View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

FOMC NOTES - PRF

SEPTEMBER 24, 1996
Mr. Chairman:
I will be referring to the four pages of color charts
distributed to the Committee this morning.
As you can see on the first page, U.S. short-term, forward
interest rates rose steadily following your last meeting but then
began to decline in early September, particularly following the
releases of the August employment report, CPI and retail sales,
before jumping up a bit last week.
German forward rates have declined slightly since the
Bundesbank lowered its repo rate by 30 basis points to 3 percent
on August 22nd. Japanese forward rates have also declined since
your last meeting, moving sharply on the release of the Bank of
Japan's Tankan survey which reported a surprising decline in the
manufacturing index. Market participants now expect both the
Bundesbank and the Bank of Japan to be very much on hold for the
months ahead.
Turning to the second page, in light of these shifts in
forward rates, it is not so surprising that Japanese and German
bond markets outperformed our own over the period, although the
U.S. bond market did have a bit of a rally in early September.
More intriguing is the consistency with which German and
U.S. equity markets rallied together in early September, as the
German economy came to be perceived as somewhat stronger than
feared and the U.S. economy as somewhat less strong than feared.
Turning to the third page, in September the dollar has
rallied back almost to the levels it had reached in early July.
In looking at these recent movements, however, I feel the burden
of too many, rather than too few, explanations. Thus, it's
harder to find a convincing, small number of discrete events to
plot on these charts.
Broadly speaking, heightened market expectations for a
firming in rates by the Committee helped underpin the dollar,
particularly against the yen -- as market participants unwound
their expectations for the Bank of Japan to follow any increase
in rates by the Committee. In last ten days of August, ten-year
differentials widened further in the dollar's favor by over 20
basis points against Germany and over 50 basis points against
Japan.

-

2

-

However, I think the proximate cause of the dollar's sharp
move up, particularly against the mark, was caused by a rush to
cover short dollar positions that had built up in anticipation
that the mark would strengthen in mid-September on the release of
a French budget that would fail plausibly to meet the Maastrict
criteria. Indeed, both the Bundesbank and the Bank of France
were quite concerned about this risk.
In the event, however, the French budget failed to generate
any immediate political or market controversy and anxiety about
the challenges of meeting the Maastrict criteria have receded
quite quickly. Thus, market participants who had positioned
themselves for an appreciation of the mark, instead saw rallies in
the U.S. bond and equity markets and they moved quickly to cover
their short dollar positions, jolting the dollar up through 1.50
against the mark and 110 against the yen.
While the larger-than-expected U.S. trade deficit last week
caused only a brief sell-off in the dollar, market participants
are now more skeptical that the trade story will remain
supportive for the dollar going forward.
Despite the sharp movements in the dollar, volatility on
currency options has remained at quite low levels.
Turning to the fourth page, market expectations for the
outcome of this meeting have shifted back and forth sharply.
Following your last meeting, the October Fed Funds futures
contract implied a 40 percent probability of a 25 basis point
tightening at this meeting. Expressed in terms of such a
quarter-point move, this shot up to a 90 percent probability
following the publication of the September 3rd Wall Street
Journal article, which suggested some prospect of a 50 basis
point hike, then declined back to around a 45 percent probability
after the release of the August employment, price and retail
sales figures, before jumping back up to almost a 70 percent
probability after the release of the Reuters "discount rate"
story last week.
These movements have stimulated some volatility in the
spread between the 2-year note and the Committee's Fed Funds
target rate, although this has been roughly comparable to the
movements which took place in July. Implied volatility on
options on the 2-year and 30-year futures contracts have recently
begun to creep up but, again, are still roughly within the ranges
seen during July.

- 3 -

Turning to domestic operations, reserve shortages were
accentuated by seasonal currency growth and the higher, targeted
Treasury balance around the mid-September tax date. A few days
are worthy of note.
On Tuesday, September 3rd, pressures in the funding market
were the result of the combination of the settlement of the
Treasury's 2- and 5-year notes, a $30 billion cash management
bill, a Social Security payment date and other heavy corporate
payment flows. Although the Desk had put a considerable amount
of reserves in the system, the funds rate traded as high as 10
percent and the effective rate on the day was 6 percent.
On Wednesday, September 4th, the funds rate briefly traded
at 20 percent. This did not appear to be the result of a followthrough from the previous day but was the result of two banks
unexpectedly finding themselves short at the very end of the day.
Funds had been trading quite comfortably on the 4th and, even
including the trades conducted by these two institutions, the
daily effective rate was only 5.35 percent.
Last week we had a miss in our estimate of the Treasury
balance, which left $3billion more reserves in the banking system
than we intended which contributed to softness in the funds rate
last week. Unfortunately, misses of this size are not uncommon
around corporate tax payment dates.
Notwithstanding a few interesting days and some instances of
elevated end-of-day rates, since your last meeting the effective
Fed Funds rates has average 5.25 percent.
Mr. Chairman, we had no foreign exchange interventions
during the period. I will need the Committee's ratification of
the Desk's domestic operations which have been reported to you in
greater detail in the Desk's Weekly and Pre-FOMC reports.

