View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC Notes -- Peter Fisher

SEPTEMBER 27, 1994

Mr. Chairman,
I will be briefly referring to the two pages of color charts
handed out this morning.

There are three main points I would like to make about
international market developments since your last meeting:
First, market participants are attempting to discern more
refined differences in the business cycles of the major
industrial countries;
Second, the dollar has traded against the mark and the yen
in ranges which reflect the clearing prices between quite
divergent views about its prospects; and
Third, Mexican financial markets were stable through the
Presidential election and the peso has responded positively
to the news that the new "Pacto" includes no change in the
speed of the peso's crawling peg to the dollar.
As the summer came to an end, market participants began to
ask themselves more focused questions about the different
economic conditions of the major countries.

Instead of asking

only whether a country was in or out of recession, whether its
interest rates were headed down or up, they have begun the more
intensive process of drawing increasingly refined distinctions
among national

cyclical conditions and prospects.

I have updated the chart of the quarterly percent change in
total-return indices for G-7 bond markets, which I showed you in
August.

Looking particularly at the latter half of the third

quarter, you can see the much greater differentiation among
markets that occurred in contrast to most of the rest of the

- 2

year.

-

I mention this because I think that, if this process of

differentiation continues, we could begin to see greater movement
in the major exchange rates than we have had over the past
several months.

Dollar-mark is little changed from its level at the time of
your last meeting.

Its relatively limited range has reflected

divergent views over whether short-term differentials will move
in the dollar's favor and over how U.S. and European bond market
developments will affect the dollar.

With respect to the short end, there are some in the market
who think that the Committee will raise rates at this meeting and
will ultimately put in 100 basis points before year-end.

There

are also a number of market participants who expect the
Bundesbank to lower official rates by as much as 50 basis points
after the October 16th German federal elections.

Thus, with

overnight rates now virtually identical, there is a plausible
view that short-term dollar interest rates could have a 150basis-point advantage over the mark by Christmas.

However, there are other market participants who expect the
Committee to wait to raise rates until November or December and
to do so only once this year.

It is also thought possible that

the Bundesbank will not lower rates again and could even raise
them.

In this view, the short-end, U.S.-German differential

-

3

-

might only be 50 basis points in the dollar's favor by year-end
or could be unchanged.

As indicated on the second page of the charts, the December
interest rate futures contracts currently imply a differential of
about 60 basis points in the dollar's favor in three-month eurorates at year-end.

However, given the losses sustained in the

first half of the year by those who traded dollar-mark on
expected shifts in short-term differentials, the current
expectations seem to be having less of an impact on dollar-mark
as exchange market participants look increasingly at bond market
developments.

With respect to the long end, there is one school of thought
which asserts that without prompt rate hikes by the Fed, pushing
U.S. 10-year yields significantly above comparable German and
European ones, the dollar will continue to move lower in the face
of our large and growing current account deficit.

While there is

an obvious logic to the view that the dollar will strengthen WHEN
long-term, interest rate differentials are decisively in its
favor, a different school of thought notes that, so far this
year, the dollar has weakened AS U.S. interest rates HAVE BEEN
rising.

Indeed, particularly in recent weeks, the dollar has

- 4

-

responded quite positively to price rallies in the bond market and
negatively to signs that yields were backing up.

If all this feels like a bit of a muddle, I think that is
precisely how -- collectively -- the exchange market feels and

why dollar-mark has traded with decreasing conviction and
direction.

Dollar-yen's recent range has also reflected contending and
divergent views, in this case between those who have thought it
might be able to move up to 105 yen and beyond and those who
think that it will either continue to grind lower or might yet
again drop sharply as a result of the trade talks.

Early in the period the dollar briefly strengthened to above
100 yen.

This appeared to reflect the market's perception of

improvements in trade-talk rhetoric and in the prospects for the
strengthening Japanese economy to absorb more imports.

Since

then, the dollar traded back and forth around 99 yen until last
Tuesday when it came off sharply following the announcement of
the worse-than-expected increase in the overall U.S. goods and
services deficit.

This data release served as a reminder of the

sluggishness of trade flows and invigorated the view that,
regardless of outcome, the trade talks are unlikely to have a
meaningful impact on the bilateral flows between Japan and the
U.S. for the foreseeable future.

-

5

-

Over the period, the Bank of Japan intervened purchasing
dollars against the yen.

