANK SWAPS
REPORT
OF THE

SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL
EXCHANGE AND PAYMENTS
OF THE

JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE
CONGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES
TOGETHER WITH

ADDITIONAL VIEWS

NOVEMBER 18, 1972

Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee
85-782 O

U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE
WASHINGTON : 1972

For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office
Washington, D.C. 20402 - Price 15 cents
Stock Number 5270-01643



JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE

(Created pursuant to sec. 5(a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.)
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin, Chairman
WRIGHT PATMAN, Texas, Vice Chairman
SENATE*
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
JOHN SPARKMAN, Alabama
RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri
J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
ABRAHAM RIBICOFF, Connecticut
HENRY S. REUSES, Wisconsin
HUBERT H. HUMPHREY, Minnesota
MARTHA W. GRIFFITHS, Michigan
LLOYD M. BENTSEN, J r., Texas
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
JACK MILLER, Iowa
BARBER B. CONABLE, J r., New York
CHARLE/S H. PERCY, Illinois
CLARENCE J. BROWN, Ohio
JAMES B. PEARSON, Kansas
BEN B. BLACKBURN, Georgia
J o h n R. S t a r k , Executive Director
L o u g h l in F . M c H u g h , Senior Economist
L ucy A. F a lco ne
J o h n R. K a r l ik
L e s l ie J. B a nd er

E c o n o m is t s

R oss F. H a m a c h e k
R ic h a r d F. K a u f m a n

M in o r it y
G eorge D. K r u m b h a a r , Jr. (Counsel)

J err y J. J a s in o w s k i
C o u r t e n a y M. S l a te r
W a l t e r B. L a e s s ig (Counsel)

S u b c o m m it t e e o n I n t e r n a t i o n a l E x c h a n g e a n d P a y m e n t s

HENRY S. REUSS, Wisconsin, Chairman
HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES
SENATE
HALE BOGGS, Louisiana
WILLIAM PROXMIRE, Wisconsin
WILLIAM S. MOORHEAD, Pennsylvania
HUBERT H. HUMPHREY, Minnesota
WILLIAM B. WIDNALL, New Jersey
LLOYD M. BENTSEN, J r., Texas
BARBER B. CONABLE, J r., New York
JACOB K. JAVITS, New York
CHARLES H. PERCY, Illinois




(II)

LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL
N

ovember

15, 1972.

To the Members of the Joint Economic Committee:
Transmitted herewith for the use of the members of the Joint Eco­
nomic Committee and other Members of Congress is a report of the
Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments entitled
“Gold, SDR’s, and Central Bank Swaps.”
The views expressed in this subcommittee report do not necessarily
represent the views of other members of the committee who have not
participated in the hearings of the subcommittee or in the drafting of
this report.
Sincerely,
W il l ia m P r o x m ir e ,
Chairman J oint Economic Committee.

,

N o v e m b e r IB, 1972.

Hon. W il l ia m P r o x m ir e ,
Chairman J oint Economic Committee
Congress of the United States
Washington D.C.
D e a r M r . C h a ir m a n : Transmitted herewith is a report of the Sub­
committee on International Exchange and Payments entitled “Gold,
SDR’s, and Central Bank Swaps” together with additional views by
Senator Javits. Representative Boggs was missing in Alaska at the
time this report was under consideration. The report has the endorse­
ment of all other members of the subcommittee.
The subcommittee wishes to express its appreciation for the guidance
it has received from the administration officials and the private experts
who appeared before it as witnesses during the hearings which pre­
ceded this report.
Sincerely,
H enry S. R eu ss,
Chairman Subcommittee on International Exchange and
Payments

,

,




,

,

..

