View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019
October 25, 2013 (Corrected)
October 24, 2013

The Potential Use of Balance Sheet Actions to
Strengthen Forward Rate Guidance 1
Over recent months, FOMC communications about the asset purchase program have at times
been accompanied by movements in market interest rates that seemed outsized relative to the
information content of those communications and that were difficult to reconcile with the
Committee’s forward guidance for the federal funds rate. In light of this experience, the FOMC
might be interested in possibilities for strengthening forward guidance for the federal funds rate
through the use of open market operations and other balance sheet actions. This note reviews
five possible types of balance sheet actions that could be used for this purpose. As background,
section 1 below provides information on the recent behavior of short-term interest rates. Section
2 below provides a brief description of types of balance sheet actions that could be used to
strengthen forward guidance. Section 3 discusses some of the policy, operational, and legal
issues that could be associated with the various alternatives.
As a brief summary, the discussion below considers several possibilities for balance sheet actions
that the FOMC might employ to help keep near-term interest rate expectations reasonably well
aligned with the Committee’s forward guidance. Two of the alternatives discussed below would
be aimed at providing primary dealers with greater certainty about the path of short-term interest
rates, either by conducting long-term repurchase agreement operations or by establishing a
standing facility for overnight repurchase agreement operations. In two other alternatives, the
Federal Reserve could conduct open market operations in shorter-term Treasury securities, either
by standard outright operations or through operations in forward markets. Some variations of
these alternatives could involve announcing an explicit cap on shorter-term Treasury yields. A
final alternative considers the possibility of lowering the IOER and establishing a full-scale,
fixed-rate, overnight RRP facility. As discussed in the final section, all of these operations seem
potentially useful, although there are a number of technical and operational issues that would
need to be sorted through prior to implementing such programs. Two basic issues that merit
further analysis for any of these alternatives would be how effective they are likely to be in
influencing the path of short-term interest rates, and how the use of such tools would be
incorporated into the Committee’s overall monetary policy strategy and communications.

1. Background
Over recent months, news pointing to a sooner-than-anticipated reduction in the pace of asset
purchases has been associated with notable upward revisions in money market futures rates. For
example, following the Chairman’s press conference last June, implied rates on Eurodollar
futures maturing in late 2015 moved up 25 basis points; implied rates on contracts maturing in
June and September 2014 also increased noticeably. More broadly, as shown in figure 1, the
path of forward federal funds rate rates derived from OIS quotes moved up sharply from early
May to early September but has since moved back down, largely following the September
1

Board: Scott Alvarez, Alain Chaboud, Jim Clouse, Burcu Duygan-Bump, William English, Yuriy Kitsul, Michael
Leahy, Robert Martin, William Nelson, Min Wei; FRBNY: Benson Durham, James Egelhof , Michelle Ezer, Joshua
Frost, Frank Keane, Lorie Logan, Mike McMorrow, Simon Potter, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache.

