View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FUNDAMENTAL REAPPRAISAL OF THE DISCOUNT MECHANISM

ACADEMIC VIEWS ON IMPROVING
THE FEDERAL RESERVE
DISCOUNT MECHANISM

Prepared for the Steering Committee for the Fundamental Reappraisal of the
Discount Mechanism Appointed by
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System




The following paper is one of a series prepared by the research staffs of the Board of Governors
)f the Federal Reserve System and of the Federal Reserve Banks and by academic economists
n connection with the Fundamental Reappraisal of the Discount Mechanism.
The analyses and conclusions set forth are those of the author and do not necessarily indicate
;oncurrence by other members of the research staffs, by the Board of Governors, or by the Federal
Reserve Banks.




CONTENTS

Introduction

. . . . . . . . . . . .

Chandler, Lester

1
2

Bach, G. L

. . .

6

Bloch, Ernest

12

Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan H

21

Carr, Hobart

. , 27

Culbertson, J. M

38

Dewald, William G

41

Edwards, Edward E

48

Friedman, Milton

50

Luckett, Dudley G

61

Mayer, Thomas

......

66

Minsky, Hyman P

72

Modigliani, Franco

87

Morton, Walter A

91

Ritter, Lawrence S.

. . . . . . . .

98

Robinson, Roland 1

100

Schlesinger, James R

102

Scott, Ira 0., Jr

105

Selden, Richard T

108

Shapiro, Eli and White, William L

114

Simmons, Edward C

118

Tamagna, Frank M.

133

Tobin, James

156

Wallich, Henry C

160

Whittlesey, C. R

169




Introduction

Early in 1966 Professor Lester V. Chandler of Princeton
University, Academic Consultant to the Federal Reserve Board, wrote
to a number of interested academic economists and asked for their
views on improving the Federal Reserve discount mechanism.
Although the answers were varied, all were valuable to the
Federal Reserve in its reappraisal of the discount mechanism.

As a

matter of historical record these replies are now being published,
with their contents presented as originally received except for
minor editing in some instances prior to publication.
Professor Chandler!s request is published first and the
responses follow in alaphabetical order.

For clarification, the

numbers of the specific questions raised by Professor Chandler are
italicized in the requesting memorandum and the numbers are also
italicized when referred to in the replies.




- 2 THE FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT MECHANISM AND DISCOUNT POLICIES

The Federal Reserve System has embarked upon a comprehensive
study of its discount mechanism and discount policies.

A large part

of this work is being done by personnel within the System, at the
Board of Governors and at the several Federal Reserve banks.

However,

officials in the System have expressed a strong desire to have the
benefit of analysis, criticism, suggestions, and recommendations
from outside economists.

To this end, they have asked me to serve

as part-time consultant during the remainder of this year, with my
principal purpose being that of eliciting and transmitting the views
of economists.
I know that you have strong professional interests in monetary
policy in general and in the Federal Reserve discount mechanism and
discount policies.

I therefore hope that you will be willing to send

me your views for transmission to the Federal Reserve.

Unless

otherwise instructed, I shall indicate to fche Federal Reserve the
sources of the views expressed.

However, if you so desire, I shall

not identify the source.
The Federal Reserve intends that this study be thorough.
Among the many questions that will be studied, I would expect that
the following, some very broad and others narrower in scope, would
be included.
Question 1. What should be the role of discount policy in overall




monetary policy and its relationship to other policy
instruments?

In what ways, if at all, should its

role be altered?

.-. 3 Question 2,

What role should discounting play as a course of
liquidity to individual banks and to banks in a
region?

Can and should discounting be used to

influence the allocation of credit among banks,
regions, and types of uses?

Question 3.

What should

be the relative roles of %h& discount rate

and other methods of regulating the volume of discounting
at the Federal Reserve?

What changes, if any, should

be made in the existing system?

Question 4.

Whether or not there are changes in the Federal Reserve
discount mechanism and discount policy, do you favor
any change in the types of assets bought and sold by
the Federal Reserve in its open-market operations?
What should be the criteria for selecting such assets?

Question 5,

What changes, if any, should be made in the types of
assets eligible and acceptable as collateral for
discounts and advances by the Federal Reserve?

What

are the appropriate criteria for determining such eligibility and acceptability?

Question 6.




What should be the criteria for determining how much,
how frequently, and how long a bank may borrow from
the Federal Reserve?

.4 .
Question 7.

Should the Federal Reserve lend only to member banks,
or should it lend to other entities as well?

In the

latter case, to which types of borrowers?

Question 8.




With respect to discount rates and rate policy?

<a.

Should these rates be uniform nationally, or
should there be regional differences?

If the

latter, what should be the criteria?

]3.

Should rates be uniform on all types of paper
offered, or should they differ by types of paper?

£.

Should rates be graduated on the basis of the
amount borrowed by a bank or the duration of
its borrowings?

ci.

What changes, if any, should be made in the
method of setting and changing discount rates?
For example, should the present methods be
continued, should the discount rate be tied to
some market rate, should some other formula
be used, etc.?

£.

Would it be desirable to seek some way of decreasing
lf

the announcement effects" of discount rate changes?

If so, what methods should be used?

JE.

Should rates be changed more or less often?
By smaller or larger steps?

£.

Should the Federal Reserve be empowered to pay
interest on member bank deposits or on reserves
in excess of legal requirements?

The list of questions above is meant to be suggestive rather
than exhaustive.
issues.

You may well wish to raise and comment on other

Moreover, it is not expected that you will wish to comment

on all the questions.
I shall be very grateful for any comments that you care to
make, and I am sure the Board will feel the same.




Lester V. Chandler
Princeton University

- 6 G. L. Bach
Carnegie Institute, of Technology

In my judgment, the present Federal Reserve discount
mechanism plays a useful role in facilitating the adjustment of
reserve positions of individual banks to both market and Federal
Reserve policy changes.

Federal Reserve discount policy, hovjever,

plays a minor role in the total monetary policy mechanism.

To

improve the effectiveness of discount policy as a part of the total
arsenal of Federal Reserve policy, I believe the present system
could be substantially improved by relatively minor changes.

The Present Role of Discount Policy
The major implement for executing monetary policy is,
and should be, open market operations, which have their direct
impact on the reserve positions of commercial banks.

The discount

mechanism adds a needed element of flexibility so that individual
banks can adjust their positions; but higher or lower discount rates,
per se, have at most a marginal direct effect on total reserves, the
money stock, and interest rates under the present system.

The small

effect on these targets of changing discount rates could be readily
achieved by open market operations.
Some observers praise discount rate changes for their
"announcement" effects.

But in fact these announcement effects

appear to be uncertain and sometimes perverse.

Federal Reserve

changes in the discount rate are sometimes undertaken to signal




-7 tighter or looser money; sometimes they are merely adjustments to
changes which have already taken place in the market—in a sense,
attempts to keep the effect of major Federal Reserve policy moves
unchanged.

But changes in the discount rate are watched with

great interest by money market observers and by others in the
economy, and are generally interpreted as having great significance
as signals of Federal Reserve intentions.

Thus, they may easily be

misinterpreted.
Indeed, their effect is highly uncertain.

If the market

has elastic expectations--that is, expects a rise in the discount
rate to be a signal of further rises in interest rates — one effect
will result.

On the other hand, if a rise in the discount rate is

interpreted by the market to be a signal that the expansionary process is being pulled to a halt, it would have the opposite effect.
I know of no basis on which we can safely assume we know which
result will occur when.
Moreover, it is hard to see why such cloudy signals have
any advantage over simple use of the English language.

The Federal

Reserve authorities can readily say what they want to say, and say
it so people will understand what they are saying.

If, in fact,

changes in discount rates are used because they mirror diversity
and uncertainty within the Federal Reserve, then this announcement
system is even more unsatisfactory, because it gives obviously
imperfect signals to a world which pays more attention to them than
it should.




- 8 ~

Proposed Changes
I favor maintaining the discount mechanism, but changing it
in two respects:
1.

The discount rate should be, in essence, tied to an

important market short-term rate, probably the Treasury bill rate.

The

discount rate might be changed every week, or at other short intervals,
to conform to changes in the bill rate.

It should be kept substantially

above the bill rate—probably 1/2 to 1 per cent higher—to discourage
banks from using discounts as a regular, continuous source of reserves.
2.

At this rate, member banks should be free to borrow as

they wish on eligible paper.

Thus the present dubious, muddy distinc-

tion between borrowing as a right and as a privilege should be laid to
rest.

It doesn't work badly, but under the proposed system it would have

no useful role to play.
Basically this system would provide to individual banks
needed flexibility in adjusting their reserve positions.

Banks would

b e assured of this adjustment flexibility, thereby eliminating the
present nagging uncertainty in the minds of many bankers.

However,

this system would give banks this flexibility only at a definite
penalty over adjustments through the Federal funds market or the sale
of bills or other securities.

Fundamentally, the Federal Reserve

authorities would determine the total reserve base through open market
operations, and they could well afford to allow banks

the cushion they

need to make individual adjustments, since excess borrowing could




- 9 -

readily be offset through open market tightening if this were
desirable.
This amended system would mean giving up very little in
the way of significant discretionary Federal Reserve power, and it
would eliminate a significant source of uncertainty and even perversity in the application of monetary policy*

Even with the dis-

count rate tied to the bill rate, the monetary authorities would be
free to tighten or loosen significantly.

If, for example, the Federal

Reserve wished to tighten reserves significantly, in order to halt
inflationary pressure or to improve our balance of payments position,
open market operations could be used to tighten them; these operations would also raise the bill rate and the discount rate would rise
with it.

There would be no need to retain separate discretionary

power over the discount rate*

If special "announcement11 effects were

desired, Federal Reserve authorities could state what they were doing
and why, eliminating the uncertainty and possible perversity of the
present approach.
Some additional points deserve brief supplementary mention:
1.

How far the discount rate should be above the bill rate

(that is, how much the "penalty" should be) is a technical issue.

It

should be enough to discourage routine borrowing and to lead banks to
adjust their individual reserve position under normal conditions
through other channels, but should not be significantly higher.

An

excess of 1/2 %o 1 per cent seems probably proper to me, but experimentation might suggest another figure.




- 10 -

2.

The definition of eligible paper should be substantially

broadened over the present law, whether or not the above suggestions
are made.

Tying the discount privilege to the old commercial paper

concept is badly out of date and could lead to serious trouble in the
event of a crisis.

Just what paper should be eligible is a technical

issue; broadly, U.S. Government securities and all bank paper on which
there is minor risk of Federal Reserve loss under normal business conditions should be included*
3.

I see no basis for encouraging, or even permitting,

regional differentials in discount rates.

Differential regional dis-

count rates would represent a throwback to the outdated regionalism
of 1913.

Moreover, such differentials would represent a dubious

direct intervention of a "direct-control" sort by the monetary authorities.

If we need to improve our capital markets, differential dis-

count rates are a low-priority way of doing so.
4.

A quite different approach to improving the discount

mechanism has been suggested by Professor Tobin.

Unlike the sugges-

tions above, it would drastically increase the importance of the discount mechanism, making discount rate changes a (or even the) major
tool of monetary policy.




(a)

In essence, the Tobin proposal is:

The Federal Reserve should pay interest at the

discount rate on member bank reserve balances above reserve
requirements.

*- 11-(b)

Member banks should be permitted to pay interest on

demand deposits and time deposits.
Under these changes, the discount rate, which could be
directly varied by the Federal Reserve, would in effect set the
alternative cost to the banks of holding money as against lending it.
Thus, the Federal Reserve would have direct control over lending
interest rates, since banks would be willing to lend only when market
rates were clearly higher than the no-risk rates available on excess
reserves.

At the same time, the banks would surely compete for

deposits, since they could readily hold those deposits as interestearning excess reserves as well as use them for lending.

Thus, the

discount rate would become a major monetary weapon indeed, directly
establishing the floor under lending rates.
This approach seems to me a reasonable alternative to the
amendments I have suggested above.

I am not clear, however, that it

would be substantially better than the present system as amended, and
I foresee prolonged controversy and uncertainty arising from a proposal
to adopt the Tobin plan.

Thus, I believe, at least for the present,

the modified system outlined above would be more feasible than, and
substantially as good as, the Tobin approach.

The Tobin plan would

become increasingly attractive if future evidence indicates that the
impact of monetary policy depends largely on its interest-rate effects,
in contrast to changes in credit conditions or the supply of money.




- 12 Ernest Bloch
New York University
Two interrelated problems are embedded in the notion of
"excess11 use of the discount privilege.

The problem faced by each

district bank is to police borrowing by the member banks so that
none oversteps a limit consistent with the "privilege11 principle
of discounting.—

The problem faced by the System as a whole is

to execute monetary policy in the face of cycles of member bank
borrowing that may, at times, offset System policy moves.

The

question arises whether a method can be developed through which
district bank policing of member bank discounting can effectively
cut the amplitude of undesired discounting cycles.

This paper will

present, first, a schematic view of discounting cycles under the
current discount mechanism, move on to a discussion of suggested
remedies, and finally present a proposal that might help to
cut swings in discounting.
1.

Problems in administration of discount window.
The current method of controlling the accommodation of

member banks combines a "liberal" rate policy with restrictive
administration.

The cost of credit to all borrowing banks has been

1/ Regulation A of the Board of Governors regulates member
bank borrowing. The latest revision (Feb. 15, 1955) includes a
statement of "General principles" which sets forth some guidelines
under which member banks should or should not borrow. (See Federal
Reserve Bulletin, January 1955, pp. 8-9).
2/
— On the question of member bank reluctance to borrow from
the Federal Reserve, see M.E. Polakoff, "Reluctance Elasticity,
Least Cost, and Member-Bank Borrowing: A Suggested Integration,"
Journal of Finance, Vol. XV (March 1960), pp. 1-18.




Ernest Bloch

- 13 -

held to the level of return on the banks1 lowest yielding investments,
namely, short-term Government securities.

Looked at from a rate

point of view alone, the temptation must be great to borrow cheap
at the Federal Reserve and relend the funds at higher rates.
According to Regulation A, each district bank is supposed to keep
a tight administrative check rein on each member bank's borrowing,
but the effect of such general and imprecise guidelines had been
different degrees of ease or tightness of discount accommodation
among the various districts.
Further, as the economy moves toward a boom and loan
demand rises, a number of banks that previously did not make use
of their borrowing privilege at the Federal Reserve may then
approach the discount window.

And, in addition, some other banks

that had not displayed such reluctance to borrow in recession
and recovery may nevertheless be able to point to hardship needs
that require central bank credit accoicmodation.

As a consequence,

the volume of member bank discounting tends to rise to a peak as
business loans and the rate of business activity also approach a
cyclical peak.

While open market operations may compensate for

this "leakage11 of credit, the purpose of open market operations
may be defeated at the worst time possible; that is, when policy
shifts to ease.

For at the time of cyclical turning point, the

banks may choose to use newly provided reserves to repay loans at
the discount window rather than to expand credit.




Ernest Bloch

2.

• 14 •

Proposed remedies.
Two basic remedies have been put forth to restrain the volume

of discounting in a boom, thereby cutting the amplitude of the discounting cycle.

Both involve the use of higher rates to hold down the

"yield incentive11 to borrow at the Federal Reserve.

In ascending

order of severity, these suggestions are:
( a)

a discount rate "tied11 to a market rate, such as
Treasury bills, 3/ and

(b)

a penalty rate.

The advantage claimed for the tied-rate method of setting
the discount rate is twofold.

First, the rate so set would not lag

behind prevailing investment yields, thereby keeping the "yield
4/
incentive" to borrow from the Federal Reserve at a minimum.—
Second, the "announcement effects" and repercussions of discount
rate changes could be kept to a minimum.

Primarily because of

the first advantage, it is claimed that bank borrowing cycles could
be moderated.
The penalty rate proposal, on the other hand, would cut the
"yield incentive" for borrowing from the Federal Reserve to zero.
By eliminating such profits entirely for the most efficient banks,
and even creating a net cost for the less efficient (that is, a
discount rate higher than yields on their loans and investments), all
3/ This proposal is analogous to the Canadian system (195662), which sets a discount rate spread over bill rates and allows each
week's auction to determine the discount rate level.
4/ To the extent that the term structure of interest rates
changes, this effect may be enhanced or vitiated in unpredictable
ways.




Ernest Bloch

•* 15 ••-

banks might become reluctant borrowers, and cycles in discounting
might be sharply cut.
It appears likely that the tied-rate proposal will cut
into amplitude of discounting cycles only by improved timing.

The

incremental improvement in timing may not involve a significantly
large gain, however, because discount rate levels in the past
have been set fairly close to Treasury bill rates.

If a tied-rate

proposal were to be associated with a apread above Treasury bill
yields, it could conceivably reduce the volume of bank borrowing
and the amplitude of discounting cycles in the same manner that a
penalty rate could.

But to the extent that a tied rate is not a

true penalty rate, the problem of restrictive administration of the
discount window remains,—
A true penalty rate would avoid some of these administrative
judgments, but a penalty rate suffers from a number of defects
centering on equity of administration.

Thus a rate high enough

to deter any but emergency borrowing by the most efficient banks
would in effect provide a much higher hurdle for the less efficient.
And since it is the most efficient or "aggressive11 banks that
constitute the "hard core11 of borrowers from the Federal Reserve,
a penalty rate may have perverse effects by penalizing least those
that tend to borrow the most.

Moreover, the most efficient banks are

often also thoae having access to the cheapest or most readily available
substitutes for borrowing from the Federal Reserve.

Thus, even if

5/ On the subject of administrative rationing of credit at
the discount window, see C.R. Whittelsey, "Credit Policy at the
discount Window;" R.V. Roosa, "Credit Policy at the Discount Window:
Comment;" and Whittelsey f s "Reply", Quarterly Journal of, Economics,
Vol. LXXIII (May 1959), pp. 207-16 and 333-38.



Ernest Bloch

- 16 ~

monetary policy were to make additional credit available to offset
the lessened reserve drain through the discount window, the banks
with the least costly penalty rate might also be those with the
greater share of the incremental credit supply.

And to the extent

that these banks experience cycles in demand for loans, cycles
in discounting would remain.
These factors suggest that a somewhat different approach
to setting the discount rate might hold some promise.

For the

unresolved problem of the rate-setting devices mentioned above is that
fc e

^

sftroe discount rate is charged to all borrowers.

Such a procedure

offers the greatest possible yield spread to the most aggressive
banks, which are the largest and likeliest borrowers, no matter how
the rate is set.

If instead, the rate-setting device could be

tailored to reduce the yield incentive to the same range for each
bank, no single group of banks would have a significantly greater
rate incentive to borrow from the Federal Reserve than another.

In

this way? the discount rate could be set high enough to keep down
borrowing to the emergency level, thereby serving the purpose of
the discount window and reducing administrative problems.
3.

A modest proposal.
To put a limit on the profits that can be made from borrowings

at the Federal Reserve, it is proposed that the discount rate be set
by each bank's return per dollar of loans and investments, as indicated
in its last call report.

This rate of return may be called the

profitability ratio; it is, in fact, the equivalent of each bankfs




Eirnest Bloch

average revenue.
t ie

*

- 17 -

The proposal made here, however, applies only to

principle of associating the discount rate with each bank's

profitability ratio. Under conditions of easy credit availability
i
at the discount window, for example, the discount rate might be
set at, say, one percentage point below each bank's profitability
ratio.

When discount credit is to be tightened, its cost might be

raised to the level, or even above, the profitability ratio.—
In effect, this modest proposal attempts to take into
account the fact that commercial banks are at present involved in a
progressively more aggressive and profit-oriented management of the
cost of sources, and returns on uses, of funds.

This fact may be

observed in the changing methods of bank reserve adjustments, including,
for example, the premium bid on Federal funds, variations in rate/
maturity combinations on CD f s, and a number of other sharp-pencil devices.
If, then, changes in market rates are used by banks to bid away
reserves from other banks, why not use appropriate rate changes at
the discount window to vary the attractiveness of raising total
reserve availability from the Federal Reserve?
Finally, the 1964 amendments voted by Congress into the
Securities Act--which mandate the Federal Reserve Board, the FDIC,
and the tbmptroller of the Currency to advise on and improve standards
of member bank accounting and reporting—should also help to provide
6/ To that extent, the discount rate could approach each
bank's marginal revenue. Recent changes in disclosure requirements
already require banks to compute these rates of return (see below).




Ernest Bloch

~ 18 -

the data on which the computation of profitability ratios could
be based.
Concluding Remarks
It appears that, under the suggested method of setting the
discount rate, the

System-wide problem of aggregate cycles in

discounting and the district-type problem of "excess11 borrowing by
individual banks can be dealt with more effectively and equitably.
Consider the policy problem of the upper cyclical turning point
noted earlier.

Under the present discount mechanism, the largest,

the most aggressive, and the most profitable banks are likely to
have the greatest incentive to borrow from the Federal Reserve#
Thus, even if the Federal Reserve shifts policy at the upper turning
point of a business cycle without any recognition lag and eases
credit immediately through open market operations, a significant
volume of the easier credit will tend to be used to repay prior
discounting.

Under the present rules of the game, a high order of

administrative skill and willingness to ration credit at the discount
window is required not only to prevent excess credit leakages prior
to the peak of the boom but, in addition, to minimize perverse paybacks following the turnaround in economic conditions and policy
actions.

This is not to argue that the safety-valve aspects of

discounting are not useful but that a better mechanism than administrative
control might improve the efficiency and equity of the safety-valve
function.




Ernest Bloch

- 19 -

At this point the question occurs whether the proposed
approach to setting the discount rate would shift discounting from
a "privilege11 to a "right.11
hands of the Federal Reserve.

The answer would lie entirely in the
If the cost of discounting is set

above the profitability ratio, banks would clearly be exercising
a "right" to borrow (within limits), although that "right" is not
likely to be exercised to excess.

Conversely, if the cost of borrowing

from the Federal Reserve were set below the profitability ratio, the
"privilege" could still be controlled by the size of the spread.

In

any case, each bank could quantify its desire or reluctance to barrow
from the Federal Reserve, and the policy signals or announcement
effects that the Federal Reserve could transmit would then appear
far less equivocal than they do today.

This is particularly true in

the current environment of sharp-pencil figuring of bank costs and
returns, some of which are, themselves, a function of more flexible
Federal Reserve policies (for example, the changes in ceilings on timedeposit rates since 1962).
Still, the greatest gain from the suggested method of setting
the discount rate would go to the Federal Reserve policy mechanism.
For in an environment in which the discount rate may be used as another
market mechanism to control overdiscounting in boom, the risk of
perverse paybacks following the cyclical turnaround would be reduced.
And by the same token, the need for the shortest-possible recognition
lag for a reversal of open market operations would also be lessf




Indeedf

Ernest Bloch

- 20 *

as more experience is gained with setting this new type of discount
rate, a sharp rate reduction (in relation to profitability ratio)
might be feasible in the period following the boom as a means of
preventing undesired paybacks in the aggregate.
Finally, one of the hidden dividends of the new mechanism
would be the break in the direct linkage of discount rate to open
market rates (for example, on Treasury bills).

