View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 28, 2011

1 of 40

Conference Call of the Federal Open Market Committee on
November 28, 2011
A conference call of the Federal Open Market Committee was held on Monday,
November 28, 2011, at 11:00 a.m. Those present were the following:
Ben Bernanke, Chairman
William C. Dudley, Vice Chairman
Elizabeth Duke
Charles L. Evans
Richard W. Fisher
Narayana Kocherlakota
Sarah Bloom Raskin
Daniel K. Tarullo
Janet L. Yellen
Christine Cumming, Jeffrey M. Lacker, Dennis P. Lockhart, Sandra Pianalto, and John C.
Williams, Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
James Bullard, Esther L. George, and Eric Rosengren, Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of St. Louis, Kansas City, and Boston, respectively
William B. English, Secretary and Economist
Deborah J. Danker, Deputy Secretary
Matthew M. Luecke, Assistant Secretary
David W. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary
Michelle A. Smith, Assistant Secretary
Scott G. Alvarez, General Counsel
James A. Clouse, Steven B. Kamin, Loretta J. Mester, Daniel G. Sullivan, and Kei-Mu
Yi, Associate Economists
Brian Sack, Manager, System Open Market Account
Patrick M. Parkinson, Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board
of Governors
Nellie Liang, Director, Office of Financial Stability Policy and Research, Board of
Governors
William Wascher, Deputy Director, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Andrew T. Levin, Special Advisor to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors

November 28, 2011

2 of 40

Linda Robertson, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Seth B. Carpenter, Senior Associate Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors; Michael P. Leahy, Senior Associate Director, Division of International
Finance, Board of Governors
Joyce K. Zickler, Senior Adviser, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Brian J. Gross, Special Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
Michael G. Palumbo, Associate Director, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Beth Anne Wilson, Assistant Director, Division of International Finance, Board of
Governors
Valerie Hinojosa and Randall A. Williams, Records Management Analysts, Division of
Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Jamie J. McAndrews and Mark S. Sniderman, Executive Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of New York and Cleveland, respectively
David Altig, Alan D. Barkema, Geoffrey Tootell, Christopher J. Waller, and John A.
Weinberg, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta, Kansas City,
Boston, St. Louis, and Richmond, respectively
Mary C. Daly, Group Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Mark A. Wynne, Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
Anna Nordstrom, Assistant Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York

November 28, 2011

3 of 40

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Conference Call on
November 28, 2011

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everybody. Thank you for joining us on
this call. As you know, our main topic today is Europe and our swaps agreements. I thought I
would take a minute at the beginning, though, to talk about FOMC confidentiality issues very
briefly. As you know, on Wednesday, there was an article in the Wall Street Journal on the
question of access to Fed officials. As is often the case, there was more innuendo than fact, but
there were a couple of points. One, it was noted that I myself meet with various economists and
consultants periodically in an effort to get outside points of view and to hear what they’re
thinking and so on. And second, it mentioned that until earlier this year, the staff of the New
York Fed had been providing information on the staff forecast to the Bank’s Economic Advisory
Panel.
Let me comment briefly on responses to those issues. First of all, on my personal
calendar, the article did reflect a point that the Chairman, like other members of the Committee,
does need to have access to outside perspectives and information, which of course is why we
have not only a Board, but also panels, advisory councils, and the like. The article also
published a long quote from Michelle making the very valid point that people who meet with me
sometimes have an incentive to claim inside information, even if none such exists. And finally,
I’d like to note that my meetings are always in compliance with our policy. In particular, I
always have a staff member there taking notes, and of course I’d never disclose information that
I don’t disclose in public. So I do believe that our meetings have been in full compliance with
the policies that we passed over the summer. That said, the article illustrates that there is a
reputational risk here, and so just for your information, we have canceled all similar meetings of

November 28, 2011

4 of 40

this sort for the near term, and we’re going to look at whether there are any good alternative
ways to get outside information, input, that don’t have that particular risk. We’re taking that
seriously and trying to figure out a solution.
Second, on the New York staff forecast, this was something that had been going on for
some time but was discontinued in June after the new policy on external communication was
adopted. So it was in response to that policy that this practice was discontinued. And, in
addition, you may be aware that the past forecasts were posted on the web last week in
conjunction with an article by Simon Potter of the New York Fed on the ability of the Fed to
forecast the recession, which of course was not very good, and the forecasts were put there as an
illustration of some of the problems and issues that had come up. Now, that said, when the
reporter was researching her story and the items relating the forecast materials were shown to us,
I asked Bill English and Scott Alvarez, pursuant to our policies, to take a look at it and see if
there was anything in there that did raise issues concerning our policies, as is required by our
approach. Now, at this point, I think it’s rather moot. But it is worthwhile for us to look at this
episode briefly because we all deal with the problem of forecasts, have boards and councils, meet
with outside individuals, and talk about the outlook in various ways. So I think it would be
beneficial for us to make use of this to try to clarify for ourselves how best to use staff
forecasting information. After Scott and Bill finish their look at this particular episode, I think
we should maybe have a brief discussion at some point about how we treat forecasts and that
kind of information—in dealing with our boards, for example.
Finally, a third issue came up, which was not in the article in any way—it was not
referred to—but I got requests from an FOMC participant to look once again at the issue of the
dealer survey, which, as you know, we put out before each meeting to the dealers, confidentially

November 28, 2011

5 of 40

asking them for their views on likely Fed policies, along with issues relating to the economy and
so on. And there’s been a concern raised in meetings that the dealer survey—which, again, was
not mentioned in the article but nevertheless raises similar concerns—might provide or appear to
provide preferential information to the recipients of the survey. Now, I raised this with Vice
Chairman Dudley and Brian Sack, and from their perspective, it’s perfectly fine to go ahead and
start releasing the survey in real time, which we can do as early as Friday for the December
meeting. The alternative would be to have some kind of Committee process, which I think none
of us are particularly excited about but which I’m willing to do if there’s a strong desire for it. In
a moment I’ll ask for comment, but the proposal is just to start releasing it, and of course we’ll
look carefully at it to make sure that it doesn’t have any implied preferential information in it.
We’ll start that on Friday.
So those are just a few reactions. Vice Chairman Dudley wants to comment, and then I’ll
be happy to take any questions or comments on this particular issue. Bill.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. To clarify on the release of the primary dealer survey,
we’re talking about releasing just the questions, not the actual results of the survey.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think that’s okay, but others can comment. Does anyone
have any reactions they’d like to share? [No response] Okay. Seeing none, why don’t we turn
to the business of the meeting. I think the best way to do this would be to turn first to Brian
Sack, who will give us, as background, some markets updates, and then Steve Kamin here at the
Board will talk about what’s happening in Europe as they try to address the ongoing crisis. I’ll
say a few words about calls and contacts that I’ve had, and then we’ll open up the discussion of
the particular proposal. So let me turn it over to Brian Sack for an update on markets. Brian.

