View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

October 28–29, 2008

1 of 206

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on
October 28–29, 2008
A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in the offices of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C., on Tuesday, October 28, 2008,
at 2:00 p.m., and continued on Wednesday, October 29, 2008, at 9:00 a.m. Those present were
the following:
Mr. Bernanke, Chairman
Mr. Geithner, Vice Chairman
Ms. Duke
Mr. Fisher
Mr. Kohn
Mr. Kroszner
Ms. Pianalto
Mr. Plosser
Mr. Stern
Mr. Warsh
Ms. Cumming, Messrs. Evans, Lacker, and Lockhart, and Ms. Yellen, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Bullard, Hoenig, and Rosengren, Presidents of the Federal Reserve Banks of St.
Louis, Kansas City, and Boston, respectively
Mr. Madigan, Secretary and Economist
Ms. Danker, Deputy Secretary
Mr. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary
Ms. Smith, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Alvarez, General Counsel
Mr. Baxter, Deputy General Counsel
Mr. Sheets, Economist
Mr. Stockton, Economist
Messrs. Connors, English, and Kamin, Ms. Mester, Messrs. Rosenblum, Slifman,
Sniderman, and Wilcox, Associate Economists
Mr. Dudley, Manager, System Open Market Account
Ms. Bailey, Deputy Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board of
Governors
Mr. Clouse, Deputy Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Mr. Blanchard, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors

October 28–29, 2008

2 of 206

Mr. Struckmeyer,¹ Deputy Staff Director, Office of Staff Director for Management,
Board of Governors
Messrs. Reifschneider and Wascher, Associate Directors, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors
Messrs. Levin and Nelson, Associate Directors, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Ms. Kole, Assistant Director, Division of International Finance, Board of Governors
Mr. McCarthy, Visiting Reserve Bank Officer, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Mr. Oliner, Senior Adviser, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Mr. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Messrs. Bassett and Luecke, Section Chiefs, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Mr. Morin, Senior Economist, Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors
Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Specialist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
Mr. Moore, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland
Mr. Fuhrer, Executive Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Messrs. Altig and McAndrews, Ms. Mosser, Messrs. Rasche, Sullivan, and Williams,
Senior Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta, New York, New York, St.
Louis, Chicago, and San Francisco, respectively
Messrs. Clark and Hornstein, Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of Kansas City and
Richmond, respectively
Mr. Weber, Senior Research Officer, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

_______________
¹ Attended Wednesday’s session only.

October 28–29, 2008

3 of 206

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on
October 28-29, 2008
October 28, 2008—Afternoon Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good afternoon, everybody. We received requests from
members for more time at this meeting to discuss the economic situation and our policy
response. So as you know, we postponed the special presentations on inflation—my apologies to
the presenters. We will come back to that at the appropriate time.
What we are going to do instead is to have three rounds of briefings today and tomorrow.
We are going to start in the first round with Bill Dudley and his usual presentation on open
market operations, followed by Nathan Sheets on the swaps proposals that you have been
informed about, and then Bill Bassett will give a supplementary briefing on financial markets to
complete that round. Then we’ll have Q&A at that point. We will then turn to the economic
situation and hear from Norm Morin on the nonfinancial economy and Linda Kole on the
international economy and from Brian Madigan on our projections. Then we will have another
round of questions. Tomorrow at lunch, after the close of the formal meeting, we will have some
additional briefings on the TARP (troubled asset relief program), on the FDIC program, and on
the supervisory and regulatory implications of that. So we hope to make this a very informative
two days, and we hope to have plenty of interaction and conversation about our broad policy
response to these very difficult times. So let me start, then, by turning to Bill Dudley. Bill.
MR. DUDLEY. 1 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Today my attention will be
narrower than usual, given the briefings by Bill Bassett and Linda Kole that will
follow covering the broader developments in the equity, fixed income, and foreign
exchange markets in the United States and abroad, which have been considerable
over the past six weeks. I will focus on three topics: (1) the impact of our new
facilities and other government initiatives on market function, (2) the consequences of
the expansion of these facilities on our balance sheet and our ability to hit the federal
funds rate target over time, and (3) the travails of the hedge fund community and how
1

The materials used by Mr. Dudley are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

October 28–29, 2008

4 of 206

this could potentially add to market dysfunction. I will be referring to the chart
package that should be in front of you.
As you all know, the Lehman bankruptcy led to sharp outflows from prime money
market mutual funds into Treasury-only funds (exhibit 1). The result was a collapse
in Treasury bill yields (exhibit 2). At the same time, the cost of financing Treasury
securities via repo fell sharply—this is illustrated in exhibit 3 by the drop in the
overnight general collateral (GC) repo rate. This increased the incentive for Treasury
traders to short Treasury securities that were already hard to obtain because the
effective cost of borrowing such securities is determined by the level of the GC repo
rate. As a result, Treasury fails, which represent Treasury securities that are not
delivered as promised to their buyers, soared. Treasury fails were also exacerbated
by the withdrawal from the securities lending market of some large holders of
Treasuries, including some major foreign central banks. Although Treasury yields
fell sharply and Treasury bills were in great demand, the rise in fails resulted in a
sharp diminution of trading and liquidity in the Treasury securities market. The fact
that there are severe market-functioning problems in the asset class that is in greatest
demand—Treasuries—underscores the scope and severity of the markets’ broader
dysfunction.
At the same time, the outflows from prime money market funds led to a sharp
drop in the demand for commercial paper, a significant rise in commercial paper
rates, and a shortening of commercial paper maturities (exhibits 4 and 5). Term bank
funding spreads rose sharply, with the one-month and three-month LIBOR–OIS
spreads increasing to levels that make the earlier peaks look like modest speed bumps
(exhibits 6 and 7). The Lehman bankruptcy caused counterparty risk concerns to
intensify. Moreover, the Lehman bankruptcy disrupted a number of markets because
participants in these markets were uncertain how to adjust their long- and shortposition exposures that offset their open positions with Lehman. The result was a
sharp drop in the willingness of counterparties to engage with one another, especially
at term. Essentially, the result was a massive coordination problem that has led to a
very unattractive equilibrium. I would put it this way: “I won’t lend to you even
though I think you’re okay because I am not sure others will lend to you either. I
need some assurance that others will lend to you in order to have some assurance I
can get my money back if I need it.” Even though it has been in the interest of all
parties to engage, no party has been willing to go first.
In response, the Federal Reserve dramatically expanded its programs of liquidity
support. The size of each TAF auction has been raised to $150 billion—the same size
as the entire TAF program just six weeks ago. Fixed-rate tender dollar auctions were
implemented by the BoE, the BoJ, the ECB, and the SNB. The asset-backed
commercial paper money market mutual fund liquidity facility (AMLF) and the
commercial paper funding facility (CPFF) were implemented, and plans for a money
market investor funding facility (MMIFF) were announced. The Federal Reserve and
other central banks stepped forward to engage in transactions with a broad range of
bank and, in the case of the Fed, nonbank counterparties. The hope, of course, is that

October 28–29, 2008

5 of 206

this willingness to engage will reduce rollover risk and therefore encourage others to
re-engage with their counterparties.
At least for now, the escalation in the size of the TAF auctions appears to have
been sufficient to satisfy the demand for dollar funds in the United States. As shown
in exhibit 8, the first two auctions of $150 billion have been slightly undersubscribed.
Currently, about $300 billion of TAF credit is outstanding. Demand for dollar
funding in Europe has increased sharply even though the cost is much higher than in
our TAF auctions. Whereas the two most recent TAF auctions were stopped out at
the OIS rate, which is the minimum bid rate, the foreign fixed-rate tender operations
have been conducted at a rate of OIS plus 100 basis points. As shown in exhibits 9
and 10, swap outstandings have grown to nearly $500 billion currently. The ECB
swap size is currently about $280 billion, more than half the total amount of swaps
outstanding. The amount of outstanding swaps is likely to climb sharply when the
first 84-day fixed-rate tender operations are conducted in Europe next week.
The CPFF facility is another important element in the Fed’s program of liquidity
escalation. As you know, this facility provides a backstop for domestic issuers of
A1/P1-rated commercial paper. Issuers can sell commercial paper to the facility at
three-month term for an effective cost of OIS plus 200 basis points for nonfinancial
and financial issuers and OIS plus 300 basis points for asset-backed commercial
paper (ABCP). This facility complements the AMLF, which lends funds to banks at
the primary credit facility rate against the ABCP purchased from money market
mutual funds. Yesterday was the first day that the CPFF was open for business, and a
number of borrowers issued commercial paper to the facility totaling more than
$50 billion. At the close of business last week, 79 issuers had registered to use the
facility, paying 10 basis points, or $580 million, to cover the potential issuance of
commercial paper. The 10 basis point fee provides a little equity to get the program
off and running.
Finally, the most recent facility, the money market investor funding facility, was
announced last week. This facility will provide liquidity to five conduits that will
purchase commercial paper and certificates of deposit of designated issuers from 2a-7
money market mutual funds. It will likely be several more weeks before this facility
is operational.
The escalation in the provision of liquidity and some of the other initiatives I will
discuss shortly have led to a grudging improvement in the interbank funding markets
and in the commercial paper market. Reviewing the earlier exhibits, most term
funding spreads have narrowed, but the improvement is modest relative to the earlier
deterioration. It is unclear at this stage whether the modest extent of improvement
reflects the limited ability of additional capacity and breadth in terms of liquidity
provision to restore confidence, especially at a time that the macroeconomic outlook
has deteriorated globally, or whether it will just take time for these liquidity facilities
to restore confidence and some semblance of normality to the money markets.

October 28–29, 2008

6 of 206

The expansion of the Fed’s liquidity provisions has been accompanied by
escalations on two other fronts. First, the FDIC announced a bank funding guarantee
program. Although the terms and conditions of this program have not yet been
finalized, the program is likely to guarantee most of the new senior debt obligations
of participating depository institutions and their associated holding companies up to a
cap of 125 percent of the maturing obligations through June 30, 2009. Importantly,
new interbank funding will be covered. How this affects the federal funds market
remains to be seen. Second, the Treasury has committed $250 billion of funds from
the TARP program to inject as preferred stock into the banking system. Nine large
banks announced two weeks ago that they will accept $125 billion of preferred stock
investment from the Treasury. Over the past few days, the Treasury announced that
an additional $35 billion of capital has been committed. The FDIC guarantee
announcement and the TARP capital infusion have been effective in shoring up
confidence in the major U.S. banks. As shown in exhibits 11 and 12, credit default
swap spreads for most major U.S. financial institutions have narrowed sharply.
But the guarantee of the senior debt of depository institutions and their associated
holding companies has generated some unintended consequences for those firms not
covered by these guarantees. In particular, the credit default swap spreads for major
nonbank financials have narrowed less than those for the banks (exhibit 13).
Moreover, the funding costs for the GSEs have climbed, especially for short-term
discount note issuance. The funding costs for Fannie and Freddie for both long-term
and short-term debt are shown in exhibits 14, 15, and 16. However, the fear that
funds would flow out of prime money market funds back into bank assets guaranteed
by the FDIC has not been realized—at least not yet.
The expansion of the Fed’s facilities and the open-ended nature of the fixed-rate
tender dollar operations by the foreign central banks that we are funding by swaps
have led to rapid expansion of our balance sheet. Exhibit 17 provides a snapshot of
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet at different times before and during the crisis.
During the first 13 months, the size of our balance sheet was little changed. We
accommodated our liquidity programs mainly by selling Treasury securities. During
the next stage, which began around the time of the Lehman bankruptcy filing, we
expanded our balance sheet but drained the reserve additions primarily by having the
Treasury issue supplemental financing program bills and placing the proceeds on our
balance sheet. However, the capacity to continue to drain reserves via SFP bills was
unlikely to be a long-term solution because the Treasury would ultimately be
constrained by the debt limit ceiling.
The passage of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 granted the
Federal Reserve the authority to pay interest on reserves immediately. This was very
important because it meant that we could expand our balance sheet size by
unsterilized reserve additions but at the same time keep the federal funds rate from
crashing to zero by paying a positive interest rate on holdings of excess reserves.
Further rapid balance sheet expansion appears inevitable as the takedown from the
TAF auctions and the fixed-rate tenders expands further and as our new facilities,

October 28–29, 2008

7 of 206

such as the CPFF and MMIFF, begin operation. Although the estimates shown for
year-end in exhibit 17 are indicative—the actual size will be driven by the use of our
various liquidity facilities—it does seem likely that the Federal Reserve System’s
balance sheet will grow very rapidly through year-end. We are now nearly three
weeks into the new interest-on-reserves regime, which was implemented on
October 9. As you know, the Board of Governors initially set the spread between the
target federal funds rate and the rate paid on excess reserves at 75 basis points.
Policymakers erred on the size of a wide margin given unsettled market conditions
and the lack of experience with the new regime, recognizing that the spread could be
reduced if the federal funds rate traded soft relative to the target.
As shown in exhibit 18, despite the payment of interest on reserves, the federal
funds rate has continued to trade soft relative to the target. As a result, the Board
narrowed the spread to 35 basis points with the start last Thursday of the second
reserve maintenance period under the interest-on-reserves regime. It is too soon to
assess the effect of the narrower spread on our ability to push the federal funds rate
back up to the target because the interest rate paid on reserves is based upon the
lowest target federal funds rate during the reserve maintenance period. So currently it
is hard to separate the impact of the narrower spread on the effective federal funds
rate from the expectations for further cuts in the target federal funds rate that might
occur at this meeting. There are two complications in fixing the interest-on-reserves
spread at a level consistent with the target. First, some of the GSEs, which hold
balances at the Fed, are not allowed to earn interest on their balances. Thus they have
to sell federal funds to banks that, in turn, hold the funds and are paid the interest-onreserves rate. Second, some banks have also been selling federal funds below the
interest-on-reserves rate. We expect this to diminish over time as they gain more
experience with the new regime. However, other factors, such as concern with their
overall leverage ratios, could cause this phenomenon to persist. As a result, there has
been a significant amount of federal funds rate trading below the interest-on-reserves
rate. This is illustrated in exhibit 19, in which the circles are sized to reflect the
amount of trading at a particular rate level.
This trading of fed funds below the interest-on-reserves rate has two
consequences. First, it blurs the meaning of the effective federal funds rate with
respect to its relationship to the stance of monetary policy. Conceptually, the intereston-reserves rate, rather than the effective federal funds rate, could be viewed as
representing the default risk-free investment rate for banks. Second, it implies that
we may have to narrow considerably further the spread between the target federal
funds rate and the interest rate paid on excess reserves in order to push the effective
federal funds rate up to the target. In principle, if fed funds sales were to continue in
large volume below the interest-on-reserves rate, the interest-on-reserves rate might
need to be set right at the federal funds rate target in order to support the federal funds
rate close to that level.
Before turning to a discussion of monetary policy and inflation expectations, I
want to make a few comments about the hedge fund industry. Before this crisis

October 28–29, 2008

8 of 206

began, most of the fears about a market meltdown were focused on hedge funds.
Until now, these fears have been mostly misplaced. However, the risks that hedge
fund problems will now exacerbate the crisis have increased substantially recently.
The underlying problem is that the recent performance of the hedge fund industry has
been very poor and hedge fund viability is not very robust when net asset values slip
considerably below their high-water marks in individual funds. September was the
poorest month in the past 10 years, and so far October returns are on pace to be even
worse. Net asset value for the entire hedge fund industry is down more than
10 percent year-to-date. The average performance, shown in exhibit 20, masks
substantial dispersion in returns and particularly poor performance for certain
strategies. In particular, convertible arbitrage, emerging market arbitrage, and fixedincome arbitrage strategies suffered double-digit losses in the month of September,
and further losses are likely in October.
Poor hedge fund performance has been exacerbated by several factors. First,
policy shifts such as the short sales ban have caused big problems for convertible
arbitrage, statistical arbitrage, and long/short equity strategies. This has been an
important factor behind Citadel’s travails. Second, prime brokers continue to pull
back in their willingness to provide financing by raising their haircuts assessed
against hedge fund assets as market volatility rises (exhibit 21). Third, investors are
pulling funds out of hedge funds because of their poor performance and a generalized
increase in risk aversion. As a result, hedge funds are raising cash to meet actual and
potential redemptions, and many hedge funds are either hitting or approaching their
net asset value trigger points.
Let me say a few words about net asset value triggers. Hedge funds often
negotiate agreements with each of their prime brokers that set the terms for their
access to financing. These contracts give the prime brokers the option to seize and
liquidate collateral if the hedge fund net asset value falls by more than a certain
magnitude—say, a 30 percent decline in assets under management over a three-month
period; that’s a very common trigger. Obviously, if only a few hedge funds are close
to these triggers, there is little problem as there is no potential flood of asset sales into
the market. But when so many hedge funds are under pressure at the same time, the
risk of broader asset liquidation increases. The prime broker may have a lessened
incentive to waive its right to liquidate collateral when a greater proportion of the
industry is troubled because the first-mover advantage of selling collateral likely
becomes more important under such circumstances.
I anticipate that the pressure from the liquidation of hedge fund assets will
continue to weigh on financial markets over the next few months. Some major fund
of fund managers anticipate redemptions between now and early 2009 of at least
25 percent of the total industry, or about $500 billion based upon the estimated
$2 trillion size of the global hedge fund business.
Market participants continue to price in additional cuts in the federal funds rate
target. Of course, it is a little harder than usual to tell what they are expecting based

October 28–29, 2008

9 of 206

on futures prices because the federal funds rate has traded soft relative to the target
and those expectations are also embedded in the near-term rates for fed funds futures
contracts. Regardless of the cause, if you look at exhibits 22 and 23, there has been a
fairly sharp downward shift in the federal funds rate curve and the Eurodollar futures
curve—they have shifted downward about 100 basis points. Moreover, the curves are
considerably flatter than they were a few months ago, indicating that market
participants expect that the FOMC will be slow to raise the federal funds target in
2009. Our primary dealer survey indicates that most survey respondents expect the
Committee to lower the target federal funds rate over the next two meetings to around
1 percent and keep it there through most of 2009. This also represents a downward
shift of about 100 basis points from the survey conducted before the September 16
meeting (exhibits 24 and 25). When the survey was conducted more than a week ago,
the majority of respondents anticipated a 25 basis point cut. Since then, the
consensus has flipped, with most now anticipating a 50 basis point rate cut at this
meeting.
On the inflation expectations front, normal relationships between TIPS and
nominal Treasuries have been distorted by the illiquidity of TIPS relative to nominal
Treasuries and the high level of chronic fails in the five-year sector of the nominal
Treasury market. As a result, TIPS yields have climbed sharply relatively to nominal
Treasuries, leading to a sharp fall in breakeven inflation measures (exhibit 26). The
fact that breakeven inflation rates have fallen more sharply in the five-year sector
than in the ten-year sector has generated a rise in five-year, five-year-forward
measures of inflation (exhibit 27). The distortions in the U.S. Treasury market
suggest considerable caution in interpreting the rise in these measures. Interestingly,
our Desk survey of primary dealers shows a slight drop in long-term inflation
expectations since the September survey (exhibit 28).
Before concluding, let me note that the staff recommends approval of a
$15 billion foreign exchange swap line with the Reserve Bank of New Zealand to
help satisfy the dollar funding needs of banks that operate in New Zealand. As noted
in the memo to the Committee from Nathan Sheets and myself that was distributed on
Friday, this would complement the swap agreements that we have already enacted
with other advanced economies and would have the same technical features as those
with the smaller advanced countries (that is, Australia, Denmark, Norway, and
Sweden) with fixed swap line limits. Nathan will be discussing the potential for
additional swap line authorizations for four emerging market countries recommended
by the staff that were discussed in a second memo to the Committee on Friday.
There were no foreign operations during this period. I request a vote to ratify the
operations of the System Open Market Account that have been undertaken since the
September 16 FOMC meeting. Nathan will continue our presentation.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, Bill. Nathan.

October 28–29, 2008

10 of 206

MR. SHEETS. In response to intensified global financial stresses, the central
banks of four major emerging market economies—Mexico, Brazil, Korea, and
Singapore—have recently expressed interest in temporary liquidity swap lines with
the Federal Reserve. For the reasons outlined in our background memo, which was
circulated on Friday, the staff recommends that the Committee approve these
requests. We propose that the lines be sized at $30 billion for each of these four
countries, similar to our existing lines with Canada, Sweden, and Australia. We
envision that these lines would expire on April 30, 2009, as is the case with our other
swap lines.
We also recommend that these lines have several safeguards relative to our lines
with central banks in the advanced economies. Notably, even following initial
FOMC approval, the proposed lines could not be drawn on without further
authorization, and individual drawings would be limited to $5 billion. We
recommend that the FOMC delegate to its Foreign Currency Subcommittee the
authority to approve these drawings. The subcommittee would ensure that the dollars
drawn would be used in a manner consistent with the purposes of the swap
agreement. The central banks in these countries would also agree to publicly
announce the fact that they had drawn on their lines and the mechanisms that they had
used to allocate the dollar liquidity. These safeguards are designed to provide
protections for Federal Reserve resources and to ensure that the swap lines are used in
a manner consistent with our envisioned objectives. These safeguards, however, are
not intended to be so onerous as to discourage the use of the lines if the situation
warrants.
We see the case for these swap lines as resting on three important observations.
First, each of these economies has significant economic and financial mass. Mexico,
Brazil, and Korea are all large economies with GDP of around $1 trillion, and
Singapore is a major financial center. Given the structural interconnectedness of the
global economy and the financial fragilities that now prevail, a further intensification
of stresses in one or more of these countries could trigger unwelcome spillovers for
both the U.S. economy and the international economy more generally. Our
interdependencies with Mexico are particularly pronounced. Second, these
economies have generally pursued prudent policies in recent years, resulting in low
inflation and roughly balanced current account and fiscal positions or, in the case of
Singapore, sizable surpluses. Accordingly, the stresses that these countries are
feeling seem largely to reflect financial contagion effects from the advanced
economies, including sharp reductions in risk appetite, rapid deleveraging by global
investors, and a drying up of liquidity in dollar funding markets. Third, there is good
reason to believe that swap lines with the Federal Reserve would be helpful in
defusing the economic and financial pressures that they now face. These lines would
promote financial stability by helping to ensure that financial institutions and
corporations in these countries have access to dollar liquidity. Dollar funding
pressures in Brazil and Korea appear to have intensified significantly. Such pressures
remain less acute in Mexico and Singapore, but the authorities there view these lines
as valuable protection should such pressures intensify, particularly over year-end. In

October 28–29, 2008

11 of 206

addition, the authorities in these countries have expressed the view that these lines
could provide a significant boost to confidence, although such outcomes are
admittedly hard to predict.
I turn now to two questions that have been the focus of energetic deliberations
among the staff as we have formulated these proposals. First, is there some better
approach that we could recommend? Second, what are the risks associated with
initiating swap facilities with these emerging market economies, or EMEs?
As for the first question, we could ask these countries to rely on their sizable
stocks of foreign exchange reserves. Across many contingencies, we believe that
these countries do have sufficient resources to address financial pressures on their
own. Consistent with this observation, they don’t have any immediate plans to draw
on their swap lines. In this sense, the lines serve as a backstop. However, in the
event of intensified stresses, we believe that it would be desirable for these countries
to able to meet the dollar funding needs of their institutions by drawing on the swaps
rather than by going into the Treasury or agency markets to liquefy their foreign
exchange reserves. Alternatively, we could ask these countries to go to the IMF.
Tomorrow, the Fund is likely to approve a large, rapidly disbursing facility that might
be appropriate. That said, we see the IMF’s efforts in this area as broadly
complementary to those of the Federal Reserve. Meeting the potential liquidity needs
of these large countries would strain the available resources of the Fund. Conversely,
the Fund is much better placed than we are to judge the liquidity needs of smaller,
less systemically important countries. As an additional consideration, these top-tier
EMEs that we are recommending for swap lines are very reluctant to return to the
IMF. Given the strength of their policies, they no longer view themselves as clients
of the Fund and would prefer to go it alone rather than seek IMF financial support.
We note that there are indeed risks associated with our recommendation. One
obvious concern is that the swaps might not be repaid. However, given the large
reserve holdings of these countries, their prudent policies, the weight they place on
good relations with us, and the safeguards built into the swap agreements, we judge
the risk to Federal Reserve resources to be very low. More notable is the risk that
approving these lines might cause us to be flooded with requests from many
additional EMEs. Nevertheless, in proposing lines with these four countries, we feel
that we have set the bar quite high. Their importance to the global economy and the
quality of their policies set a standard that few, if any, other EMEs can match. In
addition, the potential IMF liquidity swap facility might be helpful to us in limiting
the risk of a slippery slope, as additional countries that request lines with us could be
asked to go to the IMF. Similarly, European EMEs seeking swap lines could be
encouraged to approach the ECB.
In assessing these issues, the staff has conferred with senior officials at the U.S.
Treasury and the State Department. In both instances, these agencies emphasized the
global economic significance of Brazil, Mexico, Korea, and Singapore. However,
they also cautioned that expanding the swap lines beyond this group could leave us

October 28–29, 2008

12 of 206

increasingly vulnerable to a “pile on” effect, which might manifest itself either in a
large number of additional swap line requests or in political pressure. Given these
considerations, the staff would benefit from some signal from the FOMC regarding
its willingness to consider swap lines with other emerging market economies. We see
two broad options in this regard. First, the FOMC could indicate that it is not inclined
to establish swap lines with other EMEs. Inquiries from additional countries could be
forwarded to the IMF. Alternatively, the FOMC could emphasize that the bar for any
additional EME facilities is high and that swap lines would be extended only if the
case is seen as being comparable to that of the four countries that are being voted on
today. Under this second approach, the FOMC might consider granting the Foreign
Currency Subcommittee the authority to establish swap lines with the central banks of
other large and systemically important EMEs. Bill Bassett will now continue our
presentation.
MR. BASSETT. 2 Thank you, Nathan. I will be referring to the exhibits labeled
in red, “Staff Presentation on Financial Developments.” The intermeeting period was
characterized by persistent strains in financial markets and a sharp drop in asset
prices. Although some markets have improved in recent days, the ongoing disruptions
have generated intense pressures on financial institutions and have contributed to a
significant further tightening of credit conditions for households and businesses. As
Bill Dudley noted, spreads on credit default swaps (CDS) for financial institutions
have been quite volatile. As shown by the top left panel of your first exhibit, median
spreads for large bank holding companies (the black line) and regional commercial
banks (the red line) declined substantially after the announcement of the Treasury’s
capital purchase program and the FDIC’s temporary liquidity guarantee program on
October 14; they ended the period almost 70 basis points lower, on balance. The
median CDS spread for insurance companies (the blue line) increased substantially
over the latter part of the intermeeting period amid concerns about the financial
condition of these firms. Judging from the wide range of dealers’ price quotes on
CDS for the same firms (shown in the top right panel), liquidity and price discovery
in the CDS market remain strained.
The functioning of markets for corporate debt is also impaired. As shown by the
blue line in the middle left panel, the staff’s proxy for the bid-asked spread on highyield bonds spiked to more than 4 percent before partially reversing course over the
past week. This spread is also unusually elevated for investment-grade bonds (the
black line). As shown to the right, the average bid-asked spread on syndicated loans
traded in the secondary market (the black line) jumped up over the intermeeting
period. Secondary market prices for syndicated loans (the blue line) dropped to
unprecedented levels, reportedly reflecting heavy sales by hedge funds that were
forced to meet investor redemptions as well as the unwinding of some types of
structured investments.
Municipal finance, the subject of the bottom two panels, was significantly
disrupted by dislocations in money market mutual funds in September and record
2

The materials used by Mr. Bassett are appended to this transcript (appendix 2).

October 28–29, 2008

13 of 206

withdrawals from long-term municipal bond funds in early October. Markets for
structured products, such as tender-option bonds, that issued short-term variable-rate
debt backed by longer-term municipal bonds were particularly affected. Yields on
those short-term instruments (shown by the black line in the bottom left panel)
jumped for a time, and the sales of the underlying long-term bonds as the structures
unwound boosted long-term municipal bond yields (the blue line). As shown to the
right, issuance slowed substantially until mid-October, when a few states—notably
California—placed a sizable amount of new debt, though they paid fairly elevated
interest rates to do so. In recent days, however, liquidity conditions have shown signs
of improvement, yields have decreased somewhat, and issuance has moved back up
from the extremely slow pace seen in the second half of September and the first half
of this month.
Please turn to exhibit 2. As noted by Bill Dudley, prime money market funds
suffered a wave of redemptions in mid-September, shown by the red bars in the top
left panel. Although the flows diminished after the Federal Reserve and the Treasury
announced steps to support money funds on September 19, prime funds lost about
one-fifth of their assets, on net, over the intermeeting period. As a result, prime funds
have dramatically reduced their holdings of commercial paper, generating significant
disruptions in that market. As shown by the black line in the top right panel,
unsecured financial commercial paper outstanding has declined sharply since midSeptember, and the ongoing contraction in ABCP (the blue line) has continued. In
contrast, the amount of unsecured commercial paper placed by nonfinancial firms (the
yellow line) was little changed, on net, over the period. As shown in the middle left
panel, broad equity prices (the black line) dropped about 30 percent over the
intermeeting period as the outlook for both economic growth and earnings dimmed,
and implied volatility increased to record levels. As depicted by the red bars to the
right, those developments were accompanied by record outflows of about $60 billion
from equity mutual funds in September. Weekly data indicate that, over the first half
of October, investors withdrew more than $100 billion from long-term mutual funds,
including about $70 billion from equity funds, but outflows have slowed in recent
days.
As shown in line 1 in the bottom left panel, M2 expanded rapidly in September
and early October as some firms and households shifted toward safer assets. Liquid
deposits (line 2) increased significantly in September and stayed about flat in
October. In contrast, retail money funds (line 3) were little changed in September but
have grown briskly this month. The sizable increases in small time deposits in both
months (line 4) were widespread, in contrast to the more concentrated gains seen over
the summer in response to elevated yields at a few financial institutions. Currency
(line 5) began increasing rapidly in recent weeks, apparently supported by higher
demand from both foreign and domestic holders.
As a result of the disruptions in short-term funding markets, a range of borrowers
turned to banks for funding. The “other loans” category (the blue line in the bottom
right panel) rose sharply beginning in mid-September as a result of both unplanned

October 28–29, 2008

14 of 206

overdrafts and draws on existing credit lines by nonfinancial businesses, money
market mutual fund complexes, foreign banks, nonbank financial institutions, and
municipalities. C&I loans at banks (the black line) have also increased significantly
in recent weeks, as a broad spectrum of nonfinancial firms tapped existing credit
lines. According to the October Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey, however, about
25 percent of the largest banks and 35 percent of other banks surveyed indicated that
C&I loans not made under previous commitment accounted for some of the recent
increase.
Additional results from the survey are the subject of your next exhibit. Large net
fractions of institutions reported having continued to tighten their lending standards
and terms on all major loan categories over the previous three months, with some
banks reporting that they had tightened lending policies considerably. As shown by
the black line in the top left panel, about 80 percent of domestic respondents
tightened their lending standards on C&I loans since July, and all but one of the 54
banks surveyed reported charging higher spreads over their cost of funds on such
loans (the red line). As noted to the right, nearly all the banks that tightened
standards or terms did so in response to a more uncertain or less favorable economic
outlook and a reduced tolerance for risk. Almost 40 percent of domestic banks
tightened in part because of concerns about their capital or liquidity position,
somewhat more than had cited those pressures in July. As indicated in the middle left
panel, a large fraction of domestic banks again reported tightening standards on
commercial real estate loans over the past three months.
Moving to loans to households, almost 70 percent of respondents tightened
standards on residential mortgages to prime borrowers (the red line in the middle
right panel). As shown by the blue line, nearly 90 percent of the institutions that
originated nontraditional mortgages tightened standards on such loans. As shown by
the short black line in the bottom left panel, about 75 percent of the respondents
tightened lending standards on home equity lines of credit, and about 60 percent
tightened standards on both credit cards (the blue line) and other consumer loans (the
red line). As noted to the right, almost 25 percent of banks, on net, reported reducing
the credit limits on existing credit card accounts of some prime customers over the
past three months, and about 60 percent of banks reported cutting existing lines of
some of their nonprime borrowers. Banks that had trimmed the limits on existing
credit card accounts most often cited the more uncertain economic outlook as a very
important reason followed, in turn, by a reduced tolerance for risk and deterioration in
the credit quality of individual customers.
Business finance is the subject of your next exhibit. The spread on BBB-rated
bonds issued by nonfinancial corporations (the blue line in the top left panel) rose
about 275 basis points over the intermeeting period, to more than 600 basis points,
whereas that on bonds of financial firms (the black line) reached nearly 1,000 basis
points before easing some in recent days. As spreads spiked and volatility increased,
bond issuance by both nonfinancial and financial corporations (shown in the table to
the right) dropped appreciably in the third quarter (row 3) relative to the pace seen in

October 28–29, 2008

15 of 206

the first half of the year (row 2). As shown in the last row, there has been no highyield issuance by nonfinancial firms so far this month, and bond issuance by financial
firms has come to a near halt.
In commercial mortgage markets, secondary market spreads on AAA-rated
commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS), shown in the middle left panel,
continued to increase on net, and no new CMBS have been issued for several months.
As noted to the right, using announced earnings for about 200 firms and analysts’
estimates for the rest, the staff expects third-quarter S&P 500 earnings to come in
about 10 percent below the level posted in the third quarter of last year. Losses at
financial companies account for the drop. Bank holding companies reported further
substantial write-downs on mortgage-related and other securities as well as higher
loan-loss provisions necessitated by widespread deterioration in credit quality. In
contrast, earnings of nonfinancial companies are projected to have risen about
12 percent from a year earlier, but increased profits of energy companies account for
virtually all of those gains. As indicated in the bottom left panel, analysts have
revised down significantly their expectations for earnings of nonfinancial firms (the
red line) over the next year, likely in response to the worsening economic outlook.
Expected earnings for financial firms (the black line) also have been cut further this
month. A rough estimate of the equity premium (shown in the bottom right panel)
stands at an extremely high level.
The household sector is the subject of your last exhibit. As shown by the top left
panel, interest rates on conforming residential mortgages have been volatile—partly
in response to the renewed pressures on GSE debt noted by Bill Dudley—but ended
the period only slightly higher at around 6 percent. The staff expects home prices
(the black line to the right) to decline significantly further through the end of 2010
and mortgage debt (the red line) to be about flat over that period. Both paths have
been marked down from the September forecast to reflect a weaker economic outlook
and tighter credit conditions. Spreads on asset-backed securities backed by credit
card loans (the black line in the middle left panel) and auto loans (the red line) have
risen more than 150 basis points since mid-September, moving well above their
spring peaks. The cumulative increase in spreads since midyear has hindered
issuance of such securities, and the volume of new deals, shown to the right, dropped
more than 50 percent in the third quarter. The latest data, available through
October 17, suggest that very little issuance has occurred this month. As shown in
the bottom left panel, consumer credit has decelerated recently. With lending
conditions likely to remain tight and with spending on durables expected to be soft,
the staff sees significant further weakness in consumer credit in coming quarters.
Summing up, although there has been modest improvement in several financial
markets recently, the worsening of the global financial crisis sharply increased
pressures on financial firms and markets over the intermeeting period as a whole.
Those pressures have led to further deleveraging, diminished liquidity, increased
concerns among investors about the economic outlook, and a reduced tolerance for
risk-taking. The resulting sharp fall in asset prices and the further tightening of credit

October 28–29, 2008

16 of 206

conditions have had substantial adverse effects on nonfinancial businesses and
households. That concludes my prepared remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. I’m going to open up in a minute to questions
for Bill, Nathan, and Bill. I want to say just three brief things about the emerging market swaps.
First, we have been talking with these countries for some time, and I think when the
conversations began it was more of a preventive measure than a response to conditions. But the
EMEs are now at a flashpoint in the financial crisis, and as I think Linda Kole will probably
discuss, the urgency has increased, and the risks to the broader global economy are probably
higher than they were a few weeks ago. Second, with respect to the choice of four countries that
Nathan proposed—as he mentioned, we have talked to the Treasury and the State Department. I
spoke to Secretaries Paulson and Rice about this. There was an interesting confluence of
agreement that, if you are going to do this, these are the right four countries and we probably
shouldn’t do more, both from an economic perspective and a diplomatic perspective in the sense
that these are the countries that among the emerging markets are the most important from a
financial and economic point of view. Third, as I think Nathan also mentioned, the IMF is
planning to create a liquidity facility, which will be a low-conditionality facility available to a
broad range of countries. So there has been some discussion back and forth about the
relationship between this, if we do it, and the IMF facility. I had a conversation this morning
with Dominique Strauss-Kahn, the head of the IMF, and we agreed that the two facilities are
complementary—that ours would provide important additional resources to the total availability
of liquid resources for these countries. If we decide to take this step, we have agreed that
tomorrow, after the IMF board approves their facility, we would jointly announce these two
actions so that it would create an impression of cooperation and coordination between the
Federal Reserve and the IMF.

