View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC BRIEFING - P.R. FISHER

SEPTEMBER 26, 1995
Before permitting myself to take advantage
of the toys in the ceiling,
and because of the number of topics I need to cover,
I thought I should exhaust the potential of older technologies.
Thus, you should find an outline of my remarks
on the table in front of you,
together with a single page of color charts.

1.

To understand the dollar's sharp sell-off last week,
I think it's helpful to distinguish the causes
of its initial rally in July and August
from the factors that led to its push above 100 yen
earlier this month.

As I discussed at your last meeting,
the dollar's appreciation in July and August,
reflected relative changes in expectations
for each of the G-3 economies, nudged along by regulatory
and monetary policy changes in Tokyo & Frankfurt and
concerted intervention.
While the dollar moved up a bit
after the Bank of Japan's September 8th rate cut,
the dollar's subsequent rally above 100 yen was
-- to a very great extent --

the result of unusual and aggressive oral intervention
by the Ministry of Finance,
aimed at Japanese portfolio managers,
talking up the benefits of outward investment,
promising a secular change in the dollar's trend,
and raising expectations of supportive fiscal and
regulatory policies.
Thus, while the dollar's overall summer rally
against the yen
was vulnerable to a consolidation,
it's extension above 100 yen was particularly vulnerable
to selling on the announcement
of the Japanese fiscal package on September 20th.
The fiscal package, itself, was somewhat larger
and more stimulative than originally expected.
But it was leaked before the fact and, thus,
already in the market.

- 2

-

Moreover, market participants had -- somewhat naively --

come to expect a grand announcement of
regulatory changes and banking sector support
at the same time as the fiscal package.
The absence of the grand announcement
became a good excuse to sell the dollar
and we traded down in Tokyo from around 104.60 to 103.60
by the time trading began in New York on the 20th.
What might have stopped as a modest retracement of dollar-yen
turned much uglier, for markets and the dollar,
when the German mark began to appreciate.
The announcement of the French government's fiscal plans,
that same day,
triggered a slight firming of the mark -not because the plans themselves are bad
but because they are viewed as politically implausible,
as evidenced by the public sector unions
subsequent strike call.
The dollar then weakened a bit
after the release of the slightly-worse-than-expected
U.S. trade deficit for July.
Finally, the mark spiked higher, against a number currencies,
following the release of remarks by
German Finance Minister Waigel and
Bundesbank Council member Jochimsen
to the effect, respectively, that Italy and France
might well not make it
into the first round of European monetary union.
While everyone in the markets understood
the limited probability of a number of countries
actually meeting the Masstricht criteria by the end of 1997,
Waigel's comment transported that future improbability
into current markets.
It is noteworthy
that the dollar has lost a greater share of its recent
rally against the mark than it has against the yen.
Thus, the good news may be
that the dollar's recovery against the yen
is a little less vulnerable than we feared.
However, the bad news is that the dollar may
continue to be vulnerable to the tensions
surrounding European monetary union
for the next few years.

- 3

2.

-

Over most of the period, the bond market rallied back
to its highest price levels of the year
but no further, and then sold off a bit.
For most of September, the market was seeing
all of the components of the soft landing
that were so eagerly hoped for last spring:
----

continued growth, somewhat below potential;
slightly-better-than-expected inflation numbers;
a firming dollar and foreign demand for bonds;

and, a Fed seen as likely to ease before year-end.
At the end of last week,
--

the four-fold increase in the Philadelphia Fed's

regional survey of manufacturing activity;
---

the dollar's abrupt sell-off, and
outright threats of default out of Washington,

were certainly enough to jolt the market back a bit.
However, given such good initial conditions,
I think it's worth asking why,
prior to the end of last week,
the market couldn't break through
the (price) highs established
earlier this year.
Most importantly, it has been hard for market participants
to get adequate assurance that
the economy will not come back more strongly
later this year and early in 1996,
given the recent production numbers.
Indeed, one of the factors that prompted the market
to rally as much as it did last spring,
was the risk of recession --

which is not now on anyone's radar screen.
Also, the net consequences for the bond market,
of the fiscal policy follies are hard to assess.
I think that the prospects for some, unspecified
improvement in fiscal policy
have been reflected in the market for some time.
While the threats of default
contributed to yields backing up last week,
the uncertainty associated
with the wide range of plausible outcomes
of the various "train wreck" scenarios
may also be making it more difficult for prices
to settle in at any one point.

