View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

WINTER 2011
Volume 2 Number 1

F refront

New Ideas on Economic Policy from the federal reserve bank
of cleveland

The Future of
Financial Market Regulation

INSIDE:

Slowing Speculation in Housing
Introducing the
Cleveland Financial Stress Index
A Bad Bank, for the Greater Good

PLUS :

Interview with Charles Calomiris

F refront

New Ideas on Economic Policy from the federal reserve bank
of cleveland

6

		WINTER 2011

Volume 2 Number 1

		CONTENTS
1	President’s Message
2	Reader Comments
4	Upfront
Unemployment Benefits: Help or Hindrance?

6	Rules and Regulations
How the Details Take Shape

10	Early Warning
Introducing the Cleveland Financial Stress Index

12	How to Build a Bad Bank
For the Greater Good

16	Keeping Banks Strong
Conference on Countercyclical Capital Requirements

12

20	Slowing Speculation
A Proposal to Lessen Undesirable Housing Transactions

26		Interview with Charles Calomiris

26
20
The views expressed in Forefront are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Federal Reserve System.
Content may be reprinted with the disclaimer above and credited
to Forefront. Send copies of reprinted material to the Public Affairs
Department of the Cleveland Fed.
Forefront
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
PO Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101-1387
forefront@clev.frb.org
clevelandfed.org/forefront

Columbia University banking scholar appraises regulatory reform

32	Book Review
All the Devils Are Here
President and CEO: Sandra Pianalto
Editor-In-Chief: M
 ark Sniderman,
Executive Vice President and Chief Policy Officer
Managing Editor: Robin Ratliff
Editor: Doug Campbell
Associate Editors: Amy Koehnen, Michele Lachman
Art Director: Michael Galka
Designer: Natalie Bashkin
Web Managers: Stephen Gracey, David Toth
Contributors:
O. Emre Ergungor
Thomas Fitzpatrick
Elizabeth Hanna
Joseph Haubrich
Natalie Karrs

Dan Littman
Lou Marich
April McClellan-Copeland
Jennifer Ransom

Editorial Board:
Ruth Clevenger, Vice President, Community Development
Kelly Banks, Vice President, Community Relations
Stephen Ong, Vice President, Supervision and Regulation
James Savage, Vice President, Public Affairs
Mark Schweitzer, Senior Vice President, Research
James Thomson, Vice President, Research

PRESIDENT’S MESSAGE
Sandra Pianalto
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Now that some of
the worst effects of the
financial crisis are fading,
our attention has properly
turned to the future. The
Dodd–Frank Wall Street
Reform and Consumer
Protection Act of 2010
contains Congress’s blueprint for addressing gaps in the financial market regulatory and supervisory framework, the types
of gaps that contributed to the tumultuous events of 2007 and
2008. Among other key provisions, the new law calls for greater
oversight of the shadow banking system, stricter supervision of
systemically important financial institutions, and a resolution
authority to deal with too-big-to-fail financial firms.
Those provisions cover a lot of territory. In this issue of
Forefront, we explain some of the ways that the details will get
worked out. Congress has asked the Federal Reserve and other
regulatory agencies to write hundreds of new rules as part of
Dodd–Frank’s implementation. The law requires many of these
rules to be final as soon as this summer.
Of course, Dodd–Frank did not cover everything. As the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland’s James Thomson argues
in this issue, the creation of a federally chartered “bad bank” to
acquire and dispose of distressed assets is another idea whose
merits should be considered. The Bank’s Emre Ergungor and
Thomas Fitzpatrick make the case for states to evaluate some
options that would make it harder for irresponsible investors
to neglect their properties.

This issue also includes an update on the Bank’s model for
detecting systemic risk in the financial system­— a model we
hope can be a useful tool for newly created entities such as the
Financial Stability Oversight Council. Finally, we interview
banking scholar Charles Calomiris, who comments on elements
specific to Dodd–Frank as well as additional ideas he considers
important to regulatory reform.
As always, we’d like your comments on these efforts, just as we
encourage all points of view about the implementation of the
new legislation.
In the past, I’ve likened the rule-making phase to the finishing
of a house. With skillful craftsmanship, we can carry out this
complicated and challenging responsibility in a way that makes
our financial house solid and secure. An open, continuous
dialogue that considers many perspectives is most likely to
achieve the goal of financial stability.
I invite you to get involved. An enormous amount of information
on the proposals is already available through dedicated websites
from the Federal Reserve and other financial system regulators.
It’s easy to comment. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s
Freedom of Information Office at www.federalreserve.gov or
visit www.regulations.gov to read the proposed rules and then
have your say.
Working together, we can build a stronger and more stable
financial system. So speak up—we are listening. ■

F refront

1

Reader Comments

Stop Investing in Stadiums… Start Investing in Kids
Forefront Fall 2010

Stephanie
Wright Byrd

Success By 6®, a strategic initiative of United Way of Greater
Cincinnati, is working to improve outcomes for young children
in support of the organization’s number one priority—
“Children are prepared for kindergarten.” Our work is
focused on improving the early childhood system by
increasing access to high-quality early childhood education
and best practice home visitation. The combination of these
services, when targeted to reach at-risk children, prenatal
through age 5, has proven to be effective in improving
health outcomes and kindergarten readiness.
The current system too often falls short in meeting the needs
of young children, in part due to misaligned goals among
child-serving programs, insufficient funding of services, and
inconsistent quality standards. In 2007, United Way established the Winning Beginnings campaign for early childhood
to provide local, private resources to improve the system
and increase access to quality services.
The scholarship model being piloted in Minnesota is a
promising way of getting children into quality programs
using demand-side incentives. Our strategies focus on both
supply and demand. On the demand side we aim specifically

2

Winter 2011

at getting children enrolled in programs that work, including
Every Child Succeeds home visitation and the Cincinnati
Public School Summer Bridge program, among others.
On the supply side, working with 4C for Children, the local
resource and referral agency, we help child care programs
achieve and maintain quality standards through leadership
development and coaching. We have established Learning
Circles for quality-rated programs to understand how to use
data to drive decisions and improve practice.
The work we are doing in the Greater Cincinnati community
is an important part of the cradle-to-career education continuum, a philosophy that has been adopted by members of
the local business, academic, and philanthropic communities.
When state and federal policymakers incorporate early
childhood education — prenatal through age 5 — into the
education continuum, with funding, aligned standards,
and consistent access, we will see improved outcomes for
children and communities across the country.
Stephanie Wright Byrd, MHA
Executive Director
Success By 6®
Cincinnati, Ohio

Rebekah
Dorman

For those of us who have been working in the field of
early childhood for years, the recent economic research
of Art Rolnick, James Heckman, and others, demonstrating
the high return on investment of early childhood programs,
has literally changed the conversation we can have with both
public- and private-sector leaders. We are now able to say
investing in early childhood is not only the “right” thing to
do—it’s the smart thing to do. We are indebted to economists for giving us this new perspective on our work and a
new way of describing its impact.
In “Stop Investing in Stadiums… Start Investing in Kids,”
Rolnick describes the Minnesota Early Learning Foundation
and its new flagship program, Scholarship Plus. Rolnick
outlines four key aspects of the work in Minnesota: Start
early (prenatally), be able to go to scale, measure results,
and engage parents. I am proud to say that in Cuyahoga
County, Ohio, we have a 10-year old, nationally recognized,
comprehensive early childhood system named Invest in
Children built on those same tenets. Invest in Children is a
public/private partnership staffed by the Cuyahoga County
Office of Early Childhood, and we have the evaluation data
to show that we are making a difference. Our independent
evaluation is conducted by the Center for Urban Poverty
and Community Development in the Mandel School of
Applied Social Sciences at Case Western Reserve University.
The continuum of services we offer begins during the
prenatal period and continues until the child reaches kinder­
garten. The continuum includes home visiting programs,
health and behavioral health programs, and a number of
child care initiatives to raise the quality of care across all
settings for children 0 to 6 years. We are in the fourth year
of our Universal Pre-Kindergarten Program, which provides

high-quality care to 1,000 preschoolers across the county
and makes it accessible to low- and moderate-income
families via parent scholarships. Many of our families access
multiple programs, according to their needs and the age
of the child, and over 160,000 children have been served in the
past decade.
Here are some of our evaluation results:
■

 edical concerns were addressed at 39 percent of
M
the nurse home visits to mothers and their newborns,
potentially avoiding more costly forms of medical care.

	Eighty-six percent of low-income families in our Medical

■

Home Pilot Program brought their child to all of their well
child visits during the first year of life as compared to a
rate of 40 percent in the general Medicaid population.

	Children in our Universal Pre-Kindergarten Program

■

entering the Cleveland Metropolitan School District
scored three points higher on the Kindergarten Readiness
Assessment for Literacy than average for the district.
In addition, children who had scored the lowest on
cognitive measures upon entrance to the program
showed the most significant gains at exit.
We are all aware that tough choices lie ahead on state and
local budgets. It is our hope that at a time when funds are
tight, policymakers will use limited dollars where they can
have the greatest impact. We encourage private funders to
do the same. In the words of Rolnick, “I think it’s important
for communities to get their priorities in order to make it
clear that this is an area we can’t afford not to invest in.”
Rebekah L. Dorman, PhD
Director
Office of Early Childhood Invest in Children
Cleveland, Ohio

Using the CRA to Fight Vacancy and Abandonment
Forefront Spring 2010
While I don’t disagree with the proposal of using CRA money
to fight vacancy and abandonment, this situation would not
have occurred had the banks not created it through foreclosure in the first place. Though this proposal would assist
with rebuilding neighborhoods, it would be of greater assistance not to allow this situation to occur in the first place.
One of the biggest issues nationwide is banks’ reluctance
to write off principal and allow moderate-income families
to stay in their homes. Then, adding insult to injury, these
homes remain vacant, until the bank writes off the loan,

then sells the property at auction for less money than the
original homeowner (who now is unable to obtain another
mortgage due to foreclosure and bad credit) could have paid.
In addition to these measures, CRA funds should be used to
allow those who have suffered foreclosure to receive alternate
mortgage loans with no time frame penalties, and also be
used to write down principal. It has never made sense to me
to foreclose on someone and then sell their house for a price
that the original owners could have paid.
Jody Veler
Egg Harbor City, New Jersey

F refront

3

Upfr nt
Unemployment Benefits: Help or Hindrance?
Amy Koehnen,
Associate Editor

Almost 15 million Americans
were jobless as of the end of 2010,
a strikingly high 9.4 percent of
the would-be working population.
Although the mass layoffs that
marked the beginning of the
recession have tapered off, people
who are out of work are having a
hard time finding new jobs. A full
6.2 million of the unemployed have
been that way for at least half a
year. On average today, the unemployed stay out of work for a recordhigh 34 weeks, about 50 percent
longer than in previous cycles.
As a consequence, more unemployed Americans than ever are
tapping federal unemployment
insurance (UI) benefits after
exhausting state benefits. This
situation has reignited a policy
debate: Are overly generous benefits at least partly responsible for
the rising unemployment rate?

The debate centers on two main
arguments. One is that UI increases
the nation’s unemployment rate
and lengthens unemployment spells
because job seekers put less effort
into the search, a form of what
economists term “moral hazard.”
The other is that UI is not a signifi­
cant factor in unemployment
duration or rate, and something
else is mainly responsible for the
high numbers of both.

A New Deal
Signed into law by President Franklin
Roosevelt in 1935 in response to the
Great Depression, the Social Security
Act provided the original framework
of the unemployment insurance
system. UI provides benefits for
eligible workers who have lost their
jobs involuntarily. Regular benefits
are based on a percentage of an
individual’s earnings over a recent
52-week period and are paid for
a maximum of 26 weeks in most
states.

Unemployment Benefits:
A Disincentive to Job Seeking?
Harvard economist Robert Barro
is one of the highest-profile critics
of unemployment benefits. In a
recent Wall Street Journal op-ed,
he argued that in trying economic
times, it is reasonable to adopt a
more generous UI program—but
not one that lasts almost two years.
Unemployment benefits decrease
efficiency, Barro and others argue,
because the program subsidizes
unemployment and can cause
insufficient job search, job acceptance, and levels of employment.
An unemployed person drawing
benefits, for example, might search
less vigorously for a job or be more
selective about accepting offers
than he would be in the absence
of benefits.