October 28–29, 2008

17 of 206

So those are just a few additional pieces of information. I’m sure that you have plenty of
questions. Who is first? No one? Ah, President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Just to follow up on your note, Mr. Chairman, I spent four years as the
senior trade negotiator with all four of these countries, and I’d just like to comment on their
importance to us. Mexico is obvious. It’s a national security risk. We’re interlinked
economically. They have a sophisticated central bank and a very good central bank governor,
and I think that would be number one on the list. Singapore is unique. I doubt that Singapore
would ever go to the IMF. It would be beneath Lee Kuan Yew’s dignity. It is a vital link in
terms of that sphere of the world. You made the case earlier, or at least Nathan made a case, as
to the uniqueness of Singapore. In terms of Brazil, I’d say that is the dodgiest of the lot.
However, we should remember that 40 percent of the GDP of Latin America south of the
Yucatan is produced by that one country and roughly 60 percent of the population is represented
by that one country. It has made significant progress since Cardoso was president, and it is a
robust economy relatively speaking. Every economy in Latin America borders upon it. It does
have a unique negotiating history—and Tim knows this as well as I do, having spent a lot of time
negotiating with them—but I would say that it is a critical part of our hemisphere and that is the
justification for including them in the package. Finally, we have been trying to negotiate a free
trade agreement with Korea for some time. Korea is an underrepresented country in terms of
discussions about developments in that part of the globe, and yet it is inordinately successful. I
would argue that it is also a strong case to make. The only other country that I would include
under the rubric that we might ever consider is Chile. Even though it is tiny, its representation is
important and its nature unique. I think you could justify doing this by virtue of their immediate
impact on our economy, their unique role in our hemisphere, and the fact that I doubt that they

October 28–29, 2008

18 of 206

would want to go to the IMF in the first place. Therefore, it is complementary to the package
you announced earlier. My only discomfort in the discussion would be the idea of allocating to
the Foreign Currency Subcommittee the authority to approve additional countries. As to the
supplement for these four countries that has been proposed, I would be in favor of that. Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thought there was some pretty good risk
management described in the memo, but I didn’t really follow or don’t understand exactly the
process by which we would generate a loss through these swap lines. Could you take us through
the state of the world in which we would actually generate a loss? I raised this question before
with the industrialized countries, and the answer was that because those are very high quality
countries, we don’t really have to worry about that. I understand that they follow pretty
reasonable economic policies during normal times. But what are the safeguards, and what would
be the process by which we would generate a loss?
MR. SHEETS. I very much agree with the thrust of the question—it would take a very
severe state of nature for us to sustain losses on these. We are protected by the full faith and
credit of our central bank counterparty. In addition to that, when we give them dollars, we take
their domestic currency. So I suppose, in some very extreme state of the world, one could
imagine that the loan that was made in dollars defaulted on the central banks, the central bank
chose not to make us whole, and the currency that was escrowed for us had depreciated
significantly in value. But I’d say that you are multiplying three very small possibilities,
particularly the last two, that the central bank would choose to default on us, and there would

October 28–29, 2008

19 of 206

have to be such a substantial fall in their currency that it would reduce the value of that effective
assurance or collateral or whatever you want to call it.
MR. EVANS. Okay. But it would be that we have their currency and presumably that
would be a state in which it had depreciated.
MR. SHEETS. Absolutely. These would function very similarly to the swap lines that
we have with the advanced economies. In addition, we are going to allow them to draw only
$5 billion at a time at the discretion of the Foreign Currency Subcommittee. When the Foreign
Currency Subcommittee makes the determination as to whether or not a drawing should occur, it
has the scope and the mandate to look broadly at what is happening in the economy and make
sure that the resources are going to be used in a manner that is consistent with the terms and the
expectations of the swap agreement.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman?
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. A clarifying question, Mr. Chairman. Nathan, on page
4 of the memo, at the last bullet, you say, “FRBNY would have broad ‘set-off rights.’”
MR. SHEETS. Yes, indeed. Maybe Trish and Bill want to jump in here as well. What
this means is that, in extinguishing any obligation that arises from the swap agreement, if the
central bank for some reason doesn’t pay us, we can take other assets on the books that are being
held by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to extinguish those liabilities. Does that make
sense? So if the Brazilians are holding some additional assets at the New York Fed that are
unrelated to the swap and they are not making good on the swap, we can draw on those other
assets to extinguish the obligations from the swap.

October 28–29, 2008

20 of 206

MR. ROSENGREN. But there is nothing that prevents them from withdrawing those
assets before that, right? Presumably, if they’re in a situation of default, they would withdraw
any Treasury securities held here first.
MR. SHEETS. They could do that. But any drawing under the swap agreement would
be no longer than three months, and some drawings would be much shorter. So they would have
to move very quickly, given the short nature of these transactions. But there are certain states of
nature that are so severe that we couldn’t rule it out.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Let me just state my understanding of this so that I can
be corrected by Nathan or by Bill. These countries hold substantial amounts of their reserves in
dollars. They hold a substantial fraction of those dollars in accounts at the New York Fed. If
they defaulted on their piece of the swap and the falling value of their currency left us with some
exposure, we would have the ability to take assets from their accounts to cover any loss. So it’s
better than the fact that this is a sovereign credit and it is better than the fact that we have an
asset on the other side of the swap, because they hold substantial foreign exchange reserves with
us. The way to think about this is just as a mechanism to help them transform the composition of
their dollar reserves in a way that might be more effective in responding to lender-of-last-resort
needs in dollars, rather than having to sell Treasuries or agencies into the market in a period of
panic or distress to meet that cash need. I meant it as a confirming question.
MR. SHEETS. I agree.
MR. STERN. But I thought we were concerned about a shortage of Treasury collateral in
the market. So why wouldn’t we want them to sell, and in fact, what are reserves for if they
don’t use them in these circumstances?

October 28–29, 2008

21 of 206

VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I have never stood in their shoes, so I’m not sure I
fully understand it. You are right that the world is a little short of the risk-free asset now, and so
a greater supply would be terrific in some sense. But they have a general view, which I think our
people share, that to meet the kind of lumpy, unpredictable, potentially large needs for lender-oflast-resort purposes you may face in our currency, you have to manage reserves in a way that you
can meet those needs without selling Treasuries or agencies. It would not be so terrific for the
world. I have never stood on the other side, but that’s my basic sense. Another way to think
about this is that the privilege of being the reserve currency of the world comes with some
burdens. Not that we have an obligation in this sense, but we have an interest in helping these
guys mitigate the problems they face in dealing with currency mismatches in their financial
systems. We have an interest in helping them meet that in some sense. It’s not our obligation.
We have the same basic interest that led us to be responsive to the European need in some cases.
These guys are different in that they actually have managed the countries’ balance sheets better
because they at least have a huge amount of their assets in dollars. That should make us in some
ways as comfortable as—maybe more comfortable than—doing it with the Europeans because
they ran a banking system that was allowed to get very, very big relative to GDP with huge
currency mismatches and with no plans to meet the liquidity needs of their banks in dollars in the
event that we face a storm like this.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker, you had a two-hander?
MR. LACKER. Yes. President Geithner, you described the EMEs as motivated by a
desire to transform their reserves from illiquid Treasuries or from Treasuries to some more
fungible and more convenient form of dollars. That strongly suggests collateralizing their swap

October 28–29, 2008

22 of 206

line with the Treasuries rather than their own currency. What would be the disadvantage of
doing that?
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I think effectively we have done that by the way in
which the thing is structured.
MR. LACKER. But the point that President Evans made is that we’re not constraining
them to not withdraw the reserves.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Do you mean that you want to put a reserve floor on
them, too?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. The question is whether, in an unlikely but possible state of
the world in which they don’t want to pay us back, they could withdraw their Treasuries in
advance of defaulting.
MR. LACKER. Or we could lend to them, collateralized by the Treasuries rather than by
their own currency.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Well, lots of things are possible. I think this is a pretty
good conservative balance.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That would basically be a repo agreement, I guess.
MR. SHEETS. For what it’s worth, the ECB has entered into something similar to that
with the Hungarians, in which the Hungarians are able to repo to them long-term eurodenominated stuff and get euros back.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thanks. I think I’d be a little concerned about stigmatizing the swaps by
saying that we have enough doubts about these other countries that we need to take collateral—
we don’t have confidence that their central banks will meet the obligations that they have taken

October 28–29, 2008

23 of 206

on. So my preference would be to stick with the extension of our current swap agreements to
these countries. I think they all are using their reserves to some extent already, so this is not a
case of them not touching their reserves and instead taking the swaps. They say they don’t
intend to use them, but they could very well use them. They’re already using them.
The other market that the Treasury has expressed some concern about is the agency
market. If they were just meeting a huge demand for Treasuries by selling Treasuries, that might
be one thing—although intermediate- and longer-term Treasury yields themselves have moved
up presumably because of supply pressures there. But the agency spreads have widened quite a
bit, and I think forcing them to sell agencies in a kind of lumpy way would feed back on our
mortgage markets. It would not be in our interest.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher, a two-hander?
MR. FISHER. Just responding to President Lacker. I think it would be an insult to these
four parties, particularly given the fact that we appear to have negotiated, again, the ability to
attach other assets. I am, frankly, surprised that Singaporeans would go along with that. If we
got that, I’d use it and pocket it. But I would argue, especially for the case of Mexico, that I
don’t see any reason that we should differentiate between them and Canada, for example. It
would stigmatize them in a way, and it would be an insult to these people. At the same time, as I
think I understand the explanation from Vice Chairman Geithner and from Nathan, we do have
some ramped-up security here—so it’s a special arrangement. I think going further than that
would not be appropriate.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me say just a couple of quick things. One is that this
would require renegotiating the whole thing from the beginning, and we would like, if possible,
to do this tomorrow with the IMF. The second point I would make is that we do have

October 28–29, 2008

24 of 206

considerable security, and we will be dispensing this—under strict conditions—in limited
tranches. I think we could monitor pretty well what was going on. But the point is well taken.
President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I have just a clarification. This is a question. Don’t we already have a
swap line, a standing facility, with Mexico as a part of NAFTA? So we don’t have to add it.
MR. SHEETS. We do have a swap line with Mexico. It’s a standing swap line. It’s
$3 billion under the North American Framework Agreement. It’s the counterpart to NAFTA.
Under that agreement, we also have a $2 billion swap line with Canada. Here we would be
adding a new temporary liquidity swap line, so it would be a new legal construct.
MR. PLOSSER. I guess my question is why we can’t use the swap line that is already in
existence.
MR. SHEETS. In principle, if you were so inclined, you could probably just raise the
size of the existing swap line to $30 billion. However, we built in a variety of mechanisms and
safeguards in this proposal. In addition, the structure of what we’re putting forward is tailored
particularly to meet the kinds of challenges and liquidity pressures that exist right now. So in
some sense this one is structured to meet the challenges that the Mexicans are most likely to face
in the current episode rather than the more generic one that already exists on the books.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me go to President Rosengren, who has been waiting
patiently.
MR. ROSENGREN. I have two unrelated questions. One follows up on this, but the
other one is on the term auction facility. First, given how much we have expanded the term
auction facility, is there any consideration to having a minimum stop-out rate, given that the last
two have had fairly low stop-out rates? I wonder if that was being considered at all, given how

October 28–29, 2008

25 of 206

much we expanded the size. Then the second question gets to the stigma issue related to the
swap lines. There was quite a lot of discussion about how to differentiate the countries. I had
the same thought that President Lacker had—if we could have set-off rights that enable them to
collateralize the swaps. I do think going to the IMF will attach a fair amount of stigma to the
organization. So I am worried that the spillover benefits to other countries will be negative, not
positive, because of that stigma. One option would be to say that either you could go to the IMF
or we would provide collateralized loans for other than these four, since it sounds as though
these four are a done deal. But rather than trying to draw the line and figure out whether Chile or
some other country is appropriate, we could collateralize it. If they held enough Treasury
securities at the New York Fed, then it would seem that we would have no reason not to do it. If
they didn’t have Treasury securities, which would probably partly reflect some of their own
mismanagement in their countries, then they wouldn’t be able to use the facility and would have
to use the IMF. But it would seem to be a way to get around some of the stigma issues, if
someone chose to come to us and fully collateralize it. That might be an alternative way to draw
the line rather than trying to come up with criteria that seemed a little difficult to understand, as I
went through the memo.
MR. DUDLEY. Under the term auction facility, there is a minimum bid rate, the OIS
rate. So when we have a $150 billion auction and let’s say there are propositions of $120 billion,
the winning bid rate is the OIS rate for everybody.
MR. ROSENGREN. But I’m just wondering, as the OIS rate has come down, when you
think of the band that we have for excess reserves, it does seem that the OIS provides a much
bigger band, for example, than what we have even for excess reserves. I wonder whether, during

October 28–29, 2008

26 of 206

periods in which people are considering a reduction of as much as 50 or more basis points, the
OIS ends up being a very low lower bound.
MR. DUDLEY. Yes, right now it is a very low rate because the market is building in
future rate cuts. So I think the OIS rate is now below 1 percent on a three-month basis.
MR. ROSENGREN. But as we narrow the target for excess reserves and have a narrow
band there, you wonder whether the stop-out rate, having a lower band that is a little higher than
the OIS, might be an alternative way to think about it, now that we have the excess reserves
option as to the lower bound.
MR. DUDLEY. I think that is something worth considering. The emphasis right now
has been getting term funding out in as much size as possible and not worrying so much about
whether the cost of the funds is or is not at a penalty. So I think the emphasis of the program did
shift a bit over the past six weeks. Obviously, if things settle down and the demand at the TAF
auctions subsides, then you can have the option of cutting the size of the auctions or increasing
the minimum bid rate or some combination of the two.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Mr. Chairman, may I make an amendment to Eric’s
question or suggestion? I think that, when we have a chance to breathe and we feel as though we
have achieved some durable stability in the panic, then we will want to reassess not just the basic
complement of our facilities and how we think about the future but the relative economics of
what we’ve done with the dollar swaps and our existing open-end auction facilities for
institutions. Ideally, we want a situation in which it is more attractive for them to borrow from
their foreign central banks—the dollars we provided through the swaps—than to come to us in
our auctions and other areas through their U.S. affiliates.

October 28–29, 2008

27 of 206

I am a bit less troubled by the point you made than I am by the fact that we have set up a
regime in which the incentives for them to come to our facilities are still substantial when they
have now the ability they didn’t have before to go to their foreign central banks for dollars in
large scale. As we think about consolidation and not just exit—about how we prepare the
ground for a shift over time—I think we want to come back to looking at the relative economics
between our dollar facilities for U.S. banks and U.S. affiliates of foreign banks and what is open
to them from their home country central banks now. As part of that, we could think about size,
reserve price, and price in our auction.
MR. DUDLEY. The awkward thing right now is that we are trying to add liquidity as
powerfully as we can. So to raise the minimum bid rate or do anything that somehow suggests a
pulling back would be a bit inconsistent with the LIBOR–OIS spread widening that we have seen
and the fact that it still remains very, very elevated. You might want to do exactly what you
suggested, President Rosengren, at some future date, but I think that doing it now would send a
very mixed message to the market. I think people would be confused about what we are doing.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Hoenig. I’m sorry, Nathan had an answer.
MR. SHEETS. Could I just respond to President Rosengren’s second question?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Go ahead.
MR. SHEETS. I think you put your finger on two very difficult judgments that we made
when structuring this facility. I don’t see the risk of creating stigma for emerging market
economies that are not in our swap network as being a first-order concern. It is broadly
recognized that the folks that we are recommending are larger, more systemically important, and
as well managed as anybody else. If you were sitting down to make a list—and the Fund has
recently done this—the economies that we’re recommending would be at the top of the list, and I

October 28–29, 2008

28 of 206

think that is recognized by essentially all observers. So I see what we’re doing here as really
ratifying perceptions rather than creating new ones.
On the second point, the choice between the swaps versus the repos, that one is
particularly tricky. I very much agree that the repos would give us a little more security. On the
other hand, the swap framework gives the emerging market economies a little more flexibility.
As to how they are going to proceed, as President Fisher mentioned, it also creates symmetry
between the industrial countries and the way we’re treating them and the emerging markets and
the way we’re treating them. Given the successes of many of these economies over the past ten
years, I see this as being an appropriate step. Nevertheless, I admit that the choice between the
swaps and the repos is a difficult one. Another thought is that the repo structure might provide a
bit more security, but we have tried to get that security through other ways—through tranching,
careful reviews, and so on.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Hoenig, I’m sorry. Go ahead.
MR. HOENIG. No, no. In fact, it follows right on with what Nathan was just answering.
That is, for the moment we are creating kind of a broader in-list for these four countries and
stigma with the non-accepted group at this point. What will happen, then, if we do have an issue
that involves—pick a country—Chile? Are we going to send them to the IMF? Are we going to
have our subcommittee make a decision as to whether to give them a swap? If we do that, will
that then create uncertainties about others? Are you really not concerned about the stigma and
the implications of this, especially—I guess they are asking this in anticipation of the possibility,
even though they think it’s fairly remote—would we not be increasing the probabilities of a
problem by doing this now? I know these are tough questions; but in this environment, I am
anticipating a bad event. So what do we do in the case of that bad event?

October 28–29, 2008

29 of 206

MR. SHEETS. I would hope that initiating these swaps would reduce the probability of
bad outcomes in the emerging market economies. Certainly, if Brazil, Mexico, and Korea are up
against the ropes and experiencing significant financial stresses, my sense is that it would be an
environment in which many other EMEs would be experiencing negative spillovers. So to the
extent that we can backstop these major linchpins in the emerging market world, I see that as
having very positive effects for others. That would be one point. Second, the decision as to how
to handle Chile, if Chile comes to us for a swap line, I think is very much a policy decision for
the Committee to determine. As I said in the remarks, we as staff members would very much
appreciate some sort of signal from you as to whether you want to say four and that’s all we’re
willing to do, and everyone else—Chile, India, and South Africa—goes to the Fund? Or is the
Committee open to having potentially a few other large, important emerging market economies
have swap lines with the Federal Reserve? I see that as being a policy decision.
MR. HOENIG. But it’s something that we ought to think about sooner rather than later
because the likelihood is that, if you take care of these four and you get another request, you are
going to get three others and not one other.
MR. SHEETS. Wherever you draw the line, there is going to be somebody who is just a
bit away from the line that says, “I am very similar to those folks.” I am reasonably comfortable
with where we draw the line. Here there is as much gap as you’re going to find. In my mind, the
next one for which you could make a case would be India. However, India’s financial system
isn’t as developed as is the case with these folks. They are not as integrated into the global
financial system as is the case with these, so there is a bit of space there. But these are
admittedly hard judgments, which we tried to flesh out regarding some of these issues in our
memo.

October 28–29, 2008

30 of 206

MR. FISHER. Have we been approached by any other countries?
MR. SHEETS. Yes, indeed, we have. We have been approached by 552 U.S.C. (b)(4)
, and we have had very informal inquiries from a couple of other countries, including
552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

.

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. But we have not encouraged that.
MR. SHEETS. We have done everything we possibly can to discourage it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Just to be clear.
MR. SHEETS. That’s right. We’re not advertising.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Another question for Nathan on swap lines is how this works
exactly. If the pattern holds and Mexico, for example, supports its banking system—in the case
of Mexico it is a little different from others, in that all of the large banks are foreign-owned
(Citibank owns Banamex, and the Spanish banks own the other two or three large banks)—
where does our responsibility stop and theirs begin? Is it possible for the subsidiary of a U.S.
bank or a Spanish bank to draw dollar liquidity in Mexico and with fungible dollars move that
around the world? Or does it in one manner or another stay in Mexico?
MR. SHEETS. A couple of thoughts. Certainly these home-versus-host issues bedevil
many, many discussions of banking issues right now. They are true in Mexico, as you suggested,
and they are true in spades in Central and Eastern Europe, where instead of U.S. banks there are
European banks in the tension between the home and host. So these considerations are very
relevant and also exceedingly complicated.
If the Bank of Mexico or the Mexican authorities move to address tensions in their
financial system, the standard that has been set by several Federal Reserve actions, the Brits in

October 28–29, 2008

31 of 206

the things they have done, and I believe a number of the other countries is to include subsidiaries
of foreign firms that are operating in that country. So, for instance, for the United States,
Deutsche Bank’s U.S. subsidiary has had access to our various facilities, and that has been the
coin of the realm in the announcements today. So my feeling is that Banamex, which is owned
by Citi, would have the same access to these kinds of facilities as other Mexican institutions.
Now, there is no guarantee of that, but that would be my feeling. Regarding the question of,
once a Mexican institution gets its hands on dollars, what happens to those dollars, my
understanding is that they can move around. In fact, in a discussion, Guillermo Ortiz indicated
that to date Mexican institutions were net suppliers of dollars to the United States rather than the
other way around.
MR. LOCKHART. So in the case of a foreign bank—they lend to a foreign bank in their
country, in Mexico in this case—defaulting, whose problem is it? Is it the home country
supervisor’s problem, or is it Mexico’s problem vis-à-vis us?
MR. SHEETS. I would guess that it is a joint problem.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chair.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I’m not sure that this is helpful, but maybe I can give a
slightly different example from another perspective. We have a bunch of U.S. affiliates of some of
the weakest European institutions that have faced very substantial dollar funding needs and have
come to us and asked for substantial ongoing access to liquidity. When they have a substantial
amount of lendable collateral, collateral with substantial market value relative to the needs, we have
been comfortable meeting those needs. When their needs have substantially exceeded or might
potentially exceed the market value of their eligible collateral, then we have talked to the home
central bank. We have said that, in effect, if you want us to be able to meet those needs and they

October 28–29, 2008

32 of 206

have collateral in your market that is substantial relative to those needs, then the better way for us to
do this is for the home country central bank to meet their dollar liquidity needs against the collateral
there or meet the liquidity needs and we provide the dollar’s worth of guarantees from the central
bank.
So this home–host thing is a delicate balance, and as Nathan said, it shouldn’t all fall on the
host central bank. The best thing possible is for the home country central bank to take most of the
responsibility for meeting the liquidity needs and for us to help them facilitate that where necessary.
But when those needs exceed what we would normally give in terms of access, then you have to
have a conversation with the foreign central bank. So, for example, if a weak U.S. institution in
Mexico faces substantial needs in Mexico well in excess of their eligible collateral in Mexico, I
suspect they would call us and say, “We want you to meet those needs.” We would have to
consider at that point where they are in the liquidity-solvency spectrum and how comfortable we are
in meeting those needs.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Very good. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. I have a question for the staff. You noted that the countries believed that
this would help market confidence. So the choice of extending a line is potentially consequential
here. I have a two-part question. First, what do you think the risk is of the uncertainty surrounding
whether particular other countries will or will not in the future be able to obtain a swap line from the
Federal Reserve? Second, what would you suggest that we say if asked by the public or if the
Chairman is asked in the Congress about what criteria or principles we used to draw the line
between the countries that have swap lines and those that don’t? I know that you posed the question
to us, but what would you suggest that we say?

October 28–29, 2008

33 of 206

MR. SHEETS. As outlined in the memo and then also my remarks, the first is that we are
looking for economies that are large and systemically important. The second is that we are looking
for economies in which their policies have been strong and it appears that they are largely being
influenced by contagion. The third piece is countries for which we believe that the swap line might
actually make a difference.
Now, let me just give you a concrete case of the third criterion because that’s a little more
abstract than the first two. Iceland came to us and requested a swap line of approximately $1 billion
to $2 billion, which would have been 5 to 10 percent of Iceland’s GDP—so it was fairly large
relative to the size of the country. But the liabilities of the banking system were on the order of
$170 billion, and the underlying problem was really that there was a loss of confidence in its banks.
We came to the conclusion that a $1 billion to $2 billion swap line was very little ammunition to use
against a potential loss in confidence in this $170 billion financial system. For that reason, we as
the staff recommended against a swap line for Iceland.
Those are the three conditions that we’d emphasize. Sort of subsidiary to that is that I think
it is very appropriate for all the European EMEs to report to the ECB for their liquidity needs. That
would further constrain the list of countries that we’d look at. As we work down the list of
countries, I think it gets easier to say “no” in that fewer and fewer of the countries can make a case
that they are large and systemically important. With the risk of creating stigma, some countries are
big, and some aren’t, and that’s pretty darn objective. Now, you can debate about, well, what’s big
and what isn’t and where you draw the line, but it just so happens that these three major economies
that we’re putting forward all have GDP of around $1 trillion. That seems like a reasonable line to
draw. Again, there’s an element of arbitrariness here, but any line you draw will have an element of
arbitrariness to it.

October 28–29, 2008

34 of 206

MR. LACKER. And the first part of my question?
MR. SHEETS. Oh, I thought I got it. What was the first part?
MR. LACKER. What sort of uncertainty might this engender about the likelihood of other
countries qualifying? My recollection is that many economists have claimed that the IMF had this
trouble in the 1990s, when interventions would give rise to uncertainty about subsequent
interventions in other cases.
MR. SHEETS. Well, I guess I’m not sure I know exactly what you’re driving at. Are you
concerned that, by moving on these, we’re sending a negative message about the ones we’re not
moving on?
MR. LACKER. I’m just wondering about the uncertainty that might be created about the
lack of clarity about who’s in, whether this is the final list, and so on.
MR. SHEETS. Our press release that we are negotiating lists, as clearly as one can in a
press release, the criteria that we were looking at—that they are large, well-managed, fundamentally
sound, systemically important countries. So we are trying to communicate that. In addition, in
conversations when these folks come to us—and especially if we get some direction from the
FOMC as to how you’d like to proceed on this issue—we can be very, very blunt with them in
telling them why the answer is “no” or “yes,” depending on which way the FOMC goes.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chair, did you have a two-hander?
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Well, I just want to point out that I think these are
absolutely the right kinds of questions about this. But I think these concerns are substantially
mitigated by the fact that the IMF is putting in place a facility at basically the same time, which will
be there with relatively little stigma for a range of other countries that need it. There will be a
universe of other countries that would not meet the test for eligibility for this swap type of facility,

October 28–29, 2008

35 of 206

for the IMF or us, that will have to go through a program with conditionality and a bunch of
adjustments such as Iceland is going through or Hungary will go through.
So it is right to raise these questions. But the boundary problems around our swap lines are
substantially mitigated by the fact that there is a new facility coming out that’s going to the same
place. Raising the question of why we need to do our swaps is good, too, but you’ve heard lots of
good arguments for that, and I think that realistically there’s a natural division of labor between
what central banks have classically done with each other in the swap context and what the IMF
does. What we’re doing is a natural extension of what central banks do. The IMF is moving a little
further in from where they are in this case, and I think that will mitigate some of the signaling
problems and uncertainty created by having this evolution in the scope of swap lines.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I guess I’m worried about this for all of the considerations that President
Hoenig and President Lacker have just been talking about. I don’t know where we draw the lines,
and when we have to go to the State Department and start asking what countries we can or can’t
develop swap lines with, I’m not sure those are the criteria we want to be using. We mentioned the
countries already. What happens when

552 U.S.C. (b)(4)

? You can just go down the list.
MR. SHEETS. We have already said “no” to some of those.
MR. PLOSSER. I understand, but if you really follow the logic of the argument about being
large and systemically important, if we draw a line somewhere, we start expanding this now bit by
bit and we draw a line somewhere, and the question then becomes, Will markets begin to question
other countries on the periphery and create problems? It’s not that any one of them— 552 U.S.C. (b)(4)
, I don’t know, pick one—is large and systemically important, but by doing what we’re

October 28–29, 2008

36 of 206

doing and creating the uncertainty that President Lacker was referring to, maybe we are forced to go
and do it collectively because they all band together and as a group say, “We’re all facing this
problem. Why can’t we have the same access?” Partly I like President Rosengren’s suggestion
about using repos with securities, which we have here as a mechanism. Alternatively, if the IMF is
creating a largely unconditional or low conditionality type of program, why not just say that
everybody else goes to them first? If they tap out of the IMF access, maybe then we might consider
being a backstop rather than their coming to us in the first place. I just don’t know where this ends.
I think that, with all of the questions you raised and tried to answer, you hit it right on the head. On
all of them that you said were kind of marginal, you went one way, and I’m leaning the other way
on the same criteria.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser, a couple of things. The IMF has very
limited resources. They’re not remotely able to meet the needs of—
MR. PLOSSER. We don’t know what the needs are yet, do we?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, the resources are very limited. The other thing is that
the staff asked for guidance on the limits here. I’d like to propose that, when we get to that point, to
ask the voters to suggest how they stand and what qualifications they might have. One thing that
you could do, for example, would be to say, “I do or do not support this, but if I do, I think a very
sharp line should be drawn at this point and be communicated that way.” The legislative history can
be part of this, and we can communicate to the staff how we feel about potential extensions.
MR. SHEETS. Just to put some numbers on IMF lending capacity—total IMF lending
capacity is about $250 billion. To get even that high they have to call in some special arrangements
that they have with a variety of countries. The maximum capacity is $250 billion. So the
$120 billion that we’re proposing today would be essentially half of what the IMF could do. In that

October 28–29, 2008

37 of 206

sense I really see what we’re proposing as our taking off the IMF’s hands some of the largest
potential liquidity needs, which then allows them to focus on a whole range of additional countries.
A related point is that I understand that, in an IMF executive board meeting today, the managing
director indicated that they are getting a fair amount of interest in this new facility. It really is a
different kind of facility, and frankly, even a week ago if you told me that the IMF was going to be
able to put this facility together in this quick a time, I would have said, “No way. There’s no way
that the IMF can move this quickly.” So it is about as good as we could expect and maybe even
better than what we could have expected from the Fund. I think that they are doing what they can to
minimize stigma. On the other hand, they don’t have enough lending capacity to really handle these
folks that we’re talking about today.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. In the Bluebook here, it says, “Additionally,
the Swiss National Bank announced plans to draw on its swap line to help finance up to $60 billion
in purchases of assets from a major Swiss bank.” So is that really what you have in mind here for a
country like Brazil—that they’ll draw on their swap line to purchase assets from banks?
MR. SHEETS. No, and maybe the folks in New York want to talk a bit more about this.
The transaction with the Swiss National Bank was a very special transaction that occurred outside
the typical constraints of the swap lines that we’d be agreeing to with these folks. In the swap lines
with these folks, they would have to tell us up front how they’re going to allocate the resources. We
would envision that it would be done in something similar to an auction, in a very transparent,
on-market sort of way. But it would not be that kind of a transaction, which was a special case in
order to help a particular financial institution.

