View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 29–30, 2013

1 of 239

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on
October 29–30, 2013
A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in the offices of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C., on Tuesday, October 29, 2013,
at 1:00 p.m. and continued on Wednesday, October 30, 2013, at 9:00 a.m. Those present were
the following:
Ben Bernanke, Chairman
William C. Dudley, Vice Chairman
James Bullard
Charles L. Evans
Esther L. George
Jerome H. Powell
Eric Rosengren
Jeremy C. Stein
Daniel K. Tarullo
Janet L. Yellen
Richard W. Fisher, Narayana Kocherlakota, Sandra Pianalto, and Charles I. Plosser,
Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Jeffrey M. Lacker, Dennis P. Lockhart, and John C. Williams, Presidents of the Federal
Reserve Banks of Richmond, Atlanta, and San Francisco, respectively
William B. English, Secretary and Economist
Deborah J. Danker, Deputy Secretary
Matthew M. Luecke, Assistant Secretary
David W. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary
Michelle A. Smith, Assistant Secretary
Scott G. Alvarez, General Counsel
Thomas C. Baxter, Deputy General Counsel
Steven B. Kamin, Economist
David W. Wilcox, Economist
Thomas A. Connors, Michael P. Leahy, Stephen A. Meyer, Daniel G. Sullivan,
Christopher J. Waller, and William Wascher, Associate Economists
Simon Potter, Manager, System Open Market Account
Michael S. Gibson, Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board of
Governors
James A. Clouse, Deputy Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors

October 29–30, 2013

2 of 239

Jon W. Faust, Special Adviser to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
Linda Robertson, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Trevor A. Reeve, Senior Associate Director, Division of International Finance, Board of
Governors
Ellen E. Meade and Joyce K. Zickler, Senior Advisers, Division of Monetary Affairs,
Board of Governors
Eric M. Engen, Michael T. Kiley, Thomas Laubach, and David E. Lebow, Associate
Directors, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Marnie Gillis DeBoer, Deputy Associate Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board
of Governors
Rochelle M. Edge, Assistant Director, Office of Financial Stability Policy and Research,
Board of Governors
Eric Engstrom, Section Chief, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
David H. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Mark A. Carlson, Senior Economist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors;
Robert J. Tetlow, Senior Economist, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of
Governors
Blake Prichard, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
David Altig, Glenn D. Rudebusch, and Mark S. Sniderman, Executive Vice Presidents,
Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta, San Francisco, and Cleveland, respectively
Craig S. Hakkio, Evan F. Koenig, Lorie K. Logan, and Kei-Mu Yi, Senior Vice
Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of Kansas City, Dallas, New York, and Minneapolis,
respectively
Anna Nordstrom and Giovanni Olivei, Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of New
York and Boston, respectively
Argia M. Sbordone, Assistant Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Andreas L. Hornstein, Senior Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Satyajit Chatterjee, Senior Economic Advisor, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

October 29–30, 2013

3 of 239

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on
October 29–30, 2013
October 29 Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good afternoon. I’d like to start by asking President
Rosengren and President Bullard what they bet on the outcome of the World Series. [Laughter]
MR. ROSENGREN. Traditional beer bet.
MR. BULLARD. Local brews.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Today is Debbie Danker’s last FOMC meeting. Of a total
of 66 meetings, most of them sitting right here to the right of the Chairman, Debbie has done a
commendable job of keeping the Chairman and the FOMC mostly on track, although I wish she
had a more elastic policy about recording every comment I make in the transcripts. [Laughter]
Over her career, Debbie has brought expertise that’s led her on a tour of the major policymaking
institutions, including the New York Fed, the Council of Economic Advisers, the World Bank,
the Treasury, and, of course, the Board, where she has worked her way up through the ranks to
be deputy director and deputy secretary for the FOMC. So, for 66 meetings, we thank you for
putting up with this group and wish you the very best in your retirement. [Applause]
MS. DANKER. Can I just say, it’s been a great privilege. Thank you very much.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Before we get started, I want to say a couple
words on external communications. The first is that I’m tentatively planning to announce very
shortly a press conference at the January meeting, which will be my last meeting. That will give
us three consecutive meetings with press conferences and, I hope, will enhance our
communication over the next few months.
The second thing is that I’d like to ask folks—I know it’s tempting to comment on when
the FOMC may or may not take a first step toward reducing asset purchases, but it’s probably not

October 29–30, 2013

4 of 239

a wise thing to do. In fact, our policy on communications explicitly precludes making comments
about “a prediction . . . about Committee action in advance of the Committee’s announcement of
such decisions.” What I hope you will do rather than speculate on timing is to articulate a set of
principles, and I would recommend three. First, data dependence. We’re going to be tying our
decisions, as always, to the incoming data—not one particular piece of data, of course, but the
whole general outlook. The second principle I would suggest would be noting that our criterion
of “substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market” has a retrospective and a
prospective component. Retrospectively, we have seen a good bit of improvement—the term
I’ve used is “meaningful” improvement—since September 2012. It’s worth pointing that out. I
recollect where we feared we might be at this point, and we’re actually in much better shape in
the labor market than we thought a year ago. There’s also a prospective component to our
criterion. We’re hoping to see evidence that the recovery and the improvement in the labor
market will continue—and I hope that’s not an excessively high burden, but simply that the
outlook for the labor market will continue to improve. And the third principle I’d recommend to
folks is—it’s a phrase I don’t care much for, but—tapering is not tightening, necessarily. Even
as we make the shift from asset purchases to rate policy going forward—and I think this is
reflected in our statements—the Committee intends to maintain a highly accommodative policy
as needed to achieve recovery and hit our inflation target. Again, I recognize that there’s a lot of
temptation, a lot of speculation. I think we’re probably better off if we stick to some principles
on this issue. Any comments or questions on that? [No response]
If not, why don’t we go now to our agenda? Item 1 is “Financial Developments and
Open Market Operations,” and let me call on Simon Potter.

October 29–30, 2013

5 of 239

MR. POTTER. 1 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Domestic financial conditions eased
over the intermeeting period as market participants revised up their expectations for
future monetary policy accommodation. The shift in expectations was driven largely
by the outcome of the September FOMC meeting, combined with the implications of
the federal government shutdown and the weaker-than-expected September
employment report. The debt limit impasse dominated market attention and affected
a number of money markets and institutions for a time. The direct effect in other
markets appeared to be relatively limited, though market participants highlighted the
potential long-term implications for U.S. financial markets of repeated standoffs over
the debt limit. Foreign financial conditions were driven primarily by U.S.
developments and also eased over the period.
As shown in the top-left panel of your first exhibit, domestic financial markets
were driven by several key developments that led market participants to revise their
outlook for U.S. monetary policy. The Committee’s decision not to reduce the pace
of its asset purchases at the September meeting evidently surprised many market
participants, and other Federal Reserve communications that day—including the 2016
target rate projections—were also perceived as more accommodative than expected.
The shutdown of the federal government delayed the publication of key economic
data and increased uncertainty about the economic outlook. These effects, along with
a resolution to the shutdown and debt limit that could put both fiscal issues back into
play in early 2014, reportedly increased expectations for no reduction in the pace of
Federal Reserve asset purchases at the next few meetings. These expectations were
reinforced by the weaker-than-expected nonfarm payrolls release last week.
Changes in most domestic asset prices over the period are consistent with
expectations for a more accommodative future stance of monetary policy. As shown
in the top-right panel, the 10-year nominal Treasury yield decreased 34 basis points.
Option-adjusted spreads on agency MBS narrowed 17 basis points, and interest rates
on 30-year fixed-rate mortgages declined 44 basis points. High-yield corporate credit
spreads narrowed 14 basis points, the S&P 500 index increased 3 percent, and the
DXY dollar index depreciated 2 percent. Roughly half of these changes came on the
day of the September meeting. TIPS yields declined in line with comparablematurity nominal Treasury yields over the period, leaving measures of inflation
compensation little changed and within their recent ranges.
The results from the Desk’s Survey of Primary Dealers and other surveys show
large shifts over the period in expectations for the timing of the initial reduction in the
pace of asset purchases, the path of SOMA holdings, and the path of the target federal
funds rate.
As shown in the middle-left panel, averaging across dealers’ probability
assessments from the most recent Desk survey, they now see a roughly 90 percent
chance that the initial reduction in the pace of purchases will be announced at some
point in 2014 or later, with the highest average probability on the March meeting.
1

The materials used by Mr. Potter are appended to this transcript (appendixes 1 and 2).

October 29–30, 2013

6 of 239

Dealers’ probability assessments over meetings in 2014 are quite flat, indicating
either relatively little conviction in their views on the timing of the initial reduction or
data dependence. The median response for the most likely total amount of purchases
through 2014 increased nearly $400 billion—the largest such intermeeting increase
since the announcement of outcome-based purchases at the September 2012 meeting.
Once reductions start, dealers continue to expect roughly equal-size reductions in
each asset class, as discussed in the memo on the composition of reductions in
purchase pace that was sent to the Committee, though a few expect reductions to
occur more quickly in Treasuries than in MBS.
The revisions to dealer expectations for the path of the federal funds rate over the
period were also sizable. As indicated in the middle-right panel, more than half of the
dealers pushed out their expectation for the most likely timing of the initial target rate
increase. Moreover, the average expectation for the most likely level of the target
rate in 2016 and 2017 declined as much as 37 basis points. This is the largest
intermeeting-period decline in the expected target rate path since September 2012.
The dealer expected path now lies below the path from the survey ahead of the April–
May FOMC meeting, prior to the rise in interest rates over the spring and summer.
Market pricing also reflects large revisions to expectations for the path of the
target rate. As shown in the bottom-left panel, the path of the federal funds rate
implied by a straight read of interest rate futures shifted down, retracing a substantial
portion of its rise from early May. Market-implied rates in 2016 and beyond remain a
bit above their pre-JEC levels, in contrast to the dealer survey.
Following the September meeting, many market participants expressed a lack of
confidence in their ability to forecast the Committee’s future actions. For example,
many were surprised that the 7 percent unemployment rate guidepost for the end of
asset purchases that was suggested following the June meeting appeared to have been
downplayed. As shown in the bottom-right panel, on the most recent dealer survey
the average rating of the Committee’s communication with the markets and the public
was the lowest on record. Nevertheless, most dealer survey measures of uncertainty
and disagreement about the path of SOMA holdings and the target federal funds rate
were little changed or a bit lower, and measures of interest rate–implied volatility also
declined around the September meeting and over the period. These declines may
reflect the resolution of uncertainty about future Federal Reserve leadership, as well
as reduced investor demand for hedging interest rate risk, as a near-term change in the
pace of asset purchases is seen as unlikely.
Turning to exhibit 2, developments related to U.S. fiscal policy were followed
closely overseas but had limited direct market effects. As shown in the top-left panel,
financial conditions in the United States and Europe eased some following the
resolution of the debt limit, in contrast to the experience in 2011, when conditions
tightened sharply. The divergence is attributable to the considerable differences
between the economic and market backdrops in the two episodes, including S&P’s
downgrade of the U.S. sovereign credit rating and a more tenuous financial stability

October 29–30, 2013

7 of 239

situation in Europe in 2011, as well as a more accommodative current global stance
of monetary policy relative to then.
This easing of financial conditions can also be seen in longer-dated global
sovereign yields, shown in the top-right panel. U.K. and German yields were
reportedly driven primarily by developments in the U. S. In Japan, government bond
yields extended recent declines and are now at levels last seen in early May, prior to
the elevated volatility following the start of the BOJ’s asset purchase program. The
declines in Japanese yields have been accompanied by improved secondary-market
liquidity and reduced interest-rate-implied volatility.
While longer-dated sovereign yields have recently moved in line with U.S. yields,
shorter-dated U.K. and euro-area forward rates appear to have become somewhat less
sensitive to changes in analogous U.S. forward rates since the introduction of the
BOE’s and ECB’s forward guidance. The middle left panel shows one simple
illustration of this, plotting daily changes in German one-year-forward one-year rates
on the y-axis against daily changes in U.S. one-year-forward one-year rates on the
x-axis. Dates before the announcement of the ECB’s forward guidance are shown in
light blue, and dates after are shown in dark blue. As seen from the best-fit lines
drawn through each set of points, the pass-through of changes in U.S. rates has fallen
somewhat since the forward guidance was introduced. A similar pattern is observed
for U.K. rates.
In addition to forward guidance, ECB officials have continued to discuss other
actions they might take to prevent increases in money market rates that they view as
inconsistent with economic fundamentals. This is of particular concern to them as
LTRO repayments have reduced excess Eurosystem liquidity, shown in the middleright panel. A significant further drop in excess liquidity could cause EONIA rates to
rise some, in which case the most likely policy response would be for the ECB to add
liquidity back to the system, such as with LTROs.
The outlook for Chinese economic policy has also been in focus. While the
acceleration in third-quarter GDP, which Steve will discuss in his remarks, alleviated
some near-term concerns over the direction of the Chinese economy, much of the
expansion was fueled by rapid credit growth that many market participants view as
unsustainable. These developments have been accompanied by an increase in
financial inflows. Chinese authorities have responded by allowing interbank funding
rates to rise, taking macroprudential steps to stem upward pressure on housing prices,
and resuming gradual appreciation of the renminbi against the dollar, shown in the
bottom-left panel.
As shown in the bottom-right panel, emerging market currencies appreciated over
the period, reflecting both actions by foreign authorities and the shift in market
expectations for U.S. monetary policy. Some of the sharpest recent appreciation has
been in the currencies of emerging market countries with large external funding needs
that came under the greatest pressure between May and August—such as the Indian
rupee—suggesting an increased willingness for some investors to take on risk.

October 29–30, 2013

8 of 239

Emerging market equity and bond markets also rose sharply following the September
FOMC. Market participants have reported that these moves are consistent with a
broader increase in demand for high-yielding assets, through a return of so-called
carry trades predicated on low volatility and expectations for highly accommodative
U.S. monetary policy.
Your next exhibit briefly reviews primary dealer expectations for the size of the
SOMA portfolio, then moves on to Desk operations. It concludes with a discussion
of the possible conversion of temporary swap arrangements into standing ones.
Consistent with the revisions to dealers’ expectations for the pace of Federal
Reserve asset purchases that I noted earlier, their probability assessments of the
likelihood of significantly higher balance sheet outcomes increased. As shown in the
top-left panel, averaging across their probability assessments, dealers now place a
25 percent chance on the SOMA portfolio exceeding $4.5 trillion at the end of 2014.
Dealers, on average, assess a less than 10 percent probability of a portfolio below
$4 trillion, compared with an assessment of about 60 percent before the September
meeting.
The top-right panel shows the median dealer expectation for future MBS
purchases over recent surveys as a percentage of the contemporaneous TBA-eligible
stock. With the increase in purchase expectations since September, projected future
purchases represent about 15 percent of the outstanding purchasable stock. This
suggests that, even if MBS purchases were to be significantly higher than current
dealer expectations, lack of availability of TBA-eligible securities would be unlikely
to pose a constraint on the Desk’s ability to operate. That said, increasing the Federal
Reserve’s ownership share in an environment of declining gross issuance could
possibly cause some disruptions to liquidity.
Turning to Desk operations over the intermeeting period, execution metrics in
both Treasury and MBS purchases were within recent ranges, with no notable
disruptions even during the period of debt limit–related stress. Broad liquidity
conditions in longer-term Treasury securities and MBS were about unchanged on net.
Looking ahead to the end of the year, trading volumes in both Treasury and MBS
markets typically decline in December and early January, as shown in the middle-left
panel. There are also some signs of modestly thinner liquidity in Treasury markets
over that period, as bid–asked spreads tend to widen a bit. Last year, the Desk
adjusted its purchase calendar so that the majority of Treasury and MBS purchases
would not occur during the days with the lowest trading volumes, and we plan to take
a similar approach this year. We do not expect this to garner much market attention,
given that the practice is communicated in advance and is in line with Desk
operations in recent years.
The next two panels provide some details on the overnight reverse repo exercise
the Desk is currently conducting. As noted in the memo we sent to the Committee,
last month, the Desk began offering fixed-rate overnight investments to 139 eligible

October 29–30, 2013

9 of 239

counterparties at 1 basis point, with a maximum allotment of $500 million each.
Early operations were executed smoothly, with no technical problems; as such, after
consulting with the Chairman, the maximum bid amount was raised to $1 billion, and
recently the rate offered was raised to 2 basis points.
Counterparties’ participation in the operations has been influenced by their desire
to test systems and to park funds over quarter-end. As shown in the middle-right
panel, peak participation thus far came on the quarter-end date of September 30, with
$58 billion allotted to 87 counterparties. Participation in the operations has been
sensitive to the spread between overnight money market rates—proxied in the
bottom-left panel by the GCF repo rate—and the operation’s fixed rate. This has
been particularly true for government money market mutual funds, and to a lesser
extent for prime funds and the GSEs. These institutions have been the largest lenders
in the operations to date and are expected to find investment in it more attractive,
given that they are not eligible to earn interest on reserves.
The overnight RRP operations do not appear to have had any meaningful impact
on money market rates or market functioning, and participation has been small
relative to the size of the market. The staff will continue to monitor market activity.
Your final panel illustrates that, while the current usage of dollar swap lines is
minimal, they have been important tools during times of market stress. I would like
to ask for a vote to approve the resolution on the swap line arrangements that was in
the memo Steve Kamin and I sent the Committee on October 21. A copy of the
resolution is in the handout titled “Action on Liquidity Swap Lines.” It would
convert the existing temporary dollar and foreign currency liquidity swap
arrangements with the Bank of Canada, the Bank of England, the Bank of Japan, the
European Central Bank, and the Swiss National Bank to standing swap arrangements
and would remove the quantity limits in the agreement with the Bank of Canada.
Standing swap lines would reduce uncertainty among market participants as to
whether and when these arrangements would be renewed and would limit the risk that
decisions regarding the renewal of these arrangements would be misinterpreted. I
would emphasize that moving to a standing arrangement in no way diminishes the
FOMC’s control over these lines. Drawings on these swap lines will be approved by
the Chairman in consultation with the Foreign Currency Subcommittee and with the
FOMC prior to the initial drawing, if possible under the circumstances then
prevailing. In this context, I should note that we anticipate that the ECB will continue
to make small draws on its dollar liquidity swap line, reflecting the modest bids it
receives at its dollar-providing operations. The FOMC will have the opportunity to
reauthorize the lines on an annual basis. The Chairman may change the rates and fees
on the swap arrangements by mutual agreement with the foreign central banks and in
consultation with the Foreign Currency Subcommittee. I should note that if you vote
for approval, the coordinated public announcement will be at 2:00 a.m. eastern
daylight time on Thursday, October 31. Thank you, Mr. Chairman, that completes
my prepared remarks.

October 29–30, 2013

10 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Are there questions for Simon or for
Steve Kamin? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Simon, could you repeat what you mentioned
when you were talking about slide 14, and then you rolled over to slide 15, with regard to
year-end activity—that “increasing the Federal Reserve’s ownership share could possibly cause.
. .”. Would you repeat that sentence, please?
MR. POTTER. One of the things we found in our operations recently is that, even
though we’re approaching the monthly issuance in the market, we haven’t experienced any
liquidity problems.
MR. FISHER. Right.
MR. POTTER. Exhibit 14 shows you that the outstanding stock that we could still
purchase is large. It wouldn’t be a large percentage of that. However, we don’t know, if we
sustained this for a long period of time, where we’re purchasing out of stock, whether that would
perhaps affect liquidity conditions in the MBS market.
MR. FISHER. So we’ll just feel our way along the stones?
MR. POTTER. We will, as always, monitor and alert you if we’re seeing any market
malfunctioning from it, but so far it has gone better than we expected.
MR. FISHER. And then your comment on slide number 6—the slide shows the dealer
survey, but you also said “and the public.” How do we determine how the public would
respond?
MR. POTTER. Oh, that’s just the way that we ask the question.

October 29–30, 2013

11 of 239

MR. FISHER. Okay. Of the dealers. And then the last question I have—which may be
based on ignorance, Mr. Chairman—you did mention, Simon, that we’ve increased the quantity
limits with regard to the swap lines with the Bank of Canada, correct?
MR. POTTER. We are going to take the caps off. They have not used those lines. So
it’s hard to say exactly how much usage there will be.
MR. FISHER. And the natural question for me is: Mexico is not included—is that
because we continue on with the program that we currently have? And is there a reason to
differentiate between Canada and Mexico?
MR. POTTER. Within the foreign currency arrangements that Canada has with the other
four central banks, there were no caps. So what we were trying to do is make the arrangements
look symmetric across those six central banks. The NAFTA lines that were introduced in ’94 are
really for a separate purpose.
MR. FISHER. Is there a need to communicate with Mexico at all to make that clear, or
have we done so—or does it matter?
MR. POTTER. I believe that if the Committee approves this resolution, if the Bank of
Japan approves tomorrow, and we announce, there will be a lot of interest from other central
banks in this standing relationship that we have. I don’t believe the Mexicans will view this as a
really big change, given that they weren’t in this temporary network that we have.
MR. FISHER. My sensitivity tells me—or maybe it’s too sensitive—that it might be
advisable, at least. Are we giving them advance notice?
MR. KAMIN. No, we’re not. We never provide advance notice.
MR. FISHER. Well, we might provide them simultaneous notice.

October 29–30, 2013

12 of 239

MR. KAMIN. I take your point. I think that the announcement will certainly remind
many emerging market economies of these swaps, some of whom have requested it, and so I
think taking some proactive action just to—
MR. POTTER. I could certainly give a call to my counterparty at the central bank.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I would recommend that. They’re highly sensitive, and,
again, it is part of NAFTA, and with any differentiation between Canada and Mexico, I would
suggest politely that we let them know at the earliest opportunity, and before others, if possible.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you for that suggestion. Are there other questions?
President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Is this the appropriate time to comment on the swap lines?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Certainly.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I generally favor them, but one thing that struck me about the
proposal is that a lot of the arguments that were being made to convert the temporary swap line
into a more permanent standing arrangement could also be used to argue in favor of having a
standing term auction facility as well. When we had this discussion about the term auction
facility in our teleconference call, I was struck by the length of time that it would take the staff to
stand up such a facility. A lot of the concerns that we have about the temporary liquidity lines in
terms of the signaling, et cetera, would also be true if we tried to stand up a TAF in the midst of a
crisis. That would send a signal that maybe we’re concerned about things, whereas if we have a
permanent facility that’s being run at a relatively small level, we have staff expertise always
there, and we don’t really have to worry as much about the signaling content of our decision.

October 29–30, 2013

13 of 239

The memo makes a very strong case for that being true for the temporary liquidity lines being
converted to a standing situation. That was my only comment. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker, would you like to comment?
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Richmond Fed is traditionally opposed
to foreign swap lines. In the past, my predecessor and I have voted against these on the grounds
that they were an adjunct to foreign exchange operations that were essentially fiscal policy and
should be the responsibility of the U.S. Treasury subject to the authorization of the U.S.
Congress. Today we’re being asked to make these things that were adopted on a renewable basis
in the midst of the crisis into a relatively permanent arrangement. Their purpose is not for
exchange market intervention this time, but the provision of dollar funding by foreign central
banks to overseas financial institutions. I recognize that the SOMA would not bear exchange
risk or credit risk in these transactions, but nonetheless, we’d be facilitating yet another
expansion of central bank backstop lending commitments, and I don’t think that’s the best path
to financial stability. So I would oppose authorizing the manager’s request.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Any other questions or comments? President
Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I share some of Richmond’s concern about it. I have a question: I
gather from the discussion that because we’ve already coordinated with all of the foreign banks
that will announce on the 31st, it’s kind of a foregone conclusion that we’re going to do this?
MR. POTTER. No. They’re all aware that it’s dependent on the vote here and the vote
that the Bank of Japan is taking.

October 29–30, 2013

14 of 239

MR. PLOSSER. I’m still not convinced why renewing these things on a regular basis or
approving caps is problematic from a management standpoint. Would you care to elaborate a
little bit more on that?
MR. POTTER. I find it hard to think what the caps would be in all of the circumstances
that might happen over the next few years. That’s assuming that they would be reauthorized.
Among the things that we discussed with you last year about a financial market utility in another
area—London was the example we gave you—was that it’s very difficult to contact people in
real time to do that. Now, in terms of how big the swaps could be, that’s really going to be up to
the people around this table if we again get into a financial crisis like we saw in 2008. There’s
nothing in here that prevents you from standing up an individual swap arrangement, to put in
place some cap, to effect the fees, and so on.
MR. PLOSSER. But just as a matter of process, though, there’s a difference between
saying that we have the right to change something, or we have to proactively act to do something
either less or more, or change the price, as opposed to there being a request that has to come in.
MR. POTTER. I would distinguish between a continuing request, where we put the
framework in place—which is where we are right now with the temporary swap lines, with the
pricing in there and the lack of caps, which is supposed to give the impression of a backstop, and
has been very successful in that way—and other circumstances in which—it’s hard to think of
it—in which the FOMC might decide it would limit what the individual swap draw could be,
even within these arrangements. It doesn’t prevent you from doing that. What the cap with the
Bank of Canada prevented you from doing was having a backstop without a limit on it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions? [No response] If not, let me first ask
us to vote to ratify the domestic open market operations. Any objection? [No response] Seeing

October 29–30, 2013

15 of 239

none. On the liquidity swap lines, President Lacker has expressed his concern. Is there anyone
else who would like to be on record? [No response] All right. If there’s no objection, I’m going
to call for a voice vote, not an individual vote. All those in favor of approving the swap line
directive as given in the handout, please say aye. [Chorus of ayes] Opposed. [No response]
Okay. Thank you very much. I hope you’ll all be up at 2:00 a.m. to hear the announcement.
[Laughter]
All right. Moving on to item 2, “Economic Situation,” let me call on David Lebow.
MR. LEBOW. 2 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be referring to the single exhibit
marked “Forecast Summary.” As you know, the government shutdown disrupted the
production of a number of key economic statistics, and thus the amount of data
available at the time the October Tealbook was finalized was somewhat more limited
than usual. But we did receive the September jobs report in time for the Tealbook,
and some other important data were not available for the Tealbook but are available
now.
As you can see from the top-left panel, given the data in hand when the Tealbook
was closed, we marked down this year’s expected pace of real GDP growth by about
¼ percentage point relative to our previous projection. The downward revision to
real private spending was concentrated in personal consumption—shown in the
top-right panel—which appears to be on a somewhat weaker trajectory than we had
anticipated in September. This morning’s data on retail sales for September did not
change that assessment; while nominal sales posted a larger gain than the average of
recent months, we had already conditioned our forecast on such a reading.
As for the other data published after the Tealbook closed, the September figures
on orders and shipments of capital goods were disappointing, and the increase in
manufacturing output last month was more modest than we anticipated, but the
international trade data for August were a little stronger than expected; so, on net, the
post-Tealbook news had little implication for our near-term projection of GDP
growth.
Beyond the effect of incoming data, we have reduced our forecast of fourthquarter GDP growth by about ½ percentage point to reflect the effects of the
government shutdown. Most of that shutdown effect comes from the direct hit to
government activity. While there are a variety of channels through which the
shutdown plausibly could have affected the private economy, our guess is that such
spillover effects are quite small. We could certainly be wrong about that judgment,
but in any event, we think that any spillover effects, as well as the direct effects of the
2

The materials used by Mr. Lebow are appended to this transcript (appendix 3).

October 29–30, 2013

16 of 239

shutdown, ought to be temporary. Thus, as you can see from our fiscal impetus
estimates in the middle-left panel, the effect of the shutdown is basically to shift real
GDP growth out of this year and into 2014, with no net change to the level of output.
Beyond the near term, we made small upward revisions to our projection for real
GDP growth. Except for the small swing induced by the government shutdown, our
fiscal policy assumptions are essentially unchanged from the September Tealbook; in
particular, we continue to believe that fiscal policy is providing considerable restraint
to the growth of aggregate demand this year, but that this restraint will diminish
substantially in the coming years. Our monetary policy assumptions are also
essentially unchanged from the previous Tealbook: We continue to assume that the
federal funds rate will lift off from its effective lower bound in the second quarter of
2015 and rise gradually thereafter, reaching 2 percent in the last quarter of 2016. We
also continue to assume that the Committee will end its asset purchases under the
current LSAP program by the middle of next year. That said, we slightly increased
our estimate of the cumulative amount of purchases under this program, to about
$1.3 trillion. Overall financial conditions are expected to be a little more
accommodative in this forecast, primarily reflecting downward revisions to the
projected paths of longer-term interest rates and the foreign exchange value of the
dollar—revisions that, in part, reflect market perceptions of a more accommodative
monetary policy. We also slightly revised up our projections for house prices and
equity prices.
Taken as a whole, the revisions that we have made to our conditioning factors are
a positive for GDP growth over the medium term. However, their effect is partly
offset by a downward revision that we have made to next year’s consumer spending
forecast (back in the top-right panel). Specifically, because consumer spending has
not yet shown a clear sign of the faster growth we have been expecting, we think that
factors such as tight credit conditions or consumers’ pessimism about their future
income prospects may have been weighing on consumption by more than we had
previously assumed, and that such factors could be somewhat persistent. A memo
sent to the Committee by my colleagues Andrew Figura and Geng Li discusses many
of the issues surrounding our projection for consumer spending.
All told, the revisions that we have made to our various conditioning assumptions,
to the near-term outlook, and to next year’s consumption growth forecast combine to
leave the level of real GDP at the end of 2016 just slightly lower than in our
September projection.
Turning to the labor market, we read the September employment release as a little
weaker than we had anticipated overall. Total nonfarm employment was about in line
with our expectations, but private payrolls—which we think provide a better signal of
the underlying momentum of labor demand—rose only 126,000 in September; taking
into account revisions to July and August, private payroll gains averaged 130,000 per
month in the third quarter, about 20,000 less than we were expecting. The
unemployment rate ticked down to 7.2 percent last month, a tenth lower than we

October 29–30, 2013

17 of 239

expected, while labor force participation was unchanged, which also was a touch
lower than we had expected.
We think that the labor data for October will show some imprint of the
government shutdown, with the government furloughs pushing the unemployment
rate up about ¼ percentage point to 7½ percent and associated temporary job losses
among private contractors holding down payrolls by about 25,000. Looking through
those temporary effects, we now project total payroll gains to average 150,000 per
month in the fourth quarter, 15,000 per month less than in our previous projection.
We project that the unemployment rate will be 7.2 percent in November and
December—the same as in our September forecast.
Over the medium term—and in line with previous Tealbook projections—we
expect that labor market conditions will improve further as actual real GDP growth
outpaces potential. As you can see from the middle-right panel, the projected path of
the unemployment rate is about unchanged in this forecast relative to September,
reflecting the fact that the projected path for real GDP is also little changed. Hence,
as in the previous Tealbook, we project that the unemployment rate will cross the
Committee’s 6½ percent threshold in the first quarter of 2015. At the end of 2015,
our current projection is ¾ percentage point lower than the forecast we made in
September of last year, when the FOMC first tied its asset purchase decisions to an
improvement in the labor market outlook. The level of total payroll employment over
the medium term—shown in the bottom-left panel—is also little changed from the
previous Tealbook, and we continue to expect monthly total payroll job gains to
average about 200,000 next year, 250,000 in 2015, and 200,000 in 2016—a contour
that broadly matches that of projected output growth. By the end of 2015, the level of
payroll employment is expected to be a little more than 500,000 higher than our
September 2012 projection.
Finally, the limited incoming data on inflation have been in line with our
expectations—and I should note that we will receive the September CPI, whose
release was also delayed by the government shutdown, tomorrow morning. We
continue to expect headline PCE inflation—the bottom-right panel—to average
1½ percent over the second half of this year, pushed higher by an upturn in energy
prices and a modest projected pickup in core inflation from the low readings seen
earlier in the year. Further out, our inflation forecast is little changed from
September; in particular, we expect inflation to be about 1½ percent per year through
2016, though if you look carefully you can see the slight uptilt in that projection. The
headline index runs a tenth below the core index (not shown) through 2016, as
projected declines in crude oil prices put downward pressure on retail energy prices.
Thus, PCE inflation is anticipated to remain below the Committee’s 2 percent longerterm objective throughout the medium term. Steve Kamin will now continue our
presentation.
MR. KAMIN. During the annual meetings of the IMF and the World Bank that
took place a few weeks ago, the attention of policymakers from around the world was
squarely focused on the United States: Would the debt ceiling be raised, and when

October 29–30, 2013

18 of 239

would the Fed start tapering? By comparison, developments abroad have been
reasonably tranquil since your previous meeting: Financial conditions in the euro
area remain suspiciously calm, stresses in emerging markets have eased, and
incoming economic data have been largely in line with our expectations. Thus, for
the most part, we have not altered our forecast for economic growth abroad to pick up
over the next few years—from only 2 percent in the first half of this year to a healthy
3½ percent by 2016—but our faith in this outlook has been strengthened.
In the advanced foreign economies, GDP had already expanded a solid
1¾ percent in the second quarter—a little above what we estimate to be the trend rate
for those economies—and we estimate that growth posted a similar pace in the third.
To be sure, the third-quarter growth partly reflected a rebound of the Canadian
economy from serious flooding back in June, while the pace of expansion in both
Japan and the euro area appears to have fallen back. However, we aren’t taking a lot
of signal from these decelerations.
Starting with the euro area, we had always expected that economy to emerge from
recession only haltingly, and we understood that its expansion of 1 percent in the
second quarter was boosted by transitory factors. Accordingly, we were not that
surprised by data pointing to a slowing of growth to about ½ percent in the third
quarter. Although the euro area faces numerous headwinds that will keep the
recovery quite subdued, several factors, including diminishing financial strains,
reduced fiscal drag, and accommodative monetary policies, should push GDP growth
up to 2 percent by 2015. Naturally, this forecast depends on the euro-area crisis
continuing to wind down. We are encouraged that financial stresses in the region
have indeed continued to ease, and policymakers are making progress, albeit slowly,
on important reforms. Last week, the ECB released its long-awaited blueprint for
assessing the health of euro-area banks, a prerequisite for its assuming supervisory
control over these institutions next year.
In Japan, growth has also slowed, but from an unusually high 4 percent rate in the
first half of this year. Moreover, at an estimated 2 percent in the third quarter, the
pace of expansion—driven by yen depreciation, rising stock prices, and improved
confidence—remains far above its trend rate of about ½ percent. Going forward, we
are looking for output to decelerate to a little over 1 percent over the next three years
as the consumption tax is doubled, thereby offsetting much of the BOJ’s aggressive
monetary stimulus. Even so, this should be sufficient to make significant inroads into
Japan’s resource slack and help push inflation up to 1½ percent by 2016, a
performance that, if sustained, would mark the end of Japan’s long deflation.
All told, we are looking for growth in the advanced foreign economies to edge up
to just over 2¼ percent by 2016. Together with the acceleration we are projecting for
the U.S. economy, this should provide further impetus to the emerging market
economies. GDP growth in the EMEs has already picked up considerably from its
slowdown earlier this year, rising from 2½ percent in the second quarter to an
estimated 3¾ percent in the third. Part of that acceleration reflected an apparent
rebound in Mexican GDP from its surprise contraction in the second quarter.

October 29–30, 2013

19 of 239

But perhaps more significantly, Chinese GDP soared an estimated 9½ percent in
the third quarter, nearly 2 percentage points higher than our September forecast. To
be clear, we do not believe the Chinese economy is returning to the days of doubledigit growth rates. In fact, we are projecting growth to fall back to about 8 percent in
the current quarter and to edge down further over the next few years. However, when
Chinese growth downshifted to about 7 percent in the first half of this year, we had
been worried that this might presage a further sharp slowing that could drag down
many of China’s trading partners as well. Accordingly, although China’s economy
faces many challenges—including still-rapid credit growth and a resurgence of
property prices—its recent pickup reassures us that a hard landing is more of a risk to
the outlook than a near-term certainty, and this is good news for EMEs more
generally. In our projection, total EME growth rises further to 4½ percent next year
and beyond, roughly its trend pace, as the recovery in the advanced economies leads
to a strengthening of global trade.
Besides a hard landing in China, another risk to this outlook is that a resurgence
of financial stresses might push one or more especially vulnerable economies into
crisis, provoking a pullback by investors and triggering more-generalized turmoil in
the EMEs. We are encouraged that emerging markets appear to have settled down a
bit in the past couple of months, as Simon discussed. But a number of open questions
remain. First, how will emerging markets respond when you finally reduce the pace
of asset purchases? By our reckoning, a small reduction in these purchases should
not be all that consequential, but we know that anticipations of tapering roiled
emerging markets starting last spring, and that your decision not to taper in
September helped diminish these stresses. Second, even if tapering proceeds
smoothly, how vulnerable are emerging markets to the longer-term normalization of
global interest rates that will take place as the recovery in advanced economies
matures? In principle, the current configuration of bond yields and exchange rates
should incorporate market expectations for future rises in global interest rates, but
especially after developments since May, we cannot be so sure. And finally, how
assiduously will the more fragile EMEs work to correct their underlying
vulnerabilities? Years of low interest rates and ready access to international capital
diminished the zeal with which EME policymakers addressed their fiscal and other
structural problems, and it remains to be seen how quickly these countries can pivot
toward more aggressive reforms. Thank you. David and I will be happy to answer
your questions.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Questions for the staff? President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First let me say, I appreciate the special
memo on consumption. It got me curious about productivity, though. Your outlook is for
productivity growth to pick up going forward. Nonfarm business productivity has averaged
0.7 percent per year over the past three years, and is at an annual rate of 1.7 percent, I think, over

October 29–30, 2013

20 of 239

the next three years in your forecast. I wondered if you could help us understand what drives
that acceleration.
MR. LEBOW. Sure. Some of our interpretation of the performance of the labor market,
as you know, is the story of normalization following unusually rapid job losses during the
recession itself. We’ve seen a somewhat faster improvement of the labor market than would be
expected under normal circumstances, given the GDP growth as it’s measured over the past
period, and that’s reflected in the productivity figures that you’ve seen. Going forward, it’s very
hard to know when this period of normalization will end—what the right timing really is—but
our projection is that it is coming to an end, and that we’ll see GDP growth picking up, going
forward, bringing it more into line with the pace of labor market improvement. So we’ll see the
faster productivity growth reflecting the end of that normalization period.
MR. WASCHER. The other thing I might note is that, if you’re comparing the forecast
with recent years, we do think that the financial crisis and deep recession had an effect on the
supply side of the economy, and that structural productivity was weaker than, say, it had been
prior to the crisis. A lot of that occurred through capital deepening—just very low rates of
investment affecting the capital stocks and capital services. We also think there is probably
some slowing in multifactor productivity that was associated with the deep recession through
things like reduced R&D spending or reduced business formation. Going forward we have the
growth rate of structural productivity reverting back to where it had been prior to the crisis.
We’re not catching up in terms of the level, but we are assuming a return to the growth rate that
was evident prior to the crisis. So we are projecting structural productivity growth at a little less
than 2 percent, and we think it fell to about 1¼ percent in, say, the 2008–10 period.

October 29–30, 2013

21 of 239

MR. LACKER. Okay. Could I follow up, Mr. Chairman? In your narrative what
happened during the recession was the opposite of labor hoarding. It was sort of overly
aggressively labor dis-hoarding in some sense, right? And since then firms have been able to
meet a given expansion in demand. They want to hire more workers to get back to the normal
level of staffing relative to the demand that they’re seeing. Intuitively I’d picture that tailing off
as looking like demand growth continuing to be met, but with lower employment growth. In my
mind, that would conjure up a narrative in which demand keeps growing at the same rate—we’ve
been getting 2 percent—and employment growth falls, rather than output growth rising for a
given employment growth.
MR. LEBOW. I think that’s right. I think that this story of labor market normalization is
not an argument for faster GDP growth going forward. I think our projection of faster GDP
growth stems from other reasons.
MR. LACKER. Okay.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions? President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Just a question about how to read the market’s expectations for the
fed funds rate: It was striking that the primary dealer survey shows a huge number of people
expecting the funds rate liftoff to be in the third or fourth quarter of 2015. But when you look at
the expected fed funds rate, while it is consistent with liftoff around then, it is also consistent
with the fed funds rate at about 1½ percent at the end of 2016. The primary dealers are saying
around 2 percent at the end of 2016. When we look at the mode, it looks like liftoff won’t be
until 2017. This is a question for Simon, or for anybody: How am I supposed to understand
what the market expectations for monetary policy are when there is such a big difference

October 29–30, 2013

22 of 239

between the mode and the implied fed funds rate—which is, I think, the reasonable view given
the zero bound—as well as between the mean and the primary dealer survey?
MR. POTTER. The term premium could account for some of this, but it seems it would
have to account for a lot of it. The model that produced this is the floor and caps—is that right,
Bill? This is in Tealbook, Book A, I think.
MR. ENGLISH. No. I think the chart that you’re showing is just based on the means
and assuming no term premium.
MR. POTTER. I think President Williams is looking at the chart from Tealbook A, that
has the mode and the closing caps.
MR. WILLIAMS. I’m actually looking at the Monday morning briefing chart.
MR. ENGLISH. I think on that chart we showed both the mean and the mode. For the
means, we have done exercises looking at the term premiums implied by our yield curve models
applied to OIS. Those term premiums have moved around over time and have accounted for
some of the run-up and then some of the run back down again in those charts, which are plotted
assuming no term premium. So there is some effect of term premiums there. On the modes, I
actually am not exactly sure. Jim, can you tell us what’s assumed there?
MR. CLOUSE. Yes. We don’t make any adjustment for term premiums in the modes
either. We have a lot of difficulty in teasing out the correct term premium for these futures
paths, so we tend to show the straight readings.
MR. WILLIAMS. A question I also have is just how low these expectations are. The
mode has the fed funds rate at zero through 2016 and at basically 75 basis points in the middle of
2017. What is your interpretation of why that is so low compared with the primary dealer
survey?