Of this total,

as their agent.

the Desk purchased

Looking forward to September 30th, the dominant expectation
is that the trade talks will result either in modest progress in
some sectors or in a papering over of disagreements.

While

market participants have begun to consider the possibility of
some limited sanctions being applied, I think that HOW the
September 30th announcement is made is likely to be as important
as WHAT is announced.

For example, I can imagine an announcement

of modest progress and no sanctions, but which is accompanied by
extreme, national-competitiveness rhetoric, as having AS negative
an impact on dollar-yen as would a calm, business-like
announcement of limited sanctions described as intended to reduce
the bilateral trade deficit.

Mexican markets fared quite well through the Presidential
election and the peso has gained following this past weekend's
announcement that the new PACTO contains no change in the rate of
the peso's devaluation in its crawling peg to the dollar.

Late

last week, as the market came to expect the announcement of no
change in the peg, the peso strengthened, one-year interest rates
fell by over 50 basis points and the stock market gained.
Yesterday was a bit choppier: the stock market sold off -- it

being at rather lofty levels-- and the peso firmed a bit further,

-

6

-

then sold off, but still closed higher than Friday's close.

The

peso faced some difficult circumstances this week as a result of
the combination of this meeting, the maturity today of a large
amount of dollar-indexed Mexican government debt and regular
quarter-end demand for dollars.

However, from Thursday's close

to yesterday's close, the peso was up 0.8 percent.

The Canadian dollar has also strengthened, following the
much narrower-than-feared victory of the Quebec separatist bloc
in the provincial elections which reduced prospects for the
success of a separatist referendum.

With the Canadian dollar up

over one and a half percent since September 12th, the Bank of
Canada acted last Wednesday to maintain its existing mix of
monetary conditions through money market operations indicating a
25-basis-point reduction in its target range for call money
rates.

Mr. Chairman we had no intervention operations during the
period.

However, we have distributed a memorandum on certain

changes that are planned for the investment of Deutsche mark
reserves.

I would be happy to answer questions perhaps first on

my report and second on the memorandum.

CHART 1

Quarterly Percent Changes of G-7 Total Return Bond Indices

4.0

4.0

2.0

2.0

0.0

0.0

-2.0

-2.0

-4.0

-4.0

-6.0

-6.0
Jan

Feb
US

Mar

Apr

May

Jul

Aug

Sep

Germany Japan France Canada

UK

Italy

Foreign Exchange Function: FRBNY
Updated September 23, 1994

Jun

Source: JP Morgan

CHART 2

Interest Rates Implied by Prices of December 1994
3-Month Eurodeposit Futures Contracts
6.2

6.2

6.0

6.0

5.8

5.8

5.6

5.6

5.4

5.4

5.2

5.2

5.0

5.0

4.8
Jul

4.8

Sep

Aug

Interest Rates Implied by Prices of Series of
3-Month Eurodeposit Futures Contracts
----- - -

8.0 - - - - - - - -- - - - - - - -- - -

8.0
7.5

7.0 -----

---

7.0

Euro $
-------------

6.5-----Q-

-

6.0 -- -----

--------------

Euro DM

6.5

----

6.0

- -

5.5

5.5
- - -

5.0 -----d

P

0~

5.0
~.

:

%

Foreign Exchange Function: FRBNY
Updated September 23,1994

c

^^

s

0-

oo

C

c

to
.

C
-

Co
o

c

\N

Z-

Source: Bloomberg Information Service

Notes for FOMC Meeting
September 27, 1994
Joan E. Lovett

During the intermeeting period, we sought to maintain
the firmer degree of reserve pressure adopted at your August 16
meeting, with Federal funds expected to trade around 4 3/4 percent.

The borrowing allowance was left unchanged at that time

because the full 50 basis point hike in the discount rate, also
approved that day, was allowed to show through fully to the
reserves market.

The allowance was lifted by $50 million in two

steps early in the interval and later cut back by $25 million, in
each case to accommodate movements in seasonal demands.
stands at $475 million.

It now

Adjustment borrowing was generally very

light and averaged just $35 million.
The sizable reserve shortages we faced at the start of
the intermeeting period were expected to deepen further in
September, first as a result of high levels of currency and
required reserves around the Labor Day holiday, and later when
inflows around the September 15 corporate and individual
nonwithheld tax date would lift the Treasury's Fed balance.
To help address the largest expected reserve shortages,
we resumed purchasing securities from foreign accounts, acquiring
about $900 million of Treasury bills from this source in the
early days of the period.