(in )




GOLD, SDK’S, AND CENTRAL BANK SWAPS

During the week of September 11,1972, the Subcommittee on Inter­
national Exchange and Payments conducted 3 days of hearings to
review U.S. policies regarding (I) continued reliance upon gold as
reserve asset, (II) the future of special drawing rights (SDK’s), and
(III) the use of the central bank swap network to defend exchange
rates. The subcommittee did not investigate the full range of issues
that must be resolved among the members of the International Mone­
tary Fund (IM F) before an agreed monetary reform can be imple­
mented. Instead, we were interested primarily in interim measures
that would help reinforce the Smithsonian Agreement, announced
December 18, 1971, and preserve the multilateral operation of the
international payments system. Some of our suggested interim
measures do, however, carry implications for long-term reform.
Monetary reform will take at least a year and probably longer to
negotiate. During this interim, it is important that the payments
mechanism among IM F members function as smoothly as possible and
that the introduction of any new payments restrictions be kept to an
absolute minimum. These objectives are worth while in themselves as
a means of encouraging continued expansion in international trade
and of facilitating a recovery in the U.S. balance of payments. In
addition, the type of reform that is ultimately negotiated will be
influenced by events during the period of transition that began on
August 15, 1971, and will end only when a reworked system is finally
implemented. To the extent that the United States is cooperative,
helps preserve a multilateral payments system, and acts to minimize
any disturbances that occur during the period of negotiations, reform
will probably be agreed upon more quickly, and other countries also
will tend to be less adamant about their own positions.
T h e F o cus

of t h e

H e a r in g s

Gold has long tended to be a stumbling block among the industrial
countries whenever they have attempted to devise a common solu­
tion to international monetary problems. The French have frequently
championed those interests that desired to preserve or even expand
gold’s international monetary role. By contrast, the United States
has through both dollar-financed deficits and announced policies
sought to diminish the role of gold as a reserve asset. As the following
recommendations demonstrate, action can be taken even before a com­
prehensive monetary reform is negotiated to remove gold from the
area of contention. These initiatives would at the same time pave the
way for ultimately phasing out gold as a reserve asset and substituting
an internationally created and managed asset, such as special drawing
rights (SDK’s), in its stead.
In August the Federal Reserve System resumed use of the currency
swap network among central banks for the purpose of intervening



(1)

2
in the foreign exchange market to support the dollar. This was the
first time the United States had drawn upon the swap network since
before the introduction of the new economic policy about a year earlier.
While the Federal Reserve intervention was small, it was well timed
and widely hailed as an indication that the United States cared about
preserving the Smithsonian Agreement and the multilateral payments
system. The subcommittee, however, was concerned that currency
swaps might once again, as in August 1971, become a vehicle for main­
taining an overvalued dollar exchange rate. In the course of the hear­
ings, Under Secretary of the Treasury Volcker and Chairman Burns
of the Federal Reserve Board both assured us that, to the best of their
abilities, they would ensure that the United States would not again
intervene directly or indirectly in exchange markets to support the
dollar in the face of an enduring disequilibrium.
I . D e e m p h a s iz in g G old

as a

R eserve A sset

The functions of gold in the international monetary system have
been very substantially circumscribed since 1960. After a rush by
foreign central banks to exchange dollars for gold in late 1960, the
monetary authorities of seven major industrial countries formed the
London Gold Pool the following year to help conserve existing mone­
tary gold stocks. When private demand for gold in the London market
was high, the pool supplied enough of the metal to keep the price near
the then $35 per ounce official level. When there wTas an ample supply
of gold in the London market, the pool purchased. This arrangement
worked satisfactorily until early 1968, when private speculative de­
mand for gold became almost insatiable and the members of the pool
were called upon to supply more gold than they were willing to relin­
quish. As the major participant in the pooling arrangement, these
losses of gold reserves fell most heavily upon the United States.
In March, 1968, therefore, the members of the pool gathered in
Washington and agreed to suspend operations. A two-tier gold market
was established. In the free market, private purchasers and sellers
meet and exchange gold at whatever price happens to be dictated
by the convergence of supply and demand. In the other, official mone­
tary institutions continued to exchange gold among themselves in
balance-of-payments settlements at the official value of $35 per ounce.
The United States continued to maintain the convertibility of foreign
officially held dollars into gold. The pool members also agreed not to
buy gold directly from South Africa or on the free market and not
to sell it to private parties.
Some European nations, however, wanted South African gold to
continue entering the international monetary system. This position was
opposed by the United States. A fter over a year and a half of wrangling
about how the output of South African mines w^ould be handled,
a compromise was reached under which the International Monetary
Fund agreed to buy gold from South Africa whenever the price fell
below the $35 per ounce official level or whenever South Africa had a
payments deficit. Under this agreement, the IM F purchased $640 mil­
lion worth of South African gold in 1970 and $138 million worth
last year. None, however, has been purchased by the Fund since August,
1971.