October 29–30, 2013

23 of 239

MR. ENGLISH. I read the primary dealer survey as telling us something about the mean,
like the mean values that are in that chart. And the difference between the mean and the mode is
largely the zero bound. It’s just that if you think the most likely path is some trajectory, you
can’t go below zero. But if the economy picks up and the funds rate goes up, you can end up
quite a bit above that mode, and so the mean is going to just be pulled above the mode by the
zero bound.
MR. POTTER. So is it possible the mode is still not that likely?
MR. ENGLISH. Well, yes, absolutely. And there is probably considerable uncertainty,
so there may not be that much weight around the mode. There’s a lot of uncertainty about the
outlook for the funds rate, for sure.
MR. CLOUSE. Just for what it’s worth, the models that we use to try to tease out the
true underlying expected path were actually shown in one of the memos we sent to the
Committee. And those models would have the term premium being negative, so that means the
actual expected path is higher. At least according to that particular model, the expected funds
rate at the end of 2016 is more like 2½ percent, which is actually a bit above where the
Committee’s expectations were and seemingly a little bit better aligned.
MR. WILLIAMS. Okay. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions for our colleagues? [No response] If
not, then we can begin our economic go-round, and I have Charlie Plosser at the top of my list.
President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. There has been little change in Third
District conditions since our previous meeting, with our region continuing to grow at a moderate
pace. Indeed, this has been true since our June forecasting exercise as well. The partial

October 29–30, 2013

24 of 239

shutdown of the federal government has yet to show any noticeable adverse impact on our
overall economic activity or the outlook for the region. Housing and commercial real estate
activity continue to pick up; manufacturing continues to expand. Philadelphia leading indexes
point to continued growth over the next six months, and the outlook among our business contacts
remains positive. Our October Business Outlook Survey came in about as strong as our
September survey did. The general activity index has now posted five consecutive positive
readings and shows broad-based strength. The indexes of new orders, shipments, and
employment remain well into positive territory, suggesting improving conditions. The robust
growth in housing activity in July did show to a somewhat more modest pace than in August and
September, although the data have not permitted us to be more precise about September housing
permits as yet. The pace of commercial real estate activity has actually improved over the past
couple of months. Our business contacts in the retail and service sectors continue to report
modest growth through early October. Third District banks continue to report modest increases
in loan volumes. Labor markets in our three-state region continue to slowly strengthen. Payroll
employment has expanded over the past three months, and my staff forecast is for modest
improvement in the regional labor markets over the next year.
On the national front, the outlook has changed little since June as well. The near-term
outlook for 2013 has been marked down slightly, but the medium-term outlook for 2014 and ’15
remains pretty much the same as it has been for several forecasting periods. The September jobs
report received more than its share of attention, given the delays in other important data releases.
Although the report was perceived as weak, the overall state of the labor market continues to
improve. It’s important to recognize that since the recovery began, the first estimates of payroll
increases have been revised up, on average, by 29,000 jobs each month. I would also note that

October 29–30, 2013

25 of 239

the standard deviation of the revisions between the first print and the last print is more than
46,000. So I think we would be well advised to put very little weight on these initial estimates
and avoid letting them play a large role in our policy decision process.
Looking past the monthly ups and downs, the economy continues to add jobs, and
unemployment continues to fall. In this context, the recent drop in labor force participation rates
has been viewed with some concern. The decline in participation rates leads some to view the
fall in unemployment as overstating the progress being made in the labor market. There is also
some concern that the unemployment rate might even reverse and move back up as discouraged
workers return to the labor force. Research by my staff, using micro data from the Current
Population Survey on the reasons for nonparticipation, questions this view. Since the start of
2012—that is, over about the past year and a half or two years, roughly speaking—the
unemployment rate has declined a little more than 1 percentage point, and the participation rate
has declined about 0.5 percentage point. Research by my staff indicates retirements can entirely
accounted for the decline in the participation rate. Now, the decision to retire may well be
affected by the state of the economy, but reentry rates from retirement are historically very, very
low and indeed have not changed very much, even over this cycle. Thus, it appears unlikely that
those who left the labor force, at least over the past couple of years, will seek employment and
return to the labor force as the economy improves.
Overall, my view is that the medium-term outlook has changed very little since June.
Output continues to grow; unemployment continues to fall; employment continues to grow; and
we still forecast inflation to return toward our goal. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.

October 29–30, 2013

26 of 239

MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston’s
forecast is quite similar to the staff’s Tealbook forecast, including some of the interesting
contours of that forecast. Like the Tealbook, we expect that the second half of this year will look
much like the first and that we will finally live up to our New Year’s resolutions over the past
few years and GDP growth will rise from 2 percent to 3 percent beginning in the new year. But
just how confident can we be that this time we will achieve our resolution?
Looking at some of the initial conditions, one can certainly argue that an uptick to growth
is a realistic expectation. An important component of this forecast is the increase in consumer
spending due to a variety of factors that, by historical standards, appear to be quite favorable.
Consumers are wealthier, as both the stock market and housing prices have surprised on the
upside over the past year. While the recent payroll employment numbers have been
disappointing, total payroll employment has risen by more than 2 million jobs over the past year.
Oil prices have come down, leaving more disposable income to purchase other items. Finally,
consumer balance sheets are healthier, and interest rates on auto loans and home loans remain
quite low by historical standards.
I would have expected these same positive events to have carried over to improved
consumer sentiment. However, that has not been the case. Work by the Boston staff finds that
sentiment remains surprisingly low, not only by historical standards but also relative to factors
that normally drive consumer sentiment. If one forecasts sentiment using economic variables
that capture income, employment, inflation, commodity prices, and stock prices, there is a fairly
tight in-sample fit. However, currently sentiment is roughly 10 points lower than what would be
expected from the out-of-sample forecast equation. The source of the depressed consumer is
hard to pinpoint, but it does raise a concern that after New Year’s Eve, the morning-after

October 29–30, 2013

27 of 239

hangover may not lead consumers to spend as currently projected by models using historical
data. Certainly, one might conjecture that another prolonged discussion about the debt ceiling
and government shutdown will do little to boost consumer confidence in the future.
This highlights a second potential risk to the forecast: the outlook for fiscal policy. Even
during less fiscally entertaining times, forecasts of government spending have economically
meaningful standard errors. Work by the Boston staff looked at how well forecasts of
government spending captured subsequent government spending. One might have expected that
with an improved budget process, government spending would be fairly predictable. However,
the standard errors for both semiannual and annual forecasts of spending since 1979 are
relatively large and indicate a fairly high degree of uncertainty about the accuracy of government
spending forecasts. In many cases over the past 25 years, the forecast errors have indicated that
when the economy is weaker than expected, government spending tends to be larger than
forecast. I am concerned that this time the correlation may switch sign. Government spending
remains difficult to predict. But while the precise timing and nature of the next fiscal agreement
remain quite uncertain, the risk that we will experience disruptive fiscal discussions followed by
more short-term fiscal austerity than is needed in the current economy remains quite elevated.
In fact, my own recent forecast errors suggest that that pattern is something to worry
about for the coming year. Over the past few years, my baseline forecasts up to the actual fiscal
decisions were that the 2011 debt ceiling discussion would not be disruptive, that the
sequestration would not be implemented, and that this year we would avoid a government
shutdown and another disruptive debt ceiling discussion. That I have consistently assumed that
irrational fiscal policy that damages the economy would be avoided, and that those errors have
all gone in one direction with downside consequences for the economy, makes me pause as I

October 29–30, 2013

28 of 239

think about a 2014 forecast that once again assumes that fiscal shocks will not drag down growth
next year.
Despite these concerns, I still expect the 2014 economic data to be better than the series
of disappointments we experienced in the 2013 economic data, with real GDP growth
accelerating from the 2 percent rate we expect in the second half of this year to 3 percent next
year. However, my forecast, based on an optimistic expectation of improved consumer spending
and fewer headwinds from fiscal policy, does not have balanced risks. The downside risks
should make us unwilling to reduce stimulus until the economic growth we are expecting is
clearly in the data, not just in the forecast. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Data collected during the past six weeks
suggest that economic activity in the Eighth District has grown at a moderate pace. Most
business contacts in the District think their businesses are performing better than a year ago, but
that business conditions in the third quarter were similar to those in the second quarter. In other
words, there does not appear to have been any marked upturn in business performance so far
during the second half of 2013, contrary to the Committee’s hopes earlier this year.
Some signs from the District’s formidable transportation industry do seem to indicate that
improved macroeconomic performance is possible during the coming quarters. One large firm
indicated that capital expenditure outlays will likely double next year, even in the face of
relatively lackluster business conditions currently and relatively high levels of business
uncertainty. This was a clear case of trying to put cash to work rather than allowing it to lie idle
on a firm’s balance sheet. Another large firm indicated some difficulty in attempting to hire
about 4,000 temporary seasonal workers to handle increased holiday traffic. This could be an

October 29–30, 2013

29 of 239

indication that labor markets are somewhat firmer than the Committee has been expecting
recently.
Reports for planned activities in manufacturing and most services have been positive.
Real estate conditions in the District continue to improve in terms of both quantity and price.
District job growth has been modestly slower than job growth in the nation as a whole. The
District’s unemployment rate, measured across District MSAs, was 7.4 percent in the latest
reading, somewhat above the national unemployment rate. One concern of mine during 2013 has
been that the District unemployment rate has begun to run slightly above the national rate, while
historically, the District rate was well below the national rate. This is a trend to watch going
forward.
Nationally, the economy shows few signs of the momentum swing to the upside that the
Committee has been hoping for during 2013. Nonfarm payrolls were weaker than expected in
September. Furthermore, there has been a marked slowing in the pace of private nonfarm
payroll hiring over the past few months, relative to the first half of the year and the last quarter of
2012. Consumption spending is likely to come in lower than we would like during the third
quarter, with especially slow spending in the service sector. Also worrisome, as mentioned
earlier: There is, at this point, little evidence of a sustained rebound in labor productivity
growth.
I still see inflation running well below our target of 2 percent. I view it as important to
the credibility of our inflation target that we be able to hit the target over a reasonable time
frame. With crude oil prices having recently turned down, it is probable that consumer energy
prices will follow. Although inflation-sensitive data are sparse because of the government
shutdown, available data have mostly come in lower than expected. Market-based inflation

October 29–30, 2013

30 of 239

expectations over the next five years remain around 1¾ percent, with inflation expectations over
the next two years lower, a bit less than 1½ percent. I take that number very seriously.
Residential and nonresidential construction activity nationally appeared to advance at a
fairly healthy pace during the third quarter. Still, continued declines in the housing affordability
index are expected to dampen growth in residential housing.
Despite the lackluster data available as of this meeting, I caution the Committee to wait
until the dust has settled on 2013 outcomes before judging the results, and on this dimension I
agree with President Plosser. As always, our readings on the economy are highly variable and
could be substantially revised.
I continue to see the case for an improved macroeconomic outlook in 2014 as good. In
particular, with Europe finally exiting its recession and global growth prospects generally
improving, a reasonable forecast is that 2014 U.S. GDP growth will top 3 percent. While it is
true that many forecasts of U.S. GDP growth in recent years, including my own, have tended to
be overly optimistic, I think it is unlikely that the U.S. economy will continue to surprise on the
downside, barring a catastrophic event.
Speaking of catastrophic events, let me now turn to make a few comments on the national
pastime. I refer not to the St. Louis Cardinals and Boston Red Sox World Series matchup,
although I have recently marked up my probability of a disaster outcome in that sector [laughter]
significantly. In particular, I may soon be forced to pay off my bet with President Rosengren
concerning a six-pack of the “local brew” to the winner. No, I refer not to baseball but to the
other national pastime: partisan bickering in Washington. While I agree with much of the
analysis in the Tealbook concerning the potential effects of the government shutdown and the
associated brinkmanship on macroeconomic outcomes, I am very cautious about any intimation

October 29–30, 2013

31 of 239

from this Committee that partisan volatility is a new variable governing monetary policy. This
Committee may well need to make key monetary policy decisions at junctures when the level of
partisan volatility is higher than desired, as it has in the past. And, accordingly, I think it is
undesirable to suggest that the Committee will necessarily remain on hold until Washington
waters are completely calm. That may be a very, very long wait. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Before I get to my economic report, I
want to get a jump on the praise and honors that you will deservedly be receiving over the next
three months. It turns out, in 1932, the Coca-Cola Company sponsored a portrait of Santa Claus,
and they have decided to update it this year to make it more modern. And my deadline for input
is in early November. So with your permission—
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We’d have to check with my Yiddish grandmother on that.
[Laughter]
MR. LOCKHART. By the way, just to prove the point, that’s what Santa Claus used to
look like. Next year— [Laughter]
The tone of anecdotal reports from a pretty large sample of contacts in the Sixth District
over the past three weeks was downbeat compared with the period before the September meeting
and earlier in the year. Many had expected a pickup in activity in the second half. That
acceleration has not materialized. While most anticipate continued slow growth in the near term,
many of our contact reports sounded the themes of increased uncertainty and greater caution.
The fiscal drama seems to have adversely affected household and business sentiment at
least for a while. The Affordable Care Act, the sequestration, and the regulatory environment
were also cited as factors weighing negatively on confidence.

October 29–30, 2013

32 of 239

A trucking firm expressed concern over a soft holiday season as some of its large
customers, notably big-box and dollar stores, recently began cutting shipments. A national
distributor of maintenance and replacement industrial parts described flat demand from its
150,000 industrial customers and offered that manufacturers are building for orders, not for
inventory. Retail industry reports were mixed, but most contacts reported a decline in sales and
demand following a slower-than-expected summer and back-to-school season. Some retailers
also indicated that they planned to hire fewer seasonal staff, reflecting less optimistic
expectations about the upcoming holiday season. We did hear reports of strength in consumer
spending at the high end, reinforcing the perception of a two-tier consumer spending picture.
We heard concern expressed that households with tighter budgets may incur a hit to disposable
income because of higher health care insurance expense.
Business investment appetite and intentions remain soft, with outlays aimed at equipment
replacement rather than expansion. We heard a number of reports of deferred investment
decisions. Our anecdotal feedback on employment trends and intentions was mixed. Sectors
such as energy, IT, auto, and construction continue to report incremental hiring. In the auto
sector, however, a provider of temporary labor reported a slowdown in manufacturers’
converting temporaries to permanent employees. A director in the hospital industry reported
layoffs due to reduced Medicare reimbursement. Otherwise we mostly heard reports of delaying
additions to employment levels and resorting to increased hours to meet business demand.
As regards price pressures, our contacts reported little concern about inflation. Cost
pressures seemed to be well contained. Isolated industries, including fast food, grocery, and
commodity construction materials, reported being able to get the market to accept small price
increases. Wages remained stable across most industries.

October 29–30, 2013

33 of 239

To sum up, many of our business contacts this cycle reported revising down their
expectations for the fourth quarter and 2014. I think it is prudent not to overreact to mood
swings among our public contacts, particularly directly after the spectacle of fiscal impasse here
in Washington. That said, my sense of the data points to continued slow growth in the vicinity of
2 percent rather than the hoped-for acceleration to something closer to 3 percent. So I am once
more marking down my near-term outlook and struggling with the question of whether to scale
back economic growth projections for the medium term. At the very least I feel I have to put
more weight on downside risk for economic growth and inflation at this juncture than I did in
September.
The Tealbook’s economic growth projection was revised downward a touch in 2013, but
revised up marginally in 2014 and 2015. My forecast continues to be less optimistic over the
medium term than the Tealbook, and I admit to growing embarrassment with my persistently
overly optimistic growth forecasts. I’m increasingly skeptical that the explanation is an unusual
sequence of one-off events and temporary headwinds, and even if the reality is not something
more persistent, I’m finding it hard to convince myself that the economy will not limp along, if
not indefinitely, then for quite a while longer. This makes a tapering decision look more like a
policy choice requiring extremely deft explanation, and I’ll elaborate more in the next round on
that.
In the very near term, we may not get much help in clarifying the economic picture from
incoming data, some of which are likely to be less reliable. Also, the potential for some kind of
replay of the fiscal drama clouds the near term through February at least. These are frustrating
circumstances in which to wrestle with the question of appropriate monetary policy, and I look

October 29–30, 2013

34 of 239

forward to the next two rounds for enlightenment from my colleagues. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I hope all don’t take that attitude. [Laughter] President
Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I had suggested in a note to our colleagues
that we put our ear to the ground and try to get a feeling for how the government shutdown is
actually affecting businesses and consumers, and I’ll just give my own little report. First, with
regard to our District, the 11th Federal Reserve District, most firms reported that the government
shutdown had little to no effect on their business. The most severe impact was in airlines, energy
permitting, and small business lending largely because of the e-system delays. A subsequent
follow-up of our investigation indicates that at least in airlines and energy permitting there has
been a snapback.
I then asked whether or not MasterCard could include a question in its spending pulse
survey, which, as you know, I hold in high regard, as to whether or not it showed an impact of
the government shutdown. It’s a more thorough database, more national, obviously; it extends
way beyond our District. And this gets to a point that President Rosengren raised. It’s not clear
that there was a direct impact, but there is a constant corrosive effect as we go through time.
We’re in for our ninth commission since 2010 investigating how we might deal with the budget
issues, and although it’s not clear from the analysis of those data, there does seem to be a
cumulative depressive effect on consumers as well as on business operators. I just wanted to
mention that because I think it’s important for us to keep our ear to the ground in the Districts
when we don’t have reliable data that might come from central authorities because the
government was shut down. My summary is pretty much that which the CEO of MasterCard

October 29–30, 2013

35 of 239

provided. I think it just wears you down, President Rosengren, over time. I don’t think it augurs
well for the future as long as this keeps going on and we revive it again in February and March.
With regard to my own District, we just completed and reported this morning the third of
a series of our surveys. Just so that everybody is on the same plane, our survey collection period
is October 15 to 23. So, Mr. Chairman, it’s the most up-to-date of the surveys. I know Kansas
City’s is October 16 to 21. The rest of them are a little bit earlier. There is a bifurcation in what
we discovered in our own surveys. Manufacturing activity in the 11th District picked up further
in October. The production index, which is a key measure of state manufacturing, rose, and it
suggests that output increased at a slightly faster pace than in September. New orders came in
slightly higher than in September—that’s the sixth consecutive month of increased demand. The
labor market indicators are interesting: They reflect continued employment growth and longer
workweeks and some upward pressure on prices and compensation costs. This differs somewhat
from, and actually is somewhat contrary to, what we released this morning with our servicesector data and the subsurvey we do on retail sales. As opposed to the manufacturing sector,
which I suspect is largely driven by exports, and particularly energy-sensitive exports, and which
seems so positive still, service-sector activity slowed somewhat in October. The revenue index
dipped a little bit. The employment index, however, increased, but hours worked decreased, in
sharp contrast to what happened in the manufacturing sector. Price pressures increased while
wage pressures, as you would expect, eased in October. So we have a mixed signal again in
terms of the difference between what happened in the manufacturing survey and the servicesector survey. With regard to retail prices, we’re seeing them begin to increase, but again, wage
pressures are easing in October. So there’s a bifurcation, as I suggested earlier, between the
manufacturing sector and the more important service and retail sector.

October 29–30, 2013

36 of 239

I also asked Dunkelberg’s organization to do a special survey of our District. What I
found most interesting is that 55 percent of the businesses in the National Federation of
Independent Businesses in my District have no desire to take on loans, and only 2½ percent cite
credit as a problem in terms of the issues that they’re faced with as businesses. So it doesn’t
appear that credit is an issue for the small businesses covered by that survey as it applies to the
11th Federal Reserve District.
With regard to my corporate interlocutors and the broader group that I personally survey
across the nation, from all Federal Reserve Districts, I would say, as President Lockhart said
earlier, that the assumption for the growth rate is roughly in the 2 percent range—not much
acceleration. The highest I heard was actually from the express companies, including one in
your District, President Lockhart—maybe 2½ percent—but in terms of the activity, it’s still
rather sluggish. I would say that the generic answer to my question “Why are you not hiring?” is
as follows: “Why should I? My stock is up 150-plus percent. My margins are high and stable.
My productivity is excellent, and I keep driving it”—and I’ll come back to that in just a second.
“My balance sheet is uberstrong and ubercheap, restructured, strongly financed.” Nobody is
telling me that we’re about to see significant macroeconomic growth, as President Lockhart
pointed out earlier. “Capacity utilization is not much of a strain. I’m not sure what my taxes are
going to be, but I think they’re going to go up. I have no idea how I’m going to be regulated.”
And here’s an interesting point that somewhat differs with theory. “Nobody, including you,
President Fisher, is telling me that inflation is about to be a problem, but I’m absolutely
convinced it will be a problem long-term unless you manage the exit more thoughtfully than I
believe the Federal Reserve is capable of doing.”

October 29–30, 2013

37 of 239

So what am “I” doing in the meantime? One would think that, if one feared that we
might have some inflation that resulted from our policy, one would begin to hire and one would
begin to commit capital. Instead what they’re doing is hoarding, and they’re just driving their
current workers to the maximum productivity before they add further. I know it seems like it’s
antitheoretical, but I think we have to put ourselves in the mindset of how CEOs actually think
and how they actually act, and the way they’re acting right now is basically harboring resources,
manipulating the price of their stock by buying it back in or increasing dividends, and using the
cheap cost of capital rather than putting people back to work.
I remain convinced, Mr. Chairman, that the combination of fiscal policy and monetary
policy is working principally for the benefit of the higher-income groups, not of the two middleincome quartiles. And I want to just conclude on a personal note. Next week I’m going to be in
Australia. I’m going to visit the courthouse in which my father was sentenced to prison, at the
age of six, for seven years—you know the story—and I’m actually going to go to the railway
station where he was picked up. This was after the Panic of 1907. The Fed was founded three
years after he was arrested and imprisoned. One of the reasons the Fed was founded was to
make sure that we didn’t have these kinds of massive movements that resulted in—and you
know more about this history than I do—these huge swings of recession and depression, and we
created a central bank that would help and would aid stability. And it may be a chip on my
shoulder, but I remain convinced—looking at the S&P 500; looking at the Nasdaq; looking at the
spread, which, as pointed out earlier, has narrowed on triple-C credits; looking at what’s
happening in the credit markets and the disjunction that occurs now between that and our second
mandate of employment—that the policy that we pursue is aiding and abetting the rich and the
quick, but it is not benefiting the middle-income quartiles and in the end will be damaging to the

October 29–30, 2013

38 of 239

poor. This is my biggest concern. I’ll discuss it a little bit tomorrow. I thank you for letting me
speak, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you. I don’t see the economic outlook much differently today
than I did at our previous meeting. So I suppose I could stop there, but I will offer a few reasons
as to why I don’t see the outlook as changed.
As has been mentioned, the government shutdown has interfered with the flow of data
that we would typically receive during an intermeeting period. Based on our Beige Book calls
and outreach to my business contacts, economic activity in my District has generally continued
to expand at a fairly steady pace, with particular strength in autos and shale gas extraction
activities. But many District contacts emphasize the uncertainty about the outlook that rose as
the government shutdown dragged on. They stated that they were waiting to see how that
dispute would be resolved before making larger investment and hiring decisions. The
postponement of finding a satisfactory resolution to the fiscal problems is being taken as just
that—a postponement rather than a resolution. Depending on how business confidence evolves,
there is room for either stronger economic growth, as the recent ISM data show, or more of the
same slow growth trajectory.
Of course, the BLS did eventually release the September labor market report, and in my
view it was a mixed bag of information. The employment gains continued at a rate of 148,000 in
September, which is not statistically different from the average pace of gains over the previous
six months. The media coverage following that release focused on whether that 148,000 pace
might persuade this Committee to delay the slowing of our purchase programs. Because of that,
it was hardly noticed that the unemployment rate dipped another tenth, to 7.2 percent. While it

October 29–30, 2013

39 of 239

certainly would be more encouraging to have stronger employment growth, the progress in the
unemployment rate over the past 12 months has been primarily the result of employment gains
that cumulatively, in my view, have been substantial.
As the staff memo on alternative simple rules for large-scale asset purchases
demonstrates, expectations for the labor force participation rate are critical to any assessment of
substantial progress in the outlook for labor markets. Despite the fact that participation rates
remain about 3 percentage points lower than prior to the recession, a strong case can be made
that much of the reduction in the participation rate has been due to demographic trends, not the
business cycle. The reductions in participation that have occurred generally have been consistent
with models of trend participation that are maintained by my staff and that were published in
research done by the Board’s staff several years ago. Relative to recent declines in participation,
and the demographic trend that is pushing the participation rate lower, the Tealbook’s projection
of only gradual declines in the participation rate from today’s level actually represents a small
cyclical rebound in participation. And it’s worth noting that even when we did see those
relatively stronger employment gains during this recovery, we didn’t see evidence that there
would be a cyclical rebound in participation.
Now, in addition, my Bank’s analysis of labor market flows continues to show a
fundamentally less dynamic labor market, as measured by the churn rate, compared with either
the 1980s or the 1990s. These changes look to be a part of a longer-term trend and, thus, are less
likely to represent cyclical factors. My Bank’s analysis suggests that the less dynamic labor
market and a flat-to-declining participation rate make job gains of about 150,000 per month the
expected outcome. In this model, these moderate employment gains result in steady progress in
the unemployment rate, as we have in fact experienced over the past six months. So as much as

October 29–30, 2013

40 of 239

we’d all prefer a faster pace of job growth, we should not view the recent pace of job gains as
inadequate for making progress in labor markets. While these results are model dependent, the
labor market data of the past few years have repeatedly shown that this recovery does not require
200,000 jobs per month to make progress on the unemployment rate. Indeed, the unemployment
rate has declined 2.8 percentage points since its peak at 10 percent in 2009. Again, although a
faster decline would have been helpful, given the high starting rate of unemployment, the decline
in the unemployment rate in this recovery turns out to be comparable to or faster than that in the
prior two recoveries.
Turning to inflation, we will have to be cautious in interpreting incoming price reports for
some time. While people are generally discussing the effects of the shutdown on employment
figures, the shutdown of the BLS also has the potential to add more noise to our price data.
Analysis at my Bank suggests that the errors due to missed price observations at the individual
item level will be the largest in the October data, but that errors can persist for up to six months,
as not all items are surveyed every month. Of course, errors in the CPI will also affect the PCE
price index, given the common source data for these indexes. Given these issues, it seems most
likely that the somewhat reduced signal in incoming data will lead us to conclude that the
inflation rate has remained low but should gradually head higher.
While uncertainty has increased, and data releases over the next few months will have
more noise than usual, my forecast is little changed from the previous FOMC meeting, and I
continue to see slow but steady improvements in labor markets and a gradual rise in inflation
toward our 2 percent longer-term objective. I continue to judge the overall risk to economic
growth, unemployment, and inflation as broadly balanced. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Williams.

October 29–30, 2013

41 of 239

MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The partial government shutdown has
complicated our job, but only in three relatively minor ways. First, the drop in governmentworker hours creates a one-time dip in fourth-quarter real GDP. But with retroactive paychecks
for all federal employees, fourth-quarter nominal GDP and GDI are unaffected, and those
measures are arguably the more relevant ones that are determining aggregate demand in this
situation. The indirect impact on private-sector contractors and suppliers also seems modest.
Second, the budget and debt ceiling battles had a broader effect on confidence and sentiment, but
that effect appears to have been transitory. Daily measures of policy uncertainty spiked in midOctober, but then they fell back rapidly after the government reopened. Similarly, daily Gallup
polls of consumer confidence bounced back significantly after dropping in the first half of
October. Such ephemeral shifts in uncertainty and consumer confidence should leave relatively
little imprint on household and business spending. Third, the shutdown delayed some
macroeconomic data releases, but we are far from flying blind. Only two releases are still
missing: September new home sales and the September CPI. The CPI will be released
tomorrow morning, but already private-sector data have helped fill the gap. We have the
September and October inflation readings from the Billion Prices Project developed at MIT.
Each day this initiative scrapes Internet price data and creates an index that closely tracks the
CPI. Its latest readings, running through near the end of October, show a CPI-consistent
inflation rate of about 2 percent, indicating that overall inflation remains in line with recent
trends. I might add that the initial read on third-quarter GDP, which won’t be available
tomorrow as originally scheduled, is mostly an aggregation of publicly available monthly data,
plus BEA assumptions about missing months. And it typically doesn’t add much to our existing
information set.

October 29–30, 2013

42 of 239

Now, to further make up for any remaining data shortfall, we have the Beige Book and
other business reports. My contacts suggest that the forces driving a pickup in economic growth
remain on track. For one, demand for housing and home-related products has remained resilient
despite the run-up in mortgage rates. Similarly, in commercial real estate, the rise in CMBS
spreads is not hampering activity, but merely prompting developers to switch to bank loans as a
source of funding. More broadly, my business contacts do not see significant changes in
financial conditions. Large corporations can still readily find funds at low rates, and credit
availability for smaller firms and those with below-average credit qualifications has not
deteriorated either. More broadly, with record highs in the stock market, a depreciating dollar,
and shrinking junk bond yield spreads, I see little evidence of a significant tightening of overall
financial conditions since the spring. This conclusion is supported by measures of aggregate
financial conditions compiled by Bloomberg, the Chicago Fed, and Goldman Sachs, which are
little changed or even looser than earlier this year.
Let me turn to labor market conditions; I’m going to echo some of the comments
President Pianalto just made. That is, to interpret recent employment reports, it is important to
set a realistic benchmark. Researchers at the Chicago and San Francisco Feds have estimated
that job gains of more than 125,000 jobs per month should be enough to continue pushing down
the unemployment rate. September payrolls rose more than that. Likewise, a range of other
measures, including the unemployment rate, have shown diminishing labor market slack. As I
have noted previously, the unemployment rate is a highly reliable, though not perfect, measure of
labor market strength.
Recent work by my staff at the San Francisco Fed has studied the reliability of the
unemployment rate by reexamining the relationship between GDP and unemployment, otherwise

October 29–30, 2013

43 of 239

known as Okun’s law. Over the past several years, we have heard repeatedly that Okun’s law is
dead, but because it is one of the few things I learned in economics, I really want to keep to it, so
I’m going to argue that it’s still alive. The main evidence for the demise in Okun’s law is a
surprising divergence in the movements of unemployment and GDP during the recession and
recovery. Early in the recession, the unemployment rate rose rapidly, while GDP fell more
slowly. As the economy recovered, the reverse occurred, and the unemployment rate has come
down significantly while GDP growth has been moderate at best. My staff revisited this issue
using both real-time and revised data, and they found some pretty interesting results. They found
that in real time the initial data releases on the growth in real GDP per capita and changes in the
unemployment rate did indicate some breakdown in Okun’s law. However, revised data showed
no such disruption in the typical relationship between GDP and unemployment. GDP now
shows a sharper decline during the recession and faster growth during the recovery than the
original estimates, restoring the normal Okun’s law relationship. This analysis also found that
the recent behavior of Okun’s law is remarkably consistent with the pattern in other deep
recessions, looking back at 1973 and 1981–82. Interestingly, if you use real gross domestic
income as a measure of output rather than GDP, Okun’s law was never particularly out of line,
either in real time or with the revised data. Altogether this evidence suggests that the
unemployment rate is not out of line with signals from the aggregate output and income
statistics. This reassures me that the unemployment rate continues to provide a reasonably
accurate signal about the strength of the labor market and the degree of slack in the economy.
Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.

October 29–30, 2013

44 of 239

MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As best I can tell from the data in hand and
my business contacts, the economic situation hasn’t changed a great deal since our September
meeting, so in some respects, like President Pianalto, I could stop at this point. I’ll go on briefly.
It’s still difficult to assess the strength of the economy, especially the effect on activity of
the financial market tightening overall since last spring. Not only was the data flow interrupted
by the government shutdown, but it is also hard to interpret the data and anecdotal information
we do have, because they are colored by households’ and businesses’ reactions to the drama in
Washington. With that caveat, and as in the Tealbook, it looks to us like economic growth is
continuing to muddle along at about a 2 percent rate. Two thousand thirteen will likely turn out
to be yet another example of events intervening to dash our beginning-of-year hopes for a
meaningful step-up in activity. The recent labor market data are consistent with this assessment.
My conversations with directors and business contacts also reinforce this view of muddling
along.
On the positive side, auto sales continue to be relatively strong. Demand and pricing for
steel has remained solid. Businesses have breathed a sigh of relief with Europe finally beginning
to grow again, and there are fewer worries now about slowing in China. But the downside risks
remain substantial. In addition to the usual suspects—perhaps it is a national pastime—there is
the new risk that Washington will schedule quarterly tournaments in brinkmanship. It’s sort of
exasperating. In such circumstances, businesses and households are exceedingly unlikely to
accelerate their spending plans. Indeed, none of my business contacts expressed plans to
increase hiring or capital expansion through the first half of 2014 and certainly not before
customer demand increases substantially, as President Fisher also alluded to. And inflation
continues to be low.

October 29–30, 2013

45 of 239

In this environment, accommodative policies remain essential to supporting the economic
growth prospects that we do have. In sum, the limited information we have received since our
September meeting did not strengthen the case for making an initial reduction in the pace of asset
purchases. We are still very much in a wait-and-see mode for our long-awaited virtuous cycle.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. During the intermeeting period,
we heard numerous reports in the Ninth District that indicated that employers were finding it
more challenging to find workers. Both small and large businesses from around the District told
us that they saw the pool of available workers as being smaller and systematically lower quality
than a year ago. These reports are congruent with the low unemployment in our District. As of
August, the District unemployment rate was around 5 percent.
However, despite the reports of labor market tightness, there is little evidence yet of
accelerating wage pressures. Businesses largely continue to think of wage growth in the 3 to
4 percent range as being appropriate. Indeed, the Ninth District Beige Book reports that, just like
over a year ago, more than 40 percent of companies report no plans to raise wages. We should,
of course, be cautious about generalizing to the entire country from the small Ninth District. But
that said, I do see these observations as suggesting that wage and goods inflation pressures will
remain muted nationally, even when unemployment is considerably lower and when workers
have become much harder to find.
In passing, I will comment on some of the work that President Williams summarized
and the work that President Pianalto summarized. I think that this work is very valuable in trying
to provide a benchmark look at the labor market, but I also think that wage pressures and

October 29–30, 2013

46 of 239

inflation really are a very important guide in terms of thinking about whether or not labor
markets are improving too rapidly or insufficiently rapidly. And I will come back to that when I
talk about the national picture, which I am about to turn to now.
So let me turn to the national economy. It’s tempting at this point in my remarks to
spend a great deal of time on the evolution of labor market indicators since last September. After
all, our communication—indeed, our thinking—about the asset purchase program has tended to
center on the following question: Has the labor market improved sufficiently relative to last
September to warrant reducing the flow of purchases? But the reactions of markets and the
public to our communications over the past six months have convinced me that our focus on this
backward-looking question is leading us astray. In my view, the markets and the public see the
FOMC as being forward-looking decisionmakers. As a result, markets and the public are not all
that interested by what we meant in September 2012 by the words “substantial improvement,” or
even what we mean by those words now. Instead, they operate under the presumption that we
will reduce the flow of purchases whenever we believe that doing so is necessary to curb an
overly rapid rate of expansion of prices and/or employment.
This assumption by markets and the public that we will taper when we feel the economy
is in danger of overheating is exactly what makes near-term tapering so challenging. Under what
I perceive to be the Committee’s monetary policy stance, my outlook for the national economy is
not all that different from Tealbook, Book A’s. I see inflation remaining below target for the
next four to five years, and unemployment falling only slowly to its lower, long-run level. How
should the Committee respond to such an outlook? Both prices and employment are too low
relative to the Committee’s long-run goals. With this outlook, talking about tapering sends the

October 29–30, 2013

47 of 239

following message: “The Committee is trying to slow the recovery down even though the
economy remains far from the FOMC’s stated long-run goals.”
And just forget about the employment picture for the moment. There is a long-standing
debate in economics about the effect of monetary policy on employment. That debate has gone
on for many years and will continue to go on. There is much less of a debate on our ability to
influence prices. So let’s just focus on inflation. It is running at about 1.2 percent, and we
expect it to rise only slowly back to 2 percent. Reducing accommodation, given that outlook for
prices, tells the public that we actually prefer to see persistent gaps between realized inflation
and our target. With that messaging in mind, I don’t think we should be surprised that our recent
communications have created considerable policy uncertainty.
Now, as it turns out, I think the markets and the public are right that the FOMC is
ultimately a forward-looking body of decisionmakers. I think what the markets and public are
missing is that there is something else in our thought processes, that our choices about asset
purchases are not based solely on our assessment of the economic outlook, or whether the
economy is overheating or not. Instead, our decisions about this tool are being influenced in
important ways by costs and efficacy considerations. In my view, our real communication
problem is that we have not been sufficiently transparent about the importance of these other
factors in our thinking. So what I’m suggesting here, Mr. Chairman, is that in addition to the
three principles you laid out, we should consider adding a fourth principle of communication:
that we should emphasize the cost and efficacy considerations that make LSAPs distinct in our
mind from the fed funds rate. I will have more to say about this issue of transparency in the next
go-round. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President George.

October 29–30, 2013

48 of 239

MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The District economy continues to grow. It
has been supported by a notable pickup in construction. Employment continues to expand at a
moderate pace in most District states, although those gains have slowed somewhat over the past
six months in part because of job losses in the federal government and energy sectors. District
manufacturing activity expanded in September and October, and manufacturing survey
respondents expect a similar pace of expansion over the next six months. Energy activity
remained steady in September, with rig counts roughly flat and coal production improving
slightly. The corn and soybean harvest is well under way across the Midwest. Yields are
healthy, and as a result we are experiencing lower crop prices, which have helped the livestock
industry to surpass breakevens for the first time in over a year. But despite projected lower farm
incomes, District farmland values have continued to rise to about 20 percent higher than a year
ago.
My District business and labor contacts met last week, representing a variety of national
and global businesses in areas such as children’s apparel, supplying stores like Wal-Mart, Target,
and Kohl’s; fueling stations and convenience stores; sawmill and wood products; cement
manufacturing; and an electrical workers union. Most are optimistic about business profits,
although all noted growing regulatory burdens, leading some of them for the first time in their
company history to add regulatory compliance departments and staffing. A number of them
highlighted the direct or indirect effects of the government shutdown on their businesses,
focusing particularly on heightened uncertainty and lower confidence levels. And, finally,
contacts expressed concerns that they were experiencing now, or would soon experience,
shortages of skilled labor in trade professions as construction activity continues to pick up.

