View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note
The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 01/08/2021.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC – Restricted Controlled (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book B
Monetary Policy:
Strategies and Alternatives
October 22, 2015

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

October 22, 2015

Monetary Policy Strategies
The top panel of the first exhibit, “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection,”
provides near-term prescriptions for the federal funds rate from four policy rules: the
Taylor (1993) rule, the Taylor (1999) rule, an inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule,
and a first-difference rule. 1 These prescriptions take as given the staff’s baseline
projections for real activity and inflation in the near term, shown in the middle panels.
All of the Taylor-type rules prescribe an immediate increase in the federal funds rate.
The Taylor (1993) and Taylor (1999) rules call for sizable adjustments in the policy rate
to values higher than 2 percent over the near term. By contrast, the inertial Taylor (1999)
rule counsels a level of the federal funds rate of only ½ percent in the fourth quarter of
2015 because this rule places a considerable weight on keeping the federal funds rate
close to its lagged value. The first-difference rule, which responds to the projected
inflation gap and to expected changes in the output gap, calls for the policy rate to edge
above the current target range next quarter. These prescriptions are generally a little
higher than in the September Tealbook, reflecting the staff’s upward revision to the
trajectory of inflation in the short run.
The bottom panel of the first exhibit reports the Tealbook-consistent estimate of
one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate, r*, generated using the FRB/US
model. This measure is an estimate of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained,
closes the output gap in 12 quarters. The current estimate of r*, at 0.74 percent, is similar
to the corresponding estimate in September, reflecting the fact that the staff forecast for
resource utilization and the path of the real federal funds rate are similar to those in the
September Tealbook. The panel also reports a measure of the current real federal funds
rate constructed as the difference between the current federal funds rate and the trailing
four-quarter change in the core PCE price index. The current real federal funds rate
is -1.17 percent, almost unchanged from the September Tealbook. To facilitate
comparisons with r*, the panel further reports the average of the real federal funds rate

1

The appendix to this section provides details on each of the four rules.

Page 1 of 50

Strategies

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Strategies

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection

Near-Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules1
(Percent)

2015:Q4

2016:Q1

Taylor (1993) rule
Previous Tealbook

2.28
2.11

2.53
2.37

Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook

2.18
2.01

2.48
2.34

Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook outlook

0.44
0.44

0.75
0.73

First-difference rule
Previous Tealbook outlook

0.23
0.13

0.31
0.13

Key Elements of the Staff Projection
GDP Gap

PCE Prices Excluding Food and Energy
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

2

3.0

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

-3

0.5

0.5

-4

0.0

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

2016

2017

2018

3.0

2.5
1

2015

Percent

2

1

-4

Four-quarter average

2019

2020

2021

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

0.0

Real Federal Funds Rate Estimates2
(Percent)

Current
Tealbook
Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*
Current real federal funds rate
Average projected real federal funds rate3

0.74
−1.17
0.21

Current Quarter Estimate
as of Previous Tealbook
0.71
0.28

Previous
Tealbook
0.47
−1.16
0.09

1. For rules that have a lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable, the column denoted "Previous Tealbook outlook" reports rule prescriptions based
on the previous Tealbook’s staff outlook, but jumping off from the realized value for the policy rate last quarter.
2. Estimates of r* and of the average projected real federal funds rate may change at the beginning of a quarter even when the staff outlook is unchanged
because the 12-quarter horizon covered by the calculation has rolled forward one quarter. Therefore, whenever the Tealbook is published early in the quarter,
the memo includes an extra column labeled "Current Quarter Estimate as of Previous Tealbook" to facilitate comparison with the current Tealbook estimate.
3. The average projected real federal funds rate is the 12-quarter average of the current real federal funds rate and its projected values under the Tealbook
baseline over the next 11 quarters.