Forward Rate Agreements

Page 1

US Forward Rates Shift Up and Down
July
August

Percent

August
FOMC

July
FOMC
9x12

9X12

o

m

3

5
7/1

4.5

7/8

.

7/15

Euro$Deposit

7/22

7/29
8/5
8/12
8/19
18/26
9/2
9/9
9/16
July FOMC Minutes; July Durable Goods
Chicago PMI
August Employment Data
August CPI; August Retail Sales

German Forward Rates Slightly
Lower After Bundesbank Repo Cut

4
9x12

6x9
3.5

3x6

3 mo. EuroDMDeposit
E

2.5

I

7/17/1

7/8

7/15

7/22

7/29

8/5

8/12
8/19
Bundesbank cuts RP rate

8/26

9/2

9/9

9/16

German Q2 GDP

Japanese Forward Rates Decline on Waning Business Confidence
-9x12

-- 1.6

6x9
1.2

3 x6
0.8

0.4

3 mo. EuroYenDeposit

7/15

7/22

7/29

8/5

8/12
8/19
8/26
Bank of Japan Tankan Survey

9/2

9/9

Japanese Q2 GDP

9/16

Page 2

Germany and Japan
104

104

103

103

102 -

102

101

101

100

100

99

99

98
7/1

98

US and German Equities Continue Rally while Japanese Equities Lag
(re-indexed to July 3, 1996)

102

102

100

100

98

98

96

96

94

94

92

92

90

7/1

90
8/12

8/19

8/26

9/2

9/9

Bank of Japan Tankan Survey
German 02 GDP
August Employment Data
August CPI: August Retail Sales; Japan 02

Page 3

Dollar Strengthens Against Mark and Yen

DM/$
1 53

1.53

August

FOMC

I

1.52

1.52

Dollar - Deutschmark Exchange Rate
1.51

1.51

1.5

1.5
I

1.49

1.49
- -

1.48

1.48

July

1.47
7/1

FOMC
7/8

7/15

7/22

7/29

8/5

8/12
8/19
Bundesbank cuts RP rate

8/26

9/2

9/9

9/16

1.47

German 02 GDP
Yen/$

US Trade Data

111

111

110.5

110.5

110

110

109.5

109.5

109

109

108.5

108.5

108

108

107.5

107.5

107
106.5

107
7/1

Perc ent
10

106.5

8/12
8/19
8/26
9/2
Bank of Japan Tankan Survey
US Fires Missiles at Iraq

Implied Volatility of 1-month Currency Options Remained Near Record Lows
$-Yen

9

8
$-DM
7

67/1
7/1

7/8
7/8

7/15
7/15

7/22
7/22

7/29
7/29

8/5

8/5

8/12

8/12

8/19

8/19

8/26

8/26

9/2

9/2

9/9

9/9

9/16

9/16

Page 4

Probability of September 25 basis point rate hike

Percent Implied by October Fed Funds Futures (CBOT)
100

August
FOMC

0

40

41

2

21

7/1

7/8

7/15

7/22

7/29

8/5
8/12
8/19
8/26
July FOMC Minutes; July Durable Goods

9/2

9/9

9/16

Chicago PM
"Jackson Hole" WSJ Article

Percent

August CPI; August Retail Sales
"DiscountRate" Story'

Interest Rate Spreads

1.2

Augu s t

2YR minus FF Target Rate

FOMC

1

30YR minus 2YR

0.7
7/1

7/8

7/15

7/22

7/29

8/5

8/12

8/19

8/26

9/2

9/9

9/16

Implied Volatility on Options on Futures Contracts (CBOT)

Percent

Based on September and

December Fuures

2YR Note Volatility
(right axis)

2.5

30YR Bond Volatility

(left
axis)
7/8

7/15

7/22

7/29

9/16
9/2
9/9
8/19
8/26
8/5
8/12
July FOMC Minutes; July Durable Goods
Chicago PMI
"Jackson Hole" WSJ Article
August CPI; August Retail Sales
"Discount Rate" Story

Michael J. Prell
September 24, 1996
FOMC BRIEFING
The data received in an interval between Committee meetings
rarely, if ever, provide an entirely coherent and persuasive
indication of where the economy is headed.