November 28, 2011

MR. SACK. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Concerns about whether an orderly
resolution to the European sovereign debt crisis can be achieved have intensified
further, dominating developments in global financial markets in recent weeks.
Investors have come to view the measures that were agreed to in October,
including the possibility of leveraging the EFSF funds using private capital, as
inadequate to provide a credible backstop to European sovereign debt markets. The
absence of this backstop, along with the decision to include a larger degree of privatesector participation in the voluntary restructuring of Greek debt, has put considerable
pressure on European sovereign debt markets. Yields on Italian and Spanish debt
have increased over 100 basis points over the past three weeks, with the 10-year yield
approaching 7 percent in Spain and surpassing that level in Italy. Liquidity in these
securities has deteriorated significantly as the perceived risk has increased.
At this point, the only backstop in the market is the purchases of sovereign debt
by the European Central Bank under its Securities Markets Programme. However,
the ECB is seen as somewhat reluctant to perform this role, and its purchases have
been paired with a constant reminder from European officials that the ECB cannot
provide monetary financing to governments. Many observers feel that the ECB will
not take a more aggressive approach until there is greater clarity on a longer-term
solution to Europe’s fiscal challenges, which will likely take some time.
Given these circumstances, investors have increasingly considered the possibility
of a more disorderly outcome for the euro area, including broader debt restructuring
or changes in the composition of the currency union. Reflecting such concerns, core
European countries have increasingly been swept into the negative market dynamics.
Ten-year yields in France, Austria, Belgium, and the Netherlands have all come under
upward pressure, increasing by 50 to 150 basis points since the most recent FOMC
meeting. Even German debt yields began to rise last week, with investors’ concerns
reflected in a very weak auction of 10-year debt.
The anxiety about European sovereign debt is also apparent in the CDS written on
that debt. At this point, five-year CDS is at 555 basis points for Italy, 488 basis
points for Spain, 408 basis points for Belgium, 245 basis points for France, and
117 basis points for Germany. Those compare with a CDS rate of just 59 basis points
for the United States despite our own set of fiscal issues.
The intensification of concerns about European sovereign debt has weighed on
the prices of risky assets broadly, with the S&P 500 index off about 10 percent since
the Friday before the most recent FOMC meeting. Over that period, corporate bond
spreads and other private debt spreads have widened notably, and Treasury yields
have fallen. The dollar has appreciated, including a sharp gain against the euro.
The financial sector has been under the most significant pressure over this period,
with equity indexes for U.S. banks and financial institutions falling 15 to 20 percent.
This repricing appears to be driven by worries about direct exposures to European
markets as well as by concerns about the indirect channels through which an

6 of 40

November 28, 2011

unraveling of the situation in Europe could create difficulties for U.S. firms. Equity
prices of many European financial firms have fallen even more sharply than those of
U.S. firms over this period.
For European banks, investors’ concerns have transmitted into greater difficulties
obtaining short-term funding. These firms have faced increasing costs for borrowing
euros in the market, with three-month euro LIBOR moving to a spread of nearly
100 basis points above the OIS rate. Moreover, some European firms have turned
more heavily to the ECB for funding, causing euro-denominated funding provided by
the ECB to increase sharply, particularly for Italian and French banks.
European banks have also continued to face pressures on their short-term dollar
funding. As we have described before, consistent access to unsecured dollar funding
has been limited to tenors of one week or less for most European firms. Moreover,
the implied three-month dollar funding rate that could be obtained by borrowing at
euro LIBOR and using FX swaps to convert to dollars has moved up sharply,
reaching 200 basis points last week. Liquidity in the FX swaps market has worsened
for horizons beyond one month.
Based on these conditions, the ECB’s operations to provide 84-day dollar funding
at a rate of 100 basis points above the OIS rate under the current swap arrangements
would be well in the money. Indeed, it is somewhat disappointing that the presence
of these arrangements has not provided a more effective cap on dollar funding rates
for European banks. As Steve Kamin will describe, the staff is proposing a reduction
in the pricing of the dollar swap lines to 50 basis points above the OIS rate. The ECB
and our other central bank counterparties hope that this repricing will encourage a
greater willingness of firms to participate at the dollar funding operations, and hence
result in a more effective cap on their dollar funding rates.
The story for U.S. financial institutions is more positive, as these firms have not
experienced notable difficulties obtaining short-term funding. Dollar-based LIBOR
rates have moved higher, even for the U.S. banks included in the panel, and forward
rates suggest that this rise is expected to continue. However, the increase has been far
smaller than that in euro-based rates. Moreover, U.S. banks are not borrowing much
in the term unsecured funding market, as they generally have considerable liquidity
from other sources.
Another key consideration is that short-term secured funding markets appear to be
holding their ground. Indeed, repo markets continue to function normally for
Treasury and agency debt collateral. Even for nontraditional collateral, there has
been no meaningful change in haircuts, and bid–asked spreads have moved up only
slightly in recent months.
However, even though short-term funding markets for U.S. institutions appear to
be functioning fairly well, we see considerable risk that the funding situation could
change abruptly. The recent developments at MF Global serve as a reminder that
funding can dry up quickly for a firm that is seen as having too much risk exposure.

7 of 40

November 28, 2011

Such concerns may be more pressing when markets are as volatile as they have been
of late, and it seems likely that this volatility will continue as investors have to
contend with a wide range of possible policy outcomes in Europe.
Moreover, the U.S. financial sector is still in the process of recovering from the
events of recent years and adjusting to a changed environment. A notable risk in this
regard is that at least one rating agency is likely to take near-term actions to
downgrade U.S. financial firms, reflecting a systematic review of its government
support assumptions for these firms.
Lastly, it should be noted that CDS rates and longer-term debt spreads for U.S.
financial firms have moved up again, reaching very elevated levels. Indeed, as of last
Friday, five-year CDS rates were more than 500 basis points for Morgan Stanley and
more than 400 basis points for Bank of America and Goldman Sachs. These rates
imply that it will be difficult, or at least quite costly, for these firms to roll over their
longer-term debt as it matures.
Overall, even though most U.S. financial firms have ample liquidity today and are
not experiencing notable difficulties with short-term funding, the financial sector
continues to face a range of risks going forward, and it could quickly come under
significant pressure in response to a disorderly outcome in Europe. Steve Kamin will
now continue the presentation.
MR. KAMIN. 1 As Brian has discussed, the attempt by European leaders in late
October to promote a comprehensive solution to the euro-area financial crisis has
largely failed, and the crisis is deepening and threatening to spill over from the
European periphery to the core. In Greece, the government collapsed two weeks ago
and was replaced by a temporary caretaker government headed by former ECB Vice
President Lucas Papademos. Greece’s main opposition party has generally signed on
to the fiscal reforms Greece has agreed to with the IMF and EU, but in order to repay
its creditors and finance its deficit over the coming couple of years, Greece is
negotiating a new €130 billion program with the IMF and EU, and this new loan is
contingent on Greece’s private-sector creditors voluntarily writing down the face
value of their claims on Greece’s government by 50 percent. However, the
discussions between the Greek government and its private-sector creditors on this
debt restructuring have been fractious, putting the new loan package in jeopardy and
adding to speculation that Greece may soon default and possibly withdraw from the
euro area.
If the European leaders had succeeded in putting the financial backstops in place
to protect Italy, Spain, and other governments from contagion, the Greek situation
would be just a sideshow with limited potential to destabilize broader markets.
However, efforts to strengthen the euro-area financial backstop have been stymied.
The October plan was to leverage the remaining €270 billion in uncommitted
resources of the EFSF with private-sector funds to achieve over €1 trillion in
1

The materials used by Mr. Kamin are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