Page 2 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

over the 12 quarters beginning in the current quarter under the Tealbook baseline. 2 This

The second exhibit, “Policy Rule Simulations,” reports dynamic simulations of
the FRB/US model under each of the policy rules. These simulations reflect the
endogenous responses of inflation and the output gap when the federal funds rate follows
the paths implied by the different policy rules, subject to an effective lower bound of
12½ basis points for the federal funds rate. 3 The results for each rule presented in these
and subsequent simulations depend importantly on the assumptions that policymakers
will adhere to the rule in the future and that the private sector fully understands the policy
that will be pursued as well as its implications for real activity and inflation.
The second exhibit also displays the implications of following the baseline
monetary policy assumptions in the current staff forecast. 4 As discussed in Tealbook A,
the staff assumes that the first increase in the federal funds rate will occur at the
December FOMC meeting. After departing from its effective lower bound, the federal
funds rate is assumed to follow the prescriptions of the inertial version of the
Taylor (1999) rule. The federal funds rate increases about 25 basis points per quarter for
the first three years after liftoff, reaching about 3¼ percent by the end of 2018. The pace
of tightening subsequently slows, and the federal funds rate moves close to 4 percent in
2020—consistent with the higher projected level of resource utilization around that
time—before eventually returning to its longer-run normal level of 3¼ percent later in the
decade.
All of the policy rules in these dynamic simulations call for policy rates above the
current target range in the fourth quarter of 2015, the first period in the simulation,
though the increases prescribed by the inertial Taylor (1999) rule and by the firstdifference rule are small. The unemployment rate in all the simulations runs near or
2

While r* and the average projected real federal funds rate are calculated over the same
12-quarter period, they need not be associated with the same macroeconomic outcomes even when their
values are identical. The reason is that, in the r* simulations, the real federal funds rate is held constant
over the entire 12-quarter period whereas, in the Tealbook baseline, the real federal funds rate can vary
over time. Distinct paths of real short-term rates can, in turn, generate differing paths for inflation and
economic activity.
3
Because of these endogenous responses, prescriptions from the dynamic simulations can differ
from those shown in the top panel of the first exhibit.
4
The dynamic simulations discussed here and below incorporate the assumptions about
underlying economic conditions that are used in the staff’s baseline forecast, including the macroeconomic
effects of the Committee’s asset holdings from the large-scale asset purchase programs.

Page 3 of 50

Strategies

average is currently 0.21 percent, 0.53 percentage point below the current estimate of r*.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Strategies

Policy Rule Simulations
Effective Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Unemployment Rate
Percent

6

Taylor (1993) rule
Taylor (1999) rule
Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
First-difference rule
Tealbook baseline

5

6

Percent

6.0

6.0

Staff’s estimate of the natural rate
5

4

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

5.5

5.5

5.0

5.0

4.5

4.5

0
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Real Federal Funds Rate
Percent

3

2

3

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

4.0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

4.0

PCE Inflation

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

3.0

Four-quarter average

Percent

3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

0.0

0.0

-2

Real 10-year Treasury Yield
Percent

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-0.5

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation. This choice of rule
specification was made in light of the tendency for current and near-term core inflation rates to outperform headline
inflation rates as predictors of the medium-term behavior of headline inflation.

Page 4 of 50

-0.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

below the staff’s estimate of the natural rate through 2021. The Taylor (1993) and
above the Tealbook baseline over the next few years, leading to higher unemployment
rates (that is, less undershooting of the natural rate) than in the baseline. Later in the
simulation period, the Taylor (1993) rule, which places less weight on the output gap than
the Taylor (1999) rule, calls for slightly less overshooting of the nominal policy rate’s
longer-run value of 3¼ percent. As a consequence, the Taylor (1993) rule generates a
lower trajectory of the unemployment rate than the Taylor (1999) rule. Because priceand wage-setters anticipate a slightly more accommodative policy trajectory and this has
implications for resource utilization, inflation is a touch higher under the Taylor (1993)
rule over the medium term relative to the Taylor (1999) rule and the baseline projection.
Under the inertial Taylor (1999) rule, the federal funds rate initially rises a bit above the
baseline but subsequently tracks the baseline path almost exactly. 5 Macroeconomic
outcomes are essentially the same as under the Tealbook baseline.
Starting in 2016, the first-difference rule prescribes a pace of increases in the
federal funds rate that is similar to the Tealbook baseline through 2018. At that point,
under the first-difference rule, the federal funds rate levels off. This divergence results
from the slower pace of economic growth expected to occur late in the decade because
the first-difference rule responds to the expected change in the output gap rather than to
its level. That lower path of the federal funds rate in the medium run under the firstdifference rule, in conjunction with expectations of higher price and wage inflation in the
future, leads to a lower path of long-term real rates and to higher levels of resource
utilization and inflation in the short run. The first-difference rule generates outcomes for
the unemployment rate over the forecast period that are markedly below the staff’s
estimate of the natural rate and the unemployment rate paths generated under the other
policy rules. Relative to the other simple policy rules, inflation runs a bit closer to the
Committee’s 2 percent longer-run inflation objective over the next few years before
overshooting the target by a greater margin later in the decade.
The third exhibit, “Optimal Control Policy under Commitment,” compares
optimal control simulations for this Tealbook’s baseline forecast with those reported in
September. Policymakers are assumed to place equal weights on keeping headline PCE
5