Unemployment Benefits:
An Economic Booster?
Some people may indeed take
longer to find a new job because of
unemploy­ment insurance extensions,
but many economists think that UI
is not a large contributing factor in
driving up the rate of unemployment
or in lengthening its average duration.

Timeline of the Emergency Unemployment Compensation Program (EUC08)
June 30, 2008 EUC08 program is introduced, with a 13-week

maxi­mum extension of benefits; set to expire March 28, 2009
(last day to file).

2008

February 17, 2009 Expiration date extended to December 26, 2009;

everyone receiving benefits under EUC08 to receive an additional
$25 weekly benefit.

2009
November 21, 2008 Maximum extension of benefits increased to

20 weeks; Tier II benefits introduced, providing up to an additional
13 weeks of benefits for those who worked in states with a total
unemployment rate of at least 6 percent.

4

Winter 2011

Economists at the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco compared
the duration of unemployment
in four categories: involuntary
job losers, voluntary job leavers,
new labor market entrants, and
re-entrants. Their goal was to find
out whether there was a difference
in length of unemployment between
involuntary job losers (who are
usually eligible for UI) and job leavers,
new labor market entrants, and
re-entrants (who usually are not).
The results showed that involuntary
job losers remain unemployed
slightly longer than unemployed
workers who are not eligible for
benefits, indicating that extended
UI benefits have a modest impact
on unemployment duration.
The economists concluded that
the impact of extended insurance
benefits on the unemployment
rate for all of 2009 and the first half
of 2010 was about 0.8 percentage
point. So, at the end of June 2010,
the unemployment rate would have
been 8.7 percent (compared with
9.5 percent if no UI program had
been in place).
Another analysis looks at the broad
economic effects of unemployment
insurance. Federal Reserve Bank
of Philadelphia senior economist
Shigeru Fujita contends that the

positive relationship between the
level of benefits and the duration of
unemployment is socially desirable.
The benefits can improve unemployed people’s well-being, he says,
by helping them avoid large drops
in consumption in the face of job
losses.

period when extended unemployment insurance was in effect, job
openings in the U.S. economy were
at very depressed levels.” In other
words, the unemployed couldn’t
have gone off the rolls if they had
wanted to—there was no work
for them.

Since UI benefits increase the
amount of cash the unemployed
have, their consumption is supported, Fujita says, which improves the
economy’s welfare. And when these
workers continue to receive benefits,
the pressure to accept a low-paying
job is reduced. While this pattern
initially seems counterproductive,
it also may serve as motivation for
creating higher-paying jobs in order
to attract workers—another boost
to the economy.

It’s logical that it would take some
time for the unemployment rate to
come down after a large shock like
the one our nation recently experienced. Tasci’s view is in keeping with
that of many other economists: that
a large part of the unemployment
rate increase results from the severe
recession and the accompanying
decline in output, not from extended
benefits. ■
Recommended readings

Moreover, UI cannot explain the
doubling of the unemployment rate
during the recession, even when an
estimate of UI’s effect is on the high
end. “I do believe that the effect
on the unemployment rate is not
more than 1 percentage point,
probably less,” says Murat Tasci, an
economist at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland who specializes in
business cycles and labor markets.
“My conclusion is based on my
observation that, for most of the

November 6, 2009 Tier II benefits extended to 14 weeks and no
longer dependent on a state’s unemployment rate; Tier III (providing
up to 13 more weeks to those in states with an average unemployment
rate of 6 percent or higher) and Tier IV (providing up to an additional
six weeks if the state unemployment rate is at least 8.5 percent)
introduced.

Fujita, Shigeru. 2010. “Economic Effects of
the Unemployment Insurance Benefit.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia,
The Business Review (Q4): 20–7.
Valletta, Rob, and Katherine Kuang. 2010a.
“Extended Unemployment and UI Benefits.”
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
Economic Letter 12 (April 19).
Valletta, Rob, and Katherine Kuang. 2010b.
“Is Structural Unemployment on the Rise?”
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
Economic Letter 34 (November 8).

December 6, 2010 Federal unemployment benefits extended and

will remain in effect through the end of 2011 for workers who have
been laid off for more than 26 and less than 99 weeks.

2010
December 19, 2009 Expiration date extended to February 28, 2010.

2011
April 15, 2010 Expiration date extended to June 2, 2010.

March 2, 2010 Expiration date extended to April 5, 2010.

July 22, 2010 Expiration date extended to November 30, 2010.

F refront

5

Rules and Regulations:
How the Details Take Shape
April McClellan-Copeland,
Community Relations and Education

Last summer, Congress approved the most sweeping reforms to the financial
market regulatory system since the Great Depression with the Dodd–Frank
Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010. But that was only the
beginning. Now come the details—hammering out more than 250 rules among
11 different regulatory agencies (the Federal Reserve itself is responsible for
developing more than 50 new rules). Many of the rules are geared toward the
same goal—preventing a replay of the financial crisis that crippled the economy
from 2007 through 2009.

6

Winter 2011

Most people know the Federal Reserve for its highestprofile job—conducting monetary policy. But it’s the
Federal Reserve Board’s role as a regulatory agency that
empowers it to write rules to govern banks and protect
consumers’ financial transactions. In years past, the
Federal Reserve has aimed to protect Americans in their
financial dealings by implementing and enforcing laws
such as the Truth in Lending Act and the Credit Card
Accountability, Responsibility, and Disclosure Act.
Americans have been able to comment on proposed rules
and regulations in the federal decision-making process
for many years, but the rule-writing phase of the Dodd–
Frank implementation provides an unusually significant
opportunity for people to weigh in. Consider that the
Federal Reserve Act of 1913 was all of 31 pages long;
the Dodd–Frank legislation was more than 2,000 pages.
The impact of Dodd–Frank is wide and deep. It is safe to
say this is the best opportunity for citizens to influence
federal regulatory policy in generations.

The Writing of a Regulation
Laws often do not include all of the details needed to
explain how an individual, business, state or local government, or nonprofit might follow the law. To make laws
practical on a day-to-day basis, Congress authorizes certain
government agencies—including the Federal Reserve’s
Board of Governors—to create regulations.

The impact of Dodd­– Frank is wide and deep. It is safe
to say this is the best opportunity for citizens to influence
federal regulatory policy in generations.
New rules under Dodd–Frank will reach nearly every
piece of the financial market apparatus. Among the key
provisions:
•	A Financial Stability Oversight Council, whose members
include the Federal Reserve Chairman, Treasury
Secretary, and Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
head, to monitor systemic risks

Examples of Past Board of Governors Regulations

Regulation CC

Regulation B

Regulation C

Check Clearing for the
21st Century Act (Check 21)

Equal Credit Opportunity Act

Home Mortgage Disclosure Act

Enacted in 2003, this regulation prohibits
lenders from discriminating against credit
applicants, establishes guidelines for
gathering and evaluating credit information, and requires written notification
when credit is denied.

As amended in 2002, this regulation
provides the public with loan data that
can be used to help determine whether
financial institutions are serving the housing
needs of their communities; assists in
identifying possible discriminatory lending
patterns; and enforces anti-discrimination
statutes.

The 2003 Check 21 Act allows banks
to process more checks electronically
with a new negotiable instrument called
a substitute check. If you need to retrieve
a record of canceled checks, now you
can see copies of check fronts and backs,
the legal equivalent to the real thing.

F refront

7

The Rule-Making Process
PROPOSAL AND NOTICE
■

Agency proposes regulation, issues

PUBLIC COMMENT
	Public has a comment period

■

a press release, and lists it in the
Federal Register as an advance
notice of proposed rule­making,
which invites the public to participate
in the rulemaking process.
■

(usually 30 to 90 days), during
which time written comments
either supporting or opposing
the proposed regulation or ideas
for changes can be submitted at
www.regulations.gov or through
specific regulatory agencies.

 gency sends proposed regulation
A
to the Office of Management and
Budget (OMB) for approval.

•	Comments can be simple or

contain detailed arguments.

•	Anyone—from professional

lobbying groups to organized
interest groups to individuals—
can submit comments on a
proposed rule.

What’s the Difference
Between a Law and a Regulation?
Law: a rule of conduct or procedure established by custom,
agreement, or authority; once approved by Congress and the
president, a new law is called an act
Regulation: specific requirements issued by governmental
agencies about what is legal and what is not

Rule-making: the process by which regulations are developed

•	Enhanced standards for all large bank holding companies
—those with greater than $50 billion in assets—as well
as certain nonbank financial firms (insurers such as AIG,
for example)
•	Greater transparency to the over-the-counter derivatives
market; derivates include vehicles such as credit default
swaps, a sort of insurance that was blamed for the
buildup of risk that led to the financial crisis
•	A Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, funded by
the Federal Reserve but operating independently, to
administer consumer financial protection laws
And that’s just for starters. Other elements will reform the
regulation of credit rating agencies and require registration
by hedge fund managers with the Securities and Exchange
Commission.

8		Winter 2011

■

Recent research finds evidence
that public input influences policy
content, especially when the public
is involved in the early stages,
though there are conflicting opinions
about the role that public feedback
plays during rulemaking.

The rule-writing phase of Dodd–Frank began in earnest
early last fall. By the end of 2010, the Federal Reserve,
sometimes jointly with other agencies, had already opened
comments for seven proposals and initiated studies on
several others. A study of the proposed Volcker Rule,
for example, was launched with the Financial Stability
Oversight Council to learn more about the impact of
limiting the amount of proprietary trading—essentially,
playing the market with their own money—that banks
can do. In late December, the Board asked for comments
on a rule to establish new standards on debit card interchange fees, trying to ensure that debit card transactions
are reasonable and proportional to their costs. ■

GOVERNMENT OVERSIGHT
	OMB reviews the proposed regula-

■

tion and the analysis supporting it
and makes sure the proposal fits with
current administrative policy. In the
majority of cases, OMB approves the
regulation as is.

FINAL RULE

AMENDMENTS

The agency considers all the comments,
revises the regulation accordingly, and
issues a final rule, which is published in
the Federal Register.

	Agency proposes changes to the

■

final rule, based on a new law or
review of the regulation.
■

•	The OMB review has historically

 hanges are offered for public
C
comment.

	Final amendments are approved

■

been a confidential process, though
the level of confidentiality changes
with each administration.

by the agency and published in the
Federal Register.
■

• In recent years, special interest

groups have sprung up to promote
open government, accountability,
and citizen participation.

I f there are unusual circumstances,
an agency may instead issue an
interim final rule.