During recessions, this

would permit greater flexibility in setting discount rate levels,
even while a relatively high floor were being placed under Treasury
bill rates or other interest rates to meet possibly conflicting policy
goals set for debt management.




- 21 Karl Brunner
Ohio State University

Allan H. Meltzer
Carnegie-Mellon University

A separate discount policy is not needed because little
can be accomplished by discount policy that cannot be accomplished
by other policies, for example, open market operations. A standard
argument for discount policy —

that it has an announcement effect —

might at first glance suggest that discount policy plays a separate
role by indicating the direction in which the Federal Reserve wishes
to change monetary policy•
be introduced.

However, qualifications must immediately

First, changes in the Federal Reserve's discount rate

generally follow rather than precede changes in market interest rates,
a pattern that does not seem to be entirely consistent with the
argument about annouacement effect.

Second, and more important,

if the Federal Reserve does not follow up its "announcement11 by
operations that support the announcement, the effect of announcing
a change is negligible.
Recent experience bears directly on this point.

The rise

in the discount rate in December 1965 was followed by a substantial
increase in monetary base (reserves plus currency) between
December and January.

In other words, the increase in the discount

rate was more than offset by the movement of the base in the
following month. Whatever might have been gained by 1fannouncingtf
a more restrictive policy was offset by the highly expansionary
increase in the rate of increase of the monetary base.




Karl Bruhner and Allin H. Meltzer —

22

One defense of a separate discount policy is implicit in the
argument that discounting permits small banks to obtain reserves
temporarily on terms that do not differ substantially from the price
that large banks must pay for purchases of reserves in the Federal
funds market.

This argument is based on the view that one of the

responsibilities of the Federal Reserve is to maintain the dual
banking system and the smaller banks. The inability of small banks
to trade in the Federal funds market, it is suggested, should be
offset by the Federal Reserve willingness to lend to them on terms
that are at least as favorable as those that large banks can obtain
in the market or from the Federal Reserve. This position is contingent on how one views the costs of maintaining small banks versus
the gains that might be obtained from having a banking system that
would distribute its reserves internally without the aid of the central
bank.
Our views are summarized in the report that we prepared for
the Banking and Currency Committee of the U.S. House of Representatives
in 1964. We argued there that a most important question remaining
to be resolved is whether the Federal Reserve is going to direct the
main thrust of its policy toward full employment, price stability,
and other national goals or whether the Federal Reserve will continue
to direct the primary thrust of its policy toward the money market.
Any judgment that can be made about the future of discount policy must




Karl Brutmer and Allati H. Meltzer -*• ^3
start from an interpretation of the role that discount policy plays
in the range of policy actions. Our view is that the first question
that has to be resolved is whether the Federal Reserve is going to
continue to be as concerned with money market conditions as it has
been in the past.

If the Federal Reserve remains attached to "money

market conditions*1 as an indicator of monetary policy, it is unlikely
to abandon its traditional position that discounting is a privilege
to be used by banks only in case of "need.11
There are, therefore, two answers about the Sole of discount
policy.

The first is that discount policy should be abolished, the

discount window should be closed, and banks should be permitted or
required to make their own reserve adjustments.

This view has much

merit, and our minor objection is that it would increase the cost
of longer-term borrowing (up to 6 months) by banks in rural areas at
times of local distress, for example, crop failures.
The second answer is that the discount function of the reserve
banks should be continued but altered substantially.

Our views on

this subject are part of a set of prescriptions about the conduct
of monetary policy that we will attempt to restate briefly.
If monetary policy takes as its primary interest the
maintenance of full employment, stable prices, and so forth, the
best way to achieve these goals is to have more consistent direction
for policy operations. The direction of monetary policy should be
set for longer than a 3-week period and policymakers should ignore




Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer — 24

the temporary, random, self-reversing changes in the money market
toward which they now devote an inordinate share of their attention.
Primary attention should be directed instead toward maintaining a
steady growth rate in the monetary base.

If this is done, discount

policy would have to adapt to the decision about monetary policy
made by the Open Market Committee.

Our proposal for this adaptation,

assuming that discounting is maintained, is that the Manager would
be instructed to offset daily borrowing with open market operations
on the following day.

The Open Market Committee would decide upon

the appropriate growth rate of the monetary base for a period of 3 to
6 months. The Manager would be given responsibility for carrying
out this policy by buying and selling securities at a relatively
steady rate.

If banks are permitted to discount, the Manager would

subtract the net amount of discounts on the previous day from his
open market purchases or add them to his open market sales. Thus
he would not permit the volume of discounts to change the growth
rate of the base decided upon by the Open Market Committee.
There are a number of advantages that would stem from
adopting this proposal. First and foremost, the Open Market Committee
would have a clear and definite indicator of the action that the
Manager was taking and the extent to which he was deviating from
their expressed statement of the direction of policy.

Second, the

role of the discount window would be reduced to that of a minor supplement to the Federal funds market as a mechanism for distributing




Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer — 25
reserves among different types of banks. The Federal Reserve would
decide on the volume of reserves and currency that would be available;
the banks would decide on the distribution of reserves.
As indicated above, we would not be averse to the elimination of discounting.

However, we recognize that this is a radical

departure from traditional central banking functions, and that a
case can be made for the maintenance of the multiple-bank system on
grounds other than economic ones. We believe, however, that policy
should be conducted so as to avoid conflict between policies that are
aimed at stabilizing the money market and distributing reserves and
policies aimed at promoting full employment and price stability.
If our proposal is adopted, the discount rate should be
maintained above the Federal funds rate.

It should be free to move

with the Federal funds rate so that banks would be encouraged whenever possible to make their reserve adjustments through the Federal
funds market, the Treasury bill market, or some other market.

If

the argument for maintaining the discount rate is primarily one of
permitting small banks to borrow on terms roughly similar to those
of the larger banks, the discount rate should be slightly higher than
the Federal funds rate, but not substantially so. Most important
of all it should move with the Federal funds rate so that it would
reflect the price that banks are paying at any particular time for
the use of an additional or incremental volume of reserves.




Karl Brunner and Allan H* keltzS* ** 26

We attach little importance to the particular types of assets
that are used for open market operations.

It is useful to choose

assets that have well-developed markets, but it is extremely likely
that an announcement by the Federal Reserve that it planned to use
a particular asset for open market operations would improve the market
for that asset substantially*




- 27 -

Hobart C. Carr
New York University

Preliminary to any discussion of the questions relating to
discound rates, administration of discounting, or the role of disccunt
policy, the present use of the privilege must be studied.

As you know,

Teigen, Smith, Friedman, Meigs, and others have either directly or by
implication asserted that if market rates on short-term paper are above
the discount rate (in other words, a positive spread) there will be a
notable use of discounting; thus such spreads would lead a bank to make
frequent and sizable use of the discount privilege just as though there
were few or no restrictions on such use imposed by the Federal Reserve.
I have always assumed the restrictions to be sostringent as to make such
profit-making opportunities very infrequent for the individual b a n k so infrequent, in fact, that they were no real source of profit.

I

have assumed further that even those opportunities could not be fully
used lest the bank find itself unwelcome as a borrower when last-minute
outflows were pressing against its reserve position.

(By nvery in-

frequent borrowing/1 I mean borrowing for no more than six reserve
periods every 6 months.)

I have further assumed, as a corollary to the

above assumptions, that a positive spread between short-term market
rates and the discount rate would only lead to additional borrowing as
more and more banks, brought up to the choice of selling or borrowing
by reserve stringencies, are led by such spreads to make use of their




- 28-

restricted privilege rather than to adhere to their more usual practice
of satisfying their reserve needs by other means.
In contrast to others then, I have felt a positive spread
contributed very little to use of the borrowing privilege and even less
to any increase in borrowing when a restrictive monetary policy continued
for any length of time.

To determine facts, the Federal Reserve should

study its own operations and determine frequency, duration, and amounts
of borrowing by individual banks over a period of time long enough to
encompass subperiods of both positive and negative spreads.
In the absence of any study, I will assume that I am right and
that elasticity of borrowing to a positive spread is slight.

My answer

to questions on the list will reflect this assumption.
Question 1.
abolished.

There are those who urge that discounting be

They believe that the privilege constitutes a leak in open

market policy.

Those who defend the practice regard it as a safety

valve in the event that open market policy in pursuit of aggregative
objectives becomes too restrictive for the individual bank.

They also

defend it as a means of attracting membership in the System; without
this privilege they think membership would be dangerously reduced.
Abstracting from the defense, I incline toward abolition.

I

agree that the System needs a safety valve, but I argue that one would
remain after abolition of the discounting privilege, namely the use of
repurchase agreements.




If the market indicates too much stringency now,

- 29.*-

RP f s are resorted to.

Why couldn!t the same procedure apply in the

absence of the discounting privilege?

Certainly, the System would then

have more control of any n leakages. n
The use of RP f s under these conditions would require broadening.
The System might even need to resume the undertaking of open market
operations in Chicago and begin RP operations in San Francisco, but
these should constitute no great hardship.

Use of the RP "privilege1

would also need to be extended-^to bank dealers, for example.
I do not think that this proposed use of RP f s would have a
harmful effect on the Government securities market,

Rather, I am in-

clined to believe that carrying out the proposal would strengthen
that market—not merely through the probable expansion in the volume
of trading resulting from its greater use by the System and by banks
in adjusting their reserve positiions, but also through the concomitant
extension of market facilities as dealers seek better ways of accommodating their customers.
The proposal would probably be a boost to correspondent banking.
Smaller banks, deprived of direct access to the Federal Reserve would
turn even more frequently to their correspondents in making reserve
position adjustments.

Such a development may be viewed by some as a

retrogression, but I think it would have a number of advantages:
greater efficiency in the use of reserves (through the enhanced ability
of larger banks to mobilize excess reserves of smaller intitutions);




- 30 >
greater sensitivity to Government securities market developments by more
non-money market banks of medium size (through their activities relative
to modating their small-bank customers); and as for the adverse effects
of this proposal on System membership, might be a serious point.

However,

they might be diminished if the proposal were modified so as to allow
member banks to borrow from the Federal Reserve for emergency purposes,
such as a run on the bank.

And if, as has been suggested, the Federal

Reserve were to pay interest on member bank reserves or excess reserves,
the force of this point would be considerably lessened.
As a conclusion, it should be pointed out that abolition of runof-the-mill discounting would obviate such questions as: what to do about
"announcement effects,fi whether there should be differential discount
rates on a geographical or a purpose basis, what assets should be considered "eligible,f! how to deal with the limitations imposed by pledged
assets, what role should be given to discounting as against other monetary
policy instruments, whether to install variable rates depending on the
amount borrowed, and so on.

Question 2.

Assuming the continuation of discounting more or less

along the present lines, no differentiation among uses and regions, whether
by preferential rates or by other means, should be attempted.

In the

first place, regional differentiation of rates probably would not work.
(Ask the San Francisco Bank for the details of its experience with bank
response to lower rates in other districts some years back.)




The network

- 3i of interbank relationships including Federal funds would lead to a leakage
of funds to nonpreferred users or uses.

Actually, the fluidity of bank funds

would probably break down any other means of preference; for example, a
quota system or collateral privileges for certain assets,

Question 3,

There have been suggestions that the rate be the

sole means of rationing the use of the discount window.

Such suggestions

appear to be based on a conviction that non-price rationing is distasteful
and interfers with the economic process.

It would be better, proponents

hold, to open up the discount window to all and in any amount.
Again, assuming continuation of the practice of discounting (see
the answer to Question 1 ) , this suggestion appears to have considerable
merit.

It would make the market place—-costs of funds there and yields

on assets there—the sole criterion of use of the discount window.

The

Federal Reserve would have a powerful influence over the amounts borrowed
and over market rates as it put the discount rate up and down.
Yet such a device raises important problems.

For one, relative

to which rates in the market would the discount rate be fixed?

At various

times, certain types of money market paper yield more than others, and
yield curves also vary both in height and in shape.

If the criterion

were to be a fixed type of paper, there would then be arbitrage opportunities.

The number of opportunities and their effect would depend on how

high the discount rate were fixed.
the level of the discount rate.




A second problem would then be fixing

Presumably the discount rate would be a

* 32 penalty rate, at least with respect to some possible rate or asset yields;
if not, the discount mechanism would become a freely used source of funds —
the amount of which would be governed by the demand for certain types of
credit—rather than a limited access to liquidity funds*

If a penalty

rate were to be instituted, certain problems would remain.

If the base

for the penalty were to be the highest possible alternative asset yield,
presumably the discount window would only be used when a bank were in such
desperate need that the cost of money was secondary.

If the base were

set at something less, borrowing short and lending long might conceivably
be encouraged.
A final problem resulting from this suggestion would be the
distribution of banks according to the efficiency of their employment of
funds.

Some inefficient banks are able to earn less on a given type of

asset and on all assets than tohers.

Under these conditions, a penalty

rate for one bank might not be a penalty rate for another.

Thus borrow-

ing would be a source of funds for efficient banks but not for those less
efficient.

If efficiency is a function of size, as some data indicate,

borrowing for purposes other than despearate needs would be confined to
large banks.
As might be concluded from the tenor of the above discussion,
I do not recommend replacement of the present system by one relying completely on the discount rate.

I would suggest, however, that some way be

found for the rate to bear more of the burden of rationing.
on this later.




I shall touch

- 33 Question 4,

Other than Government securities, the assets

purchases and sold ought to be selected on the basis of their importance
to the national economic fabrice

For example, the reason for continuing

operations in the bankers1 acceptance market is to demonstrate to the
participants that the trade underlying the paper is if sufficient importance for the Federal Reserve to provide a stabilizing force in that
market.

To me there are two other markets important enough for the

Federal Reserve to demonstrate the same kind of interest through nominal
activity.
market.

They are the municipal bond market and residential mortgage
The first requires no legislation to make a beginning, merely

the determination by the Federal Reserve that State and local government financing is in the same order of importance as bankers1 acceptancefinanced activity, that restrictive monetary policy affects the municipal
bond market extremely, and of course, that open-market operations would
provide a continuum to the market.

The second is also strongly affected

by extremes in cyclical monetary moves, but open-market activity in
residential mortgage ought to be undertaken by an agency other than FNMA
(and on a different basis), the Federal Reserve is not the agency.

If

such activity is done at all, it should be undertaken by the Federal
Home Loan Bank Board,

Question 5.

Again, if the practice of discounting is to be

continued, and on the same basis as present, the silly rules now prevailing as to collateral ought to be abandoned.




After all, if the

~ 34 ~

Federal Reserve wishes to give a bank a limited access to Federal Reserve
credit, why should the collateral matter so long as it is reasonably
sound?

And why should a bank be deprived of the credit simply because its

Government securities were gone or pledged or its

eligible

paper

exhausted?

Question 6,

The criteria for frequency, amount, and length of

borrowing from the Federal Reserve ought to be two:

size and function.

Surely a larger bank has need for greater amounts for brief periods.
Size, however, should not be the sole influence upon the amount, frequency, or duration of permissible borrowing—function should enter in
too,

I refer specifically to the support given by certain banks to the

Government securities market, to the bankers1 acceptance market, or to
any other market for financial instruments in which the Federal Reserve
conducts open market operations.

After all, if the Federal Reserve

depends on the banks to provide important support to the markets—for
example, loans to Government securities dealers—instead of performing
those functions itself, it should grant recognition to that support?

Question 7.

No.

It should not lend to nonmembers if it wants

to preserve the discount mechanism at all.

But this assumes the mechanism

is worth preserving.

Question 8,
c.

a and b have been dealt with,

This suggestion makes sense only if administrative

restrictions on the use of discounting are dropped and rationing by




- 35 ~

rates alone is adopted.

In my view, a scheme by which a bank is allowed

to borrow for longer periods, or in larger amounts if a higher rate is
apid, is certainly tantamount to a shceme that drops nonprice restrictions.
I have already cornnented on that proposal.
I would like to add to this:

The safety valve thesis ( as a

reason for existence of the discount mechanism) relates primarily to the
provision, on a limited scale, for uncalculable liquidity needs of banks.
Why should the larger banks pay more because their needs, under the
limitations now imposed on borrowing, are larger?

8 d and e.

Under present restrictions, the discount rate

sometimes leads changes in market rates—or perhaps stated more accurately,
leads open market operations~«and sometimes follows such changes.

There

are often long periods when the disccunt rate is below rates on 3-month
Treasury bills and every other prominent money market instrument.

If

policy of leading market-rate developments were continued, the
"announcement effects

would be maximized; if the discount rate were

"tied to some market rate," these effects would be minimized.
I prefer minimizing announcement effects.

Reading the meaning

of monetary policy and of developments in the economy is a practice in
which economic observers will always be engaged, and more or less correct
readings are at best difficult.

Announcement effects compound the problem

of arriving at correct readings and are likely to lead to abrupt swings
in expectations.




Abrupt swings in expectations in turn are more likely

to compound than to simplify the problems of monetary policy^ which must
both divine from market behavior the correct policy and influence the
market so as to achieve the desired results*
I suggest, therefore, that the discount rtte be set in relation
to the 3-month Treasury bill rate.

It should be set at some penalty with

respect to that rate so that use of the privilege costs something in comparison with some assets.

On the mechanics of setting the rate, I suggest

that the Federal Reserve adopt a procedure similar to that used by the
Federal Home Loan Bank System, which is to average the last three debenture issues, add 1/4 of 1 per cent, and round that figure to the nearest
10 (?) basis points.
This answer assumes, of course, the preservation of the discount
instrument.
8 f.

From the above, my position on frequency of discount rate

changes can be deduced.

However, I shall state it specifically:

Discount

rate changes should be made whenever the prescribed formula calls for it.

8 g.

Under present circumstances, I do not favor paying interest

on either required or excess reserves or total reserves.

I do not believe

such a step is necessary to hold the present system and membership I
believe the existing membership adequate as a base for monetary policy.
Further, I do not believe that the additional resources are needed by
the banks.




Finally, I believe that either step would unbalance the

-"'37 correspondent banking system and lead small banks to be even more out of
touch with money market conditions.
On the other hand, if such a step were found to be the
necessary price for abolition of the discount mechanism, I would favor
any version that would accomplish that end.




- 38 J. M. Culbertson
University of Wisconsin

This is in response to your request for views for transmittal
to the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Rather than

discussing the questions individually, I am limiting myself to several
general observations.
I am strongly opposed to any effort to use the discount
mechanism as a means of influencing the allocation of credit by region,
type of borrower, or type of debt instrument.

The paramount task of

the Federal Reserve System is management of the nation's monetary
system.

Its performance in this regard is deficient by the standards

I apply.

This seems to arise in part from the fact that the System

is not quite clear as to just what it is doing, which leads to a
tendency to ride off now in one direction and now in another.

To add

additional functions would only add to the confusion and add to the
hazard to the nation's economic stability posed by monetary mismanagement.

I am not aware of any demonstration of the need for direct

Government involvement in credit allocation beyond innumerable Government

credit programs existing, and in the absence of such demonstra-

tion--and clear guides to such selective credit control—any move in
that direction would be a grave error.

In this connection, I oppose

Federal Reserve open market operations in assets other than U.S. securities, although a provision permitting acquisition of other assets under
emergency conditions (severe market panic) might be worth considering.
I also would reject the idea of Federal Reserve lending to other than
member banks.




- 39 -

I favor moving toward abolition of discounting as it now
exists.

I believe that control over the monetary system would be

more effectively exercised without such regular borrowing from the
Federal Reserve Banks at the option of the borrower.

The objectives

of general monetary policy can be more effectively achieved by open
market operations at the option of the Federal Reserve.
of discounting as a

The function

lf

safety valve11 for individual banks is probably

superfluous, so long as the penalties for reserve deficiencies are
not too great.

The function of discounting as an inducement for

banks to be members of the Federal Reserve System may need replacement.

So long as discounting is continued, it might be helpful to

reduce the disturbing effects of large, discontinuous adjustments in
the discount rate, as through some system of automatic setting of the
rate in relation to market rates (with provision for Federal Reserve
override under unusual conditions)^
I would strongly oppose payment of interest on reserves
except as a part of some general program of reform.

A case perhaps

can be made for a combination of increases in reserve requirements
and payment of interest on reserves.

As a substitute inducement in

case of removal of discounting, there might also be something to be
said for payment of interest on reserves.

In the event that member-

ship in the System is made compulsory -- which I favor -- a case also
might be made for payment of interest; I should want to think in
detail about any such proposal before being ready to support it.




# 40

If the questions are indicative of the direction that the
System proposes to head in reform proposals, I am very unsympathetic.
As I see it, what the System needs is a rationale for what it does
and simplification of its procedures rather than the assumption of
new functions for which D O clear rationale or justification exists.




- 41 -

William G. Dewald
Ohio State University

The Federal Reserve should be interested in two interrelated
aspects of discounting: first, the cyclical or short-run effect of discounting on the determination of the quantity of money, interest rates,
and expenditure; and second, the long-run effect of discounting on the
allocation of resources.
It would appear that discounting has sometimes misled the
monetary authorities about the effects that variables under their
control have on magnitudes that matter.

Declines in the demand for

borrowings during the contractionary phase of the business cycle may
reflect that discount rates--though they have fallen--have declined
less than market rates of interest.

Thus, borrowings become relatively

more expensive, and thereby, other things being equal, monetary policy
may have a restrictive effect on the economy.
Let me expand on this point.

Using member bank borrowings

as an indicator of the expansionary (or contractionary) effects of
monetary policy is a source of possible error in the implementation of
monetary policy.

Borrowings (and free reserves) are, at least partly,

determined by the market.

Any sought-after effects of discount policy

or open market operations have to work their way through changes in
bank portfolios to interest rates; but discount policy also affects




William G. Dewald -- 42

desired borrowings (and free reserves).

The problem is that many

market forces other than those controlled by the Federal Reserve affect
borrowings (and free reserves); thus it is generally not correct to
conclude that a contraction in borrowings (or increase in free reserves)
indicates an expansionary monetary policy or that the opposite changes
reflect a contractionary policy.
If market interest rates fall because of a decline in total
planned spending, then borrowings would tend to drop and free reserves
to rise even without any Federal Reserve policy actions such as changes
in the discount rate, Federal Reserve holdings of open market securities,
or required reserve ratios.

This point seems obvious enough.

Neverthe-

less, a source of possible error occurs when borrowings, free reserves,
or market rates of interest are used as indicators of the effects of
changes in the tools of monetary policy under circumstances where these
variables are simultaneously being affected by both market forces and
monetary policy.

It is then incorrect to interpret changes in borrow-

ings, free reserves, or interest rates as resulting solely from changes
in policy-determined variables.

Indeed one possibility is that market

factors and policy-controlled factors work in opposite directions on
borrowings, free reserves, and interest rates.