3
For about the last year. South Africa’s balance of payments has been
strong, and gold prices in the free market have remained above the
official level. Consequently, (South Africa has not been able to meet the
criterion for gold sales to the International Monetary Fund. More­
over, the amount of gold it has supplied to the private market has
been reduced, since South Africa has not needed to sell its full output
in order to meet payments to foreigners. Both the reduction in supply
and increasing speculative demand have contributed to pushing the
free market price to around $70 an ounce, or nearly double the official
value of $38 per ounce. For a few weeks, the private market price of
gold fluctuated between $65 and $70 an ounce, but the price has now
dropped.
The high private market price of gold has tended to strain the
monetary arrangements devised at the Smithsonian. Soaring gold
prices place the exchange value of the dollar under suspicion. More­
over, the high private market price of gold has made official monetary
institutions reluctant to use the metal in settling balance-of-payments
deficits. Because the value of special drawing rights is also defined
in gold, a similar reluctance to use SDK’s has emerged. While the pro­
portion of gold in total international monetary reserves has declined
from 70 percent in 1950 to 50 percent in 1970, and now stands below
30 percent, it is not a healthy development to have a significant por­
tion of the world’s monetary reserve assets immobilized.
Before August 15, 1971, when the United States continued to main­
tain convertibility into gold of foreign officially held dollars, it made
sense to prohibit central banks from selling gold in the private market.
Otherwise, these institutions would have been able to obtain gold from
the United States at $35 per ounce and then sell it at a higher price to
private purchasers, thus causing a drain of U.S. monetary gold. Now,
however, the rationale for prohibiting sales of gold in the private
market by the monetary authorities no longer exists.

Recommendation 1. The March 1968 two-tier gold agree­
ment should be modified to permit, at their own initiative
and volition, sales of gold in the free market by the Inter­
national Monetary Fund and central banks. On the other
hand, the prohibition against central bank purchases of
gold in the free market or directly from South Africa
ought to be maintained.

The March 1968 agreement is embodied only in a communique issued
by the representatives of the former Gold Pool countries. This ar­
rangement could be easily modified by the group of the 10 major
industrial nations or by the Executive Directors of the IMF. Sales of
gold in the free market by the International Monetary Fund or by
central banks at their own volition would have a number of beneficial
effects.
First, such sales w^ould reduce the free market price and therefore
help ease the apprehensions that currently exist about the viability of
the Smithsonian monetary arrangements. In addition, a lower free
market price would make monetary authorities less reluctant to use
their remaining gold reserves and their SDK’s in international settle­
ments.