Resources
For updates on regulatory reform progress, the Federal Reserve provides
a number of resources, including
The Federal Reserve Board’s “Regulatory Reform” news webpage at
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform.htm

The Federal Reserve Board’s Freedom of Information Office at
www.federalreserve.gov or www.regulations.gov, where you can view or
comment on a proposed rule
The Federal Bank of St. Louis’ “Dodd–Frank Regulatory Reform Rules”
webpage at www.stlouisfed.org/regreformrules

F refront

9

Early Warning:
Introducing the
Cleveland Financial Stress Index
The financial crisis has raised interest around the world in developing models that
can spot the emergence of systemic risk. Last year in these pages, we described
the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland’s new early warning system, SAFE—short
for Systemic Assessment of the Financial Environment. (For an explanation of how
SAFE helps supervisors monitor the financial landscape, see Forefront Spring 2010,
“Spotting a Financial Crisis Before it Happens.”) Now we’d like to describe one of its
essential elements—an index that tracks financial stress.
Stephen Ong,
Vice President,
Supervision and Regulation

Building a model to forecast the condition of the financial
system is daunting in and of itself. Before a condition can
be forecast, it must be measured. And even before it can
be measured, it must be defined. In developing SAFE as
a robust tool for supervisors, we needed to take a fundamental step by first defining what systemic risk actually is
and then creating a measurement of it.
The key to defining the slippery concept of systemic risk
depends on the ability to recognize when stress in the
financial market reaches critical levels. While there is
no magic threshold, it’s fair to say that the probability of
10

Winter 2011

systemically risky financial conditions rises when financial
stress measures become elevated. Stress may be observed
in the movements of various financial market components,
including swings in the stock market or the rates of interest
required to issue debt.
That’s where the financial stress index comes in. With this
index, supervisors are better able to pinpoint when levels
of financial market stress have reached worrisome levels.
It’s much like the Dow Jones Industrial Average or the
S&P 500, which are designed to measure the level and
activity of the equity markets. Each index consists of a

unique set of components that are combined using related
index construc­tion methods. Interestingly, prior to 2007, a
public financial stress index for U.S. financial markets did
not exist. Since then, several have been developed, each
with its own unique elements and methods.
The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland has developed
its own financial stress index for use with its SAFE early
warning system. The Cleveland Financial Stress Index
(CFSI) is a continuous index constructed of daily public
market data. These data are collected from four sectors
of the financial markets: credit markets, foreign exchange
markets, equity markets, and interbank markets, providing
broad coverage of elements that may be indicators of
financial stress.
For example, components from credit markets include
various interest-rate spreads associated with debt instruments such as bonds. These spreads indicate perceived
risk in these instruments, and point to potential stress
in the markets. When the spread on a typical corporate
bond is large, for example, it suggests that investors have
grown wary of the borrower’s ability to stay current.
Various components from the equity markets represent
volatility and, therefore, the degree of stress in those
markets. In total, 11 different components derived from
these four markets are combined into a single index that
represents relative stress in the financial markets.
Using historical data, figure 1 depicts the CFSI and its
measurement of stress in the financial system since 1994.
Also included are indications of periods of financial stress
events. Notice that the index began to spike even before the
events in 2008 made clear the depth of the financial crisis.
Figure 2 shows the movements of specific components
within the FSI, providing insight into the amount of
stress that the four distinct markets of the component
inputs contributed to the overall index. As the figure shows,
the component from the foreign exchange market contributed substantially less to overall financial stress than did
the other markets. Measures from the credit, interbank,
and equity markets indicate significant levels of stress from
each, contributing to the overall financial stress of the
recent crisis.
The CFSI is not designed to predict, but rather to reflect,
current relative levels of systemic financial stress. It is
what’s known as a coincident indicator. That said, its use
of daily data—rather than less-frequent data, such as
weekly or monthly input—provides earlier indications

Figure 1. Cleveland Financial Stress Index
Index
6
Early 2000s recession

Asian crisis

5

LTCM crisis

4

Beginning of
recession

Terrorist attacks

3
2
1
0
–1
–2
–3
1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

Figure 2. Components of the Financial Stress Index
Percent
100

Q3:2007

Q2:2008

80
60
40
20
0
Dec
2006

June
2007

Dec
2007

Credit
market

June
2008

Interbank
market

Dec
2008
Equity
market

June
2009

Dec
2009

June
2010

Dec
2010

Foreign exchange
market

Note: First shaded bar represents the onset of the crisis and the second-steepest
rise on record; second shaded bar represents the peak of the crisis.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

of the existence of stress in the financial markets. Used in
tandem with our SAFE early warning system, the CFSI
acts as a robust measure of stress in the financial markets.
In addition, the design of the index and its use of com­
ponents from four distinct financial markets allow for
identification of the origin of the stress. To supervisors
charged with alleviating systemic risk, this is useful
information indeed. ■
Coming soon
The Cleveland Financial Stress Index will be posted on the Bank’s
homepage. Watch for it at
www.clevelandfed.org
F refront

11

How to Build a Bad Bank
­— for the Greater Good

James B. Thomson,
Vice President
and Financial Economist

Among the many unwanted things that taxpayers get
socked with during a financial crisis is a portfolio of
deeply distressed assets—loans gone sour, millions of
them, many of them sliced and bundled into securities
that nobody can sell because nobody wants to buy. The
overwhelming uncertainty around these troubled assets
can paralyze the financial system. Almost inevitably, they
fall into the government’s hands as a side effect of efforts
to rehabilitate the financial system and restore credit flows.
It’s an important and necessary step in nursing the financial market back to health. The government usually takes
possession of troubled assets either through receivership
of failing financial institutions or through programs that
strip distressed assets from struggling but still open-andoperating financial firms.1
1.	The originally planned use of the $700 billion in TARP funds was to strip
(through an outright purchase of) distressed assets from the balance sheets
of banks, thrifts, and nonbank financial firms.

12		

Winter 2011

These assets often go by the infamous term “toxic assets,”
the likes of which throttled so many financial institutions
in 2008 and 2009. And despite the economic damage they
did over the past few years, the problem of what to do about
them persists. Elements of the Dodd–Frank legislation
go a long way toward averting and dealing with financial
market meltdowns, as the legislation establishes a separate
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) resolution
authority for nonbank financial firms. But absent from
this legislation are provisions for handling troubled assets
on the scale generated during a financial meltdown.
It is true that the FDIC’s receivership operations are
set up to dispose of the assets from the estates of failed
financial firms during non-crisis times. U.S. federal deposit
agencies are funded by assessments on the industries they
insure, which limits their resources for dealing with largescale banking problems.
In other words, the FDIC’s operations currently are not
geared toward dealing with the volume of distressed assets
that would likely need to be managed in the aftermath of a
financial crisis; systemic crises require the marshalling of
resources beyond those normally available to the deposit
guarantor. Hence, there is a need for an institution whose
sole purpose is large-scale asset salvage—to acquire,
manage, and then dispose of the overhang of distressed
assets on the books of banks and other financial firms.

Such an institution is not a new concept. The government
and even the private sector have created special-purpose
entities to deal with troubled assets in all of the recent
financial crises. From the Great Depression to the 1980s
savings and loan debacle, vehicles of this sort have played
a role in getting the financial market functioning again.
		Some have done their jobs quite well; others not.
			Drawing on these lessons, I propose the creation of
				a resolution management corporation, or RMC. Call
		it an asset-salvage entity, or bad bank. The RMC that I
propose would be sponsored by and operated by the federal
govern­ment. It would become operational only in response
to a financial crisis where the volume of troubled assets
that needs to be managed and disposed of exceeds the
capacity of the FDIC’s receivership operations.
The RMC’s overarching goal: restoration of a stable, healthy
financial system at a minimal cost.

The Trouble with Assets
An asset is said to be troubled, toxic, impaired—pick
your term—under a number of different conditions. If it
is a mortgage loan, it may be “nonperforming,” that is, the
borrower is no longer making payments. It could be an
entire bundle of mortgages made to subprime borrowers,
in which case finding a market value may be impossible.

It’s like a carton of eggs in a supermarket. They might
appear to be fine eggs, but if shoppers suspect they might
be tainted on the inside, the eggs might not sell at any
price. The market reaction to toxic assets is much the same.
These toxic assets, if large enough in scale, could wreak
havoc on the economy. Financial institutions are reluctant
to sell them, because the markets for these assets, if working
at all, tend to be very thin. The problem is made worse
if financial firms holding the assets are undercapitalized
and likely reluctant to undertake any actions that would
require them to recognize losses on these assets. Creditors
and counterparties grow nervous about doing business
with toxic-asset-owning financial institutions. Over time,
the uncertainty bleeds out into the real economy, freezing
the fundamental financial-sector activities of facilitating
people’s and firms’ borrowing, saving, and investing.
The logic of stripping away toxic assets from their current
owners is the same as ripping off a bandage—it hurts, but
it’s best to get it over with quickly. Otherwise, you only
prolong the pain.
History clearly teaches us the downside of nursing along
struggling firms—from the savings and loan industry in
the 1980s to Japan’s banks in the 1990s. Instead of shutting
them down and seizing their assets, the government

Some Bad Banks of the Past
Year established

Reconstruction
Finance Corp.

FDIC rescue of
Continental Illinois

Grant Street Bank

Resolution Trust Corp.

1932

1984

1988

1989

Take out problem loans,
place them in a “bad bank,”
leave the performing loans in
Continental Illinois

Split Mellon Bank into two,
with good assets remaining in
original bank and bad assets
moving to Grant Street

Manage and dispose of
assets that came into the
government’s hands from
the estates of failed thrifts

Purpose

Varied, but shifted to solvency
support of banking industry
		
		
Structure

Purchased equities from troubled
Part of FDIC operations
Separately chartered and
institutions as a means to 		
capitalized bank
recapitalize them; established 			
with its own balance sheet, 			
funded largely by issuing its own
debt claims

Results
Somewhat successful
Successfully allocated cash flows
		
associated with the distressed
		
assets between the existing
		
shareholders and the FDIC
			
Authority
Federal law—Reconstruction and
structure
Finance Corporation Act of 1932
		

Effective liquidation of Mellon’s
troubled assets by tying returns
to Mellon directly to the recovery
value of Grant Street’s troubled
assets, aligning incentives

Existing FDIC authority
Private company action
		
		

Constrained by funding
limits; lacked a clear mission
and had competing objectives;
no clear exit strategy

Delays in bringing troubled
assets from zombie thrifts
into the RTC’s portfolio,
with negative implications
for asset recovery value
Federal law—Financial
Institutions Reform, Recovery,
and Enforcement Act of 1989
F refront

13

injected these firms with liquidity and capital, further
exacerbating and extending the economic decline. By one
study (DeGennaro and Thomson), regulatory forbearance
—a policy of delaying a receivership process—quadrupled
the cost of the savings and loan crisis for taxpayers.
Until now, the way the government has gone about
trying to restore order hasn’t been very systematic. Past
experience with bad banks is mixed. The Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation had some success in setting up
a bad bank to handle the rescue of Continental Illinois
Bank and Trust Company of Chicago in May 1984; the
1989-created Resolution Trust Corporation, by contrast,
was hobbled for various reasons in its ability to manage
assets from failed thrift institutions (see box: Some Bad
Banks of the Past, page 13).

Four Keys
So, how should we go about establishing an effective bad
bank? Four features are crucial to the proper design of my
proposed resolution management corporation:

1	Transparency and accountability: Taxpayers need to be
able to track losses and gains. This can be accomplished
by a crystal-clear separation between the “good” and
“bad” assets, acknowledging at the start the losses from
toxic assets and the costs associated with managing and
disposing of them. This allows for an auditable allocation
of losses, which in turn properly aligns incentives for
efficient management and disposition of the toxic assets.

The more transparent decisions are at the beginning,
the more likely it will be that the financial system can be
rehabilitated quickly and credit flows restored. A straightforward way to accomplish a transparent separation of
toxic assets from the financial system would be to put the
failing institution through a receivership process.
A systemic regulator—perhaps the Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System along with either the FDIC,
the SEC (for securities broker–dealers), or the Federal
Insurance Office (for insurance companies), in consultation
with the Secretary of the Treasury—would make the call
on which firms should pass into receivership.

The troubled assets—mortgage securities and so forth—
would be set in a pile and valued as fairly as possible
(which, granted, could prove difficult). The creditors
might receive a certificate with a percentage claim to any
future cash flows from the asset. There might even be a
certain comfort level in handing over the assets because of
the next stage of the process.

2	A simple, unambiguous mission: A resolution management corporation should aim to maximize net recoveries
on the portfolio of distressed assets under its management. Period.

The bad bank must quickly return assets to the private
sector at the highest possible recovery value. A fast realization of losses is the surest path to economic recovery, as
financial market players can effectively take their lumps and
move on. The sick institutions themselves could be passed
into a bridge institution where they would be recapitalized,
and the bad assets moved into the resolution management
corporation for management and rehabilitation.
If it’s a security with, say, parts of 1,000 subprime mortgages,
there may be no initial market in which to sell it. So the
RMC would hold the security, and perhaps even take the
time and effort to “rehabilitate” some of its underlying
mortgages. Perhaps a certain homeowner had been out
of work and not paying, but then found a job. The RMC
could conceivably be the one that makes the phone calls
to get the borrower back on a payment schedule, even if
at a reduced rate.
There must be confidence that the bad bank will care for
the assets and then speedily return them to the private
sector, or be held responsible if not. The Government
Accountability Office should conduct periodic audits;
Congress should hear regular testimony from the bad
bank’s chief; and Congress should establish an independent
body to oversee the operations and activities.

3	Adequate resources: Bad banks need funding and
staffing. The funding is to pay for operations and costs
associated with stripping troubled assets from the failing
institution.

