View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Introduction ........................................................................................................................2
Summary of Recommendations .....................................................................................10
I. Promote Robust Supervision and Regulation of Financial Firms ...........................19
II. Establish Comprehensive Regulation of Financial Markets...................................43
III. Protect Consumers and Investors from Financial Abuse ......................................55
IV. Provide the Government with the Tools it Needs to Manage Financial Crises ...76
V. Raise International Regulatory Standards and Improve International
Cooperation .....................................................................................................................80

1

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
INTRODUCTION
Over the past two years we have faced the most severe financial crisis since the Great
Depression. Americans across the nation are struggling with unemployment, failing
businesses, falling home prices, and declining savings. These challenges have forced the
government to take extraordinary measures to revive our financial system so that people
can access loans to buy a car or home, pay for a child’s education, or finance a business.
The roots of this crisis go back decades. Years without a serious economic recession
bred complacency among financial intermediaries and investors. Financial challenges
such as the near-failure of Long-Term Capital Management and the Asian Financial
Crisis had minimal impact on economic growth in the U.S., which bred exaggerated
expectations about the resilience of our financial markets and firms. Rising asset prices,
particularly in housing, hid weak credit underwriting standards and masked the growing
leverage throughout the system.
At some of our most sophisticated financial firms, risk management systems did not keep
pace with the complexity of new financial products. The lack of transparency and
standards in markets for securitized loans helped to weaken underwriting standards.
Market discipline broke down as investors relied excessively on credit rating agencies.
Compensation practices throughout the financial services industry rewarded short-term
profits at the expense of long-term value.
Households saw significant increases in access to credit, but those gains were
overshadowed by pervasive failures in consumer protection, leaving many Americans
with obligations that they did not understand and could not afford.
While this crisis had many causes, it is clear now that the government could have done
more to prevent many of these problems from growing out of control and threatening the
stability of our financial system. Gaps and weaknesses in the supervision and regulation
of financial firms presented challenges to our government’s ability to monitor, prevent, or
address risks as they built up in the system. No regulator saw its job as protecting the
economy and financial system as a whole. Existing approaches to bank holding company
regulation focused on protecting the subsidiary bank, not on comprehensive regulation of
the whole firm. Investment banks were permitted to opt for a different regime under a
different regulator, and in doing so, escaped adequate constraints on leverage. Other
firms, such as AIG, owned insured depositories, but escaped the strictures of serious
holding company regulation because the depositories that they owned were technically
not “banks” under relevant law.
We must act now to restore confidence in the integrity of our financial system. The
lasting economic damage to ordinary families and businesses is a constant reminder of
the urgent need to act to reform our financial regulatory system and put our economy on
track to a sustainable recovery. We must build a new foundation for financial regulation
and supervision that is simpler and more effectively enforced, that protects consumers
and investors, that rewards innovation and that is able to adapt and evolve with changes
in the financial market.
In the following pages, we propose reforms to meet five key objectives:
2

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(1) Promote robust supervision and regulation of financial firms. Financial institutions
that are critical to market functioning should be subject to strong oversight. No financial
firm that poses a significant risk to the financial system should be unregulated or weakly
regulated. We need clear accountability in financial oversight and supervision. We
propose:
x

A new Financial Services Oversight Council of financial regulators to identify
emerging systemic risks and improve interagency cooperation.

x

New authority for the Federal Reserve to supervise all firms that could pose a
threat to financial stability, even those that do not own banks.

x

Stronger capital and other prudential standards for all financial firms, and even
higher standards for large, interconnected firms.

x

A new National Bank Supervisor to supervise all federally chartered banks.

x

Elimination of the federal thrift charter and other loopholes that allowed some
depository institutions to avoid bank holding company regulation by the Federal
Reserve.

x

The registration of advisers of hedge funds and other private pools of capital with
the SEC.

(2) Establish comprehensive supervision of financial markets. Our major financial
markets must be strong enough to withstand both system-wide stress and the failure of
one or more large institutions. We propose:
x

Enhanced regulation of securitization markets, including new requirements for
market transparency, stronger regulation of credit rating agencies, and a
requirement that issuers and originators retain a financial interest in securitized
loans.

x

Comprehensive regulation of all over-the-counter derivatives.

x

New authority for the Federal Reserve to oversee payment, clearing, and
settlement systems.

(3) Protect consumers and investors from financial abuse. To rebuild trust in our
markets, we need strong and consistent regulation and supervision of consumer financial
services and investment markets. We should base this oversight not on speculation or
abstract models, but on actual data about how people make financial decisions. We must
promote transparency, simplicity, fairness, accountability, and access. We propose:
x

A new Consumer Financial Protection Agency to protect consumers across the
financial sector from unfair, deceptive, and abusive practices.

x

Stronger regulations to improve the transparency, fairness, and appropriateness of
consumer and investor products and services.

x

A level playing field and higher standards for providers of consumer financial
products and services, whether or not they are part of a bank.
3

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(4) Provide the government with the tools it needs to manage financial crises. We need
to be sure that the government has the tools it needs to manage crises, if and when they
arise, so that we are not left with untenable choices between bailouts and financial
collapse. We propose:
x

A new regime to resolve nonbank financial institutions whose failure could have
serious systemic effects.

x

Revisions to the Federal Reserve’s emergency lending authority to improve
accountability.

(5) Raise international regulatory standards and improve international cooperation.
The challenges we face are not just American challenges, they are global challenges. So,
as we work to set high regulatory standards here in the United States, we must ask the
world to do the same. We propose:
x

International reforms to support our efforts at home, including strengthening the
capital framework; improving oversight of global financial markets; coordinating
supervision of internationally active firms; and enhancing crisis management
tools.

In addition to substantive reforms of the authorities and practices of regulation and
supervision, the proposals contained in this report entail a significant restructuring of our
regulatory system. We propose the creation of a Financial Services Oversight Council,
chaired by Treasury and including the heads of the principal federal financial regulators
as members. We also propose the creation of two new agencies. We propose the
creation of the Consumer Financial Protection Agency, which will be an independent
entity dedicated to consumer protection in credit, savings, and payments markets. We
also propose the creation of the National Bank Supervisor, which will be a single agency
with separate status in Treasury with responsibility for federally chartered depository
institutions. To promote national coordination in the insurance sector, we propose the
creation of an Office of National Insurance within Treasury.
Under our proposal, the Federal Reserve and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation
(FDIC) would maintain their respective roles in the supervision and regulation of statechartered banks, and the National Credit Union Administration (NCUA) would maintain
its authorities with regard to credit unions. The Securities and Exchange Commission
(SEC) and Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) would maintain their
current responsibilities and authorities as market regulators, though we propose to
harmonize the statutory and regulatory frameworks for futures and securities.
The proposals contained in this report do not represent the complete set of potentially
desirable reforms in financial regulation. More can and should be done in the future. We
focus here on what is essential: to address the causes of the current crisis, to create a more
stable financial system that is fair for consumers, and to help prevent and contain
potential crises in the future. (For a detailed list of recommendations, please see
Summary of Recommendations following the Introduction.)
These proposals are the product of broad-ranging individual consultations with members
of the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets, Members of Congress,
4

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
academics, consumer and investor advocates, community-based organizations, the
business community, and industry and market participants.
I. Promote Robust Supervision and Regulation of Financial Firms
In the years leading up to the current financial crisis, risks built up dangerously in our
financial system. Rising asset prices, particularly in housing, concealed a sharp
deterioration of underwriting standards for loans. The nation’s largest financial firms,
already highly leveraged, became increasingly dependent on unstable sources of shortterm funding. In many cases, weaknesses in firms’ risk-management systems left them
unaware of the aggregate risk exposures on and off their balance sheets. A credit boom
accompanied a housing bubble. Taking access to short-term credit for granted, firms did
not plan for the potential demands on their liquidity during a crisis. When asset prices
started to fall and market liquidity froze, firms were forced to pull back from lending,
limiting credit for households and businesses.
Our supervisory framework was not equipped to handle a crisis of this magnitude. To be
sure, most of the largest, most interconnected, and most highly leveraged financial firms
in the country were subject to some form of supervision and regulation by a federal
government agency. But those forms of supervision and regulation proved inadequate
and inconsistent.
First, capital and liquidity requirements were simply too low. Regulators did not require
firms to hold sufficient capital to cover trading assets, high-risk loans, and off-balance
sheet commitments, or to hold increased capital during good times to prepare for bad
times. Regulators did not require firms to plan for a scenario in which the availability of
liquidity was sharply curtailed.
Second, on a systemic basis, regulators did not take into account the harm that large,
interconnected, and highly leveraged institutions could inflict on the financial system and
on the economy if they failed.
Third, the responsibility for supervising the consolidated operations of large financial
firms was split among various federal agencies. Fragmentation of supervisory
responsibility and loopholes in the legal definition of a “bank” allowed owners of banks
and other insured depository institutions to shop for the regulator of their choice.
Fourth, investment banks operated with insufficient government oversight. Money
market mutual funds were vulnerable to runs. Hedge funds and other private pools of
capital operated completely outside of the supervisory framework.
To create a new foundation for the regulation of financial institutions, we will promote
more robust and consistent regulatory standards for all financial institutions. Similar
financial institutions should face the same supervisory and regulatory standards, with no
gaps, loopholes, or opportunities for arbitrage.
We propose the creation of a Financial Services Oversight Council, chaired by Treasury,
to help fill gaps in supervision, facilitate coordination of policy and resolution of
disputes, and identify emerging risks in firms and market activities. This Council would
5

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
include the heads of the principal federal financial regulators and would maintain a
permanent staff at Treasury.
We propose an evolution in the Federal Reserve’s current supervisory authority for BHCs
to create a single point of accountability for the consolidated supervision of all companies
that own a bank. All large, interconnected firms whose failure could threaten the stability
of the system should be subject to consolidated supervision by the Federal Reserve,
regardless of whether they own an insured depository institution. These firms should not
be able to escape oversight of their risky activities by manipulating their legal structure.
Under our proposals, the largest, most interconnected, and highly leveraged institutions
would face stricter prudential regulation than other regulated firms, including higher
capital requirements and more robust consolidated supervision. In effect, our proposals
would compel these firms to internalize the costs they could impose on society in the
event of failure.
II. Establish Comprehensive Regulation of Financial Markets
The current financial crisis occurred after a long and remarkable period of growth and
innovation in our financial markets. New financial instruments allowed credit risks to be
spread widely, enabling investors to diversify their portfolios in new ways and enabling
banks to shed exposures that had once stayed on their balance sheets. Through
securitization, mortgages and other loans could be aggregated with similar loans and sold
in tranches to a large and diverse pool of new investors with different risk preferences.
Through credit derivatives, banks could transfer much of their credit exposure to third
parties without selling the underlying loans. This distribution of risk was widely
perceived to reduce systemic risk, to promote efficiency, and to contribute to a better
allocation of resources.
However, instead of appropriately distributing risks, this process often concentrated risk
in opaque and complex ways. Innovations occurred too rapidly for many financial
institutions’ risk management systems; for the market infrastructure, which consists of
payment, clearing and settlement systems; and for the nation’s financial supervisors.
Securitization, by breaking down the traditional relationship between borrowers and
lenders, created conflicts of interest that market discipline failed to correct. Loan
originators failed to require sufficient documentation of income and ability to pay.
Securitizers failed to set high standards for the loans they were willing to buy,
encouraging underwriting standards to decline. Investors were overly reliant on credit
rating agencies. Credit ratings often failed to accurately describe the risk of rated
products. In each case, lack of transparency prevented market participants from
understanding the full nature of the risks they were taking.
The build-up of risk in the over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives markets, which were
thought to disperse risk to those most able to bear it, became a major source of contagion
through the financial sector during the crisis.
We propose to bring the markets for all OTC derivatives and asset-backed securities into
a coherent and coordinated regulatory framework that requires transparency and
improves market discipline. Our proposal would impose record keeping and reporting
6

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
requirements on all OTC derivatives. We also propose to strengthen the prudential
regulation of all dealers in the OTC derivative markets and to reduce systemic risk in
these markets by requiring all standardized OTC derivative transactions to be executed in
regulated and transparent venues and cleared through regulated central counterparties.
We propose to enhance the Federal Reserve’s authority over market infrastructure to
reduce the potential for contagion among financial firms and markets.
Finally, we propose to harmonize the statutory and regulatory regimes for futures and
securities. While differences exist between securities and futures markets, many
differences in regulation between the markets may no longer be justified. In particular,
the growth of derivatives markets and the introduction of new derivative instruments
have highlighted the need for addressing gaps and inconsistencies in the regulation of
these products by the CFTC and SEC. 
III. Protect Consumers and Investors from Financial Abuse
Prior to the current financial crisis, a number of federal and state regulations were in
place to protect consumers against fraud and to promote understanding of financial
products like credit cards and mortgages. But as abusive practices spread, particularly in
the market for subprime and nontraditional mortgages, our regulatory framework proved
inadequate in important ways. Multiple agencies have authority over consumer
protection in financial products, but for historical reasons, the supervisory framework for
enforcing those regulations had significant gaps and weaknesses. Banking regulators at
the state and federal level had a potentially conflicting mission to promote safe and sound
banking practices, while other agencies had a clear mission but limited tools and
jurisdiction. Most critically in the run-up to the financial crisis, mortgage companies and
other firms outside of the purview of bank regulation exploited that lack of clear
accountability by selling mortgages and other products that were overly complicated and
unsuited to borrowers’ financial situation. Banks and thrifts followed suit, with
disastrous results for consumers and the financial system.
This year, Congress, the Administration, and financial regulators have taken significant
measures to address some of the most obvious inadequacies in our consumer protection
framework. But these steps have focused on just two, albeit very important, product
markets – credit cards and mortgages. We need comprehensive reform.
For that reason, we propose the creation of a single regulatory agency, a Consumer
Financial Protection Agency (CFPA), with the authority and accountability to make sure
that consumer protection regulations are written fairly and enforced vigorously. The
CFPA should reduce gaps in federal supervision and enforcement; improve coordination
with the states; set higher standards for financial intermediaries; and promote consistent
regulation of similar products.
Consumer protection is a critical foundation for our financial system. It gives the public
confidence that financial markets are fair and enables policy makers and regulators to
maintain stability in regulation. Stable regulation, in turn, promotes growth, efficiency,
and innovation over the long term. We propose legislative, regulatory, and
7

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
administrative reforms to promote transparency, simplicity, fairness, accountability, and
access in the market for consumer financial products and services.
We also propose new authorities and resources for the Federal Trade Commission to
protect consumers in a wide range of areas.
Finally, we propose new authorities for the Securities and Exchange Commission to
protect investors, improve disclosure, raise standards, and increase enforcement.
IV. Provide the Government with the Tools it Needs to Manage Financial Crises
Over the past two years, the financial system has been threatened by the failure or near
failure of some of the largest and most interconnected financial firms. Our current
system already has strong procedures and expertise for handling the failure of banks, but
when a bank holding company or other nonbank financial firm is in severe distress, there
are currently only two options: obtain outside capital or file for bankruptcy. During most
economic climates, these are suitable options that will not impact greater financial
stability.
However, in stressed conditions it may prove difficult for distressed institutions to raise
sufficient private capital. Thus, if a large, interconnected bank holding company or other
nonbank financial firm nears failure during a financial crisis, there are only two untenable
options: obtain emergency funding from the US government as in the case of AIG, or
file for bankruptcy as in the case of Lehman Brothers. Neither of these options is
acceptable for managing the resolution of the firm efficiently and effectively in a manner
that limits the systemic risk with the least cost to the taxpayer.
We propose a new authority, modeled on the existing authority of the FDIC, that should
allow the government to address the potential failure of a bank holding company or other
nonbank financial firm when the stability of the financial system is at risk.
In order to improve accountability in the use of other crisis tools, we also propose that the
Federal Reserve Board receive prior written approval from the Secretary of the Treasury
for emergency lending under its “unusual and exigent circumstances” authority.
V. Raise International Regulatory Standards and Improve International
Cooperation
As we have witnessed during this crisis, financial stress can spread easily and quickly
across national boundaries. Yet, regulation is still set largely in a national context.
Without consistent supervision and regulation, financial institutions will tend to move
their activities to jurisdictions with looser standards, creating a race to the bottom and
intensifying systemic risk for the entire global financial system.
The United States is playing a strong leadership role in efforts to coordinate international
financial policy through the G-20, the Financial Stability Board, and the Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision. We will use our leadership position in the international
community to promote initiatives compatible with the domestic regulatory reforms
described in this report.

8

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
We will focus on reaching international consensus on four core issues: regulatory capital
standards; oversight of global financial markets; supervision of internationally active
financial firms; and crisis prevention and management.
At the April 2009 London Summit, the G-20 Leaders issued an eight-part declaration
outlining a comprehensive plan for financial regulatory reform.
The domestic regulatory reform initiatives outlined in this report are consistent with the
international commitments the United States has undertaken as part of the G-20 process,
and we propose stronger regulatory standards in a number of areas.

9

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
SUMMARY OF RECOMMENDATIONS
Please refer to the main text for further details
I.

PROMOTE ROBUST SUPERVISION AND REGULATION OF FINANCIAL FIRMS
A. Create a Financial Services Oversight Council
1. We propose the creation of a Financial Services Oversight Council to
facilitate information sharing and coordination, identify emerging risks,
advise the Federal Reserve on the identification of firms whose failure could
pose a threat to financial stability due to their combination of size, leverage,
and interconnectedness (hereafter referred to as a Tier 1 FHC), and provide a
forum for resolving jurisdictional disputes between regulators.
a. The membership of the Council should include (i) the Secretary of the
Treasury, who shall serve as the Chairman; (ii) the Chairman of the
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System; (iii) the Director
of the National Bank Supervisor; (iv) the Director of the Consumer
Financial Protection Agency; (v) the Chairman of the SEC; (vi) the
Chairman of the CFTC; (vii) the Chairman of the FDIC; and (viii) the
Director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA).
b. The Council should be supported by a permanent, full-time expert staff
at Treasury. The staff should be responsible for providing the Council
with the information and resources it needs to fulfill its
responsibilities.
2. Our legislation will propose to give the Council the authority to gather
information from any financial firm and the responsibility for referring
emerging risks to the attention of regulators with the authority to respond.
B. Implement Heightened Consolidated Supervision and Regulation of All Large,
Interconnected Financial Firms
1. Any financial firm whose combination of size, leverage, and
interconnectedness could pose a threat to financial stability if it failed (Tier 1
FHC) should be subject to robust consolidated supervision and regulation,
regardless of whether the firm owns an insured depository institution.
2. The Federal Reserve Board should have the authority and accountability for
consolidated supervision and regulation of Tier 1 FHCs.
3. Our legislation will propose criteria that the Federal Reserve must consider
in identifying Tier 1 FHCs.
4. The prudential standards for Tier 1 FHCs – including capital, liquidity and
risk management standards – should be stricter and more conservative than
those applicable to other financial firms to account for the greater risks that
their potential failure would impose on the financial system.
5. Consolidated supervision of a Tier 1 FHC should extend to the parent
company and to all of its subsidiaries – regulated and unregulated, U.S. and
10

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
foreign. Functionally regulated and depository institution subsidiaries of a
Tier 1 FHC should continue to be supervised and regulated primarily by their
functional or bank regulator, as the case may be. The constraints that the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLB Act) introduced on the Federal Reserve’s
ability to require reports from, examine, or impose higher prudential
requirements or more stringent activity restrictions on the functionally
regulated or depository institution subsidiaries of FHCs should be removed.
6. Consolidated supervision of a Tier 1 FHC should be macroprudential in
focus. That is, it should consider risk to the system as a whole.
7. The Federal Reserve, in consultation with Treasury and external experts,
should propose recommendations by October 1, 2009 to better align its
structure and governance with its authorities and responsibilities.
C. Strengthen Capital and Other Prudential Standards For All Banks and BHCs
1. Treasury will lead a working group, with participation by federal financial
regulatory agencies and outside experts that will conduct a fundamental
reassessment of existing regulatory capital requirements for banks and BHCs,
including new Tier 1 FHCs. The working group will issue a report with its
conclusions by December 31, 2009.
2. Treasury will lead a working group, with participation by federal financial
regulatory agencies and outside experts, that will conduct a fundamental
reassessment of the supervision of banks and BHCs. The working group will
issue a report with its conclusions by October 1, 2009.
3. Federal regulators should issue standards and guidelines to better align
executive compensation practices of financial firms with long-term
shareholder value and to prevent compensation practices from providing
incentives that could threaten the safety and soundness of supervised
institutions. In addition, we will support legislation requiring all public
companies to hold non-binding shareholder resolutions on the compensation
packages of senior executive officers, as well as new requirements to make
compensation committees more independent.
4. Capital and management requirements for FHC status should not be limited
to the subsidiary depository institution. All FHCs should be required to meet
the capital and management requirements on a consolidated basis as well.
5. The accounting standard setters (the FASB, the IASB, and the SEC) should
review accounting standards to determine how financial firms should be
required to employ more forward-looking loan loss provisioning practices
that incorporate a broader range of available credit information. Fair value
accounting rules also should be reviewed with the goal of identifying changes
that could provide users of financial reports with both fair value information
and greater transparency regarding the cash flows management expects to
receive by holding investments.
11

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
6. Firewalls between banks and their affiliates should be strengthened to protect
the federal safety net that supports banks and to better prevent spread of the
subsidy inherent in the federal safety net to bank affiliates.
D. Close Loopholes in Bank Regulation
1. We propose the creation of a new federal government agency, the National
Bank Supervisor (NBS), to conduct prudential supervision and regulation of
all federally chartered depository institutions, and all federal branches and
agencies of foreign banks.
2. We propose to eliminate the federal thrift charter, but to preserve its interstate
branching rules and apply them to state and national banks.
3. All companies that control an insured depository institution, however
organized, should be subject to robust consolidated supervision and
regulation at the federal level by the Federal Reserve and should be subject to
the nonbanking activity restrictions of the BHC Act. The policy of separating
banking from commerce should be re-affirmed and strengthened. We must
close loopholes in the BHC Act for thrift holding companies, industrial loan
companies, credit card banks, trust companies, and grandfathered “nonbank”
banks.
E. Eliminate the SEC’s Programs for Consolidated Supervision
The SEC has ended its Consolidated Supervised Entity Program, under which it
had been the holding company supervisor for companies such as Lehman
Brothers and Bear Stearns. We propose also eliminating the SEC’s Supervised
Investment Bank Holding Company program. Investment banking firms that seek
consolidated supervision by a U.S. regulator should be subject to supervision and
regulation by the Federal Reserve.
F. Require Hedge Funds and Other Private Pools of Capital to Register
All advisers to hedge funds (and other private pools of capital, including private
equity funds and venture capital funds) whose assets under management exceed
some modest threshold should be required to register with the SEC under the
Investment Advisers Act. The advisers should be required to report information
on the funds they manage that is sufficient to assess whether any fund poses a
threat to financial stability.
G. Reduce the Susceptibility of Money Market Mutual Funds (MMFs) to Runs
The SEC should move forward with its plans to strengthen the regulatory
framework around MMFs to reduce the credit and liquidity risk profile of
individual MMFs and to make the MMF industry as a whole less susceptible to
runs. The President’s Working Group on Financial Markets should prepare a
report assessing whether more fundamental changes are necessary to further
reduce the MMF industry’s susceptibility to runs, such as eliminating the ability
of a MMF to use a stable net asset value or requiring MMFs to obtain access to
reliable emergency liquidity facilities from private sources. 
12

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
H. Enhance Oversight of the Insurance Sector
Our legislation will propose the establishment of the Office of National Insurance
within Treasury to gather information, develop expertise, negotiate international
agreements, and coordinate policy in the insurance sector. Treasury will support
proposals to modernize and improve our system of insurance regulation in
accordance with six principles outlined in the body of the report.
I. Determine the Future Role of the Government Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs)
Treasury and the Department of Housing and Urban Development, in
consultation with other government agencies, will engage in a wide-ranging
initiative to develop recommendations on the future of Fannie Mae and Freddie
Mac, and the Federal Home Loan Bank system. We need to maintain the
continued stability and strength of the GSEs during these difficult financial times.
We will report to the Congress and the American public at the time of the
President’s 2011 Budget release.
II.