4
Second, sales by central banks—without purchases—would decrease
the global stock of monetary gold reserves. A gradual decline in the
stock of gold reserves is consistent with and would help advance the
longrun U.S. objective of phasing gold out as a monetary reserve asset.
Third, official sales would demonstrate that gold has no immutable
intrinsic value. The private price of gold is based on a limited number
of transactions in an extremely thin market. This market is protected
by the umbrella of the March 1968 two-tier agreement and the Decem­
ber 1969 IMF-South African accord. From 1934 into the 1960’s, it was
the United States which guaranteed the value of gold. More recently
this duty has been shared cooperatively among several industrial na­
tions. It is time, now that we have special drawing rights created by
the IM F, to begin withdrawing the mantle of official protection over
gold.
Fourth, as the largest official gold holder in the world, the United
States would profit from a share of the sales in the private market.
At the end of July, the United States had $10.5 billion wrorth of gold,
Germany held $4.4 billion worth, Franch $3.8 billion, Switzerland
$3.2 billion, Italy $3.1 billion, the Netherlands $2.1 billion, and Bel­
gium $1.7 billion. All other nations, including Canada and Japan, held
less than a billion dollars worth of gold.
Currently the IM F Articles require 25 percent of quota subscription
payments to the Fund to be made in gold. Thus, whenever a new mem­
ber joins the Fund, it must obtain by some means a sufficient quantity
of gold to pay one-quarter of its quota in this fashion. The remaining
75 percent is paid in its own national currency. An even more intense
scramble for gold occurs whenever the quotas of all IM F members are
reviewed, and an across-the-board increase is introduced. The re­
sultant swaps and loans of gold among the Fund and its members to
meet the letter of the articles is a testament to the financial imagination
of that institution, but little else. In addition, if a member holding
gold in its reserve stock borrows from the IM F, repayment of this loan
must be made in gold according to the relative proportion of that metal
in the country’s total reserve holdings.
Ultimately special drawing rights should become the backbone of
the international monetary system, and the supply of reserves should
be determined jointly by the membership of the International Mone­
tary Fund. Consequently, the role of SDK’s should be accentuated
whenever possible and gold should be gradually de-emphasized.

Recommendation 2. Under a reformed international
monetary regime, special drawing rights should be made
acceptable in lieu of gold in all transactions between the
IMF and its member countries.

Once SDK’s become the chief international reserve asset, the path
will be open to removing the mystique from gold and making it a
commodity like silver, tin, copper, or platinum. Just like any other
commodity, the value of gold should be determined by the economics
of mining and refining it, on the one hand, and by demand for in­
dustrial and artistic uses and for investment as a personal store of
wealth, on the other. A major step in this direction will have been
achieved when private American citizens are free once again to buy,
sell, and hold gold at their own discretion.



5
In discussing repeal of the present statutory prohibition against
private ownership of gold by U.S. citizens, Under Secretary Volcker
testified, “The time for sympathetic consideration to the elimination
of our own restrictions is when the shape of the new monetary struc­
ture emerges, and the monetary system is fully insulated from insta­
bility in private gold markets.” One could argue that the international
monetary system is already largely insulated from events in the private
gold market. Indeed, a very substantial rise in the free market price
of gold has not impaired international trade or contributed substan­
tially to restrictions on capital flows. The ability of the system to con­
tinue functioning despite large fluctuations in the private price of gold
is evidence of a degree of insulation. Nevertheless, once an interna­
tional monetary reform has been negotiated and put into effect, the
system will undoubtedly be even more effectively protected from fluc­
tuations in private speculative demand for gold and variations in the
amount supplied by South Africa and the Soviet Union. Once the
coming reform has been achieved, therefore, there should be no further
reason to deny American citizens the same privilege that is enjoyed by
private individuals in many other countries.

Recommendation 3. As soon as the international mone­
tary reform that is currently being negotiated is achieved,
all prohibitions on the purchase, sale, and holding of gold
by American citizens should be promptly abolished.

Both occasional sales of gold by monetary authorities in the free
market and the abolition of the statutory prohibition against owner­
ship of gold by private Americans would be steps toward removing
the mystique from gold and making it a commodity that is traded in
the same manner as other metals.
A third factor contributing to the unique status of gold is the Decem­
ber 1969 agreement with South Africa under which the International
Monetary Fund agreed to purchase gold from that country under speci­
fied circumstances. The March 1968 two-tier marketing agreement,
as it is currently being applied, and the December 1969 arrangements
between the IM F and South Africa together insure that the price will
not fall below $35 per ounce.
At the moment any such prospect seems fanciful. However, given
sales by monetary authorities, dishoarding by Europeans, Middle
Eastern sheiks, and Indians—all combined with the absence of any
commitment by the IM F to buy South African gold—the price could
fall to a level unknown since before 1934. On the other hand, permitting
Americans to hold and deal in gold would tend to have the opposite
impact.
But there would be no need under an SDE-based monetary system
to be concerned about whatever the free market price of gold happened
to be. If some nations wished to retain some gold reserves and have
these assets appraised at their official value, such a desire should create
no special problems. The supply of reserves would be governed by the
rate of distribution of special drawing rights, and balance-of-payments
surpluses and deficits would be settled either in SDR’s or in assets,
such as gold or foreign exchange, whose value would be determined by
their relationship to special drawing rights. The preservation of in­
ternational monetary stability does not oblige either the United States