-

3.

4 -

In domestic operations:
during the period,
we used temporary operations,
supplemented with purchases from foreign accounts,
to manage reserve conditions.
Last week, we faced several days of large deficiencies,
and low operating balances,
as a consequence of high Treasury balances
resulting from quarterly tax receipts.
On Tuesday, I decided to operate earlier than normal,
in order to improve our prospects
of receiving a sufficient volume of propositions,
to meet our need.
I mention this for two reasons:
First, our flexibility in doing this

was certainly enhanced by the Committee's
policy of announcing changes in policy.
Second, our need to operate early,

in order to have adequate assurance
that we will have sufficient collateral,
reflects the fact that the financing market
has been shifting to earlier in the day,
leaving our current operating time
as something of an afterthought to the rp market.
In the context of the thoughtful annex to the Bluebook,
on the possible impact of sweep accounts
on reserve balances,
Don and I will be considering a number of ideas
to ensure that the Desk can continue
effectively carrying out the Committee's directives.
In the upcoming period, the fiscal "train wreck" may create
some challenges for the desk.
A partial shutdown of the government, after October 1st,
would be likely to make it more difficult to forecast
the Treasury balance.

-

5 -

Any likely adjustments
to the Treasury's auction calendar
through early November,
would have minimal impact on the portfolio.
Even the cancellation of the 2-and 5-year auctions
at the end of October,
would have little impact on SOMA,
because of our low holdings of these issues.
Given the 3 7 billion of maturing securities and
and $27 billion of interest payments,
all on November 15th,
no one expects the Treasury to be able to make it beyond
mid-November.
In contingency planning,
for a possible default by the Treasury,
we -- like other market participants --

face a number of uncertainties.
We are still unsure whether it will be possible
to transfer matured and unpaid Treasury securities
over the book-entry wire;
Assuming that some means could be found to transfer
and settle these securities
we will have to consider
whether we will accept them
in our RP operations,
and, if so, what the appropriate haircut should be.
Given the likely breakdown of payment flows
that would result from a Treasury default,
we would expect
demand for excess reserves to rise sharply.

4.

Portfolio review:
Mr. Chairman, I had hoped to provide the Committee
with an initial report
on our review of the portfolio's maturity structure
in time for the Committee to have a preliminary discussion
at the November 15th meeting.
However, I am afraid that I will need some more time,
and I hope to be able to come to the Committee
in either December or January.

- 6

5.

-

Mexican Swap Renewal
While we had no foreign operations during the period,
I would like to inform the Committee
that we have an expectation
that the Mexican authorities will repay
half of each of the outstanding one billion dollars
on the System's and the ESF's short-term swaps
(500 million each)
by the time of the swaps next maturity date on October 30th.
We would then roll-over the remaining 500 million each
on the System's and the ESF's swaps
until their final maturity in January,
when we expect them to be repaid in full.
There remains 10.5 billion dollars outstanding
on the ESF's medium-term facility.

6.

Ratification of Operations:
Mr. Chairman, I will need the Committee's ratification for our
operations during the period.
I would be happy to answer any questions.

Yields Implied by 3-Month Futures Contracts
Percent
8.0

Percent
8.0

September 20, 1995

June 20, 1995

-

6.0

--Dec 95

.- EuroMa
.

.
Euro$

----.-----

.

0ep 95

-Euro $

6.0

EuroYen

Mar 96

Jun 96

Dec 96

Sep 96

Mar 97

Jun 97

EuroYen
Sep 97 bec 95

Mar 96

Jun 96

Sep 96

Dec 96

Mar 97

Jun 97

Sep 97

Dec 97

Spreads of Ten-Year Bond Yields Less Overnight Rates

Percent
4.0

4.0

- r- n-------------QG~ .an^S.^
m

3.0 -----------------30

(1.0) - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - 0.0

2.0l
o

........