October 29–30, 2013

49 of 239

Turning to the national economy, my overall assessment is largely unchanged from
September. The challenge, as others have noted, over the next few months will be to sort
through the likely temporary shifts in employment related to the government shutdown and debt
ceiling debate and to assess the underlying momentum for the economy. When I look at the
August 2011 debt ceiling crisis as a proxy, I note that the three-month moving average of
monthly payroll growth slowed from 210,000 in June to 140,000 in August. And yet within
three months the measure of employment growth bounced back to 190,000, and it further
accelerated to 270,000 by February 2012. Measures of consumer confidence followed a similar
pattern, down sharply in August 2011 but back to earlier peaks by February 2012.
As I look beyond current fiscal headwinds and disruptions, my outlook for the labor
market continues to improve. I would note that the Survey of Professional Forecasters’ oneyear-ahead forecast for nonfarm payroll growth was 149,000 in the third quarter of 2012, and it
is now 181,000. I expect inflation to pick up in the second half of this year and next year as
labor market conditions continue to improve, private demand strengthens, and inflation
expectations remain stable.
And, finally, a comment on banking conditions based on banking contacts’ and
supervisory staff’s feedback: I continue to watch the challenges that the banking industry faces
around these extraordinarily low interest rates as their net interest margins compress and the
search for yield continues. Among smaller banks, I see renewed interest in commercial real
estate lending, with particularly stiff competition resulting in longer maturities and fixed rates.
Among larger banks, a sizable release of reserves related to better asset quality now suggests
very thin coverage of future losses at a time when lending to commercial and industrial
customers is growing, and some of those quite leveraged. Results of our shared national credit

October 29–30, 2013

50 of 239

review and the Senior Loan Officers Opinion Survey corroborate some of these concerns. Of
course, I see plenty of evidence that examiners have this in focus, but to stem the tide of searchfor-yield incentives will be difficult as long as this low-rate environment persists. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Our survey indexes haven’t changed much
in the past month. Manufacturing numbers are essentially flat, and our services numbers remain
positive without much change. Our anecdotal reports are generally consistent with the sense that
little has changed, with the exception of widespread reports of slowing activity in the D.C. area
due to the government slowdown, but these are not at all inconsistent with the staff assessment
reported by David Lebow—essentially that this will be virtually entirely a transitory affair. We
have also heard reports of some offsets in the form of increased traffic at private amusement
parks, private Civil War sites and museums, hardware stores, and fishing supply stores, where
the increase in weekday traffic was particularly noted.
In addition, we have heard a lot from our contacts about the fallout from the Affordable
Care Act. There have been many reports of employers’ keeping staff levels under 50 and cutting
employees’ hours to under 30. In fact, we heard of a pair of franchises that were arranging to
share some full-time employees to keep them under 30 hours each at each firm. More broadly,
many contacts reported that the ACA was having a chilling effect on business because of the
general uncertainty about its implementation.
We have also heard ubiquitous reports of shortages of skilled labor from our contacts. In
addition to the usual stories about IT workers, many reports center on skilled trades, such as
maritime maintenance, sewer workers, pipefitters, auto mechanics, plumbers, and carpenters.

October 29–30, 2013

51 of 239

Contacts say that the entry of younger workers is not keeping up with the need to replace retiring
workers.
Turning to the national economy, this Tealbook’s narrative is a familiar one. First, it
acknowledges that real economic growth has not been as strong as had been predicted. Second,
it pulls down the near-term forecast. And, third, it reiterates that growth will pick up
significantly within a couple of quarters—in this case, one or two quarters—and will continue at
that higher rate for several more years. But real GDP growth was 2.0 percent in 2011, 2.0
percent in 2012, and is now predicted to be 2.0 percent in 2013. I recognize that reasonable
people can disagree on the relative weight to place on recent experience versus the more distant
past, years when significantly higher growth rates were more typical, but for me the current data
loom large.
The staff prepared a very helpful memo for this meeting providing more detail on the
underpinnings of their forecast of an acceleration in consumer spending. I very much
appreciated the additional insight into their thinking. While the story hangs together given the
underlying premises, I find myself unpersuaded by the premises. One key driver of the
acceleration is improvement in consumer optimism. This has been commented on around the
table so far. This is an intangible factor that forecasts are inherently subjective on, so a wide
range of views are possible. Another premise of the acceleration-around-the-bend hypothesis is
the pickup in growth in real disposable income. Some of this represents anticipated fiscal policy
shifts, but the bulk appears to stem from a persistent pickup in productivity growth in the
Tealbook, as I was asking about earlier. Growth in output per hour in the nonfarm business
sector has averaged 0.7 percent per year for the past three years, and the Tealbook has it
averaging 1.7 percent for the next three years. To me, productivity growth seems likely to be 0.7

October 29–30, 2013

52 of 239

in the years ahead rather than 1.7, particularly given the extent of anecdotal reports of regulatory
impediments to investment and economic growth.
All of this leads me to believe that consumer spending is unlikely to accelerate much at
all in the near term. And outside of consumer spending, it’s difficult to find any other
components of demand that are likely to fuel a significant pickup in top-line economic growth.
As a result, my outlook is very much like the projection I sent in for the most recent SEP, which
had growth at only slightly above 2 percent for next year and beyond. I think we need to take
very seriously for our policy deliberations the possibility that growth continues to come in at 2
percent. If we get 2 percent rather than the acceleration projected by the Tealbook and others, I
think it’s likely to be because productivity doesn’t accelerate to the late-20th-century average. If
so, I don’t think 2 percent growth should be taken as any sort of monetary policy failure. And
tying balance sheet policies to a pickup in growth that may never come may keep us on a
hamster wheel of asset purchases for a long time to come. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I certainly don’t want to stay on a hamster wheel.
[Laughter] That doesn’t sound very attractive.
I don’t have much to add to what has already been said. On the economic growth side,
we still seem stuck around 2 percent, as President Lacker has said. And this pickup that most of
us anticipate has not yet been realized. It remains a forecast. Focusing on the growth side of the
ledger, I am a bit disappointed by the recent data, to the extent that we have data. Three areas
have gotten my attention. First, payroll employment growth appears to have slowed, even before
the effects of the government shutdown. Second, it looks like the earlier rise in mortgage rates
has taken some of the zip out of housing. I’m particularly struck by the weakness in pending

October 29–30, 2013

53 of 239

home sales. And, third, capital spending is a bit weaker than I would have anticipated, given the
favorable fundamentals of the corporate sector—a high level of profitability, very liquid balance
sheets, and readily available credit at low interest rates. In particular, with respect to capital
goods orders, the most recent durable goods orders report was quite weak when you look past the
big upsurge in aircraft orders.
Now, all of that said, prospectively, I am still becoming more optimistic, once again.
First, financial conditions have eased significantly over the past few months. Longer-term
interest rates are down, stock prices are up, and the dollar is a bit softer. Second, it appears that
credit availability is improving. This is evident not only in the results of the Senior Loan Officer
Opinion Survey, but also in my conversations with some of the smaller but well-established
businesses in my District, who say that the banks are now tripping over themselves in their
willingness to do business. Third, we have had a recent drop in gasoline prices, and that will
help support real disposable income growth. Fourth—and this is one I say with great
trepidation—I do think the risk of another debt ceiling debacle has fallen, given the negative
political consequences for those who have wanted to use it as a weapon. We’ll see if that turns
out to be right or not, but that’s my presumption. And, fifth, every month we get a little bit
further through this period of significant fiscal restraint. As the staff has noted, the fiscal
restraint in 2014 will be roughly half of what we experienced in 2013. As the degree of fiscal
restraint wanes, I think that should lead to a somewhat stronger growth pace. So despite my
having been wrong before, I continue to expect that economic growth will be a bit faster in 2013.
On inflation, given the delay in the release schedule caused by the government shutdown,
there is very little new information since the previous meeting. But I will look at the Billion
Prices data set. Anecdotally, when I talk to businesspeople, there seems to be very little price

October 29–30, 2013

54 of 239

pressure in terms of inputs or in terms of their ability to raise the prices on outputs, and the
situation doesn’t really seem to have changed materially in recent months. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. It’s challenging to make monetary policy in
the fog, and at the moment that fog is especially dense. The latest employment report did show
an upward revision to the rather tepid payroll gains originally reported for August. Even so, the
pace of monthly payroll gains shows a worrisome downward trend: 185,000 over the past
12 months, 163,000 over the past six, and 143,000 over the past three. The unemployment rate
in September rounded down one-tenth from August, but the participation rate failed to reverse
any of its earlier declines. Given the noise that the government shutdown will introduce into the
next employment report, it may be some time before we get a clearer read on whether the
slowing we are seeing in the pace of labor market improvement is just a temporary step down
along a path that will eventually exhibit greater momentum, as in the Tealbook baseline, or
whether the data instead portend a more lasting shift to a scenario of slower progress.
In June, the central tendency of our GDP growth projections for the second half of 2013
was about 2¾ percent. Now the Tealbook projects just 2¼ percent, and only a small portion of
this downward revision is due to the effects of the government shutdown. Once again, the hope
for acceleration appears to have receded into the future. I recall President Rosengren drawing an
analogy to Waiting for Godot in the previous meeting. This observation is sobering not only
because the current state of the labor market is unacceptably weak, but also because of what it
says about our ability to forecast the economy’s future course. It thus raises questions not only

October 29–30, 2013

55 of 239

about the appropriate stance of policy today, but also about the appropriate conduct of policy in a
world characterized by such great uncertainty.
At the risk of oversimplifying, perhaps it is useful to consider four scenarios for the
economy going forward, all of which, to me, have some plausibility. In scenario 1, the run of
bad luck we have experienced over the past several years is about to end, and we are poised to
see a notable pickup in growth along the lines of the Tealbook’s faster-recovery scenario. In
scenario 2, growth picks up as the various headwinds restraining demand abate, but more
gradually, as in the Tealbook baseline. In scenario 3, we are already at the new normal as far as
economic growth is concerned because structural damage to the economy from the recession and
the financial crisis exceeds that in the baseline. In this supply-side-damage scenario, the job
market, along the lines that President Lacker described, will continue to tighten even absent any
meaningful pickup in demand because structural productivity growth has declined. Finally, in
scenario 4, structural productivity growth has not declined, but private spending picks up over
time by less than the staff project, a scenario that seems entirely possible given the huge
uncertainties surrounding our forecasts of private consumption and investment spending. In this
scenario we remain stuck in the mud, with economic growth continuing at a trendlike pace and
little further progress in the labor market.
Thoughtful arguments have been made around the table in support of each one of these
scenarios. Of course, like the Tealbook, many of us have been making overly optimistic
predictions over the past several years. Although there are some tangible factors we can point to,
such as the European economic and financial situation and the course of federal fiscal policy in
the U. S., I believe it’s fair to say that we do not fully understand why growth has remained so
persistently slow.

October 29–30, 2013

56 of 239

My own modal outlook follows scenario 2, something similar to the Tealbook baseline. I
see the economy developing momentum, but only gradually and only in a context in which
monetary policy continues to provide accommodation for a long time. To be sure, I’m quite
uncertain about this outlook, as it reflects more a tendency to draw inferences from past forecast
errors than any clearly articulated view of exactly why aggregate demand is picking up so
slowly.
The other scenarios that I outlined also seem possible. For example, as the staff have
noted, the fact that growth of gross domestic income has outpaced GDP growth suggests that
demand may already have picked up more than we recognize. The structural-damage scenario
also strikes me as a realistic possibility. It is entirely plausible that the weak productivity growth
we have seen since 2010 reflected at least in part the reversal of productivity toward its structural
level following outsized gains in 2009. But if payroll gains continue at the pace we saw last year
in the face of only 2 percent GDP growth, could that still reflect catch-up? The longer
productivity keeps growing in the 1 percent range, the greater the likelihood that we may find
ourselves in a world similar to that characterized in the supply-side-damage scenario of the
Tealbook. Scenario 4 is, to me, the most worrisome possibility. There, productivity growth does
pick up, but GDP growth does not, and the pattern of improvement we have seen in the labor
market over the past year continues to stall out.
Given the plausibility of all these scenarios, we need to ensure that policy will be
appropriately positioned no matter which one unfolds. In this respect, our current plans with
respect to asset purchases and our threshold-based forward guidance work reasonably well, as I
see it, in the first three scenarios. If the headwinds lift more rapidly—scenario 1—we will be
able to wind down the asset purchase plan as envisioned in June, and if unemployment reaches

October 29–30, 2013

57 of 239

6½ percent sooner than we anticipate, we could begin to remove accommodation sooner than in
the baseline, as would be appropriate. In scenario 2—the Tealbook baseline—our current plan to
taper asset purchases as more evidence accumulates that we are on track and to maintain an
accommodative policy for some time thereafter will get us back to our full employment and
inflation goals, although the projected pace of progress is quite slow. If slow productivity
growth continues because of structural damage—scenario 3—our plan should also work. The
labor market would continue to improve even though growth may not pick up, but we can taper
asset purchases as we see that progress, and if unemployment declines quickly, it would likely
also be appropriate to remove accommodation sooner than in the baseline.
What worries me most is scenario 4, in which we’re stuck in the mud and progress stalls,
because here the risks of stagnation and disinflation are significant, and policy does not seem
appropriately positioned right now to respond. In particular, we may not then be able to end our
asset purchase program with a declaration of victory, and the outlook, absent further policy
measures, would be unacceptably weak. Tomorrow I will reflect a bit more on how we might
respond to such a scenario.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think a good many of the interventions in
this go-round have continued the theme of the past several meetings of asking two questions.
The first is: How much underlying momentum is there in the economy for faster economic
growth in the near to medium term? And the second is: To the degree that momentum is
lacking, what’s the relative persuasiveness of explanations based on some form of structural
damage—which is presumably not susceptible to repair through monetary policy—as opposed to
continuing or post-crisis headwinds, which monetary policy accommodation should be able to

October 29–30, 2013

58 of 239

offset, at least in part? I agree with those of you who have already suggested that there may not
be a whole lot that is useful to add to explanations on either of those questions since the previous
meeting. It’s only been six weeks. Some of the relevant data are unavailable or potentially
inaccurate because of the shutdown, and it’s likely that the shutdown and fiscal cliff dramas
themselves have affected economic activity and confidence.
I actually didn’t feel as though there was much useful that I could add in terms of
economic analysis at this meeting. In fact, it was kind of summed up for me last week when I
was in a supervisory meeting at which senior managers of a large financial firm observed that
there was a noticeable uptick in inquiries from clients on both IPO and M&A activity. And then
as soon as that was noted, the senior managers themselves began to disagree as to whether this
interest would actually ripen into a lot of deals and whether, even if it did, those potential deals
were a one-time surge that had built up over some longer period or the beginning of a steadier
flow of transactions. At that point I just became the observer as these people within the same
firm argued back and forth, and after about 10 or 12 minutes, they all agreed that they’d have to
wait a few months to make a more informed judgment because everything recently was sort of
distorted.
So I thought about using this time to address areas—labor market or housing or business
investment topics—that are less dependent on current information, but because I’m going to have
a good bit more to say during the second go-round, I’ll stop here on the theory that it does one’s
colleagues a service not to say much if there’s not much useful to say.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Stein.

October 29–30, 2013

59 of 239

MR. STEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The current picture and recent news seem to be,
as many people have said, somewhere between mixed and tepid. I won’t try to review the
particulars, because they’ve been well explored by others.
Looking forward, my baseline outlook is broadly similar to the Tealbook in that I’m still
holding to my belief in unicorns and faster economic growth in 2014. But for the purposes of
thinking about policy, I thought about it very much as Governor Yellen did, which is that the
interesting and challenging scenario for us to spend time thinking about is the one where the next
six to nine months evolve kind of like the previous period, where there’s this muddle, and we
have this difficult identification problem—is it structural, is it demand? It’s really hard to tell
when things are just not going all that well. And given that: What are we going to do in
December? What are we going to do in March? What are we going to do in June? I think the
answer is pretty clear for December at this point—that we will be sitting tight. I think as we get
toward March, this muddle scenario becomes a really interesting and open set of questions, and
as President Lockhart said, I think this is where we’re going to have to really be very deft.
I want to mention very briefly one specific issue with regard to the issue of deftness.
Whenever we get to the point to start talking about tapering again, what might this do to
markets? How much of a further leg up in rates might it cause? What might that, in turn, mean
for our ability to pull the trigger? In other words, the now famous market dynamics that were
unleashed in May and June—are we going to revisit those? On the one hand, if you think about
it in terms of the level of rates or term premiums, I think you draw a fair amount of comfort. In
other words, rates are still—even though they’ve backed down a bit—substantially higher than
they were in May. So if you think that that’s the measure of froth, I think you could feel quite a
bit more comfortable about where we are. On the other hand, I’ve been wondering if there’s any

October 29–30, 2013

60 of 239

independent information in the fact that interest rate volatility as implied in swaptions has
actually come down quite significantly since the September meeting. What might that do to the
willingness of various market players to take on leverage, to reengage in carry trades, and all of
that?
This is obviously hard to do systematically. On the notion that the plural of anecdote is
data, I looked at eight of the research reports put out by the broker–dealers in the last month on
rates. It’s interesting. It’s just a collection of stories, but the uniform theme that comes across
very, very strongly in these eight reports is that the levered-yield-curve carry trade seems to be
back, at least as an item of discussion. To be clear, these eight reports were divided on what they
were telling their clients to do. Five of them said, “You should max out on the carry trade, five
to seven years; take leverage, do that.” The other three said, “Don’t do that. Everybody else is
doing that, and if you do that, you’re going to get hurt.” So there’s no implied investment advice
in any of this, but it was clear that this was a topic of conversation. Again, you take this all with
a fairly large grain of salt, and even if I was sure it was right, I don’t mean to suggest that there’s
a clear-cut normative implication for what we should do. I think it’s just a way of underscoring
what Dennis said earlier. It’s going to be an environment where we’re going to have to be pretty
deft because I think as we go along longer, especially if we go out to March, there’s just going to
be more of this kind of uncertainty built up in the markets—uncertainty from our perspective as
to how markets will respond to anything we do. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Nobody does that trade anymore. It’s too crowded.
[Laughter] Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My conversations with bankers and other
business executives and financial market participants suggest continued gradual improvement in

October 29–30, 2013

61 of 239

conditions. Not one of my correspondents offered a narrative of significant improvement, nor
did anyone see significant weakening in conditions. On the other hand, many offered negative
comments about the course of events in Washington, and there was a division between those who
saw the shutdown and the debt ceiling standoff as having hurt their results and those who did not.
It is not at all implausible to me that there will be another confrontation over the debt ceiling
early in the new year. For those who engineered the last confrontation, maybe not much has
changed. I would agree with Bill that the likelihood of such a confrontation has fallen, but I
actually think it is higher than people think it is.
Turning to the data, at the time of the September meeting there was some evidence of
weakening in the economy. And since then, in my view, at the margin there are additional signs
of weakness as, perhaps, more accommodative financial conditions have not quite offset the drag
from the confrontation.
I believe that there has been significant progress in the labor markets since September
2012, and for me payroll gains in the range of 150,000 to 175,000 would be sufficient for a taper
in the right circumstances. Nonetheless, if you look at the private payroll numbers, private
payrolls were about 212,000 per month in the first quarter, 190,000 in the second quarter, and
129,000 in the third quarter. And there is no denying that that is troubling. My own version of
the unicorn that Governor Stein referred to is wondering whether there isn’t a remaining element
of the seasonal adjustment algorithm problem that we talked about in the past couple of years,
which would suggest that payrolls should strengthen as we go into the cold months. I want to
believe that; I guess we’ll see.
The narrative around higher economic growth in 2014, on the other hand, depends, as it
must, on a significant increase in consumer spending. And like others, I thought that the memo

October 29–30, 2013

62 of 239

on the staff forecast for PCE by Andrew Figura and Geng Li was very well done and useful in
thinking about this issue. My own takeaway is that there are plenty of good reasons—and they
are set forth pretty clearly in the back end of the memo—why consumption may remain on a
lower trajectory than that included in the forecast. I would include uncertainty about the effects
of increasing house prices, lingering concerns about future income, uncertainty about
government fiscal and regulatory policy, and rising inequality. I thought that the consumer
restraint alt-sim captured that scenario pretty well. And I would echo Governor Yellen’s and
others’ concerns that that is really the troubling situation, and I have to say it’s not at all unlikely.
My bottom line is that I am not inclined to change my September SEP forecast of
2 percent growth for 2013, modestly increasing to about 2½ percent in 2014. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Thank you all for a very efficient
go-round.
Coffee is ready. Why don’t we take a break and come back at 3:30? Thank you.
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Why don’t we recommence? Let me try to give a
brief summary of the go-round on the economy. The outlook doesn’t appear to be much
changed, with continued moderate economic growth in the second half of this year. Some saw
improved growth in 2014, reflecting less fiscal restraint and more consumer spending. However,
this upswing is at best a forecast at this stage, and some, of course, were more pessimistic.
Important questions are whether productivity will pick up and whether there has been structural
damage to the economy. Inflation, on the other hand, remains subdued and below target.

October 29–30, 2013

63 of 239

In the household sector, labor markets are improving slowly, with unemployment
declining. Participation rates are also declining, in part because of retirement and other
demographic factors. Retirees are unlikely to return to the labor force. Employment gains have
also been held down by a less dynamic labor market with less churn. Those are structural
interpretations. On the other hand, payroll gains have been slowing recently; wage growth has
also been slow, suggesting that slack is playing some role. Housing activities continue to pick
up, although affordability is weakening as prices and mortgage rates have risen. Household
finances seem better, with balance sheets improved, wealth and income up, and gas prices down.
However, consumer sentiment remains unusually low, perhaps because of the fiscal risks.
Whether consumption will pick up is a key question for the outlook. A number of people
discussed that point.
In the business sector, we have reported for a number of meetings that businesses do see
continued slow economic growth but remain generally cautious. Fiscal and regulatory issues are
weighing on their confidence. Hires and cap-ex are, therefore, being delayed accordingly. Some
firms reported difficulty in finding skilled workers. Retail firms reported mixed results, and
some retailers expect to hire fewer seasonal employees this Christmas. Manufacturing indexes
suggest some degree of optimism in that sector. Auto demand is strong. Energy and agriculture
are doing well. And commercial real estate activity improved in some Districts.
There was more than the usual discussion of fiscal policy today. The direct effects of the
shutdown appear to have been limited and localized, except perhaps for the effects on data
availability. Further fiscal disruptions do pose a downside risk, including to confidence. Fiscal
policy more broadly should become less restrictive, although government spending is difficult to
forecast.

October 29–30, 2013

64 of 239

Looking around the world, Europe is exiting recession and global economic growth is
improving, all of which should help U.S. growth. And there are also fewer worries about a
slowdown in China.
In the banking sector, slow loan growth may reflect weak credit demand rather than tight
supply. Most firms can find credit, and financial conditions have eased recently. Business
balance sheets are strong. Compressed net interest margins are pressuring banks into a search for
yield, and interest rate volatility is down, which is also indirectly a potential risk to financial
stability.
Finally, on inflation, the shutdown of the BLS will add noise to the price data, although
private-sector measures like the Billion Prices Project are available as substitutes. Inflation
continues to run below the Committee’s target. Businesses have little pricing power. Wage
gains remain slow. Inflation expectations are stable. Nevertheless, some businesses fear
inflation in the long term, depending on the management of the Fed’s balance sheet.
Any comments, reactions, questions? [No response]
Let me make just a few remarks about the outlook. Because a number of things have
been already discussed, I’ll try not to be repetitive. First, I want to say a word about financial
conditions. There wasn’t too much discussion of the fact that financial conditions have eased
pretty significantly since our previous meeting. In introducing that point I would make the
distinction between clarity and credibility. We may not have been terribly clear in
communicating our action at the previous meeting, but I think actually our credibility was
enhanced, not reduced, because we did what we said we would do, which was tie our policy
decisions to the data. And the evidence for that is that the rate expectations embedded in the
financial data, which were inconsistent with our forward guidance before the meeting, are now

October 29–30, 2013

65 of 239

pretty much in line with our forward guidance. And that, together with a partial retracing of the
increase in the term premium that occurred over the summer, led to fairly significant—but not
complete, obviously—retracing of the general tightening in financial conditions that we saw over
the past five months or so.
Those improvements in financial conditions since September are, I think, economically
meaningful. Just one metric is that the staff’s assessment of the effect of changes in financial
conditions since September on the level of GDP at the end of 2015 is 45 basis points—almost
½ percentage point, which is fairly meaningful. So our action did ease financial conditions in a
meaningful way and in doing so better aligned market expectations with our forward guidance,
all of which is positive. At the same time, as we will discuss in the next go-round, we will face
challenges in keeping expectations aligned with our guidance and in managing expectations for
policy from here.
I’ll skip a couple of things and just talk a little bit about the longer-term effects of fiscal
policy on this recovery. In the context of this, I asked the staff to give me more details about
their projection that the federal funds rate would remain very low out to 2016 and beyond. As
you know, similar to what many of us submitted in the Summary of Economic Projections, the
Tealbook has the federal funds rate at 2 percent at the end of 2016, compared with 4 percent,
which is more or less the neutral level, in 2020. And there is a box in the Tealbook about that,
but I asked for a little bit more quantitative analysis of what was going on there, and I got some
helpful simulations from John Roberts of our staff.
What he did was essentially ask the question: How can you change the 2016 projection
in order to get the funds rate that is implied closer to a more neutral level? So he did three
things. The first was that the equity premium remains above normal in the projection as of 2016.

October 29–30, 2013

66 of 239

In 2016, it’s about 40 basis points above the 2020 value, which is a more normal long-term
historical value. And he set that equal to the 2020 value. That appears to account for about
¼ percentage point on the funds rate, about 25 basis points of the low funds rate. In other words,
the remaining risk aversion is one factor. The second thing he did was that he took away the
negative add-factors affecting business fixed investment, which you can think of as being
business confidence, uncertainty, credit availability—any issue that would affect business
investment conditional on interest rates and output. He set those add-factors equal to the 2020
levels, and that gives you another ¼ point. Putting those two things together suggests that the
persistent effects of the financial crisis and the recession on confidence, uncertainty, credit
availability—all of those factors—seems to account for about ½ percentage point of the 2
percentage points by which the funds rate in 2016 is below the longer-run normal level.
Now, the bigger factor—and this is the punch line I’m coming to here in a moment—is
fiscal policy. If you set the structural fiscal deficit in 2016 equal to the 2020 value—it’s just a
way of trying to look at a more long-run value for the fiscal deficit—that by itself adds a
percentage point to the equilibrium funds rate in 2016. Now, this is a complicated calculation
because, on the one hand, the fiscal deficit in 2020 is not on a sustainable path. That’s one
concern. On the other hand, this is relative to a zero benchmark, and it’s not taking into account
the normal response of fiscal policy to a recession and a recovery. If you look at that—I’ve
discussed this point before; it’s an obvious point, but it’s really worth mentioning, given the
comments that were just made around the table—it’s true that real GDP has grown at a little over
2 percent rate in this recovery, as has been noted by several people. Real GDP, less government
consumption and investment, has grown at a 3.2 percent rate during this recovery. So fiscal
restraint has been an important and ongoing factor that has held back the economy. My

October 29–30, 2013

67 of 239

calculation there implicitly assumes a multiplier of 1. Another way of looking at this—again, a
point that I’ve made elsewhere—is that, from the trough of the recession until now, total
government employment, including state and local, is down 600,000. At the same stage of the
recovery in the 2001 recession, it was up 400,000. So that’s a difference of about 1 million in
the cyclically adjusted, if you will, fiscal response.
What I conclude from this is that one important factor that we should not forget about is
that fiscal policy, for potentially good reasons—obviously, we started with a much higher debtto-GDP ratio this time than we have in previous recessions—has been more restrictive than
normal, and we should take that into account as we think about policy. In particular, as we think
about the 2 percent economic growth for 2013, if you take the CBO’s estimate of the fiscal drag
in 2013, something like 1½ percentage points, we overcame, in some sense, quite a bit of fiscal
drag. So I don’t think you can fairly conclude from the 2013 economic performance that
monetary policy has not had any beneficial effect on economic growth.
Those are just a couple of points I wanted to make. I had a discussion on the rationale for
the pickup in 2014 and the importance of consumption growth. That’s been touched on by a
number of people. And I think it’s fair to say that, while reduced restraint on the fiscal side
should provide some benefit—and we’ll get even more benefit if the current negotiations,
through some miracle, end up loosening the effects of the sequestration a bit in exchange, for
example, for some longer-term cuts—a good bit of the projected increase in economic growth in
2014 still does depend on consumers behaving more as they have in the past, given their wealth,
income, and other factors. We’ve been watching labor markets very carefully, which is
appropriate, but we should also be paying close attention to consumer behavior and trying to
assess whether, in fact, they will become the source of more-rapid economic growth going

October 29–30, 2013

68 of 239

forward. Any questions or comments? [No response] Again, thank you for your input in that
last go-round.
While I have the floor, let me say a couple more words to introduce the next go-round,
which we’ll start in a moment with a staff presentation. I thought this would be a good meeting
to have a general discussion of our policy tactics and strategy. As I mentioned, we have press
conferences for the next three meetings, and those meetings are a little bit more constrained in
terms of time. So in this meeting, we’ll have, I hope, the opportunity to get the participants’
views on some of these issues.
As Governor Yellen was saying, we have several scenarios going forward. Ideally, we’ll
see some strengthening of the economy, or at least some continued improvement in the labor
market, which will allow us to begin the process of winding down our asset purchases. I think
there is a reasonable chance that it will happen, but, obviously, it’s not certain. The other
possibility is that the data will remain weak, in which case we’ll need to communicate—as
President Kocherlakota has already indicated—other criteria, including costs and efficacy
criteria, for modifying our policy. In either case, an important issue in the transition is going to
be addressing the signaling effect of reduced purchases. This is something that we tried to
address. We weren’t unaware of this in June. But, nevertheless, the reduction in purchases had
the effect of bringing in market expectations of when short-term rates would rise. And if we
want to mitigate the effect of slowing purchases on overall financial conditions, we’ll need to
address that signaling issue.
There are a number of ways to do that, and these are some of the things we can talk about
in this go-round. Obviously, we’ve already talked quite a bit on several occasions about
strengthening the forward guidance. A new suggestion is to use balance sheet tools, market

October 29–30, 2013

69 of 239

interventions of some type, to strengthen the guidance. One set of tactics involves trying to
mitigate the effects of slower asset purchases via the signaling channel on expectations about
policy tightening. Another strategy for exit is to improve our communication about the asset
purchase program itself. There are a number of possibilities, and there’s an open question
among the ones that were circulated to you for ideas about how we could better explain the
criteria for reducing asset purchases. One specific possibility is that we do something more
mechanical, and the staff presentations discuss that possibility. Finally, there is the issue that
we’ve talked about a few times, which is the composition of a reduction in asset purchases—
what combination of Treasuries and mortgage-backed securities we would want to use in our
reduction of purchases.
So there are a number of issues here. Let me say one last thing before I turn it over to the
staff. Some of these issues—like strengthening the forward guidance, the IOER, and the mix of
Treasuries and MBS—are things that we’ve talked about a number of times already in this
Committee. I hope today that we’ll get some clarity from participants on where you are on these
issues that can help us think about future tactics and future staff work. There are a couple of
things on this list that are relatively new, like the market interventions and the mechanical
adjustments of the balance sheet. Here I assume that most people would agree that the value of
such tools will depend on the context and how things evolve. So for those things, I’d be
interested just to hear some impressionistic views. We don’t have to make any decisions on
anything today—certainly not on those ideas that are being introduced, essentially, for the first
time. Again, the purpose of this go-round is to do what we call “blue-sky” thinking around here
and get some input from participants on some different approaches to our communication and

October 29–30, 2013

70 of 239

our tactics going forward. So with that fairly lengthy prologue, let me turn it over to the staff to
present some of their background work.
MR. TETLOW. 3 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be referring to the handout titled
“Material for Policy Planning.” Turning first to forward guidance, as noted in the box
at the top of the first exhibit, the Committee may wish to consider adding an inflation
floor to its forward guidance for the federal funds rate to signal its commitment to
price stability when inflation is unusually low. Importantly, because an inflation floor
would be an addition to existing forward guidance, which already includes an
inflation threshold, an inflation floor would not amend prior commitments and could
clarify that the Committee is committed to defending its inflation objective both from
above and from below.
The model-based analysis in the memo suggests that an inflation floor of
1½ percent would produce economic benefits more often than not, but those benefits
are likely to be small. In the stochastic simulations, the floor is binding in only about
one-fourth of the draws, and in only about one-half of the cases where it is binding
does it shift out the liftoff date for the federal funds rate by more than one quarter.
That said, those simulations in which the inflation floor is particularly helpful—ones
in which inflation is low, of course, but also when the unemployment rate stalls near
its threshold value—are simulations in which losses without the floor are high.
Accordingly, an inflation floor might be best thought of as a hedge against certain bad
states of the economy.
With regard to communications, adding an inflation floor would help clarify the
symmetry of the FOMC’s inflation objective, but it might also present
communications challenges. To the extent that forward guidance is already complex,
the addition of an inflation floor could further tax the public’s understanding.
Moreover, the rollout of an inflation floor could be taken as signaling that the
Committee is more worried about inflation remaining persistently low.
The lower panel discusses the provision of more information about the post-liftoff
behavior of the federal funds rate. As you know, monetary conditions today depend
on the entire path of the future funds rate, not just the date of liftoff. Hence, a policy
that defers liftoff of the funds rate for longer than otherwise can nevertheless result in
a tightening of the stance of monetary policy if the subsequent increase in rates is
steeper. In the staff memo, we examined the implications of committing to a policy
for the federal funds rate, for the period after liftoff up to the point when the
unemployment rate falls to 5½ percent, that is more inertial than the inertial Taylor
rule that we normally use. We found that this more gradual post-liftoff rule would
not likely affect the liftoff date but would result in a more gradual climb in the federal
funds rate for some time after liftoff. This results in small improvements, on average,
in economic performance.

3

The materials used by Messrs. Tetlow and Clouse are appended to this transcript (appendix 4).

October 29–30, 2013

71 of 239

Implementation and public communication of such a change in post-liftoff
policy would present challenges for the Committee, not the least because that event is
likely to be well off in the future. The meaning of a state-contingent gradual increase
in the federal funds rate may be difficult for the public to understand. At the same
time, this addition to forward guidance, if timed appropriately, could be used to draw
a distinction between federal funds rate and asset purchase policies.
The second page of the handout covers the material on simple policy rules to
guide decisions on reducing the pace of asset purchases. The memo you received on
this subject introduced three rules for purchases: one based on the unemployment rate
and two others based on changes in payroll employment. As you know, different
measures of labor market conditions can send different signals, which can present
pitfalls for simple rules that are written in terms of one variable, to the exclusion of
others. Revisions to the data aside, the choice among these rules matters when the
unemployment rate and payroll gains co-move unusually. If recent declines in the
labor force participation rate (LFPR) continue, while payroll gains stay near current
levels, the unemployment-based rule would call for faster reductions in LSAPs than
would the payroll-based rules. But if recent declines in the LFPR are largely cyclical
and are reversed, the unemployment-based rule might call for slower reductions, even
if payroll gains are strong.
Communicating an LSAP policy rule would present some challenges for the
Committee, some of which are summarized in the bullets at the bottom of the exhibit.
The most obvious concern would be handling conflicts in the signals coming from
different labor market indicators. A second issue is the coordination of an LSAP rule
with existing thresholds for the funds rate, at least for employment-based rules.
Under some conditions, those LSAP rules could prescribe purchases to continue after
the 6½ percent unemployment rate threshold governing funds rate guidance has been
crossed. Based on our stochastic simulations, we computed the likelihood of this
occurring to be roughly 7 percent. A third issue pertains to communication of
whether the new rule only allows the pace of purchases to ratchet down. In the
memo, we suggested that these and other obstacles might argue for a measure of
vagueness in the initial communication of a rule, vagueness that could be shaped and
clarified in longer-form discussions—potentially including press conferences,
speeches, and testimony—and through repetition. Thank you.
MR. CLOUSE. Thanks very much. I’ll be referring to the bullets on the third
page of your packet that summarize two background memos prepared for this
meeting: one focusing on possible actions that the FOMC could take to strengthen its
forward guidance for the federal funds rate and another focusing on issues the
Committee may wish to consider in developing plans for reducing the pace of asset
purchases.
As noted in the bullets at the left, under the first potential approach to
strengthening its forward guidance, the Committee would announce that it is prepared
to conduct long-term repurchase agreement operations against all OMO-eligible
collateral at a pre-announced fixed rate. By committing to conduct term repos to a

October 29–30, 2013

72 of 239

fixed end date and over a defined period—for example, until the end of 2014—the
Committee would likely put a cap on term repo rates and provide dealers with
certainty about their financing costs for a considerable period. Arbitrage by dealers
should then tend to drive down yields on any shorter-term Treasury securities whose
yields initially exceed the Federal Reserve’s term repo rate. However, market
participants have noted that balance sheet constraints of various types may limit this
arbitrage process to some degree.
In a second alternative, the Federal Reserve would simply announce that it stands
ready to purchase shorter-term Treasury securities, perhaps those with maturities
prior to the end of 2014, at a price corresponding to a pre-established yield of, say,
20 basis points. By purchasing all eligible securities offered at this pre-announced
rate, the Federal Reserve would establish a cap on short-term Treasury yields. In a
variation of this approach, the FOMC would not attempt to establish a formal cap on
yields but rather would conduct operations as necessary to try to prevent the path of
short-term rates from departing significantly from the Committee’s policy intentions.
As discussed in the memo, choosing the end dates for such date-based programs
in a way that is consistent with the FOMC’s threshold-based forward guidance for the
federal funds rate presents some challenges. For example, while the current staff
forecast suggests that the thresholds in the FOMC’s forward guidance will not be
crossed until mid-2015, one of the thresholds could be crossed considerably earlier if
the economy were to strengthen substantially. In such a scenario, the Federal Reserve
might need to end these programs earlier than originally announced, and market
uncertainty about whether programs such as these would remain in place could
undermine their effectiveness.
Alternatively, the FOMC could announce that it stands ready to conduct overnight
repo operations at a predetermined rate as long as the economic thresholds have not
been crossed. For example, the Desk could commit to conducting overnight repos
with the primary dealers at a fixed rate of 20 basis points until one of the thresholds is
crossed. This type of program should put a cap of 20 basis points on overnight repo
rates. Alternatively, the Federal Reserve could sell options that provide the holder
with the right to participate in overnight repos with the Federal Reserve at a preestablished rate until one of the thresholds is crossed. Threshold-based programs
such as these would address the difficulty with the fixed end dates discussed in the
first two alternatives but would require being very clear, ex ante, about what would
constitute “crossing a threshold.”
Under a fourth program, analogous to the foreign exchange operations of some
central banks, the Federal Reserve could conduct operations in the forward market for
Treasury securities. For example, the Federal Reserve could contract today to
purchase six-month Treasury bills one year from now at a price agreed upon today.
Such operations would allow the Federal Reserve to address pressures at particular
points on the yield curve without expanding its balance sheet in the near term. This
type of operation could be conducted in various ways and, similar to alternative 2,
might allow the FOMC to follow a fairly flexible approach in addressing unwarranted

October 29–30, 2013

73 of 239

upward pressures on short-term yields. A program like this would require careful
consideration of technical issues, such as a process for establishing appropriate
margins for such forward positions.
As a final alternative, the first memo also discussed the possibility of lowering the
interest rate on excess reserves (IOER) and, at the same time, implementing a
standing overnight reverse repurchase facility with no size limits. For example, the
IOER could be lowered to 15 basis points, and the rate on the overnight reverse
repurchase facility could be set at perhaps 5 basis points. Cutting the IOER would
put downward pressure on the federal funds rate and many other money market rates,
while the overnight reverse repurchase rate would establish a firmer floor on money
market rates. This action would amount to a modest easing in the stance of monetary
policy and could have important signaling effects on expected future levels of shortterm rates. As noted in previous staff memos, a full-scale overnight reverse
repurchase program could help address strains in financing markets that would
otherwise push repo rates below zero, but it could also have implications for activity
in the federal funds market and for dealer financing.
As a final note, various policy, legal, and operational issues would need to be
addressed before implementing any of these programs. The staff could do more
analysis of such issues for any of the alternatives that are of interest to policymakers.
The second staff memo reviewed a number of factors that the FOMC may wish to
consider in developing plans for reducing the pace of asset purchases. The memo
discussed the benefits and costs of alternative time paths for reductions in the pace of
total asset purchases, and the benefits and costs of trimming the monthly purchases of
either Treasury securities or MBS more quickly than the other, along any given path
for total asset purchases.
In staff models, the effect of LSAPs on market yields stems from investors’
expectations for the current and future stock of longer-term Treasury securities and
MBS available to the public. And in this framework, small variations in alternative
paths for reductions in the pace of total asset purchases or in the composition of asset
purchases should have only modest effects on yields. Nonetheless, as noted in the
bullets at the right, the FOMC might prefer to announce a modest initial reduction in
the pace of asset purchases, rather than a large initial reduction, as a way to signal that
further reductions in the pace of asset purchases are likely to be gradual.
Policymakers might also favor this approach if they judged that it could mitigate the
potential for an outsized market reaction to the first reduction in the pace of
purchases.
On issues related to the composition of reductions in asset purchases, the memo
notes several considerations that could argue for initially trimming monthly purchases
of one asset class by more than the other, along any given path for total asset
purchases. For example, a decision to pare the pace of Treasury purchases relatively
rapidly while maintaining a somewhat higher path for MBS securities might be
viewed as a way to signal the Committee’s continued strong interest in fostering

October 29–30, 2013

74 of 239

recovery in the housing market. It might also be appropriate if the FOMC views
purchases of MBS to be a somewhat more powerful tool than purchases of Treasury
securities. Alternatively, the FOMC might prefer to reduce its pace of MBS
purchases relatively more rapidly than Treasuries if it believed that elevated
purchases in the MBS market could have important adverse consequences for market
functioning or if MBS purchases were viewed as more likely to result in credit
misallocations. Of course, the Committee might prefer to cut purchases of Treasuries
and agency MBS in roughly equal increments; that approach seems to be about what
markets expect and, as noted in the memo, would allow for the gradual reduction in
the pace of purchases for both types of securities.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Let me thank the presenters, Bob
Tetlow and Jim Clouse, and the very many staff members who were involved in developing
these background memos. A great deal of work went into that, and we’re very grateful for that
work. Are there any questions for the staff? [No response] I see no questions. Then we can
begin a go-round, and I’ll start with President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Red Sox have had a striking
turnaround from last year. The most visible signal of their commitment to start that turnaround
was to choose to increase beard production. The one option left out of the memos was for more
of us to follow the Chairman’s lead, but let me turn to the options the staff has actually
suggested.
This spring I was surprised by the market’s reaction to the discussion of the possibility
that we would reduce purchases if our forecast of a stronger, more sustainable recovery occurred.
The increase in long-term rates of over 100 basis points was more than was predicted or needed,
given the still-weak economic recovery. Even more surprising was the increase in shorter-term
rates. In effect, our desire to get a small rotation of the yield curve resulted in more of a large
steepening in the yield curve, including at the shorter end, which only complicated our economic
and communication challenges.

