View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

SUMMER 2012
Volume 3 Number 2

F refront

New Ideas on Economic Policy from the FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
of CLEVELAND

Rebuilding
Communities

		
Lessons from:
a mayor
■ an educator
■ an economist
■ and more
■

P LUS :

	The too-big-to-fail subsidy
	“How” to innovate

F refront

New Ideas on Economic Policy from the FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
of CLEVELAND

		SUMMER 2012

Volume 3 Number 2

		CONTENTS
1	President’s Message
2	Upfront

Electronic payments update; early economic impact of Ohio casinos

From the cover

		Rebuilding Communities:
Lessons from the Cleveland Fed’s 2012 Policy Summit
4	The Shifting Landscape of Economic Development
More cooperation, less corporate subsidization

6	Working Out an Equation for Education Reform

Cutting-edge efforts to improve America’s education system

8	The New City

Some practical lessons about policy implementation from city (and county) hall

4

10	Getting to the “How” of Innovation

Public policy can help drive innovation levels,
but some approaches are more effective than others

16

16	Why Manufacturing (Still) Matters—And How It Can Endure
Insights from the National Association of Business Economics’
first industry-specific conference

20	Housing and the Economic Recovery

What academic experts see in the housing market’s near future

24	Hot Topic

How Big Is the Too-Big-to-Fail Subsidy?

26	Interview with Alex Kotlowitz

The journalist and documentary producer talks about his reports
from inner-city Chicago

28	Book Review

The Power of Habit: Why We Do What We Do in Life and Business

20

26

The views expressed in Forefront are not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Federal Reserve System.
Content may be reprinted with the disclaimer above and credited
to Forefront. Send copies of reprinted material to the Public Affairs
Department of the Cleveland Fed.
Forefront
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
PO Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101-1387
forefront@clev.frb.org
clevelandfed.org/forefront

President and CEO: Sandra Pianalto
Editor in Chief: M
 ark Sniderman
Executive Vice President and Chief Policy Officer
Executive Editor: Robin Ratliff
Editor: Doug Campbell
Managing Editor: Amy Koehnen
Associate Editor: Michele Lachman
Art Director: Michael Galka
Web Designer: Natalie Karrs
Digital Media Strategist: Lou Marich
Contributors:
Todd Clark
Anne DiTeodoro
Kyle Fee
April McClellan-Copeland
Anne O’Shaughnessy
Editorial Board:
Kelly Banks, Vice President, Community Relations
Paul Kaboth, Vice President, Community Development
Stephen Ong, Vice President, Supervision and Regulation
Mark Schweitzer, Senior Vice President, Research
James Thomson, Vice President, Research

PRESIDENT’S MESSAGE
Sandra Pianalto
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland

Too often, public policies

A recurring theme in each of these sessions was that public

that seem great in theory

policies are most effective in combination with one another—

lose some of their appeal

for example, school reform efforts that acknowledge students

when applied to the real

will have a better chance of succeeding if they live in stable

world. At the Federal

households, and economic development that takes into account

Reserve Bank of Cleveland, we have sought to bridge that crucial

the affordability of local housing or the quality of workforce

gap from abstract to concrete with our annual Policy Summit.

development programs.

It brings together academics and researchers with community
development practitioners, elected officials, bankers, funders,
and policymakers to explore economic policy and community
development issues. Our 10th annual conference, held this past
June, aimed at identifying effective strategies and programs to
strengthen and rebuild communities, with a special emphasis
on taking a holistic approach to community development.
In this issue of Forefront, we highlight some of the marquee
sessions from the 2012 Policy Summit. Leading researchers and
practitioners discussed new approaches in economic development and education reform. For a useful reality check, public
officials from some of the Midwest’s largest metro areas explained
how they balance extremely tight budgets with the need for longterm community investments. I also encourage you to read the
interview with journalist Alex Kotlowitz and visit our website for
video excerpts from his moving description of anti-gang violence

I applaud the Policy Summit’s stress on designing programs in
ways that will produce credible data for further research and
learning. However, we cannot let the quest for perfection keep
us from getting off the starting blocks—so we must develop
programs in a manner that allows us to test, learn, and make
adjustments as we go. We stand a much better chance of doing
that if we share information and listen to the many voices
involved in community development.
Moreover, the Policy Summit reflects the approach taken by the
Federal Reserve in all of our work, which is based on objective
research, factual analysis, and broad public input. Every year,
I am encouraged to see that there is so much growing interest
in exploring new approaches to important issues in community
development and public policy. I’m already looking forward to
next year’s event.

■

efforts in Chicago, which put a human face on the stories only
hinted at in the data.

F refront

1

Upfr nt
Payments System Survives,
Thrives During Recent Tax Season

Anne DiTeodoro
Communications
Coordinator

A longtime partnership between the
U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland is expanding in
scope, and the payoff could come
in the form of reduced government
costs.

from April 2011 to March 2012, it
processed an average of 14 million
transactions worth $18 billion each
month. But it wasn’t until this past
April that the software enhancements were truly put to the test.

For the first time, Debit Gateway—
the Treasury’s payments processing
application supported solely by
the Cleveland Fed—processed tax
lockbox transactions during a tax
season.* Debit Gateway has been
able to process tax lockbox trans­
actions for quarterly tax payments
since mid-2011, when the Cleveland
Fed’s eGovernment (eGov) function
enhanced the software. In fact,

The result: More than 29 million
transactions worth a record $141
billion were processed efficiently
and accurately during the 2012 tax
season, meeting goals for both the
IRS and the Treasury. With Debit
Gateway, the benefits include
increased efficiency in government
collection processing and reduced
costs in processing received funds.

A Spike at Tax Season in Debit Gateway Transactions
Billions of dollars
150

Millions of items
30

100

20

50

10

0

Jul

Aug

Sep
Oct
2011

Nov

Dec

Jan

Feb

Mar

Apr
2012

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

* A lockbox is a collection and processing service provided by a third party.

2

Summer 2012

May

Jun

Jul

0

The Federal Reserve System has
been acting as a fiscal agent for
the federal government for almost
100 years. Today, eGov provides
services that include technical
solutions. Debit Gateway now
enables the System to process a
multitude of transactions, including
anything from a passport fee to a
government-funded small-businessloan payment.
The Debit Gateway process begins
as the consumer writes a check or
makes an electronic payment. Debit
Gateway presents the payment to
the bank and credits the appropriate
government agency.
Picture a large funnel housed in
Cleveland. This is the collection point.
Payments from you or me—for
anything from a student loan to a
national park fee—enter the opening
from three points, either over the
counter (in person), mail, or online.
The payments get “funneled” through
the Debit Gateway application and
come out as electronic transactions
that are then presented to the appropriate banks. From there, the money
travels to the government agencies
to settle the debts. So, most likely, as
consumers, we have all had a Debit
Gateway encounter, without even
knowing it.
New and higher-volume customers
include the Office of Natural
Resources, Bureau of Prisons,
U.S. Postal Service, and Veterans
Administration. By the end of 2012,
the Debit Gateway is projected to
process more than 20 million
transactions per month. ■

Betting on a Big Impact
April McClellan-Copeland
Community Relations
and Education

Some numbers are in, but it may still
take a roll of the dice to determine
whether Horseshoe Casino Cleveland,
Ohio’s first casino, will provide the
economic payout that developers
had promised.
That’s because new tax revenues
aren’t the only positive expected
from gambling—so is spillover
business to the city’s wider entertainment sector. While we have some
tax data already, it will take a while
longer to fully register just how
successful the Horseshoe has been
in driving customers to nearby
restaurants and hotels.
From its opening day on May 14
through the end of July, Horseshoe
Casino Cleveland grossed $66.5
million after paying out winnings,
according to the Ohio Casino Control
Commission.
Ned Hill, dean of the Maxine
Goodman Levin College of Urban
Affairs at Cleveland State University,
says it’s way too early to tell what
type of economic impact the casinos
will have on the regional economy.
The premise of allowing casinos to
operate in Ohio was in part to capture
tax revenue that otherwise was going
across the border. But of equal appeal
is how much casinos help create new
energy in the downtown areas where
they are being built.

A complex mix of variables are at
play, such as whether customers are
coming from within or outside the
region, and whether the entertainment dollars are being repurposed or
shifted from other types of entertain­
ment. Beyond that, the durability
of the new casino jobs has yet to
be tested, and long-term revenue
streams—from which the state takes
a bite—are unknown.
Horseshoe officials have touted
the casino as a way to pull in dollars
not only for itself, but for other
downtown businesses.
“This casino [Horseshoe] has a different model from the others,” Hill
notes. “They are trying to build it
into the fabric of the entertainment
district.” Add it to the Medical Mart,
the Rock and Roll Hall of Fame and
Museum, and the Lakefront Bikeway
that’s expanding—the casino is part
of that mix.
Horseshoe’s adjusted gross income
at the end of July, which is the
amount left after winnings are paid
out, was $23.9 million, an 8 percent
drop from one month earlier when
the adjusted gross income was $26.1
million.
And the state’s second casino, Holly­
wood Casino Toledo, went from
$20.4 million in June to $19.1 million
in July. It opened May 29.

Is the novelty of Ohio’s first casinos
wearing off? Or was this drop in
revenue predictable?
“I knew the initial
opening attendance
would be up and
there would be a
great deal of interest,
and over a period of 90 days there
would be some leveling off,” says
Matt Schuler, executive director
of the Ohio Casino Control Commission. “I still believe it will take some
time before we get a performance
trajectory.”
Horseshoe Casino Cleveland, a
300,000-square-foot facility inside
the historic Higbee building in
downtown Cleveland, offers 2,100
slot machines and 65 table games.
The casino brought 1,600 new casino
jobs to the region.
Hollywood Casino in Toledo has
2,000 slot machines and 60 table
games. It upped the number of new
jobs by 1,300.
A casino in Columbus opened on
October 8, and one will open in
Cincinnati in the spring of 2013. The
four casinos were approved by Ohio
voters in 2009.
Despite the drop-off in revenue,
early numbers from the Ohio
Department of Taxation indicate that
the casinos’ economic impact could
be felt across Ohio’s 88 counties,
where the money is distributed in
proportion to the population of each
county.
The Ohio Department of Taxation
made its first quarterly distribution of
$19.7 million in July. The tax money
is split between counties, host cities
such as Cleveland, school districts,
the Casino Control Commission, and
other agencies. ■

F refront

3

federal reserve bank of cleveland

P O L I C Y

2 O 1 2

S U M M I T

The Shifting Landscape
of Economic Development
More cooperation, less corporate subsidization
Rebuilding Communities:
Lessons from the Cleveland
Fed’s 2012 Policy Summit

Doug Campbell
Editor

For 10 years, the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland has hosted a unique gathering of
researchers and practitioners to talk about
community development policies. The 2012
Policy Summit continued the tradition of
marrying research and theory with on-theground “what works” know-how. Everything
from low-income housing programs to
workforce development was put under the
microscope, and no neat-sounding hypothesis was left unexamined by the practical eye
of experience.
In the following pages, Forefront zeroes
in on the Policy Summit’s headline sessions
covering economic development and
education reform.
For links to a full roundup of the two-day
event, including video excerpts from keynote
speaker Alex Kotlowitz’s moving address,
visit us online at www.clevelandfed.org/
forefront.