ESTABLISH COMPREHENSIVE REGULATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
A. Strengthen Supervision and Regulation of Securitization Markets
1. Federal banking agencies should promulgate regulations that require
originators or sponsors to retain an economic interest in a material portion of
the credit risk of securitized credit exposures.
2. Regulators should promulgate additional regulations to align compensation of
market participants with longer term performance of the underlying loans.
3. The SEC should continue its efforts to increase the transparency and
standardization of securitization markets and be given clear authority to
require robust reporting by issuers of asset backed securities (ABS).
4. The SEC should continue its efforts to strengthen the regulation of credit
rating agencies, including measures to promote robust policies and
procedures that manage and disclose conflicts of interest, differentiate
between structured and other products, and otherwise strengthen the integrity
of the ratings process.
5. Regulators should reduce their use of credit ratings in regulations and
supervisory practices, wherever possible.
B. Create Comprehensive Regulation of All OTC Derivatives, Including Credit
Default Swaps (CDS)
All OTC derivatives markets, including CDS markets, should be subject to
comprehensive regulation that addresses relevant public policy objectives: (1)
preventing activities in those markets from posing risk to the financial system; (2)
promoting the efficiency and transparency of those markets; (3) preventing
market manipulation, fraud, and other market abuses; and (4) ensuring that OTC
derivatives are not marketed inappropriately to unsophisticated parties.
13

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
C. Harmonize Futures and Securities Regulation
The CFTC and the SEC should make recommendations to Congress for changes
to statutes and regulations that would harmonize regulation of futures and
securities.
D. Strengthen Oversight of Systemically Important Payment, Clearing, and
Settlement Systems and Related Activities
We propose that the Federal Reserve have the responsibility and authority to
conduct oversight of systemically important payment, clearing and settlement
systems, and activities of financial firms.
E. Strengthen Settlement Capabilities and Liquidity Resources of Systemically
Important Payment, Clearing, and Settlement Systems
We propose that the Federal Reserve have authority to provide systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement systems access to Reserve Bank
accounts, financial services, and the discount window.
III.

PROTECT CONSUMERS AND INVESTORS FROM FINANCIAL ABUSE
A. Create a New Consumer Financial Protection Agency
1. We propose to create a single primary federal consumer protection supervisor
to protect consumers of credit, savings, payment, and other consumer
financial products and services, and to regulate providers of such products
and services.
2. The CFPA should have broad jurisdiction to protect consumers in consumer
financial products and services such as credit, savings, and payment products.
3. The CFPA should be an independent agency with stable, robust funding.
4. The CFPA should have sole rule-making authority for consumer financial
protection statutes, as well as the ability to fill gaps through rule-making.
5. The CFPA should have supervisory and enforcement authority and
jurisdiction over all persons covered by the statutes that it implements,
including both insured depositories and the range of other firms not
previously subject to comprehensive federal supervision, and it should work
with the Department of Justice to enforce the statutes under its jurisdiction in
federal court.
6. The CFPA should pursue measures to promote effective regulation, including
conducting periodic reviews of regulations, an outside advisory council, and
coordination with the Council.
7. The CFPA’s strong rules would serve as a floor, not a ceiling. The states
should have the ability to adopt and enforce stricter laws for institutions of all
types, regardless of charter, and to enforce federal law concurrently with
respect to institutions of all types, also regardless of charter.
8. The CFPA should coordinate enforcement efforts with the states.
14

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
9. The CFPA should have a wide variety of tools to enable it to perform its
functions effectively.
10. The Federal Trade Commission should also be given better tools and
additional resources to protect consumers.
B. Reform Consumer Protection
1. Transparency. We propose a new proactive approach to disclosure. The
CFPA will be authorized to require that all disclosures and other
communications with consumers be reasonable: balanced in their
presentation of benefits, and clear and conspicuous in their identification of
costs, penalties, and risks.
2. Simplicity. We propose that the regulator be authorized to define standards
for “plain vanilla” products that are simpler and have straightforward
pricing. The CFPA should be authorized to require all providers and
intermediaries to offer these products prominently, alongside whatever other
lawful products they choose to offer.
3. Fairness. Where efforts to improve transparency and simplicity prove
inadequate to prevent unfair treatment and abuse, we propose that the CFPA
be authorized to place tailored restrictions on product terms and provider
practices, if the benefits outweigh the costs. Moreover, we propose to
authorize the Agency to impose appropriate duties of care on financial
intermediaries.
4. Access. The Agency should enforce fair lending laws and the Community
Reinvestment Act and otherwise seek to ensure that underserved consumers
and communities have access to prudent financial services, lending, and
investment.
C. Strengthen Investor Protection
1. The SEC should be given expanded authority to promote transparency in
investor disclosures.
2. The SEC should be given new tools to increase fairness for investors by
establishing a fiduciary duty for broker-dealers offering investment advice
and harmonizing the regulation of investment advisers and broker-dealers.
3. Financial firms and public companies should be accountable to their clients
and investors by expanding protections for whistleblowers, expanding
sanctions available for enforcement, and requiring non-binding shareholder
votes on executive pay plans.
4. Under the leadership of the Financial Services Oversight Council, we propose
the establishment of a Financial Consumer Coordinating Council with a
broad membership of federal and state consumer protection agencies, and a
permanent role for the SEC’s Investor Advisory Committee.
15

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
5. Promote retirement security for all Americans by strengthening employmentbased and private retirement plans and encouraging adequate savings.
IV.

PROVIDE THE GOVERNMENT WITH THE TOOLS IT NEEDS TO MANAGE
FINANCIAL CRISES
A. Create a Resolution Regime for Failing BHCs, Including Tier 1 FHCs
We recommend the creation of a resolution regime to avoid the disorderly
resolution of failing BHCs, including Tier 1 FHCs, if a disorderly resolution
would have serious adverse effects on the financial system or the economy. The
regime would supplement (rather than replace) and be modeled on to the existing
resolution regime for insured depository institutions under the Federal Deposit
Insurance Act.
B. Amend the Federal Reserve’s Emergency Lending Authority
We will propose legislation to amend Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act to
require the prior written approval of the Secretary of the Treasury for any
extensions of credit by the Federal Reserve to individuals, partnerships, or
corporations in “unusual and exigent circumstances.”

V.

RAISE INTERNATIONAL REGULATORY STANDARDS AND IMPROVE
INTERNATIONAL COOPERATION
A. Strengthen the International Capital Framework
We recommend that the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS)
continue to modify and improve Basel II by refining the risk weights applicable to
the trading book and securitized products, introducing a supplemental leverage
ratio, and improving the definition of capital by the end of 2009. We also urge
the BCBS to complete an in-depth review of the Basel II framework to mitigate its
procyclical effects.
B. Improve the Oversight of Global Financial Markets
We urge national authorities to promote the standardization and improved
oversight of credit derivative and other OTC derivative markets, in particular
through the use of central counterparties, along the lines of the G-20 commitment,
and to advance these goals through international coordination and cooperation.
C. Enhance Supervision of Internationally Active Financial Firms
We recommend that the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and national authorities
implement G-20 commitments to strengthen arrangements for international
cooperation on supervision of global financial firms through establishment and
continued operational development of supervisory colleges.
D. Reform Crisis Prevention and Management Authorities and Procedures
We recommend that the BCBS expedite its work to improve cross-border
resolution of global financial firms and develop recommendations by the end of
2009. We further urge national authorities to improve information-sharing
16

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
arrangements and implement the FSB principles for cross-border crisis
management.
E. Strengthen the Financial Stability Board
We recommend that the FSB complete its restructuring and institutionalize its
new mandate to promote global financial stability by September 2009.
F. Strengthen Prudential Regulations
We recommend that the BCBS take steps to improve liquidity risk management
standards for financial firms and that the FSB work with the Bank for
International Settlements (BIS) and standard setters to develop macroprudential
tools.
G. Expand the Scope of Regulation
1. Determine the appropriate Tier 1 FHC definition and application of
requirements for foreign financial firms.
2. We urge national authorities to implement by the end of 2009 the G-20
commitment to require hedge funds or their managers to register and disclose
appropriate information necessary to assess the systemic risk they pose
individually or collectively
H. Introduce Better Compensation Practices
In line with G-20 commitments, we urge each national authority to put guidelines
in place to align compensation with long-term shareholder value and to promote
compensation structures do not provide incentives for excessive risk taking. We
recommend that the BCBS expediently integrate the FSB principles on
compensation into its risk management guidance by the end of 2009.
I. Promote Stronger Standards in the Prudential Regulation, Money
Laundering/Terrorist Financing, and Tax Information Exchange Areas
1. We urge the FSB to expeditiously establish and coordinate peer reviews to
assess compliance and implementation of international regulatory standards,
with priority attention on the international cooperation elements of prudential
regulatory standards.
2. The United States will work to implement the updated International
Cooperation Review Group (ICRG) peer review process and work with
partners in the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) to address jurisdictions
not complying with international anti-money laundering/terrorist financing
(AML/CFT) standards.
J. Improve Accounting Standards
1. We recommend that the accounting standard setters clarify and make
consistent the application of fair value accounting standards, including the
impairment of financial instruments, by the end of 2009.
17

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
2. We recommend that the accounting standard setters improve accounting
standards for loan loss provisioning by the end of 2009 that would make it
more forward looking, as long as the transparency of financial statements is
not compromised.
3. We recommend that the accounting standard setters make substantial
progress by the end of 2009 toward development of a single set of high quality
global accounting standards.
K. Tighten Oversight of Credit Rating Agencies
We urge national authorities to enhance their regulatory regimes to effectively
oversee credit rating agencies (CRAs), consistent with international standards
and the G-20 Leaders’ recommendations.

18

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
I. PROMOTE ROBUST SUPERVISION AND REGULATION OF FINANCIAL FIRMS
In the years leading up to the current financial crisis, risks built up dangerously in our
financial system. Rising asset prices, particularly in housing, concealed a sharp
deterioration of underwriting standards for loans. The nation’s largest financial firms,
already highly leveraged, became increasingly dependent on unstable sources of shortterm funding. In many cases, weaknesses in firms’ risk-management systems left them
unaware of the aggregate risk exposures on and off their balance sheets. A credit boom
accompanied a housing bubble. Taking access to short-term credit for granted, firms did
not plan for the potential demands on their liquidity during a crisis. When asset prices
started to fall and market liquidity froze, firms were forced to pull back from lending,
limiting credit for households and businesses.
Our supervisory framework was not equipped to handle a crisis of this magnitude. To be
sure, most of the largest, most interconnected, and most highly leveraged financial firms
in the country were subject to some form of supervision and regulation by a federal
government agency. But those forms of supervision and regulation proved inadequate
and inconsistent.
First, capital and liquidity requirements were simply too low. Regulators did not require
firms to hold sufficient capital to cover trading assets, high-risk loans, and off-balance
sheet commitments, or to hold increased capital during good times to prepare for bad
times. Regulators did not require firms to plan for a scenario in which the availability of
liquidity was sharply curtailed.
Second, on a systemic basis, regulators did not take into account the harm that large,
interconnected, and highly leveraged institutions could inflict on the financial system and
on the economy if they failed.
Third, the responsibility for supervising the consolidated operations of large financial
firms was split among various federal agencies. Fragmentation of supervisory
responsibility and loopholes in the legal definition of a “bank” allowed owners of banks
and other insured depository institutions to shop for the regulator of their choice.
Fourth, investment banks operated with insufficient government oversight. Money
market mutual funds were vulnerable to runs. Hedge funds and other private pools of
capital operated completely outside of the supervisory framework.
To create a new foundation for the regulation of financial institutions, we will promote
more robust and consistent regulatory standards for all financial institutions. Similar
financial institutions should face the same supervisory and regulatory standards, with no
gaps, loopholes, or opportunities for arbitrage.
We propose the creation of a Financial Services Oversight Council, chaired by Treasury,
to help fill gaps in supervision, facilitate coordination of policy and resolution of
disputes, and identify emerging risks in firms and market activities. This Council would
include the heads of the principal federal financial regulators and would maintain a
permanent staff at Treasury.

19

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
We propose an evolution in the Federal Reserve’s current supervisory authority for BHCs
to create a single point of accountability for the consolidated supervision of all companies
that own a bank. All large, interconnected firms whose failure could threaten the stability
of the system should be subject to consolidated supervision by the Federal Reserve,
regardless of whether they own an insured depository institution. These firms should not
be able to escape oversight of their risky activities by manipulating their legal structure.
Under our proposals, the largest, most interconnected, and highly leveraged institutions
would face stricter prudential regulation than other regulated firms, including higher
capital requirements and more robust consolidated supervision. In effect, our proposals
would compel these firms to internalize the costs they could impose on society in the
event of failure.
A. Create a Financial Services Oversight Council
1. We propose the creation of a Financial Services Oversight Council to
facilitate information sharing and coordination, identify emerging risks,
advise the Federal Reserve on the identification of firms whose failure could
pose a threat to financial stability due to their combination of size, leverage,
and interconnectedness (hereafter referred to as a Tier 1 FHC), and provide
a forum for discussion of cross-cutting issues among regulators.
We propose the creation of a permanent Financial Services Oversight Council (Council)
to facilitate interagency discussion and analysis of financial regulatory policy issues to
support a consistent well-informed response to emerging trends, potential regulatory
gaps, and issues that cut across jurisdictions.
The membership of the Council should include (i) the Secretary of the Treasury, who
shall serve as the Chairman; (ii) the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System; (iii) the Director of the National Bank Supervisor (NBS) (described
below in Section I.D.); (iv) the Director of the Consumer Financial Protection Agency
(described below in Section III.A.); (v) the Chairman of the Securities and Exchange
Commission (SEC); (vi) the Chairman of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission
(CFTC); (vii) the Chairman of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC); and
(viii) the Director of the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA). To fulfill its mission,
we propose to create an office within Treasury that will provide full-time, expert staff
support to the missions of the Council.
The Council should replace the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets and
have additional authorities and responsibilities with respect to systemic risk and
coordination of financial regulation. We propose that the Council should:
x

facilitate information sharing and coordination among the principal federal
financial regulatory agencies regarding policy development, rulemakings,
examinations, reporting requirements, and enforcement actions;

x

provide a forum for discussion of cross-cutting issues among the principal federal
financial regulatory agencies; and

20

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
x

identify gaps in regulation and prepare an annual report to Congress on market
developments and potential emerging risks.

The Council should have authority to recommend firms that will be subject to Tier 1 FHC
supervision and regulation. The Federal Reserve should also be required to consult with
the Council in setting material prudential standards for Tier 1 FHCs and in setting riskmanagement standards for systemically important payment, clearing, and settlement
systems and activities. As described below, a subset of the Council’s membership should
be responsible for determining whether to invoke resolution authority with respect to
large, interconnected firms.
2. Our legislation will propose to give the Council the authority to gather
information from any financial firm and the responsibility for referring
emerging risks to the attention of regulators with the authority to respond.
The jurisdictional boundaries among new and existing federal financial regulatory
agencies should be drawn carefully to prevent mission overlap, and each of the federal
financial regulatory agencies generally should have exclusive jurisdiction to issue and
enforce rules to achieve its mission. Nevertheless, many emerging financial products and
practices will raise issues relating to systemic risk, prudential regulation of financial
firms, and consumer or investor protection.
To enable the monitoring of emerging threats that activities in financial markets may
pose to financial stability, we propose that the Council have the authority, through its
permanent secretariat in Treasury, to require periodic and other reports from any U.S.
financial firm solely for the purpose of assessing the extent to which a financial activity
or financial market in which the firm participates poses a threat to financial stability. In
the case of federally regulated firms, the Council should, wherever possible, rely upon
information that is already being collected by members of the Council in their role as
regulators. 
B. Implement Heightened Consolidated Supervision and Regulation of All
Large, Interconnected Financial Firms
1. Any financial firm whose combination of size, leverage, and
interconnectedness could pose a threat to financial stability if it failed (Tier
1 FHC) should be subject to robust consolidated supervision and regulation,
regardless of whether the firm owns an insured depository institution.
The sudden failures of large U.S.-based investment banks and of American International
Group (AIG) were among the most destabilizing events of the financial crisis. These
companies were large, highly leveraged, and had significant financial connections to the
other major players in our financial system, yet they were ineffectively supervised and
regulated. As a consequence, they did not have sufficient capital or liquidity buffers to
withstand the deterioration in financial conditions that occurred during 2008. Although
most of these firms owned federally insured depository institutions, they chose to own
depository institutions that are not considered “banks” under the Bank Holding Company
21

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(BHC) Act. This allowed them to avoid the more rigorous oversight regime applicable to
BHCs.
We propose a new, more robust supervisory regime for any firm whose combination of
size, leverage, and interconnectedness could pose a threat to financial stability if it failed.
Such firms, which we identify as Tier 1 Financial Holding Companies (Tier 1 FHCs),
should be subject to robust consolidated supervision and regulation, regardless of whether
they are currently supervised as BHCs. 
2. The Federal Reserve Board should have the authority and accountability
for consolidated supervision and regulation of Tier 1 FHCs. 
We propose that authority for supervision and regulation of Tier 1 FHCs be vested in the
Federal Reserve Board, which is by statute the consolidated supervisor and regulator of
all bank holding companies today. As a result of changes in corporate structure during
the current crisis, the Federal Reserve already supervises and regulates all major U.S.
commercial and investment banks on a firm-wide basis. The Federal Reserve has by far
the most experience and resources to handle consolidated supervision and regulation of
Tier 1 FHCs.
The Council should play an important role in recommending the identification of firms
that will be subject to regulation as Tier 1 FHCs. The Federal Reserve should also be
required to consult with the Council in setting material prudential standards for Tier 1
FHCs.
The ultimate responsibility for prudential standard-setting and supervision for Tier 1
FHCs must rest with a single regulator. The public has a right to expect that a clearly
identifiable entity, not a committee of multiple agencies, will be answerable for setting
standards that will protect the financial system and the public from risks posed by the
potential failure of Tier 1 FHCs. Moreover, a committee that included regulators of
specific types of financial institutions such as commercial banks or broker-dealers
(functional regulators) may be less focused on systemic needs and more focused on the
needs of the financial firms they regulate. For example, to promote financial stability, the
supervisor of a Tier 1 FHC may hold that firm’s subsidiaries to stricter prudential
standards than would be required by the functional regulator, whose focus is only on
keeping that particular subsidiary safe.
Diffusing responsibility among several regulators would weaken incentives for effective
regulation in other ways. For example, it would weaken both the incentive for and the
ability of the relevant agencies to act in a timely fashion – creating the risk that clearly
ineffective standards remain in place for long periods.
The Federal Reserve should fundamentally adjust its current framework for supervising
all BHCs in order to carry out its new responsibilities effectively with respect to Tier 1
FHCs. For example, the focus of BHC regulation would need to expand beyond the
safety and soundness of the bank subsidiary to include the activities of the firm as a
whole and the risks the firm might pose to the financial system. The Federal Reserve
would also need to develop new supervisory approaches for activities that to date have
not been significant activities for most BHCs.
22

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
3. Our legislation will propose criteria that the Federal Reserve must consider
in identifying Tier 1 FHCs.
We recommend that legislation specify factors that the Federal Reserve must consider
when determining whether an individual financial firm poses a threat to financial
stability. Those factors should include:
x

the impact the firm’s failure would have on the financial system and the economy;

x

the firm’s combination of size, leverage (including off-balance sheet exposures),
and degree of reliance on short-term funding; and

x

the firm’s criticality as a source of credit for households, businesses, and state and
local governments and as a source of liquidity for the financial system.

We propose that the Federal Reserve establish rules, in consultation with Treasury, to
guide the identification of Tier 1 FHCs. The Federal Reserve, however, should be
allowed to consider other relevant factors and exercise discretion in applying the
specified factors to individual financial firms. Treasury would have no role in
determining the application of these rules to individual financial firms. This discretion
would allow the regulatory system to adapt to inevitable innovations in financial activity
and in the organizational structure of financial firms. In addition, without this discretion,
large, highly leveraged, and interconnected firms that should be subject to consolidated
supervision and regulation as Tier 1 FHCs might be able to escape the regime. For
instance, if the Federal Reserve were to treat as a Tier 1 FHC only those firms with
balance-sheet assets above a certain amount, firms would have incentives to conduct
activities through off-balance sheet transactions and in off-balance sheet vehicles.
Flexibility is essential to minimizing the risk that an “AIG-like” firm could grow outside
the regulated system.
In identifying Tier 1 FHCs, the Federal Reserve should analyze the systemic importance
of a firm under stressed economic conditions. This analysis should consider the impact
the firm’s failure would have on other large financial institutions, on payment, clearing
and settlement systems, and on the availability of credit in the economy. In the case of a
firm that has one or more subsidiaries subject to prudential regulation by other federal
regulators, the Federal Reserve should be required to consult with those regulators before
requiring the firm to be regulated as a Tier 1 FHC. The Federal Reserve should regularly
review the classification of firms as Tier 1 FHCs. The Council should have the authority
to receive information from its members and to recommend to the Federal Reserve that a
firm be designated as a Tier 1 FHC, as described above.
To enable the Federal Reserve to identify financial firms other than BHCs that require
supervision and regulation as Tier 1 FHCs, we recommend that the Federal Reserve
should have the authority to collect periodic and other reports from all U.S. financial
firms that meet certain minimum size thresholds. The Federal Reserve’s authority to
require reports from a financial firm would be limited to reports that contain information
reasonably necessary to determine whether the firm is a Tier 1 FHC. In the case of firms
that are subject to federal regulation, the Federal Reserve should have access to relevant
23

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
reports submitted to other regulators, and its authority to require reports should be limited
to information that cannot be obtained from reports to other regulators.
The Federal Reserve also should have the ability to examine any U.S. financial firm that
meets certain minimum size thresholds if the Federal Reserve is unable to determine
whether the firm’s financial activities pose a threat to financial stability based on
regulatory reports, discussions with management, and publicly available information.
The scope of the Federal Reserve’s examination authority over a financial firm would be
strictly limited to examinations reasonably necessary to enable the Federal Reserve to
determine whether the firm is a Tier 1 FHC.
4. The prudential standards for Tier 1 FHCs – including capital, liquidity and
risk management standards – should be stricter and more conservative than
those applicable to other financial firms to account for the greater risks that
their potential failure would impose on the financial system.
Tier 1 FHCs should be subject to heightened supervision and regulation because of the
greater risks their potential failure would pose to the financial system. At the same time,
given the important role of Tier 1 FHCs in the financial system and the economy, setting
their prudential standards too high could constrain long-term financial and economic
growth. Therefore, the Federal Reserve, in consultation with the Council, should set
prudential standards for Tier 1 FHCs to maximize financial stability at the lowest cost to
long-term financial and economic growth.
Tier 1 FHCs should, at a minimum, be required to meet the qualification requirements for
FHC status (as revised in this proposal and discussed in more detail below).
Capital Requirements. Capital requirements for Tier 1 FHCs should reflect the large
negative externalities associated with the financial distress, rapid deleveraging, or
disorderly failure of each firm and should, therefore, be strict enough to be effective
under extremely stressful economic and financial conditions. Tier 1 FHCs should be
required to have enough high-quality capital during good economic times to keep them
above prudential minimum capital requirements during stressed economic times. In
addition to regulatory capital ratios, the Federal Reserve should evaluate a Tier 1 FHC’s
capital strength using supervisory assessments, including assessments of capital adequacy
under severe stress scenarios and assessments of the firm’s capital planning practices, and
market-based indicators of the firm’s credit quality.
Prompt Corrective Action. Tier 1 FHCs should be subject to a prompt corrective action
regime that would require the firm or its supervisor to take corrective actions as the
firm’s regulatory capital levels decline, similar to the existing prompt corrective action
regime for insured depository institutions established under the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA).
Liquidity Standards. The Federal Reserve should impose rigorous liquidity risk
requirements on Tier 1 FHCs that recognize the potential negative impact that the
financial distress, rapid deleveraging, or disorderly failure of each firm would have on the
financial system. The Federal Reserve should put in place a robust process for
24

