View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS

THIRD QUARTER 1991

A Perspective C
on Banking
Reform

ongress has introduced major
banking legislation this year to
reform the U.S. financial industry.
The Financial Institutions Safety and
Consumer Choice Act potentially
represents the most sweeping
financial and regulatory reform
since the Great Depression. A concern that the U.S. banking industry
has become less competitive in
both domestic and international
markets has been a strong motivating force behind the legislation.

"Outdated banking laws
that do not

adequately

reflect the changes
that have occurred in
financial

markets have

impaired the competitive
position of U.S.

banks."

The debate surrounding this
banking legislation has centered
on several key issues, including
expansion of geographic and
product markets, regulatory restructuring and deposit insurance
reform. The House Banking Committee approved a set of reform
measures in late June that followed
in large part the reform proposal
released in February by the Treasury
Department. The Senate Banking
Committee approved its version
of a banking reform bill in early
August. While the legislation is still
moving through the committee
process, final versions of each bill
are expected sometime this fall.
Most analysts expect that a major
banking bill will be passed this year.
While the debate continues on how
best to proceed with substantive
changes, there is now broad agreement that outdated banking laws

that do not adequately reflect the
changes that have occurred in
financial markets have impaired the
competitive position of U.S. banks.
Technological advancements in the
processing and transmission of information have enabled nonbank
competitors to provide many new
financial products. While consumers
have benefited from these innovations,
banks have suffered because regulatory restrictions have prevented them
from competing fully in the expanded
marketplace. As a result, most analysts
now agree that banking reform is
needed. In this issue, we review the
major factors that have contributed
to the changing trends in bank
profitability and offer our perspective on the likely impact of the
legislation on the banking industry.
What Caused the Decline
in U.S. Bank Profitability?
Banks generally prospered
throughout most of the post-World
War II period. Separations in geographic and product markets
protected banks from competitive
pressures, and deposit insurance
increased the value of the banking
franchise. During the past decade, the
banking environment has changed
dramatically, partly as the result of
technological innovations and the
emergence of new competitors.

This publication was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org)

Chart 1
Profitability of Insured U.S. Commercial Banks
Return on assets (percent)
•8 - i

1934-39

I

1940s

I

1950s

I

1960s

I

1970s

I

1980-84

I

1985-89

1

1990

D A T A S O U R C E S : U.S. Treasury Department (1991), Modernizing the Financial System: Recommendations
for Safer, More
Competitive Banks (Washington, D.C.: G o v e r n m e n t Printing Office): Federal Deposit Insurance Corp.,
Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues.

Chart 1 highlights the changes in
U.S. bank profitability. After the
tumultuous 1930s, the return on
banking assets rose sharply and
trended upward through the 1970s.
Since then, however, bank profitability has dropped at an alarming
rate, declining to 0.55 percent in the
late 1980s and 0.5 percent in 1990.
In addition to the overall downward trend in profitability, regional
bank earnings have been highly
volatile. Banks in the Eleventh
District, which comprises Texas,
southern New Mexico and northern
Louisiana, experienced huge losses
during the late 1980s. However, the
return on assets at Eleventh District
banks increased to 0.44 percent in
1990 and strengthened further to
approximately 0.7 percent during
the first half of 1991. The turnaround in District bank performance
is primarily attributable to improvement of the troubled asset ratio at
the region's banks. The ratio of
past-due loans, nonaccrual loans
and foreclosed real estate to total
assets fell to 2.4 percent in the
second quarter of 1991, slightly
lower than its year-earlier level. In

contrast to this improvement,
preliminary reports indicate that in
the second quarter of this year
banks elsewhere generated a return
on assets of only 0.5 percent and
had a troubled asset ratio of 3-3
percent. Other regions of the
country, particularly New England,
have experienced deteriorations in
asset quality similar to the difficulties that emerged at Eleventh
District banks during the 1980s.
Both the downward trend in
profitability and the boom-to-bust
banking patterns evident on a
regional basis stem from fundamental changes in the financial services
industry. The traditional role of
banks has been to intermediate
between depositors and borrowers
by channeling short-term liabilities,
including demand deposits, into
longer-term loans. Because banks
specialize in lending, they historically have been able to reduce the
cost of acquiring timely information
on the credit quality of individual
borrowers, thereby lowering the
cost of credit. However, recent
technological advances in the
processing and transmitting of