Page 1 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

FOMC meeting. As shown in tables 1-3, judging from the results of primary dealer surveys,
these shifts in forward rates did not seem to be occasioned by sharp revisions in investors’
economic outlook.
Shifts in the forward federal funds rate curve can reflect revisions in the expected funds rate path
and in term premiums, and news about the pace of purchases could affect both of these
components. News about the pace of purchases could be associated with shifts in the expected
path for the federal funds rate for several reasons. For example, if the reduction in the pace of
purchases is taken by investors as a reduction in policy accommodation that would need to be
offset through more accommodative funds rate policy, then all else equal, the expected date of
liftoff might shift out or the trajectory after liftoff could shift down. On the other hand, if a
prospective reduction in asset purchases is taken as news that the economic outlook is better than
previously thought, investors’ expected date of liftoff could move in and their expected funds
rate path thereafter could shift up. Alternatively, if the reduction in the pace of purchases is seen
as motivated by financial stability concerns related to the low level of interest rates, it might be
natural for market participants to raise the odds that the date of liftoff for the funds rate will be
sooner than previously thought and the post-liftoff trajectory for the funds rate could be steeper
as well.
News about the pace of asset purchases could also affect term premiums. For example, news
pointing to an increased likelihood of a reduction in the pace of asset purchases could spur an
increase in uncertainty about the future path of short-term rates or an increase in investors’
aversion to risk. Both of these factors could contribute to higher term premiums and thus
increase yields.
While it is very difficult to disentangle all of these possible effects on expected federal funds
rates and term premiums, a staff term structure model does suggest that a sizable portion of the
increase in OIS rates over the summer was associated with an increase in term premiums. That
conclusion seems consistent with an uptick in some measures of policy uncertainty. As shown in
figure 2, the model also suggests a significant amount of variation in the model-implied expected
path of the federal funds rate and the anticipated date of the initial increase in the target federal
funds rate. For example, in early September, this model suggests that the expected funds rate
path had moved up considerably relative to its level in early May and the date of the liftoff for
the federal funds rate had been pulled forward appreciably as well.
While clear communications should help investors better understand the distinct roles of asset
purchases and the forward guidance for the funds rate, it is certainly possible that news about a
possible reduction in the pace of asset purchases could once again prompt increases in the
expected path of the federal funds rate or term premiums and thus produce an unintended
tightening in overall financial conditions. That possibility provides an important motivation for
possible steps the Federal Reserve could take with open market operations and other balance
sheet actions to strengthen the forward guidance for the federal funds rate and push against shifts
in short-term rates that run counter to the FOMC’s intentions.

Page 2 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

Figure 1: OIS-implied Instantaneous Forward Rates
Percent
May 1, 2013
Sep. 5, 2013
Oct. 21, 2013

3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0

May

Aug.
2013

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2014

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2015

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2016

Nov.

Feb.
2017

Figure 2: OIS-implied Expected Policy Rate Path (Mean)
Percent
May 1, 2013
Sep. 5, 2013
Oct. 21, 2013

3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0

May

Aug.
2013

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2014

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2015

Page 3 of 13

Nov.

Feb.

May Aug.
2016

Nov.

Feb.
2017

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

Primary Dealer Forecasts at Recent FOMC Meetings
(Medians Across Dealers)

Table 1: Unemployment Rate (Q4 Level)
May Meeting
June Meeting
July Meeting
September Meeting

2013
7.40%
7.30%
7.30%
7.20%

2014
6.85%
6.80%
6.60%
6.60%

2015
6.30%
6.30%
6.20%
6.10%

Table 2: GDP Growth (Q4/Q4 Growth)
May Meeting
June Meeting
July Meeting
September Meeting

2013
2.40%
2.20%
1.90%
2.00%

2014
2.80%
2.80%
2.80%
2.75%

2015
3.00%
3.00%
3.00%
3.00%

Table 3: Inflation (Headline PCE, Q4/Q4 growth)
May Meeting
June Meeting
July Meeting
September Meeting

2013
1.60%
1.30%
1.30%
1.30%

2014
1.90%
1.90%
1.80%
1.80%

2015
2.00%
2.00%
2.00%
1.90%

Page 4 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

2.