Jun

Japanese
--

- .--3 -.-.-.- - - -.-.--.--.-.-.--- -..

-

- - - - - - - - - - - -

-----

--------

"

- -- (10)
0.0

-- 1.0

Sep

Aug

Jul

------

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

3.0
3

Percent Change of Spot Exchange Rates from June 1st, 1995

Percent

25.0

25.0
20.0 - - - -

- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

15.0 - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -

-

-

- -- - - - - -

- -

- -

-

- - - - -- 20.0

- - - - - -

- -

-

- - - - - - - - --

15.0

$/Yen
10.0 --

(5 .0)
Jun

. .

-

- - - - - - - -

. .

- -

- - - - - - -

- - - -

.

- -

. ..
...
Aug

Jul

- - -

-

.

-

- - - - - -

-

.
Sep

.. .... .....
..

. '

-- 10.0

( .0)
5

U.S. Government Bond Yields from Jan 1st, 1995

Percent
8.0

80

7.5 --- -----------

-

7.0 - - - - - - - - - - - -

-- - ---------

- -

--------

---------

- - - - - - - - -

-

-- - - -

-

-- -

6.0-----------------------------------------------------------5.5 --------------------------

Feb

FRBNY Markets Group

-

-------

-

----

------

-- --

- - - - - - - --

-------------

2 Year
Jan

-

.

-------- -

- - - --

--------------

-------------------

Aug

75
--- 7.0

60
5.5

Sep

Updated September 25, 1995

Michael J. Prell
September 26, 1995
FOMC BRIEFING
The forecast we've prepared for this meeting could
be characterized as singularly unexciting.
from the last time almost imperceptible,
output

Not

reasonably

only are the changes

but our projections

for

growth and inflation look so flat as to suggest that the

economy--or at least the

staff--is in a state of suspended animation.

In fact, though, we believe that some important dynamics will be
playing out in the economy over the next year
at this point, we don't know nearly
wiggles

or two.

It's just that,

enough to try to anticipate

the

that inevitably will occur.
In the interest of time, I won't

quarter accounting

recapitulate the current-

discussed in the Greenbook.

Suffice it to say

that, sifting through all of the available information, we think that
a GDP growth rate in the vicinity of 2 to
reasonable

call.

My sense is

that most

2-1/2 percent is a

outside analysts

see

it about

the same way.
The bigger question is where the economy is headed from here.
Doing the proverbial two-handed economist one better,
quite different,

yet plausible, answers.

in which the

is a scenario

I'll offer three

At one end of the spectrum

economy quickly returns to a pace of

expansion brisk enough to elevate resource utilization significantly-say,

real GDP rising at 3 percent or more.
Analysts holding this view tend to point to one or more of

the following factors as driving the
path:

First,

it is argued,
To be

stimulative.

economy away from a more moderate

financial conditions are,

sure, real

short-term interest

on balance,

rates

are above

longer-term averages, but they aren't high by the standards of the
And, moreover,

past decade.

appreciably this

long-term rates have come down

year, providing obvious lift to the housing market

and making other household and business
well.

capital outlays less costly as

If anything, the economy is awash with liquidity, as indicated

by the aggressive
and the run-up

lending behavior of banks and other intermediaries

in stock prices.

Second, the degree of fiscal

restraint in the offing is much

less than what we've assumed in the Greenbook.
package that

is passed will be

will be liberal use of smoke

Any deficit-reduction

considerably back-loaded, and there

and mirrors,

so that the fiscal drag

-2-

actually imposed on the economy will be less

than the budget numbers

might suggest.
Third, U.S.

producers

are in a strong competitive position

internationally, and especially now that some of our major trading
partners have moved to get their economies on more
tracks,

our net exports will

solid growth

soon turn upward.