We then purchased about $4 1/2 billion

of Treasury coupon issues in the market on August 30.

2
Temporary operations met the balance of remaining

reserve needs.

We arranged a total of seven multiday System

operations and five overnight RPs, most of which were customerrelated.

The larger multiday operations came in the first full

maintenance period ahead of the coupon pass.

Much smaller-sized

RPs were generally arranged in subsequent periods.
Our market entries in the current maintenance period-which ends tomorrow--have been particularly light.

The earlier

outright purchases, cumulative downward revisions to currency,
and a Treasury balance that never quite reached the higher levels
that were first anticipated for mid-September left the reserve
estimates in this period close to path or even showing a modest
surplus.

Consequently, we have entered the market on just two

occasions during this period, arranging a modest volume of
customer RPs.

The revisions to currency growth were a surprise:

the growth rate for the two months ending in September was an
estimated 6 1/2 percent, about 1 1/2 percentage points below the
New York staff's mid-August forecast and about 5 percentage
points below the average rate for the first seven months of the
year.

Data are available only for August and suggest that the

slower growth then was not due to a weakening of foreign demand.
The effective funds rate often traded with a slightly
soft cast over the interval, partly reflecting a general absence
of large reserve deficiencies on most days.

Since your last

meeting, the effective rate has averaged 4.71 percent.

3
In the securities markets, interest rates were buffeted

by shifting perceptions about the economic outlook, the pace of
inflation, and the immediacy of Fed policy actions.
participation in the market was sometimes very light,

Investor
but was

interspersed with bouts of intense activity on some days.
policy moves announced in August were viewed favorably.

The
Very

short-term rates immediately backed up to reflect the tighter
reserve conditions, but yields on Treasury coupons dropped 5 to
10 basis points that day.

Since then, however, these yields have

worked their way higher in erratic fashion, rising a net 20 to
40 basis points, accompanied by some steepening in the yield
curve.
Over the first several weeks after the August meeting,
movements in yields generally backed and filled within
established trading ranges.

The data released during this time

provided a somewhat mixed picture of the economy, which
contributed to some volatility in rates, best illustrated by the
gyrations that followed the release of the August payroll data in
early September when the market both gained and lost ground on
the same day.
Yields broke out decisively on the upside in midSeptember as the evidence seemed to tilt toward a visible
quickening of price pressures.

Steep losses on two consecutive

Fridays brought yields to new highs for the year.

To many

analysts, the August PPI report was a first glimpse of higher
inflation rates in a broad-based measure which some of the more

4
leading price indicators had been hinting at previously.
the

industrial production

Then,

and capacity utilization reports

released a week later were taken as a sign that some strains were
already being placed on operating capacity in the manufacturing
sector, and yields surged higher across the yield curve with the
current bond yield moving above 7 3/4 percent.

Most analysts now

seem confident that, after a pause in the current quarter,
economic activity will resume at a pace into next year that will
maintain some upward pressure on inflation, although views
diverge on where these forces will peak in the current cycle.
The financial markets did not have to absorb a
significant amount of new supply this intermeeting period, either
from the Treasury or in other sectors.

The Treasury paid down a

substantial amount of bills, about $19 billion, mostly when
several cash management bills came due last Thursday.

The

expected reinvestment demand associated with these maturing bills
and a desire to stay defensive in the current market climate
helped keep short-term rates in check until last week, when the
market actively began to revise its near-term rate outlook.

Net

issuance of coupon securities was also fairly moderate, about
$15 billion altogether, which does not include the two-year notes
that will be sold early this afternoon or tomorrow's five-year
offering.

5
A reassessment of policy prospects has accompanied the
changing perceptions about the economy over the past few weeks.
Many analysts believe that Fed tightening to date will not
.suffice to bring growth to a non-inflationary pace, and that
policy will eventually reach a greater degree of restraint than
they previously thought.

There is also a fairly general

consensus that the next policy step, whenever it comes, will take
the form of a 50 basis point hike in rates, although the
possibility of a smaller move is not entirely ruled out.
While the perception remains that rates are headed
higher, and that a Fed move is possible sooner than expected only
a few weeks ago, views are split on the need for immediate
action.