6
or the International Monetary Fund to saddle itself with the responsi­
bility of guaranteeing a market for South Africa’s chief export com­
modity. The purchasing agreement with South Africa, therefore,
ought to be allowed to expire naturally in December 1974.

Recommendation 4. The current agreement committing
the International Monetary Fund to purchase gold from
South Africa under certain conditions ought not to be
renewed. Instead, it should be terminated in 2 years
when it expires.

II. S t r e n g t h e n in g t h e S p e c ia l D r a w in g R ig h t s M e c h a n is m
When the special drawing rights mechanism was added to the
IM F Articles of Agreement, the drafters envisioned that decisions
would be made to distribute SDK’s every 5 years. Instead, the initial
agreement was to allocate 9.3 billion of SDR’s over a 3-year period.
The last of the agreed distributions was made on January 1, 1972.
Consequently, a decision must be reached shortly on whether to con­
tinue creation and allocation of special drawing rights or to permit the
facility to fall into disuse for at least an interim period.
Cogent arguments can be made to the effect that, because there is
currently an excess of international liquidity resulting from the almost
$30 billion U.S. official settlements deficit in 1971, no more SDK’s
should be distributed at this time. A break in the distribution of spe­
cial drawing rights, the exponents of this position might argue, would
tend to increase their scarcity value and make them even more desirable
as reserves. The most recent problem regarding SDK’s, however, has
been an unwillingness on the part of holders to use them because their
value is defined in terms of gold. High free market prices for gold
have made monetary authorities reluctant to use not only that metal
as payment for external deficits, but special drawing rights as well.
W ith the issuance of further SDK’s, their actual use—which is the im­
portant criterion—should increase at least marginally.
On the other hand, any additional issue of SDK’s for the 2 years
remaining in the current “basic period” should probably be of nominal
proportions. If the U.S. balance of payments strengthens markedly,
this development would make monetary authorities more willing than
they currently are to hold dollars as reserves. Currently many monetary
authorities are unwilling holders of excessive dollar reserve balances.
The development of a U.S. payments surplus would improve the qual­
ity of these balances and, by prompting central banks to hold willingly
larger quantities of dollars, would probably increase the net amount
of reserves that are available to finance payments imbalances. By con­
trast, if the United States continues to run official settlements deficits,
foreign official dollar balances will expand further. Both the reluctance
on the part of surplus nations to accept dollars, and the unwillingness of
deficit countries to relinquish gold and SDK’s, will grow. In either case,
it is difficult to maintain that a large issue of special drawing rights
would either promote international monetary stability or substantially
enhance the long term viability of the SDK mechanism. Whatever
distribution is agreed upon, therefore, should be limited in amount.




7
Recommendation 5. To prevent the International Mone­
tary Fund’s special drawing right facility from falling
into disuse, the members of the IMF should promptly
agree to distribute a reasonable amount of SDR’s in 1973
and 1974.