October 29–30, 2013

75 of 239

Where did our communications go wrong? One area of confusion is something I don’t
think the FOMC itself has settled yet, and that is whether decisions about policy changes were
being driven primarily by costs and efficacy or whether they were being driven primarily by data
consistent with a more optimistic forecast. In my own view, it is the latter that should be driving
our decisions and our communications. However, I realize that not everyone on the Committee
will agree with me. I worry that our lack of consensus has made it difficult to provide the public
with a clear view of the Committee’s assessment of the costs of the balance sheet size.
While markets have certainly reacted strongly to our communication, the recent
fluctuations in rates certainly suggest that markets view purchases as quite efficacious in moving
interest rates and asset prices. The problem is not whether we affect rates, but that the effects are
still not well described by our models. Why did we affect rates so much, both in July and, more
recently, at the September meeting? One potential explanation is that communication is a
potentially powerful tool but is much more difficult to manipulate than the instruments we are
used to, in part because we can communicate along so many dimensions, but also because we
have to have some reasoned assessment of how the markets will react to our language along
these different dimensions. So I agree that we have a significant communications challenge, but
I see no reason to make that challenge more difficult. I think part of the challenge could be met
if all of us more explicitly agreed to decision-consistent communications about the conditions
that undergird our policy actions. In my view, this would be a statement that policy is being
driven primarily by incoming data and not some vague notion of costs and efficacy.
Implicitly, the last two press conferences have, in effect, laid out a three-part test for
tapering. First, we need to observe a sustainable improvement in real GDP. Our communication
should make clear that to achieve full employment in an appropriate time frame implies growth

October 29–30, 2013

76 of 239

well above the 2.2 percent we’ve been averaging during the recovery. Second, we need
continuing gains in labor markets, and speeches or communication could be that, to achieve full
employment within an appropriate horizon, we need payroll employment growing closer to
200,000 jobs per month. Third, we need stronger evidence that inflation is trending back to 2
percent. In speeches, we could make clear that inflation well below our target is not acceptable,
and that we need to see data consistent with our target, which is tied to the PCE inflation
measure and is currently at only 1.2 percent. I would note that explaining why we want inflation
to go up presents a communications challenge for many audiences, but it’s one we should work
on together.
Even if one does not personally agree with this three-part test, if it is agreed to by the
Committee, there should be an obligation to clearly communicate the sense of the Committee for
the actions it has taken. The first-best solution is that, first, we agree to the action to be taken;
then we agree on how best to communicate our action; and, finally, we each consistently
communicate that action. Communicating dissent should not lead to the market misinterpreting
the communication of the Committee as a whole. A clear communication strategy is far better
than introducing another set of complicated actions.
To be fair, it’s important to acknowledge that another aspect of our communication
challenge is that, even with agreement on how we discuss potential Committee actions, the
multiple policy tools with different thresholds for action that we are currently employing are just
inherently more complicated to clearly communicate to the public than more traditional
monetary policy. Policies based on the federal funds rate were difficult enough to convey, but
the nuances of balance sheet tools and the variety of forward-guidance tools are going to be very
difficult to convey to a general audience. However, adding a whole new set of tools to reinforce

October 29–30, 2013

77 of 239

our current tools is likely to make our communications even more difficult, not easier. If
communication is the problem, finding simpler ways to convey our message implies not using
instruments and actions that, by their very nature, are likely to only complicate our message.
Thus, before introducing more complicated actions, I would prefer to have a more concerted
effort at clear and consistent messaging. If clear and consistent messaging does not work, either
because of our own governance issues or because the message is just too difficult to convey to
the broader public, we should look for simple reinforcing measures as the next most promising
area.
My preference would be to use interest on reserves as that signaling device. Given that
the current interest rate paid on reserves is much more than the rate on short-term Treasuries, the
rate is hard to justify on economic grounds. Moreover, a reduction in the IOER to a more
justifiable level may be a useful signaling mechanism to reinforce the distinction between the
decision about QE tapering and the federal funds liftoff—that is, policy decisions focused on the
long end of the yield curve may not signal a tightly linked policy change at the short end. One
way to implement this is a discrete reduction in IOER when tapering is justified. However, my
preference would be to move in 5 basis point increments and reduce IOER when we begin to
taper or at any time that short rates diverge significantly from what is consistent with our
guidance on short-term rates. If this is viewed as primarily a signaling tool, moving at 5 basis
point increments would give us five opportunities to publicly reinforce our message before the
IOER rate hit zero.
If communications and this signaling are not sufficiently effective, I would not rule out
using the other tools described in the memo. However, because these policy interventions are
not simple, they will likely be difficult to communicate. Explaining why we are purchasing

October 29–30, 2013

78 of 239

fewer longer-term assets by possibly buying substantial amounts of short-term assets in order to
achieve our monetary policy goals is fraught with potential problems. While I would not rule out
anything at this time, it’s imperative that we address our communication problems by more
clearly describing the considerations on which our policies are based. Good communication
requires not only that one speaks in a way that can clearly be understood, but also that one
speaks in a way that will not be misunderstood. This requires speaking in simpler terms and, as
much as possible, with one voice. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And I add my thanks to the staff for an
excellent set of memos.
Before addressing the questions, I’d like to summarize how I perceive the policymaking
context in the near term. As I noted in my first go-round remarks, I’m increasingly of the mind
that our decision tree has to incorporate the possibility that next year will play out much like the
past three. The employment situation continues to improve on some dimensions, but with
persistent underperformance on others, such as the number of long-term unemployed, elevated
levels of part-time employment, and weak hiring rates. Real GDP growth is failing to
convincingly accelerate away from the 2 percent track. Inflation remains stuck substantially
below our objective. Contrast this picture with the three conditions—the three-part test
mentioned by President Rosengren—for tapering that was proposed by the Chairman on behalf
of the Committee at his June and September press conferences. They were confidence in the
labor market improvement, an acceleration of GDP growth, and inflation moving back toward
2 percent.

October 29–30, 2013

79 of 239

Speaking for myself, it’s hard to have strong conviction about the acceleration in growth
that is written in the Tealbook forecast and was projected in the September SEP. Based on data,
economic conditions do not call for a withdrawal of stimulus, and the near-term outlook is
clouded by consequences of the fiscal struggle in the Congress. If such a view is widely adopted
at the time of the December SEP, the Committee will be presenting a downwardly revised
outlook in that communication. I question whether we can, over any relevant horizon, anticipate
that tapering or ending our asset purchase program will be justified on the basis of acceptable
economic conditions. Given my skepticism about a taper-justifying forecast materializing, I see
a policy dilemma shaping up. I think there’s a basic question to be grappled with before we
address the more tactical questions posed for this go-round. And I’ll frame that question this
way: Suppose 2014 is a carbon copy of 2013 and consistent with 2012 and 2011. What would
be our position on asset purchases?
I see two possible answers. One, we commit to remain all in on the open-ended nature of
our asset purchase policy. If that is the direction we’re willing to go, we should be clear among
ourselves that that is the case and communicate our intention clearly. Two, if we’re not
completely committed to a truly open-ended asset purchase program, then we need to begin
positioning our communications to include as decision criteria a wider set of considerations. I
think President Kocherlakota suggested this in the last round. To my mind, these include
progress achieved since September 2012 on unemployment, as the Chairman suggested earlier,
as well as appreciation of the tradeoff between incremental benefits of prolonged asset purchases
and the challenges and risks, however uncertain, associated with the process of normalizing the
balance sheet over coming years.

October 29–30, 2013

80 of 239

I think there is sentiment around the table that the asset purchases have to come to an end
at some point for prudential reasons, and the debate is about: when, how, and based on what
explicitly communicated rationale? Realistically, I see the March meeting as the earliest juncture
for consideration of a tapering decision, and I doubt that the situation then will bring the clarity
desired for a decision purely on the basis of economic conditions. If March is realistic, we have
time to reposition somewhat the tapering decision criteria using a variety of communications
methods.
So with those comments on context, as I see it, let me respond to some of the questions
posed in the memo. On the first question, about clarifying or strengthening rate guidance, I favor
strengthening the guidance we now have in place as a way of offsetting the wind-down of asset
purchases and preserving at least some of the market-perceived stimulus. As to when we do it, I
think language in the statement that strengthens rate guidance is appropriate before the decision
to taper—or simultaneously should we decide to begin tapering earlier than I expect. In the next
round, I will argue against inserting the qualitative guidance language at this meeting, largely
because there’s no press conference to explain the obvious question of the meaning of “patient.”
So I would favor the December meeting, all things being equal.
The qualitative guidance language in paragraph 6 of alternative B addresses the path of
the policy rate post-liftoff. I think it’s important to do this at least qualitatively. I am not closed
to the idea of communicating Committee expectations in quantitative terms—if not in the
statement, then in a press conference or speech. One idea mentioned, with different numbers, in
a staff memo is to add one or two more unemployment thresholds, saying something like, “The
Committee further expects that the federal funds rate target will remain below 1 percent until the
unemployment rate approaches or reaches 6 percent and below 2 percent until overall

October 29–30, 2013

81 of 239

employment conditions approach full employment.” This is a variation of the idea in one of the
staff memos. This sort of communication would have to be consistent with the SEP, of course,
and would have to be positioned as neither triggers nor firm thresholds. As regards an inflation
floor, I am also open, if not overly enthusiastic, to this addition to our forward rate guidance. I
prefer the forward-looking forecast of headline inflation because it allows consideration of a
wider array of information and seems to be less binding in the event of unexpected
circumstances.
Regarding the second question, on market interventions, I support, in principle, the idea
of announcing and executing market interventions in support of both the fed funds rate and the
overnight repo rate. My thinking is that such action would put an exclamation point behind
enhanced rate guidance and say, in effect, “We mean it.” Following through on interventions
would back up words with action.
The third question, on lowering the fed funds rate target range and IOER, asks if we
support further study. I support looking at these options a bit further. We may need a full
arsenal to avoid the perception and reality of tightening when we begin to reduce asset
purchases. Again, I think this idea says, “We mean it.” Earlier consideration of narrowing the
fed funds rate range points up risks to key markets and financial industry segments—the money
market fund industry, for example. Obviously, we’d have to satisfy ourselves that these actions
would not do more harm than good. So if questions 2 and 3 were intended to smoke out any
strong objections, I don’t have strong objections to doing further work on these possible tools.
On question 4, regarding LSAP guidance, here I expect that my views are different than
the views of many on the Committee. Again, I’m thinking we may make a decision to begin
tapering in much more ambiguous economic conditions than earlier envisioned, and the rationale

October 29–30, 2013

82 of 239

for that decision will, of necessity, include a wider set of decision criteria than we have
positioned so far. Under those circumstances, I think it would be best to carry through with a full
phaseout of asset purchases without much conditionality. An escape clause might incorporate
the condition of the very material reversal of current trends, a strongly negative deviation from
the outlook. Otherwise, I would favor winding up the program. So I prefer announcing a road
map to zero asset purchases at the time of the decision to begin tapering. Such a move would
reduce uncertainty in financial markets, put incremental attention on our rate guidance, and
accelerate the necessary transition to an LSAP-free environment. At the same time, I think
balance sheet guidance that emphasizes the stock effect as a component of accommodation might
help the cause of preserving accommodation. It might help to provide qualitative guidance
pointing out the reality that holdings will grow during tapering, flatten out until a decision is
made to begin balance sheet normalization, and then decline gradually thereafter.
On the fifth question, regarding the sequencing or mix of reductions, I don’t have a
strong opinion. I share the ambivalence that I read in the staff memo. I’m guided by the view in
the October 17 memo that the estimated financial effects of various options are small. On
balance, I would support having MBS reductions lag Treasuries as a way to preserve support for
the housing market.
I’ve taken a lot of time, and I’ll skip the last question. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, appreciate the staff memos and all
of the work that went into them. I found them very informative.
Let me begin with two preliminary points. The premise of this set of questions is that
“asset purchases and forward guidance concerning the policy rate are separate policy tools.”

October 29–30, 2013

83 of 239

While this is accepted dogma here on the Committee, it is hotly disputed in financial markets.
So, following some of the commentary in the memos, let me question for a moment the extent to
which these policy tools are truly separate. First, both tools are designed to provide policy
accommodation and are therefore directed toward the same end. Markets may perhaps be
forgiven if they infer from a policy action concerning one tool that the Committee has decided
that the economy requires less accommodation than previously believed, and that the Committee
may therefore be similarly inclined to change a stance with regard to the other tool at some point
in the future. Second, the Committee has stated that both tools represent state-contingent
monetary policy. Altering the setting for one policy instrument relative to previously held
expectations must mean that the outlook for the economy has changed in an important way, but
this means that the other policy instrument, which is also state contingent, might be altered in a
similar way. Again, I think markets might be forgiven for viewing the two policy tools as more
closely tied together than they are in the minds of us policymakers.
A second premise of this set of questions is that interest rate policy is the more powerful
of the two approaches to providing accommodation and, therefore, that forward guidance is the
preferred area of focus for the Committee in the coming quarters. I remind the Committee that
the Japanese monetary policy has been to keep the short-term nominal interest rate near zero for
more than 15 years. During the period from the mid-1990s up until the recent rise with Shinzo
Abe, the zero policy rates seemingly produced neither a consumption boom nor a rise in inflation
or inflation expectations. The staff models we use do not have this outcome embedded in them
as a possibility and therefore are silent about the probability of the U.S. economy falling into
such a state. I think we have to be careful in assuming that even greater commitments to low
short-term nominal interest rates, beyond the ones we already have, will produce desired

October 29–30, 2013

84 of 239

macroeconomic outcomes. I’m not against trying to improve the forward guidance, but we
should be cognizant that zero rates alone, no matter how far in the future they are promised, may
not provide the desired level of policy accommodation. Indeed, in contrast, one conclusion from
the June and September decisions of this Committee is that changes in the pace of asset
purchases have rather large and highly conventional easing and tightening effects in financial
markets—that is, the financial market signature of those actions is clear and unmistakable as
conventional monetary policy. If we’re looking for an effective policy tool, I believe we have,
indeed, found it. And on this dimension, I agree with President Rosengren on the efficacy of
policy.
I know that a lot of people on the Committee are concerned about the size of the balance
sheet, but, as I’ve reminded people before, the size of the balance sheet relative to GDP is not
that large compared with that for other central banks—the ECB, the Bank of England, or the
Bank of Japan. I think we still have room to maneuver on that dimension. We’re in the low 20s
on that. And I’d like to see more emphasis on that question about how far you are willing to go
relative to the size of GDP, instead of just citing big round numbers with respect to the size of
the balance sheet.
Let me turn briefly to the six questions that were posed. On modifying forward guidance,
if we do try to improve our forward guidance, I support including an inflation floor in the
statement. In my view, the floor should be 1.5 percent to maintain symmetry with the
2½ percent threshold that we have on the high side. My preference would be to base inflation
thresholds on actual year-over-year PCE inflation rates, not on forecasts. No central bank worth
its salt would project a substantial miss of an inflation target over the medium term, and so using
the forecast of inflation allows, in my view, too much flexibility to explain away low-inflation

October 29–30, 2013

85 of 239

outcomes as temporary aberrations. It makes the policy, then, less effective. I also think that the
inflation floor is likely to be far more effective than what is suggested in the staff memos. The
Committee has inadvertently sent a signal that we will raise policy rates when unemployment or
labor market conditions reach certain levels, independently of what’s going on with the inflation
rate. And we could take that “independently” clause off the table by making it clear that if
inflation is very low, then we’re not going to be in too much of a mood to raise rates.
On the other aspects of improving forward guidance—the notion of raising the policy rate
gradually at some point in the future when we do come off the zero lower bound—as I’ve argued
before, if that’s what you want to do, a superior policy is actually to just remain at the zero
bound longer instead of coming up off the bound more slowly. So for those who want to go in
that direction, I think you should say, “Well, I just want to push out the amount of time that we’ll
be at the zero lower bound.” I also think that this notion of raising the policy rate gradually is
not easy to communicate, and the staff memos did a great job of pointing this out. More
gradually than what? And what were you expecting before? To get the stimulative effect from
that is very difficult to do because it’s hard to know what the benchmark really would be and this
is something that’s occurring many years in the future.
Finally, on forward guidance, I prefer not to change the 6½ percent unemployment
threshold and, instead, to stick with the interpretation that this is a threshold and not a trigger.
Shifting the threshold would likely badly damage our credibility concerning thresholds generally.
Thresholds become, in effect, movable objects based on the convenience of the Committee.
Thresholds may then cease to be as useful as they have been for the Committee, and so I’d rather
not move that threshold. If there are ways to keep that threshold and provide more guidance,
beyond the 6½ percent, I might have an open mind about that.

October 29–30, 2013

86 of 239

Let me turn now to targeted market interventions. My overall comment on this class of
suggestions is that I see these not so much as balance sheet policies but instead as more elaborate
versions of interest rate targeting. I think that the best that can be said for these for now is that
they require a lot more study. I have several remarks. First, some approaches seem to represent
a return to calendar-based policy. We’ve spent a lot of time on the Committee trying to
eliminate calendar-based approaches to policy in favor of those that are based on macroeconomic
fundamentals. In my opinion, we should not return to stating policy in terms of particular dates.
Second, and maybe more important, intervention directly in markets where we are trying to read
market expectations has an important downside in that it can remove a source of information for
the Committee on the state of market expectations. We would be, in effect, masking the
information that the market is trying to provide to us, and this might leave us unprepared in
situations in which market expectations are particularly valuable signals. Third, to the extent that
our commitment via market instruments became untenable, perhaps because of new information
that had become available during the intervening time period, markets would come in and test
the Fed’s commitment, possibly leading to a large expansion of the Fed’s balance sheet. This
possibility is discussed under the “Credibility” section of the memo. I see this as a very difficult
situation for the Committee. Finally, just in general, I thought that some of the effects that were
being talked about here on shorter-term rates seem quite small and, in a macro sense, likely to be
inconsequential.
On question 3, lowering the interest rate on excess reserves, I’ll make a brief comment. I
do support, as I have in the past, lowering the interest rate on excess reserves actually all the way
to zero and possibly into negative territory. I’m not sure why we are paying banks to hold
reserves during a period when we would rather encourage lending and money creation. I do not

October 29–30, 2013

87 of 239

think that going to 10 or 15 basis points on the IOER would make any difference, and so I’d
recommend not working on this if that’s what we’re going to do. But if we wanted to push this
harder—go to zero or look into negative rates—I think that that might be beneficial for the
economy and might be a game-changer, in fact, and I’d support further study of that. So I
actually am agreeing with President Rosengren once again, despite the Red Sox. I’m agreeing
with him twice in one statement here.
On question 4, more-explicit rules for QE tapering, in my view, this has a lot of merit as a
way to pin down expectations about the QE program and how we’re going to proceed with the
QE program going forward. I think any rule should refer to inflation as well as to
unemployment, because you could also state that if inflation starts to move back toward target as
we expect, then that would give us more comfort with the tapering decision, and if
unemployment continues to come down as we expect, then that would give us more comfort with
the tapering decision. It’s not that hard to write down a simple equation that would put both in.
I think we know from experience around this table that getting agreement on a numerical
rule is unlikely. However, we might be able to make a lot of progress with an informal rule that
guides the Committee discussion and the staff analysis in thinking about where we want to be as
the economy goes forward. At which combinations of year-over-year PCE inflation and
unemployment might we be comfortable saying, “Okay, that’s where we’d like the program to be
finished”? My example for this is a Taylor rule. The Committee certainly never agreed on a
Taylor rule and was opposed, including by the former Chairman, Alan Greenspan. However, I
think it did a great service in guiding Committee discussion and in describing actual Committee
decisionmaking quite well. So a rule like this can exist somewhat outside of what actually goes
into the policy statement and still be valuable in terms of getting everybody into one place about

October 29–30, 2013

88 of 239

what we’re thinking about and where we think we might be going. I think that something similar
could be done with more-explicit rules for QE tapering.
On MBS versus Treasuries, let me say that, on balance, I think equally weighted
reductions in MBS and Treasuries are the way to go here. The other options sounded
complicated to me. I know that the paper by Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jørgensen that was
presented at Jackson Hole is good and interesting, but I’m not ready to make policy based on that
particular paper. So I think that that’s probably the best to way to go on this dimension.
And question 6: Are there any others? As you know, I have expressed a preference to
have a press conference after every meeting. I appreciate the Chairman’s decision to announce a
press conference at the January meeting. I think that that will keep more options on the table for
the Committee going forward. It keeps more decision points out there, and, I hope we can pick
up on one of them and make a key decision there. Thanks very much, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Obstruction or interference? Inside question.
[Laughter] President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I do think this is an opportune time to
discuss our policy plans, and I appreciate the staff memo. They did an excellent job of
summarizing the wide variety of options we have on the table.
We have a lot of irons in the fire, so to speak, and we seem to find ourselves wanting to
tweak and adjust policy on lots of different margins. That makes policy very complicated and
very hard to explain. So I think it’s a good time for us to engage in some planning about how we
would want to think about conducting policy going forward, how the different elements that we
have specified interact, and how we wish to communicate those elements. As I said, the staff has
circulated several memos regarding how we should proceed with reducing the pace of asset

October 29–30, 2013

89 of 239

purchases, how we should proceed with forward guidance on the policy rate once our thresholds
have been crossed, and how that forward guidance might be strengthened with open market
operations. And I appreciate the staff’s efforts.
Before I present my views regarding these proposed initiatives, I’d like to take a little
different perspective on our policy challenges and strategy. Our communication regarding the
stance of policy has been less than perfect, and it’s become increasingly complex. Our
September decision not to taper our purchases came as quite a surprise to financial markets.
Even if it was unintended, the markets clearly thought we were likely to taper, and then we
didn’t follow through. This contributed to volatility, policy uncertainty, and other things. Now,
I’m not sure how much credibility we lost from that episode—I would certainly guess some—but
if such surprises continue to happen, we will almost surely lose more of it as time goes on.
I see our difficulties stemming, in part, from two related but different issues. The first
has to do with the fact that, as a Committee, we’ve not come to any agreement regarding our
policy reaction function, whether for LSAPs or for the fed funds rate. What actions we will
follow after we cross the stated threshold is another case in point. More generally, we’ve not
agreed on whether our attempt to provide more information about future policy actions is an
attempt at Woodford-style forward guidance or is simply an attempt to better explain how we
will change policy based on the anticipated evolution of economic outcomes—that is, our policy
rule. In the former case, we are attempting to commit to a future path that would otherwise be
time inconsistent in order to get better economic outcomes today. In the latter case, we are
conveying information about our policy rule, coupled with our outlook for the economy. I think
that until we resolve internally what we are attempting to do with our forward guidance and our

October 29–30, 2013

90 of 239

communications, it’s going to be impossible to communicate clearly our stance of monetary
policy and the implied conditionality of those policies on the state of the economy.
The second issue has to do with a fundamental tension between having a clearly
articulated reaction function and the Committee’s desire for discretion—that is, the desire to
keep open the possibility of doing whatever seems right at any particular moment in time. This
is a fundamental tension because, in a world in which unforeseen events can happen, there’s
value to commitment and there’s value to discretion. There can be a reasonable divergence of
views among policymakers as to which of those is a more important guiding principle of
policymaking. I personally favor commitment to simple rules, but I don’t expect that all
members of the Committee will agree with me. I do think, however, that our stated desire for
transparency and clarity regarding our future actions is in serious conflict with our desire, often,
for discretion. This is one reason that I think we get ourselves tied up in knots with our
statements. It’s confusing to the public when we claim or express the desire to commit to either
a well-articulated reaction function or some other forward-looking action, yet we simultaneously
talk and act as if we would want to retain complete discretion. We’ll get to the point—in fact,
we may already be there—where our statements are more confusing than clarifying. The bottom
line is, if we wish to be transparent and accountable, we should agree, then, to articulate a clearly
defined reaction function. If we are unable to do so, we should be more tightlipped about our
policy intentions in the future because we’re acting under discretion. Discretion does not lend
itself well to being clear and transparent about a policy framework or about the future path of
policy. Needless to say, I do prefer a more clearly articulated reaction function and the
transparency that goes with that.

October 29–30, 2013

91 of 239

Let me turn now to the policy initiatives—at least some of them—that the staff has put
before us. Regarding LSAPs, I found the idea of tying cuts to actual indicators of labor market
improvement sensible in concept, but, to my taste, it became overly complicated. Our
experience over the last year convinces me that the communication challenges presented by a
flow-based LSAP program greatly exceed any benefits of the automatic stabilization features that
some found so attractive a year ago. I favor some simplification. We should consider going
back to the formulation we used in the first two LSAP programs, whereby we announced a total
amount and a path of monthly purchases to get there. After all, we all decided that it was the size
of the balance sheet and the size of the program that mattered. I think it is fine for the
Committee to use the suggested staff rules to determine maybe the total amount of assets to be
purchased and the time to completion. The path could be one of constant equal purchases, or it
could be a declining path. I sense from reading the staff memos on the size and composition of
the cuts that it doesn’t matter that much which path we choose, provided that we tell market
participants exactly what we intend to do. This is how we implemented QE2, and I do believe
that that implementation created less policy uncertainty and less confusion than the current
program has.
Of course, the Committee could retain the option to engage in an additional round of
asset purchases later if, after the current round, they thought it was necessary to do more and if
they thought it would be helpful. But at least the current program would be brought to an end
with some predictability and some determinate size of the balance sheet. I also think such a
simplification would help separate the issues of program decisionmaking for LSAPs from our
forward guidance on the funds rate, and that might have some benefits.

October 29–30, 2013

92 of 239

I’m reminded of the story about Armand Hammer, the industrialist, who was once asked
how he lived to be 95. He said, “Well, I smoked five cigars a day and drank three glasses of
brandy.” And the interviewer responded by saying, “My father did that, but he died at 66.”
Armand’s answer was, “Well, he just didn’t do it long enough.” [Laughter] Moving right
along—it’s hard when I try to be funny; I’m really not very good at it.
Regarding forward guidance on thresholds, I’ll reiterate what I said earlier. We need to
recognize that there are two different sets of rationales for signaling a very gradually rising
interest rate path once we reach our thresholds. One reason is that, by promising to keep interest
rates exceptionally low in the future, we are encouraging economic activity now. Another reason
is that interest rates need to be low in the future because we expect the situation to exist such that
the real interest rate is going to be exceptionally low for a long time even though all of our gaps
are going to be zero. Ultimately, explaining how that occurs will be important.
Now, these two reasons for keeping rates low have very different implications for the
implied degree of commitment by this Committee. Under the first view, we are promising to
keep rates low in the future even in the face of rising inflation rates. This is what I take to be the
Woodford-style forward guidance. This requires a high degree of commitment. The pressure to
raise rates when inflation rates are beginning to rise and reserves are beginning to flow out of the
system in copious amounts will be quite intense. Under the second view, there’s much less
required commitment. We will keep interest rates low because we now project that real rates
will be low. I take this to be the key implication of the financial headwinds point of view. In
this case, if our projections turn out to be incorrect, then we would raise rates more quickly. Yet
this, too, has a challenge associated with it for communications. I think that justifying a zero real

October 29–30, 2013

93 of 239

funds rate when the unemployment gap is zero and inflation is close to 2 will require some
nimble communications.
The Committee has not agreed on which of these two reasons is the primary motivation
for keeping rates low past our thresholds. Unless we have a strong consensus, my preference
would be not to change our current thresholds or introduce any more of them. Instead, I would
prefer that we convey that, once we are past one of our current thresholds, we will return to a
more normal-looking policy-setting framework and let policy be guided by some version of the
Taylor rule that we may choose to indicate. The big advantage of doing this, in my mind, is that
we will be telling the public how we intend to normalize monetary policy rather than giving them
yet another reason to think that we are even further away from normality than we had earlier
projected. We have time to work as a Committee on what is the proper way to communicate the
return to a normal policymaking framework. In the meantime, I think it is best not to tinker with
the thresholds, which would cause more confusion than it would clarity.
Regarding the use of balance sheet actions to strengthen forward guidance, my view is
that such a tool is fraught with risks to our credibility and dangers. I believe that if we convey
our policy reaction function clearly, market interest rates will reflect our desired policy path. If
we fail to clearly convey our forward guidance and our reaction function, our attempts to cap
interest rates by shoring up various asset prices and the term structure are liable to invite
speculative attacks and create other problems for us, depending on which mechanisms we
choose. Open market operations should not be a substitute for clarity regarding our reaction
function.
In summary, my preference is to conduct our LSAP program in the way that we
conducted our earlier programs: Declare a total amount that we think is consistent with our

October 29–30, 2013

94 of 239

outlook and a path for those purchases and then terminate them at some known point in the
future. I think this will reduce market uncertainty and will permit an easier separation between
our LSAP program and the forward guidance on interest rates, which is an important part of our
arsenal. Regarding forward guidance, my preference is to convey that we will return to some
version of rule-like behavior once we cross the current thresholds. This will set us on a path
toward normalization of policy, reducing uncertainty about future policy, and underscore our
positive outlook for the economy. And, finally, regarding open market operations, I believe that
if we can clearly convey our reaction function to the public, we will not need to strengthen our
forward guidance by directly shoring up the prices of various types of assets. If a mismatch
develops between our desired policy path and market expectations, we could work to educate the
public about our reaction function. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. You’ve set an ambitious agenda for today.
I’ll try to keep up.
First, in an attempt to be as brief as possible, let me give you my executive summary. In
order to enhance our unconventional policy tools’ effectiveness, I favor simple remedies
whenever possible. One of the simplest adjustments is to lower the unemployment threshold to
6 percent or lower. This is a relatively simple adjustment for the public to digest, and it
smoothes over several of the rough spots in the public’s current assessment of our policy
strategy.
So let me get started. We’re seriously underrunning our inflation objective at a time
when unemployment remains dangerously high. Our biggest credibility risk with the public, to
me, is this: They aren’t confident that we will stick with our already announced intentions to

October 29–30, 2013

95 of 239

provide bountiful policy accommodation in order to achieve our statutory dual mandate goals
within a reasonable period of time. I will note at this point that, around this table and in our
public commentary, we use the notion of credibility risk in very different ways. That’s just the
nature of this, but I’m using it in a way that’s different than some others already today.
From April until September, long-term Treasury rates increased about 100 basis points.
This was not an old-fashioned inflation scare. Inflation remains low. Investors and the public at
large were concerned that the Fed would be tightening monetary policy earlier than they had
expected, and, at that time, they didn’t share the June SEP’s optimism for a stronger economic
recovery. Investors’ tightening concerns even carried over to tighter expectations for funds rate
increases in the futures markets prior to our reaching our 6½ percent threshold, I would say. The
public acted as if they were revising down their expectations of the Fed’s resolve to do whatever
it takes to be successful. This is what I would call a Bank of Japan risk—the danger of removing
accommodation too quickly. That’s our largest credibility risk today. Our decision in September
that reinforced the economic conditionality of the LSAP program was a big boost to shoring up
our credibility on providing adequate policy accommodation. Mr. Chairman, I agree completely
with your assessment on that. That action was important, and so are the actions we begin to
consider today.
Now, I personally believe that our open-ended LSAPs and forward guidance have made a
substantial positive difference for economic growth and inflation. Our actions to date have
modestly offset ferocious headwinds, and you alluded to some of these just a few moments ago,
Mr. Chairman. These headwinds come from restrictive, austerity-style government spending
cuts and tax increases, as well as severe household deleveraging—deleveraging that continues.
Amplifying these influences, the zero-lower-bound constraint has prevented us from more easily

October 29–30, 2013

96 of 239

offsetting their negative effects. But I also believe that these tools have not been as effective as
they could have been, in part because of our difficult and narrow path to consensus. In order to
maximize the effectiveness of our unconventional monetary policy tools amid all of our diverse
public commentary, we need to better tune our formal Committee communications on forward
guidance. Our challenge is to state our policy actions as a set of consensus views that are often
in conflict with individual views expressed in public, while trying to convince the public that we
will stick with our policy pronouncements as a Committee. We want to maintain the public’s
expectation of our resolve to do whatever it takes to be successful. That’s my opinion. In this
setting, the public and markets are constantly monitoring our statements for signs that we are, in
fact, reluctant to maintain this course. They worry that we will instead engineer a Bank of
Japan–style policy reversal.
Moving now, more specifically, to our communications challenges, the largest difficulty
has been describing what we mean by “threshold” in our forward guidance. I believe we need to
do more to enhance and protect the accommodation that it provides. So, what’s the simplest
thing that we could do? To me, it would be, at the appropriate juncture, adjusting our forwardguidance unemployment threshold down to 6 percent or lower. President Kocherlakota’s earlier
proposal for 5½ percent would be acceptable to me. Our 2½ percent inflation safeguard ought to
be enough to allay any concerns that this enhancement would provide excessive accommodation
in terms of inflationary risks. With a 6 percent unemployment threshold, an inflation floor
doesn’t seem necessary, to me. Although I can’t say this with 100 percent certainty, I have every
expectation that inflation will be higher along this enhanced forward-guidance path where we
maintain the funds rate at zero for longer, at least until unemployment falls to 6 percent.
Essentially, the inflation floor suggestion is an elaboration of what we mean by “threshold,” as

October 29–30, 2013

97 of 239

opposed to “trigger.” And the unemployment threshold is simpler and dominates the more
complicated inflation floor, in my opinion.
I think the appropriate time for a change in our forward guidance would be when we first
reduce the flow purchase rate of assets, but I’m open minded to other people’s opinions on that,
of course. No matter when it happens, there’s a good chance that the reduced purchase flow
would be interpreted as a restrictive policy move. I apologize, Mr. Chairman. That’s going
against your principle 3 that you laid out at the very beginning of this meeting, but I think there
is that chance.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. My principle is what we should say, not what the market is
going to believe.
MR. EVANS. Well, because I think this is likely to be the case, it’s more difficult to say
that. But okay. Anyway, there’s a chance that it’ll be interpreted as restrictive, and so enhanced
forward guidance should be used to more than offset this interpretation. I would be open to
further explicit guidance on LSAP pace reductions at that time.
The final element in my preferred simple set of announced policy enhancements would
be to include some language describing a conditionally shallower path of funds rate increases. I
favor either the alt-B language or greater explicit reference to the inertial Taylor (1999) type of
policy responses, which I doubt the public has fully taken on board but which is embedded in the
Tealbook baseline. Overall, I think this package is a simple and direct approach to enhancing
our communications’ effectiveness.
Okay. I’ve already covered much of my thinking on these issues, so let me briefly go
through the specific questions, if I can. Regarding the first question on the inflation floor, I share
President Bullard’s objective to get inflation up. I think the question is just how we go about

October 29–30, 2013

98 of 239

doing that. Let me express my concern again, and I’m happy for more discussion on that. I
don’t really prefer the 1½ percent inflation floor. If the public understands what we mean by our
threshold, it strikes me that this is redundant information. For example, if unemployment is
6.4 percent and inflation is 1.4 percent, it seems to me that a threshold means we would keep
policy on hold at that point. I would hope that the public would already have that expectation.
Because this communication seems redundant, the public would question why we’ve inserted it
into the FOMC statement: “Why is this extraneous piece of information being offered up?
There must be a reason for it. Let me think this through more carefully. Maybe it means that our
threshold doesn’t mean what I thought it meant.” And I think that would be especially true if we
chose an inflation floor of 1½ percent with actual inflation closer to 1.4 percent, which,
unhelpfully, the current Tealbook assessment had up a little bit closer relative to their analysis.
So I worry about a Bank of Japan risk that people would be concerned that we’d take away the
long-promised accommodation too soon.
The alternative post-liftoff policy in the staff memo didn’t seem to add much beyond the
inertial Taylor (1999). I don’t have strong preferences either way on that.
In terms of targeted market interventions, I guess I would say I’m not a big fan of that
approach. I wish there had been a little more questioning—I would have asked a question, but it
went very quickly. I guess the kind of question that I would have had would be along these
lines. We’re reluctant to tell the market what we think that their pricing ought to be—rightly so,
because we want price discovery and we want that information to come back to us. But if we
were going to do interventions, we’re pretty close to telling them what we think pricing ought to
be. So, what if we just published our assessment of the yield curve and the appropriate pricing
based on our understanding of what our policies were supposed to do, and we didn’t really stand

October 29–30, 2013

99 of 239

behind market interventions of that, but we just continually updated what we thought our policy
should be providing? There could be some daylight between that. There could be some daylight
between our interventions and whether or not they actually achieve that as well. Is this any
worse? How much worse is it? That’s the kind of question that I would have. So it just seems
more complicated. I prefer things to be simple.
Regarding the third question of the lower range for the funds rate or IOER, I was
intrigued by President Rosengren’s suggestion of 5 basis point buckets of lowering the IOER.
I’m sympathetic to reducing IOER to zero. We’ve done it in the past. If we were to do it,
conditional on things that are happening, maybe that would be useful.
And when it comes to balance sheet adjustments in conjunction with simple and stronger
forward guidance, I’m open to this. I tend to think it’s still pretty complicated, but the major
firepower has to come from our forward guidance. At some point, we do have to bring the asset
purchases to a close, and so I’m open minded on that. In terms of composition of the purchases,
I’m sympathetic to providing more in terms of MBS and reducing Treasuries, if we ever get to
that point.
But at any rate, let me conclude. Simpler is better. I think the lower unemployment
threshold of 6 percent or lower, once we begin to taper, would be a good idea. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. I have one question for President Evans, because this idea of tapering
but then strengthening forward guidance at the same time has been kicked around the Committee
before. Are you worried at all that this would send a conflicting signal? You want to pull back,
but you don’t want to pull back. Are you worried about that at all, or not really?

October 29–30, 2013

100 of 239

MR. EVANS. I’ve learned to worry about more of this ever since we came to recognize
that our communications haven’t always had the follow-through that we expected. So, yes,
that’s true. I’ve taken on board that there is more of a unidimensional aspect to what we’re
trying to do than just the plain language of, “We’ve got two tools. We can use them differently
at different times.” The markets haven’t really been willing to embrace that. I think what they
are doing is trying to guess what our true resolve is, which is what I tried to talk about at the
beginning. That single principal component in terms of our ultimate resolve to follow through is
what’s most important. Therefore, if we get to the point where tapering makes sense and we
make that adjustment, I fear that the markets will think of that as being on a path to an ultimately
more restrictive balance sheet. And if we then offer them this strengthening to say that we intend
our forward guidance to indicate that we’re going to be in it for longer, that could be helpful.
That’s how I think about it, and I can’t say it would happen.
MR. BULLARD. Okay. I appreciate it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. To build on this conversation,
which I think is really at the heart of the matter in a lot of ways, President Evans refers to a point
in time when it’s right to taper but, at the same time, it’s also right to strengthen forward
guidance. I think that, at such a point in time, it’s very hard to explicate that economic
conditions can justify both at the same time, unless we follow up on what President Lockhart
referred to, explaining why the two tools really are different in terms of some other feature
beyond our dual mandate considerations.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That’s an important point.
MR. EVANS. I agree with that.

