View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

September 16–17, 2015

1 of 240

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on
September 16–17, 2015
A joint meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee and the Board of Governors was
held in the offices of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C.,
on Wednesday, September 16, 2015, at 1:00 p.m. and continued on Thursday, September 17, 2015,
at 8:30 a.m. Those present were the following:
Janet L. Yellen, Chair
William C. Dudley, Vice Chairman
Lael Brainard
Charles L. Evans
Stanley Fischer
Jeffrey M. Lacker
Dennis P. Lockhart
Jerome H. Powell
Daniel K. Tarullo
John C. Williams
James Bullard, Esther L. George, Loretta J. Mester, Eric Rosengren, and Michael Strine,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Patrick Harker, Robert S. Kaplan, and Narayana Kocherlakota, Presidents of the Federal
Reserve Banks of Philadelphia, Dallas, and Minneapolis, respectively
Brian F. Madigan, Secretary
Matthew M. Luecke, Deputy Secretary
David W. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary
Michelle A. Smith, Assistant Secretary
Scott G. Alvarez, General Counsel
Steven B. Kamin, Economist
Thomas Laubach, Economist
David W. Wilcox, Economist
David Altig, Thomas A. Connors, Michael P. Leahy, William R. Nelson, Daniel G.
Sullivan, William Wascher, and John A. Weinberg, Associate Economists
Simon Potter, Manager, System Open Market Account
Lorie K. Logan, Deputy Manager, System Open Market Account
Robert deV. Frierson, Secretary of the Board, Office of the Secretary, Board of
Governors
Michael S. Gibson, Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board of
Governors

September 16–17, 2015

2 of 240

Nellie Liang, Director, Office of Financial Stability Policy and Research, Board of
Governors
James A. Clouse and Stephen A. Meyer, Deputy Directors, Division of Monetary Affairs,
Board of Governors
William B. English, Senior Special Adviser to the Board, Office of Board Members,
Board of Governors
David Bowman, Andrew Figura, David Reifschneider, and Stacey Tevlin, Special
Advisers to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Trevor A. Reeve, Special Adviser to the Chair, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
Linda Robertson, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Christopher J. Erceg, Senior Associate Director, Division of International Finance, Board
of Governors; David E. Lebow and Michael G. Palumbo, Senior Associate Directors,
Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Ellen E. Meade and Joyce K. Zickler, Senior Advisers, Division of Monetary Affairs,
Board of Governors
John J. Stevens, Deputy Associate Director, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Stephanie R. Aaronson, Assistant Director, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors; Francisco Covas and Elizabeth Klee, Assistant Directors, Division of
Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Eric C. Engstrom, Adviser, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Penelope A. Beattie,¹ Assistant to the Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Board of
Governors
Katie Ross,¹ Manager, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
David H. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Elmar Mertens, Senior Economist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Randall A. Williams, Information Management Analyst, Division of Monetary Affairs,
Board of Governors
________________
¹ Attended Wednesday’s session only.

September 16–17, 2015

3 of 240

Gregory L. Stefani, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Alberto G. Musalem, Executive Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Mary Daly, Troy Davig, Evan F. Koenig, Paolo A. Pesenti, Samuel Schulhofer-Wohl,
Ellis W. Tallman, and Christopher J. Waller, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve
Banks of San Francisco, Kansas City, Dallas, New York, Minneapolis, Cleveland, and St.
Louis, respectively
Giovanni Olivei, Keith Sill, and Douglas Tillett, Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks
of Boston, Philadelphia, and Chicago, respectively

September 16–17, 2015

4 of 240

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on
September 16–17, 2015
September 16 Session
CHAIR YELLEN. Good afternoon, everyone. I would like to welcome Rob Kaplan to
his first FOMC meeting. Rob became president and CEO of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas
just last week. In his new role, President Kaplan brings to bear 10 years of academic experience
at Harvard University, where he served as a professor and a dean; a long and distinguished career
in global finance; and broad experience on corporate and noncorporate boards. I have to say,
you chose to join us at a very interesting time. [Laughter] We all look forward to working with
you.
MR. KAPLAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. I appreciate it.
CHAIR YELLEN. Let me mention, as was indicated in the agenda, that the entire
FOMC meeting will be conducted jointly as an FOMC and Board of Governors meeting—and
this will likely be true going forward. I need a motion to close the Board meeting.
MR. FISCHER. So moved.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. And without objection. Our first item of business is
“Financial Developments and Open Market Operations.” Let me call on Simon to give us the Desk
report.
MR. POTTER. 1 Thank you, Madam Chair. Over the intermeeting period, a sharp
rise in concern about emerging market growth, particularly in China, triggered a
broad decline in global risk-sensitive assets. Oil and other commodity prices fell, at
times reaching levels last observed in early 2009, and inflation compensation
measures in the United States and other advanced economies continued to decline.
Most emerging market currencies depreciated, in some cases quite sharply. Nominal
Treasury yields were relatively little changed, reportedly in part because flight-toquality demand was offset by large-scale reserve sales by emerging market central
banks, which intervened heavily in foreign exchange markets in a bid to stabilize the
value of their currencies. Toward the end of the period, as U.S. markets calmed
1

The materials used by Mr. Potter and Ms. Logan are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

September 16–17, 2015

5 of 240

down, investors were intensely focused on the prospects for Federal Reserve policy
firming in light of the positive news on U.S. real activity during the intermeeting
period.
I will begin by discussing these financial market developments. Lorie will then
discuss money market developments and operational matters.
The People’s Bank of China unexpectedly devalued the renminbi versus the dollar
following a long period of stability and predictability in the management of that
exchange rate, as shown in the top-left panel of your first exhibit. Although the
devaluation was relatively small compared with the increase in China’s tradeweighted exchange rate over the past year, it came on the heels of a string of weak
Chinese economic data and the unwinding, at least in part, of a bubble in Chinese
equities. The devaluation appeared to intensify greatly the existing concerns among
market participants about the severity of the growth slowdown in China and the
ability of the Chinese authorities to address it appropriately. Sentiment toward
Chinese policymaking had already been fragile, especially in light of the often heavyhanded and ultimately unsuccessful effort over the past few months to halt the selloff
in equities. Following the devaluation, capital outflows from China accelerated
markedly from already high levels. These outflows led, within a couple of days, to
large-scale foreign exchange intervention to prevent further renminbi depreciation.
The concerns raised by the devaluation, along with a number of significant
developments in other emerging markets that I will discuss later, contributed to a
broad selloff in global risk assets. As shown in the top-right panel, equity price
indexes in both emerging and developed economies declined sharply. The S&P 500
index fell by more than 10 percent over a two-day period before recovering somewhat
and is about 7 percent lower, on net, over the period.
Nominal Treasury yields changed only modestly over the period, and real yields
actually increased somewhat at most tenors. The middle-left panel shows a
decomposition of the changes in forward nominal rates into real and inflation
compensation components. Some market participants expressed surprise that nominal
yields did not fall substantially and found the rise in real yields incongruous with the
decline in global risk sentiment and flight-to-quality effects that are ordinarily
expected to push yields down in such circumstances.
Many market participants believe that this relative stability in nominal yields
reflects the downward pressure of typical flight-to-quality flows being offset by
upward pressure stemming from sizable sales of Treasuries by Chinese and other
emerging market reserve managers intervening to support their currencies. Your
middle-right panel presents information about Chinese intervention activity. PBOC
official reserve data for August showed a decline in reserve holdings of about
$100 billion. Many market participants believe that this figure might understate the
scale of Chinese sales—for example, by omitting intervention via foreign exchange
derivatives—and estimate that the PBOC’s intervention might have been up to
$200 billion last month. Contacts believe that the PBOC funded outright

September 16–17, 2015

6 of 240

interventions in large part via sales of shorter-dated, off-the-run nominal Treasury
securities, and, as Lorie will discuss later, primary dealers’ inventories of these
securities rose rapidly. In addition, the PBOC was reportedly active in a range of
other assets and across a variety of other currency pairs.
Market participants generally expect continued high levels of intervention to stem
depreciation pressures on the renminbi, with some expecting that intervention could
total several hundred billion dollars through the spring of next year. The combined
effect of these actual and anticipated sales probably will put significant upward
pressure on Treasury yields, although it is difficult to quantify the effects. Chinese
officials appear to be hoping that various recently introduced so-called
macroprudential measures will stem capital outflows and reduce the corresponding
need for further FX intervention and asset sales to stabilize the currency at around its
current level. However, investors appear skeptical that these measures will have
much effect on capital flows, which are thought to be motivated by expectations for
further renminbi depreciation and a loss of confidence in the Chinese economic
outlook.
As further evidence of the possible effect of intervention on U.S. Treasuries,
market participants have pointed to a narrowing of swap spreads—the difference
between interest rate swap rates and cash Treasury yields—shown in the lower-left
panel. According to this argument, the narrowing of swap spreads reflects
underperformance of Treasuries versus other fixed-income assets in large part due to
the concentrated flow of Treasury sales by reserve managers. The narrowing has
been most notable in short-dated tenors, in which the majority of reserve selling has
likely taken place.
Concern about a slowdown in China and other emerging markets also drove a
steep decline in oil and other commodity prices. As shown in the lower-right panel,
oil prices fell 13 percent on net over the period amid very high volatility. In addition
to demand-related concerns, the decline in commodity prices also partly reflects
expectations for oil production, both by OPEC member countries and by shaleexploration firms, to respond to recent price declines more slowly and to a lesser
extent than earlier believed, as well as expectations for a significant rise in oil exports
from Iran following the lifting of trade sanctions.
Declines in commodity prices, the surprise renminbi devaluation, and concern
about fragility in many emerging economies have contributed to a significant
decrease in emerging market asset prices, most notably in commodity-exporting
economies. The top-left panel of your next exhibit illustrates the relationship
between countries’ intermeeting currency performance, on the vertical axis, against
the share of their exports that come from commodities, on the horizontal axis. This
panel shows that countries for which energy is a more important export experienced
larger currency depreciations; for example, the currencies in the lower-right quadrant
depend most on energy exports and exhibited the largest depreciation. These large
exchange rate moves appear to reflect concern about the effect of sizable changes in
the terms of trade on the economic health and fiscal, financial, political, and social

September 16–17, 2015

7 of 240

stability of countries whose fortunes are closely tied to commodity exports and to
China. The performance of the Turkish, Brazilian, Malaysian, and Russian
currencies, which lie well below the best-fit line in this figure, also reflects the effects
of political developments in these countries as well as, in the case of Brazil, a credit
downgrade by Standard & Poor’s to non-investment grade.
The decline in energy prices has also contributed to a continued fall in inflation
compensation at both short and long horizons. The top-right panel shows the
evolution of 5-year inflation compensation as measured in the swaps market over the
past several years in the euro area and the United States. Each measure is well below
its respective 10-year average, represented by the dashed horizontal lines. In the
United States, 5-year inflation compensation fell about 25 basis points over the
intermeeting period and is now near mid-2010 levels, although market measures of
deflation probabilities are lower than they were in that earlier period. In addition to
the drop in oil prices, market participants cite low inflation data, the appreciation of
the trade-weighted dollar, and concerns about global economic growth as placing
downward pressure on U.S. inflation compensation. Longer-dated forward inflation
compensation also fell over the intermeeting period in the United States and the euro
area. Respondents to the Desk’s surveys continue to report that their own forward
inflation expectations are little changed. At the same time, they attribute about onethird of the decline in long-forward inflation compensation over the period to a
decline in the markets’ overall assessment of inflation expectations, which is more
than is attributed to this factor by most term structure models used in the System.
In response to increased concerns about the inflation and growth outlook, the
ECB at its September 3 meeting signaled a willingness to change the size,
composition, and duration of its purchase program, should conditions warrant, and
adjusted one of the key parameters of its program to give more room to enlarge it if
necessary. Sustained asset price response to this communication was limited. At its
meeting this week, the Bank of Japan lowered its expectations for exports and
production because of the slowdown in emerging markets but suggested the Japanese
economy continues to recover moderately and kept its inflation outlook unchanged.
A majority of Japanese market contacts believe the BOJ will expand the scope of its
QE program later this year in pursuit of its inflation goal.
Some contacts report concerns that advanced-economy central banks—many of
which are facing persistently low inflation while already at the zero lower bound and
using quantitative easing measures—will be unable to adequately react to an external
shock stemming from a significant global growth slowdown. In a new survey
question, we asked the dealers to estimate the probability that the global economy
will be in a recession six months from now. The average probability was 20 percent,
with a range of individual beliefs from 5 to 50 percent. For comparison, the average
probability associated with a recession in the United States was 13 percent.
Separately, market participants report uncertainty about how well some countries,
most notably Brazil, will cope with tighter U.S. monetary policy, and note that many
countries experienced significant challenges during the 2013 “taper tantrum.”

September 16–17, 2015

8 of 240

However, it is important to emphasize that most market participants assess that these
difficulties in individual countries by themselves are not material to the U.S. outlook.
However, with policy firming likely to take place in the United States in the near or
very near future, it is useful to recall that one of the lessons of the taper tantrum was
that dollar carry trades might be more pervasive than standard measures indicate, and
that their unwind can produce a deterioration of financial conditions in the United
States through a decline in global risk appetite. Thus, it will be important to monitor
closely for evidence of carry-trade-type linkages in offshore dollar markets. This is
particularly true for activity running through Hong Kong, which is in the unusual
position of maintaining a peg to the U.S. dollar while having the most open capital
markets with mainland China.
The rise in uncertainty associated with the global economic outlook prompted an
increase in volatility across most assets. Your middle-left panel shows the increase in
implied volatility, most notably in equities and foreign exchange, in the period since
the PBOC’s devaluation. Implied volatility for equities in particular remains
elevated, although it has come off its highs. Market participants reported that
liquidity conditions, especially in foreign exchange and equity markets, deteriorated
over the period, and that this contributed to some punctuated moves in asset prices,
particularly on August 24. As in earlier events, such as the Treasury market moves
last October 15, there seemed to be increased intraday volatility when large shocks or
belief swings required big position unwinds. In this context, commentary over the
period highlighted the effect of position adjustments by so-called risk parity strategies
on market volatility. To date, these liquidity events have been transitory and do not
seem to have materially affected market pricing. It is possible that these events are
just part of the new landscape for financial markets with no implication for policy.
While market participants continue to see an increase in the federal funds rate at
this meeting as a real possibility, expectations for this declined notably amid the
financial market volatility. The middle-right panel shows the market-implied
probability of liftoff at or before the September meeting, derived from federal funds
futures prices and data from the Desk’s surveys about where the effective rate will
trade in the target range following liftoff. The probability had been about 50–50
before the PBOC devaluation and is now about 1-in-4 to 1-in-3. Market participants
have suggested that diverse views expressed in policymaker communications over the
period added to uncertainty surrounding the timing of liftoff. Thomas will discuss
policy expectations and possible market reactions more in his briefing.
Turning to conditions expected at liftoff, for some time the Desk surveys have
asked about expectations for inflation between one and two years ahead at the time of
liftoff. As shown in the lower-left panel, the mean expectation is now that inflation
between one and two years after liftoff will run a bit low, at 1.8 percent. This decline
appears to reflect a belief that subdued inflation will be somewhat more persistent
than earlier thought.
Let me conclude by noting the tightening in many common components of
financial conditions indexes over the intermeeting period. Your lower-right panel

September 16–17, 2015

9 of 240

shows the intermeeting performance of assets that form the core of most such
indexes. As the panel shows, conditions in the equity, high-yield credit, foreign
exchange, and real interest rate markets all tightened, with mortgages the significant
exception. These moves were large both in absolute terms and in comparison with
recent historical behavior. This illustrates that adverse developments in China and
other emerging market countries have the potential to affect U.S. asset prices in a way
that, if sustained, might have significant implications for the U.S. economic outlook.
David Wilcox and Steve Kamin will discuss the implications of this risk further in
their briefings.
Lorie will now discuss money markets and operational matters.
MS. LOGAN. As Simon noted, measures of domestic financial conditions
tightened over the intermeeting period, though this tightening was not accompanied
or led by any increase in dollar funding strains.
We have, however, observed a relatively modest but steady increase in some
money market rates since earlier this year, as shown in the top-left panel of your third
exhibit. This trend continued over the period, and the average effective federal funds
rate for the month of August, excluding month-end, reached 14 basis points, its
highest level in over two years. Market participants have speculated that the increase
in the effective rate over recent months has been the result of a number of factors,
including the pull of higher secured money market rates.
In explaining the more recent rise in repo rates, a number of contacts have pointed
to foreign official sales to fund the FX intervention that Simon discussed and an
associated increase in demand from primary dealers to finance these Treasury
securities. Indeed, as shown in the top-right panel, primary dealers’ Treasury
holdings have increased since early July, leaving them with a larger amount of
Treasury collateral to finance. The recent upward pressure arising from these
developments is similar to the upward movement in repo rates and the effective rate
observed during the maturity extension program, when the Federal Reserve was
selling short-dated Treasury securities.
Amid these higher money market rates, total daily RRP take-up declined
somewhat outside month-ends, averaging $78 billion versus $140 billion last period,
as shown in the middle-left panel. The pattern of counterparty participation was
generally consistent with prior periods, with money market funds continuing to
account for most of the participation. The Federal Reserve also continued to test TDF
operations over the intermeeting period. Take-up at the two overlapping TDF
operations in August totaled nearly $125 billion, moderately lower than in the
previous operations in May.
Meanwhile, foreign RP pool participation, shown in grey, was relatively steady
over the period. As discussed at the July FOMC meeting, the staff communicated the
changes in the repo pool terms of service to FIMA accounts, including the removal of
individual target levels and of the requirement that we be notified in advance of

September 16–17, 2015

10 of 240

changes in daily investment levels in excess of $100 million. The new terms took
effect on September 4. We anticipate that the size of the foreign RP pool will grow
$50 billion over the next several months based on indications from one large account
holder that it plans to increase its use of the service. This institution noted that it
plans to increase its liquid investments in anticipation of potential market turbulence
over the next year related to U.S. monetary policy normalization.
Despite the recent upward drift in some money market rates noted earlier,
expectations for the constellation of short-term interest rates following liftoff have
remained quite stable. Responses to the Desk’s surveys and outreach to a wide range
of counterparties, summarized in your middle-right panel, suggest that market
participants view the Federal Reserve as having the necessary tools to control shortterm interest rates following liftoff. Specifically, the modal expectation is that the
effective rate will print only slightly below the midpoint of a 25 to 50 basis point
target range, and this expectation has been stable in responses to the Desk’s surveys
for some time. Other money market rates, with the exception of Treasury bills, are
expected to trade at relatively similar spreads to the effective rate as they have over
recent months.
While respondents to the Desk’s surveys generally express confidence that the
effective rate will print within the target range after liftoff—and assign very small
probabilities to outcomes outside the range—they do assign a meaningful probability
to it printing toward the bottom of that range. In particular, some commentary has
highlighted that the effective lower bound may be providing support to money market
rates that will recede as the target range is lifted. Other commentary has focused on
the risks that increased demand for short-term, high-quality assets related to SEC
money fund reform and continued declines in dealer repo books will put downward
pressure on repo rates and pull down the effective federal funds rate.
More recently, market participants have noted that the timing of liftoff relative to
the debt ceiling might also affect the path of money market rates. Over the
intermeeting period, Treasury Secretary Lew extended the debt issuance suspension
period through October 30, which allows the Treasury to continue to use
extraordinary measures to remain under the statutory debt limit while issuing new
securities. Staff and market projections suggest that these measures should allow the
Treasury debt that is subject to the limit to stay below the statutory ceiling until
around late November. Staff projections, shown as the dotted light blue line in the
bottom-right panel, suggest that bill supply could temporarily decline another
$171 billion from current levels if the debt ceiling is not lifted in the near term. This
reduction in supply could put downward pressure on money market rates, particularly
for outstanding bills, and the potential combination of lower money market rates and
reduced bill supply might prompt a sizable increase in demand at our reverse repo
operations, particularly at quarter-end. Demand for RRPs could be further boosted if,
as in the past, money funds seek to avoid so-called at-risk securities or increase their
investments in short-term, cash-like instruments in anticipation of possible
redemptions. These pressures could increase the risk that demand at the ON RRP
operations exceeds the current aggregate $300 billion limit.

September 16–17, 2015

11 of 240

At this point, we have not seen evidence of concern about a possible disruptive
debt ceiling outcome in financial markets. That said, in past episodes, and as shown
in the top-left panel of your final exhibit, bill yields did not reflect such concern until
closer to the date when the Treasury was expected to exhaust its extraordinary
measures. As in previous episodes, the staff intends to prepare contingency plans for
a variety of scenarios and will provide an update to the Committee at the October
meeting or sooner, if needed.
Looking ahead, as detailed in a note sent to the Committee during the
intermeeting period and outlined in the top-right panel, the Desk plans to offer term
RRPs over the September quarter-end. Should the Committee decide not to increase
the target range, the Desk would propose offering $250 billion in term RRPs at
3 basis points over the ON RRP offered rate, apportioned between seven- and twoday maturities. This increased offering amount should mitigate, to some extent, the
risk that a drop in Treasury bill supply might lead to more quarter-end pressure than
we anticipate. This would be somewhat higher than the $200 billion offered over the
past two quarter-end dates but below the $300 billion offered in December 2014.
If the Committee decides to raise the target range at this meeting and directs the
Desk to temporarily suspend the cap on the ON RRP, the Desk plans to continue to
offer the already announced $200 billion in two term operations, also with seven- and
two-day maturities, but at a 0 basis point spread to the ON RRP rate. Without
offering any financial incentive for investing cash for term instead of overnight, we
would anticipate limited take-up in the term operations and larger take-up at the ON
RRP operations.
Finally, I would like to provide a brief update on reinvestments. The Desk
continues to reinvest principal payments on holdings of agency debt and MBS into
agency MBS through secondary market purchases, and these operations proceeded
smoothly over the intermeeting period. Following our update at the July meeting, the
Desk began aggregating agency MBS CUSIPs during the week of August 17, as
planned.
Over the period, there was some focus on the FOMC’s reinvestment policy
following the discussion in the July FOMC meeting minutes. As in prior surveys, and
shown in your middle-left panel, respondents view a phasing-out of Treasury security
and agency MBS reinvestments as the most likely scenario and generally expect that
reinvestments will be phased out over a 10- to 12-month period. As shown in your
middle-right panel, according to the Desk’s surveys, the median respondent expects
that the FOMC will cease some or all Treasury security and agency MBS
reinvestments 9 months and 8 months following liftoff, respectively. Both of these
numbers represent a modest increase from median expectations in the July surveys
and continue to reflect a wide range of expectations.
Thank you, Madam Chair. That concludes our prepared remarks.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you very much. The floor is open for questions. Jim.

September 16–17, 2015

12 of 240

MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’m looking at exhibit 2, figure 7—“FX
Performance over Intermeeting Period and Net Commodity Exports.” What is the lesson I am to
draw from this chart?
MR. POTTER. In general, countries that export a lot—mainly to China—and have done
very well over the past 10 years are suffering quite a lot of exchange rate pressure right now. In
addition, you see some big outliers down there that I discussed that have idiosyncratic events
going on right now, probably the most important of which is Brazil, due to its size.
MR. BULLARD. One interpretation is that this line is pretty flat, and everybody
depreciated against the dollar. Maybe it’s not so much related to commodities—it’s just
everyone depreciated against the dollar.
MR. POTTER. There’s a bit of a scale issue here and I agree that nearly everyone did
depreciate against the dollar, but there is a relatively weak relationship here, and it does have a
negative slope. If you took into account the depreciation over a longer period of time, you’d see
more of a consistent one here. At the previous briefing, I discussed Canada and Norway in terms
of the depreciation that they’ve had, and we saw less of that in this intermeeting period, but it’s
been substantial leading into this intermeeting period. The point we’re trying to get across is,
these are really big relative price shocks for these countries, and some of what we saw in the loss
of risk appetite is how well they deal with these big, relative price shocks.
MR. BULLARD. Countries have also been changing their monetary policy stance,
something that would tend to depreciate their currency.
MR. POTTER. Exactly.
MR. BULLARD. So it’s not just commodities—it’s commodity market developments in
conjunction with monetary policy developments.

September 16–17, 2015

13 of 240

MR. POTTER. The theory is that you can get some economic stabilization by having a
flexible exchange rate. And we’re on the other side of that, as you pointed out.
MR. BULLARD. I have a question about panel 12, which gives key components of
financial conditions. Could you just plot the financial conditions index that you think is the most
appropriate? Because if you do it this way, then I’ve got to compute in my head what happened
to the financial conditions index.
MR. POTTER. I think there’s a new one of those produced each day.
MR. BULLARD. Yes. [Laughter]
MR. POTTER. And they have differences among them with respect to their construction.
There’s one that’s been very prominent in the past week, and that one has been given some
weight by people outside this building. For the people around this table, I think you can’t rely on
an index constructed by someone else for how you should look at the deterioration in financial
conditions.
I tried to emphasize that it’s been mixed. Mortgages tightened. If you put a lot of weight
on the housing sector, then this doesn’t look as bad as some other periods. If you put a lot of
weight on the exchange rate, then this is a pretty big intermeeting move. If you look at some of
the bigger indexes that are in the first percentile for the stock market, this is still pretty small.
We could give you one index, but I think that would be misleading because every situation is
different. The weights might have worked well in the past, but they might not work well going
forward.
MR. BULLARD. Okay. So your point is that it’s a mixed picture with respect to
financial conditions.
MR. POTTER. Yes. That, we hope, is our spin.

September 16–17, 2015

14 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. I have President Evans next.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. Simon, could you talk more about chart 11 on
inflation expectations between one and two years after liftoff? I assume this comes from the
dealer survey?
MR. POTTER. It’s from both the dealer survey and the Survey of Market Participants.
MR. EVANS. Okay. It seems to show that in June and July of 2014, inflation was
expected to be above 2 percent. Is that because they thought we would be late to liftoff? We
were taking a while to taper and we hadn’t finished the tapering, and now should I infer that
we’re early to liftoff or right about time for liftoff? Also, is there any information from this
about how longer-term inflation expectations might be moving? I understand that it’s short term,
but any information about credibility anchors?
MR. POTTER. I can’t look into the heads of the people who put this answer down.
MR. EVANS. But you do statistical analysis of other things.
MR. POTTER. We do, but not psychology, which I’m not so good at. What has been
the case, if you look at the probability distributions we have collected over the past year to a year
and a half, there’s less probability assigned to the higher inflation outcomes, so that naturally
drags down the average inflation rate that people expect. In terms of the probability that
inflation will be less than 1.75 percent over one to two years ahead, the dealers think there’s a 30
percent chance, which is not as high as they thought in March. The buy side places a slightly
higher probability on that outcome than they did in March. If you average the dealers and buy
side together, you get about 45 percent probability, and that’s consistent with the subdued
inflation we’ve seen and the current inflation outlook.
MR. EVANS. Thank you.

September 16–17, 2015

15 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you. I want to follow up on President Bullard’s question on
panel 12 and then I want to make a link to panel 5. I noticed that the MBS OAS came down. I
have a clarifying question and a more analytical one. When the Treasury nominal swap spreads
come down, that means that the swap rates are coming down more than the Treasury rates, right?
MR. POTTER. They’re both going up, but by less.
MR. WILLIAMS. Yes, but they’re actually both coming down, on net, over the period.
MR. POTTER. This is the one-year forward rate, so you have to be careful with it. And
it’s not updated for what happened yesterday. If you look at the two-year note, it was 80 basis
points at close yesterday. And you did see swap spreads also fall again yesterday.
MR. WILLIAMS. Okay. So, first, the swap rates have fallen?
MR. POTTER. Yes.
MR. WILLIAMS. And the second question is, do we have a view on what is more
correlated with the interest rates we think matter for borrowing, like corporate rates, other
borrowing rates in the economy, and mortgage rates—is it swap rates or the Treasury rates?
Treasury securities can have special features that mean that there’s a special premium associated
with those, and possibly swap rates are more correlated with the private borrowing rates that we
probably think actually matter—that is my question.
MR. POTTER. It’s definitely true that this could be taken as something the private sector
would like if they want to swap floating for fixed. Overall, though, if you look at high yield
OAS, that did move out a reasonable amount but it’s still not a really big change. I’ve got 14
basis points over the intermeeting period, which we quoted as being at the 31st percentile. One
of the intermeeting periods was 128 basis points, which occurred with the fall in oil prices and

September 16–17, 2015

16 of 240

the effect of the energy credits. What we tried to do in chart 12 is to give a feeling for the
richness of how you might measure financial conditions.
MR. WILLIAMS. Are other borrowing rates besides mortgage rates, like corporate bond
rates—
MR. POTTER. I think corporate bond rates have moved out, so they’re higher, and that’s
definitely something that’s been happening over the past few months. But as Lorie emphasized,
we’ve seen absolutely zero evidence of signs of stress in funding markets. Again, as I said, it’s a
new world, and maybe we’ll learn there’s a great index that would’ve told us what to do in a
year’s time.
MR. WILLIAMS. So what we really need is a daily r* out of all this.
MR. POTTER. Thank you. You and Thomas can work on it, then. [Laughter]
CHAIR YELLEN. Vice Chairman Dudley.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Just a very short intervention on the swap rate. The
swap rate really is not a good indicator of what other corporate rates are going to be because it
doesn’t really have a credit default component in it. When the swap is struck, there’s no notional
value, so the swap rate doesn’t really reflect corporate credit rates in a—
MR. POTTER. But holding that constant, it does.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. It affects relative supply, and I think the way Simon was
using it was to show that there’s a lot of Treasury supply that’s entering the market, presumably
from the liquidation of foreign exchange reserves, and that’s causing swap rates to fall relative to
Treasury rates.
MR. POTTER. There are some other explanations the Tealbook discusses as well.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Rosengren.

September 16–17, 2015

17 of 240

MR. ROSENGREN. My question is for Lorie, and it’s concerning the challenges of
implementing the reverse repo facility when we decide to start raising rates. It’s a two-part
question. One is from panel 15. Were you surprised there wasn’t more activity in the reverse
repo facility around the end of August and the beginning of September? And as you think about
the volatility we’ve been experiencing in financial markets—the debt ceiling, the government
shutdown, and end-of-the-year effects—how do you weigh those things in terms of thinking
about the challenges to actually doing liftoff when we want to lift off? Are there things that
particularly concern you as we think about October, December, or next year and what’s going to
be happening, whether we’ll actually be able to lift off effectively when we want to?
MS. LOGAN. With respect to the first question on not seeing more usage, I guess you’re
referring to the financial volatility in markets and flight to quality. We didn’t see any funding
pressures, as Simon just discussed. I would think that the type of volatility we’d expect to affect
the overnight RRP would be more closely connected to funding pressures than asset price
volatility going longer out. So I wasn’t particularly surprised, but we were monitoring it closely
to be sure.
With respect to the year-end and the debt ceiling, given that the Committee is considering
suspending the cap at liftoff, I don’t think we would expect to see year-end issues associated
with managing the rate because there would be plenty of room to accommodate year-end
pressures while targeting the overnight rate. There are other issues associated with liquidity in
financial markets— there might be an exaggerated move in broader asset prices just because
there’s not as much trading going on during that time of year. So I think there are two separate
issues when you look at liftoff at the end of the year. One is related specifically to
implementation, and I think the cap should go a long way toward alleviating that if it was lifted.

September 16–17, 2015

18 of 240

The other is just broader financial market volatility, and I think that one is harder to assess, but I
would say that there’s a lot less liquidity at year-end.
With respect to the debt ceiling, I think it can go both ways. One the one hand, with the
reduction in bill supply, we should expect there to be more pressure to use the overnight RRP
due to a shortage of collateral. On the other hand, we don’t know when that really is going to
start, and we also don’t know how markets are going to treat the at-risk securities. If market
participants think the ON RRP facility is going to be there, they may not withdraw from the
money funds that might give them those at-risk securities, and so we might not see the pressures
there. I think it’s hard to know with respect to the debt ceiling.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Madam Chair. I thought panel 12 was quite
informative. I was wondering if you know or if you could provide a similar metric with regard
to the decline in market-based measures of inflation compensation during the intermeeting period
in terms of a percentile. I thought the percentile metric was very helpful.
MR. POTTER. I don’t have that in front of me. At times it was large—you can just look
at the time series chart to see that. It’s going to vary by which measure you use. There was
definitely a period, around the middle-to-late part of August, when it was falling quite strongly,
but I don’t have that offhand. We can find it for you.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes, if you could.
MR. POTTER. I think it’s not going to be as big as some of the moves we’ve seen in the
past. Remember, when I show you a chart like this, it doesn’t tell you what level we start at. A
lot of people say, “The stock market was a little high, and so it naturally came down.” And it
could be that some of those big moves down occurred when inflation compensation was

September 16–17, 2015

19 of 240

relatively high compared with where it is today. So this is neutral on these statements. This is
really looking at some change in change, you could almost argue.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. But if you could provide that to me, that would be useful.
MR. POTTER. Yes, will do.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Further questions?
MR. KAMIN. If I could just offer a little bit of additional information regarding
President Bullard’s question about the relationship between commodity prices and exchange
rates. We’ve done some research on this: basically, econometrically relating changes in
currency values to the share of a country’s trade that’s in both oil and non-oil commodities. It
turns out that if you run that regression over the entire past year, starting when the dollar started
to fall, you actually get pretty precise, statistically significant estimates of the effect of both oil
prices and non-oil commodity prices on exchange rates. That explains somewhere in the
neighborhood of half of the cross-sectional dispersion of exchange rate depreciations.
Now, if you take a snapshot of the previous intermeeting period, you might expect that,
as it’s a more tumultuous time and a shorter period, you’d get a less precise reading on the
relationship between commodity prices and exchange rates, and that is indeed what we found.
You still have a statistically significant effect of oil prices on currencies, but it’s a smaller
coefficient, and a not-statistically-significant effect of non-oil commodity prices on currencies.
That’s all to say that I think the basic relationship between commodity prices and a
country’s exchange rate still holds, but it’s been obscured in this past month and a half with the
more general market volatility.

September 16–17, 2015

20 of 240

MR. BULLARD. Just to respond to that—why should they depreciate against the dollar?
They should really depreciate against a basket of currencies of noncommodity countries, so the
dollar is sort of proxying for the noncommodity—
MR. KAMIN. Well, they probably are.
MR. BULLARD. Yes. But that would be a big part of the world if you include the yen
and the Europeans.
MR. POTTER. Well, the euro and yen went up against the dollar, so the currencies of
commodity countries depreciated against them as well.
CHAIR YELLEN. Any further questions or comments? [No response] I need a motion
to ratify domestic open market operations since July.
MR. FISCHER. So moved.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Without objection. We’re next going to turn to “System
Open Market Account Reinvestment Policy,” and I’m going to call on Beth Klee to start us off.
MS. KLEE. 2 Thank you, Madam Chair. Chris Erceg and I will be referring to the
materials titled “SOMA Reinvestment Policy.”
At the July FOMC meeting, participants discussed various aspects of the decision
to end reinvestment, including the appropriate economic conditionality of such a
decision and the macroeconomic effects of alternative strategies. In that context, you
recently received a follow-up memo that addressed a number of these questions. As
noted in the upper panel of your first exhibit, key questions include the following:
How much might the choice of reinvestment strategy matter for economic outcomes?
How much might the choice of reinvestment strategy affect the path of the federal
funds rate? And can reinvestment strategies that are linked to the federal funds rate
improve economic outcomes in situations when the effective lower bound on the
federal funds rate is binding? In our briefing, Chris and I will provide evidence on
these issues and discuss possible implications for the reinvestment language options
included in alternative C of the September Tealbook.
To start, under the trigger strategies considered in the staff memo—and as noted
in the lower panel—the Committee would announce that full reinvestment of the
principal payments from Treasury and agency mortgage-backed securities would
2

The materials used by Ms. Klee and Mr. Erceg are appended to this transcript (appendix 2).