October 28–29, 2008

38 of 206

MR. BULLARD. Well, if you think that there are systemically important institutions in
these countries, why not?
MR. SHEETS. Again, we’re drawing lines here. I am not prepared to give these folks carte
blanche. That’s why we’ve added additional safeguards and additional governance structures to
these facilities. Maybe the Committee has a different view on that, but I wouldn’t be prepared to let
them do whatever they wanted with these resources.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. To continue to grill you, Nathan—
MR. SHEETS. I’m earning my pay today.
MR. LOCKHART. You know, the atmosphere right now is largely precautionary on their
part—they are well capitalized with foreign currency reserves. But if we want to deal with
hypotheticals, let’s assume that some of these recipients of the swap lines get into a liquidity crisis.
Is the European Central Bank being approached for swap lines? I recognize that they need dollar
liquidity, but in a general liquidity crisis, the euro would do as well to help. Do we have any sense
of whether the ECB is considering swap lines for some of these emerging markets?
MR. SHEETS. I don’t have details on that. As I’ve mentioned, I know that they have
created a facility with the Hungarians, a €5 billion facility. They were also approached by Iceland
at the same time that we were. I would speculate, but I don’t have any basis for that speculation,
that given the emerging tensions in Central and Eastern Europe and Northern Europe that they
probably are being approached, but I don’t have any details on that.
MS. MOSSER. My understanding is that they have been approached. I don’t know what
decisions have been made other than the ones that may have been mentioned. In addition, they have
opened a swap line with the Danish Central Bank in euros, which was virtually identical to the

October 28–29, 2008

39 of 206

dollar arrangement that we have with the Danish Central Bank. So they definitely have been
approached for swap lines. On how many of them they’ll put into place, we don’t have any
particular information at this point.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I just want to clear up the question. I think Tim and Nathan may have
both answered this, but it’s a question that President Lockhart raised earlier. In Mexico’s case, for
example, where almost all the major banks are foreign owned—EU banks, Spanish banks—those
banks clearly have access to dollars through the ECB swap line. There’s no reason that the dollar
funding needs of those banks, to the extent that they can move these things around, can’t be satisfied
by access to dollars from the ECB. Is that a correct or an incorrect assumption?
MR. DUDLEY. The collateral isn’t always in the right place. You are absolutely right if
the collateral could be easily moved; but the collateral oftentimes isn’t in the right place.
MR. FISHER. Let me ask Nathan a question to follow up, if I may. Obviously you’ve been
approached by the governor of the Central Bank of Mexico—Ortiz has been here to visit.
MR. SHEETS. Indeed.
MR. FISHER. So what’s his argument? I would assume that you asked these questions.
MR. SHEETS. Yes, absolutely.
MR. FISHER. So inform us as to what his justification is.
MR. SHEETS. Mexico is experiencing increased financial stresses, particularly in its
corporate sector, where recently some bad bets on structured finance products have emerged, and
Ortiz was very concerned about continued confidence in the Mexican economy. Now, that said,
from what he had to say, dollar funding pressures had not yet emerged, and he was emphatic that

October 28–29, 2008

40 of 206

they would not draw on these until the time that those funding pressures emerged or until the time
that they saw a significant further deterioration in conditions in their economy. He was very
specific about the fact that they would use their own reserves as their first, second, and third lines of
defense.
MR. KOHN. Just to add to that, he said that, to deal with the issue that Nathan raised about
the problem with their businesses and the kind of dollar needs they had, they were meeting those
needs out of their own foreign exchange reserves. So they were not going to engage in a swap with
us in order to meet that particular problem, but they were concerned about the dollar pressures more
generally on their financial segment, particularly as year-end approaches.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. If it’s okay, maybe we could just go ahead with the votes on
this. I’d like first to do the open market operations, which I hope are not too controversial. There
was no discussion of the New Zealand swap line. I’ll ask to see if there is any comment on that.
Then on this issue, I’ll take a set of positions from the voters, if that’s okay. So let’s go back to
domestic open market operations.
MR. KOHN. I move that we approve.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Without objection. The New Zealand swap.
MR. KOHN. I move we approve that, too.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Is there any discussion or concern? All right. Without
objection. Now, turning to the resolution on the EME swaps, in the interest of time I propose—and
I hope it is okay—to go through the voters and ask each one to state whether you are in favor or
opposed. You can say what you want and, if you want, whether you have some argument to make
or if you’re conditionally in favor—for example, I’m in favor if X or if we do Y—but just to get a

October 28–29, 2008

41 of 206

sense of where everybody is, and then we’ll decide what to do. Okay? So let’s go down the roll
here. I’m in favor.
MR. FISHER. Any conditionality?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think we should be fairly tough at this point. Vice
Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I’m in favor. On the basic question of how you would
deal with other requests beyond the four, Nathan gave two options. One is that you delegate to the
subcommittee discretion to make those judgments. The second option was to say, “No, not without
coming back to the Committee.” I do think it makes sense to see how the IMF thing works and how
it is received, how much participation they get, and how these boundary problems and the signaling
problem play out, and it is probably a good idea for the Committee to have at least a briefing about
how that is playing out so that there is some context going forward. I would be in favor of your
delegating that authority to the subcommittee, as you would expect me to be, just because
sometimes these judgments need to be made quickly. But I certainly understand why people would
want to have a better sense of how this is unfolding and how we deal with it. The boundary
problems are going to get worse if we have to go broader than this.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. I’m in favor.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. I’m in favor Mr. Chairman, and I would also favor, in terms of the screening
device for future requests, that you come back to the full Committee. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. That’s understood. Governor Kohn.

October 28–29, 2008

42 of 206

MR. KOHN. I’m in favor, Mr. Chairman. I think these boundary problems are difficult. I
agree with the Vice Chairman that our having the IMF there mitigates them. I was encouraged by
Nathan’s sense that there are some people interested in the IMF, so there might not be much stigma
there. I would be in favor of very strongly encouraging other countries to go to the IMF.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Kroszner.
MR. KROSZNER. I, too, favor the facility. I think it’s very important that we are tranching
this and using somewhat different ways of providing the money to these countries than we have
with other countries because, as President Bullard and others mentioned, if we’re not careful, this
could be used for purposes with which we are not comfortable. It could be used for supporting a
currency, and I don’t think we’d be particularly comfortable with that. Obviously, we have to be
realistic. Money is fungible. They have very large reserves. They could be using the reserves for
these other purposes and using the swaps for purposes that we find acceptable. But I think, given
the circumstances, it makes sense to be coming up with something that’s complementary to the IMF
facility and make sure that the IMF facility and our facility together are sufficient to deal with the
pressures in this environment. I would be satisfied to delegate the authority to the subcommittee.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. I’m also in favor of the program, and I agree with Vice Chairman
Geithner’s comments that this announcement along with the IMF program should be sufficient. But
if there are other requests, I think it is important to bring them back to the Committee.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Understood. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I guess I’ll approve, but with reluctance. I think this is a very slippery
slope. I’m worried about other central banks ganging up on us as a group, saying that they have to
have this. I would prefer that even these large countries use some combination of the IMF facility

October 28–29, 2008

43 of 206

plus their own reserves to meet these needs. I think that would be a better outcome and better for us
in that regard. So that’s a very reluctant “yea” vote. I’d also insist that any further expansion come
back before this Committee.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Stern.
MR. STERN. I’m reluctantly in favor of this. I won’t elaborate very much. I’m just not
persuaded that this is a very valuable contribution, as best as I can judge it. I would be in favor of
limiting it to these four countries. I don’t know if that’s credible, though. Certainly I would be in
favor of any additional considerations coming back to the full Committee.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Mr. Chairman, I support the proposal on the floor. I think the safeguards are
meaningful and real and should help. I think the bar for further consideration, as Nathan described,
should be high, but we shouldn’t overstate what that bar is, given how circumstances can change
quickly. I wouldn’t want to have to change that rule in the middle of the game, but I think the highbar language works. On the question of delegating to the subcommittee, I think in the interest of
speed it would be appropriate; but given the sense around the table, certainly making sure that the
folks around the table were at the very least briefed as to the thought process might be a prudent
path forward.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. So the sense I hear is that people are
willing to accept it, but the bar for additional countries should be high. We should bring any
country that we propose to add back to the FOMC for approval, and we will keep you well briefed
on the conditionality, the draws, and anything else that happens. Okay? May I have a motion?
MR. KOHN. So moved.

October 28–29, 2008

44 of 206

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I am going to say without objection because we had a
unanimous view. Okay. Thank you. Let me go on next to the economic situation.
MR. LACKER. Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes.
MR. LACKER. Do we have time for a brief question for the Manager about the funds
market? It has behaved a little unusually in the last period.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Go ahead.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman—I appreciate this. I have a three-part question.
As you said in your presentation, the effective funds rate (the average of brokered transactions) has
been below the interest rate on reserves, and there are all of these institutions that apparently aren’t
eligible to earn interest on reserves. One, what’s the policy reason for excluding them from
eligibility for interest on reserves? I understand the policy reason for excluding them from credit,
but this is the opposite, and so I’m not quite sure why we screen them out. Second, as I read the
data on your operations, it seems to me as though we have added enough reserves to drive the funds
rate virtually down to the interest rate on reserves. I want to know if that’s a fair characterization of
the state of open market operations and the funds rate. Third, I’m interested in knowing, especially
if that’s true, why don’t we just give up and say that the interest rate on reserves is our target rate?
MR. DUDLEY. Okay. Let me take them in reverse order. I don’t like to give up, but if I
could just exclude that portion of it, it’s possible that you might want to consider the interest rate on
reserves or some reasonable facsimile thereof as your target because that is essentially the risk-free
rate that banks face. That may be the purer measure of what you’re really trying to accomplish in
terms of its link to monetary policy than the federal funds rate. It’s possible. There are obviously
important governance issues that surround that choice, though, in terms of what’s the Board’s

October 28–29, 2008

45 of 206

prerogative and what’s the FOMC’s prerogative. But that’s a completely reasonable thing to think
about, just as long as we don’t characterize that as giving up.
Have we added enough reserves to drive the federal funds rate down to the interest on
reserves? Well, I think not. I wouldn’t look at it quite that way because the gap in principle, if other
things are not going on, should be the difference between us as a counterparty and a bank as a
counterparty. One is an unsecured loan between one bank and another bank, and the other is us as
the counterparty. So normally there should be a spread between the interest on reserves and the
federal funds rate. Now, obviously what complicates that in the current environment is the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation’s guarantee on interbank funds going forward. So federal funds may
be covered—in fact, they look as though they could be covered by that guarantee. In that
circumstance, one might argue that the federal funds rate and interest on reserves should probably
be the same rate because there’s no difference in credit risk.
MR. LACKER. Excuse me. Without interest rates on reserves, there’s that spread plus a
scarcity factor, and we’ve essentially driven that scarcity factor down to zero—that’s how I meant
the question.
MR. DUDLEY. Right, but I still think that generally a bank faced with a choice of having
risk with the Fed or selling fed funds to another bank would want to be compensated for that risk of
selling, so they are going to get some positive spread.
MR. LACKER. I understand that.
MR. MADIGAN. I would say that we may well be in a situation where the interest rate on
excess reserves is the effective tool for controlling the federal funds rate, and there may be a spread.
As Bill said, we are in the process of learning how this works, and it may well be the case that we
need to push that interest rate on excess reserves very close to the federal funds rate.

October 28–29, 2008

46 of 206

MR. DUDLEY. It would not surprise me at all if, when we are finished with this process—I
hope over the next six weeks as we go through a couple more reserve maintenance period rounds—
that that margin might be zero and we might see the federal funds rate trading right on top of the
interest rate on reserves. But we are going to have to see. I think our presumption at the current
time would be to recommend to the Board next round to narrow that spread further—it is 35 basis
points today. Another thing that we don’t know is how much learning is going to go on by banks.
So the selling of fed funds below the interest rate on reserves is not just the GSEs; it is also banks,
and so it’s a little hard to understand exactly why they’re doing that unless the leverage ratio is
what’s driving that behavior. Maybe they are just not very well informed or they haven’t gotten
their first check for the interest rate compensation, so I think it’s a little too soon to be certain about
how they’re going to behave going forward. You had one other question about the policy reason for
excluding the GSEs.
MR. MADIGAN. There’s not really a policy reason. I would say there’s a legal reason.
The statute allows us to pay interest only on balances held by depository institutions. My own view
is that it would be a good thing if we were able to pay interest to the GSEs exactly for the reasons
that we’ve been discussing. It might be something we could seek authority for at some point in the
future.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Just a clarification. If we were to take that step, are there any other
institutions that participate, other than the GSEs?
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Chile, Mexico—

October 28–29, 2008

47 of 206

MR. MADIGAN. We would have to look at that. I think there are more than just the three
GSEs that we usually think of. But they’re the biggest institutions that participate in the federal
funds market.
MR. DUDLEY. It is not at all clear that their behavior is going to persist necessarily,
because they may decide to manage their short-term liquidity in a different way than selling at a
very low federal funds rate to banks.
MS. DUKE. Mr. Chairman, if I could.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Oh, yes.
MS. DUKE. As part of my preparation when I talked to the banks, I asked them specifically
this question about interest on reserves, and every single one of them said, “We haven’t had time to
even focus on it. We don’t even know what’s going on with that. We’re not changing anything.”
There’s so much going on right now. So I think we’re really going to have to wait until some of the
other decisionmaking has worked through before we can draw any conclusions as to what behavior
this might drive.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Learning theory in practice. Thank you very much. Very
helpful. All right. Mr. Morin.
MR. MORIN. 3 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be using the packet with the green
lettering on the cover entitled “Staff Presentation on Nonfinancial Developments.” Over
the intermeeting period, the data we received on real activity were considerably
weaker than we had been expecting. That, combined with the intensification of
financial turmoil since mid-September, led us to significantly mark down our nearterm and medium-term projections for economic activity.
Your first exhibit focuses on the near-term outlook. As shown by the blue bars in
the top left panel, we currently expect real GDP to fall at an annual rate of slightly
more than 1 percent, on average, in the second half of 2008—a reduction of about
2 percentage points from our projection in the September Greenbook (the red bars).
One factor that has informed our thinking about the near-term forecast is the labor
market, which looks weaker than at the time of the last FOMC meeting. As you
3

The materials used by Mr. Morin are appended to this transcript (appendix 3).

October 28–29, 2008

48 of 206

know, payrolls fell steeply in September. Since then, initial claims for unemployment
insurance (the black line in the top right panel) have been quite elevated, even after
adjusting for factors that are temporarily boosting claims (the red line). As shown in
the inset box, the latest claims data point to another sizable drop in employment this
month.
Turning to spending, sales of light motor vehicles (plotted in the middle left
panel) have been dismal of late and are expected to stay that way at least through the
end of the year. Motor vehicle sales have been depressed, in part, by financing
constraints, limited sales incentives, a retreat by the automakers from leasing, and
worsening consumer assessments of car-buying conditions. More broadly, as you can
see by comparing the black and red lines in the panel to the right, consumer spending
excluding motor vehicles has been significantly softer in recent months than we were
expecting. In addition, the conditions influencing consumer outlays have worsened
considerably, including a sharp drop in household wealth, tepid real income gains, a
weakening labor market picture, historically low levels of sentiment, and reduced
credit availability. Consequently, as reported in the inset box, we substantially
revised down the projection for overall real PCE in the second half of the year. In the
housing sector, single-family starts, shown in the bottom left panel, fell to about
550,000 units in September—6 percent below our expectation. Even with the
ongoing cutbacks in production, the weak demand has left the months’ supply of
unsold new homes (not plotted) very elevated, and we expect starts to decline well
into next year. In the business sector, the spending data in hand are somewhat stale—
tomorrow morning we receive the advance reading on durable goods shipments and
orders in September—but the information we do have points to softening business
investment in the third quarter. Moreover, as shown on the right, the first available
surveys on business activity in October plunged to very low levels.
Exhibit 2 summarizes the enormous changes to the key conditioning factors that
we confronted in putting together the staff forecast. As shown in the top left panel,
reflecting the recent plunge in equity prices, the stock market path in this projection is
markedly below the path anticipated in our September forecast. This downward
revision, together with the projected declines in house prices that Bill Bassett
presented in his briefing, leaves the level of the wealth-to-income ratio, plotted to the
right, substantially lower than in the September Greenbook. As a result, over the next
two years, household wealth exerts a much greater drag on consumer spending than
we assumed earlier. Yields and spreads on corporate bonds, illustrated by the Baa
rate in the middle left panel, soared over the intermeeting period. We expect the
higher cost of capital in this forecast to weigh on business capital spending over the
projection period. A further drag on economic activity in the medium term is the
recent jump in the exchange value of the dollar, shown to the right. While we expect
the dollar to decline a touch more quickly than in the September Greenbook, by the
end of 2010 it remains more than 4 percent above the level assumed in our previous
forecast. In addition, as Linda Kole will discuss shortly, the outlook for foreign
activity has deteriorated. A partial cushion to these factors depressing activity is the
plunge in oil prices over the past few weeks; the bottom left panel shows the spot

October 28–29, 2008

49 of 206

price of West Texas intermediate crude oil. The path for oil prices over the projection
period, based on futures quotes, averages nearly $30 per barrel below the September
Greenbook path and should provide some countervailing support to household
purchasing power and consumer spending. As noted to the right, according to our
standard forecasting models, the lower level of equity prices, the higher bond rates,
and the higher exchange value of the dollar—all of which are intertwined with the
intensification of financial turmoil—exert a considerable drag on real activity over
the next two years. Through conventional wealth, cost-of-capital, and terms-of-trade
channels alone, these developments would lead us to revise down real GDP growth
about 1¼ percentage points, on average, in 2009 and 2010. But these effects likely
understate the full extent of the fallout on real activity from financial turmoil. This is
because our standard models do not explicitly account for the additional effects of
such factors as tighter lending standards and heightened uncertainty.
Consequently, for some time we have been using supplementary analyses to try to
account for these credit-channel effects in our judgmental projection. Your next
exhibit provides some detail on how we updated these adjustments in light of the
intensification of financial stress during the intermeeting period. Two measures that
we have found useful for measuring the extent of financial turmoil are plotted in the
top row of your third exhibit. On the left is an index of financial market stress, and
on the right is an index of bank credit standards derived from the Senior Loan Officer
Opinion Survey. Both indexes have skyrocketed lately, reflecting the sharp
deterioration of financial conditions. As discussed in the past two Greenbooks, we
use two basic empirical approaches to try to quantify the effects of financial turmoil
on real activity that are not captured by our standard models: One is based on the
historical correlations between these financial turmoil measures and errors in FRB/US
spending equations, and the second method incorporates these indicators of turmoil
into small-scale vector autoregressions.
The middle left panel shows estimates of the cumulative effect of our judgmental
adjustments for financial turmoil, outside the conventional channels noted earlier.
The effects are shown relative to the level of real GDP in the fourth quarter of each
year. The solid black line is the judgmental estimate built into the current Greenbook
forecast, whereas the red dashed line plots the estimates used in the September
projection. The shaded area shows the range of results from the model-based
estimates detailed in Part 1 of the October Greenbook. As you can see by comparing
the black and red lines, we now expect that financial turmoil, outside the usual
channels, will impose a markedly greater drag on real activity than we projected in
the last Greenbook. For 2008, we think that much of the unexpected weakness
observed recently in the spending data reflects financial turmoil effects, which puts
our judgmental adjustment near the bottom of the model-based range. In contrast, our
adjustment for 2009 is in the middle of the range of model-based results, whereas for
2010 our adjustment is near the top end of the range. We are more optimistic than the
models for 2010 in part because none of the model-based estimates fully accounts for
what we assume will be the likely restorative effects over time of the actions taken by
governments to mitigate the problems afflicting the financial system. As shown in

October 28–29, 2008

50 of 206

the middle right panel, these restraining influences, taken together, led us to mark
down our assumed path for the federal funds rate. We now assume that the funds rate
is lowered to ½ percent by early next year and is held at that level until mid-2010.
Although the path for the funds rate is appreciably lower than we had assumed in
the September Greenbook, the additional monetary easing only partially offsets the
greater restraint on activity from the other factors shaping the projection. All told, as
shown in the first line of the table at the bottom of the page, we project that real GDP
will fall at an annual rate of nearly 1 percent in the first half of 2009 and then turn up
modestly in the second half. In 2010—with the drag on activity from the strains in
financial markets beginning to ease, housing market conditions stabilizing, and an
accommodative monetary policy in place—activity accelerates further, and real GDP
increases 2.3 percent over the four quarters of the year. The contributions of selected
domestic spending categories to changes in real GDP are shown in lines 3 to 5. As
you can see, we think that consumption will begin to recover next year and that the
drag from housing will diminish over time. In contrast, we expect business fixed
investment to remain quite weak next year, reflecting in part the lagged effects on
investment of declining business output, the high cost of capital, and heightened
uncertainty. Although each of the major components of private domestic demand
contributes to the acceleration in economic activity in 2010, the contribution to
growth from net exports (line 6) is expected to turn slightly negative late next year.
As shown in the top panels of exhibit 4, the margin of slack both in labor markets
(the panel to the left) and in the industrial sector (the panel to the right) is expected to
remain substantial through the end of the projection period. We expect this persistent
slack to be a source of downward pressure on inflation. Other influences are also
likely to hold down inflation over the projection period. As shown in the middle
panels, energy prices and core goods import prices decelerate sharply from their
recent elevated paces. The projected path for consumer energy prices (the left panel)
largely reflects the effect of the intermeeting plunge in oil prices, and the forecast for
core import prices (the right panel) reflects both the sharp drop in commodity prices
and the stronger dollar. As shown in the bottom left panel, while the Michigan
survey readings on near-term inflation expectations have remained elevated (the black
line), those on longer-term inflation (the red line) have more than retraced the run-up
observed earlier this year. Taken together, as shown in line 7 of the bottom right
panel, we now expect core PCE inflation to move down to 1½ percent in 2009 and to
slow further to 1¼ percent in 2010, roughly ½ percentage point less in each year than
projected previously. Total PCE inflation (line 1) is projected to run at about the
same rate as core PCE inflation in both years.
Turning to exhibit 5, a critical feature of the staff forecast is our assumption that
the strains in financial markets will ease gradually over the next two years. However,
the current situation is so extraordinary, in terms of both the financial disruptions and
the policy responses to those disruptions, that an extremely wide band of uncertainty
surrounds this assumption: Matters could easily turn out much worse or much better.

October 28–29, 2008

51 of 206

To give some sense of possible magnitudes, this exhibit reviews two alternative
scenarios from the Greenbook.
In the first scenario, outlined in the top left panel, financial turmoil intensifies
further over the projection period rather than gradually abating, and the
accompanying economic fallout turns out to be more severe than in the baseline
projection. Specifically, risk premiums on loans, corporate bonds, and equity jump a
further 50 basis points and are slower to fall back over time; in addition, the level of
house prices falls an additional 10 percent relative to the baseline. We also assume
that credit-channel and other nonconventional effects are even more restrictive in
2009 and 2010 than those built into the staff forecast—to a degree more in line with
the bottom end of the range of empirical estimates I presented earlier. As shown by
the red line in the middle left panel, with the intensification of the financial turmoil
and the larger judgmental adjustments for the impact of financial stress on economic
activity, real GDP is significantly weaker than in the baseline (the black line). As a
result, the unemployment rate (plotted to the right) rises faster and farther, peaking at
nearly 8½ percent at the end of 2010, more than 1 percentage point above the
baseline. Reflecting the greater accompanying slack, core PCE inflation (shown in
the bottom left panel) moves down appreciably faster than in the baseline, reaching
just ¾ percent at the end of 2010. With substantial slack and a low and falling
inflation rate, the funds rate remains pinned through 2010 at ½ percent and continues
at that level through 2012 in the extended simulation presented in the Greenbook.
In the second scenario, outlined in the top right panel, the stress weighing on
financial institutions and markets lifts much more quickly than in the baseline,
perhaps in response to the extraordinary recent government actions. Here, we assume
that risk spreads recede by early next year to the levels that were projected in the
September Greenbook, and as a result, equities reverse most of their recent losses by
the middle of next year. In addition, we cut back the size of the judgmental
adjustments for financial turmoil to their September Greenbook levels. As shown by
the blue lines in the middle panels, economic activity responds fairly vigorously to
the improvement in financial conditions, with GDP growth reaching about 4½ percent
by the end of 2010 and the unemployment rate moving down to 5¾ percent. As
shown in the bottom left panel, the narrower margin of slack in the alternative
scenario tempers the decline in core PCE inflation relative to baseline. Finally, as
shown to the right, the federal funds rate, under an optimal control monetary policy,
declines briefly to 1 percent early next year but then moves up steadily as it becomes
clear that the financial strains are lifting rapidly. Linda Kole will now continue our
presentation.
MS. KOLE. 4 I’m referring to the next exhibits that are attached to the material you
are already looking at. Since the September FOMC meeting, financial market distress
has intensified and has spread around the world, threatening many emerging market
economies that previously had been less affected by the U.S. and European credit
crisis. As shown in the top left panel, equity prices have fallen sharply in Europe,
4

The materials used by Ms. Kole are appended to this transcript (appendix 4).

October 28–29, 2008

52 of 206

Japan, and the United Kingdom. Indeed, the Nikkei is at a 26-year low today. The
carnage has been just as pronounced in emerging markets, shown on the right. Credit
spreads between industrial countries’ risky corporates and government bonds (plotted
in the middle left panel) soared, especially in the euro area; and as shown in the right
panel, credit default swap premiums on sovereign debt in many emerging market
economies have skyrocketed. The widespread pullback from risk led to safe-haven
flows into dollar assets; as shown in the bottom left panel, the dollar appreciated
nearly 11 percent against the major currencies (the black line) despite a 9 percent
depreciation against the yen (the red line) as carry trades were unwound. The dollar
strengthened 9 percent against the currencies of our other important trading partners.
As shown on the right, effective exchange values of the currencies of Brazil, Mexico,
and Korea were particularly hard hit.
In your next exhibit, the top left panel shows the extent to which investors fleeing
risk have been liquidating emerging market equity funds. Several foreign
governments, notably Russia’s, have fought related currency pressures by drawing
down their reserves (the top right panel). For instance, since the peso fell sharply
against the dollar in early October, the Bank of Mexico has deployed 15 percent of its
reserves to shore up its value. China and Russia have even intervened to stem the fall
in their equity prices. Following the collapse of Lehman Brothers, credit markets
seized up, and dollar funding needs intensified. Since then, governments around the
world have taken several steps to support their banking systems (the middle panel).
Some central banks have injected massive amounts of liquidity, and many have cut
policy rates or reserve requirements or both. In addition to the countries joining the
Fed in a coordinated 50 basis point rate cut on October 8, a wide range of other
economies have eased policy lately. Note that there have been a few exceptions:
Hungary, Iceland, and Denmark increased rates to counter currency pressures.
Governments have also expanded bank deposit insurance and guaranteed new bank
lending in order to improve confidence and liquidity. Following a similar initiative in
the United Kingdom, euro-area governments announced plans to guarantee the
issuance of new medium-term senior debt by banks and to directly assist their
recapitalization if necessary. In recent weeks, authorities have announced capital
injections into a number of banks whose financial soundness was in question. The
swap lines extended by the Federal Reserve to foreign central banks have been
expanded. The ECB approved a €5 billion swap line for Hungary and a €12 billion
one for Denmark, and several Asian countries are currently negotiating swap lines
with each other as well. Private firms in several emerging market economies have
confronted pressures in rolling over foreign currency funding, and authorities there
have also raised deposit guarantees, guaranteed bank lending, and injected capital into
vulnerable banks. Finally, several countries have applied to the IMF for assistance.
The bottom left panel shows median credit default swap premiums for banks in
Europe, the United Kingdom, and the United States. The declines since the beginning
of this month suggest that the announcement of these plans has improved confidence
in banks’ safety, even if they have not restored confidence in broader economic
prospects. As shown by the implied OIS forward rates in the bottom middle panel,

October 28–29, 2008

53 of 206

market participants expect considerably more monetary policy easing in Europe than
they did at the time of the last FOMC meeting. We assume that further cuts in
official rates (shown on the right) will be forthcoming as output falls short of
potential and inflation recedes.
As can be seen in exhibit 3, highly stressed global financial conditions and the
weaker U.S. outlook have led us to take a whack out of our outlook for foreign
growth. Comparing lines 1 and 2, we have marked down our estimate of total foreign
growth for the third quarter more than 1 percentage point, and we have slashed our
forecast even more for Q4 and 2009. We project outright recessions in the advanced
foreign economies (lines 3 through 7) and in Mexico (line 12). In other emerging
economies, we foresee growth rates well below potential. Chinese real GDP growth
(line 10) is estimated to have slowed considerably in the third quarter. We expect
some payback in Q4, but beyond that we have revised down our outlook. As can be
seen in the middle left panel, exports fell in August in many of our largest trading
partners, though they still chugged along in China through September. The black line
in the middle panel shows that the volume of exports from Canada has been falling
for some time, but exports had held up in Japan and Germany until the third quarter,
when they fell. Industrial production in Japan (the red line in the middle right panel)
has fallen nearly 5 percent below its year-ago level, and IP has also fallen over the
past year in the United Kingdom and the euro area. As global demand has slumped,
oil prices (the black line in the bottom left panel) have plummeted, and nonfuel
commodity prices have fallen as well. The decline in commodity prices along with
slackening economic activity is projected to help bring down inflation in all of the
regions shown (on the right).
Exhibit 4 focuses on the outlook for Europe. Banks remain leery of lending to
each other, as evidenced by the growing amount of funds parked at the ECB’s deposit
facility. The latest BoE bank lending survey (the top right panel) pointed to further
tightening of U.K. lending standards in the third quarter and suggested that banks
expected to tighten them somewhat further in the fourth quarter (the striped bars).
Notably, this survey was taken before Lehman failed. A confidential conversation
with a contact at the BoE who had talked with a few bankers more recently suggested
that the latest survey considerably underestimated the recent tightening of standards.
The quarterly growth of U.K. loans to nonfinancial corporations (the red line in the
middle left panel) fell from double-digit paces for the past two years to 5 percent in
the third quarter. Credit expansion to households (the dashed line) declined as well.
Loan growth in the euro area (the middle panel) also slowed. Europe has clearly
moved into recession. The middle right panel shows that house prices have fallen
over the past year in the United Kingdom and Ireland and have also slowed in other
European locales. But it is not just the property sector that has slumped. Business
confidence (the bottom left) has disintegrated. Total economy purchasing managers’
indexes (the middle panel) are in the downturn range in both the United Kingdom and
the euro area. Unemployment rates have increased, especially in France and Spain,
where construction activity has slowed sharply.