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
continuously monitoring the liquidity risk profiles of these institutions and their liquidity
risk management processes.
Federal Reserve supervision should promote the full integration of liquidity risk
management of Tier 1 FHCs into the overall risk management of the institution. The
Federal Reserve should also establish explicit internal liquidity risk exposure limits and
risk management policies. Tier 1 FHCs should have sound processes for monitoring and
controlling the full range of their liquidity risks. They should regularly conduct stress
tests across a variety of liquidity stress scenarios, including short-term and protracted
scenarios and institution-specific and market-wide scenarios. The stress tests should
incorporate both on- and off-balance sheet exposures, including non-contractual offbalance sheet obligations.
Overall Risk Management. Supervisory expectations regarding Tier 1 FHCs’ riskmanagement practices must be in proportion to the risk, complexity, and scope of their
operations. These firms should be able to identify firm-wide risk concentrations (credit,
business lines, liquidity, and other) and establish appropriate limits and controls around
these concentrations. In order to credibly measure and monitor risk concentrations, Tier
1 FHCs must be able to identify aggregate exposures quickly on a firm-wide basis.
Market Discipline and Disclosure. To support market evaluation of a Tier 1 FHC’s risk
profile, capital adequacy, and risk management capabilities, such firms should be
required to make enhanced public disclosures.
Restrictions on Nonfinancial Activities. Tier 1 FHCs that do not control insured
depository institutions should be subject to the full range of prudential regulations and
supervisory guidance applicable to BHCs. In addition, the long-standing wall between
banking and commerce – which has served our economy well – should be extended to
apply to this new class of financial firm. Accordingly, each Tier 1 FHC also should be
required to comply with the nonfinancial activity restrictions of the BHC Act, regardless
of whether it controls an insured depository institution. We propose that a Tier 1 FHC
that has not been previously subject to the BHC Act should be given five years to
conform to the existing activity restrictions imposed on FHCs by the BHC Act.
Rapid Resolution Plans. The Federal Reserve also should require each Tier 1 FHC to
prepare and continuously update a credible plan for the rapid resolution of the firm in the
event of severe financial distress. Such a requirement would create incentives for the
firm to better monitor and simplify its organizational structure and would better prepare
the government, as well as the firm’s investors, creditors, and counterparties, in the event
that the firm collapsed. The Federal Reserve should review the adequacy of each firm’s
plan regularly.
5. Consolidated supervision of a Tier 1 FHC should extend to the parent
company and to all of its subsidiaries – regulated and unregulated, U.S. and
foreign. Functionally regulated and depository institution subsidiaries of a
Tier 1 FHC should continue to be supervised and regulated primarily by
their functional or bank regulator, as the case may be. The constraints that
the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLB Act) introduced on the Federal
Reserve’s ability to require reports from, examine, or impose higher
25

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
prudential requirements or more stringent activity restrictions on the
functionally regulated or depository institution subsidiaries of FHCs should
be removed. 
The financial crisis has demonstrated the crucial importance of having a consolidated
supervisor and regulator for all Tier 1 FHCs with a deep understanding of the operations
of each firm. The crisis has made clear that threats to a consolidated financial firm and
threats to financial stability can emerge from any business line and any subsidiary. It is
not reasonable to hold the functional regulator of a single subsidiary responsible for
identifying or managing risks that cut across many different subsidiaries and business
lines.
The GLB Act impedes the Federal Reserve’s ability, as a consolidated supervisor, to
obtain information from or impose prudential restrictions on subsidiaries of a BHC that
already have a primary supervisor, including banks and other insured depository
institutions; SEC-registered broker-dealers, investment advisers and investment
companies; entities regulated by the CFTC; and insurance companies subject to
supervision by state insurance supervisors. By relying solely on other supervisors for
information and for ensuring that the activities of the regulated subsidiary do not cause
excessive risk to the financial system, these restrictions also make it difficult to take a
truly firm-wide perspective on a BHC and to execute its responsibility to protect the
system as a whole.
To promote accountability in supervision and regulation, the Federal Reserve should have
authority to require reports from and conduct examinations of a Tier 1 FHC and all its
subsidiaries, including those that have a primary supervisor. To the extent possible,
information should be gathered from reports required or exams conducted by other
supervisors. The Federal Reserve should also have the authority to impose and enforce
more stringent prudential requirements on the regulated subsidiary of a Tier 1 FHC to
address systemic risk concerns, but only after consulting with that subsidiary’s primary
federal or state supervisor and Treasury.
6. Consolidated supervision of a Tier 1 FHC should be macroprudential in
focus. That is, it should consider risk to the system as a whole. 
Prudential supervision has historically focused on the safety and soundness of individual
financial firms, or, in the case of BHCs, on the risks that an organization’s nondepository subsidiaries pose to its depository institution subsidiaries. The financial crisis
has demonstrated that a narrow supervisory focus on the safety and soundness of
individual financial firms can result in a failure to detect and thwart emerging threats to
financial stability that cut across many institutions or have other systemic implications.
Going forward, the consolidated supervisor of Tier 1 FHCs should continue to employ
enhanced forms of its normal supervisory tools, but should supplement those tools with
rigorous assessments of the potential impact of the activities and risk exposures of these
companies on each other, on critical markets, and on the broader financial system.
The Federal Reserve should continuously analyze the connections among the major
financial firms and the dependence of the major financial markets on such firms, in order
to track potential impact on the broader financial system. To conduct this analysis, the
26

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Federal Reserve should require each Tier 1 FHC to regularly report the nature and extent
to which other major financial firms are exposed to it. In addition, the Federal Reserve
should constantly monitor the build-up of concentrations of risk across all Tier 1 FHCs
that may collectively threaten financial stability – even though no single firm, viewed in
isolation, may appear at risk.
7. The Federal Reserve, in consultation with Treasury and external experts,
should propose recommendations by October 1, 2009 to better align its
structure and governance with its authorities and responsibilities.
This report proposes a number of major changes to the formal powers and duties of the
Federal Reserve System, including the addition of several new financial stability
responsibilities and a reduction in its consumer protection role. These proposals would
put into effect the biggest changes to the Federal Reserve’s authority in decades.
For that reason, we propose a comprehensive review of the ways in which the structure
and governance of the Federal Reserve System affect its ability to accomplish its existing
and proposed functions. This review should include, among other things, the governance
of the Federal Reserve Banks and the role of Reserve Bank boards in supervision and
regulation. This review should be led by the Federal Reserve Board, but to promote a
diversity of views within and without government, Treasury and a wide range of external
experts should have substantial input into the review and resulting report. Once the
report is issued, Treasury will consider the recommendations in the report and will
propose any changes to the governance and structure of the Federal Reserve that are
appropriate to improve its accountability and its capacity to achieve its statutory
responsibilities.
C. Strengthen Capital and Other Prudential Standards Applicable to All Banks
and BHCs
1. Treasury will lead a working group, with participation by federal financial
regulatory agencies and outside experts, that will conduct a fundamental
reassessment of existing regulatory capital requirements for banks and
BHCs, including new Tier 1 FHCs. The working group will issue a report
with its conclusions by December 31, 2009.
Capital requirements have long been the principal regulatory tool to promote the safety
and soundness of banking firms and the stability of the banking system. The capital rules
in place at the inception of the financial crisis, however, simply did not require banking
firms to hold enough capital in light of the risks the firms faced. Most banks that failed
during this crisis were considered well-capitalized just prior to their failure.
The financial crisis highlighted a number of problems with our existing regulatory capital
rules. Our capital rules do not require institutions to hold sufficient capital against
implicit exposures to off-balance sheet vehicles, as was made clear by the actions many
institutions took to support their structured investment vehicles, asset-backed commercial
paper programs, and advised money market mutual funds. The capital rules provide
insufficient coverage for the risks of trading assets and certain structured credit products.
27

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
In addition, many of the capital instruments that comprised the capital base of banks and
BHCs did not have the loss-absorption capacity expected of them.
The financial crisis has demonstrated the need for a fundamental review of the regulatory
capital framework for banks and BHCs. This review should be comprehensive and
should cover all elements of the framework, including composition of capital, scope of
risk coverage, relative risk weights, and calibration. In particular, the review should
include:
x

proposed changes to the capital rules to reduce procyclicality, for example, by
requiring all banks and BHCs to hold enough high-quality capital during good
economic times to keep them above prudential minimum capital requirements
during stressed times;

x

analysis of the costs, benefits, and feasibility of allowing banks and BHCs to
satisfy a portion of their regulatory capital requirements through the issuance of
contingent capital instruments (such as debt securities that automatically convert
into common equity in stressed economic circumstances) or through the purchase
of tail insurance against macroeconomic risks;

x

proposed increases in regulatory capital requirements on investments and
exposures that pose high levels of risk under stressed market conditions, including
in particular: (i) trading positions; (ii) equity investments; (iii) credit exposures to
low-credit-quality firms and persons; (iv) highly rated asset-backed securities
(ABS) and mortgage-backed securities (MBS); (v) explicit and implicit exposures
to sponsored off-balance sheet vehicles; and (vi) OTC derivatives that are not
centrally cleared; and

x

recognition of the importance of a simpler, more transparent measure of leverage
for banks and BHCs to supplement the risk-based capital measures.

As a general rule, banks and BHCs should be subject to a risk-based capital rule that
covers all lines of business, assesses capital adequacy relative to appropriate measures of
the relative risk of various types of exposures, is transparent and comparable across
firms, and is credible and enforceable.
We also support the Basel Committee’s efforts to improve the Basel II Capital Accord, as
discussed in Section V.
2. Treasury will lead a working group, with participation by federal financial
regulatory agencies and outside experts, that will conduct a fundamental
reassessment of the supervision of banks and BHCs. The working group
will issue a report with its conclusions by October 1, 2009.
As noted above, many of the large and complex financial firms that failed or approached
the brink of failure in the recent financial crisis were subject to supervision and regulation
by a federal government agency. Ensuring that financial firms do not take excessive risks
requires the establishment and enforcement of strong prudential rules. Financial firms,
however, often can navigate around generally applicable rules. A strong supervisor is
28

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
needed to enforce rules and to monitor individual firms’ risk taking and risk management
practices.
The working group will undertake a review and analysis of lessons learned about banking
supervision and regulation from the recent financial crisis, addressing issues such as:
x

how to effectively conduct continuous, on-site supervision of large, complex
banking firms;

x

what information supervisors must obtain from regulated firms on a regular basis;

x

how functional and bank supervisors should interact with consolidated holding
company supervisors;

x

how federal and state supervisors should coordinate with foreign supervisors in
the supervision of multi-national banking firms;

x

the extent to which supervision of smaller, simpler banking firms should differ
from supervision of larger, more complex firms;

x

how supervisory agencies should be funded and structured, keeping in mind that
the funding structure can seriously impact regulatory competition and potentially
lead to regulatory capture; and

x

the costs and benefits of having supervisory agencies that also conduct other
governmental functions, such as deposit insurance, consumer protection, or
monetary policy.
3. Federal regulators should issue standards and guidelines to better align
executive compensation practices of financial firms with long-term
shareholder value and to prevent compensation practices from providing
incentives that could threaten the safety and soundness of supervised
institutions. In addition, we will support legislation requiring all public
companies to hold non-binding shareholder resolutions on the
compensation packages of senior executive officers, as well as new
requirements to make compensation committees more independent.

Among the many significant causes of the financial crisis were compensation practices.
In particular, incentives for short-term gains overwhelmed the checks and balances meant
to mitigate against the risk of excess leverage. We will seek to better align compensation
practices with the interests of shareholders and the stability of firms and the financial
system through the following five principles. First, compensation plans should properly
measure and reward performance. Second, compensation should be structured to account
for the time horizon of risks. Third, compensation practices should be aligned with sound
risk management. Fourth, golden parachutes and supplemental retirement packages
should be reexamined to determine whether they align the interests of executives and
shareholders. Finally, transparency and accountability should be promoted in the process
of setting compensation.
As part of this effort, Treasury will support federal regulators, including the Federal
Reserve, the SEC, and the federal banking regulators in laying out standards on
29

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
compensation for financial firms that will be fully integrated into the supervisory process.
These efforts recognize that an important component of risk management involves
properly aligning incentives, and that properly designed compensation practices for both
executives and employees are a necessary part of ensuring safety and soundness in the
financial sector. We will also ask the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets
(and the Council when it is established to replace the PWG) to perform a review of
compensation practices to monitor their impact on risk-taking, with a focus on identifying
whether new trends might be creating risks that would otherwise go unseen.
These standards will be supplemented by increased disclosure requirements from the
SEC as well as proposed legislation in two areas to increase transparency and
accountability in setting executive compensation.
First, we will work with Congress to pass “say on pay” legislation – further discussed in a
later section – that will require all public companies to offer an annual non-binding vote
on compensation packages for senior executive officers.
Additionally, we will propose legislation giving the SEC the power to require that
compensation committees are more independent. Under this legislation, compensation
committees would be given the responsibility and the resources to hire their own
independent compensation consultants and outside counsel. The legislation would also
direct the SEC to create standards for ensuring the independence of compensation
consultants, providing shareholders with the confidence that the compensation committee
is receiving objective, expert advice.
4. Capital and management requirements for FHC status should not be limited
to the subsidiary depository institution. All FHCs should be required to
meet the capital and management requirements on a consolidated basis as
well.
The GLB Act currently requires a BHC to keep its subsidiary depository institutions
“well-capitalized” and “well-managed” in order to qualify as a financial holding
company (FHC) and thereby engage in riskier financial activities such as merchant
banking, insurance underwriting, and securities underwriting and dealing. The GLB Act
does not, however, require an FHC to be “well-capitalized” or “well-managed” on a
consolidated basis. As a result, many of the BHCs that were most active in volatile
capital markets activities were not held to the highest consolidated regulatory capital
standard available.
We propose that, in addition to the current FHC eligibility requirements, all FHCs should
be required to achieve and maintain well-capitalized and well-managed status on a
consolidated basis. The specific capital standards should be determined in line with the
results of the capital review recommended previously in this report.
5. The accounting standard setters – the Financial Accounting Standards
Board (FASB), the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB), and
the SEC – should review accounting standards to determine how financial
firms should be required to employ more forward-looking loan loss
provisioning practices that incorporate a broader range of available credit
30

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
information. Fair value accounting rules also should be reviewed with the
goal of identifying changes that could provide users of financial reports
with both fair value information and greater transparency regarding the
cash flows management expects to receive by holding investments.
Certain aspects of accounting standards have had procyclical tendencies, meaning that
they have tended to amplify business cycles. For example, during good times, loan loss
reserves tend to decline because recent historical losses are low. In determining their
loan loss reserves, firms should be required to be more forward-looking and consider
factors that would cause loan losses to differ from recent historical experience. This
would likely result in recognition of higher provisions earlier in the credit cycle. During
the current crisis, such earlier loss recognition could have reduced procyclicality, while
still providing necessary transparency to users of financial reports on changes in credit
trends. Similarly, the interpretation and application of fair value accounting standards
during the crisis raised significant procyclicality concerns.
6. Firewalls between banks and their affiliates should be strengthened to
protect the federal safety net that supports banks and to better prevent
spread of the subsidy inherent in the federal safety net to bank affiliates.
Sections 23A and 23B of the Federal Reserve Act are designed to protect a depository
institution from suffering losses in its transactions with affiliates. These provisions also
limit the ability of a depository institution to transfer to its affiliates the subsidy arising
from the institution’s access to the federal safety net, which includes FDIC deposit
insurance, access to Federal Reserve liquidity, and access to Federal Reserve payment
systems. Sections 23A and 23B accomplish these purposes by placing quantitative limits
and collateral requirements on certain covered transactions between a bank and an
affiliate and by requiring all financial transactions between a bank and an affiliate to be
performed on market terms. The Federal Reserve administers these statutory provisions
for all depository institutions and has the power to provide exemptions from these
provisions.
The recent financial crisis has highlighted, more clearly than ever, the value of the federal
subsidy associated with the banking charter, as well as the related value to a consolidated
financial firm of owning a bank. Although the existing set of firewalls in sections 23A
and 23B are strong, the framework can and should be strengthened further.
Holes in the existing set of federal restrictions on transactions between banks and their
affiliates should be closed. Specifically, we propose that regulators should place more
effective constraints on the ability of banks to engage in over-the-counter (OTC)
derivatives and securities financing transactions with affiliates. In addition, covered
transactions between banks and their affiliates should be required to be fully
collateralized throughout the life of the transactions. Moreover, the existing federal
restrictions on transactions between banks and affiliates should be applied to transactions
between a bank and all private investment vehicles sponsored or advised by the bank.
The Federal Reserve’s discretion to provide exemptions from the bank/affiliate firewalls
also should be limited.
31

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Finally, the Federal Reserve and the federal banking agencies should tighten the
supervision and regulation of potential conflicts of interest generated by the affiliation of
banks and other financial firms, such as proprietary trading units and hedge funds.
D. Close Loopholes in Bank Regulation
1. We propose the creation of a new federal government agency, the National
Bank Supervisor (NBS), to conduct prudential supervision and regulation
of all federally chartered depository institutions, and all federal branches
and agencies of foreign banks.
One clear lesson learned from the recent crisis was that competition among different
government agencies responsible for regulating similar financial firms led to reduced
regulation in important parts of the financial system. The presence of multiple federal
supervisors of firms that could easily change their charter led to weaker regulation and
became a serious structural problem within our supervisory system.
We propose to establish a single federal agency dedicated to the chartering and prudential
supervision and regulation of national banks and federal branches and agencies of foreign
banks. This agency would take over the prudential responsibilities of the Office of the
Comptroller of the Currency, which currently charters and supervises nationally chartered
banks and federal branches and agencies of foreign banks, and responsibility for the
institutions currently supervised by the Office of Thrift Supervision, which supervises
federally chartered thrifts and thrift holding companies. As described below, we propose
to eliminate the thrift charter. The nature and extent of prudential supervision and
regulation of a federally chartered depository institution should no longer be a function of
whether a firm conducts its business as a national bank or a federal thrift.
To accomplish its mission effectively, the NBS should inherit the OCC’s and OTS’s
authorities to require reports, conduct examinations, impose and enforce prudential
requirements, and conduct overall supervision. The new agency should be given all the
tools, authorities, and financial, technical, and human resources needed to ensure that our
federally chartered banks, branches, and agencies are subject to the strongest possible
supervision and regulation.
The NBS should be an agency with separate status within Treasury and should be led by
a single executive.
Under our proposal, the Federal Reserve and the FDIC would maintain their respective
roles in the supervision and regulation of state-chartered banks, and the National Credit
Union Administration (NCUA) would maintain its authorities for credit unions.
2. We propose to eliminate the federal thrift charter, but to preserve its
interstate branching rules and apply them to state and national banks.
Federal Thrift Charter
Congress created the federal thrift charter in the Home Owners’ Loan Act of 1933 in
response to the extensive failures of state-chartered thrifts and the collapse of the broader
financial system during the Great Depression. The rationale for federal thrifts as a
specialized class of depository institutions focused on residential mortgage lending made
32

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
sense at the time but the case for such specialized institutions has weakened considerably
in recent years. Moreover, over the past few decades, the powers of thrifts and banks
have substantially converged.
As securitization markets for residential mortgages have grown, commercial banks have
increased their appetite for mortgage lending, and the Federal Home Loan Bank System
has expanded its membership base. Accordingly, the need for a special class of
mortgage-focused depository institutions has fallen. Moreover, the fragility of thrifts has
become readily apparent during the financial crisis. In part because thrifts are required
by law to focus more of their lending on residential mortgages, thrifts were more
vulnerable to the housing downturn that the United States has been experiencing since
2007. The availability of the federal thrift charter has created opportunities for private
sector arbitrage of our financial regulatory system. We propose to eliminate the charter
going forward, subject to reasonable transition arrangements.
Supervision and Regulation of National and State Banks
Our efforts to simplify and strengthen weak spots in our system of federal bank
supervision and regulation will not end with the elimination of the federal thrift charter.
Although FDICIA and other work by the federal banking agencies over the past few
decades have substantially improved the uniformity of the regulatory framework for
national banks, state member banks, and state nonmember banks, more work can and
should be done in this area. To further minimize arbitrage opportunities associated with
the multiple remaining bank charters and supervisors, we propose to further reduce the
differences in the substantive regulations and supervisory policies applicable to national
banks, state member banks, and state nonmember banks. We also propose to restrict the
ability of troubled banks to switch charters and supervisors.
Interstate Branching
Federal thrifts enjoyed the unrestricted ability to branch across state lines. Banks do not
always have that ability. Although many states have enacted legislation permitting
interstate branching, many other states continue to require interstate entry only through
the acquisition of an existing bank. This limitation on interstate branching is an obstacle
to interstate operations for all banks and creates special problems for community banks
seeking to operate across state lines.
We propose the elimination of the remaining restrictions on interstate branching by
national and state banks. Interstate banking and branching is good for consumers, good
for banks, and good for the broader economy. Permitting banks to expand across state
lines improves their geographical diversification and, consequently, their resilience in the
face of local economic shocks. Competition through interstate branching also makes the
banking system more efficient – improving consumer and business access to banking
services in under-served markets, and increasing convenience for customers who live or
work near state borders.
We propose that states should not be allowed to prevent de novo branching into their
states, or to impose a minimum requirement on the age of in-state banks that can be
33

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
acquired by an out-of-state banking firm. All consumer protections and deposit
concentration caps with respect to interstate banking should remain.
3. All companies that control an insured depository institution, however
organized, should be subject to robust consolidated supervision and
regulation at the federal level by the Federal Reserve and should be subject
to the nonbanking activity restrictions of the BHC Act. The policy of
separating banking from commerce should be re-affirmed and
strengthened. We must close loopholes in the BHC Act for thrift holding
companies, industrial loan companies, credit card banks, trust companies,
and grandfathered “nonbank” banks.
The BHC Act currently requires, as a general matter, that any company that owns an
insured depository institution must register as a BHC. BHCs are subject to consolidated
supervision and regulation by the Federal Reserve and are subject to the nonbanking
activity restrictions of the BHC Act. However, companies that own an FDIC-insured
thrift, industrial loan company (ILC), credit card bank, trust company, or grandfathered
depository institution are not required to become BHCs.
Companies that own a thrift are required to submit to a more limited form of supervision
and regulation by the OTS; companies that own an ILC, special-purpose credit card bank,
trust company, or grandfathered depository institution are not required to submit to
consolidated supervision and regulation of any kind.
As a result, by owning depository institutions that are not considered “banks” under the
BHC Act, some investment banks (including the now defunct Bear Stearns and Lehman
Brothers), insurance companies (including AIG), finance companies, commercial
companies, and other firms have been able to obtain access to the federal safety net,
while avoiding activity restrictions and more stringent consolidated supervision and
regulation by the Federal Reserve under the BHC Act.
By escaping the BHC Act, these firms generally were able to evade effective,
consolidated supervision and the long-standing federal policy of separating banking from
commerce. Federal law has long prevented commercial banks from affiliating with
commercial companies because of the conflicts of interest, biases in credit allocation,
risks to the safety net, concentrations of economic power, and regulatory and supervisory
difficulties generated by such affiliations. This policy has served our country well, and
the wall between banking and commerce should be retained and strengthened. Such
firms should be given five years to conform to the existing activity restrictions imposed
by the BHC Act
In addition, these firms were able to build up excessive balance-sheet leverage and to
take off-balance sheet risks with insufficient capital buffers because of the limited
consolidated supervision and weaker or non-existent consolidated capital requirements at
the holding company level. Their complex structures made them hard to supervise.
Some of the very largest of these firms failed during the current crisis or avoided failure
during the crisis only as a result of receiving extraordinary government support. In fact,
some of these firms voluntarily chose to become BHCs, subject to Federal Reserve
34