September 16–17, 2015

21 of 240

continue until the federal funds rate reaches the trigger—either 1 percent or 2
percent—and then stop permanently. These strategies have several key features.
First, they are state dependent and, therefore, in line with the Policy Normalization
Principles and Plans document, which indicates that the timing of the end of
reinvestment will depend on the economic outlook. Second, these strategies link
reinvestment to the level of the policy rate, a feature that may be conceptually
attractive as it then indirectly links the end of reinvestment to economic conditions.
Third, the conditionality is limited because the triggers, as constructed, imply that
reinvestment ends permanently once the trigger is reached. Of note, although we
assume for illustrative purposes that the trigger strategies are geared toward specific
numerical values of the funds rate, these strategies could be communicated through
qualitative guidance about how far policy normalization had to proceed before
reinvestment would be ended.
Your next exhibit explores some consequences of the trigger strategies if
economic conditions evolve in line with the modal outlook. Panel A compares the
evolution of the SOMA portfolio under the baseline reinvestment strategy—for which
it is assumed that reinvestment ceases roughly six months after liftoff, and which is
depicted by the solid black line—with the trigger strategies. The 1 percent trigger—
the blue dashed line—delays the end of reinvestment only briefly, while the 2 percent
trigger—the red dotted line—delays the end of reinvestment until two years after
liftoff, to late 2017. The larger balance sheet under each trigger strategy causes the
term premium—panel B—to run a tad lower than under the baseline strategy.
Because the inertial Taylor rule assumed to govern the federal funds rate in our
simulations does not raise policy rates enough to counteract this additional balance
sheet stimulus, long-term real interest rates decline a touch compared with the
baseline—panel C—and, consequently, the unemployment rate also falls a little more
quickly—panel E. However, it is clear that the macroeconomic effects are small,
even under the more accommodative 2 percent trigger.
You might look at the results and wonder if reinvestment policy could matter
much for macroeconomic outcomes. Returning to the top of the exhibit, consider a
polar case—shown by the green dash-dotted lines in panel A—in which the FOMC
announces that the SOMA portfolio will be held constant at its current level for a very
long time. In this case, the term premium drops about 40 basis points on the
announcement—the green line in panel B—and the unemployment rate, panel E, falls
about ¼ percentage point below baseline by 2018. This example highlights the result
that reinvestment policy can have sizable effects, albeit under an extreme strategy.
Turning to your third exhibit, the stimulus from the alternative reinvestment
strategies can be offset by a somewhat higher funds rate than implied by the inertial
Taylor rule. As seen in panel A, we implement this offset for each strategy by
boosting the intercept term of the Taylor rule by enough to achieve nearly the same
macroeconomic outcomes as in the Tealbook baseline. As seen in panel B, only a
small upward adjustment of the federal funds rate path is required under the trigger
strategies—the blue and red lines—to mimic the baseline outcomes for
unemployment, panel C, and inflation, panel D. By contrast, offsetting the effects of

September 16–17, 2015

22 of 240

maintaining a constant portfolio requires a noticeably higher funds rate—the green
line in panel B.
Chris will now continue our briefing starting with your next exhibit.
MR. ERCEG. Thank you, Beth. Although the macroeconomic effects of the
baseline and trigger reinvestment strategies do not differ greatly under the modal
outlook, trigger strategies can provide considerably more balance sheet
accommodation in response to adverse shocks, particularly those shocks that would
drive the federal funds rate to the ELB. To illustrate this, in exhibit 4 we consider a
recessionary shock that pins the federal funds rate at the ELB for three years under
the baseline reinvestment strategy—the solid black line in panel A—and results in the
unemployment rate—panel B—rising to 7½ percent. Under the 2 percent trigger
strategy, the red dotted line in panel A, the public expects that the federal funds rate
will remain below 2 percent until 2021. Accordingly, SOMA holdings, panel C, are
expected to remain at their current level until the funds rate reaches 2 percent in 2021.
The larger balance sheet under this strategy results in a much lower path for the term
premium—the red line in panel D. As a result, the trigger strategy mitigates
somewhat the rise in the unemployment rate—panel B—with the peak rise about 0.4
percentage point lower than under the baseline strategy.
The bottom panel discusses three key implications of trigger strategies. First, the
balance sheet stimulus under the trigger strategy in an adverse scenario comes from
an expectations channel: Because reinvestment is tied to the policy rate, which is
expected to remain low for a long time, the balance sheet is expected to remain large
for much longer than in the baseline. Second—and relatedly—a “calendar based”
strategy that simply delayed reinvestment for a couple of years after liftoff would
provide much less economic stimulus in adverse scenarios. This outcome is
illustrated by the strategy labeled “liftoff plus 2 years” shown by the dashed blue lines
in panel C. It delays the end of reinvestment by two years after liftoff, to late 2017,
and thus extends the SOMA holdings. Because the effects on the term premium—
panel D—are quite small, this alternative approach only slightly mitigates the rise in
unemployment, the blue lines in panel B, relative to the baseline.
Returning to the bottom panel, the third key implication is that the trigger strategy
only provides noticeable stimulus if the adverse shock occurs before the policy rate
reaches the trigger. If the recessionary shocks occurred later, the trigger strategy—
through delaying balance sheet adjustment a year or two—would provide only a small
degree of additional stimulus. A strategy that would restart reinvestment in response
to sufficiently bad shocks could potentially do better in limiting their adverse
macroeconomic effects than would an irreversible trigger strategy, at least if this
strategy were well understood by market participants. Of course, the greater state
dependence of this policy might make it more difficult to communicate.
As noted in your final exhibit, paragraph 4 of alternative C provides two options
to characterize the Committee’s thinking about when to cease or begin phasing out
reinvestments. The first is to continue reinvesting “until normalization of the level of

September 16–17, 2015

23 of 240

the federal funds rate is well under way,” and the second is to continue reinvesting “at
least during the early stages of normalization of the level of the federal funds rate.”
You might view “well under way” as qualitatively consistent with the trigger
strategies discussed in the memo. In particular, market participants might interpret
this language as suggesting that reinvestment would not cease until economic
conditions had led the Committee to increase the target range for the federal funds
rate more than a few times. In addition, the public might conclude that, in the event
that the economic outlook deteriorated, reinvestment could continue for a long time.
This qualitative language would leave some ambiguity about how high the federal
funds rate would have to rise to trigger an end of reinvestment, although
policymakers could help clarify the public’s understanding through speeches,
testimony, and other communications.
In contrast, “at least during the early stages” might be interpreted as indicating
that the Committee intends to cease or phase out reinvestment after a few hikes in the
policy rate even if the federal funds rate stayed relatively low thereafter. Market
participants would probably view this language as indicating that policymakers place
a relatively high priority on beginning to normalize the size of the balance sheet fairly
soon. However, the qualification “at least” would likely suggest that the Committee
wanted to retain some option to continue reinvestments if the labor market was to
weaken or if inflation was stubbornly low.
Thank you very much. Beth and I will be happy to take your questions.
CHAIR YELLEN. Let’s start with questions for Beth and Chris, after which I’ll be very
interested in seeking the Committee’s views on these different options. I expect that in the notso-distant future I will be asked more about our thinking, and I’m looking for some Committeeapproved language that I could use.
Why don’t we start with questions, and then we’ll have an opportunity for comments.
We’ve got a list of people who have asked to comment, and others can join on. But now,
questions. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes. Thank you, Madam Chair. First of all, thanks a lot for
the excellent memo—I thought it was very informative and very useful. I’d be interested in your
perspectives, in terms of the language that you propose, why you decided to go with as
ambiguous or qualitative a characterization as you did as opposed to at least mentioning the

September 16–17, 2015

24 of 240

federal funds rate or maybe actually talking about some numerical range for the federal funds
rate. Why use the term “well under way,” which is open to a lot of possible interpretations?
MR. ERCEG. I think that the trigger strategies potentially can be communicated in
different ways. The minutes suggested that the Committee preferred qualitative guidance about
the balance sheet, so we wanted to avoid really making it seem that the triggers we provide in
our quantitative exercises for concreteness purposes really should be treated as numerical
triggers as such.
CHAIR YELLEN. We had a discussion about this at our previous meeting, and I think
our interpretation of the sense of those on the Committee was that they preferred qualitative
language to an explicit quantitative characterization. Other questions? President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’m looking at panel B of exhibit 2 about
the term premium effect, especially the line associated with the constant portfolio. Drawing on
the simulation, you said there was around a 40 basis point effect on the term premium over a
decade. Usually we teach people that there’s monetary neutrality, and monetary policy can only
have temporary effects. This looks pretty much like a permanent effect.
MS. KLEE. The 40 basis points is correct. There are a couple of different things. If you
structure the balance sheet so that it’s constant for a very long time, our models suggest that has
a very large term premium effect. I think in the memo we estimated it was going to be about 20
years until the size of the portfolio was normalized under this scenario. I think over time the
Federal Reserve has used its portfolio in order to affect longer-term interest rates, and there’s a
question as to what is neutral. When we have traditionally reinvested, we’ve done it in a way
that’s neutral to the Treasury’s issuance of securities. But I think that there are different ways
you can think of a neutral portfolio and whether it actually will affect—

September 16–17, 2015

25 of 240

MR. BULLARD. According to this, if we can grow the portfolio at the pace of nominal
GDP growth, we’ll depress term premiums permanently, and we’ll get permanently lower
unemployment. That is long-run nonneutrality of monetary policy.
MS. KLEE. I think it fades over time. I don’t think it’s—
MR. BULLARD. Where does it fade in the picture? You’ve got—
MS. KLEE. Further out.
CHAIR YELLEN. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. The amount of government debt in the hands of the public is lower as
long as we’re holding a portfolio of a given size, and that’s what the nonneutrality is—it’s on the
size of the government debt, and that’s a particular monetary policy that has been undertaken in a
way that does, in fact, make a change in the government debt, and it’s nonneutral.
CHAIR YELLEN. Chris.
MR. ERCEG. I just wanted to add that it might be helpful to think of the balance sheet
policy as essentially affecting what we might call the equilibrium real rate or the natural real rate.
From that perspective, balance sheet policies that depress term premiums very persistently would
in essence be tantamount to raising the natural real rate. And that’s essentially what’s happening
in these exercises, and it would be underscored in exhibit 3, in which you see the increase in the
federal funds rate at relatively long horizons.
Now, of course, this effect is derived from an estimated model. It’s taken from the Li and
Wei model, which is estimated over the 1994 to 2007 pre-crisis sample period. It’s consistent
with relatively large and persistent effects on term premiums associated with very protracted
changes in the level of long-term assets on the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. So that drives

September 16–17, 2015

26 of 240

these very persistent effects, but it’s certainly based on an estimated model over the pre-crisis
period.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes. Thank you, Madam Chair. I think of this kind of policy
intervention as really more akin to a fiscal policy intervention. It’s not about the increase in the
liabilities, but really more in terms of the composition of assets that are in the hands of the
public, as Governor Fischer was suggesting. And so the change in the composition of the assets
in the hands of the public lowers the term premium below what it would be otherwise in a
permanent fashion, for a given particular time path of public debt issuance by the Treasury.
MR. BULLARD. Show me a model.
CHAIR YELLEN. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. I think, President Bullard, the fundamental non-neutrality theorem says
that if all the exogenous nominal variables are changed in the same proportion, that will be
neutral. But this is not a change that changes them in the same proportion and so it is nonneutral.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thomas.
MR. LAUBACH. If I may just quickly elaborate on some of the things that President
Kocherlakota and also Chris mentioned. You might think of this as if you kept the balance sheet
permanently larger, you would have a permanent shift in the equilibrium real interest rate. If you
didn’t accommodate that or didn’t take that into consideration in your policy rule by moving the
intercept appropriately, you would end up missing your inflation target permanently.
Now, the policy rule has, of course, the 2 percent inflation target hardwired into it, so it
would constantly push against the resulting inflation overshoot that would result from not

September 16–17, 2015

27 of 240

adjusting the intercept of the policy rule. But it’s still the case that if you properly took into
account the resulting shift in the equilibrium real interest rate in the policy rule, then you would
end up reaching your inflation target over time.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. I’m looking at exhibit 3. We discussed this last time, that in principle, a
change in the funds rate path should be capable of completely and exactly offsetting the effect of
a different balance sheet path. So I’m surprised at these little differences in C and D—why
doesn’t the funds rate path for the constant portfolio result in the same unemployment and
inflation rates as the baseline case? Why didn’t you nail it in C and D? And, second, the
intercept term in the inertial Taylor rule changes a lot, as shown in A—for example, look at the
constant portfolio case—10 years from now, it’s still above 2 percent. How come, in 10 years,
the difference in the funds rate paths between the constant portfolio and the baseline case isn’t
closer to the difference in the intercept terms? So why didn’t you nail it, and why is the funds
rate not that much different at the end?
MR. ERCEG. I think that in the FRB/US model this is an implementation issue. We
were trying to, within the confines of the model, use a relatively simple way of offsetting the
additional stimulus. It’s imperfect in exactly insulating the macroeconomic effects, but it comes,
I believe, very close. In a smaller-scale model that I set up, one can achieve, as one might
expect, that perfect insulation, but it’s difficult to do in a much larger model.
MR. LACKER. Is this just a computational issue? I mean, there’s some number that
nails it, right? Is that true in the FRB/US model?
MR. ERCEG. Yes, in principle. You can alternatively adjust the intercept in a smallscale model or put an extremely large coefficient on the output gap. And by doing so—say, the

September 16–17, 2015

28 of 240

latter approach—you’ll completely insulate the economy from the effects of what is essentially
an increase in the natural real rate.
MR. LACKER. So were you just guessing and moving and then just gave up before you
got there? [Laughter]
MR. ERCEG. Well, I honestly didn’t implement these simulations myself. But,
nonetheless, it is difficult to do this in much larger scale models with—
MR. WILCOX. Very rich transmission structures.
MR. ERCEG. Exactly. Transmission that is much more realistic than in our simple
models. In simple models, you can completely insulate. It’s easy to do. You have many
different ways of doing so. Under an optimal strategy that didn’t penalize the change in interest
rates, you can exactly insulate the macroeconomy from the effects of a shift in the natural rate.
In bigger models, it’s a lot harder to do.
MR. LACKER. It’s a little mysterious. So the right-hand side variables in the Taylor
rule are virtually the same—the only thing different is the intercept term. So why isn’t the funds
rate path different by about the difference in the intercepts?
MR. ERCEG. It’s going to depend as well on the exact way that the intercept change is
phased in. There are a number of complications.
MR. LACKER. But it was, like, 0.15 every period, and after 10 years you’d get—
MS. KLEE. Toward the end it’s exactly the same. If you look in 2025, they’re both
about 50 basis points apart.
MR. LACKER. Okay. Thanks.
CHAIR YELLEN. Okay. Any other questions, or can we begin comments? President
Rosengren.

September 16–17, 2015

29 of 240

MR. ROSENGREN. Regarding your choice of a discrete stop versus a tapering
strategy—there are pretty large standard errors around how we think this would actually work,
because the understanding of this is somewhat experimental, as this has occurred just since the
financial crisis. As you think about a strategy that just allows reinvestment to stop completely
versus a tapering strategy, why did you pick the particular one that you did? And why not show
a tapering strategy, as that’s where the market seems to think we’re going to go?
MS. KLEE. Our Tealbook baseline is with a complete cessation of reinvestment six
months after liftoff. We could have chosen a phaseout strategy—it doesn’t make a whit of
difference in these models in terms of the macroeconomic outcomes. It’s more of a marketfunctioning issue.
CHAIR YELLEN. Okay. I have a list of people who’d like to comment, and, again, I’m
really interested in your views on the alternative C options. Let’s begin with the Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Madam Chair. I have a brief comment.
First, I very much appreciate the staff memo. I thought it framed the issues very well—very
small effects when using the modal forecast scenario, but more significant effects in terms of
insuring against adverse outcomes. In other words, reducing the probability of returning to the
zero lower bound, which I think is the key issue that we’re really talking about here.
In terms of the language in alternative C, I think we need a small addition. I’m fine with
the phrase “until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under way,” but I
think we should add an additional condition that we think that the normalization is expected to
prove sustainable or something similar. Paragraph 5 in alternative C might read something like
“The Committee anticipates doing so until the normalization of the level of funds rate is well
under way and is expected to prove sustainable.”

September 16–17, 2015

30 of 240

The notion I have in mind here is that the end of reinvestment should not be tied
mechanically to the level of the funds rate but also tied to the economic outlook. I could imagine
supporting an early end of reinvestment at a relatively low federal funds rate if the economy was
forecast to grow very rapidly over the following year with very few downside risks in terms of
the economic outlook. In that case, the likelihood would be that the Committee would raise the
federal funds rate further over the next year, and the probability of an early return to the effective
lower bound would be very low. In contrast, I’d favor waiting to end reinvestments if the
economy was lacking forward momentum even at a somewhat higher federal funds rate. That’s
because the risk of returning to the effective lower bound would be higher in that case.
The point I’m trying to make is that we’re delaying reinvestment for a reason—to reduce
the probability of returning to the effective lower bound. That should really be the parameter
that we’re focusing on. That probability is not just governed by the level of the federal funds
rate, but also the economic outlook at the time. We want to end reinvestments when that
probability is relatively low, and I think that’s not sufficiently summed up just by “well
advanced.” I think you have to get the concept of the outlook in there as well.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’m glad to say I’m comfortable with
either version of the reinvestment language in alternative C and most other aspects of alternative
C as well. Oh, but I’ll leave that to tomorrow’s discussion. [Laughter] I thought you might
appreciate that.
I’d like to make a few observations about the staff memo, quite honestly picking up on
most of the themes that were discussed in response to some of the questions and also Vice
Chairman Dudley’s comments.

September 16–17, 2015

31 of 240

In terms of the staff memo, making decisions about the appropriate size of the balance
sheet, I think it’s very important that we weigh both the costs and the benefits under a wide range
of plausible scenarios. The memo emphasized one specific adverse scenario in order to illustrate
a potential benefit of using a state-dependent rule for any reinvestments. As was described in the
memo and in the presentation, in this particular scenario, a state-dependent rule continues
reinvestment for several years beyond the baseline, and the larger resulting balance sheet
provides additional stimulus relative to the case of ending reinvestments on a preset path.
But in considering the merits of such a state-dependent rule, we shouldn’t lose sight of
the bigger issue of the relative costs and benefits of maintaining a very large balance sheet.
Indeed, taking the analysis of the memo to its logical extreme, we should always maintain a very
large balance sheet, arguably even larger than what we have today, to provide insurance against
negative shocks. Now, I’m picking up on something implied by Vice Chairman Dudley’s
comment because, according to the Board analysis we discussed, a large SOMA portfolio lowers
the term premium and effectively shifts the IS curve out, and this implies a higher equilibrium
federal funds rate—it’s about ½ percentage point higher than baseline for the constant portfolio.
What does that do? It provides us with more buffer to use the federal funds rate as a policy
instrument to respond to negative shocks.
I see this memo not really being about this scenario or about the strategy for ending
reinvestments. Really, it’s a question of, fundamentally, do we need a bigger buffer, especially
in light of concerns about a continuing very low equilibrium real interest rate? In a way, I think
the memo narrows the question too much to just the specific language concerning how we would
end reinvestments, and we really should think much more carefully about both the benefits more
generally of having a large balance sheet, and also revisit the costs around that because the

September 16–17, 2015

32 of 240

memo obviously can only cover the benefits. Now, we’ve decided through our discussions in the
past that the costs of holding a very large balance sheet outweigh the benefits at most times, and
we shouldn’t lose track of that in thinking through some of these issues in terms of the
reinvestment strategy, as opposed to just focusing on the benefits under certain scenarios.
Now, I recognize I am veering into the topic of the long-run policy strategy that the Chair
has initiated and is under way, but I do think this is an important issue to think about. If we
really do think we’re in a world of a lower equilibrium real rate and we are worried about
downside risks, I think we really should be thinking in very broad terms about what the costs and
benefits of the balance sheet are. And getting back to President Bullard’s question, what do we
really understand about the effects of the balance sheet on the equilibrium real interest rate, and
what are these tradeoffs that we’re facing?
I think that the memo is fine—I have no quibbles about the memo—but it narrows this
discussion down far too much. The discussion we need to be having is about this broader issue
of the costs and benefits of the balance sheet and not just thinking through this one experiment
because, more generally, in a stochastic environment, we’re going to get hit by both positive and
negative shocks.
Again, I’m looking forward to the work that’s being started in the work group with regard
to the long-run policy initiative, but I do hope that this is one of the issues on which they give us
better guidance, and sooner rather than later. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. All right. Good. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. Thank you, Madam Chair. We’ve had questions from President Bullard
and discussions already by Vice Chairman Dudley and President Williams. There’s a very
interesting issue present in this discussion, which is: How should we think of the influence of

September 16–17, 2015

33 of 240

the balance sheet? And what this analysis has brought out has been that, essentially, in the
“stock” view of what it is that quantitative easing does, all of the quantitative easing that has
been done so far is in the balance sheet—it’s there and it’s having an effect. Let me ask the next
question and then I’ll tell you the effect.
When we do quantitative easing, the short rate remains unchanged. Well, what happens
to other interest rates? Our analysis is that quantitative easing goes into the term premium. We
buy up assets, and the money that’s put into the system goes into longer-term assets and reduces
the term premium.
So the next question is, what do we want to do over the longer term, after we’ve
normalized the federal funds rate? If we had already reduced the balance sheet to its steady-state
level, we might have a lower federal funds rate. At some point, we might even reach the point at
which we would be at a near-zero federal funds rate again. What the large balance sheet is doing
for us is keeping us away from the effective lower bound, as both Vice Chairman Dudley and
President Williams pointed out, and it’s providing us with a twist in the term structure which we
probably like. We haven’t really seen the effects of quantitative easing show up in investment
spending very much, but, in principle, it is a factor encouraging investment. And the question is:
What do we want to do? Do we want to keep this effect of having a higher federal funds rate and
a lower longer-term rate?
We’d like the possibility of keeping the federal funds rate positive for longer, I assume,
because we don’t like what we’d have to do if we got back down to zero, and it will be
politically controversial and so forth. So it’s useful to have this “stock of QE” under our control.
We can reduce it at some time by stopping reinvestment, and we could in effect reduce the stock

September 16–17, 2015

34 of 240

of QE under our control. So this is a kind of investment and also a monetary policy choice, in
terms of what term structure we are looking at.
What this analysis did in my case was to make me think better of holding the larger
portfolio for longer because then it would be safer for us and for the economy in terms of
keeping us away from the zero lower bound in the event that we get a lot of negative shocks.
Well, we may get them, we may not get them, but they’re a risk, and we’d prefer not to be there.
So I don’t know which of these strategies I’d like more. I think we should look at the likely
quantitative effects of the two approaches. I think that what the analysis does show, particularly
with that green line which goes out there forever, is that the effect of QE is 40 basis points on the
federal funds rate—that’s what our models say, precisely.
I conclude that we ought to rethink and keep reinvestment going a little longer. We have
a slight problem in the fact that when you read what people say, they all assume it’s six months
after normalization begins before we end reinvestment. Simon, I must get a different set of
analyst remarks from that you get, but that’s what I find in the analyst remarks that I read—six
months, nine months—and I think we might want to go longer. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Mester.
MS. MESTER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I also want to thank the staff for the memo. I
actually thought it was very helpful. I’m sympathetic to the notion that you can’t take into
account everything, so for my purposes, this actually worked quite well.
My view is that we have our normalization principles, and unless we’re rethinking those,
at some point we’re going to have to end reinvestments because we want to get the balance sheet
back down to what the normalization principles say. And I found the memo actually helpful in
thinking about that. To my mind, I didn’t see that much difference in either the adverse scenario

September 16–17, 2015

35 of 240

or the normal scenarios with the 1 percent trigger or the 2 percent trigger. I like the fact that
we’re tying the end of reinvestments to the funds rate because we’re using the same economic
conditions. It’s a state-contingent strategy.
The one thing the memo did for simplicity is not allow for us to start up reinvesting
again. I would prefer to end reinvestments when the trigger is 1 percent, and then if need be—if
things turn out to be worse than our baseline scenario—we can always start reinvesting again.
This is a simple memo because, by necessity, it should be to be clear, but in terms of how we
approach policy, we could reverse the decision at some point, and I think that’s what my
preference would be, because at some point we’re going to have to end reinvestments.
Concerning the language, the one issue the memo didn’t address is when the Committee
would want to provide the public with more concrete information, and I think that’s really a
question for Simon and the Desk—how much advance notification do market participants need
about what our strategy is going to be? If we can agree on a strategy and if you come back and
say there are benefits to being clear, we might want to be more explicit in the liftoff statement
about what our strategy is, including putting in, if we agree on a trigger, what that trigger is.
If you think that we don’t really need to be that explicit in qualitative language, perhaps
you could say something like “when normalization is further along” that would be in between the
two choices on the table for alternative C. But I think it’s a question really for the Desk about
how much advance notification market participants need to prepare for the end of reinvestments.
Thank you.
MR. POTTER. I think if it’s a 100 percent stop, then that has the potential to affect
market functioning, and that’s one thing we could talk about. If it was a phaseout and market

September 16–17, 2015

36 of 240

participants were aware it was going to be a phaseout, I think we shouldn’t worry so much about
those market functioning issues because the phaseout should take care of them.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. I appreciated the staff memo. My
comments are going to dovetail with some of the previous comments that were made by
President Lacker and President Williams.
Overall, I want to think of the FOMC as just choosing the level of accommodation.
That’s maybe just a better way to think about it. Accommodation can be provided through two
channels—either through the federal funds rate or through a balance sheet policy action. In the
first set of simulations, the FOMC acts by following an inertial Taylor rule. In reality, the
Committee chooses how much monetary accommodation to provide based on macroeconomic
circumstances. So the effects of a particular reinvestment strategy of the type outlined in the
memo could be completely offset by an appropriate choice of the federal funds rate path, as has
been discussed in the previous comments. This is illustrated in the memo.
So what’s the meaning of different reinvestment strategies and probably different levels
of accommodation? We want to leave it up to the Committee to change policy based on
whatever the Committee thinks. And surely we want that deliberation to go on, and we want the
Committee to be looking at the right level of accommodation at a particular point in time. So
I’m not sure it’s a useful exercise, the way it’s constructed in the memo. And as far as our policy
is concerned, I think we might as well stick to the baseline strategy of ending reinvestments six
months after liftoff, and then go ahead and let the Committee choose the federal funds rate path
that it judges provides the appropriate level of accommodation.

September 16–17, 2015

37 of 240

In the second exercise in the memo—reinvestment strategies under the adverse
scenario—a similar conclusion can be drawn. In this scenario, the economy is forced back to the
zero lower bound in 2017 for three years. A trigger-type reinvestment strategy could provide
accommodation in this scenario, but of course the Committee can simply choose the appropriate
level of accommodation by choosing the appropriate level of the balance sheet—that is,
presumably by reinstituting QE. I know you’re swearing off QE, but if you get in the right
circumstance, you’re going to use the tool again. The FOMC could get exactly the right level of
accommodation and not have to rely on the approximate amount offered by the trigger strategy.
So why are we going through this elaborate exercise of having the trigger strategy, and then
we’re going to adjust our path of the funds rate that’s going to give the right level of
accommodation, taking into account what the trigger strategy is going to do over the forecast
horizon?
I’m not sure that this is that useful of a way to think about it. It’s due to the
substitutability of the two approaches to providing monetary accommodation. It appears that
there’s little to be gained by tampering with the existing reinvestment strategy. I think we might
as well just allow reinvestments to end at some point after we lift off and call it a day. Thank
you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kaplan.
MR. KAPLAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. Maybe because I’m the newer person, I’m a
little more sensitive and maybe even uncomfortable on two fronts as we do the execution. I’m
sensitive to the fact that we have some uncertainty regarding the effect of beginning the process
of raising rates—that creates its own set of uncertainties, particularly when we start from the
lower bound. I’m also particularly uncertain about the effect of beginning to phase down

September 16–17, 2015

38 of 240

reinvestments. Even though I agree with the overall debate and having that second discussion
about the broader costs and benefits, I think, from an execution point of view, the one way we’ll
find out what the effect of doing each of these is when we do it.
From a risk-management and prudence point of view, my own bent—which is why I like
the “well under way” language you have here—is to first make sure we are well under way when
going through the first exercise of raising the federal funds rate, seeing what we learn, making
sure we are in fact well under way. Only after we’re comfortable with that—not only what the
prospects are, but what we’ve learned from that process—can we then think about beginning the
second process, which will have its own degree of uncertainty and learning that come from that.
I’d rather start that second process second, rather than intermingling these two at the same time.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. In terms of our reinvestment policy, once it’s
appropriate to raise rates, I’m fine with the language in alternative C that states we expect to
continue reinvestments “until normalization of the level of the federal funds rate is well under
way.” The risk-management benefits from the 2 percent trigger exercise seem desirable to me.
Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Madam Chair. I thought the questions that were raised by
President Williams were important considerations and ones we should think more about, as well
as the communication issue that President Mester raised in the context of our existing
normalization principles. The staff has helped us think about these triggers, but we probably
need to think more.

September 16–17, 2015

39 of 240

As it relates to alternative C, I have a slight preference for the language that says “at least
during the early stages of normalization,” based on how we have already characterized our
normalization principles. I think that language preserves optionality, whereas the alternative
language could limit our flexibility to begin the process sooner if we wanted to. That would be
my suggestion. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I strongly agree with President Williams’s
comments about this. I really think this is a big subject. I was surprised during the July
meeting’s discussion to hear so much sentiment for holding on to a much larger portfolio than I
thought we were contemplating a year or two ago. If we get on the road to thinking through a
strategy in which we’ve got a big buffer stock, that will be the third normalization strategy for us
to adopt over the past three years—we had one last year and one a couple of years before that.
I was glad to hear there was a fair amount of recognition that on the cost side, there were
some political-economy issues and questions involved, and I think those are very important. I
won’t go into them. I think a “global” assessment of the costs and benefits of different
approaches needs to take that into account.
As for language, I was uncomfortable with “well under way”—it suggests a long time
after we raise rates. “At least during the early stages”—I wasn’t clear on how we are dividing up
normalization into stages, but I guess it’s just a figure of speech that means “early.” I liked the
sound of President Mester’s suggestion about “until normalization is further along.” Before the
benefit of a more thorough discussion that convinces me that a bigger buffer would be useful,
I’m more in the camp of wanting to end early, as I was at the July meeting. But these are
important issues and deserve some careful consideration. Thank you.

September 16–17, 2015

40 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Madam Chair. It’s been a very rich discussion
already. I have to admit that I was pretty surprised at the July meeting when it became apparent
that more than a few FOMC participants viewed halting reinvestments as being a decision that
would be very costly to reverse by reinitiating purchases or by beginning reinvestments again, as
President Mester suggested. I think this lack of reversibility is pretty crucial in terms of how we
think about the appropriate long-run size of the balance sheet, the matter President Williams
raised. If, as President Bullard and President Mester suggested, we’ll just turn on this tool when
we need it and, if we hit the effective lower bound and we need more accommodation, we’ll
begin reinvestments again or we’ll begin active purchases again, then I think it’s a very different
question than if we view halting reinvestments as having enormous costs associated with it. And
then we have to weigh the political economy—assuming that those costs are coming from
political economy considerations—against the political economy considerations that President
Lacker pointed to, which are also very real in maintaining a large balance sheet. These are very,
very challenging issues.
If we take as given this lack of reversibility—and that’s the way the memo drafted the
problem and, in light of what I heard at the July meeting, I am very sympathetic to that way of
drafting the memo—this irreversibility leads to worse economic outcomes if we have to return to
the effective lower bound. As I argued at the July meeting, to me this means we should only be
willing to halt reinvestments at a point in time when we’re willing to increase the effective lower
bound on interest rates. Basically, halting reinvestments is taking a tool away from yourself.
You should only be willing to do that if you are actually willing to take away another tool, which
is to increase the effective lower bound on interest rates.

September 16–17, 2015

41 of 240

My own thinking is, in light of where I think the long-run neutral real rate is going to be
and given our recent experience, I’m pretty loath to throw away these kinds of tools at this stage.
My preference at this point would be to leave out any reference to reinvestment policy at the
time of liftoff.
I thought President Kaplan raised some great points, too, about the learning that’s going
to occur. He hasn’t been involved in these conversations before, so he hasn’t gotten totally into
the “inside the tent” kind of thinking that we all have about this, and I think that’s good. I think
that having an opportunity to learn about how this process is going to work before starting to talk
about a new thing that we aren’t sure how it is going to work is wise counsel.
At the time of liftoff, the Chair could say that this matter remains under study by the staff
and principals. I think it allows us an opportunity to dovetail our thinking about reinvestments
with the longer-run operating framework exercise that the Chair initiated.
One comment on the normalization principles. The normalization principles certainly
have indicated that the Committee likes having a smaller balance sheet. On the other hand, the
normalization principles have also said we want to keep as large a balance sheet as is necessary
to be able to conduct effective monetary policy. That could be a lot larger than we thought it was
going to be three or four years ago—it might be larger than we think it is today. I think this
Committee will have to engage in some serious conversations about that.
Now, assuming the Committee does want to make a reference to reinvestments, I’m
concerned about the vagueness of what’s in the draft of alternative C. If Committee members
can agree among themselves to the idea of tying reinvestments to something specific in the
outlook, something specific regarding the federal funds rate, as was done in the memo, it would
be really great to offer that kind of clarity.

September 16–17, 2015

42 of 240

President Evans was chastising me for smiling at Chris’s suggestion that we rely on the
speeches of the presidents to elucidate what the Committee means by this language. The
intermeeting period has not given me the kind of confidence that maybe I would like to have
with that as a communications device. [Laughter]
As I’ve indicated before, I think if we can agree on a tie to something like the federal
funds rate, it would be really good to be able to make that connection as opposed to relying on
everyone’s interpretation of what that might mean. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you. The language in the normalization principles that you
referred to—large enough to conduct monetary policy effectively—my recollection is that the
meaning of that was effective control of the funds rate, and I didn’t envision it to be this large.
But this wouldn’t be the first time different Committee members had different readings of the
same phrase.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I think that the language is capable of bearing multiple
interpretations. [Laughter]
MR. LACKER. As does most of our language.
MR. TARULLO. Which is precisely what it’s doing.
MR. EVANS. We’re expecting to have effective control of the funds rate with a very
large balance sheet from the outset, and if not from the first move, then certainly pretty soon
thereafter. So I’m not sure exactly how determinative that is for this.
MR. LACKER. You remember, it was the idea that in a corridor system you’d need
lower reserves.

September 16–17, 2015

43 of 240

MR. EVANS. I just think we’re bringing more assumptions to bear on what we mean by
that. That’s all.
CHAIR YELLEN. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’m sympathetic with the substantive
policy leaning that Bill and Stan and others have articulated, which I think is consistent with the
memo, although not necessarily foursquare with all of the details of the memo.
My concern is the one I raised at the July meeting, which is about potential
contingencies. I think President Williams’s caution—to be clear about costs as well as benefits
of keeping the balance sheet where it is—is important. As people probably don’t recall, but I’ll
remind you, I raised a couple of things that might happen—which I don’t expect to happen, but
which might happen—in the early stages after liftoff. One could be a blowing-out of the ON
RRP program beyond what we currently expect. Another would be a flattening, or even
inversion, of the yield curve.
Under those circumstances, an earlier cessation of reinvestment might be among the more
efficacious tools at our disposal. In the interest of clear communication, if we’re going to say
something in the statement, I hope we can find a way to put in an appropriate qualification that
allows the public and markets to understand that our default position is that we’re going to let
rates go up for a while for the reasons Stan said, but that if some dodgy things start happening in
financial markets, we might take a somewhat different approach. I don’t have a formulation for
that, Madam Chair—I apologize. But I think it’s going to be something like that, with that
phrase that we always used to stick in—“in the context of price stability.” We used to talk about
19 things we were going to do “in the context of price stability,” which gave the message that if

September 16–17, 2015

44 of 240

inflation started to go too far one way or the other, it might vary what we were going to do.
Maybe people could come up with a similarly euphemistic phrase that would do the trick.
I hope we can go in sequence here, and I hope we can get some of the benefits that Beth
and Chris were talking about in their memo, but I think we need to allow for the possibility that
we won’t be able to keep as pristine a separation of the two policy tools as we would like. Thank
you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Madam Chair. I have a strong desire, which I assume is
widely shared, to avoid returning to the effective lower bound. I also suspect that the possibility
of doing so is uncomfortably high.
On gearing up quantitative easing again, I want to say a couple of things. First, I think
we’ve never looked at asset purchases as other than a second-best tool. I think that’s been the
way it’s been talked about since the very beginning—uncertain as to its effect, uncertain as to
bad effects, and certainly uncertain as to political economy characteristics.
I would put a decision to end reinvestments and then a decision to reverse that as not at
all akin to a decision to start asset purchases again. To me, they’re two completely different
things. I think if the Committee were to decide to end reinvestments and then six months later
there were a shock, I think it would be an easy decision to begin reinvestments again on the
grounds that we would have so little to work with in the way of rate cuts to make. So I look at
those decisions as very different.
Those things lead me to a strong preference for the “until normalization of the level of the
federal funds rate is well under way.” I could learn to like the 1 percent or 2 percent thresholds.
I will say that the real economy effects are tiny, and, if I’m right they would be even smaller if,

September 16–17, 2015

45 of 240

in fact, the irreversibility assumption is really not right as a practical matter. But I’m open to
learning more about those. I’d prefer to work with interest rates until we get way away from the
effective lower bound. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Brainard.
MS. BRAINARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. My judgment is animated by, first, a
desire to maintain the parsimony and clarity of our policy framework and, second, by what I
believe to be asymmetric risk-management considerations over the period that we are
considering. Those considerations lead me to favor a 2 percent quantitative target.
The policy framework that we’ve agreed to over the past year makes the federal funds
rate the focal point for our policy stance. It’s clear, it’s familiar to market participants, and it’s
empirically well understood, and I’d like to keep the focus on that. In addition, we’ve spent
considerable effort over the past several meetings trying to make the public understand that our
policy framework is based on the economic outlook and not on a calendar. I’d be very reluctant
to have our reinvestment policy in any way migrate back toward a time-based framework.
I think the most parsimonious way to capture economic developments is to condition our
reinvestment policy very clearly on the behavior of the one variable that we have focused on,
which is the federal funds rate. It summarizes information from a wide variety of economic
indicators on progress toward our goals.
With regard to risk-management considerations, I think the staff analysis did a very nice
job of laying those out. Like others, I don’t believe the bar for reinitiating QE is at all similar to
a bar for a 25 basis point cut, for instance, or turning on and off reinvestment. So I do believe
that that effective lower bound constraint is a very important one.