The independent bad bank should be given a revolving line
of credit with the U.S. Treasury, enough to fund operations
during the start-up period—perhaps about $100 billion.

14

Winter 2011

Kane’s Principles for Unconflicted Asset Salvage
Edward Kane, a Boston College economist, laid out the basic principles
for an effective asset-salvage entity more than 20 years ago. The entity
charged with maximizing net recovery on troubled assets needs to be
proficient in:
• rescue (peril reduction)
•	appraisal (damage evaluation, that is, documenting and valuing
inventories of damaged goods)

•	property management (efficiently protecting and enhancing
existing value)
•	sales (searching out potential buyers, communicating appraisal information to them, and running auctions or bargaining for the best price)
Moreover, for effective asset salvage, the public salvor must have access
to experts in each core activity as well as experts on the specific types of
assets that come under its supervision.

Source: Kane, Edward J. 1990. “Principal–Agent Problems in S&L Salvage.” The Journal of Finance 45(3): 755-64.

In this initial phase, the bad bank can acquire assets in
a manner that preserves their value and reduces losses
that insolvent and possibly neglectful institutions had let
mount. After that, the bad bank should seek permanent
operational funding from direct Congressional appropriations and issuance of bonds. The principal and interest on
the bonds would be funded through the (eventual) liqui­
dation of the assets. Because assets should be acquired at
fair value, little or no additional funding should be required
to cover shortfalls in the value of assets sold.
However structured, a bad bank should essentially be
established as a shelf organization. Its charter, funding
authority, and authorization for staffing and other resources
would always be in place, but the RMC itself would be
dormant until activated. And that activation should happen
only in case of a real fire—a widespread financial crisis, not
the sort of higher-frequency disruptions that are normal
in a cycle. Who would declare the RMC’s activation is a
matter of preference—it could be the FDIC’s board, the
newly created Financial Stability Oversight Council, the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, the
Secretary of the Treasury, or some combination of these.

4	A limited life span: Once the troubled assets have been
repaired and re-sold, the bad bank can fold up.

Establishing a fixed expiration date clearly ties the existence
of the RMC to its function. Ten years seems like a reasonable maximum life for such an entity. Once the need for
the function goes away, the RMC does, too. It also reduces
incentives to speculate on asset-recovery values by limiting
the maximum time any asset can be held. There is also the
more technical but important benefit of easing uncertainty

among market players about who will issue claims against
the expected cash flows from the troubled assets. They
will have a rough idea when the cash will start flowing,
because they know the bad bank will cease to exist when
its job is done. Any assets remaining on the RMC’s books
when its charter expires could be turned over to the FDIC’s
receivership function for eventual sale or liquidation.

A Necessary Reform
The way we respond to crises can either help or hinder the
recovery. The establishment of a government-chartered
RMC could go a long way along the “helping” path. At
best, a national “bad bank” should be seen as a complement
to other financial-crisis rescue efforts. We will still need
emergency liquidity and credit programs, for example.
But financial crises have grown more frequent in recent
decades. Perhaps if we had a system for dealing with the
most troubled assets up front, we would lessen the need
to deal with another crisis in the near future. ■

Recommended readings
Fitzpatrick, Thomas J., and James B. Thomson. 2011. “An End to Too
Big to Let Fail? The Dodd-Frank Act’s Orderly Liquidation Authority.”
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Commentary (January 6).
www.clevelandfed.org/research/commentary/2011/2011-01.cfm

Thomson, James B. 2010. “Cleaning Up the Refuse from a Financial Crisis:
The Case for a Resolution Management Corporation.” Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland Working Paper 10-15.
www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/2010/wp1015.pdf

DeGennaro, Ramon P., and James B. Thomson. 1996. “Capital
Forbearance and Thrifts: Examining the Costs of Regulatory Gambling.”
Journal of Financial Services Research 10(3): 199-211.

F refront

15

Keeping Banks Strong—
Countercyclical Capital Requirements

James B. Thomson,
Vice President
and Financial Economist

Joseph Haubrich,
Vice President and Economist

To measure a bank’s strength, one could look at factors
like profitability or stock price, but few gauges are as
revealing as a bank’s capital level. That is why supervisors
are increasingly turning to formal capital regulation as a
way to promote financial stability. The belief is that the
stronger individual institutions are, the safer the entire
financial system will be.
But capital requirements can have unintended effects
because they tend to be “procyclical.” During economic
expansions, banks need a smaller equity cushion to absorb
unanticipated losses in their assets than they do during
contractions. As a result, they increase leverage to accommodate credit demand in good times. They see little need
to boost capital levels when credit losses are low and
expected to remain that way. But in bad times, higher creditdefault rates force banks to eat into their capital buffers.

16		

Winter 2011

Faced with continued losses, banks look to conserve their
remaining capital, partly by reducing the credit supply.
The upshot of procyclical capital requirements is that
economic swings are more intense than they otherwise
would be. This is how credit bubbles are formed and burst.
That’s what happened in the Panic of 2008, when the
banking system corrected for its earlier exuberance by
dramatically curtailing lending activity and hoarding capital.
How can we avoid that problem in the future? How can
regulators encourage financial institutions to increase their
capital in good times, anticipating their needs when times
turn bad? How can we start thinking about the merits of
countercyclical capital requirements?
Last October, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland held
a conference to address these questions.

Performance, Risk, and Capital Buffer under Business Cycles and
Banking Regulations: Evidence from the Canadian Banking Sector

by Alaa Guidara, Van Son Lai, and Issouf Soumaré
(Laval University, Québec)

Canada offers an interesting case study for the United States. Although
their economies are closely connected, the two nations’ banking
sectors differ in both structure and performance. Canada’s system is
dominated by a handful of nationwide banking companies. The United
States has more than 10,000 insured depository institutions and,
although it has a few mega-banks, it has no truly nationwide bank.

To see how capital buffers affect the Canadian banking system’s
performance, the authors test the relationship between changes
in the capital buffer, bank risk, and bank performance. They find
evidence that Canadian capital buffers tend to be countercyclical.
Moreover, they find a positive relationship between Canadian banks’
capital buffers and their riskiness.

Guidara and his colleagues note that besides the Basel international
capital standards, Canadian banks are subject to a leveraging constraint
that could be adjusted according to the phases of the business cycle,
producing what’s known as a variable capital buffer. U.S. banks are
also subject to a leveraging constraint, but theirs is fixed and cannot
change with the business cycle.

What these authors do not account for, however, is that Canadian
banks are likely to have higher charter values than their U.S. counter­
parts—and charter values act as a constraint on risk-taking. If this
structure results in Canadian banks having high charter values, then
they would be expected to hold less risky portfolios than U.S. banks
and be better positioned to weather an economic downturn.

Countercyclical Provisions, Managerial Discretion,
and Loan Growth: The Case of Spain

by Santiago Carbó-Valverde and Francisco Rodríguez-Fernández
(University of Granada)

Spain provides another useful model for countercyclical regulatory
policy. In Canada, the buildup of capital buffers might simply represent
passive accumulation of earnings during a strong growth phase. But
starting in 2000, Spain adopted a policy of countercyclical loan-loss
provisioning, which sets aside reserves when bank profits are high
and loan growth is strong.

To analyze how Spain’s dynamic provisioning policy affects loan
growth, the authors use quarterly data on a sample of Spanish banks
from the first quarter of 2001 through the first quarter of 2010. They
test whether loan-loss provisioning in Spain before and during the
financial crisis resulted in procyclical reserving, income smoothing,
countercyclical loan growth, or some combination of them. Overall,
they find evidence of procyclical reserving and income smoothing,
although both of these effects decrease over the sample period.
The authors do not, however, find evidence that dynamic loan-loss
provisioning dampened loan growth at the peak of the credit cycle.
That is to say, the Spanish policy failed to do one of its most important jobs—smoothing loan growth over the credit cycle by reducing
incentives to overlend during the peak of the cycle.

By forcing banks to set aside reserves in good times, the policy reduces
the near-term profitability of bank lending and reduces incentives
to overlend. In doing so, this policy tames procyclicality in the bank
credit cycle. Dynamic provisioning also reduces the impact of loan
portfolio deterioration on bank credit decisions. This happens because reserves for loan losses can be drawn down during recessions,
lessening the need to set aside additional earnings to cover them.

The Trade-offs between Capital and Liquidity
Requirements: Theory, History, and Empirical Evidence

by Charles Calomiris
(Columbia University)

Calomiris reminds us that formal capital regulation is a relatively
modern phenomenon. For most of U.S. banking history, supervision
focused on liquidity (the liability side of the balance sheet rather than
the asset side). Because banks’ liabilities—banknotes before the
Federal Reserve era and bank deposits after—are an important part
of the money supply, regulation ensured that banks could meet
maturing obligations, particularly during periods of financial distress.
A bank’s failure to redeem banknotes or inability to offset deposit
withdrawals would mean closing its doors. Bank clearinghouses arose
in the nineteenth century partly to provide a liquidity backstop for
their members and, sometimes, for the broader banking system.

The next iteration of the Basel international capital accords (Basel III)
will include two kinds of liquidity standard. One is a coverage ratio
that requires banks to hold enough liquidity to withstand 30 days of
net cash outflows. The other is a net stable funding ratio that aims to
lessen mismatches between the maturity structures of assets and
liabilities. For example, a bank wouldn’t want to have all of its assets in
long-term mortgages and most of its liabilities in short-term deposits.
Liquidity risk also gets attention in the 2010 regulatory reform act.

A lesson from the past, which was relearned during the crisis of
2007–09, is that general market liquidity tends to dry up in response
to shocks to the system, particularly when firms start hoarding their
liquidity as part of a preservation strategy. To put it another way, a
source of liquidity is protective only if it can be tapped during a crisis.

Calomiris argues that regulatory policy should refocus on liquidity
and liquidity risk. But when establishing liquidity standards, the devil
is in the details. As Calomiris sees it, a practical approach to measuring
liquidity and implementing liquidity standards remains elusive. An
open question is whether policymakers’ current efforts to reward
financial market firms for limiting liquidity risk will prove productive.

F refront

17

Incentive Compensation, Accounting Discretion, and Bank Capital
Most writing on regulatory reform doesn’t bother with connections;
it often treats the effects of policy in isolation. A useful corrective to
this practice is provided by researchers at the Atlanta Fed, who look
at how new regulatory guidance on bankers’ pay will interact with
accounting rules to affect how banks adjust their capital buffer in good
times and bad.
Because accounting rules allow discretion in how firms report
gains and losses, it’s not surprising that firms engage in earnings
management, generally smoothing their earnings over time. Nor
is it surprising that bankers’ compensation affects how they smooth
earnings. And because retained earnings increase bank capital, and
declaring losses lowers it, anything that affects earnings management
affects bank capital.

by Timothy W. Koch, Dan Waggoner, and Larry D. Wall
(Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta)
price. If it’s earnings, the new guidance will reinforce the current counter­
cyclical pattern that results from smoothing earnings. With more
compensation coming from deferred bonuses with a potential clawback (that is, the ability of the firm or regulators to seek repayment
of some or all of a bonus payment), managers will want to make sure
earnings stay steady in the future, so that they actually see that bonus
when it is due to arrive. And with less sensitivity to performance,
bumping up earnings this year won’t add a lot to that bonus.
Putting more of the bonuses in stock, the other alternative, could
have the opposite effect. Managers could want a high price when
they sell their stock or exercise their options, so they might want to
goose earnings in the short term to boost share prices when they sell.

Regulatory guidance on compensation will have somewhat contradic­
tory effects on the cyclicality of bank capital. A lot depends on whether
the banker’s pay is based more on accounting earnings or on stock

The upshot is that incentive guidance on capital may have ambiguous
effects, which is less than satisfying. But there is really a larger point at
stake—the need to consider these sorts of interactions when making
policy, setting regulations, or establishing guidance.

Accounting for Banks, Capital Regulation, and Risk-Taking

by Jing Li
(Carnegie Mellon University)

Li formulates the regulatory question as one of choosing a capital
requirement and how bank capital is measured (that is, the accounting
standard). The question comes down to which accounting regime
most effectively controls excessive risk-taking by banks, given that
the regulations can have costly side effects.