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
supervision, in part to address concerns by creditors regarding the effectiveness of the
alternative regulatory frameworks.
Thrift Holding Companies
Elimination of the thrift charter will eliminate the separate regime of supervision and
regulation of thrift holding companies. Significant differences between thrift holding
company and BHC supervision and regulation have created material arbitrage
opportunities. For example, although the Federal Reserve imposes leverage and riskbased capital requirements on BHCs, the OTS does not impose any capital requirements
on thrift holding companies, such as AIG. The intensity of supervision also has been
greater for BHCs than thrift holding companies. Finally, although BHCs generally are
prohibited from engaging in commercial activities, many thrift holding companies
established before the GLB Act in 1999 qualify as unitary thrift holding companies and
are permitted to engage freely in commercial activities. Under our plan, all thrift holding
companies would become BHCs and would be fully regulated on a consolidated basis.
Industrial Loan Companies
Congress added the ILC exception to the BHC Act in 1987. At that time, ILCs were
small, special-purpose banks that primarily engaged in the business of making small
loans to industrial workers and had limited deposit-taking powers. Today, however, ILCs
are FDIC-insured depository institutions that have authority to offer a full range of
commercial banking services. Although ILCs closely resemble commercial banks, their
holding companies can avoid the restrictions of the BHC Act – including consolidated
supervision and regulation by the Federal Reserve – by complying with a BHC exception.
Formation of an ILC has been a common way for commercial companies and financial
firms (including large investment banks) to get access to the federal bank safety net but
avoid the robust governmental supervision and activity restrictions of the BHC Act.
Under our plan, holding companies of ILCs would become BHCs.
Credit Card Banks
Congress also added the special-purpose credit card bank exception to the BHC Act in
1987. Companies that own a credit card bank can avoid the restrictions of the BHC Act,
engage in any commercial activity, and completely avoid consolidated supervision and
regulation. Many of these companies use their bank to offer private-label cards to retail
customers. They use their bank charter primarily to access payment systems and avoid
state usury laws.
The credit card bank exception in the BHC Act provides significant competitive
advantages to its beneficiaries. Credit card banks are also more vulnerable to conflicts of
interest than most other banks because of their common status as captive financing units
of commercial firms. A substantial proportion of the credit card loans made by such a
bank provide direct benefits to its parent company. As with ILCs, the loophole for
special-purpose credit card banks creates an unwarranted gap in the separation of banking
and commerce and creates a supervisory “blind spot” because Federal Reserve
supervision does not extend to the credit card bank holding company. Under our plan,
holding companies of credit card banks would become BHCs.
35

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Trust Companies
The BHC Act also exempts from the definition of “bank” an institution that functions
solely in a trust or fiduciary capacity if: (i) all or substantially all of the institution’s
deposits are in trust funds and are received in a bona fide fiduciary capacity; (ii) the
institution does not accept demand deposits or transaction accounts or make commercial
loans; and (iii) the institution does not obtain payment services or borrowing privileges
from the Federal Reserve. Although these FDIC-insured trust companies enjoy less of
the federal bank subsidy than full-service commercial banks, they do obtain material
benefits from their status as FDIC-insured depository institutions. As a result, they
should be treated as banks for purposes of the BHC Act, and their parent holding
companies should be supervised and regulated as BHCs. Under our plan, holding
companies of trust companies would become BHCs.
“Nonbank Banks”
When Congress amended the definition of “bank” in the BHC Act in 1987, it
grandfathered a number of companies that controlled depository institutions that became
a “bank” solely as a result of the 1987 amendments. As a result, the holding companies
of these so-called “nonbank banks” are not treated as BHCs for purposes of the BHC Act.
Although few of these companies remain today, there is no economic justification for
allowing these companies to continue to escape the activity restrictions and consolidated
supervision and regulation requirements of the BHC Act. Under our plan, holding
companies of “nonbank banks” would become BHCs.
E. Eliminate the SEC’s Programs for Consolidated Supervision
The SEC has ended its Consolidated Supervised Entity Program, under which it
had been the holding company supervisor for companies such as Lehman Brothers
and Bear Stearns. We propose also eliminating the SEC’s Supervised Investment
Bank Holding Company program. Investment banking firms that seek
consolidated supervision by a U.S. regulator should be subject to supervision and
regulation by the Federal Reserve.
Section 17(i) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (Exchange Act), enacted as part of
the GLB Act, requires the SEC to permit investment bank holding companies to elect for
consolidated supervision by the SEC. In 2004, the SEC adopted two consolidated
supervision regimes for companies that own an SEC-registered securities broker or dealer
– one for “consolidated supervised entities” (CSEs) and the other for “supervised
investment bank holding companies” (SIBHCs). The major stand-alone investment
banks (and several large commercial banking organizations) opted into either the CSE
regime or the SIBHC regime. The stand-alone investment banks that opted into one of
these regimes generally did so to demonstrate to European regulators that they were
subject to consolidated supervision by a U.S. federal regulator.
The two regimes were substantially the same, although the CSE structure was designed
for the largest securities firms. Under both regimes, supervised entities are required to
submit to SEC examinations and to comply with SEC requirements on reporting,
regulatory capital calculation, internal risk management systems, and recordkeeping.
36

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
In light of the failure or acquisition of three of the major stand-alone investment banks
supervised as CSEs, and the transformation of the remaining major investment banks into
BHCs supervised by the Federal Reserve, the SEC abandoned its voluntary CSE regime
in the fall of 2008. The SIBHC regime, required by section 17(i) of the Exchange Act,
remains in place, with only one entity currently subject to supervision under that regime.
The SEC’s remaining consolidated supervision program for investment bank holding
companies should be eliminated. Investment banking firms that seek consolidated
supervision by a U.S. regulator should be subject to comprehensive supervision and
regulation by the Federal Reserve.
F. Require Hedge Funds and Other Private Pools of Capital to Register
All advisers to hedge funds (and other private pools of capital, including private
equity funds and venture capital funds) whose assets under management exceed
some modest threshold should be required to register with the SEC under the
Investment Advisers Act. The advisers should be required to report information
on the funds they manage that is sufficient to assess whether any fund poses a
threat to financial stability.
In recent years, the United States has seen explosive growth in a variety of privatelyowned investment funds, including hedge funds, private equity funds, and venture capital
funds. Although some private investment funds that trade commodity derivatives must
register with the CFTC, and many funds register voluntarily with the SEC, U.S. law
generally does not require such funds to register with a federal financial regulator. At
various points in the financial crisis, de-leveraging by hedge funds contributed to the
strain on financial markets. Since these funds were not required to register with
regulators, however, the government lacked reliable, comprehensive data with which to
assess this sort of market activity. In addition to the need to gather information in order
to assess potential systemic implications of the activity of hedge funds and other private
pools of capital, it has also become clear that there is a compelling investor protection
rationale to fill the gaps in the regulation of investment advisors and the funds that they
manage.
Requiring the SEC registration of investment advisers to hedge funds and other private
pools of capital would allow data to be collected that would permit an informed
assessment of how such funds are changing over time and whether any such funds have
become so large, leveraged, or interconnected that they require regulation for financial
stability purposes.
We further propose that all investment funds advised by an SEC-registered investment
adviser should be subject to recordkeeping requirements; requirements with respect to
disclosures to investors, creditors, and counterparties; and regulatory reporting
requirements. The SEC should conduct regular, periodic examinations of such funds to
monitor compliance with these requirements. Some of those requirements may vary
across the different types of private pools. The regulatory reporting requirements for such
funds should require reporting on a confidential basis of the amount of assets under
management, borrowings, off-balance sheet exposures, and other information necessary
to assess whether the fund or fund family is so large, highly leveraged, or interconnected
37

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
that it poses a threat to financial stability. The SEC should share the reports that it
receives from the funds with the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve should determine
whether any of the funds or fund families meets the Tier 1 FHC criteria. If so, those
funds should be supervised and regulated as Tier 1 FHCs.
G. Reduce the Susceptibility of Money Market Mutual Funds (MMFs) to Runs
The SEC should move forward with its plans to strengthen the regulatory
framework around MMFs to reduce the credit and liquidity risk profile of
individual MMFs and to make the MMF industry as a whole less susceptible to
runs. The President’s Working Group on Financial Markets should prepare a
report assessing whether more fundamental changes are necessary to further
reduce the MMF industry’s susceptibility to runs, such as eliminating the ability of
a MMF to use a stable net asset value or requiring MMFs to obtain access to
reliable emergency liquidity facilities from private sources. 
When the aggressive pursuit of higher yield left one MMF vulnerable to the failure of
Lehman Brothers and the fund “broke the buck,” it sparked a run on the entire MMF
industry. This run resulted in severe liquidity pressures, not only on prime MMFs but
also on banks and other financial institutions that relied significantly on MMFs for
funding and on private money market participants generally. The run on MMFs was
stopped only by introduction of Treasury’s Temporary Guarantee Program for MMFs and
new Federal Reserve liquidity facilities targeted at MMFs.
Even after the run stopped, for some time MMFs and other money market investors were
unwilling to lend other than at very short maturities, which greatly increased liquidity
risks for businesses, banks, and other institutions. The vulnerability of MMFs to
breaking the buck and the susceptibility of the entire prime MMF industry to a run in
such circumstances remains a significant source of systemic risk.
The SEC should move forward with its plans to strengthen the regulatory framework
around MMFs. In doing so, the SEC should consider: (i) requiring MMFs to maintain
substantial liquidity buffers; (ii) reducing the maximum weighted average maturity of
MMF assets; (iii) tightening the credit concentration limits applicable to MMFs; (iv)
improving the credit risk analysis and management of MMFs; and (v) empowering MMF
boards of directors to suspend redemptions in extraordinary circumstances to protect the
interests of fund shareholders.
These measures should be helpful, as they should enhance investor protection and
mitigate the risk of runs. However, these measures should not, by themselves, be
expected to prevent a run on MMFs of the scale experienced in September 2008. We
propose that the President’s Working Group on Financial Markets (PWG) should prepare
a report considering fundamental changes to address systemic risk more directly. Those
changes could include, for example, moving away from a stable net asset value for
MMFs or requiring MMFs to obtain access to reliable emergency liquidity facilities from
private sources. For liquidity facilities to provide MMFs with meaningful protection
against runs, the facilities should be reliable, scalable, and designed in such a way that
drawing on the facilities to meet redemptions would not disadvantage remaining MMF
38

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
shareholders. The PWG should complete the report by September 15, 2009. Due to the
short time-frame and the work that is currently on-going, we believe that this report
should be conducted by the PWG, rather than the proposed Council, which we propose to
be created through legislation.
The SEC and the PWG should carefully consider ways to mitigate any potential adverse
effects of such a stronger regulatory framework for MMFs, such as investor flight from
MMFs into unregulated or less regulated money market investment vehicles or reductions
in the term of money market liabilities issued by major financial and non-financial firms.
H. Enhance Oversight of the Insurance Sector
Our legislation will propose the establishment of the Office of National Insurance
within Treasury to gather information, develop expertise, negotiate international
agreements, and coordinate policy in the insurance sector. Treasury will support
proposals to modernize and improve our system of insurance regulation in
accordance with six principles outlined in the body of the report.
Insurance plays a vital role in the smooth and efficient functioning of our economy. By
insulating households and businesses against unforeseen loss, insurance facilitates the
efficient deployment of resources and provides stability, certainty and peace of mind.
The current crisis highlighted the lack of expertise within the federal government
regarding the insurance industry. While AIG’s main problems were created outside of its
traditional insurance business, significant losses arose inside its state-regulated insurance
companies as well.
Insurance is a major component of the financial system. In 2008, the insurance industry
had $5.7 trillion in assets, compared with $15.8 trillion in the banking sector. There are
2.3 million jobs in the insurance industry, making up almost a third of all financial sector
jobs. For over 135 years, insurance has primarily been regulated by the states, which has
led to a lack of uniformity and reduced competition across state and international
boundaries, resulting in inefficiency, reduced product innovation, and higher costs to
consumers. Beyond a few specific areas where the federal government has a statutory
responsibility, such as employee benefits, terrorism risk insurance, flood insurance, or
anti-money laundering, there is no standing federal entity that is accountable for
understanding and monitoring the insurance industry. Given the importance of a healthy
insurance industry to the well functioning of our economy, it is important that we
establish a federal Office of National Insurance (ONI) within Treasury, and that we
develop a modern regulatory framework for insurance.
The ONI should be responsible for monitoring all aspects of the insurance industry. It
should gather information and be responsible for identifying the emergence of any
problems or gaps in regulation that could contribute to a future crisis. The ONI should
also recommend to the Federal Reserve any insurance companies that the Office believes
should be supervised as Tier 1 FHCs. The ONI should also carry out the government’s
existing responsibilities under the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act.
In the international context, the lack of a federal entity with responsibility and expertise
for insurance has hampered our nation’s effectiveness in engaging internationally with
39

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
other nations on issues related to insurance. The United States is the only country in the
International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS – whose membership includes
insurance regulators and supervisors of over 190 jurisdictions) that is not represented by a
federal insurance regulatory entity able to speak with one voice. In addition, the
European Union has recently passed legislation that will require a foreign insurance
company operating in its member states to be subject to supervision in the company’s
home country comparable to the supervision required in the EU. Accordingly, the ONI
will be empowered to work with other nations and within the IAIS to better represent
American interests, have the authority to enter into international agreements, and increase
international cooperation on insurance regulation.
Treasury will support proposals to modernize and improve our system of insurance
regulation. Treasury supports the following six principles for insurance regulation:
1. Effective systemic risk regulation with respect to insurance. The steps proposed
in this report, if enacted, will address systemic risks posed to the financial system
by the insurance industry. However, if additional insurance regulation would help
to further reduce systemic risk or would increase integration into the new
regulatory regime, we will consider those changes.
2. Strong capital standards and an appropriate match between capital allocation
and liabilities for all insurance companies. Although the current crisis did not
stem from widespread problems in the insurance industry, the crisis did make
clear the importance of adequate capital standards and a strong capital position for
all financial firms. Any insurance regulatory regime should include strong capital
standards and appropriate risk management, including the management of
liquidity and duration risk.
3. Meaningful and consistent consumer protection for insurance products and
practices. While many states have enacted strong consumer protections in the
insurance marketplace, protections vary widely among states. Any new insurance
regulatory regime should enhance consumer protections and address any gaps and
problems that exist under the current system, including the regulation of
producers of insurance. Further, any changes to the insurance regulatory system
that would weaken or undermine important consumer protections are
unacceptable.
4. Increased national uniformity through either a federal charter or effective action
by the states. Our current insurance regulatory system is highly fragmented,
inconsistent, and inefficient. While some steps have been taken to increase
uniformity, they have been insufficient. As a result there remain tremendous
differences in regulatory adequacy and consumer protection among the states.
Increased consistency in the regulatory treatment of insurance – including strong
capital standards and consumer protections – should enhance financial stability,
increase economic efficiency and result in real improvements for consumers.
5. Improve and broaden the regulation of insurance companies and affiliates on a
consolidated basis, including those affiliates outside of the traditional insurance
business. As we saw with respect to AIG, the problems of associated affiliates
40

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
outside of a consolidated insurance company’s traditional insurance business can
grow to threaten the solvency of the underlying insurance company and the
economy. Any new regulatory regime must address the current gaps in insurance
holding company regulation.
6. International coordination. Improvements to our system of insurance regulation
should satisfy existing international frameworks, enhance the international
competitiveness of the American insurance industry, and expand opportunities for
the insurance industry to export its services.
I. Determine the Future Role of the Government Sponsored Enterprises
(GSEs)
Treasury and the Department of Housing and Urban Development, in consultation
with other government agencies, will engage in a wide-ranging initiative to develop
recommendations on the future of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, and the Federal
Home Loan Bank system. We need to maintain the continued stability and strength
of the GSEs during these difficult financial times. We will report to the Congress
and the American public at the time of the President’s 2011 Budget release.
The 2008 Housing and Economic Recovery Act (HERA) reformed and strengthened the
GSEs’ safety and soundness regulation by creating the Federal Housing Finance Agency
(FHFA), a new independent regulator for Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal
Home Loan Banks.
HERA provided FHFA with authority to develop regulations on the size and composition
of the Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac investment portfolios, set capital requirements, and
place the companies into receivership. FHFA is also required to issue housing goals for
each of the regulated enterprises with respect to single-family and multi-family
mortgages. In addition, HERA provided temporary authority for Treasury to purchase
securities or other obligations of Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, and the Federal Home Loan
Banks through December 31, 2009. The purpose of this authority is to preserve the
stability of the financial market, prevent disruption to the availability of mortgage
finance, and protect taxpayers.
The growing stress in the mortgage markets over the last two years reduced the capital
positions of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. In September 2008, FHFA placed Fannie Mae
and Freddie Mac under conservatorship, and Treasury began to exercise its GSE
assistance authorities in order to promote the stability and strength of the GSEs during
these difficult financial times.
Treasury and the Department of Housing and Urban Development, together with other
government agencies, will engage in a wide-ranging process and seek public input to
explore options regarding the future of the GSEs, and will report to the Congress and the
American public at the time of the President’s 2011 budget.

41

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
There are a number of options for the reform of the GSEs, including: (i) returning them to
their previous status as GSEs with the paired interests of maximizing returns for private
shareholders and pursuing public policy home ownership goals; (ii) gradual wind-down
of their operations and liquidation of their assets; (iii) incorporating the GSEs’ functions
into a federal agency; (iv) a public utility model where the government regulates the
GSEs’ profit margin, sets guarantee fees, and provides explicit backing for GSE
commitments; (v) a conversion to providing insurance for covered bonds; (vi) and the
dissolution of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac into many smaller companies.

42

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
II. ESTABLISH COMPREHENSIVE REGULATION OF FINANCIAL MARKETS
The current financial crisis occurred after a long and remarkable period of growth and
innovation in our financial markets. New financial instruments allowed credit risks to be
spread widely, enabling investors to diversify their portfolios in new ways and enabling
banks to shed exposures that had once stayed on their balance sheets. Through
securitization, mortgages and other loans could be aggregated with similar loans and sold
in tranches to a large and diverse pool of new investors with different risk preferences.
Through credit derivatives, banks could transfer much of their credit exposure to third
parties without selling the underlying loans. This distribution of risk was widely
perceived to reduce systemic risk, to promote efficiency, and to contribute to a better
allocation of resources.
However, instead of appropriately distributing risks, this process often concentrated risk
in opaque and complex ways. Innovations occurred too rapidly for many financial
institutions’ risk management systems; for the market infrastructure, which consists of
payment, clearing and settlement systems; and for the nation’s financial supervisors.
Securitization, by breaking down the traditional relationship between borrowers and
lenders, created conflicts of interest that market discipline failed to correct. Loan
originators failed to require sufficient documentation of income and ability to pay.
Securitizers failed to set high standards for the loans they were willing to buy,
encouraging underwriting standards to decline. Investors were overly reliant on credit
rating agencies. Credit ratings often failed to accurately describe the risk of rated
products. In each case, lack of transparency prevented market participants from
understanding the full nature of the risks they were taking.
The build-up of risk in the over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives markets, which were
thought to disperse risk to those most able to bear it, became a major source of contagion
through the financial sector during the crisis.
We propose to bring the markets for all OTC derivatives and asset-backed securities into
a coherent and coordinated regulatory framework that requires transparency and
improves market discipline. Our proposal would impose record keeping and reporting
requirements on all OTC derivatives. We also propose to strengthen the prudential
regulation of all dealers in the OTC derivative markets and to reduce systemic risk in
these markets by requiring all standardized OTC derivative transactions to be executed in
regulated and transparent venues and cleared through regulated central counterparties.
We propose to enhance the Federal Reserve’s authority over market infrastructure to
reduce the potential for contagion among financial firms and markets.
Finally, we propose to harmonize the statutory and regulatory regimes for futures and
securities. While differences exist between securities and futures markets, many
differences in regulation between the markets may no longer be justified. In particular,
the growth of derivatives markets and the introduction of new derivative instruments
have highlighted the need for addressing gaps and inconsistencies in the regulation of
these products by the CFTC and SEC.
43

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
A. Strengthen Supervision and Regulation of Securitization Markets
The financial crisis was triggered by a breakdown in credit underwriting standards in
subprime and other residential mortgage markets. That breakdown was enabled by lax or
nonexistent regulation of nonbank mortgage originators and brokers. But the breakdown
also reflected a broad relaxation in market discipline on the credit quality of loans that
originators intended to distribute to investors through securitizations rather than hold in
their own loan portfolios.
We propose several initiatives to address this breakdown in market discipline: changing
the incentive structure of market participants; increasing transparency to allow for better
due diligence; strengthening credit rating agency performance; and reducing the
incentives for over-reliance on credit ratings.
1. Federal banking agencies should promulgate regulations that require
originators or sponsors to retain an economic interest in a material portion
of the credit risk of securitized credit exposures.
One of the most significant problems in the securitization markets was the lack of
sufficient incentives for lenders and securitizers to consider the performance of the
underlying loans after asset backed securities (ABS) were issued. Lenders and
securitizers had weak incentives to conduct due diligence regarding the quality of the
underlying assets being securitized. This problem was exacerbated as the structure of
ABS became more complex and opaque. Inadequate disclosure regimes exacerbated the
gap in incentives between lenders, securitizers and investors.
The federal banking agencies should promulgate regulations that require loan originators
or sponsors to retain five percent of the credit risk of securitized exposures. The
regulations should prohibit the originator from directly or indirectly hedging or otherwise
transferring the risk it is required to retain under these regulations. This is critical to
prevent gaming of the system to undermine the economic tie between the originator and
the issued ABS.
The federal banking agencies should have authority to specify the permissible forms of
required risk retention (for example, first loss position or pro rata vertical slice) and the
minimum duration of the required risk retention. The agencies also should have authority
to provide exceptions or adjustments to these requirements as needed in certain cases,
including authority to raise or lower the five percent threshold and to provide exemptions
from the “no hedging” requirement that are consistent with safety and soundness. The
agencies should also have authority to apply the requirements to securitization sponsors
rather than loan originators in order to achieve the appropriate alignment of incentives
contemplated by this proposal.
2. Regulators should promulgate additional regulations to align compensation
of market participants with longer term performance of the underlying
loans.
The securitization process should provide appropriate incentives for participants to best
serve the interests of their clients, the borrowers and investors. To do that, the
compensation of brokers, originators, sponsors, underwriters, and others involved in the
44

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
securitization process should be linked to the longer-term performance of the securitized
assets, rather than only to the production, creation or inception of those products.
For example, as proposed by Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB), Generally
Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) should be changed to eliminate the immediate
recognition of gain on sale by originators at the inception of a securitization transaction
and instead require originators to recognize income over time. The proposed changes
should also require many securitizations to be consolidated on the originator’s balance
sheet and their asset performance to be reflected in the originator’s consolidated financial
statements.
Similar performance-based, medium-to-long term approaches to securitization fees
should enhance incentives for market participants to focus on underwriting standards.
For example, the fees and commissions received by loan brokers and loan officers, who
otherwise have no ongoing relationship with the loans they generate, should be disbursed
over time and should be reduced if underwriting or asset quality problems emerge over
time.
Sponsors of securitizations should be required to provide assurances to investors, in the
form of strong, standardized representations and warranties, regarding the risk associated
with the origination and underwriting practices for the securitized loans underlying ABS.
3. The SEC should continue its efforts to increase the transparency and
standardization of securitization markets and be given clear authority to
require robust reporting by issuers of asset backed securities (ABS).
The SEC is currently working to improve and standardize disclosure practices by
originators, underwriters, and credit rating agencies involved in the securitization
process. Those efforts should continue. To strengthen those efforts, the SEC should be
given clear authority to require robust ongoing reporting by ABS issuers.
Investors and credit rating agencies should have access to the information necessary to
assess the credit quality of the assets underlying a securitization transaction at inception
and over the life of the transaction, as well as the information necessary to assess the
credit, market, liquidity, and other risks of ABS. In particular, the issuers of ABS should
be required to disclose loan-level data (broken down by loan broker or originator).
Issuers should also be required to disclose the nature and extent of broker, originator and
sponsor compensation and risk retention for each securitization.
We urge the industry to complete its initiatives to standardize and make transparent the
legal documentation for securitization transactions to make it easier for market
participants to make informed investment decisions. With respect to residential
mortgage-backed securities, the standards should include clear and uniform rules for
servicers to modify home mortgage loans under appropriate circumstances, if such
modifications would benefit the securitization trust as a whole.
Finally, the SEC and the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) should
expand the Trade Reporting and Compliance Engine (TRACE), the standard electronic
trade reporting database for corporate bonds, to include asset-backed securities.
45