September 16–17, 2015

46 of 240

For all those reasons, I would like to see the reinvestment conditioned on a 2 percent rate.
I think it’s clear, it gives us that cushion, and we can easily avoid the notion that you turn off
reinvestment permanently once you’ve hit 2 percent by making clear that only while you’re
above 2 percent would reinvestment cease. I think that would be pretty easy to introduce into the
language. That would be my strong preference. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you very much. Is there anybody else who’d like to
comment? Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. Thank you, Madam Chair. This is not only because I failed to thank the
staff for their very good work the first time around, so I asked for a second time. Thank you for
the quality of the work you did.
I think the issue of whether we can stop running off the portfolio at a certain point is
critical to this discussion. President Bullard made it sound like it was very easy, but I think it
will actually take some thought about how to present that before we can get that as part of the
solution. What Governor Brainard just said is possibly the solution and what we need—that is,
we can begin reinvesting again if the federal funds rate goes below a certain level, and 2 percent
sounds attractive. That gives us a conditional reinvestment policy, which I think makes a lot of
sense in terms of combining the risk-management feature, as I think Governor Brainard and
Governor Tarullo called it, with our desire to reduce the size of the portfolio.
We need to think about what’s going to happen as the portfolio starts getting down to the
target level. What happens, in that case, if we suddenly find ourselves heading off in a direction
that we don’t want to go with the interest rate beginning to decline for a variety of reasons and
this leads us to begin to worry? We then actually want, at that point, to start buying assets, I
think—that is, to do quantitative easing before it’s quantitative easing at zero interest rates,

September 16–17, 2015

47 of 240

which is a bigger problem. This is just another way of saying we need flexibility on the issue of
when we’re allowed to increase the size of the balance sheet in terms of the conditions we place
on ourselves.
I think that’s something the staff can work on very well. My conclusion from this
discussion is that not everybody, but quite a few people, have referred to the possibility of
turning on and off the end of the reinvestment process and that the 2 percent level is a good one.
And then we might need to specify in more detail what it is that will happen that will allow us to
explain why we’re turning it on and off in terms that are clear, understandable, and acceptable to
the public.
I think this has been an extremely useful discussion. What has come out of it is a way of
rethinking our principles for reducing the size of the portfolio. Do we have to stick by what we
said when we haven’t actually implemented anything? If we have found a better way, are we not
allowed to use it because we hadn’t thought of using it until now? There must be an elegant
solution.
Last night, I was watching an interview of Justice Souter by Charlie Rose, and there was
a discussion on the topic, What do words mean? Charlie Rose kept inventing complicated
situations and asking, “Is that acceptable under the law?” And Souter kept saying, “Well, words
are not precise, and that’s why the law can work. If there are ways of doing what needs to be
done and that everybody understands needs to be done, we need to find a way within the words
that exist.” Well, I wonder if we can do that for ourselves as well. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Any further comments?
MR. TARULLO. Just a question, Madam Chair, for Simon, to return to a consideration
that a few of us talked about last time. Simon, the consideration is the size of the maturations

September 16–17, 2015

48 of 240

that are actually occurring at any one time. If I recall correctly, we have about a two-year
window from around the middle of next year to 2018 when the amount maturing is relatively
small with an occasional month that’s—
MR. POTTER. That’s in the Treasury securities market, yes.
MR. TARULLO. But then, in 2018, it picks up quite a bit.
MR. POTTER. Yes.
MR. TARULLO. If we ended up delaying cessation of reinvestment until 2018 or later,
do you anticipate that would be, in operational terms and in terms of effect on markets,
significantly more challenging than if it were to happen during that two-year window? Or does it
depend on so many other factors that it’s probably not worth using as a criterion?
MR. POTTER. The operational part for Treasury securities is not that difficult because
we’re rolling over at auctions. To reinvest the MBS—remember that we’re purchasing in the
secondary market, so that has operational cost to it. But it’s the same costs that we have right
now, and we also have the experience. There’s one issue, which is that if we stopped
reinvestment and had to restart, we still have to have the experience to restart. And that’s
something that we should think about after the discussion today.
CHAIR YELLEN. Okay. This has been a useful discussion. If somebody asks me at the
press conference tomorrow, I’ll stick with what’s in our normalization principles while we
consider this further. For the moment, I’m probably best saying this is something the Committee
is discussing and no further judgments have been made yet. But I think this has been very
productive. President Bullard, did you want to add something?
MR. BULLARD. Madam Chair, how do you want to proceed on this? Because, it seems
to me, this would be a change in the normalization principles or a change in what we said.

September 16–17, 2015

49 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. I will stick with what’s in the normalization—
MR. BULLARD. For today. I mean, moving forward, is there going to be some future
discussion of normalization principles?
CHAIR YELLEN. I assume we’ll need to consider what came out of the discussion
today and return to you with further proposals or options.
MR. BULLARD. And what would be the goal with regard to when we would want to
aim to be able to tell market participants what we have in mind?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Well, we certainly know the Chair would be asked after
liftoff about reinvestments. So the more definitive we could be at that moment the better. That’s
a goal.
CHAIR YELLEN. Right. And that was the purpose of today’s discussion.
MR. BULLARD. Arguably, we have to do this soon.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Well, I think that’s a goal.
CHAIR YELLEN. It’s a goal. We could always say, “We don’t have anything new for
you now. It’s a matter that we continue to discuss, and we’ll let you know further details when
we make decisions.” We don’t have to provide the information, but I agree it would be desirable
to be able to do so. But we need to think through what the way forward is after today’s
discussion.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Okay. Let’s go to the staff briefings on the economic outlook. We’ll
begin with David Wilcox.
MR. WILCOX. 3 Thank you, Madam Chair. I will be referring to the packet
titled “Material for the U.S. Outlook.”
3

The materials used by Mr. Wilcox are appended to this transcript (appendixes 3 and 4).

September 16–17, 2015

50 of 240

The news since the July Tealbook torqued our assessment of the two legs of your
policy mandate in different directions.
On the real-activity side, we now see the economy as having been operating, and
likely to continue to operate, at a higher level of resource utilization than we thought
at the time of your July meeting. This reassessment combines four main categories of
information.
First, as you can see in panel 1 of your forecast summary exhibit, real GDP
growth now appears to have been considerably stronger during the first half of this
year than we thought at the time of your July meeting.
Second, the most recent indicators, including yesterday’s encouraging report on
retail sales, suggest that some of that greater momentum has carried over into the
second half of this year. In particular, taking on board the stronger retail sales news,
which is not reflected in your exhibit, we’ve marked up our forecast for currentquarter GDP growth about ½ percentage point relative to the July Tealbook and now
have it at about 2¼ percent.
Third, we interpreted the two labor market reports that were issued during the
intermeeting period to be a little stronger than we had expected. The August
unemployment rate, at 5.1 percent, was 0.2 percentage point lower than we had
expected. The average monthly gain in payroll employment over the past three
months is currently reported to have been 220,000, essentially the same as our July
Tealbook forecast; however, in line with the average experience in recent years, we
expect the first estimate of job gains in August to be revised up about 60,000.
Fourth, we have also, of course, noted the more-restrictive turn in some of the key
variables that shape our outlook, including the decline in equity prices, the higher
path for the exchange value of the dollar, and the less-robust outlook for foreign
economic activity, and we have tempered our GDP growth outlook in light of these
changes.
All told, as Missaka showed in his pre-FOMC briefing yesterday, the adjustments
we made in response to these four sources of information result in an output gap that
is about ¾ percentage point tighter than before in the second quarter of this year, and
we have essentially carried that greater tightness into our projection through the next
two years. By 2018, a faster pace of monetary normalization begins to gain some
traction and the delta in the GDP gap begins to narrow.
As a check on our judgmental thinking, panel 3 compares our judgmental estimate
of the output gap with a couple of purely model-based estimates that I have shown the
Committee before. The dotted blue line shows our Tealbook estimate of the output
gap. The red line shows the production-function variant of the output gap from the
EDO model, which is one of our DSGE models. The black line shows the estimate
that comes out of a state-space model embedded in the FRB/US model. This
FRB/US estimate is developed by pooling a range of real-side indicators including

September 16–17, 2015

51 of 240

GDP, GDI, and the unemployment rate. The model also includes a New Keynesian
Phillips curve with anchored expectations, in an effort to sharpen the model’s
inference of the natural rate of unemployment and the level of potential GDP. These
three estimates—our judgmental assessment and the two model-based estimates—are
unanimous in taking the view that resource utilization has just about returned to its
maximum sustainable position. However, before anyone takes too much comfort
from the unanimity among these three estimates, I would note that other models in
use around the System give markedly different answers. For example, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s PRISM model shows a GDP gap in the second
quarter of nearly 7 percent, and one of the models maintained at New York shows a
gap of a little more than 2 percent. Also, even the confidence interval that I’m
showing here around the FRB/US estimate extends about 2 percentage points in either
direction, and that confidence interval surely understates our ignorance because it sets
aside both parameter uncertainty and model uncertainty.
One important judgmental adjustment in the Tealbook forecast this time around
pertained to the unemployment rate. If we had maintained the supply-side
assumptions that were embedded in our July forecast and put through our normal
translation of the adverse changes in the key environmental variables that I mentioned
earlier, we would have shown an unemployment rate that was flat or even rising a
touch from its current level. Considering the ongoing pace of improvement in labor
market conditions, that did not seem the most plausible baseline forecast. To
accommodate some further reduction in the unemployment rate, we needed to widen
the differential between actual GDP growth and potential GDP growth. In the context
of our Okun’s law framework, it didn’t matter much how that wider differential was
achieved, but because we were already at the very low end of the spectrum of outside
analysts in terms of our forecast for GDP growth, we split the difference and shaved
one-tenth or so from our forecast of potential GDP growth in the period ahead and
added one-tenth or so to our forecast of actual GDP growth. Even with this
judgmental add factor, our GDP forecast remains near the pessimistic end of the
range of outside forecasters.
Let me now turn to the inflation leg of your mandate. Our forecast here is
summarized in panels 4 and 5 of your exhibit. As you can see from panel 4, we now
expect total PCE inflation to turn slightly negative in the fourth quarter on a
quarterly-average basis, reflecting a steeper decline in consumer energy prices that in
turn results from the lower projected path for crude oil prices. We have also edged
down our near-term projection of core inflation—panel 5—in response to slightly
weaker-than-expected incoming data and a downward revision to our forecast for
imported goods prices. Over the remainder of the medium term, our projections of
both total and core inflation are essentially the same as in July. This morning’s CPI
release, which is summarized in a separate exhibit titled “Material for Consumer
Price Index Update,” had no material implications relative to our Tealbook
expectations. Although the core CPI inflation rate was several basis points softer than
we had expected, that had little implication for our assessment of PCE inflation,
partly because some of the surprise was in airfares and medical care prices, neither of

September 16–17, 2015

52 of 240

which feed into the PCE price index, and partly because the small downward surprise
in housing prices receives a smaller weight in the PCE index than it does in the CPI.
The increase in financial market volatility during the intermeeting period affected
the baseline through channels that have been standard in macro models for decades—
mainly, lower stock prices feeding into a wealth effect, higher private borrowing
rates, and a stronger dollar. But if we learned anything from the financial crisis, it has
to be that disturbances originating in the financial sector can have serious
implications for the real economy reaching far beyond these standard channels.
Marco Del Negro and Marc Giannoni at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York have
been working with one of the more interesting recent models that aims to allow a
more meaningful role for financial disturbances to affect real outcomes. To shed light
on the potential implications of a more serious and protracted version of the
turbulence that surfaced last month, they were kind enough to generate one of the
alternative simulations that we presented in the Tealbook. In their model, the Baa
bond spread proxies for financial turbulence and has strong predictive power for real
outcomes during periods of financial distress. Since the beginning of this year, the
Baa spread has increased about 75 basis points. In the alternative scenario, we
assume that it goes up in the fourth quarter by a further 200 basis points relative to
baseline and then gradually returns to a more normal level. Real GDP contracts
sharply almost immediately, and as you can see in panel 6, the unemployment rate—
the blue dashed line—rises as much as ¾ percentage point above its baseline
trajectory, the black line. As severe as these results are, they could have been worse.
The funds rate in the alternative scenario runs about 100 basis points below baseline,
a policy response that prevents the fallout from being even more serious. This
simulation helped inform our assessment that the risks to our forecast for real GDP
are weighted to the downside and, especially in light of the adjustments we made to
the baseline, that the risks to our unemployment projection are now weighted to the
upside.
Finally, I have updated the “Lockhart dashboard” that I first showed you in July.
This exhibit, which is the last page in your packet, summarizes a few of the key
pieces of information that will be available to you at the next couple of FOMC
meetings. Specifically, the data that will first be available at the October meeting are
in the gold-shaded region, and the additional observations that will become available
in time for the December meeting are shaded in red. (The data that are newly
available for today’s meeting are shaded in blue.) September Tealbook projections
regarding these variables are shown in regular font, while our forecasts from the July
Tealbook are shown in italics. A new memo item at the bottom of the exhibit gives
the revisions to equity prices and the foreign exchange value of the dollar since July,
as those were two of the key drivers of the revision to our assessment of the outlook.
As in July, we expect that inflation will continue to run at a low level through the
end of this year. At the time of your December meeting, the latest reading on PCE
prices that you will have in hand will be the one for October. We now forecast that
topline prices over the three months ending in October will decline at an annual rate
of nearly ¾ percent. Over the 12 months ending in October—the next pair of lines

September 16–17, 2015

53 of 240

down—we expect that topline prices will have been unchanged. Core inflation is
expected to run below 1½ percent through this period, whether measured on a
3-month or 12-month basis.
As for the labor market, we have revised down our forecast for the unemployment
rate and now expect that you will have a 5 percent print in hand at the time of the
December meeting. We also expect to see continued solid payroll job gains. The
much bigger jobs number that shows up in the September column in this display
incorporates both the gain of 210,000 that we expect to be reported for September
itself, as well as the upward revision that we expect to be applied to the August
number.
As I mentioned earlier, we have nudged up our forecast of third-quarter real GDP
growth from the 1.9 percent figure shown in the exhibit to around 2¼ percent. Steve
Kamin will now continue our presentation.
MR. KAMIN. 4 Thank you, David. I will be referring to the material titled “The
International Outlook.”
Since your previous meeting, developments in China triggered fears of a global
economic slowdown and led to widespread turbulence in markets. Turning points in
the global business cycle are notoriously difficult to forecast, and though we have
seen a few in recent decades, we have not predicted any of them. Bearing that in
mind, even after a very rocky month and a half, we are still projecting a strengthening
of foreign growth over the next few quarters. However, as indicated in panel 1 of
your first exhibit, based on data that came in over the past month and a half, we now
estimate that aggregate foreign GDP growth, which was already quite weak in the
first quarter, dropped further, to only 1 percent in the second, the slowest pace since
2009. Furthermore, weak incoming data for the third quarter, along with the
turbulence in global financial and commodity markets, led us to write down a notably
lower path going forward. Finally, although we believe the financial market
responses to events in China were probably overblown, we agree that downside risks
have increased to a material degree.
The developments in China that Simon reviewed earlier have raised two interrelated concerns with investors. The first is that China’s economy is not only slowing
from the double-digit growth rates of earlier years, but may be falling into something
akin to an actual recession. As indicated by the solid red line in panel 2, we do see
Chinese growth coming down from its transitory surge in the second quarter, but we
are looking for growth to flatten out at around 6 percent, not fall precipitously further.
Still-strong retail sales suggest that the Chinese economy retains sources of strength,
and signs of recovery in the property market are somewhat encouraging.
Nevertheless, weak incoming data, concerns over the management of economic
policy, and our sense that the authorities now face a more difficult task rebalancing

4

The materials used by Mr. Kamin are appended to this transcript (appendix 5).

September 16–17, 2015

54 of 240

the economy in the context of financial vulnerabilities have led us to revise down our
forecast from the July Tealbook, the red dashed line.
All that said, we are unconvinced by arguments that actual Chinese growth has
fallen well below the pace indicated by the official GDP statistics. The blue line in
panel 2 shows the results of our nowcasting model, which uses data on industrial
production, imports, and retail sales to estimate contemporaneous GDP growth.
Smoothing through the wiggles, the nowcasting model has continued to track the
trend in the official GDP statistics reasonably well this year—again suggesting that
growth has declined but not collapsed.
Besides prospects of a Chinese recession, a second and highly related concern for
investors has been that August’s 3 percent devaluation of the RMB would be
followed up by substantial further depreciation. Certainly, the prospect of the world’s
second-largest economy allowing its currency to drop precipitously at a time of
fragile global demand would be cause for worry. But barring extreme circumstances,
a very large further depreciation of the RMB seems unlikely. At present, China’s
authorities appear to be walking a tightrope between their longer-term strategy of
increasing the role of market forces in determining the exchange rate and avoiding
large, abrupt movements that could destabilize financial markets. As indicated in
panel 3, our sense is that, in response to further capital outflows engendered by
ongoing concerns about either the economy or future exchange-market policy, the
authorities will allow the RMB to slide another couple of percent against the dollar.
Somewhat further down the road, assuming growth stabilizes and worries of a hard
landing subside, we anticipate upward pressures on the renminbi will resume.
As Simon has described, the recent developments in China led to especially sharp
downdrafts in global markets because many economies, especially in emerging
markets, were already struggling with disappointing growth, pronounced
vulnerabilities, and anticipations of monetary policy tightening in the United States.
These market downdrafts, in turn, will likely put additional pressures on global
growth over the near term. As shown in panel 4, oil prices took another sharp notch
down during the intermeeting period. Although most of the declines in oil prices
since mid-2014 appear attributable to increased oil supplies, the downturn in August
appears to owe mainly to concerns about slowing in China—which accounts for
11 percent of global oil demand—and its knock-on effects on other economies. To be
sure, we continue to view declines in oil prices as an eventual plus for the global
economy. But our econometric analysis, as well as recent experience, suggests that,
in the near term, lower oil prices can be a drag on global growth, as their decline may
restrain spending in oil exporters more than it boosts spending in oil importers.
Besides declines in oil prices, various other market movements have affected the
outlook, including widespread declines in equity prices, increases in credit spreads,
and, as shown in panel 5, a further appreciation of the dollar. The modest devaluation
of the RMB by itself added only about ½ percent to the dollar’s value, but
sympathetic depreciations of other Asian currencies, hits to so-called commodity
currencies, and general gloom about EME prospects, taken together, led the dollar to

September 16–17, 2015

55 of 240

appreciate about 2 percent in total. We see the dollar rising a little higher during the
rest of the year, reflecting our projection of some further depreciation of the RMB as
well as the assumed tightening of Federal Reserve policy, before the dollar flattens
out and eventually gives back some of its gains. As shown in panel 6, the higher path
of the dollar implies that net exports are a source of a bit more drag on the economy
than they were in the July Tealbook.
In light of developments in China and other emerging markets, the downside risks
to the global outlook appear to have increased. Your next exhibit presents three interrelated scenarios to examine the effects of a crisis in China that lowers Chinese GDP
7 percent below its baseline path and leads to a 10 percent devaluation of the
renminbi against the dollar. The first scenario, which is represented by the green
lines in panels 2 through 5, illustrates the direct effect of such a crisis on the U.S.
economy, excluding any indirect effect that a China crisis might exert via spillovers
to China’s trading partners. Turning to panel 3, because China is not a dominant
destination for U.S. exports, the direct effects of this shock—again, the green line—
lower U.S. GDP only a little below its baseline path—the black line. Similarly,
headline inflation (panel 4) and the federal funds rate (panel 5) are only slightly
restrained. All told, this scenario illustrates that a hard landing in China will lead to
significant damage to the U.S. economy only to the extent that it induces broader
economic and financial disruptions around the world.
The second scenario is labeled “EME slowdown.” In this scenario, turning to the
blue line in panel 2, we assume that the China crisis described in the first scenario
spills over to other EMEs to an extent consistent with past historical correlations, so
that aggregate EME GDP growth falls to zero. However, we assume no financial
spillovers to advanced economies, and effects on U.S. growth, inflation, and interest
rates, while quite noticeable, are hardly eye-popping.
To get eye-popping, our third scenario—represented by the red lines in the
panels—embeds the assumption that the recession in China generates much sharper
disruptions in other EMEs, along the lines of the distress associated with the Asian
and Russian crises of the late 1990s. Aggregate EME GDP growth (panel 2) falls
below zero and EME currencies decline more than 20 percent against the dollar. We
also assume that the turbulence in emerging markets spills over to financial markets
in the United States and other advanced economies, triggering sharp declines in
equity prices and a widening of credit spreads. The U.S. economy falls into recession
and deflation, and the federal funds rate falls back to the zero lower bound. But
taking into account the assumptions required to achieve this result, we view the
likelihood of this risk materializing as fairly remote.
If I could make one final point without sounding like a complete worrywart, I
would note that although the global financial turbulence of the past month was
triggered by developments in China, anticipation of FOMC liftoff may have played
some role in making markets a little more skittish and thus more responsive to
Chinese events than they otherwise might have been. Our anticipation is that when
you decide to start tightening, volatility in emerging markets will likely remain

September 16–17, 2015

56 of 240

contained, but scenarios 2 and 3 in this exhibit provide some sense of the tail-risks
involved should investor concerns about EME vulnerabilities and the global outlook
lead markets to react much more strongly to U.S. monetary tightening that we
currently expect. That concludes my remarks, and I’ll pass it on to Francisco.
MR. COVAS. 5 Thank you, Steve. I will be referring to the packet labeled
“Material for Briefing on the Summary of Economic Projections.”
Exhibit 1 summarizes your economic projections, which are conditional on your
individual assessments of appropriate monetary policy. Almost all of you project that
real GDP growth this year will be at or very slightly above your assessments of its
longer-run pace. And almost all of you see real GDP growth picking up somewhat in
2016 before slowing toward its longer-run rate in 2017 and 2018. As shown in the
top panel, the medians of your projections of real GDP growth this year and during
the next two years are a bit above the 2 percent median of your projections of longerrun growth, but a bit below the 2½ percent growth rate recorded in 2013 and 2014.
Most of you project that the unemployment rate, shown in the second panel, will
decline further this year and be at or below your estimate of its longer-run normal rate
from 2016 through 2018. As shown in the third panel, the median of your projections
of headline PCE inflation is 0.4 percent this year but climbs to 1.7 percent in 2016
and rises further in 2017. Almost all of you project total PCE inflation to be within
1/10 of a percentage point of the Committee’s goal in 2018. The final panel indicates
that most of you project core PCE inflation near 1.4 percent this year, about the same
as in 2014, before increasing gradually over the remainder of the forecast period.
Exhibit 2 compares your current projections with those in the June Summary of
Economic Projections and with the September Tealbook. As indicated in the top
panel, the median of your forecasts of real GDP growth in 2015 has risen since June.
Most of you noted that stronger-than-expected growth in the first half of this year
more than offsets a weaker projection for the second half. In contrast, the median
values of your projections of real GDP growth for 2016 and 2017 are lower than in
June, with several of you attributing the decline in your forecasts to slower projected
productivity growth. As shown in the second panel, the median of your projected
paths for the unemployment rate shifted down roughly 0.3 percentage point
throughout the forecast period, with some of you attributing a downward revision in
your projections to the greater-than-expected decline in the unemployment rate in
recent months. All but a few of you also lowered your projections for the longer-run
normal rate of unemployment, bringing the median down to 4.9 percent. As the third
panel indicates, the median of your projections regarding headline PCE inflation was
marked down this year, reflecting an appreciation of the dollar and further declines in
oil and commodity prices. The median of your forecasts for core PCE inflation was
also marked down slightly in 2016 and 2017.

5

The materials used by Mr. Covas are appended to this transcript (appendix 6).

September 16–17, 2015

57 of 240

The Tealbook forecasts for both economic growth and inflation are slightly below
the medians of your projections for the next three years, while the staff’s forecast for
the unemployment rate is roughly in line with the median of your projections.
Exhibit 3 provides an overview of your assessments of the quarter in which you
currently judge that the first increase in the target range for the federal funds rate will
be appropriate and of the economic conditions you anticipate at that time. As shown
in the top panel, many of you currently view the fourth quarter of 2015 as the most
likely time of liftoff. Since June, six of you pushed your prescribed date of departure
from the effective lower bound from the third to the fourth quarter of this year. Four
of you now judge that it will not be appropriate to raise rates this year, while only two
of you held that view in June. As shown by the bottom-left panel, most of you see
policy normalization beginning when the unemployment rate is 5 percent or
5.1 percent. Most of you project that the unemployment rate at the appropriate time
of liftoff will still be above its longer-run normal level. Your projections of core
inflation at the time of liftoff are more dispersed, with all but one between 1.2 and 1.5
percent.
Exhibit 4 provides an overview of your assessments of the appropriate level of the
federal funds rate at the end of each year of the forecast period and over the longer
run. The medians of your funds rate projections now stand at 0.4 percent at the end
of 2015, 1.4 percent at the end of 2016, 2.6 percent at the end of 2017, and
3.4 percent at the end of 2018. A sizable majority of you revised down your
projections of the appropriate federal funds rate throughout the forecast period, and
several of you cited downward revisions to the inflation outlook and to your estimate
of the equilibrium real interest rate as reasons for doing so. The median of your
projections declined 25 basis points in 2015 through 2017. Eleven of you also
revised down your projection of the longer-run nominal federal funds rate, typically
by 25 basis points. A majority of you project that, at the end of 2018, the appropriate
level of the federal funds rate will be close to, albeit still below, your individual
judgment of its longer-run level.
As in June, almost all of you project levels of the federal funds rate over the next
couple of years that are below the prescriptions of a non-inertial Taylor 1999 rule
given your projections of core inflation, unemployment gap, and longer-run nominal
federal funds rate, indicating that you do not see the Taylor rule as likely to prescribe
appropriate policy for the next few years. The medians of these Taylor rule
prescriptions, plotted as red diamonds, have shifted up in 2015 and 2016 since June,
primarily reflecting the rule’s response to the downward revision in your
unemployment rate projections, but have edged down in 2017. For 2015 through
2017, the gap between your projections and the rule’s prescriptions, given your
individual forecasts of unemployment and inflation, has widened since June, on
average. For 2018, the discrepancy between your federal fund rate projections and
Taylor-rule-implied rates narrows considerably as most of you project that the dual
mandate can be achieved with the federal funds rate being close to its longer-term
normal level.

September 16–17, 2015

58 of 240

The final exhibit shows your assessments of the uncertainty and risks surrounding
your economic projections. As shown in the figures to the left, your views regarding
uncertainty have not changed in a material way. Most of you continue to judge the
level of uncertainty about your individual projections of GDP growth, the
unemployment rate, and inflation as broadly similar to the average level over the past
20 years. As shown in the panels to the right, most of you continue to see the risks to
real GDP growth and the unemployment rate as broadly balanced, though seven of
you now view risks to GDP growth as weighted to the downside—three more than in
June—and four more of you now see the risks to unemployment as weighted to the
upside. The downside risks to GDP growth that you cited include a weaker outlook
abroad and tighter financial conditions than currently embedded in your forecasts. As
reported in the third and fourth panels on the right, nine of you now see risks to
inflation as weighted to the downside—four more than in June. Recent declines in
market-based measures of inflation compensation and commodity prices and the
appreciation of the dollar were noted as factors that could place greater downward
pressure on prices than currently embedded in your forecasts.
Thank you. That concludes the presentation.
CHAIR YELLEN. Okay. The floor is open for questions. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Madam Chair. Thanks for the briefing, as always.
I found the discussion of the alternative scenarios in Tealbook A quite informative, as usual. I
was struck by how many of them seemed to me as downside alternatives, especially in terms of
the price stability mandate. If the staff were asked to talk about scenarios that might give rise to
an overrun in inflation, what would that potentially look like?
MR. WILCOX. We actually contemplated putting in one of those. The one that I think
is plausible for us is that there’s some drift that occurs in inflation expectations. We debated
whether the more plausible direction of drift in inflation expectations is up or down. But I do
think that an upward drift of inflation expectations is certainly within our confidence intervals.
At the moment, the more natural mechanism, it seems to me, is that the little bit of extra
transitory restraint that’s in the inflation pipeline from the dollar and the oil prices is going to put
a little more gravitational pull downward on inflation. And so my own assessment is that while I
see inflation expectations drift in either direction as quite plausible, I think it’s a little more likely

September 16–17, 2015

59 of 240

downward. But if I were to put my finger on one scenario that could provide for some upward
lift on inflation, I’d point to that one, importantly out of our collective professional ignorance
about the basic mechanisms that form inflation expectations.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. David, let me pick up where you left off there,
and thanks for panel 3 on output gap estimates, which makes my question a little more relevant
because you mentioned the FRB/US model. When I was looking through Tealbook A, on page
79, I came across alternative models and the FRB/US model. I noticed that the core PCE
projection coming out of the FRB/US model has 2017 inflation moving down to 1.0 percent,
whereas in the June Tealbook it’s at 1.5 percent. I wonder what features of the data and the
model are generating that somewhat aberrant behavior.
MR. WILCOX. The FRB/US model has a different wage-price mechanism than the
judgmental forecast does. The model pays attention to compensation trends. There’s an
equation for price markup over marginal cost in the FRB/US model. I’m going to look here for
confirmation from my former FRB/US colleague.
MR. REIFSCHNEIDER. That’s correct.
MR. WILCOX. I don’t think we provide you with a graph of the markup of price over
marginal cost in your Tealbook materials, but in putting together our inflation projection, the
staff has pretty much written that relationship off as noninformative. The FRB/US model, partly
for a bit of intellectual diversity, hasn’t chucked that specification overboard and views the high
level of prices over marginal costs as posing a downside impetus on inflation. And so that’s
mainly what’s generating this difference.

September 16–17, 2015

60 of 240

MR. EVANS. So the forecast was already pretty low in the June Tealbook at 1½ percent
for 2017, but the differential data coming in seem to have moved it downward.
MR. WILCOX. Yes. My guess is that two things are going on there. One—probably
the more material of the two—is the recent tranche of disappointing compensation news that we
got. The other—which I suspect is quantitatively tiny, but might be there in principle—is that
there was a tiny upward revision in nonmarket prices in the annual revision. So the FRB/US
model might be picking up on that, but I’m guessing that the larger of those two is the
compensation.
MR. EVANS. Just to close this out, is it fair to say that this implementation of the
FRB/US model is putting less weight on the longer-term inflation expectations anchor than other
analyses that we normally are looking at or the preferred inflation model that you’re using?
MR. WILCOX. I think so. There’s an inflation objective for policymakers in the
FRB/US model, and that has complete credibility. So households and businesses don’t question
the 2 percent objective.
MR. EVANS. I’m sorry. Let me clarify. Yes, it has that feature in there, but that’s not
enough to pull up the inflation forecast given the other countervailing data developments.
MR. WILCOX. Yes, that’s evident in the projection that you’re pointing to.
MR. EVANS. Yes, okay. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Further questions? [No response] An unusually quiet crowd today.
Okay. Seeing none, I suggest we take a coffee break, maybe until 3:45—20 minutes.
[Coffee break]
CHAIR YELLEN. Let’s return to it and get started. We’ll start our go-round with
President Rosengren.

September 16–17, 2015

61 of 240

MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Madam Chair. Since our previous meeting, we have
seen further improvement in labor markets, although the recent data on wages and prices are
consistent with the continued persistent undershooting of our 2 percent inflation goal. Earlier
evidence of accelerating compensation in both average hourly earnings and the employment cost
index has been revised away, resulting in almost all wage measures continuing to rise at a
surprisingly steady 2 percent. Because both aggregated and disaggregated data on wages and
prices continue to come in quite low, my own forecast does not expect us to reach our inflation
target within two years. This is qualitatively consistent with the staff forecast of inflation in the
Tealbook.
Because wages and prices have not responded to much-improved labor market conditions
in aggregate or, really, even in the disaggregated data, I have lowered my estimate of the longerrun unemployment rate to 4.8 percent. In addition to the evidence from wages and prices, this
estimate of the longer-run unemployment rate is consistent with the rising share of the workforce
that is more highly educated and older, demographic groups that historically have had lower
unemployment rates.
However, the most pertinent data for this meeting are probably not the government data
releases on wages, prices, and real activity, but rather the financial data that have been unusually
turbulent since August 24. Stock markets in many parts of the world are down 5 to 10 percent,
with some emerging markets down appreciably more in dollar terms. In addition, volatility has
risen significantly not only because of the sharp stock price declines, but also because of rising
interday and daily volatility.
During periods of significant financial turbulence the FOMC has tended to follow easier
policy, a point that will be made in a Boston Fed paper to be presented at our October conference

September 16–17, 2015

62 of 240

on financial stability. After Black Monday in October 1987, the FOMC had daily calls through
the end of that month to monitor financial and economic conditions and lowered interest rates.
Recent stock price movements have been much more modest. On Black Monday, the stock
market fell 22 percent, whereas on August 24, the Dow opened with a decline of over 1,000
points, or about 6 percent, but ended the day down a bit over 3½ percent. Nonetheless, the stock
price declines did receive significant attention.
It is certainly possible that some of the eye-catching declines have more to do with
problems related to financial market structure rather than a change in the economic outlook. On
August 24, with the Shanghai index down a little over 8 percent, the New York Stock Exchange
imposed Rule 48, which allows market makers to not post prices prior to opening. Along with a
1,000 point drop at the opening, a large number of individual stocks, ETFs, and other exchangetraded securities hit circuit breakers, with trading halted over 1,200 times across 466 securities,
with 300 of the securities being ETFs.
In addition, the prices of a surprising number of large ETFs declined dramatically, with
188 declining in excess of 30 percent. Some ETFs declined by more than 50 percent. In some
instances, two ETFs with similar strategies experienced materially different interday price
movements. Further, the affected securities spanned different sectors and sizes—that is, they
were not singularly focused. This, again, speaks to potential fragilities in the financial market
structure.
It’s quite possible that Rule 48 and circuit breakers in individual stocks complicated
normal ETF arbitrage, leading to unusually large temporary declines. Ironically, the circuit
breakers were implemented in response to May 2010’s flash crash in which the Dow experienced
an interday decline of over 1,000 points. In a manner similar to August 24’s events, many stocks

September 16–17, 2015

63 of 240

and ETFs experienced sharp price declines that reversed within a short period. If problems with
market mechanics explain much of the recent volatility in financial markets, we have some
significant financial stability analysis that needs to be done to better understand both the role of
market mechanics and, possibly, regulatory policy solutions.
But, for now, the appropriate response to this financial upheaval is to reflect the realized
loss of wealth and exchange rate movements in our model equations and assume the additional
economic information content is modest. Of course, there is some risk in doing so, as it is not
yet clear how persistent asset price movements will be and, generally speaking, households and
firms tend to respond to such price movements only when they persist for some time. In any
event, this is roughly how we folded the events into our own baseline forecast.
However, there is a darker potential story. Our models do a poor job of integrating
financial market information, something that David mentioned and something we were all too
aware of in 2008. It is possible that financial markets are reflecting weaker global growth or
other more-fundamental problems that we do not fully understand. In this case, my modal
forecast is too optimistic, and the downside risk should be significantly elevated. Unfortunately,
I do not think we have enough time to fully process recent market turbulence. We certainly do
not want to begin our first tightening amid a global slowdown. I can also imagine the difficulty
of keeping the reverse repo facility small during a period of very elevated market turbulence, as
many might flock to this convenient source of safe short-term financing during a time of
financial tumult.
Although my baseline forecast involves the assumption of relatively modest effects from
the recent financial turbulence, with magnitudes similar to those of the Tealbook, I think it would
be wise to wait for more data that can validate the assumption of modest disruption before taking

September 16–17, 2015

64 of 240

action based on that assumption. I will discuss this in more detail tomorrow. Thank you,
Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. My remarks today will be centered on
what has changed and not changed with respect to the national economic outlook since our
previous meeting. My view is that the general contours of the national outlook have not changed
very much during the intermeeting period, and that we are on the precipice of making a decision
that will demonstrate excessive sensitivity of the Committee to short-term movements in
financial markets, especially equity markets.
Historically, the Committee has not wanted to react directly to equity price movements,
as they are far too unpredictable over short periods and are as likely as not to reverse themselves
over the medium term. If the Committee is changing its view on this issue, we should say so as
forthrightly as possible and inform private-sector players about how we plan to proceed when
future movements in equity market prices present themselves, either up or down, in future
meetings of this Committee.
One way to get a handle on the intermeeting financial market turmoil is to consider socalled financial conditions indexes or the closely related financial stress indexes. A 2012
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review article by Kevin Kliesen, Michael Owyang, and
Katarina Vermann documents the similarities and differences between a wide variety of such
indexes.
Of course, we have a favorite, which is the St. Louis Fed financial stress index, and it has
indeed risen sharply over the intermeeting period. Still, the level of the index remains well
below the levels reached during the height of the European sovereign debt crisis in 2011 and

September 16–17, 2015

65 of 240

2012, not to mention far below the levels reached in 2008 and 2009. In addition, the index was
arguably abnormally low during recent quarters and years, with volatility at low ebb and some
interest rate spreads unusually compressed. From this point of view, one might welcome at least
some of the return to a more normal market operation.
In short, the increase in the St. Louis Fed’s financial stress index, or other related
indexes, is not enough to cause me to make sufficient revisions to my forecast that would alter
my path for monetary policy. I understand that many may be worried about a weaker growth
outlook globally than would have been projected at the previous FOMC meeting, but my view is
that many of the weak spots globally were clearly flagged during June and July, and that
marginally weaker growth prospects globally are unlikely to have a meaningful effect on U.S.
growth prospects. Accordingly, we have continued to project in St. Louis above-trend growth
for the second half of 2015 and, indeed, over the forecast horizon. We think our growth call for
the remainder of 2015 is close to the September 10 Blue Chip forecast, which itself is notably
above the Board staff view.
Although it is always good to be cautious, we think, on the basis of the data available
today, that the staff view is overly pessimistic concerning near-term growth. In addition, the
Committee has now received information on the revisions to first-half real GDP growth, which
now appears to have been above trend, adding to the picture of an economy that continues to
push forward even in the face of a large dollar appreciation over the past year or more.
Above-trend growth is likely to continue to mean even tighter labor markets. Jobs
reports since the previous meeting have generally been very good. And, if recent history is a
guide, I would expect more upward revisions to currently reported jobs numbers as we go
forward. The staff noted this as well.

September 16–17, 2015

66 of 240

Unemployment insurance claims per person in the labor force is at a multidecade low.
Job openings per unemployed worker is exceptionally high, and the unemployment rate itself fell
to 5.1 percent in the latest reading, matching what the staff projected at the previous meeting
would only happen two and a half years from now, at the end of 2017.
I appreciate that the staff has now added some downward tilt to its unemployment
projections, which have consistently been too pessimistic over the past several years. Still, it is
probably not enough, as the unemployment rate is likely to fall below 4½ percent over the
forecast horizon with above-trend growth and no major negative shocks. I think these outcomes
are already in train, as the Committee has already committed to a very easy monetary policy
during this coming phase of the business cycle.
There has, of course, been considerable talk about Chinese growth prospects during the
intermeeting period. My assessment is as follows. The Shanghai composite index is not a
meaningful indicator of U.S. growth prospects and probably not of China’s growth prospects
either. This index rose from around 2,000 in the first half of 2014 to 5,000 by June of 2015
before falling to around 3,000 during the intermeeting period. This was a bubble that burst
because of factors specific to China. I take the signal for the United States to be small or zero.
Of course, many have commented that China may be growing slower than the official
numbers indicate. I have, in fact, flagged this comment from business contacts with significant
operations in Chinese markets in past meetings, especially those in the energy and manufacturing
sectors. I do think that growth may be somewhat slower than official data suggest, but I do not
think this is news compared with what was known at our previous meeting. It is an old issue.
And, in my view, there is scant evidence at this point that China is entering a true hard landing,
and on this point I agree with the Board staff analysis.