Thus, borrowings dur-

ing economic contractions may be less than they otherwise would be
because the discount rate has risen relative to market rates of interest.
And interest rates during contractions may be higher and therefore less
expansionary than otherwise because of slower growth in Federal Reserve




William G. Dewald -- 43

holdings of securities (adjusted for required reserve ratio changes).
The opposite movements during economic expansion can be equally misleading.

In essence, borrowings, free reserves, and market rates of

interest are market-determined magnitudes and as such may be highly
misrepresentative indicators of monetary policy.
Despite the fact that it may have been the source of some
destabilizing monetary policy in the past, monetary policy would not
necessarily be more efficient if member bank discounting were eliminated.

All that is required is that the monetary authorities assess

the effect of the variables they can control on the variables they
wish to affect, other things equal.

Thus, if an expansionary policy

is wanted, the authorities would have to make sure--by reducing discount rates, increasing Federal Reserve securities holdings, or
reducing required reserve ratioa--that borrowings fell less than they
otherwise would, that free reserves increased more than they otherwise
would, and that interest rates decreased more than they otherwise would.
"Ceteris paribus11 historically has gotten economists into trouble in
many ways.

In my judgment the interpretation of market-determined

indicators of monetary policy is an example.

Thus, to study member

bank borrowing, the Federal Reserve and others should study all of the
variables upon which discounting depends and in particular the role
that discounting may play in transmitting the effects of changes in
policy-controlled variables on policy objectives.




William G. Dewald -- 44

The second major consideration in studying member bank
borrowing relates to its effects on long-run economic efficiency.

In

large part the discount mechanism is ill suited to affect differentially
credit allocation from what would otherwise occur in the money market.
If demands for credit are high in California (or in industry X) relative
to the rest of the country, higher rates there could be expected to draw
capital to California (or to industry X).

Manipulating discount rates

or discount administration between Federal Reserve districts (or types
of collateral) likely could not effectively alter this flow of credit,
at least not without a cost in efficiency.

However, the question is an

empirical one and should be investigated carefully.

My judgment is

based on the fact that transactions costs in Federal funds and Government securities markets are so small that I am willing to guess that
any attempt to keep the discount rate higher in one region than others
would be almost altogether offset by interregional portfolio adjustments.
In essence banks in the low discount-rate areas would borrow more and
hold more securities, while the opposite would be true in relatively
low discount-rate areas.

Thus, efforts to change interest rates inter-

regionally or otherwise by discount policy would tend to be offset by
an outflow of funds from areas with relatively low discount rates.
Question 1.
tary policy.

Only open market operations are really essential to moneNevertheless, changes in discount rates also affect the

supply of money and interest rates; and it would be worthwhile to learn
more than is known about the magnitude of the effects.




If the discount

William G. Dewald -- 45

rate is one of several tools of monetary policy, then the best mixture
of policy tools requires knowledge about each and the way they work
interdependently.

For example, high discount rates and low required

reserve ratios might be expected to reduce both borrowings and the
responsiveness of borrowings to changes in credit market conditions or
interest rates.

This effect on the responsiveness of borrowings depends

on the presumption that desired excess reserves would increase with an
increase in the discount rate or a decrease in required reserve ratios.
Banks would have less need to borrow in response to financial disturbances.

Hence, a given Federal Reserve open market purchase (or sale)

would cause a lesser feedback effect of reduced (increased) borrowings.
It would probably be a useful alteration if the relationship of the
discount rate to market rates of interest were atabilized; for example,
by automatically fixing the discount rate at a margin above the Treasury
bill rate.

This policy would avoid one source of change in the respon-

siveness of money and interest rates to open market operations.
Question 2.

In general, it would appear to be wrong for the Federal

Reserve to try to influence the allocation of credit through discount
policy.

Bargain discount rates would be a subsidy to banks.

Assuming

the public really supports the subsidy, the recipient would generally
be better off with a direct payment of money than with a change in the
prices he faces.

Despite this fact discounting might conceivably play

some marginal role in improving the allocation of resources in a
country with many small banks.




If the costs to society of providing

William G. Dewald —

46

loans to banks are less than costs to banks of alternately buying and
selling securities, then banks facing losses of deposits could adjust
their portfolios without liquidating their assets.

Of course, the

resultant increase in total bank reserves should appropriately be offset by open market operations.

Payment of interest on excess reserves,

as well as lengthened and staggered reserve settlement periods, could
have a similar effect in reducing the burden of reversible portfolio
adjustments.
Question 3.

Unless a case can be made for the imperfectness of the

money market and the possibility of this being offset by the rationing
of loans to banks, discount administration is a bad way to control the
volume of discounting.

It is bad over the business cycle for it may

change the responsiveness of money and interest rates to other monetary
policy tools and make more difficult the prediction of effects of policy
actions.

It is bad with respect to the allocation of credit because it

may lead to discounting at different terms in different regions or on
different classes of collateral.

Discount administration is necessary

but simply to insure that the borrower can repay his loan with reasonable likelihood.

The discount rate must be high enough to prevent

unwarranted expansion of bank reserves and the supply of money, even
though some banks might find it profitable to borrow more or less
continuously from the Federal Reserve.




William G. Dewald -- 47

Question 4*

The Federal Reserve should be free to buy, sell, and issue

Government securities of all maturities.

Privately issued securities,

including bankers1 acceptances, should not be purchased if the market
is efficient enough to direct credit allocation without interference by
the Federal Reserve,

The Federal Reserve should take responsibility

for managing the Federal debt by conducting its open market operations
(and new issues of securities if authorized) to cause the average
maturity of the Federal debt to rise during periods of threatening
inflation and to fall during periods of recession.

The principal

advantage of assigning this responsibility to the Federal Reserve is
that it could easily make small sequential adjustments in outstanding
maturities through the established open market mechanism.




- 48 -

Edward E. Edwards
Indiana University
Question 1.
Except for the fact that we have a unit banking system,
I would argue (1) that there should be no discount window or
(2) that discount policy should be completely independent of
monetary policy.

Open market operations, assuming the existence

of a Federal funds market and a bond market, would be the only
tool needed to implement monetary policy.

If discounts were per-

mitted, the rate should be at market rate or higher, and the Open
Market Committee should adjust its net purchases or sales to a
changing volume of discounts in the same way that it adjusts to
changing volume of currency in circulation, or changing float, or
changing Treasury deposit balances.

Of course, market rates

would be affected by monetary policy, and this would -- or should
—

affect the discount rate,

but it would be an incidental effect.

But we have a unit system, and in such a system there
may be a proper role for the discount window as a tool of monetary
policy.

For example, monetary policy might well be concerned with

who the recipients are when reserves are injected into the system;
who is squeezed the most under restrictive monetary policies.

I

assume money flows quickly and freely between New York and Chicago
and other financial centers.

I am less certain as to how freely

funds flow into and out of -- but especially into -- smaller
communities.

Thus I believe that a good case can be made not only

for keeping the discount window open but also for encouraging its
use.




49 -

Here I am arguing for the discount window solely as a
means of compensating for impediments to the flow of funds through
geographic regions and among banks of different competitive strength,
impediments that would not exist in a nationwide branch system.

I

do not argue that monetary policy should be concerned with the
ultimate recipient of bank credit or its use*

However, it should

be rather obvious that a conversation at the discount window about
the undesirability of certain types of loans or borrowers might be
more effective than a public speech on the subject by a member of
1/
the Board of Governors*
My doubts as to the free flow of funds in a unit banking
system center chiefly in the ability of small banks, and especially
those in smaller cities and towns, to reverse or even to halt the
flow of funds out of their communities in periods of strong demand
for funds in money centers*

Such a drain is more important when

some local communities are suffering a loss of funds because of
locally adverse business conditions or lack of confidence in local
J7 In the light of 1966 experience, I would also argue that it
would be better when money is tight for large banks to obtain
funds at the discount window, with the Federal Reserve selling
a comparable amount of Treasury bills, than for the banks to
sell CD's in the open market. Why? Bankers would exercise a
bit more restraint, perhaps, but the main reason would be to
prevent the highly damaging competition among all financial
intermediaries. No one cares what the banks pay the Federal
Reserve for money, but when they advertise maximum rates on
CD's, every financial institution in the nation is affected.




- so institutions*

I do not believe we should allow unit banks to fail

because of lack of liquidity -- and more on that later —

and I do

not believe we should settle for less from monetary policy than
might be achieved solely through open market operations if we had

1/

nationwide branching.

As a final observation, I should think that discount
policy might bear some relationship to the volume of required
reserves and Federal Reserve notes outstanding on the one hand and
the volume of marketable Government obligations on the other.
Reserve Bank liabilities must be matched with assets of some description. For the Reserve Banks to acquire more and more Government obligations interferes with the free market in Government
securities and may also be depriving the private sector of its
most desirable liquid asset.

Thus gradual substitution of dis-

counts and advances for Government securities on the asset side
may be desirable -- unless, of course, investment powers are
broadened, reserve requirements are reduced Or eliminated, or
Treasury currency substituted for Federal Reserve notes.
Question 2.
As argued above, in a unit banking system discounting
can and should be used to compensate in part for the many
2/ Some economists are opposed to discounting because it
"encourages the survival of unit banking, whereas branch
banking would be better. The Board of Governors cannot
accept that argument, since it is not its responsibility
to determine what kind of system we should have, but rather
to make the system we have work effectively.




- 51 impediments to the free flow of funds among banks and between regions
and communities.

Discounting will probably also influence types of

uses of credit.

However, this does not mean that the Federal Reserve

should become a bank for development or redevelopment.

Its concern

should be with its member banks, that they are not discriminated
against unfairly by the impact of monetary policies carried out primarily by open market operations and that they in fact do have access
to the bank of last resort.
Discounting in its role as a source of liquidity is
probably the most important reason why discounting should be a major
feature of Federal Reserve policy.

Unless unit banks can absolutely

depend on their central bank as a source of funds in the event of
deposit drains or unusual loan demand, they must each maintain a
strong liquidity position.

Doing this deprives the local communities

of the full use and benefit of the savings the communities generate.
It also shifts the supply of funds into the large money markets,
which in general, and especially with a unit banking system, have
limited ability to move funds back into local communities.
[Limited ability may not be the best choice of words here.
For example, money market funds can easily be put into the hands of
nationwide finance companies and could easily be channeled back to
local savings and loan associations through the Federal Home Loan
Bank System. Also, money market funds may get back to large borrowers through participations, with big banks taking the excess over
legal limits of the small banks. What I have in mind is the lack




- 52 of any flow of funds back to the smaller bank in any way comparable
to what would be possible with a branch system.

While theoretically

a small bank from a small community might compete in the money
markets with negotiable certificates of deposit, as a practical
matter CD's move money in only one direction, namely, to the big
banks in the big money markets.]
Under a nationwide branch banking system, a branch in a
capital-short community can lend not only 100 per cent of its
deposits but also quite a bit in excess of that amount.

I doubt

if the Federal Reserve should go as far as would the home office
of a nationwide commercial bank in this direction, but I do believe
that the Federal Reserve could contribute to economic growth and
stability by permitting those banks with greatest local needs for
funds to lend a higher percentage of their deposits than would be
possible without the assured availability of discounting.

Note

that I am not arguing that discounts be used as a permanent source
of loanable funds, but only that banks be permitted -- and encouraged
—

to count on their Federal Reserve Bank for some part of their

liquidity.
The continued trend among many of our banks toward becoming savings institutions emphasizes the need for discounting as a
source of liquidity.

Experience shows that savings deposits need to

be fully invested in order for savers to have a fair return and in
order for the savings institutions to maintain an adequate capital




- 53 base«

Experience also shows that savings institutions in most

communities must emphasize local loans and investments in order
to compete successfully for savings. Local loans and investments, despite their quality, have little liquidity or shift
ability.

Thus member banks with a large proportion of savings

deposits face an almost impossible dilemma unless they can
absolutely depend on Federal Reserve credit to keep them in
business during a period of savings deposit drain or unusually
strong demand for loans.

Since such a period might last for

several months or longer, fairly continuous or long-term borrowing by some banks or by most or all banks in some regions should
not be considered too unusual.
Whether banks as a normal practice borrowed continuously
and invested the funds in highly liquid assets, or held few liquid
assets but did no borrowing except in emergencies, would seem to
make little difference if the bankers knew they could borrow when
the need arose,

I would prefer to have most banks using the dis-

count window frequently, with many
time.

banks borrowing at any given

This would not affect the amount of Federal Reserve credit,

since changes in the volume of advances could easily be offset by
open market operations.

But it would demonstrate that the Federal

Reserve is willing to provide at least some of the liquidity needed
by a unit banking system.
Before leaving this point, I would suggest that if
Federal Reserve Banks are not going to meet liquidity needs of




- 54 their member banks, then we should provide for membership of
commercial banks in the Federal Home Loan Bank System, or set up
eome netf rasezrve credit institution to give unit banks a borrowing
route to the money and capital markets*

Unless member banks can

depend on discounting, their only route to the market is by selling money market assets. This limitation either threatens their
existence in case they do not maintain adequate liquidity or
prevents them from serving their local communities as fully as
they should.
I would further suggest that the development of discounting will do more than any program other than compulsion to make
member banks of the thousands of banks now outside the System.

The

record of membership is adequate argument that our central bank
doesn't do much for most of our banks.
lar in certain quarters by

I once made myself unpopu-

stating that the Federal Reserve Banks

did not do as much for their savings-minded members as the Federal
Home Loan Banks do for theirs. Since the statement was true, I
reaffirm it.
Question 3.
If the volume of discounting has to be regulated, the
proper tool would seem to be the discount rate. But it is foolish
to talk about regulating volume through price in a market as
J3/ The 1966 experience suggests that the Federal Home Loan Banks
sometimes fail to do as much as they should, and could, for their
members.




- 55 -

artificial as the present discount market.

Unless and until the

Federal Reserve is willing to consider discounting as a proper use
of Federal Reserve credit on the one hand and a proper source of
funds for member banks on the other, the discount rate will continue to be a bit of central banking folklore.
Two major changes should be made.

First, the Federal

Reserve should consider discounting as a proper activity, not to
be discouraged by the preservation or encouragement of "taboos"
against discounting.

Second, the several banks, with approval of

the Board of Governors, should keep the discount rate as close as
possible to market rates for money -- even slightly on the low side
in periods of tight money -- thus encouraging members to discount.
As a result of the two changes, some banks, somewhere, even when
money is easy, would be borrowing because the imperfections in the
money markets and in the unit banking system forced them to rely
on this source of liquidity.

And when banks generally are faced

with strong demands for funds, most banks would be discounting, at
least part of the time.
Why would this be better?

For only one reason:

it would

be more compatible with the unit banking system the Federal Reserve
is supposed to serve and protect.
Question 4.
With a change in policy that would result in a much
larger volume of discounts and a smaller holding of Government securities, I would see no reason for any change in assets bought and sold.




- 56 -

Without the change, then I believe some broadening of investment
powers might be desirable,

I would suggest as a starter the short-

term obligations of Federal agencies, especially those of the
Federal Home Loan Banks.

However, a better approach to solving

the Federal Reserve's asset problem might be to reduce the need
for assets by the elimination of reserve requirements on savings

it/

deposits.

Question 5The only test I would suggest for borrowing by member
banks would be creditworthiness of the borrower plus an appropriate
use for the funds, and the better the credit the less I would worry
about the use.

In general, I would favor unsecured advances rather

than discounts or collateral loans.
Reserve makes no sense.

Secured lending by the Federal

If the borrowing member does not fail, the

collateral is unnecessary.

If the borrowing member fails, foreclos-

ing on the collateral merely increases the loss that must be borne
by someone who was less able than the Federal Reserve to know the
direction the bank was heading.

I think the Reserve Banks are

fully able to take their share of any losses from failed banks.
To try to define or establish rules of eligibility and
acceptability for collateral can only lead to trouble; the worst
kind of trouble is the failure of the bank of last resort to perform

4/ The elimination of reserve requirements on savings deposits would
make membership more attractive and would in no way interfere with
monetary policy.




- 57 -

its function when most needed.

Central bankers should be concerned

with their members1 need for funds and their potential for repaying.
Setting up rules of eligibility of paper diverts attention away
from the main issue, sets up artificial barriers to performance,
and gives central bankers excuses not to do what they are supposed
to do.
Question 6.
Each Federal Reserve Bank should establish its own
criteria, with the Board of Governors or Open Market Committee
limiting its concern to the total amount of credit extended and
perhaps the rate charged.
Question 7.
If a loan to a nonmember bank would keep it from failing
or enable it to serve better the borrowing needs of its community,
then I should think a Federal Reserve Bank would want to, should
be able to, and should make the loan.

As a face-saving device,

possibly such credits should not extend beyond some time period,
5/
perhaps 6 months, unless the borrower applied for membership.
Question 8a.
I see no reason for insisting on absolute uniformity, but
I should think reasonable uniformity would be necessary if member
banks kept the

discount window open.

.5/ This would be largely a theoretical question if the Federal
Reserve made membership more attractive, which it easily could do
by a greater reliance on the discount window for injecting Federal
Reserve credit and by reducing reserve requirements.




- 58 8b.
The rates might be different for different purposes or
different maturities
8c.
Possibly, but I would leave rate differentials to the
12 Reserve Banks.
8d.
If the Federal Reserve considered discounting as a proper
medium for Federal Reserve credit, the rate question likely will be
solved, by market forces, and the present excessive attention to the
discount rate would quickly evaporate.

From the standpoint of

monetary policy, the important variable would be how much credit has
a Reserve Bank extendedi not how much it charged.

Very likely some new

types of controls or restraints over the 12 Reserve Banks might need
to be developed, but these should be aimed primarily at regulating
the amount of reserve credit extended and possibly the distribution,
such as between bonds and discounts and advances.
8e.
Yes.

No comment on methods.

8f.
No comment.
8g.
Almost 30 years ago I suggested that the Federal Reserve
pay interest on excess reserves, for what I thought then was a good
reason.




Too many bankers were too much concerned with their

Government bond portfolio, when they should have been calling on
farmers, automobile dealers, homebuilders, and other loan prospects.
Whether the same thing holds true today

I doubt, but paying

interest on excess reserves at the Federal Reserve's earning rate
would be fair and would save thousands of bankers a lot of useless
time and effort now spent in avoiding any excess reserves, yet meeting legal reserve requirements.
Many years later I suggested that "Uncle Sam should take
his hand out of the till,11 referring to what seemed to me to be
excessive legal reserve requirements.

Since then reserve require-

ments have been lowered, but they are still higher than necessary.
I would rather see them lowered and eliminated altogether on savings
deposits rather than have the Federal Reserve pay interest on required
reserves.




-•60 Milton Friedman
University of Chicago

I have made a systematic analysis of discounting in my little
book, A Program for Monetary Stability.

Any answers that I might give

to your questions now would be more offhand and less satisfactory than
that statement.

I have seen no reason to revise my basic position

since that statement.

The material relevant to your inquiry is concen-

trated on pages 35-45, 52-65, and 71-76.




- 51 Dudley G. Luckett
Iowa State University

1.

Discount mechanism*

I have no analytical comments to

make with respect to the discount mechanism.

My opinion is that the

mechanism per s_e is a very useful adjunct to the banking system.

Its

value lies in the fact that each bank that applies for an advance may
be treated as an individual case and judged on its own merits.

Thus

when local conditions warrant (for example, a crop failure in an
agricultural community), the Federal Reserve is able to make temporary
accommodation to a member bank until more fundamental adjustments can
be taken.
The fact that funds lent to a specific bank for a specific
purpose constitute a net addition to total bank reserves should not
obscure the essential soundness of the discounting procedure.

It is

of course true that Federal Reserve discounts and advances rise during a tight money period; but this is in no way surprising.

Banks

are, after all, almost by definition relatively illiquid during tight
money periods, so that random events which in easier times would not
affect them may prove quite disturbing.

Extending the reserve base

through the discount window, a process which can easily be offset
through open market operations, seems to me a small price to pay for
the greater stability insinuated into the banking system through the
discount window.




- 62 -

2.

Discount policy*

with discount policy:

There are three possible ways to deal

(a) abolish it; (b) leave it as it is; (c) make

it into a more powerful and distinctive tool of monetary policy,
(a)




Abolishing discount policy could be accomplished either
by doing away with the discount mechanism entirely
[Friedman], or by posting the discount rate some fixed
percentage above the Treasury bill rate each week [Smith].
As I pointed out above, I do not see any useful purpose
to be served by abolishing the discounting mechanism.
Warren Smith's proposal, however, seems to me to have
considerable merit,

I seriously doubt that discount

policy is able to accomplish any objective of monetary
policy which cannot more
open market operations.

easily be achieved through
At the same time, discount policy

has disadvantages of which the "announcement effect" is
perhaps the most serious.

The recent controversy between

the administration and Chairman Martin over the rise in
the discount rate is a case in point.

The controversy was

focused on the essentially minor question of the proper
level for the discount rate rather than on the major
question of the appropriate tightness of monetary policy.
Moreover, as nearly as I can judge [it is sometimes difficult to tell from lovza ] the Federal Reserve was forced into

an early rise in the discount rate by considerations of
Treasury financing —
(b)

a wholly irrelevant issue.

I dislike the present system of discount policy largely
for the reasons noted in (a) above.

It is perhaps worth

a single additional comment to remark that the present
system leaves discount policy and the discount mechanism
hopelessly intertwined*

The present system is based on a

theory of commercial and central banking which probably
never had a real-world counterpart and in any case has
certainly not had one for the last 30 years.
(c)




There is a third proposal, associated with the name of
James Tobin, which suggests, first, that banks be permitted
to pay interest on demand deposits, and second, that the
Federal Reserve pay a rate of interest on excess member
bank reserves.

The presumed advantage of such a proposal

is that it would give the Federal Reserve a more direct
influence over the customer loan rates of commercial banks
by giving the Federal Reserve direct control over the
opportunity cost of the banks1 funds.

I confess I fail

to see much merit in this proposal.
In the first place, the opportunity cost of idle bank funds
is currently the Treasury bill rate -- and this rate is very
strongly influenced by Federal Reserve policy.

The additional

control over bank loan rates gained by the Federal Reserve




- 64 under the Tobin proposal would, it seems to me, be highly
marginal.
On an operating level, there are three possibilities:
First, a low rate on excess reserves and a high rate on
Treasury bills.

This is essentially the way the system now

works (the rate on excess reserves is zero), and so presumably this is not what is being proposed.

Second, a high

rate on excess reserves and a low rate on Treasury bills.
This possibility would shift banks out of the bill market
and into excess reserves as a source of secondary reserves.
This shift in turn would result in the loss of a major
market for the public debt and give the banks a windfall
gain not open to other asset holders.

In my opinion this

would not have any advantage.
The third possibility is that the Treasury bill rate and
the rate paid on excess reserves would move roughly in
tandem.

If so, then the ability to set the rate on excess

reserves is not an independent policy instrument but rather
an appendage of the open market operations.