8 of 40

November 28, 2011

capacity. But with outside investors showing little enthusiasm for this scheme and
the EFSF itself having difficulty raising funds, it appears unlikely that the EFSF, by
itself, would be able to protect Italy and Spain from a major run on their debt.
In the absence of a credible backstop, investor concerns about sovereign default
have begun to snowball, as Brian has described. In Italy, soaring borrowing costs,
along with weakening economic conditions and calls for more budget cutting, led to
the fall of the Berlusconi government and his replacement by former EU
commissioner Mario Monti. Although this change may bode well for future
economic reforms, the political transition has been chaotic and has further roiled
financial markets. Indeed, investors remain uncertain as to whether Italy’s new
government of unelected technocrats will be able to muster the political support
needed to push through unpopular fiscal austerity measures.
And now, alarmingly, market pressures are spreading to core euro-area
economies, with France’s and Belgium’s borrowing costs rising, Belgium’s credit
rating being downgraded by S&P, and, as Brian mentioned, even Germany having a
poor bond auction last week. Calls are mounting for the ECB to stem the panic by
taking a more active role in funding vulnerable governments, possibly by channeling
funds either through the IMF or the EFSF. An alternative approach, involving greater
fiscal centralization and the issuance of Eurobonds guaranteed by the euro area as a
whole, is also mustering support, including most recently by the European
Commission. However, Germany and the ECB so far have continued to resist these
options, increasing investor concerns that the financial crisis could deepen while
European officials watch either helplessly or passively from the sidelines. Moreover,
the recently announced plans for the recapitalization of Europe’s banks are believed
likely to promote deleveraging and contribute to a credit crunch that will further
weigh on Europe’s economy.
Turning to the economic outlook, our October forecast for only slight declines in
euro-area GDP this quarter and next now seems optimistic. Retail sales, industrial
production, and new orders fell sharply in September; October surveys show
continued declines in business and consumer confidence; and the euro-area composite
PMI in October and November has fallen well into contractionary territory. Given
the escalating financial stresses, the troubled banking sectors, and ever-increasing
calls for fiscal consolidation, we are currently anticipating that the recession in
Europe will be more severe and prolonged.
These conditions present a significant risk to U.S. financial systems and to the
U.S. economic recovery. With this in mind, the FOMC might want to consider
changes to its liquidity swap lines with foreign central banks aimed at easing funding
stresses and bolstering investor confidence. Accordingly, as detailed in the proposed
resolution circulated earlier this morning, we are seeking your approval of a
six-month extension of the existing dollar swap lines through February 1, 2013, along
with the establishment of additional swap arrangements with our central bank
counterparties to support the provision by the Federal Reserve of liquidity in
Canadian dollars, British pounds, Japanese yen, euros, and Swiss francs. These

9 of 40

November 28, 2011

10 of 40

foreign currency swap lines are not needed today, but they would be established as
part of a broad network of bilateral swap lines intended to address potential future
funding needs and to support market confidence by demonstrating cooperation among
the major central banks. Before the initial drawing on these new swap lines, the
Foreign Currency Subcommittee would consult with the Federal Open Market
Committee if possible under the circumstances then prevailing. These new
arrangements would also expire in February 2013.
Both for the dollar swap lines and for the new lines providing other currencies, we
propose that the Chairman establish the interest rates by agreement with the foreign
central banks and in consultation with the Foreign Currency Subcommittee. He
would keep the Federal Open Market Committee informed, and the rates agreed
would be consistent with the principles discussed with the Committee. In this regard,
we have reached tentative agreement with our foreign counterparties on a reduction in
the cost of borrowing through the existing dollar swap lines of 50 basis points—from
100 basis points over OIS to 50 basis points over OIS. The reduction in borrowing
costs should help reduce banks’ aversion to using the swap facilities, thus
strengthening their liquidity positions and reducing the pace of their deleveraging and
associated impacts on credit conditions. These actions, if approved, will be described
in a coordinated announcement by the Federal Reserve and our five central bank
counterparties—the European Central Bank, the Bank of England, the Swiss National
Bank, the Bank of Japan, and the Bank of Canada. That announcement is likely to be
made Wednesday morning. That concludes my remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Are there questions for Brian or
Steve? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Steve, can you bring us up to date on what is likely to occur in the G-7 in
terms of addressing solvency issues? That’s the first of many questions I have, but it seems to
me that we have to have a backdrop. And I’m curious as to what you expect—or what we
expect, Mr. Chairman—to come out of these discussions, in addition to our committing to
addressing liquidity needs. That’s question number one. What do we know that is not in the
press?
MR. TARULLO. Nothing.
MR. KAMIN. Yes. On question number two, I do not believe we know that much that’s
not in the press, but perhaps the Chairman can add to that. On the issue of solvency, a couple of
things. First, clearly, the G-7 is engaged on this, and they have had talks recently. But

November 28, 2011

11 of 40

ultimately the role of the non-European members of the G-7 is really going to be to advise and
perhaps pressure the European leaders on steps that need to be taken. They are addressing both
the liquidity and the solvency issues, and those do need to be addressed jointly. The liquidity
issue is quite obvious, which is that the possibility of a self-fulfilling prophecy of an investor run
leading to default looms very large, and so you do need some backstops. At the same time,
particularly the European leaders are keenly aware that there are solvency issues involved. They
are very reluctant to put liquidity rescue measures in place if they cannot be assured that Italy,
Spain, and other peripheral countries will put in place the fiscal reforms needed to guarantee
solvency and sustainability. In that regard, the most obvious option now on the table is basically
that any rescue measures be done in conjunction with an IMF program to enforce the
conditionality needed to provide comfort to the European leaders.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher, before we begin our general discussion in
just a minute, I can talk about some calls I’ve had. On solvency, just to reiterate what Steve said,
the clearest case of insolvency is Greece, which is being addressed in various ways. Arguably,
for example, the increase in the German interest rate is not a solvency issue; it’s a concern about
the stability of the euro and about self-fulfilling panics. So I think there is arguably, for many if
not most of the countries other than Greece, a significant element of panic or liquidity issue, as
opposed to a solvency issue. But again, to reiterate what Steve said, the Europeans are very
focused—some would say too focused—on the moral-hazard solvency issues and are addressing
that from a number of different fronts.
MR. FISHER. Brian, am I correct that two-year Greek debt is trading over 100 percent?
MR. SACK. Yes, 120 percent.

November 28, 2011

12 of 40

MR. FISHER. Thank you. Mr. Chairman, as I understand this—obviously, there’s a
code among central bankers. These don’t seem to be extraordinary. I’m curious as to whether—
we’ll have a discussion in just a minute—part of this package is that we’re going to reduce the
domestic discount rate as well. In other words, what lies herein is extending swap arrangements,
which we’ve all, for the most part, agreed to, and adding the new dimension of providing
liquidity in Canadian dollars, British pounds, Japanese yen, euros, and Swiss francs if requested
by the appropriate Reserve Bank—I presume that means Richmond, largely, or New York for B
of A, and then the other big institutions, but it might include others. The suggestion here, as
stated in the current intention, is that we reduce the rate on existing lines to OIS plus 50. OIS is,
what, 12 basis points? So that would be less than the 75 we charge domestic institutions to
borrow. Implicit in this is that we would reduce the domestic discount rate. Or can we justify—
even though they are central banks—lending money to foreigners—to use the term that our
overseers might use—at a cheaper rate than we lend to our highest-quality domestic banks? Is
that our intention?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That’s our current intention. I was hoping to address that,
though, before we begin our substantive round. Would you allow me to do that?
MR. FISHER. Yes, sir—of course.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’ll come back to it.
MR. FISHER. And then the last thing is—and maybe this is a point you wish to
address—in terms of adhering to Bagehot principles, not just regarding the rate we charge, but
also regarding the collateral that is accepted, that this is an intra–central bank facility. But to
take an extreme example, if during the course of time we decide to roll it over between now and