Which accounting standard is best? The answer depends partly on
which comes first, the accounting standard or the capital requirement.
The government might coordinate these requirements, but the Federal
Reserve and the Financial Accounting Standards Board are quite
independent of each other.

The paper considers three accounting regimes: “historical cost”
accounting, in which assets are valued at their historical price; “lower
of cost or market value” accounting; and “fair value” accounting, in
which assets are marked to market prices. The accounting regime
that is adopted may effectively reduce capital, driving levels below
what regulators require and forcing an intervention. For example,
under fair-value accounting, a drop in the price of the asset would show
up as a loss, reducing capital, while value measured at historical cost
would show no change. If, as seems likely, asset prices move along
with the business cycle, the choice of accounting standard also affects
the amount of cyclicality in bank capital.

Overall, regulators face a rather complicated problem. Capital
requirements can reduce risk, but setting them too high shrinks the
banking system and reduces the liquidity they provide. Adopting the
appropriate accounting standard can help, but at the cost of curtailing
bank loans to productive enterprises. Regulators must balance the
relative importance of two bank activities: funding new businesses
and providing deposit accounts. Instead of coming to a once-and-forall decision, Li’s paper highlights the trade-offs and tough choices that
banking regulators and accounting boards must face.

Countercyclical Regulation under Collateralized Lending
Some banking historians have described the evolution of the recent
financial crisis as a run on collateral, especially in the repo market,
where institutions agree to sell securities and then repurchase them
at a specified date and price.
Bank capital regulation that focuses on credit risk doesn’t prevent the
type of contagion that exists in the interbank collateralized lending
markets. After all, the banks in Valderrama’s model are assumed to

18		

Winter 2011

by Laura Valderrama
(International Monetary Fund)
be default-free. So she proposes that regulators adopt policies that
deal specifically with the “spread of systemic liquidity risk” through
collateral runs. She shows that under certain conditions, adding a
liquidity buffer, a capital buffer, or a regulatory haircut on collateral
could reduce the probability of a repurchase run and help stabilize
financial markets.

Credit Derivatives and the
Default Risk of Large, Complex Financial Institutions
These authors explore a method of setting explicit numerical values
for bank capital requirements. By looking at the risk in 16 large,
complex institutions as well as the risk in the market for credit default
swaps, their paper paints an intriguing picture of risk transmission.
The story begins with a standard measure of risk that comes from
Nobel Prize winner Robert Merton, something called distance to
default. Let’s say the bank owns a portfolio of assets—loans, government bonds, cash in its ATMs—and that its portfolio is risky. Loans
may go bad, bond prices may fall, and robbers may steal the cash.
The bank also has debts, mainly to depositors but also to investors
who have bought senior and subordinated bonds. Merton assumes
that when the value of the assets falls below the value of the debt,
the firm is bankrupt and must close down (this leaves out accounting
issues, such as when the value is declared—admittedly important
but sometimes a distraction).
How far is the bank from defaulting? The distance-to-default approach
starts by finding out the bank portfolio’s risk or, put another way, its
variability. This is measured in standard deviations, perhaps familiar
from statistics classes. The distance to default is the number of standard
deviations that the bank’s value must fall before it drops below the
value of the debt. The more standard deviations, the further the
distance to default and the lower the chance of failure. Using standard

Managing Credit Booms and Busts
The authors ask how policymakers should respond to the continual
booms and busts in credit and asset markets. They point out that if
there is too much of something, one solution is to tax it. They argue
that there is too much borrowing, and prescribe a “pigouvian tax”
(after Arthur Pigou, the late Cambridge University economist). Of
course, this adds the problem of determining the right tax level,
which Jeanne and Korinek tackle.
The root of the problem is that excessive borrowing makes the
economy vulnerable to a feedback spiral when an adverse shock
arrives. Falling housing prices, worsening unemployment, or other
shocks make credit tighter, so people spend less. This further reduces
asset values and makes credit even tighter, continuing the downward
spiral. So the financial system exacerbates booms and busts in credit
and asset markets and, ultimately, in output and employment.

by Giovanni Calice (University of Southampton),
Christos Ioannidis (University of Bath), and
Julian M. Williams (University of Aberdeen)
deviations allows us to compare the riskiness of different-sized banks.
It would also make sense to declare a distance-to-default equivalent
to how much money a bank would have to lose to become insolvent,
but that might make a bigger bank look safer than a small one, even
if their chance of failure is the same.
It turns out that the distances to default of large, complex financial
institutions (like Citigroup and Goldman Sachs) often move together.
The distances also move together with the volatility of two indexes
of credit-default-swap markets. Credit default swaps are a way to
protect against bonds defaulting. One party to the swap “buys
protection,” paying what amounts to an insurance premium. The
other party “sells protection” by agreeing to make a large payment
if the bond defaults. There are two indexes for stocks, the Dow Jones
and the S&P; likewise, there are two indexes for credit defaults, the
iTraxx and the CDX. Using these indexes, Calice and his colleagues
show that the volatilities of bank assets and credit default swaps
move together. The authors put this down to the transmission of
volatility across banks via credit default swaps.
Furthermore, the distance to default measure provides a natural
stress test for a bank’s capital: Is the capital buffer large enough to
make default unlikely? The influence of the aggregate iTraxx and
CDX indexes, then, adds a cyclical component across firms.

by Olivier Jeanne (Johns Hopkins University) and
Anton Korinek (University of Maryland)
Curiously, the authors’ solution—to discourage excessive borrowing
by taxing it—is exactly the opposite of U.S. policy, which subsidizes
borrowing by making interest tax deductible for businesses and home
mortgages.
Jeanne and Korinek then take a step that too often is skipped: They
set out to quantify how much tax should be levied. Using U.S. data,
they estimate that imposing an additional tax of 0.5 percent on
household borrowing, and slightly more on business borrowing,
would counteract the effect of excessive borrowing. For example,
households might pay 4.5 percent instead of 4 percent on a loan.
Furthermore, the tax rate should vary with the business cycle. In
a boom, the tax slows the growth of debt; but during a recession,
the tax drops to avoid a worse decrease in spending. ■

Conference on Countercyclical Capital Requirements
For links to conference papers, go to
www.clevelandfed.org/research/conferences/2010/
10-14-2010_capital/index.cfm

Resources
Countercyclical capital requirements are the subject of some proposed
rules under the Dodd–Frank Act. For more information, see
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/reform.htm

F refront

19

Slowing Speculation:
A Proposal to Lessen
Undesirable Housing Transactions
Thomas J. Fitzpatrick IV,
Economist

O. Emre Ergungor,
Senior Research Economist

In the City of Cleveland, 8.2 percent of the housing stock
sits vacant or abandoned, according to the U.S. Postal
Service. In this environment, private investment in fore­
closed properties may sound like welcome news. Indeed,
some speculative purchases can add liquidity to a distressed
market and help heal distressed neighborhoods when
properties are purchased for rehabilitation.
But if speculators fail to keep up with maintenance and
taxes, allowing properties to sit empty and in disrepair, the
opposite happens. In weak-market cities like Cleveland,
some speculative investments extend the time that properties sit vacant, lower the value of nearby homes, and make
the vacancy problem much more challenging to fix.
But are such speculative investments a large enough
problem to demand a policy response? We believe they
are. Evidence shows that some investors may be transacting
irresponsibly, potentially hurting neighboring homeowners
in the process. We outline one of many policy options
states might consider if they are looking for solutions to
this problem.

20		

Winter 2011

Financing Holds the Key
The key to understanding—and addressing—these
harmful transactions is to look at how most speculative
transactions are financed. When a homebuyer applies for a
mortgage, the bank requires that all claims on the property,
including tax and code enforcement liens, be paid off by
the closing. Banks also require that past-due taxes that
have not yet become liens be paid prior to closing, so they
do not supersede the bank’s claim on the property.
But speculative home purchase transactions are not always
funded through the banking system. If investors pay cash
or secure nonbank seller financing, they can postpone
paying off liens, past due taxes, and housing code assessments against the property, often for many years.
To address this problem, policymakers would need a rule
that discourages investors from trying to quickly flip lowvalue properties without maintaining or improving them.
One potential solution would require that all past-due taxes
and code enforcement penalties be cleared before county
recorders declare a property transfer official. This change
would target the speculative activity that destabilizes weak
housing markets.
This rule would apply to all residential property transfers
but, in practice, would affect only the cash or sellerfinanced transfers of property with outstanding taxes or
housing code assessments. To see how widespread cash and
seller-financed transactions are, we analyzed the property
transfers in Cuyahoga County, Ohio (home to Cleveland),

Keep in mind that a markup as low as a few hundred
dollars can still provide a significant return in places such
as Cuyahoga County, Ohio, where more than 40 percent
of properties sold by financial institutions after a fore­
closure are priced at less than $10,000, according to a 2008
Case Western Reserve University study (see “Resources”
at the end of this article). This speculative activity seems
to be most common among bulk buyers who purchase
low-value properties in large numbers.

We consider speculation harmful when the buyer has no
intention of improving or maintaining the property or paying
its taxes—but expects to resell as much of its stock as possible
quickly, “as is,” and at a small markup.
in 2009. Transfers totaled 16,828 excluding foreclosures;
about half of them did not have any associated mortgage
as reported under the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act.
That is, they were most likely all-cash or seller-financed
transactions. All transactions with conveyance amounts
less than $10,000 (almost 3,000 of them) were in this
category. Of those small-dollar transactions, almost one
in three had a tax delinquency at the time of transfer.
We do not suggest that all of these transactions involved
harmful speculation, as many delinquencies clear around
the time of the transfer. For a significant number of properties, however, tax delinquency is persistent or grows
after the transfer. These are the properties that will likely
be affected by this proposal. (Note: While we include
housing code assessments in our proposal, we are unable to
report the data on this component of the problem because
of lack of uniform record-keeping across municipalities.)

Undesirable Housing Transactions
in Cuyahoga County, Ohio
We consider speculation harmful when the buyer has
no intention of improving or maintaining the property
or paying its taxes—but expects to resell as much of its
stock as possible quickly, “as is,” and at a small markup.
Speculators tend to factor in the probability that some
of their purchased properties will languish or be lost to
tax foreclosure. But they buy them anyway because the
markup on properties sold is high enough to pay for the
lost properties.

How is this strategy profitable? When buying foreclosed or
lender or real estate-owned (REO) properties, irresponsible
buyers have a built-in advantage over rehabbers. While
rehabbers must take into account the costs of improvements
and delinquent tax payments, speculators who plan to flip
the property at a quick profit don’t, so they can bid higher.
Typically, after taking over the property, the speculator
sells it as soon as possible to an unsuspecting out-of-state
(or even out-of-country) buyer who believes the property
is a great investment.
This belief could be rooted in the promise of future
appreciation or a predictable rental income stream after
minor rehabilitation. Only after the transaction closes does
the new buyer find out that the property has more in
delinquent taxes than the price paid to acquire it, or that
the property is in need of substantially more rehabilitation
than was originally thought. More often than not in these
situations, the new buyer abandons the property, which
may go into tax foreclosure and be sold at auction, where
it may once again be acquired by a bulk buyer. As this
cycle continues, the property remains vacant, falls into
further disrepair, and becomes a nuisance to the entire
neighborhood.
Consider what would happen if these speculators didn’t
exist. First, distressed property values would fall, freeing
up resources for rehabbing or demolition. Second, a large
amount of distressed property would go on the market,
which would allow for large-scale rehabilitation, redevelop­
ment, or demolition and the associated economies of scale.

F refront

21

For example, the Cuyahoga County Land Bank (which
acquires distressed properties to demolish, rehabilitate, or
repurpose for long-term neighborhood stability) has been
able to regularly solicit bids in small and bulk packages for
demolition as its inventory has grown. As a result, the land
bank reports that it has seen its average demolition cost
fall by nearly 35 percent.
Figure 1. Outcomes for Homes Sold out of Foreclosure
in Cuyahoga County, Ohio, 2007–09
Large Investors

Small Investors

Individuals

(percent)

(percent)

(percent)

69

15

22

31
78

85

Vacant

Occupied

Source: Cuyahoga County Auditor.