4

Summer 2012

Economic development used to be
easy to define. In its most traditional
form, it was designed to motivate
businesses to add new jobs, open
plants, or move into town. That was
about it.
Today, economic development
professionals need more space to
explain what they do. Their efforts
have grown more varied and more
interconnected. And they hope
their results have likewise grown
in magnitude.
“Too much economic development
at the state and local levels has been
throwing goodies at employers,”
said Harry Holzer, a professor of
public policy with the Public Policy
Institute at Georgetown University.
“We’re talking about economic
development that provides some
value-added… that works with
companies to develop their skill mix,
the services the companies provide
to employees, and helps them to
access the talent they often have a
hard time getting on their own.”

Holzer joined two other national
experts at the Cleveland Fed’s 2012
Policy Summit in laying out a new
approach to economic development
—one that is multipronged, holistic,
and long in its planning and execution
horizon.
That long horizon is crucial, because
returns from investments are often
not immediate. On any given day in
any given neighborhood, economic
and community development
professionals are working hard to
improve conditions, get people jobs,
and make streets safer. Yet for all of
their efforts, they face a recurring
question: So what?
Here is how Michael Rubinger,
president and CEO of Local
Initiatives Support Corporation
(LISC), framed the problem: “You’ve
developed housing, you’ve undertaken physical revitalization—but
so what? Have you really changed
these communities and improved
the lives of residents who live there?

If we really are serious about creating
sustainable communities, where
people willingly come to work and
live, we somehow have to address
the other daunting issues.”
Gone are the days when luring new
companies to town was the name
of the game. Addressing the needs
of low- and moderate-income
communities in particular means
providing more than jobs—it means
providing workforce development
opportunities, good schools, safe
neighborhoods, access to health care,
cultural amenities, housing, and
transportation, among other things.
Granted, that’s asking a lot.
Priorities must be set. LISC’s
strategy to encompass all of these
approaches is called Building
Sustainable Communities, and it
involves everything from setting up
Financial Opportunity Centers to
supporting charter schools and afterschool programs. But it’s difficult
to find ways to connect the various
organizations with a common
mission, Rubinger said. School
officials have enough on their plates
without coordinating with local
housing authorities, for example. But
Rubinger emphasized the strategy
is not—and cannot be—about the
individual projects, no matter how
effective or innovative they may be.
“It’s about how these are woven
together in a mutually reinforcing
way in a single, targeted neighborhood to achieve greater force and
impact,” Rubinger added. This year,
LISC is active with such efforts in
50 communities across the country.
The current slow economic recovery is only adding to the challenge,
making it harder to raise funds and
reverse economic decline. “We’re
making progress, but let’s be clear—
our work has only just begun.”
A localized experiment in comprehensive economic development
is happening in Akron, Ohio. Eric
Anthony Johnson, executive director
of the University Park Alliance,

described plans to transform the
50 blocks around the University of
Akron into an economically, socially,
and culturally vibrant community.
Anchored by the university, a medical
center, and three primary education
schools, the plan looks to create more
than 2,500 jobs over the long term.
In the University Park Alliance’s
strategy, commercial development
projects go hand in hand with neighborhood revitalization. A company
considering a business investment in
the region may be more willing to do
so if it sees a healthy neighborhood
with a built-in, skilled labor pool.
And for families and individuals, the
decision to move to the community
may likewise be based on nearby
employment prospects.
“The old economic development
model is throwing out a fishing pole
and hoping to land the big company,”
Johnson said. “That doesn’t happen
now. Our emphasis is on place.”
Both the LISC and the University
Park Alliance approaches aim to
break institutions and organizations
out of their traditional silos. Holzer
noted that overcoming the inertia
of institutions is difficult because
they often lack incentives to change.
Historically, for example, the U.S.
Department of Education has not
always tried to align its policies with
the Labor Department’s workforce
development programs.
Students may get a decent education
in public school, but they may still
lack basic information about the most
in-demand skills and occupations in
the labor market. And when they do
recognize opportunities, they often
can’t get the education they need.
“We have all these stories during the
recession of unemployed workers
going back to college, community
colleges especially. They knew that
health care and health technology
remained a strong field despite the
recession,” Holzer said. “And the
classes were always oversubscribed
because the institution didn’t have

 he old economic development model
T
is throwing out a fishing pole and hoping to
land the big company. That doesn’t
happen now. Our emphasis is on place.
the incentive to expand capacity in
those high-demand areas. That’s part
of the problem of education and workforce not being integrated and the
two of them not being responsive
to the demand side of the labor
market.”
What works, Holzer said, are some of
the very approaches taken by LISC
and the University Park Alliance.
Local schools must connect with
one-stop workforce development
shops that are in turn connected to
local employers. Good data will help
identify where the jobs are located
and which sectors are growing. And
intermediaries are essential to bring
together the industries, the associations, the employers, the training
providers, and the workers. Above
all, the strongest returns come when
educational programs match labor
market needs.
The first step is simply recognizing
the need to make connections—
that the kind of housing one lives
in has a direct correlation with how
well children do in school; that just
because a factory moves to town
doesn’t mean qualified candidates
have access to transportation that
would bring them to the workplace.
Silos must be broken down.
“The implication for community
development,” Rubinger said, “is that
we have to be comprehensive in our
approaches.”
The next step is arguably harder. That’s
when results have to be produced—
when you have to answer the “so what”
question. ■
Watch video clips from this session
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/
ff_2012_summer_06.cfm

F refront

5

federal reserve bank of cleveland

P O L I C Y

2 O 1 2

S U M M I T

Working Out an
Equation for Education Reform
Cutting-edge efforts to improve America’s education system

Anne O’Shaughnessy
Community Development
Project Manager

Education reform prompts no shortage of heated policy
debates. Do teacher incentives work? Are charter schools
delivering better results than public schools? Will U.S.
children fall further behind their global counterparts if we
don’t push more math and science? And how important
is the role of early childhood education?
Not in dispute is that education is a critical component of a
strong economy. A wide body of research, including some
by economists at the Cleveland Fed, shows that better
educational outcomes contribute to greater individual
earnings potential, a stronger workforce, lower rates of
incarceration, and stable neighborhoods and communities
—all of which drive a strong regional economy. That’s why
efforts to improve America’s education system took the
spotlight at the Cleveland Fed’s 2012 Policy Summit.
The big question is this: What public policies can
best promote better schools
and improved outcomes?
As with many complex issues,
there is no one-size-fits-all
solution. Budget constraints are

6

Summer 2012

among the many challenges facing school districts and
education policymakers across the nation. Researchers
at the Policy Summit delivered several messages, none
clearer than the recurrent theme that “evidence matters.”
“It’s important not only to evaluate research, but also to
engage stakeholders in using and generating evidence,”
said Rebecca Maynard, Commissioner, National Center
for Education Evaluation and Regional Assistance at the
U.S. Department of Education’s Institute of Education
Sciences (IES).
Determining what’s most useful to educators and policymakers has been the work of IES, which in 2002 developed a database of educational research on policies and
programs it evaluates based on stringent criteria. To date,
some 6,500 studies have been reviewed; 6 percent meet
IES standards. IES shares this scientific evidence on its

website along with practice guides that offer a more
practical, applied resource for educators in the classroom.
“We want educators to be able to make evidence-based
decisions about, for example, what content to teach,”
explained Maynard.
IES also provides research-based training on tactics for
classroom management, strategies for retaining and
motivating teachers, and techniques for classroom
instruction, all aimed at helping teachers and school
administrators improve student outcomes. To ensure
consistency and efficiency, regional representatives work
with other government agencies to create a single portal
for educators to learn about these opportunities.
But what works in one district or with one set of students
may not work elsewhere. New programs are developed all
the time based on research, anecdotal evidence, and the
passion of educators and parents. Many show promise, but
which ones are worth funding? Trying them is not a bad
investment, said Maynard, provided there are clear measures
built in to assess whether they work, and how well.
Kimber Bogard, from the Institute of Medicine at the
National Research Council, shared evidence on the value
of early childhood programs. She pointed to certain aspects
of early childhood programs that research shows are
working. “Quality of program matters,” she said. “Teacher
quality matters. And mobility and absenteeism matter.”
She also advocated for greater collaboration among
researchers, social scientists, child development specialists,
and economists. You can’t look at education policy from a
single perspective—whether the child’s, the educator’s, or
the taxpayer’s. “You need a more comprehensive approach
to find out what’s really going on,” she noted, “and to learn
what works. Quality research depends on it.”
Quality research, however, can sometimes be diffi­
cult to set up or conduct. Panelist Susan Dynarski,
an associate professor of public policy at
the University of Michigan, explained that
one reason charter schools are such a
hot-button issue in education reform
is that it is hard to tell whether they are
actually better than public schools.