October 28–29, 2008

54 of 206

Your next exhibit takes a quick tour through the rest of the world. In Japan,
business confidence (the red line) has plunged, partly because lending terms faced by
firms, particularly small and medium-sized enterprises, have become more restrictive.
Investment intentions (not shown) have deteriorated as shipments (the black line) and
exports have declined. The labor market has deteriorated, with the ratio of job offers
to applicants (in blue) falling to its lowest level in the past four years. The Bank of
Japan recently downgraded its outlook and stepped up measures to deal with financial
market stresses. In China, investment spending (the black dashed line in the top right
panel) continued to be strong through September, and retail sales accelerated.
However, industrial production (middle left panel) slowed this summer partly because
of efforts to reduce pollution in Beijing during the August Olympics but also because
of declining steel production, suggesting further slowing. Industrial production has
also slowed in Korea and Taiwan, and export orders (shown on the right) are falling
in China, Brazil, and Singapore. As shown in the bottom left panel, Mexico has
suffered a steep fall in remittances, flattening industrial production, and declining
auto exports. Oil revenues (not shown) are down as well. Finally, global PMI and
new orders indexes, which aggregate data for 26 major countries, are both in
contractionary territory but have not yet reached their depths at the trough of the 2001
recession.
Exhibit 6 reviews the main elements of the U.S. external outlook. As shown in
line 1 of the top panel, net exports contributed 1.8 percentage points to growth in the
first half of this year, but we expect this contribution to drop off considerably in
coming quarters as exports (line 3) slow with foreign growth and imports (line 5)
remain flat. Total foreign growth (the black line in the middle left panel) is now
projected to dip down about as much as U.S. growth, while the dollar (shown on the
right) is well above the level we projected in the September Greenbook. As shown in
line 3 of the table, we now expect export growth to move down sharply starting in the
current quarter and to remain well below what we’d written down in our last forecast.
Although lower U.S. demand caused us to lower import growth (line 5), the projected
contribution of net exports to GDP growth has, on net, been revised down a bit over
the forecast period. The bottom panel gives a longer perspective on U.S. external
deficits. The non-oil trade deficit (the dashed orange line) and current account deficit
(the red line) have continued to narrow over the past year and a half although oil
imports have remained large. The current account deficit to GDP ratio is forecast to
fall below 3 percent in 2010, a level last reached in 1998. Brian Madigan will
continue with our presentation.
MR. MADIGAN. 5 I will be referring to the separate package labeled “Material
for Briefing on FOMC Participants’ Economic Projections.” Exhibit 1 shows the
central tendencies and ranges of your current forecasts for 2008; corresponding
information about the Committee’s most recent projections, those from June, is
shown in italics, and Greenbook projections are included as a memo item. Your June
projections regarding GDP growth and inflation for the first half of 2008 turned out to
be quite close to subsequent BEA data releases; therefore, the revisions in your
5

The materials used by Mr. Madigan are appended to this transcript (appendix 5).

October 28–29, 2008

55 of 206

projections for the year as a whole are almost entirely due to the changes in your
implicit projections for the second half of 2008.
As shown in the right column of the top panel, your GDP growth forecasts for
2008:H2 now range from minus 2½ percent to minus ¾ percent; compared with June,
each of you has marked down your projection for second-half growth by at least
2 percentage points. As shown in the second panel, your forecasts of the fourthquarter average unemployment rate fall in a range of 6.3 to 6.6 percent, more than
½ percentage point higher than in June. In accounting for the sharp deterioration in
the near-term outlook for activity, your narratives point to the intensification of the
financial crisis and its impact on credit conditions and stock market wealth as well as
the weakness of incoming data on consumer spending and labor market conditions.
Your assessments of inflation in 2008 have also shifted significantly since June.
The central tendency of your forecasts for overall PCE inflation during 2008:H2 (the
right column of the third panel) is now about 1½ to 2¼ percent, a drop of about
2 percentage points from June. In this regard, a number of you noted the implications
of recent sharp declines in energy and commodity prices that were apparently
triggered by the worldwide slowdown in economic activity. In contrast, your
projections for core PCE inflation in 2008:H2 (the right column of the bottom panel)
are a notch higher than in June.
Exhibit 2 reports your projections for the next three calendar years. Most of you
anticipate little or no GDP growth during 2009; as with your implicit forecasts for the
second half of 2008, these projections are about 2 percentage points lower than in
June. A few of you are projecting even weaker outcomes, with output declining
about 1 percent, whereas a few others are projecting stronger economic growth of
about 1½ to 1¾ percent. The width of both the ranges and the central tendencies of
your projections for real GDP growth for 2009 and 2010 has increased noticeably.
Still, all of you anticipate that economic expansion will resume by 2010, and most of
you expect a further pickup in growth during 2011. In the narratives accompanying
these projections, a number of you said that you expect the pace of recovery to be
damped by persistent credit market strains, ongoing adjustment in the housing
market, and economic weakness abroad. Apparently, only a few of you assumed that
additional fiscal stimulus would be enacted.
Most of you project that the unemployment rate will peak at around 7 to
7½ percent in 2009 and decline gradually over the subsequent two years. However,
you generally expect that, even by the end of 2011, the unemployment rate will still
be at or above 5½ percent. Moreover, most of you anticipate that the unemployment
rate in 2011 will remain well above your own projections of the longer-run
unemployment rate that were provided in your trial-run submissions.
The central tendency of your projections for overall PCE inflation is about 1¼ to
2 percent for 2009 and about 1½ to 1¾ percent for 2010 and 2011—roughly the same
as for your forecasts of core PCE inflation. About half of you projected inflation

October 28–29, 2008

56 of 206

rates in 2011 close or identical to your own individual assessments of the rate of
inflation consistent with Federal Reserve’s dual mandate for promoting price stability
and maximum employment, where we have again judged the latter from your longerterm trial-run submissions. But half of you are projecting that inflation in 2011 will
be below your own individual assessments of the mandate-consistent inflation rate by
about ¼ to ½ percentage point, and in one case, by more than 1 percentage point,
mainly reflecting the lagged effects of weak economic activity and the relatively
sluggish pace of recovery.
In your forecast submissions, several of you indicated that the appropriate path of
monetary policy would involve less near-term easing than assumed in the Greenbook,
and more than half of you expressed the view that policy tightening would need to
occur several quarters earlier and at a substantially more rapid pace than in the
Greenbook.
Exhibit 3 presents your views on the risks and uncertainties in the outlook. As
shown in the top left-hand panel, all of you now see uncertainty about growth as
elevated relative to historical norms. As shown to the right, most of you continue to
perceive the risks to growth as weighted to the downside even with the downward
revision in your modal projections. Several of you pointed to the possibility that
financial market turmoil might not subside as quickly as anticipated and to significant
risks of an increasingly negative feedback loop between credit markets and economic
activity. As shown in the bottom left-hand panel, most of you also continue to see an
elevated degree of uncertainty about inflation. In June, most of you judged the risks
to the inflation outlook as skewed to the upside, but as shown to the right, nearly all
of you now see the risks to the inflation outlook as either balanced or tilted to the
downside.
Exhibit 4 summarizes the results of the trial run on longer-term projections.
These projections were intended to represent values to which variables would
converge over time, say five to six years ahead, under the assumption of appropriate
monetary policy and in the absence of any further shocks. For real GDP growth,
your longer-term projections have a central tendency of 2½ to 2¾ percent and a range
of about 2 to 3 percent. For the unemployment rate, your longer-run projections have
a central tendency of 4¾ to 5 percent and a range of about 4½ to 5¾ percent. For
both variables, the central tendencies are very similar to those of the projections for
2010 that you made in October 2007, shown in the bottom panel, a point at which
many of you viewed the modal outlook for 2010 as being fairly close to the balanced
growth path of the economy. For PCE inflation, your longer-run projections have a
central tendency of about 1¾ percent and a range of 1½ to 2 percent. The range of
these projections is identical to the range of two-year-ahead inflation projections that
you made last October; the minutes from that meeting indicated that those projections
were influenced importantly by your judgments about the measured rates of inflation
consistent with the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate of promoting price stability and
maximum employment.

October 28–29, 2008

57 of 206

The request for the trial-run projections suggested that convergence might
typically occur over a period of five to six years. One of you noted that the
convergence process this time will likely occur over an even longer period because of
the severity of the economic crisis. However, apparently most of you thought that
convergence would occur sooner than that, suggesting that the configuration of this
trial run produces a good representation of FOMC participants’ views of the steady
state values of GDP growth, unemployment, and inflation.
As usual, the staff will be preparing a summary of economic projections (SEP)
and will be circulating drafts to you over the next few weeks along with drafts of the
minutes. The published SEP, and hence the drafts, will not incorporate the longerterm projections from the trial run. The staff will provide to you separately a version
of the SEP that has been modified to incorporate the longer-term projections
generated by the trial run. The subcommittee will consult with the Chairman about
next steps. One possibility would be for the Committee to discuss experience with
the trial run at its December meeting and make a provisional decision at that time as
to whether to proceed in January with regular longer-term projections; a final decision
could be made in January. Thank you. That concludes our presentation.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Before we go too long, we’ll take a coffee break,
but now let’s take some questions. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. In the forecast, the federal funds rate goes to 50 basis points, and I take it
that’s essentially as low as you think it can go. You treat that as sort of the lower bound on nominal
interest rates. Is that right?
MR. STOCKTON. That’s how we were thinking of it. The 50 basis points, however, was
not done on the basis of any deep analytical analysis of whether that, in fact, is the zero bound, and I
think that’s an issue that the staff will need to address pronto. But the message in the forecast with
that funds rate path was that we think this shock is large enough that you will need to lower the
funds rate as low as you think it can feasibly go.
MR. LACKER. Well, whatever that lower bound is, I have a question that’s kind of
hypothetical. I wasn’t a member of the Committee five years ago. My understanding, though, is
that much thought was given to how we would conduct monetary policy if we needed to reduce the
nominal federal funds rate to zero or its effective equivalent. My understanding is that the general

October 28–29, 2008

58 of 206

conclusion—and my understanding is that this is mainstream economists’ general view as well—is
that the way we would do that would be to expand the monetary base, perhaps by buying assets
outside the normal range of assets that we would buy. Now, the first question is, Is that correct?
Then I have a follow-up.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. May I? You can answer, but let me just make a suggestion,
which is that there were a number of memos and studies done in 2003. I think we ought to look at
them, update them, and circulate them fairly soon. So we’ll do this in some detail; but by all means,
let’s hear the answer.
MR. MADIGAN. President Lacker, I would say that there are a number of strategies that
the Committee could think about if it were at the point that it felt it couldn’t lower the federal funds
rate any further, be that zero or some higher level. One would be communications that suggest to
market participants a willingness to hold short-term rates at very low levels for a very long period of
time. Of course, one could view the 2003 experience as implementing that strategy with the
“considerable period” language. But obviously the idea is to try to hold down the longer-term rates
that matter for spending to a larger degree than might be implied by market participants’ views that
you might instead begin to firm monetary policy sooner.
There are a number of other possibilities. As you suggest, one would be simply to expand
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet further—engage in a sort of quantitative easing. The
effectiveness of that could be debated. Another possibility that was discussed, at least in the period
in which the studies were done, would be to change the composition of the Federal Reserve’s
balance sheet. Of course, we’ve already done a lot of that with the various lending facilities, and so
the scope for additional expansion there would need to be thought through.

October 28–29, 2008

59 of 206

MR. LACKER. The reason I ask is that my understanding is that the strategy of expanding
the monetary base would work through increasing inflation or reducing deflation.
MR. MADIGAN. That’s not how I would think about it. I would think about it as giving, if
it works, depository institutions increased incentives to expand their lending by providing them with
a great deal more funding than they actually need and thereby increasing spending propensities. I
would see this more as part of a package of various ways to stimulate spending by reducing real
interest rates but not as something that would feed through directly to inflation. Rather this would
more properly be viewed, at least in the way I think about things, as fighting deflation rather than
trying to cause a higher positive rate of inflation.
MR. LACKER. My understanding is that economists such as Woodford and others who
have studied this believe that, by using monetary assets to purchase other assets, we can make the
price level and thus the inflation rate higher than it otherwise would be. Is that a fair understanding?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t think that’s right. I think the thrust of the elementary
approach to quantitative easing is the old Milton Friedman idea—that changing the composition of
money and other assets changes relative returns. So it’s a way to bring down returns on other assets
and create stimulus even if the policy rate is down to zero.
MR. LACKER. The mechanism Friedman sketched ultimately produces a proportionate
increase in the price level, doesn’t it?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Eventually, but through the aggregate demand mechanism.
MR. LACKER. Right.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We should look at the Woodford thing, but I don’t think that’s
quite the right characterization of his view.

October 28–29, 2008

60 of 206

MR. LACKER. Well, the reason I ask all of this is that, with an interest rate on reserves
above zero, that’s effectively equivalent to a zero lower bound on nominal interest rates. So we are
effectively doing this quantitative easing.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We’re pretty close, yes.
MR. LACKER. Right. So the thought that sparks is that, if the mechanism involves
creating inflation, then I’d wonder what checks we have on the scale of open market operations now
to ensure that we’re not, by expanding our balance sheet as much as we have, risking an increase in
inflation.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I don’t think that’s the right characterization, but I’d be happy
to talk about it off line. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I have a question. As you characterized the forecast in the Greenbook, it is
really the result of very large adjustments to the financial constraints piece—in fact, they’re about
double what they were in the September Greenbook—and those adjustments or factors really
account for a large portion, maybe not all, of the downward revision in the forecast. Now, one of
the inputs in the financial factors are spreads of various kinds in the VARs that you used to estimate
those. But those spreads we’ve learned are very, very volatile. They can rise very quickly, as we’ve
seen. They also can fall very quickly sometimes. Spreads have actually come down a little in the
last few days, which is the good news. If our facilities are successful, they actually may fall
further—knock on wood; that would be very nice. But I get a little nervous making our forecast be
driven so much by something that’s potentially very, very volatile.
Now, we get a bit of a picture of this—and I want to applaud the staff—in I guess it was
exhibit 5, where you were comparing the baseline forecast and the two alternative scenarios,
particularly the one in which you get quicker recovery in the financial sector. I thought that was a

October 28–29, 2008

61 of 206

very useful exercise, and I really appreciate it. My interpretation or intuition is that the “more rapid
financial recovery” scenario is what the forecast would look like had we not done the additional add
factors in October and instead held them to what they were in September. That suggests that the
real data, whether on spending or other things, have driven the forecast down a little, but not a
whole lot. In fact, in that scenario, you imply that the funds rate would actually be held constant at
1½ percent. So, in looking at those two scenarios and trying to parse out how much risk or how
much probability to attach to them, what is the staff’s view? Obviously here’s what you thought the
baseline would be, but if I ask you what you think the probabilities are on some of these different
scenarios—in particular, I’m interested in this sort of faster recovery—do you have any sense of
what the probabilities of these two different outcomes might be and how one might think about
that? They imply very different paths for the funds rate and very different forecast profiles, but their
differences depend on variables that are very, very volatile. So can you give me some probabilities
of how you think about those two scenarios?
MR. STOCKTON. I can give you some probabilities, but I don’t know how seriously
you should take them. [Laughter]
MR. PLOSSER. You can give me a distribution.
MR. STOCKTON. What we wanted to convey in the alternative scenarios that we
showed this time—and we reduced the number because we thought the possible little risks that
you might be facing were being swamped by some really big ones—was our sense that the
likelihood function is pretty flat around the baseline and the two alternative scenarios that we
show here in exhibit 5. I share your discomfort. As I was telling President Evans at lunch today,
I feel a bit as though the forecast is going to depend a lot on when the clock stopped, given how
much volatility there has been in the stock market and in corporate spreads. When the clock

October 28–29, 2008

62 of 206

stopped, we had close to a 25 percent weaker level on the stock market, 200 basis points higher
on the Baa spread, and a 7 percent higher dollar. There were a whole lot of negative forces
operating on this forecast. Indeed, both the conventional wealth effect and cost-of-capital
channels account for about one-third of the downward revision we made. The special
nonconventional credit channel effects account for a third, and a third of the downward revision
really is a combination of the stronger dollar and the weaker foreign outlook.
The part that I feel most comfortable with in this forecast is that there has been a very
significant negative shock to the economy and that it is difficult to imagine that activity will not
be affected importantly by that. The part that I feel most uncertain about—and, as you point out,
is relevant to the policy decisions that you are going to make over the next several meetings—is
that I have no idea about the timing or the manner in which this will fade away. So we have it
fading away gradually over the next two years. I think that a more rapid recovery is certainly a
possibility. As you noted, even that scenario doesn’t go back to where we were in September.
One, the incoming data suggest that the underlying economy is starting out at a weaker place,
and even if conditions were to improve very rapidly over the next quarter or two, you have still
sustained a hit that is going to take some time to play out through the system. By the same
token, I don’t think that you can discount the more extended and deeper financial fallout here.
We have certainly been surprised over the past year in many ways by just how virulent and
persistent this shock has been. Two, looking at the current state of aggregate demand and
aggregate activity, I think we are probably still just at the front edge of the credit constraint
effects on actual spending. So you could still be faced with some very substantial restraint on
spending—and more than we have built into the baseline forecast.

October 28–29, 2008

63 of 206

So, and as you noted, the difference in the policy prescriptions there—the worse scenario
is that the funds rate stays as low as it can stay for several years. The other would be—putting
too fine a point on it—that optimal control, even with the more rapid recovery, goes down to
1 percent on the funds rate and then starts recovering to 1½ percent. But that is obviously a very
different policy picture. I just don’t think that, at this point, science is going to allow us to put a
lot of probability mass on one of those scenarios versus the other two.
MR. MORIN. One quick follow-on comment. In exhibit 3, in the middle left panel, if
you look at our financial turmoil effects, with the gray shading, the bulk of the markdown in
2008 actually is what we’re labeling the financial turmoil. But those are data we pretty much
already have in hand. We are calling much of the shortfall in consumption that we expect to see
in the third quarter as “financial turmoil.” So much of the weakness in the second half of this
year isn’t just taking a flyer on what we think turmoil is going to do; some of it is already in the
data.
MR. PLOSSER. I was looking at the table in the Greenbook, at the bottom. That’s
where I was trying to back out some of this. Thank you very much.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. I have a question and a statement disguised as a question.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Not anymore. [Laughter]
MR. FISHER. A quick question on fiscal policy, both domestic and international. Being
struck, Ms. Kole, by your verbs “whacked” and “disintegrated”—very forceful language—what
are your assumptions about fiscal policy in terms of staff projections, first, for the domestic
economy and, second, for other economies? That’s the question part.

October 28–29, 2008

64 of 206

MR. MORIN. Right now, although the odds are that there will be a fiscal package next
year, it is not a feature of the baseline forecast. We discussed two alternative simulations for
different packages, but additional fiscal stimulus is not a feature of the baseline.
MR. STOCKTON. We made a deliberate decision in constructing the forecast, given the
enormous uncertainty about both the size and the composition of those fiscal packages. We had
so many moving parts in our baseline forecast that we wanted to present you with that and then
show you what the consequences might be, first, of a stimulus package that looks a lot like the
one we had this year—which we think probably gave a shock, but a very short-lived shock, to
aggregate demand and then faded away. That doesn’t really have many important consequences
for the outlook. The second was a much larger package that delivered some stimulus over the
next two years. That had a bit of an effect in terms of raising GDP growth and lowering the
unemployment rate. But even that $300 billion fiscal package wasn’t enough, in our baseline
forecast, to lift the funds rate assumption off the floor. So I think one of the messages would be
that, to have a fiscal package that would actually influence your current policy discussion, you
have to think both that it would be extremely large and that it would deliver stimulus over an
extended period of time to be effective that way.
MS. KOLE. I think that in many of the major foreign countries there is room for fiscal
stimulus. That may be a bit of an upside risk to our forecast because, for example, China has
already put some things in place. They have increased exporter rebates, and they are also putting
more money into homebuilding and trying to prop up the construction industry. Japan just
announced a bigger package. I’m not so sure if it will go through. Korea has announced—and
even some of the oil producers are announcing—plans to put money into the system. I don’t

October 28–29, 2008

65 of 206

think we have fully incorporated that. Maybe we have thought about it in China’s case because
we think that they will do everything they need to do to keep that economy growing at a—
MR. FISHER. So it’s possible that we might have marginally higher rates of growth
than—
MS. KOLE. Right. I think that the United Kingdom, too, is expanding fiscal policy.
Europe hasn’t really announced much yet, but perhaps they will do more as well.
MR. FISHER. The second thing goes back to this business of the judgmental effects of
financial market turmoil. Do you have any concern that the financial turmoil may have reduced
the marginal effectiveness of changes in the funds rate? In other words, if you think in my
simple way of a patient on the operating table, we have an IV tube into them, we titrate the fed
funds rate—we have been cutting rates—but the tube has been crimped. The flow, I would
suggest may not be as full as it would have been before. Is it possible that we haven’t felt the
full effects or, all things being equal, we haven’t felt the same effects that we would have felt if
the pipes hadn’t been crimped? I’m curious as to your view on that.
MR. STOCKTON. The answer to that is “yes”—it is certainly possible. Obviously, it is
very difficult to separate things that might actually have changed the transmission channel of
monetary policy from just big financial developments that have offset the beneficial effects of
easing policy. We built an assumption into the baseline forecast that GDP responds close to the
average response to a fed funds rate reduction, as would normally be the case. The one small
technical area in which it seems as though the effect almost certainly would be smaller is that,
with the equity premium so high right now, any given change in the funds rate is likely to result
in a smaller change in the required return on equity and probably a smaller stock market response
than you would normally get. So I think, basically, it is certainly possible, but in our forecast we

October 28–29, 2008

66 of 206

have assumed that the additional reductions will have GDP consequences along the lines of the
normal response.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Why don’t we take fifteen minutes for coffee, and
then we’ll do part of the go-round. Thank you.
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, why don’t we turn part of our dinner period to the goround. Let’s start with President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Most of the anecdotal information from
the Sixth District is consistent with the downbeat picture that has been emerging in the national
data. The sentiment of directors and their contacts has turned decidedly more pessimistic
regarding current economic conditions and the near-term outlook. Banking contacts indicate a
further tightening of credit standards, while stresses on household and small business finances
have resulted in increased credit card usage. A state economic-development official noted that
some banks have halted their 90/10 SBA lending. Bankers active in the VRDN (variable rate
demand note) market noted that municipalities are under pressure with declining revenues and
higher financing costs. Nonresidential building contractors noted a large increase in the number
of canceled projects. Advisory council members described a substantial decline in domestic
shipping and transport activity for most goods, other than energy products, and some slowing of
export volumes through regional ports. Finally, retail contacts, in anticipation of the coming
holiday season, noted that orders are down, and heavy price discounting has begun already.
Thematically, Atlanta’s forecast is consistent with the Greenbook, but we are projecting a
slightly more severe and protracted downturn in business activity than the Greenbook baseline.
My assumption is that the cascading dynamic at work in the financial markets may take longer

October 28–29, 2008

67 of 206

than projected in the Greenbook to come to an end. As a consequence, I view the Greenbook’s
scenario entitled “more financial fallout” as the most plausible storyline among the likely range
of outcomes. I should acknowledge that we’re in an interval between the announcement of the
TARP and its full implementation. The encouraging improvement in credit spreads and term
funding we have seen in recent days may accelerate once the TARP is operational.
With inflation abating more or less as expected and with such uncertainty surrounding the
playing out of continuing and recently worsening turmoil in the financial markets, I have to view
the balance of risks as more negative for growth than upside for inflation. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I think it is clear that inflation has been rolled over by the
steamroller of the credit crisis. I am not going to belabor what I have heard from the CEOs I
have spoken to. Basically, the best summary is that things have gone from interesting to
unbelievable. We have had an implosion of economic activity. Business women and men, not
having any pricing power, are doing what you would expect them to do: They are cutting their
costs of goods sold, which means they are shedding head count dramatically. They are
stretching out their ROI assumptions, and they are cutting back on cap-ex and, basically,
assuming pro-cyclical behavior on the downside. I doubt that any of us are going to report
anything different, particularly since I think I am in a District that, relatively speaking, is still
strong. I would hope that during our discussions today we would each take the time, or at least
ask, for some response. I would like some response from you in particular. The situation is dire.
There is no question about that. We are in dire straits. There is no inflationary tail, or if there is,

October 28–29, 2008

68 of 206

it is completely flattened in terms of the foreseeable future. The risks are to the downside on
economic growth.
A question I have is, What do we do next? Actually, I should address the issue of what
we do first. I don’t think doing dribbles and drabs is an answer. I think we just do nothing—and
I could make that case because we’ve done an awful lot—or we do something that is a firm
statement. But in response to that statement, the question has to be, What do we do as next
steps? I’m particularly curious about whether or not we address during this meeting, and tonight
and tomorrow, not only next steps but what the end game is. Where do we want to be? How
long are we going to be there, and eventually, how do we exit? But that is, of course, the
ultimate question that I think we can delay. So, Mr. Chairman, I’d like to suggest that we not go
through our standard ritual of reading about our Districts and so on because I don’t think there is
going to be a whole lot of difference. The real question is, What do we do about it, and what’s
the cognitive road map from here? Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, I for one will certainly give my response to that at the
appropriate time, and we need to hear from everybody. But everyone is obviously free to talk
about whatever they want to talk about. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. In the run-up to Halloween, we have had a
witch’s brew of news. Sorry. [Laughter] The downward trajectory of economic data has been
hair-raising—with employment, consumer sentiment, spending and orders for capital goods, and
homebuilding all contracting—and conditions in financial and credit markets have taken a
ghastly turn for the worse. It is becoming abundantly clear that we are in the midst of a serious
global meltdown. Like the Board staff, I have slashed my forecast for economic activity and
now foresee a recession with four straight quarters of negative growth starting last quarter. I

October 28–29, 2008

69 of 206

wish that I could claim that I place a lot of confidence in the sobering forecast, but I am sorry to
say I can’t. In fact, I think we will be lucky if the adverse feedback loop that is under way
doesn’t wrench us into a much more pronounced and more protracted downturn. The outlook for
inflation has shifted markedly, too, with the days of heightened upside inflation risks behind us.
In fact, I am concerned that beyond next year we run the risk of inflation falling below the level
consistent with price stability.
Even before the extraordinary deterioration in financial market conditions over the past
few weeks, there were numerous signs that the economy had weakened dramatically. I won’t
recite the litany of disappointing data but instead try to touch upon some high, or I guess I should
say low, notes based on what my contacts tell me. They are consistent with President Fisher’s
observations. Consumer purchases of durable goods, especially motor vehicles, have been
particularly hard hit by the one–two punch of tight credit and reeling consumer confidence. The
mood on showroom floors is downright grim. One auto dealer in my District reports that he is
now experiencing the worst period in his thirty-plus years in the business. A home appliance
retailer adds that he has never seen more uncertainty and gloom from both the retailers and the
vendors. This sentiment is echoed by a large retailer who says simply, “The holiday shopping
season is going to stink.”
Businesses are under siege from weak demand, high costs of borrowing, curtailed credit
availability, and pervasive uncertainty about how long such conditions will last. Our contacts
report that bank lines of credit are more difficult to negotiate. Many have become more cautious
in managing liquidity and in committing to capital spending projects that can be deferred. They
are even cutting back trade credit to customers. Even firms that are currently in good shape
report that they are hunkering down, cutting back on all but essential spending, and preparing for

October 28–29, 2008

70 of 206

the worst. Our venture capital and private equity contacts tell us that they are instructing their
portfolio companies to cut costs, put expansion plans on hold, and draw down existing credit
lines. The market for commercial mortgage-backed securities has all but dried up, and lenders
have also become less willing to extend funding. With financing unavailable, I am hearing talk
about substantial cutbacks on new projects and planned improvements on existing buildings, as
well as the potential for distress sales of properties whose owners will be unable to roll over debt
as it matures. The deterioration in overall financial conditions since the September FOMC
meeting is truly shocking. Even with today’s 900-point increase in the Dow, broad indexes are
still down about 20 percent, and the latest data suggest house prices in a freefall. Baa corporate
bonds are up about 200 basis points since our last meeting, low-grade corporate bonds are up a
staggering 700 basis points, and to top it all, the dollar has appreciated nearly 10 percent against
the currencies of our trading partners. The sharp deterioration in financial and credit conditions
will weigh heavily on economic activity for some time. In addition, prospects for the one
remaining cylinder in the engine of growth—namely, net exports—are bleak owing to the
slowdown in global demand and the appreciation of the dollar.
We now expect real GDP to decline at an annual rate of 1¼ percent in the second half of
this year and to register two more negative quarters in the first half of next year. That forecast is
predicated on cutting the funds rate to ½ percent by January, as assumed in the Greenbook, and
also is premised on another fiscal package. An absolutely critical pre-condition for the economy
to recover next year is for the financial system to get back on its feet. In that regard, I have been
greatly heartened by the important actions that the Treasury, the FDIC, the Fed, foreign
governments, and other central banks have taken in recent weeks to improve liquidity and inject
capital into the financial systems. But we are fighting an uphill battle against falling home

October 28–29, 2008

71 of 206

prices, an economy in recession, and collapsing confidence. It is not clear whether these steps
will reopen credit flows to households and businesses, especially those with less than sterling
credit. Under the Greenbook forecast we will see further large declines in housing prices over
the next two years. Banks and other financial institutions will likely suffer larger losses than
many had anticipated, and that will mute the impact of recent capital injections. The interaction
of higher unemployment and rising delinquencies raises the potential for even greater losses by
banks and other financial institutions and for an intensification of the adverse feedback loop we
have worried about and are now experiencing. Such a sequence of events plausibly could lead to
outcomes described in the “more financial fallout” alternative scenario in the Greenbook.
There are considerable downside risks to the near-term outlook as well. As I mentioned,
the most recent economic data have consistently surprised on the downside, and I see a real risk
that the data may continue to come in weaker in the near term than the Greenbook has assumed.
For example, a dynamic factor model that my staff regularly uses is much more pessimistic in
the near term than is the Greenbook. This model aggregates the information contained in more
than 140 data series. Based on the most recent economic and financial data available, this model
predicts that real GDP will fall 2½ percent in the fourth quarter. The model’s pessimism reflects
the combination of the recent weak data releases for the month of September, followed by the
abysmal data that we have available so far for October, including financial market prices,
regional business surveys, and consumer sentiment.
Turning to inflation, the most recent data have been encouraging. Looking forward, the
sharp decline in commodity prices, especially oil prices, will bring headline inflation down
relatively quickly. More fundamentally, the considerable slack in labor and product markets will
put downward pressure on the underlying rate of inflation over the next few years. A number of

October 28–29, 2008

72 of 206

my contacts already report that their businesses are working on lower margins in the more
challenging economic environment. I expect headline PCE price inflation to decline to about
1½ percent in 2009 and core PCE price inflation to be 1¾ percent next year. I expect both
inflation rates to edge down to 1¼ percent in 2010. Given the sizable downside risk to the
forecast for growth, the risks to the inflation forecast are likewise weighted to the downside.
In conclusion, I think the present situation obviously calls for an easing of policy, as I
assumed in my forecast. Given the seriousness of the situation, I believe that we should put as
much stimulus into the system as we can as soon as we can.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. In spite of the fact that I am going to validate
what President Fisher said in terms of content, I am reminded of what candidate Ronald Reagan
said in 1980 against George Bush. To paraphrase, “I paid for the plane ticket down here. I’m
going to tell you what I learned.” [Laughter]
Pessimism is running deep, and no one I spoke with this round was immune to the current
economic and financial turmoil. Even contacts who have sworn for months that their prudent
financial management had insulated them from funding difficulties now report being stressed.
The speed of the turnaround in sentiment has been breathtaking. Some of these new reports
about changes in financing conditions came from large manufacturing firms that had been doing
well this cycle. For example, John Deere noted that its financing subsidiary was having
difficulty rolling medium-term notes that fund their customer leases. This seems symptomatic of
financial stress because the subsidiary has a large capital cushion with high-value collateral
backing the leases. Caterpillar did have better luck getting such funding but only because it went
to the market during a very brief window when lenders were actively seeking customers with

October 28–29, 2008

73 of 206

high credit quality. I also heard numerous reports of businesses having difficulty renewing longstanding lending arrangements with their banks; and for those who were able to get new loans,
the terms were typically viewed as unattractive—at least they felt so.
Several Chicago directors indicated that businesses were successfully tapping existing
loan commitments and revolving credit, much along the lines that President Yellen just
mentioned. However, this was not greeted enthusiastically by their bankers. In fact, I heard a
very interesting story about a major New York bank CEO who spent some time in Chicago a
couple of years ago. He was calling a large customer to assure him that their credit lines were
good and that they didn’t need to be taken down preemptively. The customer, who is our
chairman, listened politely and then tapped the line anyway. [Laughter] No wonder banks are
worried about their liquidity position.
With regard to nonfinancial developments, reports on both current and expected real
activity have turned uniformly more negative. An abrupt change occurred in September. People
are spooked—sorry—[laughter] and it is showing through to spending. Retail sales are weak. I
have grown accustomed to the inherent pessimism of one of my retail contacts. He has often
said that business has never been weaker in 40 years, but this time he said never in 46 years. I
also heard many reports about how the slowing in demand is worldwide.
In my District, the sharp slowdown is evident in the Chicago purchasing managers’
index. In October, it plunged nearly 20 points, to 37.8, the lowest level since the last recession in
May 2001. This index will be publicly released on Friday. Businesses appear to be responding
to the drop in demand by doing anything and everything they can to cut back spending. Labor
demand is way off. My Manpower contact indicated that even companies that are doing well
had turned cautious about hiring and are trying to squeeze out more productivity. He thought

October 28–29, 2008

74 of 206

that the drop in sentiment could have some extra impact, given that it was occurring during the
annual planning cycle for corporations. The idea was that a lot of harder-to-sell structural
adjustments were being implemented anyway and that CEOs wanted to get these moves done
quickly and have them behind them by early 2009. This is consistent with a range of reports we
have heard that new capital spending is dead in the water or that planned expansions are being
canceled. On a positive note, I think we are seeing the benefits of the structural improvement
and inventory management that has occurred over the last 25 years. My contacts are reporting
some increases in inventories, but they think that so far they have kept stocks under relatively
good control. With prompt production cuts, we may not get the additional downside of a big
inventory swing later in the cycle, perhaps when it is more painful.
Turning to the national outlook, our forecast envisions a full-blown recession, roughly on
the scale of the Greenbook. But like everyone else, I have a great deal of uncertainty about this
projection. Things could turn out a lot worse. In contemplating the transmission from recent
financial events to the real economy, there seem to be at least two channels to note. First, there
is the dramatically reduced availability and higher cost of credit. Second, a recessionary
psychology has emerged strongly in households and businesses. With regard to the psychology,
I haven’t spoken with anyone this round who thought there was a good reason to undertake any
kind of discretionary expenditure. Clearly, the self-reinforcing dynamics implied by these and
other reports could generate a deeper downturn than I have written down in my forecast. That’s
a big risk. With regard to the credit channel, the hit to the nonfinancial sector has intensified a
good bit. We clearly are sailing in uncharted waters when it comes to quantifying these effects.
The factors identified in the Greenbook highlight the unprecedented nature of the financial
impulses to the economy.