Finally, as an extra added attraction, if the factors I've
just listed do result in a fairly buoyant final demand
businesses will need

picture,

to stock up accordingly and thus inventory

investment may provide some lift to activity.
The implication of this analysis

is that

the Fed is going to

have to tighten soon, or else inflation will gather

speed over the

coming year.
At the other end of the
for a period of quite

spectrum is a view that we are headed

subdued growth in activity--not a recession, but

perceptibly short of the

2-1/4 percent kind of expansion we've

described in the Greenbook for the next few quarters.
The argument

goes

expansion is enervated:

something like this.

The current economic

households are up to their ears in durables

and debts, and business capital

spending is already at such a high

level that further sizable increases cannot be justified in terms
reasonable capacity growth.

of

Furthermore, the federal budget not only

is being slashed, but there are unprecedented programmatic changes
that could be seriously disruptive to activity.

The Japanese economy

will remain bogged down for a while, and Mexico isn't going to recover
soon, either;

consequently, our trade deficit will continue to suffer.

The stock market

is overvalued and overdue for a setback, which will

have adverse effects on wealth and the cost of equity capital.
of course, short-term interest
environment in which real

And,

rates are unduly high, especially in an

rates will be moving up as the softening

economy pushes inflation down.
The policy implication is that,

unless you wish to

seize upon

this as the opportunity to achieve that next significant notch down in
the inflation rate, it would be appropriate to
conditions appreciably in the

ease money market

near future.

The Greenbook forecast sits between these
However,

I should emphasize that we didn't just

between the two to arrive at our projection.

scenarios.

split the difference

Rather, we see

something

along the lines of our projection as constituting the mode of the

probability distribution--the most likely of the alternatives,
conditional on our monetary and fiscal assumptions.

Of course, we're

not saying you should take seriously each and every decimal place in
the projection tables.

Indeed, we'd vigorously warn against it.

But

we do believe that it would be a reasonable premise for your policy
decision today to anticipate that, without a significant change in the
funds rate, growth would average just a little below trend over the
next several quarters and that inflation would be essentially stable.
The simple logic of our output forecast is that, in the near
term, the boost to final demand from this year's capital market rally
is offsetting most of the drag from the inventory adjustment that is
underway.

As we move through 1996, the financial impetus from this

year's stock and bond rallies wanes in force and the assumed fiscal
restraint takes hold:

these forces are only partially offset by the

completion of the inventory adjustment and a diminution in the
negative contribution from net exports.
This kind of outlook for activity suggests that resource
utilization rates can be expected to ease a bit in the months ahead.
At least, this is so if the labor force resumes a mild uptrend, as
we've predicted, and if all this manufacturing investment we're
witnessing is in fact raising plant capacity at a brisk clip.

This

still leaves open some questions about the inflation picture, however.
Dave Stockton noted last time that there might be a case for more
optimism about where, in conventional Phillips curve terms, the
natural rate of unemployment is.

The latest price index readings

certainly have not weakened that case:

Notably, they have largely

reversed the deterioration in the trend of core CPI inflation that
occurred earlier this year--despite the fact that the unemployment
rate has remained in the 5-1/2 to 5-3/4 percent range.
As you know, we have projected that the core CPI will
continue to rise at a pace just under 3 percent over coming quarters,
even though we are anticipating that the jobless rate will remain
below 6 percent until late next year.

While such a pattern might

suggest that, in effect, the natural rate is closer to 5-1/2 percent
than to 6, we still view this as a matter too close to call.
Basically, we see the economy as operating in the
neighborhood of full employment of labor and capital, but with some
special factors working to moderate price pressures in the short run.
Certainly, speed effects are no problem; to the contrary, we think it

likely that the widening of markups that has been occurring will
abate.
that,

The likelihood of this happening is enhanced by the prospect
despite the dollar's

import prices will

recent backsliding on exchange markets,

rise less

rapidly than they did earlier this year.

And, while there may be some tendency for compensation increases to
creep upward--partly because cuts in medical benefit
will be harder to come by--we

costs probably

suspect that the continuing

restructuring of corporate America will keep workers

sufficiently

insecure that they won't exert very much inflationary pressure.
None of these factors would be

expected to improve the short-

run inflation-unemployment trade-off permanently, but in our
they don't have
the

to:

By 1997,

point that a gradual

the benefit

forecast

resource utilization rates have eased to

disinflationary trend can continue without

of special influences.