Substantiating Anecdotes: Data on
Housing Transactions and Tax Delinquency
Some transactions illustrate the bulk-buyer business model.
For example, Cuyahoga County records show that one
tax-delinquent property was acquired by a bulk buyer from
a securitization pool for $1 and resold four days later for
$10,000. The new owner (a low-volume investor) resold
the property six months later for $72,000.
A fascinating transaction, but how frequently are properties
sold in bulk transactions? And what is the evidence for
harmful activity? We looked at the period from 2007 to
2009 and divided investors into groups: high-volume
(large) investors, who purchased or sold 11 or more properties, and low-volume (small) investors, who purchased
or sold four to 10 properties. The great majority of transactions occur among people who buy or sell three or less
properties over four years; we classify those as “individuals”
buying or selling for consumption purposes.
Cuyahoga County Auditor’s records show that of 18,692
residential properties sold out of foreclosure by financial
institutions and government agencies in the 2007–09
period, about one-quarter were bought by large investors,
another one-quarter by small investors, and most of the
rest by individuals. As figure 1 shows, 31 percent of the
properties bought by large investors were still vacant as of
June 2010.
22		

Winter 2011

The vacancy rate was 22 percent for small investors and
15 percent for individuals (and these differences persist
after controlling for property characteristics). Clearly,
outcomes for homes bought by some investors are worse
than for those bought by others.
Furthermore, large investors seem to have a preference
for tax-delinquent properties. In 2009, 21 percent of the
properties sold with a tax delinquency from the previous
year were purchased by large investors. Yet, they purchased
only 9 percent of properties sold without a delinquency.
This preference for tax-delinquent properties wouldn’t
matter if the buyers paid those taxes, but that isn’t the case.
The weighted average of the green bars in figure 2 shows that
44 percent of the properties purchased by large investors
in 2009 were later tax-delinquent, despite being current the
previous year. Comparable figures are 39 percent for small
investors and 21 percent for individ­uals. In trans­actions
where large investors sell to small and other large investors
(red and green bars farthest to the right in figure 2), this
pattern is particularly pronounced. In almost 60 percent of
such transactions, the purchaser does not pay property taxes.
Meanwhile, the data show that when individuals and
financial institutions (yellow and blue bars in figure 3)
purchase a tax-delinquent property from any group,
delinquencies consistently get paid more than half of the
time. Large investors, however, consistently avoid paying
back taxes. The most glaring result is when large investors
sell tax-delinquent property to other large investors;
delinquent taxes are paid in only 13 percent of those cases
(green bar farthest to the right in figure 3). When large
investors sell to small investors, back taxes are paid in
23 percent of the trans­actions (red bar farthest to the right
in figure 3). Added up, the data show that most of the
time, individuals transact more responsibly than small
and large investors.
A final situation worth paying attention to is when a property’s tax balance actually grows after a purchase (figure 4).
In these transactions, not only are back taxes not being paid,
but purchasers are not paying current taxes as they come
due. Again, the culprits are mostly large investors who sell
to other large investors (green bar farthest to the right in
figure 4)—who allow the delinquent tax balance to grow
nearly 76 percent of the time. In almost all types of property
transfers, investors are the worst tax avoiders.

Status Changes of Tax-Delinquent Properties in Cuyahoga County, Ohio,
by Seller and Buyer Type, 2009
Buyers

Figure 2. Properties That Fell into Tax Delinquency
Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Small
investors

Financial
institutions

Government

Individuals

Large
investors

Small
investors

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Small
investors

Financial
institutions

Financial
institutions

Government

Individuals

Large
investors

Financial
institutions

Government

Large
investors

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Small
investors

Financial
institutions

Government

Individuals

Large
investors

Sellers

Figure 4a. Properties Whose Tax Balance Grew
after a Purchase: Low-value Transactions

Figure 4. Properties Whose Tax Balance Grew
after a Purchase

Small
investors

Individuals

Figure 3a. Properties That Became Current:
Low-value Transactions

Sellers

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Government
Sellers

Figure 3. Properties That Became Current

Small
investors

Large
investors

Figure 2a. Properties That Fell into Tax Delinquency:
Low-value Transactions

Sellers

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Financial
Individuals
institutions		

Individuals

Large
investors

Sellers

Percent
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

Small
investors

Financial
institutions

Government

Individuals

Large
investors

Sellers

Note: Low-value transactions have conveyance amounts of less than $10,000.
Source: Cuyahoga County Auditor.
F refront

23

Taken together, these findings
support the anecdotal reports
that large and small investors
pay the taxes on properties
they purchase less frequently than financial institutions,
governments, or individuals. The problems are more
acute in the low-value cash or seller-financed transaction
category with conveyance amounts of less than $10,000
(figures 2a, 3a, and 4a).

A more promising policy solution would require a change in
state law: preventing county recorders, who are charged with
tracking owners of real estate, from recording any new ownership of property that has outstanding delinquent taxes or code
violation penalties.
While we have no direct evidence of harmful activity,
owners of tax-delinquent properties are not likely to have
the incentive to maintain them because they can be taken
away in a tax foreclosure. The result can be devastating to
neighborhoods.

Potential Remedies
Some have suggested that one way to address the harmfultransaction problem would be to create a list of known
repeat offenders and prevent them from acquiring property.
A law of this type exists in Pennsylvania, where municipalities may petition to prevent a foreclosure auction
purchaser from acquiring a property if that purchaser
has been convicted of a housing code violation and has
not corrected it.1 But using blacklists to prevent property
acquisition may not be effective in a world where anyone
placed on such a list could incorporate a new entity to
continue acquiring property, which can be done quickly
and inexpensively. In that sense, blacklists may be
under-inclusive.
A more promising policy solution would require a change
in state law: preventing county recorders, who are charged
with tracking owners of real estate, from recording any new
ownership of property that has outstanding delinquent
1.	See 53 Pennsylvania Statutes § 7328(b.2) & 72 Pennsylvania Statues
§ 5860.619(c) (2010), enacted in 1998. Missouri attempted to create a similar
provision that prohibits persons from bidding on property at sheriff’s sales,
VAMS § 141.550.2(2) (1998), but the entire bill containing the law was struck
down because the title of the bill was vague, violating Missouri’s constitutional
requirement that bills have clear titles. See Home Builder Association v. State,
75 S.W.3d 267 (Sup. Ct. Mo., 2002).

24

Winter 2011

taxes or code violation penalties. Currently, the Ohio
Revised Code requires recorders to record authentic instru­
ments properly presented.2 Changing the law to prevent
tax avoiders from closing on a transaction would directly
address the problem by undermining the business model
undergirding undesirable transactions. Unless purchasers
paid taxes, improved the property, or kept up to code, they
would be unable to legally transfer ownership.
This solution would give every purchaser an incentive
to maintain properties and keep them on the active tax
rolls, or they would be unable to turn over inventory.
Such a transfer restriction would discourage buyers from
purchasing property for which they could not provide
upkeep. It might also prevent corporate shell games, where
a corporate entity sells a property to another corporate
entity controlled by the same owner or owners in order to
delay delinquent tax or housing code enforcement actions.
A few words of caution: Because well-meaning purchasers
can fall behind on taxes, broad transfer restrictions may be
overly inclusive. Policymakers should carefully craft such
restrictions to minimize unintended consequences. In
the presence of such a restriction, for example, depository
institutions may be reluctant to foreclose on a property if
the property owner failed to pay taxes and they were not
paid by the lender. Transfer restrictions may also chill the
acquisition of properties with large amounts of outstanding
taxes or code violations, even when potential purchasers
would seek to rehabilitate the property or otherwise
ensure its productive use.
These unintended consequences can be mitigated to some
extent. For example, policymakers may want to allow
properties to be transferred to public entities or land banks,
to facilitate voluntary surrender of property despite back
taxes and code violations. This type of exception may
involve a county’s forgiving some or all back taxes when
responsible buyers purchase property or allowing ownership transfers if the new owner agrees to pay taxes or code
violations over time. Additionally, it may make sense to
allow involuntary property transfers related to a death,
bankruptcy, foreclosure, or divorce, despite back taxes or
code violations. These exceptions to transfer restrictions

2.	 Ohio Revised Code §§ 317.13 & 317.22 (2010).

should be carefully crafted. Broad exceptions may allow
undesirable transactions to continue, while narrow exceptions may inhibit healthy transactions.
Even with these exceptions, there could be a short-run
slowdown in transfer activity as the market adjusts to the
new rules. While some homeowners in the affected areas
may see this as a negative outcome, we believe there are
positive long-run consequences for all weak markets.
Properties will be channeled to the land bank or to private
rehabbers at lower cost in the absence of irresponsible
buyers. This frees up resources for rehabilitation or demo­
lition. A smaller and more pristine housing inventory
should stabilize home prices and strengthen the market
in the long run.
Another possible unintended consequence of this proposal is that in the short run, the restriction would slow
the transfer of all property because of the time it takes to
check for back taxes and assessments. This delay could
be significant if records on real property taxes and other
public assessments are not kept in an easily accessible
electronic format.
According to an informal survey we conducted with
county recorders, at least four of Ohio’s 88 counties do
not yet keep electronic tax records. Code violation records
are kept at the municipal level, and it is unclear how many
are kept electronically. To avoid slowing the transfer of real
property, the state legislature may choose to allow counties
to opt in or out of restrictions on transfer. In any case, law­
makers would need to work closely with lenders, real estate
buyers and sellers, community development practitioners,
and county governments to create exceptions and minimize
unintended consequences while limiting harmful transfers.

Final Thoughts
Stories about irresponsible property speculators abound.
Their very business model allows them to pay more than
bidders who are interested in rehabilitation. Our analysis
shows that large investors focus on tax-delinquent properties and often fail to pay property taxes. As a result, entire
communities sometimes are unable to break the cycle of
disinvestment and decline of their housing stock.

Requiring all past-due
taxes and code enforcement
penalties to be cleared
before transfer could help
many neighbor­hoods in
their battle against vacancy,
abandonment, and blight. It is one of many ways policymakers could discourage the transactions that hinder the
rehabi­lita­tion of housing stock. At a time when government budgets are stretched thin because of declining
tax revenues, this policy proposal may give a jolt to the
collection of property taxes. Cuyahoga County, for
example, could have collected approximately $8.5 million
in past-due taxes in 2009 under this proposal, notwithstanding the likely decline in the number of property
transfers one would expect as high-volume investors left
the market. This tax revenue could be used to acquire and
rehabilitate or demolish additional distressed properties.
Still, the availability of such untapped resources to all
Ohio counties and municipalities may create an incentive
for private investors to fund efforts to improve electronic
record-keeping of taxes and code enforcement programs.
In other words, the public entities could fund their efforts
through bond issues that would be repaid with the
enhanced property tax receipts. While this latter point is
not necessarily a policy recommendation, it shows that
this proposal may have advantages that go beyond the
prevention of harmful transactions. The overall benefits
certainly seem to outweigh the costs. ■

What do you think?
We’re interested in hearing your comments as we refine this proposal.
Send comments to forefront@clev.frb.org
Recommended reading
Coulton, Claudia, Michael Schramm, and April Hirsch. 2008.
“Beyond REO: Property Transfers at Extremely Distressed Prices in
Cuyahoga County, 2005–2008.” Case Western Reserve University
Center on Urban Poverty and Community Development.
Resources
For suggested reading and information about states that restrict
transfers of tax-delinquent properties, go to
www.clevelandfed.org/forefront

F refront

25

CHRIS PAPPAS

Interview with
Charles Calomiris

Calomiris is the Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial
Institutions at the Columbia University Graduate School of
Business and a professor at Columbia’s School of International
and Public Affairs. Among his many other affiliations, he is
a member of the Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee,
the Shadow Open Market Committee, and the Financial

Charles W. Calomiris is not one to keep his thoughts to

Economists Round­table, and is a research associate of the

himself. His 55-page curriculum vitae lists dozens of academic

National Bureau of Economic Research. He has worked as an

articles with titles like “Firm Heterogeneity, Internal Finance,

economist for the Federal Reserve and consulted for central

and Credit Rationing”—and just as many op-eds in popular

banks around the globe.

periodicals, like the Wall Street Journal piece, “Blame Fannie
Mae and Congress for the Credit Mess.” It is not unusual for
him to begin scratching out an editorial response to new
legislation moments after he first hears about it in the news.
A more outspoken and influential U.S. banking scholar you are
not likely to find.