October 28–29, 2008

75 of 206

Looking ahead, I expect that the improvement in financial conditions will be somewhat
faster than in the Greenbook. That is my cautious optimism. Still, in our forecast, financial
headwinds weigh substantially on growth throughout 2009 and continue, to a degree, into 2010.
Accordingly, substantial resource gaps remain open throughout the projection period. Also, I
expect inflation expectations to decline in this depressed environment. With greater slack, lower
inflation expectations, the reduction in energy and other commodity prices, and the higher value
of the dollar, we are projecting core inflation to move under 2 percent by 2010. And I won’t be
shocked if the Greenbook projection for this to happen in 2009 actually happens. So, on balance,
I think that inflationary risks are low but the downside risks to the economy are very high. Much
as President Fisher indicated, it is much in line with the reports so far. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Business and consumer sentiment in the
Fifth District has deteriorated markedly. Even though economic conditions were already
decelerating heading into our September meeting, a discrete shift in outlook seems to have
occurred. It seems to me to have originated during the week of September 15 or shortly
thereafter. Our business contacts express anxiety about the national economy, and they express
uncertainty about the meaning for their firms’ prospects of the astonishing sequence of events
that began unfolding that week. Both consumers and firms have been increasingly unwilling to
make long-term commitments and engage in discretionary expenditures. Consumers are
delaying large and discretionary expenditures. Firms have adopted a wait-and-see attitude on
investments.

October 28–29, 2008

76 of 206

Our regional survey released this morning shows a substantial drop in business conditions
as well. Our business survey respondents report that obtaining business loans is more difficult
than three months ago, and there are widespread reports of lenders tightening credit terms and
seeking to reduce exposures. Most respondents, however, also indicated that they would still be
able to satisfy their borrowing needs. When you listen to bankers, they will tell you that they are
tightening standards, but they also report that they are still extending credit to solid borrowers
with high-quality deals.
I find it difficult right now to pin down the real effects of the financial market turmoil of
the last few weeks. As the Greenbook notes, assessing such effects “poses significant
identification challenges.” Specifically, it is hard to disentangle the effects of the increased cost
of bank capital from those of the deterioration in the economic environment facing borrowers.
Personally, I suspect the latter are playing the more prominent role in the tightening of credit
terms right now.
Looking on the bright side, the near-term inflation picture has eased noticeably since our
September meeting, mainly because of the decline in oil and other commodity prices. The
Greenbook carries this moderation into its long-term forecast, where PCE inflation now
converges to 1 percent in 2013. I did a double-take when I saw that—it had me wondering
whether the Greenbook was ghost-written this month by President Plosser. [Laughter]
Whoever’s forecast it is, the longer-term projected moderation in inflation relies heavily on the
opening-up of a large and persistent output gap. In the current circumstances, I am not sure how
plausible that story is. In particular, I have been struggling with how to think about the effect of
credit market disruptions on the concept of potential output. To the extent that we think of these
disruptions as analogous to shocks to intermediation technology—and that is what the models of

October 28–29, 2008

77 of 206

these kinds of credit channel effects generally tell you to do—it seems to me that we should see
them as pulling down potential as well as actual output. I believe this point has been made at
previous meetings. We have also talked before about the tenuous nature of the Phillips curve
relationship, and it is difficult to forecast. The slope is sort of flat. We had been scheduled to
discuss inflation dynamics, and we postponed that, for good reasons I believe. I hope we can get
back to it soon because I think it’s going to be relevant to how we see our way through this. In
any event, I think we should be careful not to be overly optimistic about the forecast of an
inflation decline driven by a large output gap. The shift in the Greenbook’s long-term inflation
projection is noteworthy for another reason, I believe. We are getting closer to a 1 percent target
federal funds rate, and we may actually reach 1 percent at some meeting soon. The last time this
happened it sparked a widespread discussion of and concern about the zero lower bound on
nominal interest rates.
I want to make a couple of related observations. First, a key to conducting monetary
policy at the zero bound is being able to keep inflation expectations from falling and thereby
increasing real interest rates. From this perspective, the revision of the Greenbook’s forecast
from 1.7 percent one meeting ago to 1.0 percent for five-year-ahead inflation implies that we run
a monetary policy regime in which five-year-ahead expected inflation varies pretty significantly
in response to contemporaneous shocks. I don’t think that variability in long-run inflation
projections can help our ability to manage inflation expectations at the zero bound. We’d be
better if we ran a policy in which long-run expected inflation was more anchored, more stable.
You can tell where I’m going with this, I’m sure. This highlights the value of an explicit
inflation objective as well as the value of being able to communicate clearly about how we view
the functioning of monetary policy at the zero bound. Second, I will just note briefly that the

October 28–29, 2008

78 of 206

economics of monetary policy at the zero bound are closely related to the economics of paying
interest on reserves at close to the target rate. In fact, if I’m not mistaken, they are virtually
identical. I think progress on both fronts would be useful right now.
Finally, let me just comment on financial market conditions. My sense is that what the
public has seen—the large failures, the variety of resolution techniques, the deliberations leading
up to the Congress’s adoption of the bill it adopted—taken together have added up to significant
pessimism on people’s parts and have altered optimal strategy for a lot of financial institutions.
So I think that is altering how people allocate portfolios and has led to further volatility in certain
markets. It has led some institutions to adopt a wait-and-see attitude, to see how particular
programs are going to be implemented. I think that we are seeing at least some dead-weight loss
associated with the burdens of shifting financial flows between things that are covered and things
that aren’t and we are seeing a good deal of rent-seeking behavior as well. What we are seeing is
going to have the effect of masking the evolution of underlying fundamentals. It is going to
make it harder to see our way through this and understand just what is happening. I think that is
going to be a thicket that we will need to cut through in the months ahead. That concludes my
comments, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. While the LIBOR–OIS spread has
narrowed somewhat, the mutual fund industry is no longer experiencing waves of redemptions, and
commercial paper market conditions have improved, we’re still not back to the short-term credit
conditions that prevailed before the failure of Lehman Brothers. This outcome is striking
considering the historic interventions that have occurred in the past month. With all of the new

October 28–29, 2008

79 of 206

government guarantees and equity infusions here and abroad, the limited improvement in short-term
credit markets attests to the degree of concern and risk aversion prevailing in financial markets.
These concerns are likely to become even more elevated if the economy slows to the degree
expected in most forecasts. Like the Greenbook, our forecast anticipates a significant recession.
The Boston forecast includes three consecutive quarters of negative GDP growth and results in an
unemployment rate peaking above 7½ percent. The weakening labor market and the large losses in
housing and stock wealth make it quite likely that consumption will shrink in the second half of this
year. While we need housing to reach bottom, mortgage rates relative to federal funds rates remain
quite high, and further job losses are likely to aggravate the upward trend in foreclosures and add to
the downward pressure on housing prices. With limited new home purchases and demand for
vehicles weak, consumption of consumer durables is unlikely to recover until next year.
Commercial real estate, which has held up reasonably well, all things considered, is likely to be
much weaker next year as new and rollover financing is difficult to obtain and staff cuts and hiring
freezes affect the space needed by businesses. More generally, firms are likely to have little
incentive to make new investments until the severity of the downturn becomes much clearer.
Unfortunately, many of our trading partners are likely to face an even more severe downturn,
aggravated by their slow fiscal and monetary response to deteriorating economic and financial
conditions. While the Greenbook assumes the stock market will rise by 8 percent for the remainder
of this year—it looks as though that happened today—
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Nice job, Dave. [Laughter]
MR. STOCKTON. I think that just offset the decline that had happened since the time we
finished the Greenbook. [Laughter]
MR. ROSENGREN. —I would say that I’d be surprised by that outcome.

October 28–29, 2008

80 of 206

There are several looming financial problems that are likely to affect financial markets. Bill
Dudley highlighted the one that I think is the biggest for me, which is that the NAV (net asset value)
triggers for hedge funds will be a significant problem in the fourth quarter. Without comprehensive
information on hedge funds, it’s difficult to know the extent of the problems they are facing.
However, since the stock market remains one of the few markets available for the disposing of
assets in bulk without a significant liquidity haircut, I’d expect significant selling in the fourth
quarter. My second big concern is that rollover financing will become more problematic as
financial problems persist. Particularly exposed are real estate developers and highly leveraged
private equity firms. My third worry is that neither insurance companies nor commercial banks
have reserved for the economic outcome in our baseline forecast. Under-reserving and high payout
ratios are likely to limit the amount of additional lending that banks are willing to take on. These
financial problems place additional downside risk to our forecast.
Our forecast, like the Greenbook forecast, expects the rate of inflation to slow as a result of
falling food and energy prices and significant excess capacity emerging in the economy. In fact, our
equations indicate there is a non-negligible risk that deflation will be a problem in the outyears of
our forecast. Unlike President Lacker, I was surprised that it stayed as high as 1 rather than as low
as 1. The outlook for a weak real economy and falling inflation highlights the need for both
monetary and fiscal policy to offset some of the financial and economic problems that we are likely
to experience. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me just briefly say that, in our region, we
have continued to do actually better than the national average, but that is beginning to wane. We are
seeing, obviously, the energy effect show itself as rigs are being put out of production and you see a

October 28–29, 2008

81 of 206

slowing there. We are seeing some concerns being raised about agricultural prices and the boom
that has been going on in that part of the economy.
That said, there’s still a reasonable amount of business going on that they haven’t frozen up.
We asked our directors and our other advisers how they were seeing things, and it varies. There
were some organizations that say that our non-investment-grade borrowers from the banks, if they
had credit already, are still able to access those lines. If they lost some portion because of a bank
problem or something like that, they cannot get new credit, so it is cut off in that way. I think that’s
important to keep in mind. Businesses themselves are beginning to pull back on their capital plans.
They’ve said that. Their balance sheets—obviously outside the auto industry—are still decent, but
they’re saying, “We’re looking at this, and we’re pulling back until we see how it plays out.” You
are beginning to hear more of that. They feel that they can get credit. Some of them are talking
about actually trying to pull down their lines to make sure they have the money, and the only thing
keeping them from doing that is they don’t know what to do with it once they get it. So that’s their
dilemma. They’re afraid of losing their credit, but they also know that it costs if they pull it down.
So the dynamics there are interesting.
On the national outlook, I’ll be brief. I think that obviously the projections for recession are
in place. Down is where we’re going. How much, though, is speculation right now. I don’t know.
I don’t know that anyone does until we begin to see things settle out. Inflation should be down as
well. Obviously, when you have a recession, you will back off from that, but how much? That’s
not clear at this point. There is a lot in play, and that’s why we don’t know the answers to those
questions. We have these liquidity facilities and an enormous amount of liquidity out. We have the
TARP that is now in process but not completed. That’s going to have an impact, and I think those
are very important. As we discuss our own policy, we are very close to the point of the quantitative

October 28–29, 2008

82 of 206

easing discussion that we had, as you said, in 2003. Pulling that material out and taking a look at
that is important as we decide what we’re going to put our money into as we try to stimulate this
economy. Right now we’re subject to waiting and seeing. There’s been a lot done, and attitudes are
a critical part of this now, and we just have to wait to see how those change over the next quarter or
two. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m not going to say much about the District
conditions. In the Third District, as many of you have noted, they’ve weakened considerably. I will
make just a couple of observations that I think might be pertinent. Our last Business Outlook
Survey, the one that was released a week ago, had actually gone into positive territory in September
to 3.8, which was the first positive reading we had had since January—since, I guess, last
December, actually. And it dropped from that plus 3.8 to minus 37.5 in one month. Now, it’s
relevant to know the timing of this a bit. Our survey is done during the first 2 weeks or the first 10
or 12 days of each month—which meant that the September survey was closed on September 12, 4
days before that weekend. So what we see is a very precipitous, dramatic change in the tone that
had as much to do with events and perhaps policy actions as with what was actually going on in the
economy.
I share a bit of President Lacker’s concern to try to disentangle a little the tone and feel of
the economy, which really did feel as though it fell off a cliff in September, unlike any other month
that I’ve seen during this episode. We have to think carefully about disentangling that effect not just
because something fundamental happened to the economy but also to see to what extent policies,
whether our policies or Treasury’s policies, have contributed to a change in tone and increased
uncertainty and aggravated what might be the real fundamentals going on. I don’t know the answer

October 28–29, 2008

83 of 206

to that question, but it suggests something that many of us have argued over time—that moreconsistent and more-predictable policies can help us avoid some of that.
One special question that was asked in this survey in October was whether firms had trouble
getting credit. Interestingly enough, only 14 percent of the respondents reported that they had
trouble obtaining credit, but twice that number, almost 30 percent, reported that they believed that
their customers were having trouble getting credit, which was an interesting dynamic going on that
leads to a bit of uncertainty. I guess the best thing I can say about the Third District right now is
“Go Phillies!” [Laughter] Maybe that will turn things around in the Third District.
Anyway, let me turn briefly to the national outlook. It has deteriorated, certainly more than
I expected, from what I thought in June. In our conference call on October 7, I indicated that I was
revising my forecast downward. I expect the economy to contract during the second half of this
year and perhaps in the first quarter of next year—but that’s less clear to me—and then gradually
approach what I would consider trend growth over 2009, so that by the end of 2009 we’re getting
back toward what might be considered trend growth, which I consider to be about 2.5 to 2.7 percent.
In essence, for 2010-11, I pushed out my recovery of the economy by somewhere between six and
nine months because of the current turmoil. I expect the unemployment rate to peak around mid’09 at about 7¼ and then to decline gradually to its long-run rate of about 5 percent by the end of
2010. Inflation pressures have subsided somewhat since June, and inflation expectations have
remained contained. I expect core inflation to decline gradually from the current levels to my goal
of about 1.7 percent by 2010.
Now, my overall forecast is considerably better than the Greenbook baseline forecast. In
fact, it’s similar to what we talked about as the “more rapid financial recovery” scenario, which
makes some of the adjustment for the financial turmoil somewhat quicker and somewhat less

October 28–29, 2008

84 of 206

dramatic than in the baseline. The fed funds rate path underlying my forecast is less
accommodative than the Greenbook. I assume that the fed funds rate remains at 1½ percent through
the spring of next year and then gradually begins to rise, reaching 4¼ percent by the end of 2010.
Now, there are certainly risks around that forecast. Somebody at this table has to be a little more
optimistic after all, and we have risks around all forecasts in this environment. Certainly mine is no
exception. In particular, the effect of the financial markets, as we’ve all been talking about, remains
highly uncertain and highly risky, and I am not trying to disregard that. Every day it seems as
though there’s a new development, usually negative, although I guess 900 points on the Dow today
should be considered good news.
But in fact, I believe that the risks around the Greenbook baseline forecast are to the upside,
as I have alluded to. First, the baseline entails a sizable downward adjustment based at least partly
on the volatile financial data, especially spreads. Spreads can fall dramatically, although they don’t
always do so. But they can rise and fall very quickly, and I think it’s very risky to base monetary
policy, which ought to be taking a longer-term perspective, on week-to-week movements in such
volatile variables. If spreads do continue to fall over the next quarter or two as they have in recent
days and if the financial market tools we’ve put in place have the desired effect, we could see the
economy becoming much stronger than the Greenbook’s baseline. Second, in the Greenbook,
inflation falls and remains low despite a very low fed funds rate path. In fact, it’s reminiscent of the
funds rate path in 2003-04. This apparently is due to the sizable output gaps that open up in the
forecast period. Now, these output gaps arise in the forecast because the effects of the financial
turmoil show up mainly in aggregate demand. However, as I’ve suggested in previous meetings
and as President Lacker alluded to, I think a plausible alternative view is that the financial market
disturbances we’ve experienced—resulting in a restructuring of the financial system and a lowering

October 28–29, 2008

85 of 206

of the efficiency of financial intermediation—act on the supply side as well, much like a somewhat
persistent productivity shock with an associated damping effect on measures of potential GDP for
some period of time. If so, we’ll see much smaller output gaps opening up, and that means the risk
of higher inflation than in the Greenbook, especially if the baseline funds rate path is followed as
they lay out.
In thinking about the appropriate monetary policy going forward, it’s important that we not
let our policy be whipsawed by volatile market data. We have been lowering the funds rate since
January, largely in anticipation of a recession or to mitigate the chances of one occurring. Now, it
may finally have arrived. Does that mean we have to lower more? A difficult question. The level
of the funds rate is always a difficult question. Clearly, if we experience a sustained slowdown in
real economic activity, which suggests a lower equilibrium in the real rate of interest, policy needs
to allow the funds rate to fall with the equilibrium rate, and I based my recommendations
throughout the year on such a forecast. But I think it’s a mistake to overreact to volatile data,
especially when it’s the stock market. Although there has always been the desire and much pressure
from markets to do something when we see such swings in the market, in my view, the economy is
better served if monetary policy is a steadying hand, taking appropriate action when the
intermediate-term view dictates, but not overreacting to fluctuations in the market with an
inappropriate tool. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I have a question about the potential output view. So you
would also have to argue that the natural rate of unemployment is higher because of this.
MR. PLOSSER. Yes.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You think that’s plausible? I mean, I understand why
productive capacity would be affected, but why do you—

October 28–29, 2008

86 of 206

MR. PLOSSER. Well, I don’t like the NAIRU, but in my baseline forecast, my natural rate
of unemployment is higher than what the Greenbook has.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. But it rises because of the financial situation. I see.
MR. PLOSSER. Yes, right.
MR. LACKER. If I could, Mr. Chairman, in the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium
models, one of which I understand has been adopted by the staff for use in forecasting, employment
fluctuates with shocks to productivity, and it’s the natural correspondent to that. So in some sense
the unemployment rate rises because the natural rate rises, but that’s a way of saying that the natural
rate goes up in recessions. I’m not sure if proponents of the natural rate view that as consistent with
that old model, but that’s what happens in these models.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Employment fluctuates, but to get unemployment you need a
richer picture of matching, or something like that.
MR. LACKER. Right. You need some matching model, and you get intersectoral flows.
You get the same thing.
MR. PLOSSER. But even in my steady state, if I view this as a permanent inefficiency in
financial intermediation that changes things, the unemployment rate is a little higher.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll start with a few comments about the District
economy, which will sound pretty familiar by now. The preponderance of the anecdotes from
business contacts that I’ve talked with since our last meeting have been distinctly negative. It’s not
just a slowing of activity or some deterioration but a sharp contraction in activity, particularly with
regard to discretionary spending or discretionary projects, beginning in the middle of September.
The one exception to that is commercial construction, where there are enough things under way that

October 28–29, 2008

87 of 206

business remains pretty good. But the backlogs are dropping, and so weakness certainly is
anticipated next year. I thought another possible exception to the negative tone was the housing
market in the Twin Cities—not that the housing market in the Twin Cities is in and of itself so
important but that it might be representative of some middle-of-the-road markets across the country.
Clearly, it’s not indicative of what’s going on in Florida, California, or places like those because
sales volumes in the Twin Cities had been up distinctly. Some of that is no doubt due to short sales
and foreclosures; nevertheless, there were some other signs that were favorable. The affordability
index has really improved a lot. It is back to levels of 2002-03, which Realtors call very
comfortable. The ratio of housing prices to rent has moved back to the levels of 2002-03, and that’s
also encouraging. I already mentioned the higher sales volumes.
Unfortunately, when you get beyond those statistics and look at other things, it’s too early to
declare stability in the housing market or anything resembling underlying improvement. Part of the
problem is something that we’ve talked about before. The inventory of unsold, unoccupied
properties remains very substantial—by historical experience way above anything resembling
normal. Second, even though the price-to-rent ratio has come down, it’s still elevated relative to the
longer-term historical experience. So it looks to me as though, even in that market, there are some
further price declines to come and it’s going to take some more time to get through all of this—
probably well into next year.
As far as the national economy is concerned, I, too, have marked down my outlook for real
growth for the balance of this year, for all of next year, and into early 2010 as well. This reflects to
some extent the nature of the incoming data but also the intensification of the financial problems
and associated headwinds, the impact of the negative wealth effect, and so on. When I looked at my
June forecast, back then the forecast obviously looked better, although there were a number of what

October 28–29, 2008

88 of 206

I called “identifiable negatives.” They have proven, for worse rather than for better, to be relevant.
I already talked about some of them. In addition, we still have the problem in housing with excess
inventories. We have steady declines in employment, which obviously have negative implications
for consumer spending, and the credit headwinds as well. So now I have the economy contracting
through the middle of next year, modest growth resuming thereafter, and robust growth beginning
with the second quarter of 2010—quite some distance off.
On the inflation outlook, I have for some time been thinking that inflation would begin to
slow this quarter. With the decline in commodity prices, the evolution of the economic outlook, and
so forth, my confidence in that forecast has increased, and I do expect inflation to diminish over the
forecast period. So I think I’ll conclude with that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I concur with the view that we face a very
serious situation. In most respects I agree with the Greenbook baseline projection, with the
reasoning that the Board staff used to arrive at the projection, and with their view that the risks to
growth are to the downside. Like the Greenbook projection, my projection is heavily influenced by
judgments that we are bringing to the projection from forces that are not captured by our models.
The magnitude of the judgmental adjustment has become strikingly large, as we talked about earlier,
and I realize that, if one wanted to be a skeptic about the Greenbook baseline, one would have to
look no further than these assumptions and question their significant influence on the outlook.
But I am not a skeptic. During the past few weeks, in our Bank we have stepped up our
contacts with business people from large, medium, and smaller businesses, bankers, and local
government officials. We have been asking them to tell us not so much what they think and feel but
what has actually happened to their order books, production runs, and account receivables and what

October 28–29, 2008

89 of 206

actions they are taking as a result. It suffices to say that the feedback about the environment was
overwhelmingly negative. Respondents say that their situation has gone either from good to bad or
from bad to worse, and I want to share just two anecdotes that I think capture the essence of what
we are facing—one of them from a business perspective and the other from a consumer perspective.
One of my directors is the CEO of a company that produces and sells forklift trucks all over the
world. He reported last week that his sales are down and orders have fallen off dramatically, and he
expects to be announcing some layoffs soon. But what was making a greater impression on him is
the fact that orders for the forklift parts have fallen off as well, and this tells him that the warehouse
operators have cut back on the use of trucks that they already own. My second story concerns the
owner of a body shop that is located in a solid, middle class community. He told us that he was
doing record business all year until last month, when business just went dead. He said it is not that
people suddenly don’t need auto repairs, but in fact, they are collecting the insurance money and not
fixing their cars. They want the cash and they don’t want to pay out the deductible.
Stories like these convince me that the Greenbook baseline is on the right track. I do part
company with the Greenbook in one respect—namely, the longer-term inflation outlook. I think it
is quite likely that we are going to experience some costly reallocation of resources across some
sectors of the economy. Finance and construction are two obvious examples. Going forward, I
think there is reason to think that fewer workers and less capital are going to be employed in these
sectors. The costly adjustment is going to be characterized by slower productivity growth, higher
trend unit labor costs, and a smaller output gap than would otherwise occur, leading to somewhat
less disinflation in the outyears in my projection. Nevertheless, with output and inflation expected
to decline sharply over the coming quarters, I think it is essential for us to be thinking about the zero
bound in conducting monetary policy in a low inflation environment, and I will address the

October 28–29, 2008

90 of 206

magnitude, timing, and communication aspects of our monetary policy in tomorrow’s go-round.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Economic conditions in the Eighth District
have deteriorated since the September Beige Book. Citing weak demand and higher input costs, a
variety of manufacturing firms throughout the District reported job cuts and plant closings. The
decline in manufacturing activity has been concentrated in firms producing durable goods. Service
sector activity also continues to decline. In particular, recent layoffs have been reported in business,
medical, and financial services. Two large auto dealers have closed and filed for bankruptcy. Retail
sales are steady, but contacts have noticed that consumers are trading down to lower-priced
products. The residential real estate sector continues to decline across the District. As lending
standards have tightened for commercial building projects, industrial construction has slowed.
Payroll employment numbers continue to vary across the Bank’s Branch cities. The most
recent figures suggest that Memphis and St. Louis continue to lose jobs at a pace faster than at the
national level. Louisville has moved from two consecutive months of positive year-over-year
employment growth to negative growth in the most recent month. Little Rock continues to
experience positive year-over-year employment growth. Unemployment rates in St. Louis and
Memphis remain above 7 percent—that’s 7.2 percent and 7.1 percent, respectively. Louisville’s
unemployment rate is 6.6 percent. In opposition to the national trend, Little Rock’s unemployment
rate has fallen to just 4 percent.
The national outlook is clouded by dramatically increased uncertainty fueled by the financial
market turmoil. The explosion of uncertainty is driven in part by speculation about the nature of the
government response to the turmoil, both in the United States and abroad. We know from past

October 28–29, 2008

91 of 206

experience that, when economic actors—investors, businesses, and consumers—are faced with new
and substantial uncertainty, they tend to adopt a “wait and see” approach, during which they make
as few commitments as possible. This seems to be a reasonable expectation in the current
environment, so we should expect to see many types of important economic decisions being
deferred. Anecdotal evidence seems to support this idea. Most likely, this means we will
experience an important deterioration in economic activity during the second half of 2008 and into
2009.
In times of increased uncertainty, it can be useful to consider distinct alternative scenarios
instead of considering a baseline scenario with many possible offshoots. The financial sector crisis
that we are experiencing has some admittedly inexact parallels with the banking crises that occurred
in Japan since 1990 and in the Nordic countries in the early 1990s. The general tenor of the
literature on these events is that the Nordic countries dealt forthrightly with their financial sector
problems, suffered through recessions, but were well positioned to grow once the crisis had been
addressed. For Japan, real economic performance was subpar for a long time, and it is the Japanese
outcome that is a looming risk for the U.S. economy. Part of the Japanese experience was the
lowering of nominal interest rates to zero. This was done, no doubt, in the name of doing
everything possible to help the economy recover. It was not very successful and, in fact, may have
been counterproductive.
Recent academic work—I’m thinking of Jess Benhabib here—has emphasized the
possibility of a low nominal interest rate, low inflation rate, steady state equilibrium, and a trap at
very low or zero nominal interest rates. This steady state coexists with the targeted steady state, the
one we know and love, which has inflation at our specified target and relatively high nominal
interest rates. So there are two possible focal points for the economy. Markets clear at both of these

October 28–29, 2008

92 of 206

focal points. My main concern is that if we choose to continue to flirt with the trap steady state, we
should think clearly about the possible implications given the current environment. The trap steady
state is associated with very low inflation expectations, actually deflation. This is, in fact, what
happened to Japan. They experienced deflation of about 1 percent for a number of years. Since our
core problems are in the housing market, which is dominated by nominal contracting, deflation
could sharply exacerbate our problems and lead to further difficulties. I am, frankly, not sure that
this is a wise route for the Committee or for the nation. My preferred approach would be to
maintain rates at the current low level and to use alternative fiscal policy actions to address the
particular concerns in financial markets. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Well, it’s a little after 6:00 p.m., a long afternoon.
Why don’t we recess the meeting until tomorrow morning? There’s a reception and a dinner up on
the terrace, which is for your convenience. There’s no business being conducted, and we’ll see you
in the morning. Thank you.
[Meeting recessed]

October 28–29, 2008

93 of 206

October 29, 2008—Morning Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everybody.
PARTICIPANTS. Good morning.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We have some data this morning. Dave, would you like to
discuss this?
MR. STOCKTON.6 Yes. You have at your place a table on orders and shipments of
durable goods, one of the more inscrutable releases to actually make sense of, but the bottom line is
very little effect on our basic outlook here. As you can see in that second set of numbers, the
shipments area excluding the aircraft line was up 2 percent in September. That was actually a little
stronger than we had penciled in, but only enough to add a few basis points to GDP growth in the
third quarter. Then you can see that it has basically been averaging flat for the last two months.
This is a September figure, so it’s fairly dated at this point. The orders figures, the set of numbers
above—again looking at the “excluding aircraft” line—have been coming down. I wouldn’t say
that they’re collapsing, but they’re certainly weakening some. So this really has no appreciable
effect on our outlook for a small decline in equipment spending in the third quarter and a more
appreciable decline in the fourth.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Does the resolution of the Boeing strike have any macro
implications?
MR. STOCKTON. We actually predicted that the strike would end this week. It did.
MR. PLOSSER. My, you’re good.
MR. STOCKTON. It wasn’t looking too good last week. [Laughter] But we’re expecting
that it would provide a small rebound effect on first-quarter GDP growth. It’s going to take a little
while to get production back on track here.
6

The materials used by Mr. Stockton are appended to this transcript (appendix 6).