The amendment to the Articles of Agreement empowering the Inter­
national Monetary Fund to create and distribute special drawing
rights incorporated a compromise specifying that SDK’s would be al­
located according to each nation’s quota in the IM F. A country’s
quota signifies how much in gold and its own currency that particular
nation has contributed to the assets of the IM F. The size of individual
member’s quotas is determined by their GrNP, population, value of in­
ternational transactions relatives to GNP, and several other factors.
But the decision to distribute SDR’s in proportion to quotas was a
purely political compromise. It has no economic rationale and, in fact,
liies in the face of equity. The outcome of this compromise has been
to give most of these assets created by the Fund to the industrial giants
of the world—those nations with the highest per capita incomes. Sixtythree percent of the SDR’s created have been allocated to industrial
countries, 9 percent to other less wealthy developed nations, and
only 28 percent to developing countries.
Because of the obvious inequity engendered by allocation of most of
the IM F’s new international money to the wealthiest nations of the
world, the SDR distribution mechanism has been under attack almost
since its inception. Suggestions have been made to modify the allocation
arrangements and make them more equitable. Two of the options, for
example, are either to increase the quotas of the developing countries
directly or to allocate some portion of SDR distributions to the Inter­
national Development Association (IDA) the soft-loan affiliate of the
World Bank.
The less developed countries have unified behind a demand for mod­
ification of the SDR distribution mechanism in any reformed inter­
national monetary system. If these nations stick together, they have
sufficient votes to block any amendment of the IM F Articles of Agree­
ment that would be necessary to implement an agreed reform proposal.
Fortunately, several of the industrial countries—but not yet the United
States—have now altered their positions to favor a change in the
SDR distribution mechanism that would give developing countries
a larger share than they currently receive.
A change in the pattern of SDR distributions would have a minimal
impact on the international monetary system. Since the developing
countries would undoubtedly spend most of their additional special
drawing rights for increased imports or use them to service existing
debts to industrial-country creditors, the SDR’s would still eventually
end up in the possession of central banks in industrial nations. Oppo­
nents have argued that increasing the proportion of SDR’s allocated
to developing countries would tend to lead to excessively large global
distributions. But under the existing SDR amendment, 85 percent of
the voters in the Fund must be in favor of a suggested distribution
if it is to be approved. With a 15 percent negative vote able to block
distribution, any significant reservations should certainly be able to
prevent IM F profligacy.
The Joint Economic Committee has long been interested in the
potential for using reserve creation by the International Monetary



8
Fund to finance an increased transfer of real resources from industrial
to developing countries. The initial position of this subcommittee, in
1965, was to maintain independent and separate mechanisms for creat­
ing reserves and providing development assistance.1 However, after
consideration of a report submitted later in 1965, by Representatives
Henry S. Reuss and Robert F. Ellsworth,2 a study by staff economist
John R. Karlik published in April, 1969,3 and testimony received in
hearings during May, 1969,4 the subcommittee reversed its position
and submitted a report proposing to link reserve creation and develop­
ment assistance.5 While there are disadvantages to a link, further
analysis had indicated that the drawbacks could be curtailed and would
be outweighed by the benefits from increasing the flow^ of financial
assistance to poor nations. The essence of the August, 1968, report was
endorsed by the majority of the Joint Economic Committee in its
annual report issued in March, 1970.6 The same point of view was
expressed by the full committee in a bipartisan analysis of interna­
tional economic issues contained in the 1971 annual report,7 and was
again confirmed by the majority in the 1972 report.8
Another problem that must be resolved as a part of a comprehensive
international monetary reform is how to dispose of the excess dollar
balances that foreign central banks have accumulated as the conse­
quence of U.S. payments deficits and now hold involuntarily. The most
frequently offered suggestion would entail an exchange of official dol­
lar assets in excess of working balance requirements for a special issue
of SDR’s. It is likely that the interest rate paid on special drawing
rights will be increased in the process of monetary reform to make
these assets more attractive to official holders. Nevertheless, the possi­
bility exists that the International Monetary Fund may earn more
on the dollar assets turned in to it by national monetary authorities
than it pays on the special issue of SDR’s distributed in exchange. Such
net profits, if they indeed accrue to the Fund, could also be channeled
to IDA for the benefit of developing countries.