Moreover, as

noted above, since the opportunity cost of holding excess
reserves is in any case the bill rate, it is by no means
clear in what way this option would enhance the effectiveness of monetary policy.
I should think that the benefit to be derived from the
proposal to pay interest on demand deposits (a greater

- 55 -

stability of velocity) would occur even in the absence of a rate paid
on excess reserves.

Permitting banks to pay a rate of interest on

demand deposits has much to recommend it in other respects also—notably the added competitiveness which would result among commercial
banks.

I would add that a necessary pre-condition for repealing this

law should be the extension of deposit insurance to i ^ per cent of
all deposits, so that depositors are fully protected against bad bank
management.




- 66 Thomas Mayer
University of California at Davis

I believe that the discount mechanism should be revised
substantially.

In its essentials it has been changed little since

the early days of the Federal Reserve.
fundamentally in three ways.

Yet conditions have changed

First, the "real bills11 doctrine has

been abandoned; second, open market operations have been developed
as the main tool of monetary policy; and third, there now exists a
combination of Government security holdings as a first line of defense and the FDIC as a final line of defense to guard the banking
system from panics.

As a result the discount mechanism has lost

most of its function.
One function it has definitely lost is controlling the
quality of credit.

This has been recognized in part by the revi-

sion of Regulation A.
far enough.

But it is doubtful that this revision goes

Is any purpose served by requiring a particular type

of collateral in support of the bank's loan application?

Insofar

as the purpose of the collateral is to protect the Federal Reserve
in case the borrowing bank fails, why is this collateral limited
to Government securities and eligible paper?

Surely, if the only

purpose is to protect the Federal Reserve, any sound asset should
be acceptable as collateral.

One might go further and ask if the

Federal Reserve should be protected by collateral at all.

If a

bank does fail, the burden is carried by another Government agency,




Mayer

~

the FDIC.

67

Admittedly, there is a case, though perhaps not an over-

whelming one, for protecting the Federal Reserve and letting the
FDIC carry the whole cost of bank failures; namely, that FDIC losses
show up in FDIC insurance assessments.
other.

In effect, banks insure each

But, if the whole purpose of collateral is to ensure that the

ultimate burden of bank failure rests with the banking system rather
than with the Federal Reserve, this purpose could be accomplished
simply by having Federal Reserve loans to banks covered by FDIC insurance.

If the insurance system were extended in this manner, no

collateral at all would be needed.
The second function of the discount mechanism is to allow
the Federal Reserve, by changing the discount rate, to change the
reserve base.

Nowadays, this can be done much more efficiently by

open market operations through which the Federal Reserve is able to
change bank reserves by the exact amount it desires.

Admittedly,

changing the discount rate has a much greater announcement effect
than open market operations, but the announcement effect is likely
to be more of a nuisance than a help. 1/
This leaves only one of the original purposes of discounting—the provision of reserves for specific member banks short of
reserves.

Although, as pointed out above, this purpose is by no

\J On this issue I find quite convincing the arguments given by
Warren Smith in ffThe Instruments of General Monetary Control,11 The
National Banking Review, September 1963, pp. 47-67.




Mayer

- 63 -

means so important now as it was earlier, it has not completely
disappeared.

Particular banks might prefer discounting to selling

off Government securities or borrowing Federal funds, particularly
if they could discount without having to use their dwindling stock
of unpledged Government Securities.

The discounting privilege is

probably a major inducement for membership in the Federal Reserve
System.
I would therefore advocate keeping the discount window
open rather than abolishing discounting altogether.

But in order

to get rid of the announcement effect, I would like to see the discount rate pegged to the Treasury bill rate.

I am not sure exactly

what the proper relationship of these two rates should be.

To pre-

vent excessive use of the discount window, it may be necessary to
keep the discount rate above—rather than equal to--the bill rate.
However, I am not sure that the quarter of a per cent differential
used by the Canadians is the right one.

One-eighth of a per cent,

or even a smaller differential, might suffice in view of the reluctance of banks to borrow.

One of the relevant criteria for choosing

the differential is the desired incentive for Federal Reserve membership.

(Since this consideration does not apply in Canada, the quar-

ter of a per cent might be too great a differential for the United
States.)

Whatever differential is chosen--as long as it is signif-

icantly different from zero—would allow the Federal Reserve to
operate the discount window without controlling the amount and




Mayer

- 69 *

frequency of bank borrowing, apart from exceptional cases, which
in any event might be handled better by means of bank examination.
This answers all the questions except numbers 4 and 7
and parts of questions 2 and 8,

Question 2 asks, in part, whether

discounting should be used to influence the allocation of credit.
I would oppose this for two reasons.

First, it is an excessive

interference with a free market, an interference that ideally
could improve resource allocation, but that in practice, as a result
of political pressures, is likely to worsen resource allocation.
Second, if we <lo want to use monetary policy to influence the allocation of credit by region or by use, there are probably other ways of
doing it more efficiently than by the discount mechanism.
Question 8a raises a very interesting issue.

I am not sure

that the traditional answer—namely that small differences in discount
rates set off disturbing capital flows--is necessarily correct.

Why

should these capital movements necessarily be disturbing rather than
equilibriating?

Moreover, even if they are disturbing under the

present arrangement, would they necessarily be disturbing if the discount rate were made into a moderate penalty rate with the differential between the discount rate and the bill rate different in various
regions?

I don't know the answer to these questions and am not

advocating regional differences, but merely am suggesting that the
question should be studied.




Question 8c asks if the discount rate should be graduated.

Mayer

- 70 **

If it is pegged above the bill rate, I see no reason for graduating
the rate or for otherwise punishing banks because of large-scale
borrowing.
Part g of question 8 deals with interest payments on reserves.

I am quite impressed with Tobinfs proposal to pay interest

on excess reserves, zJ but I see little reason for paying interest
on

required reserve balances.

The Tolley-Friedman resource alloca-

tion argument for such interest payments strikes me as invalid. _'
Competition from nonbank financial intermediaries does not seem to
hurt banks so much that they need interest payments on reserves to
4/
survive. —' Given the current and foreseeable budgetary strain, the
Treasury's needs seem greater than the banks 1 .
In reply to question 7, I feel that the Federal Reserve
should, in normal circumstances, lend only to member banks so that
banks have an incentive to join the System.

In a financial crisis,

however, the Federal Reserve should lend to nonmember banks too.

The

present system of standing ready to lend to nonmember banks, but at a

2/ James Tobin, "Towards Improving the Efficiency of the Monetary
Mechanism,ff Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1960, pp. 277-78,
2/ George Tolley, "100 Percent Reserve Banking,11 in In Search of a
Monetary Constitution, edited by Leland B. Yeager (Cambridge, Mass.:
Harvard University Press, 1962) ; Milton Friedman, A Program for Monetary
Stability (New York: Fordham University Press, 1959), pp. 71-75. For a
criticism see my "Interest Payments on Required Reserve Balances,11
Journal of Finance, March 1966.
kj See Joseph Aschheim, Techniques of Monetary Control (Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins Press, 1961), Ch. 7.




Mayer

- 71 -

higher rate, seems sensible.

Perhaps the differential charge

against nonmenbers should be raised, but nonmembers should be given
a statutory right to borrow.

(If the discount rate is made into a

penalty rate, administration of the discount window is no longer
necessary and hence statutory borrowing rights for all banks are
feasible.)
This leaves question 4 dealing with open market operations.
I welcome the abandonment of "bills preferably11 and would like to see
the Federal Reserve operate in as broad a market as possible,

(I have

not thought about this topic enough to specify any clear-cut limits.)
The empirical evidence seems to suggest that it is the long-term rate
rather than the short-term rate that affects investment.

Hence, if

we want monetary policy to be effective we must obtain significant
changes in the long-term rate and do so without a long delay.

If the

long-term rate moves only trivially, then for much investment the only
impact of monetary policy comes through the availability effect, and
I don't think that this is powerful enough.




~ 72 Hyman P. Minsky
Washington University

1#

General.
The division of labor between the discount window and open

market operations should be determined by the special characteristics
of these instruments, the existing structure of financial markets, and
economic policy objectives relative to the structure of financial
markets.

There are three attributes —• two are inherent in the in-

struments and one is not -- that are worthy of consideration in determining the use of these instruments.

The essential differences

between the two instruments are that (1) whenever reserves are supplied
by discounting, some units will be constrained by the newly created
debt to the Federal Reserve System, whereas open market operations do
not entail the de nova creation of debt and (2) in discounting the
Reserve System sets terms such as defining eligible collateral and the
market determines how much will be furnished, whereas with open market
operations the Reserve System determines how much and what instruments
to use and the market determines the price.

(Note that whenever the

Reserve sets the price of an instrument in ample supply, the quantity
of reserves generated by open market operations is at the initiative
of the market.

Whenever this takes place, one of what I called the

essential distinctions becomes blurred.

Open market operations take

on some of the characteristics of discounts.)




The difference between

the two that is not essential to the in struments but rather is a
characteristic of the American way of looking at banking is that open
market operations are viewed as furnishing reserves to an impersonal
market, whereas discounting operations are viewed as furnishing reserves
to a particular bank.
Ideally, the discount window can serve as the mechanism by
which transitory pressures from the money market, or if you wish, from
various money markets, are transmitted to the Reserve System.

If we

accept that there are defensive and dynamic objectives in the supply
of reserves by the Federal Reserve, the dynamic objectives can best
be served by open market operations and the defensive objectives by the
discount window.

Fundamentally, the dynamic objectives are served by

the trend rate of growth of reserves, commercial bank lending, and
the money supply.

The principal factors which enter the determination

of these trends need not concern us; however, given the different ways
ia which our economy can function it seems unwise to set this trend rate
of growth once and for all by adopting any rule.

The Board of Governors

must have continuing discretionary powers with respect to the target
rate of growth in these fundamental monetary variables; however, changes
in these rates of growth should not take place on the basis of shortrun needs.

Fundamentally, cycle and growth characteristics and

objectives would be the major dete4minants of changes in the rate of
growth of reserve credit by means of open market operations.




- 74 Therefore, during any period of stable economic policy objectives,
the rate of growth of the reserve base would be constant; only when
either the behavior of the economy or a change in policy objectives forces
a reconsideration of past decisions would the rate of growth of the
reserve base by means of open market operations be affected.
The discount window is an obvious technique by which pressure
arising from banking and financial market processes, including seasonal
currency drains, can be transmitted to the Board of Governors,

A rise

in market demand for banking accommodations, due to growth or cycle
characteristics, beyond what can be accommodated by the open market rate
of growth of bank reserves, will lead to a rise in borrowing from the
Federal Reserve that will be in excess of the seasonal and mechanicalbanking norms.

These reserves should be furnished to the financial

system on an ever-tightening set of terms.

It may be desirable that

impersonal instruments such as Treasury bills should not be eligible
for rediscounting —

that rediscounting should always take the form of

borrowings by a financial institution on a private market instrument
at terms that are penal and under considtions where the extent of
borrowing by any market operator determines the terms at which the
borrowings are executed.

That is, the discount window might not be

an infinitely elastic source of credit to any particular market unit.
The economic-policy-determined rate of growth of the reserve
base by way of open market operations will, at times, lead to a decrease




- 75 ~
in the proportion of reserves furnished by the discount window.

If

this decrease reflects a slackening of demand for loans by the market,
due to a shortfall of real aggregate demand below target, rather than
an excessive rate of increase of owned bank reserves, an improvement of
portfolios in those financial markets where borrowers at the discount
window had been concentrated will take place.

Some spillover from such

portfolio improvement to the financing of demand can be expected to
take place — and this should be reinforced by discount rate decreases.
However, whenever market conditions are such that owned reserves,
supplied by the Reserve System, are used to clean up balance sheets
rather than to finance operations even after suhc easing in terms takes
p lace, there is some basic weakness in the underlying demand situation.
This should be taken as a signal that some increase in the fiscal
component of the expansionary forces is needed.

In other words, if

we view the dynamic monetary policy target variables as consisting of
a rate of growth of reserves, earning assets, and money, whenever the
rate of growth of own reserves exceeds the rate of growth of reserves,
earning assets, and money a signal is being flashed that monetary expansion cannot do all that is needed and an increase in the weight of
fiscal measures is needed.
To summarize, increased weight on the discount window -especially a discount window in which loans collateralized by government debt are not allowed -- sems to be a desirable way of making the
money market an emitter of clearer signals as to policy requirements.




- 76-Under present market arrangements, there is a single pool of
reserves for those banks which I call money market banks ~

banks

which actively engage in managing their money position and which have
a clearly articulated policy of being fully invested.

Whether or not

it pays for a bank to be an active money market participant depends
upon the size of the bank, the set of market interest rates, and the
state of the art (defined as the money market institutions that exist
and the costs of participating in these markets)*

As a minimum an

active money position management policy involves dealing in the
Federal funds market and participating in the financing of security
dealers.

Active money position management may also involve the

management of the investment portfolio as a buffer between the banks1
reserve needs and the loan portfolio,
A money market bank which borrows at the Federal Reserve to
make its position is not necessarily doing this because of its own
activities.

It is borrowing because it was at the end of the line

in the Federal funds market,

A bank borrows because of the luck of a

draw combined with an unwillingness or an inability to take losses on
its investment portfolio.

The market really is borrowing rather than

the individual bank*
Nevertheless, it is a particular bank that is, so to speak,
the agent of the market.

The debtor constraint, which is an essential

characteristic of discount operations, is operative at a particular bank.




There is nothing in the mechanism that guarantees that the debtor
constraint will be operating as a desired point in the financial
system.

Although the distinction between productive and speculative

uses of credit is specious, and in particular, the distinction is a
very poor guide for Federal Reserve policies, it may very well be that
banks which have a heavy business loan demand may be borrowing from
the Federal Reserve, at a time that banks which finance security transactions are acquiring borrowed reserves from the Federal funds market.
That is, to the extent that the Federal Reserve System may wish to discriminate among types of paper, the present scheme of having banks use
the window is not efficient:

an efficient scheme would be to encourage

the development of an active market in some instrument and allow the
market participants to acquire their residual financing at the discount
window.
To the extne that bank holdings of government securities, in
excess of the collateral required for deposits, have almost vanished,
the option of selling investments as an alternative to borrowing to make
a reserve psoition has decreased in importance*

Thus, increasingly we

can expect to see the alternatives to be rediscounting or a restrictive
loan policy.

Bank business strategy, as well as the short-run profit-

ability of loans, indicate that rediscounting can expand beyond its
present scope before a marked change in the portfolio strategy of banks
will take place.




Of course, the price for loans will respond to the

- 78 -

effective discount rate.
permissive

One characteristic of a banking system with

rediscounting is that the supply of loans is elastic at a

price, and the price varies with the discount rate.*
From the perspective of open market operations, central bank
action determines the reserve base and thus the quantity of money.
From the perspective of rediscount operations, central bank action
determines conditions in some chosen set of financial markets.

The

market determines the reserve base and the quantity of money.
With present practices, the one clear case in which a market
uses the discount window centers around the role that some New York
City banks play as lenders of last resort to the government bond
dealers:

then banks stand ready to finance the dealers even if by

doing this they are forced into borrowing from the Federal Reserve
Bank.

At one time the Board of Governors considered allowing the

government bond dealers to execute repurchase agreements at the
initiative of the bond dealers.

This would effectively allow the

Federal Reserve Banks to be the direct lenders of last resort to the
government dealer market, rather than by way of these New York banks.
If only because the indirect way introduces noise into the system, it
might be desirable to reconsider whether or not government bond dealers
should have the right to borrow at the window.

Presumably the borrowing

would be at a penal rate.
* The earlier suggestion of allowing the price to vary with the amount
a particular borrower borrows will serve to keep the various market
operators in step.




- 79 -

The above consideration introduces the classic division of
labor among central bank policies:

the discount rate was set to

determine the interest-rate pattern, and open market operations were
used to make the rate effective.

The classical doctrine had bank

rate primacy; U.S. usage has a quantity of reserves primacy.

The

view that what is to be controlled is the terms upon which financing
is available is in marked contrast to the view that what is to be
controlled is the quantity of some particular set of financial instruments.

The money quantity view dows not center around the

question of how in fact does the price system operate in these markets;
the financial markets view does.
The above suggestion —
at the discount window —

that the dealers be allowed to borrow

is one step toward going

lI

British.n

The

other step would be to bar money market banks from the discount window.
The British technique makes it obvious that it is the residual pressures
in some markets that force borrowing from the central bank.

In addition,

because banks, barred from the discount window, will want to have some
claims on the market that has recourse to the window, the pooling of
reserves will become obvious.
A by-product of "Going British11 would be to make very precise
the point at which the debtor constraint upon the borrower at the Federal
Reserve System enters financial markets.

Debtor constraint would enter

by way of the carrying costs for dealers in eligible paper; the first




- 80 -

pressure would be on position taking in such paper by way of the
financing of the position.

If eligibility for discounting is restricted

to Treasury bills and perhaps bankers1 acceptances, market pressures
would first tend to affect security prices and the costs of taking
position in financial markets.

In particular the financing costs of

underwriting nex? private issues will be affected.

Within such an

institutional framework, the loan portfolio of banks would be better
insulated from transitory reserve pressures than with current practices.
Federal Reserve practices —
market operations or discounting —
pattern.

whether they be called open

should not be frozen into a rigid

The Federal Reserve really has somewhat inconsistent re-

sponsibilities.

One is to accept the market as is in determining the

techniques that will use to feed reserves into the System,

The second

is by discriminating among instruments, and by having ever-evolving
doctrines of eligibility to guide the evolution of the market in a
direction that is desired by some criteria, based upon its views as
to the relation between financial practices and the growth, stability,
efficacy, and income distribution characteristics of the economy.
Perhaps the most important aspect of taking * the market as
it is

in determining the technique the Federal Reserve will use is

to recognize that the domain of responsibility of the Federal Reserve
System is the entire financial system of the United States, not just
member banks,




(To the extent that the role of the dollar as an

~ 81 -

international reserve currency is taken seriously, the domain of
responsibility is the world's financial system.)

The interrelations

among the various financial institutions is clearly a Federal Reserve
concern when the role of the Federal Reserve as lender of last resort
is considered.

The special roje of commercial and more narrowly member

banks as a Federal Reserve responsbility lies in the peculiar fact that
the Federal Reserve can, in the short run, effectively control changes
in the amount of reserve money in existence, and thus set upper limits
to net new position taking by banks.

Any effective lender of last

resort or even a defensive operation by the Federal Reserve System
affects commercial bank portfolios.
At present Federal Reserve practices have to assimilate the
fact that negotiable CD ! s are a significant portion of the liabilities
of money market banks.

These instruments, while falling under the

heading of time deposits, are in many ways the most volatile of commercial
bank liabilities.

Even though individual demand deposits may be volatile,

in total the volume of demand deposits is quite stable.
CD's, the total outstanding is quite volatile.

In the case of

The volume outstanding

is sensitive to interest-rate differentials, and in addition there is a
tendency for due dates to bunch.

If serious liquidity squeezes upon

commercial banks are going to occur in the near future, it seems quite
likely that these certificates will be the source of the squeeze.

Any

liquidity squeeze for the System as a whole from CD's will reflect the




-.82--

difference in reserves required by demand deposits and CD's,

If dealers

with Federal Reserve discounting rights are in a position to take up
CD's either from the market or from issuing banks without limit, then
the potential pressure on bank liquidity from the bunching of CD's can
be constrained.

That is, the growth of negotiable CD's as a major

financial instrument may very well make it more vital than earlier that
the discount window be opened to money market agencies, rather than be
restricted to commercial banks:

however, it may also require making

CD's eligible perhaps by being endorsed by a money market dealer.
It may be useful to use CD's to illustrate the somewhat "split"
responsibility of the Federal Reserve.

If negotiable CD f s like Topsy

were allowed to grow, the Fed's immediate responsibility is to make sure
that no cumulative deflationary pressure results from these instruments.
There should be no "pass through" of pressure from banks either to
security markets or to borrowers from any volatility in the volume or
location of these deposits.
open to the Federal Reserve:

In the longer run two possibilities are
one is to encourage the continuation of

the CD, the other is to induce the banking system to unwind its commitment to CD's.

In either case a temporary pressure on bank ability

to hold assets should be offset.

To encourage CD's, the Federal Reserve

might stand ready, as previously indicated, to finance positions in
CD's by dealers on terms that will normally enable the dealers to make
on the carry of CD's and to stand ready to refinance positions in CD's




~ 83-

(if there

s a rising term structure) that normally are financed by

other means,

Once again, very short-term corporate and bank funds will

be the usual source of financing normal positions in CD's, and an
extraordinary market condition will lead to the financing of dealer
positions by borrowing from the Federal Reserve,
If it is the view of the Federal Reserve that CD's are volatile
deposits that are capable of generating undesired financial instability,
then a turly penal rate for financing positions in CD's should be
instituted.

Perhaps a shifting reserve requirement that recognizes the

volatility of maturing CD's may be introduced.

For example, the reserve

requirement of CD's at reserve city banks with more than 90 days to run
may be the same (4 per cent) as for passbook savings; for CD's with
between 90 and 60 days to maturity a 7 per cent reserve requirement may
be instituted; for CD's with between 60 and 30 days to go, the reserve
requirement may be set at 10 per cent; between 30 days and 14 days the
rate may be 13 per cent axid for DC f s with less than 14 days to maturity,
the reserve requirement would be the same as against demand deposits
(for country banks similar steps in reserve requirements would be in
effect).

Only if CD's are refunded when they still have 90 days to go

will the full reserve saving be available.
The Federal Reserve!s essential discriminating policy is to
determine whether it will encourage or discourage any market usage:
this may be more important than its discretionary power with respect to
quantity of reserves or the discount rate.




- 84 <*
II.

Comments on Specific Questions,'

1.

See general comment.

2.

Reserves are fed into the national market by rediscounting,

however, the Federal Reserve can determine what type of paper is eligible.
The discounting mechanism enables the central bank to favor particular
types of paper.

If the Federal Reserve wants interest rates on mortgage

loans to be lower than on other paper, it can achieve this goal by buying
and discounting this paper at favorable terms.

3.

I suggest a rising rate to the market participant borrower

as a function of his borrowing; however free access at discretionary
rates may be better,

4.

Any instrument could be used in open market operations.

In particular there is no reason why the Federal Reserve should not buy
and sell Federal funds on the open market.

Such dealing in the Federal

funds market may be another way of separating the dynamic from the
transitory introduction of reserves.

5.

Basically, eligibility is a form of protection and hence

subsidy to a particular market instrument*

If market dealers can use

the window, the leigibility is a determinant of their portfolio.

Thus

the criteria are what type of paper and therefore what type of underlying transaction do you want to support.




6.

In my general comment I indicated that the System would

be stronger if it were recognized that it is the market rather than a
particular bank that borrows.

It may be desirable to classify banks

as money market banks and other, depending upon their type of business.
Money market banks would not be able to borrow directly from the Federal
Reserve; the others would.

7.

Once again, it might be better for the Federal Reserve to

lend only to market operators.

8.

a.

Instrument differentials might be desirable; any

regional differential is a type of instrument differential.