One camp holds that the Fed must move without delay to

prevent price pressures from building further, and that not
acting now would court the emergence of an inflation psychology.
Others feel that the case for an immediate move is not conclusive
and that there is an acceptable risk to holding off, awaiting
some confirmation of the economy's momentum in upcoming reports
or until the November meeting.

Current market surveys would

probably place the majority in the second camp.
to answer any questions you may have.

I would be happy

Michael J. Prell
September 27. 1994

FOMC BRIEFING

It
having to
of

is with more than

report to you,

near-term economic

a little

once

chagrin that

again, that

growth.

Moreover,

we

have

I find myself

raised our

the surprising

momentum of

activity suggests to us that money market rates may still
short of the level needed to hold inflation
Admittedly, it
of a sharper
in the

our thesis.

Notably, durable

in July, and production worker hours

August.

looked for

short

a while like

of the

of light vehicles

smartly:

this pattern

earlier slump in

spending in August,

surveys,

fit

in the

surged

orders dropped

slipped

a bit

in

third-quarter GDP growth might

in August as

production

provided validation for

retail
but

with the

goods

quickly tipped back in the other direction.

sales owed

report on non-auto

seemed to

Indeed,

last Greenbook forecast.

But the scales
Sales

previous forecast

in activity was wrong.

appreciably

even fall

our

of the intermeeting period, the incoming indicators

support

It

be well

in check.

certain that

second-half deceleration

early part

seemed to

is not yet

forecast

importantly to

sales

revealed

fairly buoyant

face of a continuing

the story that the

supply problems.

not

upward revisions

picked up

only a healthy

to prior months.

sentiment
rise

evidenced

in interest

Next,
advance
All

of

rates

against much slackening in the pace of
only did

overall

expansion over the summer

production

months.

Not

percent,

but manufacturing output

soared

rise an estimated

0.7

a full

point.

percentage

this

that many

for August clearly argued

industrial production data

in

in household

analysts had thought would damage confidence.
The

the

FOMC Briefing--September 27,

1994

Michael J.

Prell

With upward revisions to each of the prior three months as well,

it

now looks like factory output will rise almost 7 percent, at an annual
rate, in the third quarter.
Meanwhile, initial claims for jobless benefits have remained
near their lowest levels of this expansion, suggesting that the
September labor market report will reveal a sustained strong pace of
payroll growth.
If these data were not enough to call into question our
notion that the negative effects

of higher interest rates on aggregate

demand were about to manifest themselves more clearly, the figures on
housing permits and starts released last week certainly did.

The

report showed that single-family building in August was at virtually
the same level as had prevailed since the spring.

We still

see some

signs of softening in this sector in other indicators, but the starts
data did seem to require some upward adjustment of our forecast of
residential

investment.

Given these developments--and also the prospect of a steeper
rise in auto assemblies than we had anticipated earlier

(barring a

strike)--we decided to elevate our fourth-quarter GDP forecast
point,
could
always

be giving up
a hazard in

on a good

perceive the

is

rates

recognized the

as that

of

falling

But,

that

said,

we

revised near-term forecast

to be

short.

conclusion, we

any reasons we could

asked ourselves whether

identify for why the

might be having a relatively muted effect

One answer to that

risk that we

before it's proven correct--

hard to pin down.

In arriving at that
there were

idea just

risk of overshooting our

least as great

we

forecasting, especially because the timing of

monetary policy effects

at

In doing so,

2-3/4 percent.

to

a half

question may be that

on

the normal

rise in interest

aggregate demand.
financial

FOMC Briefing--September 27,

1994

Michael J.

Prell

transmission mechanisms have not been working as one might anticipate.
The dollar has depreciated since the beginning of the year: the stock
market has given up rather little of what
rich valuation earlier this year:

appeared to be an awfully

and bank credit availability has

been improving, possibly substantially.

Moreover, it is.arguable that

the rise in bond yields has been at least in part a reflection of
heightened inflation expectations--limiting the rise in the real cost
of capital.
It's also possible that we've underestimated some of the
forces buttressing demand at given interest

rate levels.

For

instance, it could be that the pent-up demand for single-family homes
is greater than we judged.