September 16–17, 2015

67 of 240

That brings us to U.S. equity prices, which are down approximately 7 percent during the
intermeeting period as of the Tealbook publication. This is news, and, indeed, this is why I am
concerned that our pending action will be viewed as a reaction to this development. One thought
that I alluded to earlier is that this may be a more appropriate valuation than previously. We
should think of an appropriate level of equity prices relative to potential GDP, and we should
expect equity valuations—really, the value of the U.S. corporate sector—to return to this
appropriate level regardless of week-to-week volatility. If that’s the view, then temporary
movements in equity valuations would not have an effect on macroeconomic forecasts and,
therefore, on monetary policy.
My final comments concern inflation, which is running low today but is likely to
strengthen over the forecast horizon. According to my board of directors, the firms represented
there all expect wages to increase 3 percent this year, even firms that have workers that are on
the lower end of the income distribution. I was surprised by that.
Low oil prices are having a large effect on inflation, but this effect will dissipate going
forward. In any event, low oil prices are ultimately a bullish factor for the U.S. economy, not a
negative factor. TIPS-based expected inflation measures are low and have fallen during the
intermeeting period. I would normally be quite concerned about this, but these measures are
unfortunately highly conflated with oil price movements and so are difficult to read in the current
circumstances.
Overall, I am very concerned that the Committee does not overreact to what are
essentially financial market developments as opposed to real-side developments during the
intermeeting period. I see very tight labor markets ahead, barring a large shock. I also see risk

September 16–17, 2015

68 of 240

of substantial financial-stability issues arising ahead, particularly if we are viewed as an enabler
of asset price bubbles. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Madam Chair. The Fifth District economy continued to
expand in recent weeks, although our survey results softened a bit. Our manufacturing report
was mixed. The composite index fell to 0 in August from a reading of positive 13. As we saw
when it dipped earlier this year, the index is at odds with the generally upbeat assessment by our
contacts, who indicated that activity remains moderately strong despite less-favorable exchange
rates and softer growth in emerging market economies.
In contrast, service-sector activity remained robust in recent weeks, according to both
survey results and contact reports, especially on the retail side. The current retail revenues index
rose to 44 in August from 35 in July and 15 in June, reaching the fourth-highest reading in the
22-year history of that series. The nonretail services index slipped a bit in August but, at 28, was
still the third-highest reading in that series. Readings on expected activity remained strong
across both services and manufacturing. Preliminary results for September are a tad softer than
August—they won’t be released for a couple of weeks, but they tell the same basic story.
Fifth District housing markets continue to strengthen despite supply constraints on the
building side that were said to be holding back activity. Several builders report the construction
of single-family homes would be higher if not for shortages of labor and lots. The time required
to go from initiation to completion of a single-family home is said to have increased. There are
some reports of homebuyers accelerating purchases in anticipation of rising interest rates.
Spec building is increasing at price points around $1 million, and we have heard several
contacts use the term “bubble” in connection with the multifamily sector. That said, vacancy

September 16–17, 2015

69 of 240

rates remain low, and I am never quite sure what people mean by the word “bubble.” Contacts
generally reported that commercial real estate and building activity were robust in many regions
within our District. Some markets have seen a surge in hotel construction and the emergence of
spec office construction.
Reports of labor shortages and difficulty finding qualified workers continue to proliferate.
Contacts say the number of unfilled job openings is rising, as is the time it takes to fill openings.
Employers are converting temporary workers to permanent status more rapidly to avoid losing
them, and they are making more initial hires on a permanent basis rather than a temporary one.
Although labor scarcity is not universal across occupations, it appears to go well beyond IT and
skilled trades. Many contacts cite shortages for lower-wage jobs, such as those in the hospitality
and retail sectors.
I continue to hear widespread reports of wage pressures in the Fifth District. I recognize
that the second-quarter ECI number appears to have thrown cold water on the notion of nominal
wage acceleration in the national data. Nevertheless, our contacts report that wage pressures are
resulting in some outsized wage gains, and they suggest that such pressures are prevalent in a
broadening array of industries and occupations. Additionally, the wage components of our
manufacturing and service-sector surveys have strengthened considerably over the past year or
so and are now quite close to historic highs.
Perhaps the gains we hear about are being offset by weaker wage gains in other
occupations, but our reports do seem to indicate that a broader portion of the labor market has
tightened in recent months. Despite these indications of rising labor costs, there are no new
reports of broad-based acceleration in prices and inflation expectations, at least as evidenced by
our survey results, and contact reports suggest that expectations appear to be well anchored.

September 16–17, 2015

70 of 240

Turning to the national picture, the most notable aspect of recent economic performance,
in my view, besides the unexpectedly rapid tightening in labor markets, is the behavior of
household expenditures. Real consumer spending accelerated from less than 2 percent in the
years prior to 2014 to over 3 percent since. This faster pace was interrupted in the first quarter of
this year by what are now known to have been temporary factors, including unusually harsh
winter weather. But with that pothole behind us, consumption growth has returned to a 3 percent
annual rate.
Reflecting the momentum in labor markets, real income growth is likely to continue at a
solid pace. I expect real PCE growth to remain in the 2½ to 3 percent range, distinctly higher
than the average from 2010 through 2014. This sustained step-up in the pace of consumption
growth is important to my thinking about interest rates. I’ll say more about this later, but,
broadly speaking, higher real consumption growth should be associated with higher real interest
rates.
Other components of GDP are showing reasonably healthy growth as well. Business
fixed investment weakened beginning late last year, but recent reports indicate that capital goods
orders bottomed out last spring and have been increasing since. Nonresidential construction
spending, apart from oil and gas, has registered strong gains as well, as has residential
investment spending. Even before the August employment report, I would have argued that we
had seen substantial further improvements in labor market conditions this year. With monthly
job gains averaging over 200,000 per month and growth in the prime working-age population
having slowed considerably, it is not surprising that the unemployment rate has continued to
decline at an impressive rate. The August employment report obviously revealed additional
labor market improvement.

September 16–17, 2015

71 of 240

I have spoken in past meetings about broader measures of labor utilization. I have also
spoken about alternative approaches to calculating an appropriate benchmark to gauge labor
market conditions. At this point, however, it seems clear that virtually all measures of labor
market utilization have fallen enough to be statistically indistinguishable from any plausible
normative benchmark one might choose to represent maximum employment. As a result, I don’t
see how we can say we have not seen further improvement in labor markets.
Some argue that there is likely to be additional slack in labor markets if nominal wage
rates are not accelerating. But real wage rates are related to productivity growth, and
productivity growth has been slow for several years now. Wage growth in real terms has at least
kept pace with productivity gains over that time period and, in the past year, has significantly
outpaced productivity. So I don’t see the behavior of wage rates as providing evidence that there
is any remaining labor market slack.
The JOLTS data also seem to suggest that labor market slack is minimal. Job openings
have been increasing more rapidly than hiring for several years now, but the divergence has
widened at an increasing pace this year. As of July, job openings have increased by 12½ percent
from their average in the fourth quarter of 2014, while the hiring rate has been virtually flat. The
natural interpretation would seem to be that employers are having an increasingly hard time
finding suitable workers to hire, and slack in any meaningful sense has been substantially
reduced.
A solid economic outlook and the relative stability of inflation expectations, I think,
should give us confidence that inflation will return to 2 percent once the temporary effect of the
recent fall in oil prices and strengthening of the dollar have dissipated. The behavior of inflation
following the previous oil and dollar moves should bolster that confidence. Over the past six

September 16–17, 2015

72 of 240

months—that is, from January, which is when energy prices bottomed out, to July, which is the
latest month for which we have this data—headline PCE inflation has averaged 2.2 percent,
while core PCE inflation has averaged 1.7 percent.
One might argue that the strength in headline inflation was aided by the 7.8 percent
rebound in energy prices from January to July, but core inflation was relatively close to 2 percent
despite the continuing decrease in import prices this year. I think our experience following the
previous disinflationary surprise is good evidence that the 1½ percent decline in the overall price
level over the six months prior to last January was transitory and left no lasting effect on trend
inflation. Thus, to the extent that the current disinflationary impulse from energy prices and the
dollar resembles the previous one, it ought to bolster our confidence that inflation will rebound to
2 percent as it did earlier this year.
Recent financial market volatility both here and abroad has captured popular attention
and seems to have shaped a great deal of market commentary about our pending policy decision.
For me, it’s hard to discern meaningful implications for U.S. growth prospects or inflation
trends, and it hasn’t had a significant effect on my policy views. These recent events bring to
mind several historical instances—President Rosengren cited one or two—in which large stock
market declines have occurred in the midst of extended economic expansions. The years 1966,
1987, and 1998 stand out. In each of these instances, it is clear with hindsight that stock market
gyrations did not signal a deflection in the trajectory of U.S. economic activity, and, in fact, in
each case the economy continued to expand.
I also think it’s clear with hindsight that our policy reactions were too accommodative.
For example, in the fall of 1998, we cut interest rates three times following financial market
reactions to the emerging market turmoil and, as a result, fell behind the curve in 1999. I think

September 16–17, 2015

73 of 240

the lesson is that we should be careful to not overreact to financial market volatility that is not
demonstrably connected to weaker economic fundamentals. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Mester.
MS. MESTER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I spent a lot of time during the intermeeting
period talking with business contacts, and I thank President Evans for hosting a joint meeting
between the Chicago and Cleveland boards that allowed me to gain insights from a wider array
of businesses and geography.
Over the intermeeting period, the Fourth District economy continued to expand but at a
somewhat slower pace than in July. Our diffusion index of business contacts reporting better
versus worse conditions fell to 9 in August, down from 18 in July, which is about the level it’s
been for most of the year. But this aggregate number masks some differences across industries.
The auto industry is doing very well. Strong motor vehicle sales reflect mainly retail rather than
fleet sales and include a large share of trucks for which profit margins are high. One of my
directors, an auto industry executive, indicated that auto manufacturers and suppliers find it
challenging to keep up with demand. Most companies expanded production some time ago by
using alternative work schedules with multiple shifts, and there are few other options available to
quickly boost capacity. His company is adding workers to each shift to avoid bottlenecks and to
step in for absent employees.
Activity in the construction sector, particularly nonresidential construction, remains
strong, and the outlook for residential construction has improved as household formation rates
have begun to accelerate and house prices have increased. A director whose company is a large
supplier to the construction sector has a very positive outlook. However, steel manufacturers in

September 16–17, 2015

74 of 240

the District remain under pressure—feeling the effects of the appreciation of the dollar, slower
growth abroad, and weak demand from the domestic energy sector.
Conditions in District labor markets remain quite positive. The District unemployment
rate stood at 5.1 percent in July, and it has been essentially stable at this low level since late last
year. District payrolls continue to grow at a better than 1 percent pace. Business contacts report
that labor markets are tightening and compensation pressures are increasing. In the auto
industry, manufacturers and suppliers have been making widespread use of bonuses and
overtime.
Notable were reports we received from business contacts that wage pressures are now
being felt not only for skilled workers in certain fields like construction and IT, which have faced
difficulties in finding workers for some time, but also for less-skilled occupations, such as those
in the restaurant industry. Another notable aspect of my conversations with business contacts
was that, although they certainly noticed the gyrations in the stock market, none suggested that
the volatility and decline in equity prices was causing them to change their plans regarding
hiring, investment, or spending.
That volatility partly reflects renewed concerns about China’s growth prospects and its
implications for commodity prices and growth in other emerging market economies. The dollar
has appreciated and oil prices have fallen since our previous meeting, but the recent moves were
considerably smaller than those seen last summer, and their implications for economic activity
and inflation should be smaller as well. Nonetheless, there has been some tightening of financial
conditions in the United States—in particular, lower equity prices and somewhat higher credit
risk spreads—but conditions have tended to stabilize and partially reverse over the past couple of
weeks.

September 16–17, 2015

75 of 240

I see the consequences of this tightening in financial conditions as a risk to my forecast,
but it hasn’t materially changed my outlook for the national economy. The incoming data have
been in line with my expectations for accelerating activity, further improvements in labor
markets, and a gradual firming of inflation over time.
We’ve had confirmation that growth in the second quarter was robust, and the economy
has entered the third quarter with some momentum. Averaging the estimates from the Cleveland
Fed’s two nowcasting models puts third-quarter growth at 2 percent, which is the median across
Federal Reserve System nowcasts included in the Tealbook.
I’ve marked up my growth forecast for this year to reflect the strong growth we’ve seen
in the first half. Partly reflecting somewhat slower-than-expected global growth, I’ve reduced
my growth forecast for 2016 and 2017 two-tenths compared with my June projection. But in this
projection, based partly on the revisions to past productivity growth, I’ve also revised down my
longer-run growth rate two-tenths to 2.3 percent. So the trajectory of the economy in my
forecast remains the same, with GDP growth picking up to an above-trend pace later this year
and remaining above trend next year, supported by highly accommodative monetary policy and
sound economic fundamentals, including improving household balance sheets and strengthening
labor markets.
The labor market has made significant progress. Since our previous meeting,
unemployment and underemployment rates have declined, payroll growth has remained solid,
and the job openings rate has increased. Current labor market conditions are stronger than at the
time we began raising rates in June 2004. Today the unemployment rate is 5.1 percent, which is
the Board’s staff estimate of the natural rate. At our June 2004 meeting, the unemployment rate
was 5.6 percent, which was 0.6 percentage point above the Board’s staff estimate of the natural

September 16–17, 2015

76 of 240

rate at the time. Looking at job growth, today payroll employment is 2.8 percent above its prerecession peak. Based on the real-time data available in June 2004, payrolls were more than 1
percent below their pre-recession peak.
I believe the economy is at or nearly at full employment. Research by Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland and Board staff indicates that the gap between the current labor force
participation rate and its long-term trend based on demographics is only about 20 basis points. If
actual participation stays flat, the gap is expected to be eliminated by next spring.
In this SEP projection, I moved down my estimate of the longer-run unemployment rate
to 5.2 percent from 5.5 percent. Of course, in view of the error bands associated with long-run
estimates, I admit this is not a statistically significant change. Still, it recognizes that the
unemployment rate has been falling more sharply than I’ve been anticipating, and wage
pressures have not yet risen significantly. With above-trend growth, I see the unemployment rate
falling to 4.8 percent by the end of next year and remaining below its longer-run level until 2018.
Currently, headline inflation is running below target, but I project inflation will return to
our 2 percent objective in early 2017. This is slightly later than in my June projection to allow
for the transitory effects of the most recent declines in energy and import prices to pass through.
I continue to anticipate inflation will gradually return to our target because I expect output
growth to be above trend, labor markets to continue their strengthening, and inflation
expectations to remain stable.
In light of the volatility and flight-to-safety moves in financial markets since our previous
meeting, I, like the Tealbook, take little signal about inflation expectations from the downward
move in inflation compensation measures. The estimate of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland’s measure of 10-year inflation expectations for September was very little changed

September 16–17, 2015

77 of 240

from August; it actually went up by 2 basis points, but the measure is up about 10 to 15 basis
points since early this year.
Indeed, although the latest decline in energy prices was not anticipated, inflation
dynamics have played out as the Committee suggested they would. In particular, the effects on
inflation of last summer’s decline in oil prices and drop in import prices were transitory, as
expected. Like President Lacker said, if you look at the six-month annualized rate of PCE
inflation, it has moved from negative readings early this year to over 2 percent in July. Sixmonth core PCE inflation increased from less than 1 percent earlier this year to 1.7 percent in
July, and a similar pattern is seen in the CPI, core CPI, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas trimmed
mean PCE, the Cleveland Fed median CPI, and the Cleveland Fed trimmed mean CPI.
The six-month annualized change in all of these measures as of July is 2 percent or more.
This pattern is consistent with the FOMC’s statement that it anticipates inflation will begin
gradually moving up as the effects of earlier declines in oil prices and import prices dissipate.
Seeing the inflation numbers play out this way should give us more confidence in our inflation
forecast. Now, it’s true that the most recent decline in oil prices and import prices will send the
headline readings back down again for a time, but based on past experience, this will also be
transitory. Of course, as we discussed here and as the interesting papers at this year’s Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Jackson Hole Symposium underscore, we have to be humble.
There’s considerable uncertainty associated with the inflation forecast, but probably not more
uncertainty now than in the past.
Although there are pros and cons to any particular study, I read some of the Federal
Reserve research that President Lacker cited in a recent speech as saying that we should not be
too quick to throw out the models and tools we’re currently using to forecast inflation, most of

September 16–17, 2015

78 of 240

which suggest a gradual return to target. In the historical data, inflation surprises are frequent
and large. In DSGE models, these surprises are often attributed to shocks to the mark-up of price
over cost, and they play a key role in modeling inflation dynamics. We shouldn’t be too
surprised that our inflation measures are pushed away from target when the economy is hit by
large shocks, but we also should not overreact to such shocks.
Finally, underlying my forecast is a funds rate path that incorporates a liftoff from the
zero lower bound this quarter and a gradual rise thereafter. My path is more shallow than in my
previous SEP submission. I revised down my long-run funds rate by 25 basis points to
3½ percent, and I anticipate the funds rate to be at that level by the end of 2017. Thank you,
Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’ll start with a few observations from
our District contacts over the past few weeks. Those contacts were representatives of businesses
and, this time around, of state and local government.
Sentiment in the business community continues to be almost uniformly positive regarding
conditions and the outlook. Retailers reported good sales activity and optimism about future
sales prospects. Homebuilding and commercial real estate industry participants are upbeat.
Auto industry contacts remain delighted with sales, trends, and prospects. Enough of our
interviews occurred during the recent period of market volatility to give us a read on concern
raised by those developments. We detected little concern that momentum will be disrupted by
global economic and financial events.
Over this intermeeting cycle, we were attentive to perceptions of general conditions in
labor markets and, especially, wage trends. We got the clear impression that hiring challenges

September 16–17, 2015

79 of 240

persist and have intensified. A number of our contacts described significant labor shortages and
are implementing new strategies to attract personnel—for example, referral and signing bonuses.
Firms are increasingly willing to spend on employee training to address skills
requirements. This was the fifth consecutive cycle of contacts in which we heard comments on
growing wage pressures for selected job categories or in selected geographies or both. It was
noteworthy that, this past cycle, the District contacts yielded a more generalized sense of rising
wage pressures.
Turning to my outlook, my baseline forecast for growth falls in the 2½ to 3 percent range
over the next few years, which puts me on a stronger growth path than the current Tealbook. My
growth outlook is accompanied by continued absorption of labor market slack, broadly defined,
and accelerating measured wage pressure. I continue to have confidence that inflation will move
to target in the medium term, but I’m not very optimistic we’ll see much improvement in the
inflation trend this year. I expect transitory factors, such as oil and commodity prices, will exert
downward pressure on headline and core inflation measures for the next few quarters at least.
This view lines up with the Tealbook.
The only meaningful change in my assessment of the economy from the July meeting
pertains to my sense of the balance of risks. The recent volatility in the markets, apparently a
response to increased uncertainty triggered by global economic and financial developments, has
not subsided entirely as of this meeting date. It’s too early to know whether this episode
amounts to a bona fide shock or just a nervous spasm in the markets. It’s also too early to detect
any significant effect on the real economy. I’m not projecting a material effect, but evaluation of
that question will require some time. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Williams.

September 16–17, 2015

80 of 240

MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Madam Chair. I do have one comment about the
Twelfth District economy, specifically the Bay Area economy. I don’t know if you saw this in
the news, but our housing crisis is so extreme that the Salesforce conference, which is going on
all week in San Francisco—another reason I’m happy to be here and not at home—brought in a
luxury cruise ship to provide housing for the people coming to their big conference because the
hotels were all booked. At Airbnb.com, which is very popular in San Francisco, the rates were
described as “astronomical.” I think, the fact that people are now living on luxury cruise ships
gives you a sense of the state of the San Francisco economy.
Over the past five years, real GDP growth has averaged a little over 2 percent, and the
unemployment rate has fallen nearly 1 percentage point per year. All indications are that this
pace of expansion, both in terms of growth and the labor market, is continuing despite the sizable
global headwinds.
Now, my contacts point to a virtuous cycle of job growth and consumer spending across a
broad set of regions and sectors, and I see moderate GDP growth combined with a still-subdued
pace of productivity growth, implying that the unemployment rate should continue its downward
trajectory at least through next year.
This ongoing strengthening of the labor market is in the context of an economy that’s
already at or very near full employment. Therefore, my forecast, like that in the Tealbook,
implies that the unemployment rate will fall significantly below the natural rate of
unemployment next year and remain there for quite some time. Now, like President Bullard, I
see this as already in train, in that the momentum in the economy is already in place to create
those circumstances, and it doesn’t depend on any policy decisions we make at this time.

September 16–17, 2015

81 of 240

Running such a high-pressure economy arguably has some benefits, at least for a while.
It may speed the processes of squeezing out remaining pockets of labor market weakness and
drawing in some of those who are still sitting on the sidelines. It should also accelerate progress
in reaching our 2 percent inflation target. But there are risks as well, especially if this is allowed
to go on for too long. The economic pot may move from a healthy simmer to a full boil and
eventually boil over. Managing this risk requires that we respect the lags between monetary
policy actions and the effects they have on the economy, and that we not allow imbalances to
emerge and grow that can ultimately destabilize the economy.
The paths to expansion provide a cautionary tale in this regard. In both cases, the
unemployment rate drifted lower and lower, falling below the natural rate, and eventually the
economy outran its fundamentals and became increasingly fueled by excessive optimism. In the
end, the high-pressure economy proved unsustainable, collapsing under its own weight, at great
social and economic cost—a topic I will return to tomorrow.
Of course, managing this risk also requires one to know how far is too far, and that brings
me to the question of the natural rate of unemployment. I’ve argued in the past that I view the
unemployment gap, the gap between the unemployment rate and its natural rate, the long-run
equilibrium value, as being a good gauge of overall slack, but that leads us, of course, to think
hard about what the natural rate of unemployment is and how to best estimate that.
We have spent a lot of time in the Federal Reserve System, and especially the San
Francisco Fed, thinking about this issue over the years. And on the heels of the Great Recession,
my staff and many others in the System really wrestled with the possibility that the persistent
labor market dysfunction related to mismatch or worker scarring might have substantially

September 16–17, 2015

82 of 240

increased the natural rate, and our conclusion then and now is that the long-run natural rate
wasn’t, in fact, much affected by these factors.
And now we’re faced with a different question, and that is, with the unemployment rate
so low today, we’re asking ourselves whether the natural rate may actually be lower than its prerecession levels. Now, of course, a recent analysis by Board staff, as Governor Tarullo
commented on at one of our previous meetings, considers this possibility, and that definitely
spurred some further research at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. The Board staff
analysis concluded that the secular decline in the labor share of income, which is well
documented, has pushed down the natural rate of unemployment as well in recent decades. They
argue that, basically, the decline in the labor share reflects a decline in worker bargaining power
which lowers labor costs and makes it more profitable for businesses to hire workers. With the
greater profitability of hiring workers, firms want to go out and create more vacancies in order to
take advantage of this opportunity to hire more workers and make more money. In addition,
with this increase in job vacancies, it also should be easier for workers to find jobs. So we
should see some signs that job-matching rates are going up.
In their paper, they find some evidence for the first hypothesis. There is a positive
correlation between labor share and the ratio of vacancies to unemployed across industries and
states. And we found this idea intriguing—in fact, provocative. But after a deeper look at the
theory and the evidence, I’m unconvinced.
First, the theoretical implications of a declining labor share for the natural rate of
unemployment are far from definitive. Some work by my own staff shows that a decline in labor
share doesn’t automatically imply that firms can get higher profits by creating new jobs. There’s
an example they studied, that if financial intermediaries are receiving an increasing share of the

September 16–17, 2015

83 of 240

surplus from output, businesses and workers are both being squeezed and job creation will fall
along with the labor share. So, in their model, you would find a fall in labor share could actually
push up the natural rate of unemployment.
But, more importantly, the evidence is inconsistent with the theory. Looking at the time
series data for the United States, vacancies per unemployed worker have not increased as the
labor share has fallen over the previous couple of decades. If anything, the data show somewhat
of a downward rather than upward movement in recent decades. And looking at the worker side
of the equation, you see the same thing. The job-finding rates appear to have fallen, not risen, as
the theory would suggest, and we’ve looked at this across different subgroups—short-term and
long-term unemployed, and people out of the labor force. Again, the consistent finding is that
job-finding rates are not rising the way the theory would suggest. So I really don’t see
convincing evidence that the natural rate has come down because of a fall in labor share.
With little evidence that the labor market has become more dysfunctional, my staff has
gone back to the tried-and-true method of thinking about the natural rate of unemployment,
building on some research that was done at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, and that’s to
focus on the composition of the labor force. Basically, we’re going back to George Perry’s work
from 1970 that said the time needed to find a good job match varies across worker groups,
depending on age and other things. Think about young workers—they tend to have less-stable
employment patterns than older workers. That translates into higher unemployment rates on
average.
It’s an old and well-studied idea in labor markets, and studies differ in how they account
for this influence on the overall unemployment rate. What my staff did is, they looked at the prerecession average unemployment rate for groups defined by age, gender, education, and race.

September 16–17, 2015

84 of 240

They weighted them up by changes in the population shares since 2007, and based on average
unemployment rates for the 20 years before the recession, this method yields an estimate of the
natural rate prevailing today of 5.0 percent.
Now, the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago staff did a very similar analysis and used
similar methods. They looked at a shorter period of time, and they got a somewhat lower
estimate. But, again, going back to this research that we’ve been doing about labor market
dynamics and whether there have been structural shifts in the labor market, we’re not really
finding any evidence of that. We decided to stick with looking at a 20-year pre-recession
sample, and that’s where we came up with the 5 percent number. Now, I don’t expect
demographic factors to actually change much over the next few years. So that is my long-run
view of the labor market.
As I said earlier, I expect the unemployment gap to turn negative later this year and
remain so in coming years. This will push up underlying inflation more quickly toward our
target, and that is a good thing. In my forecast, we achieve our 2 percent inflation objective in
early 2017 when the effects of the dollar appreciation and of falling oil prices have dissipated—I
think this is similar to President Mester’s view.
I’d just mention, we did spend quite a bit of time with the annual revisions, thinking long
and hard about some of our long-run views. And, similarly to President Mester, I did bring down
somewhat my estimate of not only the natural rate to 5 percent, but also long-term growth to
about 1.9 percent—based on our research on trends, demographics, and productivity—and the
real natural rate of interest to 1.5 percent.
And for those who like to read all the details or they can’t sleep at night, I am respondent
number 6 in the SEP. Thank you.

September 16–17, 2015

85 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you.
MR. ROSENGREN. There’s a two-hander.
CHAIR YELLEN. Yes. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I don’t want to ask President Williams to give away his punch
line from tomorrow, but I was wondering what you have in mind when you talk about the
economy boiling over. Are you talking in terms of inflation, or are you talking in terms of low
unemployment leading inexorably to, unfortunately, very high unemployment? On the real side,
or on the nominal side?
MR. WILLIAMS. I’ll give a very short answer to that. I am thinking in this case about
an economy that’s basically becoming unsustainable—living off froth, if you will—and then
when it turns, it turns into recession. I’m really not thinking about the inflation aspect in this
particular case, but more that the economy is running off a cliff and then falling. So that, really,
is the example.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Okay. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. President Harker.
MR. HARKER. Well, thank you, Madam Chair. As President Mester just pointed out, in
the Philadelphia District we don’t have a luxury cruise ship, but you can spend the night on the
Battleship New Jersey if you want to. [Laughter]
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Sounds attractive.
MR. HARKER. Well, they thought about it with the Pope. They were going to open it
up for the Pope—not for him, but for others. [Laughter] So, back to business. Although there
has been a slight deceleration in economic activity in the Third District, growth is continuing at a
modest pace, and our contacts, for the most part, remain optimistic. While employment growth

September 16–17, 2015

86 of 240

slowed measurably over the past three months, all of the slowdown can be attributed to a 1.6
percent decline in New Jersey’s job creation rate during July. There’s some evidence, though,
that this outsized decline may be due to seasonal adjustment.
With slower job growth, our region’s unemployment rate held steady in July at
5.6 percent. Total compensation, however, has picked up a bit, with 2.6 percent growth in the
ECI in the Philadelphia metropolitan area now exceeding that of the nation. Our coincident
indexes for the region, which are largely driven by labor market conditions, have grown between
3.02 and 3.88 percent year over year, roughly in line with the nation.
Reflecting the softness in manufacturing nationally, the general activity index in our
August business outlook survey came in at 8.3, which is slightly below its nonrecessionary
average. Shipments were a bit stronger at 16.7, and the employment index returned to positive
territory after a small negative reading in July. Optimism remained high, as the Future General
Activity Index rose to 43.1, well above its nonrecessionary average. However, the August
survey was conducted before the recent turmoil in financial and oil markets, so the preliminary
data we have for September’s report, which will be released tomorrow morning, is of particular
interest.
As expected, some of the nervousness in global financial markets has spilled over into
survey respondents’ views, but, with the exception of the headline index, the spillover was
relatively minor. September’s Current General Activity Index declined to negative 6, although
the indexes for new orders and employment increased somewhat to 9.4 and 10.2, respectively,
and shipments held fairly steady at 14.8. Also, the Future General Activity Index was largely
unchanged in September at 44.0. Broadly speaking, the tenor of the report is slightly upbeat.

September 16–17, 2015

87 of 240

My take on the numbers and what we are hearing is that we are not seeing much spillover from
financial markets to the real economy, at least not in the Third District.
The service sector has shown some limited improvement since we last met, but the
indexes for activities, orders, and sales still remain below historical averages. The relative bright
spot is the region’s tourism industry, which is reporting record summer activity.
Housing in the region continues to recover and appears to be gaining some momentum.
Recent months have seen record-high multifamily permits, and single-family permits are
improving modestly. In the Third District, multifamily construction is outpacing the nation as a
whole. House prices, however, continue to grow more slowly than in the nation as a whole, in
part because of much lower house price depreciation during the housing crisis. Regionally,
nonresidential construction has also improved, with the value of contracts for both commercial
buildings and all nonresidential buildings rising appreciably in July.
Turning to the nation as a whole, I believe the real economy remains on solid footing, and
that the waning in price pressures is a temporary phenomenon. Although recent negative
developments in foreign economies and the stock market are of some concern, I do not anticipate
that they will have a large or persistent effect on U.S. growth. Specifically, my forecast calls for
real GDP growth of about 2.3 percent this year, as the economy has rebounded from a weak first
quarter. I expect healthy consumer spending to underpin output growth that is modestly above
my longer-term trend of 2.3 percent over the medium term.
The recent data continue to point to a healthy labor market, and I expect the
unemployment rate will edge slightly below my estimate of the natural rate over the next three
years. Although the recent data on inflation have been on the weak side, I see this mostly due to

September 16–17, 2015

88 of 240

the fall in energy prices, so I expect the weakness to be temporary and inflation to begin moving
up.
In addition, I am encouraged by survey evidence showing that business owners plan to
increase labor compensation. Research by my staff indicates that movements in actual
compensation or earnings lag survey measures by 9 to 12 months, so we may soon see increases
in wages that get passed through to inflation. That said, I am a bit concerned about the seeming
downward tilt in inflation expectations and will be watching this closely going forward.
On balance, I expect that inflation will rise gradually over the next three years and reach
our 2 percent target in 2018. Underlying my forecast is a path for the federal funds rate that is
somewhat stronger than the Tealbook, although it is within the range of outcomes suggested by
monetary policy rules that we look at. The recent data have not altered my view that the real
economy will grow at a pace not too far from trend growth over the next few years, and that it is
able to sustain a gradual renormalization of monetary policy. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kaplan.
MR. KAPLAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. I am going to start by talking about the
outlook for the energy sector. This will build on some of Steve Kamin’s comments.
Oil price uncertainty, as measured by the oil volatility index, is approaching
exceptionally high levels, similar to what we saw at the start of this year and in 2011. Our view,
informed by discussion with industry contacts, is that there is likely to be more downside than
upside risk at current prices. That is, we believe oil prices may well fall further from here and
stay lower for longer than had been previously expected.
Let me explain some of the reasons why. First, on the demand side, a significant issue,
which we have all talked about, is a possible further slowing of growth in China and China-

September 16–17, 2015

89 of 240

linked economies. Second, the summer driving season—which, by the way, was very strong—
has ended, and we have yet to enter the peak winter heating season. Third and lastly, refineries
are now shutting down for normal scheduled maintenance, and that will go on for the next few
months.
On the supply side, inventories of crude are large and growing. Global production is
more than 2 million barrels per day above global consumption. And although rig count has
notably declined, this is more than offset, in our view, by a very large shadow inventory of
drilled but uncompleted wells that could be brought into production rapidly, depending on oil
prices. We have accumulated this supply overhang even as supply outages outside the United
States have restricted world oil production by an estimated 3½ million barrels per day. If any of
these outages are resolved—for example, in Libya or Iran—the additional production could
easily offset supply declines expected in the United States in coming months.
In addition, much of the world’s marginal cost production is located in the United States,
and, to a much lesser extent, in Canada and the North Sea. So if supply adjustments are required,
which we think they will be, they are going to need to take place mostly in the United States. In
our view, this is going to be challenging and very painful economically, and it is going to be
primarily in the area of the shale producers.
In response to all of this, producers, as you would expect, are cutting their capital
outlays—in some cases, for the second or third time. For North America as a whole, we expect
energy industry cap ex to fall as much as 10 to 15 percent in 2016 versus 2015. Despite the
initial surge of capital that came into the sector early this year, multiple Beige Book contacts
reported that the credit situation is in fact worsening for many small- to mid-cap independent
producers. And potential new capital is now resetting its expectations much more realistically to

September 16–17, 2015

90 of 240

lower prices for longer. We believe this will likely lead to more defaults, debt restructurings,
and merger activity. Based on all of these factors, it is our view that it may not be until
sometime in 2017 that global supply and demand get into some reasonable degree of balance.
With that backdrop, let me talk about the Eleventh District. There certainly will continue
to be negative spillovers from all of this in the Eleventh District. We see it in the manufacturing
survey, and, in fact, our most recent survey shows that the new orders component dropped 13
points to negative 12½ after having reached positive territory in July for the first time this year.
The service sector is stronger and more resilient and still growing at close to its expansion
average, but we are seeing signs that retail sales are beginning to weaken. In addition to the
effect of the energy sector, Beige Book contacts suggest some of this retail weakness is due to
the strength of the dollar, which really affects Texas maybe more than other states because it
hurts the purchasing power of Mexican shoppers who contribute significantly to retail sales in
the state of Texas.
Despite all of this, employment in the Eleventh District has been surprisingly resilient,
probably because of the diversified nature of the economy. Even factoring in these negative
energy developments, our regional economists still predict that Texas jobs will grow at an
annualized pace of 1.3 percent over the final five months of this year, which is the same rate as
the first seven months.
Although reductions in energy-related jobs have been a negative factor, as of yet they
have not affected the regional unemployment rate as much as we would have expected. What is
happening is that many of the people who moved to the area to work in the oil fields have now
left and returned to their previous locations. Those who have remained have taken lower-paying
jobs in other sectors, which, until recently, have struggled to attract new employees.