That said, the recent

period may still be remarkable for its statistical muddle.

Indeed,

the latest Greenbook may have seemed to you to be a story of why every
other number released since the twentieth of August should not be
believed.
I want to review just briefly a few of the anomalies we've
identified.

First, on the labor front, the plunge of the unemployment

rate in August to 5.1 percent seems questionable, and probably
reflects in part seasonal adjustment problems.

We're anticipating

that there will be at least some retracement in September, involving
another bounce back up in the participation rate.

Labor demand

clearly has been strong, as indicated by the employment and initial
claims figures, but not so robust as to be able to chop three-tenths
off the jobless rate this summer.
On the spending side, we're cautioning against reading too
much into the reported net decline in retail sales from May to August.
We're predicting that there will be some upward revision or a nearterm resurgence in sales, given our assessment of the demand trends
that should be associated with the strong income and wealth and
buoyant sentiment we've seen lately.
We also told you in the Greenbook that the recent data on
nonresidential construction contracts seemed oddly weak, against the
backdrop of a reported firming of the commercial real estate market;
we therefore predicted that actual building activity would hold up

FOMC Briefing - Michael Prell

- 2 -

September 24, 1996

better than the trend in contracts suggested.

Since the Greenbook,

we've received a report on contracts showing upward revisions to
earlier months and a big jump in August, so we feel our forecast is on
firmer ground now.
On the other hand, we told you that you shouldn't believe
that sales of new homes soared in July, as initially reported, and
that housing demand actually has been tapering gradually since the
spring.

Now, I also have to tell you to discount heavily the August

figures on housing starts, which came out last Thursday and showed a
spurt in single-family units.

It looks to us like the high starts

figure last month reflected a combination of statistical noise and
perhaps an unusually quick drawdown of permits.

But, that said, it

may well be that homebuilding has held up better than we judged.
We told you that the BEA's figures on federal purchases seem
to be fouled up, but that it doesn't matter for the near-term
projection because they will come up with sensible "best-change"
estimates even if the levels are wrong.

Admittedly, not a very

satisfying story, but potentially an important one--as demonstrated by
the surprises in recent GDP numbers.
We told you that the July figures on international trade were
misleading, because of seasonal adjustment problems, one-time payments
related to the Olympics, and the usual noise in the monthly data.

Net

exports really aren't weakening that much.
And, finally, we indicated that you should believe that wage
inflation is on the upswing, as underscored by the August report on
average hourly earnings; however, at the same time, we advised you to
resist the temptation to extrapolate the good news on price trends in
the subdued August PPI and CPI numbers.
So, where does this all leave us?

FOMC Briefing - Michael Prell

- 3 -

September 24, 1996

Well, first, we're pretty sure that the economy is on a solid
growth path, with little risk of recession or even seriously subpar
growth in the near term--at least absent some significant exogenous
shock.

The economy appears to be enjoying ample liquidity under the

current monetary policy settings, and fiscal policy probably is
exerting only a modest degree of restraint on demand.

As I've

suggested, there are enough positives in the consumer sector currently
to counterbalance any concerns related to debt and delinquency
problems.

Manufacturers' order books indicate favorable prospects for

capital goods production for at least a while.

Although we still

think that homebuilding is peaking, the latest data suggest the
improbability of a marked weakening in the absence of an appreciable
further rise in mortgage rates.

And, though the July trade figures

reinforce our sense that net exports are still on a downward path,
this doesn't appear likely to be an overwhelming drag on activity.
All this leads us to the prediction that growth will be more
moderate over coming quarters, but still sufficient to hold resource
utilization in the recent high range.
forecasters in this regard:

We are in the mainstream of

Our 2.1 percent 1997 GDP projection is

just a tenth above the early September Blue Chip consensus.

Looking

at the two wings of the Blue Chip forecast distribution, I'd have to
say that I'm somewhat more impressed by the arguments for greater
growth than we've projected in the next few quarters.

Perhaps this is

just because we're coming off a strong period--which is a
psychological trap one needs to avoid.

But, I do worry, for example,

that housing starts and the stock market are telling us that higher
bond yields are not biting into final demand even to the moderate
degree we think, and that stronger sales could in turn prompt
businesses to build inventories more aggressively.

FOMC Briefing - Michael Prell

- 4 -

September 24, 1996

In the end, I don't think the probability distribution around
our growth forecast is severely skewed, but you'll undoubtedly want to
assess that distribution in the context of the inflation implications
of a deviation from the predicted track.