The

criteria obviously are who and what do we want to subsidize.
b.

Same answer as 'a 1 .

c.

Once again, thinking in terms of a bank borrowing may be

misleading.

d.

No comment.

e.

No comment.

f.

No comment.

g.

The issue of paying interest on reserves mixes up reserves

and other assets.

The function of reserves and the reserve ratios is to

determine the amount of earning assets the banking system can acquire.




- 36 -

Offhand, the present technique works quite well in parcelling the ability
to acquire assets among the various banks; hence I do not see any sense
in trying to change from a system in which such reserves exist.

The

only possible reason for paying interest on reserves is if it is felt
that bankers deserve a subsidy.

It may be desirable to have the

Federal Reserve pay interest on reserve balances in exchange for the
elimination of service charges on checks.




- 37 Mddigliani
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Preliminaty Notes on the Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism
and Discount Policies

1.

Framework
In answering the questions raised in the memorandum, I rely

on the following general framework*

By and large, open market policy

is the most useful and effective device for controlling the amount of
reserves available to member banks.

Accordingly, I would propose to

design a discount window mechanise and a discount rate and related
policies which would tend to minimize fluctuations in free reserves-either in absolute terms or in relation to the total monetary base.
At the same time, the system must retain, through the discount x^indow,
the role of the central bank as a lender of last resort*

From this

framework the following implications seem to follow.

2.

How to Regulate the Discount Rate
Since there is a fair amount of a priori reasoning and

empirical evidence to suggest that the bank borrowing is positively
associated with the spread between short-term market yields and the
rediscount rate, I favor making that spread a constant as nearly as
possible.

Accordingly, I would advocate tying the discount rate to

the 3-month bill rate.

Specifically, the base level of the discount

rate should be set a fixed number of basis points above the bill
rate [I have not thought out what the appropriate spread should b e } .
I refer to "base level11 because, as noted below, I also favor a systemof




- 88 -

penalty tates.

Under the proposed set-up, the rediscount rate would

fluctuate continuously and automatically, thus also avoiding announcement effects which, on the whole, I regard as a nuisance,

I do feel

that under many circumstances the central bank could further its
goals by explaining to the market what it is trying to do.

But this

should be done explicitly and not through the devious device of discount change announcements, which the market must then interpret as best
it can.

3.

Limiting the Use of the Discount Window
Because I favor minimizing the volume as well as fluctua-

tions of borrowing by member banks, it is important to find ways of
limiting this practice.

Fixing the rate above the bill rate will

help but may not prove sufficient.

I therefore favor a schedule of

penalty rates above the base rate, although I have not thought out
in detail the structure of the penalty.

At the same time, I would

favor facilitating borrowing, as long as the bank is willing to pay
the price.

I would, therefore, be very liberal in the kind of secur-

ity that should be acceptable to the central bank as collateral.

It

is also obvious that the borrowing rate should be independent of the
collateral.

Also, because I am anxious to encourage all banks to

become members of the System, I would recommend limiting borrowing
privileges to member banks in good standing.




- 89 4.

Payment of Interest on Excess Reserves
While I have not thought this problem out completely, I am

inclined to favor payment of interest on excess reserves at a rate
tied to the bill rate and hence to the base rediscount rate.

I favor

this because it would probably tend to reduce fluctuations in excess
reserves, a desirable goal in order to stabilize free reserves.

In

fact, under present arrangements, when short-term market yields, such
as the bill rate, are low, banks —particularly country banks—tend to
hold a relatively large volume of excess reserves since the opportunity cost of these reserves is roughly measurable by market yields.

As

the bill rate and other market yields go up, banks tend to reduce the
amount of these excess reserves.

Suppose on the other hand that they

received interest, say r e , on their excess reserves, and let r be a
representative short-term market yield (say, the bill rate, or the
Federal funds rate).
below r.

Suppose that we can fix r e at a fixed discount

Then, under the new set-up, the opportunity cost of holding

excess reserves would be r - r
e

which, by construction would be roughly
' J

a constant, independent of r.
It should be noted that under the present set-up, the Federal
funds market effectively provides a way by which banks can earn a
return on their surplus reserves and that this return is automatically
tied to short-term market rates.

However, the Federal funds market is

not too readily accessible to small country banks.

A payment of interest

on excess reserves would also tend to equalize the opportunities for
banks of all sizes.




I realize, of course, that there are a number of problems
posed by the interest payroeot suggestion, which I have not thought
out fully.

In particular, how could r

be set?

If we want to continue

the present system in which banks, rather than the Federal Reserve,
are encouraged to hold bills, then presumably r
what below the bill rate.
rate?

should be set some-

How should it relate to the Federal funds

I doubt that it should be directly tied to daily fluctuations

in the Federal funds rate, but tying r e to some average of the daily
rate might be sensible.

One also runs into the difficulty that, if

r e is below market rates, then when market rates become low enough,
r e would hit zero and could not be reduced any further.

This is un-

fortunate, but what it merely implies is that this reform cannot
eliminate liquidity-trap phenomena-sunless one took the radical step
of making r e negative (levying a penalty on excess reserves) when
market yields become really low.1




- 91 Walter A. Morton
University of Wisconsin
1. Discount policy should continue to have the dual role of
accommodating the individual bank and of regulating the total volume of
bank reserves for the purpose of maintaining the appropriate volume of
money and of liquidity,
2.

At present the ability of the large banks operating in a

national market to obtain deposits through use of negotiable CD f s makes
it desirable to keep open to individual banks throughout the nation the
ability to replenish reserves when necessary and desirable. The use of
the CD could shift deposits to the financial centers and with that shift
would drain outlying or smaller banks of their reserves.

These banks

could counter by selling secondary reserve assets or by also issuing CD's,
However, I believe that it is desirable to make it possible for such
banks to borrow directly from the Federal Reserve.
To me the central fact about the growth of CD's is that the
deposits of a bank need no longer be closely related to the community
in which they operate. A strong bank can draw deposits from the whole
nation if it wishes to pay a high enough deposit rate.
Discounting should be, as in the past, at the initiative of
the member banks. However, the Fed. must put restraint upon the volume
of discounting by traditional means when it is used to expand the total
volume of reserves beyond the desired amount.

Whole states or regions

may be accorded liberal discounting privileges when, in fact, employment




could be increased in such regions by use of otherwise idle resources*
Discounting then must remain a means of creating a truly fluid national
money market in which the resources of individual institutions in
financial centers do not unduly influence the operations of other less
powerful institutions in other parts of the country*

I do not believe,

however, that it is feasible, and for the most part it is not desirable,
to use the discount mechanism for qualitative control of credit or for
the allocation of resources.

If that use should be necessary, and I

hope not, it should be done by other devices.
3.

I would regard the discount mechanism as supplementary to

open market operations and alterations of required reserve ratios.

I

do not believe that the height of the discount rate is as important as
the decision of the Federal Reserve at various times to make credit
more or less freely available. We have ample experience of countries
continuing to inflate with short-term interest rates as high as 15 per
cent.

A high discount rate does not stop credit expansion if the money

is made available to finance expansion at an inflationary pace.

Under

those circumstances, because of expected higher prices, the nominal
marginal efficiency of capital rises faster than interest rates.
I believe emphasis should not be placed upon the level of
interest rates as a guide to policy but on the quantity of money and
of liquid assets with respect to the volume of unemployed resources
and the resulting delfationary or inflationary tendencies.




- 93*Depending upon the circumstances, the tradition against
continual borrowing should be invoked to prevent inflation or it
should be overlooked when borrowing is used in particular localities
to expand the volume of employment without inflation.
It requires a tight ropewalker to balance the individual with
the national interest, but the Federal Reserve Governors did not accept
their appointments because they thought the job was easy.

By now,

they also know that although there may be guideposts, there is no
simple rule that will save them from errors of judgment.
I do not believe that any fundamental change should be made
from the recent practice whereby monetary policy is determirfid basically
by open market operations, and rediscounting is used by individual
institutions to adjust their reserve positions,
4,

Because I do not believe it to be a prime objective of

the Federal Reserve to affect the level of structure of interest rates,
I would not use open market operations to do so,

I agree, of course,

that changes in reserve positions will affect interest rates, but I
would regard the latter as a result of polic y determined by other
objectives.
While I would not dogmatically adhere to the "bills preferably11
doctrine and would buy assets of various maturities, I still hold the
view that the Federal Reserve should not attempt to directly determine
long-term interest rates.




It should influence member banks reserves

* 94 and leave it to market d6fcand to determine the level of rates and to
expectations to determine the structure of rates.

I would be opposed

to a direct attempt to set the long-term bond rate. That action would
bring a return to the conditions before the Accord which, unfortunately,
some are now beginning to forget.

In a national liquidity crisis, no

rules would hold, and the Federal Reserve might have to buy anything.
At present there is no need to depart from the practice of buying
government securities with a maturity of 5 years of less.
5«

I see no reason for applying different rediscount rates

to different kinds of assets. The Federal Reserve should continue to
insist on government securities or on business paper of good quality
without the limitation implied by the "commercial paper11 theory*
in an emergency it should lend M on any satisfactory asset.11

But

In any

case, it should maintain the position that rediscounting is a "privilege11
and not a "right.11
6.

Consequently, the Federal Reserve must retain the right

of determining how much, how often, and how long a bank can borrow.

As

mentioned under (2) the Federal Reserve must prevent a squeeze upon
any bank or any region.

Such a squeeze might permit the bank or region

to remain in debt for a long time.

But the basic consideration must be

the same as for total credit policy, the effect on total member bank
reserves and on total output and employment.

I do not believe it wise

to establish either by law or by rule any definite rule concerning these
matters.




- 95 -

7.
question.

I have not enough first-hand knowledge to answer this

I am inclined to the view that the Federal Reserve should

lend only to banks but its lending to nonmember banks would depend upon
the effects that might have on interbank relations and upon membership
in the Federal Reserve System.

For the most part, I do not believe

that the small country banks are in need of this assistance.

But I

would modify my opinion if there is evidence to the contrary.

80

af

Discount rates should be uniform nationally, except

where there is strong evidence that some locality needs differential
treatment in the national interest.

The criterion for such differential

treatment would be the need for additional loans in the area to stimulate
employment or conversely the need for restrant to correct a dangerous
inflationary tendency.

On the whole, I believe that a uniform rate,

with, however, lending policies operated by the district Federal
Reserve Bank so as to encourage or restraint member bank borrowing is
the best way of bring about the desired influence.

But I would not be

dogmatic about it if that method proved too difficult or ineffective.

b.

Rates should be uniform on all types of paper.

However,

the Federal Reserve should be able to warn member banks or to refuse
loans if they bring in inferior paper.

c.

No,

The amount borrowed should be controlled primarily

by the needs of national monetary policy and/or the peculiar needs of




96

a bank or region.

The same is true of the duration of borrowing.

All

other criteria, except some mechanical rule which related borrowing to
total assets, would be difficult to administer and would not serve a
national monetary purpose,

d.

The only criterion for determining the disc ount rate is

the effect of the rate on the willingness to borrow.

But what u the market11 is will depend on

market encourages borrowing.
the demand for credit.

A rate below the

Presuably, a discount rate above the bill rate

would prevent borrowing to buy bills, but only one above the prime
rate would inhibit borrowing to lend to customers.

I do not believe it

possible to set in advance the particular market rate to which the redicount rate should be related.

It could be the bill rate, the CD

rate, the prime rate, or even the customer's rate.

In the event of an

inflationary tendency the rediscount rate should be set above the highest
of these rates.

In case of large unemployment, it should be set at

whatever rate will stimulate borrowing without promoting reserves so
excessive that they might later result in excessive expansion and inflation.

I believe the right rediscount rate during depression is low

but just how low depends primarily on the volume of excess reserves.

e.

At present the

l!

announcementl! effect seems to be that the

Federal Reserve is determining what level of interest rates should
prevail.




That I think undesirable.

I believe it would be preferable

- 97 *
for restraint to be placed by open market operations to be followed by
a higher discount rate. That is the opposite from the December 1965
policy which seemed to put the discount rate up first, followed a few
months later by gentle restraint. The main effect of this procedure
has been to make the Fed "responsible11 for higher interest rates and
still make them open to the criticism that they are doing nothing to
prevent inflation.

f,

Past practice of changing the discount rate seems to me

to be quite satisfactory.

g,

Interest on member bank reserve balances would tend to

destroy the Federal funds market.

Unless there was a rate advantage

a bank would not lend Federal funds. Hence, the banks now borrowing
Federal funds would be forced to rediscount,

I feel sure the banks

would adapt themselves to any new rule, but I believe the net effect
of interest on deposits in the Federal Reserve would be a larger volume
of total reserve holdings. Seeing no advantage to this, I would not
favor a change.




- 98 Lawrence S. Ritter
New York University

I have no strong views about the discount rate or window,
and I have no real objections to the way the discount mechanism has
been employed in the past decade.

I think the so-called penalty rate

is a bit of a mirage--penalty relative to what?--and do not espouse a
floating rate (as Canada had) nor a variable differential as some have
proposed from time to time.

The reason I feel this way is because to

a large extent it is like a dog chasing its own tail.

Since the

Federal Reserve can substantially influence the bill rate by its other
policies, one is sort of kidding himself to say, "If the bill rate goes
above the discount rate, the latter must be raised."

The bill rate

goes above the discount rate in part when the Federal Reserve wants it
to, and usually at such times the Federal Reserve will want to raise
the discount rate as well in order to re-inforce its policies.

There

should not be any automatic compulsion that this need always be done,
however.
I am very much against closing the discount window (a la
Friedman), for I think it serves a useful and necessary purpose in
easing pressures on the banking system where and when those pressures
are greatest.
All this is more or less by way of saying that pre-1966
administration of the discount rate and discount policy has been suitable in my view.
made.




I see no important changes which I think should be

- 99 -

On the subject of eligibility provisions, however, I would
very much liice to see a change in the law.

Present eligibility

provisions are a hangover from the days of the real bills doctrine
and should be completely eliminated.

I would like to see the law

changed so that the Reserve BanKs could—without any rate differential
--lend on the basis of any "satisfactory" collateral.

Legislation has

been introduced by the Federal Reserve to this effect several times,
but nothing has come of it so far.
By the way, I still favor legislation requiring all bankd
to be members of the Federal Reserve System, or failing that, requiring all banks to hold such reserves as the Federal Reserve specifies
and then permitting all of them access to the discount window.




- 100 -

Roland I, Robinson
Michigan State University

My suggestions are as follows:
Question 1.

Discounting is just one of several ways of

adjusting the money positions of banks.

The fact that it is the

only way that also influences the total volume of bank reserves is
of almost no consequence to the individual bank unless it becomes
sensitive to direct pressure by the discount administrator of its
Federal Reserve bank.
Question 2,

For the Federal Reserve the discount mechanism

is primarily a safety mechanism.

If harsh and aggressive open market

action is needed--or if reserve requirements should need to be
increased—the discount window would help banks that are unusually
heavily affected.

Miscalculations have less impact.

One exception

• ••
Question 3»

The announcement effect of changing the discount

rate does have some helpful aspects and, in my opinion, is worth retaining.

However, I should like to see these rate changes made so as to

keep the level of discount rates just a little above the comparable
money market rates, such as bill yields and the CD rates offered by
banks.

I should not want a harsh penalty rate but one that removes

profit reasons for wishing to use the discount facility,

I still think

it strange to have the Federal funds rate even occassionally above the
discount rate.




- 101 -

Question 4.

The administration of the discount window

would not be so paternal if rates were a bit higher.

Neither of

the two extreme words--"right" and "privilege"—in the foreward to
Regulation A is helpful.

Banks need some reluctance to stay in

debt or else the Federal Reserve would lose its initiative with
open market operations.

But to have some banks never use the dis-

count facility is too extreme also.

Empirical work by the Federal

Reserve on the extent of use of the facility would be useful.
Questions 5 to 8.

I see little reason for broadening

the type of assets used by the Federal Reserve for open market
operations.

Our public debt is big enough; any other form would

raise questions about relative interest rates—and I don't like
the Federal Reserve tampering with relative rates.

I also see no

need for attempts to move funds regionally; our capital markets do
this very well automatically.




- 10? -

James R. Schlesinger
RAND Corporation

Excerpt from a letter from Dr. Schlesinger:
There is one matter on which I should like to express a
tentative judgment.

Given the existing institutional arrangements,

I believe that major benefits could be obtained by freeing the
discount rate from the month-to-month administrative determination
and having it float in some steady relationship to the average
Treasury bill rate in some preceding period.

The episode of last

December 1965 had a special impact in impressing upon me the
political rigidity involved in administrative determination.

The

lagging adjustment of the discount rate indicates that deleterious
financial consequences occurred because of apprehension of untoward
political consequences.

Moreover, when adjustment of the discount

rate is finally made, a political furor is likely to result, a furor
which is wholly disproportionate to the real significance of the
action taken.

I feel that these political distrubances can be

avoided and the discount mechanism can function more smoothly, if
the rate is permitted to move automatically.
In the United States the discount mechanism necessarily
plays a more limited role than its British counterpart; yet many of
hoary beliefs in the community regarding the initial importance of the
discount rate reflect misleading inferences drawn from the British
shilling.




The Federal Reserve discount rate is at present essentially

James R. Schlesinger — 1*03

a derivative rate, which should appropriately be adjusted to its own
place within the structure of money market rates.

Its role is the negative

one of avoiding the provision of dysfunctional incentives within the money
market.

The existing procedure, however, results in the poor

and risky fulfillment of this limited function.

If the fanfare (and

the fears) associated with the raising of the discount rate could
be avoided, the discount function could be performed far more
efficiently.

The automatic and continual adjustment of the rate

within the rate structure would go a long way toward alleviating this
problem.
action.

I realize that such a change might require legislative
It would also result in a further reduction of the responsi-

bilities of the district banks, but this consequence may not be
altogether undesirable.
From what I have said, I think you will gather that I do
not regard as very desirable the transformation of the discount
mechanism and its bolder employment to stimulate or restraint credit
expansion.

While some case can be made for such action, I think

we can rely on open market operations as fully adequate in this
connection.
So much for the broader problem:
relatively minor observations.

let me make two other

First, I think that the eligibility

requirements are both obsoltte and unduly restrictive.

I would be

inclined to fulfill the promise of the Banking Act of 1935 and to
make borrowing permissible on almost any sound asset at the normal




James R. Schlesinger --

rate.

In the course of this, I would drastically simplify the paper-

work associated with the borrowing process.

Second, I would make

less use of acceptability or other devices for curtailing access
by member banks to Federal Reserve credit.

I think that such

devices lead to the possibility of discrimination among banks,
which is excessive, which can have untoward consequences, and
which is not essential to the achievement of the purposes of the
Federal Reserve System.




- 105 -

Ira 0, Scott, Jr.

Question 1,

The discount window should remain as an instrument of the
central bank in its role as lender of last resort.

Because

of its effect on monetary variables, the discount rate
should be shifted according to over-all stabilization needs.
Although I do not feel there should be a change in the use
of discount policy, I believe the mechanism should be
changed.

Specifically I believe we should adopt a penalty

rate system and that funds should be made available freely
to the borrowing bank at the penalty rate.

This would

eliminate the undesirable arbitrary elements in the administration of the discount window.

question 2.

Discount accomodation should be an important source of
liquidity to individual banks and regions but at a cost in
excess of the return on short-term credit instruments.

Dis-

counting should not be used to influence the allocation of
credit among banks, regions, or types of assets.

Question 3.




The discount rate should be the sole regulator of the volume
of credit extended.

As suggested earlier, a penalty-rate

system should be introduced,

I would not, however, favor an

automatic penalty system such as the one which has been used
in Canada,

Rate changes should be made at the discretion of

the Federal Reserve System,

- 105 -

v\iestion 4»

I do not favor the acquisition of assets other than U.S.
securities by the F.0#M.C.

Juestion g-

I believe the Federal Reserve System should be free to
ascertain the elibibility and acceptability of collateral
to be used at the discount window.

Indeed, System officials

should be given the authority to liberalize the criteria
sufficiently to prevent a general liquidity crisis should
one threaten again.

jfoftsfiion—6.

A bank should be permitted to borrow as much and as long
as it wishes from the Federal Reserve at a penalty rate.

•Question 7.

The Federal Reserve should lend to the primary dealers in
U.S. securities as well as to member banks.

Question 8«




a. Discount rates should be uniform nationally.
b. The rates should be uniform on all types of paper offered.
c. The rates should not be graduated.
d. The present method of changing discount rates should be
maintained.
e.

fl

The announcement effects11 of discount rate changes

should be preserved.
f. The frequency and size of credit changes should be
determined by economic conditions.

In general I would

see no need for a marked change in present practice.




- L07 -

g. 1 believe there might be merit in studying the possibility
of interest on reserves held in the form of deposits.

Such

a practice might be accompanied by granting permission to
member banks to pay interest on their own demand liabilities.
The Federal Reserve System might also consider accepting
time deposits.

- 108 Richard T. Selden
University of Virginia

The following responses to Professor Chandler's suggested
questions are rather brief and assertive; unfortunately I have not
been able to spend the amount of time on these subjects that would
be necessary for a full and carefully reasoned treatment.

I never-

theless hope that these responses will be of some help to the Board
in its timely study of the discount mechanism.
Question 1.

In my judgment the discount mechanism does not,

and should not, play a major role in the United States,

Its only

importance would seem to flow from the following considerations:
a.

Member bank borrowing constitutes a

ir

leakage!!.

It

tends to undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy since
it weakens Federal Reserve control over the volume of bank
reserves and hence over the volume of money (and credit); this
is especially apt to be true if discount rates are changed
only infrequently, while open market rates are experiencing
fairly wide swings,
b.

On the other hand, a change in the discount rate is

a dramatic and well-publicized action which is noted throughout the economy.

Moreover, because it is a point of contact

between the Federal Reserve and member banks, the discount
window may provide useful information about the economic
climate.

Finally, the mere existence of the discount facility

probably exerts some cairaing effect on the economy, somewhat in
the same manner as deposit insurance.




- 109 -

None of these considerations seem terribly significant.
Perhaps the supposed advantages under (b) could be retained while
.aost of the disadvantages in (a) are eliminated by converting the
discount rate into a true penalty rate which would be kept approximately 2 percentage points above the rate on Treasury bills.
Another possible means of checking abuses of the discount privilege
would be to prohibit all growth in a bank f s earning assets so long
as it is in debt to the Federal Reserve.

However, such a prohibition

would be inferior, in my opinion, to the establishment of a flexible
penalty rate.
Question 2.

I do not believe that complete elimination of

the discount facility would have any drastic effect on individual bank
operations, in view of the wide range of alternative sources of funds.
Initially there would probably be an increased desire to hold excess
reserves, but I would not expect wide fluctuations in excess reserves
over time.

It is possible, however, that some small banks would be

hit hard by elimination of discounting; participation in the Federal
funds and CD markets would be expensive or impossible for many of
our smallest banks.