Nevertheless, the lottery system that many charter schools
employ to enroll students provides researchers with a
decent randomized trial sampling. The results from one
study show statistically significant numbers that charter
schools can make a positive difference. More research
must be done, she added, before any conclusive assessments can be made. That goes for just about any program,
she said: “Make sure you’re driving with the headlights on.”
One conclusive finding Dynarski pointed to is the growing
inequality among students with a bachelor’s degree and
those without. Where can policy changes help? And how?
Maynard said policy ought to be driven by science, though
she acknowledged that in reality it is driven by many other
things, such as budget constraints, public sentiment, and
competing political interests. “If I could change one thing,
I would stop rolling out big things—like teacher value-add
[a method of teacher evaluation]—without building in
science to learn from it,” Maynard said. “Policy changes
should be more incremental.”
If I could change one thing, I would stop rolling out
big things… without building in science to learn from it.
Timing is important, too. Noted Dynarski: “Invest in the
right programs that work, of course, but it’s also important
to know when—at what point on the timeline or education
continuum.”
Finally, no policy or program exists in a vacuum. “It’s never
just the classroom or the neighborhood,” the National
Research Council’s Bogard said. “Families, too, are essential
for successful outcomes.” Education reform is one piece
of the puzzle, and it may be more effective when inter­
connections with other efforts are recognized.
“When you’re talking about schooling, you’re talking about
kids, you’re talking about a school, you’re talking about
teachers, you’re talking about a workforce, you’re talking
about a system,” Bogard summed up. “Working together
is going to give you the biggest bang for your buck.” ■
Want to learn more?
Check out the Institute of Education Science’s evaluations of
thousands of education reform efforts at www.ies.ed.gov/ncee/wwc
Watch video clips from this session
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_07.cfm
F refront

7

federal reserve bank of cleveland

P O L I C Y

2 O 1 2

S U M M I T

The New City
Some practical lessons about policy
implementation from city (and county) hall

Amy Koehnen
Managing Editor

Many cities are fighting for survival in a post-recession,
still-feels-like-a-recession economy. Against the backdrop
of dwindling tax revenues and lean budgets, just keeping
the trains running has become a challenge. Long-term
planning to address chronic unemployment, improve
human services, and reform the education system increasingly has to take a backseat.
That tension between the daily-grind reality of running
an American city versus high-minded, future-oriented
community development was the focus of a special panel
at the Cleveland Fed’s 2012 Policy Summit. Leaders from

8

Summer 2012

three major Midwest metro areas—Cleveland, Pittsburgh,
and Cincinnati—talked about the difficulty of balancing
short-term necessities with long-term planning, and how
tough budgets are forcing them to make even tougher calls.
“How to do more with less” has become the motto of
many local governments. Before the financial crisis,
hundreds of millions of dollars streamed in from both
the federal and state governments. Historically, those
were localities’ main funding sources for certain projects,
“where you have to generate the money to do the big
brownfield cleanups, infrastructure improvements,” and
other projects to revitalize cities, said Rich Fitzgerald,
chief executive of Allegheny County, Pennsylvania.
Likewise, roads, bridges, mass transit, and airports have
all traditionally used state and federal dollars that are no
longer available. Those dollars have dried up.

Another emerging problem: Some of today’s fastestgrowing employers tend not to contribute so much in the
way of tax revenue.
Take downtown Pittsburgh. It’s one of the most booming
urban areas in the country, according to Fitzgerald, thanks
in large part to its two research universities—the University
of Pittsburgh and Carnegie Mellon University, along with
its medical centers. But these institutions are nonprofits
that do not pay property tax. “For most cities,” said
moderator Tom Murphy, the former mayor of Pittsburgh
now with the Urban Land Institute, “we are forced to try
to make something work in a box that is unworkable.”
With less money to work with, cities need to innovate to
position themselves to succeed in the future, all the while
taking care of today. Cleveland Mayor Frank Jackson
summed up the panelists’ strategy this way: You have to
plan for good times and for bad times. When the hard times
come, he said, it’s too late. Jackson said his administration
had already made a lot of hard cuts before the 2008 financial
crisis, trimming anything not deemed critical. As a result,
he said, Cleveland’s landing was softer because the city
had planned for it. It was still hard, Jackson admitted, but
because the city wasn’t forced to tap money set aside for
investments in the future, it was better positioned to take
advantage of improving conditions.
Roxanne Qualls, Cincinnati’s vice mayor, echoed Jackson’s
sentiments. In Cincinnati, as in Cleveland, the mantra is
to have a structurally balanced budget. But she argued that
while budgets have been cut—slashed, even—there seems
to be “a lack of will on the revenue side.” The city reduced
the workforce by 1,000 people, but Qualls still sees a lack
of investment in some of Cincinnati’s neighborhoods.
Cincinnati’s solution is twofold: 1) building a new “prioritydriven budget” by working with communities on setting
priorities for expenditures, and 2) establishing a tax commission to look at how tax policies grow or inhibit jobs.
Results, Qualls said, should be in by the end of the year.
Allegheny County’s Fitzgerald made a novel observation:
Tax rates aren’t as important to businesses as they are made
out to be. It’s a myth, Fitzgerald said, that if you cut taxes,
from l-r: Roxanne Qualls, Vice Mayor, City of Cincinnati; Rich Fitzgerald,
Chief Executive, Allegheny County (PA); The Honorable Frank Jackson, Mayor,
City of Cleveland; Tom Murphy, Senior Resident Fellow, Urban Land Institute

businesses will come to your community. “Companies
rarely say that that is what they want. They want help with
training employees. ‘Can you provide better transit for
our employees to get to work? We need an off-ramp to
get goods and services in and out of this community.’
But day after day we see politicians signing pledges to
never raise taxes [on businesses]. It’s shortsighted and
goes against good governance.”
It’s a myth, Fitzgerald said, that if you cut taxes,
businesses will come to your community.
The main issue, as Fitzgerald sees it, is that leaders simply
“haven’t restructured for a new city and region.” As the
manufacturing sector fades in relative dominance, new
industry–government partnerships need to be formed.
“We still have manufacturing, but we’ve diversified,”
Fitzgerald said. “We have information technology, life
sciences. We make movies.” He also pointed to the area’s
success at spinning off the research initiatives into
companies and into jobs.
Moreover, even during times of belt-tightening, there is
room for forward-looking projects. One of Cincinnati’s
most promising developments is happening on its
riverfront, where a series of public–private investments
has created a bustling retail and entertainment district.
Elsewhere in the city, partnerships with universities and
hospitals in the Uptown neighborhood have produced new
efforts to improve human, social, economic, and physical
conditions in the area. And a newly created innovation
task force is trying to help spin more commercial ventures
out of the world-renowned Cincinnati Children’s Hospital
Medical Center.
But why encourage these types of institutions to grow when
they don’t directly contribute to the region’s tax coffers?
Because indirectly, they do.
The key is the “connectivity between the institutions,”
Jackson said. “If this happens in the right way, it offsets
what they don’t pay in property taxes because you grow
an economy. Our hospitals… procure billions of dollars
in goods and services each year. The more it can flow into
our economy, the more it can support local business, and
the more people will stay employed.” ■

F refront

9

Getting to the “How”
of Innovation
Innovation—everyone is for it. In fact, one of the most firmly established principles in economics is the importance
of innovation in driving growth and prosperity. The ability to produce knowledge and use it commercially is the
main determinant of whether—and how well—nations and regions thrive.
Yet how to drive innovation remains elusive. We really don’t know much about the production, diffusion, and
application of knowledge. At the same time, economics is pretty good at providing some rules of thumb—many of
which, unfortunately, tend to be ignored. With that in mind, Forefront asked some economic experts for their take
on how best to capture the fruits of innovation.

Doug Campbell
Editor

Why innovation is important for growth
Let’s start with the question of how we know that innovation powers economic growth. This key insight came from
Nobel economist Robert Solow, who found that standard
economic models failed to account for almost half of
the economy’s output. There was something beyond the
accumulation of physical capital—a residual that most
people now ascribe to technological innovation. We at the
Cleveland Fed have defined it as “finding a better way to
get things done with what you already have.”

10

Summer 2012

Over the years, economists have refined Solow’s growth
theory to clarify the role of technological innovation.
Real-world evidence on the importance of innovation is
also mounting. Looking over a 75-year period, Cleveland
Fed economists and their co-authors have found that
patents were the single largest factor explaining income
differences across U.S. states. High levels of patents in
states like Connecticut, Massachusetts, and New Jersey
explain most of their income growth going back to 1939.
This implies strong innovation and knowledge-building
in places with vigorous income growth. Overall, our
economists concluded, innovation is the most important
factor in determining people’s welfare.

Why we think policies can help innovation

Why innovation is so important right now

Once we understand the importance of innovation, the
next logical question is whether public policy can help
raise innovation levels. Our nation’s go-to policies include
tax credits for research and development, robust patent
protections for innovating firms, grants and subsidies
to entrepreneurs and academic researchers, and so on.
Are they working?

The nation’s struggle to claw back from a severe recession
would be motivation enough to think about ways to boost
innovation. But another motivation comes from the longrun trend of productivity growth—in the wrong direction.
As economist Tyler Cowen explains in his 2011 e-book,
The Great Stagnation, America has enjoyed a long period
of picking low-hanging fruit, in the form of new technology
to fuel a fast-growing labor force. But since the 1970s, the
lowest branches have become increasingly bare. “That’s a
sign that the pace of technological development has been
slowing down,” Cowen notes. “It’s not that something
specific caused the slowdown, but rather we started to
exhaust the benefits of our previous momentum without
renewing them.”

According to Andy Atkeson, an economist at the University
of California, Los Angeles, and a visiting scholar at the
Minneapolis Fed, the litmus test for most economists is
whether the free market would drive innovation more
efficiently than government policy. After all, the main
reason firms might want to innovate is to boost their profits.
If firms are going to innovate anyway, why should the
government step in and risk distorting the market?
The answer is that firms may not invest in innovation
as much as the rest of us would like. That’s because, as
Atkeson notes, the benefits of innovation don’t flow just
to the innovators. Society gains as well.
Ideas generally can’t be stopped from spilling over into the
wider world, and firms learn from each other. In fact, it’s
the social element of innovation that makes it beneficial to
the wider economy. To take a classic example: Synthetic
fiber was invented in the chemical industry, but the knowledge that created it spilled over to the textile industry.
Atkeson offers a more recent example: “Apple’s investment
in R&D has been amply rewarded in the company’s profits.
But they can’t patent the market categories they created,
like the smartphone. They showed people what it should
look like, and now lots of others are copying it. That means
they didn’t get the full return from their investment. In the
end, there is a big intellectual component from innovation
that’s not captured by the innovator.”
The very existence of knowledge spillovers suggests that
we might not be getting as much from them as we could.
All the same, economists strongly suspect that companies
will invest in research and development only to the extent
that they can profit from it. The part that spills over is
extra, not something they factor into the equation.
But from a societal standpoint, we want as much of the
innovation spillover as possible. That’s where policy can
make a difference.

The litmus test for most economists is whether the
free market would drive innovation more efficiently than
government policy.
You can see the stagnation in productivity data. Since
1973, the rate of productivity growth has fallen below the
trend in the post–WWII period.