Consequently, to achieve the anticipated

degree of demand restraint through the housing sector, it may take a
further deterioration in affordability measures--perhaps including a
further rise in short rates that makes it less attractive to use ARMs
to circumvent the higher initial cost of fixed-rate

loans.

Whatever the case--whether it is the lesser financial
restraint or the greater underlying demand--we simply do not yet see
the evidence of a decisive slowing in this expansion.

Under the

circumstances, we concluded that--while we do still anticipate
meaningful lagged effects of the earlier

rate increases--we should

assume a greater monetary policy tightening than in our previous
projection.

So, we added 50 basis points to the 50 basis points of

additional funds rate increase already assumed in our last forecast.
Expecting that the dollar will not depreciate further and that credit
supply conditions will not continue to ease, we think that this may
suffice to produce the slackening of aggregate demand growth that we
believe essential if inflation is to be held in check.

- 3

FOMC Briefing--September 27.

1994

Michael

J.

Prell

Let me turn now to the issue of the inflation outlook.

We've

raised our forecast for price increases through next year for two
reasons.

The first is that the level of output is higher in this

projection than in the last,

until the latter part of 1995.

This,

in

itself, would imply a higher level of resource utilization and thus
greater potential inflationary pressure.

But, in the case of the

manufacturing sector, the tensions are compounded by the upward
revisions to prior levels of factory utilization.

At 84.3 percent

now, the rate is within a point of the 1989 peak and considerably
above levels that in the past have been associated with accelerating
prices.
In fact, we could be said to be discounting the importance of
this observation in our forecast; a Phillips-curve type model using
capacity utilization rather than unemployment as the slack variable
would point to a greater pickup in inflation than we have written
down.

Given the wide standard error attending any such econometric

prediction, this normally wouldn't cause much anxiety; but in a period
when the meaning of the unemployment rate has been obscured by the
revision to the household survey, this gives one a little pause.
As it is,

the run-up in capacity utilization is

one of the

factors behind our forecast of roughly 3-1/2 percent core CPI
inflation through the first part of 1995.

We believe that the rise in

utilization is a key factor explaining the ongoing surge in industrial
materials prices, which is likely to be passed through to finished
goods prices--at least to some degree--in the near term.

As activity

slows and capacity utilization ebbs a tad next year, we expect that
the rise in materials prices will taper off.
As you know, we've also identified the pass-through of higher
crude oil prices and firmer non-oil import prices as giving some

FOMC Briefing--September 27,

1994

Michael J.

impetus to inflation in the near term.

Prell

And. with labor markets fairly

taut, there likely will be some tendency for the acceleration of
prices to feed through to wages, thus raising unit labor costs and
giving some momentum to higher core inflation in the latter part of
1995.

This is why we've presented a forecast that produces subpar

growth for a time and a slight increase in unemployment:

We wanted to

present the Committee with a baseline forecast that did not involve a
reversal of the disinflationary trend of the past decade.
If I may attempt to anticipate a question, our quarterly
model says that, starting from the Greenbook forecast, the difference
between our funds rate path and holding the rate at 4-3/4 is.

by 1996,

the difference between a minimal downward tilt to inflation versus a
slight upward tilt.

But this really is putting far too fine a point

on what such models can tell one.

And this exercise doesn't answer

the question of whether our Greenbook forecast is broadly correct and
a substantial further policy tightening truly is needed to moderate
aggregate demand.
I would say that

such a view is implicit in the market yield

curve as well as in the analyses of most private forecasters.
have been wrong before, and it

Of course, they, and we

is

possible

that we are all being misled by a tendency to look at the much greater
size of past funds rate upswings in gauging what it might take to rein
As I've noted previously, that could be a

in a cyclical expansion.

misleading standard, given that fiscal policy is relatively
restrictive this time, and that we've had a disproportionate rise in
bond yields.

Moreover,

past major upswings

in rates typically

culminated in recessions--which is not our current design.
on the other side of this

However,

ledger, as I've noted this morning, is the

observation that we have not had in the current episode much

FOMC Briefing--September 27,

1994

Michael J. Prell

reinforcement of the money market tightening in other aspects of the
financial environment--at least not yet.
On that point, let me turn the floor over to Ted for some
comments on how the dollar and other aspects of the external sector fit
into the picture.