Hence, any such proposal would undoubtedly

encounter strong resistance.
I see no reason why the discount mechanism should not be
preserved, as suggested in question 1 above, as a source of funds that
would be attractive only to banks that are faced with bona fide
emergencies,
With respect to the use of discount policy as a form of
selective credit control, experience elsewhere indicates that such an




110 -

apprbach could have substantial effects on the pattern of allocation
of credit.

Nevertheless I would be disturbed by any tendency for

discount policy to evolve in the direction of selectivity, because
of the danger that the end result would be pervasive public controls
over the allocation of capital.

In general I am not impressed by

the alleged need for regional or other selectivity in economic
policy, and insofar as there is such a need I would prefer that it
be realized by means other than monetary and credit policies.
Question 3,

In my judgment the discount mechanism should

operate as nearly as possible in accordance with clearly stated
objective rules that apply to all banks.

Aside from the possibility

mentioned in question 1, that a bank should not be permitted to
expand its earning assets while it is in debt to the Federal Reserve,
I would recommend virtually complete reliance on the discount rate as
a rationing mechanism.

It would be wise, perhaps, to maintain the

distinction between a "right" and a "privilege,11 so that Federal
Reserve credit could be shut off in the event of unforeseen contingencies.

However, I see no reason why the notion of "reluctance11

should be nurtured by Federal Reserve officials.

Set the rate and

allow banks to borrow as much as they see fit.
Question 4.

I believe that the Federal Reserve should be

empowered to buy and sell a wide range of financial claims, including
commercial paper, corporate and municipal bonds, and mortgages.

It

is conceivable that on some future occasion the Federal Reserve's
power to determine the volume of bank reserves would be impaired under




- Ill -

present rules.

However, I regard this as a very remote possibil-

ity.
While I have no firmly held views with regard to "bills
only,11 for two reasons I would favor primary reliance on Treasury
bills for open market operations.

First, the immediate effects on

the prices of the securities traded is much less important than the
impact on the availability of bank credit through the creation or
destruction of bank reserves; the latter impact can be achieved by
operations in either bills or bonds.

Second, since the market for

bills is much broader and much more active than the markets for longterm securities, the Federal Reserve can best carry out its open
market operations without disrupting normal trading drastically if
these operations are confined to bills.
Question 5.

I favor the proposed amendment to the Federal

Reserve Act which would permit the Federal Reserve to accept any bank
asset as collateral for discounts and advances.

Indeed, I see no

reason why the Federal Reserve should not be permitted to make unsecured
loans to member banks.
Question 6.

As I have already indicated, under a flexible

penalty rate, the volume and frequency of borrowing would be determined by the borrowing bank, although the Federal Reserve would maintain
the right to refuse accommodation.

I see no need to alter the present

rules regarding the maturity of borrowings.
Question 7.

I x^ould like to see the Federal Reserve have

authority to lend to a wide range of nonbank lenders, purely as an




- 11? -

emergency measure that might come in handy during some future crisis.
Extension of borrowing privileges to nonmembers during normal periods
would seem to eliminate the principal advantage that a bank now gets
from membership.

Under these circumstances membership would become

largely meaningless.
Question 3.
a.

Uniform nationally.

b.

Uniform for all collateral.

c.

Graduated rates would be unnecessary under my proposal.

d.

I would favor weekly establishment of the discount rate

by the Board of Governors.

I would recommend that the Board

normally set the rate 2 percentage points above the weekly
auction rate on 132-day Treasury bills; however, this margin
would be determined by the Board, not by any legislative mandate.
e.

The announcement effects should be reduced and, more

generally, the mystique that enshrouds central banking should
be removed.

The principal means of reducing the announcement

effects of discount rate changes is to make such changes much
more frequently than at present.
f.

More often, by smaller steps.

g»

At present member banks are, in effect, being taxed

for the privilege of operating in a regulated industry which,
as a matter of public policy, io protected from certain normal
business risks.

Moreover, if the Federal Reserve were to begin

paying interest on reserve balances, present holders of bank




- 113 -

stock would enjoy very sizable capital gains.

Hence I am not

enthusiastic about paying interest on total member bank reserves.
However, the payment of interest on excess reserves only
is a proposal that merits closer study.

The gains conferred

upon bank owners would be comparatively small; yet the functioning of monetary policy might be improved somewhat since banks
would have much less incentive than at present to vary their
excess reserves in a cyclically de-stabilizing manner.

It might

be wise to limit interest payments to individual banks to (say)
the prevailing discount rate as applied to the first 4 or 5 per
cent of excess reserves (taken as a percentage of required
reserves).




- 114 Eli Shapiro and William L. White
Harvard University

The Federal Reserve discount mechanism and discount policies
should have as their purpose the provision of liquidity to the commercial
banks in this country.

1.

Banks1 needs for liquidity arise at three levels:

(1)

There may be a national liquidity need arising
from either domestic or external events which
could be characterized as a systemic need for
liquidity.

(2)

The banks in a region may find themselves pressed
for liquidity arising from economic events that
affect the entire regionf

(3)

The individual bank may need liquidity for any of
a variety of reasons,

National Liquidity Needs
Discount policy by the Federal Reserve System should deal

only with the last two of these problems, but not the first.

In the

event of the need for systemic liquidity, the Federal Reserve System
should follow B&gehot's dictum and move with alacrity, vigor, and
courage by engaging in open market operations in any assets and in a
sufficient order of magnitude to avert a liquidity crisis.
2. and 3.

Liquidity Needs of Individual Banks and of Banks in a Region
For an individual bank or for banks in a region subject to

needs for liquidity, there are three sources of liquidity:




(1)

The liquidity of the portfolio. (As explained
later, our suggestion for discount policy would
still provide incentives for the bank to be concerned about the liquidity of its portfolio,
since it would secure liquidity by discounting
at the expense of growth in its assets so long
as it is in debt to the Federal Reserve.)

- 115 -

(2)

The banks 1 ability to compete for funds. In this
connection we would urge the complete elimination
of the interest ceiling on time and savings
deposits, thereby freeing the banks to plan to
incur additional costs in competing for funds when
their portfolio provisions are inadequate to meet
their liquidity needs. We are ambivalent about
eliminating the prohibition of the payment of
interest on demand deposits. However, if pressed,
we would opt for the elimination of this prohibition. Payment of interest on demand deposits would
allow individuals and businesses to treat money as
an earning asset in their portfolio choices and
would lessen uneconomic switches from demand
deposits to time and savings deposits and vice
versa.

(3)

We have developed a viable national market in Federal
funds which enables individual banks or banks in a
region to secure temporary access to liquidity.

It is in terms of these existing capacities for meeting the
liquidity needs of individual banks or banks in a region that discount
policies should be formulated.




Our views are as follows:

(1)

Discount policy should be changed to provide
individual banks or banks in a region subject to
liquidity needs with the right to obtain the
necessary liquidity by discounting any asset they
hold with the Federal Reserve Bank. It is imperative that we eliminate the notion of eligible paper
which is a vestigial remain of the commercial loan
theory which has plagued central banking in this
country since 1913.

(2)

In giving the individual banks the right to
discount any asset, we much insure that the Federal
Reserve does not lose active control over the reserve
base. Therefore, any bank in debt to the Federal
Reserve should not be allowed to increase its assets
so long as it remains in debt. This would assure
that discounting is used to meet liquidity needs as
opposed to supporting asset expansion.
Since the bank in debt is punished by not being able
to expand its assets, the interest rate at which it
can discount is not critical. But to encourage the
individual banks to use the proceeds of loan repayment or new deposit inflows to retire their




- 116 -

indebtedness to the Federal Reserve, we would
tie the discount rate to the Treasury bill rate
and have it move automatically with changes in
the bill rate.
While we appreciate that the bill rate is subject
to a whole series of influences and therefore may
not be a perfect measure of underlying money
market conditions, it is adequate for our needs.
Such a tie would have the added advantage of avoiding the current problems of the "announcement
effects" of changes in the discount rate by the
Federal Reserve.
An alternative proposal would be to use a punitive
schedule of rates where the punishment is a function
of both the size aad the duration of the discounting.
This policy would require open-market operations by
the Federal Reserve to assure control over the overall reserve position of the banking system. In our
judgment the punitive rate(s) is a less desirable
choice than the proposal outlined above.
A third choice would be to pay interest on commercial
bank reserve balances at the Federal Reserve. We
think this is even more awkward and less certain to
provide liquidity than either of the two alternatives
above.
(3)

We recognize that the small bank would find it more
difficult than would a large bank to secure liquidity
by using promissory notes, CD f s, or borrowing in the
Federal funds market. Moreover, if the liquidity
need pertains to a region, the individual bank in
that region will have even more difficulty in securing liquidity through the financial markets* Thus,
the r
i%ht to rediscount with the Federal Reserve is
a necessary concomitant of the banking structure in
the United States and the need to provide liquidity
to the individual banks.

(4)

The allocation of credit among banks, regions, and
types of uses should be made by the individual banks,
not by the Federal Reserve System. Discriminatory
discount policy should not be used for this purpose.




- 117 -

(5)

The right to discount should be available to all
commercial banks in the United States. However, as
a condition for the availability of this right, the
banks must join the Federal Reserve System. Such a
proposal would preclude the existence of the "dual
banking system" from interfering with the provision
of liquidity to commercial banks by the Federal
Reserve System.

- 118 -

Edward C. Simmons
Formerly of
Duke University

Question 1,

Unfortunately there is widespread confusion as to what

is meant by monetary policy.

To me monetary policy means controlling

the size of the stock of money.

It is really the only reason to

have a central bank in a market economy.

Without a central bank the

volume of money would behave capriciously because money today
consists primarily of demand deposit claims against profit-seeking
commercial banks.
When the central bank acts to control the size of the stock
of money, money rates may tend to shift about and also the ease with
which borrowers can obtain funds for various purposes may alter.
But it must be understood that the central bank does not exist to
produce such phenomena.

They are merely incidental, although some

persons have tried to make out that the central bank has as its
principal concern the "cost and availability of credit.11
Obviously in this memorandum we cannot discuss the ultimate
goals of monetary policy.

We must stop short of that and simply

say that we need a central bank because we have fallen into the
unfortunate position of using debt claims on commercial banks as
means of payment.

It is an absolute necessity for government

somehow to control the aggregate amount of such debt claism.




We have

Edward C. Simmons — H 9

devised a fairly effective way of doing this within the framework
of our fractional reserve banking structure.

In simple terms we

control the aggregate amount of member-bank reserves, and we
prescribe a minimum reserve ratio.

Thus there is fixed an upper

limit to the expansion of bank deposits.
Central banks have usually been encumbered with powers to
do many things which are only remotely related to their primariy
task -- seeing that the stock of money behaves appropriately.

To

accomplish this purpose their principal weapon is open market operations.

This weapon is impersonal and unquestionably effective.

On

rare occasions minimum reserve requirements may have to be changed.
The rest of the weapons of central banking are superfluous and some
are even irrelevant.
Obviously this view leaves no role for discount policy.
Why then does the discount mechanism exist?
It is one of those vestigal historical survivals which
abound in our dynamic society.

Because this country has long had

a fragmented banking structure with thousands of banks, smaller
banks have come to lean in bigger banks, borrowing and obtaining
other forms of aid from them.

When the Federal Reserve came upon

the scene, borrowing from the central bank seemed perfectly natural.
Indeed at times the new central banking institutions acted much as
if they were themselves just bigger commercial banks.

In the days

before we had a large national debt and a highly organized government




Edward C. Simmons --

securities market, borrowing by commercial banks to adjust reserve
positions was probably indispensable.

But since at least the end

of World War II there has been no genuine reason for banks to use
this means of reserve position adjustment.
Banks emerged from World War II liberally endowed with
government securities.

An entire generation of bankers had grown

up without knowing what it was to borrow at the Federal Reserve.
They began to borrow toward the close of World War II simply
because the configuration of money rates shifted in such fashion
that the use of the discount facility became advantageous.

It was

a major mistake of Federal Reserve policy to allow this to happen.
Although many commercial banks have shifted out of government securities since that time, all banks have the opportunity to
hold adequate secondary reserves in the form of short-term government securities.

These they can use to adjust reserve positions

as funds flow out.

When funds flow in, obviously secondary reserve

assets must be acquired.

However, when it is easy to borrow at

the Federal Reserve» many banks find it preferable to meet reserve
drains by borrowing.
Abrupt withdrawal of discount privileges would create
chaotic conditions in the money market, but it is still true that
the discount mechanism should never have been revived after World
War II.




Edward C. Simmons --

Borrowing in the course of normal banking operations is not
necessary.

Many banks have demonstrated this.

Perhaps in the face

of an incipient panic, direct loans by the central bank may be called
for, but this memorandum is not intended to delve into such matters.
I do not believe that raising or lowering discount rates or
altering the terms on which the central bank lends to member banks
is needed to control the size of the stock of money.

To put it

bluntly, I see no role for discount policy in monetary management.
The Federal Reserve should look toward the gradual atrophying
of discount operations.

Each time money market conditions ease,

some additional obstacle should be placed in the way of borrowing by
member banks.

Gradually discounting will then vanish with a

minimum of disturbance.
[_ In the remainder of this memorandum we discuss some
aspects of how the discount mechanism should function during the
fade-out phase^/
Question 2.

It is assumed here that if they do borrow member banks

do not remain long in debt.

They borrow only to meet reserve

drains that threaten them with a reserve deficiency penalty.—

They

1/ We shall pass over the absurd notion that borrowing for longer
periods permits banks to meet seasonal demands for loans in particular areas, such as agriculture. There is no magic by which the
central bank in manufacturing money in response to discounting can
bring into existence new capital goods and then destroy these
capital goods when the peak has passed. From the outset the Federal
Reserve has been obsessed with the idea that it exists to meet
seasonal needs. Actually it appears that the System's founders
confused a seasonal "need" for hand-to-hand money with a seasonal
"need11 for loans.




Edward C. Simmons -- \

must dispose of earning assets fairly quickly to pay off their
borrowings.

Thus deposits and assets move about from bank tp

bank, facilitated possibly by the ability of banks to borrow,
but in a fashion no different than if borrowing were not
possible.
If an entire region faces a reserve drain, borrowing by
that region*s banks can do no more than delay briefly the asset
liquidation in that area which the deposit migration calls for.
In the case either of the region or of the individual bank, if
banks follow adequate secondary reserve practices, drains can be
met without borrowing and without hardship.
Obviously there is no net creation of liquidity by reason
of short-term borrowing, provided the general level of member-bank
indebtedness remains constant.

If more liquidity is needed, and

that can mean only more money, open-market operations will suffice.
To permit commercial banks on their own initiative to force the
Federal Reserve to create additional bank reserves seems a
curiously inefficient way of managing the nation's money.

To

the individual banker the thought of being able to borrow may be
reassuring, but it might be well to eliminate such encouragement of
imprudent extension of resources.
At least since the 17th century the notion has been
current that banks are remarkable institutions that permit persons
banded together to increase the liquidity of the economy by issuing




Edward C. Sitraadhs

—

generally acceptable debt claims based on the wealth of the ''company."
Dosing the economy with liquidity in this fashion proved disastrous
in the land bank era.
form.

But the idea persists today in variant

Now it is in the form that the central bank improves the

lot of mankind by responding favorably to the requests of the commercial banks for loans.
Discount policy should certainly not be employed to influence
the allocation of loanable funds (credit) among banks, regions, or
types of use of funds.

The market mechanism can perform the task

of allocating scarce resources, of which capital is one, among
alternative uses.

What is more, the market mechanism can perform

this taks better than any board or commission of experts.
Question 3.

The change I propose is to gradually eliminate discounting

and thus to rely more and more upon open market operations.

Because

for some time discounting would continue, the matter of the discount
rate calls for brief comment.
I would urge that the Federal Reserve rely on price rationing rather than on other types of rationing along with some price
rationing.

Other types of rationing are such things as "eligible

paper11 definition, "acceptable paper*1 definition, and "judgment,11
that is, "direct pressure."




Edward C. Simmons-- 1?4

Where there are thousands of banks, all profit-seeking,
the only fair and workable rule is to set a price on accommodation
that will not encourage so many to borrow so much that arbitrary
rationing will need to be imposed.

The Federal Reserve never seems

to have understood one of the most elementary economic propositions,
namely that the market achieves rationing of scarce things through
the price mechanism.
Specifically the recommendation here is that the discount
rate be make a true penalty rate.

There is ample precedent for this

recommendation in central banking history.

And it would accomplish

the one most essential reform, the elimination of discretion in the
granting of accommodation.

A further necessary step is to eliminate

discretion in the setting of the rate itself.

This may be done

by establishing a fixed differential between the discount rate and
the Treasury bill rate, say 2 or even 4 per cent.
Question 4.

Ideally the central bank should be permitted to deal in

all sorts of assets at will.

Historically limitations were imposed

because of the idea that the central bank's own liquidity depends
on its being able to sell its assets to someone.

But since the

central bank's liquidity, unlike that of the commercial banks,
does not derive from the ability to shift assets to others, but
from the central bank's unique ability to create money, there
is really no logic to the customary restraints.




Edward C. Simmons — 1 2 5
The only real concern is that the central bank can buy
enough of whatever it is authorized to deal in to keep member-bank
reserves at the desired level.

With a national debt of the present

size, the supply of assets would seem to present no problem.
Restricting the Federal Reserve to dealing in national debt
securities minimizes the need for "experts" who can determine
the correct relative prices for a wide range of assets.

Even

in the government securities case, as was learned during the "bills
only" controversy, there is the thorny problem of the relative
price of long-term as against short-term government securities.
The idea advanced in some quarters that the central bank
should buy and sell a wide range of assets simply to alter their
relative prices, while intriguing to many persons, is not to be
entertained.

The market mechanism must be relied upon to determine

the relative price structure.

Although someone can always point

to episodes in which the market mechanism worked sluggishly, its
performance in the long run is likely to be a good deal better than
that of any board of experts.

Modern socialism provides abundant

examples of mismanagement in the area of relative price structure.
Question 5.

Whatever lending is done by the central bank should be

only on member banks 1 own short-term notes secured with short-term
U.S. government securities.

This requirement would stimulate bank

interest in maintaining good secondary reserves.

If there is to be

a panic provision, such as section 10(b) of the 1933 Emergency
Banking Act, a broader list obviously will apply in such instance.




Edward C. Simmons — V? ,
The entire eligibility and acceptability doctrine is a sad
and confused piece of business.
vigorously, even ruthlessly.

Here the broom should be used

There is no deeper mystery anywhere

than that which surrounds "eligibility" and "acceptability" to say
nothing of "appropriate" and "inappropriate" uses of Federal Reserve
credit.

The matter approaches the level of religious doctrine.

Question 6.

This question indicates how far we have gone toward

accepting the idea that nonprice rationing should be practiced by
the central bank.

Instead of this approach, it is proposed in this

memorandum tba t a price be set high enough to perform the requisite
rationing. Any other kind of rationing will, as Federal Reserve
history demonstrates, be arbitrary, inconsistent, and even ineffective.
Federal Reserve people seem to delight in administering
various homemade rationing techniques.

I was amazed in visiting

several Reserve Banks during the late 1950fs to find that discount
officers took positive joy in devising rules and schemes to govern
the amount of accommodation to be granted.

One suspects this sort

of thing stems from a bureaucratic love of possession of some
small kingdom over which sovereignty may be exercised.
Question 7.

I do not see that there is really any need for any lending

to any one, but if the Federal Reserve must lend, let the member
banks be the only customers.




Edward C. Simmons -- i'27
There is no problem unless we delude ourselves, as many
persons interested in economic development do, with the idea that
the central bank should function as a source of funds for building
dams and other social betternment projects.

Once we grasp

the

essential truth of the idea that the central bank exists only to
control the size of the stock of money, clearly all of its dealings
should be of the minimum and at tis own discretion and confined to
monetary institutions.

If for no other reason than to simplify

its task, it should exclude all others except member banks and government security dealers.

It must have contact with the latter to

engage in open market purchases and sales, but it must not, of
course, make loans to them.

Even repurchase agreements with govern-

ment security dealers should be eliminated, if possible.
Question 8a. If we are to go on forever with the present awkward
structure of a duodecimally fragmented central bank, there should be
only one discount rate for the entire nation.

The compartmentaliza-

tion suggested by Federal Reserve district boundaries is meaningless,
and any other identification of "regions11 would be equally lacking
in sense.
Question 8b.

There should not be several classes of paper.

The pro-

liferation of types of paper is the delight of the bureaucratically
minded whose unawareness of his faith in the effectiveness of nonprice rationing is pitiful.




Edward C. Simmons -- 128
Question oc,

No.

All this is rationing by some criterion other

than price.
Question 8d.

The rate should be a penalty rate, well above the highest

rate earned on any class of assets,
above the Treasury bill rate.

I propose a rigid differential

The discount rate, however, should

be changed only once a week simply to simplify record keeping.
The ceremony of changing the rate by administrative process ought
to be eliminated.

What useful purpose does it serve to have a

weekly Board meeting and the recording of a vote, which is reported
in the press?

Let those who say that this is a way for the

Board to exert an influence on the economy consider alternative
ways of communicating economic intelligence.
Question 8e.

By making the rate a penalty rate at a fixed differen-

tial above the Treasury bill rate, to be changed once each week,
the announcement problem would disappear.
Question 8f.

This question is irrelevant if the recommendation made

in this memorandum is accepted.
Question 8g.

An interesting point is raised here, although the

relevance of the subpoint to the main question is not apparent.
There is some advantage in paying interest on member-bank
deposits in Federal Reserve Banks; the commercial banks would be
mollified.




However, there is no substance to the proposal.

Edward C. Simmons — 4.29
The commercial banks are frequently unable to see any real
difference between a balance of the Federal Reserve and any other
asset.

Practical bankers find it hard to understand that reserves

at the Federal Reserve are a device to control the size of the
money stock.

To understand the matter one need only ask himself

how the money stock could behave if bankers were left to their own
devices.

Late 19th century English banking demonstrates what mis-

chief can arise even in a moderately well-run banking system under
circumstances where there is not even a convention as to holding to
some minimum ratio in terms of some scarce asset.
To pay interest on reserve balances would be simply to
take one step toward denying that the Federal Reserve is a central
banking institution.

It would not enhance the effectiveness of

monetary control, and no step which does not lead in that direction
should be considered.
To pay interest on excess reserves is to accomplish by
indirection something that can be done directly.

If excess reserves

threaten to bring about an undesired expansion, they should be
eliminated by open market operations or in extreme case by changing
reserve requirements.

Payment of interest on excess reserves is

another gadget, something to delight those who see virtue in
complexity.




Edward C # Simmons -Question 9.

It is alleged in some quarters that the discount mechanism

enhances the ability of the Federal Reserve to manage money.

When

these claims are examined they are seen to rest on the view that
monetary management means concern with amount and kind of lending
that banks (and even other lenders) -do.
It is argued in this memorandum that concern with such
matters represents a mistaken view of the purpose of the central
bank.

Whether the claims themselves are true or false are not

discussed here.