October 29–30, 2013

101 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I would just get the Committee’s sense. If we went to 6:00
and left whatever remained for tomorrow morning, would that be okay with everybody? So
another hour, and let me turn to President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Do I have a whole hour? [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes, you do.
MR. EVANS. Well, I just want to point out that I’m acting against my own interest in
agreeing to that, having just finished my own attempt to be as brief as possible. [Laughter].
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, thank you, President Evans.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Your selflessness is appreciated.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, appreciate the staff’s background
memos on this important topic. As others have said, they’re very helpful in thinking through
both the pros and cons of these various issues.
As I discussed in September, I support strengthening our forward guidance to clarify that
future tapering of asset purchases does not imply imminent liftoff of the funds rate. President
Kocherlakota made a very good point just a moment ago. I think that if we want easier monetary
conditions, or more monetary stimulus, through our forward guidance—I’ll talk about IOER in a
moment—we should do that now and not necessarily tie it to the tapering decision. However, we
also should avoid extending our forward guidance beyond the point where there is strong
consensus on the Committee. I’m picking up some themes that have already been touched on.
In thinking about this tradeoff, I find it very helpful to divide forward guidance into two
periods—the post-threshold guidance and then the post-liftoff guidance. Post-threshold forward
guidance describes what we’ll do once the unemployment rate falls below 6½ percent. Post-

October 29–30, 2013

102 of 239

liftoff forward guidance describes what we’ll do after we raise the funds rate for the first time. I
strongly favor strengthening our post-threshold forward guidance, and I would do that at this
time. The unemployment rate has fallen substantially, and a 6½ percent unemployment rate,
which once seemed so far away, is now looming large. Because that threshold could be upon us
relatively soon, it’s becoming increasingly important to clarify what we will do when we cross it.
In particular, we should make it clear that crossing the threshold does not imply an imminent
tightening of the funds rate. Therefore, I favor language along the lines of paragraph 5 in
Tealbook alternative A.
Now, I don’t have a strong view about including an inflation floor, and I think we’ve
heard the pros and cons on that already. I will just reiterate that the background memos suggest
that putting in an inflation floor would have relatively minimal effects. If we were to go to an
inflation floor, I would recommend doing the 1½ percent for symmetry. However, even without
the inflation floor, I would just mention that the language in alt-A would reinforce the point that
the threshold is not a trigger and that inflation, which is explicitly mentioned, will be one of the
considerations in the timing of liftoff.
I am much less supportive of post-liftoff forward guidance at this time. In principle,
post-liftoff guidance could also give markets and the public a better understanding of the likely
path of future policy. However, the date of liftoff is further off, according to the SEP, so the
benefits of post-liftoff guidance are not as great as the benefits of post-threshold guidance right
now. I also see two major difficulties with post-liftoff guidance. First, when we conducted the
consensus forecast experiment last year, we found that reaching a consensus forecast for the next
few years was very challenging—that’s a good Fed phrase—and this project was shelved for the
time being. It’s not going to be any easier for us to agree on a consensus forecast for the funds

October 29–30, 2013

103 of 239

rate, for the same reasons. And, even though I think I’m only the sixth person, we’ve already
heard the various the different issues—whether it’s headwinds or a modified Taylor rule or
“lower for longer”—that come up when people think about what the appropriate level of the
funds rate is for late 2016. Second, the SEP already provides information about the likely path
of the funds rate without conveying a false sense of consensus and, arguably, inappropriate
commitment. Even better, the SEP provides information about the uncertainty and diversity of
views surrounding the median or central tendency. We don’t want to give markets a false sense
of certainty by ignoring that disagreement. Thus, while I strongly support the post-threshold
forward guidance at the current meeting, I would defer post-liftoff guidance until we are closer to
liftoff or until market expectations make that guidance necessary.
Now, turning to the other questions, I do not support the targeted market interventions
along the lines outlined in the staff memo at this time, although I do want to emphasize how
important it is to do this kind of blue-sky thinking. If we communicate effectively—and perhaps
that’s like Governor Stein’s unicorn; it’s a hope—so that market expectations are aligned with
our own, I think these interventions would be unnecessary. The memo’s proposed policies
represent a form of interest rate targeting, which has already been mentioned. That would carry
substantial risks and uncertainty, and these should be considered only as a last resort, in my
view.
I fully support lowering the interest on excess reserves—and I would say, lower it to
10 basis points—along with lowering the target range for the fed funds rate. In fact, I wish we
had done this a long time ago. Lowering the IOER rate not only pushes down market rates, but it
also has the added benefit of reinforcing our communication that we want continued low interest
rates. If staff members have concerns about money market functioning that could be addressed

October 29–30, 2013

104 of 239

by using this reverse repo facility, then I would support using reverse repos to put a floor of, say,
5 basis points.
Like some comments by President Rosengren, I would not change our forward guidance
on asset purchases unless we have a strong consensus for doing so. The forward guidance on
asset purchases we have given has been confusing at times, in part because there wasn’t a
sufficiently strong consensus on the Committee regarding the reasons for adjusting the pace of
purchases and ending the program. And I think it’s exactly the issue a number of people have
already brought up—the fact that it’s not only the economic benefits, but there is also some
notion of costs and efficacy that goes into the reasoning around the asset purchase program. I
would recommend caution in introducing new forward guidance around the asset purchases so
that we don’t make that mistake again. In terms of tapering, I don’t have a strong view about the
mix. Reducing purchases of Treasuries and MBS in roughly equal proportions is fine and has
the added benefit of simplicity.
My final suggestion for the Committee’s communications—and although people have
already mentioned this, I’ll reiterate it—is to pay more attention to the simple maxim that less is
more. Several years ago, the San Francisco Fed held a research symposium on behavioral
economics. The striking conclusion from that literature is that giving people fewer nuances
makes it easier to get the message across. With too many contingencies, people get confused and
the message can be muddled. So as much as we can, we should try to keep our message simple
and to the point. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You have 55 more minutes.
MR. WILLIAMS. I was keeping it simple and to the point. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President George.

October 29–30, 2013

105 of 239

MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would like to also align myself with those
who think that simpler is better. I think that should guide us as we look at this.
For me, the communication challenge we face is really less about convincing markets that
LSAPs and forward guidance are separate policy tools and more about clarifying the sequencing
of our future actions relative to those tools. Because of that, the staff’s work, which was very
helpful in thinking about this, made me wonder if it would be worthwhile to return to the
discussion that we had in June about the path or guidelines for policy normalization? For
example, if markets now believe that we might wait until March to start adjusting purchases and
then end them late next year, at a time when the unemployment rate could be quite close to
6½ percent, I think having more daylight between the end of purchases and the 6½ percent
threshold is important if we want to move deliberately and carefully toward the first rate hike.
We will likely want a period when we hold the balance sheet constant and then cease
reinvestments, which are accompanied or shortly followed by temporary reserve-draining
operations. These shifts in our balance sheet and operations carry some risk in terms of how
markets will respond, and so, for that reason, I have felt that starting to adjust LSAPs sooner
would give us more time to properly lay the groundwork before the first rate hike and help
mitigate the possibility of a sharp rise in longer-term rates, which could threaten the recovery and
financial stability. These considerations and communications suggest to me that it may be
worthwhile for the Committee to reconsider the discussion we had earlier and talk about the
sequencing of those steps.
Relative to the ideas that the staff raised in their memos, let me start with forward
guidance. In terms of our communication strategy and forward guidance, it is tempting, as some
have noted, to remodel that guidance as a way to provide more emphasis on its intent. But it

October 29–30, 2013

106 of 239

seems to me that guidance works best if it is consistent and often repeated, and so making
changes at this point seems counterproductive. Every time we change our guidance, markets
must reassess the implications for policy and ask why we changed it, which then increases
uncertainty and could raise questions about credibility. This is particularly important because a
diverse group of consumers and investors can easily interpret our actions in many different ways,
particularly in ways that can be contrary to our intentions.
Given the risk in adjusting forward guidance, I think we should approach the issue of
adding an inflation floor cautiously. Under the right circumstances, I could support its intent. At
this point, though, I would not want to send a message that our risk assessment that inflation will
fall further has increased, especially given that we have seen some modest upward movement in
core PCE inflation. Should we see further broad-based slowing in prices, though, adding the
inflation floor to signal our commitment to achieving our target may be effective.
I do not favor using targeted market interventions, as such actions move us into further
attempts at fine-tuning and are likely to distort the information content and signals from markets
regarding expectations for monetary policy. To me, it is unclear how this would improve
communication. Right now, markets expect liftoff to occur after the 6½ percent threshold is
reached, so they do not question our commitment to follow through with the current thresholdbased guidance. In addition, the expected path of the funds rate should move in response to our
communications, LSAP expectations, and changes in the outlook. Expecting LSAPs to
surgically operate only on the term premium seems unrealistic, and I prefer other strategies to
address this.
In terms of cutting IOER, I am open to this, although, as others have noted, we’ve left
that option on the table for several years now, and to raise it at this point by pairing it with more-

October 29–30, 2013

107 of 239

aggressive use of the overnight reverse repo facility could send some mixed messages and offer
yet another communication challenge.
Regarding LSAP rules, I support rules-based, systematic policy reactions, but I believe
that any rule should exploit the connection between the instrument we’re adjusting and the target
we are trying to hit. The connection between LSAPs and any measure of labor markets,
including the unemployment rate or employment growth, especially at such a short horizon,
strikes me as rather weak. Instead, I think we should simply try to be clear with the public and
markets about when we anticipate the start of tapering, because that is likely to elicit the
strongest market reaction. If we try to state a reaction function for asset purchases, which is not
fully understood, then we may also be expected to provide a reaction function for the fed funds
rate.
In terms of the mix of assets, I am open to any of the options. I could support a decision
to adjust the mix based on some research that suggests that the benefits of Treasury purchases are
modest. Once tapering begins, reducing Treasury purchases quickly would probably do little to
tighten broader financial conditions.
I also like the idea of trying to use the SEP to provide balance sheet guidance. I think
there is an opportunity to talk about the appropriate timing for ending asset purchases, similar to
how we do appropriate timing of policy firming. And I will stop with that. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, want to thank the staff for their
good work on the memos that were prepared for this policy planning discussion.
Before I lay out answers to the questions that were posed, let me take a moment to give a
general overview of my position. I am supportive of taking actions that will reinforce our

October 29–30, 2013

108 of 239

message that policy is and will remain highly accommodative. However, in light of my outlook
that the economy will continue to improve, I do not see a need to take actions that would add
accommodation. In addition, while our asset purchases do not appear to have had negative
effects on market functioning or financial stability thus far, in my mind, the potential longer-run
risks continue to grow with the size of the balance sheet. How we reduce our asset purchases,
how we communicate our plans, and how we assure the public of our commitment to maintain a
highly accommodative monetary policy after we end our asset purchase program do pose
immense challenges, and the events of this past summer make those challenges clear. Thus, I
believe that our path forward should be governed by a dominant principle, and that is simplicity,
as several others have already suggested.
Applying this principle of simplicity, I strongly favor some type of simple rule for asset
purchase reductions that can be easily communicated to the public. I know that a simple rule is
unlikely to be the first-best option, but a simple rule may still give us the economic results we
desire. A simple rule facilitates clarity and enables the public and financial markets to form
reasonably accurate expectations. Moreover, with markets already expecting us to proceed in a
pretty simple way, ratifying those expectations may be beneficial, especially in light of the
communication challenges we had this summer. Along many dimensions, we are at a juncture
where a simple, easily explained, second-best policy rule probably dominates a complex firstbest solution that would be difficult to implement.
Similarly, I would favor simple and reasonable adjustments to our forward guidance to
ease concerns about a premature tightening of policy. However, I do not think it is a good idea
to change the thresholds in our forward guidance, because doing so could make markets doubt
whether we will actually carry through with what we say, thus reducing the effectiveness of that

October 29–30, 2013

109 of 239

guidance. For maximum effect, I believe that any adjustment to our forward guidance should be
timed to coincide with the announcement of our first reduction in the pace of asset purchases.
For example, the proposed language in alternative B, paragraph 6, would be a good addition to
our statement when we announce that the pace of asset purchases will be adjusted. Timed in this
way, this adjustment to our forward guidance could help separate asset purchases and short-term
interest rates in the eyes of the public by emphasizing that we have not pulled in our expected
path of the funds rate.
So with those ideas as a guide, let me briefly answer the questions that were posed.
Regarding the first question, imposing a 1½ percent floor on projected inflation seems like a
sensible option to enhance and reinforce forward guidance. If we are projecting such low
inflation, it is unlikely that we would begin to raise the fed funds rate target anyway. So this
floor is intuitive. As I just mentioned, the best time to make any adjustment to the funds rate
guidance would be coincident with the first adjustment in asset purchases.
For the second question, I do not see targeted market interventions as being appropriate at
this juncture. Many of the options in the memo move away from my desire for simplicity to
enhance communications. In addition, some options border less on reinforcing guidance and
more on adding a slight amount of accommodation, and I do not think the two concepts are
synonymous.
Regarding IOER, in the third question, I have previously been open to a cut in the IOER
rate. However, it is not clear whether such a cut would really provide much signal about the
Committee’s intention to keep rates low well into the future. In fact, adding ever so slightly
more accommodation by cutting the IOER could create noise if markets interpret the cut as a
signal of pessimism about the outlook on the part of the Committee.

October 29–30, 2013

110 of 239

In terms of asset purchase guidance, in question 4, I would strongly favor a simple rule,
as I just said, to guide reductions in asset purchases. Linking asset purchase reductions with
decreases in the unemployment rate, as Governor Stein has previously suggested, appears to be
the best option, but I could also support other mechanical rules, such as a rule linked to payrolls
that does not require unrealistic payroll gains. What is most important to me is that we begin the
process of adjusting our asset purchases.
For the mix of purchases, in question 5, I would be inclined toward an approach that is
simple and aligned with market expectations to avoid possible communication problems. The
simplest solution would be to make modest, simultaneous downward reductions in both
Treasuries and MBS at each step. That said, I recognize that a case might be made for initially
reducing Treasury purchases more than MBS purchases, based on our larger role in the MBS
market.
Finally, the sixth question asks about other enhancements to communications. Here I
would suggest that we learn from previous experience. In my view, some of our past
communication enhancements have solved the problems at hand, but they have not always
proven to be robust to future developments. In light of this experience, I suggest that we try to
evaluate how proposed communication solutions would hold up under some alternative
economic scenarios. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like others, I’ll make a few remarks before I
address the listed questions.
As a general matter, I am sympathetic to clarifying our communications and forward
guidance, but I’ll echo what people have said about the value of simplicity and just highlight the

October 29–30, 2013

111 of 239

incredible complexity of what we are trying to communicate with the statement we have. I think
that, going forward, we ought to be setting a pretty high bar for introducing additional elements
to forward guidance or additional elements of complexity about how we portray or execute our
policy.
The second point I want to make is that, as I said at the last meeting and as President
Bullard said, I think it’s unreasonable to expect markets not to draw inferences about the funds
rate path from what we do with asset purchases. Now, I understand that it’s really easy for us.
We see all of the information we see. We have this discussion. There’s a lot we see in this room
that markets don’t see, and so it’s easy for us to picture: “Yes, I can decide to taper, and it
doesn’t change at all my view about what funds rate path we’re likely to choose in the future.”
But I think President Bullard has it right. Inevitably, market participants are going to be
inferring about some hidden information—not that we’re hiding information. But inevitably,
they are going to make inferences about our subjective assessments of the incoming data and the
economic outlook from one instrument. So, what we do with one instrument is bound to spill
over into what they view about the other instrument.
I think it is worth pointing out here that, paradoxically, to the extent that our decision at
the last meeting not to taper is perceived as reflecting a desire to push back on the markets’
pulling forward of the funds rate path, we ourselves have linked the two policy instruments. So
now a decision to taper is going to imply a willingness to tolerate the kind of market move that
led us to not taper in September. At this point, for me, this is another reason not to get our hopes
up about achieving a clean separation in the public’s mind between asset purchases and the funds
rate path.

October 29–30, 2013

112 of 239

Now, this isn’t to say we shouldn’t push hard on those expectations at the point when we
choose to taper. We should feel as if we are capable of speaking forcefully and ratcheting up the
volume on what we expect about the funds rate path. I don’t view this as strengthening forward
guidance in the sense of introducing some other communication device intended to push down
the yield curve, because I think President Bullard is about right. This wouldn’t be about adding
some little trick to pull the yield curve down. It would be something that would forcefully say,
“Yes, we believe this is the likely path of the funds rate”—just to emphasize that we think it
ought to stay where it is now.
The third point I want to make is that, personally, I think we should hold off any other
forward guidance until we decide to taper. Let’s just lie low. We’ve tried multiple times this
past year to communicate. I’m not sure we wouldn’t call it a mixed success at best. Anything
we’re likely to say now about tapering is going to have limited credibility. It’s going to raise
questions: Is this consistent with June? Is it consistent with September? Is it consistent with the
original guidance? So I think that we should just wait until we’re ready to taper and do it—and
communicate clearly at the time and recognize that long rates could well move a lot.
As the discussion has gone around the table, down the other side, and back again, I’ve
been thinking a lot about what President Rosengren said about clarity and achieving a shared
consensus in this room, at least at a workable level, on what we’re about. I think it’s an
important thing, and it’s worth reflecting on. I’m not sure I have anything terribly organized to
say about it, but I was thinking about it when President Lockhart talked about our being clear on
whether we’re all in. If we’re hitching this to a rise in GDP growth, are we prepared to stick
with it, pedal to the metal—the hamster-wheel scenario? And that’s a tough question. We
haven’t addressed that. We didn’t really talk about that. At no point did we really talk about it,

October 29–30, 2013

113 of 239

and I think we’ve all assumed that, yes, there’d come a point when we’d want to find a way out
of it.
I think what President Plosser said about commitment versus discretion is very germane.
Whenever forward guidance comes on the table, we ought to revisit this, because our statement
is clearly worded as if it’s just a forecast of our future selves and represents no commitment to do
anything we would not otherwise want to do at the time. And yet, so much of the language in the
minutes and discussion around the table acts as if it is an independent policy tool, which, to some
extent, presumes either a discrepancy between our understanding of our future selves and the
markets or some willingness to commit.
For me, I take away this broader message in Eric’s observation that, looking back, there’s
an extent to which you could say that we focus a lot on getting an agreement, meeting by
meeting, on that meeting’s tactical measures, as opposed to the deeper understanding. And when
we’re talking about how we’re going to react in the future, a lot of times we seem to push off
things that it would be better to get a consensus about early. Just as an example, look at this
discussion. We received a set of questions for discussion. Every one of us has felt it necessary
to preface our remarks with a bunch of things that weren’t addressed in the questions. The
questions are all about these tactical issues about particular instruments, and everyone felt it
necessary to address deeper, broader issues before they address the tactical stuff.
So now I’d like to talk about the tactical questions we were to address. Regarding the
first question, I think an inflation floor seems like a potentially constructive change, and I’m
generally for it. But I’d point out that, to some extent, it’s this off-equilibrium communication
that we shouldn’t often do. It’s not clear that there are that many states of the world that it really
tells anybody anything about. I generally favor it. It would be nice if it was handled

October 29–30, 2013

114 of 239

symmetrically with the 2½ threshold so that it was one clear, simple thing rather than two
different contraptions. The “headwinds” language about post-liftoff interest rates is highly
problematic. The way it’s written, to me, clearly signals greater pessimism on the part of the
Committee. So I think it’s vulnerable to Woodford’s critique, and I don’t think it’s a good thing
to add to the statement. Plus, if our purpose is to compensate for tapering, then it is not clear that
we should do it now rather than when we taper.
Regarding the second question on market interventions, I’m generally skeptical that
market interventions can strengthen our forward guidance. The staff memo notes that the
effectiveness of the interventions “would depend on investors’ confidence that the facilities
would remain available for the period of time defined by either a date or a threshold.” It’s not
clear to me that starting the interventions would be viewed as any more of a commitment to
follow through on them than anything we say. As someone else has said, the standing purchase
facility would be date-based as opposed to data-dependent. I’m a little puzzled about why we’d
take that step backward. We moved away from date-based forward guidance for good reasons.
Plus, just a centennial perspective—I think William McChesney Martin, Thomas McCabe, and
Marriner Eccles would be rolling over in their graves. I think Carter Glass would be spinning in
his grave if he knew we were contemplating these.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Why those guys in particular?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Why is that a problem? [Laughter]
MR. LACKER. Yet another reason for a deeper discussion.
A third alternative was to commit to overnight RPs at a predetermined rate until the
threshold was crossed. But my interpretation of the motivation of this discussion is to help
people understand how long we think it will be until the thresholds are crossed, not our degree of

October 29–30, 2013

115 of 239

commitment about what we’ve said we would do until the thresholds are crossed. Committing to
doing something different until the thresholds are crossed—it’s not clear that that’s going to
change people’s minds about how long it’s going to be until the thresholds are crossed. So I’m a
little puzzled about that. I think the idea behind forward operations seems to be that we’d take
positions that commit us to losing money if short rates go up at some specified time in the future.
We haven’t actually committed not to let rates go up. Plus, because we’re already pretty well
positioned to lose a lot of money if rates go up, I’m not sure how much additional credibility this
would buy us.
The third question concerns lowering the funds rate when we taper or lower IOER. I’m
skeptical about whether it would help for the reasons someone said. We would be using one
instrument while we’re tapering, which would be perceived as moving another way with another
instrument, and that would be confusing. In addition, the current level of the funds rate doesn’t
really say anything to anybody about how long the rate’s going to be low, and I think the
disconnect problem is about how long it’s going to be until liftoff. That’s the major issue of the
funds rate curve. And, if we’re going to lower IOER now, I think it raises a really awkward
question as to why we haven’t done this in the last five years. It’s just a little bit awkward that
we haven’t lowered it until now. If there’s some reason we can point to, then that might be good,
but I think that’s awkward.
And, finally, regarding the mix of assets, I favor reducing MBS purchases only.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. One rationale is that we have this reverse repo thing now.
That’s one, if you’re looking for a rationale. President Kocherlakota.

October 29–30, 2013

116 of 239

MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. A lot of great things have been
said already. President Fisher asked me to speak until 6:00, but, given how many great things
have already been said, it’s going to be hard for me to meet that challenge.
I do want to associate myself with the remarks that President Evans made about the main
risk that we face, which is that the public and the markets don’t see us as sufficiently committed
to sticking with the long program of accommodation that is going to be required to meet our dual
mandate objectives. We continue to be falling short of our dual mandate objectives over the
medium term, and I would say that that is one way for us to simplify our communication on an
ongoing basis. In January 2012, we set forth a strategic plan of what we are trying to achieve.
We came back and reaffirmed that strategic plan. One way to simplify communication is to be
making reference to that plan on an ongoing basis as a benchmark for what we’re about. For
example, why would we think about lowering IOER now? Well, actually, we’re falling short on
both of our mandated objectives. We’re falling short of what we’re trying to achieve as an
organization in terms of our strategic direction. That provides an explanation for why we would
take this step of lowering IOER at this time. I think one way to achieve the simplicity—and I
won’t be the one holdout, saying, “Yes, we should get more complicated if we can”; I also favor
simplicity—is to be speaking more in terms of our goals and less in terms of the tactical moves
that we are forced to confront on a meeting-by-meeting basis. Now, with that said—that I think
we should be trying to be persuasive that we’re in it to win it, and that we’re there to try to get
the recovery accomplished and get inflation back to 2 percent—I sense that we are going to want
to back away from the asset purchase tool before we have accomplished full employment and
before we have gotten back to 2 percent inflation.

October 29–30, 2013

117 of 239

President Rosengren laid out some arguments for not thinking about costs and efficacy.
I’m actually quite sympathetic to the line of reasoning that Eric put forth, but I do not think it’s
commonly shared. So we have to have a way to talk about this publicly—why is it that we’re
going to back away from this tool when we’re still short of our goals? And this is the problem
we faced with our recent communications about near-term tapering. We’ve been sending the
following message: We’re willing to curtail or reduce monetary accommodation. Mr.
Chairman, despite your third principle, I think reducing the flow of purchases is going to be seen
as taking away a tool when the unemployment rate is expected to fall only gradually and the
inflation rate is expected to rise only slowly back toward desired levels. That kind of
communication is telling the public that we’re quite comfortable with relatively long-term
deviations from our employment and price goals. It really tells that our strategic plan isn’t that
relevant for our thinking about monetary policy. With that message, it’s not surprising that the
markets see it as a very real possibility that we might be willing to raise short-term interest rates
relatively soon. We can fix this communication problem—I think President Lockhart hit on this,
and I mentioned this in my last go-round—by being more transparent about how we’re thinking
about purchases. Why are we talking about reducing purchases in the face of a disturbingly
weak macroeconomic outlook? It’s because many around the table have expressed growing
discomfort with this unconventional tool in light of their concerns about its costs, its efficacy,
and its just general “unknownness.” That’s not a word, I don’t think.
MR. EVANS. It could become one.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Well, I encourage you to use that at the next press conference.
Yet, when I look at alternative C, I see no mention of efficacy or costs or these general
concerns in the proposed justification for tapering. This lack of clarity about the Committee

October 29–30, 2013

118 of 239

participants’ concerns about asset purchases means that the public does not have a clear
understanding of why we see asset purchases as distinct from the fed funds rate as a tool of
monetary policy. And President Lacker and President Bullard are right—there’s always going to
be this inference problem, but we certainly have set ourselves up for magnifying that problem by
not saying we see any distinction between these two tools as a way to stimulate aggregate
demand.
Mr. Chairman, I encourage the staff to recirculate the one-page handout about the asset
purchase program that you distributed at the December 2012 meeting. There were a lot of great
things in that handout, but I really like this one terse but, I felt, really apt phrase, which was,
“Exiting from the program: Rhetoric should focus on ongoing evaluation of efficacy and costs.”
I’ve been considerably more long winded today than you were in that handout, but I arrived at
that same conclusion. To make clear that we view asset purchases as a distinct tool from the fed
funds rate, our communications about ending the program should emphasize the costs and
efficacy considerations associated with this unconventional tool. To be clear, I’m not saying we
should mention only those. It’s that we’re balancing those off against the dual mandate benefits
of using the tools and reaching the conclusion that, given that balancing act, it’s appropriate at
this time to curtail the use of this tool.
So, as many have done, I’ve had this overall opening statement. Let me turn to the staff’s
six questions
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota, could I ask for an elaboration? Let
me ask the following question. I’m just trying to understand your argument. Part of your
argument sounds like, as long as we’re not meeting our targets, we should put all instruments to
the max. Now, that’s not obviously true. In normal circumstances, with a Taylor rule, we’d put

October 29–30, 2013

119 of 239

the interest rate below the neutral rate when we’re not at our objective, but we wouldn’t
necessarily go to zero. So, what if I think about our overall policy thrust as being our rate
guidance plus the special thing, the asset purchases, which help us drive the effective rate below
zero? As we move forward in time and as the economy gets better—and we have seen a lot of
improvement—why can’t we drop part of the set of tools and still remain highly
accommodative? I’m not saying this is where we are. I’m just asking, as a theoretical matter,
why we couldn’t argue that we have made a lot of progress and the economy has improved
enough that we don’t need this additional booster rocket to get, ultimately, to our objective. I
didn’t quite understand that.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I think that’s a great question and a very important question,
although I do feel as though we might have switched roles on this discussion in the last two years
[laughter]—there’s nothing wrong with that. But let me try to answer that question. I think that
if we were in a position where the outlook was always consistent with our dual mandate
objectives, then we would be responding to the changes in economic conditions as you describe.
But I guess I look back over the past couple of years, and I see a situation where we’ve been
falling short on both prices and unemployment. That seems to call for more accommodation
than we currently have in place. So the reason to say we should be doing the maximum is simply
that, given the level of accommodation we have in place—which seems like a lot—we still are
falling short of our goals. That means we want to provide more in order to achieve an even
faster rate of improvement toward those objectives.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. But “falling short” doesn’t mean at this moment that we’re
short, but rather that you’re assuming we could get to our objectives more quickly.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes.

October 29–30, 2013

120 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Our projections do show us reaching our objectives.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. But I’ll focus on inflation. They show there that we’re taking
five or six years to reach our objectives. So this would be to facilitate a faster rate of
improvement toward those goals. That’s a better way to say what I was trying to say,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Sorry to interrupt you. Go ahead.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. No, I appreciate the attempt to make me more clear than I was
being.
So I favor simple and transparent approaches, but it’s not just simplicity and
transparency. I would favor those approaches if they foster faster progress toward our dual
mandate objectives. The outlook in the Tealbook, Book A, justifies more stimulus, as others
have talked about. On forward guidance, I thought that President Williams’s divide between
post-liftoff and post-threshold is really nice, but I like the idea of talking about what we would
do at the 6½ percent unemployment threshold. And I would favor reducing the unemployment
rate threshold. I continue to favor reducing it down to 5½ percent. If we go back to July, the
staff prepared a great memo that I thought did an excellent job of rationalizing why it would be
beneficial to do so. Our price stability objective is to keep inflation close to 2, so I’m not sure
why we would be thinking about raising rates if the medium-term outlook for inflation is as low
as 1½ percent. I’m not sure what we’d be adding by adding such a low floor. People have also
talked about the last sentence in alternative B(6). That sentence is packed with a lot of
economics. It’s very rich. I know what it’s trying to do, but I think it’s better to try to unpack
that than to try to have that one sentence carry all of that weight. I think that the SEP, plus the

October 29–30, 2013

121 of 239

press conferences, can really do a good job of trying to convey what we’re attempting to do
there.
Regarding question 2, I see the various alternatives to use market interventions to put
caps on medium-term interest rates as potentially valuable. But I think we need to have a lot
better understanding of their limitations and challenges before we proceed. The key question for
me is one of pass-through. We could do all of these interventions in targeted markets, but we
really want to get out there to the rates that households and firms actually pay.
To move on to question 3, I don’t think that a change in the IOER or the fed funds target
would have large effects necessarily, but, certainly, lowering it is directionally consistent with
fostering more-rapid progress to our dual mandate objectives. It’s very easy to explain to the
public. It’s got transparency and simplicity—all of those things—going for it. I actually would
go further. I would ask the staff—and this follows from President Bullard’s suggestion—to
examine whether it’s legally possible for the Board of Governors to lower the interest rate on
excess reserves below zero. I think it’s worth exploring that. It doesn’t mean we necessarily
have to do it. But is that even legally possible? President Bullard has raised that as an economic
possibility, but is it legally possible for us to do that? I think such a move would be a very
powerful signal of the strength of our commitment to our dual mandate objectives.
The fourth question asks about mechanistic rules for the reduction of asset purchases. In
general, and especially in such unusual times, this Committee is loath to adopt mechanistic,
backward-looking rules. Any such rule confronts us with the risk that we will make the mistake
of leaving out factors that end up shaping our outlook and our views about appropriate policy.
Why, then, are we contemplating a mechanistic approach to this particular part of our policy
menu, the reduction of asset purchases? As I understand it, the goal is to reduce the influence of

October 29–30, 2013

122 of 239

asset purchase reductions on the public’s belief about the future course of the fed funds rate. But
I think this is a second-best treatment—and there’s a better treatment—for the problem. We
should be a lot more transparent about the factors that are influencing our decisionmaking about
asset purchases. Why are we contemplating any reduction in asset purchases when the outlook
would not lead us to consider an increase in the fed funds rate? That’s really the question that
we’re trying to drive home to markets and the public—that we’re willing to reduce asset
purchases when we still think of ourselves as not being willing to consider an increase in the fed
funds rate. We see the programs as not being substitutable. The reason that that’s true is that
many around this table see asset purchases as having costs and efficacy considerations that don’t
apply to the fed funds rate tool. And our external rhetoric needs to be a lot more consistent with
this internal reality. If we’re clear about those distinctions, then our decisions about reducing the
flow of asset purchases would have little informational content about our future decisions
concerning the fed funds rate. And I don’t see a need to have that special mechanized rule for
reducing the flow of asset purchases. For the usual reasons that I’m pretty sure we would regret
such a rule very rapidly, I would advise against doing so.
On question 5, I prefer simplicity here—equal-proportion reductions. There might be
some small benefits to fine-tuning along those lines, but, boy, those have a lot of possible
communication costs, as the memo laid out.
And on question 6, I’ve already made my main comment along these lines. We should be
much more fully transparent about how efficacy and cost considerations are weighing on the
Committee in thinking about asset purchases. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.

October 29–30, 2013

123 of 239

MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I like the phrase “less is more,” but not too
long ago, I sent around a memo, if you remember, showing the word count of our statement.
Since we started our unconventional monetary policy, we’ve gone from the mid-250s to 700 or
so. It seems to me that there’s a conflict between transparency, which we wish to achieve—
providing a market signal and allowing people to discount what we’re likely to do—and this
“less is more” mantra that all of us seem to agree with. I mention that only because I’m now
going to speak more, not less, and I will try to keep it within 700 words. I know you want to quit
at 6:00.
And, Eric, I just want to tell you that wounds can heal after two years, because it’s taken
me two years to get over what St. Louis did to the Texas Rangers. I actually agree with
President Bullard at this juncture, which I haven’t done for about two years. So it may be
possible for you, if you lose in the World Series, to find some of his arguments appealing.
MR. BULLARD. Will you just refresh my memory, President Fisher?
MR. FISHER. I don’t want to refresh your memory. [Laughter] I think we can have an
arbitrage among Shiner Bock, Sam Adams, and Urban Chestnut—or whatever.
Here are some observations, which are somewhat “Bullardian,” if I may use that term.
The premise of the introduction to the set of questions—that asset purchases and forward
guidance are distinct policy tools—is, to me, open to question. We had evidence earlier this year
that our asset purchase plans can affect perceptions of future rate policy. Some of us suspected
all along that this was the case, and that a significant portion of the benefits claimed for our
Treasury purchases actually derive from the inferences people were drawing about future interest
rates—the expectations channel—not just term premium effects. There’s currently also a very
practical linkage between our asset purchase policy and future interest rate policy. As the start of

October 29–30, 2013

124 of 239

tapering has been delayed and the unemployment rate consistently edges slightly lower, it
becomes increasingly likely that liftoff will be constrained by our need to bring asset purchases
to an end rather than by our 6½ percent unemployment threshold.
So we ask, are there better ways of communicating our interest rate intentions? I spoke
of forward guidance at the September meeting, I’ve spoken of it several times, and I’m
convinced that the answer to this question is yes. I’m just not satisfied we’ve found the right
approach. Getting forward guidance right from the start is important because people must
believe that we’ll follow through on whatever it is that we promise to do or that they believe we
have promised to do, especially if we want that promise to be effective. We can’t just say “never
mind” one or two or six months or a year from now. Therefore, it’s important that we not
commit to a rule that may prove to be dysfunctional, forcing us either to accept a bad outcome or
to renege.
By the way, I find the stochastic simulations that the Board has begun reporting very
helpful for identifying policy rules that are possibly likely to perform well in a wide range of
circumstances. I want to thank the staff, as everybody else has done, for the good work that
they’re doing. One observation I have is that vague statements of intent allow more flexibility
and are easier for us to negotiate at the table, but they are unlikely to be very effective. I find
that they are too easily misinterpreted and too easy to reinterpret when they become
inconvenient. So, like many others at the table, I would prefer more rule-based decisionmaking,
if possible. Among the lessons that I take away from the staff simulations are the following:
The optimal funds rate path is highly sensitive to changes in economic assumptions and the
economic outlook. An implication is that it will generally not be a good idea to put a time
constraint on liftoff, to try to peg a future path to the fed funds rate, or to simply too strongly

October 29–30, 2013

125 of 239

signal the intention to target a particular funds rate. Another takeaway for me is that, whatever
its intuitive appeal, a promise to deter liftoff until the inflation rate rises at least to X is probably
of little value. I actually think it may be harmful. At least, this is the feedback I get from
microeconomic operators, Mr. Chairman. It’s difficult for me to explain, but I worry about the
fact that, if we wait until inflation rises to at least X and then we act, it will be viewed as our
tolerating X plus Y. I would underscore that the policy that people expect after liftoff, as I have
argued many times at the table and as many other people have argued here, is more important
than when liftoff occurs or what liftoff is conditioned on. To me, a half-point cut in the
unemployment threshold, by itself, accomplishes very little.
So those are just some observations. What are the practical implications of this slightly
discursive set of observations? First, the most straightforward way to prevent tapering from
running up against our 6½ percent unemployment liftoff threshold—and so maintain some
semblance of separation between our asset purchase policy and our interest rate policy—is to tie
reductions in the pace of purchases directly to the unemployment rate. There is a version of that
in paragraph 4′ of policy alternative C, and I think it should be considered. Second, MBS
purchases are like some of the recently introduced antidepressive medications. I’ve used this
metaphor in my speeches. They are a very powerful tool; they are a drug that has clear,
immediate benefits. I believe that our actions on that front did have an important benefit of
helping turn that market. But they also have long-term adverse side effects. They are worth
using only in the case of a crisis, which we did, and if you’re desperate, which we were. We
wanted to see a turn in that market. Once you start those medications, it’s dangerous to
prescribe them forever, but it’s also dangerous to stop them too quickly. I’d very much like to
phase out the purchase of both MBS and Treasuries. As in September, I’m willing to weight

October 29–30, 2013

126 of 239

initial tapering moves toward Treasuries, if that would allay concerns about the housing
recovery. That said, my discussions with the homebuilders this last go-round—I did not mention
this in my economic intervention—indicate that mortgage rates are just one factor that is
interrupting the housing recovery and has led to a pause. They cite the most significant factors
as being (a) they priced themselves too aggressively too quickly and (b) there is a shortage of
materials and skilled labor such that now, what used to take 7 months takes 14 months. That
said, the majority at this table may still consider the backup in rates on mortgage-backed
securities to be something that we need to pay special heed to.
With regard to alternatives 1, 2, and 4, potential use of balance sheet actions, like many
others, I don’t favor them. I do think they possibly inhibit price discovery. At least in the case
of 2 and 4, for me, they hint at date-based forward guidance, and I’d like to get away from datebased forward guidance as much as possible. As you were suggesting, President Bullard, you
want to drive a stake through the heart of that concept. But those sound, to me, a little bit too
much like date-based forward guidance. Alternative 3 in that same memo, which is use options
to provide state-contingent forward guidance, may be more appealing because it’s state
contingent. But I think the implementation problems cited in that memo are quite daunting.
As previously mentioned, making liftoff contingent on an inflation floor doesn’t appear
to be an especially promising approach to forward guidance, in my view. I’m not excited about
complicating our communications, to no real purpose. We need to keep in mind that the public’s
time and patience are limited—one of the reasons we want to have less rather than more. Along
that line, I think the public’s patience would not be enhanced by what I consider well-intended
but ill-defined, open-ended, amorphous words like “eventually” and “patient,” such as in
paragraph 6 of policy alternatives A and B. I also have very strong reservations about using

October 29–30, 2013

127 of 239

persistent “headwinds” as a justification for additional post-liftoff policy inertia, as is done in
paragraph 6 of A and B. First of all, I find it implausible that significant headwinds will extend
well into 2016. That’s eight years after the peak of the crisis. To me, that strains credulity. And
regarding a definition, I think the important thing to realize is, the headwinds that we’re facing,
as far as I’m concerned now, stem from fiscal policy, not from financial market strains. These
fiscal headwinds are only very indirectly caused by the financial crisis. We could argue about
that, but I don’t find the term useful.
I suspect that, with regard to funds rate inertia, the reason that increased funds rate inertia
seems to help economic performance in the staff simulations is because it keeps the funds rate
lower for longer in the period after liftoff, partly offsetting a more-restrictive-than-desired
policy-setting in earlier years. If people regard the promise of future extra-easy policy as
credible, it should promote recovery today. The problem with using inertia in this way is that the
amount of future extra stimulus is not linked to the size of the past stimulus shortfall. So if the
recovery suddenly picks up steam, inertia locks you into providing more future stimulus than is
desirable. You may more than offset past policy errors.
With regard to lowering the IOER rate to offset a probably minor economic impact of the
announcement of an unemployment-contingent taper of our asset purchase program, it might
have some benefits. The above-market rate that we are paying banks, based on their excess
reserves, is awkward. And the joint Board–New York Fed memo makes a good case that a
reduction in IOER would not seriously disrupt financial markets. But that said, it seems to be
tinkering at the margin. My bottom line, Mr. Chairman, is that I would suggest lying low, as
President Lacker said, and pausing here and taking a deep breath, not adding more words. But if

October 29–30, 2013

128 of 239

we do anything, it ought to be large. I think tinkering at the margin might just add further
confusion in the marketplace.
I have just a couple of last comments. We’ve talked a lot about LSAPs. We talk about it
constantly. The one thing I never hear at this table, other than dealer expectations, is, what are
the limits? What are the limits? How long do we go? President Lockhart made a very good
point that—I think this is what he said, if I recall that far long ago in the conversation—once we
decide to start dialing back, or putting an end to expansion, we ought to make clear what the path
is going forward. But I’ve yet to hear anybody explicate clearly how far we’re willing to go,
other than getting estimates from the dealers. So I would like, at some point, for someone to
articulate what is the total amount of large-scale asset purchases we’re willing to contemplate.
And then, finally, with regard to communications, I’ve argued this from the very
beginning—future Chair Yellen has heard me say this from the first time we had a
communications meeting—I would strongly advocate that the Chairperson have a press
conference after every single meeting that we have. We can’t just keep adding words to the
statement. There’s a great deal of nuance, and I think only the Chairperson, as primus inter
pares, can explain those nuances.
I hope that was less than 700 words, Mr. Chairman. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t think so. [Laughter] But it is now 6:00. I thank
everyone for some very thoughtful interventions. We start tomorrow morning at 9:00. A
reception and dinner are available.
[Meeting recessed]

October 29–30, 2013

129 of 239

October 30 Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everyone. To start, let me call on David
Lebow to report on data releases.
MR. LEBOW. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. This morning we received the CPI for
September, delayed because of the government shutdown. The CPI was right in line with our
expectations. The total index rose 0.2 percent. Ex. food and energy rose 0.1 percent. So this
ought to have no effect on our inflation projection, or on our translation of yesterday’s retail
sales data. This morning we also received the ADP estimate of payrolls in October. You’ll
remember the employment report was scheduled to be released this coming Friday. It’s been
delayed by a week. The ADP usually comes out two days in advance; the ADP is on its regular
schedule. The ADP showed an increase in private payrolls of 130,000. Our Tealbook estimate
was 135,000, held down 25,000 by some effect of the government shutdown. So the ADP has
limited reliability, but still it was very close to our estimate. So there were no surprises there.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Any questions? [No response.] Okay. Let’s
begin this morning by completing our go-round on policy planning, and I have the Vice
Chairman first up.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I’m glad I’m not going to have to revise my comments
in light of the data. Like others, I think it’s useful, before answering the six questions, to be clear
about the potential problems that we’re trying to address, and I’m going to really focus on the
decision to taper because I think that’s the thing that we’re all wrestling with.
I think it really does matter whether the taper is motivated by success—we’ve achieved
our objectives in terms of substantial improvement in the labor market outlook—or failure—
we’re not tapering because we’ve achieved our objective, but because the costs associated with

October 29–30, 2013

130 of 239

the purchase program are increasing as our balance sheet increases in size. In the former case,
we don’t need to take actions to offset the impacts of the taper as long as the taper does not lead
to a more substantial tightening in financial conditions than we expect. But in the latter case,
where we basically failed to achieve our objectives, we will likely need to take offsetting actions
because we don’t want financial conditions to tighten at all, and the decision to taper is likely to
tighten financial conditions through the signaling channel as we’ve seen earlier in the year. This
suggests to me that, compared with the first case, the policy response needs to be much more
forceful in the second case to offset the undesired tightening.
If the taper is warranted by the economic outlook, the problem will be mainly just trying
to ensure that market participants don’t overreact, and I think this can be accomplished in a
number of ways. It may just require reminding people that the thresholds are not triggers, and
that we’re happy where financial conditions are. We might be forced to respond should financial
conditions tighten. You can imagine if we did the taper because of success, we could just say,
“Look, we are happy with where financial conditions are now. We don’t want the financial
conditions to back up, and if they were to tighten a lot, especially the forward trajectory of shortterm interest rates, we might want to respond to that.” We’d have to do some planning about
what our escalation options would be if financial conditions subsequently tighten, despite our
guidance, but it’s not obvious to me that we’d have to implement such measures at that time.
In contrast, if the taper is motivated by, say, balance sheet size, then I think we have to do
more immediately. And in that case I think taking away the caps on the reverse RP program,
lowering the IOER, strengthening the forward guidance in words, and being prepared to take
actions by market interventions that strengthen the forward guidance may all be necessary to
offset the undesired tightening of financial conditions that’s likely to occur.