Alternatives for Open Market Operations and Other Balance Sheet Actions

The discussion below reviews five possible types of balance sheet actions that could be used to
strengthen the FOMC’s forward guidance. Under the first program, the Federal Reserve would
create a standing term repo facility for primary dealers with an announced rate and time period
for which this facility would be operational. This facility could be structured to encourage
counterparties to purchase shorter-dated Treasury securities, thereby driving down the yields on
those securities. By establishing a low rate for term repurchase agreements through a given date,
such a facility may also have an important signaling effect in influencing the expected future
path of the target federal funds rate. Under the second program, the Federal Reserve would
create a standing purchase facility to enforce an announced cap on yields at the short end of the
Treasury yield curve. In this case, the Federal Reserve would stand ready to purchase Treasury
securities with relatively short maturities, at prices that correspond to a predetermined yield to
maturity. Under a third type of program, the Federal Reserve could create a cap on overnight
repo rates by establishing a standing overnight repo facility. The Federal Reserve could
announce that primary dealers may enter repurchase agreements with the Federal Reserve at a
pre-determined rate that would be available as long as one of the thresholds in the forward
guidance for the federal funds rate had not been crossed. Certainty regarding the rate for such
repurchase transactions should help to counter any upward pressures on expected short-term
rates that are not driven by changes in the economic outlook. As a variation on this approach,
the Federal Reserve could consider auctioning options that provide the holder with the right to
enter overnight repurchase agreements with the Federal Reserve at the pre-determined rate at any
time before one of the thresholds is crossed. A fourth alternative for balance sheet actions would
involve the Federal Reserve operating in forward markets for short-term Treasury securities as a
way of putting direct downward pressure on forward yields and signaling the FOMC’s intentions
regarding the path of future short rates. The possibility of lowering the interest rate paid on
excess reserves (the IOER rate), perhaps coupled with a fully operational fixed-rate, full
allotment overnight RRP facility is discussed below as alternative 5.
While each of these alternatives is discussed separately below, some could be used in
combination. For example, the Federal Reserve could establish a standing overnight repo facility
as in alternative 3 and also conduct purchases of shorter-term Treasury securities as in
alternative 2 or in forward markets as in alternative 4. Moreover, all of the alternatives for open
market operations could be coupled with other actions, such as a reduction in the IOER rate or
changes in statement language that could further emphasize the Federal Reserve’s intention to
keep rates at exceptionally low levels at least until the unemployment or inflation thresholds are
reached. 2

2

For example, the forward guidance language in the last paragraph of recent FOMC statements could be
strengthened to more clearly rule out situations in which the federal funds rate might be increased prior to the time
when one of the thresholds has been reached. This might be accomplished by stating that the Committee “will”
keep the target rate at its current level (rather than “currently anticipates”) until one of the thresholds has been
crossed. Moreover, as discussed in the Tealbook, the FOMC could clarify that other factors that will determine how
long the FOMC maintains an exceptionally low federal funds rate will come into play only after a threshold has been
crossed.

Page 5 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

Alternative 1: Standing Fixed-Rate Term Repo Facility
Description: Under this program, the Federal Reserve would establish a standing term repo
facility that would provide term repurchase agreements to primary dealers at a single, fixed rate
established by the FOMC. Term repurchase agreements under the facility would be provided to
primary dealers until an announced date, with the tenor of repos extending up to that date. The
Committee could, of course, choose whatever date it wished, but for the purpose of this
discussion we will assume that term repos are provided with maturities at the end of 2014. 3
Under the most straightforward version of this facility, the Federal Reserve would accept any
OMO-eligible collateral in these term repo operations. Under another variation, the collateral
eligible to be pledged in these operations could be limited to only Treasury securities that mature
prior to the end of 2014. In some ways, this version of the program would act like a “funding for
lending” facility aimed specifically at lowering the yields on shorter-term Treasury securities. 4
Under either version of the program, primary dealers would have an incentive to bid up the
prices of any eligible securities with yields exceeding the Federal Reserve’s term repo facility
rate. Ultimately, yields on shorter-term securities should be driven down close to the Federal
Reserve’s term repo rate if investors are confident that the term repo facility would remain open
until the end of 2014 (the announced date for the conclusion of the term financing facility).
An Example: Based on current quotes, the yields on Treasury securities maturing from now to
the end of 2014 rise from about 0 basis points in the very near term to about 20 basis points on
those maturing at the end of 2014. Based on these quotes, if the Federal Reserve offered term
repo agreements at 15 basis points to the end of 2014, primary dealers would currently have an
incentive to bid up the prices for Treasury securities with maturities close to the end of 2014 and
pledge those securities in Fed term RP operations. 5 Primary dealers should continue to purchase
such securities to eliminate any risk-free arbitrage, and that process should drive yields on these
securities to a rate just a little above 15 basis points, with the spread over the Federal Reserve’s
term repo rate reflecting dealers’ intermediation costs. 6
Alternative 2: A Standing Purchase Facility
Description: As a closely related alternative to a term repo facility, the Federal Reserve could
announce a cap for yields on Treasury securities that mature prior to the end of 2014 and then
3