Recommendation 6. In the process of reforming the in­
ternational monetary system, the SDR distribution
formula should be revised to assure that a larger propor­
tion of these assets than in the past will be allocated,
directly or through international institutions, to devel­
oping countries. Also, if the exchange of excessive out­
standing dollar reserves for a special issue of SDR’s
causes net profits to accrue to the International Monetary
Fund, these profits should also be used to increase finan­
cial assistance to developing countries.

1 Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments, Joint Economic Committee,
U.S. Congress, Guidelines for Im proving the International M onetary System , Report,
August 30, 1965, pp. 11-12.
2 Representative Henry S. Reuss and Robert F. Ellsworth, Off Dead Center: Some Pro­
posals to Strengthen Free W orld Economic Cooperation, A Report to the Joint Economic
Committee, U.S. Congress, December 20, 1965, pp. 14—17.
3 John R. Karlik, On Linking Reserve Creation and Development Assistance, A Staff
Study prepared for Use of the Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments of
the Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, April 14, 1969.
4 Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments, Joint Economic Committee,
U.S. Congress, Linking Reserve Creation and Development Assistance, Hearing, May 28,
1969.
5 Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments, Joint Economic Committee,
U.S. Congress, A Proposal to L ink Reserve Creation and Development A ssistance, Report,
August 15, 1969.
6 Joint Economic Committee, UJS. Congress, 1970 Joint Economic Report, pp. 52-53.
7 Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, 1971 Joint Economic R eport, pp. 13-15.
8 Joint Economic Committee, U.S. Congress, 1972 Joint Economic R eport, pp. 65-66.



9
I I I . T h e U se of C u r r e n c y S w a p s T o F in a n c e C e n t r a l B a n k
I n t e r v e n t io n i n E x c h a n g e M a r k e t s

In 1962 the Federal Reserve System and several foreign central
banks established an arrangement under which they agreed to ex­
change, or swap, equivalent amounts of their currencies when such
transactions would oe useful in smoothing what would otherwise be
large fluctuations in exchange rates. Swaps have usually been arranged
between the central banks of strong and weak currency countries. The
monetary institution responsible for defending a currency under at­
tack would generally initiate the swap and then use the foreign cur­
rency so obtained to buy its own money in the exchange market. Swaps
have usually been negotiated when private speculators, because of balance-of-payments trends or political developments, have anticipated
an exchange rate change and therefore have moved short term assets
across national boundaries so as to profit from the expected devalua­
tion or upward revaluation. When monetary authorities have disagreed
with the private speculators’ analysis for the need for an exchange
rate change, then the officials would generally use the swap network
to counter the effects in exchange markets of capital flows.
On June 30,1971, the Federal Reserve System’s net drawings under
swap arrangements amounted to $650 million. By the close of business
on Friday, August 13, this amount had increased to over $3 billion.
Most of this increase, amounting to nearly $2.4 billion, occurred dur­
ing the week of August 8 to 13.
During August, 1971, the United States was an essentially passive
participant in decisions to use the swap network. As the dollar came
under attack, foreign central banks purchased these dollars with their
own currencies. They did so to prevent the dollar value of their own
currencies from breaking through the 1 percent ceiling above parity
that was then specified by the IM F. As these foreign monetary au­
thorities accumulated dollars, they requested an exchange rate guar­
antee against the risk they were assuming. The alternative would have
been to insist upon exchanging these dollars for gold. In effect, the
Federal Reserve agreed to exchange dollars that were not covered by
any guarantee for others that were. When swap lines became ex­
hausted, foreign authorities were offered instead Treasury securities
bearing a similar guarantee.
The availability of the swap mechanism and Treasury securities
incorporating maintenance-of-value clauses tended to postpone con­
frontation of the basic reality that the dollar was overvalued and that
existing exchange rates could not be maintained. As a result of the
exchange rate realignment that was finally negotiated, the Federal
Reserve and the Treasury together will be required to ante up a total
of approximately $330 million to meet the cost of the guarantees they
had extended. This amount—while hardly insignificant—is less impor­
tant than the consequences of postponing exchange rate realignment
in terms of expanding imports into the United States, depressing our
exports, and encouraging investment abroad.
In their testimony, both Under Secretary Volcker and Chairman
Bums assured the committee that, to the best of the capabilities of
their respective institutions, the swap mechanism would never again
be used to prop up an overvalued dollar exchange rate or delay a
necessary exchange rate adjustment.