information have enabled other
financial intermediaries to compete
more effectively with banks.
Nonbank competitors have made
considerable inroads into banking
markets. Chart 2 highlights recent
changes in the importance of banks
relative to other financial intermediaries. Commercial banking assets
accounted for 32 percent of the
total assets of major types of financial intermediaries in 1990, compared with 37 percent in 1980. The
market shares of pension funds,
mutual funds and money-market
funds rose over the decade. Correspondingly, growth in commercial
paper issued by nonfinancial
borrowers has far exceeded growth
in commercial and industrial loans
extended by banks, as Chart 3
shows. Improved information
technologies and the associated
increase in the availability of credit
information on large borrowers has
helped spur the high growth in the
commercial paper market relative
to bank lending.
Banks have attempted to reconfigure their lending activities as
business borrowers increasingly
have turned to alternative sources of
financing. As Chart 4 shows, most
of the growth in bank loan volume
over recent years can be attributed
to increased real estate lending,
which has been the primary source
of recent bank losses. Many analysts
contend that banks assumed increased risk through real estate
lending to compensate for reduced
profit margins in their traditional
banking markets.
This reduction in the market
share of U.S. banks has shifted the
emphasis of banking policy away
from the concern that banks, if left
unrestricted, might gain excessive
economic power and toward a
concern that regulatory restrictions
are preventing banks from competing effectively in global financial
markets. Product restrictions, for
example, have prevented banks
from diversifying across product
lines and reducing costs through
the efficient production of a full

line of financial services. Branching
restrictions have made it difficult
for banks to realize the benefits of
geographic diversification, thereby
making banks less efficient and
more susceptible to regional
economic downturns. It is now
widely acknowledged that greater
geographic diversification likely
would have helped reduce the
concentration of bank failures in
the Southwest and, more recently,
in New England.
The reductions in bank product
and geographic restrictions that are
expected from the pending legislation will help banks regain at least
part of their lost competitiveness.
But concerns persist that relaxation
of product and geographic restrictions, while beneficial, will not be
sufficient to establish a stronger,
more efficient banking industry.
Lessons from the thrift industry
suggest that efforts to deregulate
financial markets can be counterproductive if the remaining incentive structure does not complement
the reforms. In particular, the 1980s
demonstrated the unintended
consequences of partial reforms
that gave depository institutions
expanded powers without reforming the system of federal deposit
guarantees.
Deposit Insurance Reform:
Has the Time Come?
The current system of federal
deposit insurance represents an
attempt to protect depository
institutions and the public from
the potentially damaging effects of
banking panics, in which depositors
indiscriminately withdraw funds
from the banking system by converting bank deposits into currency.
Since its beginning in 1934, federal
deposit insurance coverage has
been expanded repeatedly, so now
it is not uncommon for all deposits,
regardless of size, to be protected
from loss when a bank fails.
By guaranteeing the full value of
deposits, federal deposit insurance
greatly reduces the potential for

Chart 2
Market Share of Selected Financial Intermediaries
Percent
40 -,

C o m m e r c i a l Banks

Pension Funds

Mutual Funds

D A T A S O U R C E : Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Annual

banking panics, but the extension
of federal deposit guarantees has
created its own problems. Without
deposit guarantees, the threat of
withdrawal by uninsured depositors
concerned about the safety of their
deposits provides a disciplinary role
in guiding banks to maintain
sufficient capital and limit risktaking. While the current system of
deposit insurance reduces the
likelihood of banking panics, it also
effectively removes the incentive
for depositors to monitor banks and
withdraw deposits from banks that
approach insolvency or assume
increased asset risk, because the
safety of deposits is guaranteed.
This lack of deposit market discipline encourages banks to reduce
their capital-to-asset ratios and
pursue high-risk investments. As
increased competition has reduced
the value of bank charters in recent
years, banks have had less to lose
in the event of failure and, consequently, are more prone to respond
to the risk-taking incentives provided by deposit insurance.
The system of regulatory constraints designed to substitute for the

Statistical

Money Market Funds

Digest, various issues.

monitoring and disciplining role of
depositors has not been fully effective.
The difficulty of imposing adequate
regulatory discipline in the current
competitive environment is reflected
in the unprecedented financial losses
from recent bank and thrift failures.
Losses at the nation's insolvent thrifts
crippled the Federal Savings and
Loan Insurance Corp. insurance
fund, and banks are now faced with
the growing expense of recapitalizing the Bank Insurance Fund when
low profitability has already strained
the industry's ability to compete in
the market for financial services. To
an increasing number of banks, the
price of deposit insurance may
become prohibitively high.
Reform measures currently
under consideration link regulatory
discipline to bank capital levels,
culminating in bank closure
before insolvency, as measured
by regulatory standards. But concerns persist regarding whether
such changes will be sufficient,
particularly because it is widely
acknowledged that difficulties
remain in the measurement of
regulatory capital.