September 16–17, 2015

91 of 240

One of the pronounced features of our District is severe labor shortages in various
areas—construction trades, manufacturing, food, nursing, truck driving, retail, and restaurants.
Because of that, despite all of these negative factors from energy, we still see upward wage
pressure. And, related to that, we see a very strong real estate market.
If you look at the areas of the state which are less dependent on energy, the real estate
sector remains robust. Our latest reading of Texas home values is up 8 percent year over year in
the second quarter. And we didn’t see much deceleration from quarter to quarter during the first
two quarters of this year. With that, downward price pressures actually accelerated notably in
surveys in August. According to our manufacturing surveys, and in the service sector, our
selling price index slipped below zero, which is its first negative reading in nearly five years.
So, with all of this, there are a lot of crosscurrents in the state. But all in all, even though
the Eleventh District has remained resilient, we believe the negative effects of a potentially lower
oil price for longer are continuing to unfold, and that probably means the risks in the District are
to the downside.
Turning to the national economy, we expect to see the unemployment rate reach its
longer-term sustainable level by the end of this year—that is, 5 percent—and then fall below that
level. With unemployment low and falling, and with longer-run inflation expectations well
anchored, we believe inflation should begin moving up toward our 2 percent objective as the
effects of the fall in oil and the rise of the dollar eventually pass through inflation calculations.
By the end of 2017, we believe we are going to be very likely near our inflation target of
2 percent. We believe conditions outside the United States do pose a real threat to the scenario I
just described, though. Major economies—including China, Europe, Brazil, and Japan, for
example—face serious demographic, fiscal, and structural challenges. These challenges have the

September 16–17, 2015

92 of 240

potential to create spillovers, which could negatively affect the United States, and we believe
these challenges are likely to take years versus months to unfold and address.
Lastly, regarding the recent volatility in U.S. and other global financial markets, for us
this is not, as of yet, a major factor in our assessment of overall conditions, and let me explain
why. Although a decline in market value certainly could have negative wealth effects, we
believe it has to be viewed in the context of overall valuation levels. And, in that regard, we
believe valuations heading into the summer were fulsome by historical standards—certainly in
the United States, but you can make the same argument about non-U.S. markets, maybe even to a
greater degree.
When we look at expected earnings, price/earnings ratios, and other key valuation
factors, we believe that, in that context, an equity market correction like the one we recently had
could potentially be healthy and, in fact, indicative of appropriate reassessment of risk‒return by
market participants. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. As we evaluate progress toward achieving our
employment mandate within a reasonable period of time, I think we can check the box for
“reasonable confidence.” Most of my business contacts thought domestic demand was relatively
strong. In the auto industry, low interest rates and incentives have continued to support very
robust light vehicle sales. Meanwhile, my director from a large credit card bank indicated that
growth in consumer spending, other than gasoline, has been healthy but not spectacular. He and
other bankers also noted that consumer credit performance outside the category of student loans
has been very good, with delinquency rates near all-time lows. A number of contacts reported
gains in residential and commercial construction. Indeed, real estate markets are quite strong in

September 16–17, 2015

93 of 240

some areas. However, construction equipment manufacturers are not so upbeat, with Caterpillar
seeing only modest gains and Deere reporting flat demand. Each had stronger expectations for
the year back in January.
We did hear a few other notes of caution. United Airlines reported that business travel
was down for the entire industry. And Manpower Employment Services said orders for temp
workers have softened, reflecting clients’ uncertainty about the demand for their products.
Manpower’s permanent placements were up, but only for skilled workers. Similarly, wage gains
were confined to these hard-to-fill occupations.
On the international front, most contacts expressed caution about the prospects for global
growth. I did hear a number of positive reports on activity in Europe, with some of the strongest
being about Spain. The gains, though, are coming from low levels. Not surprisingly, just about
everyone was pessimistic about China, and there were some dire comments about Latin America,
especially Brazil, which one large manufacturer described as “going off a cliff.”
Turning to the national outlook, my own assessment has not changed a great deal. I
expect growth will average about 2½ percent over the forecast period. That is above the
Tealbook, reflecting in part my somewhat higher path for potential output. I expect the
unemployment rate will fall to 5 percent by the end of this year, which would match my
assessment for the current level of the natural rate. I agree with the Tealbook that, on net, other
labor market indicators point to some additional slack beyond what the unemployment rate
shows. But I expect these gaps will diminish, too, as we move through this year and next.
But inflation continues to be another story. I think we are still quite a way from
reasonable confidence that inflation will rise to target over the medium term. Indeed, the news
since July has been disappointing. We have been expecting that the disinflationary influences of

September 16–17, 2015

94 of 240

energy and import prices would dissipate soon. Instead, over the intermeeting period, oil prices
and the dollar have broken in the “wrong” direction.
The glimmer of higher wage growth we thought we saw in the ECI in the first quarter
also has vanished. President Rosengren was pretty accurate in forecasting this second-quarter
change at our previous meeting. And the year-over-year increase in core PCE inflation is still
just 1.2 percent. Not long ago, some were putting more emphasis on three-month inflation,
which had picked up. Now the three-month change in core PCE has moved back down. The
Tealbook speculated that the elevated second-quarter core number was an aberration, in part due
to residual seasonality, and that was a pretty good call.
My own forecast is very close to the Tealbook. I also see inflation only slowly marching
up to 1.9 percent in 2018. But getting up to this 1.9 percent inflation assessment continues to be
tough for me. None of the inflation models we regularly run at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Chicago get us to 2 percent within the forecast horizon. Nonetheless, like the Tealbook, and like
most of us around this table, my judgmental forecast embeds the assumption that inflation
expectations will exert a substantial upward pull on actual inflation. But this projection is
fraught with uncertainties.
The recent memo by Travis Berge, Brad Strum, and Kei-Mu Yi summarized the inflation
models used around the Federal Reserve System. The collection of models reported suggests
that one needs to put a good deal of weight on survey measures of long-term PCE inflation
expectations, which are flat at 2 percent, in order to get a model projection up to target. But
relying on long-term inflation expectations isn’t always enough. As I have discussed here
before, our Chicago DSGE model also uses the SPF 10-year CPI expectations to inform its latent

September 16–17, 2015

95 of 240

inflation trend. The declines in those long-term CPI expectations over the past year and a half as
well as other data keep the model’s core PCE inflation forecast down at only 1½ percent in 2018.
In a somewhat similar vein, the Board staff’s long-run inflation attractor is currently
anchored at 1.8 percent rather than 2 percent. I still find that worrisome. Taken together, these
results highlight that current survey inflation expectations could be less helpful than we think,
and, to the degree that they are less helpful, any slippage in long-term inflation expectations
could put our inflation forecast at even greater risk. An important ingredient in my SEP forecast
is that we avoid such slippage, and that we instead have long-term expectations that are firmly
anchored at our inflation target. It is crucial, then, that the public’s inflation expectations be well
supported by monetary policy.
In my SEP forecast, long-term inflation expectations are anchored by a policy rate path
that aggressively aims to achieve our symmetric inflation target and is not overly averse to
inflation outcomes that run moderately above 2 percent. Given what we know today, in my SEP
forecast such a policy is consistent with a mid-2016 liftoff in the funds rate and a subsequent
shallow path that reaches 3 percent by the end of 2018. My premise is that it will be the middle
of next year before we and the public finally see core inflation moving up more consistently. By
then, I hope we will also have experienced a few months of relative quiet on the energy and
dollar front. This delayed liftoff also provides some extra buffer against important downside
risks to the outlook. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Madam Chair. The Tenth District economy expanded only
modestly since the previous meeting, as weakness in commodity prices and a stronger dollar
continue to weigh on the region’s energy, agriculture, and manufacturing industries. As a result,

September 16–17, 2015

96 of 240

District bankers are monitoring closely their loan portfolios and reviewing collateral values. Our
business contacts continue to note difficulty finding qualified labor, and with this, along with the
headwinds in the agricultural and energy sectors, we are seeing slowing in employment growth
throughout much of the District.
Turning to the national outlook, since our July meeting, the recent revisions in incoming
data have led me to slightly raise my overall expectations of 2015 growth. After expanding only
modestly in the first quarter, output growth bounced back significantly in the second quarter. I
expect more modest growth in the third and fourth quarters that is sufficient to push 2015 growth
to 2.1 percent, which is about 0.3 percent higher than my previous forecast. And although I see
current growth as somewhat above trend, I did mark down my longer-term estimate of growth to
1.8 percent, incorporating some of the soft productivity readings and recognizing the
demographic factors pulling trend growth lower over the next several years.
Labor market indicators, as others have noted, continue to signal further improvement
and a return, in many cases, to pre-crisis characteristics. The NFIB survey, for example, reported
almost half of its respondents as seeing few or no qualified applicants for job openings, and that
almost 30 percent of businesses are not able to fill some positions. Both of these indicators are
above their July 2007 levels and consistent with reports from our District contacts.
Likewise, the number of unemployed people per job opening is near its pre-crisis level.
And if you consider the pool of unemployed workers plus people who want a job but are not in
the labor force, that measure is also near its pre-crisis level. These factors not only point to
ongoing labor market improvement, but also support expectations of stronger wage growth.
Given projected growth and labor market advances, I continue to see reasonable evidence
that inflation will rise over the next few years toward 2 percent. Although market-based

September 16–17, 2015

97 of 240

measures of inflation compensation have softened, both the median CPI and PCE survey-based
five-year, five-year forward measures of expected inflation rose slightly in the most recent SPF.
Over the past six months, core PCE inflation has been running at 1.7 percent, compared with a
0.8 percent pace last January.
I also find it encouraging that over the past six months, the trend in the broad components
of the PCE price index appear to have shifted. For example, in February, the services component
was running at 1.6 percent, its softest six-month pace since 2011. Most recently, the annualized
six-month change is 2 percent. The patterns are similar for durables and nondurables.
In general, there is a distinct bottom based on the six-month change in inflation since last
January. Since that time, the broad components of core PCE inflation have all moved higher. In
addition, the BEA revised up inflation in 2012 and 2013 by about ¼ percentage point each year,
which means that the price level is about ½ percent higher than we thought it was at the time of
our July meeting.
In terms of emergent risk, the recent concerns regarding global growth are worth keeping
in mind. The downward trend in the New Export Orders Index from the ISM manufacturing
survey suggests exporters are facing real headwinds. As a result, I have taken a bit softer export
growth into my baseline forecast.
Concerns about global growth have also spilled into financial markets, as is evident from
the recent stock market volatility. Markets have priced in some headwinds through lower equity
prices, although not enough to cause me to alter my forecast for consumer spending. In addition,
the VIX is already back to what can be considered a relatively normal range, so any knock-on
effects to the real economy from the recent bout of market volatility are likely to be rather
modest. Thank you.

September 16–17, 2015

98 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Madam Chair. Before I go into my prepared
remarks, I will offer a brief comment on remarks that others have made. I thought President
Bullard offered some great perspectives on how financial market data should be influencing this
Committee. I think it is important that we use financial market data only as a signal of the
underlying real conditions and not as a driver of policy itself, which I took to be his admonition.
The one point on which my perspective might diverge most sharply from his is on
interpreting the behavior of market-based measures of inflation compensation—or inflation
expectations, I would say. I continue to be quite concerned about the downward movement
there. It certainly influenced my Summary of Economic Projections submission. Some of you
might have noticed that I am number 13, and I offered a negative funds rate as being appropriate
monetary policy. I think, in view of the decline we have seen in longer-term inflation
expectations, this is an appropriate response. Obviously, the consensus of the Committee is to
view this decline with sanguinity. I hope that that turns out to be the correct attitude.
In terms of the flight-to-quality issue, one way to get rid of that issue that President
Mester noted is in Treasury breakevens is to look at zero-coupon inflation swaps, which are not
contaminated by that. Zero-coupon inflation swaps are also showing that same downward
movement, really going back at least a year, possibly a year and a half. So I think these are, at
least to me, markers of real concern to take from financial market data.
Now, Madam Chair, for the rest of my time, I really ask for the indulgence of the
Committee, as I intend to spend my time today in a somewhat unorthodox fashion. And for the
benefit of Presidents Kaplan and Harker, I advise you don’t try this at home. [Laughter] Rather
than speaking about the current state—

September 16–17, 2015

99 of 240

MR. TARULLO. Actually, if they are going to do it, they should do it at home.
[Laughter]
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Perhaps a better point, Governor Tarullo. Rather than
speaking about the current state of the economy, I will offer some thoughts about the strategic
framework that guides the Committee’s policy decisions. This framework will inform the
Committee’s decisions about liftoff but, of course, will also inform the long sequence of
decisions to be made after liftoff. Governor Fischer has made the point several times that, really,
it’s not just liftoff that we have to think about, it’s also the framing of the decisions afterward
that really matters.
Now, currently, the Committee has said relatively little publicly about what its policy
framework will be. This state of affairs has some obvious downsides in terms of creating policy
uncertainty, but there is a silver lining in this cloud of uncertainty. I think the Committee has
room to choose the desirable policy framework without being seen as having violated prior
commitments of some kind.
My sense from the internal discussions here is that there is a strong desire to return to the
“normal” policy framework that was employed during the Great Moderation. My sense, too, is
that the Committee’s unwillingness to communicate openly about its post-liftoff framework
tends to foster this perception among outsiders that we are going to go back to the way business
was conducted before 2008.
I am going to suggest over the next couple of days that this would be a mistake. In my
view, a good policy framework should automatically engender something that approximates a
desirable monetary policy response to severe shocks like the one that hit the economy in 2008.

September 16–17, 2015

100 of 240

Our pre-2008 policy framework failed in this dimension. It led the Committee to
deliberately promulgate persistent shortfalls in prices and employment. What I’ll do today is
point out what I see as being the key conceptual flaw in the pre-2008 framework, and tomorrow I
will suggest what I see as a better framework and describe what that better framework would
imply for current decisions.
To understand my criticism of the pre-2008 framework, it’s useful to go back to the
November 2009 meeting, which was the very beginning of the recovery. At that meeting, the
latest unemployment reading was 9.8 percent and the staff’s nowcast for core inflation was
1.4 percent. The median participant’s assessment was that, under appropriate monetary policy,
the unemployment rate would still be 7 percent in three years. At the same time, the median
participant’s assessment was that, under appropriate monetary policy, PCE inflation would only
rise back to 1½ percent three years later. So, three years later, we had unemployment at
7 percent and inflation at 1½ percent.
When I was reading these numbers, I found them quite surprising. You can draw one of
two conclusions from them. On the one hand, you can say that the Committee was willing, in
November 2009, to forgo the timely creation of hundreds of thousands, possibly millions, of jobs
in the absence of any inflationary threat that was perceived by the Committee. On the other
hand, you can focus only on the price-stability mandate and say that monetary policy can’t do
much about unemployment. That is a view that has been expressed around this table before. Or,
you can focus only on the price stability mandate and say that the Committee was willing to
make policy choices and put the credibility of its then-informal 2 percent target in jeopardy.
However you put it, it is hard to understand these projections—7 percent unemployment
and 1½ percent inflation three years later—as representing the outcome of appropriate monetary

September 16–17, 2015

101 of 240

policy. Why did the Committee view such a persistent and extreme shortfall with respect to its
objectives as being appropriate?
A quick side note: Labor market recovery actually turned out to be much worse than
that. Unemployment was 7.8 percent three years later, and labor force participation declined
much more than the Committee anticipated—or anyone else anticipated, for that matter.
Inflation ended up being around what the Committee viewed as being desirable—thanks, I think,
in no little part, to choices made by the Committee. But why did the Committee, in November
2009, view such a persistent extreme shortfall with respect to its objectives as being appropriate?
The answer, I believe, lies in the pre-2008 policy framework, which centered on variants
of the Taylor (1993) rule. And this framework continues to live on in the collection of interest
rate rules that we see in Tealbook B. In my view, all of these rules have a key conceptual
shortcoming. The Committee has a dual mandate, which is to promote price stability and
maximum employment. The Taylor rules are based on the presumption that the Committee has
other objectives in terms of the time path of interest rates that are independent of the objectives
for employment and prices.
The original Taylor (1993) rule implicitly presumes that the Committee does not like
interest rate gaps. The FOMC desires to keep the federal funds rate close to its long-run level.
The rule then trades off the Committee’s unmandated aversion to interest rate gaps against its
mandated aversion to unemployment and inflation gaps. Otherwise, if you saw unemployment
and inflation gaps going in the same direction—unemployment too high, inflation too low—you
should just lower rates some more. But the Taylor rule says, wait a second, you shouldn’t be
doing that, because actually you don’t want to move interest rates around too much.

September 16–17, 2015

102 of 240

The way that the Taylor rule resolves this tradeoff—interest rate volatility and gap
volatility—especially when the Phillips curve is as flat as it’s proven to be, can result in very odd
outcomes. So, in November 2009, the staff’s outlook was based on the Taylor (1993) rule. That
outlook had unemployment above the natural rate for four years and inflation at or below
1.6 percent for five years. We didn’t get to see the staff outlook beyond a five-year horizon, so I
don’t have any sense of when it ever got back to 2 percent.
My reading of the transcript, in terms of participants’ contributions, is that aversion to
accommodation, as opposed to inflation or unemployment, was really at the heart of that
discussion. The big debate at that meeting was, should we plan to raise rates when the
unemployment rate is in the 9s or in the 8s? The Summary of Economic Projections shows that
the key motivating factor for this debate was not really inflation. Rather, it was the Committee’s
willingness to give up on its dual-mandate goals in order to get back to normalizing policy more
rapidly.
Madam Chair, the Federal Reserve did such a heroic job of successfully healing
extraordinary financial market turmoil in the latter part of the past decade. But our monetary
policy response was not as successful. I attribute this to the Committee’s policy framework,
which deliberately directed the economy toward relatively persistent large employment and
inflation shortfalls. I think we need to have a policy framework that works considerably better in
the face of adverse shocks than we had available in November 2009.
I have argued today that shortcomings of our pre-2008 framework can be traced to its
reliance on variants of the Taylor rule. These rules implicitly impose a large penalty on
historically unusual settings of the federal funds rate and other forms of accommodation. We
need to have a policy framework that is much less averse to an unusual use of our tools as

September 16–17, 2015

103 of 240

opposed to achieving our objectives. Tomorrow I will talk about such a framework and some of
its implications for our current decisionmaking. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Madam Chair. Just going back to President
Kocherlakota’s comments, I don’t remember November 2009 quite that way. Just for the record,
we didn’t have tools at the time that could generate a more rapid return, and we were gradually
inventing them.
CHAIR YELLEN. We had already cut the funds rate target to zero. We had already
engaged in some asset purchases. The way I remember it, I think it’s fair to say, it took a while
before we decided we could and should really scale up our asset purchases—
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes. We learned by doing.
CHAIR YELLEN. —yes—and use more unconventional forms of forward guidance that
would push expectations way out.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Our toolkit today has a much better, deeper set of tools
to help us achieve our objectives than the one we had in November 2009 did. I remember that, at
the time, we were very uncomfortable with actually buying Treasury securities. And the initial
Treasury purchase program was quite small, if I remember correctly, because we weren’t even
sure how markets were going to react to that purchase program and whether we were actually
going to get the desired effect in terms of financial market conditions. But anyway—
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. This is a great conversation. We should continue it—
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. We can take it offline.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I will say that the framework the Committee had in place
shaped the way market participants were thinking about when interest rates would rise. A lot of

September 16–17, 2015

104 of 240

the surveys, for example, done by the Open Market Desk had a number of primary dealers seeing
interest rates going up when the unemployment rate was still in the 9s. There were tools that
were under our control and at our disposal. But I think this is certainly something we can talk
about over drinks.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. And beyond. [Laughter] Over many drinks. Okay.
Switching gears, as far as I’m concerned, the economy has been on essentially the same
trajectory now that it has been on for some time, growth slightly above trend and sufficient to
lead to a gradual tightening in the labor market. To me, the key question is whether this is going
to continue. When I look at the key sectors of the economy, I agree with others. Consumer
spending seems to have relatively firm underpinnings because it has solid job gains and low
inflation, and the inflation shocks actually are boosting real income.
The housing sector also seems to be a positive, with activity encouraged by strengthening
sales and rising prices. Sturdy job gains and low mortgage rates have provided, I think,
significant support for the sector, and I certainly expect the housing sector to continue to recover
over the year ahead.
Nevertheless, I do think there are risks in terms of growth, and I think they’ve very much
swung to the downside. Despite what I think is a relatively sturdy second-quarter GDP report, I
believe the economy has somewhat less forward momentum than maybe some others around the
table think, and, most significantly, I think the risks around that baseline outlook are tilted to the
downside.
Turning to the economic growth outlook, I think there are a number of reasons for
concern. Most importantly, we do have a quite dicey international situation, with growth
slowing in China and commodity prices weakening broadly, and I think this is putting

September 16–17, 2015

105 of 240

considerable strain on a wide array of emerging market economies. For example, last week we
had the downgrade of Brazil’s sovereign debt rating to junk bond status by S&P. So we’ll see
how that actually plays out.
I think generally what’s happening is that we’re undergoing a pretty significant regime
shift from a few years ago when strong Chinese demand was keeping commodity prices well
above the marginal cost of new production. The result was a very favorable terms-of-trade shift
for many EMEs that are commodity producers and a very strong impetus to investment in those
countries. Now, all of that has been reversing, and I think the risks are that the consequences for
global growth could turn out to be stronger and longer lasting than we’d expected.
The terms-of-trade reversal we’ve already seen is leading to a sharp slowdown in EME
growth, currency weakness, a deterioration in many countries’ fiscal positions, and significant
political stress. I think there is a nonnegligible risk of an unfavorable dynamic that could persist
for some time. So let me just sketch this out. I’m not saying this is going to happen, I just think
there’s some probability mass on this outcome.
Weakness in commodity prices leads to further stress on many EMEs. That leads to
corporate difficulties, which we haven’t seen much of yet, further capital flight, and further
currency weakness. For us, it means that dollar strength persists, and this erodes our own growth
momentum and puts further downward pressure on inflation. Also, the strong dollar increases
the stress on EME corporates that have significant dollar-denominated debt exposure.
The stronger dollar also squeezes U.S. profit margins, leading to weaker corporate
earnings and a softer U.S. equity market. U.S. financial conditions keep tightening. I don’t
know how much weight to put on this scenario, but what I think is interesting about this scenario

September 16–17, 2015

106 of 240

is that it has several important reinforcing feedback loops. We saw in the financial crisis that
that’s how you can get pretty bad outcomes.
It strikes me that the risks here are not zero. When we went around the table, a lot of
people were just saying, “There’s stuff going on in the markets.” I think the markets are
reflecting fundamental developments that are occurring in the global economy, and as a
consequence of that, I take those financial market developments more seriously.
Financial conditions have already tightened significantly as the dollar has appreciated on
a broad trade-weighted basis, and the U.S. equity market has weakened. I, like others, don’t put
much weight on the equity market decline yet because it hasn’t been in place for very long, but
the dollar strength has been persistent and does threaten to undermine U.S. net exports. I’m
particularly struck by the weakness of the Canadian dollar and the Mexican peso versus the U.S.
dollar because we generally think that those countries have pretty good economic policy and
institutional structures. Yet currently the Canadian dollar trades at 1.32 per U.S. dollar; a year
ago it was at 1.10. The same for the Mexican peso, which has depreciated about 30 percent over
the past year and nearly 10 percent over the past three months. These are two major U.S. trading
partners whose currency has moved a lot, and I don’t think we’ve really seen the consequences
of that in terms of our trade.
Moreover, apart from international developments, I think there are other reasons to be
concerned about the growth outlook. So let’s just set aside the international stuff for a minute.
First, job gains have been strong relative to the underlying growth trajectory. People
have said, “Well, that’s just going to continue.” It’s not obvious to me that that would continue
because one thing that is happening is, profit growth is really slowing down. And we’ve heard

September 16–17, 2015

107 of 240

that a number of corporations are now really looking at how they are going to raise earnings, and
maybe they’re going to have to start being tougher and begin to think about downsizing.
Second, I think we’ve had a pretty significant climb in inventory investment, and that
provided a significant contribution to growth in the first half of the year. In the second quarter,
the real nonfarm inventory build was almost $120 billion at an annual rate. That’s probably
more than double what’s sustainable over the longer term.
Third, earlier this year, we were talking about how the household savings rate seemed
high relative to what was implied by the historical relationship between household net worth and
disposable income. That was making us feel more optimistic about consumption, that
consumption could grow faster than income for a time because the household savings rate was
high. But after revisions, it doesn’t look high anymore. We’re back at 4.8 percent of disposable
income. That’s the same level we saw in 2013 and 2014, so I don’t think we have so much
support from that.
With respect to inflation, with the exception of the softness in commodity prices, I also
don’t think the situation has changed much, and I don’t think it is particularly worrisome as long
as the economy continues to grow at an above-trend pace. If you could guarantee that the
economy was going to grow at an above-trend pace, I wouldn’t be that worried about the
inflation outlook, but because I’m worried about the strength of U.S. growth, that does make me
worry about the mechanism that’s going to push inflation back up toward our objective.
The fact is that, despite falling energy prices and weaker import prices, the trend for core
inflation has flattened out. This suggests to me that if growth does remain above trend, then the
low inflation problem will take care of itself. That said, the fact that nominal wage growth has
not picked up yet implies that we still, in my mind, have excess slack in the labor market.

September 16–17, 2015

108 of 240

Combined with the sluggish growth trend and the downside risk to growth threatened by
international developments, this suggests to me that the costs of waiting, in terms of beginning
monetary policy normalization, are pretty low right now.
My preference would be to wait a bit longer so we can better assess the consequences of
developments in China and among the EMEs in terms of the implications regarding U.S. growth
and inflation. As I see it, the risks around liftoff right now are asymmetric. If we go now and
the international market developments prove to be of sufficient intensity to deflect the U.S.
economy away from our objectives, the cost could be quite high to us. Conversely, if we wait a
little bit longer and the effect turns out to be insignificant, then we can go before year-end, and I
don’t really think we give up much in terms of our ability to achieve our objectives. Speaking
for myself, I won’t feel particularly bad if we waited and then it turns out everything is fine. I
think I’ll feel pretty good about that. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. Thank you, Madam Chair. My views about the likely trajectories of
economic activity and inflation are not very different from the views I held in July. I believed
then that we were closing in on full employment, and I believe that is even more true today. And
I said then that I was reasonably confident that inflation would move back toward 2 percent in
the not-too-distant future, and that is still my view.
However, like most of you, I’ve become more concerned about the situation abroad over
the past several weeks, and this leads me to attach more downside risk to my projection than I
would have done at our previous meeting. The effect of foreign developments has been
reasonably small so far, though, of course, these developments may well take longer to affect us

September 16–17, 2015

109 of 240

than the short period since China’s exchange rate adjustment, and we shall simply have to keep
monitoring these developments.
There has been a lot of discussion about inflation over the intermeeting period and during
this meeting so far. That is no surprise, considering that this is the part of our mandate on which
we are most obviously missing our target, and so I’d like to focus the remainder of my remarks
today on inflation.
Many discussions of inflation start with the 12-month core PCE inflation rate, which is
currently 1.2 percent and projected to be 1.3 percent by the end of the year, although total PCE
inflation is projected to be only 0.3 percent at that time. The main reason for the 1 percentage
point difference between the core and the total rates of PCE inflation arises from the recent
declines in oil prices, which are expected to be temporary. However, changes in oil prices have
an effect on PCE prices that goes beyond the prices that are excluded by using the core PCE
inflation rate. Oil prices affect the cost of production of many goods. Moreover, the
appreciation of the dollar has direct effects on the prices of many goods.
The additional effect of recent changes in oil and import prices on the inflation rate—
over and above what’s picked up in food and energy prices—is estimated by staff at
approximately 0.4 percentage point this year. Accordingly, we can conclude that the declines in
oil and import prices together have reduced the overall inflation rate by approximately 1.4
percentage points. More-rigorous methods of stripping out the transitory factors, such as using
the Dallas Fed trimmed mean PCE or a weighted median PCE price index and other measures,
yield a reasonably similar conclusion on balance.
But regardless of the exact figure we use, I think that a good portion of the factors
holding down underlying inflation are transitory, the result of changes in oil and other

September 16–17, 2015

110 of 240

commodity prices and of the exchange rate. If the exchange rate stops appreciating, and that is
highly likely, its downward pressure on core inflation will gradually stop. Similarly, if the price
of oil eventually stops decreasing, its drag on core inflation will also abate. Although it’s
difficult to predict when the exchange rate and the price of oil will stop rising and falling,
respectively, it is almost certain that current trends in these two variables will stop in the medium
term. As a result, I am reasonably confident that inflation will move back toward 2 percent in
the medium term. I leave the rest for tomorrow, Madam Chair. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Madam Chair. Like, I think, most of you, no matter your
disposition on monetary policy, I haven’t changed my baseline outlook very much over the
course of the past six or seven weeks. But as Vice Chairman Dudley explained a couple of
minutes ago, the downside risks are palpably greater than they were, even though, in July, I and
people to my left—I don’t mean ideologically, I mean geographically [laughter]—were also
concerned about potential downside risks.
I would embrace everything Vice Chairman Dudley said and just add one other piece of
information here. I think if it had just been U.S. equity markets going down, even if it had gone
down 6 percent over the day rather than 3 percent, I truly would have taken no notice of that,
particularly after a long period of appreciation of equity markets. And even if it had just been
China’s equity markets in isolation, I wouldn’t have taken too much signal from that. But it’s a
combination of what have long been known to be building concerns with the amount of leverage
and credit in China in the background as Chinese officials responded in a less-than-fullyconsidered fashion to what was going on with the correction in the job market. And I believe the
reason they responded in a less-than-fully-considered fashion was not because they’re bad or

September 16–17, 2015

111 of 240

uninformed or inept policymakers. To the contrary, they’re really quite good at what they do,
but it’s a difficult situation, and whenever you’re in a difficult situation, there are no great policy
options.
My impression is that the thing that worries Chinese officials most in the near term is the
amount of margining that lies behind a lot of those holdings in equity markets, and the margining
is connected very directly to the amount of credit extended through the shadow banking system.
I think what is less fully realized is how closely that connects to the regular regulated banking
system as well in China.
I read the concern with putting a floor under Chinese equities to be indicative of the level
of concern with the state of credit and leverage throughout the Chinese economy right now.
Obviously my impression is based on incomplete information and selected contact, but the
impression I have is that if the decline in Chinese equity markets was to renew and continue for a
while, there would, notwithstanding the concerns and the failures last time around, be some sort
of effort to put another floor under it because there’s going to be another point at which the
amount of potential losses are such as to provide more-direct risks to the banking system.
So, I think, as Bill was suggesting, it’s what lies behind both the market movements and
the policy responses and some of the policy uncertainty about the market movements that
suggests potential for longer-term problems. And, like Vice Chairman Dudley, I think we really
don’t know how this will play out. I think it’s almost certain that over the next several years,
China is going to have challenges, but whether those challenges translate into the somewhat
lower growth hypothesized by the Board staff or something a little more disruptive, we just don’t
know.

September 16–17, 2015

112 of 240

I want to spend the rest of my time on labor markets, and having made a joke about what
Narayana is doing, I’m going to proceed to do something not dissimilar, which is to try to give a
bit of perspective on how we’ve been assessing labor markets, not monetary policy as a whole.
There is a lot of talk within this room, by many of you outside this room, and by many other
people about how we are close to or at fill-in-the-blank: the natural rate, full employment,
maximum employment, whatever it may be.
And what I want to know is, how do people know this? I mean, it is tautological to say
that we’re closer to full employment, maximum employment, the natural rate, than we were at
the July meeting and the June meeting and the meetings before that because, during this period,
unemployment has been going down and job creation has been such that we’re creating more
jobs than the number of entrants into the labor market. Almost tautologically, we are closer. But
how much closer are we, and how do we know how much slack remains?
Conventionally, the way in which we collectively made judgments about labor market
tightness or getting to the natural rate or getting to the non-accelerating inflation rate of
unemployment was by looking at prices or, oftentimes, actually, more directly at wages, which
were thought to be a leading indicator of prices. Remember that the “I” in NAIRU stands for
inflation, and that was where we and other analysts were trying to make that connection.
Now, I didn’t count, but six or seven of you referred to wage pressures being reported
from your Districts. I have to say, a number of presidents have been reporting wage pressures
from their Districts for some years now, and I take it to be the case that the number of you now
talking about it suggests that we may be closer to the point at which wage pressures start
translating into the data. But as of this moment, they really haven’t translated into the data as a
whole. That, of course, is a reminder of what people have also commented on, which is that the

September 16–17, 2015

113 of 240

Phillips curve broke down as a predictor of what would happen to inflation based on
unemployment well before the crisis and the recession, during a period in which labor markets
were changing significantly in what quite likely seems to have been a secular, rather than a
purely cyclical, fashion.
Now, people, including the people around this table and their staffs, have subsequently
made efforts to assess labor market tightness based on some set of past relationships, but to date I
don’t think these relationships really panned out as particularly robust. It’s not the fault of
anybody. I don’t think anybody knows what those relationships are now.
A few years ago around this table, I remember people were talking about how the
persistence of the rightward shift in the Beveridge curve showed that there was structural
unemployment and, therefore, the natural rate must be higher, and we were all of a sudden going
to begin seeing wage inflation. That didn’t happen, right? Remember there was a suggestion a
couple of years ago that since short-term unemployment rates were now back to pre-recession
levels, we were functionally getting close to the natural rate of unemployment. It was a good try,
but that one didn’t work out either.
President Williams has just suggested another approach—to use demographics and try to
project where the “natural rate” would lie. But I think if you disconnect the concept of the
natural rate of unemployment from at least wage inflation, if not price inflation, then the whole
concept actually gets more than a little bit squishy, because what is it that we’re talking about
now? Are we talking about “satisficing” unemployment? Do we think it’s good enough, it’s low
enough? I think we’re not actually any longer in the realm of doing analysis, but instead acting
on some intuition. Just because U-3 is toward the low end of where it has been over the course
of the past couple of decades doesn’t tell us much. Maybe it’s temporarily lower now because of

September 16–17, 2015

114 of 240

elevated part-time employment for economic reasons and the lower-than-trend labor
participation ratio. Maybe not.
For me, this dilemma—and I mean to project it as a dilemma rather than people being
wrong, because we’re all wrong, in a sense, because nobody actually has a convincing set of
explanations. But for me, it was crystallized in the staff briefing to the Board at yesterday’s
meeting when I noticed that the projected path of wages over the next couple of years was rising,
and the explanation given in the briefing was not principally because of labor market tightness,
but because productivity gains would be passed through and inflation would pull up wages. Of
course, I asked about the productivity gains issue because, I think my understanding is that
productivity gains matter for how much wages can go up over the medium-to-long term, but in
the short term, wages really should be about the supply and demand of labor rather than nearterm productivity increases. But even so, productivity gains clearly haven’t been passed through
in anything like one-to-one or even 50 percent fashion in recent years. They might be at some
point, but it’s a little hard to predict.
Then, what about inflation? Well, where did the inflation come from that was going to
pull up wages? It came from inflation expectations, and we’re back, as David Wilcox noted a
little earlier this afternoon, into a reliance on a mechanism that we don’t completely understand,
and what we really don’t understand is how those expectations change. They seem to have
worked, and I think the reason the staff has hit upon the approach they’ve taken is, they’ve found
some things that had been working reasonably well over the past five or six years. Assuming
anchored expectations and assuming that the now-low productivity gains will get passed through
seems to be working, but not because there’s a theory regarding why this is all working this way.

September 16–17, 2015

115 of 240

Instead, it just kind of seems to be working. And, in the absence of anything better, that’s what
we’re going to use.
As is almost always the case, I admired the staff’s straightforwardness in explaining what
they knew and what they didn’t know, and why they were doing what they did. But in the
absence of that theoretical understanding that comports with empirically observed facts, we’re
left not knowing whether we’re just in an extended period of reversion to a certain set of
correlations and causal relationships that existed for a long enough time to produce a bunch of
economic laws and curves that then find their way into people’s textbooks, or whether the
changes that have been noticed in labor markets over the past 15 to 20 years have now
cumulatively created a new set of correlations and causal relationships that are nontransitory and
that we don’t fully understand.
And, President Williams, the Board research paper that you referred to by Andrew and
David is another effort to get into that. I think you were slightly unfair because I think you were
referring to the aggregate data and they made a big point of trying to disaggregate the data. I
don’t think anybody thinks you can figure out much from the aggregate data. But even if we
abstract from that, they’re being very tentative, as I think everybody has to be right now.
So, this level of uncertainty, as I’ve said before, about even the theories on which we’re
operating, seems to me to argue for more than the normal amount of doubt about the reliability of
forecasting based on past observed relationships, particularly medium-term forecasting. And I
cannot resist this. I pulled out the September 2014 SEP. With the exceptions of Presidents
Harker and Kaplan—who weren’t here—everybody around this table was wrong, and we were
all wrong in the same direction on both inflation and unemployment for 2015. We all projected

September 16–17, 2015

116 of 240

unemployment as being higher than it actually is, and we all projected inflation as being higher
than it actually is. And that was just a year ago.
And I suspect, again, it’s because of the difficulty of reading what’s going on now, and to
me that suggests reliance on a more pragmatic policy approach, which is a little bit more—sorry,
Jim and Esther—a little bit more of a show-me approach. I actually want to see some hard data
before acquiring reasonable confidence in the direction in which we’re going and a little bit more
skepticism about projecting what will happen based on past observed relationships.
Let me end by saying that I honestly do not mean this to be an argument of “low rates
forever because of uncertainty.” We saw an example just this morning in the United Kingdom.
After a period of growth being noticeably above trend, their wage report was really quite strong.
We would love to be getting a 2.9 percent wage report like that, and it may be that the kind of
pressures that more of you are now hearing about anecdotally will translate into that in the nottoo-distant future, in which case I think we can all feel more confident about the fact that we
really are getting somewhat closer to a meaningful concept of the natural rate. But I do think
that the reliance on past correlations is something that can lead us astray in a period that has,
maybe only temporarily but certainly for a while, really disrupted a lot of those correlations.
Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Madam Chair. I used to succeed Jeremy Stein in these
events, as most of you will remember, and in many cases I would think, you know, I’d really
rather think about what Jeremy just said than read my remarks. And I sort of feel that way now.
Dan has raised some very thoughtful points, which will take me some time to digest.