November 28, 2011

13 of 40

February 1, 2013, and the euro is no longer the euro that we know, I’m curious as to how this is
actually secured. How would they pay us back?
MR. KAMIN. On that issue, a couple of points are worth making. First of all, in our
bilateral agreement with the ECB, basically, they would be beholden, as per the contract, to
return dollars to us in any event, even if the collateral that we were holding—the euros—no
longer had the standing that they did beforehand. So, first, from a legal perspective, we are still
owed the dollars. Second, presumably, the euro would still be exchangeable for the currencies
that would succeed the euro if it came to that. So, in that instance, too, there will be value. And
finally—and I think this is important—right now, we’ve got two different tenors of swaps, the
one week and the three month. Certainly, the one-week swaps are short enough so that we could
foresee an event and not lend any of those. Even the three-month swaps seem to have a
sufficiently short time frame that if it looked as though the demise of the euro area were
imminent, we could basically not participate in those swaps. So I think we have a reasonable
amount of comfort on all of those fronts that the demise of the euro area, while no longer as
unthinkable as it once was, probably does not pose a threat to the safety of these swaps.
MR. FISHER. Thank you very much. I have other questions, Mr. Chairman, but I’ll
defer them until we get into the discussion. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Any other questions for Brian or Steve? President
Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Will these be sterilized?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That had not been our plan. But if they become large, I
think we would have to consider that. Up to now, of course, it’s been essentially irrelevant
because the draws have been tiny. And frankly, I don’t expect large draws. I think this is

November 28, 2011

14 of 40

viewed as a backstop rather than as a major source of funding. But if they became large, we
would have to consider that, yes. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Do we have in mind, Mr. Chairman, a limit in terms of the expansion of
our balance sheet?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, as I said, this is technically an unlimited swap line, as
we have had since 2008. Of course, we do have to agree to each individual draw. Is that correct,
Scott?
MR. ALVAREZ. Yes.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. If they became excessively large, we could either restrict
them or sterilize them. So, no, I wouldn’t anticipate that our balance sheet would grow
meaningfully because of this, but that would be a decision for the FOMC to undertake.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Other questions for Steve or Brian? [No response]
Well, let me add just a few points. President Fisher asked whether we had information that was
not in the newspapers. I would say that the answer in some technical sense is no, but we have a
lot more, call it soft, information, which comes from extensive discussions with European
policymakers and other policymakers. I had the pleasure of taking two G-7 calls beginning at
7:00 a.m. on Thanksgiving morning. There were two calls. The first was with both the G-7
central bank governors and the finance ministers, and the tone of these discussions remains, I
think, fairly discouraging. A generous interpretation from the finance ministers’ perspective is
that they are approaching this on two fronts. One the one hand, they’re taking a longer-run
perspective—they’re trying to address moral hazard issues, structural reform, building their
fiscal union, and moving toward a long-term solution, which obviously is an important

November 28, 2011

15 of 40

component of an overall solution—at the same time that they are taking short-run steps, like
leveraging the EFSF, capitalizing the banks, imposing near-term austerity measures, and
allowing the ECB to buy government debt. I think the concern people are recognizing is that the
process is too slow and that the short-run measures on this trajectory are not going to be
adequate. So there is, obviously, a lot of concern. There are very important political constraints.
The ECB, in particular, is in a very delicate position. They have been quite frank with me that
although they talk about legalities, they view their main constraints as political. Essentially,
what will the Germans allow the ECB to do? Their position is quite delicate in that respect, and
frankly, I think it’s kind of perverse that their strategy is to actually buy for their balance sheet
Greek debt, as opposed to lending to some vehicle or to the European Investment Bank or some
other bank to indirectly finance government debt. But that’s where their arguments about
monetary policy have led them. So the main inside information I would share with you is that
there’s considerable concern and a lot of pessimism among the policymakers in Europe.
I think it’s also important to note—and I’m hearing this more on calls—the growing
concern about the European economy. As Steve mentioned, the indicators have deteriorated in
just the past few weeks. Draghi noted the risk of a mild recession in his first press conference
recently, but on conference calls, he’s pointed a number of times to a burgeoning credit crunch.
That is, the banks are deleveraging very sharply, and that’s beginning to have palpable effects on
economic activity in Europe. So it’s a stress situation. I believe that this would be the thrust of
what Brian was saying—that while short-term funding markets for banks and financial
institutions in the U.S. remain reasonably stable, the movements in stock prices and swap and
CDS spreads for U.S. financial institutions suggest that we are at some risk of having the stress
imported here.

November 28, 2011

16 of 40

The second call I had immediately consecutive to that was with the G-7 central bankers,
and there I would just want to convey to you the sense that it’s really important for central banks
globally to work together, to be seen to be coordinating and cooperating. It was felt that
cooperation in this particular matter would be another example that would be reassuring to
markets in general. In particular, there was very strong support across all of the central banks for
taking additional steps on the swaps. The proposal that has come from the group collectively—
this was not really the Fed’s initiative; it was partly our initiative, but it was a collective
decision—has three parts. One is to extend the swap lines. Of course, we could do that later, but
as part of a package, it seems to make sense. And the February 1, 2013, expiration would take us
over the year-end. The second element of the proposed package that we discussed in our call
was creating a complete network of swaps—every bilateral pair. Until now, it’s been U.S.
versus other counterparties; this would create a full, dense network of swaps between all bilateral
pairs of the G-7 currencies. In particular, that would mean that we would be signing up for the
option, of course—which we don’t have to use and probably wouldn’t use—of reciprocal swaps,
where we could access pounds or euros or yen if we so needed. I don’t anticipate we would need
that, but it does provide yet another element. The third element, as you know, would be to
reduce the swap rate to 50 basis points plus OIS. As was mentioned by Brian, the swap line rate
has just recently gone in the money at its current rate. We’re not seeing any activity. It’s
obvious that there is a significant stigma issue, and if the stigma is strong enough, then
essentially the backstop is ineffective. It doesn’t have any impact on market confidence. So
there was a view that by reducing the swap rate, making it more economical, we would reduce
the perceived stigma, and even if it were not heavily used—and I don’t anticipate it to be heavily

November 28, 2011

17 of 40

used—it would have a stabilizing effect, or at least a positive effect, on European funding
markets and then indirectly on U.S. credit markets as well.
President Fisher asked about the primary credit rate, and he’s correct that on this
proposal, the rate on swaps would be a little bit below the primary credit rate. I discussed this
with the Board, and I would have to say that our view is not strongly one way or the other. I
think that we could certainly take it up again. Clearly, there is some risk, as President Fisher
suggested, that we would be criticized for lending to “foreigners” at a lower rate than to U.S.
banks. There are a couple of arguments in the other direction, though, which I want to note. The
first is that we’ve been trying over time—and Dallas is one of the Federal Reserve Banks that
has pressed this—to normalize the spread between the funds rate and the primary credit rate.
And when we, in fact, moved up the primary credit rate to 75 basis points, it was actually quite a
communications challenge and led to some market swings. So, barring any need in terms of
domestic market conditions to cut the primary credit rate, it seems as though if we did that—
besides possibly signaling more concern than we have—we would then be in a situation where
we would have to again, in the future, move up the rate, and we would be further than ever from
a more normal spread between the funds rate and the discount window rate. So that’s one
observation, not necessarily dispositive. The other point, though, on the question of lending to
European banks: One advantage of keeping the primary credit rate where it is now is that it
would be very clear that we would want European banks to borrow from the ECB with those
additional credit guarantees rather than from our discount window. And that’s something we can
do with moral suasion, but this provides a market incentive for them to borrow from the ECB
rather than from us. I think that’s a good thing for us as well. So those were the reasons that the
Board—again, informally—seemed to have a mild preference for not cutting the PCR. But

November 28, 2011

18 of 40

again, this is something that we can certainly revisit, particularly if there’s a reaction that is
negative. But I guess my sense right now is that the benefits of leaving the PCR where it is are
slightly greater than the costs.
You’ve now heard the proposal. I’m happy to now open the floor. We don’t have to
have a formal go-round, but, of course, anyone who has questions, comments, or reactions is
more than welcome to speak. This is, of course, a meeting, and so your expressing your views
on policy is obviously perfectly appropriate. Who would like to start? President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I really have an FYI that leads to a
question. I take it from remarks earlier about the idea of a network of bilateral swap
arrangements that you would draw the line with the G-7 currencies.