Chart 3
Commercial Paper Issued by Nonfinancial
Borrowers vs. Bank Commercial and
Industrial Loans
Index, 1975 = 100

1,2001,1001,000900800-

Commercial Paper

700600500400300200100-

Commercial and Industrial Loans

0- l i i i i i i i i i i i i i i n
75

'77

'79

'81

'83

'85

'87

'89

'91

DATA SOURCE: CITIBASE, Citibank Economic Database.

Can We Trust the Market
to Discipline Banks?
Many observers agree about the
problems associated with the
current system of deposit insurance
and the associated lack of depositor
discipline. Considerable disagreement persists, however, over the
degree to which reintroducing
deposit market discipline will result
in severe banking panics. A distrust
of market forces has been the
cornerstone of U.S. banking policy
throughout most of this country's
history. The key consideration is
whether this distrust is warranted.
Recent attention to this topic
suggests that the potential for banking panics to affect adversely the
health of banks and macroeconomic

Chart 4
Bank Lending*
Billions of constant (1982) dollars
1,800-|
1

Real Estate Loans

•

C&l Loans

I

Other Loans

* Nominal value of each loan category deflated by the
consumer price index.
DATA SOURCE: CITIBASE. Citibank Economic Database.

activity has been exaggerated.
Throughout most of U.S. banking
history, financial losses on bank
deposits were actually very small
and similar in magnitude to losses
from failures of nonbank businesses.
Moreover, evidence suggests that a
spillover effect from the failure of a
large bank to other banks has been
limited. Thus, it is possible that the
failure of a large bank would not
have a severe, adverse effect on
general economic activity. Finally,
even if a potentially damaging panic
developed, the central bank can
offset and reverse a generalized
outflow of deposits from the banking system by extending credit to
solvent banks through the discount
window or by injecting reserves
through open market operations.
It is thus plausible that changes
that reintroduce a greater role for
deposit market discipline in controlling bank risk-taking would
improve the overall performance
of the banking industry. Our
concern is that if market forces are
prevented from monitoring and
shaping bank risk-taking because
of implicit 100-percent deposit
guarantees, expanded powers for
banks and a capital-based system
of regulatory oversight will not
be sufficient to promote a sound
banking system.
Concluding Remarks
Considerable evidence suggests
that the appropriate policy response
to current banking difficulties would
be to relax the geographic and
product restrictions under which
banks currently operate while
allowing market forces to play a
much larger role in guiding bank
actions. In our view, successful
financial reform will rely increasingly
on the incentives and self-correcting
processes provided by the market to
produce a safer, stronger and more
efficient banking industry.
— Genie D. Short
Jeffery W. Gunther
Kelly Klemme

Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas
Financial Industry
Studies Department
President and
Chief Executive Officer
Robert D. McTeer, Jr.
First Vice President and
Chief Operating Officer
Tony J. Salvaggio
Senior Vice President
George C. Cochran, III
Vice President
Genie D. Short
Senior Economists
Jeffery W. Gunther
Robert R. Moore
Kenneth J. Robinson
Financial
Analyst
Kelly Klemme
Financial Industry Issues is
published by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Dallas. The views
expressed are those of the
authors and do not necessarily
reflect the position of the Federal
Reserve Bank of Dallas or the
Federal Reserve System.
Articles may be reprinted on
the condition that the source is
credited and the Financial Industry
Studies Department is provided
a copy of the publication
containing the reprinted article.

Subscriptions are available free
of charge. Please send requests
for single-copy and multiplecopy subscriptions, back issues
or address changes to
Public Affairs Department
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Station K
Dallas, Texas 75222
(214) 651-6289
(800) 333-4460, ext. 6289