In sum, the Greenbook projection

suggests that maintenance of the current federal funds

rate for a

while

patient

longer is likely to be consistent with a gentle,

approach to the

goal of price stability.

E.M. Truman
September 26, 1995
FOMC Presentation -- International Developments

As a complement to Mike Prell's presentation, I thought it might be useful to add a few
comments about the external sector.
We raised our projection for the dollar in the Greenbook, after leaving it unchanged since
March. In light of the dollar's strength over the previous month or so, we raised the dollar's path by
about 2-1/2 percent, as indexed by the G-10 weighted average.

The ink was not dry on the forecast

before the dollar came under substantial downward pressure from a number of factors, as Peter has
discussed, including the U.S. trade data that were released on Greenbook day, the Japanese fiscal
package that was announced the same day, and the financial turmoil in Europe.

I will turn to each of

these developments in a minute, but first I thought I would comment about our projection for the
dollar and its implications for our forecast.
We had expected all along that the dollar would recover somewhat. Partly for that reason, the
staff forecast never has envisaged a very large contribution to U.S. real GDP from the external sector.
This is in contrast with some of the private forecasts that were predicting that the dollar's weakness
would produce a large external stimulus.

In fact, our forecast has not differed much from those of

private forecasters who pay particular attention to the external sector. The reason is that even as the
dollar was declining, growth abroad was weakening, with roughly offsetting effects on net exports.
Nevertheless, if the dollar now should remain around its current lower level, closer to its projected
level in the last few Greenbooks, we estimate that the impact on real net exports would be about $10
billion by the fourth quarter of 1996, moving from a slight negative contribution to real GDP to a
slight plus over the four quarters of next year.
With respect to the July data on trade in goods and services that were released last
Wednesday, they were very much in line with our thinking.

We anticipated some deterioration

-2based on our assessment that the seasonal adjustment of the trade data appears to be incomplete. This
phenomenon produces relatively strong exports in the fourth quarter and relatively weak exports in the
first and third quarters, especially in July. Nevertheless, the release of the data apparently resonated
in the market, combined with other factors, including Fred Bergsten's comments about the dollar's
strength undermining improvement in our trade balance.
The release of the long-awaited Japanese fiscal package on Wednesday also appeared to
disappoint the market, though as Peter has suggested this may have been a case of buying on the
rumor and selling on the news. The fundamental question is how we now should evaluate Japanese
economic and financial developments. Our answer is that we are somewhat encouraged. The
monetary and fiscal steps by the Japanese authorities over the past several months suggest that they
are more determined to do what they can to bring about a sustained recovery in the Japanese
economy. At the same time, they appear to be making progress with respect to strengthening the
financial system, notwithstanding or, perhaps, as evidenced by, today's announcement of losses by
Daiwa. These policy actions, along with the unexpectedly strong second-quarter GDP data and the
substantially weaker yen, have led us to move up our forecast of Japanese growth somewhat.
However, I would stress that even with this improved outlook, growth only barely reaches our current
estimate of potential -- about 2-1/2 percent -- over the next two years. We anticipate that the financial
headwinds in Japan will continue to blow with considerable fury. Thus, we still have a rather
conservative forecast.
Finally on the European situation, we have seen over the past week the influence of
developments that we may not have fully appreciated: changing prospects for EMU. We have
factored into our outlooks for the individual European countries judgments about the influence of the
Maastricht criteria on fiscal policies, we have only partial convergence of long-term interest rates
within Europe over our forecast period, but we have implicitly assumed that EMU will blast off on

-3schedule on January 1, 1999. However, we have not been explicit about which countries will be part
of the crew, or what kind of mess the rocket will leave behind even if it succeeds in reaching orbit.
What I am suggesting by my use of yet another transportation metaphor in discussing EMU is that it
is a source of uncertainty. Based on events over the past week, considerable uncertainty about EMU
is likely to prevail over the next several years and to add to volatility in European interest rates and in
intra-European and dollar exchange rates in the process. The net influence on growth is likely to be
negative, and this may be a downside risk to our forecast.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman, that concludes our comments.