552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

, who’s the governor of the central bank, and in a private
discussion, he made an appeal. Even though they have quite ample reserves at the moment, he
made an appeal for a swap line because they are concerned about the turbulence that could come
out of Europe that would affect hot money flows back and forth into
Maybe the Board has already heard officially from

552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

. So that’s the FYI.

or some other country, but I wanted to

mention that. The question, really, is the following: Is the current thinking that we would draw
the line with simply G-7 countries?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, we have a lot of interest from emerging market
economies in swap lines. As you know, we were up to 14 counterparties during the crisis.
552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

would very much like to have a swap

line with us. Obviously, today we’re talking about the G-7. My own sense is that, first of all,
there should be a higher bar to going to the emerging market counterparties, in part because of
greater counterparty risk. Second, the concerns they have are still prospective rather than actual

November 28, 2011

19 of 40

for the most part. Obviously, if we reached a very destructive situation, we would have to look
at that again. However, at this point in time, I am not planning to propose any further expansion.
But, of course, again, this is an FOMC decision, and if conditions warrant and the FOMC wants
to address it, that’s fine. But there’s no current plan in place to go beyond the G-7. Other
questions? President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I guess I’d advise against this. I think that,
basically, theatrics are important in a situation like this, and coordinated central bank action
would more or less send a panic signal without doing very much to actually help the situation.
We had the 100 basis point policy in place all the way through 2008 and 2009. It actually
worked quite well in that instance and did a lot to chase borrowers out to the market once
conditions returned to a more normal status. I like the 100 basis point penalty that we had
before, and given that it is battle tested, I don’t really see a good reason to change it here. I also
think the 50 basis point backstop would be unlikely to address any stigma issues. If there are
stigma issues, there’s stigma. And, as you point out, 100 basis points is already in the money
right now, and it doesn’t seem to me that things would change that much if we moved that to
50 basis points. We’re going to be under a lot of pressure and a lot of criticism that we’re
somehow bailing out the Europeans. That’s a very dangerous situation for the organization.
Also, I think that in Europe, the recent discussions of enforcing fiscal austerity at the EU level
are the first serious signs I’ve seen of some kind of significant reform that would actually address
the problem instead of piling debt on top of existing debt problems. So I’d be very reluctant to
take the pressure off the politicians in Europe on that process, however mild that might be,
because we’re a long way away and this is relatively minor policy on that.

November 28, 2011

20 of 40

On the extension, I would prefer to extend in some kind of regularly scheduled meeting,
preferably the January meeting. Then you could review swap lines every year in January and not
review them in the heat of the crisis when you’re actually sending a signal in conjunction with
the review of the swap lines. I think we’ve often been reviewing these in the heat of the
moment, and I’d prefer to review them at regularly scheduled times that do not contribute to the
problem. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Just a quick comment. I think there are a number of efforts
under way to address moral hazard and fiscal reform issues. The market situation is one that
might not comfortably await a regular meeting. We’ve also had these discussions with the
foreign central banks, and they all believe that this would be a positive for markets and a positive
for perception of cooperation and coordination. But again, that’s a judgment you have to make.
Other comments? President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. I’m strongly supportive of this action. I do think the financial
markets are badly disrupted, and it does make sense to address it in a coordinated effort. I do
have two questions. One is whether we have communicated with the other central banks about
the moral suasion issue—that there is an expectation that banks would be borrowing in their
home country when there is access to a swap line. Has that communication occurred, and do we
have a reason to believe that that moral suasion will be effective? Because I would have a mild
preference for actually having the rate at which both domestic and foreign banks borrow be the
same if we thought that moral suasion would be effective. My second question is on disclosure.
One part is whether or not we would be disclosing who’s tapping the lines by central bank in our
own releases. And the second part is whether any other central banks have different disclosure
requirements—in terms of banks borrowing from their central banks or in terms of them

November 28, 2011

21 of 40

borrowing from us. Have we thought through all of the disclosure issues? Because when we
think of stigma, disclosure is an important component of stigma, and given the Dodd–Frank
requirements for providing more information, I’d be curious about how we were thinking about
those disclosure issues across countries. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes—I’d be happy to get any help that’s needed—but let
me just say that on the moral suasion issue, we’ve been very clear, not only in the context of the
swaps, but also more generally, that the discount window is a very short-term facility, and that
we expect the Europeans and their regulators and their finance ministries to make sure that
European banks’ issues are being addressed by Europeans and not by the Federal Reserve.
We’ve gotten a few troubled cases out of the window, as you know, and I don’t believe we
currently have any significant lending to European banks. So, yes, we’ve been very clear
throughout that we don’t want the discount window to be used as a first resort for European
banks.
On disclosure, if I understand correctly from our previous practice, we would disclose
regularly the amounts drawn by each counterparty—that is, each central bank. We would not
know necessarily to whom they were lending, and I don’t know about each of the five
counterparties, but as far as I know, none of them disclose to whom they lend, although
sometimes it’s either obvious to figure out or becomes known. But, no, we would certainly not
be doing that, because our counterparties are the individual central banks.
MR. ALVAREZ. If I could add something there, Mr. Chairman. However, if we do the
reciprocal lines, and, for example, we then do transactions in yen with domestic banks, that
would be considered open market operations. We would disclose those eight quarters after the
transactions occurred.

November 28, 2011

22 of 40

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. This is an interesting question—I should have asked you
this before: If we got yen, could we lend yen through the discount window, or would it be only
an OMO type of thing?
MR. ALVAREZ. That’s a question of first impression. Because the System has never
lent any currency other than dollars, we’re looking into that. We clearly can do open market
operations with anyone in the market. If we consider it that way, then we would buy and sell the
yen, and we would treat that as open market operations for the Dodd–Frank Act. That would
involve eight-quarter disclosure.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. To get back to Eric’s question of disclosure, I’m trying to understand this.
If someone draws down one of these swap lines—I’m talking about the dollar lines—we’d book
it as a loan to a central bank. Is that correct?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes.
MR. FISHER. Once it is lent out, then, from that central bank—
MR. ALVAREZ. It’s not a loan. It’s a swap.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. But the counterparty is the central bank.
MR. ALVAREZ. Correct.
MR. FISHER. Right. Once that central bank lends it out, does it shift to a loan to
depository institutions, or does it stay as a swap?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. It stays as a swap.
MR. ALVAREZ. It stays the same.
MR. FISHER. So we have no way of knowing, to answer President Rosengren’s
question, where this ultimately ends up. It’s not disclosed. Is that correct?