*****************

E.M.Truman

September 27,
FOMC Presentation

1994

-- International Developments

I would like to add three comments about the external
sector to amplify Mike's presentation.
First, the outlook for economic growth abroad has
improved substantially.

Since the beginning of the year, we have

added more than a percentage point to our projection of 1994
average growth abroad as well as to growth in the foreign G-7
countries.

Information received since the August FOMC meeting

about growth in foreign industrial countries during the second
quarter and initial indications about the third quarter have
reinforced our tendency to mark up our forecasts.

In the case of

Japan, second-quarter GDP, contrary to the general expectation,
dropped 1.6 percent at an annual rate.

However, it is

instructive that there was essentially no reaction in financial
markets or in public commentary to these data.

The reason may be

that information received on business sentiment, orders, and
consumer demand during the third quarter suggest that

the

Japanese economy most likely has turned the corner.
In our forecast, aggregate foreign growth averages a
shade under four percent in 1994 and 1995.

Given the large

output gaps in most foreign industrial countries, such an outlook
hardly amounts to a boom, but growth abroad is a definite upside
risk to our overall outlook.
Second, let me try to explain our forecast for the
dollar.

Sentiment toward the dollar continued to be somewhat

2

-

bearish during the intermeeting period primarily under the
influence of continuing concern about U.S. inflation.
Notwithstanding the further slight depreciation of the dollar, we
have not changed our projection for the dollar:

we expect the

dollar to appreciate by a couple of percentage points from its
current level and to remain around that level for the balance of
the forecast period.

Our reasoning involves several

considerations.
First, our assumption about the near-term course of
short-term dollar interest rates coincides fairly closely to
market expectations, but we see much less tightening in foreign
monetary policies than the market expects.

In the case of

Germany, for example, the futures market is projecting that
three-month interest rates will rise by 100 basis points by June
of next year while we think they will be unchanged.

We think it

is likely that the financial markets have over-estimated the
strength of the recovery abroad.

As implicit projections of

growth abroad are revised down, dollar assets should look
relatively more attractive.

In addition, for those who believe

along with Fred Bergsten that for the past seven years we have
been operating an exchange rate regime of de facto target zones,
I would note that the dollar is about five percent below its
average value for the period since the Louvre meeting in early
1987: our forecast implies some regression toward the mean.
The dollar's depreciation so far this year has been a
surprise.

It has vitiated one of the normal channels of

restraint on the U.S. economy exerted by higher interest rates.

-

3

-

Moreover, further weakness in the dollar cannot be ruled out.
Thus, the dollar is an additional upside risk to our forecast of
growth and inflation.
My third point concerns our forecast that the external
sector of the U.S. economy ceased to be a negative factor for GDP
growth in the third quarter.

You might ask how we square this

projection with July's near-record deficit on trade in goods and
services that was announced last week.

Part of the explanation

can be traced to the influence of special factors in July such as
a temporary drop in aircraft deliveries.

Our implicit projection

for the deficit in August and September is about $1-1/2 billion
lower.

The remainder of the explanation for the third quarter

involves the difference between the balance in nominal terms and
the balance in real terms.

Because of such factors as the spike

in oil prices during the summer and the boost to prices of nonoil imports from the dollar's depreciation, in nominal terms we
are projecting a $5 billion deterioration of the third-quarter
deficit while in real terms we estimate a $5 billion improvement.
For the remainder of the forecast period, our projection
for the U.S. external sector relies on the influence of three
basic factors:

faster growth abroad, a slowing of growth in this

country, and the influence of the decline in the dollar on
balance so far this year.

As a consequence, real net exports of

goods and services are projected to be about neutral in their
contribution to U.S. real GDP over the next six quarters;

this

would amount to about $30 billion less real restraint by the
fourth quarter of next year than we were projecting in January --

-

4

-

equal to a bit more than half a percentage point on the level of
projected real GDP in that quarter.
Mr. Chairman, I have reached the end of my written
comments.

September 27,

1994

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn
As Mike has discussed,

the incoming data may be

suggesting that the Committee may not have the

seen as

luxury of a more

or less automatic

"no-change" decision that
The persist-

it perhaps anticipated after the last meeting.
ent strength

of aggregate demand and higher level

of re-

source utilization raise questions about whether policy is
yet positioned to head off increasing inflation--much less
make progress

toward the longer-run goal of price stability.