October 28–29, 2008

94 of 206

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions for Dave? Okay. If not, let’s continue with
our go-round. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We expect a recession at
least as bad as the 1990–91 recession, with a significant risk of a deeper, more protracted downturn
worse than the ’80s, and a very substantial rise in the unemployment rate. Inflation is decelerating
quickly, and deflationary forces are ascendant around the globe. The huge decline in energy and
commodity prices will add to a very substantial downward pressure on core inflation from increased
economic slack around the world. We could see an abrupt change in inflation expectations into
deflationary territory.
We’ve seen a lot of policy action over the past few weeks. One question is whether
policymakers should wait to measure the effects of these measures before going further, and I want
to talk a little about that question. My view is that I don’t think so. The outlook has been
deteriorating ahead of the policy response. This is true both here and around the world. The
magnitude and speed of the tightening financial conditions, the erosion in business and consumer
confidence, the fall in actual spending, and the shift in inflation risk together present very grave
risks to growth and to the financial system. Mitigating these risks is going to require more monetary
policy here but even more so in the other major economies. But in addition to the very substantial
easing in the global stance of monetary policy ahead, the substantial damage that has already
happened to financial intermediation globally suggests that a broad-based and quite large fiscal
stimulus will be critical to prevent an excessive fall in aggregate demand.
How quickly and how far should we reduce the federal funds rate in the United States? The
Greenbook and the Bluebook present a very strong case for moving down another 100 basis points
quickly. In fact, if I read the pictures in the Bluebook correctly, they might imply a need to get real

October 28–29, 2008

95 of 206

rates to the negative 3 to negative 5 percent territory relatively quickly, if we could do that. If we
don’t move another 50 today, we’ll be behind again. Monetary policy has effectively tightened
substantially since the summer, of course, because of the intensification of financial pressures and
because of the rise in forward real interest rates that have come with the rapid deceleration in
expected future inflation. Beyond this meeting and this choice, our choices are harder. I think we
need to get real rates lower and, to make sure we get them there, we need to keep them low enough
long enough. This requires that we get the nominal fed funds rate as low as possible as soon as
possible. I don’t see a good case for monetary policy gradualism in the current context. The risks
are too great. If we’re too tentative, the damage to the financial system and to the real economy
could be much greater and much harder to correct. If we end up doing too much, we can always
adjust. That’s an easier problem to solve. It just requires will. With global financial markets
placing progressively more weight on a very severe global recession, the “keep our powder dry” and
“reserve our remaining ammunition” arguments don’t seem that compelling to me. We don’t have
much ammunition left in the fed funds rate anyway. If we hold that back, it will likely be less
effective when we ultimately use it. The more powerful escalation options we have left will
probably involve communications, such as continued commitments to keep rates low enough long
enough that we avert creeping expectations of deflation and can be confident that inflation will
come in around our target level over the forecast period.
I don’t have a strong view now about how low we can go with the nominal fed funds rate
without causing too much risk of damage to the functioning of financial systems. We need to look
at all possible options, though. I think the principal focus of our staff’s work in the coming weeks
will be to put together a set of alternative policy options going forward along with the analysis of
their benefits and risks so that we’re in a position to act quickly enough to be effective. Just a few

October 28–29, 2008

96 of 206

final points. I think this basic risk-management choice really involves three dimensions of
judgment. One is about the relative probability of alternative outcomes. The second is about the
relative consequences of or the damage caused by those alternative scenarios. Importantly, it also
involves a judgment about the ease of correcting, adjusting, or mitigating the consequences of being
wrong.
This is just a stylized presentation, but in the staff notes yesterday, there was a nice way to
think about those choices. I just wanted to point out one thing about this stylized framework of
those choices, which is the consequence. If you look at exhibit 5, the bottom left panel, which
shows the inflation outcome associated with the “more rapid recovery” scenario, in this presentation
you don’t have much risk of a very bad inflation outcome in the event that we end up doing too
much with too much policy and have to take that back. Again, it’s important to recognize that it’s
not just about the probability that we attach to the alternative scenarios. It’s not just about the
relative impact of the consequences of those scenarios. It’s about the ease with which we can
correct for a judgment that was wrong—in this case, a judgment that we did too much. This may
understate the complications in correcting for that error and may make it look easier than it may
ultimately be, but I think it’s a nice framework.
Finally, I just want to point out, just to underscore the basic point: This is not going to be
principally about monetary policy going forward. If you look at the broad framework of policies
that are now in place, both here and globally, and the instruments we have to play with, along with
the fiscal authorities: we have monetary policy; we have the liquidity arrangements and what we do
with our balance sheet over time; we, the collectively integrated government, have the broad fiscal
policy questions and the scope for either a broad-based substantial fiscal package or more-targeted
fiscal measures, as the Chairman suggested, to focus on the credit markets; and we have the

October 28–29, 2008

97 of 206

capacity to alter the framework of capital and guarantees that is now in place. Beyond that, the
government here also has the ability to change what the GSEs, the FHA, and the FHLB can do. So
when we think about escalating going forward, to go to President Fisher’s question from yesterday,
we have the ability on all these fronts to do more if that’s necessary and prudent. But I think the
mix has already changed substantially. It was probably mostly fiscal nine months ago. It is
certainly mostly fiscal now in a broader sense, except that many of the major economies going
forward will have to move monetary policy very substantially. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. A number of the presentations yesterday talked
about falling off a cliff in the middle of September. I think we need to remind ourselves that we
were sliding downhill pretty fast before we hit that cliff. The third-quarter data, which aren’t really
affected by what happened in the last two weeks of September, indicate that the economy was
weaker than we thought at the time of the last FOMC meeting. I think Dave Stockton or Norm
Morin noted that about a third of their downward revision reflected incoming data rather than the
credit tightening. That was especially true for consumption, with real consumption spending falling
through the summer, responding to lower employment and tighter credit. Private domestic final
purchases were revised down to a decline of 3½ percent in the third quarter after being flat in the
first half.
Housing price declines picked up in August, and I think the deteriorating economy and
concerns about the economy were reflected in increased nervousness in financial markets over the
summer into the first half of September. It was really those worries about what the losses were
going to be and how they would spread from mortgages to loan books generally—that deepening
pessimism—that doomed the marginal institutions like AIG and Lehman and the GSEs. They just

October 28–29, 2008

98 of 206

didn’t have a chance to recapitalize or stabilize themselves when so many of the other market
participants were worried about what their own positions would be. The resulting flight to liquidity
and safety, the loss of confidence that followed, the deepening gloom, and the failures and near
failures and associated losses triggered a tremendous tightening of financial conditions over the
intermeeting period—President Yellen and others discussed this—despite the 50 basis points of
easing. Even after the 900 point increase yesterday, equity prices are down about 20 or 22 percent
over the intermeeting period. The dollar is up 10 percent. Corporate borrowing rates are up for
investment-grade corporations 200 to 250 basis points. Banks tell us that they’re tightening across
every dimension of their lending; and other lenders, like finance companies, are also cutting back
very, very sharply. You can see this in autos clearly, but the stress is much broader than just the
auto finance companies.
We have good programs in place to deal with many of these problems—the capital, the
FDIC guarantees, and the Federal Reserve balance sheet facilities—and they are having some
effects relative to the freezing up of markets that we had in mid-September. We can see that
interbank spreads and LIBOR have come down some. Commercial paper rose, I guess, on Monday
with the introduction of our facility. Declines in money market mutual funds have abated, though
they’re still there, and there are some signs that maturities are beginning to lengthen in funding
markets. As these programs are more fully implemented, we’ll see some greater effects—including,
I hope, some greater willingness to extend credit. I also assume that the fiscal package is necessary,
as in the Greenbook “fiscal stimulus” alternative.
But we need to remember that the improvement we’ve seen over the last couple of days is
relative to a situation in which funding markets were in effect frozen beyond a very short term, and
although a sharp snapback is possible, as President Plosser was noting yesterday, I think further

October 28–29, 2008

99 of 206

gains are more likely to be gradual. In the past few days, the declines in LIBOR have seemed very
grudging and gradual, and LIBOR remains quite high—I think close to 75 basis points higher—
relative to what it was in mid-August, before we even cut rates. This was three-month LIBOR that I
looked at this morning. In an environment of economic weakness, spreading credit problems,
falling house prices, a number of false dawns in this episode so far, and death and near-death
experiences, lenders and investors are going to continue to be very cautious and conserve their
liquidity and capital. So despite further improvements, financial conditions will remain quite tight.
The effects of lower wealth, higher borrowing costs, the stronger dollar, and tighter nonprice terms
of credit will play out over the next few quarters, putting downward pressure on an economy that
was already in recession.
At the same time, heightened uncertainty and fear of future problems caused a sharp
deterioration in attitudes and spending even apart from the effects of credit. Judging from the
Conference Board index, regional purchasing manager surveys, and anecdotes—including what we
heard around the table yesterday—it feels like a recessionary psychology, as I think Charlie Evans
called it. Others talked about pulling back and curtailment of discretionary spending in train, and
this is not just caused by credit effects. This is just fear. So we’ve had a downward shift in
aggregate demand as well as a movement along the aggregate demand curve, and this downward
shift in aggregate demand will propagate through multiplier–accelerator effects even if attitudes
begin to improve some.
The global dimensions of the shock are important. As we talked about yesterday,
heightened risk aversion has had a pronounced effect on emerging market economies as well as on
industrial economies. Net exports cushioned domestic weakness in the first half of the year, but
with the dollar strong, if anything we’ll be absorbing weakness from abroad, not exporting it, as the

October 28–29, 2008

100 of 206

rest of the year goes on and we get into next year. Growing credit problems abroad will only add to
pressures on many large global lenders who might have thought they were diversified
geographically. But a little like our U.S. housing market, they will find that diversification doesn’t
really work when there’s a global recession.
The net effect of all of this is a much weaker growth path for the economy. In my forecast, I
had a somewhat steeper near-term decline in economic activity and a slightly sharper bounceback
than the staff, including my fiscal assumption, but I also have the unemployment rate peaking at
over 7 percent, as the Greenbook did. With commodity prices plunging, the added slack maintained
through several years, and declines in inflation expectations, inflation will be on a clear downward
track. In the Greenbook, this downward track for inflation obtained even with the assumption of
some rebound in commodity prices and the resumption of dollar weakness. In my forecast for
inflation from next year on, inflation was at or below the 1½ to 2 percent rate I would like to see as
a steady state consistent with avoiding the zero bound when adverse shocks hit.
Critically, the downside risks around activity forecasts are huge and tilted to the downside. I
think they’re huge because we’ve never seen a situation like this before, certainly not in my
experience dating all the way back to 1970, and have only the vaguest notion of how it will play out
in financial markets and spending. I think they’re tilted to the downside because I, like the staff,
assumed a gradual improvement in financial markets. That could be delayed or even go in the
wrong direction for a time, further tightening financial conditions. In addition, the effect on
spending of the heightened concerns and tighter credit conditions could be larger and longer lasting
than I assumed. For some time an important downside risk to the forecast has been a sharp upward
revision to household saving as wealth, job availability, and borrowing capacity eroded. I assumed
a moderate increase in the saving rate, but I can definitely see the possibility that adverse

October 28–29, 2008

101 of 206

developments will galvanize a more thorough rethinking by the household sector of what saving is
needed, and that will affect investment as well as consumption. We’ll get to the policy implications
of all of this in the next round. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The first sentence of the Greenbook said that
“recent economic and financial news has been dismal”; and the last sentence on page 1 of the
Bluebook said that “markets generally remain extremely illiquid and volatile.” I can’t do better than
that, but I can certainly do worse; so let me give that a try. [Laughter]
Market prices and official and corporate data confirm an additional leg down in midSeptember, which has been much discussed. I think it is going to become increasingly clear that
October, particularly the first 20 days of the month, was materially worse. So if we fell off the cliff
in the middle of September, I think that once the data come out and find their way into the
marketplace in October, the Greenbook forecast might look a bit more positive than the facts on the
ground would suggest. As a result, my own forecast is less optimistic than the Greenbook, but there
is plenty of uncertainty, as I think Dave Stockton talked about yesterday.
Let me make a few comments about financial markets before turning to the broader
economy. I expect a prolonged period of significantly strained credit markets, and that strain is
likely to be exacerbated between now and year-end and I suspect even well into 2009. The credit
intermediation process that we’ve talked about is fundamentally broken. I talked six months ago
about the financial architecture that was fundamentally being changed. I think that has all happened
faster than I could have anticipated. Confidence, not just in counterparties but in basic rules of
doing business across financial markets, has been lost, and my own sense is that loss of confidence
is not easily fixed, even by well-intended government programs. We should all be quite patient in

October 28–29, 2008

102 of 206

terms of seeing the benefits of the rather dramatic actions taken by the official sector, both here in
the United States and overseas. Corporate bond rates and other risk spreads may well fall from their
recent peaks, as suggested in the Greenbook, but spreads across asset classes are likely to stay far
wider than historical norms throughout the forecast period. I think these new spread relationships
are uncertain. So what we thought would be sort of normal spreads of LIBOR and normal spreads
of corporate bonds, all have to be reassessed not just by us but also by market participants. Even if
credit is now made more available to businesses through some of these new Treasury and other
programs, I suspect the all-in cost of capital is likely to materially impede business investment,
particularly given expectations by businesses for a weaker economy in the upcoming period. As
Vice Chairman Geithner suggested, monetary policy might be able to do a bit about this, but it is not
going to be able to change it very much.
Let me turn to three points on the economy before closing. First, in the near term, given my
sense of how October is tracking, it’s likely to be extraordinarily weak. I expect weaker fourthquarter consumption than the Greenbook, weaker labor markets going into 2009, and a materially
weaker fourth-quarter GDP print. Some labor surveys—including some of my own preferred
measures, like the JOLTS—seem to be holding up; but I’m not sure that that’s going to hold for
another couple of months. So I’d expect the labor markets to trend more materially in the direction
that I’ve discussed.
Well, what about beyond the near term? What about 2009 and beyond? It strikes me that
the catalysts for marked improvement are lacking. When I think about fiscal policy, regulatory
policy, tax policy, and trade policy, which I talked about previously, it’s not obvious to me that any
of those are going to provide some kind of catalyst for a marked change in the contour of the
economy. On the fiscal front, I assume that the fiscal stimulus is likely to be larger, maybe even

October 28–29, 2008

103 of 206

materially larger, than in the Greenbook alternative simulation, but my own conclusions are similar
to the Greenbook’s, which is that I’m not sure it’s going to be terribly effective. I’m not sure it’s
going to be constructed in that way, and I’m not sure it will do nearly as much as it will inevitably
be advertised to do. A more disturbing trend probably even than the efficacy of a fiscal package—
which in my own view is absolutely necessary, but again I query whether it’s going to be structured
in a way to do what it needs to do—is that potential output in the forecast period is likely to fall.
Trend growth rates are coming down, and I expect productivity to fall perhaps even more than in the
Greenbook projection. The vaunted resilience of the U.S. economy, which I’ve talked about for a
long time, is certainly going to be tested during this period. Business investment, it strikes me, will
be a useful gauge as we get into the first quarter of 2009 to see how tough an economic period we
have in front of us, and I worry about the decisions that business people will be making. Now, of
course, against all of this, markets could snap back, as we saw a little yesterday—2009 could look
better. We have to remain open minded about the possibility that the economy will continue, as it
has over the past ten or fifteen years, to outperform model-based expectations.
Let me turn to foreign growth. These decouplers, which were so prominent for so long, are
somehow hard to find these days. Foreign growth strikes me as likely to fall faster and stay lower
than in the Greenbook projection. The road back is not likely to begin as early as the first quarter of
2009 for our major trading partners. The “more financial fallout” alternative simulation strikes me
as significantly more likely for foreign growth. In light of a growth trajectory that is better here in
the United States than outside the United States, at least relative to current market expectations, I’d
expect the foreign exchange value of the dollar on balance to strengthen against a basket of foreign
currencies.

October 28–29, 2008

104 of 206

So let me turn finally to inflation. The trend on import prices, the broad measures of
commodity prices, and the expected dollar strength all suggest that inflation problems are abating
markedly. I think an open question, which isn’t likely to be dispositive but is likely to be
interesting, is how sticky prices are, particularly from the consumer product companies during this
period—how long the various surcharges and increases in prices we’ve seen can stay high and the
companies attempt to keep profit margins. My guess is that they can make profit margins look
decent for another quarter or two; but beyond that, prices across a broad set of products and services
are likely to retrace some of the gains in recent periods. I’ll save the balance of my remarks for the
next round. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kroszner.
MR. KROSZNER. Thank you. Well, the autumnal bonfires have really sort of heated up
since the last FOMC meeting. I think we have evidence in the United States and now worldwide of
what emerging market literature calls “sudden stops”—a sudden stopping of the flow of capital, the
so-called flow of hot money, into Latin America or other countries and the devastating impact that
could have when suddenly credit is no longer available. I’ve been talking about the slow burn of the
problems in the credit markets, but I think we saw that move up to a different level globally over the
past six weeks. This is the concern that we had earlier in the year about a regime shift. We seem to
have moved from a growth regime to a sliding-by-with-some-growth regime and now to a
contractionary one and the nonlinear effects that we had been concerned about.
As we always say, it’s particularly difficult to predict where the economy is going to go.
But there’s evidence of why it’s so difficult because almost any measure of volatility is up
dramatically. That’s true on the financial market side, on the real side, as well as just in movements
of consumer confidence. So I think that we can say with some confidence that it is particularly

October 28–29, 2008

105 of 206

difficult to predict which way things are going to go. As many people have said before, a few
spreads have come down, but given the extent of our actions and those of other governments around
the world—central banks, fiscal authorities, et cetera—it is surprising that there has been so little
effect.
Now, maybe it’s just because so much is going on that there’s a fair amount of confusion
and uncertainty about what the programs mean, how they will actually be implemented, and to
whom they will be applied. I think that’s perhaps part of the reason for some of the spreads not
coming down with respect to interbank borrowing—there is a lack of clarity about exactly how the
FDIC program will operate and exactly how the TARP will operate. We’ll hear more about that in
a bit, but I think it’s going to take time for people to feel confident about how that will work. Also,
I think there is real uncertainty because after thirty days some banks may not get the guarantees or
may have the guarantees pulled back. I think there is also a lot of uncertainty about who will get
TARP funding and who is qualified for TARP funding. As information comes out about people not
being qualified or markets being concerned that individual institutions are not going to be qualified,
that could put on a lot of pressure. Unfortunately, that’s going to be coming in addition to the endof-the-year pressures. So I see a number of looming risks, particularly in the financial services
sector, as we fully implement and clarify some of the programs that I think on balance can be
helpful but that can actually cause some uncertainty at individual institutions. Others have also
mentioned broader challenges in the emerging markets and the insurance companies and certainly
we have the hedge fund redemptions that are looming. I’m very concerned about trying to get over
the end of the year with so many different pieces putting additional pressure on. Even some of the
pieces that we thought would be helpful potentially have a lot of downside risk to them.

October 28–29, 2008

106 of 206

But even if we get through this—and the government guarantee programs, the special
liquidity facilities, and the negative real rates that we have and potentially may make even more
negative would provide some support—the fundamental uncertainty is not going to be resolved until
we see what is going to work in the financial sector, what’s going to be the successful business
model, and what are going to be the new sets of activities that can be undertaken. Will certain
funding markets come back and at what spread once you take away all these special programs?
Until that is worked out, I don’t see how the markets can figure out who will survive and who
won’t, who is going to be there in three months and who isn’t. I think that the programs are very
valuable in providing a time out—a time for people to reassess. But until there’s greater clarity in
those financing markets going forward, I don’t think the markets will actually be able to recover.
That why the alternative simulation that puts things off a bit more seems quite sensible to me.
Some specifics on consumption. As I often do, I talked with some of the largest providers
of consumer credit in the United States. They are reporting, exactly as Governor Kohn said, that
consumption or spending growth was decelerating through the summer, but it did seem to get much
more rapid in September and October. One of the large companies actually reported significant
contraction on the consumer side of spending. On the small business side, it was still positive but
down from double-digit growth in the second quarter to basically flat. They also looked across
income categories. This is not a phenomenon of just the people at one or the other end of the
spectrum. It seemed to be across the board for what they looked at. All of them have reported, just
as the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey did, a significant reduction of credit lines. So even if
we’re not seeing credit in and of itself having contracted yet, the ability to get credit down the line is
going to be much, much more difficult. Also the funding markets for the credit card companies

October 28–29, 2008

107 of 206

have effectively closed. They may reopen. Things may come back, but I think it’s going to take
time for that to happen, and they were certainly not optimistic about that.
As virtually everyone has mentioned, inflationary pressures for a variety of reasons are
much lower, and I think that fits into what the Vice Chairman said about thinking about the costs of
moving now and perhaps moving “too quickly.” There seem to be lower costs now in being a bit
more aggressive than, let’s say, six months ago because much less inflationary pressure seems to be
out there. I think a prudent risk-management point of view would certainly take into account those
costs and benefits. We need to use our monetary policy tools as effectively as we can and then
work with the other tools that a number of others have mentioned to try to get the markets to be
more comfortable with where things will go and then be able to lend to each other—to have the
unlocking of the credit markets without government guarantees, without negative interest rates, and
without extraordinary liquidity facilities. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I focused on the “more rapid financial
recovery” scenario, not so much because I thought it was the most likely but just trying to think
what it would take to bring that about. I’m not sure that the policy changes we have done
recently will do that, but I am fairly certain that we are going to keep at it until we find
something that restores confidence.
I was shocked when I was looking at the Bluebook at how short a time has passed since
the meltdown of all these major financial institutions—Fannie, Freddie, Lehman, AIG, WaMu,
and Wachovia. There is a sense among those who were affected, who lost from it, that they just
really didn’t see it coming, at least not at this speed, and that all of them had adequate regulatory
capital, and the bankers at least were used to watching a sort of gradual burndown of that capital

October 28–29, 2008

108 of 206

before institutions failed. They had a sense of being unable to predict who was going to be
saved, who was going to get whacked, and who would be the winners and the losers. So
subsequently both the banks and their customers froze, and there has been very little activity
since then. All the banks I talked to reported having stopped doing business with one or more
counterparties and that one or more counterparties had stopped doing business with them, and
they were shocked by both of those things.
So, first and foremost, it is clear that we need to restore confidence and predictability. In
this sense, the recent moves to increase deposit insurance, to guarantee interbank short-term debt,
and to provide capital on the same terms to banks of all sizes should be helpful—but only as long
as we can do this without creating new uncertainty about who is going to benefit and who is not.
Without being too subjective or too cute, we need at this point just to create confidence in our
entire system. The demonstrable and preemptive support of the nine largest financial
institutions; our public support of AIG; similar support of globally important banks by their
home countries; and the resolution of Wachovia and National City, the two largest troubled
institutions, without loss should help us avoid shocking surprises while everybody calms down.
In this light, my conversation with the banks centered mostly on their reactions to the
recent policy changes. All thought the deposit insurance increase was helpful. They varied in
their estimates of the importance of the increase to $250,000, with a lot of them pointing out that
for consumers they had already really restructured deposits to insure fairly large amounts, and
several were using the CDARS (Certificate of Deposit Account Registry Service) program for
larger depositors. They were even more enthusiastic about the coverage of transaction accounts,
although one banker felt as though this coverage really hadn’t gotten as much visibility as it
should, particularly with corporate treasurers, and many had already seen corporate and

October 28–29, 2008

109 of 206

institutional deposits move into Treasuries and felt as though it was going to be difficult to get
those back. There was even much more confusion about the guarantee of short-term debt. One
banker questioned how they would know whether the fed funds sold to another bank actually fell
inside the 125 percent cap. Another one thought that the all-or-nothing structure of the guarantee
was a little difficult to work with. Interestingly, and as I pointed out yesterday when I asked
about interest on reserves, nobody had even focused on it. They had bigger fish to fry. So I
wouldn’t read anything into those early results.
As for capital injections, most were taking a hard look at it. Two large community banks
had just issued private capital to support growth that had been attracted from competitors, but
they thought that they could profitably deploy the new capital. Other banks were interested in
having the capital just in case they had the opportunity to buy weaker competitors, particularly
deposits or branches in problem resolutions. None was really concerned about the announced
restrictions, but a number of them were somewhat suspicious of the possible restrictions that
might come later. Some small banks with already high levels of capital somehow felt pressured
to apply anyway just to show that they would qualify, although they didn’t think it would give
them much growth. In all cases, capital is only part of the story. They also need reliable funding
if they are going to expand lending. This will have to come either from reliable deposit growth
or from the reopening of secondary markets because all of them were reluctant to increase
borrowing from any source. The loan-to-deposit ratio is growing new fans. In terms of lending,
all reported that they were still lending to their relationship customers, and they were cutting
back on credit to credit-only customers. As one defined it, if 90 percent of the revenue is coming
from credit, then that was a customer relationship they wanted to exit.

October 28–29, 2008

110 of 206

They still report no significant deterioration in the C&I book. I asked about drawdowns
from companies, and across the board they said they had seen it in a couple of instances but
really they had not seen an awful lot of that, so that might be some posturing rather than actual
drawdowns on the credit. They are, however, exercising strong pricing discipline, and the
pricing decisions, more than credit decisions, are being escalated up the approval chain, actively
outreaching to customers that they want to keep and assuring them of credit availability. But
because they have no pricing power on the funding side and pricing became very skinny on loans
in recent years, there is a high level of sticker shock going on, which might explain some of the
complaints about unreasonable terms. They also report very high levels of caution from their
customers, with the descriptions ranging from “hunkering down” to “wait and see.” There were
more anecdotal reports of companies riding trade credit by trying to accelerate receivables or
extend payables. Now, whether this is due to the actual or to the perceived unavailability of
credit from banks is not yet clear.
Real pressure is on commercial real estate lending. They are very selective in new
projects. They are processing renewals for only one year, using the opportunity to shore up
pricing and underwriting, and no longer writing mini-perms. Nobody is doing those. So far, the
performance is holding up on commercial properties, with strong performance on apartments and
weakness showing up in retail. Residential construction and land development continues to be a
problem. In visiting the San Francisco and the Kansas City Banks, I was shocked to hear the
same story from large builders about land sales. One builder had a 300-acre parcel with a cost of
$75,000 an acre, listed it for $15,000 an acre, and sold it for $10,700. Another reported a
property with a cost basis of $120 million selling for $12 million. Apparently, the impetus for
both of these transactions was a judgment that the cash received from tax refunds was more

October 28–29, 2008

111 of 206

advantageous than holding out for better pricing. So the outlook for lending in residential
construction or commercial real estate is dim far into the future, and I would say the same thing
for syndicated or participated lending. However, to the extent that banks can exit those
segments, it should free up funds for normal lending for businesses and consumers. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I would like to ask Governor Duke a question. Do you
sense in this deep dive into the institutions that you talked to that they are benefiting from cuts in
the fed funds rate? Are they enthusiastic or not about the prospect for a lower fed funds rate?
MS. DUKE. Actually, I have heard a couple of reports that, when we did that last
50 basis point cut, banks did not lower their prime. A lot of banks still have prime-related
credits. As we lower the rates, whether it makes a difference on anything else, it affects the
prime, and there are still an awful lot of 5 percent CDs out there. So as we lower rates, we are
cutting into those margins, and it is likely to turn some of them negative.
MR. LACKER. Mr. Chairman?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. I would just echo that. I have heard the same thing from bankers in our
District—just vociferous complaints about lowering rates because their loan rates go down but
their cost of funds doesn’t.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, if I could just add one other thing. We are hearing more
and more about people switching to LIBOR, trying to shift their lending contracts to LIBOR
rather aggressively, obviously, because they are higher rates. But I’m wondering if you’re
picking that up as well.

October 28–29, 2008

112 of 206

MS. DUKE. Well, I don’t know. But just as soon as they get them switched over there,
maybe we’ll be successful at bringing LIBOR down.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. Let me try to summarize all that I heard
today and yesterday, and then I’ll try to add some new comments to that. The outlook for
economic growth appears to have deteriorated quite significantly since the last meeting. Data on
consumer spending, production, and employment had weakened more than expected even before
the recent intensification of the financial crisis. Over the past six weeks or so, however, financial
conditions have greatly worsened, and risk aversion has increased, despite actions here and
abroad to stabilize the banking system. Equity values have declined sharply amid conditions of
low liquidity and extraordinary volatility.
Credit market conditions have improved modestly since the global actions to recapitalize
banks and guarantee their deposits, assisted also by additional central bank liquidity actions.
However, in almost all credit markets, spreads remain much wider, maturities shorter, and
availability more constrained than was the case before the intensification of the crisis. Firms
face continued funding risk and rollover risk. Banks have probably not reserved sufficiently for
the credit losses to come, and hedge funds will be hitting their net asset value triggers in greater
numbers, forcing them to liquidate assets. The duration of future financial turmoil is hard to
judge, but it could be lengthy.
The worst thing is that financial conditions appear already to have had a significant and
remarkably quick effect on activity and consumer and business expectations and plans. Most
Committee participants see us in or entering a recession and have marked down significantly
their expectations for near-term growth or for the pace of the recovery. The difficulty of
predicting the course of the crisis or its effects on the economy has also increased forecast

October 28–29, 2008

113 of 206

uncertainty. In particular, the ultimate effects of some major policy actions, such as the creation
of the TARP and the bank guarantee, are not yet known. Uncertainty about future policy actions,
as well as uncertainty about the economy, has affected behavior in markets and the broader
economy.
Consumer spending has weakened considerably and probably fell sharply in the third
quarter, reflecting in part a recessionary psychology. Consumer durables, such as automobiles
and discretionary expenditures, have been particularly hard hit. This weakness reflects the same
set of negative influences on consumption that we have been seeing for a while, now
compounded by losses of equity wealth and confidence effects on prices, although lower oil
prices may provide some relief. The labor market continues to decline, with many firms
reporting that they are cutting back workers. The housing sector has not been noticeably worse
than expected, and reports are somewhat mixed. But on a national basis, the contraction is
continuing, and recent developments in the economy and credit markets are likely to have
adverse effects. Inventories of unsold new homes remain high, putting pressure on prices.
Nonresidential construction continues at a moderate pace; but backlogs are falling, and the sector
is looking increasingly vulnerable to weakening fundamentals and tighter credit conditions.
Whether a new fiscal stimulus package will be passed and to what extent such a package would
be helpful remain open questions. Manufacturing production has weakened significantly as have
expectations of demand, including export demand. Credit is becoming more of a problem for
many firms and their customers. Spending on equipment and software appears to have slowed,
reflecting greater pessimism and uncertainty. Falling commodity prices may reduce mining
activity and cool the boom in agriculture. On the plus side, firms are reporting fewer cost
pressures, and inventories do not appear excessive.

October 28–29, 2008

114 of 206

Deterioration in global growth expectations has been marked. Industrial economies had
already shown signs of slowing, and they have been hit hard by recent financial developments.
Emerging market economies, until recently evidently not much affected by the U.S. slowdown,
have in recent weeks also been hit hard by the spreading financial crisis. Together with the
stronger dollar, these developments are likely to restrain future growth of U.S. exports.
Inflation risks have declined materially, reflecting the fall in the prices of energy and
other commodities, the stronger dollar, and the prospect of considerable economic slack. Firms
report much reduced pricing power and lower markups. Inflation expectations have come down,
both in the surveys and in the TIPS market, though it wasn’t noted—but I will note—that the
TIPS market is distorted by illiquidity and other problems there. Most participants see both
overall and core inflation moderating in the coming quarters toward levels consistent with price
stability, with some seeing a risk of undesirably low rates of inflation. Some note, however, that
financial dislocations affect aggregate supply as well as aggregate demand and may reduce the
extent to which slower growth damps inflation. So that’s just my sense. Any comments?
Additions?
Let me make just a few additional comments, none of which will be radically different
from what we have already discussed. I do think it is overwhelmingly clear that we are now in a
recession and that it is going to be a severe one. To give some sense of perspective, the postwar
record for duration is 16 months. If the NBER sets this experience as having begun early this
year, I think we have a reasonable chance to break that record. The largest increase from peak to
trough in unemployment rate was in 1981. It was 3.6 percentage points. Starting from
4.4 percent, I think we have a chance to come close to that number. Yesterday’s drop in
consumer confidence in one month from 61 to 38 shattered the previous low of 43 in December

October 28–29, 2008

115 of 206

1975. So I think we are talking about an episode here that could easily be among the largest
postwar recessions.
We don’t know how things would have evolved without the developments in September,
but obviously we have to deal with that reality. It was just a few weeks ago that we were dealing
with what might have been a true systemic crisis, in the week leading up to the G-7 and IMF
meeting. I think it has been very fortunate that Europe, the United States, and other countries
have adopted vigorous responses to that, including bank capitalization, bank guarantees, and
other measures. That has been very important in calming the situation somewhat and reducing
the systemic aspects of investor concerns. That being said, concern about counterparties remains
very strong. Risk aversion is intense, spreads remain high, and I think that this has now become
really pervasive. It isn’t just a question of junk bonds and weak borrowers or weak credit
histories. The spreads on GSE debt, on high-grade corporate debt, and other areas have also
widened, leading to a very broad based tightening in credit conditions. So I think that, overall,
any reasonable reading of financial conditions suggests that the tightening of credit or financial
conditions in the last six weeks or so has been quite substantial and overwhelms the effects of
our coordinated rate cut.
Now, normally you would expect to see a tightening of credit conditions affect the
economy with some lag. It takes time for people to borrow money and to use the money they
borrow to make expenditures. But compared with that prediction, we have instead seen a sudden
stop—a remarkable and very rapid effect on economic activity. It is possible this is due less to
the direct effects of credit availability and more to the psychological impact of these events. One
possible analogy is the 1980 Carter credit controls, when the government announced what
seemed to be a tightening of credit. There was a very sharp response in economic activity,

October 28–29, 2008

116 of 206

probably based more on expectations than on actual credit availability. Unfortunately, the credit
controls could be removed by government fiat; we are not able to do that today.
One interesting development is that the labor market has not yet shown as much
weakness as one would expect. Unemployment insurance claims and other indicators do not yet
show a marked deterioration. I expect that we will see more deterioration of the labor market.
Besides the intensification of the financial crisis that has markedly increased the
restrictiveness of financial conditions, I think the other very important development since our last
meeting has been the internationalization of the crisis. We had already seen weakening in
Europe before the most recent intensification, but it has become much more severe. There is
little doubt that the United Kingdom and Europe are in or about to enter recession. My sense is
that their monetary policy responses will be stronger than what the Greenbook anticipates. I
believe they will be very aggressive in responding to that.
A new and particularly worrying development is the fact that the crisis has now spread
beyond the industrial countries to the emerging markets. The G-7 weekend was quite an
interesting one. It was a striking experience. I heard over and over again from the Indians, from
the Brazilians, and from all over the world that, until the middle of September we were fine, we
were not being much affected, we didn’t see much effect on our trade flows, and suddenly
everything changed; and now we are under severe stress. We are seeing tremendous outflows.
Our currencies are plummeting. Commodity price declines are hurting many countries. I think
that is going to be a very significant development as we go forward.
Just to give some data, in just a few weeks the EMBI spread, the emerging market
sovereign debt spread, went from 280 basis points to 850 basis points; and the emerging market
equity index has fallen about 40 percent since the last meeting. It is not obvious that these

October 28–29, 2008

117 of 206

changes were justified by economic fundamentals. Many of these countries are very well run
and had shown a lot of progress in their domestic policies and their domestic economies.
Instead, I think they are suffering contagion from us mostly. Unfortunately, the implications of
this will be not only the usual trade and commodity price type of implications but also, and even
more important, financial implications. We are now seeing that the adverse feedback loop,
which we’ve been talking about for a long time in the United States, is becoming a global
phenomenon. In particular, European banks are very heavily exposed to emerging market debt.
So we are going to see yet more of this interaction between the financial markets and the broader
economy, except at a global rather than a national level. These developments, obviously, are
very disturbing and don’t bode well for U.S. growth or now for global growth. Somewhat
ironically, all of this deterioration in the global outlook has led the dollar to appreciate very
sharply, which is interesting to say the least. For us that obviously also has important
implications for inflation, and as Governor Kohn mentioned, it means that we will be less a
recipient of foreign strength and more a supporter of foreign weakness than we have been until
now.
On inflation, I know there is some discomfort in talking about a 1 percent policy rate and
promising to keep it low for a protracted period—and all those things. We have seen this movie
before, and I think we all have to recognize the importance of watching the implications of that
for our economy and for asset prices and to take quite seriously the responsibility for removing
accommodation in a timely fashion once the crisis has begun to moderate. That being said, I
don’t think that there is really any case in the near term to be worrying very much about
inflation—or, perhaps even less so, the dollar—as we look at our policy. Pricing power is
evaporating. And given what is happening in the global economy, I don’t see a commodity price

October 28–29, 2008

118 of 206

boom any time soon, although I think as the economies do begin to recover in the next year or so
that we might see some recovery in commodity prices.
So I think that, as everyone has indicated, this is a very worrisome situation. I don’t think
we have control of it. I don’t think we know what the bottom is, so we have to remain very
flexible and very open to new initiatives as they become necessary. There has been some
comparison of this to the Japanese situation. I’m beginning to wonder if that might not be a
good outcome. The advantage of the Japanese was, first of all, that they were isolated. The rest
of the world was doing okay, and they were able to draw strength from their exports and the rest
of the global economy. Although they had very slow growth, they never really had a deep
recession or big increases in unemployment. I think we are looking at perhaps a much sharper
episode, and our challenge will be to make sure that it doesn’t persist longer.
I do think that one lesson of both Japan and the 1930s as well as other experiences is that
passivity is not a good answer. We do have to continue to be aggressive. We have to continue to
look for solutions. Some of them are not going to work. Some of them are going to add to
uncertainty. I recognize that critique. I realize it’s a valid critique. But I don’t think that this is
going to be a self-correcting thing anytime soon. I think we are going to have to continue to
provide support of all kinds to the economy. Let me stop there and, unless there is any question
or comment, ask Brian to introduce the policy round.
MR. MADIGAN. 7 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I will be referring to the version
of table 1 that was distributed to you on Monday. It is reproduced in the package
before you labeled “Material for Briefing on Monetary Policy Alternatives.” Changes
in the language relative to the Bluebook version are shown in blue.
Starting on the right-hand side of the table, even though members saw the
economic and financial information that became available over the intermeeting
period as worse than expected, they might be inclined to leave the stance of policy
unchanged at today’s meeting, as in alternative C. As noted yesterday, your
7

The materials used by Mr. Madigan are appended to this transcript (appendix 7).