November 28, 2011

23 of 40

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. It’s not disclosed. We could inquire, of course, but our
counterparty is the central bank. And they’re the ones who are responsible to us.
MR. FISHER. Okay. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman Dudley.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I strongly support this. I think creating a more effective
backstop for dollar liquidity is important. The way that it’s being proposed will signal
international policy coordination; we’ve seen historically through the crisis that international
policy coordination is perceived by the market very favorably. And cutting the rate will
encourage somewhat more usage, which will help destigmatize the facility. A destigmatized
facility is a more effective backstop than one that’s heavily stigmatized. I think the outcome
we’re trying to seek here is that by having a more effective dollar backstop, we’ll have less
forced deleveraging by European banks of their dollar books of assets How fast they deleverage
those books of assets has real consequences for the United States’ economy. That’s really the
connection in terms of what’s in it for us; I think there really is something in it for us, and we
shouldn’t lose sight of that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I would commend to the group an article by my excolleague at Princeton, Hyun Shin, which looks at the transmission of credit from U.S. dollar
sources and other dollar sources through the European banking system. Much of that dollar
funding flows back into the United States. This, in fact, is addressing a funding problem of a
credit source, which in turn affects U.S. borrowers. So there is a connection that we can point to.
Other questions or comments? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I’m torn on this issue. There is a code among central
bankers. I think Vice Chairman Dudley is correct from the standpoint that we’re most effective

November 28, 2011

24 of 40

when we work together. We’ve learned this from our own history. I think we have a
communications problem here, which I would ask you to address. You made the correct point
that we—and you used the term “we”—are trying and have been making efforts to normalize
rates. And you’re right—Dallas and one other Bank have been rather aggressive on that front.
I’m very worried about what’s going on in Europe. It’s a political mare’s nest, and the
sovereignty issues are horrifically vexing. I’m also quite concerned about where the European
banking system is—the false stress tests that they put together before and now the real effort—I
know we’re having an influence on them—to make sure that they get their capital ratios
organized. Obviously, we know how they’re doing it. They’d like to issue tier 1 equity, but
that’s not easy in these markets. They’re cutting back, therefore, on their risk-weighted assets
and on their lending. The Commerzbank call to the analysts this past week had very clear
instructions and a revelation that they’ve instructed their bankers to lend only to Poland and to
Germany, and they’re just cutting out other activities. So we know some deleveraging is taking
place. Shriveling up of other credits, including dollar-based credits, is happening, and I think
Vice Chairman Dudley is absolutely correct. We all understand this. It comes back to bite us on
the rear end.
What I’m most concerned about here is the reaction to our lending to others at less than
we lend to the highest-quality community, regional, and large banks in this country. I wouldn’t
understate or underestimate how that might reverberate negatively against us. I’m a little
concerned that we’ve agreed to OIS plus 50 basis points. If it were OIS plus whatever equates to
75, assuming OIS is 12, I’d be more comfortable. And that just gives me pause. I don’t think
that just issuing this statement, which does not refer to the OIS plus 50, is problematic. I do
think it becomes problematic in terms of the execution and, again, in the minds of those on both

November 28, 2011

25 of 40

sides of the aisle in the Congress. There is a tradeoff here. We do want to normalize rates, but
we’ve been presented with a very difficult circumstance that poses risk to us. And I think we
need to noodle that through before we make a decision. Again, I’ve been probably the most
aggressive advocate for normalizing rates. We’ve pulled back from that recently, but just
because of the circumstance. I don’t think we could easily answer those questions unless we
deal with our highest-quality domestic credits. I think it would be very, very difficult,
particularly with the community banks, the regional banks—which are high quality, from which
we demand substantial and measurable collateral to make a loan—to say that we’re trusting other
institutions. Again, they’re our brethren. These are central bankers. We understand the code.
But it presents a huge communications problem, and the question is whether we should take
action or just try to deal with it through communications. And I’d leave that up to the rest of the
group to decide, but I wouldn’t understate it. I think the optics are not very good, particularly
when we’re under the microscope—or certainly the magnifying glass. That’s my biggest
concern, Mr. Chairman. I’m torn on whether or not I can support this, unless we have a clear
understanding of how we’re going to deal with that. It might be through a press conference on
your part. It might be through other efforts to communicate. But it’s a hard sell. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me make a couple of comments. Others on the Board
can speak to this if they wish. As I said, while there was not a strong preference in this regard,
there was the advantage of pushing European banks away from our window toward the foreign
central banks, which, by the way, because they are our counterparties, you could argue that, from
a credit risk perspective, they’re actually better risks than banks. But I suppose that’s a different
question. I would say two other things, if I could. One is that—and President Bullard raised this

November 28, 2011

26 of 40

as well—while deliberation is certainly important, we are in a very serious situation, one that is
changing quickly. I don’t think we’re in a mode, of course, where we should be panicking or
anything like that. But obviously, I think speed is useful and preemption is useful. I hesitate to
make this argument, but I will anyway: I personally negotiated some of these ideas with my
counterparts in the other central banks. And I do need to have a little bit of flexibility, I hope, to
represent the Federal Reserve’s point of view in international discussions. Now, obviously, if
you’re opposed to this action, by all means, you should vote against it. But if you’re close to the
edge, I would ask that to be an additional consideration. It’s very difficult for me to consult
continually with the FOMC at the same time that we’re having calls and discussions and
meetings with our foreign counterparties. But to go back to your main point, President Fisher,
rather than defend this to the death, if in fact we do run into problems, the Board can consider
making a change. We can do it in a few hours if we have to.
MR. FISHER. I think, Mr. Chairman, first of all, that nobody wants to undermine you,
and I certainly personally never wish to undermine you. And I do think you have to have the
leeway you discussed. I do find more convincing the explanation you gave us earlier, which is,
we’re not lending through the discount window. And we’ve had criticism of lending to foreign
borrowers through the discount window, so we’re not changing there. We’re lending to another
central bank and within the fraternity and sorority of central banks around the world. All I’m
suggesting is that we really think through how this will be communicated, because we know—or
at least I’m willing to surmise—that there will be tough questions asked, and we just have to be
clear. And that goes beyond what the statement said. So the question is whether there is a
vehicle for you to do that. I’m not against the proposal; I have concerns about the proposal. Its
effectiveness will be dependent on how we communicate it. I’m just raising that flag and asking

November 28, 2011

27 of 40

us to think this through, as to how we get it done so we don’t end up pulling the rug out from
underneath you or from the purpose of the exercise. That’s my point.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I appreciate that. I agree—communication is a big part of
this. President Bullard was next on my list.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. On expected usage, I understood Vice
Chairman Dudley to argue that usage would probably be up substantially because of the
deleveraging in Europe, but I understood you to say that you didn’t think these swap lines would
be used that much. So I think we should try to get some clarity on where we really think usage is
likely to go. I’d also say that under the 100 basis point policy, we didn’t seem to have any
trouble getting people to use the facility during 2008 and 2009. So I’m wondering what’s
changed this time. And I’m a little concerned that at 50 basis points, if the dollar funding
remains in the money, then you could end up with the addicted banking system in Europe that
wants the dollar funding over the long term, and then we don’t really get out of the swap lines
the way we did in 2008 and 2009. The 100 basis point policy was very useful from that point of
view, and you got those banks to seek other sources during that time.
As far as the signaling goes, I disagree with the way the other central banks see this.
They want to send a united signal, which I would interpret mostly as they want to get the Fed on
board, but I don’t think that this is the way to go in this crisis. What you’ve got are governments
that are counting on central banks to bail them out, and you need to keep pressure on those
governments to get the fiscal austerity that they need. They’ve borrowed way too much, and
they’re certainly hoping that central banks will somehow bail them out, so we’re sending exactly
the wrong signal. I can believe other central banks want to do it, but I don’t think it’s a good
idea, and I don’t think it’s a good way to manage a crisis. Again, I would prefer to review swap