September 16–17, 2015

117 of 240

Anyway, domestic developments since the July meeting have been mixed but positive on
balance. Abroad there are increased risks of a global slowdown that could create headwinds for
U.S. growth and inflation, and, in particular, we face tighter financial conditions here in the
United States in the form of a stronger dollar and lower equity prices, among other factors.
Governor Tarullo made this point, and I was going to make it tomorrow, but I’ll just echo
it today, which is that this really has nothing to do with a drop in the U.S. stock market. I have
been a stock market investor for a long time. I would say that a 7 percent stock market decline
after a very long period of expansion would mean just about literally nothing for the U.S.
economy. This is about a story of a plausible tail risk, or maybe more than a tail risk, of a global
economic slowdown. There is nothing about an equity put. And to the extent there is any
confusion, our communication should be clear publicly on that.
Data on the real economy have come in better than expected. Payroll growth has been
strong. Unemployment has declined faster than the staff forecast. First-half GDP was revised up
by 1 full percentage point since the previous meeting. Inflation has come in about as anticipated,
but it is likely to be held down at least for a while by the stronger dollar and the additional
decline in oil prices. Looking forward, the tighter economy should move inflation higher in the
medium term, but for now inflation is both below mandate and declining—a situation that
complicates the setting for our policy decision, as I will discuss tomorrow.
Wages and compensation have continued on their path of 2 percent growth or a little
better, disappointing hopes, including my own, that they would be moving to a higher plane.
However, with very low inflation and trend productivity, real unit labor costs have actually been
rising modestly—rising about as fast as they were before the crisis and as fast as they have for a
long time. And employers may be taking the view for now that the current wage increases fully

September 16–17, 2015

118 of 240

compensate workers for their real marginal product. Now, a real employer would never use
those words, but it’s not hard to imagine an employer thinking, Why would I be paying higher
wages in a world in which inflation is incredibly low, growth is slow, and productivity increases
are quite slow? I find that to be quite a plausible narrative, although I also believe that wages are
sending a signal about slack.
I think the Chair has been very careful not to make wages a litmus test for a rate increase,
and I would say, I think that’s the right place to be. I can imagine a world in which we had price
inflation that went up and wages that don’t respond, no matter how low unemployment goes. I
can imagine a different world in which wages go up more than price inflation does, and the longtime decline in labor share starts to reverse. I wouldn’t want to stand in the way of that if it was
to happen. I think we ought to focus on price inflation, which is, of course, our statutory
mandate.
Although my September SEP forecast is close to the Tealbook baseline, I expect the
unemployment rate to fall faster and inflation to move to 2 percent sooner than in the baseline.
In the Tealbook, growth for 2016 to 2018 continues at 2 percent, which is almost exactly the
average over the past four years. But there is a sharp slowdown in the number of payroll jobs,
from an average of 2.6 million over the past four years to an average of 1.5 million for the next
three years. I understand that to be a way of returning productivity growth closer to trend. But
this is a key assumption that has critical implications for policy.
For the four years ending in 2015, again, growth was 2.1 percent and unemployment
declined at 0.9 percent per year. For the next three years, growth is 2.0 percent and
unemployment declines 0.1 percent per year. Now, productivity may increase in the next three
years, and I certainly hope that it does. But, of course, predicting it in the short term is

September 16–17, 2015

119 of 240

treacherous, and it seems to me there is a reasonable probability that there won’t be such a sharp
break in the data. If there isn’t, then taking the growth forecast as given, the result would be
higher payroll growth, lower productivity growth, and a substantially faster decline in the rate of
unemployment, what might be called the “more of the same” scenario, and that is, in fact, my
forecast.
With growth much like that in the Tealbook, I have the unemployment rate declining to
4½ percent, or perhaps even below, in 2017, well below my estimate of the natural rate of
4.9 percent. By the way, I am number 2, as we are giving out our numbers [laughter]. And that
path is consistent with the idea that we ought to be prepared to let unemployment decline below
the natural rate to help lift trend inflation and support a more robust recovery from the ravages of
the global financial crisis.
While my point forecast is reasonably optimistic, as others have noted I think we need to
acknowledge the risk of a period of global economic weakness, which has clearly increased since
the previous meeting. Weakness and policy misfires in China have meant declining commodity
prices and financial turmoil, putting pressure on a range of emerging market economies, and
tightening financial conditions globally. In recent years, we have had frequent briefings focused
on the potentially significant ramifications for the U.S. economy of a slowdown or a crisis in the
emerging market economies, and there are two such alternative simulations in this cycle’s
Tealbook.
Although China faces significant structural difficulties and very challenging longer-term
transition issues, I see it as unlikely that there will be a near-term crisis. But China’s growth is
slowing, and that is having sizable effects on the rest of emerging Asia and other emerging
market commodity producers. The usually reliable hand of China’s technocrats has seemed

September 16–17, 2015

120 of 240

much less sure of late. As capital flows from emerging market economies have increased
recently and some key countries like Brazil and Russia are already in precarious economic
situations, the risk of a broader crisis has clearly risen.
I think the Committee has gone to extraordinary lengths to be both patient and transparent
about the path of policy. The rest of the world has had plenty of warning and time to get ready
for U.S. tightening. Still, tightening into an actual emerging markets crisis scenario is something
else again. And although I see that as unlikely, I am at least inclined to pause to allow this risk
to evolve. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Brainard.
MS. BRAINARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. As I always do, I benefit from hearing
from every member of the Committee, save for the Chair, which I appreciate, and it helps inform
my perspective.
Recent developments reinforce, perhaps, or intensify the crosscurrents that we have seen
in the economy for some time, and, I think, in a material way that affects current and expected
future progress toward our objectives. On the one hand, the underlying momentum on domestic
real activity has strengthened, and we have seen some nice progress on the employment leg of
the mandate. On the other hand, the foreign economic outlook, I think, has again contributed
materially to financial tightening and poses downside risks to the outlook. We see no indication
of an acceleration in either wages or prices, and inflation remains stubbornly below our target.
Let me just spend a moment on each of these. As you all have noted, the labor market
has continued to improve nicely. The three-month moving average of payroll employment
growth was 220,000 in August, similar to average gains so far this year, and August payrolls are
likely to be revised up. In addition, there continues to be improvement, on balance, along the

September 16–17, 2015

121 of 240

three main margins of labor market slack. Despite this, the ongoing diminution of slack has yet
to result in any noticeable acceleration in our three broad measures of wages.
Average hourly earnings through August as well as compensation per hour and the
employment cost index through the second quarter all suggest that nominal wage growth is only
in the 2 to 2¼ percent range, which is little different than the pace we have seen over the past
several years. The absence of such acceleration suggests that resources still are not fully utilized,
and I think other data send a similar signal. Participation for prime-age adults remains well
below pre-recession levels and below what pre-crisis trends in participation for this group would
suggest. The share of employees working part time for economic reasons remains well above
longer-run norms, even allowing for some move-up in the equilibrium level in recent years. As
others have pointed out, although it is difficult to know with any precision what the natural rate
is, the absence in recent quarters of any upward movement in nominal wage growth and price
inflation has to be seen as some indication that the natural rate is below the current level. And I
think it’s interesting to note that since our submissions in June, it appears that nine Committee
members—and I’m just staring at the dots—have moved their point estimates for the natural rate
below 5 percent.
More broadly, domestic activity has been proceeding at a reassuring pace on most
dimensions, suggesting demand is solid. Although inventory investment in the second quarter
looks elevated, suggesting a negative contribution in the second half of the year, other
components of business investment look better than they did in July. In particular, nonresidential
building investment rose strongly in the second quarter, offsetting the weakness that we had seen
in drilling investment, and indicators of equipment investment have also turned up of late.

September 16–17, 2015

122 of 240

Strong auto sales and growth in other components of retail sales suggest consumer
spending is rising at a welcome pace moving into the second half. Continued job growth and
lower gas prices should continue to support this. And the latest data on building permits and
starts continue to paint a picture of gradual recovery in housing.
Overall, despite an anemic contribution from government spending, domestic demand is
advancing. Domestic final sales rose 2½ percent in the first half of 2015, and the Tealbook
expects similar growth in the second half. By contrast, manufacturing exports are on the soft
side, and that brings me to the crosscurrents.
Looking back over the past year, it is very clear that foreign economic conditions are
weighing on real activity and inflation as well as on financial conditions in the United States. At
the end of last year, persistently weak aggregate demand in the euro zone and in Japan, as well as
the policy response, were kind of the main story. More recently, weakness in foreign demand
has really focused on emerging market economies. Growing recognition of this weakness has
pushed the dollar up further, so after the 12 percent we saw earlier, we now have an additional
movement, and the dollar now lies 15 percent above its level last summer.
China, in particular, has been the focus of an intermeeting reassessment of global growth
prospects. I think China’s contribution really has to be seen in the broader context of spillovers
both in real activity and the financial sector, not directly through trade channels to the United
States but as they reverberate around the global economy. In particular, China has been at the
center, really, of a commodity supercycle that has now endured for over a decade and has been a
very important source of demand for many commodity exporters and is also very closely
connected to many of the other neighboring economies in the region.

September 16–17, 2015

123 of 240

Most immediately, the buildup of past property and more recent stock market bubbles,
together with a rapid run-up in business debt levels and growing perceptions that Chinese
policymakers are not managing policy or communications as deftly as previously anticipated,
have raised concerns, I think, about broader global growth prospects and potential downside
risks. And those risks are compounded and perhaps amplified by well-known weakness in the
quality of macroeconomic data that, I think, risks perpetuating the fog around the growth
trajectory.
Looking forward, in terms of the U.S. economy, I, like several other members of the
Committee, really don’t see the intermeeting developments as narrow equity market corrections
centered on the United States. I really see it as a broader reassessment of global growth
prospects and questions about China’s trajectory. I think there is a nontrivial probability that we
will see, sometime in the next few quarters, an additional adjustment of China’s exchange rate
regime. I can’t tell you when or by how much, but it does seem like they are in the midst of an
adjustment process, and that in turn is likely to reverberate, particularly because many other
foreign economies facing weak internal demand—including in East Asia, the euro zone, and
Japan—will have to adjust their policies accordingly. The direct and indirect effects of that
further adjustment will remain a material risk to our own outlook.
Moreover, my sense is that the effects of dollar appreciation, even the dollar appreciation
we have seen so far, are likely to be quite persistent, and those effects, if the dollar appreciates
further, are likely to lead to additional restraint both on real activity and on U.S. inflation.
That comes against a backdrop in which U.S. core PCE inflation remains quite subdued.
The underlying trend, as many have noted, remains between maybe 1¼ to 1½ percent, similar to
the pace that we have seen in the past couple of years and noticeably below our target. If you

September 16–17, 2015

124 of 240

look at the 12-month change in core PCE prices, or even if you look at the change in the Dallas
Fed trimmed mean, we are still substantially below our target and have not made any progress.
And although survey expectations provide some reassurance, the risks seem tilted to the
downside, as inflation compensation has moved back to the historically low levels reached at the
beginning of the year.
For all those reasons, I do see considerable value to waiting, and that value outweighs the
cost. But because we will have an opportunity to return to this tomorrow, I’d be particularly
interested to hear from those who put the start of policy normalization in the third quarter of this
year about the potential risks of waiting, because I think that would be helpful in informing my
own policy outlook. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you, and thanks to everyone for a very interesting round of
comments and, I think, some very interesting observations on the current situation. I thought I
would wrap things up, if you wouldn’t mind, by giving a summary of my own assessment of the
incoming data and their implications for the outlook.
Starting with the labor market, as almost all of you noted, we’ve seen continued solid
gains in monthly payrolls. And at 5.1 percent, the unemployment rate stands just a touch above
the median of our estimates of its longer-run normal level. Broader measures of labor utilization
like U-6 also have moved down as the number of discouraged workers continued to decline, and
involuntary part-time employment edged down further.
Consistent with the views I heard expressed around the table, I think these developments
confirm that labor market conditions have improved considerably since earlier in the year. For
me, they’re also consistent with the conditions that, at the July meeting, I said in my own view
could warrant raising the funds rate in September.

September 16–17, 2015

125 of 240

But back in July, I also indicated that stronger readings on wages would strengthen the
case for liftoff, and instead, exactly the opposite has occurred. And so, for me, wage
developments weaken the case. At the time, the available data seemed to suggest that wages
were finally beginning to respond to diminishing slack. Since then, new readings on the ECI,
hourly earnings, and compensation per hour all indicate that we’re still stuck at wage increases in
the vicinity of 2 percent, a very subdued pace if the economy really is near full employment.
I don’t want to make too much of the news. The relationship between nominal wage
growth and slack is far from tight, and other factors you’ve mentioned around the table, such as
weak productivity growth and global competition, may explain why wage gains remain anemic.
Still, firms continue to attract and retain workers without raising wages, and even though we’ve
seen an impressive increase in job openings, the quits rate has flattened out, and that is despite all
the reports we hear about how difficult firms find it to fill some jobs. On the margin, the
disappointing wage data have reinforced my sense that we are still a ways from full employment,
even if the economy is very close to the longer-run normal rate of unemployment.
The current rate of involuntary part-time employment remains more than 1 percentage
point above its pre-recession level, and the labor force participation rate remains below the
staff’s estimate of its trend. Moreover, with the public dissatisfaction with the state of the labor
market so widespread, I suspect that the current level of the trend participation rate is actually
higher than the staff’s estimate, although I’m fairly confident in the trend’s downward slope,
which I think can be estimated more reliably.
Eliminating slack along these additional dimensions may well necessitate a temporary
decline in the unemployment rate below its longer-run normal level. For example, pulling
discouraged workers back into the labor force may require a period of especially plentiful

September 16–17, 2015

126 of 240

employment opportunities and strong hiring. Similarly, firms may be unwilling to restructure
their operations to use more full-time workers until they encounter greater difficulty filling parttime positions.
Beyond these dynamics, which effectively imply that the natural rate of unemployment is
likely to run below its longer-run value for a time, a temporary undershooting of the longer-run
level of unemployment could have other advantages, including speeding the return of inflation to
2 percent and even possibly reversing some of the adverse supply-side effects of recent years.
Turning to growth, like most of you, I anticipate that labor market conditions will
improve somewhat further over the rest of this year and into 2016, helped by continued moderate
growth in real GDP. My forecast is not too different from the one I had back in June. The data
on spending and production received since then, in fact, have been somewhat stronger than I
expected and—I think this coincides with what I heard around the table—stronger than what
many of you expected. Most prominently, real GDP growth in the first half of the year has been
revised up by more than 1 percentage point to 2¼ percent. Readings on consumer spending and
residential construction into this summer have been solid, while the remarkable contraction in
drilling activity appears to have bottomed out.
Nonetheless, I would not describe overall growth as robust. First, the strong growth in
real GDP in the second quarter was most likely a payback for transitory weakness in the first.
And, second, overall growth is being held back by an appreciable and continuing drag generated
by the behavior of net exports. After factoring in the recent monthly trade data and the expected
restraint from dollar appreciation and weak foreign growth, the staff estimates that real GDP is
likely to expand at an annual rate of only 2 percent in the second half of the year and in 2016.

September 16–17, 2015

127 of 240

One implication of the incoming data and the near-term outlook is that the economy’s
equilibrium real interest rate remains low and shows no obvious signs of rising this year. That’s
an inference that follows directly from the combination of continued moderate growth and a real
funds rate that remains well below zero. This stasis would seem to conflict with the story told by
our medium-term forecasts, which imply a significant increase in the equilibrium real rate over
the next few years as various headwinds restraining economic activity continue to fade.
The explanation, of course, is that one headwind—namely, exchange rate appreciation
and weak foreign growth—has strengthened over the past year. This restraint has increased
further since our previous meeting with the recent appreciation of the dollar, especially as it has
been accompanied by an appreciable fall in stock prices and a modest rise in risk spreads on
corporate bonds.
FRB/US model simulations suggest that these intermeeting financial and international
developments, if they persist, would have demand effects similar to those generated by a 50 basis
point hike in the federal funds rate. Whatever their implications for the modal outlook, recent
movements in the dollar and other financial factors, coupled with increased concerns about the
prospects for growth in China and the emerging market economies, certainly suggest that the
downside risks to the U.S. economy have increased to some degree, and several of you have
noted the same thing.
Turning to inflation, information received since our previous meeting, specifically lower
oil prices and a higher dollar, suggests that the transitory factors currently holding down inflation
are likely to fade a bit more slowly than I previously judged. For example, the Tealbook now
shows overall PCE inflation on a four-quarter basis running at only 1 percent through the first
three quarters of next year. That’s down ¼ percent from the July Tealbook. Nonetheless, I still

September 16–17, 2015

128 of 240

expect that inflation will gradually return to 2 percent, provided—and this is key—that the labor
market completes the return to full employment and long-run inflation expectations remain well
anchored at 2 percent.
As I mentioned a moment ago, I anticipate that the labor market will continue to improve
in coming quarters and, barring some adverse shock to the economy, I expect that the economy is
likely to stay in the general vicinity of full employment over the medium term, assuming
appropriate adjustments to monetary policy over time. That said, we can’t say with certainty
what those adjustments will be, as we do not know how foreign economic conditions will evolve,
how financial conditions will develop, or how rapidly the remaining domestic headwinds will
fade, as recent events amply illustrate. But I’m cautiously optimistic that this condition for
meeting our inflation objective will be met.
I also judge long-run inflation expectations to be reasonably well anchored and at a level
consistent with the gradual return to 2 percent inflation. That said, the decline in inflation
compensation over the past year concerns me somewhat, even if staff analysis suggests that it’s
primarily related to shifts in risk and liquidity premiums. I said at our previous meeting that
from my standpoint, a renewed decline in inflation compensation would give me pause, and, in
fact, it has declined quite substantially. All in all, my confidence that inflation will gradually
return to 2 percent over the medium term has not increased during the intermeeting period.
Let me stop there. I look forward to hearing your views during the policy go-round. I
suggest that we break now and have dinner, but I would suggest that we begin early. There is a
press conference tomorrow. I want to give everybody adequate time for what’s bound to be an
interesting policy discussion. I would like to propose that we start off tomorrow morning at
8:30, and Thomas will then begin his briefing.

September 16–17, 2015

129 of 240

[Meeting recessed]

September 16–17, 2015

130 of 240

September 17 Session
CHAIR YELLEN. Good morning, everybody. I think we’re ready to begin our policy
go-round. Let me call on Thomas to brief us on the monetary policy alternatives.
MR. LAUBACH. 6 Thank you, Madam Chair. I will be referring to the handout
labeled “Material for Briefing on Monetary Policy Alternatives.”
As has been the case at each meeting since June, the key issues for your decision
today are whether or not the criteria for beginning policy normalization have been
met and, in either case, how to communicate in an effective way the reasons for the
decision and the Committee’s thinking about the likely response of policy to
economic developments going forward.
Since you submitted economic projections in June, the incoming information on
economic activity and the labor market has been stronger than you anticipated, and
the unemployment rate is now lower than you expected—developments that clearly
mark further progress on the Committee’s labor market criterion for liftoff. Inflation
has continued to run below the Committee’s 2 percent objective, held down
importantly by declines in energy prices and prices of non-energy imports. In
addition, as discussed earlier, global economic and financial market developments
over the intermeeting period have led to a tightening of financial conditions and could
pose downside risks to economic activity while putting further downward pressure on
inflation in the near term.
As summarized on exhibit 1, alternatives A, B, and C provide policy options that
reflect differing assessments of the potential effects of recent economic and financial
developments on the outlook. Starting with alternative B, paragraph 1 states that
“economic activity is expanding at a moderate pace”—in line with the Committee’s
previously stated expectations—and indicates that, apart from the continued softness
in net exports, the expansion has been somewhat more broadly based than earlier in
the year. The paragraph also presents a more confident assessment of the diminution
of economic slack than in previous statements, suggesting that, in the Committee’s
view, labor market conditions are quite close to meeting the criterion for liftoff. In
contrast, it casts recent inflation developments less favorably, suggesting that the
effects of the declines in energy prices are not yet behind us and recognizing that
market-based measures of inflation compensation have moved lower.
Paragraph 2 continues to describe an outlook in which economic activity will
expand at a moderate rate and labor market indicators will move toward mandateconsistent levels. In describing the risks to the outlook, alternative B acknowledges
that developments abroad “may restrain [domestic] economic activity somewhat”—a
concern that many of you cited in your SEP comments on the outlook. However,
paragraph 2 indicates that, while the Committee is monitoring developments abroad,
6

The materials used by Mr. Laubach are appended to this transcript (appendix 7).

September 16–17, 2015

131 of 240

those developments have not, at this point, tilted the balance of risks to the outlook
for economic activity and the labor market appreciably to the downside. Regarding
the outlook for inflation, alternative B indicates that recent global developments “are
likely to put further downward pressure on inflation in the near term.” This
assessment seems consistent with the fact that many of you have lowered your
projections for inflation over the near term as well as with the increase in the number
of you who see the risks to inflation to be to the downside. With this assessment of
the outlook for inflation, and the decision to leave the target range for the federal
funds rate unchanged, the Committee would convey that it is not yet reasonably
confident about its expectation that inflation will move back to 2 percent over the
medium term.
As summarized in the middle panel, the Committee’s characterization of the
recent information on economic activity and the labor market in alternative A would
be the same as in alternative B. Nonetheless, its description of recent inflation
developments would show greater concern, and it would indicate that recent global
developments have shifted the risks to the outlook for economic activity to the
downside and will impose some additional restraint on inflation. As a result, the
Committee would signal that it does not expect to begin normalizing policy for some
time. Moreover, alternative A states that if the Committee did not “soon” see
incoming information indicating “that inflation is beginning to move back toward
2 percent,” the Committee would provide additional accommodation to achieve that
goal within one to two years.
As indicated in the lower panel, alternative C would begin normalizing the level
of the federal funds rate. In summarizing the economic background for such a
decision, paragraph 1 offers the perspective that economic growth has been moderate,
on average, so far this year, and, after citing some key factors showing further
improvement in the labor market, it states more definitively that resource slack has
diminished. Paragraph 2 provides further support for the assessment that labor
market conditions have met the criterion for liftoff by indicating that labor market
indicators are “approaching” mandate-consistent levels. In evaluating the risks to this
outlook, the Committee would acknowledge the need to monitor developments
abroad but would not suggest that those developments are likely to be consequential
for the United States, or that they have altered the Committee’s assessment of risks to
the outlook.
In alternative C, the Committee would also state that, although inflation is
anticipated to remain low over the near term, policymakers have gained sufficient
confidence that inflation will move back to 2 percent over the medium run to begin to
remove policy accommodation. In paragraph 2, the Committee would state its
assessment that the transitory factors holding down inflation “will dissipate,” and that
the key determinants of the inflation outlook—continuing improvement in the labor
market and stable longer-term expectations—are in place.
I should note that even if you view the policy choice in alternative C to be
premature in the present circumstances, you may want to comment on whether

September 16–17, 2015

132 of 240

paragraph 4 should include the bracketed “balanced approach” language that you
discussed at the July meeting. Beth and Chris already highlighted in their briefing the
language options regarding reinvestment policy.
Your second exhibit reviews market and participants’ monetary policy
expectations and some factors likely to shape the market reaction to statements like in
the drafts for alternative B or C. As shown in the top-left panel, market participants’
assessment of the probability of a September liftoff, as derived from federal funds
futures, varied significantly over the intermeeting period, as Simon already
mentioned. The probability appeared to respond to the turbulence in global financial
markets, policymaker communications, and incoming economic data. The probability
distribution of the timing of liftoff derived from the responses to the Desk’s latest
Survey of Primary Dealers—shown to the right—suggests that the perceived odds of
policy firming at this meeting are slightly less than 30 percent. As shown by the table
in the middle-left panel, although federal funds futures imply notably lower perceived
odds of an imminent rate hike than was the case a day before the 1994 and 2004
tightening moves, they still indicate significantly higher odds than were attached to
liftoff right before the June meeting.
The measures of expectations also signal a considerable degree of uncertainty
about the timing of liftoff. Market participants, on average, place fairly similar odds
on liftoff this week, later this year, and next year, as indicated by the fairly uniform
distribution of the blue bars in the upper-right panel across the September, December,
and later meetings. This could, in principle, reflect disagreement among survey
respondents who individually are quite certain in their views. However, even among
respondents who selected September as the most likely date of liftoff, the median
probability attached to a September liftoff was only about 50 percent. This fact
highlights that, indeed, many of them do not seem to hold strong convictions about
any one given date. Moreover, as shown in the middle-right panel, views are
considerably dispersed. As the distribution of the dots in the leftmost column shows,
respondents to the Desk’s surveys of primary dealers and market participants report
probabilities for a rate increase at this meeting that range from zero to 60 percent, and
the degree of dispersion is similarly high for the December and March meetings.
In sum, the current state of market expectations seems consistent with your
communications that have for some time emphasized data dependence and, in light of
the mixed signals coming from the labor market and inflation, created optionality for
when to move. At the same time, as discussed in the bottom-left panel, whether or
not the FOMC decides to raise the target federal funds rate, there could be a revision
in investors’ policy expectations that may result in a noticeable market reaction—and
one that is hard to predict. A key point, however, is that the overall market response
will be shaped not only by the decision about whether to lift off, but also by the
Committee’s communications, including the language in the statement, its economic
projections, and the SEP dots. The dots, in particular, indicate that your outlook has
not changed materially. The path of the federal funds rate based on the median
projection in the SEP, shown in the bottom-right panel, not only remains fairly
shallow, but also has shifted down a bit. Such a shallow path might diminish the risk

September 16–17, 2015

133 of 240

of an outsized market reaction to a statement like alternative C because it conveys the
Committee’s intentions to continue to provide a high degree of accommodation for
some time. Similarly, as your projections of the federal funds rate continue to
indicate that many of you see policy normalization likely to begin later this year, a
draft statement like alternative B might be read as clearly keeping interest rate
increases later in the year on the table and need not lead to a significant change in the
expected path of policy.
Having said so, as noted back in the bottom-left panel, there are certainly some
risk factors that might trigger an outsized response, especially when you decide to
first raise the target range. The fact that longer-term Treasury term premiums are on
the low end of their historical range raises the possibility that, after years of the
federal funds rate at its effective lower bound, the first rate hike may trigger an abrupt
rise in term premiums toward more typical levels, as witnessed during the taper
tantrum. In addition, technical factors and market dynamics could play an important
role in amplifying movements in interest rates, as witnessed during the taper tantrum.
If investors were to unwind positions abruptly in response to a monetary policy
surprise, this could amplify interest rate movements.
Thank you, Madam Chair. That completes my prepared remarks, and I’ll be
happy to take questions.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Does anyone have questions for Thomas? President
Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. I have one quick question on the middle-left panel of exhibit 2,
“Probability of Tightening the Day before the FOMC Meeting.” My memory of the 1994
tightening cycle was, not only was it a little bit of a surprise when we started, but also that the
pace was somewhat surprising. As a result, the 10-year rate went up quite abruptly. How do you
think about not only the start of tightening, but also the pace of tightening once we begin?
MR. LAUBACH. In fact, there is, as you may have noticed, a box in Tealbook B that
looks in greater detail at some of these events. It’s interesting that, actually, the pace of
tightening expected over the first six months in 1994 wasn’t all that rapid, and, as you point out,
there was then a substantial surprise over the course of the year. So that clearly could lead to
stronger market responses subsequently over time. Here, in my exhibit, I try to focus essentially
on the liftoff event, not on, say, the six months or a year following that event.

September 16–17, 2015

134 of 240

Now, while I certainly don’t want to downplay potential financial stability challenges for
some institutions if such a scenario came to pass, I think it is still noteworthy that that, of course,
happened basically against the backdrop of an economic situation that was more favorable than
expected. So that should be a positive, all else being equal.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Are there other questions? President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. Simon, could you give us any indication—do
market commentators or the people you talk to provide any information about how the SEP
funds rate numbers might inform their assessments of the pace of liftoff or anything like that?
MR. POTTER. We added a new question to get numbers back on the SEP medians,
because you’re now presenting the medians. In terms of the dot plot, I’d say that the medians we
got back from the responses look pretty close to what will be published today. They’re basically
expecting about 25 basis points to be knocked off the medians, and that’s what I think the SEP
shows. Could you just repeat the second part of your question?
MR. EVANS. Will the dispersion of the dots or anything about the distribution of what
we give them and how they—
MR. POTTER. I think they’ll be focused on how many participants have moved liftoff to
2016. I’d say that, having read some of the commentary, the notion of four participants putting
liftoff in 2016 is probably about what market participants expected—I know this sounds a little
bit strange because I’m talking about your choices here. There will be focus on dots 4 to 7, and
that’s where a lot of people look for a median, as opposed to taking the median of all 17
responses. My answer was probably a little bit confusing.
MR. EVANS. No, that’s helpful. We’ve said things like that before, too. Thank you.

September 16–17, 2015

135 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I have a question. Conditional on not moving today,
where do you think the probability mass for today would shift, based on how B is currently
written and the SEP dots? This question is for either Thomas or Simon.
MR. LAUBACH. The one thing that struck me when reading the dealers’ responses was,
I did not find a lot of evidence for the, as it has come to be called, “one or none” view—namely,
that not moving in September would immediately lead dealers to assume that, therefore, there is
not going to be any move over the remainder of this year. So I didn’t find in the write-ups
anything that pointed in that direction.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Do you think the mass would move to December so that
December would go up a lot, or would it be spread across—
MR. POTTER. You’re seeing a little bit more weight on the next meeting. Part of that
will depend on how they assess whether there has to be a scheduled press conference for a move
at the October meeting. What I think Thomas was saying is, we definitely expect mass to go to
December. We’re unsure, and it might depend on the press conference, exactly where it goes
relative to October. And then some mass will go into next year, and that’s basically because
stuff can happen over the next few months. There are a lot of things that can happen regarding
the debt limit that will push people to move further out, I think.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. I would guess that what will happen to the market’s views depends very
heavily on what is said in the press conference and what guidance we give for the coming
months. So I’m not sure we get a very good guess independent of that.

September 16–17, 2015

136 of 240

MR. POTTER. Yes, but there’s also one market commentary I saw, which indicated that,
if everyone was given the transcript, the statement, the SEP, and the transcript of the press
conference in advance, most people could still not guess what the market reaction would be.
[Laughter] It’s useful to be humble when trying to predict what might happen, whichever
outcome is chosen.
CHAIR YELLEN. Does anyone have other questions for Thomas? Okay. Seeing none,
with your indulgence, I would like to start off today’s policy go-round by recommending to the
Committee that we adopt alternative B and keep the federal funds rate target range unchanged.
Let me explain the basis for this recommendation.
I recognize that a good case can be made for moving today. The data that we’ve received
since our July meeting on the labor market and domestic spending have been strong, arguably
stronger than we expected. Domestic spending appears to be on a solid course, and the labor
market has continued to improve, with the unemployment rate declining into the central tendency
of the longer-run normal rate of unemployment.
There may well be enough domestic momentum to overcome the slightly greater-thananticipated drag due to the behavior of the external sector and the tightening of financial
conditions. Inflation is way below our target, but there’s no news there. We expected that to be
the case. A significant portion of that shortfall is due to transitory factors, particularly oil prices
and the dollar. Although core inflation, even abstracting from the depressing effect of import
prices, is running below our objective, with the labor market continuing to improve and survey
measures of inflation expectations remaining stable, we should eventually see upward pressure
on inflation, returning it to target. There are lags in the effect of policy, so we need to move in a
timely fashion to avoid overshooting our 2 percent objective.

September 16–17, 2015

137 of 240

In terms of communications, we’ve prepared the markets for the beginning of
normalization later this year. We’ve consistently argued that the significance of a decision to
make a small upward adjustment in the funds rate range should not be overblown. What matters
is the path of the funds rate, and we’ve said that we see good reasons why that path is likely to be
shallow.
Conceivably, raising the target range for the funds rate might even boost the confidence
of households and businesses, spurring rather than retarding domestic spending, and perhaps the
incessant market focus on the timing of liftoff has itself become a source of uncertainty that’s
roiling markets and raising volatility. Perhaps our credibility is at stake if we don’t get on with
the job. We may seem as though we’re overreacting to market volatility. I see this as the case
for raising rates.
I also see a case for not raising rates today, however. And, in the final analysis, I think
that case is stronger. Perhaps most important, my judgment that we should stay on hold reflects
my assessment of the balance of risks. In particular, should it turn out that we’ve waited a bit too
long to raise rates, thereby raising the odds that inflation overshoots our 2 percent inflation
target, or that we’re forced to move rates up less gradually than we’d prefer—I see those risks as
less severe than the risks of moving too soon.
I do not want to repeat the experience of other central banks that have tried to free
themselves of the zero bound prematurely and later had to reverse course, allowing inflation to
move lower during the process. I’m also concerned about what we will communicate to markets
and the public about our reaction function and our likely future behavior if we move today, at a
time when concerns about the global outlook have created uncertainties that have been reflected
in the recent market turmoil and after financial conditions have already tightened notably.

September 16–17, 2015

138 of 240

We’d be moving when additional deflationary pressure from further dollar appreciation
and lower oil prices is working to delay at least slightly our likely return to our inflation target
and when it’s hard to find evidence of any fear whatsoever in the marketplace of a 1970s-like
inflationary spiral or any sense that the FOMC is “behind the curve.” I’m concerned that we will
appear to be hell-bent on raising rates, with the consequence that the dollar might rise
significantly and market expectations about the likely future policy path could also shift up
substantially. The fact that markets attach only around 30 percent odds to a move today
heightens this concern.
We set out two criteria for raising rates—that we see some further improvement in the
labor market, and that we have reasonable confidence that inflation will move back to our
2 percent target over the medium term. As I said during the economic go-round, we clearly have
seen some further improvement in the labor market. But as I also noted yesterday, incoming data
pertaining to the inflation outlook have not, on balance, improved my confidence that inflation
will move up to our target over the next few years. The dollar has strengthened yet further
during the intermeeting period. Oil prices have moved yet lower. And, importantly, those initial
indications of an acceleration in wages we thought we had seen have disappeared entirely from
all of the main national wage and compensation measures.
I’ve gone out of my way to insist that wage acceleration not be viewed as a litmus test for
raising the funds rate. But wage trends are not irrelevant to assessing the remaining degree of
slack in the labor market, and the absence of any broad-based wage pressures adds to the case
that there remains significant labor market slack. In effect, I see the short-run natural rate of
unemployment as considerably lower than my estimate of the longer-run normal unemployment
rate. This means that there is more scope for improvement in the labor market before inflation

September 16–17, 2015

139 of 240

pressures emerge, and I see no penalty in allowing the unemployment rate to drift below its
estimated longer-run normal value if such an outcome has no adverse implications for inflation.
I’d ask you to recall simulations in past Tealbooks of an optimal control path that
attaches no weight to unemployment outcomes—it weights only inflation outcomes. Those
simulations of an optimal control path tell us that we should be acting more aggressively,
pushing unemployment down well below its longer-run normal level. And the benefit would be
that we would promote a more rapid return of inflation to 2 percent. Indeed, this is a reason why
I think it makes sense to continue setting as a condition for a first increase in the federal funds
rate that we see some further improvement in the labor market.
Lastly, I’d note that inflation breakevens have moved yet lower, significantly lower.
Despite all of the familiar reasons, this isn’t a definitive indication that inflation expectations
have moved down, but it’s certainly disquieting. While the decline in inflation compensation
may not reflect any change in the modal outlook for inflation, I think it plausible that at least a
portion of the decline reflects increasing downside risks to inflation. After all, market
participants are increasingly concerned about the global outlook. They appear to perceive the
equilibrium real rate as quite low. And, with the funds rate at the zero bound and inflation
already well below our target, they likely worry that the Fed will have very little ammunition to
respond to negative shocks. This means that inflation could easily fall short of the target in
coming years.
I share these concerns, and that’s an important reason, I believe, that the risks around our
projection that inflation will return to 2 percent are unbalanced to the downside. Of course, the
tighter the labor market becomes, the more balanced the risks also become.

September 16–17, 2015

140 of 240

There are additional reasons to hold off raising rates today. They pertain to the global
outlook and the fact that overall financial conditions have tightened materially in recent weeks.
As we discussed yesterday, risks to the global outlook have certainly increased. The continuing
decline in commodity prices is restraining growth in a number of countries that are commodity
exporters. Two of our most important trading partners, Mexico and Canada, have been
significantly affected. The prospects, as we discussed, for Chinese growth are highly uncertain,
with rising downside risks. Net exports placed a considerable drag on U.S. growth during the
first half of the year, and we could see a yet greater effect. In addition, I’m concerned that we
could see significant further appreciation of the dollar. Thus, I believe it would be prudent to
have some additional information to inform our evaluation of the global outlook before raising
rates.
Finally, we have seen a material tightening in financial conditions in recent weeks, with
U.S. equity prices down and the value of the broad dollar and risk spreads higher. We must
always be careful not to allow monetary policy to respond to volatility in the markets. But the
shifts we have seen represent a material tightening in overall financial conditions. Not
surprisingly, recent indicators of consumer confidence have retreated somewhat. It’s
conceivable that markets will rebound in the coming weeks and the perceived risks to the global
outlook may subside. If so, a failure to move today will not leave us far behind the curve, if at
all.
So my recommendation to the Committee is that we not raise rates today, and that we
explain that decision by highlighting that global economic and financial developments have
imparted some restraint to the economic outlook and have placed further transitory downward
pressure on inflation. We would explain that we have seen continued improvement in the labor

September 16–17, 2015

141 of 240

market and gained greater confidence about the outlook for domestic spending. The U.S.
economy in that important sense is doing well, but we want to wait for some additional evidence,
which could include further improvement in the labor market, to bolster our confidence that
inflation will rise to 2 percent in the medium term.
We would also emphasize that, despite these recent developments, we have not
fundamentally altered our outlook, and that an initial increase in the federal funds rate is a real
possibility later this year and what most participants still expect. I believe communications
along these lines would be entirely consistent with the criteria we’ve established for an initial
hike in the funds rate and with sensible risk-management considerations.
Let me stop there, and we’ll continue our go-round. We’ll start with President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I think now’s the time to raise the federal
funds rate target. I’ve felt this way for some time, as you all know, but I haven’t been hell-bent
on dissenting. I’ll be listening to this morning’s discussion with great interest, but, at this point,
my sense is that it’s going to be difficult to persuade me to support further delay.
Our decisions about policy are inevitably decisions about the appropriate level of the
short-term real interest rate. There are a number of approaches to assessing the appropriate real
rate, but I’ll start with consumption growth. Basic economic theory tells us that a sustained
increase in consumption growth should be associated with higher real interest rates. Granted,
this connection isn’t always tight in the data, but the underlying reasoning strongly suggests that
a negative 1.2 percent real interest rate is unlikely to be appropriate for an economy with
persistent consumption growth at the rate we’ve been seeing.
Now, admittedly, there are good arguments for why today’s short-term real interest rate
should be lower than historical norms, and these include the global savings glut, an increase in

September 16–17, 2015

142 of 240

demand for safe assets in the wake of this financial crisis, and ongoing caution on the part of
American households. Indeed, a range of attempts at quantification yield measures of the natural
real interest rate that are relatively low by historical standards, yet all of these estimates are
markedly higher than the actual current level of the real federal funds rate of negative 1.2 percent
as reported in the Tealbook.
The Laubach-Williams estimate that we’ve been discussing in the past couple of
meetings is approximately zero right now—minus 0.1 percent. Economists at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond have developed an alternative approach to the Laubach-Williams
exercise, one that’s somewhat more agnostic about identifying assumptions and yields an
estimate of 0.72 percent. But the error bands encompass the Laubach-Williams figure, so it’s a
very similar estimate.
The Tealbook’s estimate of what they call the longer-run funds rate is 1.25 percent, and
this is what’s used in the Taylor rule implementations that they report on in Tealbook B. The
Tealbook’s FRB/US-model-based estimate of what they call the equilibrium real funds rate is
now positive 0.47 percent. Taking any one of these measures as a guide, short-term real interest
rates are too low now. Taken together, I think they argue strongly for a rate increase.
A related and complementary approach to assessing interest rate policy is to compare
current interest rate settings with patterns of behavior that have been successful for us in the past.
The standard approach to summarizing our past behavior is through algebraic policy rule
formulas, such as the various versions of the Taylor rule. Tealbook B, as I said, lists the
predictions of several of these, and all but one now support raising the nominal funds rate. The
one that does not support an increase in rates is the first-difference rule, which, in a sense, is

September 16–17, 2015

143 of 240

predicated on the assumption that a zero federal funds rate was appropriate last quarter, an
assumption that is by no means obvious.
The intercept in a Taylor rule is often identified with the natural rate of interest, and some
argue that if the natural rate has declined, we should make a corresponding downward
adjustment to the prescriptions of those rules. I point out, however, that the Tealbook already
uses a lower natural interest rate assumption than it used to. Now it’s at 1¼ percent in the way it
implements those rules. One would have to argue for a natural interest rate that’s far lower than
the estimates I cited—implausibly lower, I might argue—in order to rationalize the current real
federal funds rate in the usual Taylor (1993) or Taylor (1999) rule as well as in the inertial
Taylor (1999) rule.
Of course, one should be wary of using any of these Taylor rules to dictate how to behave
at any one meeting. However, I think the consistent story they tell reinforces the view that the
time has come to raise rates. The historical pattern of behavior that’s encapsulated in these rules
has delivered generally good outcomes over the past several decades and has conditioned public
beliefs about how we’re likely to behave in the future. Such beliefs provide essential
foundational support for the monetary stability that we currently enjoy, and we should not take
this stability for granted.
If we were to continue to delay, we would be departing even further from the pattern of
behavior that has served us well in the past. The historical record strongly suggests that such
departures are risky and raise the likelihood of bad outcomes. In particular, the most damaging
departures have been associated with the pursuit of estimates of full-employment unemployment
rates that proved, in hindsight, to be too optimistic.