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
4. The SEC should continue its efforts to strengthen the regulation of credit
rating agencies, including measures to require that firms have robust
policies and procedures that manage and disclose conflicts of interest,
differentiate between structured and other products, and otherwise promote
the integrity of the ratings process.
Credit rating agencies should be required to maintain robust policies and procedures for
managing and disclosing conflicts of interest and otherwise ensuring the integrity of the
ratings process.
Credit rating agencies should differentiate the credit ratings that they assign to structured
credit products from those they assign to unstructured debt. Credit Rating Agencies
should also publicly disclose credit rating performance measures for structured credit
products in a manner that facilitates comparisons across products and credit ratings and
that provides meaningful measures of the uncertainty and potential volatility associated
with credit ratings.
Credit rating agencies should also publicly disclose, in a manner comprehensible to the
investing public, precisely what risks their credit ratings are designed to assess (for
example, likelihood of default and/or loss severity in event of default), as well as material
risks not reflected in the ratings. Such disclosure should highlight how the risks of
structured products, which rely on diversification across a large number of individual
loans to protect the more senior investors, differ fundamentally from the risks of
unstructured corporate debt.
Credit rating agencies should disclose sufficient information about their methodologies
for rating structured finance products, including qualitative reviews of originators, to
allow users of credit ratings and market observers to reach their own conclusions about
the efficacy of the methodologies. Credit rating agencies should also disclose to the SEC
any unpublished rating agency data and methodologies.
5. Regulators should reduce their use of credit ratings in regulations and
supervisory practices, wherever possible.
Where regulators use credit ratings in regulations and supervisory practices, they should
recognize the potential differences in performance between structured and unstructured
credit products with the same credit rating.
Risk-based regulatory capital requirements should appropriately reflect the risk of
structured credit products, including the concentrated systematic risk of senior tranches
and re-securitizations and the risk of exposures held in highly leveraged off-balance sheet
vehicles. They should also minimize opportunities for firms to use securitization to
reduce their regulatory capital requirements without a commensurate reduction in risk.
B. Create Comprehensive Regulation of All OTC Derivatives, Including Credit
Default Swaps (CDS)
OTC derivatives markets, including CDS markets, should be subject to
comprehensive regulation that addresses relevant public policy objectives: (1)
preventing activities in those markets from posing risk to the financial system;
46

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
(2) promoting the efficiency and transparency of those markets; (3) preventing
market manipulation, fraud, and other market abuses; and (4) ensuring that
OTC derivatives are not marketed inappropriately to unsophisticated parties.
One of the most significant changes in the world of finance in recent decades has been
the explosive growth and rapid innovation in the market for financial derivatives. Much
of this development has occurred in the market for OTC derivatives, which are not
executed on regulated exchanges. In 2000, the Commodity Futures Modernization Act
(CFMA) explicitly exempted OTC derivatives, to a large extent, from regulation by the
Commodity Futures Trading Commission. In addition, the law limited the SEC’s
authority to regulate certain types of OTC derivatives. As a result, the market for OTC
derivatives has largely gone unregulated.
The downside of this lax regulatory regime for OTC derivatives – and, in particular, for
credit default swaps (CDS) – became disastrously clear during the recent financial crisis.
In the years prior to the crisis, many institutions and investors had substantial positions in
CDS – particularly CDS that were tied to asset backed securities (ABS), complex
instruments whose risk characteristics proved to be poorly understood even by the most
sophisticated of market participants. At the same time, excessive risk taking by AIG and
certain monoline insurance companies that provided protection against declines in the
value of such ABS, as well as poor counterparty credit risk management by many banks,
saddled our financial system with an enormous – and largely unrecognized – level of risk.
When the value of the ABS fell, the danger became clear. Individual institutions believed
that these derivatives would protect their investments and provide return, even if the
market went down. But, during the crisis, the sheer volume of these contracts
overwhelmed some firms that had promised to provide payment on the CDS and left
institutions with losses that they believed they had been protected against. Lacking
authority to regulate the OTC derivatives market, regulators were unable to identify or
mitigate the enormous systemic threat that had developed.
Government regulation of the OTC derivatives markets should be designed to achieve
four broad objectives: (1) preventing activities in those markets from posing risk to the
financial system; (2) promoting the efficiency and transparency of those markets; (3)
preventing market manipulation, fraud, and other market abuses; and (4) ensuring that
OTC derivatives are not marketed inappropriately to unsophisticated parties. To achieve
these goals, it is critical that similar products and activities be subject to similar
regulations and oversight.
To contain systemic risks, the Commodities Exchange Act (CEA) and the securities laws
should be amended to require clearing of all standardized OTC derivatives through
regulated central counterparties (CCPs). To make these measures effective, regulators
will need to require that CCPs impose robust margin requirements as well as other
necessary risk controls and that customized OTC derivatives are not used solely as a
means to avoid using a CCP. For example, if an OTC derivative is accepted for clearing
by one or more fully regulated CCPs, it should create a presumption that it is a
standardized contract and thus required to be cleared.
47

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
All OTC derivatives dealers and all other firms whose activities in those markets create
large exposures to counterparties should be subject to a robust and appropriate regime of
prudential supervision and regulation. Key elements of that robust regulatory regime
must include conservative capital requirements (more conservative than the existing bank
regulatory capital requirements for OTC derivatives), business conduct standards,
reporting requirements, and conservative requirements relating to initial margins on
counterparty credit exposures. Counterparty risks associated with customized bilateral
OTC derivatives transactions that should not be accepted by a CCP would be addressed
by this robust regime covering derivative dealers. As noted above, regulatory capital
requirements on OTC derivatives that are not centrally cleared also should be increased
for all banks and BHCs.
The OTC derivatives markets should be made more transparent by amending the CEA
and the securities laws to authorize the CFTC and the SEC, consistent with their
respective missions, to impose recordkeeping and reporting requirements (including an
audit trail) on all OTC derivatives. Certain of those requirements should be deemed to be
satisfied by either clearing standardized transactions through a CCP or by reporting
customized transactions to a regulated trade repository. CCPs and trade repositories
should be required to, among other things, make aggregate data on open positions and
trading volumes available to the public and make data on any individual counterparty’s
trades and positions available on a confidential basis to the CFTC, SEC, and the
institution’s primary regulators.
Market efficiency and price transparency should be improved in derivatives markets by
requiring the clearing of standardized contracts through regulated CCPs as discussed
earlier and by moving the standardized part of these markets onto regulated exchanges
and regulated transparent electronic trade execution systems for OTC derivatives and by
requiring development of a system for timely reporting of trades and prompt
dissemination of prices and other trade information. Furthermore, regulated financial
institutions should be encouraged to make greater use of regulated exchange-traded
derivatives. Competition between appropriately regulated OTC derivatives markets and
regulated exchanges would make both sets of markets more efficient and thereby better
serve end-users of derivatives.
Market integrity concerns should be addressed by making whatever amendments to the
CEA and the securities laws which are necessary to ensure that the CFTC and the SEC,
consistent with their respective missions, have clear, unimpeded authority to police and
prevent fraud, market manipulation, and other market abuses involving all OTC
derivatives. The CFTC also should have authority to set position limits on OTC
derivatives that perform or affect a significant price discovery function with respect to
regulated markets. Requiring CCPs, trade repositories, and other market participants to
provide the CFTC, SEC, and institutions’ primary regulators with a complete picture of
activity in the OTC derivatives markets will assist those regulators in detecting and
deterring all such market abuses.
Current law seeks to protect unsophisticated parties from entering into inappropriate
derivatives transactions by limiting the types of counterparties that could participate in
those markets. But the limits are not sufficiently stringent. The CFTC and SEC are
48

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
reviewing the participation limits in current law to recommend how the CEA and the
securities laws should be amended to tighten the limits or to impose additional disclosure
requirements or standards of care with respect to the marketing of derivatives to less
sophisticated counterparties such as small municipalities.
C. Harmonize Futures and Securities Regulation
The CFTC and the SEC should make recommendations to Congress for
changes to statutes and regulations that would harmonize regulation of futures
and securities.
The broad public policy objectives of futures regulation and securities regulation are the
same: protecting investors, ensuring market integrity, and promoting price transparency.
While differences exist between securities and futures markets, many differences in
regulation between the markets are no longer justified. In particular, the growth of
derivatives markets and the introduction of new derivative instruments have highlighted
the need for addressing gaps and inconsistencies in the regulation of these products by the
CFTC and SEC.
Many of the instruments traded on the commodity and securities exchanges and in the
over-the-counter markets have attributes that may place the instrument within the
purview of both regulatory agencies. One result of this jurisdictional overlap has been
that economically equivalent instruments may be regulated by two agencies operating
under different and sometimes conflicting regulatory philosophies and statutes. For
example, many financial options and futures products are similar (and, indeed, the returns
to one often can be replicated with the other). Under the current federal regulatory
structure, however, options on a security are regulated by the SEC, whereas futures
contracts on the same underlying security are regulated jointly by the CFTC and SEC.
In many instances the result of these overlapping yet different regulatory authorities has
been numerous and protracted legal disputes about whether particular products should be
regulated as futures or securities. These disputes have consumed significant agency
resources that otherwise could have been devoted to the furtherance of the agency’s
mission. Uncertainty regarding how an instrument will be regulated has impeded and
delayed the launch of exchange-traded equity, equity index, and credit event products, as
litigation sorted out whether a particular product should be regulated as a futures contract
or as a security. Eliminating jurisdictional uncertainties and ensuring that economically
equivalent instruments are regulated in the same manner, regardless of which agency has
jurisdiction, would remove impediments to product innovation.
Arbitrary jurisdictional distinctions also have unnecessarily limited competition between
markets and exchanges. Under existing law, financial instruments with similar
characteristics may be forced to trade on different exchanges that are subject to different
regulatory regimes. Harmonizing the regulatory regimes would remove such distinctions
and permit a broader range of instruments to trade on any regulated exchange. Permitting
direct competition between exchanges also would help ensure that plans to bring OTC
derivatives trading onto regulated exchanges or regulated transparent electronic trading
systems would promote rather than retard competition. Greater competition would make
49

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
these markets more efficient, which would benefit users of the markets, including
investors and risk managers.
We also will need greater coordination and harmonization between these agencies as we
move forward. The CEA currently provides that funds trading in the futures markets
register as Commodity Pool Operators (CPO) and file annual financials with the CFTC.
Over 1300 CPOs, including many of the largest hedge funds, are currently registered with
and make annual filings with the CFTC. It will be important that the CFTC be able to
maintain its enforcement authority over these entities as the SEC takes on important new
responsibilities in this area.
Pursuant to the CEA, the CFTC currently employs a “principles-based approach” to
regulation of exchanges, clearing organizations, and intermediaries, while pursuant to the
securities laws; the SEC employs a “rules-based approach.” Efforts at harmonization
should seek to build a common foundation for market regulation through agreement by
the two agencies on principles of regulation that are significantly more precise than the
CEA’s current “core principles.” The new principles need to be sufficiently precise so
that market practices that violate those principles can be readily identified and subjected
to enforcement actions by regulators. At the same time, they should be sufficiently
flexible to allow for innovations by market participants that are consistent with the
principles. For example, the CFTC has indicated that it is willing to recommend adopting
as core principles for clearing organizations key elements of international standards for
central counterparty clearing organizations (the CPSS-IOSCO standards), which are
considerably more precise than the current CEA core principles for CFTC regulated
clearing organizations.
Harmonization of substantive futures and securities regulation for economically
equivalent instruments also should require the development of consistent procedures for
reviewing and approving proposals for new products and rulemakings by self-regulatory
organizations (SROs). Here again, the agencies should strike a balance between their
existing approaches. The SEC should recommend requirements to respond more
expeditiously to proposals for new products and SRO rule changes and should
recommend expansion of the types of filings that should be deemed effective upon filing,
while the CFTC should recommend requiring prior approval for more types of rules and
allowing it appropriate and reasonable time for approving rules that require prior
approval.
The harmonization of futures and securities laws for economically equivalent instruments
would not require eliminating or modifying provisions relating to futures and options
contracts on agricultural, energy, and other physical commodity products. There are
important protections related to these markets which must be maintained and in certain
circumstances enhanced in applicable law and regulation.
We recommend that the CFTC and the SEC complete a report to Congress by September
30, 2009 that identifies all existing conflicts in statutes and regulations with respect to
similar types of financial instruments and either explains why those differences are
essential to achieve underlying policy objectives with respect to investor protection,
market integrity, and price transparency or makes recommendations for changes to
50

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
statutes and regulations that would eliminate the differences. If the two agencies cannot
reach agreement on such explanations and recommendations by September 30, 2009,
their differences should be referred to the new Financial Services Oversight Council. The
Council should be required to address such differences and report its recommendations to
Congress within six months of its formation.
D. Strengthen Oversight and Functioning of Systemically Important Payment,
Clearing, and Settlement Systems and Related Activities
We propose that the Federal Reserve have the responsibility and authority to
conduct oversight of systemically important payment, clearing and settlement
systems, and activities of financial firms.
A key determinant of the risk posed by the interconnectedness of financial institutions is
the strength or weakness of arrangements for settling payment obligations and financial
transactions between banks and other financial institutions. Where such arrangements are
strong they can help guard against instability in times of crisis. Where they are weak
they can be a major source of financial contagion, transmitting a financial shock from one
firm or market to many other firms and markets.
When major financial institutions came under significant financial stress during 2008,
policymakers were extremely concerned that weaknesses in settlement arrangements for
certain financial transactions, notably tri-party repurchase agreements and OTC
derivatives, would be a source of contagion. For several years prior to 2008, the Federal
Reserve had worked with other regulators and market participants to strengthen those
arrangements. In the case of CDS and other OTC derivatives, significant progress was
achieved, notably the cessation of unauthorized assignments of trades, reductions of
backlogs of unconfirmed trades, and efforts to compress portfolios of outstanding trades.
Still, progress was slow and insufficient.
Progress in strengthening payment and settlement arrangements is inherently difficult
because improvements in such arrangements require collective action by market
participants. Existing federal authority over such arrangements is incomplete and
fragmented. In such circumstances, the Federal Reserve and other regulators have been
forced to rely heavily on moral suasion to encourage market participants to take such
collective actions. The criticality of such arrangements and the slow progress in
strengthening certain key infrastructure arrangements indicates a need for clear and
comprehensive federal authority for oversight focused on the risk management of
systemically important payment, clearing, and settlement systems and of systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement activities of financial firms.
Responsibility and authority for ensuring consistent oversight of all systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement systems and activities should be assigned to
the Federal Reserve. The Federal Reserve has long played a role in the supervision,
oversight, development, and operation of payment, clearing, and settlement systems. It
also has played a leading role in developing international standards for payment, clearing,
and settlement systems. As the central bank, it inherently has a special interest in
promoting the safety and efficiency of such systems, because they are important to the
liquidity of financial institutions and the implementation of monetary policy. The
51

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
authority we propose to give to the Federal Reserve should supplement rather than
replace the existing authority of regulators of clearing and settlement systems and
prudential regulators of financial firms.
Systemically Important Systems
We will propose legislation that broadly defines the characteristics of systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement systems (covered systems) and sets
objectives and principles for their oversight. We propose that the Federal Reserve, in
consultation with the Council, to identify covered systems and to set risk management
standards for their operation. We will propose legislation that defines a covered system
as a payment, clearing, or settlement system the failure or disruption of which could
create or increase the risk of significant liquidity or credit problems spreading among
financial institutions or markets and thereby threatening the stability of the financial
system.
The Federal Reserve should have authority to collect information from any payment,
clearing, or settlement system for the purpose of assessing whether the system is
systemically important. In the case of a system that is subject to comprehensive
regulation by a federal market regulator (the CFTC or the SEC), the market regulator will
remain the primary regulator of the system. The Federal Reserve should first seek to
obtain the information it needs from the primary regulator, but may request additional
information directly from the system if it is determined that the information is not
currently collected by or available to the primary regulator.
The risk management standards imposed by the Federal Reserve on covered systems
should require such systems to have consistent and robust policies and practices for
ensuring timely settlement by the systems across a range of extreme but plausible
scenarios. The standards for such systems should be reviewed periodically by the Federal
Reserve, in consultation with the Council, and should take into account relevant
international standards.
A covered system should be subject to regular, consistent, and rigorous on-site safety and
soundness examinations as well as prior reviews of changes to its rules and operations in
order to ensure that the amended rules and operations meet the applicable risk
management standards. If a system is subject to comprehensive regulation by a federal
market regulator (CFTC or SEC), the market regulator should lead those exams and
reviews. The Federal Reserve should have the right to participate in the exams, including
in the determination of their scope and methodology, and should be consulted on rule
changes that affect the system’s risk management. The Federal Reserve and the market
regulator should regularly conduct joint assessments of the system’s adherence to the
applicable risk management standards.
If a covered system’s risk management policies and practices do not meet the applicable
standards, the Federal Reserve should have adequate authority to compel corrective
actions by the system. If a covered system is subject to comprehensive regulation by a
federal market regulator (CFTC or SEC), the market regulator should have primary
authority for enforcement. If the Federal Reserve concludes that corrective actions are
necessary, it should recommend those actions to the market regulator. If the Federal
52

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Reserve and the market regulator cannot agree on the need for enforcement action, the
Federal Reserve should have emergency authority to take enforcement action but only
after consultation with the Council, which should attempt to mediate the agencies’
differences.
The Federal Reserve should have authority to require a covered system to submit reports
for the purpose of enabling the Federal Reserve to assess the risk that the system’s
operations pose to the financial system and to assess the safety and soundness of the
system. In the case of a covered system that is subject to comprehensive regulation by a
federal market regulator, the Federal Reserve should have access to relevant reports
submitted to that regulator, but its authority to require reports should be limited to
information that cannot be obtained from reports to the other regulator.
Systemically Important Activities
We will propose legislation that broadly defines the characteristics of systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement activities of financial firms (covered
activities) and sets objectives and principles for their conduct. We propose that the
Federal Reserve, in consultation with the Council, to identify covered activities and to set
risk management standards for their conduct by financial firms. We propose to define a
covered activity as a payment, clearing, or settlement activity of financial firms the
failure or disruption of which could create or increase the risk of significant liquidity or
credit problems spreading among financial institutions or markets and thereby threatening
the stability of the financial system.
If the Federal Reserve has reason to believe that a payment, clearing, or settlement
activity is systemically important, it should have authority to collect information from
any financial firm engaged in that activity for the purpose of assessing whether the
activity is systemically important. In the case of a firm that is subject to federal
regulation, the Federal Reserve should have access to relevant reports submitted to other
regulators and its authority to require reports should be limited to information that cannot
be obtained from reports to other regulators.
Compliance by financial firms with standards established by the Federal Reserve with
respect to a systemically important activity will be administratively enforceable by the
firm’s primary federal regulator (if applicable). The Federal Reserve, however, will have
back-up examination and administrative enforcement authority with respect to such
standards.
The Federal Reserve should have authority to require financial firms engaged in a
covered activity to submit reports with respect to the firm’s conduct of such activity. In
the case of a firm that is subject to federal regulation, the Federal Reserve should have
access to relevant reports submitted to other regulators, and its authority to require reports
should be limited to information that cannot be obtained from reports to other regulators.

53

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
E. Strengthen Settlement Capabilities and Liquidity Resources of Systemically
Important Payment, Clearing, and Settlement Systems
We propose that the Federal Reserve have authority to provide systemically
important payment, clearing, and settlement systems access to Reserve Bank
accounts, financial services, and the discount window.
The safety and efficiency of financial institutions and markets depend critically on the
strength of the infrastructure of the financial system—the payment, clearing, and
settlement systems that are used to clear and settle financial transactions. In particular,
confidence in financial markets and financial market participants depends critically on
the ability of the payment, clearing, and settlement systems used by the markets to meet
their financial obligations to participants without delay. Many systemically important
payment, clearing, and settlement systems currently depend on commercial banks to
perform critical payment and other financial services and to provide them with the
liquidity necessary to convert margin and other collateral into funds when necessary to
complete settlement. These dependencies create the risk that a systemically important
system may be unable to meet its obligations to participants when due because the bank
on which it relies for such services (or another market participant) is unable or unwilling
to provide the liquidity the system needs. During the recent financial crisis some
systemically important settlement systems have encountered performance and other
issues with their banks. At the same time, many market participants have had trouble
obtaining liquidity by pledging or selling collateral, even the forms that are most liquid
under normal circumstances.
The risk posed by such impediments to timely settlement would be eliminated by
providing (where not already available under other authorities) direct access to Reserve
Bank accounts and financial services and to the discount window for payment, clearing,
and settlement systems that the Federal Reserve, in consultation with the Council, has
identified as systemically significant. Discount window access for such systems should
be for emergency purposes, such as enabling the system to convert noncash margin and
collateral assets to liquid settlement funds in the event that one of the system’s
participants fails to settle its obligations to the system and the system’s contingency plans
for converting collateral into cash fail to perform as expected on the day of a participant
default. Systemically important systems would be expected to meet applicable standards
for liquidity risk management for such systems, which generally require systemically
important systems to maintain sufficient liquid financial resources to make timely
payments, notwithstanding a default by the participant to which the system has the largest
exposure under extreme but plausible market conditions.