As discussed in more detail in section 3, there are significant complications associated with combining a datebased market mechanism such as this with the FOMC’s threshold-based forward guidance for the federal funds rate.
4
One distinction between this proposed program and funding for lending programs is that the latter are aimed at
increasing the aggregate supply of bank loans. In contrast, the aggregate supply of Treasury bills is largely
exogenous, but the availability of term repurchase agreements for primary dealers could induce them to hold more
Treasury bills in their inventories than would otherwise be the case and drive down the yields on Treasury bills in
the process. For more information on funding for lending facilities, see the memos on this topic prepared for the
September 2012 FOMC meeting entitled “Discount Window Options to Boost Bank Lending,” and “Recent
Initiatives to Boost Bank Lending by the Bank of England and the Bank of Japan.”
5
If the Federal Reserve wished to offer term repo at 15 basis points, policymakers presumably would choose to
lower the interest rate on excess reserves (IOER). This possibility is discussed in more detail in alternative 5.
6
The average spread between the rates on repurchase agreements and reverse repurchase agreement is one common
measure of dealer intermediation costs; current repo-reverse spreads are about 5 basis points.

Page 6 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

conduct open market operations so as to keep yields on eligible securities below the cap. 7 Under
this type of program, the Federal Reserve could announce a cap of, say, 20 basis points, on all
Treasury securities maturing prior to the end of 2014 and conduct open market operations to
keep yields on short-dated securities below that cap.
To take a specific example, the Federal Reserve could announce that, until further notice, it stood
ready to purchase any nominal Treasury security that matured on or before December 31, 2014,
at a price consistent with a yield of 20 basis points. As time passed, the maturity date of
securities eligible for purchase would not necessarily change. Any program with explicit caps of
this sort raises questions about the extent of Federal Reserve operations necessary to enforce the
cap and the behavior of interest rates in cases when market participants anticipate the cap could
be eliminated. 8
Alternative 3: Overnight Repo Operations– Standing Facility or Options
Description: Under this type of program, the Federal Reserve would stand ready to provide
overnight repos against all OMO-eligible collateral at a pre-determined rate to primary dealers as
long as one of the thresholds in the forward guidance for the federal funds rate had not been
crossed. The program could be implemented either as a standing fixed-rate overnight repo
facility or through the sale of options that provided the holder with the right to obtain overnight
repos from the Federal Reserve at a pre-determined rate.
Under the standing facility approach, the Federal Reserve would announce that it would conduct
fixed-rate, full allotment, overnight RP operations every day at, say, 20 basis points until one of
the thresholds is reached. The availability of repos from this facility and the expectation that
such transactions would remain available at this rate until one of the thresholds is crossed should
help to establish a cap on current and expected future repo rates at 20 basis points.
Under the option approach, the Federal Reserve would auction options that provide the holder
with the right to enter overnight repurchase agreements with the Federal Reserve at 20 basis
points as long one of the thresholds had not been breached. 9
7

The Federal Reserve operated such a regime during the 1940s as part of government-wide efforts to facilitate war
time finance. For more information on this historical episode, see the memo prepared for the June 2003 FOMC
meeting entitled “Targeting the Yield Curve: The Experience of the Federal Reserve, 1942-51.”
8
Additional information on the use of open market operations and caps to target points on the yield curve is
provided in the memo prepared for the October 2010 FOMC meeting entitled “Strategies for Targeting Interest
Rates Out the Yield Curve.”
9
The Federal Reserve has sold options on two previous occasions. In the months leading up to Y2K, the Federal
Reserve sold options that provided dealers with the right to obtain overnight repos from the Federal Reserve over
specified periods at a rate set 150 basis points over the target federal funds rate. The options sold at a low price,
reflecting market confidence that interest rates would be kept low, but they were an effective means to bolster
market confidence that repo financing would be available over the century date change. The Federal Reserve also
sold options during the financial crisis under the TOP program. Options under this program provided the owner
with the right to obtain short-term TSLF loans at a predetermined fee over selected dates. The TOP was largely
intended to ease dealer financing pressures around key dates such as quarter-ends and year-ends. All TOP auctions
offered TSLF loans against so-called “schedule 2” collateral—a basket that included standard OMO eligible
collateral along with other private investment-grade securities that met the requirements of the TSLF program.