The starting point
Innovation is not a linear process; it’s messy and iterative.
Ideas bop around until they are fine-tuned into something
with real market value. Failure is a key part of the process.
For that reason, there seem to be many potential entry
points where policies can affect innovation. These begin
with basic research—the most fundamental stage of
innovation, where ideas are beginning to germinate and
most likely have no specific commercial use in mind. Then
there is applied research, in which commercial entities
transform ideas into prototypes and processes. Also crucial
is funding—entrepreneurs need financial backing to get
their ideas into development and production. Intellectual
property rights and associated patent protection policies
are also important. And of course, educational institutions
perform a number of roles, from idea and business generators to workforce preparation.
Scott Shane, BusinessWeek blogger and economist at Case
Western Reserve University, suggested where innovation
policy could be most useful.

F refront

11

Productivity Change in the Nonfarm Business Sector, 1947–2011
Average annual percent change
4

3

2

1

0

1947–73

1973–79

1979–90

1990–2000

2000–07

2007–11

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

You can see the stagnation in productivity data.
Since 1973, the rate of productivity growth has fallen
below the trend in the post–WWII period.
The starting point, Shane believes, is weighing the costs
and benefits. Often, he says, it’s not clear that policies
aimed directly at firms would create better outcomes than
the private market would on its own. In other cases, it
seems that the government provides windfall subsidies
beyond the point where companies would have invested
otherwise.
“It’s very hard to link what economic developers are
saying should be done to some specific evidence of what
would work,” Shane explains. “Why should we advocate
policies to create innovations if we don’t even know
whether they work?”

Innovation “maybe nots”
With that yardstick in mind, here are the innovation
policy staples that some economists have identified as
needing careful cost–benefit analysis.
Incubators are a favorite “innovation-friendly” government
program. Incubators typically feature a building whose
small-business tenants share space, computer and office
equipment, and onsite counsel. Putting innovators in the
same place, it is hoped, will encourage them to swap ideas,
contacts, and funding sources. The same principle is behind

12

Summer 2012

		 the notion of agglomeration—the idea
that people and firms working within the
same region increase their ability to share and profit from
knowledge.
The National Business Incubation Association counts
about 1,200 business incubators across the country. Many
are supported by local governments and universities.
The way Shane sees it, you most often end up with
promising young firms that choose to operate in the
incubator because they can get free or inexpensive space.
The clustering and specialization that firms can experience
as part of an incubator can help their performance. He
wonders, “If the private sector benefits from providing
space for new firms, why doesn’t it do it?”
Direct financial subsidies to companies are premised on
the theory that young firms in particular don’t have the
resources to engage in serious research and development
on unproven ideas, and they can’t attract investors in their
very early stages. Subsidies can take the form of grants or
loans, sometimes funneled through public venture-capital
funds. Local policymakers often use multipliers to justify
these investments, arguing that every $1 invested turns
into a certain number of new jobs, for example.
The problem with the direct subsidies approach, several
economists contend, is that it may distort market outcomes. The government could get itself into a situation
of picking winners and losers, and prematurely at that.

Private markets are much better at sorting out winners
from losers than anyone trying to foresee which idea may
eventually gain traction.

7 percent. The GAO also noted a number of shortcomings in
the R&D tax-credit system, including disparities between
the amount of the credit and its actual incentive effects.

Patent protection, counterintuitively, may sometimes
stifle innovation. This is the argument made by George
Mason University’s Alex Tabarrok, author of Launching
the Innovation Renaissance (2011). Patents are supposed
to reward innovators by handing them a monopoly on
their product for a certain number of years. Profit-seeking
investors will be more likely to put their money into
projects they think will be insulated from competition,
the thinking goes. Patent protection certainly makes sense
in situations where the costs of innovation greatly exceed
the costs of imitation—like the pharmaceutical industry.

But there is a wider issue to consider: Any innovationinvestment payoffs will be counterbalanced by the taxes
businesses will pay on their profits. Atkeson explains it
this way:

But Tabarrok sees too many situations in which patent
protection is overused. The problem is particularly acute
with innovations that produce intermediate goods, that is,
goods that are used to produce other goods and innovations.
Tabarrok’s example is the “oncomouse,” a genetically
engineered mouse used in biomedical research. For years,
he says, Harvard and DuPont wielded virtual control over
the oncomouse, even though others could have greatly
enhanced biomedical research with access to it. The upshot
was that strong patent protections increased the cost of
building on previous research and thus discouraged further
innovation.
“The patent system is now being used as a weapon for
innovative firms to attack other innovative firms and slow
them down,” Tabarrok said.
The tax code is a critically important consideration in
innovation policy. To Atkeson, the tax code is in fact the
most important consideration because it bears so directly
on whether entrepreneurs choose to enter the market.
Consider the offsetting effects of the U.S. tax code on
research and development tax credits. R&D credits were
established in 1981 as an incremental subsidy—a tax
credit to supplement a defined base amount of spending.
In recent years, the value of the subsidy has ranged between
$4 billion and $8 billion a year. A 2009 Government
Accountability Office report found that the R&D tax
credit reduced the business costs of new research by about

When you’re considering creating a new firm, you
tally up all the revenue you think you can make versus
the expenses. That includes projections of a subsidy
for innovation that you might get, as well as payment
of corporate taxes on profits. As anyone who evaluates
business plans knows, if the present value of your
investment is positive, you should enter. If not, you
shouldn’t. So, from a purely business plan perspective,
a subsidy is dollars coming in and taxes are dollars
going out. I would think those two policies would just
cancel each other out. But in fact, our research has
found that they don’t cancel each other out, because
the corporate tax is bigger than the subsidies!
So the discouragement of entry that we have with the
corporate tax is much larger than the encouragement of
innovation with the R&D tax credit.
“If policies discourage entry, that’s not good,” Atkeson
said. “The rule should be to evaluate the universe of
policies based on whether they affect an entrepreneur’s
decision to enter.”
The discouragement of entry that we have with the
corporate tax is much larger than the encouragement of
innovation with the R&D tax credit.

Innovation “do’s”
Just as economists have reservations about certain policies,
they are enthusiastic about others. These include:
Investment in basic research. The federal government is
the main source of funding for basic research, which is
mostly conducted at academic institutions. Meanwhile,
according to the National Science Board, only about
3.8 percent of industry-sponsored R&D can be classified
as basic. The federal government’s annual contribution is
about $37 billion of the $62 billion total spent on basic
research in the United States.

F refront

13

Experts agree that when it comes to spurring long-term
innovation, the federal government should do much
more investing in basic research, which is the lifeblood of
innovation. Basic research increases the technologies that
lead to new industries and new products in the future.
 e ought to grab up smart people who want to come here,
W
and do it now when they still want to come.
The internet is Exhibit A. Without coordinated effort and
investment by federal agencies in the 1960s and 1970s, the
internet infrastructure never would have been built. Most
of these dollars went directly to universities and research
institutions, well before it was clear that the “packet
switching” technology dreamt up at MIT would blossom
into the internet of today.
“The best way policymakers can fund basic research
is through government labs or to support academic
research,” Shane contends.
Improve education. To bring ideas from the lab to the
marketplace requires more than a single genius. But
in a country where one of every four American men
doesn’t even graduate high school, access to that help is
a challenge.
Tabarrok advocates a range of efforts to improve
educational outcomes that drive innovation. These include
rewarding good teachers, creating more vocational
educational programs and apprenticeships, and encouraging
more students to go into math and science fields.
A body of other research points to early childhood education
as a potential source of fuel for innovation. As Art Rolnick,
co-director for the Human Capital Research Collaborative
at the University of Minnesota, puts it, “Early childhood
education is economic development, and the research
shows it’s economic development with a high public
return—very high.”

14

Summer 2012

Let high-skilled immigrants work here. Another way to
improve the labor force is to open our doors more fully to
high-skilled immigrants. As Tabarrok argues, the United
States has a workforce of 150 million but annually allows
only 120,000 employment visas. And each country has
a limit on the number of immigrants allowed each year,
regardless of the needed skills.
Tabarrok describes this as low-hanging fruit with an expiration date. Wait too long to change policy, and eventually
conditions will improve in the immigrants’ home countries
to the point where they have little incentive to emigrate.
“We ought to grab up smart people who want to come here,
and do it now when they still want to come.”
Ken Simonson, chief economist of the Associated General
Contractors of America, agrees, saying current U.S.
immigration policy sends a mixed message: “We welcome
students from abroad into our science, engineering, and
technology programs, and then we say, ‘Sorry, we don’t
want you working here.’ That’s just at the point when they
could be our innovators!”

Don’t forget the private sector
Beyond these policy recommendations, where does the
private sector fit in? Eugene Fitzgerald, an engineering
professor at MIT and formerly a scientist at AT&T Bell
Labs, brings a perspective from the trenches. He invented
something called “strained silicon electronics,” a way to
improve the performance of integrated circuits that was a
huge technological advancement.
The interaction between corporate and public America
was central to this process, in Fitzgerald’s telling. Back in
the 1950s and 1960s, he says, the back-and-forth between
corporate labs, government labs, and university researchers
was robust. Ideas were swapped and knowledge spread to
benefit end users.
Today, large corporate labs have largely disappeared. They
went away, Fitzgerald says, because global competitors
sprouted up to take on the virtual monopoly firms in the
United States. For example, Kodak suddenly had to deal
with Fuji, and pressure shifted to maintaining short-term
profits. Before, big U.S. firms could wait a decade for a
return on their research investments, but that’s too long in
today’s hypercompetitive environment.

With mainly government and university research left to
carry the load, the crucial feedback loop with the private
sector was severed, and innovation became less efficient.
Fitzgerald cites this trend to explain the drop-off in
productivity growth starting in the 1970s.
Fitzgerald sees the absence of corporations from the
innovation pipeline as contributing to an “innovation gap”
that slows the overall pace of innovation. The innovation
pipeline may currently produce a lot of research and
patents, he says, but not a whole lot of economic growth.
Figuring out the mechanism for bridging the gap is
another matter. Theoretically, the R&D tax credit should
induce long-term investment in innovation. Fitzgerald
says he is working on an index that measures “innovation
capacity” in a company. The IRS could eventually use this
metric to confirm tax credits are being properly channeled
to long-term investments.
“There is no way the free market alone can get corporations
to invest 15 years out,” Fitzgerald adds. “You need long-term
government funding. They’re the only ones who can
recover their investment over the long term, because they
get it back in tax revenues and growth.”