Commonly employed is the doctrine that it is good

for banks to be in debt to the Federal Reserve when "tight money11
conditions are appropriate because this condition makes the banks
"reluctant".

This doctrine is said to support the usefulness of

the discount mechanism as a device of monetary restraint.
In its modern form this is a modified version of W. W #
Riefler's "reluctance theorem," which, it will be recalled, was
advanced to explain money-rate movements.

In recent years the index

used to measure the condition of the money market has been "free
reserfes" rather than "memb2r-har.ik indebtedness."

It should be

observed that even the combining of the indebtedness of all member
banks yields an aggregate that must be interpreted with care.

This

is true because member banks differ widely from one another as well
as from one time to another in their reaction to being in debt.
This caution becomes even more significant when "free reserves"
replaces member-bank indebtness as the index because there is an added




Edward C* Simmons -factor.

The algebraic adding together of the excess reserves of

some banks and the borrowing of others yields a purely synthetic
magnitude that measures nothing that is operationally meaningful.
Ho bank is ever (except by accident) both a holder of excess
reserves and a borrower at the same time.
Less significant is the consideration that making the
center of focus the dollar amount of free reserves places the real
objective in the shadows.

The debate becomes one over whether the

degree of tightness or ease in the money market is correct rather
than one over whether or not the stock of money is behaving
appropriately.
Although it may possibly be demonstrated that the rate at
which the money stock changes bears some measurable relationship
to the volume of free reserves, such a demonstration does not lead
to the conclusion that the best possible way to control the money
stock is to manipulate with one hand the volume of member-bank
borrowing and with the other the volume of excess reserves so as to
obtain some given level of free seserves.

That there are enormous

difficulties in this approach is apparent when one reflects that
member-bank reactions are highly variable.

Member-bank borrowing

patterns and responses seem almost to deny rational explanation,
depdnding as they do on a host of nonprice restraints.

Some banks

will not borrow under any circumstances, others borrow at every
opportunity.




The Federal Reserve's discount policy contains a vast

Edward C# Simmons —•
array of restraints of one sort and another encluding the so-called
"tradition against borrowing11 —

a tradition about as venerable as

those enshrined on the campuses of colleges founded in 1913*

(It

is amusing to note how the Federal Reserve labored in the 1950fs to
revive this tradition,)

Some banks do not borrow because they have

become angry with the Federal Reservefs persuasiveness.

Some banks

do not borrow because they wish to exhibit a spirit of independence.
Some do not because they believe it is not profitable.

And

unquestionably many borrow less than they would because someone
in the Federal Reserve has talked them out of it or because of a
fear of being interrogated.
If the nonprice restraints were constant over time forecasting would be less difficult than it is.
cannot be forecast reliably.

The behavior of banks

A given amount of free reserves will

produce one effect at one time and a quite different effect at
another.
There is no virtue in trying to use the discount mechanism
to control the size of the stock of money.

Were open market opera-

tions unknown and were the variable reserve ratio unknown, then, as
in fact during the early days of the Federal Reserve, discount policy
would be the important central bank weapon as it was in a long-closed
era.

The Federal Reserve, however, harks back to that time

possibly because all bureaucracies are incapable of surrendering any
piece of territory, no matter how inconsequential, once sovereignty
over it has been won.




- 133 Comments on
The Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism and

Policies

Frank M. Tamagna
The American University, Washington, D.C.

1.

The continuity of monetary mechanisms - A monetary

instrument, is a means to an end.

There is no uniformity in the way

such instruments are applied by the various central banks, and any
identities in their terminology may be highly misleading and of little
help for comparing their forms and uses in different countries and at
different times.
There has been, however, a definite continuity in the way
each central bank has handled its own tools of monetary policy.

In-

struments are adapted in a gradual way to the structure of financial
markets, in dya-to-day operations, and to the objectives of national
policy, to the attainment of which they are intended to contribute.
Radical changes in monetary instruments, like in the institutions to
which they are related, are more likely to prove disruptive of existing
relationships than constructive of a more efficient system.

There is,

nevertheless, a continuing need on the part of the authorities to refurbish their tools, in line with changing market practices and policy
objectives.
The special role of the discount mechanism in monetary policy
derives, in my opinion, from the flexibility of its application by
central banks as they pursue their purposes and functions.




This is

- 134 -

related, in turn to a triple nature of this facility, in the sense that:
(a) through its rate, the discount mechanism provides a yeardstick of
the cost of money that influences the market pattern of interest rates;
(b) through the eligibility of the paper on which it is extended, it
can be focused on setting credit standards of n soundness n and "selectivity,11
in accordance with economic considerations; and (c) through the discretion given to the central bank, each operation provides an occasion
for a review of the lending practices of the applicant bank and the
establishment of common credit practices in the banking system.
In accordance with these principles, and in view of recent
market changes and current credit problems at this time (1966), I
assume that the questions in the Board memorandum have been formulated
having in mind the problem of how to influence the allocation of credit
among users, given a policy framework of over-all credit restraint,
and as a related objective the maintenance of an orderly interest-rate
structure.

I assume also that, as a matter of terminology, the emphasis

on "discount" and the absence of any reference to f'advances11 in the
memorandum do not imply a distinction between discount and advances in
the lending mechanism of the Federal Reserve.

2»

Jhe. y°)-e^9£ jiivS?oyj!t_and%JLts^ adaptation as a qualitative

mechanism - Advances and discounts have found a proper place in Federal
Reserve policy as the most appropriate instrument for meeting temporary
and specific needs of individual banks; open-market operations are used




- 135 -

to make short run but continuing and general adjustments in the liquidity
of the financial markets, and reserve requirements provide for longerrun changes in the reserve level of the banking system,

I see little

to be gained from any basic change in this arrangement, but see
advantages to be obtained by introducing greater flexibility in the
complementary uses of these instruments.
Through the years discount mechanisms have been adapted in
many qualitative ways.

During the 1920 f s, for in stance, the Reserve

Banks applied differential discount rates, eligibility criteria, and
credit lines with a view to local or external objectives—agricultural
financing, exchange stabilizations~-with mixed results.

Even under

current policy, the broad discretionary principles enunciated in the
Board's Regulation A have a distinct qualitative flavor, in their
reference "to the purpose of the credit and to its probable effects
upon the maintenance of sound credit conditions, both as to the individual institution and the economy generally11 - though in actual
application the use of the facility has been restricted to short run
adjustment with little evidence of "qualitative11 selectivity.
In more recent years, and particularly in the postwar decade,
some central banks of European continental countries (France and Belgium,
for instance) have relied on the discount mechanism for assuring an
adequate provision of credit to certain sectors or purposes (such as
short-term export credit and intermediate equipment financing).




Their

- 135 -

experience was mixed, but generally the discount commitments underlying
such policy led to a greater expansion of credit than the monetary
authorities would have extended otherwise, or conversely made their
task in restraining credit that much more difficult.

Principally,

for this reason, these central banks have since cut back the granting
of discount commitments, except for specified types of paper arising
from foreign trade, subject to special advance review of the underlying
transaction.
In developing countries, particularly in Latin America, the
discount mechanism has been used for various purposes, such as introducing
new credit instruments, channelling bank credit toward sectors dependent
on money lenders, and altering the distribution pattern of bank credit.
For instance, negotiable commercial and mortgage credit instruments
found their way in various markets following their acceptability for
discount by central banks.

This has been in line with a prevailing

trend toward more uniform and lower interest rates, a redirection of
credit from commerce to development, and the promotion of nexv financing
practices and institutions.

Success has been greater where limited

and specific purposes have been sought through the discount mechanism—
in Mexico and Costa Rica for instance—while global goals have generally
met with unsuccess.

Cn the other hand, policies pursued by certain

central banks in the 1950's to regulate through the discount mechanism
the over-all distribution of bank credit (by combining discount quotas
and differential rates, as in Colombia and Chile) led to serious




- 137 -

administrative complications and inflationary monetary expansions,
which caused such policies to be abandoned in stabilization programs
during the 19o0 f s.
These experiences give rise to doubts as to whether the use
of the discount mechanism for regulating credit allocation among users so as to give proportionately more to some and less to others - cound
be of any general effect and to concern that its use might prove
particularly inconsistent with the conduct of a stable monetary policy.

3.

The discount as an enforcement instrument - The granting

or withholding of the discount, being applied as a "privilege" and not
a "right," may, on the other hand, prove effective for enforcing other
and more direct forms of credit regulation.

That is, by determining

the conditions under which a bank could have access to the discount
window, the Federal Preserve may induce and give effect to "qualitative" concepts of credit policy.

Such a procedure would seem con-

sistent with existing principles of the System's discount policy and
with precedents set by other central banks.
Direct regulation of credit expansion, set forth in the
forms of percentage ceilings on over-all increase and of limitations
on particular types of credit, has become widely recognized as a
most effective instrument of policy, x^here qualitative objectives
are sought jointly with an over-all quantitative restraint.

Its

application has spread among advanced and developing countries, ever




since it was first introduced, betx>reen the late 1950's and the early
1960 f s, by the Bank of Mexico, with respect to the acceptance of
short-erm accounts and the extension of mortgage lending, and by the
Bank of England, with respect to consumer and inventory financing.

In

Mexico this direct regulation came as part of a long-range economic
development policy, in Britain it was part of a balance of payments
stabilization policy, and in both cases the limitations were extended
to financial institutions in general, whether banking or others.

This

type of regulation has been last applied, smong ethers, by the Swiss
authorities since 1964, for containing the expansion of bank credit
in general, and in particular of mortgage financing and the offering
of securities on the capital market.

Of course, the Federal Reserve

itself has used it, quite successfully, for holding back the expansion
of bank lending to foreigners.
Direct credit regulation has naturally a compensatory effect:
any limitation of credit with respect to certain purposes (regarded as
speculative or marginal) releases credit for other purposes (generally
classified as

;:

productive:: in domestic or balance of payments terms);

thereby this type of regulation softens the impact of the restrictive
policy.

If these special credit-claiming sectors of the economy were

tc be given, instead, a privileged access to discount facilities, the
central bank would in turn be compelled to find recourse to alternative
measures for compressing correspondingly other types of financing.




- 139 -

The point of view that the discount facility could be best
used for the enforcement of qualitative regulation, rather than as a
qualitative instrument itself, finds support, for instance, in the
practices of the Bundesbank of Germany and the Bank of Italy.

Since

the introduction of guiding ratios concerning the use of capital resources and the liquidity structure, the Bundesbank has made compliance
with such ratios a condition for giving banks and other financial institutions access to its discount and related credit facilities, under
the general principle that whether or not an advance "can be granted
in an actual individual case will be decided according to the general
credit situation and the individual circumstances of the would-be
borrower.1' The Bank of Italy is not committed by any formal statement
or regulation, but administers its discount policy on a flexible, dayto-day basis, with very sparing use of changes of the discount rate
and close coordination with other types of credit accommodation.

In

actual operations, the Bank of Italy attaches great importance to an
informal review of lending practices, whenever a banking institution
approaches it for the use of the discount facility.

4.

Redefining the role of the discount mechanism - The view

that direct regulation of credit can be more effective by enforcement
through the discount facility does not exclude the advisability of reconsidering the scope of the mechanism itself within the framework of




- 440 -

present practices and policies.

Its temporary use appears particularly

appropriate to certain specific purposes, carrying broad qualitative
implication, such as:
ju




Where the nature or term of the credit need by a bank

is seasonal or local, and partkcularly under conditions of
a tightening policy, the provision of reserves to banks
through the discount mechanism appears distinctly superior
to open market operations.

In the first

place, by bringing

the bank in need to the "discount window,rt the discount
procedure provides an opportunity for a review of its lending practices by Reserve Bank officers, independently of
any formal credit regulation.

In the second place, the dis-

count operation, while effectively meeting a specific need,
places the borrowing bank under the definite commitment to
reduce its borrowing as the need terminates, either by
reversing the operations that gave rise to it or by earmarking new resources to such purpose;
ii.

Where a bank, or a group of banks, suffers an unexpected

loss of deposits (and reserves) through no fault of its own
(due, for example, to the exodus of business from the area,
or a poor crop, or a worsening of the terms of tra de of
the region vis-a-vis other parts of the country), the discount mechanism can be used to "lend time,11 making available
the credit necessary to such banks while adjusting their
loans and investments to the new position;

- 141 -

iii.

Where a Lank, or a group of banks, in a certain area

is faced with an unexpected loan demand of high priority
(due, for example, to an unusually large crop, a sudden inflow of defense orders, or Federal actions involving business
participation in "depressed area" programs), the discount
mechanism could be used to "anticipate time,1' by extending
credit that the banks would repay out of the expected inflow of new funds into the area.
These three cases above may be regarded as more or less typical
of the application of the discount mechanism as jad_ hoc instrument with
a qualitative purpose.

In all cases, its temporary use could be

strengthened by the application of graduated discount ra tes, progressively rising to a sharp penalty level the longer a bank uses the facility;
the rising rates would induce the bank to make prompt repayments consistently with the nature of its need, the limit set to the operation,
and intent of the authorities.

This approach is in line with the

established principle that the use of the discount facility, as a
privilege but not a right, rests on the judgment and discretion exercised
by the Reserve Bank in each particular case, within the framework of
the System^ general policy.

Such a procedure might need to be strength-

ened by closer coordination between the discount practices of the individual Reserve Banks and the monetary policy decisions of the System
as a whole, particularly during tightening phases requiring the excerise




-' 142 of greater discrimination in the review of discount applications from
member banks in the various Reserve districts,

5. The complementary use of other instruments - These purposes
could admittedly be served by some modified use of other instruments.
For instance, greater flexibility in the reserve requirement would
enable the Federal Pveserve to make temporary and case by case adjustments for any bank or group of banks by:
jU

Lowering requirements to the extent and period necessary

to enable such banks to meet temporary, local, or other
special needs of the type indicated above;
ii.

Raising requirements, in order to "freeze11 temporarily

a concentration of excess liquidity in one or some banks,
so as to prevent the excess liquidity from spreading through
the banking system.
Such adjustments of reserve requirements could just as well
be done by a combination if discount and reserve requirements:

for

instance, by the Reserve Banks lending to banks in need against their
reserves, at the discount rate or at a penalty rate, and by the System
borrowing excess reserves from banks by offering to pay interest at the
discount rate, or at the prevailing Federal funds rate.
As a matter of fact, a combination of discount mechanism,
reserve requirements, and open market operations could open the way
for the System's intervention in the Federal funds market, thereby




- 143 -

adding a tool that might at times facilitate the transmission of its
day-to-day operations to the market.

By using these existing procedures

the System may extend its "repurchase agreements

for day-to-day

accommodations to Federal funds1 dealers on any week or day when undue
pressures would seem to develop, or when the easier conditions that are
being sought are in the market.
System could enter

By adopting a reverse procedure, the

t!

borrowing orders" for Federal funds in days or

weeks of liquidity outburst or when a tightening effect is sought, so
as to maintain the degree of liquidity or tightness consistent with its
policy and also with orderly market conditions.

This would, in effect,

be a way for the System to pay interest on excess reserves offered by
banks, without assuming a definite commitment to pay a fixed interest
on all or any predetermined part of the excess reserves of the entire
banking system.

In times of easing policies, the extension of the

System's credit facilities to banks through Federal funds market would
lessen the reliance on the discount window and also on the need of the
System to purchase Treasury bills; in time of tightening policies, the
borrowing of excess reserves by the System would compel more "deficit11
banks to the discount window, thereby enhancing the effectiveness of
the discount mechanism without resorting to sales of bills.
The adjustment of reserve requirements (or liquidity coefficient)
for very short-terms for seasonal purposes (crop movements, tax payments)
has been used extensively in such countries as France, New Zealand, and




- 144 some Latin American countries. Similarly, the borrowing of liquid
funds from individual banks at the discretion of the central bank
finds a precedent in the Treasury Deposit Receipts (TDR), which acquired
great importance in the United Kingdom during and for a period after
the war.

Also, the extension of "Lombard Loans11 (against the collateral

of Government securities), for providing day-to-day liquidity to the
market, is used by European central banks; such loans carry a somewhat
higher rate than the normal discount, because of their occasional and
short-term nature, in contrast to the somewhat longer period required
of discount operations,
&•

Flexibility and reversibility of discount operations -

These approaches to monetary policy follow the philosophy that the
Federal Reserve should avoid any definite commitment, but should
maintain complete discretion and flexibility in the use of instruments
and the setting of terms and conditions, so as to preclude any automatic
access of banks to its discount window.

In the exercise of its dis-

count authority, a Reserve Bank should also be free (as I believe it
has always been) to apply special conditions upon a borrowing bank;
for instance, that it should reduce its securities1 holdings or seek
participation of other banks in its loans, as a prerequisite for the
granting of the use of the facility.
These principles are consistent with the view that neither
the kind of paper offered by the borrowing bank nor differences in




- 145 -

rates based on such paper are of significance, as are the need for which
the discount is sought and the lending practice of the bank seeking it.
The principle that the discount is not to be used as a permanent addition
to a bank's own resources should remain firm, but the temporary nature
and reversibility of the need giving rise to demand for the discount
should continue to be the guiding element in the Federal Reserve
decision,

A time-progressive rate structure could be applied, that,

without taking the place of, would nevertheless strengthen the repayment
provisions stipulated in the discount operation.
If the System and the banks were to abide by these principles,
I see little to be gained from arbitrarily setting any shorter discount
limits than the nature of each operation requires and the law stipulates.
The System could, therefore, extend its discounts to its full permissible
limits, up to the 9-months allowed for agricultural paper and n o t e s ~
always subject, however, to the rule that each discount operation should
not be constrained within any shorter, nor be allowed to extend over
any longer, period than the time required for the reversibility of the
need for which the discount was granted.
Along with this flexibility of maturities and repayment
conditions, similar discretion would seem warranted with respect to
quantitative limits.

Discount ceilings, as have been set by certain

central banks on the basis, for instance, of the capital of commercial
banks, may be justified on pragmatic grounds but bear no relation to




- 14, -

the need for which a bank might seek rediscount nor to the purpose
which the authorities might intend to meet. Moreover, they tend to
undermine the monetary policy itself, as such ceilings or quotas have
generally become identified with minimum or normal credit lines, giving
the banks an expectation and claim of automatic and permanent access to
discount.

In such cases, the central banks have found themselves in-

duced or compelled to provide additional discount facilities whenever
the banks reached a "fully-borrowedt! position; discounts above, not
under, the discount line have thus become the decisive factors of
monetary policy.

Central banks in advanced countries like Prance and

Japan and in developing countries like India and those in Latin America
have had this experience; neither these experiences nor that the System
in the 1920fs has much to recommend in favor of a return of the discount
facility to quota or ceiling systems.
7,

Extension of discount facilities to other institutions -

The working of the discount mechanism in the United States involves a
co-responsibility of policy and operations: The Reserve Banks extending
discounts, as part of the implementing process of monetary policy, to
member banks that meet the guiding principles set forth by the Board.
In this interrelation between the authorities and the members of the
System, the discount is, in effect, a counterpart for compliance with
policy rules, exemplified by reserve requirements, interest rates, and
portfolio regulation.




The extension of this facility to other institutions

- 147 -

(whether nonmember banks or nonbanking financial intermediaries) could
hardly be considered outside of this reciprocal context;

the discounts

could not and should not be regarded as a gratuitious benefit to be
conferred without regard to the acceptance by the recipients of correspondent policy rules.
The financial system of the United States, with its pluralistic
and shifting pattern of banking and other institutions, gives rise to
problems that are not so corcmon in other countries, where the financial
structure is usually closely integrated with a few large and stable
banks, diffused in their organizations and diversified in their
functions.

Where specialized institutions exist to any significant

extent, the central bank has established contacts - whether by giving
banks access to its discount facilities, or by intervening in the
markets of their securities (by operations or regulations), or by
requiring them to maintain minimum balances or liquidity coefficients
(whether by law or more frequently by gentleman's agreements), or,
finally, by the influence that its direct regulations, letters of request,
moral suasion, or simple advice usually carry.

In all cases, the ex-

tension of discounts by the central bank is but a part of this policy
interrelation that extends in some countries far beyond banking institutions, to cover, directly or indirectly, offerings of corporate
securities to the market and investments in securities by financial
institutions.




The Federal Reserve, by joint Board and Bank decisions, has
considerable leeway in its formulation of discount policies and extension of discount facilities to others than member banks - not excluding individuals, partnerships, and corporations '' in unusual and
exigent circumstances.n

The question of extending the discount facility

beyond the banking system is obviously related to changes in the
financial structure.

Pending a resolution of the broad and difficult

problem related to the "specialization11 or the "mixing" of banking and
nonbanking institutions, any extension of discount might be considered
primarily with respect to those institutions closet in their functions
to member banks:

that is, nonmember banks, the intermediate credit

system and the savings and loan system.

In a limited and circumscribed

way, the Federal Reserve is authorized to open the "discount window1
to nonmember banks, and in a more direct and explicit way to the
Federal Intermediate Credit Banks:

powers that the Reserve authorities

have exercised very sparingly, the former only occasionally in recent
years and the latter not since about the 1920fs.
The repeal of Section 13-b in 1958 brought to an end the
Federal Reserve experience with direct lending to industrial and
commercial businesses.

In view of the role of the System as monetary

authority, the nature of the discount as monetary instrument, and the
adequacy of the financial structure in providing to the credit needs of
the economy, no purpose would be served by any resumption of direct




- 149 lending to business.

This involves technical and risk judgments for

which the System is hardly equipped; there is also danger tha a too
broad or loose expansion of lending practices outside of the banking
structure would make it more difficult for the System to contain its
operations when a tightening of credit TOuld be called for.
Any extension of the discount facility within the financial
system should be viewed from the standpoint of its contribution to
the Federal Reserve responsibility for maintaining a viable monetary
system based on the orderly functioning of financial markets.

The

discount instrument may be particularly effective in bringing abcut
closer coordination between Federal Reserve and financial institutions
in general, and Federal lending agencies in particular, and in making
them more responsive to changes that would help in the direction and
degree of monetary policy.

This subject has been widely discussed

and has attracted great attention within and outside the System, and
has already induced positive steps and measures toward such coordination.
These purposes and the principle that the extension of the
discount facility should be tied to policy conditions could both be
achieved by appropriate amendments to the pertinent legislation.

The

same purposes, however, might as well be attained by the Federal
Reserve offering access to its discount window by certain institutions
(nonmember banks, Federal intermediate credit banks), and Federal home
loan banks), upon their acceptance of such stipulations as:




- 150 -

a.

Nonmember banks would maintain deposit balances with the

Reserve Bank in lieu of the reserves required of member banks.

Non-

member banks could be expected to maintain minimum balances at ratios
to deposits equivalent to those of comparable member banks.

The amount

of balances to be held by the Federal intermediate credit and home loan
banks could be stipulated by agreement (between their respective Boards
and the Federal Reserve Board), on the basis of pertinent considerations,
such as that these Federal agencies would in turn obtain correspondent
balances from productive credit associations and savings and loan
associations.
b.