The answer in the Greenbook was no--that a considerable further tightening is

likely to be necessary to

accomplish the Committee's objectives.
outlook it may be important to

In evaluating this

keep in mind that

ening assumed over the next few quarters is
with market expectations for this period.

the tight-

about in line
As a consequence,

the rise in short-term rates is not thought likely to produce major

changes

in longer-term interest rates

or the

weighted average exchange value of the dollar--two key
variables

in the transmission of monetary policy.

In these

circumstances, however, a failure to tighten in line with
market expectations could well lead to a lower dollar and
lower long-term real rates
rates),

(though perhaps not nominal

effectively moving these two important

influences on

-2aggregate demand in a stimulative direction relative to
their current values as well as to the staff forecast.
That would not be a concern if markets have overshot--if long-term real rates have moved up excessively,
building in more policy tightening than will prove to be
appropriate; certainly it would not be the first time that
capital markets over-reacted and miscalculated.

In fact,

extending the forecast horizon, the Greenbook projection
does assume that aggregate demand will be softer and inflation less than built into the markets, producing a decline
in long-term rates later in 1995.
But evidence of actual or expected overshooting is
not yet obvious.

Real rates have risen, but they are not

unusually high by historical standards, and have not shown
through substantially in interest-sensitive spending.
Moreover, other financial or related markets--such as those
for commodities, equities or private debt instruments--do
not show signs that market participants see the increases in
real interest rates as significantly inhibiting activity.
And, in contrast to some other tightening episodes, the
dollar has fallen.

These market responses themselves in-

hibit some of the usual channels through which policy affects the economy.

Credit markets have tended to react to

incoming data suggesting strength in spending or the potential for inflation by building in additional Federal Reserve
tightening.

That may in part be simply their reading of

-3your

reaction function, but

likely to over tighten,
term structure and its

if markets sensed that you were

one might expect that a hump in the
imbedded forward rates would emerge,

and none is evident.
As to the near-term, the staff forecast does not
necessarily assume tightening at

this meeting, and market

views on what might happen today are mixed.

The key task

for the Committee would seem to be assessing if the evidence
that has accumulated since the last meeting points
enough to the need for immediate action.
determination, the Committee may find

strongly

In making that

reason to demand a

heavier burden from that evidence than for previous tightenings this year.

For

one,

the funds rate was increased a

full 50 basis points just six weeks ago.

The magnitude of

that action was intended to be somewhat pre-emptive--to
allow a period of policy rest to
earlier moves.
markets

Moreover, this

evaluate the

results of

intention was conveyed to

in a statement that held out the distinct

possi-

bility of at least a short hiatus in policy changes, creating market expectations

to

future statements of that
reasons for
as

overriding its

compelling.

that effect.

The

credibility of

sort could be impaired unless the
implied commitment are

perceived

Second, with another tightening--especially

one of 50 basis points--Federal Reserve policy could be seen
as

in a new place.

including the August

Previous

tightenings this year, even

action, can be

interpreted

as moving

-4interest rates broadly into line with historical experience
for periods of stable inflation rates.

A 50 basis point

action would push real short-term interest rates toward the
upper end, if not above what many have characterized as
policy neutrality.

The FOMC might want especially clear

indications that the economy were not moving onto a sustainable growth track or that prices had already accelerated
before moving policy into what might be perceived as a
posture of restraint.
But restraint may in fact be needed if the response
of spending to higher rates is damped, or exogenous factors
are pushing on aggregate demand.

And, there are potential

risks from demanding too clear a signal from the evidence,
especially in an economy operating around its potential.

In

particular, if price pressures are building, delay can complicate the future conduct of policy and possibly adversely
affect the performance of the economy.

Prompt action can

reduce tie levels that nominal and even real rates will
eventually have to reach to achieve a given inflation objective in a specific time frame.

Smoother rate paths should

be associated with smoother paths for the economy and fewer
strains on the private sector, including financial intermediaries.

The cost of waiting could be particularly

severe, if it were feared that inflation expectations might
adjust higher more readily than they adjust lower from
current inflation levels, which are at the lower end of

-5experience over the past 30 years. The recent behavior of
financial markets does suggest a certain predilection for
expectations to rise, and if inflation itself accelerated
for any period, those expectations could become more general
in labor and product markets.