The waiting is the hardest part
The final ingredient in spurring innovation in America
may be patience. All of these efforts will take time before
any return is evident. In today’s results-now world, waiting
a decade for the payoff seems like an eternity. Politically,
a multipronged approach to increasing innovation would
probably have to survive at least two presidential administrations and several more Congresses.

Resources
Find links to readings mentioned in this article at
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_05.cfm

Find links to Alex Tabarrok’s 2011 book, Launching the Innovation
Renaissance, and related materials at http://marginalrevolution.com
Read columns on innovation and entrepreneurship by Scott Shane
at www.businessweek.com/authors/2250-scott-shane
Recommended reading

The challenge is to create linkages between our longterm innovation goals and the short-term needs of the
institutions that play a part in the innovation process. It’s
a lot simpler to articulate that challenge than to actually
address it.

Andrew Atkeson and Ariel Burstein. 2011. “Policies to Stimulate
Innovation: How Effective Are Policies to Encourage Investment
in Innovation by Firms, and What Impact Do They Have on the
Macroeconomy?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Policy
Papers (October).

Fortunately, the stakes are high enough to give policy­
makers plenty of incentive to make it happen. The future
of innovation depends on their determination. ■

Eugene Fitzgerald, Andreas Wankerl, and Carl Schramm. 2011.
Inside Real Innovation: How the Right Approach Can Move Ideas
from R&D to Market—And Get the Economy Moving. World
Scientific Publishing Company. Also, find a synopsis on Inside Real
Innovation at www.forbes.com/sites/ciocentral/2011/01/31/why-the-

www.minneapolisfed.org/publications_ papers/pub_display.cfm?id=4752

government-needs-to-invest-in-innovation/

F refront

15

Kyle Fee
Senior Research Analyst

In 1960, the manufacturing sector employed about
one of every four Americans. Today, it’s one of every 10.
In terms of nominal GDP, manufacturing has gone from
driving 25 percent of the economy to less than half that
over the past 50 years.
These trends raise a natural question: Does manufac­
turing still matter in the U.S. economy? The answer,
supplied at a recent conference held at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland, is a solid “yes,” though it
comes with some interesting wrinkles.

While it may never provide the employment base or
comprise the share of GDP it once did, U.S. manufacturing seems positioned to remain a vital part of the
economy for the foreseeable future. That forecast, how­
ever, depends on whether the country can implement
policies to address potential problems and capitalize on
current strengths.
The views expressed in this article were largely gleaned
from presentations at the May 30-31, 2012, industry
conference, Making It in America: Manufacturing Matters,
co-sponsored by the National Association for Business
Economics and the Cleveland Fed.* The conference
focused on the changing dynamics and rebalancing of
U.S. manufacturing industry in the global economy.

* 	Anything not directly discussed at the conference is attributed to other sources.

16

Summer 2012

Here are four questions that permeated conference
discussions:

1

	Why won’t manufacturing be
the major employer it once was?
It’s no secret that the United States has lost manufacturing
jobs to the offshoring of production processes to countries
with low labor costs and a large population of low-skill
workers. Low-skill, labor-intensive jobs are inherently
mobile, and many of them will never return to the United
States because it is simply unprofitable to locate those jobs
here. We see this dynamic playing out across the globe as
companies readily move production facilities from country
to country in search of lower costs.
Take China, for example: previously a reliable source
of low-cost labor, the country has seen labor costs rise
markedly over the past decade. According to the Bureau
of Labor Statistics (BLS), Chinese wages increased
100 percent from 2002 to 2008. As recounted in a recent
article in the Economist, rising wages in China have
spurred the movement of some jobs to other lower-cost
Asian countries.
Global trade and competition have also affected U.S.
manufacturing. Comparative advantages make certain
manufacturing activities more productive in other countries.
So when firms from different countries compete in the
global market, the firms that can best take advantage of
the strengths of a certain location will be successful, and
the less strategic ones will close, with their resources
reallocated to more productive uses.
It is easy to conclude that when domestic companies
move production facilities overseas, it is with intentions
of importing back into the domestic market. However,
it is more a reflection of the companies’ interest in participating in the global market than in exporting back to the
United States. Total world sales by foreign manufacturing
affiliates have increased by $1 trillion from 2000 to 2009,
while sales to the United States have remained stagnant at
roughly $200 billion, according to the Bureau of Economic
Analysis (BEA).
The real smoking gun for why manufacturing will not
provide the employment base it once did is directly tied
to the industry’s own success in improving productivity.

It now takes only 170 workers to produce what it used to
take 1,000 workers to produce in 1950, according to the
BLS. Technological advancements to control costs as well
as to improve product quality have increased productivity.
This remarkable increase is analogous to the agricultural
sector’s performance during the 20th century. Farm
employment declined dramatically even as output shot up.
While much of the advancements in farming happened
earlier in the century, manufacturing saw its largest upticks
in productivity beginning in the 1970s, as new technologies
began to be incorporated into production processes.
Within the manufacturing industry, productivity increases
were especially pronounced in the production of durable
goods over the last 30 years, thanks in part to the adoption
of such process-improving technologies as Computer
Numerical Control machining tools and AutoCAD.
Moreover, as technological advances have continued to
accrue, manufacturing productivity has continued to
outpace productivity gains for the larger economy.
Productivity, Thy Name is Manufacturing
Average annual percent change
5
4

Nonfarm Business

Manufacturing

3
2
1
0

1950s

1960s

1970s

1980s

2000s

2010s

2010–11

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Simply put, manufacturing companies today can do more
with less. And they have. Manufacturing employment has
fallen 1.5 percent per year since 1980, according to the BLS.
At the same time, manufacturing output rose 3.1 percent
per year, according to the Federal Reserve Board. In the
end, increased productivity levels make it quite improbable
for manufacturing to be the major employer it once was.
“When you look at the labor side, it’s not a pretty story,”
said Bill Strauss, senior economist and economic adviser
at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. “We still need
millions of workers in manufacturing, but in terms of
growing that workforce, most of the output has increased
based on productivity.”
F refront

17

2

	Why won’t manufacturing comprise
as much of a share of GDP as it once did?
Manufacturing’s share of GDP has declined over the years
partly by virtue of the industry’s own success. Increased
productivity has allowed manufacturers to lower unit-labor
costs, leading to lower relative prices for manufactured
goods. Put another way, prices of manufactured goods
have not increased as fast as other prices have. Holding
the changing price level constant, manufacturing output
has grown, on average, 1.7 percent per year since 1960
while total output has grown, on average, 3.1 percent per
year. Thus, as a matter of accounting, manufacturing has
made up a smaller share of GDP over time.

Still Recovering: Manufacturing Productivity
and Employment Since the Recession
Index, 2007=100
105
100
95

Employment

90

Production

85
80
75

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

2012

Sources: Federal Reserve Board; Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The recent recession and recovery have only accelerated
this trend of doing more with less. The recession saw
manufacturing employment and production fall roughly
17 and 20 percent, respectively. Production levels have
regained nearly 15 percent of lost production, but employ­
ment levels have recovered only about 3.5 percent. This
translates into stronger productivity gains, averaging
4.6 percent over the past two years, than posted during
the 1990s or 2000s. Amazingly, manufacturing employment levels have now fallen to levels not seen since 1941,
even as production levels have returned to 2005 levels.

3

Can we sustain these productivity increases?

Increasing productivity depends on new technology and a
skilled workforce. Here lies one potential problem for the
future of manufacturing in America: With almost 50 percent
of production workers over the age of 45, according to the
Census (Integrated Public Use Microdata Series, or IPUMS),

18

Summer 2012

the manufacturing workforce is quickly “graying.” Older
workers will need to be replaced over the next decade,
and there may not be enough younger workers with the
necessary skills to do that.
Perhaps what manufacturing needs here is a marketing
makeover. To ensure we have enough younger workers in
the pipeline, we might need to change perceptions about
careers in manufacturing. Today’s manufacturing environment is a far cry from the caricature industrial revolutiontype factory job. It is a highly automated environment
that requires specific technical skills above and beyond a
strong back.
If anything can help change the perception about a career
in manufacturing, it is the pay and benefits manufacturing
workers receive. On average, compensation packages are
17 percent higher in the manufacturing industry compared
with nonmanufacturing jobs. Manufacturing wages and
salaries average $29.75 per hour compared with $27.47 for
nonmanufacturing jobs, while benefits average $8.52 for
a manufacturing job versus $5.37 for a nonmanufacturing
job. And three out of four manufacturing workers have both
retirement and medical care benefits, compared with only
55 percent of their private service-providing counterparts,
according to the BLS. In total, the average compensation
package for a manufacturing job is $38.27 per hour while
a nonmanufacturing job averages $32.84 per hour.
The compensation premium partly reflects the skills
and training of the underlying workforce. So if young
people can be persuaded that manufacturing has a future,
the next step is to adequately train future workforces.
We have our work cut out for us on that front. The United
States ranks 29th in math and 21st in science out of
65 countries, according to an Organization for Economic
Co-operation and Development (OECD) survey.
Another way to address a possible worker shortage is to
retrain the existing workforce. In 2010, 36 percent of
unemployed production workers were between the ages
of 16 and 34 (IPUMS). One policy approach to “upskill”
this group would be to support the network of community
colleges across the country, especially those that work
with local employers to design curricula around the needs
of the workplace. Collaborative efforts like these are a
good way to ensure the skills of the workforce better align
with the needs of the workplace.

Employee Compensation
per Hour by Major Industry, 2010
Dollars
50
40
Benefits

30
20

Wages | Salariesa

10
0

Manufacturing

Non-manufacturing

a. Wages | Salaries include paid leave and supplemental pay.
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

“Manufacturers are telling us that they’re having trouble
finding the workers they need to be able to succeed,”
said Chad Moutray, chief economist with the National
Association of Manufacturers. “We need to continue to
invest in education and change perceptions about the
value of manufacturing to make sure that manufacturers
have the workers who can work in those facilities.”

4

An increasing proportion of R&D dollars are being spent
by private companies… which are more flexible and better
able to respond to market needs than publicly funded
research dollars.

What strengths should the U.S. build on?