Page 7 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

Alternative 4: Operations in Forward Markets
Description: Analogous to the operations of some central banks in forward FX markets, the
Federal Reserve might be able to use operations in near-dated forward markets for Treasury
securities to provide a signal about its expected path of short-term rates. 10 Under this alternative,
the Federal Reserve would enter into forward agreements to purchase, say, six-month Treasury
bills at some point in the future. For example, the Federal Reserve could agree today to purchase
six-month bills at selected points in the future—perhaps 12 months from now, 18 months from
now and so on. 11 The purchase of six-month bills would allow operations targeting fairly narrow
segments of the yield curve. This type of program could be implemented with announced caps
on forward yields or, alternatively, through discretionary operations. In the latter case, the
Federal Reserve’s actions to purchase short-term securities on a forward basis could provide a
strong signal that it considered forward short-term yields to be too high, thus putting downward
pressure on expected future short rates.
A forward operation of this sort could have some advantages relative to purchasing securities
today with 18 to 24 month maturities. For example, forward purchases could be concentrated on
the particular parts of the yield curve where pressures seemed to be mounting. 12 Moreover,
when the Federal Reserve took delivery of the short-term securities upon settlement of forward
contracts, these securities would mature quickly, so the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet would not be affected for a lengthy period.
Alternative 5: Reduction in IOER and Full Scale ON RRP Facility
Another possibility that the Federal Reserve could consider as a way to underscore its intention
to keep the target federal funds rate low until the thresholds are crossed is to lower the IOER
rate. For example, the Committee might contemplate taking this action at the time when it
begins to reduce its pace of asset purchases. Currently, the IOER rate is set at 25 basis points
and the Federal Reserve could consider cutting this rate to, say, 15 basis points. In the past,
policymakers have been somewhat reluctant to reduce IOER because of possible adverse effects
on market functioning. For example, very low levels of short-term interest rates have been
associated in the past with elevated levels of fails to deliver in securities markets. And there
have been concerns that short-term rates very close to – or below – zero could cause liquidity
pressures for Treasury-only money funds. Now, however, the issue of fails to deliver has largely
been addressed by the fails charges that have been implemented in the Treasury, agency debt,
10

For example, as discussed in the appendix, the Central Bank of Brazil has conducted forward FX operations as
part of its efforts to support the value of the real.
11
Such operations would be similar to taking a long position in federal funds futures or other money market futures.
The focus here on forward purchases of bills is purely illustrative. There may be technical reasons that the Federal
Reserve would wish to take a broader approach by purchasing any outstanding Treasury security with a remaining
maturity of six months. For example, the six-month bill that will be issued twelve months from now is not currently
in existence; as a result, trades based on such a security could be heavily influenced by uncertainties about potential
future Treasury supply decisions and other idiosyncratic aspects of the bill market.
12
The targeting of specific points along the yield curve could be achieved in other ways. For example, a forward
purchase of six-month bills six months from now is approximately equivalent to the purchase today of a 12-month
bill that is financed with term repo for six months.