We still hold with some

conviction the view that the underlying trend of inflation will be
deteriorating in the period ahead unless growth of aggregate demand
slows enough to lessen significantly the pressures on resources-especially labor.
We find the evidence that wages are rising more rapidly quite
persuasive.

The evidence on total compensation is less persuasive

statistically, but it is there.

And, whatever the magnitude of the

minimum wage effect, its sign is clearly positive in the short run.
The big question is whether the trend of prices must follow
the projected acceleration of compensation.

One might argue about the

use of the word "must," but we believe that the answer is "yes, at
least eventually."

Granted that businesses are still talking about

competition depriving them of pricing leverage, but--absent favorable
supply shocks--it's not obvious what in the outlook for activity and
capacity growth would lead one to think that price markups would be
allowed to erode continuously.

At some point, it seems more likely

that a broadly experienced cost increase--like that for labor--would
be associated with some rise in prices.

Thus, despite the adjustments

we've made in response to the recent good news on the core CPI, we
remain comfortable with our forecast of an uptilt in the underlying
trend of inflation.

The only 'question is when and how much.

taken our best shot on that score.

We've

Again, you'll have to make your

own assessment of how to deal with the uncertainty surrounding our
forecast in the context of your policy objectives.

September 24,

1996

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

The Committee

is facing today the same issue, with

many of the same pros and cons, as it has faced for the last
several meetings.

As one market letter recently noted, the

data released over the intermeeting period have bolstered
the arguments both for standing pat and

for tightening.

On the one hand, prices have remained surprisingly
quiescent, and one key element of final demand--consumption
spending--has softened appreciably.

With no signs in pro-

duct markets that pressures on resources are pervasive, and
still is some chance that infla-

with demand slowing, there

tion may be contained without a policy adjustment.
standing pat will have allowed the

economy to produce at a

higher level than if the Committee had tightened.
even if inflation emerges,
ually from a base that is

If so,

Moreover,

it should do so slowly and gradlower than had been expected by

many, restraining the associated uptick in inflation expectations.

The Committee may view these circumstances as

reducing the potential risks and costs
longer to

assess the situation.
On the other hand,

GDP,

of waiting a while

the unemployment

suggest that the
potential.

the

revision to

second-quarter

rate, and the behavior of wages all

economy more likely is

Moreover, housing starts and

producing beyond its
initial claims

raise questions about whether demand is
to take the pressure off resources.

slowing sufficiently

This situation, which

is reflected in the upward tilt to inflation in the Greenbook

makes it more likely that at some point you will have
Markets

to tighten to hold inflation near its current rate.

themselves have built in a slight firming by early next
year--though this may be colored as much by their reading
about your intentions as by their
necessary to achieve your goal.

judgment

of what would be

They may also be building

in your usual response to strong economic growth.

Output

has expanded faster than potential for two and perhaps three
quarters, and faster than expected.

It would be unusual--

inconsistent, for example, with the Taylor rule--for the
Committee not to tighten at some point in these circumstances, unless inflation were receding.
One question is what sort of indicators, in advance
of actual inflation itself, might prompt a judgment--now or
in the future--that tightening had become necessary.

In the

past couple of years we have learned--or relearned--that
some of the more problematic

indicators are those purporting

to measure the degree of slack in the economy.
problems stems,

One set of

of course, from the difficulty in estimating

the level of sustainable output or the NAIRU.

Moreover, the

Federal Reserve has made a point of saying that it doesn't
arbitrarily hold down growth or target

a particular level of

output or unemployment, but instead looks for signs of

emerging price pressures.

While those signs are in short

supply to date, output appreciably beyond estimated
potential--however broad the range of uncertainty around
that estimate--poses a significant risk of inflation
strengthening.

later

Consequently, even without an overt

acceleration in prices,

if output continues to run well

above estimated potential,
utilization rises

and especially if resource

further, the Committee may need to con-

sider whether it wants more assurance that policy is not
promoting an eventual pickup in inflation.
Any such judgment can't be divorced from indicators
of wage and price developments.

But a number of aspects of

the current situation makes interpreting these data complex
as well.
perhaps

For one, while favorable supply developments-related to

job insecurity or decelerating medical

costs--are undoubtedly contributing to the surprisingly
damped increases in compensation and prices, we should not
dismiss the possibility that part of this good behavior is a
reflection of the credibility of low inflation itself.
is,

That

expectations that low inflation will continue--built on

the experience of recent years and

evident in survey re-

sults--may be providing considerable inertia
tion process.

to the infla-

The risk is that policymakers mistakenly

attribute the sluggish response of inflation to high output
entirely to

persisting favorable supply conditions.