The United States still remains the world’s top manu­
facturer, reports the OECD, accounting for 19 percent
of the globe’s manufacturing total value added. Moreover,
real manufacturing exports increased 43 percent from
2002 to 2011 compared to a 15 percent increase for real
GDP over the same time period, according to the Census
Bureau and BEA. Most of this increase is accounted for
by America’s comparative advantage in highly technical
industries like aerospace, medical and pharmaceutical
development, and computer and electronic components
production.
To remain the leader, the United States must take advantage
of its strengths. Patent laws make the United States a
premier destination for research and development dollars
and, in fact, the nation leads the world in patents per year
(OECD). More important, an increasing proportion
of R&D dollars are being spent by private companies,
according to the National Science Foundation, which are
much more flexible and better able to respond to market
needs than publicly funded research dollars. Policies
designed to motivate research allow manufacturers to
create innovative products as well as pursue technologies
that will lower costs.

“The one big advantage we have in the United States
that other countries don’t have is a very innovative
economy,” said Daniel Meckstroth, chief economist with
the Manufacturers Alliance for Productivity and Innovation.
“We have a very good infrastructure, we have the best
universities in the world, and we are able to have high
income because we are very productive and have high
value-added per worker. You get that through becoming
innovative, being technologically advanced, and applying
capital to workers to increase productivity.”
Another strength is energy. The United States has a
relatively dependable energy infrastructure network,
subject to few service interruptions and thus providing for
better management of production runs. The United States
also has access to energy-related natural resources. Low
natural gas prices allow not only for lower electricity costs,
but also for cheaper feedstocks that go into industrial
chemicals. Moreover, new innovations in exploration and
production techniques associated with shale gas reserves
are projected to provide a dramatic increase in both
petroleum and gas reserves. Thus, energy costs should
remain low for the next decade. Policies designed to
promote a reliable energy infrastructure and the development of new energy sources will provide added incentive
for manufacturers to locate in the United States.

Down but not out
Despite major changes, manufacturing does still matter
in the United States, even if it no longer provides the
employment base or comprises the share of GDP it once
did. As long as policies can be implemented to address
potential problems while capitalizing on our comparative
advantages, the U.S. manufacturing industry can remain a
global leader. ■
Watch short interviews with conference participants
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_13.cfm

Resources
For the complete set of conference presentations, visit
www.nabe-web.com/industry2012/program.html

F refront

19

Housing and the
Economic Recovery
Todd Clark
Vice President and Economist

Problems in the housing sector have proven to be one of the most

Amir Sufi
Professor of Finance at the Booth School
of Business, University of Chicago

stubborn obstacles to a full economic recovery. Is the housing market
finally turning a corner, and what policies might help it do so more
effectively? The Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland invited two housing
experts, Amir Sufi and Chris Mayer, to talk with Bank economists
and officials about their research. During a break in the presentations,
Todd Clark, vice president in charge of the money, financial markets, and
monetary policy group, sat down for this interview with these academics.

20		

Summer 2012

Chris Mayer
Paul Milstein Professor of Real Estate
and Finance and Economics at Columbia
Business School, Columbia University

Clark: Can you talk a bit about where
we stand with the housing sector today?
Are we any better off now than we were
a year ago? Amir, let’s start with you.
Amir Sufi: I think we are better off now

than we were a year ago. We’ve seen
some recovery in house prices—
mainly a leveling off. We’ve also for
the first time actually seen, in the last
few quarters, a positive contribution
from residential investment to GDP,
which is a good sign that we’re seeing
some building.
But unfortunately, we still have, in
my view, a long way to go before we’re
at what would be considered healthy
or normal levels of building and house
prices to be at levels that are sustainable with long-term growth in the
housing sector. So I think the news is
very cautiously optimistic; we’re not
in freefall anymore, but we still have
a long way to go.
Chris Mayer: I agree with Amir’s assess-

ment. I think we have hit a bottom;
much of it’s because we have a lot of
cash buyers—investors—coming into
the market who are willing to rent
out houses, so roughly 30 percent of
houses are going to people who are
not going to live in them. But that
still has helped put a bottom on house
price decline.
But there’s a very uneven recovery.
The place that we haven’t seen much
improvement has really been on the
credit side, which is the ability of new
homebuyers to borrow. It would seem
credit is, if anything, tighter today than
it was a year ago.

Clark: To what extent do you think
the problems in the housing sector have
been holding back the pace of recovery,
and to what extent do we need to
address those problems to get a faster
pace of recovery in the overall economy?
Sufi: I have a strong view on that. I

think that housing ends up being very
important for the recovery precisely
because households have a lot of
debt associated with those houses.
Mortgage debt and home equity
debt were at historic highs when the
housing market collapsed and that
continues to be something that’s, in
my view, holding back the recovery.
When households have extremely
high debt burdens, they have a more
difficult time accessing credit. They
also may feel poorer just in terms of
where they need to be in their net
wealth position. And so a very natural
reaction, something we found very
strongly in our research, is that people
pull back on their spending behavior
when they find themselves over­
burdened with debt associated with
their home.
So either you have to have a robust
recovery in house prices, or you would
have to have some kinds of proposals to
allow borrowers to access credit more
easily. Or, perhaps more dramatically,

you do something to help try to write
down the debt burdens that households have. And if you were able to
do one of those three things, I think
you would see a much more powerful recovery. But in the absence of
one of those three things—either a
house price recovery, helping people
refinance into lower rates, or writing
down debt burdens—my view is
that the recovery is going to be quite
weak. We’ll see economic growth, but
not the kind of economic growth we
would want to generate significant job
growth.

People pull back on their spending behavior
when they find themselves over-burdened
with debt associated with their home”
Mayer: I’m probably only slightly more

optimistic. Just to put some other
numbers to it, in a typical recovery
we’d be building 2 to 2¼ million
houses. We’ve been building at about
500,000; that’s probably 2 to 3 percent
of GDP. Two to 3 percent of GDP is
the difference between anemic growth
(which doesn’t create many jobs) and
a much more robust recovery.
The optimistic piece of this is that we
continue to add 800,000-plus households a year. We have 3 million people
who haven’t formed households and
at some point are going to start forming
households. So I think we are going
to see demand grow a little bit—just
demographics, not for any other
reason—and that is going to lead to
some additional construction over
time, even with all of the headwinds.

F refront

21

Clark: Are there reasonably feasible
policies that you think would help
stimulate the pace of recovery in the
housing sector over the next couple
years?
Mayer: I’ve been a very strong advocate

of pursuing a widespread refinancing
program starting with loans that
are guaranteed by the government
through Fannie, Freddie, and the FHA
[Federal Housing Administration].
Our best estimate is that we could
easily accomplish 10 million to
15 million refinancings. We should
have done this a long time ago, and
that would have significantly helped
with the debt burdens. I think that’s
the biggest thing.
But the second is, we really have to
work through some of the problems
that we see in the system—people
who are living in houses who haven’t
been making payments for two or
three years, lenders who are still
unsure of what the rules are and often
misapplying the rules. We need to get
these things fixed finally. I think the
state attorneys general settlement will
help with this, but we really need a
system that borrowers and lenders can
rely on, so that everyone understands
what the rules are going forward. And
unfortunately, I haven’t seen the kind
of progress on that that I’d like to see.

Sufi: If you just take a step back and

look at the policy responses that the
government’s made: It’s been woefully
inadequate on the housing side. We’ve
seen very aggressive policies in terms of
fiscal stimulus and in terms of financial
assistance to financial institutions. But
in general we have not seen the kind
of widespread, successful, “affect-alarge-number-of-borrowers” types of
activities.
I also tend to think—something that
may be a little more controversial—
that we should at least have on the
table some kind of program that would
assist homeowners in modifying or
restructuring their debt. So not only
making interest payments lower, but
also trying to attack the household
debt problem directly through some
type of help in restructuring mortgages.
We’ve had some of those programs,
but they’ve proven very difficult to
implement.

Clark: Last question: the long run. We
used to think of housing’s importance
in the economy as being something
like 5 or 6 percent of GDP in terms of
residential investment, with that being
the long-run norm. Do you think we can
ever hope to get—expect to get—back
to that?
Mayer: There’s every reason to believe

that even markets that have been really
severely hammered by this crisis—for
example, California—will eventually
get back on the growth path. It may
take five or 10 years to get there.
But more important in the long run
will be productivity in the economy
and labor market. If we rely on housing
for growth or a recession, we’re in a lot
of trouble.
Sufi: I think in the long run things like
household formation, productivity
growth, and population growth will
be the determinants of the housing
market. I would add maybe one
caveat: the homeownership rate
in the United States was at about
63 percent for 30, 35 years, and then
it jumped up closer to 70 percent in
a period of about 10 years, from 1998
to about 2006.

As an economist, when I look at a
statistic that’s stayed level for 35 or
so years and then all of a sudden
jumps up very quickly, that tends to
tell me that probably the long-run
equilibrium is closer to what we had
before—the 63 percent, 64 percent
homeownership rate. ■
Watch this interview online
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_01.cfm

Recommended reading
Learn more about this interview on housing at
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_02.cfm

22		

Summer 2012

A Plausible Culprit
Maybe you’ve heard the view that the financial
crisis is to blame for the frustratingly slow pace of
the recovery. Economists Carmen Reinhart and
Kenneth Rogoff have made the highest-profile
case for this story. After examining eight centuries
of economic cycles, they argue that recessions
associated with major financial crises are likewise
expected to be major. By extension, the associated
recoveries are likely to be less than spectacular too,
the authors claim. It seems the economy has a tough
time achieving liftoff if the financial markets—
which provide crucial services for borrowers and
lenders—have suffered a meltdown.
That’s perhaps true of the global historical record, as
Reinhart and Rogoff recount. But do financial crises
adequately explain the U.S. experience? Economists
Michael Bordo of Rutgers University and Joseph
Haubrich of the Cleveland Fed recently set out to
address that question. What they find, in sum, is
that there may be a more plausible culprit for the
sluggish recovery than the financial crisis—the
housing market.
Haubrich and Bordo looked at 27 U.S. business
cycles since 1882.* Unlike Reinhart-Rogoff, Haubrich
and Bordo conclude that financial crises often breed
quite strong recoveries in the United States. In fact,
they find that a 1 percent deeper financial-crisis
recession leads to an extra 1.5 percent of growth in
the quarters following the cycle’s trough.