Page 8 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

and agency MBS markets. Moreover, short-term Treasury bill yields have been close to zero for
some time with no major adverse consequences for money funds. Nonetheless, the FOMC might
remain concerned that additional downward pressure on money market yields stemming from a
cut in IOER could create strains for some markets and institutions.13 To address this issue, the
FOMC could implement a full-scale version of the fixed-rate, full-allotment overnight RRP
facility that is currently being tested. 14 For example, the FOMC could set a rate of 5 or 10 basis
points at this facility and eliminate the current per-counterparty cap of $1 billion. That should
help to set a floor on repo rates at about 5 or 10 basis points. The combination of a reduction in
the IOER along with the introduction of the full-scale overnight RRP facility likely would be
seen as providing a modest additional degree of policy accommodation. This action could also
help to provide a signal that the Federal Reserve intends to keep rates at current levels at least
until the thresholds are crossed. 15 As noted above, that interpretation could be amplified through
appropriate wording changes to the last paragraph of the FOMC statement.
3. Policy, Operational, and Legal Issues
The alternatives discussed above could be helpful tools that the FOMC could use to strengthen
its guidance for the federal funds rate and to lean against unwelcome increases in the expected
path of short-term rates. While the alternatives above could be useful additional tools for the
FOMC, a number of policy, operational and legal issues would require further analysis before
any of these alternatives could be implemented. The discussion below reviews some of these
issues.
Efficacy: There are many questions that should be investigated regarding the likely efficacy of
the various programs discussed above, including their potential effects on longer-term yields and
private yields. Moreover, it would be useful to conduct further analysis regarding the different
channels through which these various operations might affect yields. On a related point, further
analysis of potential effects across markets and institutions would be useful. For example, the
potential impact of an overnight or term RP program could have implications for other cash
lenders in repo markets.
Challenges for Date-Based Mechanisms: Because the Committee’s forward guidance is
expressed in terms of economic thresholds, there are challenges associated with designing
dated-based mechanisms to harden the guidance such as the term repo facility or standing
purchase facility. A key challenge is picking the terminal date for such facilities in light of the
inherent uncertainty about the date when one of the thresholds will be crossed. For example,
based on the confidence bands around the staff forecast, even though the unemployment rate is
not projected to fall below 6½ percent until the first quarter of 2015, there is about a 15 percent
chance that it will do so by the second quarter of 2014. As a result, if the FOMC chose to
13

For more information on possible issues associated with lowering IOER, see the memo prepared for the October
2011 FOMC meeting entitled “Reconsidering Lowering the IOER Rate.”
14
For more information on experience to date with the overnight RRP tests, see the memo for this meeting entitled
“Analysis of Overnight Repurchase Agreement Operations.”
15
Such a program would also provide useful insight into how the overnight RRP facility would impact market rates.
That experience could be quite useful in assessing the potential role of this tool in normalizing the stance of policy
in the future.

Page 9 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

establish a date-based program like those discussed above with an announced end-date beyond
the middle of 2014, it would run the risk of committing to a program aimed at putting downward
pressure on short-term yields at a time when one of the thresholds had been crossed. This type
of complication underscores a significant advantage of some of the alternatives discussed above
that are based on the economic thresholds.
Challenges for Threshold-Based Programs: Developing economic criteria that would determine
the availability of some of the operations discussed above would present some complications.
While it would be relatively straightforward to determine if the unemployment threshold had
been crossed, the FOMC statement is not specific about the definition of projected inflation
between one and two years ahead. Moreover, the forward guidance for the federal funds rate in
the FOMC statement also includes a reference to well-anchored long-term inflation expectations.
Defining economic criteria for a standing facility and for options that are fully consistent with
this statement language could be difficult. One possibility for sidestepping some of these
complications could be to base the criteria for these programs on the FOMC’s own judgment that
one of the thresholds had been crossed. For example, the FOMC could indicate in a post
meeting statement whether it views either of the thresholds as having been crossed. On the other
hand, allowing the condition describing option expiration or the end of the facility to be
determined by the FOMC rather than by explicit, exogenous economic criteria may create some
uncertainty for market participants about the availability of the program.
Discretionary Operations and Soft Caps: Some of the alternatives discussed above involve the
FOMC announcing a hard “cap” on yields at particular maturities or on forward rates. It may be
possible to establish versions of these facilities that would involve only “soft caps.” For
example, under the standing purchase facility or the operations in forward markets, the FOMC
could indicate that it would conduct operations, as appropriate, to keep yields at levels generally
consistent with its forward guidance for the federal funds rate, but it would not announce a
specific target for yields. While discretionary operations of this type may have some advantages,
there would also be challenges. In particular, the governance for such discretionary operations
and the directive to the Desk would need to be designed carefully. Another issue with such
operations is that the discretion and flexibility associated with conducting operations in this way
would also likely entail some lack of transparency and uncertainty for market participants.
These effects could undermine the goals of the program to some extent.
Risk Tolerance and Capacity of Counterparties: Some of the programs described above—the
term and overnight repo programs and the operations in forward markets—could require
counterparties to take on potentially large positions in transactions with the Federal Reserve.
New regulatory requirements may limit the extent to which primary dealers and other possible
counterparties are willing to take on risk positions to take advantage of “low spread” arbitrage
opportunities. Given the possible constraints on arbitrage faced by primary dealers, the Federal
Reserve may need to expand the list of counterparties for some of the programs to be effective.
Of course, the process of vetting and onboarding new types of counterparties could require some
time to evaluate reputational, credit and other risks.
Uncertainty about Uptake: It is difficult to assess how large the operations under these
programs might need to be to achieve their objectives. As one benchmark, some estimates