November 28, 2011

28 of 40

lines at regular junctures, not at particular moments of intense turmoil in markets. That’s a better
way to go, and then you get rid of the signaling problem of a panic mode and a signal that the
central banks are all coming to the governments’ rescue. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. On the exit problem, the fact is, of course, that all of the
loans are for finite periods, and we can stop lending anytime we want, or we can raise the rate
anytime we want. So I don’t think that is a real issue.
I don’t know how much the swap borrowing would increase. Maybe Vice Chairman
Dudley has a thought. My thinking on why it would not be so large is that if it does create more
assurance, it will ease the flow of private money, because of the backstop feature, so that the
funding can take place through private channels. But I obviously don’t know for sure. Vice
Chairman Dudley, you have a two-handed response to that?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes. I think you’re absolutely right—we don’t know for
sure. We want some increase in usage because if we didn’t get an increase in usage, it would
just show us that the swap lines were still very stigmatized. So we want some increase in usage,
which would serve to destigmatize the swaps, make them more effective as a backstop, and
therefore keep more private-sector players in the game. I think you’d see some increase in
usage. How much depends on how well we actually are destigmatizing the facility so it serves as
an effective backstop. I don’t know if it would be substantial or small. All we can say is that
reducing the rate from 100 basis points to 50 basis points does two things: One, it increases the
economics of using the swap facilities to a degree; and, two, it allows people who had been
staying out to now say, “Oh, it’s now okay to use this facility.” If you have a number of people
use it rather than just two or three, then the facility becomes destigmatized, and so it becomes
more effective as a backstop. That’s how I see it.

November 28, 2011

29 of 40

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thanks. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support this resolution today. I think that
it’s a relatively small action given everything that’s going on. As Vice Chairman Dudley just
mentioned, I’m not sure if this will solve the stigma problem, but we can find out. Showing
coordination with the other G-7 central banks is helpful in the current situation. Having listened
to the discussion from President Fisher and President Rosengren, I am a little nervous about the
discount rate alignment. It might be worth thinking through more carefully whether or not
reducing the discount rate to 50 basis points would be a good idea to align it with the overall
borrowing incentives associated with this swap. Trying to avoid any appearance that we’re
attempting to skirt disclosure requirements might be helpful, but that’s for the Board to decide,
obviously. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you. President Fisher, I had a lot of the same concerns about what
this said in terms of the difference in the borrowing rates to our banks versus the foreign central
banks. But here is the reason I’ve come out on the side of doing nothing with the primary credit
rate at this point. First of all, I think there would certainly be some risk that in communicating
the reduction in the primary credit rate, you could get some speculation as to what U.S. banks we
were reducing it for and what the reason—changes in financial conditions in U.S. banks—for
that was. To the extent that it actually did encourage usage of our discount window at the same
time, there’s always the speculation as to who’s in there using that rate. Also, we will be
reporting to the Congress who was using the discount window. All of that seemed to me to raise
a lot of questions that might actually be more harmful to U.S. banks than not. Finally, if you
haven’t lowered it yet, you can always lower it. And if there does get to be a very public

November 28, 2011

30 of 40

criticism about the difference in the rates, then you can very specifically respond to that criticism
by changing the rate, and it seems to me that the communication challenge is a little bit easier
then. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m going to respectfully recommend that
we don’t pursue this course for many of the same reasons that President Bullard expressed. I can
understand how funding can suddenly dry up for a financial institution, as in the case of
MF Global. I can understand how funding pressures can emerge for a broad set of market
participants. But I don’t see us in a situation where there’s a deficiency of liquidity supply. Just
look at our balance sheet. There’s plenty of liquidity in dollars available in the marketplace.
What I think we see is a deficiency in the willingness to lend to particular institutions, largely for
the reason that they’re viewed as riskier. What we know both from public sources and from
supervisory sources suggests that that reluctance in the marketplace lines up pretty well with
differences in the riskiness of those counterparties. I don’t see any evidence that it doesn’t
reflect a difference in concerns about creditworthiness. And so this doesn’t seem like a matter of
market efficiency or functioning. It seems as though intervention here would be distributional.
More broadly, I think some financial strains are consistent with a well-functioning set of
markets. MF Global is a great example of that. I don’t think that’s a case where we should have
intervened, and I don’t see MF Global’s demise as a failure of market functioning, apart from the
fraud they committed relative to the use of funds. More central bank credit is always going to be
seen as positive for markets. So I don’t think the fact that markets would view this as positive is
an argument for doing this. A farm bill is always positive for agricultural land prices, but it’s not
an argument that you want an infinitely large farm bill.

November 28, 2011

31 of 40

My predecessors have a long history of dissenting on foreign exchange operations. The
reasoning is that, like other central bank credit actions, they essentially involve fiscal policy,
they’re distributional, and they’re essentially end runs around constitutional appropriations
policy, and that entangles us in political controversy. I think that, as I said, applies to virtually
all central bank credit extension. That’s why we’ve declared, as a Committee, our intention to
get back to a Treasury-only balance sheet as soon as we can. And I’d argue that this dynamic
has contributed to the hostile political environment that we currently face. More broadly, an
expansion of central bank swap lines is going to send the message of an implied backstop
commitment that I think is too large. It’s counterproductive. It will contribute to financial
instability rather than reduce it.
So I remain respectfully opposed to additional swap arrangements to support our
provision of liquidity in foreign currencies. I agree with those who highlight the political risk
that would be associated, I think, with offering these central bank swaps on terms that are more
advantageous than those we offer at the discount window to domestic borrowers. I would urge
you, Mr. Chairman, if we go down this road, to consult with your colleagues and ask them if a
straight 75 basis points would be acceptable, rather than 50 over OIS. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. I have Governor Raskin next.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a couple of operational issues that are
suggested by the text that I thought would be worth getting some clarification on. First of all, I
was wondering whether we know the timing of other central bank announcements, if we were to
go forward with this.

November 28, 2011

32 of 40

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All six banks will announce simultaneously before markets
open on Wednesday.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you. Second, in terms of the process that is suggested in the
second paragraph of the resolution, there is a sentence in it that indicates that the “requests for
drawings on the foreign currency swap lines and distribution of the proceeds to U.S. financial
institutions shall be initiated by the appropriate Reserve Bank and approved by the Chairman in
consultation with the Foreign Currency Subcommittee.” One question I have on that process is
really about the statement of approval by the Chairman, and the question is whether that is an
“approved or denied,” or is the implication that it would be, in essence, “approved”?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Scott, will you help?
MR. ALVAREZ. I think this would give the Chairman the latitude, after consulting with
the subcommittee and informing the full Committee, to deny draws or approve draws.
MS. RASKIN. So it’s “approved or denied”?
MR. ALVAREZ. Yes.
MS. RASKIN. Okay. And in that same sentence, the idea about “distribution of the
proceeds to U.S. financial institutions”—to come back to the earlier part of the conversation
regarding transparency, would the distribution of proceeds to U.S. financial institutions be
disclosed?
MR. ALVAREZ. Yes. Remember, there are two directions that these swaps would work
in. There are the swaps with the foreign central bank that they disseminate through their
mechanisms and their countries. The disclosure of that would all be done by the foreign central
bank, if at all—not by us. We do disclose that we’ve had the swap with the foreign central bank
and how much draw there has been by that foreign central bank. But the clause you’re referring