September 26,

1995

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

As noted in the greenbook, the staff forecast is
based on an assumption that there will be no significant
economic disruptions stemming directly from the current
budget debate.

Given the uncertainties surrounding the

negotiations, however, it may be worth discussing the issue
briefly.
The first key date of interest is

in just five

days, on October 1, when annual appropriations expire.

News

stories suggest a strong possibility of a continuing resolution to allow these activities to be carried on at some,
albeit reduced, level, at least for a time after October 1.
In the absence of such a resolution, or following its expiration, the overall effects on aggregate demand of a lapse
in annual appropriations still should not be large, even if
it persists for several weeks.

Spending under most entitle-

ments and to protect life and property would continue.
remainder amounts to only about
week, at an annual rate.

.15

The

percent of GDP each

Moreover, multiplier effects

from

the cut in spending should be small as government employees
draw on savings to maintain consumption--though the size of
the knock-on effects

could increase over time as some

employees exhaust their liquid assets or become concerned

about the nature of an eventual settlement.

Ultimately,

employees would be called back to work and spending would
resume, perhaps even with a temporary boost from some catch
up in deferred purchases.

There is probably little monetary

policy can or should do about such a brief mild shock.
Indeed, attempts to offset the shock would likely be
inflationary, given the lags in the effect of policy and the
fact that government workers, even while laid off, are
unlikely to make themselves available to produce goods and
services in the private sector.
The second stage of the confrontation will be about
the debt limit.

The staff currently estimates that without

an increase in borrowing authority--and without resorting to
extraordinary measures, such as a drawdown of trust funds-the Treasury will be unable to meet its obligations by no
later than November 15--the date of the next scheduled FOMC
meeting.

In one sense, the macro effects of default would

be less than with an appropriations lapse, since the government would continue to incur obligations--it would just take
a little longer for the obligors to get paid.

But the

failure to meet obligations promptly could have disruptive
effects on the financial markets and on the liquidity of
individual transactors counting on payments.

The extent of

the disruption might depend on how the government handles a
number of technical issues that would have a bearing on the

intensity of liquidity pressures.

The markets' reaction

will be affected as well by the perceived impact of the
impasse on the eventual size of the deficit reduction
package.

The odds on a significant disruption with broad

implications for markets and even spending are small--but
not zero.

However, there may be a self-limiting aspect to

the situation; the worse the problems created by a debt
ceiling impasse, the sooner the political process may be
likely to deal with it.

Permanent effects from default also

are hard to predict, outside some risk premium on Treasury
debt.
Thus, the confrontational process of reaching
agreement on the federal budget is not, by itself, likely to
give rise to developments that would dictate a change in the
basic policy stance of the Committee.

Of course, the out-

come of the process could be a fiscal policy that differs
substantially from that now embodied in the staff forecast-or in the expectations of markets, which themselves may be
subject to considerable volatility as participants handicap
the outcome.

Moreover, as Peter noted, reserve management

could be complicated by either an appropriations lapse or a
debt ceiling crisis; the latter in particular might dictate
a more flexible provision of credit through open market
operations and the discount window to meet highly variable

demands for

reserves as planned payments and receipts

are

unexpectedly delayed.
However, the Committee might see reasons for the
budget
policy.

confrontation to affect the near-term tactics of
For one, the range of possible outcomes for

policy might appear wider than usual

fiscal

right now but likely to

diminish appreciably in the next few months, which could add
weight to arguments for a "wait and see" position under
alternative B.

In addition, people will be looking care-

fully for how monetary policy might respond to
fiscal policy.

emerging

An easing, in particular, might risk being

misinterpreted, and adding uncertainty about policy intentions to markets already displaying considerable skittishness and tendencies toward downward pressure on the dollar.
If an easing were undertaken because of reasons not directly
related to fiscal policy, the Committee might want to be
careful it had a clear, credible case for such action, which
it could enunciate.