Attempts to stimulate aggregate demand to utilize the

seemingly more ample aggregate supply will be unsuccessful
over time and only result in an eventual deterioration in
inflation and inflation expectations.
A second complexity in interpreting wage and price
indicators is the nature of the inflation problem that may
be emerging.

The circumstances facing the Committee in this

expansion may be somewhat different than those in some
previous inflation cycles.

Pressures seem more evident in

labor than product markets.

In part because of the sizeable

investment in capital equipment, capacity utilization has
dropped from its recent peak, but the unemployment rate is
at a new low for this cycle.

Continuing slack in foreign

industrial economies, damping inflation abroad and stimulating foreign competition with U.S. manufacturers, may also be
alleviating pressures in product markets.

In these cir-

cumstances, any pickup in inflation should be slow and
perhaps delayed.

Nonetheless, the Committee may not be able

to take very much comfort from the absence of such traditional early indicators of price pressures as
modity and intermediate materials prices,
deliveries.

rising com-

or slower

supplier

Instead, in the staff forecast, tightness in

the labor market gradually puts
through over time

pressures on costs, feeding

into rising rates of increase in prices.

I've already noted the key role of damped expectations holding down inflation.
may want to be alert to signs

In that

regard, the Committee

in financial and related

markets that those expectations are beginning to drift
higher after a long period of stability.

In the past, the

Committee looked at movements in the dollar, long-term
interest rates and commodity prices among other variables
for clues in this regard.

It is important to view these and

other financial indicators in combination--especially how
they react to incoming news on the economy or prices.

A

rise in long-term rates by itself may not indicate increasing inflation expectations, but rather a judgment that
higher real rates over the next few years will be required
to hold the economy close to potential.

But a rise in rates

associated with a steady or declining dollar, other things
equal, for example, might be a warning that inflation
expectations, not expected real rates, were being revised
higher.

So far this year, a dollar on the firm side has

tended to confirm that the rise in long-term rates since
January likely has been mainly real.

To be sure, price or

rate changes in financial markets may not be easily parsed
into various types of expectations or readily explainable as
an appropriate response to news.

The amazing resilience of

the stock market this year suggests a note of caution in
expecting to extract rational views from the market.

More-

over, financial market responses may not be mirrored in
attitudes in labor and product markets.

It seems unlikely

that price and wage setters react as strongly or to the same
types

of information that affect financial markets.

But

financial market reactions themselves can create difficulties for the Committee and at times they may foreshadow
more far-reaching changes in attitudes.
For flows in financial markets, with levels of
interest rates not expected to move much on balance, the
staff sees growth of broad money and credit going forward
about in line with the projected expansion of nominal
spending.

The linkage is far from tight, despite the better

behavior of M2 demand of late.

But since our projections

embody a slight upward tilt to inflation, substantially more
rapid money and credit growth on a persistent basis might be
another warning sign of significant inflation pressures.
If, at this meeting or some time in the future, you
do raise the funds rate, the odds are high that other interest rates will rise as well.

How much is a more difficult

call.
Some have argued in the past that a firm show of
resolve by the Federal Reserve will damp inflation expectations enough to offset higher real rates and reduce longterm interest rates.

We have had, unfortunately, over the

intermeeting period a couple of experiments in which markets
learned something about purported Federal Reserve intentions
with respect to policy actions, divorced from news about the
economy or prices.

In these cases, information that the

Federal Reserve might tighten caused interest rates across

the maturity spectrum to increase, shifting up forward rates
far into the future.
In addition, over the last decade, long-term rates
have in fact tended to move considerably more in response to
policy actions that represented a change in direction than
to those that kept rates going in the same direction--a
tendency that has concerned some of you in the current
situation.
Thus, markets--equally as well as debt--are likely
to respond substantially to a tightening, even if such
action is forecast by the majority of analysts and mostly
priced into future rates.

Such a reaction would reflect a

response to news not only about the level of short-term
rates, but also about your assessment of the economic risks.
Nonetheless, as we noted in the bluebook, much market commentary does seem to have bought onto the idea that any
change in policy direction need not be the start of a long
string of actions in the same direction. In part, this
reflects the effect of some of the incoming data, which have
been read as indicating that inflation pressures will not be
so intense as to require a major policy adjustment.

In

addition, the minutes of your meetings have noted that many
Committee members share the view that policy is not so
tilted to the accommodative side as to suggest the need for
much adjustment.
tighten, market

As a consequence,
reaction is

if the Committee were to

likely to be smaller than might

-8-

be inferred from previous changes in policy direction.

The

wording of the announcement could improve the chances that
the market would see the tightening as limited in scope.