October 29–30, 2013

131 of 239

There are these two tracks, but regardless, I think in both cases we need to further
develop the options that are available, and I think the staff memos were very good work on that.
I also think, though, not only should we develop the options, we should also develop escalation
protocols. In other words, what we would do in response to different sets of developments as
things unfolded because we’re not really going to know going in exactly what’s actually going to
happen. So we need to have a plan in terms of how we would escalate it if financial conditions
tighten more than what we think is appropriate.
Turning to the questions, on the first question concerning modifying the forward
guidance, I’m very skeptical that adding an inflation floor, especially, and, to a lesser degree,
lowering the unemployment rate, is the right approach. It seems to me that a better approach is
just to communicate the type of circumstances—such as a low inflation rate or an unemployment
rate drop caused by a decline in participation—that would cause us to be more patient. I think
we should just keep reiterating that the 6½ percent unemployment rate is a threshold, not a
trigger, and communicating those circumstances in which we would wait. I think if we did that, I
don’t think we get much additional benefit by, say, adding an inflation floor, because the number
of instances where the inflation floor would be relevant would be pretty modest in that case.
Also, I think adding an inflation floor has two additional problems. On the one hand, it’s too
simple. An appropriate decisionmaking framework can’t be summarized just by one or two
parameters. On the other hand, it’s too complex. It will be difficult for market participants to
assess the joint probability of the unemployment threshold and the inflation floor and how they
actually intersect. I think market participants would just be very confused trying to solve that
problem.

October 29–30, 2013

132 of 239

Turning to question 2, in terms of targeted interventions, I think of this as very much
analogous to foreign exchange market intervention, so I want to outline sort of a three-stage
approach, and you would go through these stages, escalating as needed. You don’t immediately
go to a full program of intervention with bright lines drawn in the sand. You only do that as it is
necessary. So let me sketch out how this might work.
In stage 1 we make it clear that we do care about the expected path of short-term rates
because this is an important component of financial conditions, and financial conditions are
important because they govern the impulse of monetary policy to the real economy. Thus, we’re
going to be monitoring expectations concerning the short-term rate path closely to see if the
short-term rate path diverges materially from what we think is likely. And we say if there is a
major divergence similar to what we experienced this past summer, we will be prepared to act—
but we don’t specify precisely the way—to push against it because that would be an
inappropriate tightening of financial market conditions and it would conflict with our monetary
policy objectives.
In stage 2, if, despite this threat of intervention, market expectations still move to what
we view as an inappropriate place, then we intervene in modest size as a signaling device to
protest the tightening of financial conditions. I’m open-minded about what the best medium is
for this intervention, but one simple approach would be to buy short-dated Treasury securities—
say with maturities out to 18 months or less—to signal the fact that we’re unhappy with where
short-term interest rate expectations go.
In stage 3, if that signaling is also insufficient to push down short-rate expectations, then
we could move to a more open-ended program or facility to push against the rise in short-term
rates. With respect to how we intervene in that case, I’m open-minded. The staff has put

October 29–30, 2013

133 of 239

forward a number of different suggestions. On the one hand, a Treasury purchase program,
either spot or forward, I think, has the benefit of acting on the market directly. On the other
hand, a term RP program adds, while it’s negative in the sense that it adds an additional
transmission step—you give the money to the dealers and you’re asking the dealers to act on the
market—it does have the advantage that the dealers are free to use the funding however they
want. You’re not just targeting the Treasury market. The money is flowing broadly into the
markets more generally. So I’m not really sure which is the better approach, and I think it would
be good for the staff to sort of work on this a little bit more to sort of suss out which one would
be more effective in generating what we want, which is pushing financial conditions back down
to where we think is appropriate.
With respect to question 3, I would favor exploring the use of the reverse RP facility as a
means of adding additional monetary policy accommodation, in combination with the IOER rate.
So I think removing the caps on the reverse repurchase facility and moving IOER rate down to
10 or 15 basis points when we begin to taper is worth considering. I think this is a case in which
you can justify it whether or not we’ve achieved our objectives with respect to substantial
improvement in the labor market outlook because this might not only add a little bit of
accommodation, but it would also tighten up the relationship among the different money market
rates. So I think it’s good to do for its own sake, independent of whether you’re trying to rein in
financial conditions.
With respect to question 4 regarding the Committee’s guidance regarding the balance
sheet, I don’t favor a mechanical rule at this time. The reason is quite straightforward. I haven’t
seen a rule that accommodates the necessary tradeoff between simplicity, which we need for
communication purposes, versus robustness in terms of changing economic circumstances. So

October 29–30, 2013

134 of 239

it’s really hard to get the balance right. How do you communicate something that’s really simple
but actually works in a wide variety of economic circumstances? I’m just skeptical that we can
do that.
With respect to question 5 on the mix of asset purchases, I think I’m inclined where most
other people are, that maybe I think MBS have a little bit better effect than Treasuries. But I’m
not absolutely certain of the reason for the difference, and if someone asked me to explain why I
think that, I wouldn’t have a very compelling case to make. And the benefit of doing more in
MBS versus having MBS stay higher relative to Treasuries is pretty darn modest. So I think at
the end of the day it’s just not worth the trouble to try to actually do anything that’s less than
proportionate. What you could do is you could make the first step bigger in Treasuries than in
MBS just to equalize the level. Right now we’re 45 and 40. You could go to 40 and 40 or 30
and 30 and then do it proportionately after that, but I just don’t think it’s worth it. The
complexity doesn’t get you much.
With respect to question 6, other ways to improve communications, I think we’ve got to
revisit the SEP process again. We were trying to de-emphasize it. We were trying to move to a
consensus forecast, but we failed. And now the SEP has come back, and it has become very,
very important in the communication process, and we do have some issues with the SEP. Do we
want to identify who the submissions are? I would favor doing that. At a minimum, at least
distinguish between voters and participants. I also think we have the question of the common
monetary policy assumption. We have forecasts that are essentially inconsistent with each other
because everyone uses his or her own monetary policy assumption. If the SEP is really going to
be as important as it seems to be, going forward, I think we need to go back and work on that
some more. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.

October 29–30, 2013

135 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I welcome this opportunity to exchange
views on how best to communicate our policy intentions. As we’ve seen since May, this is a
challenging undertaking. We unfortunately have to recognize that our statements and actions
may induce reactions we didn’t anticipate and find difficult to rationalize. As a general rule, I
think we stand the best chance of avoiding needless and harmful volatility if we aspire to clearly
articulate how our actions and plans serve to achieve the objectives that we’ve laid out in our
consensus statement.
Currently, I think we are not in all that bad a place as far as our communications are
concerned. So perhaps the best we can do at this point is to continue to enunciate the key
principles of our current policy framework, those you noted in your opening comments
yesterday, Mr. Chairman—namely, data dependence, a focus on achieving substantial
improvement in the outlook of the labor market retrospectively and prospectively, and the
Committee’s view that asset purchases are a separate tool from rates policy so that even as we
reduce asset purchases, policy is likely to remain highly accommodative for quite some time. I
think it’s important right now to do no harm by adopting significant changes that might be
confusing or disruptive. Still, things can easily change in the coming months, and this discussion
is valuable for the purpose of prudent planning. I want to thank the staff for an excellent set of
background memos for this discussion.
Turning to the question of how we might render our forward guidance more robust and
effective, I think, first and foremost, we can attempt to clarify aspects of our reaction function
that are currently left largely unspecified in our statement. Specifically, we could explain how
we intend to change the federal funds rate target after a threshold is crossed. In that regard,

October 29–30, 2013

136 of 239

enumerating several indicators that we’ll be looking at after one of our thresholds has been
crossed in deciding when to raise the federal funds rate might be helpful not just in its own right,
but also to cement the message that thresholds are not triggers.
Because of the unprecedented nature of current circumstances, addition of language as in
paragraph B(6) might provide another useful clarification of our reaction function. It provides a
forecast and describes a feature of our reaction function conditional on that forecast. Given the
long string of disappointments pertaining to the pace of recovery, it makes sense to convey that
headwinds, including fiscal policy, will likely serve as drags on economic growth for several
years, even after we’ve begun to raise the funds rate. If so, satisfactory progress toward our
objectives will probably require us to be more patient in removing accommodation than the
historical record from previous recoveries would suggest. I, therefore, think that guidance in this
regard along the lines the Chairman gave in his September press conference and along the lines
of B(6) is helpful.
Equally important, in my view, is the conditionality that’s clearly expressed in the draft
statement language. If, for once, we’re pleasantly surprised and the economy improves more
rapidly than we anticipate, the premise of the statement no longer applies. Even if some of these
clarifications of the reaction function would be valuable, there’s a question as to how they would
best be conveyed. Having them be part of the FOMC statement has the advantage of carrying
the imprimatur of the Committee, but I also recognize that the statement can carry only so much
water.
I agree with the motivation for the inflation floor language. We would be less likely, all
else equal, to raise the funds rate after the unemployment rate threshold has been crossed, if
inflation is running well below our 2 percent objective. What gives me pause about the

October 29–30, 2013

137 of 239

suggested language is that it is missing an “all else equal” qualifier. The inflation floor language
that is contemplated is unconditional. This would, in my view, carry a risk of committing us to a
course we might come to regret. Moreover, I’m not so clear on the benefits. I think we can quite
plausibly assert that if there’s slack in the economy and inflation is weak, removing
accommodation would be counter to accomplishing our objectives. But I wholeheartedly agree
with the view that we must be every bit as vigilant in defending our inflation objective from
below as above.
The targeted market interventions discussed in the staff memo might send a powerful
signal of our commitment to accommodation and to our forward guidance. But they are also
associated with some risks and complications that were well described in the staff memo. I think
we should leave such interventions on the table as options to be considered in the future, likely in
extraordinary circumstances.
Concerning simple rules for the pace of our asset purchases, I think this is an idea that has
its heart in the right place. It would be helpful to be able to communicate a simple rule that
reduces purchases smoothly to zero as the labor market improves but, as the staff memo
highlights, it is difficult to specify a rule that is simple and yet still reliably promotes our
objectives across a broad range of plausible scenarios. I favor using simple rules as guideposts,
however, in our internal discussions, and I am also open to exploring whether there are rules that
strike a better point on the tradeoff between use of communication and reliability in achieving
our economic objectives.
Finally, on MBS and Treasuries, on balance, I think it’s best to keep things simple and
reduce them in tandem.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.

October 29–30, 2013

138 of 239

MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like many of you, I wanted to make a few
overall comments before getting to the specific issues.
I thought, listening to the interventions yesterday, all of them were necessarily a mix of
expressions of substantive policy preference or orientation with tactical issues of communication
that were raised in the questions for discussion. I’m going to try—maybe not succeed—to make
my comments weighted more toward the tactical. That is, I’m going to try to hypothesize
substantive positions the Committee might take and then suggest how those decisions can best be
executed. A second introductory point is that a number of people yesterday expressed that a
sense of simplicity should be a key criterion in deciding on how to communicate Committee
intentions. I think it’s always difficult to argue against simplicity. The only point I’d make is
that simplicity may not exist in a vacuum. That is, adopting a simple rule right now with respect
to asset purchases or forward guidance, for example, coming on top of everything we’ve done
and said before, might actually make things more complex, certainly in communication, rather
than truly simplify the policy decisions. And, third, a point made by a number of people
yesterday with which I strongly associate myself is that we need to be more straightforward in
explaining what factors are relevant in our decisions, particularly on LSAPs. And I’ll say more
about that in a minute.
By and large, I thought the questions that were circulated raised two broad sets of issues
on communication. The first is how we might deal with problems associated with market
expectations around our forward guidance. What people commented on, in particular, is that
recently markets seem to think that we’ve got a single reaction function, notwithstanding the fact
that we think we have two policy instruments and two reaction functions. And, the second, as

October 29–30, 2013

139 of 239

many people have already addressed, are the issues generally around communication with our
LSAP policy.
It seems to me that the LSAP issues raise more-immediate problems for us than the
forward guidance, but let me address the forward guidance issues for a few minutes. For all the
bumps that we encountered in getting there, I think we are now at a place where market
expectations of when the first increase in the federal funds rate will take place are reasonably
close to those of the Committee. It is true, somewhat ironically, that this convergence may be a
consequence of the very assumption of a single reaction function that originally led to the
divergence between market expectations and the SEP. So markets may have come to the right
conclusion for what we might not consider quite the right reason, but, first, as Narayana and Jim
noted yesterday, maybe we are a little closer to having a single reaction function than we have
been telling ourselves. And, second, even if that’s not the case, if markets have reached the right
conclusion, the impact on financial conditions shouldn’t be too different from what we would
want, notwithstanding how they reach that conclusion.
Of course, depending on what we do over the next several meetings, we could face
renewed divergence. If so we may need to take some additional steps on communication as
suggested in the various memos that have been circulated. But for now I don’t think there is
actually a need to do very much. Moreover, as several people suggested yesterday, if we are
principally worried that a tapering decision may pull forward the assumed date of a first federal
funds rate increase, there may be some merit to holding whatever tools we decide we do prefer
and deploying them at the time we are communicating the tapering decision, so as hopefully to
offset at least some of what might be a strong market reaction. I think Bill already touched on
this point, but I was also going to say that because we can’t really foresee with precision right

October 29–30, 2013

140 of 239

now how significant this potential divergence might be and why exactly it may reoccur, we
should probably be somewhat provisional in expressing views on the policy instruments in the
staff memos and mentioned in the questions prior to the meeting. So my prior is to keep most
things on the table. But, like many of you, I will try to suggest some leanings at least.
I think it does seem like it would be an unqualifiably good idea to offer qualitative
guidance as to how we will proceed after the unemployment threshold is passed. My current
thought is it would be useful to do this at the time we begin tapering, although that may be
subject to more consideration. And I’d do this even if we didn’t think there was at that time a
particular divergence between market views and our intentions. It just seems like a sensible
thing to do. For reasons that Charlie Evans, yesterday, and Bill and Janet both, this morning,
have already said, I wouldn’t be inclined to use the inflation floor, although, again, I don’t think
we need to reject it out of hand right now. Principally, without repeating everything they said, I
think this idea may be one of those that at best doesn’t buy us too much but does carry some
nontrivial risk of confusion.
Next, as I’ve said before, I might well have supported a lower unemployment threshold at
the outset for the forward guidance. Since then, I haven’t thought it would be a good idea to
change it, in large part because of concerns about what this would suggest about the durability of
our forward guidance or other statements of intentions the Committee may choose to
communicate in the future. So I go in with some presumption against it. But, again, if we face a
situation in which there has been a much stronger reaction against the tapering, say, than we had
anticipated, it may be that the balance of costs and benefits of the use of the change of an
unemployment threshold might be warranted.

October 29–30, 2013

141 of 239

The idea of using targeted market interventions to enforce the forward rate guidance has
some appeal, but a lot of the reservations expressed yesterday resonated with me. It seems it
would have to be a reasonably big problem with market expectations before we would want to
undertake something like this. There is clearly a potential for difficult communications
challenges; we’d have to describe how this relates to the LSAPs. And as the staff memo itself
clearly showed, we need more work before we could feel comfortable embracing one or more of
the variants as a tool that was actually ready for use.
Moving now to communication around our tapering intentions, this seems to me both a
more immediate and a more difficult problem. It’s more immediate not only because it is likely
driving, to a significant degree, expectations around the federal funds rate, but also because our
decision not to taper in September has dramatically changed market expectations as to when the
first taper might occur. I didn’t really hear much about this, and I want to be clear that I’m
hypothesizing rather than advocating. But if the Committee has any thought that it might want to
taper in December or January, we would need to begin publicly laying the groundwork for such a
possible move pretty quickly. I think it’s a more difficult problem for the reasons I have noted
before and that several people have alluded to yesterday. That is, there were different
expectations around this LSAP program among Committee members who voted for it right from
the outset in September of 2012, whereas our statement was understandably read as reflecting a
fairly unified and fairly forward-leaning approach. Since then I think we have collectively
struggled to translate these differences, some of which are around efficacy and cost issues that
have never been too explicitly discussed publicly, into the terms of our public statement, which
is to say “until the outlook for labor market improves substantially.” So I think it’s almost
inevitable that there has been some confusion or uncertainty in the public because the

October 29–30, 2013

142 of 239

considerations that members of the Committee have privately are not being discussed explicitly
publicly, and, thus, as the public looks just at substantial improvement, I think they’re a little
confused as to why we at times seem to be leaning taper and at other times leaning against taper.
Our September decision was quite naturally read by markets as signaling that the
Committee needed to see a good bit more improvement than it had—in labor market conditions,
that is—which is probably interpreted as either a good bit more cumulative improvement, which
could take some time, or some pretty noticeable improvement in current performance. So now,
in the absence of significantly better current labor market performance over the next several
months, market expectations for tapering are going to be low, and I suspect that in the absence of
at least moderate improvement in indicators like job creation, even into next year markets will
not be able to discern a likely tapering point. This is the dilemma that Jay and others have been
highlighting for some time, and that many people have already restated in the go-round today. If
we want to preserve the option of tapering at the next two meetings, we will need to begin
preparing markets in a way that doesn’t get us onto a fixed time track. And, again, I’m not
advocating this; I’m just hypothesizing it. And, again, assuming that the center of gravity in the
Committee will be for tapering at some point, even in the absence of the significant current labor
market performance improvement that we all hope for, we need to begin preparing a plan B,
even if we’re not inclined to move in December or January.
The staff memo of October 22 presents one plan B option, which is for a more or less
mechanical trigger for reducing purchases. And, again, I associate myself with many of you who
have said that while the approach has some attraction, in that it would certainly shape market
expectations pretty precisely—which would be a particular point in its favor for those who have
concluded that cost and efficacy considerations already argue for change—it would basically tie

October 29–30, 2013

143 of 239

us to the mast. And it would thereby counteract the possible siren song of bad data that might
cause us to change course. But I’ve thought that much of what we’ve been trying to
communicate about the LSAP program is that we don’t have a simplistic reaction function, and
we have basically actually succeeded in that. So at the risk of overplaying my Homeric allusion,
I fear that tying ourselves to the mast would seem very odd for a Committee that has emphasized
how cognizant we are of steering around whatever rocks and crags we see in front of us. It
would be a change of course or approach that would, I suspect, leave a lot of people confused as
to what our broader policies actually are.
My instinct is that a plan B should instead be centered around a communication strategy
that gradually but steadily changes assumptions around our reaction function, and, thus, over a
period of somewhere between several weeks and a few months shapes market expectations as to
when a decision to taper may be made by reference to the factors that are actually influencing
that decision. I’m not going to try, obviously, to lay out a precise strategy for doing so, but it
seems pretty clear—and, again, I think this reflects much of what many of you have said—that
there would be two elements. One would be the reinforcement of a sense that the Committee has
been focusing on cumulative improvement in labor market conditions since September 2012. A
second critical element would be reference to the evolving calculus of some Committee members
as to costs and benefits as conditions continue their gradual improvement and as the balance
sheet grows. This straightforward acknowledgement of what would actually be driving a
tapering decision might entail a little short-term credibility loss, because the public would be
wondering why we haven’t been emphasizing that more all along. But I think it’s the best way
out of what otherwise will be continued verbal gymnastics that will leave people a bit mystified,
and, thus, in the medium term I think we enhance our credibility by taking that approach.

October 29–30, 2013

144 of 239

Tapering that is publicly justified as based principally on improvement, even on
cumulative improvement, would either confuse people or, as Narayana and Charlie explained
yesterday, damage our credibility. So I would say, again, one possibility might be to have the
first public comments focused on the substantial improvement idea, which would refer back to
the Chairman’s June statements, but in the current environment I think even the restatement of
that position would be noticed. And then, sometime later there could be public reference to the
evolving calculus of costs and benefits point, which would rightly be read as signaling something
significant about where the Committee was headed. In some sense, I am agreeing with what I
think Jeff said yesterday, which is when we think we are getting close, as a Committee, to
deciding to do it, we should probably just do it. And we should probably just lay the foundation
for doing it. Just to be straightforward about this, I think to be effective this strategy would have
to be executed dominantly by some combination of the Chairman and the Vice Chair of the
Board and the Vice Chairman of the Committee. And, ideally, the rest of us would refrain from
commenting very much during the period in question other than to echo what they had already
said.
In passing, I want to mention that the idea of just trying to get to a point and then doing it
was reflected in what Charlie Plosser said yesterday when he suggested the merits of announcing
a fixed amount of the remaining LSAP, an idea that seems pretty good in light of our experience
over the past year. Others didn’t take up this theme, but if there were interest in doing so, one
could still follow the gradual communication of a different approach, as I have suggested,
hopefully inducing some shifting of market expectations, followed by a meeting at which we
announced a fixed remaining amount of purchases instead of a tapering.

October 29–30, 2013

145 of 239

My views on IOER and the mix of asset purchase reductions are decidedly secondary to
what I think are our key tactical questions, the ones that I have just addressed. So I will say only
that I would keep IOER under consideration as a possible additional measure, quite apart from
these two sets of communication issues. On the mix and tapering, I think I am very much where
Bill is, which is I feel myself leaning weakly toward tapering Treasuries first, but I don’t have a
strong analytic reason for doing so. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Stein.
MR. STEIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. To restate the two premises of the exercise,
first, we want to minimize the potential for unintended tightening when we do begin to taper.
And, second, it seems to be that the market sees asset purchases as linked with our intended path
for the short rate. So any move toward tapering seems to have a powerful signal value above and
beyond any direct duration removal effects. That’s the concern.
So how to proceed? Basically, I think there are sort of three broad options. Option
number 1 would be to continue, as we effectively did in September, to more or less embrace the
fact that the two policies are linked in the eyes of the market, which means that if you’re willing
to continue on buying at $85 billion a month you can maintain the credibility of the program. As
a number of people said, that’s effectively what we did, and it got us to, in some sense, a good
place in effect, even if you don’t like the linking. It is kind of weird. It is arbitrary that $85
billion is what you need to do. But it’s the signaling technology we’ve got, so maybe you might
just want to use it. In that case, you would basically continue on; you wouldn’t taper until you
really got to the place you wanted to get to—a run of decisive good news or an upshift in the
pace of economic growth. To be clear, I think this option is completely coherent, and it’s in
some sense the leading option if you think there are not costs of expanding the balance sheet. So

October 29–30, 2013

146 of 239

if you want to push back against this option, as at least some of us instinctively want to do, we
need to have a theory of the cost side. And I think it’s important not to overstate the argument
here, because it’s pretty slippery.
Part of the problem is not just that we have been unwilling to talk publicly about cost, it’s
that we don’t fully have a shared understanding of the cost, and so that makes it harder to talk
about it. So let me just say a few words here. I want to be clear. I wouldn’t want to claim that I
know with any degree of confidence that there are going to be big costs, especially now. I mean,
I felt a little bit differently when we were buying bonds when the 10-year rate was at 1.5,
because I thought we were like overpaying pretty blatantly for the bonds. But that’s not true
anymore. I think we have learned that market function is not a problem, or is not really sort of a
first-order problem. I think you can’t hang it on that. I don’t think you can hang it on financial
stability issues in a sort of generic way. A very important point—it’s not to say that financial
stability is not important, but financial stability does not drive an obvious wedge between asset
purchases and lower for longer. To be sure, you can make fancy second-order theories, but to
first order both of those have financial stability issues, so you can’t say that the one is a
motivation for the other.
I think Narayana hit it exactly right, which is if you want to articulate a theory of cost, it
is not going to be an easily observable thing. It’s going to be some kind of a risk-management
case. You have in mind—and I guess those of us who think this way must have in mind—some
really unpleasant low probability event. And you can think of various possible events. One
would be: You’ve got a $5 trillion portfolio, and you get a $200 billion spike in the long rate.
On a mark-to-market basis, that’s a $500 billion or $600 billion swing in your mark to market.
It’s not in remittances, but who knows what forces get put into play. Somebody starts blogging

October 29–30, 2013

147 of 239

about it, Rand Paul gets ahold of it, and all kinds of stuff starts happening. Maybe it’s just flack
that we can bear, but there is sort of a low probability risk that there is enough flack and the
market starts thinking, “Oh my gosh, they’re going to have to sell out of this position to reduce
the flack.” Then it has a real effect, which is that you start having trouble with the long run. I
wouldn’t want to attach a probability to this scenario, but I think that if you are worrying about
this stuff it’s this kind of thing. And I’m fully aware that it feels unsatisfying and undisciplined
to offer a theory that’s empirically irrefutable, which doesn’t mean it’s wrong, but it’s sort of
something we can’t get access to. I think underlying a lot of this stuff is a discomfort with
making a case based on something like this, as opposed to market-function types of costs, which
we can see and try to measure. So I think that just goes into the mix.
The second option would be to try to enhance the numerical hard commitment aspects of
the forward guidance as a substitute for the signaling effect of the LSAPs—lowering the
threshold to 6.0. I’m reluctant to go this route. I think others have expressed the issues well. I
want to add one point, which is that if you haven’t really been clear on the costs of expanding the
balance sheet, doing this doesn’t really solve your problem. In other words, if you haven’t been
clear on the cost premise, as everybody has noted, it really should be the case that when you cut
LSAPs, people say, “Gee, I wonder what these guys are thinking about.” Therefore it should call
into question your forward guidance. Well, if you have called into question your attachment to
6.5, saying, “Well, I’ll do a more extreme thing; I’ll do 6.0” will not be more credible. That by
itself is not a complete argument against the thresholds. It’s just saying there is a credibility
issue that has to be addressed. And until that is addressed, just doing more of the thresholds is
not a solution.

October 29–30, 2013

148 of 239

Option 3 is to try to do the delinking explicitly. I think there are three components to
trying to do the delinking. First is, just to repeat, we have to be kind of clear on the cost aspect.
Second, I do think it will be helpful to have further elaboration of the forward guidance. But,
again, as many have suggested, not via numerical commitments but with a fuller explanation of
essentially the logic behind the dots being at 2 percent in 2016—a fuller development of the
headwinds theory. Here it’s important to emphasize the time consistency aspects of the
headwinds theory as opposed to the idea of making a promise that you might later regret. In this
vein, I am quite sympathetic to the sort of thing that is going on in paragraph 6 of alt-B, although
I would prefer to wait and couple this with the taper. And, third, I do think that there is some
virtue to some kind of an autopilot aspect to LSAPs, but let me qualify that in two ways. One, I
don’t think going autopilot spares you the hit the first time. I mean, you are going to have this
hit, and you are going to have to deal with it. The only hope is that it spares you a repeated hit.
In other words, if you have a discretionary step-down, each time there is potentially some
element of signaling. You can’t get away from the fact that the first one is news, but you may
hope to get away from having to revisit it three or four more times.
Now, what kind of a rule? It’s clear from listening to the discussion that I think this idea
that I floated of an unemployment-linked rule is not great, and it certainly violates the “simpler is
better” dictum. And people analogized it to something like the Taylor rule. Well, you’re trying
to link to outcomes, and then when you start trying to analogize it to a Taylor rule, you see all of
the obvious shortcomings, right? It is linked to outcomes, but it is linked to outcomes in a way
that is not really all that good. I think the intent—at least my intent—in this was very, very
different than what you would have with a Taylor rule. In other words, the intent was not to
calibrate policy to the state of the world on an ongoing basis. It’s an exit strategy. It’s just one

October 29–30, 2013

149 of 239

exit in kind of a clean and orderly way. Of course the right way to do this, the much simpler
way, would be, when we finally get there, to do it in a calendar-based way. Here we are, we’re
making the first taper, and the rest will come $10 billion a month or whatever.
Now, why we have not done that in the first place is just because that would look like a
walk-back of the data-dependent principle. So I guess I was trying to finesse it a little bit and
say, “Well, we can still have data-dependence with an unemployment rule,” in some second-best
way of still having predictability. But, listening to the conversation, that doesn’t seem to strike
the right balance. I would move back to the position that either one does a mechanical, calendarbased step-down, or you abandon it and go with discretion. I think that at least gives you a
cleaner choice to make between those two. Again, I would prefer when we finally get there to do
it calendar-based, so we don’t have to revisit things at every meeting.
On the balance sheet actions, buying Treasury bills and such, a couple of observations:
First, I think if what we really are worried about is the detaching of the very short end of the
yield curve, the December 2014 forward rate coming up, I think that particular problem is going
to solve itself just by the passage of time. That is to say, if realistically we are not going to start
thinking about tapering until March, there is a mechanical effect, which is that it’s going to take
several months to happen, and after that everybody is going to assume it’s going to be at least
another six months until we lift off. So if we’re not tapering until March, I am pretty certain we
are not going to have to worry about the December 2014 rate pulling up on us. That’s not to say
there’s not going to be all kinds of other signaling issues about the post-threshold path, but I
think that is going to be where the action is. But that we’re not going to keep the rate low to
6.5 percent is not going to be a big issue for us going forward. It is going to be what we do
afterwards; that is going to be a little harder to solve with these balance sheet measures. And,

October 29–30, 2013

150 of 239

second, just echoing what others have said, I think if we are looking to do something that is
effectively taking the sting out of tapering LSAPs, and our whole story is we don’t like to expand
the balance sheet, doing something else which expands the balance sheet in a different way is I
think, at a minimum, hard to explain.
Finally, on IOER, I am very open-minded about this. Again, I would just sort of subject
it to the “simpler is better” test. I think if we can find a way to use a reduction in IOER as a
complement to a package, I would certainly be okay with it. I don’t think that there is a big
positive kick to be had, but now that we have the RRP facility I also think we really can probably
manage it in a reasonable way. Again, I think the test is whether it sort of helps us communicate
that. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. These are my general preferences for this
meeting. Do nothing to materially modify the forward guidance. Make decisions about
strengthening guidance only at the time of the first taper. By the time the Committee does decide
to taper, the situation may well have changed since last summer, and it may be that no
strengthening of the forward guidance will be required. If the Committee judges that
strengthening is required, take a minimalist approach. Adopt only those measures that have
combined high expected efficacy and low expected cost. Finally, there are also costs to
modifying or adding gadgets to the thresholds, and I think the bar should be set high for doing
so. Others have mentioned them under the heading of “Complexity, Confusion, and Credibility.”
So that’s my executive summary, and I will resist the temptation to stop there.
Like others, I also found it impossible to think about the various tactical options without
setting them in the context of the current situation or the longer-term strategy question the

October 29–30, 2013

151 of 239

Committee may face. So I’m going to give my understanding of the current situation and the
practical choices that the Committee faces, and then talk about the tactical options, and I’m
going to leave the longer-term strategy question to the next round.
Since the September meeting, market participants have come together around the view
that the Committee is very unlikely to taper before the March meeting. The shutdown and the
debt ceiling standoff have become particularly important in the market’s assessment of the
Committee’s thinking in September. As a result, in my view, it will be difficult for the
Committee to taper in December or January unless three conditions are met. First, the
employment and other data are going to have to be very strong. Second, the core members of the
FOMC leadership—the Chairman, the Vice Chairman, and Governor/Nominee Yellen—will
have to signal credibly, well in advance, that December and January are very much on the table,
and the market would have to believe them. Scheduling a January press conference in the
immediate aftermath of this meeting would be a start. And, third, the ongoing fiscal negotiations
will have to look like they are on track to avoid another disruptive confrontation. Now, it is
possible, but not likely, to me that these conditions will be fulfilled at the time of the December
or January meetings. In my view, it is equally possible that they will not yet be fulfilled at the
time of the March meeting. In any case, if they are not fulfilled at the time of the December or
January meetings, the market will not expect a taper and the Committee will not, and probably
should not, choose to deliver a major hawkish surprise by tapering, given the risk of an openended tightening in financial conditions.
Another consequence of this state of affairs is that market participants now see a period
of four or five months, and maybe much longer, in which there is a very low probability of taper.
That means another extended period of suppressed volatility during which it is again safe to

October 29–30, 2013

152 of 239

reach for yield and use leverage, and we are starting to see that in the fund flows. A lot of it
we’re not going to see because of the lack of real-time visibility into what various categories of
investors are doing. It is likely there will be a significant buildup of risks as investors try to
make some money while the coast is clear of tapering threats, after many of them lost money
over the summer. So when the Committee does taper, there may, again, be a significant reaction
as investors unwind speculative trades.
Turning to forward guidance, market-based estimates of forward rate policy are now well
aligned with the September SEP. So I take the point of considering modification to forward
guidance to be that when the Committee tapers asset purchases it wants to discourage the market
from drawing any hawkish inferences about the Committee’s reaction function for the path of the
federal funds rate as seems to have happened over the summer. But the passage of time may
have alleviated this problem, as Governor Stein was saying. The statement says that a “highly
accommodative stance of monetary policy will remain appropriate for a considerable period of
time after the asset purchase program ends and the recovery strengthens.” Let’s say the
Committee chooses to taper in March 2014. Purchases would likely end around the end of 2014.
Under the staff baseline, the unemployment threshold would be passed at just about exactly the
same time, and there would then follow a considerable period of rates continuing at the zero
lower bound, with liftoff in late 2015. Now, the Chair and the Committee would no doubt
strongly emphasize that language at the time of taper, and as the threshold approaches. The
language in alternative A that President Williams referred to in his comments during this round
yesterday suggests consideration of a range of factors might be appropriate at that time. But the
point is that what was a problem in the summer of 2013 may not be a problem in March or June
of 2014, given the passage of time and progress toward the unemployment threshold. The

October 29–30, 2013

153 of 239

metaphor that you hear from market participants is that tapering and raising the funds rate are
like two different cars in a train. They are separated temporally, but they are connected. So that
is a good metaphor, but then at a certain point the train arrives in the station, and that is kind of
what is happening at the end of 2014 when we hit the threshold. So there’s your metaphor. I just
would emphasize that it is very possible that we will get to the point of actually tapering and
realize that we don’t need to strengthen the guidance, that in fact it is going to hold.
Turning to the questions, the inflation floor makes good policy sense to me, but it seems
to fail the efficacy test. I just don’t see that it will have much effect today in a world where no
one expects higher inflation. As far as stating that we will move very patiently, the language at
the end of B(6), I don’t see this as a material modification of the guidance. It really amounts to
including in the statement what the September SEP, the market, and the Chairman’s press
conference language from September have already agreed upon for the time being. In that sense
I’m not sure that it accomplishes much. I wouldn’t do it at this meeting. I don’t see a reason
particularly not to do it, though, down the road. I wouldn’t do it at this meeting because of the
lack of a press conference. In addition, once the Committee does taper, the cost-benefit test in
the statement regarding asset purchases kind of loses its meaning. And as we move to greater
reliance on rate policy, I think we need to have some kind of a test of that nature with respect to
rate policy. In particular, I think we need a more robust knockout for financial stability in
connection with low rates. We know that long periods of suppressed volatility can lead to the
buildup of risks and to a disruptive ending, and the idea that monetary policy can ignore that and
leave it to macroprudential tools just is not credible to me. I think we should follow the Bank of
England and be more straightforward about this, with some kind of a financial stability knockout,

October 29–30, 2013

154 of 239

if we are going to promise to hold rates low for a very long period, and we are. I’ve got no
appetite for lowering the unemployment threshold. Others have covered that very well.
As far as targeted market interventions are concerned, I do see this as worthy of further
analysis. And I liked Vice Chairman Dudley’s analysis of how to go about that. If the
Committee were to taper in March, and the Committee were to announce, say, alternative 3,
which is the overnight repo option—the idea would be to cap short-term rates until the
unemployment threshold is reached—I doubt that longer-term rates would disconnect in the face
of that kind of a strong signal. I guess the idea is that it is such a strong signal it is akin to what
the ECB did with OMTs in the summer of 2012. In the face of such a strong signal, it may not
be necessary to actually do much. And I pick option 3 because I see the problems with having a
calendar-based balance sheet program interact with data-based thresholds as not manageable. So
I suggest further work on those.
As far as IOER is concerned, I don’t see a big problem with this, but I see it as a small
thing. I think we have to get a couple of very big things right and should put aside tinkering with
smaller things and do things that really matter.
As far as LSAP rules are concerned, this is something I have struggled with since the
beginning of this program, and it would be a great thing to have, without question. On the other
hand, we see that it’s not difficult to show that any mechanical rule can deliver a false positive or
negative, which makes it a very difficult quest. There may be something in returning to a
calendar-based rule. Conditional on actually having decided to taper, it may be that calendarbased is the right way to go.
In terms of the sequence, I find myself coming around to the view that we ought to taper
Treasury securities right down to the ground and then taper MBS. And the reason is that this

October 29–30, 2013

155 of 239

recovery is hugely about housing. We can see that when consumer confidence is high,
consumers say it’s because of the housing market and increasing housing values. We have seen
a significant falloff in that as the housing market has slowed down. Broader financial conditions
have not particularly been affected by the events of last summer. I would taper Treasuries all the
way to the ground and then do MBS.
In terms of other improvements, I would say, please, no. That’s question 6. Let’s resist
the temptation to tinker. Less is more. Let’s get the two or three big things right. And I will
discuss the strategic issues in the next round. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. This has been extremely useful.
We have some very complicated communications and policy decisions to make, and people have
put a lot of effort into thinking about it, and I do appreciate it. Certainly we’re going to spend a
lot of time looking at it.
I think that I can take a few conclusions from the discussion. Obviously there is the point
about keeping it simple. That’s not always feasible, but to the extent that it is feasible, there
clearly is the sense that we need to focus on the strategy and then support the strategy with
communication and whatever other steps are necessary. I sense the general openness to
modifying the forward guidance on rates. We will need to review those comments. They were
somewhat diverse. One question is whether any modification should take place at the same time
or before our first reduction in asset purchases. I think that’s a tactical question that needs more
thought.
Another thought, which I found interesting, is that rather than trying to provide more
numerical guideposts, a fuller, more comprehensive description in qualitative terms of what we’ll
be looking at and what we’ll be considering as we make these decisions going forward—not just

October 29–30, 2013

156 of 239

the thresholds, but beyond the thresholds in the longer term—could be useful. There are
opportunities to do that, of course. I don’t know if Governor Yellen would choose to, but she’ll
have a number of opportunities to speak in the next month or so. I’ve got a few speeches.
There’s a press conference, as I mentioned. It could be that it would pay to go a bit beyond the
terse descriptions of the forward guidance in the statement and perhaps, with some consultation,
try to provide a little richer description that would capture the flavor of the inflation floor, for
example, without necessarily putting a number on it. So that’s something that’s worth thinking
about.
We had a preliminary discussion of market interventions, mechanical rules, et cetera. As
I said at the beginning, we really haven’t discussed these at length before and I don’t think we
should rule anything out based on discussions we had. But I did gather that people don’t view
market interventions, for example, as a first resort. It’s something that we should keep on the
back burner for a while, but I can imagine circumstances where we might find it worth talking
about further. With respect to mechanical rules, a number of people—again, there was not a lot
of support at this point—introduced the possibility of alternatives like a fixed amount or a fixed
calendar schedule. So on market intervention and mechanical rules, I think it was a useful first
discussion and an informative one. These are obviously not first resorts, but I think we should
not completely abandon them at this point.
There was a lot of interesting discussion of IOER, and the idea of reducing IOER and
perhaps the target range supported by the reverse repo facility got a reasonable amount of
support around the table. The Vice Chairman gave one rationale for doing it now. Another
rationale is just the fact that we have reverse repo facility now. We haven’t had it before, and
that would allow us to combine the two to have a tighter range on the funds rate. But I also agree

October 29–30, 2013

157 of 239

with Governor Powell, for example, that this is not a first-order measure. We need to think about
it in the context of signaling and what would be the appropriate time to take that step.
Just parenthetically, on MBS versus Treasuries, most people were relatively indifferent. I
didn’t hear too many people with extremely strong views on this. To the extent that there was a
bias, there were more people, I think, who favored reducing Treasury securities first in order to
signal additional support for the mortgage market.
Now, I think a very important general point that President Kocherlakota, Governor
Tarullo, and a number of other people made, was that if we’re going to rationalize slowing asset
purchases at a point before the substantial improvement criteria are met, we need to begin to talk
more about the efficacy and costs, and I would say particularly the costs because efficacy, at
least to a signaling channel, was pretty clear. So I think it’s the costs that we need to talk about.
In fairness, I’ve talked about the costs in numerous speeches and testimony and press
conferences. It’s not the case that we haven’t talked about them, but it is true that we need to
have a clearer sense of how the Committee is thinking about these costs and to what extent they
will affect our decisions on the margin.
I have a suggestion here. I think one problem is that we don’t really have a clear sense of
what people consider to be the most important costs and how much weight they put to them.
What I’d like to propose—and let me ask you about survey design in a just a minute—is to
circulate a little survey, get your answers back in a week, and based on that—and we’ll circulate
the results to everybody—just get a sense of where people are in terms of what they think the
most important costs are, and that will help us in our communication. No reason for us to
emphasize market functioning, for example, if nobody really thinks that market functioning is a
determinative factor.