More important than the role of financial markets
appears to be the role of the housing sector, say
Haubrich and Bordo. They note that residential
investment by itself may not make up a large part
of national spending, but it is linked to many other
consumer durable purchases and housing-sensitive
sectors, making its impact much larger than it
might first seem.
The authors aren’t certain whether housing is
directly to blame for the weak recovery, or merely
associated with it. Nonetheless, they determine,
“the role of housing does stand out as a marker for
weakness in the current recovery.”
This doesn’t necessarily mean that housing must
recover for the broader economy to follow suit.
Haubrich and Bordo say that’s a question for another
day. But their analysis does suggest that people
might not want to take for granted the claim that
our current woes are mainly the fault of the financial
crisis. The distinction is important as policymakers
prioritize their efforts to prevent or cushion the
blow of the next, inevitable recession. ■
—Doug Campbell, Editor

Resources
Find Michael Bordo and Joseph Haubrich’s paper, “Deep Recessions,
Fast Recoveries, and Financial Crises: Evidence from the American
Record,” at www.clevelandfed.org/research/workpaper/2012/wp1214.pdf

*		The authors used some of the same modeling techniques as in their 2010

paper that found that contractions associated with financial crises tended
to be more severe, but the paper did not examine the implications for
recoveries.

F refront

23

H t Topic

How Big Is the
Too-Big-to-Fail Subsidy?
Forefront: Critics of too-big-to-fail
financial institutions often argue that
the government is essentially giving
those institutions a subsidy. If true, can
this implicit subsidy be considered an
expenditure of taxpayer dollars, money
that could be used for something else?
Thomson: If the government is giving

Forefront talks to
the Cleveland Fed’s
James Thomson,
vice president and
financial economist.

someone something of value, this
is the same thing as an expenditure.
In the case of too-big-to-fail (TBTF),
the government is providing an option
to the stakeholders of TBTF firms to
assist them in times of trouble, and
doing so free of charge. Private entities
(such as insurance companies and
hedge funds) would charge a fair value
for such options. By not doing so, the
government is forgoing revenues that
could be used for other purposes. So yes,
the implicit subsidy (or any subsidy)
is equivalent to a tax expenditure—
like investment tax credits, fair housing
credits, and so on.

Forefront: Of course, size is only
one consideration with systemically
important institutions. You’ve written
in the past about other features—
contagion, correlation, complexity,
and concentration. Is shrinking these
institutions the overarching goal of
a policy that would make them cover
their implicit subsidy?
Thomson: Yes, the point of my 2009

policy discussion paper on these
features is that size alone does not
determine whether a financial company
is systemic (or TBTF)—it’s much
more complex than that. Charging
financial companies a fee that equates

24

Summer 2012

to the fair value of the TBTF subsidy
should result in smaller and less risky
firms. Moreover, charging TBTF
firms the cost of the subsidy would
internalize the costs of externalities
(the spillover effects) associated with
their decisions. This should produce
less risky financial companies and
reduce their systemic impact.
Forefront: If you’re a depositor at one
of these TBTF banks, you are protected
from losses. So why does that matter if
we’re talking about insured institutions?
Or, in economic terms, through which
channels is the TBTF subsidy showing up?
Thomson: There is an extensive

literature on federal deposit guarantees
and the subsidy associated with them.
When we discuss the problem of
TBTF, the problem becomes one
of subsidies associated with implicit
and explicit deposit guarantees. The
subsidy associated with explicit
deposit guarantees is not specific to
the size of an institution—it’s simply
the difference between their value and
the deposit insurance premium. The
implicit deposit insurance subsidy is
essentially the TBTF subsidy. This
occurs when financial system super­
visors don’t close a bank that is insolvent and impose losses on uninsured
depositors and other creditors. It can
also happen when supervisors handle
the bank failure in a way that extends
protection to all liabilities. TBTF
institutions boost the value of these
subsidies by increasing the risk they
incur in the course of seeking returns
on their investments.

Forefront: OK, so how big is the subsidy?
Can you put a number to it?

Forefront: Economists don’t agree,
but is there a ballpark figure?

Thomson: We don’t have a number

Thomson: Using some numbers on

that economists would agree on. But
some academics are actively working
on measuring the subsidy. Three
economists at New York University
[Professors Viral Acharya, Robert
Engle, and Matthew Richardson] are
working on measuring the subsidy
by trying to calculate the costs that
systemically important companies
impose on the financial system. This is
one of the more promising approaches,
and one way to get at the subsidy.
Ed Kane [Boston College] and some
of his coauthors are trying to measure
the TBTF subsidy using an optionpricing approach. They are trying to
measure the subsidy by valuing the
taxpayer “put”—the value associated
with being able to put the losses onto
taxpayers. In a sense, the same kind of
work is underway at various regulatory
agencies, at central banks, and at the
Bank for International Settlements
in the design and calibration of the
Basel III international capital standards.
There is a capital surcharge for systemic
risk—an indirect way of pricing it.
Calibrating the capital surcharge
implicitly requires measuring the
TBTF subsidy.
Also, conceptually, the stock market
value of a systemic financial company
should price the stream of TBTF
subsidies—something Ed Kane would
call “government-contributed capital.”
So we would need a model that
could separate out the governmentcontributed capital from the franchise
value of the firm.

the annual systemic risk premium,
you can get a number in excess of
$45 billion. If you assume that the value
of the TBTF subsidy is the capitalized
value of the annual systemic risk premium, then you get numbers between
$450 billion and $900 billion. But
these are just back-of-the-envelope
estimates.

Forefront: And I take it that getting
a more precise number is important
because that’s the amount regulators
can then properly price as the capital
surcharge. This might provide the
government’s budget some protection.
On the other hand, have you or others
thought about what might happen to
these institutions if we were able to
start charging them accurately to offset
their subsidy?
Thomson: If institutions were to be

charged a premium for the full value
of their estimated implicit TBTF
guarantee, then I suspect they would
respond by shrinking and becoming
less complex to some extent (at least
the very largest and most complex).
How much is the question.

Forefront: If institutions do respond
in these ways, would you say that the
main reason these institutions grew
to such large size and complexity in the
first place was to capture the benefits
of the subsidy?
Thomson: Well, it would be consistent

with that reason, but you could also
say that the existence of the implicit
subsidy enabled these companies to
become larger and more complex
than otherwise would have been
the case.

Forefront: Is it fair to say that even if
we can put a number on the implicit
subsidy, the ultimate costs imposed on
the rest of us are a lot larger?
Thomson: In a recent paper, a couple of
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
economists claim to have measured
the TBTF subsidy. They find it is on
the order of 20 basis points in terms
of lower funding costs. But yes, there
are externalities associated with the
TBTF subsidy that impose costs on
the rest of us. So TBTF institutions
respond to the subsidy by increasing
their risk though either engaging in
riskier activities or increasing their
leverage. While these actions may be
privately optimal, the response to the
TBTF subsidy is not socially optimal,
as it can pose huge risks to the financial
system. That’s why the ultimate social
costs of the subsidy are much larger
than the 20-basis-point private benefit
that some have found. ■

Recommended reading
For more on TBTF and the subsidy from the economists mentioned
in this article, visit
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/ff_2012_summer_03.cfm

and click on the embedded links

F refront

25

Interview with
Alex Kotlowitz
The Cleveland Fed’s 2012 Policy Summit
closed with a different kind of speaker than
most who came before him. Though not a
researcher, policymaker, or community
development practitioner, Alex Kotlowitz
shares a passion for understanding why some
neighborhoods thrive and others founder. He has spent years living
and working in inner-city neighborhoods, observing up close the
unique and steep challenges facing the people who live there.

Between these and other projects, Kotlowitz’s “day job” is writerin-residence at Northwestern University. He teaches courses every
winter and also serves as a visiting professor at the University
of Notre Dame. Forefront editor Doug Campbell interviewed
Kotlowitz following his formal remarks on June 29, 2012. An edited
and condensed transcript follows.

Forefront: You talked about the state
of our inner cities and how a man from
Englewood on the southwest side of
Chicago recently remarked how things
have gotten so bad. Do you really think
things have gotten worse in our inner
cities in the past 25 years?

Kotlowitz: What economists do and

Kotlowitz: There are a lot of things that

One of the questions that came up in
my dinner with a group of economists
last night was, why does it seem that
people living in very impoverished
communities don’t make the rational
choice? The challenge is to understand
why, for them, it might seem rational
in the moment. Not that it justifies it,
but to understand it, to try to understand who they are. I guess I hoped to
give what they do some humanity.

Summer 2012

Kotlowitz is a writer whose 1991 book There Are No Children Here
followed two years of the struggles of two young brothers living
in a Chicago housing project. The book won several awards, sold
half-a-million copies, and landed on the New York Public Library’s
list of the 150 most important books of the century. More recently,
Kotlowitz co-produced the 2011 documentary film The Interrupters,
which relates the story of three violence “interrupters” working for
an innovative anti-violence organization in Chicago.

Forefront: Today you were in a room
full of economists and other people
very comfortable with numbers, and
you were telling stories that were very
powerful, sometimes heartbreaking.
What value do you think that brings to
academics?

what policymakers do is incredibly
important. They step back and try to
look at the broad picture and try to
figure out what policy makes sense,
what policy works, what policy doesn’t
work. What I hoped to do today was
simply remind them that we’re talking
about real people, and that people are
complicated. They’re messy. I know
that economists think about people
making rational choices.

26

His first-person reporting made him a fitting voice to wrap up the
two-day Policy Summit.

have changed over the past 25 years,
and some for the good. I think the
church, especially the black church,
has become much more engaged in
these communities. There’s been the
growth of community development
corporations. The CDCs have grown,
and in some cases performed minor
miracles, but funding is incredibly
short.

There was an effort in places like
Chicago and other cities to tear down
public housing, to raze these monolithic,
monstrous structures that probably
never should have been built in the
first place. So there are things to make
us think that we are doing better. And
there are probably some good things
to say about welfare reform.
But it’s troubling to me that when you
go into these communities, especially
in the wake of the 2008 economic
collapse, you see communities that

physically look in some ways worse
than they did 15 or 20 years ago. In the
course of filming [The Interrupters]—
we filmed from the summer of 2009
to the summer of 2010—we literally
saw blocks change during the course
of that year because of the foreclosures.
Then you’ve got the stubborn persistence of the violence. You’ve got the
schools, which we are still struggling
with. We’ve been very good in our
cities in creating these terrific magnet
schools, but schools in these commun­
ities are still not functioning. The
dropout rate is still extraordinarily
high. So in some ways things have
not gotten better, and in other ways
they’ve gotten worse.
Forefront: If you’re consuming just
the top level of news, you may have
heard that crime has gone down, and
technology has spread to many places.
How is it possible that we’re still
struggling with the same problems?
Kotlowitz: I don’t think that we as a

nation, our body-politic, really wants
to contend with these issues. These
communities are where they’re at
in many ways because they’ve been
neglected, and they’re still neglected.