In light of these potential

difficulties, if the FOMC were reasonably confident that the
economy is not in the process of slowing to a sustainable
path and that inflation pressures are building, it might
give serious consideration to overcoming any inertia from
the August announcement and tightening policy promptly--as
under alternatives C or D in the bluebook.

In such cir-

cumstances, the benefits of prompt action might outweigh any
costs in the form of reduced credibility for future attempts by
the Committee to pre-commit its policy stance very far ahead.
However, if the Committee sees the data as not yet
sufficient to indicate the need for further tightening,
keeping reserve market conditions unchanged, as under alternative B, would be appropriate.

The substantial size of the

moves earlier this year and uncertainty about the timing of
their effects on the economy, together with an absence of a
clear sustained acceleration in broad measures of costs and
prices, might be seen as arguing for waiting for additional
information before taking an additional step.

Indeed, if

there were considerable restraint still in the pipeline, or
more scope for more vigorous expansion without additional

-6inflation pressures than the staff had foreseen, then substantial additional action might not be needed.

Given the

lags in policy effects, continuing to tighten until data
suggest weakness will ultimately result in policy overshooting.
Certainly the behavior of money and credit do not
suggest a building inflation problem.

After the spurt in

July, all money measures weakened in August, and data for
the first half of September suggest little growth in any of
the aggregates this month.

For the year, M2 and M3 continue

on the anemic growth paths of 1992 and 1993, while M1 has
decelerated substantially, resulting in a decline in bank
reserves and an appreciable moderation in the expansion of
the monetary base.

We believe the recent weakness of money

growth--as well as sluggish growth for the year--reflects a
natural reaction by depositors

to widening opportunity

costs--rather than any signal of a slowing in nominal spending.

The puzzle is why banks have been so laggard in rais-

ing deposit rates, especially since it is not a symptom of
credit restraint or lack of lending opportunities.

Appar-

ently they believe wholesale funds and sales from bloated
securities portfolios will be less expensive than raising
the funding cost of their retail deposit base.
Moreover, the expansion of credit remains moderate,
with no sign of any overall acceleration that might signal a
strengthening of a "borrow and spend" psychology.

Borrowing

-7early last year, but has

by nonfederal sectors picked up
shown few signs

of accelerating since then, despite more

aggressive lending by banks.
growth has been

To be sure, household debt

rapid, but business borrowing, while more

concentrated at the short end,
by state and local

Borrowing

remains moderate.

and federal governments has decelerated,

indicating a lack of demand impetus from these sectors, and
constraining overall
recent months,

debt growth to 5 percent or less in

down marginally from earlier this year.

If the Committee were to keep policy on hold at
this meeting it would need to consider how to react
incoming data.

to

If the risks of higher inflation were con-

sidered sufficiently worsening, the Committee might want to
react
strong

promptly, between meetings,

to

signs that growth was

or price pressures were mounting.

In this

case, it

might consider an asymmetrical directive, tilted toward
tightening.
There was considerable

discussion of the meaning of

an asymmetrical directive at the July meeting.

As President

Boehne and Governor Kelley noted at that time, the asymmetry
provisions may be necessarily vague, and efforts to
their meaning could be counterproductive.
was first used in the early
ed from automatic changes

Such a directive

1980s, when the Committee shift-

in reserve

to more discretionary changes.
metry afforded an element

pin down

conditions keyed to M1

In this regime,

the asym-

of flexibility and direction for

-8between-meeting moves.

The Committee has resisted spelling

out the meaning of asymmetry in any formula.

Sometimes

members have emphasized the signals it sends to financial
markets when it is published, but the directive has had
operational significance;

indeed, its value as a signal to

markets would soon deteriorate if it did not.

In general,

the asymmetrical directive signalled that the Committee sees
an imbalance in the risks to meeting its objectives going
forward, or in the costs from missing to one particular
side.

As a consequence, it had wanted to

respond more

quickly and perhaps more forcefully to evidence becoming
available between meetings suggesting the need to move in one
particular direction than it would under a symmetrical directive.

Members have used the policy discussion to try to

spell out the nature of the information they thought was
critical, but responses have rarely been tied to one particular statistic.

Intermeeting changes are far from in-

evitable under an asymmetrical directive, but they are more

likely.

From 1987 on, about 30 percent of symmetrical

directives have been followed by intermeeting changes, and
60 percent of asymmetrical directives.