October 29–30, 2013

158 of 239

Let me just briefly discuss the survey design here. I’ve heard five different costs
mentioned at various times: market functioning, inflation risk, capital losses to the Fed, financial
stability, and a fifth one, which we could call technical difficulties—for example, managing
interest rates on exit, that kind of thing. Those are some costs, and we could certainly ask people
to rank those, to give an assessment of how important they think they are. In particular, are any
of these costs ones that would—either on their own or in conjunction with other factors—be a
reason to stop asset purchases before we’ve achieved the macro objectives? I’d be very
interested to hear views on that. So why don’t I ask the staff to put together a little survey to do
that. Is that okay with everybody? Are there any suggestions? I think it would be very useful to
understand what the main concerns are, and then we can talk about them both substantively in
the Committee as well as in our communications. There’s also the question that Governor
Powell raised, by the way, which we should probably add to the survey, which is: To the extent
that you see costs of QE, are these costs the result of QE differentially relative to lower interest
rates? And to what extent should we make that distinction?
If we’re able to do that, I’ll go back and, as President Kocherlakota suggested, I’ll revise
my communication suggestion I made at the beginning of the meeting, and that Governor Yellen
repeated a moment ago. First, we should note our data dependence, and I’ve used the terms
“deliberate” and “data-dependent,” that we are looking at the data and at the outlook. Second,
our macroeconomic criterion relates to gains in the labor market outlook. Here I think it is worth
emphasizing that retrospectively there has been meaningful improvement. It really is more than
we expected when we began the program, and it has been, I think, significant. And one of the
points that came up in our meeting yesterday was that it has happened in the face of fiscal policy,
which is not only not helping but is actively working to slow economic growth. This, by the

October 29–30, 2013

159 of 239

way, is a point that’s not fully appreciated as the distinction between what’s happening here and
what’s happening in Japan. In Japan there is a real collaborative effort going on. Here the
Federal Reserve is bearing more than 100 percent of the burden, and that, I think, does affect
what we’re able to do, and that should be taken into account. I would modify my third point.
Remember, my third point was that even if we slow our asset purchases, we intend to maintain
highly accommodative policy. I would modify it by saying that we’re continuing to review the
efficacy and costs of asset purchases and that may lead us, at some point, to change the mix of
tools. However, it is our intent to provide as much accommodation as needed to achieve our
mandated objectives, and we believe that we can do that.
Thank you for this very useful discussion. It’s been a little bit of a bumpy ride for a
while, and I bear more than one-nineteenth responsibility for that. I thank you for your
tolerance. We’re trying to deal with a very complex situation where, on the one hand, we are
dealing with unfamiliar tools in an adverse environment in many ways, and nevertheless we’re
doing the best we can to try to achieve a better economic outcome, which of course is what we
all want.
So those are some observations on this go-round. We have another one in a moment, but
let me just stop and ask if there are any other comments, questions, or summary points that
anyone would like to make at this juncture. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think it’s really beneficial to have so much
discussion of what our communications strategy is. I noticed yesterday and today that in your
second point you mentioned the labor market outlook, and essentially didn’t reference a pickup
in GDP growth. Is that deliberate? Are we sort of walking back from a pickup in growth?

October 29–30, 2013

160 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. The way I think about what was intended by that and what I
think is sufficient for our purposes is—remember that our original thing is of course outlook for
labor market—what GDP growth does is it provides the reason for thinking that labor market
improvement will continue. The way I have phrased it is not that we’re looking for increased
GDP growth per se, but we’re looking for sufficient growth to support continuing gains in the
labor market. So it’s sort of tautological, and it’s not an additional criterion. It’s just saying that
the economy has to be strong enough. We have seen improvement, but because we’re looking at
the outlook for labor market, we also have to have some confidence that the economy is strong
enough to support ongoing gains, and that’s all. It doesn’t mean that GDP growth has to go to
3 percent. In particular, in the scenario that you talked about with low productivity gains,
2 percent growth might be quite adequate to continue progress and would meet our criterion, I
think.
MR. LACKER. Okay. Well, there have been times in the past year when what came
across to the public and what was reported was that a pickup in growth was sort of an additional
criterion. So I think we should be dissuading people from interpreting that as a broad concern
that we’re looking for a big pickup in the economy.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We’re looking for growth sufficient to ensure additional
gains, ongoing gains in the labor market. In other words, it wouldn’t be enough to say we’ve
achieved a lot so far, but suddenly growth has gone off the cliff and there’s no prospect of further
gains. That wouldn’t really be an improvement in the outlook for the labor market.
MR. LACKER. Well, but then the labor market wouldn’t be gaining. Is there a timing
thing here? Are you thinking of GDP as sort of a leading indicator of the labor market?

October 29–30, 2013

161 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. This goes back to discussions we’ve had. What does it
mean to say that we’re interested in the outlook for the labor market? Clearly, as we’ve said on
numerous occasions, if you’re looking at the outlook for the labor market, you really do have to
look at the broad economic outlook because it’s overall economic conditions that will determine
whether or not the labor market will continue to improve. But it is the labor market and, of
course, I didn’t say inflation going back to 2 percent—that’s implicit. But it is the labor market
that I think we ought to focus on.
MR. LACKER. All right.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Anybody else? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, yesterday you gave some interesting data in terms of
differentiating the growth of the GDP, excluding government and including government. Could
you just repeat those numbers? Because the following statement dealt with the number of jobs
lost in G; I think it was 600,000. I am trying to recall what you said because I think that was part
of the answer to Jeff‘s question.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, what I said was, in the recovery so far, measuring
from the trough quarter—I’m sure somebody will check my arithmetic here—the growth rate of
real GDP has averaged about 2.2 percent, which seems about right, while the growth rate of real
GDP less government spending has been more than 3 percent.
MR. FISHER. State and local plus federal.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Less all government C&I. So just private C plus I, no G.
On the other hand, this is just the spending part, and it doesn’t take into account whatever drag is
coming from tax and transfer policy. So it’s just the G part. Then the other observation is if we
just look at nonfarm payrolls since the trough of overall employment, there’s been a decline of

October 29–30, 2013

162 of 239

600,000 government jobs even as private employment has risen by quite a few million. At the
same point in the 2001 recovery, there had been a gain of 400,000. So compared with the
previous recession, it was about a net difference of about 1 million at this stage of the recovery,
which is obviously a pretty significant effect.
MR. FISHER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. There are a lot of great ideas that
we heard in the past few hours. One in particular that I’d like to associate myself with is the
Vice Chairman’s idea of thinking about ways to improve the SEP as a communication vehicle.
In particular, I think it would be useful to offer—at least in conjunction with, as a supplement to
our current SEP—some notion of our forecast under a common policy assumption of some kind.
I think that would be valuable communication for the public to hear. As I’ve indicated in the
past, I have often struggled to talk to the public about the thought experiment where I’m in
charge of monetary policy. They don’t find that a useful thought experiment.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. A counterfactual. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Well, on this point, I just want to remind us all that we did go down that
road with a consensus forecast experiment, and a number of participants looking very technically
at how you generate a forecast indicated that they would have trouble putting down a forecast
that was an equilibrium—sustainable and whatnot. So I certainly share the goal of what
President Kocherlakota is advocating and would hope that we could get there, but it will be a
challenge.

October 29–30, 2013

163 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes, you can’t just announce a path. In theory, you’d have
to announce some kind of reaction function. Anything else? Why don’t we take 20 minutes for
coffee and then we’ll do the monetary policy go-round?
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Why don’t we reconvene? Our last item is current
monetary policy, and let me ask Bill English please introduce it.
MR. ENGLISH. 4 Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman. I will be referring to the
handout labeled “Material for FOMC Briefing on Monetary Policy Alternatives.”
The top left panel of page 1 shows the median dealer projections for the path of
SOMA holdings from the most recent primary dealer survey (the black solid line) as
well as the median projection before the September meeting (the orange line). The
median dealer now expects holdings to peak slightly later at just under $4.4 trillion,
similar to the path that the staff wrote down for alternative A (the red dotted line).
Dealers are anticipating total purchases under their current program of about
$1.6 trillion—up from about $1.2 trillion prior to the September meeting. The panel
directly below shows that a majority of dealers now anticipate that the unemployment
rate will be about 6.7 or 6.8 percent when the purchase program is wound down,
which is roughly consistent with the simple unemployment-based stopping rule we
included in the Tealbook.
Over recent months, the public has had some difficulty understanding the
Committee’s intentions regarding future asset purchases. As noted in the bottom left
panel, the introduction of a simple rule for purchases could help clarify those
intentions, albeit at the cost of reduced flexibility. As noted in the Tealbook, and as
you also saw in the staff memo, such a rule might be based on the unemployment rate
or the level of payroll employment, either of which could help provide greater
specificity about what the Committee means in saying that its decisions about asset
purchases will be data dependent.
The three panels on the right side of your exhibit focus on federal funds rate
expectations and the Committee’s forward guidance. The top panel shows that the
median expectation for the path of the funds rate from the dealer survey shifted down
somewhat since September, roughly consistent with market measures. The middle
panel shows that this change has been accompanied by a shift further out into the
future of the expected timing of liftoff, with most respondents now seeing the second
half of 2015 as the most likely timing. I would note that the dealers’ forecasts for

4

The materials used by Mr. English are appended to this transcript (appendix 5).

October 29–30, 2013

164 of 239

when the unemployment rate will drop to the Committee’s 6½ percent threshold (not
shown) were little changed.
As noted in the bottom panel, the Committee might want to strengthen its funds
rate forward guidance, now or in the future, to clarify that it views the forward
guidance and the purchase program as distinct tools that need not move together. In
the Tealbook we offered four possibilities: a reduction in the unemployment
threshold, the introduction of an inflation floor, an explicit statement that the
Committee will consider a broad set of indicators when deciding how long to
maintain an exceptionally low range for the federal funds rate, and provision of
information about the path of the federal funds rate following liftoff.
Turning to the policy decision at this meeting, the statement for alternative B, on
page 6, might appeal to policymakers who judge that the available economic data and
the possible effects of the fiscal standoff suggest a somewhat weaker near-term path
for the economy, and that the recent indicators have not yet provided sufficient
evidence that progress toward the Committee’s objectives will be sustained.
The first paragraph of alternative B begins by highlighting that the shutdown of
much of the federal government—and, perhaps, the delays in some key data
releases—have made it more difficult to assess the evolution of economic conditions.
It then characterizes economic activity as continuing to expand at a moderate pace
and labor market conditions as having improved further, but points to a somewhat
slower pace of recovery in the housing market as a consequence of higher mortgage
rates. The second paragraph is the same as in the September statement, except that it
deletes the reference to the tightening of financial conditions. Alternative B also adds
the sentence in paragraph 6 indicating that the Committee anticipates that persistent
headwinds will make it appropriate to keep the target for the federal funds rate below
its longer-run normal value for a considerable time in order to achieve and maintain
maximum employment and price stability.
The Desk survey indicated that dealers expect no change in the pace of asset
purchases and few changes to the postmeeting statement. The new language at the
end of alternative B would certainly be noticed, but it might not affect investors’
expectations all that much, given that they already appear to anticipate a fairly
gradual rise in the funds rate after liftoff and that the Chairman included similar
language in his September press briefing. Nonetheless, longer-term interest rates
would likely decline somewhat.
Alternative C, on page 8, may appeal to policymakers who judge that the
substantial progress in labor market conditions since last fall, as well as the
underlying momentum in the economy despite the restraint from fiscal policy,
warrant starting to wind down the purchase program at this meeting.
The first paragraph of alternative C omits the reference to the shutdown and data
releases and is more upbeat about current economic conditions, pointing to the
continued decline in the unemployment rate and strengthening of the housing market

October 29–30, 2013

165 of 239

despite higher mortgage rates. Relative to alternative B, the second paragraph
removes mention of inflation persistently below 2 percent as a risk to the economy
and expresses greater confidence that labor market conditions will continue to
improve. The third paragraph announces that, in light of the cumulative
improvements in the labor market, the Committee has decided to reduce the monthly
pace of its asset purchases by $20 billion, split evenly between purchases of MBS and
Treasuries.
There are two options for paragraph 4: The first is essentially unchanged from
September, and the second introduces two possible versions of a simple statecontingent rule for asset purchases. One is based on the cumulative increase in
nonfarm payrolls relative to their level last month. The other is contingent on a
½ percentage point reduction in the unemployment rate, also relative to September.
In both cases, future reductions in the pace of purchases would be roughly
proportional to the observed progress toward the stated labor market benchmark.
Even if you are not ready to reduce the pace of purchases at this meeting, you
might still find the clarity provided by one of the rules in paragraph 4′ is appealing.
In that case, you could make no change in purchases at this meeting but announce the
rule that will guide the path of purchases going forward.
The adoption of alternative C would surprise market participants; longer-term
interest rates would rise, equity prices would decline, and the dollar would likely
appreciate. Even if the Committee chose to announce a rule but made no reduction in
the pace of purchases at this meeting, there would likely be some backup in rates as
investors saw the Committee as moving more quickly than expected to cut purchases.
Finally, turning to alternative A, on page 4, some Committee participants may
judge that the medium-term economic outlook is now weaker than foreseen in June.
As a result, they may want to avoid signaling a near-term reduction in the pace of
purchases and to modify the forward guidance on the federal funds rate to clarify the
Committee’s intentions and provide additional monetary accommodation.
The first paragraph of alternative A is similar to that in alternative B except that it
characterizes recent economic growth as “modest,” and paragraph 2 retains the
reference to the tightening of financial conditions since spring. Paragraph 3 states
that the Committee has not yet seen sufficient progress toward its objectives for the
labor market and inflation to warrant a reduction in the pace of purchases. And
paragraph 4 omits the reference to “coming meetings” in order to suggest that
purchases will not be curtailed for a while. Paragraph 5 provides the potential
enhancements to the forward guidance I discussed earlier. The sixth paragraph
provides an alternative version of the forward guidance regarding the path of the
federal funds rate after liftoff.
As Simon mentioned yesterday, expectations about the timing of the first
reduction in the pace of purchases were pushed out into 2014 over the intermeeting
period, suggesting that the language in paragraph 3 of alternative A might not come

October 29–30, 2013

166 of 239

as a great surprise to market participants. However, the changes to the forward
guidance in paragraph 5 would be unexpected, and longer-term rates would likely
decline somewhat, equity prices rise, and the dollar depreciate.
Draft directives for each of the alternatives are presented on pages 11 through 13
of your handout. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. That completes my prepared remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, Bill. Are there any questions for Bill? [No
response.] Seeing none, let’s begin our go-round with President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B but with two small
modifications. I recommend that we delete the first and the last sentences of the statement. I’ll
start with the first sentence. This sentence puts too much emphasis on the role of the government
shutdown, both in terms of the economic outlook and our own decisionmaking. As I discussed
yesterday, we are not missing key data, nor is economic performance during the intermeeting
period particularly hard to assess. Elsewhere the statement already mentions twice that fiscal
policy is restraining economic growth, and that is enough. Indeed, as a factor affecting our
outlook, the temporary shutdown is minor compared with the ongoing fiscal austerity. More
importantly, highlighting the shutdown in the lead sentence of the statement may give the false
impression that monetary policy is paralyzed in the face of short-term fiscal brinkmanship. And
it’s important to remember this fiscal brinkmanship is not likely to go away anytime soon. I
think this is not a message the Committee should be sending.
Turning to the final sentence in paragraph 6, I think it, too, should be removed. Although
the Tealbook provides some brief discussion of the effects of headwinds, the Committee needs
more-detailed quantitative analysis and discussion about the size, the scope, and source of such
headwinds in 2016, before introducing them in the statement. Now, as the Chairman said
yesterday, there is analysis around this using the staff forecast, but I think that we should both
discuss this further and see alternative models and analysis around that. In any macro model it is

October 29–30, 2013

167 of 239

possible to decompose the various factors affecting the equilibrium real interest rate, or the
headwinds, if you will, and such an analysis would be especially useful I think in thinking about
the role of headwinds in 2016. And, given the importance of our communications, it is essential
that clear and well-grounded analysis underlies our statements.
More broadly, I am concerned that this sentence attempts to impart to the public greater
agreement on this issue than exists or is in fact necessary. After all, we may agree on an action,
even if we don’t reach a consensus about why we should take that action. Most of us expect the
funds rate to lift off only gradually, but still we may disagree about the reasons for that gradual
liftoff. It could be headwinds, it could be part of a lower for longer strategy, or because we think
a high-pressure economy will draw people back into the labor force and combat hysteresis, or a
combination of all three of these. We don’t have to agree on a rationale to find common ground
on the policy path. So that brings me to a principle I stated yesterday about the danger of
extending our forward guidance beyond the point where there is a strong and clear consensus on
the Committee. Putting headwinds in the statement today provides the Committee’s
endorsement of a particular view on the evolution of the economy three or four years out. Given
the inherent uncertainty about the distant future, I doubt such a consensus exists and I think it
would be unwise to suggest it does. Moreover, because market expectations are now broadly
aligned with the views expressed in the SEP, it’s not clear that we need to fix expectations about
the path of the funds rate in 2016 and beyond.
Of course, one problem I pointed to yesterday and last month is that we are approaching
our 6½ percent unemployment threshold. We need to convey what will drive our policy
decisions once we reach that threshold, and I would add the post-threshold language from
paragraph 5, alternative A, that begins, “Once the unemployment rate reaches 6½ percent.” I

October 29–30, 2013

168 of 239

would not include the inflation floor language at this time. Bolstering our forward guidance this
way might also help with another problem we discussed yesterday and this morning, and that is
that market participants seem to have trouble distinguishing actions regarding asset purchases
from our intentions regarding future short rates. Signaling that the Committee is not in fact
itching to raise the funds rate target could help market participants make this distinction. Thank
you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As I think about our policy
decisions, I always turn back to our strategic plan, the longer-term goals and strategies statement
that we issued in January 2012 and reaffirmed in January 2013. I use that as my lodestar, so to
speak, in thinking about our decisions. And as I think about that, I see that the medium-term
outlook for prices and employment—really, a five-year outlook for prices—remains weak
relative to our longer-run goals. So I am trying to think about what would be a policy choice that
would foster a more rapid recovery toward those dual mandate objectives, and I find alternative
A attractive along those lines.
In terms of the specifics of alternative A, I sense the consensus for the broad set of
indicators approach as opposed to actually the more quantitative approach of lowering the
unemployment rate threshold. I think that both have value, and President Williams is right to
caution us about trying to structure forward guidance for which there isn’t strong Committee
support. But that said, I think a lot of the value of our forward guidance in terms of the
unemployment rate threshold has come because it has been quantitative. We have the ability to
go out and check whether or not it is working. We can assess, and I think market participants
can assess, exactly what that means. So I personally would favor a more quantitative approach.

October 29–30, 2013

169 of 239

As I have indicated in the past, at the risk of adding a little more complexity to the
statement, what we could do is add a separate paragraph about what is going to happen between
6½ and 6 or 6½ and 5½. That paragraph could have a different inflation protection in it. It could
be a lower one, 2¼ as opposed to 2½. We could consider the idea of a financial stability
knockout. I’m not advocating that by any means, but that’s something else you could add to that
new paragraph. So this would make it clear that what we are doing is offering clarity about what
is going to happen when the unemployment rate falls below 6½ percent. But with that said, the
broad set of indicators language is a positive move forward. I don’t think it’s as positive as
trying to be more quantitative, as we have done in the past.
I thought President Williams summarized some of the problems with the last sentence of
alternative A and the first sentence of alternative A, and I will associate myself with his remarks
on that dimension. So I would drop those sentences at this time in alternative A.
Having said I support alternative A at this time, let me talk a little bit about alternative C.
Despite the weak macroeconomic outlook in Tealbook, Book A, and I don’t think there’s any
prospect of that changing in the next six months materially, I do think that there will remain a
need to talk about and think about the issue of reducing the flow of asset purchases in the next
six months or so. I think the key problem or challenge for us—and I talked about this in the past
two go-rounds—is what we think about success for the asset purchase program. How we
thought about it going in, in September 2012, is different from what we think about as success
for the fed funds rate program. And I think we have to be clear about why we think those
definitions of success as being different. I think, Mr. Chairman, your idea of having a survey to
gather the reasons among the Committee about why we think about success as being different in
terms of the one tool having cost and efficacy considerations that the other tool does not, is going

October 29–30, 2013

170 of 239

to be very helpful in sharpening our communication about why we are contemplating reducing
the flow of purchases, the use of a form of greater stimulus, when our anticipated rate of progress
toward our goals remains so slow.
With that said, I would be willing to contemplate the steps described in alternative C, not
at this meeting but at some future date, if they took place after those in A, or simultaneously with
those in A, and if they were justified, at least in part, in terms of the cost and efficacy
considerations that we are going to be discussing further. And I think we should be explaining
clearly in the FOMC statement and other public communications that cost and efficacy
considerations are important drivers behind a near-term decision to reduce purchases. That is, I
think, the only way to drive home that we remain fully committed to rapid progress toward our
dual mandate objectives. I think the survey tool should help us have a much clearer
understanding among ourselves of what we mean when we talk about those costs.
To summarize, Mr. Chairman, at this meeting I favor alternative A. I personally would
simply lower the unemployment rate threshold to 6 percent or even lower, but I would be willing
to support alternative A at this meeting with the broader set of indicators language instead. I
would drop the last and first sentence. I could see supporting a version of alternative C in the
next few months, but that version of alternative C would have to include clearer language that
underscores the role of efficacy and costs as key elements, in the Committee’s thinking. Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B as written. Last
June I was expecting that by now real GDP growth would be picking up, that payroll
employment growth would be rising, and that we would have avoided disruptive fiscal policy

October 29–30, 2013

171 of 239

this fall. Had that played out as expected, I would have supported a reduction in purchases at the
September meeting. However, that is not the set of facts that we faced at the September meeting,
nor is it the set of facts facing us today. Moreover, for the second half of the year, private
forecasters, the Tealbook, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston forecast all envision GDP
growth not much different than the 2.2 percent average growth over the past four years of this
very slow recovery, along with continued sluggish expansion in payroll employment. And this
outcome is achieved only under the rather optimistic assumption that fiscal policy
decisionmaking will not suffer from another self-inflicted wound.
Since the start of this recovery, we have been assuming that monetary policy was
sufficiently accommodative to return to full employment and 2 percent inflation within
approximately a four-year timeframe. We have now had five years of a very sluggish recovery,
and we are still assuming that we are just four years away from reaching full employment and
2 percent inflation. Given the consistent pattern of over-forecasting, we should probably be
placing more weight on realized data than on our forecasts. In terms of policy, that means no
change in monetary policy until we see economic data consistent with achieving full
employment and 2 percent inflation within four years. Actually, my preference would be to do
whatever we can to achieve both those goals sooner than the four-year horizon in the Tealbook.
However, to have any chance of achieving our goals in four years, we need to see 3 percent real
GDP growth in the data, we need to see payroll employment closer to the 200,000 jobs that are
forecast next year in the data, and we need to see inflation numbers clearly trending toward
2 percent. The Tealbook forecast expects us to see that in the first quarter. If that forecast
becomes a reality, then that is when we should consider reducing our purchases. My expectation
is that evaluation is likely to be difficult before March. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.

October 29–30, 2013

172 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have one general comment and two
specific comments. In the general comment, I want to again talk about the possibility of ending
the asset purchase program by citing efficacy and costs, as has been addressed today by President
Kocherlakota, President Lockhart, Governor Tarullo, and others, encouraging us to talk more
about the efficacy and cost argument—and I know the Chairman has talked about this in the
past—and put this in the context of what Vice Chairman Dudley called ending the program
because of failure as opposed to ending the program because of success. I like Vice Chairman
Dudley’s terms here, despite the fact that he is a Red Sox fan. In fact, I have never met so many
Red Sox fans until I came here. [Laughter] Basically I think we should not end the program on
the basis of efficacy and costs, unless it is absolutely necessary. And I do not think we are near
that point right now, so I’m going to outline that argument.
I liked Governor Stein—another Boston guy here—describing the leading option for the
Committee is just to continue the program. I think it has been a successful program, and I think
we can continue, and I don’t think we’re close to a threshold where we have to think about
ending it and declaring failure on it. It would be an admission of failure to end the program
before achieving our goals, and I think enhanced forward guidance is unlikely to be an effective
substitute. And the main reason is the same one we were thinking about last year, which was
that forward guidance has to extend farther and farther into the future. And the farther you go
into the future the more unknowns there are, and, therefore, any promises you make in the distant
future are unlikely to be effective in changing economic behavior today.
Last September, in 2012, we chose to implement an open-ended asset purchase program
instead of choosing to strengthen forward guidance. At that point, we could have said that we

October 29–30, 2013

173 of 239

don’t want to do the asset purchase program, but that we want to somehow strengthen forward
guidance. We didn’t do it. We thought that asset purchase was the more potent tool. And so
that kind of tells markets that by closing down the asset purchase program and switching back to
forward guidance you are basically saying it didn’t work and we are going to do something that
is probably going to be less effective.
Let’s just break down the efficacy and costs argument into two parts. First of all, on
efficacy, and I think the efficacy argument, frankly, during the summer has been blown out of
the water. So let me just talk about that for a second. The June and September experience surely
showed that asset purchases are highly effective in the following sense. The more hawkish June
announcement by this Committee led to higher real interest rates, lower inflation expectations,
lower equity valuations, and a stronger dollar. That is exactly the financial market signature of a
surprise tighter policy announcement. The reverse—exact reverse—occurred in the aftermath of
the surprise decision by this Committee at the September meeting in 2013, just this past meeting.
Both of these events were clear monetary policy surprises and so provide compelling evidence
about the efficacy of the program, at least in terms of having the same financial signature that
you would expect from, say, a 50 basis point move in the funds rate in one direction or the other.
At a conference, Marvin Goodfriend called this the “black box” argument for the efficacy of this
program. And it is indeed a black box argument, but it is a very compelling one. I think we have
an effective tool at our disposal, and we would put it away at our peril. On the efficacy side, I
think the events of the summer, as unintended as they may have been, did give us two
experiments that showed that it is a very efficacious program, and that the flow rate of purchases
is very much a key variable that we can turn in one direction or the other in order to get the
desired effects that we want.

October 29–30, 2013

174 of 239

On the cost side, I do think, of course, we need to keep our eye on costs and on financial
stability issues. But I do not think we are close enough to any limits on those dimensions to
warrant tapering based on a citation of costs at the current time. The current size of the balance
sheet relative to GDP is not particularly large compared with other key central banks. We are in
the 20s as a percent of GDP. I think we could go to 30 or 35 percent of GDP without too much
difficulty. That’s where the other central banks are. If you thought there was some problem
with that particular size of the balance sheet relative to GDP, Europe should be in trouble, the
U.K. should be in trouble, the Bank of Japan should be in trouble—that doesn’t seem to be
happening. There is actually one central bank that has a ratio of 90 percent balance sheet to
GDP. Who is it? Is it Zimbabwe? It’s Switzerland. We should think more in terms of not just
round numbers on the size of the balance sheet, but also in terms of the size of the balance sheet
relative to GDP, and we should think harder about what we really think that limit might be. I
agree, we may get to a point where we don’t want to go farther into unknown territory than we
have to, but we should have that limit in our head. And if we do get to that juncture, then we
would have to swallow hard and make some hard decisions. But I would advise trying gallantly
not to do that, and instead I think we should continue with the program until we have better data
and a better argument than we already have—we already have a pretty good argument, but a
better argument on cumulative progress toward a substantial labor market improvement.
And, as President Kocherlakota just reminded us a moment ago, inflation is running quite
low. We have a lot of room to maneuver on that dimension. We do not have a classic monetary
policy debate here where inflation is running high but the economy is weak, and you’ve got each
side maneuvering on those two dimensions. We seem to have a lot of room on the inflation side.

October 29–30, 2013

175 of 239

The bottom line, I think, is to continue with the successful program until we get better
news, and I think we do need to be prepared to move when we have the opportunity. I would not
let it go by. We have made considerable progress over the past year among other dimensions.
One that has not been mentioned as much at this meeting is much higher equity in home prices
than we would have had last year at the time of that decision. That tends to, and does, feed into a
lot of our macroeconomic forecasts. So we don’t have to be in a hurry.
For today, I do support alternative B, but I agree completely with President Williams and
President Kocherlakota that there should be two key changes here. One of the themes of this
meeting is that less is more, so let’s just take out the two sentences, the very first sentence and
the very last sentence. For the first sentence in paragraph 1 of alternative B, which talks about
the shutdown of the federal government, my preference, as I was saying yesterday, is not to tie
monetary policy too closely to a new variable called “partisan volatility” here in Washington.
This volatility is unlikely to go away anytime soon, and so may tie our hands should we wish to
make a key decision at a point where partisan volatility is higher than we would prefer.
Financial markets are well aware that this is a concern for the Committee. There is no need to
enshrine this by putting it into the statement.
And on the last sentence of paragraph 6 of alternative B that talks about headwinds
possibly restraining economic recovery far into the future. I would omit this. I think it’s more
confusing than helpful. But, in particular, I think this sends a very pessimistic signal about the
future of the U.S. economy. I have been very concerned about the Committee sending
unwarranted pessimistic signals. We don’t know any better than anyone else what the economy
is going to be like in 2016 or 2017. The combination of us not having any real evidence to

October 29–30, 2013

176 of 239

support this statement and the notion that we shouldn’t be sending a pessimistic signal, I think,
should be a powerful argument for removing the last sentence of alternative B.
By the way, I do think if we want to argue that we are going to hold rates low far into the
future, the argument should be the Woodford argument that we are holding them lower to make
up for the time when we were constrained by the zero lower bound. That would make the most
sense. But I don’t think there is complete agreement on the Committee about that, and we
should maybe explore that further. But I wouldn’t put this in this statement at this time. I don’t
think it helps us and possibly could be counterproductive by sending this pessimistic signal.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher. Oh, I’m sorry. President
Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. A question for President Bullard. The ratio of central bank balance
sheet to GDP is an interesting ratio, but I don’t intuitively get that mechanical connection. If you
take national debt to GDP, there’s sort of the notion of the economy that services the debt should
have some relationship, but explain to me, if you would, the connection between central bank
balance sheet and GDP. How does that work?
MR. BULLARD. Well, I don’t think we have good theories about it. But what I would
encourage is that if we just talk in terms of hundreds of billions of dollars being added to the
balance sheet, that’s just a number. I think we need to get more to the economics of where that
limit is and why we think that limit is there? And I’m giving a very simple argument, which is
that other countries have far surpassed us already. They don’t seem to have created a lot of
financial instability or a lot of inflation, and so I just don’t think we have a case—not an
empirical case right now—that there’s some kind of threshold at 25 percent of GDP or at

October 29–30, 2013

177 of 239

28 percent of GDP or something like that. We just don’t see that from the available empirical
evidence and so, for now, I think it’s clear sailing. I’m not saying you want to go on forever, but
I think that scaling it is maybe a little bit better way to think about it. Also, in U.S. history, the
size of the balance sheet has been bigger than it is today, in the late 1930s, and so it’s not
unprecedented historically either.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. As I think I mentioned at the previous meeting, an efficient Committee
starts like the Balkans and ends like Switzerland, which is not quite what I meant for that
discussion. [Laughter]
I’m going to just be simple here. I’m going to join the Western–Lutheran Coalition,
meaning I agree fully with President Williams, President Kocherlakota, and President Bullard, in
terms of getting rid of the first sentence and getting rid of the last sentence of alternative B, given
that that seems to be where we’re going. Based on the discussion we had, it doesn’t sound like
we’re quite ready for A(5) or for C(4)′. Everybody at this table knows that I don’t like the
program that we’re currently undertaking, but I don’t have a vote in this meeting, and I would
suggest that President Williams is actually quite wise in his recommendation. In fact, I would
remove all of paragraph 6. I think the word “eventually” is just way too indefinite, too openended, and it might sort of look like we’re just not going to stop this program, but at a minimum,
I would get rid of the first and last sentences. He’s right. Fiscal policy retrenchment is
mentioned two other places in the statement, in the first paragraph and the third paragraph. So
I’m in accord with President Williams, President Kocherlakota, and President Bullard on that
front.

October 29–30, 2013

178 of 239

One small point, which I don’t expect you to change, but I just want to note—I
mentioned it yesterday. Talking about the housing sector, I think it’s incorrect to say that it
“slowed somewhat in response to higher mortgage rates,” although the word “somewhat” may
condition it. Again, talking to the builders, talking to the housing companies, they will point out
that is a partial reason and particularly an extreme movement of 100 basis points. The Desk
pointed out yesterday that we’ve actually had a settling down of mortgage rates. The builders
will tell you that they priced too aggressively in their eagerness to recoup the past few years.
They have a limited amount of property to work with. Due to the labor and resource situation, it
has taken them twice as long to build as they normally have in normal cycles. And then, finally,
they will mention that mortgage rates have risen, but it’s not the principal reason. So I would
simply recommend that we insert the word “partially” after “months,” “has slowed somewhat in
recent months partially in response to higher mortgage rates.” I don’t think the Committee will
accept that, but it would be viewed as more realistic by the people that are in the industry if they
were to read this statement. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t know why you’re so pessimistic, President Fisher.
I’m happy to put that on the table.
MR. FISHER. I would be delighted if you did, and I look forward to it being voted
down. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Can I just ask a question of the Western–Lutherans? If
you’re going to eliminate the last sentence, shouldn’t you just revert back to paragraph 5 as of
last time?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That’s the presumption.