Nonmember banks would be expected to abide by the interest-

rate limitations and other pertinenet regulations on savings and time
deposits and market borrowing issued by the Federal Reserve with respect
to member banks; the Federal intermediate credit and home loan banks
would be expected to enter into agreements with the Federal Reserve
Board with respect to their rates on lending to member associations and
to the exercise of regulatory powers on interest rates and accounts
of such associations.
c.

Nonmember banks, when admitted to the discount window,

would be expected to provide information on their operations, as the
Reserve Banks might require; the Federal intermediate credit and home
loan banks to consult with the district's Reserve Bank and the Reserve
Board on matters of common policy and to exchange information (on




- 15L reciprocal and advance basis) with regard to any decision or rulings
pertinent to their operations*
The admission of nonmember banks and Federal agencies to the
discount facility should not give them any automatic or continuing right
of use; the extension of each operation should be subject, as for member
banks, to discretionary and case~by-case review and decision by the
Reserve Bank and to the general policy of the Board with respect to the
exercise of the function.
S.

Extension of discounts to other instruments - There are

relatively few binding restrictions on instruments that the Federal
Reserve can discount, or lend against, or purchase, that might effectively
impede its function of providing credit to institutions or the market
under changing conditions. Therefore and in view of the universal
recourse to Government securities, the active use of bankers1 acceptances, the eligibility of obligations of certain Federal agencies, and
the emphasis on the purpose and terms of each operation, the type of
paper eligible for discount would appear to be of secondary, if any,
imoortance. An expanded eligibility schedule would necessarily include
any loan classified as "productive11 and normally carried by banks
(agricultural, industrial, commercial, foreign trade, and possibly
others), so that any new definition could hardly be significant in influencing banks in their lending:

except perhaps, in selecting some

particular paper, for form rather than substance.




Conversely, the

- 15? exclusion of any specified type of paper from the discount facility
(for instance, loans for inventories, securities transactions, consumer
ourchases) could hardly deter a bank from such lending - no matter how
many loans ineligible to discount a bank would carry, its portfolio
would always hold a volume of "eligible" paper amply sufficient to
cover its discount needs at the Federal Reserve.
A question might be raised as to whether the eligibility or
use of any instrument should be discontinued from the discount (or
purchase) operations of the Federal Reserve.

It might be noted that

eligibility to discount (or purchase) does not in any way commit the
Federal Reserve to any specific course, as it remains entirely free
to choose the instrument and scope of its operations on a time-totime basis.

The shift back and forth from long- to short-term Govern-

ment securities and the flexibility currently maintained in open
market operations confirm this approach.
More specifically, the question might be raised, for instance,
concerning banker's acceptances.

It could be argued that the original

reasons for discounting and purchasing acceptances no longer exist,
now that the market is well estab Ished and the Federal Reserve support
is no longer needed.

On the other hand, the banker*s acceptance is

the prime instrument not only in trade financing, but also in the
investment portfolio of international private banks and foreign central
banks.




In its correspondent relations with foreign central banks, for

- 15* instance, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York is frequently asked to
purchase acceptances for investment of dollar balance of these banks,
and the fact that it is in the market facilitates this courtesy function
on behalf of such institutions*

Moreover, the extent to which this

arrangement helps to keep in the United States funds which otherwise
might seek investment elsewhere is of some importance in the present
balance of payments situation.

Last but not least, now that monetary

authorities tend to depend increasingly on regulations, any actual
market contacts with and operations in credit instruments give these
authorities more immediate and sensitive

?I

feel ing" of trends and

conditions than does statistical compilation.

Continuation of these

operations, therefore, seems warranted, if for nothing else than to
keep the System's initiative in the market on a continuing and flexible
basis,
9.

Discount policy determination and effects - Nor does

there seem to be any justification for departing from established
procedures in the determination of the discount rate and policy.

The

present procedure of joint decision on rates by each Reserve Bank and
the Board has the advantage of combining national and regional considerations.

In fact, no discount rate could be set, nor any

significant change made in policy, that would not take into account other
policy organs and instruments - particularly open market operations
and the Open Market Committee,




-. 134 A major purpose of a discount decision is its "announcement
effect," which is regarded by most central banks as an important
monetary action in itself.

Such effect cannot be abandoned or de-

creased without weakening the influence of the authorities on the market
and the economy.

It is through its announcement that the Federal

Reserve is in a position to convey an indication of purpose and degree
of tightening or easing*

The moral suasion that goes with a change of

the rate has an important function in guiding and helping the banks in
transmitting the official restraint or ease to their customers and to the
economy in general.

Needless to say, such

announcement effect" tends

to wear out as the market becomes adjusted to the new level of rates
and needs, therefore, to be supported by follow-up actions and operations,
in order to hold the impact past the time of the decision.
A significant element in the "announcement effect1
extent of the rate change.

is the

The Federal Reserve tradition has been one

of narrow and infrequent changes - more usually as adjustment to prior
market changes made effective by other actions (through open market
operations, in particular), with a tendency to minimize the announcement effect.

This practice differs from that of other central banks

(such as those of England and Japan), which rely on sharp changes and
the use of the rate as a signal to the market of an impending policy
change.

On the other hand, the Federal Reserve practice - with greater

reliance on the discretionary power than on the cost of money as
determinant of its discount policy - finds closer correspondence with




-J.55 other central banks, such as France with its narrow variations and Italy
with its infrequent changes*

The interesting and theoretically appealing

experience of Canada that linked the discount rate on a * penalty basis'1
to the weekly auction yield of Treasury bills, failed to satisfy the
Bank of Canada itself - such a linking could hardly be politically
acceptable in this country and might actually result in a tendency to
depress artificially the bill rate in order to hold bank changes in
the discount rate.
For these and other reasons, it would be hazardous to suggest
how often or by how much discount rates should be changed, or at what
level they be held in relation to others.

The timing and extent of each

change need to be related to market conditions, policy objectives, and
the political climate and to be reviewed in the light of alternatives
open to the central bank in lieu of the change, at the moment when the
decision is to be made.




- 15' -

Professor Lester Chandler
Department of Economics
Princeton University
Princeton, New Jersey 08540
Dear Les:
I would like to dissent from the views expressed by some
economists who are highly critical of the present discount rate system
and advocate a system of floating discount rates.
First, I think that many of these critics exaggerate the
awkwardness and perversity of the announcement effects.

Sometimes

changing the rate is a good symbol of the Federal Reserve's diagnosis
and intentions, especially important for international interpretations.
The possibility that Federal Reserve actions will be misinterpreted
exists for its other instruments too—note the weekly commentary on
net free reserves and on the Treasury bill and flow of funds rates.
The general lesson is that the Fed should be more open and less
delphic regarding its intentions and aims.

But this lesson is no

reason to discard any particular instrument.
Second, let us consider the main difference between a
floating discount rate regime and the present system.
difference is this:

The main

The floating rate system is tighter.

That is,

a given size open market operation will have more effect on market
interest rates and on quantities of "money11 and credit.

Less

of the open market operation will be dissipated by borrowing from
or repaying the Fed.




Professor Lester Chandler

"

1S?

-

July 28, 1966

This might be considered an advantage, although
understand why.

I don't

After all, nothing prevents the Fed's Governors

from making bigger open market operations if they want to, or from
changing the discount rate if they don't want to.
But there is another side of the same coin.

A floating

rate system will also respond more radically to outside shocks and
oppose them more strongly.

Thus suppose there is a boom which

increases demands for bank loans.

Under the present system the

availability of loans at a fixed discount rate at the Fed permits
the banks to meet some of these demands, and limits the rise in
interest rates.

Under the floating rate system interest rates would

shoot up and quantities would be much less elastic.
The question is:
in the monetary system?

do you want more built-in stabilization

As in the fiscal area, built-in stabilizers

are great if you are being stabilized at the right place.

They are

a nuisance when they stick you in the wrong place.
I am certainly not convinced that a tighter system, with
stronger built-in stabilizers, is a good idea.
valve of discounting is probably good.

I think the safety

It gives the Fed time to

react to events, whether the events are its own policies of external
shocks.
Third, I suspect that the willingness to throw away the
discount rate reflects the quantitative bias of a large number
of monetary economists.




The discount rate is, or at least could

Professor Lester Chandler

~ 153 -

July

be, a powerful regulator of interest rates.

28,

1966

In my view the Fed

cannot ignore interest rates in favor of any quantitative rules
for reserves, or for M [money] in any of its various definitions. Moreover, I would like to see the Fed's control of rates strengthened,
and the allocative efficiency of the banking system improved, by
making the discount rate applicable to positive excess reserves.
In any case, is it wise to advise a government agency
to throw away a control instrument?

There may be times when a

multiplicity of goals and constraints would make the lost instrument
valuable.

[One may maintain the same bill rate either by a high

discount rate and lots of free reserves or by a low discount
rate and negative free reserves.

The implications for domestic

activity, the balance of payments, and the cost of the public debt
are not the same.]
Fourth, under most proposals, a floating discount rate
would float at a fixed differential above the market rate on Treasury
bills.

These are some real conceptual difficulties in this idea of

a "penalty rate.11
rate?

For how long can a bank borrow at today's discount

Only overnight?

If so, a constant spread from the 3-month

bill rate means a different thing depending on rate expectations.
If rates are expected to go down, it would be worth borrowing to buy
bills even at an apparent penalty rate.
expectations.




Not so with neutral or opposite

Perhaps the penalty should be a differential above a

Professor Lester Chandler

- 159 -

market rate for comparable liquidity and maturity?

July 28, 1966

Then if the

discount rate is geared to the 3-month bill rate, the Fed ! s loan
at the rate prevailing today would be for 3 months.




Sincerely,

James Tobin
Springbrook, Wisconsin
July 28, 1966

• 160 -

Henry C. Wallich
Yale University

The following principal forms of discount may be distinguished*
a.

The British,

There is no quantitative limitation upon

the market's access to the central bank.

Control of reserves is purely

through the discount rate, aside from instruments other than the discount
mechanism.

One corollary of this is that the volume of discounting in

practice will be very small.

So long as the money market rate is below

the discount rate, there is no incentive to borrow; when it goes above,
the volume of borrowing would become very large, unless the central
bank raises the discount rate,
A second corollary is that the discount rate must be changed
frequently under this system, unless other instruments are used actively
to keep the market rate below the discount rate.

In practice the Bank

of England does use open market operations very actively, at times to
the extent of virtually pegging the bill rate.
A third corollary is that the discount rate is always a penalty
rate with respect to money markets rates but not, of course, with respect
to customer loan rates,

b.

The American,

The American system has in common with the

British that only a small part, if any, of total bank reserves is
supplied through the discount window.

The great bulk comes through open

market operations and the balance of payments.




In the American system,

- 161 -

however, there are quantitative restraints, through Regulation A.
the discount rate need not be a penalty rate.

Hence

Nor does the volume of

discounting become so large, once the market rate goes above the discount
rate, as it would if there were no quantitative restraints.
The American system does to the member banks what the member
banks do to their customers:

it rations credit.

Since this seems to

be a basic part of banking tehcnique, I see no greal evil in its b eing
applied at the central bank level as well as at the commercial bank level.
It must be recognized, however, as a form of market imperfection.

On

the other hand, a perfect market, regulated only by price, may have to
undergo larger rate fluctuations than the American system.
tions in interest rates have their own drawbacks.

Wide fluctua-

When the balance of

payments is sensitive in one direction or another, wide fluctuations in
interest rates may even be inadmissable,

A rate held stable at some level

to achieve a balance of payments objective, on the other hand this would
greatly reduce the scope for domestic monetary policy of a monetary
control mechanism relying wholly on rate and not at all on rationing,

c.

Discount ceilings. Some monetary systems operate with a

very large volume of permanent rediscounts.

Here a significant part of

total reserves originates from the discount window.

The French and

Japanese systems are of this sort and also several Latin American
countries, such as El Salvador and Colombia,

This system, generally

though not always, requires rediscount ceilings.




Each bank is assigned

- 162 -

a rediscount quota which very often it utilizes rather fully.

The

effective control then flows, not through the discount rate, but through
the control of these ceilings.

This system can be combined with a

penalty rate device for discounts in excess of the ceiling, as in France.
An alternative version of this system, including the ceiling
device, leads to a relatively low exhauston of rediscount quotas, even
though a substantial part of reserves is supplied by rediscounts.
is an example.

Germany

German banks, in contrast to French, usually discount for

only a fraction of their quota.

Nevertheless, a substantial part of

their reserves is derived from discounts.

To some extent the level of

discounting seems to be governed by the rate, given the reserves supplied
by other policy tools.

At the same time, a kind of "reluctance" to

exhaust the quota seems to be operative, which makes the German system
a mixture of the French, American, and British.
The French system, with its tight ceilings, requires great
agility of the central bank in the
tightness.

open market" to avoid extreme sudden

This tendency toward an unstable degree of tightness was

enhanced by the absence, until quite recently, of required reserves in
France, as well as by the absence of a good money market.

d.

The Canadian floating rate system had too little time in

operation to permit much generalization.

Discounts under such a system

should always be small, since discounting will be profitable only,
assuming bankers have adequate supplies of bills, when the bill rate




- 163 -

during the week rises above the bill auction rate at the beginning of
the week by more than the margin fixed between the discount rate and the
auction rate.

In Canada this meant a rise of 0.25 per cent, the system

operated to my recollection.
This procedure is halfway on the road to closing the discount
window altogether*

Its operational implications for the central bank

are likely to be:

(1) The impediment to access to the discount window

makes money market rates more unstable.

(2) If the central bank wants

to avoid unstable rates, its open market operations must be agile than
when discounting is feasible.

With a good money market, as in Canada,

and with access to the New York market, the instability of interest
rates should nevertheless not be too pronounced,

e

«

Different^iaJL discount^ rates to subsidize particular purposes

exist in many parts of the world.

One

aspect is eligibility.

To make

a credit instrument ineligible is equivalent to putting a very high discount
rate upon it.
Another version is a perferentially low rate.

Many countries

practice or did practice this, and in developing countries it is the
rule.

The question is whether the subsidy or penalty for the discount-

ing bank is passed on to the customer who generates the paper.

Generally

this will be true only if the bank is discounting or planning to discount,
and possibly not even then.

Thus the system presuposes that a substantial

volume of bank reserves is derived from rediscounts.




- 154 From the foregoing, some conclusions can be drawn as to
institutional changes in the United States*
a.

I do not think that a system where discounting is

regulated purely by price is desirable for the United States.

Such a

system implies wide swings in rates, and there is widespread resistance
in this country to high rates. Wide swings required by domestic
standards may be at odds with the balance of payments situation, which
has shown itself to be sensitive.

The American economy seems better

served with a system involving some rationing.
b.

The same arguments can be made against the Canadian system*

It is true that this system is designed to take the central bank off the
hook as far as announcement effects are concerned.

But since it is the

central bank which in part determines the state of the market, it cannot
really plead "not guilty.ff

Its critics certainly will not be swayed

by such a plea.
c.

Since the volume of rediscounts ordinarily is not great,

preferential discount rates would have no great effect.

It is true that

we have the habit of subsidizing various sectors by Federal action influencing interest rates.

I hope that, in view of the low efficacy of

the discount mechanism in providing such subsidies, the Federal Reserve
can stay clear of the complications, political and otherwise, that would
result.




- .165 -

To wind up^ a few selective and, I fear, superficial comments
on your questions•
Question 1,
of banking.

The CD technique has greatly altered the nature

It seems clear that this should affect discounting.

So

long as CD's are an alternative source of funds, the need to keep the
discount window open seems to have diminished, at least for banks capable
of issuing CD's,
If large banks have less need for the discount window it should
be considered whether the discount window should give favorable treatment to banks too small to issue CD's, to maintain competitive equilibrium.
In the short run, however, the immediate effect of the CD's
may well have been to destablize the banking system.

Certainly it is

uncomfortable to see banks ooerate with heavy short-term maturities and
no obvious sources of meeting them other than the central bank.

Until

we have learned more about the likelihood of "panics" under the CD
system, nothing should be done that suddenly reduces banks1 access to
rediscoun ts,

Question 2.

A regional differential was the original intent

of the Federal Reserve Act,

Expierience has shown its limitations.

Preferential discounting for small banks may be a logical consequence
of the evolution of CD f s.

Question 3,

My answer to this was given above.

of rationing seems desirable in the American context.




Some degree

- 166 -

Question 4.

I think this is a bad idea in principle.

Purchas-

ing municipal bonds, corporate securities, or whatever is unlikely to
have a significant effect on interest rates, given the small volume the
Federal Reserve could buy.
involves subsidization.
would be tremendous.

To the extent that there is an effect, it

The problem of discrimination among issuers

If the Federal Reserve c an resist the politicians

on this, it ought to resist.

Question 5. The fact that many banks seem to have run out of
unpledged government bonds is a problem, but more liquidity than for the
ability to borrow.

For banks that really have no free government

securities, the existing range of eligible instruments ought to be
sufficient.

It would have to be shown that some banks are prevented

from discounting within the terms of Regulation A by lack of eligible
assets before changes are made.

In an emergency, all reasonable assets

should be eligible, as is the case now.

Question 6.

This question can be answered best by people

familiar with the problems of banks that come to the discount window.

Question 7.

Lending to nonmember banks seems reasonable, if

such banks meet certain conditions even though not meeting all.
possibility could be examined.

This

Mutual savings banks can become members;

the nature of their business suggests that they should have access to
the Federal Reserve only in emergencies, but in that case liberally.




- 167 *

Savings and loari associations do have their own central bank, although
I sometimes wonder whether the financing of long-term lending by the
home loan banks is very desirable.

Provision should be made for

availability of funds in an emergency.

This may involve some kind of

recourse, direct or indirect, to the Federal Reserve.

Question 8a»

Experience shown this to be useless.

8b.

Probably useless as explained above.

8c.

Worth examining, in order to minimize the

rationing aspect of our system.

8d.

As pointed out above I do not regard the

Canadian technique as desirable.

I question the wisdom also of other

alternative methods on the general grounds that, while such methods often
may give good results and frequently may protect the Federal Reserve
from criticism, occasionally they may mislead very badly.

8e.
and at other times not.

The announcement effect is sometimes desirable
I do not believe that a general formula for

weakening or strengthening it should be sought.

The Federal Reserve

should try to make its intentions clear by accompanying statements,

8f,
such as to:

More frequent changes would have many advantages,

(1) reduce the announcement effect, (2) minimize changes

in the relationship of discount and market rates, and (3) minimize the




- 168 -

need to overcome effects of such changes by means of other techniques.
They would also serve to loosen the relationship between discount rate
and prime rate as well as time deposit rates.

On the other hand, if

these relationships are regarded as valuable, for instance as a means,
for the Federal Reserve, of directly influencing prime rate and deposit
rates, changes cannot be made frequently.

The Federal Reserve probably

will have to make up its mind in which direction it wants to go.

Question 9.

The logical corollary of interest paid on reserves

is to allow banks to pay interest on demand deposits.

Given the ex-

perience with time deposit rates, I do not c onsider this move advisable.

Certainly it would strengthen the tendencies toward concentration

in American banking*
desirable.

Hence payment of interest on reserves seems un-

[In view of the rise in short-term rates since early 1966,

I am compelled to question my belief as of that date that no interest
should be paid on demand deposits.]




- 169 -

C. R. Whittlesey
University of Pennsylvania

The remarks that follow make no attempt to touch on all the
questions asked.

Omissions tend to reflect a feeling that the particu-

lar issues raised are less fundamental or that my views on them are
likely to prove less useful than on the others.
I take discount policy to refer both (1) to changes in the
rate and (2) to operations as conventionally carried on at the discount window with the Reserve Banks standing ready to meet emergency
needs (construing this somewhat broadly) but trying not to become an
easy source of supplementary capital for speculative or ordinary banking purposes.
injurious.

The first is of very little use and may be positively

Discount policy in the second sense is a useful device

for effecting reserve adjustments, particularly for banks less well
served by more sophisticated money market techniques.

It permits the

other instruments to be used more freely, without providing an escape
that seriously blunts their effectiveness.

There is little likeli-

hood, happily, that discounting to fulfill the role of lender of last
resort in the historical sense will be necessary.

But its continuing

availability for this purpose should nevertheless have a valuable
therapeutic--that is, tension relieving--effeet.
Discount policy in the second sense is primarily a means of
supplying the liquidity needs of individual banks.

It would contribute

to doing the same for a region to the extent that conditions affecting




- 170 -

the individual banks would be common to that area, (That happened a
number of years ago when there were adverse weather conditions in the
north central region.)

The success in recent years of efforts to

alter the structure of interest rates indicates that views often
expressed as to the ready substitutability of different kinds of
credit are exaggerated.

The evidence suggests that discounting may

be able to alter the allocation of credit among banks, regions, and
uses.

It is less clear that it ought to be used for this purpose,

but I should not like to preclude the possibility.
Primary reliance should be on open market operations where
the Federal Reserve wishes to play an active role, and on discounting
(advances approximately as at present) where it wishes to play a
passive role.

Discount policy is ancillary to open market operations

and not, as was once held, the other way around.

While I do not fore-

see any urgent need for changing reserve requirements, the case against
the instrument has typically been badly made.

I am not in favor of

abandoning the instrument and should like to see it made the subject of
full and careful analysis.

I should also like to see some considera-

tion given, by study or otherwise, to the possibility of discretionary
administration of the discount window.

I am not particularly attracted

to the idea of paying interest (at a variable rate?) on member bank
deposits including excess reserves but should welcome a fuller exploration of the suggestion.
Most of the questions on the second page of the request
memorandum turn on the adoption of rules of various kinds,,




The only

- 171 hard-and-fast rule that I favor is to avoid hard-and-fast rules.

Some

of the limitations and criteria suggested or implied strike me as
quite objectionable (for example, Questions 6, 8a, 8c). Others might
be worth experimenting with, while retaining freedom to alter or
abandon them if it should seem desirable to do so (Questions 8d, 8f).
Still others seem to call for elaboration with a view to indicating
more precise assumptions before expressing a specific judgment
(Questions 7, 8b).
In general, I am opposed to fixed rules and administrative
formulas.

Officials of the Federal Reserve should have authority to do

a great many things, far more than at present.

And they should be free

from inhibiting and enervating limitations on that power, other than
the sense of responsibility that goes with their office and with the
knowledge that they share obligations and accountability with other
agencies of the Government.

I do not believe that granting greatly

expanded standby powers would lead, over the long run, to more intervention and should hope that it might mean less.
"Announcement effects," including others than those related
to discount rate changes, are by no means to be condemned out of hand.
A great deal more study could well be given to the whole question of
the psychological effects of Federal Reserve policy.

The Federal

Reserve compares extremely well with other central banks and with
itself in the past with respect to providing the public with information.




But still further progress can be made in the same direction.

- 172 -

In particular, there is a strong presumption, despite all that has
been said against it, for fuller disclosure of Federal Reserve actions
and the reasoning on which they are based.