54

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
III. PROTECT CONSUMERS AND INVESTORS FROM FINANCIAL ABUSE
Prior to the current financial crisis, a number of federal and state regulations were in
place to protect consumers against fraud and to promote understanding of financial
products like credit cards and mortgages. But as abusive practices spread, particularly in
the market for subprime and nontraditional mortgages, our regulatory framework proved
inadequate in important ways. Multiple agencies have authority over consumer
protection in financial products, but for historical reasons, the supervisory framework for
enforcing those regulations had significant gaps and weaknesses. Banking regulators at
the state and federal level had a potentially conflicting mission to promote safe and sound
banking practices, while other agencies had a clear mission but limited tools and
jurisdiction. Most critically in the run-up to the financial crisis, mortgage companies and
other firms outside of the purview of bank regulation exploited that lack of clear
accountability by selling mortgages and other products that were overly complicated and
unsuited to borrowers’ financial situation. Banks and thrifts followed suit, with
disastrous results for consumers and the financial system.
This year, Congress, the Administration, and financial regulators have taken significant
measures to address some of the most obvious inadequacies in our consumer protection
framework. But these steps have focused on just two, albeit very important, product
markets – credit cards and mortgages. We need comprehensive reform.
For that reason, we propose the creation of a single regulatory agency, a Consumer
Financial Protection Agency (CFPA), with the authority and accountability to make sure
that consumer protection regulations are written fairly and enforced vigorously. The
CFPA should reduce gaps in federal supervision and enforcement; improve coordination
with the states; set higher standards for financial intermediaries; and promote consistent
regulation of similar products.
Consumer protection is a critical foundation for our financial system. It gives the public
confidence that financial markets are fair and enables policy makers and regulators to
maintain stability in regulation. Stable regulation, in turn, promotes growth, efficiency,
and innovation over the long term. We propose legislative, regulatory, and
administrative reforms to promote transparency, simplicity, fairness, accountability, and
access in the market for consumer financial products and services.
We also propose new authorities and resources for the Federal Trade Commission to
protect consumers in a wide range of areas.
Finally, we propose new authorities for the Securities and Exchange Commission to
protect investors, improve disclosure, raise standards, and increase enforcement.
A. Create a New Consumer Financial Protection Agency
We propose the creation of a single federal agency, the Consumer Financial Protection
Agency, dedicated to protecting consumers in the financial products and services
markets,except for investment products and services already regulated by the SEC or
55

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
CFTC. We recommend that the CFPA be granted consolidated authority over the closely
related functions of writing rules, supervising and examining institutions’ compliance,
and administratively enforcing violations. The CFPA should reduce gaps in federal
supervision; improve coordination among the states; set higher standards for financial
intermediaries; and promote consistent regulation of similar products. Nothing in this
proposal is intended to constrain the Attorney General’s current authorities to enforce the
law or direct litigation on behalf of the United States.
The CFPA should give consumer protection an independent seat at the table in our
financial regulatory system. Consumer protection is a critical foundation for our
financial system. It gives the public confidence that financial markets are fair and
enables policy makers and regulators to maintain stability in regulation. Stable
regulation, in turn, promotes growth, efficiency, and innovation over the long term.
Consumer protection cannot live up to this role, however, unless the financial system
develops and sustains a culture that places a high value on helping responsible consumers
thrive and treating all consumers fairly.
The spread of unsustainable subprime mortgages and abusive credit card contracts
highlighted a serious shortcoming of our present regulatory infrastructure. It too easily
allows consumer protection values to be overwhelmed by other imperatives – whether
short-term gain, innovation for its own sake, or keeping up with the competition. To
instill a genuine culture of consumer protection and not merely of legal compliance in our
financial institutions, we need first to instill that culture in the federal regulatory
structure. For the public to have confidence that consumer protection is important to
regulators, there must be clear accountability in government for this task.
The current system of regulation does not meet these needs. Oversight of federally
supervised institutions for compliance with consumer protection, fair lending, and
community reinvestment laws is fragmented among four agencies. This makes
coordination of supervisory policies difficult, slows responses to emerging consumer
protection threats, and creates opportunities for regulatory arbitrage, where firms choose
their regulator according to which entity will be least restrictive.
The Federal Trade Commission has a clear mission to protect consumers but generally
lacks jurisdiction over the banking sector and has limited tools and resources to promote
robust compliance of nonbank institutions. Mortgage companies not owned by banks fall
into a regulatory “no man’s land” where no regulator exercises leadership and state
attorneys general are left to try to fill the gap. State and federal bank supervisory
agencies’ primary mission is to ensure that financial institutions act prudently, a mission
that, in appearance if not always in practice, often conflicts with their consumer
protection responsibilities.
In addition, the systems, expertise, and culture necessary for the federal banking agencies
to perform their core missions and functions are not conducive to sustaining over the long
term a federal consumer protection program that is vigorous, balanced, and creative.
These agencies are designed, and their professional staff is trained, to see the world
through the lenses of institutions and markets, not consumers. Recent Federal Reserve
56

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
regulations have been strong, but quite late in coming. Moreover, they do not ensure that
the federal banking agencies will remain committed to consumer protection.
We do not propose a new regulatory agency because we seek more regulation, but
because we seek better regulation. The very existence of an agency devoted to consumer
protection in financial services will be a strong incentive for institutions to develop strong
cultures of consumer protection. The core of such an agency can be assembled
reasonably quickly from discrete operations of other agencies. Most rule writing
authority is concentrated in a single division of the Federal Reserve, and three of the four
federal banking agencies have mostly or entirely separated consumer compliance
supervision from prudential supervision. Combining staff from different agencies is not
simple, to be sure, but it will bring significant benefits for responsible consumers and
institutions, as well as for the market for consumer financial services and products.
1. We propose to create a single primary federal consumer protection
supervisor to protect consumers of credit, savings, payment, and other
consumer financial products and services, and to regulate providers of such
products and services.
Creating a single federal agency (the CFPA) with supervisory, examination, and
enforcement authority for protecting consumers would better promote accountability and
help prevent regulatory arbitrage. A federally supervised institution would no longer be
able to choose its supervisor based on any consideration of real or perceived differences
in agencies’ approaches to consumer protection supervision and enforcement.
The CFPA should also have the ability to act comprehensively to address emerging
consumer protection concerns. For example, under the current fragmented structure, the
federal banking agencies took until December 2005 to propose, and then until June 2007
to finalize, supervisory guidance on consumer protection concerns about subprime and
nontraditional mortgages; the worst of these mortgages were originated in 2005 and
2006. A single agency, such as the CFPA, could have acted much more quickly and
potentially saved many more consumers, communities, and institutions from significant
losses.
2. The CFPA should have broad jurisdiction to protect consumers in
consumer financial products and services such as credit, savings, and
payment products.
We propose that the CFPA’s jurisdiction should cover consumer financial services and
products such as credit, savings and payment products and related services, as well as the
institutions that issue, provide, or service these products and provide services to the
entities that provide the financial products. The mission of the CFPA would be to help
ensure that:
x

consumers have the information they need to make responsible financial
decisions;

x

consumers are protected from abuse, unfairness, deception, or discrimination;
57

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
x

consumer financial services markets operate fairly and efficiently with ample
room for sustainable growth and innovation; and

x

traditionally underserved consumers and communities have access to lending,
investment and financial services.
3. The CFPA should be an independent agency with stable and robust
funding.

The CFPA should be structured to promote its independence and accountability. The
CFPA will have a Director and a Board. The Board should represent a diverse set of
viewpoints and experiences. At least one seat on the Board should be reserved for the
head of a prudential regulator.
The CFPA should have a stable funding stream, which could come in part from fees
assessed on entities and transactions across the financial sector, including bank and nonbank institutions and other providers of covered products and services. We look forward
to working with Congress to create an agency that is strong, robust, and accountable.
The CFPA should be allowed to appoint and compensate officers and professional,
financial and technical staff on terms commensurate with those currently used by other
independent financial regulatory agencies.
4. The CFPA should have sole rule-making authority for consumer financial
protection statutes, as well as the ability to fill gaps through rule-making.
The CFPA should have sole authority to promulgate and interpret regulations under
existing consumer financial services and fair lending statutes, such as the Truth in
Lending Act (TILA), Home Ownership and Equity Protection Act (HOEPA), Real Estate
Settlement and Procedures Act (RESPA), Community Reinvestment Act (CRA), Equal
Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA), and Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA), and the
Fair Debt Collection Practices Act (FDCPA). The CFPA should be given similar
rulemaking authority under any future consumer protection laws addressing the consumer
credit, savings, collection, or payment markets.
These laws generally contain broad grants of authority to adopt and enforce rules. But
questionable practices may arise in the gaps between these laws or just beyond their
boundaries. To promote consistent protection, we propose to vest in the CFPA broad
authority to adopt tailored protections – such as disclosures or restrictions on contract
terms or sales practices – against unfairness, abuse, or deception, subject to the notice and
comment procedures of the Administrative Procedure Act. These protections would
apply to any entity that engages in providing a covered financial product or service,
including intermediaries such as mortgage brokers, as well as entities that provide
services related to consumer debt, such as debt collectors and debt buyers. We also
propose that the CFPA should have authority to craft appropriate exemptions from its
regulations.
Many of the existing consumer protection statutes contain private rights of action. We do
not propose disturbing these longstanding arrangements. In some cases we may seek
legislation to increase statutory damages.
58

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Various measures would help ensure that the CFPA’s rulemaking reflects an appropriate
and balanced array of considerations. Promoting access to financial services is a core
part of the CFPA’s mission. Therefore, our proposed legislation requires the CFPA to
consider the costs to consumers of existing or new regulations, including any potential
reduction in consumers’ access to financial services, as well as the benefits. It also
requires the CFPA to review regulations periodically to assess whether they should be
strengthened, adjusted, or scaled back. The CFPA would be required to consult with
other federal regulators to promote consistency with prudential, market, and systemic
objectives. Our proposal to allocate one of the CFPA’s five board seats to a prudential
regulator would facilitate appropriate coordination.
5. The CFPA should have supervisory and enforcement authority and
jurisdiction over all persons covered by the statutes that it implements,
including both insured depositories and the range of other firms not
previously subject to comprehensive federal supervision, and it should work
with the Department of Justice to enforce the statutes under its jurisdiction
in federal court.
We propose that the CFPA have supervisory, examination, and enforcement authority
over all entities subject to its regulations, including regulations implementing consumer
protection, fair lending, and community reinvestment laws, as well as entities subject to
selected statutes for which existing rule-writing authority does not exist or is limited (e.g.,
Fair Housing Act to the extent it covers mortgages, the Credit Repair Organization Act,
the Fair Debt Collection Practices Act, and provisions of the Fair Credit Reporting Act).
The CFPA should assume from the federal prudential regulators all responsibilities for
supervising banking institutions for compliance with consumer regulations, whether
federally chartered or state chartered and supervised by a federal banking regulator. The
CFPA’s jurisdiction should extend to bank affiliates that are not currently supervised by a
federal regulator. The CFPA should also be required to notify prudential regulators of
major matters and share confidential examination reports with them. These agencies, in
turn, should be required to refer potential compliance matters to the CFPA and should be
authorized to take action if the CFPA fails to act; the same should hold for state
supervisors of state-chartered institutions.
The Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) is unique among the panoply of consumer
protection and fair lending laws. The CFPA should maintain a group of examiners
specially trained and certified in community development to conduct CRA examinations
of larger institutions.
The CFPA should also have supervisory and enforcement authority over nonbanking
institutions, although the states should be the first line of defense. In its discretion, the
CFPA should exercise the full range of supervisory authorities over nonbanking
institutions within its jurisdiction, including supervision, information collection and onsite examination. The CFPA should also have the full range of enforcement powers over
such institutions, including subpoena authority for documents and testimony, with
capacity to compel production by court order. If a state enforcement agency brings an
action against an institution within the CFPA’s jurisdiction for a violation of one of the
59

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
CFPA’s regulations, the CFPA should have the ability to intervene in the action for all
purposes, including appeals. The CFPA, moreover, should also be able to request that the
U.S. Attorney General bring any action necessary to enforce its subpoena authority or to
bring any other enforcement action on its behalf in the appropriate court.
The CFPA should be able to promote compliance by publishing supervisory guidance
indicating how it intends to administer the laws it implements. The CFPA should also be
able to use other creative tools to promote compliance, such as publishing best and worst
practices based on surveys, mystery shopping, and information collected from
supervision and investigations.
With respect to enforcement, the CFPA will cooperate closely with the Department of
Justice. As in other areas of the law, the Department of Justice will also have
independent authority to enforce violations of the statutes administered by the CFPA. In
addition, the CFPA shall be authorized to share data with the Department of Justice to
support enforcement of statutes administered by the CFPA as well as other statutes, such
as civil rights statutes, enforced by the Department.
6. The CFPA should pursue measures to promote effective regulation,
including conducting periodic reviews of regulations, an outside advisory
council, and coordination with the Council.
To promote accountability, the CFPA should be required to complete a regulatory study
of each newly enacted regulation at least every three years after the effective date. The
study will assess the effectiveness of the enacted regulation in meeting its stated goals,
and will allow for public comment on recommendations for expanding, modifying, or
eliminating the regulation. For example, these reviews should include mandatory
assessments of consumers’ ability to understand and use current disclosures and the
adequacy of these disclosures to communicate key information that consumers need
about the costs and risks of new products. The CFPA should also review existing
regulations (such as those implementing TILA), as time and priorities allow, for the same
purpose.
Second, we propose the establishment of an outside advisory panel, akin to the Federal
Reserve’s Consumer Advisory Council, to promote the CFPA’s accountability and
provide useful information on emerging industry practices. Members of this Council
should have deep experience in financial services and community development and be
selected to promote a diversity of views on the Council.
Third, the CFPA should work with other agencies through the Council to promote
consistent treatment of similar products and to help ensure that no product goes
unregulated merely because of uncertainty over jurisdiction. Through this Council, the
CFPA should coordinate its efforts with the SEC, the CFTC, and other state and federal
regulators to promote consistent, gap-free coverage of consumer and investor products
and services. These agencies will report to Congress on their work and will be
responsible for joint initiatives where appropriate.
7. The CFPA’s strong rules would serve as a floor, not a ceiling. The states
should have the ability to adopt and enforce stricter laws for institutions of
60

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation

Today, states typically retain authority under federal consumer protection and fair lending
statutes to adopt stricter laws, so long as they do not conflict with federal law. We do not
propose disturbing these long-standing arrangements. Federal rules promulgated by the
CFPA under a pre-existing statute or its own organic rulemaking authority should
override weaker state laws, but states should be free to adopt stricter laws. In addition,
we propose that states should have concurrent authority to enforce regulations of the
CFPA.
We propose that federally chartered institutions be subject to nondiscriminatory state
consumer protection and civil rights laws to the same extent as other financial
institutions. This would restore a fairer and more measured approach to the roles of the
states with respect to federally chartered institutions. We also propose that states should
be able to enforce these laws, as well as regulations of the CFPA, with respect to
federally chartered institutions, subject to appropriate arrangements with prudential
supervisors. With respect to state banks supervised by a federal prudential regulator, the
CFPA will be the primary consumer compliance supervisor at the federal level.
8. The CFPA should coordinate enforcement efforts with the states.
Maintaining consistency among fifty states’ supervisory and enforcement efforts will
always remain a significant challenge, but the CFPA’s concurrent supervisory and
enforcement powers should place it in a position to help. The CFPA should assume
responsibility for federal efforts to help the states unify and strengthen standards for
registering and improving the quality of providers and intermediaries.
For example, the CFPA should administer the SAFE Act, under which it would set
standards for registering and licensing any type of institution that originates mortgages.
At present, the authority to administer the act is splintered among many federal agencies.
Among other things, the CFPA should be authorized to set higher minimum net worth
requirements for originators so that they will have resources to stand behind the strong
representations and warranties we are proposing they be required to make.
We further propose that the CFPA be authorized to establish or facilitate registration and
licensing regimes for other financial service providers and intermediaries, such as debt
collectors, debt counselors or mortgage modification outfits. The CFPA and state
enforcement agencies should be able to use registration systems to help weed out bad
actors wherever they may operate.
Insufficient resources were devoted to enforcement during the mortgage boom. Periods
of rapid market growth are precisely the time when government needs to be more
vigilant. Resources have been increased significantly to address the inevitable fraudulent
activities that are associated with the fallout of the mortgage crisis. When financial
services markets begin to grow again, it is critical that funding at the federal and state
levels be adequate to meet the challenge.

61

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
9. The CFPA should have a wide variety of tools to enable it to perform its
functions effectively.
Research and Data. Empirical evidence is critical to a well designed regulatory
structure. The CFPA should have authority to collect information through the
supervisory process as well as through specific data collection statutes, such as the Home
Mortgage Disclosure Act. The CFPA should use this information to improve regulations,
promote compliance, and encourage community development. The CFPA should also
establish a robust research and statistics department to conduct and promote research
across the full range of consumer protection, fair lending, and community development
finance issues. The CFPA would need the resources to acquire proprietary databases and
collect and process its own data.
Complaints. Complaint data are an important barometer of consumer protection concerns
and must be continuously communicated to the persons responsible for consumer
regulation, enforcement, and supervision. Currently, however, many consumers do not
know where to file a complaint about financial services because of the balkanized
regulatory structure. The CFPA should have responsibility for collecting and tracking
complaints about consumer financial services and facilitating complaint resolution with
respect to federally-supervised institutions. Other federal supervisory agencies should
refer any complaints they receive on consumer issues to the CFPA; complaint data should
be shared across agencies. The states should retain primary responsibility for tracking
and facilitating resolution of complaints against other institutions, and the CFPA should
seek to coordinate exchanges of complaint data with state regulators.
Financial education. The CFPA should play a leading role in efforts to educate
consumers about financial matters, to improve their ability to manage their own financial
affairs, and to make their own judgments about the appropriateness of certain financial
products. Additionally, the CFPA should review and streamline existing financial
literacy and education initiatives government-wide.
Community Affairs. The CFPA’s community affairs function should promote community
development investment and fair and impartial access to credit. It should engage in a
wide variety of activities to help financial institutions, community-based organizations,
government entities, and the public understand and address financial services issues that
affect low and middle-income people across various geographic regions.
10. To improve incentives for compliance, the CFPA should have authority to
restrict or ban mandatory arbitration clauses.
Many consumers do not know that they often waive their rights to trial when signing
form contracts in taking out a loan, and that a private party dependent on large firms for
their business will decide the case without offering the right to appeal or a public review
of decisions. The CFPA should be directed to gather information and study mandatory
arbitration clauses in consumer financial services and products contracts to determine to
what extent, and in what contexts, they promote fair adjudication and effective redress. If
the CFPA determines that mandatory arbitration fails to achieve these goals, it should be
62

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
required to establish conditions for fair arbitration, or, if necessary, to ban mandatory
arbitration clauses in particular contexts, such as mortgage loans.
11. The Federal Trade Commission should be given better tools to protect
consumers.
The Federal Trade Commission (FTC) plays a critical role in protecting consumers across
the full range of products and services. While the FTC’s primary authority for financial
product and services protections should be transferred to the CFPA, the FTC should
retain backup authority with the CFPA for the statutes for which the FTC currently has
jurisdiction. We propose that the FTC should retain authority for dealing with fraud in
the financial marketplace, including the sale of services like advance fee loans, credit
repair, debt negotiation, and foreclosure rescue/loan modification fraud, but also provide
such authority to the CFPA.
The FTC should also remain the lead federal consumer protection agency on matters of
data security, with front-end privacy protection on financial issues moved to the CFPA.
We also propose to give the FTC the tools and human, financial, and technical resources
it needs to do its job effectively by substantially increasing its capacity to protect
consumers in all areas of commerce that remain under its authority. For example, the
FTC should be authorized to conduct rulemakings for unfair and deceptive practices
under standard notice and comment procedures, and to obtain civil penalties for unfair
and deceptive practices.
B. Reform Consumer Protection
We propose a series of recommendations for legislation, regulations, and administrative
measures by the CFPA to reform consumer protection based on principles of
transparency, simplicity, fairness, accountability, and access for all.
1. Transparency. We propose a new proactive approach to disclosure. The
CFPA will be authorized to require that all disclosures and other
communications with consumers be reasonable: balanced in their
presentation of benefits, and clear and conspicuous in their identification of
costs, penalties, and risks.
We propose the following initiatives to improve the transparency of consumer product
and service disclosures.
Make all mandatory disclosure forms clear, simple, and concise, and test them regularly.
Mandatory disclosure forms should be clear, simple, and concise. This means the CFPA
should make judgments about which risks and costs should be highlighted and which
need not be. Consumers should verify their ability to understand and use disclosure
forms with qualitative and statistical tests.
A regulator is typically limited to testing disclosures in a “laboratory” environment. A
product provider, however, has the capacity to test disclosures in the field, which can
produce more robust and relevant results. For example, a credit card provider can try two
different methods to disclose the same product risk and determine which was more
63

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
effective by surveying consumers and evaluating their behaviors. We propose that the
CFPA should be authorized to establish standards and procedures, including appropriate
immunity from liability, for providers to conduct field tests of disclosures.
In particular, mortgage disclosures are due for significant reform. The Department of
Housing and Urban Development (HUD) and the Federal Reserve have made progress in
this regard. HUD, for example, recently developed new RESPA disclosures, and the
Federal Reserve is testing new TILA disclosures. The CFPA, having authority over both
TILA and RESPA, should have the responsibility to develop and test a single, integrated
federal mortgage disclosure that provides consumers with the simplicity they deserve,
and reduces regulatory burdens on providers. This provision should not, however, delay
or affect current efforts to achieve a single federal disclosure for TILA and RESPA.
Require that disclosures and other communications with consumers be reasonable.
Disclosure mandates for consumer credit and other financial products are typically very
technical and detailed. This approach lets the regulator determine which information
must be emphasized and helps ensure that disclosures are standard and comparable.
Flaws in this approach, however, were made clear by the spread of new and complex
credit card plans and mortgages that preceded the credit crisis. The growth in the types
of risks stemming from these products far outpaced the ability of disclosure regulations to
keep up. Indeed, a regulator must take time to update mandatory disclosures because of
the need for consumer testing and public input, and it is unduly burdensome to require the
entire industry to update its disclosures too frequently. In addition to detailed rules, we
propose a principles-based approach to disclosure.
We propose a regime strict enough to keep disclosures standard throughout the
marketplace, yet flexible enough to adapt to new products. Our proposed legislation
authorizes the CFPA to impose a duty on providers and intermediaries to require that
communications with the consumer are reasonable, not merely technically compliant and
non-deceptive.
Reasonableness includes balance in the presentation of risks and benefits, as well as
clarity and conspicuousness in the description of significant product costs and risks. This
is a higher standard than merely refraining from deception. Moreover, reasonableness
does not mean a litany of every conceivable risk, which effectively obscures significant
risks. It means identifying conspicuously the more significant risks. It means providing
consumers with disclosures that help them to understand the consequences of their
financial decisions.
The CFPA should be authorized to apply the duty of reasonableness to communications
with or to the consumer, as appropriate, including marketing materials and solicitations.
The CFPA should determine the appropriate scope of this duty. A provider or
intermediary should be subject to administrative action, but not civil liability, if its
communications violate this duty.
The CFPA also should be authorized to apply the duty of reasonableness to mandatory
disclosures. The regulator typically sets requirements for disclosure for mainstream
products and services. If a new product emerges that the regulator did not anticipate, the
64

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
mandatory disclosure may not adequately disclose a major risk of the product. A
deficient but compliant mandatory disclosure may lull the consumer into a false sense of
security, undermining the very purpose of a disclosure mandate. It is not fair or efficient
to make the consumer bear the cost of disclosures that are out of date. Nor is it
reasonable to expect that the regulator will have the capacity to update disclosures on a
real-time basis. Therefore, we propose that providers should share with the regulator the
burden of updating mandatory disclosures when they introduce new products.
The CFPA should be authorized to implement a process under which a provider, acting
reasonably and in good faith, could obtain the equivalent of a “no action” letter for
disclosure and other communications for a new product. For example, the CFPA could
adopt a procedure under which a provider petitions the CFPA for a determination that its
product’s risks were adequately disclosed by the mandatory model disclosure or
marketing materials. The CFPA could approve use of the mandatory model or marketing
materials, or provide a waiver, admissible in court to defend against a claim, for varying
the model disclosure. As a further example, if the CFPA failed to respond in a timely
fashion, the provider could proceed to market without fear of administrative sanction on
that basis. The provider could potentially shorten the mandatory waiting period if it
submitted empirical evidence, according to prescribed standards, that its marketing
materials and the mandatory disclosure adequately disclosed relevant risks. The CFPA
should have authority to adapt and adjust its standards and procedures to seek to
maximize the benefits of product innovation while minimizing the costs.
Harness technology to make disclosures more dynamic and relevant to the individual
consumer.
Disclosure rules today assume disclosures are on paper and follow a prescribed content,
format, and timing; the consumer has no ability to adapt content, timing, or format to her
needs. The CFPA should harness technology to make disclosures more dynamic and
adaptable to the needs of the individual consumer. New technology can be costly, and
the CFPA should consider those costs, but it should also consider that spinoff benefits
from new technology can be hard to quantify and could be substantial.
Disclosures should show consumers the consequences of their financial decisions. For
example, the recently enacted Credit CARD Act of 2009 requires issuers to show the
total cost and time for repayment if a consumer paid only the minimum due each month,
and it further requires issuers to show the amount a consumer would have to pay in order
to pay off the balance in three years. Technology enhances the ability to tailor this
disclosure, and an internet calculator would permit the consumer to select a different
period, or input a payment amount above the minimum. Such calculators are common on
the internet. The CFPA should mandate a calculator disclosure in circumstances where
the CFPA determines the benefits to consumers outweigh the costs. It should also
mandate or encourage calculator disclosures for mortgages to assist with comparison
shopping. For example, a calculator that shows the costs of a mortgage based on the
consumer’s expectations for how long she will stay in the home may reveal a more
significant difference between two products than appears on standard paper disclosures.
65