10
Under Secretary Volcker said in his testimony presented Septem­
ber 11,1972 (pp. 7-8 of his prepared statement) :
We have not embarked on any efforts to artificially prop up
the dollar counter to any basic balance-of-payments trends
in the longer run. . . . In contrast to usual practices before
August 15, . . . the basic initiative will lie with the United
States. Foreign exchange will be drawn not in a passive man­
ner after intervention by other countries, but for use in the
exchange markets by the United States in such amounts and at
such times as we believe the market impact will be favorable
and help to curb unwarranted speculative forces___Drawings
would not be made or enlarged to deal with what would be
fundamental misalinements in our own payments position. In
normal and forseeable circumstances, repayment could be
anticipated from a reversal of market flows.
Similarly, when Chairman Burns appeared before the subcommit­
tee on September 15, 1972, he said (p. 8 of his written statement) :
In the new operations, market intervention will be on the
Federal Reserve’s initiative. It will be undertaken only to pre­
vent or counteract disorderly market conditions and will be
in such amounts and at such times as are judged likely to have
a favorable impact. Swap drawings will not be made for the
purpose of providing medium- or longer-term financing of
the U.S. payments deficit. Nor will they be used as a substitute
for needed adjustments in basic economic policies.

Recommendation 7. The swap network among central
banks should be used to finance only temporary payments
outflows that can be expected to reverse themselves in a
matter of months. Exchange market intervention financed
through either the swap mechanism or Treasury obliga­
tions bearing an exchange rate guarantee should never
again be used to postpone an exchange rate adjustment
necessitated by fundamental balance-of-payment trends.




ADDITIONAL VIEWS OF SENATOR JAVITS
The Report of the Subcommittee on International Exchange and
Payments is most valuable and should be an important contribution to
the ongoing debate. I would be remiss, however, if I failed to point
out that this valuable Report does not mention the welcomed U.S.
initiative by President Nixon and Treasury Secretary Shultz at the
recently concluded IM F-IBRD Annual meeting. At this meeting the
United States clearly signaled to the world its willingness to take a
leadership role in the upcoming reform of the international monetary
system. The recent communique released after the Common Market
Summit meeting, in turn, contributes to the forward movement toward
the long term reform of the international monetary system. The out­
ward looking nature of this communique which was reinforced by the
statements of Western European leaders gives encouragement to those
of us who favor an open international trading and monetary system as
contrasted with restrictive, inward-looking trading and/or monetary
blocs.
Concerning the specifics of the report, I do not feel that it is realistic
to expect that “action can be taken even before a comprehensive mone­
tary reform is negotiated to remove gold from the area of contention.”
But, I do support the concept that gold should be relegated to the
status of other commodities over a suitable transition period, and that
the importance of SDR s within the international monetary system
should be significantly strengthened.
I strongly welcome the emphasis given in the report to using future
reserve creation by the International Monetary Fund to finance an
increased transfer of real resources from industrial to developing
countries.
This “link” is clearly the means for integrating the developing world
into the mainstream of trade and commerce, and for the long term
opening up of vital new markets for industrial goods. It is my predic­
tion that if this integration does not take place at an accelerated pace
over the short term, that the industrialized world will have jeopardized
its own future prosperity and well-being.
Better income distribution within societies leads to stronger societies
and more sustained economic growth, as the United States and Western
European examples make clear. Similarly, better income distribution
among societies through the means of future SDR creation through
the mechanism of the “link” will lead to a stronger world trading and
monetary system, accelerated world economic growth, and reduced
tensions among nations.
Therefore, while I welcomed the emphasis given in the Common
Market Summit Communique to the problems of the less developed
world, I regret that the communique did not mention the “link.”




( 11)

o