October 28–29, 2008

119 of 206

economic projections reveal that many of you anticipate that inflation pressures will
diminish less quickly than the staff anticipates, and several of you noted explicitly
that you thought less easing would be appropriate than was assumed in the
Greenbook forecast. Also, the Committee already reduced rates in early October,
responding to at least some of the adverse economic news. Moreover, the Federal
Reserve has put in place additional facilities to support credit intermediation, and the
Treasury and the FDIC are moving quickly with the implementation of other
programs that should, with time, help stabilize financial institutions and markets and
enhance the flow of credit to households and businesses. Finally, you might believe
that the Congress is likely to enact a second fiscal stimulus package, possibly
reducing the need for additional monetary policy accommodation.
The rationale section of the statement suggested for alternative C would
acknowledge the intensification of financial turmoil and the weakening of the
economic outlook. However, it would also cite the range of policy actions taken in
recent weeks as factors that should help over time to improve credit conditions and
promote a return to moderate economic growth. The language on inflation would be
essentially identical to that used in the Committee’s statement earlier this month,
noting that the upside risks to inflation have been reduced. The risk assessment
would state explicitly that the Committee’s primary concern is the downside risks to
growth, suggesting a predilection for lowering rates. Nonetheless, with market
participants anticipating an easing today—a 50 basis point move is seen as most
likely—an announcement along the lines of alternative C would point to a much
higher trajectory for the federal funds rate over the next few months than investors
had expected. Short- and intermediate-term Treasury yields would likely jump, credit
spreads probably would increase further, and equity prices might decline sharply.
If the Committee is of the view that further policy accommodation is appropriate
at this time but is also quite uncertain about the extent of rate reductions that will
ultimately be required, it might be attracted to the 25 basis point easing of alternative
B at this meeting. Members might have a less pessimistic outlook for the economy
than that presented as the baseline in the Greenbook or might at least be quite
uncertain as to the extent of the negative forces at work in the economy. At the same
time, you may view the incoming information as suggesting that the 50 basis point
easing earlier this month is unlikely to be sufficient to adequately balance the risks to
economic activity and inflation. Given these considerations, you might see modest
further easing today as appropriate and be prepared to cut rates again in coming
months should developments warrant.
The statement proposed for alternative B would note that the pace of economic
activity appears to have slowed markedly, and it would repeat language from your
early October statement indicating that the financial market turmoil is likely to exert
additional restraint on spending. The announcement would also indicate that, in light
of the decline in the prices of energy and other commodities, the Committee expects
inflation to moderate in coming quarters to levels consistent with price stability. As
noted in a box in the Bluebook, we think that, in view of your previous policy

October 28–29, 2008

120 of 206

communications, outside analysts would interpret such a statement on the inflation
outlook as indicating that the Committee anticipates that overall inflation will drop to
around 1½ percent to 1¾ percent before long, a indication that would be consistent
with the central tendency of your inflation projections for 2009. The risk assessment
in alternative B, paragraph 4, would cite the same broad range of policy actions that
was proposed in alternative C, paragraph 2. It would indicate that the predominant
concern of the Committee is the downside risks to economic growth. Market
participants see a 25 basis point easing at this meeting as possible, but at this point
they seem to place significantly higher odds on a 50 basis point reduction. The
explicit citation of downside risks to growth would suggest that further easing could
be forthcoming after this meeting, but this announcement still would suggest a higher
path for the federal funds rate than they anticipate. Consequently, short- and
intermediate-term rates might tend to edge up after such an announcement, credit
spreads might widen somewhat further, and equity prices might decline.
Under alternative A, the Committee would ease policy 50 basis points at this
meeting. An economic outlook along the lines of the Greenbook forecast would
provide one rationale for choosing this alternative. The Greenbook forecast for
aggregate demand has been slashed dramatically, importantly reflecting a sharp
decline in equity prices, a steep rise in credit risk premiums, and a considerable climb
in the foreign exchange value of the dollar. One metric for this revision is the
Greenbook-consistent measure of the short-run equilibrium real interest rate, r*,
which has been cut nearly 3 percentage points since the September meeting to a level
of about minus 3 percent. That level is about 2 percentage points below the actual
real funds rate defined on a consistent basis. The staff outlook for a protracted period
of substantial economic slack, together with the recent plunge in energy prices, points
to a considerable diminution of inflation pressures, with overall inflation falling to
1½ percent next year in the Greenbook forecast—even with the Greenbook’s
assumption of 100 basis points of further easing by early next year. But even those
who are somewhat less pessimistic about the outlook than the Board staff might view
the modal outlook as having deteriorated enough, or the downside risks as having
increased enough, to warrant a 50 basis point rate cut today.
The rationale language for alternative A in the revised version of table 1 is similar
to that for alternative B, but alternative A, paragraph 2, notes additional factors that
are restraining growth. The risk assessment, too, is similar to that for alternative B,
but it references the rate reduction that would be implemented today under this
alternative and notes that downside risks to growth remain, without saying that the
downside risks are the Committee’s predominant concern. An announcement along
these lines seems largely consistent with market participants’ expectations, and the
market reaction would likely be relatively small. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Questions for Brian? All right. If there are no
questions, why don’t we begin our go-round. President Lockhart.

October 28–29, 2008

121 of 206

MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I think that this is a tough call. I support
alternative B, with the statement wording as presented. In my thinking, a 25 basis point cut
today is part of a total 75 basis point action, including the October 8 move. I believe the
deterioration we have seen in September and October and the resulting downward revision of the
outlook merit a cumulative response of this magnitude. That said, I am sympathetic to the view
that we would be well advised to keep some powder dry to respond to shocks or developments
ahead. I anticipate that, because a number of the dynamics in the markets have not really played
out, we will have more shocks and they could come from further financial institution failures,
corporate failures, a sovereign debt crisis, and market disarray; and in other markets, such as the
municipal market, there is always a chance of a geopolitical event. In all likelihood these things
come in combination or in rapid fire. So, as I said, I am sympathetic to the “powder dry” view,
but I see the powder dry objective as being in conflict with responding to the recent
deterioration. Therefore I come to 25 basis points or alternative B to some extent as a
compromise, combined with the 50 basis points of October 8. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I favor alternative A, a 50 basis point cut in
the funds rate. This action, and even more, is justified by the dramatic developments since our
last meeting—a deepening of the recessionary outlook worldwide, the near meltdown of the
global financial system, and the abatement of inflationary pressures. Frankly, it is time for all
hands on deck when it comes to our policy tools, and the fed funds rate should be no exception.
Although we cut the funds rate 50 basis points a few weeks ago, the Greenbook inflation
projection was revised down more than that, so the ex ante real funds rate actually edged up over
the intermeeting period.

October 28–29, 2008

122 of 206

We need to do much more and the sooner, the better. One might argue against such a
policy move in favor of a wait-and-see approach to better gauge if the recent flurry of policy
initiatives will turn things around. In normal times, I would have some sympathy for this
argument, but these are about as far from normal times as we can get. We are in the midst of a
global economic and financial freefall, and the confidence of households, businesses, and
investors is in shambles. The adverse feedback loop is playing out with a vengeance. Lenders
continue to ratchet up terms and standards, sapping the ability of households and businesses to
spend. As the economy weakens, further loan defaults will mushroom.
I think strong, clear action is needed. Historical precedents, such as the case of Japan,
teach us that it is a mistake to act cautiously as the economy unravels. I think the clear lesson
from both economic theory and real-world experience is to lower rates as quickly as possible to
avoid a deeper and more protracted recession, not to keep our powder dry or to wait to use tools
until later if they are available to us now. The more medicine we give and the sooner we give it,
the better. The Bluebook optimal policy simulations tell us that, absent the zero bound, the funds
rate should be lowered well below zero next year. Since that is not an option, we should do the
most with what we’ve got and cut the funds rate aggressively now.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Like President Yellen, I support alternative A,
the 50 basis point cut. I think it’s the right response to the very, very substantial change in the
economic outlook since the last meeting. We would have cut the nominal federal funds rate by
1 percentage point and real federal funds rates by something less than 1 percentage point
depending on what you think is happening to inflation expectations. But surely inflation
expectations are coming down—and coming down substantially.

October 28–29, 2008

123 of 206

I think the incoming information, the weakness before the shock hit in mid-September
(which to me suggests that we didn’t have any insurance against that weakness at the time), the
extraordinary tightening of financial conditions, and the downshift in spending that we’ve seen
since mid-September all suggest that a 1 percentage point cut in the real rate, and even a little
less than a 1 percentage point cut, would seem a very modest and moderate response to the
shock. It’s probably a down payment. If the staff is right, we will need more. I built more into
my own forecast. But even if the economy is not as weak as the staff has built into the
Greenbook, I think a substantial cut in the federal funds rate is entirely appropriate.
All of us—without exception, I think—said that there were downside risks to their
forecasts, and a number of us have cited the possibility of a very deep recession here. So I think
we need to take action. We are starting with a situation in which the economy is declining. We
are in recession. The unemployment rate is rising. Inflation is falling. There is a global
recession in train. It seems to me, from a risk-management perspective, that the costs of not
doing enough—the costs of being reluctant to lower rates and making that situation worse—are
far larger than the costs of going a little too far because things turn around faster. I think we are
in a situation in which it is almost impossible at this point to go too far. Mr. Chairman, we may
have to take it back at some point in the future, but right now I think the 50 basis points is
absolutely justified by the conditions in which we find ourselves.
I was drawn, as the Vice Chairman was, to the staff simulation having to do with a more
rapid financial recovery. I myself think that’s a very small probability. But even if that’s what
happens, we’ll know by December whether the financial markets are recovering faster. We can
stop at 1 percent, if we’re getting that recovery; and the outcomes, as the Vice Chairman noted,
really aren’t that bad in that recovery. So I think that even the small probability of a very sharp

October 28–29, 2008

124 of 206

turnaround in the markets is still consistent with cutting rates another 50 basis points at this
meeting.
The fact that we are already low is not a reason to hold back. I don’t agree with the
“keeping the powder dry” kind of argument. I think the lessons of history, including from Japan,
are that the closer you get to the zero lower bound the more aggressive you should be. If you let
weakness build, that weakness will overwhelm your policy tools. The most effective use of the
limited scope for policy easing is to be preemptive and stop weaknesses from building.
I think a 50 basis point easing will have beneficial effects. I don’t think that the markets
will react very much. We won’t see those beneficial effects. But if I can compare it with doing
25 or nothing at all, I think doing 25 or nothing at all would have adverse effects. With 25 or
nothing, you’ll get longer-term rates up, you’ll get stock prices down, and you’ll get an erosion
of confidence at a time when we don’t need it—that the central bank doesn’t get how serious this
situation is. I agree that the last easing was largely offset by the loss of confidence and the rise
in uncertainty. I also agree that it might not feed through as directly and completely as it often
does because banks are trying to rebuild and lenders are trying to rebuild profit margins. But I
still think it will be effective. As I say, I convinced myself of that by asking about what would
happen with the alternatives, and I think the alternatives would be far worse. We need to keep
fine-tuning the TARP and the liquidity provision. We need fiscal stimulus. I agree with all of
that. We need to move on lots of dimensions. But these things will not be sufficient in and of
themselves to counter this. Monetary policy is a fairly blunt instrument, but we need to stimulate
the spending wherever we can to do this.
Some have expressed concern about circumstances forcing us to ease between meetings.
We have done 50. Will that take us further? I think we need to make clear in our statement and

October 28–29, 2008

125 of 206

our minutes—particularly in our minutes—that we do expect a weak economy going forward, at
least a moderately softer economy, and that the process may call for further easing. I think it will
call for further easing at the next FOMC meeting, but we can get to the next FOMC meeting and
see. But it should take a substantial and unexpected deterioration relative to that path to justify
an intermeeting action. So I think we are absolutely right to have a prejudice toward taking
actions at meetings, when we can sit around and discuss things. The odds are high that we will
need to go further, but we should do that at a meeting if we can. If we do have a very strong and
substantial deterioration even relative to our weak outlook and we do end up moving between
meetings, surely that move would not put us at a level that is unjustified by the circumstances.
So I think we can deal with the intermeeting situation and not have the pressures of the market,
the pressures of expectations, get us to a level at which we’re ultimately uncomfortable. In short,
I think it’s a very serious situation. We need to do all we can to counter this situation. Now is
not the time to hold back. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Like the Greenbook forecast, our forecast predicts a significant
recession. Further easing will likely help mitigate the severity of the recession. Coupled with
improvements in short-term credit spreads, a reduction in the federal funds rate should lower
rates on home equity lines of credit as well as business and consumer rates tied to LIBOR, easing
cash flow for consumers and businesses. We are facing problems of historic proportions, both
here and abroad. A 50 basis point easing, as in alternative A, is both necessary and appropriate.
Even with the easing assumed in the Greenbook, the unemployment rate remains too high for too
long. The inflation rate falls enough to be well below my target. To avoid a severe and

October 28–29, 2008

126 of 206

prolonged recession, we will very likely need further monetary easing and a significant fiscal
package, even after this 50 basis point reduction in the federal funds rate.
I would just note in terms of the language that, although I am comfortable with the
alternative A language, my actual views would be closer to saying “the predominant concern of
the Committee is the downside risk to growth” rather than “nevertheless, downside risks to
growth remain.”
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. After thinking about this for quite some time,
I cannot convince myself that alternative A is not the right way to go.
MR. KROSZNER. Let the transcript reflect that. [Laughter]
MR. EVANS. You were very effective in listing a number of dire circumstances. The
fact that we may challenge the maximum duration of a recession in the postwar period, any
mention of the 1981-82 recession is very frightening, you even mentioned 1975 in terms of the
reduction in confidence, and the 1980 credit crunch also—you were able to do that without any
mention of the 1930s, and that’s quite compelling, I would say.
So for the reasons that have been already discussed, the outlook is quite unfavorable, and
I think that this will help improve matters. But as I thought about the concerns that I have, one
concern is whether this will actually be viewed as effective today. I’m not sure about that. The
last time we cut rates, financial stress intervened to swamp any beneficial interpretation of that.
Whether that affects our credibility, I think that Don Kohn was very effective in mentioning that
there will be credibility hits in the other direction if we don’t take some action like that. I do
think that eventually things will subside and the beneficial effects of lower policy will be seen.
About the dry powder argument, we are not going to have many more actions left after this, but I

October 28–29, 2008

127 of 206

don’t see what the alternatives are other than to go ahead and put this in place. I don’t subscribe
to the view that inflation is likely to be too low, although that is a risk. Inflation concerns, the
financial stress, all of those issues, even taking into account the risk that President Bullard
mentioned the other day, I think speak strongly to the fact that we’re running out of normal
monetary policy options and that fiscal actions are going to be strongly important. So I do favor
alternative A. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Well, Mr. Chairman, I certainly understand how serious this matter is,
and I guess I am of the view that alternative A is not going to solve much. There is a
psychology, I understand, in the market that is going on, and I am not convinced that our
continuing to take these actions and then having adverse outcomes is necessarily going to inspire
confidence. I think we need to let our actions work their way through. Part of the problem is
that the credit mechanism is stuck right now because of the tremendous uncertainties. Then I
look at all of the things we have done over the last month, and the ramping up of the liquidity
facilities has really exceeded even our ability to sterilize. So we have had, in effect, a funds rate
that is well below our target. We have excess reserves in that period that were over $280 billion
when they are normally $2 billion, and that was before we added more swap lines and more
liquidity into the market. Frankly, I think we are at a point now where the liquidity mechanisms
that we’re trying to use, not our interest rate targeting, are really our monetary policy. As we go
forward, perhaps we need to think about how we are going to conduct monetary policy under a
quantitative easing environment. That is what I think we will effectively be at if we move again
today. So how we think about liquidity and about the credit mechanisms is really where more of
our attention will have to be spent. Lowering the rate may have some positive effects, but I

October 28–29, 2008

128 of 206

doubt it. So I would just stay where we are, let some of these past actions begin to work through,
and see what the effects of those are before we then take another move because I think the
market would just appreciate some stability over time in our actions so that they can see these
things begin to work. It isn’t a problem of the interest rate level right now, in my opinion, so
that’s why I would wait and see. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Clearly, forecasts have been marked down
since our September meeting—mine included. This reflects the weaker data that we have
obtained on the real side, especially consumer spending and manufacturing, but also worsening
conditions in the financial markets. Accordingly, in an intermeeting move on October 8, we cut
the funds rate 50 basis points. Yet the additional effect on the economy of financial turmoil
during the last month remains highly uncertain. Spreads in many markets remain higher than at
the time of our September meeting, but some have started to decline. If our new facilities have
the desired impact, we may well see spreads continue to fall back to September or lower levels.
It is very difficult to say at this time. Although I dislike intermeeting rate cuts, I supported the
October 8 cut because it was part of a coordinated effort among central banks around the world
and it seemed justified given that our growth outlook had deteriorated and inflation expectations
had remained stable.
We may well have to do more, but I think we are near the end of what we can do with
monetary policy. Of course, it’s difficult to determine the appropriate level of the funds rate, and
I want to draw your attention to the Greenbook, which showed that, whether we cut today or
don’t cut today, the paths of GDP, employment, and inflation over the next year or two are not
much different. In fact, in most models, cuts of that magnitude do not show up very heavily in

October 28–29, 2008

129 of 206

real variables. I would also note that, according to the Greenbook, we could cut the rate to zero
and have no effect on inflation, apparently, for the next four years. However, given the fact that
rate cuts don’t have much effect, even in the Greenbook simulations, we have cut rates. It may
not make much difference, as President Hoenig was saying. My preference at this meeting
would be to stand pat and see how the data and financial markets improve. We are already
engaged in extraordinary quantitative easing, even at this point, and we are hearing from bankers
that the funds rate will do little to stimulate lending on their part or improve their balance sheets.
Now, delaying necessary rate cuts is not desirable. But given the considerable uncertainty
around our forecast, it is not clear that further cuts are either necessary or desirable or are going
to be effective. And doing so for purely psychological reasons, from my standpoint, is a dubious
way to conduct policy.
A comparison of the baseline Greenbook forecast with the alternative scenario involving
more-rapid improvement in financial conditions suggests that the appropriate policy path is very
much dependent on knowing whether the increase in financial stress in September will be
lasting. If conditions deteriorate further, which they might, we may want to cut in December. If
conditions improve, this may not be necessary. Given the decline in confidence in our markets
and institutions, I think the Fed can play a positive role by being a steadying hand. That’s
another reason to wait a bit longer before moving again.
I do not believe that we inspire confidence by appearing to react to market fluctuations.
Even though that’s not what we’re doing, I fear that we often give that appearance. Moreover,
although we have gotten positive reactions to the creativity of our liquidity programs, I think we
have missed opportunities for raising confidence by rolling out our liquidity facilities in a
piecemeal fashion. We had announcements made every day between Monday and Wednesday,

October 28–29, 2008

130 of 206

on October 6, 7, and 8. I think it would have been far better to announce these actions as a wellthought-out package, explaining the intention of the individual pieces and how they related to
one another. For example, we now have three different lending programs designed in whole or
in part to support money market mutual funds. I have concern that we have been looking
reactive rather than proactive, even though I know that some of these programs had been in the
works for a while.
I have argued that it is important that we think about our policy choices in terms of policy
paths—that is, a dynamic path. The principles of dynamic programming suggest that we think
about our policies in a backward-looking way. This, I believe, applies not only to monetary
policy but to our liquidity programs as well. In this spirit, I believe that we must think hard
about our exit strategies both from the liquidity programs and from our very low funds rate. I
think we have dug ourselves a very deep hole in terms of the breadth and depth of our lending to
the private sector. We seem, at times, to be the lender of first resort as well as the lender of last
resort. We must make sure that we have a sturdy ladder that will enable us to climb our way out
of this hole. This is especially important given the interaction between the programs and the
differences across the programs in their current expiration dates.
On the monetary policy side, we have added significantly to liquidity in the economy, as
I alluded to earlier. Given the uncertainty surrounding our forecast, we may very well find
ourselves in a position of having to reverse those injections sooner than expected. I am even
more concerned with this planning process than I have been when I have raised this point before.
The baseline funds path in the Greenbook is quite extraordinary from my perspective. It
suggests that we can keep the funds rate low, below 1 and even close to zero, throughout most of
the forecast period. Indeed, in 2011 the funds rate is still below 2 percent, even though the

October 28–29, 2008

131 of 206

economy is growing at 4.4 percent. We may disagree somewhat on the magnitude of the
contributions of our low interest rate policies in the 2003–05 period to the current problems, but I
don’t think many of us want to repeat that episode. Yet looking at the baseline forecast and
where the funds rate remains—below 1 percent or certainly below 2 percent for the next four
years—it strikes me as a risky strategy at best and perhaps even a dangerous one. We have
previously expressed views around this table that this Committee historically has been reluctant
to raise rates in a timely fashion, and I believe that fear is reinforced by what I see in the baseline
forecast in the Greenbook. That projection worries me a great deal. We must not act in a way
that sows the seeds of the next crisis.
Despite the pressure of the here and now, we cannot and should not ignore the
consequences of our actions in the intermediate term. Managing our way from point to point,
dealing with immediate problems, can very easily lead us to a place in which we do not wish to
be—thus the importance of thinking in terms of a path. I think it would also serve us well to
think about the process we will follow to unwind our liquidity programs in advance, so that we
avoid unintended consequences across markets, and about the communication strategy that will
ease the transition back to a more market based provision of liquidity.
In sum, Mr. Chairman, although I would prefer not to move today, I recognize that my
forecast is more optimistic than most. Moreover, I also accept the notion that there is a great
deal of uncertainty about the outcomes and fragility in the marketplace, and your concerns are
well noted. Thus, I will not dissent against a 50 basis point cut. But I would like to remind the
Committee of our earlier discussions and the general agreement I thought I heard that, when the
time comes, we will have to raise rates and we may have to do so aggressively. In all likelihood,

October 28–29, 2008

132 of 206

that will occur before lagging indicators, such as the unemployment rate, are firmly on the
decline. This is not the projection offered in the Greenbook baseline. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard, you have a handout?
MR. BULLARD. I do have a handout.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Everybody have a copy? President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. 8 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I guess before I start, I just want to say
that I generally agree with everything everyone is saying. This is a dire situation, and I am
perfectly comfortable with that assessment. What I want to do with my comment here is just put
on the table one idea about why a rate reduction might be counterproductive. That is what I’m
trying to do here.
The U.S. economy now appears to be in recession. Intensified financial market turmoil
and very fluid expectations have created a very difficult situation. A key question for the
Committee is what to do with the monetary policy piece of the policy response to the situation.
We know that monetary policy is a blunt instrument that does not directly address fundamental
problems in financial markets. We have other programs in place to try to address those problems
more directly. We also have important fiscal actions, which are probably having the largest
effect in trying to stabilize the current situation. Unlike the ECB, we already lowered nominal
interest rates aggressively earlier this year in anticipation of the possibility of weak
macroeconomic performance. We are now in the middle of a further round of easing, which is
threatening to send nominal interest rates to zero, given the force of events.
Is this the optimal policy, or could it backfire on the Committee? I want to at least lay
out the possibility that a very low nominal interest rate policy may be counterproductive. My
key worry is that housing markets remain at the core of the current turmoil. Mortgage markets—
8

The materials used by Mr. Bullard are attached to this transcript (appendix 8).

October 28–29, 2008

133 of 206

$14 trillion or so, about one GDP—are based on nominal contracts. Deflation tends to be very
destructive in an environment of nominal contracting. I want to stress that macroeconomic
expectations are very important for the way the economy actually evolves and will evolve going
forward and that those expectations are very fluid in the current environment. The Japanese
experience, while it is not an exact parallel, represents an important reference point for the
current situation. Japan’s problems were very real. Some have described the outcome as a lost
decade.
So let’s turn to the graph here for just a second. This is what I was talking about
yesterday. This is an argument put forward by Jess Benhabib, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé, and
Martín Uribe. On the vertical axis is the nominal interest rate. On the horizontal axis are the
inflation rate and inflation expectations, which in this graph are going to be the same thing. The
diagonal line labeled “Fisher” is just a Fisher relationship. The nominal interest rate is the real
interest rate, r, plus inflation expectations. Then policy is described by the line with the kink in
it. The policy line means that, when medium-term inflation expectations are above target, we
raise the nominal interest rate and, when medium-term inflation expectations are below target,
we lower the nominal interest rate. That works beautifully around the targeted equilibrium, the
π* in this environment, and all goes well. It’s just that, when you go to low nominal interest
rates, strange things start to happen because you have to do something with policy as you come
to very low nominal interest rates. You could just go to zero, and then you would have the
horizontal line labeled “policy” that would go across all the way to the minus r there. Or you
could stop at some earlier level. I chose something here to illustrate what the Greenbook seems
to have in mind, say ½ percent.

October 28–29, 2008

134 of 206

But any way you cut it, this is going to create another crossing of the Fisher relation and
create a second steady state. This is the main point of the Benhabib analysis. You can layer on
top all kinds of other stuff that you would like to include in your model, but most models are
going to have a Fisher relationship, and most models are going to have the policymaker reacting
by adjusting the nominal interest rate. So this other steady state, the steady state with low
nominal interest rates, has deflation. If you get stuck there, in our current environment, this
would exacerbate the housing problem a lot and make our problems much more severe. So this
is just one caution about going to a very low nominal interest rate environment. When I saw this
six or seven years ago, it had some influence on me. Before this, I was not worried about any of
the zero bound issues. But then, this does make me a little nervous, given the core problem in
our situation, which is the housing problem. That’s the argument. So let me set that aside then.
One thing this line of research pointed out—and a whole bunch of papers have been
written since this paper—is the existence of this second steady state and that the deflation
associated with the trap steady state is a worrisome phenomenon. There are two steady states
here. You can just argue that you don’t think the lower one is going to be the one the economy
coordinates on and that eventually we are going to go back to the high one and that is perfectly
fine. However, the Japanese case seemed to be zero nominal interest rates and a moderately low
rate of deflation for quite some time. You could say that, if we coordinate on this low nominal
interest rate steady state, we can somehow take fiscal policy actions to move off that to the other
steady state. That is a more complicated issue. That has been addressed in the literature, and
that is also a reasonable thing to say. I guess my main concern about this is, since it is a very
dire situation and I think we are going to go very close to zero very soon, I want us to do it with

October 28–29, 2008

135 of 206

our eyes open. It has some possibility of creating a worse environment. That is the only thing I
wanted to say here.
So my preference based on this would be to leave rates alone and say, “Let’s use fiscal
policy.” I don’t think what we have now is an interest rate problem. What we have now are
problems in credit markets, and I think they are being fairly well addressed by the most recent
fiscal actions, including capital injections into the banking sector. So that would be my
preference at this point.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Let’s see, President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, if you had kicked around in the streets of Hong Kong in
1997, then you would have wandered into elementary schools and seen what we called at that
time “Quotrons”—children trading stocks on the lunchroom floor. It was the surest indicator
that the market was out of control. This morning I opened the Wall Street Journal, and on the
front page they describe an exercise run by the Securities Industry and Financial Markets
Association, which you know is Wall Street’s biggest trade group, with a similar program in
American schools. It says that a 13-year old in Wilmington, Delaware—Michael Ashworth—is
slumped by his computer, weary from another rough day in the stock market with all his favorite
picks—Domino’s Pizza, the Hershey Company, and Gap—surprise! [Laughter] “I’ll be honest
with you,” he confided, “before all this I asked my Mom to give me stocks for Christmas. But
then, I told her not to do it. I asked for a parakeet instead.” [Laughter] Now, this is not as
exotic or thoughtful a handout as the one from my colleague from St. Louis, but here’s the point.
He may not get that parakeet because the pet store may not have access to credit. This is, to me,
the fundamental issue that I think President Plosser—and I won’t repeat his arguments—and
President Hoenig were referring to. The concern I have is not about the price of money. In fact,

October 28–29, 2008

136 of 206

I think we are not seeing that kind of transmission mechanism—Governor Duke gave testimony
to that earlier. All of us are aware that it is not moving as quickly through the IV tube as we
would like it to because of the crimped nature of the tube.
I have no problem with the language in alternative A, except for the first paragraph, and
the phrase “including today’s rate reduction.” I have an open mind. I do think the issue in terms
of restoring the system comes back to credibility and predictability. You cannot have a
functioning capitalist system if you have total uncertainty. These are the issues that I believe
President Plosser, President Hoenig, earlier President Lacker, and others were referring to in the
first intervention. I thank President Geithner in particular for addressing the questions I asked
yesterday, and there was reference to them earlier.
We have done so much so quickly. We are in a quantitative easing period. The question
is whether it actually makes a difference if we cut rates or not and whether the price of money is
actually the issue or the fact that money is not flowing, that there are counterparty risks and
rollover risks, and all the things we have talked about at this table and each of us has articulated
in our public speeches. To be very honest with you, Mr. Chairman, I am open-minded about this
because I could make that argument both ways. If it doesn’t matter, why not cut 50 basis points?
Or why not hold? I am not convinced yet—and I’d like to listen to the rest of the arguments—
that alternative A, in terms of the action, is the right way to go. I do think it’s very important that
we be very clear and articulate in laying out how we see the world, and I do believe that the
language in alternative A does the best job of all the columns that have been presented.
But I come back to the question I asked before. What are the next steps? I’d like to
know. What is the end game? I’d like to know before I cast my vote. I will conclude with
actually once again agreeing with President Yellen, as I think I have done twice in history.