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Technology can also help consumers better manage their use of credit by providing
information and options at the most relevant times to them. For example, the CFPA
should have authority, after considering the costs and benefits of such a measure, to
require issuers to warn consumers who use a debit card at the point of sale or ATM
machines that doing so would overdraft their account. The CFPA should also promote
adoption of innovations in point-of-sale technology, such as allowing consumers who use
a credit card to choose a payment plan for the purchase.
2. Simplicity. We propose that the regulator be authorized to define standards
for “plain vanilla” products that are simpler and have straightforward
pricing. The CFPA should be authorized to require all providers and
intermediaries to offer these products prominently, alongside whatever other
lawful products they choose to offer.
Even if disclosures are fully tested and all communications are properly balanced,
product complexity itself can lead consumers to make costly errors. A careful regulatory
approach can tilt the scales in favor of simpler, less risky products while preserving
choice and innovation.
“Plain vanilla” mortgages, whether they have fixed or adjustable interest rates, should be
easy for consumers to understand. They should not include prepayment penalties and
should be underwritten to fully document income, collect escrow for taxes and insurance,
and have predictable payments. These products are also easy to compare because they
can be differentiated by a single, simple characteristic, the interest rate. We propose that
the government do more to promote “plain vanilla” products. The CFPA should be
authorized to define standards for such products and require firms to offer them alongside
whatever other lawful products a firm chooses to offer.
The Federal Reserve Board issued final regulations last year, which take effect in
October, that impose extra protections and higher penalties on “alternative” or “higher
cost” loans, that is, mortgages that are not “plain vanilla”. The CFPA should assume
responsibility for this regulation. The CFPA should consider whether to add other types
of mortgages to the class that receive additional scrutiny and higher penalties,
considering the complexity of the mortgage itself, such as negative amortization features,
and the performance of the loan type. It should leave in the class that doesn’t have these
extra protections only products that meet a plain vanilla test. The CFPA should use
survey methods to determine whether consumers who obtained the product type in the
marketplace demonstrated awareness and understanding of the product and its risks, such
as the risk of payment shock and of the balance exceeding the value of the house. The
CFPA should also consider access to credit and costs to consumers of stricter regulations.
The CFPA should be authorized to use a variety of measures to help ensure alternative
mortgages were obtained only by consumers who understood the risks and could manage
them. For example, the CFPA could impose a strong warning label on all alternative
products; require providers to have applicants fill out financial experience questionnaires;
or require providers to obtain the applicant’s written “opt-in” to such products.
Originators and purchasers of “plain vanilla” mortgages should enjoy a strong
presumption that the products are suitable and affordable for the borrower. Originators
66

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
and purchasers of alternative products should not enjoy such a presumption, and they
should be subject to significantly higher penalties for violations.
3. Fairness. Where efforts to improve transparency and simplicity prove
inadequate to prevent unfair treatment and abuse, we propose that the
CFPA be authorized to place tailored restrictions on product terms and
provider practices, if the benefits outweigh the costs. Moreover, we propose
to authorize the CFPA to impose appropriate duties of care on financial
intermediaries.
In recent years, the principle that product and service providers should treat consumers
fairly has been too often honored only in the breach. The mortgage and credit card
markets have demonstrated convincingly the need for rules that require fair contracts and
practices and remove or reduce perverse and hidden incentives to take advantage of
consumers.
The excessive complexity of many mortgage products created an opportunity to take
advantage of consumers’ lack of awareness and understanding of product risks.
Mortgage originators received direct incentives to exploit this opportunity. They were
paid for loan volume rather than loan performance and paid more for loans with higher
interest rates and riskier terms. As noted in Section II, the securitization model, without
appropriate regulation or transparency, exacerbated these problems by eroding the
capacity and incentives for originators, securitizers, and investors to ensure that loans
were viable.
In the credit card market, the opacity of increasingly complicated products led major card
issuers to migrate almost uniformly to unfavorable methods for assessing fees and
interest that could easily trap a responsible consumer in debt. Competition did not force
these methods out, because consumers were not aware of them or could not understand
them, and issuers did not find it profitable to offer contract terms that were transparent to
consumers. For a variety of reasons, regulators have not brought enforcement actions
under existing law.
We propose the following measures to promote fair treatment of consumers:
Give the CFPA authority to regulate unfair, deceptive, or abusive acts or practices.
As mortgages and credit cards illustrate, even seemingly “simple” financial products
remain complicated to large numbers of Americans. As a result, in addition to
meaningful disclosure, there must also be standards for appropriate business conduct and
regulations that help ensure providers do not have undue incentives to undermine those
standards. Accordingly, the Federal Reserve recently responded to unfair mortgage
practices with regulations imposing affordability requirements on subprime loans, and the
House recently passed a strong, comprehensive predatory lending bill. Congress,
moreover, recently improved credit card contract regulation by passing the Credit CARD
Act of 2009.
As described above, the CFPA should assume the statutory authorities to regulate unfair,
deceptive, and abusive acts or practices for all credit, savings, and payment products.
67

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The legal standards for these authorities are generally well-established and would require
the CFPA to develop a record and weigh costs and benefits before exercising these
authorities. The mortgage and credit card cases demonstrate clearly that properly tailored
restrictions not only benefit individual consumers, but also institutions and markets by
increasing consumer confidence and promoting more effective competition.
The CFPA should also have authority to address overly complex financial contracts. For
example, the CFPA should be authorized to consider whether mortgage regulations
require strengthening. The CFPA could determine that prepayment penalties should be
banned for certain types of products, such as subprime or nontraditional mortgages, or for
all products, because the penalties make loans too complex for the least sophisticated
consumers or those least able to shop effectively. The CFPA could adopt a “life of loan”
approach to regulating mortgages that provides a consumer adequate protections through
servicing and loss mitigation stages. The CFPA should also be authorized to ban ofteninvisible side payments to mortgage originators – so called yield spread premiums or
overages – that are tied to the borrower receiving worse terms than she qualifies for, if
the CFPA finds that disclosure is not an adequate remedy. These payments incentivize
originators to steer consumers to higher-priced or inappropriate mortgages. In addition,
the CFPA could consider requiring that originators receive a portion of their
compensation over time, contingent on loan performance, rather than in a lump sum at
origination.
Give the CFPA authority to impose empirically justified and appropriately tailored duties
of care on financial intermediaries.
Impartial advice represents one of the most important financial services consumers can
receive. Currently, debt counselors advise distressed and vulnerable borrowers on how to
manage and reduce their debts. Mortgage brokers often advertise their trustworthiness as
advisors on difficult mortgage decisions. When these intermediaries accept side
payments from product providers, they can compromise their ability to be impartial.
Consumers, however, may retain faith that the intermediary is working for them and
placing their interests above his or her own, even if the conflict of interest is disclosed.
Accordingly, in some cases consumers may reasonably but mistakenly rely on advice
from conflicted intermediaries. It is unfair for intermediaries to take advantage of that
trust.
To address this problem, we propose granting the CFPA authority to impose carefully
crafted duties of care on financial intermediaries. For example, the CFPA could impose a
duty of care to counteract an intermediary’s patent conflict of interest, or to align an
intermediary’s conduct with consumers’ reasonable expectations as demonstrated by
empirical evidence. The CFPA could also consider imposing on originators a
requirement to disclose material information such as the consumer’s likely ability to
qualify for a lower interest rate based on her risk profile. In that regard, the CFPA could
impose on mortgage brokers a duty of best execution with respect to available mortgage
loans and a duty to determine affordability for borrowers.

68

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The CFPA should apply consistent regulation to similar products.
Fairness, effective competition, and efficient markets require consistent regulatory
treatment for similar products. For example, similar disclosure treatment for similar
products enables consumers to make informed choices based on a full appreciation of the
nature and risks of the product and enables providers to compete fairly and vigorously.
Ensuring consistency will require judgment on the part of the CFPA because products
often have hybrid features and could fall under different statutes that call for different
treatment. The CFPA should assess consumers’ understanding and perception of such
products. In some cases, it may be appropriate to align the regulation of the products
more closely with consumers’ perceptions. In other cases, however, consumers’
perceptions may reflect a failure of existing regulations to properly inform consumers
about a product. In that case, regulations should be revised to frame the presentation of
the product more appropriately.
One example is overdraft protection plans. These are a form of consumer credit, and
consumers often use them as substitutes for other forms of credit such as payday loans,
credit card cash advances, and traditional overdraft lines of credit. However, overdraft
protection plans have not been regulated as credit, and, as a result, consumers may not
overtly think of the plans as credit. Consumers may not, therefore, take the same care in
their use of overdrafts that they take with other, more overt credit products. The CFPA
would be authorized by existing statutes to regulate overdraft protection more like a
credit product, with Truth in Lending disclosures as appropriate. The CFPA could also
prohibit charging for overdraft coverage under a plan unless the consumer has “opted in”
to the plan, just as the Credit CARD Act prohibits over-the-limit fees unless the
consumer has “opted in” to over-the-limit coverage. It could also require affirmative
consent at point of sale with debit transactions or at an ATM machine before collecting
an “overdraft fee”.
4. Access. The Agency should enforce fair lending laws and the Community
Reinvestment Act and otherwise seek to ensure that underserved consumers
and communities have access to prudent financial services, lending, and
investment.
A critical part of the CFPA’s mission should be to promote access to financial services,
especially for households and communities that traditionally have had limited access.
This focus will also help ensure that the CFPA fully internalizes the value of preserving
access to financial services and weighs that value against other values when it considers
new consumer protection regulations.
Rigorous application of the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) should be a core
function of the CFPA. Some have attempted to blame the subprime meltdown and
financial crisis on the CRA and have argued that the CRA must be weakened in order to
restore financial stability. These claims and arguments are without any logical or
evidentiary basis. It is not tenable that the CRA could suddenly have caused an explosion
in bad subprime loans more than 25 years after its enactment. In fact, enforcement of
CRA was weakened during the boom and the worst abuses were made by firms not
covered by CRA. Moreover, the Federal Reserve has reported that only six percent of all
69

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
the higher-priced loans were extended by the CRA-covered lenders to lower income
borrowers or neighborhoods in the local areas that are the focus of CRA evaluations.
The appropriate response to the crisis is not to weaken the CRA; it is rather to promote
robust application of the CRA so that low-income households and communities have
access to responsible financial services that truly meet their needs. To that end, we
propose that the CFPA should have sole authority to evaluate institutions under the CRA.
While the prudential regulators should have the authority to decide applications for
institutions to merge, the CFPA should be responsible for determining the institution’s
record of meeting the lending, investment, and services needs of its community under the
CRA, which would be part of the merger application.
The CFPA should also vigorously enforce fair lending laws to promote access to credit.
Furthermore, the CFPA should maintain a fair lending unit with attorneys, compliance
specialists, economists, and statisticians. The CFPA should have primary fair lending
jurisdiction over federally supervised institutions and concurrent authority with the states
over other institutions. Its comprehensive jurisdiction should enable it to develop a
holistic, integrated approach to fair lending that targets resources to the areas of greatest
risk for discrimination.
To promote fair lending enforcement, as well as community investment objectives, the
CFPA should have authority to collect data on mortgage and small business lending.
Critical new fields should be added to HMDA data such as a universal loan identifier that
permits tying HMDA data to property databases and proprietary loan performance
databases, a flag for loans originated by mortgage brokers, information about the type of
interest rate (e.g., fixed vs. variable), and other fields that the mortgage crisis has shown
to be of critical importance.
C. Strengthen the framework for investor protection by focusing on principles
of transparency, fairness, and accountability
In the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), we already have an experienced
federal supervisor with comprehensive responsibilities for protecting investors against
fraud and abuse. In the wake of the scandals associated with the current financial crisis,
including Ponzi schemes such as the Madoff affair, the SEC has already begun to
strengthen and streamline its enforcement process and to expand resources for
enforcement in the FY2010 budget. It has streamlined the process of obtaining formal
orders that grant the staff subpoena power and begun a review of its technology and
processes to assess risk and manage leads for potential fraud and abuse. The SEC is also
using its existing authority to make improvements in investor protections.
We propose the following measures to modernize the financial regulatory structure and
improve the SEC’s ability to protect investors, focusing on principles of transparency,
fairness, and accountability.
1. The SEC should be given expanded authority to promote transparency in
disclosures to investors.
To promote transparency, we propose revisions in the federal securities laws to enable the
SEC to improve the timing and quality of disclosures to investors.
70

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The SEC should be authorized to require that certain disclosures (including a summary
prospectus) be provided to investors at or before the point of sale, if it finds that such
disclosures would improve investor understanding of the particular financial products,
and their costs and risks. Currently, most prospectuses (including the mutual fund
summary prospectus) are delivered with the confirmation of sale, after the sale has taken
place. Without slowing the pace of transactions in modern capital markets, the SEC
should require that adequate information is given to investor to make informed
investment decisions.
The SEC can better evaluate the effectiveness of investor disclosures if it can
meaningfully engage in consumer testing of those disclosures. The SEC should be better
enabled to engage in field testing, consumer outreach and testing of disclosures to
individual investors, including by providing budgetary support for those activities.
2. The SEC should be given new tools to promote fair treatment of investors.
We propose the following initiatives to empower the SEC to increase fairness for
investors:
Establish a fiduciary duty for broker-dealers offering investment advice and harmonize
the regulation of investment advisers and broker-dealers.
Retail investors face a large array of investment products and often turn to financial
intermediaries – whether investment advisors or brokers-dealers – to help them manage
their investments. However, investment advisers and broker-dealers are regulated under
different statutory and regulatory frameworks, even though the services they provide
often are virtually identical from a retail investor’s perspective.
Retail investors are often confused about the differences between investment advisers and
broker-dealers. Meanwhile, the distinction is no longer meaningful between a
disinterested investment advisor and a broker who acts as an agent for an investor; the
current laws and regulations are based on antiquated distinctions between the two types
of financial professionals that date back to the early 20th century. Brokers are allowed to
give “incidental advice” in the course of their business, and yet retail investors rely on a
trusted relationship that is often not matched by the legal responsibility of the securities
broker. In general, a broker-dealer’s relationship with a customer is not legally a
fiduciary relationship, while an investment adviser is legally its customer’s fiduciary.
From the vantage point of the retail customer, however, an investment adviser and a
broker-dealer providing “incidental advice” appear in all respects identical. In the retail
context, the legal distinction between the two is no longer meaningful. Retail customers
repose the same degree of trust in their brokers as they do in investment advisers, but the
legal responsibilities of the intermediaries may not be the same
The SEC should be permitted to align duties for intermediaries across financial products.
Standards of care for all broker-dealers when providing investment advice about
securities to retail investors should be raised to the fiduciary standard to align the legal
framework with investment advisers. In addition, the SEC should be empowered to
examine and ban forms of compensation that encourage intermediaries to put investors
71

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
into products that are profitable to the intermediary, but are not in the investors’ best
interest.
New legislation should bolster investor protections and bring important consistency to the
regulation of these two types of financial professionals by:
x

requiring that broker-dealers who provide investment advice about securities to
investors have the same fiduciary obligations as registered investment advisers;

x

providing simple and clear disclosure to investors regarding the scope of the terms
of their relationships with investment professionals; and

x

prohibiting certain conflict of interests and sales practices that are contrary to the
interests of investors.

The SEC should study the use of mandatory arbitration clauses in investor contracts.
Broker-dealers generally require their customers to contract at account opening to
arbitrate all disputes. Although arbitration may be a reasonable option for many
consumers to accept after a dispute arises, mandating a particular venue and up-front
method of adjudicating disputes – and eliminating access to courts – may unjustifiably
undermine investor interests. We recommend legislation that would give the SEC clear
authority to prohibit mandatory arbitration clauses in broker-dealer and investment
advisory accounts with retail customers. The legislation should also provide that, before
using such authority, the SEC would need to conduct a study on the use of mandatory
arbitration clauses in these contracts. The study shall consider whether investors are
harmed by being unable to obtain effective redress of legitimate grievances, as well as
whether changes to arbitration are appropriate.
3. Financial firms and public companies should be accountable to their clients
and investors.
Expand protections for whistleblowers.
The SEC should gain the authority to establish a fund to pay whistleblowers for
information that leads to enforcement actions resulting in significant financial awards.
Currently, the SEC has the authority to compensate sources in insider trading cases; that
authority should be extended to compensate whistleblowers that bring well-documented
evidence of fraudulent activity. We support the creation of this fund using monies that
the SEC collects from enforcement actions that are not otherwise distributed to investors.
Expand sanctions available in enforcement actions and harmonize liability standards.
Improved sanctions would better enable the SEC to enforce the federal securities laws.
We support the SEC in pursuing authority to impose collateral bars against regulated
persons across all aspects of the industry rather than in a specific segment of the industry.
The interrelationship among the securities activities under the SEC’s jurisdiction, the
similar grounds for exclusion from each, and the SEC’s overarching responsibility to
regulate these activities support the imposition of collateral bars.

72

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The SEC also proposes amending the federal securities laws to provide a single explicit
standard for primary liability to replace various circuits’ formulations of different “tests”
for primary liability.
Require non-binding shareholder votes on executive compensation packages.
Public companies should be required to implement “say on pay” rules, which require
shareholder votes on executive compensation packages. While such votes are nonbinding, they provide a strong message to management and boards and serve to support a
culture of performance, transparency, and accountability in executive compensation.
Shareholders are often concerned about large corporate bonus plans in situations in which
they, as the company's owners, have experienced losses. Currently, these decisions are
often not directly reviewed by shareholders – leaving shareholders with limited rights to
voice their concerns about compensation through an advisory vote.
To facilitate greater communication between shareholders and management over
executive compensation, public companies should include on their proxies a nonbinding
shareholder vote on executive compensation. Legislation that would authorize SEC “say
on pay” rules for all public companies could help restore investor trust by promoting
increased shareholder participation and increasing accountability of board members and
corporate management. It would provide shareholders of all public U.S. companies with
the same rights that are accorded to shareholders in many other countries.
4. Under the leadership of the Financial Services Oversight Council, we
propose the establishment of a Financial Consumer Coordinating Council
and a permanent role for the SEC’s Investor Advisory Committee.
To address potential gaps in consumer and investor protection and to promote best
practices across different markets, we propose to create a coordinating council of the
heads of the SEC, Federal Trade Commission, the Department of Justice, and the
Consumer Financial Protection Agency or their designees, and other state and federal
agencies. The Coordinating Council should meet at least quarterly to identify gaps in
consumer protection across financial products and facilitate coordination of consumer
protection efforts. Our proposal will help ensure the effectiveness of the Coordinating
Council for the benefit of consumers by:
x

empowering the Council to establish mechanisms for state attorneys general,
consumer advocates, and others to make recommendations to the Council on
issues to be considered or gaps to be filled;

x

requiring the Council to report to Congress and the member agencies semiannually with recommendations for legislative and regulatory changes to improve
consumer and investor protection, and with updates on progress made on prior
recommendations; and

x

empowering the Council to sponsor studies or engage in consumer testing to
identify gaps, share information and find solutions for improving consumer
protection across a range of financial products.

73

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The SEC has recently established an Investor Advisory Committee, made up of a diverse
group of well-respected investors, to advise on the SEC’s regulatory priorities, including
issues concerning new products, trading strategies, fee structures, and the effectiveness of
disclosure. The Investor Advisory Committee should be made permanent by statute.
5. Promote retirement security for all Americans by strengthening
employment-based and private retirement plans and encouraging adequate
savings.
We propose the enactment of the “Automatic IRA” and a strengthened saver’s credit.
For many years, until the current recession, the personal saving rate in the United States
has been exceedingly low. In addition, tens of millions of U.S. households have not
placed themselves on a path to become financially prepared for retirement. In order to
address this problem, the President has proposed two innovative initiatives in his 2010
Budget: (1) introducing an “Automatic IRA” (with opt-out) for employees whose
employers do not offer a plan; and (2) increasing tax incentives for retirement savings for
families that earn less than $65,000 by modifying the “saver’s credit” and making it
refundable. Together these initiatives will expand plan coverage, combat inertia, and
increase incentives to save.
Under the “Automatic IRA” plan, employers in business for at least two years that have
10 or more employees would be required to offer an automatic IRA option (with opt-out),
under which regular payroll-deduction contributions would be made to an IRA.
Employers would not have to choose or arrange default investments. Instead, a low-cost,
standard type of default investment and a handful of standard, low-cost investment
alternatives would be prescribed by statute or regulation.
The modified saver’s credit would be fully refundable and deposited automatically in the
individual’s qualified retirement plan account or IRA. These changes make the saver’s
credit more like a matching contribution, enhancing the likelihood that the credit would
be saved. The proposal would offer a meaningful saving incentive to tens of millions of
additional households while simplifying the current complex structure of the credit and
raising the eligibility income threshold to cover millions of additional moderate-income
taxpayers.
Improve retirement security through employee-directed workplace retirement plans,
automatic IRAs and other measures.
Employee-directed workplace retirement plans (such as 401(k)s) and Automatic IRAs
should be governed by the same core principles that inform our comprehensive approach
to consumer and investor protection in the retail marketplace. Plans should be
transparent, providing information about the risks, returns, and costs of different
investment choices in terms that real people can use to make decisions. They should be
as simple as possible, designed to make savings and investment decisions easy, such as
by offering the convenience of automation. They should be fair and free from conflicts
of interest (such as those that can affect third party providers) that could harm employees.
Plan sponsors and others who provide services to the plan or to individual employees
(such as the management of employee investments) should be accountable and subject to
74

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
appropriate oversight. Finally, high-quality plans that make savings and investment easy
should be accessible to all workers.
There are a number of other critical issues in the area of retirement security that need to
be addressed. We should explore ways to encourage the use of automatic features to
increase participation and improve saving and investment behavior in 401(k) plans, and
restore more lifetime income throughout the retirement system – in defined benefit plans,
defined contribution plans, and IRAs. We should aim to reduce costs, such as investment
fees. We should investigate how to better preserve savings for retirement, reducing
“leakage” from retirement plans. Finally, we should explore means of strengthening the
defined benefit plan system.