Alex Kotlowitz
Positions

Selected Articles and Projects

Freelance writer and producer
Writer-in-residence, Northwestern University

The Interrupters, 2011, documentary about anti-gang-violence
program in Chicago

Books

“Blocking the Transmission of Violence,” The New York Times
Magazine, May 4, 2008

There Are No Children Here: The Story of Two Boys Growing Up in
the Other America, 1991, Anchor
The Other Side of the River: A Story of Two Towns, a Death and
America’s Dilemma, 1999, Anchor
Never a City So Real, 2004, Crown

I don’t think that’s changed. But you
point to something that for me is the
Great American Paradox—we’re in
a country that likes to think we’re all
in this together, and yet we’re still so
incredibly disconnected from each
other.
My first book, There Are No Children
Here, came out in 1991, and I remember when it came out people said,
“Oh my God, this can’t be.” And I felt
the same way when I began reporting
the book. People felt angry, they felt
ashamed. With The Interrupters, here
we are 20 years later, this film comes
out, and from people I still hear the
same thing—“I had no idea. I can’t
believe these communities are like
this.” And you just want to ask, where
has everybody been?
Forefront: You made a useful distinction
between the “poverty of the pocketbook,” which I think we all understand,
and the “poverty of the spirit.” What do
you mean by that and why do you think
we’re suffering from it?
Kotlowitz: This is not something new.

Poverty of the spirit has to do with
lack of aspiration, lack of hope, the
sense that “this is my life.” And that’s
one of the things that is clear to me
has not changed. That window of
opportunity has not gotten any larger.
In some cases it has gotten smaller,
especially, again, in the wake of the
economic collapse in 2008. What you
see are people who are dispirited, who
maybe haven’t given up but who maybe

“The Unprotected,” The New Yorker, Feb. 8, 1999
Awards and Honors

George Foster Peabody Award, the Robert F. Kennedy Journalism
Award, and the George Polk Award; recipient of three honorary
degrees and the John LaFarge Memorial Award for Interracial
Justice given by New York’s Catholic Interracial Council

have become resigned to the idea that
this is my life, this is going to be the life
of my children. Or who throw their
hands up because they don’t know
what the answers are, how we find
our way out of this.
Forefront: You discussed the need for
policy solutions to be holistic, and that’s
a theme of this Policy Summit. But an
interesting contrast is your look at the
group Ceasefire in The Interrupters. That
was a very targeted approach asking
“What’s the problem?” It’s too much
shooting. Then, “How do you stop it?”
You stop the shooting.
Kotlowitz: You’re absolutely right;

this group, Ceasefire, targets just the
violence. They want to get in there and
mediate the disputes. But it became
clear to us as we were filming that as
you look at all the other forces bearing
down on people, how can you not
wrangle with those? And there’s actually
a moment toward the end of the film
when one of the characters begins to
wonder aloud whether in fact what he’s
doing isn’t just a band-aid. Because
people come to him and they want jobs,
they want housing, they want all the
things that we know are so woefully
lacking in these communities.
I’ve had conversations with the people
at Ceasefire about this very thing. If
you’re a public health organization, one
of the things you’ve also got to do is
change conditions. You’re right, that’s
how Ceasefire does things; they’re
very narrowly focused, and I would
argue maybe too narrowly focused.

Forefront: Or maybe they’re a prong in
a multipronged approach.
Kotlowitz: That would be the other way
to think about it, that what they do is
very narrow and very important, which
it is. But they need to acknowledge and
understand that it’s also incredibly
critical that we find a way to provide
meaningful work in these communities,
that we need to provide better schools,
that we need to provide affordable
housing—all the things we know that
make up strong communities.
Forefront: In your work and in your
journalism, what’s the next thing
for you?
Kotlowitz: For me, in the end, I’m a

storyteller, so I’m just always looking
for good stories. And sometimes I find
my way back into these communities
that I’ve been writing about for the past
25 years. There are also other issues
that I feel are really pressing, not the
least of which is immigration. But I
intend to keep writing, and I intend
to keep writing about people who are
kind of outsiders. ■

Watch video clips from this session and
Kotlowitz’s keynote address at
www.clevelandfed.org/Forefront/2012/summer/
ff_2012_summer_10.cfm

Related link
See The Interrupters in full at
www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/interrupters

F refront

27

Book Review

The Power of Habit:
Why We Do What We Do
in Life and Business
by Charles Duhigg
Random House, 2012

Reviewed by
Robin Ratliff
Executive Editor

In just its first month of operation, the new Horseshoe
Casino in downtown Cleveland welcomed about half a
million people through its doors to hit the slot machines,
sit at the World Series of Poker table, and take their
chances at the various gaming tables. Guests have come
from near and far, including foreign countries.
Why do games of chance draw such widespread enthusiasm
and generate multiple return visits? In these times, it’s
probably not the vast sums of discretionary money lining
people’s pockets. In some significant measure, it must be
the rush that comes from a craving to win.
New York Times journalist Charles Duhigg, in his
smashingly popular new book, The Power of Habit:
Why We Do What We Do in Life and Business, gives us
the science behind the behavior. Not only does he explain
the neurology behind individual free will, he also outlines
the powerful behavior patterns that influence social
movements, marketing campaigns, and business results.

28

Summer 2012

Duhigg frames the psychology behind the individual
habit loop in a simple three-part process. It starts with a
cue (location, time of day, routines, emotional triggers)
that quickly cycles into a routine (the behavior itself,
whether physical, mental, or emotional) and ends with
the ultimate reward (the bedrock satisfaction that drives
the habit loop). He contends that if you discover the
structure behind the cue, routine, and reward cycle, you
can change the habit.
Most of us want to understand why we engage in what
seem like mindless actions, especially those that are harmful
to our health, relationships, and daily living. Not surprisingly,
it turns out that those seemingly mindless behaviors are
controlled by a primitive structure deep within the brain
known as the basal ganglia. This sector stores knowledge of
activities that have become habitual—such as putting on
our shoes or backing out of a driveway. Complex thinking,
on the other hand, occurs in the outside layers of the brain
in the prefrontal cortex. The ability to do several tasks at
once owes to the basal ganglia’s taking charge and making
our routine tasks effortless. That’s a good thing for the
most part.

But the brain’s dependence on automatic routines can
also be dangerous, because habits can be as much a curse
as a blessing. Duhigg tells a harrowing tale of a compulsive
gambler who continues to be lured back to the casinos
and ultimately loses her home and blows her inheritance
because she feels powerless to overcome the urge to win.
A cognitive neuroscientist has determined that pathological gamblers actually see near-misses on a slot machine
as wins—triggering behavior that keeps them gambling
when they should logically walk away. Duhigg reports that
gaming companies, understanding this psychology, have
been reprogramming their slot machines over the past few
decades to supply a more constant stream of near-misses
to keep people coming back.
Then there are the implications of habits for retail marketing plans. Target uses data from customer loyalty cards
and redeemed coupons to create complex individualized
demographic profiles. These profiles show when parents
are gearing up for summer camp season or when expectant
mothers are likely to deliver—all based on their purchasing
histories. The store can then use that information to push
out more promotions to keep people coming back to
shop for more.
Duhigg offers an array of examples on how habits lead
to outcomes, for both good and ill. For me, the most
compelling of his stories focus on transformational
change within organizations. For example, NFL coach
Tony Dungy used the power of habit to turn around the
foundering Tampa Bay Buccaneers starting in the late
1990s. Instead of using a thick playbook, he coached his
players to use only a handful of formations, concentrating
on where their opponents were lining up and moving on
the field. He shifted the team’s precise behavior patterns
until their performances became automatic and they
began to believe they could win. In just a few years, the
Bucs were division champs and within a decade, won the
Super Bowl.
Then there is the amazing power of “keystone habits”—
which identify a few key priorities in an organization and
fashion them into powerful levers for change. Former
Treasury Secretary Paul O’Neill accomplished this at
Alcoa when he was named CEO. By putting a laser focus
on the keystone habit of worker safety, with a goal of zero

injuries within the company, he set a standard for excellence
that every employee could salute and support. The strategy
worked—with Alcoa’s annual income increasing by a
factor of five during his tenure as leader.
Pathological gamblers actually see near-misses on a
slot machine as wins—triggering behavior that keeps
them gambling when they should logically walk away.
Without keystone habits, very bad things can happen. In the
late 1980s in a London subway station, 31 people perished
because no single person, department, or engineering chief
had ultimate responsibility for passenger safety. Operating
within their “boxes” of functional routines and failing to
escalate the emergency to the right authorities, employees
allowed a small fire to rage into a death trap.
Although Duhigg does not offer a specific example related
to the economics profession, he does provide some food
for thought. Traditional economists tend to describe
people as rational beings who are unlikely to make repeated
mistakes. Behavioral economists have made inroads by
trying to account for imperfect rationality, but it’s safe
to say that mainstream economics continues to rely on
“homo economicus”—the rational man—who, as Duhigg’s
work makes clear, is more an archetype than a reality.
The Power of Habit offers so many forceful stories and
underlying psychologies behind them that it’s hard to
stop thinking about the possibilities for old patterns to
be rethought and bad habits transformed.
What if all members of Congress committed to a keystone
habit of fixing the U.S. fiscal cliff before disaster hit? What if
a retail data mining strategy focused on giving consumers
the option to choose sustainable products to reduce
materials going to landfill rather than adding new plastic
gadgets to our homes? What if all of us took a good, hard
look at the mindless routines we follow in our own lives
and resolved to change a couple of them to make life better
for our families and co-workers? Not so crazy a habit to
get into, come to think about it. ■

Recommended reading
Find more book reviews at
www.clevelandfed.org/forefront

F refront

29

PRSRT STD
U.S. POSTAGE PAID
CLEVELAND, OH
PERMIT NO. 385

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of CLEVELAND

PO Box 6387
Cleveland, OH 44101

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing label
to the above address.

Next in Forefront:
Grant Makers

Forefront, a two-time winner in 2012

How cash-strapped foundations
are meeting community needs in
post-recession America

Harmonizing Foreclosure Rules

The Uniform Law Commission calls for
consumer voices

Award of Excellence Winner
International Association of Business Communicators,
Heritage Region Silver Quill Competition

American Inhouse Design Award Winner
Graphic Design USA
Follow the Cleveland Fed on

To subscribe, request copies, or sign up for web feeds of Forefront, visit www.clevelandfed.org/SubscribeToForefront.