However, if the Committee felt it

already had such a case, there might be something to be said
for acting at this time rather than delaying for more data,
since perceived impediments to policy actions are likely to
become larger not smaller after October 1, and a period of
"even keel"

through the budget battle could be lengthy.

In the context of the

staff forecast, the case for

easing would be made primarily on the grounds

that the

-5-

Committee was not seeking the slightly restrictive policy
stance implied by an unchanged nominal funds rate in that
forecast, with the associated gradual opening up of an
output gap.

Such a case would be even stronger to the

extent you judged the risks

on economic growth to be

weighted toward the downside, so that

lower real short-term

interest rates were needed to avoid a noticeable shortfall
in aggregate demand, or you judged the underlying inflation
picture to be more favorable, arguing for a reduction in the
nominal funds rate.

Markets have built in some odds of

easing by early next year, though perhaps a subsequent
upward tilt to rates.

The staff forecast sees no change in

long-term rates, as disappointment on the steady funds rate
is offset by a more restrictive fiscal policy than markets
now seem to anticipate.

Nonetheless, the staff outlook does

imply persistence of an unusually flat
curve, perhaps

slope of the yield

suggesting some risk of a small backup over

time in intermediate and long-term rates in the absence of
an ease, which would add to restraint.
The staff forecast has a slight downward tilt to
inflation under an unchanged funds

rate.

Alternative C

would produce a more noticeable disinflation after a
while.

This alternative was not named for "Connie", but it

might be useful to consider it and alternative policy

strategies against the background of the proposed legislation, in part as prelude to your later discussion.
Alternative C can be

seen as a step in a strategy

that would achieve price stability by running a restrictive
monetary policy--one that deliberately creates slack in the
economy to put downward pressure on inflation.
tive is the

An alterna-

"opportunistic" strategy many of you have dis-

cussed in the context of getting from low inflation to price
stability.

As

this strategy has most frequently been

described, the Federal Reserve does not seek to raise the
unemployment

rate above the natural

leans harder against shocks to the

rate, but effectively
economy that would

increase inflation than those that would decrease it.

The

resulting pattern would be one of successively lower inflation rates at cycle peaks and troughs.

This strategy has

interesting implications for how the Federal Reserve would
report under the Mack bill, which asks for an estimate of
the time it will take to get to price stability;

it's not

clear that Senator Mack has an answer like "two recessions"
in mind.
The simplest economic models do not provide a basis
for choosing between the Alternative C tight money strategy
and the

"opportunistic" strategy to achieve price stability.

In such models, the two approaches

give the same answer for

the output loss associated with getting to price stability.

That loss does not depend on whether a shortfall in demand
occurs because of high interest rates or because of, for
example, tightening fiscal policy that is not offset by
easier monetary policy.

A similar observation holds in

these models with regard to supply shocks.

A drop in oil

prices, for example, may be used to move to lower inflation
under an opportunistic strategy, but it could just as well
be taken in the form of a transitory gain in output, leaving
inflation where it was.
The world is far more complex than these models, of
course, and there are many more possible strategies than the
two we have been discussing, especially when you factor in
the subtleties and uncertainties of making policy in the
"real world".

The legislation does instruct you "to take

into account any potential effects on employment and output
in complying with the goal of price stability."

This sen-

tence clearly applies to the current transition period to
price stability and possibly also to subsequent episodes
when prices deviate from stability.

In that regard, the

Committee may see its job as damping the variance of output
on the way to price stability, leaning hard against large
shortfalls in employment as well as overshoots.

And it may

find that the speed of adjustment affects sacrifice ratios
in complicated ways that influence the choice of policy
strategies.

-8-

Restrictive monetary policy, as in alternative C,
is a
has

strategy for attaining price stability--and one that
the attractive features of being explicit in its intent

and more certain in its execution than more complex strategies.

But

Nonetheless,

it clearly is not the only possible path.
it is

interesting to think about today's

choice in the context of the bill, and the bill in the
context of policy choices today and subsequently.

policy