View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

■
For release:
October 28, 1997

NEWS RELEASE

•••••

•

•••••••••••••••••••••••

The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
St. Louis

Little Rock

Louisville

Memphis

Contact:
Charles B. Henderson (314) 444-8311

The FOMC in 1996: "Watchful Waiting"
ST. LOUIS-The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Federal Reserve' s
monetary policymaking arm, didn't tighten policy in 1996, but two economists found that it
did engage in " watchful waiting," defined as" a policy mode in which policymakers (and
probably financial markets) know the direction of the next sustained series of policy moves,
but immediate action is not considered necessary."

Michael J. Dueker, a senior economist with the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
and Andreas M. Fischer, an economic advisor with the Swiss National Bank in Zurich,
studied the 1996 actions of the FOMC for the current issue of Review, the St. Louis Fed' s
bimonthly publication of economic and policy issues.

Dueker and Fischer noted that the FOMC de-emphasized monetary targets as the
anchor for monetary policy in 1993. The current period without an explicit policy anchor,


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(more)

St. Louis Fed Review/2
they said, may go down in U.S. monetary history as an " interregnum." Thus, in 1996, the
FOMC adopted a stance of watchful waiting, not only for inflationary imbalances in the current
expansion, but also waiting to establish a new anchor for monetary policy, they said.

In addition, Dueker and Fischer found that monetary policy in 1996, on average, was
"slightly accommodative" relative to an inflation target between 2 percent and 3 percent.

They also analyzed a number of issues that economists cited in 1996 as arguments against
an immediate policy push past watchful waiting and towards price stability. These arguments,
they said, may or may not have swayed FOMC policymakers, but were certainly widely
discussed by both academics and business economists.

For example, the U.S. economy in the middle of 1996 was enjoying continued, robust
growth, low unemployment and relatively stable inflation -

advantages rarely seen in the sixth

year of an expansion. Many pundits, however, thought it was "time" for the expansion to run
out of steam, based on the historical average length of expansions. Yet empirical evidence from
many contemporary economic studies indicated that expansions don't just inevitably wither and

die. Mirroring Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan' s testimony to Congress in
February of 1996, Dueker and Fischer noted that "recessions do not occur simply because too
much time has passed since the last one."


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(more)

St. Louis Fed Review/3
That recessions are thought to be often the product of inflationary imbalances provides
policymakers a strong impetus to prevent upticks in the inflation rate, Dueker and Fischer noted,
but does little to supply a rationale for further disinflation in the near term.

Dueker and Fischer also analyzed other factors related to inflation that economists
debated publicly that year, and which may have influenced the FOMC to continue a stance of
watchful waiting and postpone adopting a new, long-term policy anchor:
• Possible bias in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) and its reliability as a measure of inflation. In
the absence of any other, more accurate barometer of inflation, policymakers may have been
reluctant to tie price stability to the CPI.
• The non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), a level of unemployment historically between 5 percent and 6 percent - at which wage increases are generally thought to
be consistent with stable inflation. Since unemployment has dipped below this figure and
inflation has still been steady, some observers have questioned whether NAIRU is still valid as a
predictor of inflation.
•"Opportunistic disinflation," a term describing a monetary policy that would have the FOMC
concentrate on sustaining an expansion near the trend rate of output growth and switch its focus,

if necessary, from shepherding real growth to controlling inflation.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

(more)

St. Louis Fed Review/4
The FOMC has received widespread credit for helping to foster and sustain the low
inflation rate the nation has enjoyed recently. Nevertheless, Dueker and Fischer maintain that
the U.S. economy will probably not achieve long-term price stability until the Federal Reserve
has a new policy anchor aimed at achieving it.

Subscriptions to Review are free and can be obtained by calling (314) 444-8809. The
publication is also available on the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis' website:
http://www.stls.frb.org.

The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis has branches in Little Rock, Louisville and
Memphis. It serves the Eighth Federal Reserve District, which includes all of Arkansas, eastern
Missouri, southern Indiana, southern Illinois, western Kentucky, western Tennessee and northern
Mississippi. In addition to serving as a bank for depository institutions and the U.S. government,
each Reserve Bank supervises state-chartered member banks and bank holding companies,
monitors economic conditions in the District and participates in formulating monetary policy.


https://fraser.stlouisfed.org
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

###