Page 10 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

suggest that the Federal Reserve’s sales of $600 billion of short-maturity Treasury securities
under the maturity extension program pushed up yields at the front end of the yield curve by
roughly 10 basis points. That experience suggests that pushing down short-term Treasury yields
through market operations could require sizable operations. The period during the 1940s in
which the Federal Reserve acted to keep Treasury yields below caps may also be instructive. In
1947, reflecting its efforts to defend the cap on Treasury bill yields of 3/8 of one percent amid
mounting inflationary pressures, the Federal Reserve’s holdings of Treasury bills rose sharply,
reaching more than 90 percent of outstanding Treasury bills at one point. On the other hand, it’s
possible that the signaling value of some of these operations could be quite powerful in the
current environment, perhaps reducing the need for the Federal Reserve to conduct large scale
operations to achieve a desired change in shorter term yields.
Legal Issues: The legal basis for some of the types of operations described above would require
additional study. For example, the Federal Reserve has no explicit authority to sell options. In
the past, sales of options (for example, the Y2K options) have been authorized under the
“incidental powers provision” of the Federal Reserve Act. Other legal issues could be associated
with standing facilities or purchases at pre-announced rates. The Federal Reserve’s authority for
open market operations requires that purchases and sales of securities must be conducted “in the
open market.” As a result, legal analysis would need to determine whether these programs can
be considered operations “in the open market.”
Credibility: Most of the alternatives described above would depend on investors’ confidence
that the facilities would remain available for a period of time defined by either a date or
economic threshold. If investors came to believe that operations under any of these programs
might be stopped sooner than expected, those expectations could undercut the power of these
programs in strengthening the Federal Reserve’s forward guidance and could lead investors to
question other aspects of the Committee’s communications as well. Similarly, if a strengthening
of the economy resulted in the Federal Reserve seeking to enforce a cap on term interest rates
that was lower than the average expected overnight rate over that term, the Federal Reserve
could end up conducting a very large amount of transactions as the market sought to test the
Federal Reserve’s resolve to defend its cap.
Other Operational Issues: There are a host of other operational issues associated with various
programs involving topics such as accounting complications, margining practices, choosing
appropriate rates and tenors for operations, determining auction formats, evaluating
counterparties, and upgrading automated systems. In some alternatives, there may also be
operational and legal issues to contend with in establishing margin accounts and working out the
details of legal contracts underlying term repo, options, and forward transactions.