November 28, 2011

33 of 40

to is the reciprocal side of the line. So if we were to allow an institution in the United States to
draw down yen that we had taken from a swap line, for example, then we would consider that an
open market operation, the sale of foreign exchange in the open market. We would have to
disclose that eight quarters after the transaction had occurred. We would make a disclosure of
our counterparty and the amount and the rate, but it would be done in the future.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions, comments? President Lacker has two
hands.
MR. LACKER. Yes, I’d like to follow up on this point. It says “initiated by the
appropriate Reserve Bank.” That seems to parallel the discount window and the way it works,
and that Reserve Bank is essentially in charge of lending to an institution in its District. But this
is an open market operation? Would this be administered through New York? And, more
broadly, should we go down this path? Do you have in mind any protocol for deciding on an
individual institution in a given District outside New York? What if the Reserve Bank doesn’t
initiate it?
MR. ALVAREZ. I’ll leave the policy issue to others, but on the operational side, the
thought was that because each financial institution—bank, in particular—has accounts at its local
Reserve Bank, it made sense for banks in particular to deal with the Reserve Bank where they
had an account and then for the Reserve Bank—say, Richmond—to obtain the currency from the
SOMA. That was an easier operational method than having banks deal directly with New York,
which wouldn’t have the account set up for the bank. So they’re OMO transactions, but we
would be dealing with counterparties beyond the primary dealers, which are normally who we do
the OMO transactions with.

November 28, 2011

34 of 40

MR. LACKER. Would this just be with banks, or could it be with any affiliates?
MR. ALVAREZ. It could be done with any financial institution, the way the resolution is
worded. So that would include affiliates as well.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think it’s important that we get these details straight, but I
would hope we don’t get too far down this line because this is a pretty hypothetical situation.
President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, the way the statement is written, there’s no mention of the
rate we would charge. It does say that “the Chairman shall establish the rates on the swap
arrangements by mutual agreement with the foreign central banks and in consultation with the
Foreign Currency Subcommittee,” and that you’ll keep us informed. I assume that paragraph
applies to both sets of swap arrangements—the dollar swaps and the foreign currency swaps—is
that correct?
MR. ENGLISH. Yes, that’s right.
MR. FISHER. Okay. And that it’ll be “consistent with principles discussed with and
guidance provided by the Committee.” Again, my guidance, for what it’s worth, as an individual
on the Committee and as a voter, is that we not lend at less than what we lend to high-quality
U.S. banks. You will have the freedom under this, in consultation with the Foreign Currency
Subcommittee, to make that decision. I want to be extremely careful here in terms of not
undermining authority. You’re primus inter pares; you’re the Chairman. But I do think it is
inadvisable for us to lend—despite the counterarguments, which are helpful and should be
articulated—at less than we lend to our domestic counterparts; I have real trouble supporting
that. I guess—and please don’t take offense—I don’t like the process with which this has been
developed. I think we should have had this discussion at some point to highlight what these

November 28, 2011

35 of 40

obstacles are. Obviously, you know us all well. You’re making the best judgment possible, and
you are the central bank in the eyes of our counterparts. But that is a very tough one for me to
swallow as an individual member of this Committee. And then the second thing, which
President Rosengren and President Evans mentioned, is the transparency issue. I’m sure we’re
going to get questions. We have to be prepared to deal with that. Again, when we release the
statement, we’re not going to state the rate, as I understand it. We are going to say that you will
establish the rate in consultation.
MR. ENGLISH. No, I think there’s a distinction that you need to make between the
resolution that the Committee will pass and the statement that will be released Wednesday
morning before the opening of business, which is being negotiated.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Right. There will be a press release.
MR. FISHER. So you’re asking us to agree, then, on the 50 basis points—is that correct?
And we would make that public?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, technically, you’re agreeing to delegate it to me, in
consultation with the Foreign Currency Subcommittee. But I’m informing you that it would be
my intention, along with the other five central banks, to agree to a rate of 50 basis points plus
OIS.
MR. FISHER. Would we record minutes of this meeting, where you had some concerns
expressed about lending at less than we would have lent to the domestic banks?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Of course. This is a formal meeting, and it’ll have minutes
and transcripts.
MR. FISHER. Well, again, I’m worried about putting you in an uncomfortable position.
There is a principle here that I’m worried about as well, and then there is the reactive aspect of

November 28, 2011

36 of 40

this, which I’m concerned about. If I may just put my cards on the table, in answer to Governor
Duke’s question, I think it would be a mistake to cut the rate to domestic banks to 50 basis points
and do it simultaneously. I believe we would then panic the markets. So, Governor Duke, I
agree with you. I think it would send a bad signal. I wouldn’t close that door, depending on
what happens in terms of economic developments. Where I come down personally is that we
should not have agreed to 50 basis points. We should have agreed to 75 or 12 basis points less
than that, wherever OIS is. But this is a dilemma because, again, we don’t want to undermine
our standing, and certainly we don’t want to undermine your standing. So I’m just being utterly
frank here. I think that’s the biggest problem with this proposal—the 50 basis points. Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman Dudley.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I just wanted to make the very simple point that we think
it’s highly unlikely that we’d ever be lending foreign currencies to U.S. depository institutions or
other financial institutions. So all of this discussion about how these bilateral swap lines would
actually work in practice is, as you said, hypothetical—extremely hypothetical. My
understanding of why the bilateral swap lines are even on the table is that this is just something
that the other central banks would like to see to signal the greatest degree of international policy
coordination, as opposed to a need that we think we actually are, under any reasonable scenario,
likely to ever have.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Any other questions or comments? [No
response] All right. Well, I thank you for the discussion. The reservations are noted. I
appreciate, Richard, the points you made. We are somewhat reactive of necessity. The world is
changing quickly, and we are trying to coordinate with five other central banks, which makes it

November 28, 2011

37 of 40

more difficult to do things with a long lead time. My view is that this is a helpful step, not a
major step. But I am quite concerned about market developments in general, and I think we
should be prepared to have another meeting should that be necessary. As I said before, my
concern is that it’s even worse than political. I think the Europeans just do not, in some sense,
get it, to use the vernacular. I don’t believe they understand quite how dangerous the situation is
that they’re involved in. They are, of course, in a situation where politicians are making the
decisions, and they have many concerns other than the ideal economic outcome.
If there are no further comments, given that there were some concerns, I think we
probably should take a roll call vote on this. Debbie.
MS. DANKER. Okay. This vote is on the resolution that was sent around this morning.
Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Dudley
Governor Duke
President Evans
President Fisher

Yes
Yes—a hundred times, yes. [Laughter]
Yes
Yes

MR. FISHER. This is just on the section in quotes, is that correct?
MS. DANKER. That’s correct. It’s the resolution.
President Fisher
President Kocherlakota
President Lacker
[Laughter]

Yes—thank you. Reluctantly, yes.
Yes
No—and I’d like to know if I can vote a hundred times, too?

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. By the way, President Lacker is voting in place of President
Plosser, who was unable to join us today.
Governor Raskin
Governor Tarullo
Governor Yellen

Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. Thank you, again, and we will do our best to
keep you well informed. And, if not sooner, we will see you in a couple of weeks. Thank you.

November 28, 2011

38 of 40

END OF MEETING