October 28–29, 2008

137 of 206

[Laughter] The last time was at the last meeting. I think it’s very important that we have all
hands on deck, that we have a unanimous decision. But, still, I would like answers to my
questions. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher, I promised you answers, and I will deliver
them. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I strongly favor alternative A, a 50 basis
point cut in our fed funds target rate today. I think it is important for us to move aggressively
and quickly to offset the strong forces that are acting to depress economic activity. I know that
some prefer a more measured response, especially as we move closer to the zero bound, but the
lesson I take from history is that more and sooner is better than taking smaller steps over time.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The economic outlook has definitely
deteriorated. On top of the slowing at the beginning of the third quarter, a sequence of policy
actions and statements has spread an inchoate fear. In response to that, a wide variety of
economic agents have delayed outlays. The breathtaking credit market interventions that we
have undertaken in the last several weeks are going to make it hard to judge whether those
markets are stabilized. It is going to make it even harder to judge how and when to withdraw.
Governor Duke asked rhetorically what it would take for recovery to begin. I think it is
not going to be a very healthy recovery unless we have made substantial progress toward
withdrawing these interventions. I know it’s probably premature in the midst of a crisis to be
talking about the recovery, but a number of people did, and I think it makes sense on the grounds
that President Plosser advanced for us to be thinking ahead. President Geithner talked about the

October 28–29, 2008

138 of 206

will and the desire and that it amounts to a matter of will to reverse course later on. I think that
in withdrawing these subsidies and these credit market interventions is where we are going to
need the will. It is going to be really hard to disenfranchise somebody who now has access to
one of these programs.
The inflation outlook has improved. Expected inflation has come down. A couple of
people have noted that. That brings the real rate where the interest rate is now—to about zero.
So I can favor a 50 point reduction in the federal funds rate target at this meeting. I think a funds
rate that is, in real terms as best as we can measure it, about minus 1 percent is how we should
see our way through here, at least in the near term. Like President Evans, I will mention the
1930s. What I take from my reading of the Great Depression is that this is what central banks
should do in times like this—keep real interest rates low.
Let me make a couple of brief observations. As I mentioned yesterday, I think we are
going to face a challenge communicating about our strategy. If we need to reduce interest rates
to the lowest practical level to which we feel we can reduce them, I think yesterday’s discussion
suggests that the Committee could use a refresher course on the monetary economics of the zero
bound. I applaud President Bullard for his breaking new ground by providing a figure from the
Journal of Economic Theory. [Laughter]
I want to put something on the table about the federal funds rate. We are voting today on
the target for the federal funds rate. The way our operations are conducted now, we are leaving
so many excess reserves in the system that we are driving the federal funds rate down to the
interest rate on reserves. The interbank risk premium is likely to become small as the FDIC
guarantee becomes well understood and more broadly effective. The GSEs are likely to catch on
that they deserve more on their funds. Small banks, as Governor Duke says, that haven’t really

October 28–29, 2008

139 of 206

paid attention to what this new regime is about are going to find that brokers are going to be able
to find them placements at closer to the interest rate on reserves. So I think that the sloppy
trading below the interest rate on reserves is going to fade over time. As long as we have excess
reserves at the scale that we do, as long as the Desk has added that many reserves, we are going
to have the effective federal funds rate at the interest rate on reserves. Because we are voting on
the federal funds target rate, I think that the Committee ought to have some understanding from
the staff that either excess reserves are going to be drawn down to the point that the effective rate
is lifted off the interest rate on the reserves floor or—and this would be my preferable course of
action—we raise the interest rate on reserves to equal the target rate. Otherwise, we are voting
on something, but we are actually doing something else. I can understand the desire to err on the
side of soft rates. This is what we did in August 2007. But as rates go down, we need to be
more and more careful about what the Committee is actually voting on.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Just to support what you said, we are obviously still trying
to find our way in how to use this in the new regime with the excess reserves interest rate. It is
possible that at some point we might decide to target that interest rate. That might be the most
straightforward thing to do. But as I understand it—and, in fact, I’m quite confident—the
intention of the staff and the Board is to try to figure out what the relationship is between the
excess reserves interest rate and the federal funds rate as normally measured. If we can establish
a reliable relationship, then we should try to—and we will—use that to hit the target. It’s
coming close to it. We certainly are not trying intentionally to come under the target. If that
fails, then we will go to what you are suggesting, which is effectively what I’m saying, and make
them the same. Then, effectively, there is no difference between targeting the interest rate on
excess reserves and targeting the federal funds rate. We are certainly open to that, and there is

October 28–29, 2008

140 of 206

no intention to do anything other than to try to figure out a way to take the FOMC’s decision and
put it into practice in the money markets. President Stern.
MR. STERN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Well, financial headwinds continue to be a
major part of my thinking about the economic outlook. Reasonable people can differ about that
issue, but it seems to me that the headwinds are significant and they are likely to persist.
Partially as a consequence and partially for other reasons, the economic outlook has deteriorated,
and the inflation outlook, fortunately, has improved. So I favor alternative A, and I am satisfied
with the language associated with it.
Let me make just one additional comment. One way of thinking about lowering rates at
this juncture and its potential effectiveness is that it is important to reduce the price of liquidity
in this environment. I think that’s what lowering the target would do. That said, if I think about
policy a bit beyond this meeting, I start with an observation that Governor Kohn made. We are
probably going to receive a batch of pretty negative economic news over the next several
months. At the same time, a lot of programs are in place, as everybody is aware; and perhaps my
optimism is ill-conceived, but I actually think that they have the promise of being effective over
time. So it’s not just a question in my mind of the nature of the news we get, but are we also
seeing signs that all these programs are getting some traction and being effective? If they are,
that ought to temper our desire to go further. Obviously, a lot of things are in play, and a great
deal of uncertainty is present here and abroad. But we will simply have to assess all these
developments as best we can as time passes. I think I’ll end my remarks there.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Warsh.
MR. WARSH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Let me begin by agreeing with Don Kohn on
two things. This is the toughest economic period I can remember in his lifetime, [laughter] and I

October 28–29, 2008

141 of 206

support alternative A. I think the inflation trends and the trends in the global economy give us
flexibility, which six months or so ago I did not think we would have. I think that gives us some
degree of freedom that, given all of the negative tone, including my own, around the table, gives us
at least some source of comfort.
Next I would say that I agree with the consensus around the table, which is that these
problems are not principally about monetary policy. But I also think that monetary policy isn’t
irrelevant to this, and all agencies of governments around the world are making tough decisions, and
the marginal benefits of further monetary policy changes strike me as not high but not irrelevant. I
think President Plosser talked a bit about the alternative policy paths in the Greenbook that range
from keeping the fed funds rate constant where it is to taking it to zero percent and the surprisingly
small differences in output, employment, and core inflation there. In some ways, in the discussion
that we’re having about 25 or 50 or moving or not, it would not be fair for any of us to overstate the
importance in terms of directly affecting the economy in the short term.
That goes to my final point, which is that the most valuable asset that we have isn’t what at
the end of this meeting might be 100 basis points left of monetary policy. Frankly, it is the
credibility of the institution and the credibility of the FOMC. If I compare our credibility now to
virtually any other organization in the United States or maybe even globally, I think our credibility
is holding up quite well, particularly relative to the degree of difficulty we have in front of us,
relative to the trauma in financial markets and the weaknesses in the economy. So it is that asset,
that credibility, that we need to continue to protect more than incremental basis point moves on the
fed funds rate. I think that credibility will be tested over this period as it will for our counterparts.
We don’t want to find ourselves in a corner come December or come a couple of brutal days in the
markets where we feel compelled to continue to act and make 50 basis point moves unless and until

October 28–29, 2008

142 of 206

we know where we want to end up on this. So I’m sympathetic to that point of view. We need to
tell the story before the story is told for us of what our lower bound is, why it’s there, and what our
diagnosis of the economy is. I think that the Chairman and the rest of us will have ample
opportunity to do that between now and December and that it is quite important to make sure we
come out of this as strong as we have been through this period so far. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Kroszner.
MR. KROSZNER. Thank you very much. Well, I’ve not been able to convince myself not
to agree with President Evans. As everyone has said, we have this very significant global shift that
has stepped down real activity and financial activity. The inflation environment has changed
dramatically from a number of months ago with the change in commodity prices, the change in the
value of the dollar, and the change in not just U.S. but also global resource utilization. I think we’ve
seen just an enormous change there. Also, when you look at the expected federal funds rate path—
we have to be careful in looking at anything in the markets these days because of liquidity, risk
premiums, or term premiums that we’re not quite sure about—the markets are expecting significant
cuts from us. They are not expecting any immediate or near-term significant increases in inflation,
and I think all of the indications are that it will be going down.
In a cost–benefit analysis, the costs seem relatively low in terms of the potential for inflation
of doing this. Now, we have to think about it in terms of benefits, and a number of people have
touched on the transmission mechanism. I do think that there are forces that mute the extent to
which a 50 basis point cut translates into 50 basis points or lower on costs, but I don’t think they
completely offset it. It still has the effect of reducing the cost of liquidity, reducing many people’s
borrowing costs. I think it still does have an effect even if there’s an offsetting risk spread and even

October 28–29, 2008

143 of 206

if there’s an offsetting bank action that affects that. So in terms of costs and benefits, at this time it
seems that the costs are relatively low or muted, and the benefits are positive and potentially high.
In particular, as I mentioned before, I’m concerned about the confluence of forces that may
make things very difficult around the end of the year. If you look at a lot of these LIBOR or
forward markets, they’re not coming down either in the United States or around the world. We
have a lot of uncertainties with hedge funds, with the potential for other institutions getting into
trouble, and with just the implementation of our policies—in particular, as I mentioned, the way the
FDIC guarantee program and the TARP program work may end up singling out institutions and
bringing them down more quickly than otherwise. So I think it makes sense in terms of cost–benefit
analysis, even more so given the tail risk around the end of the year, to act now. We have another
opportunity to act in December and obviously an opportunity to act at any point if we do see a
dramatic change. We are getting near as much as we can do, but I don’t see the costs of acting more
aggressively and more quickly here outweighing the benefits. So I support alternative A with the
language as drafted. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you. I confess I find myself torn between the position of President
Plosser and the equally compelling arguments of Governor Kohn, and that makes alternative B quite
attractive as a way, not because of any optimism about the economic outcome, but I really do
question the effectiveness of any move in the fed funds target given the actual trading of the fed
funds rate right now. When we set the interest rate on reserves, at that point I was concerned that
our interest on reserves would disrupt the market for fed funds between banks because of the risk
premium. With the FDIC insurance, I think that goes away, and so probably President Lacker’s
suggestion deserves some strong consideration. I am also painfully aware of the operational and

October 28–29, 2008

144 of 206

financial difficulties that banks experience at a 1 percent fed funds rate and the likely difficulties of
other intermediaries as the absolute level of rates falls further.
As I stated in my earlier remarks, I’m also most concerned about the importance of
predictability in returning confidence to the markets, and in that light, I am concerned about market
expectations. But having recently been an expecter rather than a decider, I’m going to suggest that
most of those doing the expecting don’t understand at all the issues that we’ve discussed here today.
There’s a thought that, if the fed funds rate just comes down, it would maybe make this pain go
away. So I agree with Governor Warsh that the public statements in the intermeeting period and as
we approach the point where we simply can’t meet market expectations anymore are critically
important to shape market expectations. So I do think it’s important that the markets focus on the
other efforts, and with that I would support alternative A.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Mr. Chairman, I support alternative A, both the action
and the language for the reasons I said earlier. I just want to make a couple of other points. I think
the only way to be predictable in a crisis like this is to be predictably inert or to be late. I don’t
understand the basic argument that you add to confidence by being inert or by being late or, as the
Chairman said, by being passive despite overwhelming evidence about changes in the outlook and
risks to financial stability. The argument that makes me most uncomfortable here around the table
today is the suggestion several of you have made—I’m not sure you meant it this way—which is
that the actions by this Committee contributed to the erosion of confidence—a deeply unfair
suggestion.
Now, a lot of things happened over the last three months and the last year, and a lot of things
happened in terms of policy over the last six weeks. There is no doubt that communication about

October 28–29, 2008

145 of 206

policy by all the arms of the U.S. government and the uncertainty created by the actions by all the
arms of the U.S. government contributed in ways to uncertainty about the policy response going
forward. There is also no doubt that inevitably in a crisis like this, when policy moves forcefully, it
is scary because a lot of people are not yet at the point of assessing or understanding the forces
driving our decisions. But I think it’s just unfair to suggest that the actions by the Chairman and this
Committee were a substantial contributor to the erosion in confidence and to uncertainty about
further policy actions, even though it’s true that when we move with force and drama it has the risk
of adding to uncertainty.
I’d be very careful to look more broadly at the full range of other things that happened in
that period of time, including, for example, the confusion established by the range of different
choices for interventions in Lehman, AIG, the GSEs, WaMu in particular, and Wachovia and what
that meant. Look particularly at the damage to confidence created by the Congress’s actions in the
weeks after the legislation was first proposed. Compare that, for example, with the announcement
effect of the initial thing. Look also at the uncertainty created around what the package was
designed to do and how it was designed. But please be very careful, certainly outside this room,
about adding to the perception that the actions by this body were a substantial contributor to the
erosion in confidence. I think that Don Kohn said it best. The whole framing, which seems to have
hardened now, that the world ended with the Lehman bankruptcy is just deeply unfair to the basic
truth. Independent of whether there was an option available at the time, the erosion in underlying
economic conditions and in confidence in the future outlook was powerful and substantial going
into August and early September. So I just offer that.
You know, everyone wants to quote FDR. FDR said at one point, “If I judge the mood of
the country right, what this calls for is bold experimentation.” I do not believe that this Chairman

October 28–29, 2008

146 of 206

and this Committee have been irresponsibly experimenting at the cost of predictability and
confidence going forward. What we have done is a relatively well designed series of escalations in
monetary policy and liquidity intended to be preemptive against what we knew was substantial risk
of a very adverse economic and financial outcome. The risks were not broadly shared, not just in
this room but outside. But I think the judgments by the Chairman were largely correct in weighing
those risks appropriately at that time, and I think we all owe him a substantial amount of deference
for the judgments he made and his wisdom. Both here in this room and in the effect he had on the
policy choices that the fiscal authorities also ultimately made look very good now and will look
even better over time as people understand how grave and substantial the risks were that we were
facing in the economy and the financial system.
One last point to President Fisher’s question. President Fisher asked the obvious question,
which is, What next? I think a very good approach to decisionmaking is to say, “I don’t want to
know so much about this. I want to know about the next three things.” I know the Chairman is
going to give a nice, thoughtful, and complete answer to this. But I would just say the following:
We don’t need to know today what is next on the monetary policy front. We know there may be
some arguments for going lower than 1 percent. We have to think through very carefully the
collateral damage consequence in terms of what that does to market functioning and behavior. We
have to look at the alternatives to that, including in communication. A range of other policy options
are within our capacity to influence and effect that will give us the ability to minimize downside risk
going forward. But I don’t think that we need to know—and we cannot know with precision—what
the optimal mix of those things is now before deciding what to do, although I’m very sympathetic to
the basic judgment. The question really is, In moving today, are we going to do more harm than
good to our ultimate objective? It’s very hard to make the case that we do damage to any of our

October 28–29, 2008

147 of 206

basic fundamental objectives and mandate. I can see a much stronger case that we do a lot of
damage to those if we don’t act today, even though we all recognize that ultimately this is going to
require more than monetary policy to address the risk here.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I’d just like to just take a moment to react. I’m not sure whom you heard
saying that the result was primarily a result of this Committee’s actions or the Chairman’s actions or
anyone else’s actions. If those were words you were putting in my mouth, that was not what I said,
President Geithner. I do think I have been supportive of almost all the actions in terms of liquidity
facilities; I supported the actions. I also was supportive of the Lehman Brothers decision. But I
think it’s a far cry from saying that uncertainty about policies contributes to uncertainty—which you
agreed to—it’s a far cry from that to saying we lay the blame at the feet of this Committee or the
Chairman. So I don’t know what straw man you were setting up, but it certainly didn’t apply to this
member of the Committee. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. Let me just offer some thoughts that may
be somewhat more expansive than usual in response to the questions that have been raised. Some of
this is extemporaneous, so you’ll have to bear with me. Let me first talk about the strategy we
pursued thus far and where we are and then think about where we might go as a country as well as
an institution going forward.
Without going through all of the familiar discussion about how the crisis began, what the
sources of it were, I think that the Federal Reserve’s responses are essentially three. First, we were
relatively early and aggressive in our monetary policy easing, particularly compared with other
countries. Second, we have been creative and expansive in our use of liquidity tools, including a

October 28–29, 2008

148 of 206

wide variety of lending programs. Third, we have used our available, but not always adequate, tools
to try to stabilize systemically critical failing institutions and to try to mitigate systemic risk.
Without sounding too defensive, I will try to argue that I think on all three of these we have
been more or less in the right direction. First, on the early and aggressive monetary policy easing,
obviously there was a lot of concern—a lot expressed abroad that we were going to create a
stagflationary 1970s type of situation and that we were going to destroy the dollar and its role as an
international currency. Our response essentially was that we thought that the increases in
commodity prices were mostly a relative price change induced by changes in real demand for
commodities and in the supply of commodities across the globe and that, at some point, those
commodity price increases would stabilize, which would lead to a moderation of the inflationary
effects and concerns. It took longer than we had expected; but once it began, it was more
pronounced than we had expected. Inflation has not become the problem that was anticipated by
many early on, and the dollar, of course, is now stronger than it was before we began our cutting of
interest rates. So in retrospect, I think our monetary policy, although not perfect certainly—and our
communication was not always perfect—broadly speaking was appropriate given what has turned
out to be a very severe economic situation.
Liquidity expansion also received some criticism early on. There was a view that this was
inducing moral hazard. There was also some question of whether this was an effective approach.
We were helped in this respect by the fact that the ECB joined us very early in this type of
aggressive policy. I don’t know the counterfactual. It has obviously not solved all of the problems.
But I think there’s a strong perception in the markets and in the general public that these actions
have been supportive, and they helped mitigate the effects of the crisis on the functioning of the
financial system. So I feel comfortable also with that approach.

October 28–29, 2008

149 of 206

The attempts to stabilize failing systemically critical institutions, beginning with Bear
Stearns, have obviously been very controversial. There have been criticisms from the right and
from the left. From the right, the initial criticism was that we have no business interfering with the
market process. We should let them fail. The market will take care of it. What are we doing? We
heard this as recently as Jackson Hole. I never took this seriously. I just don’t believe that you can
allow systemically critical institutions to fail in the middle of financial crises and expect it to be not
a problem. I don’t want to get into the issue about the inconsistency. It’s true that we treated senior
debt differently between Fannie and Freddie and WaMu and Wachovia, but I don’t think that that is
the reason we are having the financial crisis we’re having. I think there was a panic brought about
by the underlying concerns about the solvency of our financial institutions. That panic essentially
turned into a run. Companies like Wachovia that had adequate Basel capital faced a run on their
deposits, which was self-fulfilling. The investment banks essentially faced runs. We did our best to
stabilize them, but I think that it was that run, that panic, and then the impact the panic had on these
major institutions that was the source of the intensification of financial crisis. So I don’t buy the
argument that we should stay out of the business of protecting the financial system, and I think that
the major factor was, in fact, the panic that was generated by the underlying uncertainties and the
effect that had on critical institutions.
Also more recently we have heard more of a critique from the left, which is, What in the
heck were you guys doing letting Lehman fail? This is interesting given that the critique had been
the other one for quite a while. I think that critique is unfair at a narrow level in that, first, Lehman
was a symptom as well as a cause of the recent crisis and, second, the Fed and the Treasury simply
had no tools to address both Lehman and the other companies that were under stress at that time. I
think that criticism is appropriate, though, as directed toward the United States as a whole. We did

October 28–29, 2008

150 of 206

not have—as the Europeans have or as we have FDICIA for banks—a system that was set up to
allow a reasonable and responsible orderly resolution of nonbank systemically critical institutions. I
think we now have made a lot of progress there. The TARP will provide a good interim solution. It
is very important that in the future we address the too-big-to-fail problem that we have, that we find
ways to reduce that problem, and that we find ways to deal systematically with firms that are in
crisis. So given the fog of war—which has, of course, been intense going back for more than a
year—I would defend what we’ve done in terms of the general direction, acknowledging that
execution is not always perfect and that communication is not always perfect.
Now, what about the future? History suggests that, whenever a financial crisis becomes
sufficiently severe, ultimately the only solution is a fiscal solution, and we will have a fiscal
solution. There are two possibilities. One is that the financial system will muddle through, in which
case the fiscal solution will be of the sort we’ve already seen: injections of capital, support for
critical firms, support for the credit markets in general; Keynesian-style demand support. That’s
one possibility. I hope that’s where we’re going to be. In my own testimony, I argued that we
should try to focus whatever stimulus we have in solving the underlying problems rather than
simply handing out money and that we could do that, again, by addressing credit markets. I would
add, foreclosure, homeownership, and some of those issues as well. So I hope that’s where the
fiscal policy will be. I hope that will take the lead from us going forward. Obviously, we’ll have to
continue to play a supporting role in a lot of different ways.
The other possibility, of course, is that things get much worse and that we are in the same
situation as Sweden or Japan, in which case a massive recapitalization of the banking system will be
necessary. That will eventually happen, but I just note that, in all of these fiscal dynamics, there is a
political economy overlay. You have to get to the point that it is not only the right policy to induce

October 28–29, 2008

151 of 206

fiscal support but also that it is politically possible. That’s one reason that I think the TARP was not
possible before the most recent period. In fact, it was barely possible recently. So, again, I believe
that fiscal policy will have to be a critical part of the solution going forward.
Another part that we should not forget about is the international response, which is now just
beginning really to become serious. The responses after the G7 weekend on banks and bank
guarantees were important and suggested a commitment by other countries to stabilize the system.
That’s very important. I think we will see aggressive monetary policy going forward, and I think
we’ll see increasingly aggressive fiscal policy in other countries because they recognize that the
decoupling is no longer a realistic story. So that’s going to be important as well.
With respect to the Federal Reserve, just generally speaking—and I’ll come back to the
specific recommendation for today—again, I think that our liquidity provision has been
constructive. It has allowed the use of our balance sheet to help push in the deleveraging process
that’s been going on now for more than a year. My guess is it will probably expand some more, but
I don’t see it expanding a lot more, if for no other reason than we are reaching the limits of our
operational capacity as well as balance sheet capacity. I think we have been reasonably successful
in staying on the side of liquidity provision and not straying into credit or taking credit risk. I want
to stay on that side of the line both for legal reasons and because that’s the way monetary policy and
lender-of-last-resort policy are supposed to work. Again, I hope that the fiscal interventions will
now be able to take away some of these responsibilities from us, but we’ll have to see how they play
out.
I confess that I hear President Plosser’s concerns about reversing these programs. I
recognize that it’s something we’ll have to do carefully. But I just don’t see it as being something
that will be a huge problem if the economy begins to recover and credit markets begin to function

October 28–29, 2008

152 of 206

more normally. I think we’ll be able to do it. Japan was able to get out the quantitative easing
without too much difficulty. But I acknowledge the point that it is something we’re going to have to
plan for and think about.
On monetary policy, I think it is important for us to be responsive. Even if we stipulate for
the moment that the interest rate changes we might make today have a minimal effect on the cost of
capital—and I don’t necessarily agree with that, but let me stipulate it—there is still the importance
of the signaling and what we’re trying to tell the markets about what we plan to do in the future.
Frankly, I don’t think that we should try to signal that we are going to stand pat, that we are
reluctant or refuse to move lower. We have to be prepared to move as low as makes sense. By that
I mean in part that there are institutional factors that affect the efficacy of monetary policy at very
low interest rates. We’re all aware of that. I asked yesterday, and I’ll ask again, for the staff to go
back to the 2003 work, to update it, and to think it through and help us understand what I would call
the effective zero. What is the real zero? Is it zero? Is it 50 basis points? Is it 75 basis points? We
have to recognize that if we do go to literal zero, it would have very substantial effects on a number
of financial markets, and we would have to ask ourselves whether the benefits from that are worth
the dislocations. The Japanese thought they were, and for example, they did shut down the
interbank market for a long time. Maybe doing it is worth that. Those are decisions that we need to
make before the next meeting, and we will have opportunities to talk about this together and in
public as well. But I do think that monetary policy needs to be proactive and to continue to be part
of the solution here going forward.
What about today’s action? I essentially accept the general change in outlook as proposed
by the Greenbook. Since our last meeting there has been an effective tightening in financial
conditions, which has overwhelmed the 50 basis point cut that we did with the other central banks.

October 28–29, 2008

153 of 206

The outlook has become much worse. So it is important for us to act aggressively and to signal
essentially that we’re willing to do whatever is necessary to support the recovery of this economy.
There has been a lot of talk about confidence. I think the best thing we can do for confidence is to
say that we’re going to do whatever it takes, even if it involves extraordinary actions, to get this
economy back onto a path where it can begin to grow in a reasonable way again. Signaling
coyness, being cute, is not a safe strategy right now. We just need to be straightforward and say that
we’re going to do what it takes. In my view, just to be specific, 50 basis points is the right step
today.
Now, a number of concerns and objections have been raised. Let me address just a few of
them. One is President Bullard’s very interesting presentation on the inflation trap, and intuitively
it’s clear that, for a given real interest rate, you can have an equilibrium at which you have a high
nominal rate and a high expected inflation rate or you can have a low nominal rate and deflation.
Both of those things are possible. That was the trap that Japan got into. We obviously want to
avoid the deflation trap. The question is, How do you avoid it? As far as I can see—obviously we
can get further into this—the best two ways to avoid it are, first, as President Lacker suggested,
reaffirm our commitment to price stability defined as 1½ to 2 percent or whatever our Committee’s
general view is. We’re going to try to do that with our projections and potentially with the trial
projection that we’re doing, and I think we can continue to strengthen our commitment to
maintaining a positive inflation rate. The other thing, in terms of the dynamics, is to be aggressive
in trying to avoid getting to a deflationary situation, where those expectations move in that direction.
I don’t think deflation expectations will arise spontaneously because we’re cutting interest rates. I
think they’ll arise because the economy is expected to be extremely weak, and anything we can do
to eliminate that expectation in my view would be helpful.

October 28–29, 2008

154 of 206

The second objection I’ve heard is the question of whether or not these actions are effective.
I think they are effective. Maybe they’re not as effective as under normal circumstances, but let me
put it to you this way. If we cut 50 basis points today and the LIBOR–OIS spread rises 50 basis
points tomorrow, I will accept that there’s a problem. But if the LIBOR spread doesn’t move much
and the overall LIBOR drops 50 basis points, then I think that we’re having an effect. If you look at
LIBOR over the past year, you’ll see a dramatic decline even though the spreads have widened. I
don’t think you can argue that we’re not having any effect. To the extent that we’re having a muted
effect, you can just as well argue that we should be more aggressive because you need to do more to
get the same impact. So I understand those concerns, and I reiterate, responding to Governor Duke
and others, that as we get very low, there are side effects on certain institutions and financial
markets. We need to understand those, and that’s part of our decision process. But I don’t think it’s
the case that monetary policy has zero impact.
The third argument I’ve heard is the “keep the power dry” argument. Unless you think that
movements in the rate are entirely psychological in their effect, I don’t think that that’s a strong
argument in this particular circumstance. Again, we analyzed this quite a bit in the 2003 episode,
and the general outcome from the literature and from simulations done by our own staff—Dave
Reifschneider, John Williams, and others have published research on this—is that the best way to
avoid the zero bound is to be more aggressive than normal to try to avoid the accumulation of
weakness and try to avoid getting into that trap. So more-preemptive strategies are, in fact,
consistent with what we’ve done for the last year.
My recommendation for today is 50 basis points and the language in alternative A. I do
think that it will be at least moderately beneficial both in terms of psychology and in terms of
reducing the cost of funding and giving some additional support to funding markets. I hope that in

October 28–29, 2008

155 of 206

these remarks, which again are somewhat extemporaneous, I have addressed to some extent the
future steps. We ought, again, to think very hard in the next six weeks about what the real zero is
and what the implications are of going below, say, 75 basis points. Then we ought to make a
determination, and it may be that we can sit still in December. It may be that things improve quite a
bit in the markets, for example. It’s possible. One advantage of doing 50 today is that we almost
certainly will not have to do anything intermeeting because we will have done this significant step
today. So in December we’ll be able to look at the situation. We may be able to do little or
nothing—it is possible. But if we decide that further action is needed, at that point we should be
prepared to decide what the regime is going to be, how far we’re going to go, and what the effective
zero is, and I think that we shouldn’t hesitate to do that if that’s what the situation calls for. So I
think there is a way forward. I understand the need to withdraw all these policy actions at an
appropriate time. But I don’t think that focusing on the near term for the moment is at all
inconsistent with the fact that at some point these things will have to be reversed. So, any further
questions or comments? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. First, I would like to thank you, Mr. Chairman, for that very thorough and
clear elucidation. I meant to mention earlier that I actually agree with President Evans. It’s
worthwhile now and then evoking Ronald Reagan. What I mean by that is not his “Where’s the
pony?” comment, but more important, the reason he was so successful as a leader was that he had
clear objectives, they were limited, and they were well articulated. It doesn’t matter if you’re a
Democrat or a Republican. I think it’s very important for us to understand what our objectives are
in order for us to be fully supportive. By the way, Tim, as Mr. Plosser has been, I have been fully
supportive of all of these initiatives. Again, I want to thank you, Mr. Chairman, for helping us
understand better the cognitive road map because it is critical for all of us to do what Janet

October 28–29, 2008

156 of 206

suggested, which is have all hands on deck and make sure we’re all fully supportive. Against that
background I would support alternative A. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Other questions? President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Just a question or thought. As the staff prepares the review of the 2003
studies and memos and thinks about what zero effectively means and how we might operate in
those circumstances, one thing I think would be useful to include is a discussion of whether or not
when that time comes we announce that publicly and say, “Okay. This is it. From now on we have
to do X, Y, or Z,” and make it part of the communication strategy. Maybe they would anyway. But
if we get to the point where we now as a group have some concerns that, well, effectively we really
don’t want to go below X, we will have to do some other operational actions as a substitute for that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think there’s no problem doing that. I can do that. That is
not a problem. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Yes, I also strongly support your charge and direction to the staff to
assemble with all due haste updated information for the Committee about what the effective lower
bound on nominal interest rates is. But I’d urge you, along the lines of what President Plosser
suggested, to include in that charge what we would do once we got there, what we could do, and
what would be open to us. I emphasize again the relevance even if we don’t get there because
analytically we’re effectively doing that right now with interest on reserves. The classic economics
of this is that, when you get down to effective equivalence between a monetary asset and a
government bond of one-day duration or whatever, to be effective monetary policy needs to be
fiscal policy. It needs to acquire other assets that we wouldn’t normally otherwise acquire. We’re
doing that right now. So I’d emphasize the importance and relevance of that.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. Mr. Chairman.

October 28–29, 2008

157 of 206

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. I also think it would be helpful, as the staff looks at the
policy options going forward, that they do other parts of the communication options, too—not just
those but also other ways to think about how to make policy for looking at and communicating a
path that are different from what we did in 2003. It would be good to look at options for how we
talk about policy going forward in that context along with just the operational choices and the policy
choices.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Just to follow up on that—I think that’s a very excellent suggestion,
President Geithner. To be very specific about that, in our trial run, one thing that we did was to look
at what we thought was the steady state. One way to engender some communication about the
longer run might be to include what the Committee thought the steady-state neutral level of the
funds rate would be in that environment. I’d describe the path by which we got there; it would
convey some sense to the marketplace of what we thought would be in some normal world a
reasonable level of the funds rate consistent with those targets. I just throw that on the table as
something to think about.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Other comments? Would you call the roll, please,
Debbie?
MS. DANKER. Yes. This vote encompasses the language of alternative A that was in the
package passed out earlier today as well as the directive from the Bluebook, which states the
following:
“The Federal Open Market Committee seeks monetary and financial conditions that will
foster price stability and promote sustainable growth in output. To further its long-run objectives,

October 28–29, 2008

158 of 206

the Committee in the immediate future seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with reducing
the federal funds rate to an average of around 1 percent.”
Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Geithner
Governor Duke
President Fisher
Governor Kohn
Governor Kroszner
President Pianalto
President Plosser
President Stern
Governor Warsh

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. I’ll need the governors to join me in my office for
just a moment. Everyone else, let’s all take a twenty-minute coffee break. When we come back,
maybe we can start at that point with your briefing, David, on the TARP, and around 12:15 we’ll
break and get lunch and hear the end of the briefing, if that all works for everybody.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. The expected duration of the next part of our meeting is
four hours, three hours? [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. We should be done by 1:00.
MS. DANKER. It’s not part of the meeting.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. The nonmeeting part of the meeting?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. It’s only a briefing, not a meeting, once we come back. Okay.
A twenty-minute break now and then we’ll have a briefing and lunch.
[Recess]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, let me officially get to the point of adjourning the
FOMC meeting just by first noting that the next meeting is Tuesday, December 16. Put that on your
calendar.
VICE CHAIRMAN GEITHNER. That’s a long way away. [Laughter]

October 28–29, 2008

159 of 206

MR. PLOSSER. Can’t we meet before then? [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’d like to remind you that you have until 5:00 p.m. on
Thursday to submit revisions to your economic projections, in case the markets change your views.
MS. DANKER. Only through today’s meeting.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Sorry—using information only through the end of today’s
meeting. All right, the FOMC meeting is adjourned. Thank you.
END OF MEETING