October 29–30, 2013

179 of 239

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Okay. I just wanted to be clear on that. That’s really
what you’re saying.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have believed for some time that the time
really has come to end our LSAP program. I do have questions about both its efficacy and its
costs, and from a risk management standpoint, the risks of unintended consequences of how we
unwind ourselves from this. I don’t need to go into all of those at this point. And we are
struggling around the table yesterday and today with how do we go about doing that and what
the criteria are that we’re going to use. That’s been a topic of much, I think, fruitful discussion.
Given where we are, I did make the suggestion yesterday that one way to get out of this program
is to declare, like we did in QE1 and QE2, that there is a size for this program that we’re going to
target. We believe that’s the right amount, and we will do it until we reach that point. And when
we reach that point, we will make a decision whether to institute another program or not if it
seems to be called for under the circumstances.
I’ve argued for some time, vociferously, and continue to about the importance of being
state contingent; I like state contingency. And I was weakly supportive of the flow-based
program, but was troubled by it. The reason is we have neither theory nor evidence from the
historical record to go on about how to write a state-contingent rule for our asset purchase
program, and I think that’s partly what we’re struggling with. My suggestion to revert to a
balance sheet rule, in terms of how much the purchase program is going to constitute, is clearly a
second-best outcome. I’m not arguing that it’s the world’s first-best way to do this, but it
simplifies a number of things. It simplifies in the sense that it easily begins to disentangle this
confusion between our interest rate rule and our balance sheet rule. Right now, we’ve got them

October 29–30, 2013

180 of 239

interacting in a way that’s very complicated that we haven’t entirely sorted out ourselves. It does
restore that separation of how the Committee is thinking about balance sheets versus our interest
rate rule. So I think there’s some simplicity and appeal to that. After all, this Committee has
argued for some time that it really is the size or duration of the balance sheet that’s providing the
accommodation and not the flow. Let’s go back to that claim and assert that that’s how we’re
going to decide how we’re going to conduct that. I understand that’s hard, and Governor Tarullo
made some comments earlier this morning about how the communications around that might be
a little bit difficult, but I do think it has some appeal to it as a way to unwind ourselves from this.
Now, the other advantage I see to this in getting out of this is that our state-contingent
efforts to do this are quite complicated because they have implications, as Governor Yellen was
saying, for different outcomes we could experience. For example, if we stick with the
unemployment rule and we’re in one of those bad nodes where the unemployment rate stays
higher than perhaps we otherwise chose, we could be in this program for a very, very long time.
Is that really where we want to be and are we prepared to commit to that using one of these other
rules? I think that’s a risk that we have to understand, and so being able to separate there might
have some advantages. If you’re in a supply-side damage scenario versus the scenario where
fiscal policy goes on in a terrible state for a very long time, I think we pose ourselves some
problems. So I’m trying to think of ways to simplify this to extract ourselves from this when we
want to, without some of these other complications. Again, it’s not first best solution, but it
might be one that is desirable. I also worry a lot about our emphasis on fiscal policy and the
arguments about that. I do worry that we are perhaps running the risk of placing too much
emphasis in our discussions about what’s going on with fiscal policy, along the lines of President
Bullard’s comments. If we can’t end this program as long as fiscal policy is in a mess, again, we

October 29–30, 2013

181 of 239

may be in this for a very long time. Is that really where we want to be? And it moves us then to
a world where I fear, we are, to some degree, accepting a regime of fiscal dominance that may
not be in our long-run best interest. For those reasons, I think we need to be a little more creative
and open about how we sort of get out of this without boxing ourselves in in a way that perhaps
makes us engaged in asset purchases for a very, very long time.
We’re obviously not prepared to make any decisions on these difficult questions today.
So let me lend my support to alt-B in this context and support three changes, two of which have
already—maybe all three of them—been mentioned in some sense. I’ll put my hat in the ring
with President Williams. I think we need to get rid of the first sentence in that it draws too much
attention to fiscal policy, and it ties our descriptions and our actions too much to fiscal policy.
So I’d love to get rid of that first sentence. The other thing I’d like to do—and President Fisher
made this point—I think we have to be very careful in paragraph 1, when we’re describing the
economy, not to put too much weight on our interpretations of causality. It’s supposed to be
descriptive, and I think President Fisher pointed out this sort of reference to the housing market
has softened somewhat or weakened in recent months due to an increase in mortgage rates. We
don’t know that for sure, and we don’t know whether it’s going to come back or not. In fact, I’d
just make the statement “the housing sector has continued to expand, but its pace has slowed,”
period. That’s just a statement of what’s happened. We don’t need to attribute it to mortgage
rates because, in fact, if we sort of begin hanging our hat too much on what’s driving the housing
sector, we then may find ourselves in an undesirable place later where we have to ask ourselves
whether that means that we’re going to have to reduce mortgage rates even more than we already
have? So I’d prefer to get some of those causal things out of paragraph 1, and I think we would
serve ourselves better. I would get rid of the first sentence. I would get rid of the phrase “due to

October 29–30, 2013

182 of 239

higher mortgage rates.” And the third, I would go along with the sentiment on the last sentence
of paragraph 6. President Kocherlakota yesterday made the point very clear. There’s a lot of
hidden economics in that statement that are actually very complicated and potentially confusing,
and where there could be disagreements about how this comes about. I think we have to be very
careful about that, and so until we’ve done a lot more economic analysis and there’s more sort of
consensus about what this really means and why this is happening, or why this appears the way it
does in the SEP, I just think it needs a lot more thought before we go there. I would recommend
that we take that sentence out. So eliminate the first sentence, eliminate the reference to higher
mortgage rates, and take out the last sentence of paragraph 6. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I agree with a comment that Governor Yellen
made during her earlier statement that we appear to be in a pretty good place today. So I prefer
no action, and I guess that’s alt-B.
At our September meeting, we clearly indicated that we needed more and better
confirmation that the SEP outlook was concrete and achievable. Since then, the data flow was
interrupted and the fiscal developments in Washington piled greater uncertainty onto our current
setting. I don’t know, maybe I’m in the minority on that one, according to some of the
comments so far. At the margin, the economic setting is most likely worse than we thought in
September.
Now, with regard to particular elements in the statement, I don’t agree with the
suggestions about deleting the first sentence regarding the role of the government shutdown. I
think it’s a reality check and that most commentators would say that it’s more difficult to assess.
I probably didn’t hear all of the details of President Williams’s careful assessment of why things

October 29–30, 2013

183 of 239

aren’t that much more difficult to assess. I would guess that in Chicago we had computer
programs that had missing values and, when we went to run them normally, they just blew up,
and so we had to do something in order to correct them. I think it’s objectively correct that it’s
more difficult to assess, and that’s all it says, “somewhat more difficult to assess.” However,
then we say information received seems like things are actually pretty good. I think that if you
read the statement from the outset without that, it seems a bit too bright. “Information received
since the FOMC…”, I can imagine somebody—Jon Stewart—saying, “What information did
they receive during that time period?” Anyway, for me, it really adds more questions than
answers. Maybe there’s a rewording that can make this better, but that bothers me. I think the
higher mortgage rates also are a pretty good explanation for at least a partial reason why we’ve
seen housing. The other factors that President Fisher mentioned have been longer lasting, at
least in my conversations with people in the housing industry. Some of those effects have been
around for a while. It’s the increase in mortgage rates that’s been more timely and associated
with that.
Now, on the alt-A suggestion, I will admit a great deal of sympathy with the alt-A postthreshold guidance in paragraph 5, and President Williams rightly put emphasis on that
yesterday. I did not hear enough of a consensus for the 6 percent threshold change in forward
guidance, certainly not today, maybe never, and I think that some additional post-threshold
guidance helps. I do think that the production function for making it do what we want it to do
will involve an awful lot of additional commentary from the center of the Committee—namely,
you, Mr. Chairman, or Madam Chair, depending on when we do it. I think it’s going to require a
couple, three-times-a-month type of commentary on that to drive it home because it’s qualitative,
and I think people are going to start asking questions about what it really means. The 6 percent

October 29–30, 2013

184 of 239

maybe could have been dealt with, pounded in, and then it would be there. But I think that based
on the kinds of questions that the rest of us field when we go out and speak and those the wire
reporters ask us, they’re constantly asking for more information about that. And I think it would
be incumbent on us to make that effective, to do it more often; that’s a feature of that.
Regarding the last paragraph’s forward guidance on the pace of increasing the funds rate,
I do favor some type of guidance. I’m probably a little more sympathetic toward it than the
commentary so far, but my staff has more concerns about it than I do. I’ll simply mention that
when my expert staff is bringing up these same objections, it may be an indicator of how the
public may struggle with that. I definitely agree that headwinds present an enormous obstacle
and are going to continue to be that way for a while, but, to some, it might sound too downbeat
for too long regarding our assessment of future growth prospects. So it may lead the public to
believe we’re more negative about the future than I personally intend by that guidance. Now, to
address this, I think it could be helpful to add a bit more specificity if this approach is seriously
considered at some point. So I would favor adding something to qualify headwinds, like fiscal
and household headwinds that have been restraining the economic recovery, and then the
language there. I think you made an excellent observation, Mr. Chairman, about the effect of the
fiscal policy to date. It has been really big, and it would justify that type of language. And the
household sector is going to continue to assess and work to right-size its debt obligations for a
considerably period to come. I expect a long adjustment period like the analysis that we heard
yesterday, unless we see much stronger wage and income growth across all industrial and
occupational levels. I think that that could work, but I assume that it’s probably not live for
today. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lockhart.

October 29–30, 2013

185 of 239

MR. LOCKHART: Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B. I actually think
the first sentence is accurate and appropriate. It addresses a question that is held in the minds of
the public. I don’t think it overreaches, and I think it sets up the tentativeness of the conclusions
on the economy and the reasons that we’re staying the course at this meeting. So I don’t have an
objection to keeping it in. I have some sympathy with President Fisher’s “partially.” I actually
had the same thought, chose not to bring it up, but I do agree that there are other factors at work,
and it might be good to qualify that a little bit. I think the bigger question, of course, is the
forward guidance “in addition” language in paragraph 6. As I said in an earlier round, I favor
enhancing guidance with this measure of strength, if not more, but not at this meeting. I think
it’s wiser to minimize changes under the circumstances around this meeting. If it were adopted
in December as a practical matter, the Chairman would have the SEP in hand and would be able
to use a press conference to guide interpretation of that. So I prefer standing pat at this meeting
with the September language for the most part, minimizing the changes, and waiting until
December to at least consider strengthening rate guidance qualitatively and possibly even
quantitatively. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Before I comment on my preferred policy
option, I wanted to provide some background on my thinking. My estimate for the natural rate
of unemployment is 6 percent, and I know that this is on the high end of the range of estimates in
the SEP, but I take solace that I’m not the only person with this estimate. So with my natural
rate of unemployment at 6 percent, I believe that we are going to need to begin to raise the
federal funds rate when unemployment is somewhere in the range of, say, 6¼ to 6½ percent.
That is less than 1 percentage point from where the unemployment rate stands today.

October 29–30, 2013

186 of 239

Since the asset purchase program began last summer, the unemployment rate has fallen
by nearly 1 percentage point, and we have had solid, if not spectacular, growth in payrolls. So if
we wait much longer to adjust the pace of asset purchases, we run the risk of making it even
more difficult to separate our asset purchase program from our fed funds rate guidance, because
when it comes to our hopes for the unemployment rate, their boundaries start to blur together.
And separating these tools seemed like it was a key theme from our policy planning discussion
go-round. Suppose the unemployment rate continues to decline at its recent pace and the first
reduction in the asset purchase program is put off until next March at the earliest, which seems to
be what markets are thinking. In that scenario I think separation of the two programs is going to
become even more difficult. I favored slowing the pace of asset purchases at our last meeting,
and I realize that slowing purchases at this meeting is essentially impossible because it would
generate a second surprise in as many meetings.
In light of the current market expectations, I would suggest that the Committee’s
statement in the form of alternative A is going to be read as indicating that asset purchases are
unlikely to slow until some time in 2014. So I would like to see some language inserted into
alternative B that would give the Committee greater flexibility to slow asset purchases in
December or in January if the incoming data support such an action. And I think this could
easily be done by inserting the following sentence after the first sentence of paragraph 3 in alt-B.
I would suggest inserting, “In the coming months, if the Committee continues to see further
progress toward its objectives for the labor market and inflation, the Committee will likely begin
to gradually reduce the pace of asset purchases.” Then the paragraph would just continue with,
“However, at this meeting the Committee decided to wait for more evidence,” et cetera. I think
giving us a little more flexibility to move in December and January would be important.

October 29–30, 2013

187 of 239

In addition, like many others have already suggested, I would not add the last sentence in
alternative B. In my mind, the effectiveness of our communications would be best served by
only making further alterations to the forward funds rate guidance when we actually adjust the
rate of asset purchases. I think making these changes together would help to decouple our asset
purchase program from our fed funds rate guidance. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Alternative B is certainly consistent with the
decision in September to await more evidence that progress will be sustained, and in a world of
noisy data and government shutdowns, awaiting more evidence of progress increasingly seems to
be a very high bar. That said, I do not support alternative B for several reasons. As I have noted
before, it continues aggressive easing despite actual and forecasted improvement in the economy.
There has been cumulative and sustained improvement despite fiscal headwinds and slow
healing in labor markets. And despite the critique that forecasts have been too optimistic, they
have accurately projected forward momentum. The Tealbook, the SEP, as well as private
forecasters continue to do so.
I do worry about the cost of this level of accommodation, perhaps because the costs
among this Committee have remained ill-defined. Our policy planning go-round highlights the
challenges we face in several dimensions, such as how to communicate our goals, how to
understand the effects of our tools, and explaining how they will be retired. We should continue
to focus on these issues not only for consistent messaging, but, importantly, to affirm our
understanding of the efficacy of these tools relative to our goals and the realities of the economy.
The emphasis on data dependence is important, but I’ve been more focused on
cumulative progress rather than the most recent data point. Considering our progress just since

October 29–30, 2013

188 of 239

June, the unemployment rate has fallen; employment has increased by 600,000; and the
September ISM manufacturing survey had the highest reading in over two years, driven in part
by a rise in employment component. The August ISM non-manufacturing index had its highest
reading in eight years. With this backdrop, I continue to view taking steps toward slowing the
pace of asset purchases as appropriate and reasonable. It is difficult for me to see that adding
accommodation at some reduced pace represents any meaningful tightening.
I also am concerned that market expectations of the cumulative size of LSAPs could
continue to move higher despite continued job gains and declines in the unemployment rate.
Recall that primary dealers expected the unemployment rate at the end of asset purchases to be
7 percent according to the dealer survey prior to the June meeting. This estimate was unchanged
in the flash survey after the June press conference. Given the latest survey that now shows
expectations for tapering in March, the continued job growth and decline in the unemployment
rate make it likely that we will not even start tapering before the unemployment rate reaches
7 percent. Adjustments in these expectations regarding LSAPs might be appropriate if less
progress had been made than previously anticipated or the medium-term outlook substantially
deteriorated. However, the unemployment rate has fallen more than expected and private-sector
expectations for job growth are likely to exceed what had been forecast in September of 2012.
That said, it seems increasingly problematic to reinforce a direct connection between LSAPs and
labor markets as we have discussed. Moreover, postponing the start of LSAP reductions
reinforces a message in my view that we think the outlook is weak when, in fact, the growth
trajectory we continue to project shows acceleration.
Finally, I would prefer to omit the proposed new language in paragraph 1 related to the
government shutdown for reasons others have raised, as well as in paragraph 6, which I think

October 29–30, 2013

189 of 239

does little to clarify our expected policy path and might introduce yet another unobserved
variable into the policy-setting landscape. And I would also be supportive of looking at some
modification to the mortgage rate increase as the sole reason for the housing slowing. Thank
you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I was in favor of tapering at our last
meeting, and I still believe economic conditions warrant reducing the pace of our asset
purchases, given the improvements we have seen in the labor markets and the likelihood that
continued economic growth—even at 2 percent—will generate continued labor market
improvements. So I find myself in alignment with President George.
But under the assumption we do not begin tapering today, I don’t think we should be
adding any new elements to our forward guidance at this time. One reason is that the statement
is pretty long as it is. And I’ll admit I don’t have a theory of the optimal statement length, but it
has been getting longer over time. And while pondering the growing length of our statements,
my research director quipped that he half-expected to open the Tealbook one day soon and see
alternative B begin with the words, “Call me Ishmael.” [Laughter] Specifically, I find myself in
agreement with President Williams about the last sentence in alternative B and that we ought to
revert to 5. This constitutes new forward guidance, and it adds a pessimistic characterization of
the outlook. I agree with President Bullard that it is likely to be taken as a shift in the
Committee’s outlook. And for the reasons that Professor Woodford has made really clear, could
have a dampening effect on current economic growth by making people feel as if we are more
discouraged about future growth.

October 29–30, 2013

190 of 239

I also agree with President Williams about dropping the first sentence. It is not that much
more difficult to assess economic conditions. Sure, things are murky now, but I don’t remember
them being a lot less murky than they are right now. The other thing about this is that it places a
lot of importance on one month’s data, and it is the kind of thing we try and avoid doing. It
implies that we do place more attention to one month’s data than I think we really do or did
today or yesterday. In addition, it implies a connection to fiscal policy as well. The murkiness
has to do with the potential economic effects of the shutdown, not just the effects on data
collection. And there, I think, we have gotten tripped up in the past by tying monetary policy to
fiscal policy, and then having control sort of pass out of our hands and feeling hung up for a
period.
I agree with the point President Plosser and President Fisher made about housing. And I
liked President Pianalto’s suggestion about language, so I pretty much agree with all of the
suggestions for changing the statement that were made so far. Thank you very much.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, President Lacker. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B. I personally
considered our September decision a close call, but, in my view, developments have vindicated
the wisdom of our choice. We didn’t yet have sufficient confirmation that the improvements we
had seen in the labor market would be sustained, and our decision was consistent with the basic
framework that was laid out in June and got across to markets that our policy is truly datadependent and we aren’t just racing to the exits. Given that incoming data on spending and the
labor market have been weak, and what I at least see as the confusing, but hopefully transitory,
effects of the government shutdown and debt ceiling debate, it remains hard to assess the

October 29–30, 2013

191 of 239

underlying state of the recovery. So I think it is right to wait until December to gain better
visibility on the outlook.
As I mentioned yesterday, I think our September communications moved us into a better
place, and we certainly haven’t foreclosed the option of taking the first step to reduce the pace of
purchases in December if the data by that time confirm our expectation of ongoing improvement
in the labor market conditions. Whether the first taper comes in December or sometime early
next year, I think we stand the best chance of avoiding significant upheaval if we stay the course
and continue within the framework we laid out in June. Given that our policy decisions are datadependent, we should decide when first to taper based on the data regardless of whether markets
perfectly anticipate our decision at that time.
I think we are in a decent place with respect to our asset purchase program and our
forward guidance if progress toward our goals continues at the pace I view as most likely, or, as I
noted in my economic remarks, under several other plausible scenarios. Even though I would
prefer to see more rapid improvement in the labor market, it may be prudent under the modal
outlook to complete purchases sometime around the middle of next year. We have discussed the
uncertain costs and risks associated with a very large balance sheet and stopping around that time
may arguably preserve more capacity for us to respond to some future large, negative shock. But
the outlook is uncertain, and we need to be mindful that a scenario could unfold along the lines I
discussed yesterday: a scenario where economic growth does not pick up, progress in the labor
market stalls, and the economy is stuck in the mud. In such a scenario, disinflationary pressures
could also mount.
I agree with others who have said we need to have a plan for a case where we eventually
wind down our asset purchase program without a declaration of victory. And I think the survey

October 29–30, 2013

192 of 239

that you proposed, Mr. Chairman, will be extremely useful in developing that plan. I think we
have all indicated discomfort with QE-infinity. It’s not that there is some clear absolute limit to
the size of our balance sheet, but, rather, that the type of cost-benefit analysis you laid out at our
December meeting applies. In particular, we need to ask ourselves how far it would be prudent
to go with asset purchases, given our assessment of how pressing the need is for action, how
much the purchases are likely to help, the highly uncertain but presumably growing costs and
risks, as well as the availability of other tools.
Your framework provides a way to think about some subtle but important issues. For
example, do we believe that LSAPs have a larger marginal benefit in a period of real market
distress or serious deflationary forces than in the stuck-in-the-mud scenario? If so, might there
be an argument for reducing the pace of purchases in the stuck-in-the-mud economy so as to
keep some capacity in reserve? And if we were to reduce the pace of asset purchases at a time
when the outlook for employment and inflation were unsatisfactory, what other actions could we
take to support a stronger recovery and to defend our inflation target?
In summary, at this point, our current framework has provided guidance for what I
consider to be my baseline scenario, and I remain hopeful that things will play out in line with
the program we have outlined. I do, however, think it would be prudent for us to spend more
time developing a plan B for how our asset purchases might evolve under more pessimistic
scenarios and to shape our communications in a way that would smooth the transition to such an
unhappy state.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just in terms of our medium-term
planning, continuing the discussion from the earlier go-round, I will now say somewhat more

October 29–30, 2013

193 of 239

affirmatively that I think it would be worth our individually and collectively thinking more about
the alternative approach that Charlie Plosser suggested, which is to say instead of a tapering
when we are ready to make a change in the LSAP policy, we instead think about announcing a
total amount of the LSAP purchase and then just continue however many months it would take to
get us to that point.
Turning to today’s action, I, like most others, support alternative B. I have more to say
about the language than I normally do, but that is prompted in part by the comments that others
have made. I am in favor not only of retaining the first sentence of paragraph 1 but of actually
strengthening, or at least expanding, it. I mean, it is a positive and not a normative statement. It
is supposed to be, as Charlie Plosser did say, describing a situation as opposed to suggesting a
particular policy action. First, it doesn’t actually suggest that there has been significant fiscal
contraction, other than that which is already ongoing. It simply says it has made it harder to
assess economic conditions during the intermeeting period, which I find actually quite true.
Something that is omitted from that statement, though, is actually the principal reason why I find
the conclusion true, and that is the uncertainty around the lifting of the federal debt ceiling. I
think the effect of the shutdown itself was probably concentrated in Washington and a few other
areas where there were delays in contractor payments being made, and the like, and I think the
staff expects that most of that effect will be reversed in the coming weeks and months. But in
talking to market actors generally, what I found was that the run-up to the uncertainty and the
residue of questions around the federal debt ceiling had more people hitting the pause button on
things that they were thinking about doing. And it is that which, I think, makes things a little bit
more difficult to assess. Will the pre-talk about shutdown and fiscal cliff trend continue through
and be visible by December, or will the effects of the shutdown and the fiscal cliff debate linger

October 29–30, 2013

194 of 239

and be another blow to the general certainty about where the economy is headed? So I would
actually expand the statement to say that “the effects of recent fiscal developments, including the
temporary shutdown of the federal government, uncertainty around the lifting of the federal debt
ceiling, and delays in releases of some key data, have made the evolution of economic conditions
during the intermeeting period somewhat more difficult to assess.”
On the question of the higher mortgage rates, I was under the impression—but this may
be wrong—that existing home sales are more sensitive to mortgage rate changes than new
construction, for some of the reasons I think Richard explained. The only thing I’d say, though,
is if people don’t want to leave the sentence as it is, I guess I would prefer to just delete the last
phrase “in response to higher mortgage rates” rather than to insert “partially.”
I am just going to note in passing, but not suggest a language change, that I am not sure
that I, at this point, fully subscribe to the first sentence of paragraph 3, which I see is now
“consistent with growing underlying strength in the broader economy.” I think that’s actually an
open question at this point, which kind of gets back to the points I was making about paragraph
1. But I definitely do not suggest a change in the language, certainly not at this time.
And, finally, on paragraph 6, I join with many others in thinking that at least at this time
it’s probably better not to include it. Hearing some of you, it sounds as though many of you
would like to maybe see some massaging of the language itself. But in terms of timing, I agree
with what I think Jay said yesterday, and others have echoed, which is that if we are going to do
something like this it is probably better to do it at a time when we have a new SEP, which
confirms the expectation that is in there, and gives the Chairman an opportunity to explain it. On
the downbeat point, I get what people are saying. But if the SEP is downbeat, then it is a little
odd to be too worried about being downbeat in the statement. Maybe there is a reason for that,

October 29–30, 2013

195 of 239

but, as I understand it, the motivation for this language is the SEP. And we have stated our
collective expectations in the SEP, and they are not overly optimistic. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
MR. FISHER. So it’s now the Boston–Western–Lutheran coalition.
MR. TARULLO. No, no. Because they were on the first sentence, I think.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t think Governor Tarullo is Lutheran.
MR. TARULLO. That you’re right about, Mr. Chairman. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Stein.
MR. STEIN. I support alternative B. I don’t mind the first sentence in paragraph 1. I
will also join the growing chorus that wants to kill paragraph 6 of alternative B. I think timing is
part of the argument. If we’re going to do it, we want to do it at a time when we’re tapering.
Massaging the language is also an issue. But I wanted to underscore some of the points that
President Williams made. I think there are some really kind of deeper issues here. One is, if we
go in this direction, it is pretty important to be true to the idea that this is not about making
another commitment, but it is about explaining what the right time-consistent path is likely be.
It’s a delicate thing to do because in our communication, of necessity in recent times, we have, in
some sense, really blurred together the concepts of commitment and communication. We say
things like we are using communication to lower the long-term rate. I mean, communication, on
average, should be kind of like a coin toss, right? These concepts have gotten pretty blurred
together, and it will take some care to unblur them. Otherwise, I think it would be quite easy, if
we are not careful, for the market to basically hear a statement like this as we are promising the
funds rate is going to be 2 percent in 2016, which I think we probably don’t want to do, or I’ll
say I’m not sure I would want to do.

October 29–30, 2013

196 of 239

And, again, this is something that John mentioned. r* is a nice and very, very helpful
theoretical construct, not easily or simply measured. If we sat down and had a staff seminar on
this, I think we would probably be a little hard-pressed to agree on what r* is today. There is this
sort of very model-heavy thing, and there are a lot of measurement issues—the equity premium,
all that kind of stuff, which is not easy to measure. To do this guidance, we are sort of talking
about what we think r* will be in 2016, and whatever your standard errors are around its value
today, they are going to be bigger for future values. Again, that’s not a reason not to do this. I
think it’s perfectly sensible. At some level you have to have a point estimate, and I think it’s
perfectly reasonable to explain and defend the point estimate, but it needs to be done in the
context of understanding. Again, I think we are going to have to move to a regime ultimately
where we are not telling people the funds rate two or three years in advance, and we have to
make sure to communicate that carefully. Thank you.
MR. TARULLO. Just to be clear, Governor Stein, I have very strong convictions around
r*.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Powell.
MR. POWELL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I see the Committee as still operating under
the broad framework for reducing asset purchases that the Chairman articulated after the June
and September meetings. And going forward I see two broad cases. In the first case, the data are
strong enough to credibly warrant tapering and the fiscal negotiations conclude for now without
disruptive consequences. In that case the market will expect taper and the Committee should
taper in keeping with existing guidance. But what to do if the economy continues on more or
less its current path of 2 percent growth, payroll gains that oscillate between decent and meager,
and declining unemployment helped along partly by unwanted declines in the labor force

October 29–30, 2013

197 of 239

participation rate, or, alternatively, perhaps the declines in unemployment will slow or stop as
labor force participation stabilizes? I think, in that broad case, there is a choice to be made. The
Committee can just keep buying $85 billion of securities a month through 2014 and 2015,
indefinitely, what President Lacker referred to as the “hamster wheel scenario.” If we pass the
March meeting with no hint of another potential approach, then I think that is kind of the track
that we’re on. The alternative is to adopt a shift in the mix of tool strategy: gradually bring asset
purchases to a halt by the end of next year, and strengthen forward guidance only if necessary.
And I think the time may be coming to make that change. I hope not. And I’m inclined to favor
this strategy.
In terms of the timing, I think it’s important to look at the calendar, as President Pianalto
was suggesting. We’re about two years away from, in the base case, hitting the natural rate. The
range of natural rate from 6 to, say, low 5s would be hit sometime in 2016—about two years out.
If you think about the red zone of tapering as being March and June, as I think of it now today—
I would like to be wrong, I would like it to be earlier, but probably March or June are the red
zone—we effectively have almost a year of runway for the actual taper, call it nine months. At
about that time, at the end of 2014, you are hitting the unemployment threshold. Then, you have
promised to wait for a considerable period, so you have used up most of 2015 waiting to think
about actually raising rates. At the end of 2015, you are right at the beginning of the zone of the
natural rate, and now you haven’t raised rates at all, so you’ve got to get up to at least 2 percent,
even in our headwinds scenario. I guess I lay all of that out just to say that I don’t see it as in any
way premature to be having this conversation. There has been a tremendous amount of progress
made, and I think it is time to go ahead. And I think doing this in March or June of next year
would in no sense be premature in the base case.

October 29–30, 2013

198 of 239

I think there will be major communications challenges in either of these two cases, but in
the latter case where we are tapering and it’s not a great outcome, I would still emphasize the
extent of progress. I would emphasize that the program has broadly achieved the goal that the
Committee set forward of substantial improvement in the outlook for the labor market, and I
would use the Chairman’s three talking points of data-dependence, stock of progress, and
independence of tools as well.
It seems to me that it will still never be a great idea to talk about the inefficacy of asset
purchases, and I’m with President Bullard on this. I would just point out that, in my opinion,
there have been several occasions on which it would have been appropriate to taper, ignoring, for
the moment, the question of the market’s preparation. For example, June was a time of
significant optimism about the economy, with big payroll numbers. Of course, the market was
not ready for it. My point is that the Committee doesn’t have to choose a time that minimizes its
credibility. If it comes to this, it is appropriate to wait and taper at a time when credibility is
higher in terms of payroll numbers and the other tests we have laid out for ourselves.
In terms of the statement, I have heard all of the arguments. I guess I would come down:
take the first sentence out, take the last sentence out, take out “in response to higher mortgage
rates,” take it all out. [Laughter] Leave it blank. And I do kind of think we are all over fiscal
policy here. We’ve got two other mentions of it. It starts to sound like a little too much. It is
nice to mention fiscal policy, but we are doing it twice already. Those are the things I would do.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I favor alt-B. In general I think we’ve managed to get
financial conditions back to a good place in which we can expect them to be supportive of the

October 29–30, 2013

199 of 239

economy, and if this is sustained that should help generate the pickup in the overall growth rate
that we’re seeking so that we can actually be confident of seeing substantial improvement in the
labor market outlook. I think we don’t want to disturb that situation at this meeting. That
implies to me a very minimalist approach in terms of the statement.
In terms of the suggested language changes, the only one I feel strongly about is I don’t
like paragraph 6 because I think the timing is odd in the sense that you’re not going to be able to
explain it. People are going to wonder, “Why are you doing this now?” We’ve already gotten
the concept out. And, two, I just don’t think the language is very good. I mean, I’ve read the
sentence many times, and it’s just a really complicated sentence. So both in terms of timing and
in terms of sentence structure I don’t really like it. I don’t disagree with the concept at all. I
think the concept is the right one. It helps explain why the median of the SEP projections is at
2 percent in 2016. I think it’s important to flesh that out, but I don’t think it’s good for this
statement. In terms of the other suggested changes, I could go either way. The reality is the first
sentence, as written, is accurate. It’s just a question of is it important enough to include in the
statement or not? And in response to higher mortgage rates, I’m happy taking it out. I mean, the
reality is that paragraph 1 is really supposed to be more of a statement just about what we’re
seeing in terms of the data rather than having causal effects in there. So I guess I’m largely in
favor taking out “in response to higher mortgage rates.”
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. I guess there have been some pretty
clear suggestions as far as language in alt-B. Personally, I don’t think the first sentence of B(1)
is all that harmful. It does explain why this meeting has been sort of not, in some sense, as active
a meeting as it otherwise would be. But given the sense of the Committee, I guess I propose that
we cut out all the red in B(1)and start the first sentence of B(1) with “information received.”

October 29–30, 2013

200 of 239

We’ll cut down through “however.” I have no objection to eliminating “in response to higher
mortgage rates” and just simply saying, “While the recovery in the housing sector slowed
somewhat in recent months.” Is there any concern about that? [No response.] Seeing none.
B(6) was a close call. [Laughter] I’m just joking. B(6) is apparently before its time, like a fine
wine, and so I would suggest that what we would do here is simply go back to paragraph B(5)
from September, which essentially means taking the first sentence of B(6), putting it back in
B(5) without change, and then eliminating the last sentence.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. You would not have the word “eventually”?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. No. Paragraph B(5) is identical to B(5) in September
MR. EVANS. Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes.
MR. EVANS. While you’re on the last paragraph, could I ask a question, motivated by
an observation that Governor Stein made, which I think is perfectly accurate. When we talk
about the equilibrium real interest rate and if you put us in a room and we tried to say what the
standard errors are around that, I’m pretty confident that it would be measured in percentage
points or things like that, right? So to say that it’s 2 or whatever it is, we don’t have a lot of
confidence. However, from the previous discussion, I thought what this paragraph was trying to
get at was the fact that the SEP in 2016 was showing a funds rate well below what we’ve all said
is the long-run neutral rate of 4 percent while we had the unemployment rate close to our
assessment of the natural rate and inflation close to our inflation objective. If I take it at face
value that there’s no puzzle about the real interest rate, the implication is that there’s no puzzle
for the funds rate being 2 percent; the errors around what we say are so large that you shouldn’t
have to explain that as a puzzle. But I thought this was being offered as—I fully expect to get

October 29–30, 2013

201 of 239

questions about this—this is a puzzle. So therefore, there must be more force behind this. There
must be something inherent in our outlook that suggests to us that we know more about the real
rate than it’s just, unconditionally, 1 or 2 percentage points. That’s just a question.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. So I took the sense of the meeting, and in the interest of
time, I just struck it. But I actually think that there’s some value to this at some point. The SEP
in September showed that a substantial majority of the participants expected the funds rate to be
quite below 4 percent at the end of 2016; 2 percent was a median value. I explained it in the
September meeting along these lines, and the minutes of the September meeting also said that
most people around the table said this headwinds explanation was the right one. And you can
certainly tell the story that given the headwinds—including the fiscal, which is pretty
measurable—we think we can achieve full employment, but we’re going to have to do it at lower
interest rates. I mean, obviously that involves Wicksellian concepts and r* and so on, but you
certainly can explain it without any highly complex economic points.
MR. EVANS. That’s right, but what I was trying to get at is I think that Governor Stein
is exactly correct to say a single statistic doesn’t have a lot of power to shed light on whether or
not real rates are, in an equilibrium sense, low because of the headwinds that we’re facing. But
if you get more power from our forecast and everything else that we bring to bear, you’re led to
make these types of Wicksellian interpretations. Yes, I agree completely with your point myself.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Like I said, we put it in because we thought it would help
explain the September SEP and would get the imprimatur of the Committee that the Committee
thinks that low interest rate policies are likely to be necessary for some time. That all being said,
clearly there are a lot of issues here, and it’s something we can continue to discuss as part of our

October 29–30, 2013

202 of 239

broader context of guidance and so on, but I did think it was worth discussing anyway. So I’m
proposing that we go back to B(5).
MR. EVANS. It strikes me that all of those arguments push back a little bit against the
argument that Governor Stein was making, that there’s so much uncertainty we can’t really have
confidence our estimate.
MR. STEIN: No, let me if I may.
MR. EVANS. Absolutely.
MR. STEIN: I think I may have kind of sidetracked us a little bit. Really all I meant to
do was to underscore this distinction between it’s our best forecast and the headwind story is the
leading story versus we’re pretty sure that the right funds rate is going to be 2 percent, and that
there are standard errors more in the time series than in the cross section.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Market participants have commented: How do they
know what the rate is going to be in 2016? So I think your point that there’s just a lot of
dispersion around that is certainly true.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That is certainly true, but we do have a modal forecast, and
it’s consequential. People who are buying and selling 30-year bonds have to make some kind of
judgment about what r* is.
MR. EVANS. Right. No, I am in complete agreement with your explanation.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. The other two comments that I have here are President
Williams on elaborating the forward guidance and President Pianalto on strengthening the
statement about asset purchases. I think the thrust of the meeting was to keep things simple
today. I would comment, President Pianalto, I see where you’re coming from, although there is a
sentence very similar to what you suggested in the next paragraph, I think in paragraph 4: “In

October 29–30, 2013

203 of 239

judging when to moderate the pace of asset purchases, the Committee will in coming meetings
assess whether incoming information,” and so on. It’s pretty much in the same spirit of the
sentence that you suggested.
On President Williams, I found your suggestion about talking about that part of the
forward curve being useful, and that’s the reason we put this language in alt-A. But, again, I
think the thrust of the discussion on strategy was that we should take a holistic approach to the
refining of our guidance and be careful not to do it in too much of a piecemeal way. So I would
propose that we defer that.
Just to summarize, the suggestions I’m proposing on alt-B are dropping the first sentence,
dropping the phrase “in response to higher mortgage rates” in B(1), and going back to the old
B(5) from the previous meeting. Are there any questions, comments, reactions? President
Evans.
MR. EVANS. I’d just like to restate. I don’t prefer the path that you’re taking with
regard to the first sentence. I think that the first paragraph is going to appear odd because there’s
nothing in the statement that even acknowledges the events since our September meeting. If you
try to make the type of commentary that some have made like, “Oh, don’t we feel better about
the decision that we took in September because of what happened after September with regard to
the government,” there’s nothing in this statement that gives rise to that justification. It’s close
to clueless on that score.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Again, I thought this was a reasonable thing to do. The one
argument though that I heard that made me stop and think was there’s a bit of discussion in
markets about how in January and in February and in March there’s going to be yet further
rounds of debt brinksmanship and shutdowns and so on and so on, and we don’t want to give the

October 29–30, 2013

204 of 239

impression that we’re completely unable to make policy decisions whenever there’s any kind of
fiscal issue.
MR. EVANS. I would have preferred a lighter touch, which simply made an
acknowledgement of delays in data. I did not take that first sentence to really indicate that the
actions have been really negative for the economy. But a way to offset that a little bit would be
to at least add a few words around “fiscal policy is restraining economic growth a bit more than
we anticipated last time” or something that at least is a delta with regard to the government
effects.
MR. TARULLO. I agree with President Evans. I think this is going to look odd.
MR. FISHER. May I, Mr. Chairman? I disagree because there are two references about
fiscal policy; there’s one in that very paragraph.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes. We talk about fiscal policy, but not the fiscal debates.
MR. FISHER. You could say “fiscal policy and indecision” if you wanted to.
MR. TARULLO. But just to be clear, there is a difference between, on the one hand,
talking about the effect of fiscal policy when we are making a judgment about the effect that
contracting fiscal policy has had upon the economy and, on the other hand, saying that it’s been
more difficult to assess exactly what the effects are. Obviously I’m not going to vote against this
just because of it. But I think there’s been a lack of precision in people’s critiques.
MR. FISHER. If I may just add, Mr. Chairman, I don’t disagree with you. What I worry
about is the trap it sets for the future. That is, we’re going to have these arguments continually.
We might have another fight about the debt ceiling. I don’t know if Senator Murray and
Congressman Ryan are able to resolve this or not. It’s our ninth commission in the past three
years. I don’t want to be trapped by this, as the Chairman just said, into not acting in the future,

October 29–30, 2013

205 of 239

and I believe it sets a precedent for doing that. I agree that it has limited the amount of
information. I even used that phrase. It doesn’t match the instrument panel in the picture I gave,
but I think including it here unfortunately has long-term consequences, which I would prefer to
avoid. That’s my counterargument, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me offer a possible suggestion
for a lighter touch that I’m sure all sides will—well, we’ll see. [Laughter]
MR. EVANS. I stand to get nothing. So anything is better.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. So the proposed opening sentence for alternative B begins
with the word “information.” I would propose adding the three words “the relatively limited” at
the beginning of that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. No, I think that’s a little too strong. Is there enough support
for revisiting this that we should start taking a straw vote or anything like that? Yes?
MR. EVANS. I’d take it to a straw vote.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Is there any interest in Governor Tarullo’s suggestion,
something like “the effects of the temporary shutdown of the federal government, including
delays in release of some data, and uncertainty surrounding the debt ceiling debate have
made . . .”? Is there any interest in expanding it that way?
MR. TARULLO. You could also, Mr. Chairman, put it at the end of paragraph 1 rather
than at the beginning. I thought at least some of what I heard was some concern that it was the
principal thing to which we were addressing ourselves. But, as Charlie says, at this point we’re
open to taking anything. [Laughter]

October 29–30, 2013

206 of 239

MR. EVANS. Even if you change the simple sentence “fiscal policies restraining
economic growth,” to “fiscal policy continues to restrain economic growth,” the way this will be
interpreted is they’re going to put the two statements side by side and they will notice a delta. At
least it will indicate thought. That’s all, but at the moment it seems to provide zero thought on
that, and that’s just a risk that we’re talking.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You could say “fiscal policy and fiscal debates are
restraining.”
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. You could say “fiscal policy developments.” Because
that’s a little bit broader.
MR. EVANS. I’m not arguing that we need to say the shutdown had a big effect. I’m
just saying it has made it somewhat more challenging to assess.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Mr. Chairman, I’ll speak in favor of just doing what you initially
proposed, which was to eliminate the first sentence and eliminate the “however.” I just think that
everyone is well aware that the fiscal policy debate and the fiscal uncertainty are affecting the
macroeconomic outlook, and it is certainly affecting the deliberations of this Committee. The
effect of this statement will be to say we’re standing pat for today and we’re not really doing
anything today, and we’re not trying to send any messages today. And we understand that lots of
things are happening in the world, but we’re just standing pat for today.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. I agree with President Bullard. It’s worth pointing out the extent to
which the staff’s assessment is that the effect of what happened is purely transitory. We may get
another one in January, but again, it’s going to be a purely transitory thing.

October 29–30, 2013

207 of 239

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. To keep things simple how about I ask for a
straw vote just to get a sense of the Committee, and if it’s okay, the options are keeping the
sentence as written and dropping the sentence? Is that all right? Is that acceptable? Okay. All
in favor of keeping the sentence as written please raise your hand. [Show of hands] One, two,
three, four, five, six. Okay. All in favor of dropping the sentence. [Show of hands] One, two,
three, four, five. Okay. The Lutherans carry [laughter]—
MR. TARULLO: More religious clashing.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Another religious fight. Okay. We’re back to where we
were. We’re going to drop the sentence. We’ll drop the phrase “in response to higher mortgage
rates,” and we’ll restore B(5). For the last time, Ms. Danker, would you please call the roll?
MS. DANKER: Yes. This vote is on the alternative B, as the Chairman just described,
and the associated directive.
Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Dudley
President Bullard
President Evans
President George
Governor Powell
President Rosengren
Governor Stein
Governor Tarullo
Governor Yellen

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you very much. Lunch should be available
now. Please get your lunch and bring it back if you would like to hear Linda Robertson give an
update on congressional and legislative issues.
The next meeting is Tuesday and Wednesday, December 17 through 18. The meeting is
adjourned. Thank you.
END OF MEETING