Page 11 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

Appendix: Intervention in the Forward Market by the Central Bank of Brazil
Brazil’s Central Bank (BCB) has in recent months taken a number of measures designed to
counter the depreciation of the real against the dollar, including several increases in its main
policy interest rate and frequent interventions in the foreign exchange market. Even though the
BCB has ample foreign exchange reserves (more than 15 percent of GDP) with which to buy its
own currency in the spot market, the central bank has intervened almost exclusively using
operations that essentially amount to intervention in the forward market. In these operations, the
BCB auctions to financial institutions contracts that increase in value with the depreciation of the
Brazilian real against the dollar. 1 In effect, these operations alter the stock of dollar hedging
instruments available in the market, allowing the private sector to transfer exchange rate risk to
the central bank. This provides support for the foreign exchange value of the real against the
dollar.
The BCB announced in late August that it would increase the use of these contracts, committing
to conduct daily auctions of $500 million four days a week until at least the end of 2013. The
BCB stated at the time that these operations would “provide an FX hedge to agents and liquidity
to the FX market.” Since that announcement, the real has appreciated substantially against the
dollar, and dollar interest rates in Brazil have declined, both viewed as evidence of success by
the BCB, albeit amid a broad-based appreciation of emerging market currencies. We note,
however, that the BCB had begun to offer large amounts of these contracts in May of this year,
with little apparent effect on the value of the real at the time.
Brazil’s forward intervention may work through two channels, a forward guidance channel and a
risk transfer channel. First, issuing these contracts likely allows the BCB to provide forward
guidance that is more credible than merely announcing the Bank’s expectations of future
exchange rate movements. The extra credibility arises because the Bank bears a cost if the real
depreciates more than is priced into its contract. Note, however, that the guidance is not precise,
as the BCB does not target a specific level of the exchange rate, but only exerts pressure on the
exchange rate in a certain direction. Second, these contracts transfer the risk of real depreciation
from market participants to the BCB by providing market participants with a synthetic long
dollar position. The contracts therefore reduce the incentive for those market participants to buy
dollars now, removing some of the immediate pressure on the exchange rate.2
These forward transactions by the BCB have no immediate impact on its balance sheet; the
initial value of the contracts is zero and there is no immediate transfer of funds. Nor is there any
1

The contract is officially called the “Selic x U.S. Dollar Swap with Reset” (the Selic rate is Brazil’s equivalent of
our effective federal funds rate). It is often referred to as an FX swap contract, but it is not a standard FX swap or a
standard FX forward. The exact specifications of the contract are complex (it is a fixed for floating swap where the
floating leg has an exchange rate component), but the BCB presents the contract as “for all practical purposes” a
cash-settled futures contract on the dollar-real exchange rate, a description that we find to be accurate. It is a futures
contract because it is a forward instrument that is exchange-traded and margined. The contract results in a loss to
the BCB if the real depreciates more than is implicit in the forward exchange rate, or in a gain to the BCB in the
case of a smaller depreciation or an appreciation of the real. The BCB first used this type of transaction in 2002.
2
This is important, for instance, for the large number of Brazilian firms that have issued dollar-denominated debt
and have upcoming principal or interest payments.

Page 12 of 13

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 01/11/2019

exchange of principal when the contracts mature. Nonetheless, these contracts expose the BCB
to exchange rate risk. Since May 2013, the Bank has accumulated a notional position of almost
$60 billion in these contracts (a short dollar position of 2.7 percent of GDP), and the BCB is
expected to issue another $20 billion by year end.3 The BCB has argued that its current exposure
is offset by the fact that it holds a large amount of foreign currency reserves (worth $370 billion
at present). Therefore the domestic-currency value of the BCB’s dollar reserves would rise with
a weaker real, more than compensating for the drop in value of its forward contracts. In the past,
however, the BCB took the other side of these contracts to fight real appreciation. In that case, if
the real were to appreciate, the BCB’s losses on its foreign reserves would be compounded by its
forward position, as if its holdings of foreign exchange reserves had been leveraged. Of course,
in either case, the Bank could also potentially derive a net profit from its transactions.
The BCB currently issues these contracts through single-price auctions, announcing the quantity
to be auctioned ahead of time; it does not announce a goal for the price that it may be trying to
achieve. The Bank also reserves the right to call additional auctions on short notice. The recent
maturity of the contracts has varied from 60 to 225 days. Most Brazilian financial institutions
can participate in the auctions, even those not authorized to maintain foreign exchange positions,
as the contracts are cash-settled in real, not by physical delivery of dollars. After being
auctioned by the BCB, these contracts are freely tradable on Brazil’s main futures exchange4
until maturity. As such, the positions are marked to market every day, and they are subject to
margin calls. Although the forward positions themselves do not appear on the BCB’s balance
sheet, the Bank immediately records in its financial accounts the gains or losses incurred on its
outstanding contracts.

3

The size of these operations may be evidence that the risk transfer channel is more important than the forward
guidance channel, although the two channels are clearly complementary.
4
The BM&F Bovespa SA- Securities, Commodities, and Futures Exchange

Page 13 of 13