September 16–17, 2015

144 of 240

The prospect of inflationary risks may seem remote right now. “Disinflationary
pressures” appears to be the catch phrase of the day. We should remember, however, that the
economic outlook can change rapidly. In mid-2003, for example, falling core inflation evoked a
state of high anxiety. But just over half a year later, growth and inflation were rising, and the
need for tighter policy became clear. In hindsight, we moved too late and too little in that
episode as well.
One might reply that because conditions might change, why not just wait and see? That
strategy often seems attractive, particularly when financial market volatility appears to have
increased uncertainty. Waiting for the resolution of uncertainty can be a trap, however. There’s
always something new around the corner about which one could be uncertain, or, to quote
Governor Fischer quoting a former colleague of his, “It’s never clear next time. It’s just unclear
in a different way.” As I noted yesterday, we have a history of letting financial market
developments affect our policy in ways that we later regret, and we should be mindful of this.
The deeper response is that we know that policy affects the economy with lags, so we
should strive to position ourselves in a way that balances future risks. Those risks have been
shifting steadily over time as household spending has accelerated and labor market conditions
have tightened. Growth in this expansion may have been disappointing when compared with
historical averages, but not so much when compared with currently realistic assessments of our
capabilities, given productivity and population trends. In fact, U.S. economic conditions have
improved quite significantly over the past six years, all things considered. It’s time to recognize
the substantial progress that’s been achieved and align rates accordingly. Thank you, Madam
Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Lockhart.

September 16–17, 2015

145 of 240

MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Madam Chair. Although I think the policy decision at
this meeting is a close and difficult call, I support the policy decision in alternative B. I will also
support the statement as written.
I have sympathy for Chair Yellen regarding the challenge, even the danger, associated
with significant editing of the statement on the fly, particularly just before a press conference.
So I will not suggest any changes, even though I think the statement, and the Committee’s
communications more generally, may fall short of what’s needed—a point that I’ll get to in a
moment.
By the standard of some further improvement in the labor market, I believe liftoff is
justified. At the same time, I do accept that the inflation data on their face could discourage a
liftoff decision at this meeting. The combination of declining year-over-year core PCE inflation
and weakening market-based expectation measures is troubling. Nonetheless, I was prepared to
look through the inflation data and base a liftoff decision on an assumption, obviously a critical
assumption, that the positive forces at work in the economy will eventually result in upward
inflation pressures pushing us toward target in a reasonable time frame.
Why not lift off with the decision at this meeting? As I stated in the economic go-round,
recent global economic and financial developments have raised the risk to the outlook, in my
estimation, and present a challenging environment for executing liftoff. This is the deciding
factor for me. The uncertainties that are the likely cause of the recent market volatility justify
delaying liftoff a meeting or two. A delay would give the Committee time to gain confidence
that the real economy is not being derailed by these developments.
Let me turn to post-statement communication of an alternative B decision and
communication in general. I increasingly feel the statement, and our approach to communication

September 16–17, 2015

146 of 240

more generally, requires a rethink as we approach the next couple of meetings. Said differently,
I’m concerned about our approach to forward guidance, and I’d like to offer some thoughts in
that regard. I’m concerned the Committee’s communication has contributed and is contributing
to market volatility. I’m concerned we have allowed our mantra of “data dependence” to
become a liability. The shift from strict time-dependent guidance to a more flexible approach
based on economic conditionality was appropriate. Over the past several months, however, data
dependence has become, effectively, the barest-minimum practical guidance. The phrase
provides too little basis for the public to grasp what will drive the Committee’s decisions in the
near future. I perceive the need for an attempt to achieve greater consensus on what will both
trigger liftoff and drive rate decisions of the Committee as we go forward and then find a way to
communicate that consensus to the public. My concern is that, without firming up our guidance,
we will continue to fall short of providing the needed clarity about our policy intentions. I’m
concerned the guidance status quo will work at cross-purposes with attaining our objectives. We
will continue to foster a guessing game in the markets that could contribute to unsettled
conditions.
I recognize the impracticality of trying to engineer substantial statement changes in the
remainder of this meeting. To offer something concrete, however, I suggest that in the
intermeeting period, building on our answers in our SEP submissions 3(c), the Committee
conduct a virtual go-round on options for forward guidance as captured in a variety of statement
alternatives. This discussion might also include statement language at liftoff.
Again, I will not suggest actual changes to the alternative B statement. But if asked what,
concretely, I have in mind to make guidance more substantive, I would have liked to see, after
the first sentence of paragraph 3, something in substance more along these lines: First, “the

September 16–17, 2015

147 of 240

Committee is satisfied that there has been sufficient improvement in labor market conditions.”
Next, “the Committee expects that, with continued improvement in labor markets and
momentum in economic activity more generally, inflation will rise gradually toward 2 percent
over the medium term.” Finally, “in making its policy decision at this meeting, the Committee
recognized the elevated risks associated with recent economic and financial developments.
When the Committee views these risks to have dissipated—and absent material negative changes
in economic conditions—it is prepared to initiate increases in the federal funds rate range.”
Because I see an alternative B decision at this meeting as a deferral or a delay, not just a
normal course “no decision” in which the Committee holds off for more or better data, I prefer
communicating a strong predisposition—with the usual caveats, of course—to lift off at an
upcoming meeting. Statement guidance substantively along the lines of what was just suggested
would serve this purpose, in my view. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Those are very interesting suggestions. We will follow up. Thank
you. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Madam Chair. In my view, we have met the conditions
for liftoff, and I therefore prefer alternative C. On the employment side of the mandate, we are
at or very near full employment. Unemployment is at or within sight of the natural rate. And
many other measures of labor market conditions have approached or exceeded their long-run or
steady-state values. This reduction in slack gives me confidence that inflation will return to
2 percent over the next few years. The only reason inflation has not made much progress toward
that goal is the offset from the drop in commodity prices and the appreciation of the dollar.
However, these facts will only temporarily depress the inflation rate. Furthermore, alternative
measures of inflation, such as the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas’s trimmed mean rate, suggest

September 16–17, 2015

148 of 240

that underlying inflation is already closer to our objective than some other measures would
suggest.
In considering the appropriate stance of policy, I start with commonly used benchmarks
for monetary policy, such as policy rules and the optimal control simulations. Based on my
forecast, nearly all suggest that we should raise rates now or already should have raised rates
some time ago. But that’s just a starting point for thinking about policy, and there are valid
arguments for delay and continuing to err on the side of caution relative to these benchmarks.
First, the zero bound remains a constraint on our ability to deal with adverse shocks. We’ve
already done a great deal of keeping rates lower for longer, but this remains a concern. Second,
there are some notable downside risks at present, as many people mentioned, including further
dollar appreciation and concerns about growth abroad. Finally, inflation has been running below
target for quite some time, and a low-inflation environment remains in effect around the globe.
There are also compelling arguments in favor of moving sooner rather than later,
however. First, the long lags of monetary policy require taking out some insurance against the
possibility that the high-pressure economy in train for next year will boil over. We do not have
the luxury of delaying liftoff until we’ve reached or exceeded both of our policy targets. At that
point, we’d be hopelessly behind the curve.
Second, there are some upside risks to our outlook that balance the downside ones.
Lower oil prices haven’t yet sparked a surge in consumption, but that may change as households
start interpreting the decline as more permanent. Housing starts, which remain well below
historical averages, could also surprise on the upside.
Finally, I’m concerned that, by staying at the zero bound for too long, we may be creating
new economic and financial imbalances. Although these risks appear contained for the present,

September 16–17, 2015

149 of 240

we already have elevated price-dividend ratios in equity markets, high and growing house-priceto-rent ratios, continued capital movements into emerging market economies, and other riskier
investment vehicles that could become problematic. Further delay in raising rates will incite
additional search for yield and exacerbate our exposure to costly reversals.
At this point, I want to respond to President Kocherlakota’s question about what it means
to boil over. And I’m going to go back to June 2005, when I was one of the briefers of the
FOMC. We were talking about the housing bubble. You may disagree with the word “bubble,”
but house prices were very elevated in June 2005. There was a discussion of what that meant for
the economy, and I was one of the presenters as a member of the staff of the Federal Reserve
Bank of San Francisco. I remember then Vice Chairman Geithner asking me during a break,
“What do we do about it now? It’s mid-2005. House prices are, by our own estimates, 25 or 30
percent overvalued. This is already in place. Do we raise interest rates and prick the bubble? Or
do we wait around and clean up?”
Now, it’s important to remember that this was not in the context of a financial crisis—
that’s not what we were worried about at the time. That was perhaps a mistake. We were
worried about what would happen if house prices fell 20, 25, or 30 percent, and then about what
effect that would have on the economy, just from purely macroeconomic concerns. What I
realized personally in that sidebar conversation was, I didn’t actually have a good answer. Once
the overvaluation of house prices had already occurred, we didn’t have good options regarding
how to reduce these imbalances. Raising interest rates sharply would create, clearly, huge
negative repercussions and probably would accelerate the decline in the housing market, which
was unsustainable. Waiting around to see what happens and clean up afterward obviously
wasn’t a good answer.

September 16–17, 2015

150 of 240

I came away from the conversation thinking about that for the past 10 years, and I
realized, you know, the time to have that conversation was in 2002 and 2003. That’s when we
first saw signs that things were getting out of whack—concerns about and risks to the economy
were rising. And thinking about where the tradeoffs really were at that point—not being driven
by housing or stock market bubbles, because we went through this in the 1990s, too, but really
weighing what the costs are of seeing how far this economy will go and taking into consideration
those risks before they actually become problematic.
Let me put that in context. Today, according to a standard measure, the house-price-torent ratio is about 30 percent above historical norms. We can disagree about what the average
level is—and the Board’s staff has its own views on this—but if you take historical norms
between 1980 and 2000, the standard price-to-rent ratio is about where we were in 2003. And
house prices are rising very dramatically today.
Again, I’m not talking about a financial crisis, because regarding our bank supervision
and financial stability, I think we’re in a situation that’s 10 times better. In terms of
macroeconomic risk—the risk that, a couple of years from now, we’ll be in a situation in which
the economy is threatened, whether by asset prices in general or other imbalances—I believe
there are real concerns. I don’t want to get into the position, once we’re in the situation that we
faced 10 years ago, of having to ask, “Well, what do we do now?”
In the past, I’ve weighed these pros and cons and come down on the side of delaying
liftoff. But the ongoing improvement in the labor market and the general economy has tilted the
balance of these arguments in favor of raising rates sooner rather than later. I therefore believe
that a rate increase today will be the best policy choice. That said, I recognize that it is a close
call, and I did listen very carefully, Chair Yellen, to your weighing of these issues. Obviously, a

September 16–17, 2015

151 of 240

different weighting of the pros and cons that you described may lead one to prefer delaying
liftoff until the next meeting or even the one thereafter.
As such, I’m willing to be patient and support alternative B today as written. However, I
do think it is important, picking up on the comments of President Lockhart, that we do keep all
future meetings live, including October. If developments between now and then argue for liftoff,
we should be ready to take that action, call a press conference, and provide an opportunity for the
Chair to explain our decision at that time. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Madam Chair. I support alternative B. I did not view
this decision today as a close call. With little time to process recent financial market movements
and international concerns, we need more time to understand whether there’s been a more
significant underlying change in economic fundamentals. The first footnote in Tealbook A
makes clear that the economic effect of delaying a tightening by a meeting or two would have a
de minimis effect on variables we care about.
Tightening at this meeting, with excessive volatility and using new tools to get us off the
zero lower bound, risks a much more complicated start to our tightening cycle. It also risks the
possibility of tightening at the start of a more significant global slowdown, which is not in my
modal forecast but is now a more elevated risk. Reasonable risk management leads me to want
to see more data before acting.
That said, I do view the time to raise rates as being near. While the U-3 unemployment
rate is not a sufficient statistic to summarize labor market conditions, it also should not be
ignored. Employment growth has been pretty strong this year, and broader measures of slack—
U-4, U-5, and U-6—have also improved significantly. As we’ve underestimated how quickly

September 16–17, 2015

152 of 240

unemployment rates would decline, it is possible that we will face much tighter labor markets
sooner than I have in my forecast. If that were to happen, I would expect less delay in reaching
our inflation target.
In light of the recent market volatility and the uncertainty about the inflation forecast, I
would prefer that our tightening, whenever it begins, be quite gradual. A risk to waiting too long
to lift off is that we may need to tighten more quickly than is in my SEP forecast. For example,
waiting until next year risks a more pronounced decline in unemployment than is in my modal
forecast and a more rapid return to 2 percent inflation than we currently envision. Under those
conditions, we would be caught behind the curve and need to make a more rapid adjustment to
policy. I’d prefer to avoid such a circumstance.
I would like each of the meetings, whether they coincide with an SEP release and a
planned press conference, to be live. If the domestic and global economy is slowing down, there
will be no need to tighten. However, if labor markets continue to improve and the recent
financial market turbulence does not leave much trace in the data going forward, it seems
prudent to me to begin a gradual tightening process relatively soon.
I have a couple of quick comments on the reinvestment discussion. I didn’t comment
yesterday because I wanted to process people’s comments. I had a couple of quick takeaways.
First, when we don’t know what we will do, I don’t think we should provide forward guidance.
[Laughter]
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I disagree. [Laughter]
MR. ROSENGREN. I can imagine a scenario in which we actually sell long-term assets.
It is the tabletop scenario, where we meet our dual-mandate goals but commercial real estate and
residential real estate are in a bubble, somewhat like what President Williams was talking about.

September 16–17, 2015

153 of 240

In that case, I would certainly consider selling long-term assets, with the very purpose of
steepening the yield curve.
I can also imagine a scenario in which we maintain a large balance sheet. If the
equilibrium real federal funds rate is low, we may want to keep long rates low and short rates
higher than otherwise to minimize the chance that we return to the zero lower bound. It has been
costly to be at the zero lower bound. I would prefer to minimize the chance that we return there.
If we are not willing to raise our inflation target, we should consider maintaining a higher
balance sheet. The discussion yesterday was very good but implied to me that we should
maintain balance sheet flexibility as prudent risk management. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. I support alternative C for today. In
paragraph 4, I support adding the bracketed “balanced approach” language. In paragraph 5, I
suggest using the language in the bracketed choice “at least during the early stages of
normalization.”
I remain very concerned that a decision at this meeting to adopt alternative B will
essentially cement the idea of a “Yellen put” in the eyes of financial markets. The added
language in alternative B, paragraph 2, basically says that the global selloff during the
intermeeting period is our basis for nonaction. No amount of explaining will disguise this fact.
The message will be lost on no one.
I think we’re kidding ourselves about what this means for the future of the Committee.
The problem with this is that it will create questions as to how the Committee will react to future
selloffs or booms in financial markets.

September 16–17, 2015

154 of 240

Many argued yesterday that the implications for U.S. growth and inflation, not the global
financial turmoil, were the key determinants of this decision. However, most of the weak spots
around the world have been well known—Brazil and Russia were cited yesterday—and were
widely discussed at previous meetings.
The Chinese devaluation was indeed a surprise to markets during the intermeeting period,
but it was not a big enough event to have a meaningful impact on U.S. monetary policy strategy.
Chinese growth is, indeed, slowing and will continue to slow in coming years, but this has been
well known for some time and hardly qualifies as news. The evidence of an actual hard landing
in China is very limited, and our own staff assessment is that such a scenario is unlikely, on the
basis of the data available today.
In a nutshell, we are making a decision today that emphasizes vague, unspecified, and
likely quantitatively small effects on the U.S. economy emanating from the RMB depreciation
decision. This is not a good basis for U.S. monetary policy strategy. Some are claiming that
global commodity price declines are the driving factor here, but, on balance, this is a bullish
factor for the United States, not a bearish factor.
One of my concerns is that we are sending a very muddled message about our reaction
function. We have in many ways become very discretionary in our policy choices, citing
different factors on different days, even when the general nature of the economic situation has
not changed appreciably.
Concerning inflation, I’m delighted to learn that there’s been a sudden shift in sentiment
on the Committee toward strict inflation targeting—that is, running monetary policy with heavy
emphasis on inflation and little or no emphasis on output or employment gaps. I actually think
this would be a reasonable way to proceed and could lead to reasonably good policy in the

September 16–17, 2015

155 of 240

United States, but it has not enjoyed as much popularity in the past as it has recently. However,
there is a problem with what I’m calling strict inflation-targeting approaches in the current
circumstances. Strict inflation targeting says that the reason we are still at the zero lower bound
is that inflation is below target. This would be a good reason to be at perhaps a 2 percent policy
rate, still well below long-run normal levels. But it is not a good reason to be near zero on the
policy rate, 350 basis points below normal levels. That suggests a very high elasticity of the
federal funds rate to the inflation gap. In other words, a relatively small inflation gap implies a
lot of accommodation—a 0 percent federal funds rate. What that means is, as inflation rises, the
federal funds rate will, at least if you are taking this approach, rise very quickly, and that is not
what the Committee is saying.
I agree with Governor Fischer’s assessment from yesterday on the idea that temporary
factors are influencing inflation, as many have said around here. As these abate, a strict
inflation-targeting approach would suggest a rapid increase in the policy rate. We’re evidently
not planning to do that, so it’s exactly this process that will lead to perceptions that the
Committee is far behind the proverbial curve.
I see this as a poor decision today, and I just want to think about what the fallout will be
and how the Committee has to manage going forward. Even though I think we’re not making a
good decision here, we can make good decisions in the future. I see four consequences. First, I
think that the Committee will be viewed as shifting to a “late and fast” strategy and away from
an “early and gradual” strategy. The perception in markets, which is already there, will be that
the Committee will not move until we’re forced into action. It also suggests that the Committee
is perhaps more willing to scramble to catch up, if necessary—or at least that’s the way we’re
weighing that risk.

September 16–17, 2015

156 of 240

Second, this shift toward a late-and-fast strategy, combined with an undefined reaction
function, will mean even more volatility in the future due to uncertainty about Fed policy than
we would otherwise have. What we’re saying, essentially, is that when the Committee moves, it
may have to move faster. In addition, it is not that clear what the Committee might react to,
because we’re taking a very discretionary approach to our policy and a very eclectic approach to
what variables we want to cite in making our policy decision.
Third, I think there’s more risk now of an outsized increase in rates at some point in the
future, not unlike the moves of 50 or 75 basis points that were made in 1994. If you’re going to
play the late-and-fast strategy, then you’ve got to possibly be ready to move more quickly than I
think the Committee is currently ready for. Markets will sense this, and this will create
additional uncertainty in financial markets.
Finally, I think there will be a continued and exacerbated mismatch between market
expectations and FOMC expectations about future policy. The Committee will now put out its
SEP. It will have a policy rate path, but those in the markets that think the Committee will never
move will be emboldened to move even further into the future. So there will be more of a gap
now between what the FOMC expects regarding monetary policy and what the market expects.
Those gaps can’t persist indefinitely. They have to be reconciled at some point, and that process
leads to additional volatility in markets and is part of what was going on here, I think, during the
summer.
Those are my four takeaways for the consequences of today’s decision. Again, I support
alternative C. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Mester.

September 16–17, 2015

157 of 240

MS. MESTER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I believe there’s a strong case for moving the
federal funds rate up at this meeting. The Committee has laid out two criteria for liftoff—some
further improvement in labor markets and reasonable confidence that inflation will move back to
our target of 2 percent over the medium term. In my view, those conditions have been met.
Labor market conditions certainly continued to improve over the intermeeting period,
and, in my view, the economy is at or nearly at full employment from the standpoint of the Fed’s
dual-mandate goal. The inflation criterion for liftoff is appropriately based on the expected path
of inflation and not on its current level. No doubt inflation has been running below our goal of
2 percent, but the effects of last summer’s oil price decline and fall in import prices have been
passing through to the headline inflation numbers. This, combined with the fact that the labor
market has been tightening faster than expected and inflation expectations have been generally
stable even in the face of commodity price declines, should give us more confidence in our
inflation forecast. Starting normalization before we reach our dual-mandate goals is prudent if
we want to minimize the risk that we’ll have to move rates up considerably more aggressively
than we’re currently anticipating.
We’ve been indicating for some time that we expect a gradual path. I would like us to
take actions that help maintain the credibility of that scheme. As Governor Fischer said at our
July meeting, the data control the gradualness. However, our policy actions can influence the
data by influencing how the economy evolves.
Now, should the recent volatility in financial markets give us pause? I think not. The
economy has fared well through it. Volatility measures and risk spreads remain elevated but are
moving back down. As Chair Yellen pointed out, the decision to act depends on an assessment
of the risks. I view the change in financial conditions and reassessment of global growth since

September 16–17, 2015

158 of 240

our July meeting as a downside risk to the outlook rather than implying much change to the
modal outlook. But we’ve taken out insurance against this downside risk by keeping interest
rates considerably lower than almost all of the policy rules suggest, even as the Tealbookconsistent equilibrium interest rate has been rising—in this Tealbook it’s now 0.47 percent.
I believe that Chair Yellen’s insightful leadership of the Committee has prepared the
public for liftoff. In the current environment, after keeping the funds rate at zero for over six
years, I would expect some residual uncertainty surrounding the decision. The fact that there’s
not unanimity across market participants and forecasters that liftoff will occur at this particular
meeting doesn’t deter me. Most are still expecting a rate hike this year, and a resolution of some
policy uncertainty might actually be viewed favorably. In addition, no matter how well we have
prepared and signaled such a change, I’d expect some volatility in the markets at liftoff. I don’t
think we should be too bothered by that, either.
What would concern me more is if, on liftoff, the public’s expectation about the path of
policy after liftoff changes and becomes much steeper than the path we’re currently anticipating.
In other words, might liftoff be read as the beginning of rate increases at each meeting thereafter
so that we have a steep path going up?
The Chair has emphasized that the Committee anticipates that economic conditions will
evolve in a way that warrants keeping the funds rate below its longer-run level for some time.
This certainly shows up in our SEP. But the market path implied by market data is considerably
shallower than in the SEP, which suggests that the message of a gradual path is coming through
loud and clear. Thus, while there is some risk that the act of liftoff may appreciably change
policy expectations, I believe appropriate communications at liftoff will be sufficient to mitigate
this risk.

September 16–17, 2015

159 of 240

Chair Yellen and the Committee have navigated some very difficult waters over the past
year, as the start of normalization is near. With considerable effort, we’ve reached a point at
which there is a favorable alignment of expectations of a rate increase and the data that support
such an increase. I don’t believe this is something we should take for granted. Current
economic circumstances are very favorable in terms of being able to communicate the rationale
for action and post-liftoff policy, and careful communication is a crucial component of a
successful liftoff.
Yes, there are risks to moving. But there are also risks to not moving, including having
to move more aggressively later on if we delay too much further. Action is going to send a
signal, but so will inaction. We may not see such favorable conditions for communications for
some time. Thus, I believe we should seize the day and act. Of course, I do understand that this
is not the majority view, and I respect colleagues who see things differently. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Harker.
MR. HARKER. Thank you, Madam Chair. Given my economic forecast, I continue to
hold the position that it is quite important that monetary policy begin to raise rates. However, I
am not adamant that it be done at this meeting.
The recent turbulence in financial markets and the softening of energy prices and price
pressures in general probably make this meeting less than optimal for liftoff, although I expect
these are temporary headwinds. It is, however, my strong belief that we should begin our
normalization process sooner rather than later, and that the process should be gradual. At the
least, the statement language should make clear that if we continue to see improvements in the
labor market over the next couple of months, the Committee will move to raise rates.

September 16–17, 2015

160 of 240

Earlier liftoff makes a gradual path of policy firming more likely, and it will still allow us
to maintain an accommodative policy stance for some time. I’m becoming concerned that we
will find ourselves treating every bump in the economic road as a reason for delay, with the
effect that monetary policy moves further and further from what can reasonably be viewed as
normal. The longer we wait in anticipation that all signs point in the same direction, the more
likely it will be that future policy adjustments will need to be very aggressive, and I worry about
the economic consequences of being in that position.
Beginning normalization should send a reassuring message and will underscore the belief
that the economy is on solid footing, and that inflation will return to target. It seems that the
least normal element of the current economic environment is our inability to return monetary
policy to a more normal mode of conduct.
Like Presidents Williams and Rosengren, I also encourage the Committee to consider
every meeting, including October, as a potential and appropriate time for liftoff. Thank you,
Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kaplan.
MR. KAPLAN. Thank you, Madam Chair. Based on economic data and the outlook for
the economy discussed yesterday, I do believe we’re at a point at which it’s appropriate to begin
the process of removing accommodation—if not today, then very soon.
I do support alternative B today because I am of the view that economic conditions
abroad might have the potential to spill over to the United States, thereby increasing the
uncertainty about the U.S. outlook and negatively affecting data in the months ahead. However,
I would say that I believe these non-U.S. economic uncertainties will continue for some extended
period. That is, I don’t believe the overall level of this uncertainty is going to diminish in the

September 16–17, 2015

161 of 240

coming months. The nature of the weakness and spillover threats from abroad relates to deeply
embedded, in some cases, structural, demographic, and other issues that are likely to take years,
versus months, to manage and address. So my preference would be that we soon begin the
process of removing accommodation and address these potential spillover threats by adjusting
the expected path of accommodation, versus delaying much further the start of the process.
In my view, delaying for too long the start of the process of removing accommodation at
this stage carries a cost. While a lower unemployment rate, of course, is desirable, it has the
potential to create unhealthy imbalances if it’s supported by artificially accommodative financial
conditions. Such conditions maintained for too long may encourage investment and borrowing
decisions that cannot easily be reversed or unwound when policy eventually normalizes, as it
must. This increases the chances, in my view, of a hard landing, which, to me, means excess
investment, inventory buildup, and financial asset valuations that are more likely to lead to
negative economic effects later when more normal policy is put into place. In my experience,
imbalances like these are often not obvious until after the fact, and they need not be accompanied
by above-target inflation. So I would say that, on the upside, prudent risk management dictates
that we begin the process of scaling back accommodation as the economy approaches our best
estimate of potential.
I can and do support alternative B as written at this meeting, though, because I believe
that it is prudent to use the next several weeks or months to confirm that conditions for liftoff are
sustainable, allowing us to act in October or December. But I would suggest that, in the
statement, we send a signal that the economy has moved closer to satisfying the conditions for
liftoff by substituting the word “approaching” for the phrase “continuing to move toward” in the
third sentence of paragraph 2 in alternative B. So, in that third sentence, it currently says

September 16–17, 2015

162 of 240

“continuing to move toward,” and my suggestion is to instead substitute the word “approaching.”
Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Madam Chair. I appreciate your earlier comments today, and
let me say I have full confidence that, in your press conference today, you’ll describe the
conditions for our decision.
I support alternative B, which leaves our policy rate unchanged. Even with unchanged
policy, I expect that inflation will remain too low for too long. And if we start moving rates up
too soon, I fear the FOMC could lose credibility on its commitment to a symmetric 2 percent
objective. This loss could risk de-anchoring inflationary expectations, with profound
consequences in the longer run.
The Bank of Japan, the ECB, and other central banks have risked and arguably lost
credibility with regard to their inflation targets, and they may well be facing more difficult
economic circumstances because of those earlier policy choices. We should continue to tread
warily so that our own policy choices don’t lead us down the same path.
When I consider the outlook, I find it difficult to have much confidence that inflation will
sustainably get to 2 percent over the medium term. Indeed, if we don’t keep an appropriately
high level of accommodation in place, we risk this cycle ending with inflation topping out below
2 percent. That would certainly jeopardize faith in our target.
Around the world, downside inflation risks abound. Since our June SEP round, the
United States has been buffeted by additional disinflationary headwinds from low energy,
commodity, and imported goods prices. In the U.S., the improvement in the labor market has not

September 16–17, 2015

163 of 240

yet produced any meaningful signs of wage or cost pressures. It’s no wonder that none of my
business contacts cite any concerns about rising inflationary pressures.
There’s another reason I find it hard to be confident that we are headed to 2 percent
inflation at an appropriate pace. I’m referring to what I think must be a concern by many on this
Committee about a modest overshooting of our inflation target. Madam Chair, I will say that in
my initial prepared remarks here, I had “tacit concern.” But it turns out you were much more
explicit in your own concern about overshooting, and I think others have been today as well.
I sense that many participants’ SEP forecasts are trying to thread the needle to get to
2 percent without any risk of overshooting. With inflation so very low, that’s the only way I can
rationalize some of our SEP policy rate paths, at least given my outlook. I infer that these paths
reflect a serious aversion to PCE inflation heading to, say, 2½ percent. But after six or seven
years of inflation averaging 1½ percent, whether we briefly touch 2 percent during that time isn’t
really relevant. And with forecasts for several more years below target, we should be very
nervous about advocating policies that seek to eliminate any chance of 2½ percent inflation.
Outsized concerns over exceeding 2 percent inflation will risk signaling that our price
objective is a ceiling and not a symmetric target. It also risks us joining other central banks that
are struggling with the consequences of not sufficiently defending their inflation objectives from
below and of ignoring the added risk emanating from the zero lower bound.
Furthermore, I don’t see much risk of inflation running anywhere near 2½ percent over
the forecast period. To the contrary, the inflation risks largely seem to be to the downside. The
Tealbook alternative scenarios highlight this. Like President Kocherlakota, I can’t recall the last
time every alternative simulation was more pessimistic about inflation than the baseline scenario,
which isn’t that optimistic to start with. From a risk-management perspective, these adverse

September 16–17, 2015

164 of 240

alternatives suggest there could be significant benefits to delaying any substantial increase in the
funds rate in order to build up a buffer stock of inflation pressures. In turn, such a buffer would
reduce the risk of returning to the zero lower bound if these plausible shocks indeed come to
pass.
Another way to put this is that our policies should allow a higher probability of inflation
rising to the range of 2 to 2½ percent for a time. To achieve a symmetric 2 percent objective in
the face of the likely asymmetric policy risks emanating from the nonlinearity of the zero lower
bound, we have to allow ourselves a reasonable chance of going above 2 percent. Less bold
action could signal that we were content to have PCE inflation settle in at 1.5 to 1.9 percent, the
latter being the Tealbook outlook in 2018.
My SEP date for policy liftoff is June 2016. This is not as extreme as the dot chart might
suggest. After all, my overall funds rate path is not all that different from the implications of the
Tealbook’s path. If things play out as expected, the differences are mainly around near-term
timing. My SEP submission delays liftoff both to build a risk-management buffer and to allow
us time to better assess the outlook before making a policy move. At the end of 2016, I have the
funds rate range at 75 to 100 basis points. From today, that’s a total of three increases of
25 basis points each. My subsequent path is a touch steeper than the Tealbook’s, so we both
arrive at about the same rate by the end of 2018.
I believe that lower rates in the near term, followed by a bit faster ascent after we have
more confidence in the inflation outlook, would allow for better risk assessment and would be
appropriate as long as our inflation outlook is below 2½ percent. Again, the way to get to
2 percent within a reasonable period of time, or at all, is to make sure you give yourself a
reasonable chance of getting to 2 percent.

September 16–17, 2015

165 of 240

Finally, I think our medium-term policy focus should be on communicating our
commitment to a 2 percent symmetric PCE inflation objective. Like President Lockhart, I feel
that the term “data dependence” hasn’t been sufficient for the public to understand how policy
will react to incoming data. But I believe President Lockhart’s suggestions are limited to
clarifying when liftoff will take place. We need more than that. Providing more information
with respect to our funds rate path milestones and how they relate to the inflation outlook would
be quite valuable for supporting the achievement of our 2 percent objective.
The SEP dot chart should be helpful on this score if we focus most of our
communications on the central portions of the chart. Saying “more gradual than normal” isn’t
enough unless we say it a lot. Beyond today, if inflation headwinds continue to challenge our
outlook even as we begin liftoff, then I think our communications, especially those discussing
data dependence, will need to signal even more aggressively our full commitment to achieving
our 2 percent symmetric inflation objective.
I support alternative B. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Madam Chair. Alternative C aligns with my own views of
the economy’s continued expansion, even in the face of various headwinds over the past several
years—an economy that warrants a continued accommodative stance of policy but not zero
interest rates, in my view.
The benchmark policy rules that supported the Committee’s decisions to add
accommodation via LSAPs several years ago are the same ones that have been signaling for
some time that a shift in policy is appropriate. However, for a Committee that has lacked
reasonable confidence to begin a gradual normalization over the past few meetings, the prospects

September 16–17, 2015

166 of 240

of liftoff in the face of global growth uncertainty and the related headwinds to the United States
are actually less compelling, I think, today.
I understand the desire to wait for a few more meetings, with the intention of having a
clearer picture of the outlook. Waiting for more certainty over the course of a few more
meetings may seem comforting and costless. I think it carries its own cumulative risk. The
potential exists to get caught in a time-inconsistency trap by projecting liftoff in the near future
but, when the time comes, lacking the conviction to carry out the policies underpinning our
projections because of wanting to see just a few more data points.
I’ll offer three brief thoughts for today’s decision. First, in view of the continued
improvement in labor market conditions, the decision not to lift off at this meeting must surely
reflect the Committee as not yet having reasonable confidence that inflation will return to
2 percent over the medium term. If this point is not emphasized, markets may view our reaction
function as now incorporating things like market volatility and foreign developments into our
near-term decisionmaking process.
Second, I believe the heavy emphasis on data dependence is injecting substantial
uncertainty into markets and is too backward looking. So, in addition to data dependence,
monetary policy needs to emphasize being forward looking. We should place more emphasis on
how incoming data are affecting our assessment of the outlook rather than inadvertently sending
a message that we’re responding to the most recent data points.
Finally, postponing liftoff increases the probability that rates will have to be increased
more rapidly than we currently anticipate. Waiting until inflation is nearer to 2 percent and
unemployment is below its longer-run normal rate may put the Committee in a difficult position

September 16–17, 2015

167 of 240

of having to adjust rates more steeply and, as a result, create heightened risk around financial
stability and our growth outlook. Thank you.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Madam Chair. I’m going to do the risky thing
here and try to be more reactive to comments that have been offered around the table than I
customarily would be.
I will start with what President George just said, which is that the Committee should do
more both internally and externally to emphasize the need to condition monetary policy on the
outlook. We should always be seeking to make policy to align the medium-term outlook for our
goal variables of prices and employment with our longer-term objectives. Now, when I say the
term “outlook,” I mean to include risks to that outlook as well. As President Evans emphasized,
those risks really are all asymmetrically on the downside at this stage because of the zero lower
bound and our inability to be able to respond effectively to those risks.
What I heard from many around the table is a desire to incorporate other considerations
besides the outlook into our thinking. President Lacker started off by talking about how the
Taylor rule had given very good outcomes for us in the past. Embedded in the Taylor rule is a
sense of the desirability to have interest rates close to their long-run normal level.
President Lockhart talked about being satisfied with gradually moving back toward
2 percent over the medium term. I think we want to be aligned between our medium-term
outlook and our long-run goals. We have to be more aggressive than that. We want to be
actually back to 2 percent. And, as President Evans suggested, taking into account the closeness
to the effective lower bound, we might want to be willing to have some overshooting in the
medium term in terms of our modal inflation outlook, just to guard against those downside risks.