26

Winter 2011

Calomiris visited the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland last fall
to participate in the Conference on Countercyclical Capital
Requirements. Joseph Haubrich, vice president and economist
with the Bank, interviewed Calomiris on October 14, 2010.
An edited transcript follows.

Haubrich: Let’s start out with a broad
question. How would you rate the
U.S. response to the financial crisis?
Calomiris: It’s a great question.
I would start by distinguishing
between long-term response and
short-term response. I’d say that the
biggest short-term failure was not
to require recapitalization of the
investment banks between March
and September of 2008. I would have
liked to have seen recapitalization
happen during calm markets when
it was obviously necessary.

Also, with respect to the immediate
response to the crisis, I would have
designed TARP [the Troubled Asset
Relief Program, signed into law in
October 2008] differently. I don’t
think TARP was well-structured.
Congress got to write the form of
capital assistance for banks as a footnote to TARP, and it was structured
to make a profit on the transactions
rather than to encourage the right
kind of stabilization assis­tance.
In many ways, our response in the
1930s was better. I think there were
lessons from history that we could
have put to use in this crisis. And we
suffered a lot, unnecessarily, with a
liquidity crisis that wouldn’t have been
so deep if we had used better ideas
back in September and October 2008
about how we were going to support
the financial system.
The Fed’s short-term actions were
mostly appropriate—making liquidity
available to the markets in various
forms, particularly TALF [Term AssetBacked Securities Loan Facility].
I think this was a successful and
warranted program. It conforms to
what I take to be the central message
of a what a lender of last resort has
to do, which is try to take some risk
on its balance sheet during a crisis,
but to do so in as senior a way as
possible. I’m not saying the Fed got
everything right.

I think that the Dodd–Frank bill,1
which is the main form of long-term
response to the crisis, suffers from
both sins of commission (bad ideas
enacted in haste) and sins of omission
(it doesn’t really deal with some of the
key problems that underlay the crisis).
The key problems that we should
have learned about from a prudential
regulatory standpoint were, number
one, the subsidization of risk in housing
through high leverage, effectively
financed by the government, either
explicitly or implicitly. We need to
address that. Second is the failure to
accurately measure risk in the financial
system on a forward-looking basis and
to require capital accordingly. Going
forward, we really need to address
that problem, too. And third is the
too-big-to-fail problem. I don’t think
Dodd–Frank adequately tackled that
problem.
Haubrich: Part of the Dodd–Frank bill
was setting up a variety of institutions,
such as FSOC [Financial Stability Oversight Council], which are presumably
going to provide stricter regulation for
the systemically important or too-bigto-fail institutions. Do you think that
will be an adequate response?
Calomiris: My view is that we should
have an incentive scorecard for any
regulatory idea that asks how it is
going to affect the incentives of people
in the marketplace directly. And how
is it going to affect the incentives of
regulators, supervisors, and politicians
to live by the rules they write? The
creation of a new bureaucracy is not
really getting at that in any direct way.
Maybe it will help, maybe it will hurt.
But it doesn’t really get at the key
problems.

I prefer other ideas that are under study
and make a lot of sense. Contin­gent
capital certificates and the restructuring of capital requirements are very
promising. There are several people
in the Federal Reserve System who
are interested in that. If the oversight
council is going to be a way to get

good ideas like that formulated, then
in conjunction with those new ideas
it could be effective. So, it’s not a bad
idea that we’re going to have more
of a focal point on responsibility for
coming up with good ideas in some
coordinated way. Maybe it will help,
maybe it won’t. But the ultimate test
is going to be whether we see real
mechanisms that matter for incentives
coming out of those deliberations.

If there is a bona fide reason to promote
affordable housing, it’s to create stakeholders in local communities. But you’re
not a stakeholder if you have a 3 percent
down payment on your home—you are
a renter in disguise.
Haubrich: You mentioned one aspect
that hasn’t been dealt with: the
incentive for leverage in the housing
market. What would you do about the
government-sponsored enterprises
Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac?
Calomiris: I think that they should be
phased out. I think that all government
assistance to housing that’s taking the
form of lending programs that try to
subsidize affordable housing through
making lending easier, and especially
through very high leverage and very
low interest rates, are the wrong way
to subsidize housing, for two reasons:
First, it encourages systemic risk, just
like what we’ve experienced. A little
bit of a decline in housing prices causes
huge distress throughout the financial
system, precisely because of leverage.

Also, leverage encourages the wrong
kind of risk that comes to the market
because borrowers are not placing
enough of their own resources at risk;
people who are bad risks are willing to
come to the mortgage market. So you
get a bad incentive consequence in
advance. Leverage also matters after
the fact, by magnifying the losses in the
financial system created by recession
shocks or asset price declines.

1.	Dodd–Frank refers to the financial-market, regulatory-reform legislation, sponsored by
Sen. Christopher Dodd and Rep. Barney Frank, which was approved by Congress in July 2010.

F refront

27

sheet—these government supports,
through high leverage and subsidized
interest rates. But this approach doesn’t
accomplish the housing objective, and
it destabilizes the mortgage market
and creates large costs to taxpayers.

We will need the political will to
move away from the drug of leverage,
which was attractive to politicians in
the first place because it disguised the
government’s costs.
If leverage is not the way to promote
affordable housing, then that means
it is high time to phase out FHA
[the Federal Housing Administration],
Fannie Mae, and Freddie Mac.
Not only is mortgage risk subsidization through high leverage risky, it
also fails to achieve its goal. If there
is a bona fide reason to promote
affordable housing, it’s to create stakeholders in local communities. But
you’re not a stakeholder if you have
a 3 percent down payment on your
home—you are a renter in disguise.
These extremely low down payments
are a very recent trend, really the last
two decades. It was all part of the
desire to create invisibly—from a fiscal
standpoint, that is, without showing
the costs on the government’s balance

Haubrich: OK, so what specifically
would you do to ensure that home­
buyers are stakeholders in their
communities?
Calomiris: I propose a four-part plan:
Alongside phasing out Fannie Mae,
Freddie Mac, and FHA as lending
agencies, my proposal is to create a
down payment assistance program
modeled after the Australian program
but on a means-tested basis. Every
Australian qualifies for a $7,000 firsttime homebuyer subsidy. This subsidy
increases their down payment, reduces
their leverage, and makes their home
more affordable. It has a stabilizing
effect on leverage ratios and creates
a real stake for people in their homes
and communities.

A second part of that plan is to phase
in, over a 17-year period, movement
from the minimum 3 percent down
payment requirement to a 20 percent
minimum. A third policy that might
also make sense, again on a meanstested basis, is to provide some assistance for the cost of locking in longerterm interest rates for low-income
people because they’re potentially
more susceptible to the debt-service
fluctuation cost.

Finally, a fourth part of that plan might
be to create home savings accounts
that provide tax incentives for people
to accumulate equity toward the down
payment, again on a means-tested
basis. As part of that, it would be
interesting to think about also using
some tax savings from payroll taxes,
because most low-income people
don’t pay income taxes; they pay only
payroll taxes.
All of these proposed costs would be
budgeted explicitly. Let’s have transparency so we show the government
expenditure effects of these programs.
Let’s create systemic stability, not
instability. Let’s create homeowners,
not renters in disguise. To me this
would be a very rational approach to
housing finance reform. We will need
the political will to move away from
the drug of leverage, which was attractive to the politicians in the first place
because it disguised the government’s
costs. Well, it’s a little hard to disguise
them now that the costs of Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac’s losses are likely to
top $300 billion. Maybe that means
we’ll get the political will to be a little
more honest.

Charles W. Calomiris
Current Position:

Henry Kaufman Professor of Financial Institutions,
Columbia Business School;
and professor,
Columbia University School of International and Public Affairs
Other Positions:

Research associate, National Bureau of Economic Research,
October 1996–present
(faculty research fellow, October 1991–October 1996)
Member, Shadow Financial Regulatory Committee,
December 1997–December 2004 and December 2005–present
Member, Financial Economists Roundtable,
November 2007–present

28

Winter 2011

Member, Shadow Open Market Committee,
April 2009–present
Books:

U.S. Bank Deregulation in Historical Perspective,
Cambridge University Press, 2000, 2006
Emerging Financial Markets
(with David O. Beim), McGraw-Hill, 2000
Education:

Yale University, BA, 1979
Stanford University, PhD, 1985

Haubrich: Let me switch gears and
talk a little bit about the subject of the
conference we’re hosting. Can countercyclical capital regulation work?
Calomiris: I think it can. First let me
define it. We know that capital require­
ments can constrain bank lending
under some circumstances. It’s not
just government capital require­ments
but also market capital requirements.
Remember, government capital
require­ments are only about 30 years
old in the United States, and we were
the first country that I’m aware of that
passed them.

Capital requirements mean requiring
a certain ratio of your assets to be in
the form of equity capital. It’s a fairly
young idea. Before the government
required it, the market required it.
Now both the government and the
market require it. The one that’s the
binding constraint—the one that
has the effect in determining capital
requirements—is whichever is the
higher of the two.
People are worried about two
problems. First, during recessions,
banks may lose capital as a result of
loan losses. For example, during a
recession, to preserve their capitalto-asset ratio, they may have to cut
their risky assets, meaning their loans.
The other thing people worry about
is that going into booms, that constant
capital ratio maybe isn’t high enough
to discourage excessive lending.
These are the two arguments people
make for dynamic capital requirements; that is, maybe we want
capital requirements to be higher
during booms as a way to discourage
excessive lending. And maybe we
want capital requirements to fall
during recessions as a way to avoid
really severe credit crunches. I think
there is at least some evidence for
the tendency for excessive lending
in some booms. I don’t think it’s a
general problem, but it does happen
occasionally.

The key question is whether we can
measure it. Can we measure when
lending markets are excessive and
when lending markets are going
through recessions? We’d like to vary
capital requirements—to relax them
during recessions and to increase
them during booms, especially booms
where we’re very worried about excessive lending. Is this something that
can be measured? I would say yes. It
can’t be measured perfectly but it can
be measured fairly well.
A paper by Claudio Borio and Mathias
Drehmann at the BIS [Bank for
Inter­national Settlements] showed
that very severe recessions tend to
happen when lending growth is very
high just prior to the recession, during
the boom, and when asset prices are
growing very fast. So one could impose
higher capital requirements based on
a dual threshold. When loan growth
gets very high and asset prices are
growing very quickly, you’d like to
impose higher capital requirements,
and doing so will help you achieve a
better soft landing, cooling down the
loan growth and helping the economy.
Haubrich: Now capital requirements are
changing. Basel III 2 is coming up with a
set of recommendations. Could you give
us your take on those proposals?
Calomiris: They’re talking about
phasing in an increase in capital
requirements for Tier 1 capital. It’s
a maximum leverage requirement
rather than just a risk-based capital
requirement. These are good ideas.
But are they enough? No.

A little increase in capital doesn’t solve
the problem. The key problem was the
failure to measure risk on an ongoing,
forward-looking basis, fairly accurately,
and to require capital accordingly. If
you just bump up capital a little bit,
what’s to prevent risk from going up
even more? If financial institutions
want to create risk and want to hide
it from their regulators, under the
existing Basel system it’s almost
trivial to do it. The Basel system still,

unbeliev­ably, says that the way we
measure risk is asking banks what
the risk is and asking ratings agencies
what the risk is. That is not dealing
with the incentive problems that got
us into the mis-measurement of risk
in the first place, so we have to think
more creatively about mechanisms
that can solve this problem.