75

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
IV. PROVIDE THE GOVERNMENT WITH THE TOOLS IT NEEDS TO MANAGE FINANCIAL
CRISES
Over the past two years, the financial system has been threatened by the failure or near
failure of some of the largest and most interconnected financial firms. Our current
system already has strong procedures and expertise for handling the failure of banks, but
when a bank holding company or other nonbank financial firm is in severe distress, there
are currently only two options: obtain outside capital or file for bankruptcy. During most
economic climates, these are suitable options that will not impact greater financial
stability.
However, in stressed conditions it may prove difficult for distressed institutions to raise
sufficient private capital. Thus, if a large, interconnected bank holding company or other
nonbank financial firm nears failure during a financial crisis, there are only two untenable
options: obtain emergency funding from the US government as in the case of AIG, or
file for bankruptcy as in the case of Lehman Brothers. Neither of these options is
acceptable for managing the resolution of the firm efficiently and effectively in a manner
that limits the systemic risk with the least cost to the taxpayer.
We propose a new authority, modeled on the existing authority of the FDIC, that should
allow the government to address the potential failure of a bank holding company or other
nonbank financial firm when the stability of the financial system is at risk.
In order to improve accountability in the use of other crisis tools, we also propose that the
Federal Reserve Board receive prior written approval from the Secretary of the Treasury
for emergency lending under its “unusual and exigent circumstances” authority.
A. Create a resolution regime for failing BHCs, Including Tier 1 FHCs
We recommend the creation of a resolution regime to avoid the disorderly
resolution of failing BHCs, including Tier 1 FHCs, if a disorderly resolution
would have serious adverse effects on the financial system or the economy. The
regime would supplement (rather than replace) and be modeled on to the
existing resolution regime for insured depository institutions under the Federal
Deposit Insurance Act.
The federal government’s responses to the impending bankruptcy of Bear Stearns,
Lehman Brothers, and AIG were complicated by the lack of a statutory framework for
avoiding the disorderly failure of nonbank financial firms, including affiliates of banks or
other insured depository institutions. In the absence of such a framework, the
government’s only avenue to avoid the disorderly failures of Bear Stearns and AIG was
the use of the Federal Reserve’s lending authority. And this mechanism was insufficient
to prevent the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, an event which served to demonstrate
how disruptive the disorderly failure of a nonbank financial firm can be to the financial
system and the economy.
For these reasons, we propose the creation of a resolution regime to allow for the orderly
resolution of failing BHCs, including Tier 1 FHCs, in situations where the stability of the
financial system is at risk.
76

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
This resolution regime should not replace bankruptcy procedures in the normal course of
business. Bankruptcy is and will remain the dominant tool for handling the failure of a
BHC, unless the special resolution regime is triggered because of concerns about
financial stability.
The proposed resolution regime is modeled on the “systemic risk exception” contained
within the existing FDIC resolution regime. This exception allows the FDIC to depart
from the least cost resolution standard, when financial stability is at risk. Like that
authority, the authority that we propose here would be only for extraordinary times and
would be subject to very strict governance and control procedures.
We propose a formal process for deciding whether use of this special resolution regime is
necessary for a particular firm and determining the form that the resolution process for
the firm should take. The process could be initiated by Treasury or the Federal Reserve.
In addition, the process could be initiated by the FDIC, or, by the SEC, when the largest
subsidiary of the failing firm is a broker-dealer or securities firm.
The authority to decide whether to resolve a failing firm under the special resolution
regime should be vested in Treasury, which could invoke the authority only after
consulting with the President and only upon the written recommendation of two-thirds of
the members of the Federal Reserve Board and two-thirds of the members of the FDIC
Board. But, if the largest subsidiary of the firm (measured by total assets) is a brokerdealer, then FDIC Board approval is not required and two-thirds of the commissioners of
the SEC must approve. If the failing firm includes an insurance company, the Office of
National Insurance within Treasury will provide consultation to the Federal Reserve and
FDIC Boards on insurance specific matters.
To invoke this authority, Treasury should have to determine that: (1) the firm is in default
or in danger of defaulting; (2) the failure of the firm and its resolution under otherwise
applicable law would have serious adverse effects on the financial system or the
economy; and (3) use by the government of the special resolution regime would avoid or
mitigate these adverse effects.
The authority to decide how to resolve a failing firm under the special resolution regime
should also be vested in Treasury. The tools available to Treasury should include the
ability to establish conservatorship or receivership for a failing firm. The regime also
should provide for the ability to stabilize a failing institution (including one that is in
conservatorship or receivership) by providing loans to the firm, purchasing assets from
the firm, guaranteeing the liabilities of the firm, or making equity investments in the firm.
We propose that, in choosing among available tools, Treasury should consider the
effectiveness of an action for mitigating potential adverse effects on the financial system
or the economy, the action’s cost to the taxpayers, and the action’s potential for
increasing moral hazard.
Treasury generally should appoint the FDIC to act as conservator or receiver, in cases
where it has decided to establish conservatorship or receivership. Treasury should have
the authority to appoint the SEC as conservator or receiver when the largest subsidiary of
the failing firm, measured by total assets, is a broker-dealer or securities firm. The
conservator or receiver should coordinate with foreign authorities that may be involved in
77

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
the resolution of subsidiaries of the firm located in foreign jurisdictions. The existing
customer protections provided to insured depositors, customers of broker-dealers and
futures commission merchants, and insurance policyholders under federal or state law
should be maintained.
The conservator or receiver of the firm should have broad powers to take action with
respect to the financial firm. For example, it should have the authority to take control of
the operations of the firm or to sell or transfer all or any part of the assets of the firm in
receivership to a bridge institution or other entity. That should include the authority to
transfer the firm’s derivatives contracts to a bridge institution and thereby avoid
termination of the contracts by the firm’s counterparties (notwithstanding any contractual
rights of counterparties to terminate the contracts if a receiver is appointed). The
conservator or receiver should also have the power to renegotiate or repudiate the firm’s
contracts, including contracts with its employees.
The entity acting as conservator or receiver should be authorized to borrow from
Treasury when necessary to finance exercise of the authorities under the resolution
regime, and Treasury should be authorized to issue public debt to finance any such loans.
The costs of any such loans should be paid from the proceeds of assessments on BHCs.
Such assessments should be based on the total liabilities (other than liabilities that are
assessed to fund other federal or state insurance schemes).
In addition, in light of the FDIC’s role in the proposed special resolution regime for
BHCs, the FDIC should have the authority to obtain any examination report prepared by
the Federal Reserve with respect to any BHC, and should have back-up examination
authority over BHCs.
B. Amend the Federal Reserve’s Emergency Lending Authority
We will propose legislation to amend Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act
to require the prior written approval of the Secretary of the Treasury for any
extensions of credit by the Federal Reserve to individuals, partnerships, or
corporations in “unusual and exigent circumstances.”
Section 13(3) of the Federal Reserve Act provides that in “unusual and exigent
circumstances” the Federal Reserve Board, upon a vote of five or more members, may
authorize a Federal Reserve Bank to lend to any individual, partnership, or corporation.
The only constraints on such lending are that any such loans must be guaranteed or
secured to the satisfaction of the Reserve Bank and that the Reserve Bank must obtain
evidence that the borrower is unable to obtain “adequate credit accommodations” from
banks.
During the recent financial crisis, the Federal Reserve Board has used this authority on
several occasions to protect the financial system and the economy. It has lent to
individual financial institutions to avoid their disorderly failure (e.g. AIG). It has created
liquidity facilities to bolster confidence and liquidity in numerous sectors (e.g.,
investment banks, MMFs, commercial paper issuers). Further, it has created liquidity
facilities designed to revive the securitization markets and thereby restore lending to
consumers and businesses whose access to credit was dependent on those markets.
78

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The Federal Reserve Board currently has authority to make such loans without the
approval of the Secretary of the Treasury. In practice, in each instance during the crisis
in which it has used its Section 13(3) authority it has sought and received the approval of
the Secretary. Indeed, the liquidity facilities designed to revive the securitization markets
have involved use of TARP funds to secure the 13(3) loans and the facilities were jointly
designed by the Federal Reserve and Treasury.
The Federal Reserve’s Section 13(3) authority should be subject to prior written approval
of the Secretary of Treasury for lending under Section 13(3) to provide appropriate
accountability going forward.

79

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
V. RAISE INTERNATIONAL REGULATORY STANDARDS AND IMPROVE INTERNATIONAL
COOPERATION

As we have witnessed during this crisis, financial stress can spread easily and quickly
across national boundaries. Yet, regulation is still set largely in a national context.
Without consistent supervision and regulation, financial institutions will tend to move
their activities to jurisdictions with looser standards, creating a race to the bottom and
intensifying systemic risk for the entire global financial system.
The United States is playing a strong leadership role in efforts to coordinate international
financial policy through the G-20, the Financial Stability Board, and the Basel Committee
on Banking Supervision. We will use our leadership position in the international
community to promote initiatives compatible with the domestic regulatory reforms
described in this report.
We will focus on reaching international consensus on four core issues: regulatory capital
standards; oversight of global financial markets; supervision of internationally active
financial firms; and crisis prevention and management.
At the April 2009 London Summit, the G-20 Leaders issued an eight-part declaration
outlining a comprehensive plan for financial regulatory reform.
The domestic regulatory reform initiatives outlined in this report are consistent with the
international commitments the United States has undertaken as part of the G-20 process,
and we propose stronger regulatory standards in a number of areas.
A. Strengthen the International Capital Framework
We recommend that the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS)
continue to modify and improve Basel II by refining the risk weights applicable
to the trading book and securitized products, introducing a supplemental
leverage ratio, and improving the definition of capital by the end of 2009. We
also urge the BCBS to complete an in-depth review of the Basel II framework to
mitigate its procyclical effects.
In 1988, the BCBS developed the Basel Accord to provide a framework to strengthen
banking system safety and soundness through internationally consistent bank regulatory
capital requirements. As weaknesses in the original Basel Accord became increasingly
apparent, the BCBS developed a new accord, known as Basel II. The United States has
not fully implemented Basel II, but the international financial crisis has already
demonstrated weaknesses in the Basel II framework.
We support the BCBS’s efforts to address these weaknesses. In particular, we support
the BCBS’s efforts to improve the regulatory capital framework for trading book and
securitization exposures by 2010.
Second, we urge the BCBS to strengthen the definition of regulatory capital to improve
the quality, quantity, and international consistency of capital. We urge the BCBS to issue
guidelines to harmonize the definition of capital by the end of 2009, and develop
recommendations on minimum capital levels in 2010.
80

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Third, we urge the BCBS to develop a simple, transparent, non-model based measure of
leverage, as recommended by the G-20 Leaders.
Fourth, we urge the Financial Stability Board (FSB), BCBS, and the Committee on the
Global Financial System (CGFS), in coordination with accounting standard setters, to
implement by the end of 2009 the G-20’s recommendations to mitigate procyclicality,
including a requirement for banks to build capital buffers in good times that they can
draw down when conditions deteriorate. This is consistent with our proposal in Section I
that banks and BHCs should have enough high-quality capital during good economic
times to keep them above prudential minimum capital requirements during stressed
economic circumstances.
B. Improve the Oversight of Global Financial Markets
We urge national authorities to promote the standardization and improved
oversight of credit derivative and other OTC derivative markets, in particular
through the use of central counterparties, along the lines of the G-20
commitment, and to advance these goals through international coordination
and cooperation.
The G-20 Leaders agreed to promote the standardization and central clearing of credit
derivatives and called on industry to develop an action plan in that regard by autumn
2009. Market participants within the United States have already created standardized
contracts for use in North America that meet the G-20 commitment. Several central
counterparties have also been established globally to clear credit derivatives.
In Section II, we propose regulations for the Over-the-Counter (OTC) derivatives market
that go beyond G-20 commitments. Given the global nature of financial markets, the
United States must continue to work with our international counterparts to raise
international standards for OTC derivatives markets, further integrate our financial
market infrastructures, and avoid measures that may result in market fragmentation.
C. Enhance Supervision of Internationally Active Financial Firms
We recommend that the Financial Stability Board (FSB) and national
authorities implement G-20 commitments to strengthen arrangements for
international cooperation on supervision of global financial firms through
establishment and continued operational development of supervisory colleges.
The financial crisis highlighted the need for an ongoing mechanism for cross-border
information sharing and collaboration among international regulators of significant global
financial institutions.
At the recommendation of the G-20 Leaders, supervisors have established “supervisory
colleges” for the thirty most significant global financial institutions. The supervisory
colleges for all thirty firms have met at least once. Supervisors will establish additional
colleges for other significant cross-border firms. The FSB will review the colleges’
activities for lessons learned once the colleges have garnered sufficient experience.

81

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation

D. Reform Crisis Prevention and Management Authorities and Procedures
We recommend that the BCBS expedite its work to improve cross-border
resolution of global financial firms and develop recommendations by the end of
2009. We further urge national authorities to improve information-sharing
arrangements and implement the FSB principles for cross-border crisis
management.
Cross-Border Resolution of Financial Firms
The current financial crisis has affected banks and nonbank financial firms without regard
to their legal structure, domicile, or location of customers. Many of the ailing financial
institutions are large, have complex internal structures and activities, and operate in
multiple nations. The global financial system is more interconnected than it has ever
been.
Currently, neither a common procedure nor a complete understanding exists of how
countries can intervene in the failure of a large financial firm and how those actions
might interact with resolution efforts of other countries. For instance, countries differ on
close-out netting rules for financial transactions or deposits. National regulatory
authorities are inclined to protect the assets within their own jurisdictions, even when
doing so can have spillover effects for other countries.
Many countries do not have effective systems for resolving bank failures, which has
forced policy makers to employ sub-optimal, ad hoc responses to failing financial firms.
As discussed above, the United States already has in place a robust resolution regime for
insured depository institutions. Moreover, we are proposing to create a resolution regime
that provides sufficient authority to avoid the disorderly resolution of any firm whose
failure would have systemic implications.
The G-20 welcomed continued efforts by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), FSB,
World Bank, and BCBS to develop an international framework for cross-border bank
resolutions.
The United States and its international counterparts should work together to improve
mechanisms for the cross-border resolution of financial firms by:
x

creating a flexible set of powers for resolution authorities to provide for continuity
of systemically significant functions, such as the ability to transfer assets,
contracts, and operations to other firms or a bridge institution; the ability to create
and operate short-term bridge institutions; the immediate authority to resolve a
failed institution; and more predictable and consistent closure thresholds;

x

furthering the development of mechanisms for cross-border information sharing
among relevant regulatory authorities and increasing the understanding of how the
various national resolution regimes for cross-border bank and nonbank financial
firms interact with each other;
82

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
x

implementing reforms to enhance the effectiveness and efficiency of crisis
management and resolutions under the currently prevailing ‘separate entity’
approach. The BCBS should initiate further work on the feasibility and
desirability of moving towards the development of methods for allocating the
financial burden associated with the failure of large, multinational financial firms
to maximize resolution options; and

x

further enhancing the effectiveness of existing rules for the clearing and
settlement of cross-border financial contracts and large value payments
transactions, including by providing options for the maintenance of contractual
relationships during insolvency, such as through the bridge institution option
available in U.S. bank receivership law.

Crisis Management Principles
National regulators, including U.S. regulators, are implementing the FSB principles for
cross-border crisis management endorsed by the G-20 Leaders. The home country
regulators for each major international financial institution will be responsible for
ensuring that the group of authorities with a common interest in a particular financial
institution will meet at least annually.
In addition to the four above-mentioned core priorities, the United States is committed to
implementing the rest of the regulatory reform agenda that the G-20 Leaders adopted at
their Summit in April. The United States will host the third leaders’ summit in Pittsburgh
in September 2009, and would like to see progress made on the rest of the issues
addressed in the G-20 Declaration on Strengthening the Financial System, outlined
below.
E. Strengthen the Financial Stability Board
We recommend that the FSB complete its restructuring and institutionalize its
new mandate to promote global financial stability by September 2009.
At the London Summit, the G-20 Leaders called for the reconstitution of the FSF,
originally created in 1999. The FSF, now called the FSB, expanded its membership to
include all G-20 members, and the G-20 Leaders strengthened the FSB’s mandate to
promote financial stability. Under its strengthened mandate, the FSB will assess financial
system vulnerabilities, promote coordination and information exchange among
authorities, advise and monitor best practices to meet regulatory standards, set guidelines
for and support the establishment of supervisory colleges, and support cross-border crisis
management and contingency planning.
F. Strengthen Prudential Regulations
We recommend that the BCBS improve liquidity risk management standards for
financial firms and that the FSB work with the Bank for International
Settlements (BIS) and standard setters to develop macroprudential tools.
The BCBS and national authorities should develop, by 2010, a global framework for
promoting stronger liquidity buffers at financial institutions, including cross-border
institutions.
83

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
The FSB should work with the BIS and international standard setters to develop
macroprudential tools and provide a report to the G-20 by autumn 2009.
G. Expand the Scope of Regulation
1. Identify Foreign Financial Firms that are Tier 1 FHCs. Determine the
appropriate Tier 1 FHC definition and application of requirements for
foreign financial firms.
As discussed above in Section I, we propose that a stricter regime of supervision and
regulation apply to Tier 1 FHCs than to other BHCs. This regime should include, among
other things, stronger capital, liquidity and risk management standards for Tier 1 FHCs
than for other BHCs. Similarly, the G-20 Leaders agreed in April that “all systemically
important financial institutions, markets, and instruments should be subject to an
appropriate degree of regulation and oversight.”
In consultation with Treasury, the Federal Reserve should develop rules to guide the
identification of foreign financial firms as Tier 1 FHCs based on whether their U.S.
operations pose a threat to financial stability. This evaluation should be similar to that
used to identify domestic Tier 1 FHCs. The Federal Reserve could consider applying the
criteria to the world-wide operations of the foreign firm. The Federal Reserve could also
choose to apply the criteria only to the U.S. operations of the foreign firm or to those
operations of the foreign firm that affect the U.S. financial markets. Several options are
available for foreign financial firms.
In determining which foreign firms are subject to the Tier 1 FHC regime, the Federal
Reserve should give due regard to the principle of national treatment and equality of
competitive opportunity between foreign-based firms operating in the United States and
U.S.-based firms. The Federal Reserve should also consider the implications of these
determinations for international agreements negotiated by the executive branch. Under
our proposal, Treasury would not play a role in the application of these rules to specific
firms.
In addition, the new “well-capitalized” and “well-managed” tests for FHC status
proposed in this report should apply to foreign financial institutions operating in the
United States in a manner comparable to that of U.S. owned financial institutions, while
taking into account the difference in their legal forms (such as branch) from their U.S.
counterparts.
Under the current Gramm Leach Bliley (GLB) Act regime, a foreign bank that owns or
controls a U.S. bank must comply with the same requirements as a domestic BHC to
achieve FHC status, namely, all the U.S. subsidiary banks of the BHC or foreign bank
must be “well-capitalized” and “well-managed.” A foreign bank that does not own or
control a U.S. bank, but instead operates through a branch, agency, or commercial
lending company located in the United States must itself be ”well-capitalized” and ”well
managed” if it elects to become an FHC. If a foreign bank operates in the United States
through branches and subsidiary banks, both the foreign parent bank and its U.S.
subsidiary bank must be “well-capitalized” and “well-managed” if the foreign bank elects
to become an FHC.
84

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Although we propose to change the FHC eligibility requirements in this report, we do not
propose to dictate the manner in which those requirements are applied to foreign financial
firms with U.S. operations. We propose to permit the Federal Reserve, in consultation
with Treasury, to determine how to apply these new requirements to foreign banks that
seek FHC status. The Federal Reserve should also make its determination giving due
regard to the principle of national treatment and equality of competitive opportunity.
2. Expand Regulation of Hedge Funds. We urge national authorities to
implement by the end of 2009 the G-20 commitment to require hedge funds
or their managers to register and disclose appropriate information
necessary to assess the systemic risk they pose individually or collectively.
The G-20 Leaders agreed to require registration of hedge funds or their managers subject
to threshold limits and to require hedge funds to disclose appropriate information on an
ongoing basis to allow supervisors to assess the systemic risk they pose individually or
collectively. Our regulatory reform proposal expands upon the G-20’s recommendations
to include registration of advisors to other private pools of capital, along with
recordkeeping and additional disclosure requirements to investors, creditors and
counterparties.
H. Introduce Better Compensation Practices
In line with G-20 commitments, we urge each national authority to put
guidelines in place to align compensation with long-term shareholder value and
to promote compensation structures do not provide incentives for excessive risk
taking. We recommend that the BCBS expediently integrate the FSB principles
on compensation into its risk management guidance by the end of 2009.
The financial crisis highlighted the problems associated with compensation structures that
do not take into consideration risk and firms’ goals over the longer term. In April, the G20 Leaders endorsed the principles on compensation in significant financial institutions
developed by the FSB to align compensation structures with firms’ long-term goals and
prudent risk taking.
Consistent with that commitment, we propose in this report that federal regulators issue
standards for compensation practices by banks and BHCs.
I. Promote Stronger Standards in the Prudential Regulation, Money
Laundering/Terrorist Financing, and Tax Information Exchange Areas
The United States is committed to working diligently to raise both U.S. and global
regulatory standards, improving and coordinating implementation of those standards, and
thereby closing geographic regulatory gaps.
In advance of the G-20 London Summit, Secretary Geithner put forward the U.S.
“Trifecta” initiative to raise international standards in areas of prudential supervision, tax
information exchange, and anti-money laundering/terrorist financing (AML/CFT)
through greater use of objective assessments, due diligence, and objective peer reviews.
The G-20 London Summit Declaration endorsed the U.S. initiative.
85

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
1. We urge the FSB to expeditiously establish and coordinate peer reviews to
assess compliance and implementation of international regulatory
standards, with priority attention on the international cooperation elements
of prudential regulatory standards.
As part of the U.S. initiative, the FSB began joint work with international standard setters
(the BCBS, the International Association of Insurance Supervisors, and the International
Organization of Securities Commissions—IOSCO) and with the IMF to expand the use
of assessments and peer reviews. The FSB and standard setters should build upon
existing applicable processes already in use by standard setters in order to assess
compliance. The FSB is focusing particular attention on assessing compliance with those
standards related to information exchange and international cooperation.
2. The United States will work to implement the updated International
Cooperation Review Group (ICRG) peer review process and work with
partners in the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) to address
jurisdictions not complying with international anti-money
laundering/terrorist financing (AML/CFT) standards.
The International Cooperation Review Group (ICRG) of the Financial Action Task Force
(FATF) is responsible for engaging with non-compliant jurisdictions and recommending
application of countermeasures by the FATF. The United States is co-chair, with Italy, of
the ICRG and is leading efforts to revise and strengthen the procedures used to select
jurisdictions for further scrutiny. FATF will finalize the revision of ICRG assessment
procedures at its upcoming plenary meeting at the end of June.
J. Improve Accounting Standards
1. We recommend that the accounting standard setters clarify and make
consistent the application of fair value accounting standards, including the
impairment of financial instruments, by the end of 2009.
The G-20 Leaders directed the accounting standard setters to improve the standards for
the valuation of financial instruments and to reduce the complexity of financial
instrument accounting. The International Accounting Standards Board (IASB) undertook
a project to develop by July 2009 a new financial measurement standard that would
replace International Accounting Standard (IAS) 39, Financial Instruments: Recognition
and Measurement, the fair value measurement standard under International Financial
Reporting Standards (IFRS), and reduce the complexity of accounting standards.
In addition, the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) and IASB have provided
additional guidance on fair value measurement. The standard setters are also evaluating
the recommendations provided by the Financial Crisis Advisory Group (“FCAG”), a high
level advisory group that standard setters established in December 2008.
In response to FASB’s recent changes to its impairment standard for debt securities, the
IASB has committed to making improvements to its own impairment requirements as
part of its comprehensive financial instrument project, slated for an exposure draft by
October 2009. Moreover, the IASB has also committed to work with FASB as part of its
86

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
comprehensive financial instrument project to promote global consistency in impairment
approaches.
2. We recommend that the accounting standard setters improve accounting
standards for loan loss provisioning by the end of 2009 that would make it
more forward looking, as long as the transparency of financial statements is
not compromised.
In its April 2009 report addressing procyclicality in the financial system, the FSB
determined that earlier recognition of loan losses by financial firms could have reduced
the procyclical effect of write-downs in the current crisis. The FSB recommended that
the accounting standard setters issue a statement that the current incurred loss approach to
loan loss provisions allows for more judgment than banks currently exercise.
The FSB also recommended that the accounting standard setters give consideration to
alternative conceptual approaches to loan loss recognition, such as a fair value model, an
expected loss model, and dynamic provisioning.
As directed by the FSB and G-20 Leaders, accounting standard setters continue to
evaluate the issue of loan loss provisioning, including developing an expected loss model
to replace the current incurred loss model.
3. We recommend that the accounting standard setters make substantial
progress by the end of 2009 toward development of a single set of high
quality global accounting standards.
The G-20 Leaders agreed that the accounting standard setters should make substantial
progress toward a single set of high quality global accounting standards by the end of
2009. The IASB and FASB have engaged in extensive efforts to converge IFRS and U.S.
Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) to minimize or eliminate differences
in the two sets of accounting standards. Last year, the IASB and FASB reiterated their
objective of achieving broad convergence of IFRS and U.S. GAAP by the end of 2010,
which is a necessary precondition under the SEC’s proposed roadmap to adopt IFRS.
Currently, the SEC is considering comments submitted on its proposed roadmap that sets
forth several milestones that could lead to the eventual use of IFRS by all U.S. issuers.
K. Tighten Oversight of Credit Rating Agencies
We urge national authorities to enhance their regulatory regimes to effectively
oversee credit rating agencies (CRAs), consistent with international standards
and the G-20 Leaders’ recommendations.
As discussed above, the performance of CRAs, particularly their ratings of mortgagebacked securities and other asset-backed securities, contributed significantly to the
financial crisis.
The G-20 Leaders pledged to undertake more effective oversight of the activities of
CRAs. Specifically, national authorities should register and oversee all CRAs whose
ratings are used for regulatory purposes consistent with the IOSCO Code of Conduct
Fundamentals for CRAs by the end of 2009.
87

Financial Regulatory Reform: A New Foundation
Moreover, all national authorities should enforce compliance with their oversight regime
to promote adequate practices and procedures for managing conflicts of interest in CRAs
and to maintain the transparency and quality of the ratings process. The G-20 Leaders
also called for the CRAs to differentiate ratings for structured products and provide full
disclosure on performance measures and ratings methodologies.
The U.S. regulatory regime for CRAs is consistent with IOSCO’s Code of Conduct for
CRAs. Moreover, Treasury proposed, consistent with the G-20’s recommendations, that
the SEC continue its efforts to tighten the regulation of CRAs along a number of
dimensions, including through public disclosures of performance measures and
methodologies and better differentiation of structured credit from other credit products.
Given the important role played by CRAs in our financial markets, the United States will
continue to work with our international counterparts to promote consistency of national
oversight regimes across jurisdictions and that national authorities engage in appropriate
information sharing, as called for by the G-20 Leaders.

88