September 16–17, 2015

168 of 240

Several people talked about being concerned about disliking rapid increases in interest
rates. Again, this is introducing a non-goal-oriented consideration into your policy
decisionmaking. To offer some context, when we’re talking about rapid increases in interest
rates, we’re talking about increases faster than 25 basis points a quarter. I want to offer that the
baseline in the SEP is 25 basis points per quarter. I think the Committee—again, as President
Evans mentioned—would have a better alignment between its medium-term outlook and its
long-run objectives by waiting and then raising rates at a slightly faster pace. Something more
like the 2004–06 pace, which I believe was actually viewed as fairly measured, would deliver a
better outcome.
The next few meetings and the decisionmaking around liftoff are really critical not just
for the course of policy in the near term and how it’s going to affect the economy, but also in
terms of setting up the strategic framework of how the Committee is going to think about policy.
We continue to be overly influenced by a collection of Taylor-like rules. I suggested yesterday
that this had served the Committee extremely poorly during the course of the recovery.
To try to clarify one of my points in that discussion about November 2009, that was not a
QE meeting. It was a meeting in which the Committee had terminated QE1, and was thinking
about, how do we best time the removal of accommodation—specifically, the increase of interest
rates—with the improvement in the economy so as to best support the recovery? The debate
within the Committee, shaped by Taylor rules, had the dovish side in the 8s in terms of the
unemployment rate and the hawkish side in the 9s. I was there. I was on the Committee at the
time, so this is about self-reflection and self-criticism as much as anything else.
This is about the problem with our framework that was in place before 2008 imprisoning
the Committee into an unduly slow recovery. We do not want to have that happen again. The

September 16–17, 2015

169 of 240

way you don’t have that happen again is by conditioning the policy decisions now about liftoff
and afterward much more firmly on the outlook for prices and employment and by building in, I
think, risk protections along the lines that President Evans has suggested.
I look at what’s happening in the world, and we look at all of the experiences countries
have had in trying to escape the zero lower bound. And I am drawn, Madam Chair, to
alternative A. I do not think that this is the time to be considering liftoff. I look at what’s been
happening with regard to how financial markets are considering the credibility of our target.
Without meaning to be overly critical, as I listen to this debate, I can understand why financial
markets are doubting the credibility of our target, because there’s just a comfort level with,
“Eventually, we have to get back to 2 percent. It’s got to happen.” That only happens if we
make decisions to make it happen. That is how we get credibility for our target. That’s how
Paul Volcker got credibility for the target in the 1980s. That’s how we have to get there. It’s
through our decisions. If we remove accommodation now, with inflation running as low as it is
and projected to take as long as it is to get back to target, we are not sending the right message
about credibility.
I am drawn to alternative A. I think that will set us up better to have a framework that is
explicitly goal oriented. It’ll allow us to respond more effectively to shocks going forward, as
opposed to putting weight on having interest rates at some normal level. The only thing that
“normal level” should mean for this Committee is that we are hitting our price and employment
objectives over the medium term.
I’ll close in terms of President Williams’s point. I thought it was a very telling and
compelling one, in part because I bought a house in June 2005, so it really—
MR. WILLIAMS. It hurts. [Laughter]

September 16–17, 2015

170 of 240

MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. It did hurt. This is a challenging issue, and it deserves a lot
more attention from the Committee. Is the fact that house prices are 30 percent overvalued right
now a reason to be less accommodative? It’s a subject that should be discussed.
I will point out that, as I’m sure President Williams knows, if the Laubach-Williams
natural real rate is going to be low for a long time to come, house prices are going to be elevated
relative to historical norms, and that’s something we’re going to have to live with if we want to
hit our goal variables. That’s the only comment I’ll offer on that.
Madam Chair, I appreciated your setting out the alternatives at the beginning, but I felt
you left out the most compelling one, which was alternative A. Thanks.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Fischer.
MR. FISCHER. Thank you, Madam Chair. I thought we had an exceptionally
interesting discussion yesterday, and I’d like to start by reflecting on it.
Broadly speaking, two sets of views were expressed, and they were also mentioned by the
Chair in her opening remarks this morning. The first set of views starts from the two criteria we
specified earlier this year that would have to be met before we first raise the interest rate. The
criteria we set out were, first, that there be further progress in the strengthening of the labor
market and, second, that members of the Committee believe with reasonable confidence that the
inflation rate will reach 2 percent in the medium term. As I explained yesterday, I believe we’ve
met those criteria. To justify that view, one has to explain why, when the actual inflation rate is
so far from 2 percent, we can say that we’ve met those criteria.
The explanation is simple—that the current low inflation rate is due largely to declines in
the price of oil and to the appreciation of the exchange rate, both of which are temporary. By the
calculation I described yesterday—which takes into account not only the difference between the

September 16–17, 2015

171 of 240

actual and core PCE price deflators, but also the indirect effects on the inflation rate of the
decline in the price of oil and of the exchange rate—the underlying inflation rate is
approximately 1.6 percent at present.
To be sure, those two criteria are only necessary conditions for raising the interest rate.
I’ll say more on that later, for I’ll end by making the case that we can delay raising the federal
funds rate beyond the end of this month, but that if current conditions continue, we should raise
the federal funds rate before the end of the year.
The second set of views starts from the fact that there is no inflation in sight, and that we
should not raise the interest rate even though, in the view of many, the labor market is close to
the natural rate of unemployment. Rather, we should stay at the effective lower bound, possibly
allow the unemployment rate to decline below the natural rate, and raise the interest rate only
when we clearly need to deal with the inflation rate, which, if we were writing for the
newspapers, we’d say is “when we see the whites of the eyes of inflation.”
In this view, we can and should wait before raising the federal funds rate either because
the natural rate of unemployment has fallen to well below 5 percent or because we can allow the
actual rate of unemployment to fall below the natural rate and thus contribute to dealing with
aspects of the labor market that are not yet at what we think is their normal condition—we’re
talking about the participation rate, the long-term unemployment ratio, and part-time
employment for economic reasons. When we reach reasonable levels of those variables, we can
raise the interest rate and move toward the natural rate of unemployment from below. I think it’s
important to note that, at least in my view, the explicit adoption of such an approach would be
widely viewed as a change in the FOMC’s monetary policy strategy.

September 16–17, 2015

172 of 240

Now, both of these views have merit. The choice between them has been complicated by
developments abroad. Just over a month ago, on August 11, China devalued its exchange rate
rather clumsily and after a Shanghai stock market bubble had burst. And there was a bubble.
Even the governor of the Chinese central bank described it thus. The Chinese exchange rate
move created shock waves, one of which arrived at the New York Stock Exchange on August 24,
when the Dow Jones index declined in the morning by over 1,000 points and then closed down
by 588 points, about 3.8 percent. By the way, I wonder whether we’re not going to have sharper,
more rapid changes in prices in the stock markets as electronic trading develops further.
Subsequently, emerging market and developing-country problems, many of which had
started well before the Chinese devaluation, began to draw the attention of markets in the
industrialized world. For example, the Brazilian economy is in trouble. The Russian economy is
doing badly. So are other countries in Latin America. So are some countries in Southeast Asia
and Africa, and even Canada and Australia are suffering from effects of the declines in the price
of oil and of other commodities. Less mentioned are the improvements in the euro zone, the fact
that the United Kingdom’s economy is moving ahead well, the expectation that the Indian
economy will grow this year at over 7 percent, and the possibility that India is going to be the
China of the next I-don’t-know-how-many years.
What are we to do? Well, the choice between going now and going soon is very close.
In light of the genuine uncertainty caused by the Chinese devaluation and the subsequent
realization that there were other difficulties in the global economy, I can support not raising the
interest rate now and waiting until either October or December to raise the rate.
I’ve got a series of observations on our discussion that I can’t figure out where to put in
this statement at a logical place. So I’ll talk about them now, and, if they’re out of order, you’ll

September 16–17, 2015

173 of 240

make the appropriate corrections and let me know what they are so that I can improve this in
retrospect. First, we’re all very concerned about the problems in foreign economies. When I
listen to them, they sound much larger than what I found in the Tealbook in terms of their effects
on the U.S. economy. I think the Tealbook forecast was made in full knowledge of the situation
in the global economy, and we can be sure that the staff attempted to take into account the
quantitative effects of the external situation on the U.S. economy.
I do believe it appropriate that, besides expressing our worries about foreign economies
and describing links between their economies and ours, we should try to make a quantitative
estimate of how large those effects are likely to be. These are, admittedly, early days, but the
evidence so far is that those effects will not derail the impressive recovery of the United States’
economy since 2009, where, in particular, the labor market has continued to strengthen at a
remarkably steady—indeed, impressive—pace.
The next comment I’m going to make is that one keeps hearing about this “unduly slow”
recovery. I don’t think it’s unduly slow. I think it’s remarkable, in fact, what has happened to
the unemployment rate. If you’re thinking about GDP, that hasn’t recovered. But the difference
between what’s happening to labor and what’s happening to GDP is productivity, and I don’t
think monetary policy is responsible for that.
I have a few other points. We keep saying we will look through supply shocks, but we
don’t. We keep talking about how low the inflation rate is. That is largely a result of two large
supply shocks, and we’d better remember that we look through supply shocks when one day we
find inflation above 2 percent because of supply shocks. We also tend to forget that we have a
cushion of 40 basis points as a result of the enlarged balance sheet, as the discussion yesterday of
the effects of beginning to run off our portfolio made clear.

September 16–17, 2015

174 of 240

Another point is, remember that the price of housing is high because we put the interest
rate very low. So it may not be a sign of a pathology. It may be a sign of health that monetary
policy worked as planned. That, nonetheless, does mean that there’s possibly going to be some
pain when we start raising interest rates from the housing market.
There are two more things in the collection of random—but not totally random—
observations. Regarding the question of whether the real wage should start rising independent of
the behavior of productivity is an interesting one. I’ve had some discussions with people who
say, “Well, tell me where productivity comes into the Phillips curve.” Productivity comes in, in
fact, in a way that was mentioned yesterday by Governor Powell and, I believe, by someone on
the other side of the table—probably President Williams. Productivity affects the demand for
labor, and that’s where it comes in.
Finally, this is not a scientific observation, but this is one that is useful to remember. I
think that the experience of what happens when stock prices begin to go down or when
something goes wrong in the financial markets is summarized by something Warren Buffett said,
which I’m sure is more correctly attributed to someone else. You know, in the United Kingdom,
everything was said by Shakespeare or Churchill. In France, it was de Gaulle. In the United
States, it’s Lincoln or Buffett. [Laughter] Buffett said that when the tide goes out, you see
who’s been swimming naked. And mostly, as you start unwinding some excitement in the
financial markets, you discover that there’s a whole lot more that’s been going on than you knew
about. That is something that gives me pause when we say, “Well, we’re not seeing much in the
way of problems right now.” But that’s a general comment.
I clearly support alternative B. But I’d like to add that, while we may not yet be at the
maximum-employment level and are certainly not at the target inflation rate, I think we can soon

September 16–17, 2015

175 of 240

comfortably start, and should start, the gradual process of returning to a normal stance of
monetary policy.
I would like to deal with one issue that is frequently mentioned at this point in the
discussion. It’s that of the foreign central banks that raised the interest rate prematurely. Well, I
know one of those examples very well. The Bank of Israel was the first central bank to raise its
interest rate in 2009. It raised the rate from 50 basis points to 75 basis points. It did that because
the economy was growing and inflation was above the target range, largely due to the fact that
housing prices were rising rapidly. It stayed on this path of raising rates until they reached about
3 percent, when the European crisis developed and the effect of the Federal Reserve’s QE, which
had begun after the Bank of Israel had raised the rate, began to become obvious. That is to say,
they followed Keynes’s advice—when the circumstances changed, we changed policy.
That’s what I think has happened in most of these cases. I regard the proof that if you
raise the rate, you’re going to raise it too early as not recognizing the dynamics of what was
happening in the global economy, where 2009, as was mentioned yesterday, looked like the end
of the recession for many. Then, sometime around 2010, we began to realize that, actually, it
was more complicated than that and we had to do more. I could say the United States reversed
policy. Why? It invented QE. So it also cut interest rates. I don’t think that that example is
worth a whole lot, though it’s become part of, certainly, what I read in the newspapers whenever
I see a discussion of this.
Now I’ve spoken for too long, but I’m going to speak a little bit longer. Once we become
more confident that the global economy is not at the start of a serious crisis, and that the external
effect on U.S. economic activity and inflation of foreign developments is likely to be subdued, I
believe we should get started. I gave a lot of reasons for that in the July meeting. In the interest

September 16–17, 2015

176 of 240

of saving time, I won’t repeat all of them now. But let me briefly mention four of the main
reasons, with apologies for repeating myself. First, monetary policy will continue to be very
expansionary even after we start moving, for we are not about to lift off vertically. We are about
to begin the process of gradual normalization. I recommend that we think very hard about the
assertions made by even highly respected economists and policymakers that raising the federal
funds rate at this meeting or in the near future could be an epochal mistake and realize that
they’re almost certain to be wrong. Even after we make our first move, monetary policy will be
extremely expansionary. Furthermore, this will be a surprise to no one, and many around the
world agree that this change should come soon. Some in the emerging market countries even
want it as soon as possible.
Second, we’ve now held the nominal interest rate at its effective lower bound for six
years and nine months. In so doing, we’re sending a signal that the situation in the U.S.
economy is still extremely far from being normal. The interest rate aside, I do not believe that is
the current situation. If the Federal Reserve sends a well-reasoned signal that we think the U.S.
economy is now strong enough to begin normalizing, we would be providing an important boost
to confidence of businesses and households. That’s something the Chair mentioned as a
possibility in her opening statement. The improvement in confidence would have a positive
effect on spending and job creation.
Third—and this is also an important point—beginning normalization when we’ve met the
criteria that we’ve set out to meet will enhance the credibility of the FOMC. Conversely, if we
continue to delay despite meeting these criteria, market participants and Fed watchers will not
know what to make of our communications, and our credibility will suffer. Now, there is a
statement that has recently been made that practically any argument that’s made on the basis of

September 16–17, 2015

177 of 240

credibility is bound to be wrong. I think that, while we should always examine arguments that
rely on credibility with suspicion, credibility really matters for a central bank, particularly for the
most important central bank in the world. In this regard, I have considerable sympathy with
President Lockhart’s view that the markets need to understand better what we intend to do. One
of the best ways to achieve that is by doing what we have said we will do.
Fourth, the decisions we make this year are going to affect the economy next year and
after that, so we need to be moving our policy stance with future conditions in mind. If the
situation in foreign economies stabilizes—note that I am not saying “if foreign economies
stabilize,” just “if their situation stabilizes”—and if, as the SEP suggests, most of us agree that
we should start normalization this year, we need to think about whether to start it in October or
December. There is an attraction to the idea of going in October, because, if the objective
situation so justifies, that would demonstrate to the public that we can, indeed, make decisions
eight times a year, not just four times—at press conference meetings. But, of course, I do
understand the preference of not a few FOMC members for December.
To conclude, I support alternative B and believe that in our statements, we should
emphasize that we stand by our frequently repeated statement that we expect the beginning of
normalization to occur in 2015. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Madam Chair. I wasn’t going to comment on our external
communications, but I have to say I’m now going to do so because of this reference that was
made to a Yellen put.
I want to recall what the Chair has said, both externally and internally. At her June press
conference, she laid out a way of thinking about when, whether, and how we are going to raise

September 16–17, 2015

178 of 240

rates. She made reference to the SEP, which, as a factual matter, indicated that most, though not
all, participants in the FOMC, under expected conditions, thought that it would be appropriate to
raise rates later in the year. She scrupulously stayed away from any reference to a particular
month.
In our July meeting, the Chair at one point said, “Opining in public on the exact timing of
the first move, in my own view, not only detracts from our consensus-driven deliberative
process, but also can easily confuse markets and the general public, adding to volatility and,
ultimately, diminishing the effectiveness and credibility of our policy.” A few minutes later, she
went on to say, “So my suggestion for all of us is to refrain from speculating about the time of
liftoff.” Within days of the end of our FOMC meeting, many FOMC participants were out
talking about when they thought liftoff might be appropriate. There was always some formalistic
caveat stuck in there, but we all know what happens with the press when you talk about a
particular month. And that’s exactly what happened.
Maybe their intent was to try to move public expectations toward a September liftoff. At
that juncture, understandably, sentiment began to shift toward an expectation that September was
going to be the month. Then, with the China developments, there was renewed speculation about
whether that would, in fact, be the case. Now, assuming we go with alternative B—which it
sounds as though we’re going to do—with that outcome, there is, indeed, some risk that some
commentators and observers out there say, “Oh, they were ready to go, but then you had this
market instability. So, once again, the Fed feels as though it has to support markets.” I
genuinely do not believe that that risk would be as high as it is had everyone followed what the
Chair asked for in the July meeting, because it would not look as though we had done a
reversal—we lean toward September, and then, when the market instability arises, we don’t do it.

September 16–17, 2015

179 of 240

The Chair herself had set out an analytical framework that, by definition, was withholding
judgment on that.
I realize that any plea for self-discipline and collegiality is probably not going to have
much effect, but I think this is an instance in which we do run some risk of someone saying
something along those lines. But it’s because, I think, we didn’t follow the guidance that she
gave both in her June press conference and just among us in the July meeting.
Turning to the substance of this decision today, as I mentioned yesterday: I’d looked at
our SEPs for the past few years, seeing how wrong we had all been, myself included, about
where both inflation and unemployment were going to be. So I went back to look at what I said
during the economic and monetary policy go-rounds late last year, and I confirmed my own
memory that I actually expected us to be in a different place. I did expect to be on the cusp of a
decision to raise rates, based on the way I thought the economy would go. But that isn’t the way
things have turned out, and I wanted to explain why, as I said in July, I didn’t think it was likely
that I would be for a rate increase in September, although I was open to the possibility that some
things would happen in the interim that would change my mind.
I guess what I’m saying is, it didn’t take the China problems to get me to the position I
am taking today. People have alluded to this already—actual inflation, both core and headline, is
not moving in the direction of our target, and it hasn’t started moving there over the past couple
of meetings. Market measures of inflation compensation have actually drifted down a little bit,
as people noticed. Even the talismanic inflation expectations, on which we put so much
emphasis—they’re still there, but, even at the edge, there’s been a little shakiness as well.
People refer to the transitory factors, and, surely, both the dollar and oil prices themselves at
some point are going to start to have less effect on inflation.

September 16–17, 2015

180 of 240

But I do think it’s worth noting that it’s been several years now that there’s been some
reason why inflation is held down, contrary to the expectations that almost everybody on this
Committee, to a greater or lesser degree, has had during that period. This is the old Roseanne
Roseannadanna line on Saturday Night Live: “It’s always something.” It’s always something
that fades, but then something else comes in. It’s a little hard to escape the observation that
inflation has been running lower—and by a significant amount—than we all were projecting it
would be moving a year or two or three ago.
In that context, I think one has to start asking the question, “Is something different going
on here?” We talk a lot about what’s “normal” or “natural.” Those are dangerous words in
analysis because they can be a substitute for analysis—just to say, “Well, we know where the
end point is. It’s where we were before.” Sometimes, as a matter of everyday life, that’s
probably the best way to proceed. But when you come to consequential decisions after a period
in which some very unusual things have happened, it’s probably a good idea to ask yourself
whether yesterday’s normal or yesterday’s natural is still normal or natural today.
Quite apart from economics, I believe we can all think of things that, 30 years ago, were
regarded as normal and natural, but that we today regard as aberrant. Since coming here,
because I wasn’t schooled in this stuff formally, I’ve tried to read a lot of monetary policy
history. I’m struck by the fact that, over time—and I’m not just talking about the Federal
Reserve—central banks generally have made many mistakes, both to a hawkish and a dovish
outcome, because of the fact that they didn’t appreciate that the external conditions in economic
and financial markets had changed.
Now, you can’t do that every meeting, and you shouldn’t do it every meeting. But we’ve
been through this period when the economy has defied our predictions both with respect to

September 16–17, 2015

181 of 240

unemployment and with respect to inflation, and it’s done so consistently. Under those
circumstances, I think you at least have to start asking yourself that question.
I surely don’t have some substitute paradigm for thinking about inflation and monetary
policy today, but it’s that perspective that has led me to what I characterized yesterday as my
show-me attitude—not that inflation has to be at 2 percent, for heaven’s sake. That’s a
caricature. That’s not it. It’s looking for some evidence that we are actually moving in that
direction.
As I said yesterday, it can happen. If I were sitting on the U.K. MPC right now, I would
feel quite differently—with above-trend growth; inflation having moved up to, I believe, 1.6
percent and people seeming to expect it to inch up a couple of tenths more; and a nice 2.9 percent
wage gain. Frankly, a year ago, I thought we’d be around there right now and I really would feel
quite differently. But we’re not there, and there are risks to moving when I’m not seeing enough
momentum to give us some assurance that we’ve got a bit of a buffer.
It’s not a matter of, “Oh, there’s so much uncertainty.” Of course, there’s always
uncertainty. And it’s not a matter of saying, “We’ve got to get to 2.” For me, it wouldn’t even
necessarily have to be headline or core inflation or wages—it’s got to be something, though, and
that’s what I’m not seeing right now and haven’t for a while.
I want to say that I looked through the 2011 spike in commodity prices, so I know that
people look through things. But what I worry about is, we continue to tell ourselves we’re going
to look through everything, and we continue to keep looking through things, even though it’s
different things year after year. So that’s really the perspective.
I’ll offer a couple of concluding comments. First, I fully understand what the Chair and
others have said about why it’s not just liftoff, but the path of interest rates and all of that—the

September 16–17, 2015

182 of 240

Chair and Governor Fischer both said it in the go-round today. But liftoff does matter. If David
just puts 25 basis points into the models, it doesn’t seem to matter that much. But I think it does
matter because it’s going to communicate to the world how we are thinking about inflation and
our willingness to do things when inflation is where it is. I don’t think we can get around the
fact that the first move will be heavily scrutinized and interpreted.
Second, let’s not fool ourselves, either. We can talk until we’re blue in the face about
how, “Oh, we want a shallow path. We’re going to do one move, and we’re going to sit back.”
Speculation will immediately turn to, “When are they going to move next? And how frequently
are they going to do it? Do they have a timetable? Every other meeting? Every meeting? Every
third meeting? Every fourth and a half meeting? What is their presumption here?” So I don’t
think we’re going to escape those issues.
Finally, on language, I agree with President Lockhart’s top-level point but disagree with
the second point. The top-level point is, it would be good if, even internally, we could get some
more agreement and then possibly communicate it externally. Where I differ, for the reason I
said a minute ago, is in the articulation that we’re reasonably confident that inflation is there.
The improvement in the labor market is a more or less objective thing. You can argue whether
there is enough progress here or there. But either there is or there isn’t. I think that, to many
people, the reasonable confidence about inflation has come down to, “Look, we just think we’re
close enough to eliminating slack that it’s going to start happening.” That may not be irrational,
but it’s still highly subjective, and it’s hard as a basis for coming together on something that we
can agree on, even internally, as a trigger. But I definitely think it would be worth the effort.
Regarding President George’s comments, I couldn’t agree more. With respect to the data
point issue, we do not want the world thinking, “Their decision turns on whether the next

September 16–17, 2015

183 of 240

employment report is 210,000 jobs or 140,000 jobs.” That’s just not where we want to be. As
President George said, getting the discussion to be more about the outlook will be much more
productive, even if we have different outlooks individually. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Madam Chair. I will support alternative B today as written.
For me, this has been a close call, and I do think you can make the case in a pretty strong form
on either side of this decision for today. In fact, that’s exactly what the Chair did in her opening
remarks.
The Committee has guided markets to expect liftoff by the end of this year, subject to
incoming data. Those data have been, on balance, perhaps a little better than expected. But we
have additional disinflationary forces arriving, albeit ones we view as transitory, and a higher
risk of a global slowdown. In addition, U.S. financial conditions have tightened since the July
meeting by well more than 25 basis points, according to well-publicized external estimates. So
there’s no sense of the Committee getting behind the curve. To me, it makes sense to defer
liftoff for this meeting to let both the inflation picture and the global situation settle down.
I do not view the situation as it exists today as justifying a lengthy delay before liftoff. I
don’t see a need to see the rates of inflation or nominal wage growth rising prior to our liftoff. I
would be satisfied with at least some reasonable stability in the dollar, so that we could be sure
that the recurring temporary factors holding down inflation are finally abating. I would, of
course, also need to see continuing growth to support ongoing tightening in the economy.
Frankly, if real GDP growth is strong enough, then I might be persuaded to lift off even in the
absence of other factors.

September 16–17, 2015

184 of 240

Turning briefly to the Committee’s two-part test for liftoff: I view the first part of the
test—some further improvement in the labor market—as met for this meeting. There’s been
substantial improvement in the labor market. And, while there’s no doubt additional slack,
unemployment is now at or near most estimates of the natural rate. Even if the natural rate—
either the short-term rate or the longer-term rate—is significantly lower than current estimates,
which is a distinct possibility, we’re already on a path, it seems to me, to unemployment in the
mid-to-low 4s by the end of 2016. So, from this perspective solely, I think it’s getting to be
about time to start raising interest rates.But the inflation test is more complicated. In the
Tealbook baseline, inflation returns to 1.9 percent in 2018, which, one might argue, is itself a
decent argument that the test is met. After all, the test is appropriately about the medium term.
But today inflation is not just well below the 2 percent objective. It’s also very likely to decline
in the coming months, albeit due to factors we view as transitory. So declaring the inflation test
to be met would require the Committee to look through a substantial transition period and place a
great deal of weight on the Phillips curve.
To put it simply, intermeeting developments have not increased my confidence of
inflation moving toward 2 percent in the medium term. I see this as a problem, and I see a risk
of sending a signal to markets that the Committee is not serious about the 2 percent objective.
For me, delaying liftoff for a meeting or two may provide some evidence that we’re serious
about reaching the 2 percent objective and allow time to understand the evolution of global
developments.
There’s been some discussion of a so-called dovish raise, whereby the Committee would
raise interest rates at this meeting or a subsequent meeting, but then wait for some time to let the
effects settle in. The sense of this is that the Committee’s communications have been confusing

September 16–17, 2015

185 of 240

to the markets—you hear this from market participants quite a bit—and that we’re, in effect,
getting in the way of the economy now, as the Chair referenced in her remarks, and causing
trouble in the markets. That will become increasingly the case if uncertainty increases, and we
ought to just lift off get it over with. Now, I don’t support that approach at this meeting, but I do
think that if either the October meeting or the December meeting provides a reasonable
opportunity to go ahead and lift off, I would be inclined to look very carefully at that and take it,
if possible.
We had a chart today that Thomas presented that showed the distribution of expected
timing of liftoff by FOMC meeting. I’d really like to see the likelihood of liftoff be way north of
50 percent by the time we lift off. In fact, in my perfect world, it would be 100 percent. But I
realize that’s not likely in a world in which the Committee is of different views and in which
we’re being very data driven. I’d still like to see that be much higher than 50 percent, and I think
it would be very unwise to lift off at a time when the market is not expecting it. Thank you,
Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Governor Brainard.
MS. BRAINARD. Thank you, Madam Chair. Well, I appreciate the opportunity to hear
from all but one member of the Committee, and many of the considerations that have been, I
think, very eloquently put on the table on both sides of this debate also affect my own judgment
about the appropriate policy rate path.
As many of you have stated, in recent months, domestic real activity has expanded at a
resilient pace. We’ve seen improvement in consumption, growth, housing, and the labor market.
The U-3 measure of unemployment has declined further, suggesting a reduction in labor market
slack, although the absence of any firming in any wage or compensation measures suggests that

September 16–17, 2015

186 of 240

some slack remains on other margins, such as participation and involuntary part-time
employment.
By contrast, headline inflation has moved further away from our target during the
intermeeting period. Market-based measures of inflation expectations have again drifted down,
and the 12-month change in core PCE inflation appears stubbornly mired at around 1¼ percent,
where it has been for some years now.
These developments lead me to conclude we are likely still in the quadrant of inflation–
resource utilization space in which both our full employment and inflation objectives are
consistent with accommodation. I sense some concern that, by continuing accommodation at
current levels, the economy could soon breach resource constraints. But there is a risk associated
with that approach, in light of the fact that monetary policy acts with a lag, and that it may lead
to a buildup of inflationary pressures, a rise in inflation expectations, and, consequently,
persistent inflation materially in excess of our 2 percent target. However, the persistent and
sizable deflationary forces from the international environment, the estimated small effect of
resource utilization on inflation, the persistence of core inflation materially below our 2 percent
target, and the important gravitational force of inflation expectations suggest that this risk is
likely still to be relatively modest.
Financial markets appear to agree with that judgment. Perhaps most important, we have
substantial policy space for addressing this risk. Thus, while it is important to remain vigilant
with regard to the possibility of an unexpected emergence of inflationary pressures, I believe
that, at present, we should place considerably more weight on a different risk—that the
underlying momentum in the domestic economy is not strong enough to withstand the
considerable deflationary pull of the international environment. In these circumstances, by

September 16–17, 2015

187 of 240

tightening prematurely, we risk falling short of both our inflation and full employment targets
over the medium term.
Indeed, for those who believe that a hike of 25 basis points might be warranted in
September, macro models at the Board and elsewhere suggest that intermeeting international
developments alone have produced a notable tightening in U.S. financial conditions roughly
equivalent to an increase of 50 basis points in the federal funds rate. And it’s important to
underscore that most of that—indeed, almost all of it—comes from exchange rate movements
and not from movements in equity markets or domestic financial markets that may prove
temporary.
Moreover, as I discussed yesterday, the risks to the U.S. outlook from additional
international headwinds are weighted to the downside. China appears to be only partway
through a complicated adjustment of its exchange rate regime and broader financial market
reforms, and it faces considerable challenges regarding the clarity of communications as well as
piercing the fog surrounding its macroeconomic data. In these circumstances, any further policy
moves could prompt a broader reassessment of underlying fundamentals that could, in turn, be
amplified by real or perceived linkages to the exchange rates of other important economies in
their neighborhood as well as to important commodity producers. In that regard, as has been
noted, two of our closest trade partners, Canada and Mexico, have already seen sizable currency
depreciations. I view these effects on the U.S. economy as likely to be relatively persistent.
Indeed, over the past year, we’ve seen a strong feedback loop between expectations of policy
divergence between the U.S. and our major trade partners, and financial tightening that takes
place through exchange rate and financial market channels, which front-runs our policy process.

September 16–17, 2015

188 of 240

In addition, my reading of the risks is informed by the large majority of episodes in
recent years in which policy tightening in other advanced economies, prompted by improving
domestic activity, was soon followed by a reversal of policy and, in several important cases,
subsequent migration to the effective lower bound and beyond. Those episodes have all proved
costly. I think we could find only one exception, Iceland, which has several very special features
as a result of their financial crisis. Moreover, from the perspective of risk management, we have
considerably greater latitude to adjust the path of policy in response to higher-than-expected
inflation than we have to provide additional accommodation in response to additional financial
tightening.
In light of that—both the substantial financial tightening that has taken place and its
likely effect on the outlook, the additional downside risks that could materialize from global
developments, and the asymmetry of risk-management considerations—the risks of moving
prematurely seem to me to outweigh the risks of waiting.
Alternative B provides a nice summary of the Committee’s outlook and how that is likely
to condition the policy rate path for the period ahead. Paragraph 1 provides a good description of
recent developments, contrasting the reassuring growth in the many domestic components of
aggregate demand and progress on employment with considerable softness in net exports and the
additional restraint on headline inflation and market-based measures of inflation expectations. I
would note that the one important piece of information missing from this paragraph that certainly
informs my thinking is the soft indicators that have come in across the board on compensation.
I strongly support the sentence in paragraph 2 that describes the implications of
developments abroad for risk considerations. I think it’s important to acknowledge that foreign
developments are a key risk to the achievement of our objectives. Inclusion of this language

September 16–17, 2015

189 of 240

enhances the clarity of our communications by informing observers that we are paying attention
to these developments because of their potential effect, through many channels, on the U.S.
outlook. My own judgment is that recent global developments and possible future developments
pose downside risks to the outlook, but I can support the more neutral language and alternative B
more generally. Thank you, Madam Chair.
CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Madam Chair. I support alternative B as
written. I was hoping that I could support lifting off at this meeting for two reasons. First, it
would have meant that we had satisfied our criteria of labor market improvement and confidence
that inflation will return to our 2 percent objective over the medium term. Second, as I said at
earlier meetings, September is a better month to begin normalization than December, economic
conditions and outlook being equal.
Unfortunately, the global economy has not cooperated. I think there are significant risks
to the growth outlook that make it uncertain whether we will see further improvement in the
labor market and whether we will see inflation returning to our 2 percent objective over the
medium term. In terms of what happens from here, I hope the international outlook improves
and financial conditions stabilize. If this happens and U.S. growth stays on track, then I could
support lifting off relatively soon, certainly later this year. I’ve argued that December is not
ideal in terms of market functioning considerations. I don’t think that should be sufficient by
itself to deter us if everything else lines up in support of moving.
With respect to moving in October, I don’t believe we should rule that out as an option.
But if we did move in October, that might demonstrate an urgency that would be difficult to

September 16–17, 2015

190 of 240

reconcile with the fact that we have relatively sluggish growth and still-too-low inflation. People
might be confused. What’s the rush of moving in October?
I see the bar for moving at a meeting without a press conference as somewhat higher than
that for moving at a press conference meeting. I just think that’s the reality. So I’d be surprised
if, in six weeks’ time, we got data that push us over the bar.
I am very supportive of Governor Powell’s comments. It would be good for the market
to have a very high probability when we actually move. If things cooperate and everything
moves in a nice way, what I would prefer, rather than moving in October, would be to have a
very “hawky” statement in October that pointed very strongly to December, so that you could get
all of that probability mass on December, and then just go in December. I think that would be a
better way to go. Now, whether the world is going to cooperate like that, we’ll have to see.
Finally, I had a couple of comments on the so-called Yellen put. We really have to
disabuse people of this notion. We care about the economic outlook. Financial conditions
matter in terms of affecting the outlook when they change, and if those changes in financial
conditions are sustained, then we need to take them into consideration. We need to explain that
to people over and over again.
I’m sympathetic with Jim in the sense that this is a risk that people will take this reaction
as a response to financial markets, but I don’t think it is. My views of why we should wait at this
meeting have nothing to do with the fact that the stock market is a little weaker than it was
before. It has to do with the fact that there are actually some real things going on that are
affecting financial conditions, and those changes have a risk for the outlook. I think we need to
explain that over and over again. Thank you, Madam Chair.

September 16–17, 2015

191 of 240

CHAIR YELLEN. Thank you. I heard one suggestion in the go-round for a language
change in alternative B, but I think most of you who support alternative B indicated your
preference to go ahead with it as written. So unless I hear a groundswell of support for some
change, I’d like to propose that we vote on alternative B as written. Matt?
MR. LUECKE. This vote will cover alternative B on pages 6 and 7 of Thomas’s handout
and the directive on page 11 of that handout.
Chair Yellen
Vice Chairman Dudley
Governor Brainard
President Evans
Governor Fischer
President Lacker
President Lockhart
Governor Powell
Governor Tarullo
President Williams

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIR YELLEN. I recognize that, around the table, there is considerable support for
moving—if not today, then in the near future—and I promise that in my press conference, I will
do everything I can to emphasize that. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. My staff argued me out of raising a bunch of questions around
December, and Vice Chairman Dudley just addressed this. Could I ask Simon and Lorie to
comment? Sitting far from it, should I be concerned about what we’ve heard before regarding
the thinness of the market? Should I also have some concern about whether you have any
staffing issues or whether you’re just going to declare that everyone will need to cancel all of
their plans and be there for that period? In addition, I’d like to know whether there are other
execution considerations in December that, as we get conceivably closer to it, could cause us to
get more nervous that it’s too tricky. Could you address that?

September 16–17, 2015

192 of 240

MR. POTTER. I’ve got no concerns. If you want to lift off in three days’ time, we can
do it. So I don’t think you should take that into account. I believe Vice Chairman Dudley’s
viewpoint is, markets tend to be a little bit thinner in December, and some of the impact on
financial conditions could be harder to control. If it’s the case that, leading into that date,
markets are pretty sure liftoff is going to happen in December, then desks will be staffed for
some of the things that you’re interested in. People staff their desks to get cash invested at
year-end, because a lot of cash arrives at year-end. We have complete capacity to do that at any
time. There are no staffing issues. Most of my staff wouldn’t know what decision the
Committee has made until the statement is released.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Another point is, if we do get to a situation in which the
expected probability of a December liftoff are quite high, people are going to staff their desks
appropriately. So getting that probability up actually could have a benefit of minimizing some of
those risks.
CHAIR YELLEN. With respect to October, if I’m asked if it’s a possibility, I’m not
announcing now that I will have a press conference. But I will give the response that I’ve given
in the past—which is that we have the capacity to hold a press briefing if we decide to move.
Then, since every meeting is a “live” possibility, if we decided to move in October, that is what
we would do.
MR. LOCKHART. Would you have to, in your thinking, announce an October press
conference some days ahead of the meeting? Or would you just do it at the meeting?
CHAIR YELLEN. No, we would do it in the meeting. In point of fact, the reporters—
starting with today’s meeting, I guess—will now receive the statement and be writing their
stories to go out when the statement comes out at 2:00. Michelle, please correct me if I say

September 16–17, 2015

193 of 240

anything wrong here. They will be in the lockup room that is directly next door to the room over
on K Street where today, for the first time, I’ll be holding the press conference. In October, if we
wanted to move and they’re there and have the statement, we could actually have a live press
conference. We would just move them next door and do that, or there could be a press briefing.
But there really wouldn’t be any technical problems in doing that.
I could announce now that I would hold a press conference in October, but I think that
would be locking me permanently into press conferences after every meeting. For reasons we’ve
previously discussed, I’d really prefer not to do that. But there are no technical obstacles at all to
doing that.
I will do my best at the press conference to leave later this year a very live option. If the
data come in consistent with a move, as many of you have said, we will, even if we don’t move
in October, have the opportunity to change the statement in a way that raises expectations of a
move. I believe I have an economic outlook speech scheduled for early December and probably
further testimony, and there would be an opportunity, if we think we’re going to do that, to
prepare the markets to expect that that’s going to occur.
If you are staying around and care to watch the press conference, I believe there’s a TV in
the Special Library. Our next meeting will be on Tuesday and Wednesday, October 27 and 28.
END OF MEETING