The Basel system still, unbelievably,
says that the way we measure risk is
asking banks what the risk is and asking
ratings agencies what the risk is.
One paper that was published in
2003 by Don Morgan and Adam
Ashcraft in the Journal of Financial
Services Research shows that interestrate spreads on loans are very good
predictors of loan default risk. In the
common parlance we would say,
“Duh!” Because after all, that’s the
point of spreads. They’re supposed
to compensate banks for risk.
The authors showed in 2003 that we
could’ve used interest rate spreads
as good forward-looking measures
of risk. We didn’t use them! If we
had used them in the subprime crisis,
we would’ve budgeted a lot more
capital against subprime risks and
we would’ve been better off. So ideas
coming out of Basel to tweak capital
requirements in a way that’s not
related to measuring risk are doomed
to fail.
What we need to do is take risk measurement seriously in a way that deals
also with incentive problems. Notice
that my proposal to gear default risk
measures to loan spreads is incentiverobust. Why? Because no bank is
going to cut its interest rate to save a
little bit on its capital requirements.
That means that interest rates will
provide robust measures of risk, and
we can therefore reliably use those
interest-rate spreads to measure risk.

2.	The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision has been meeting since 1974 to improve and coordinate
the quality of bank supervision worldwide. The most recent effort to strengthen capital requirements was
dubbed Basel III.

F refront

29

That’s just one of several ideas that
illustrate the idea of incentive-robust
regulatory reforms. These reforms
would sometimes force banks to
maintain more capital—but capital
commensurate with risk—using
measures of risk that we could rely on.
Haubrich: Some people argue that highenough capital requirements would
reduce the incentive that banks have
for taking risk. It sounds like you don’t
agree with that?
Calomiris: The problem is that financial firms are designed to be able to
arbitrarily increase risk. Financial
contracts can reshape and re-cut risk
in many different ways to create a little
risk or a lot of risk, depending on what
they want to achieve. You can’t say that
a loan has X amount of risk, because
banks can construct loans that might
appear very similar that have very
different kinds of risk. We have to have
a flexible means of measuring risk.

What we really have to ask is what was
missing in regulation. What was missing
was what we’ve been talking about:
accurate measurement of risk on a
forward-looking basis.
If we just say we’re going to increase
capital a little bit, banks could very
easily just make sure that the composition of risks of the loans in their
portfolio are commensurately higher,
therefore achieving nothing in terms
of stabilizing a system. That’s the story
of what is sometimes called regulatory
arbitrage, that is, the private sector
undoing the effect of any regulation.
If the regulations are dumb, the private
sector will always smartly undo them.
The regulations have to be smart enough
so that they’re robust to incentives.

30

Winter 2011

Haubrich: To follow up on that, to what
extent do you think the problem behind
the crisis was, say, regulatory arbitrage,
and to what extent was it deregula­tion?
Calomiris: I’ll start with the second
part of the question. Deregulation
had nothing to do, in my view, with
the crisis. The main deregulation that
happened in the United States in the
1980s and the 1990s really dealt with
two important issues. One of them was
whether banks should be allowed to
branch throughout the United States.
In 1994, national deregulation of
branching was a culmination of state
and regional deregulation of branching
that was occurring throughout the ’80s
and early ’90s. That was a stabilizing
policy. It has been shown time and
time again for a whole host of reasons
to be a very good idea as a matter of
economic policy.

The other main deregulation was
for banks and investment banks. It
allowed banks to engage in the underwriting of corporate securities, which
they previously had been limited in
doing. This crisis had nothing to do
with the underwriting of corporate
securities.
Furthermore, subprime mortgage
activities, which were important in
creating the crisis, were something
banks could have engaged in prior
to the two deregulations I’ve talked
about, and in fact did. Deregulation
allowed commercial banks to engage
in traditional investment-banking and
corporate-underwriting practices, and
allowed commercial banks to branch.
These were stabil­izing, in fact, during
the crisis.

Why? Because of greater diversification of income. Furthermore, remember, the way we dealt with this crisis
was by allowing investment banks to
be purchased by commercial banks.
That was possible because of deregulation, and it helped to stabilize the
system in reaction to the crisis.
When you hear the political rhetoric
about deregulation, I think what
people really mean is that we had a
failed prudential regulatory system.
Banks and investment banks were both
under prudential regulation under
the Basel standards. The investment
banks were being regulated, under
Basel, by the SEC [Securities and
Exchange Commission]. And what
we can say is that it wasn’t a very
good regulatory system. We did not
maintain capital commen­surate with
risk very effectively. But starting in
2002, the investment banks were all
regulated, long before this crisis hit.
If anything, prudential regulation was
increasing over time during the phase
when the crisis took hold.
What we really have to ask is what
was missing in regulation. What was
missing was what we’ve been talking
about: accurate measurement of risk
on a forward-looking basis. The other
problem that arose between March
2008 and September 2008 was that
once we bailed out Bear Stearns,
others expected bailouts instead
of recapitalizing as they needed to.
They didn’t want to recapitalize in
a way that would dilute their stock
values. Why not take a bet, hope that
if things go badly they’ll get bailed
out? If things go well, they won’t have
to dilute by issuing new equity. That
too-big-to-fail problem needs to be
addressed, too. We’ve done little to
address those two basic problems.

Haubrich: We haven’t talked much
about monetary policy. Do you think
monetary policy contributed in a
material way to the financial crisis? 3
Calomiris: Yes. From 2002 to 2005,
the real federal funds rate was negative.
And the only other four-year period
in postwar history where that was
true was 1975 through 1978, the highinflation period. If you looked at it
from the standpoint of the Taylor rule
as a function of the unemployment
rate and the inflation rate, the Fed
stopped following the Taylor rule
during the period 2002 to 2005.4

Yes, the Fed contributed to the overpricing of real estate assets and other
assets, but that doesn’t translate into
a financial crisis. You need the other
distortions on the microeconomic
side, particularly the housing finance
distortions, to really understand the
depth of the crisis.
Haubrich: Thank you very much. ■

The Fed kept the fed funds rate about
2 percentage points on average below
what that rule would have implied. So
the Fed surprised the market from the
stand­point of the Taylor rule, ran very
loose monetary policy with a negative
real fed funds rate, and there is pretty
convincing statistical evidence that
this contributed to the underpricing
of risk leading up to the crisis.
That said, I can tell you from a histor­
ical perspective that monetary policy
mistakes like that—and I regard it as a
mistake—do not cause these kinds of
crises. They cause asset-price problems,
but to get into a banking crisis you need
the large losses relative to bank capital,
and you can’t blame that on monetary
policy. Contrast, for example, with
the dot-com boom and bust, where
the actual losses were greater than the
subprime boom and bust. Yet it didn’t
have any effect on the whole financial
system. Why? Because it wasn’t a
leveraged loss. Housing leverage and
banking leverage in the recent crisis
translated into an overpricing of some
assets and into the demise of the
financial system.

Watch video clips of this interview
www.clevelandfed.org/forefront
3.	For Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke’s take on this question,
see www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100103a.htm.
4.	The Taylor rule is the monetary policy rule for targeting the federal funds rate that
many believe the Fed seemed to be following prior to 2002.

F refront

31

Book Review

All the Devils Are Here:
The Hidden History
of the Financial Crisis
by Bethany McLean and Joe Nocera
Penguin 2010

Reviewed by
Dan Littman,
Economist
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

In All the Devils Are Here: The Hidden History of the
Financial Crisis (Penguin 2010), authors Bethany McLean
and Joe Nocera prove that there is still more to learn about
the recent financial crisis. McLean, a contributing editor
at Vanity Fair, who was among the first reporters to break
the Enron story, and Nocera, a business columnist for the
New York Times, draw their title from Shakespeare’s The
Tempest. The implication, regrettably appropriate in both
the 1600s and the 2000s, is that that plenty of hell can be
found among the living right here on earth.

32

Winter 2011

McLean and Nocera provide an outstanding, high-level
overview of the course of the recent financial crisis,
including its often-overlooked roots in the decades from
1930 to 2000, but they focus most intensely on the years
since 2000. Each chapter of the book could work as a
stand-alone piece; indeed, some of them first appeared as
magazine and newspaper articles. The book is heavier on
anecdotes about personalities, institutions, government
policies, and events than on in-depth analysis of the crisis.
It should appeal both to novices and to experts who could
use some help in putting their other readings in context.

I found three of the book’s themes especially enlightening.
The first is the interconnection of personal, institutional,
and public policy flaws that brought on the crisis. In that
sense, all the devils really were here.
The authors do not find personifications of evil. What they
find are plenty of flawed individuals in positions of power.
Some of them are at once pathetic and sympathetic, like
Stan O’Neal, the CEO of Merrill Lynch, whose isolation
from events at the nation’s largest retail brokerage company
is exemplified by his practice of playing 18 holes of golf
by himself, several times a week (though it could be noted,
in O’Neal’s defense, that J.P. Morgan famously played
solitaire for hours in his office to unwind).
McLean and Nocera also find flawed institutions, or
rather, flawed mechanisms of communication within
institutions. At AIG, for example, only the CEO was
informed about important developments in the company’s
far-flung divisions; senior leaders were deliberately kept
in the dark. This prevented wiser heads from closing down
the London unit that traded in credit default swaps, which
should have been shuttered months or years earlier. The
authors identify flawed public policy as well, with the
federal government’s multi-pronged, pro-housing policies
a particularly ripe target for criticism.
A second recurrent theme is the difficulty of being a lone
voice of reason, leaning against the wind, in institutions
making huge profits. The authors report that in companies
like AIG, Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch,
Citibank, and others, some senior officials recognized that
something was rotten in the business of mortgage securitization and credit default swaps, but found that they were
crying in the wilderness. McLean and Nocera recount
that when these employees questioned the business model,
they were sidelined to unimportant jobs or fired. The
most memorable of them was the chief risk officer at
Merrill Lynch who, despite being a longtime associate of
the company CEO, was pulled off the trading floor where
he could observe daily activities. He left the company,
returned at the urging of former colleagues, and found
himself pulled off the trading floor a second time.

A third key theme is the degree to which market participants relied more on the perceived wisdom of crowds and
the emotions of the market than on their understanding of
market fundamentals. Investment professionals throughout
the industry, including many who had doubts (however
ill-formed) about the underlying mortgage origination
and securitization business model, were more prone to
follow the initially profitable herd.
Many in the industry recognized that a lot of borrowers
and properties were unworthy of loans, or that junk
tranches in mortgage bonds repackaged as synthetic
collateralized debt obliga­tions with AAA ratings were
illogical. But as long as investment banks were willing
to buy and package the mortgages, and as long as those
banks could find willing customers for the bonds, they
continued to do so. One sad episode of this story involves
Angelo Mozilo, chairman and CEO of Countrywide, who
initially resisted entry into the subprime mortgage and
refinancing market, but then relented in order to protect
the company’s standing as the largest housing lender in
the United States. Countrywide soon became one of the
most spectacular crash stories of the financial crisis.
Ultimately, the authors paint a troubling portrait of a world
afflicted with human and institutional flaws. In ordinary
times, we accept such flaws as part of the human landscape.
In crisis times, though, such flaws are fuel to the fire of
systemic risk. This is a world in which those who lean against
the wind are dismissed by their bosses and colleagues, and
the emotions of the investment crowd matter more than
business fundamentals. It is also a world that will resist
most efforts to avoid these kinds of crises in the future.
Public policies, whether well or sloppily crafted, still have
to address the harmful but inescapable elements of human
nature. As Ariel put it in The Tempest, “Hell is empty and
all the devils are here.” ■

F refront

33

PRSRT STD
U.S. POSTAGE PAID
CLEVELAND, OH
PERMIT NO. 385

federal reserve bank of cleveland

PO Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label
to the above address.

s u
m

g,

ne

qu

sin

ali

Hou

ty

u

u

i t

p o

m

l

y
i c

H

um

an
an C
apital,

d

I

June 9 – 10, 2011
Cleveland InterContinental
Hotel and Conference Center

2011 Policy Summit

Housing, Human Capital, and Inequality
The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland will host its annual policy
summit on June 9 and 10, 2011. The theme of this year’s summit is
foreclosure fallout—how can communities deal with housing,
human capital, and inequality issues prompted or exacerbated by the
foreclosure crisis?
Confirmed keynote speakers include Federal Reserve Vice Chair
Janet Yellen and noted writer Paul Tough, author of Whatever It Takes:
Geoffrey Canada’s Quest to Change Harlem and America.
Please visit www.clevelandfed.org/2011policysummit for agenda specifics
and registration information.

To subscribe, request copies, or sign up for web feeds of Forefront, visit www.clevelandfed.org/forefront.