As noted, policy firming begins in December under the Tealbook baseline policy; however,
because the December meeting is late in the fourth quarter, the average value for the federal funds rate
remains within the current target range until the first quarter of 2016.

Page 5 of 50

Strategies

Taylor (1999) rules produce paths for the real federal funds rate that lie significantly

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Strategies

Optimal Control Policy under Commitment
Effective Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Unemployment Rate
Percent

6

Optimal control (current Tealbook)
Optimal control (previous Tealbook)
Tealbook baseline

5

6

Percent

6.0

6.0

Staff’s estimate of the natural rate
5

4

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

5.5

5.5

5.0

5.0

4.5

4.5

0
2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Real Federal Funds Rate
Percent

3

2

3

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

4.0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

4.0

PCE Inflation

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

3.0

Four-quarter average

Percent

3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

0.0

0.0

-2

Real 10-year Treasury Yield
Percent

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-0.5

Page 6 of 50

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-0.5

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

inflation close to the Committee’s 2 percent goal, on keeping the unemployment rate
changes in the federal funds rate. The concept of optimal control that is employed here
corresponds to a commitment policy under which the plans that policymakers make today
are assumed to constrain future policy choices. 6
Under the optimal control policy, the path for the real federal funds rate is more
than ½ percentage point higher on average than the Tealbook baseline path. The
trajectory for the real 10-year Treasury yield is accordingly also higher. The tighter
policy under optimal control is associated with a path of the unemployment rate that is
much closer to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate than the Tealbook baseline
projection. Headline PCE inflation is slightly lower than in the baseline over the
simulation period, consistent with lower levels of resource utilization under optimal
control policy.
The optimal control path for the nominal federal funds rate is only modestly
higher than in the September Tealbook largely because the staff now forecasts a
marginally higher level of resource utilization over the next few years. The outcomes for
the unemployment rate and inflation are little changed with respect to the September
Tealbook.

OPTIMAL CONTROL WITH ALTERNATIVE LABOR MARKET OBJECTIVES
In the standard optimal control simulations discussed above, welfare losses arise
from deviations, positive or negative, of the unemployment rate from the staff’s estimate
of the natural rate. However, some policymakers may believe that broader measures of
labor market outcomes better capture their assessment of the amount of slack remaining
in the labor market and the attendant welfare losses. Others may place no weight on
unemployment deviations on the grounds that the welfare cost of low-to-moderate
unemployment outcomes is small, or as a pragmatic response to uncertainty about
estimates of the natural rate of unemployment and the risk that poorly estimated
unemployment gaps could lead to policy mistakes. The exhibit “Optimal Control with

6

The results for optimal control policy under discretion (in which policymakers cannot credibly
commit to carrying out a plan involving policy choices that would be suboptimal at the time that these
choices have to be implemented) are similar.

Page 7 of 50

Strategies

close to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate of unemployment, and on minimizing

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Strategies

Optimal Control with Alternative Labor Market Objectives

Effective Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Unemployment Rate
Percent

7

Optimal control (current Tealbook)
OC: ugap replaced by E/P gap
OC: no weight on ugap
OC: no weight on ugap with steeper PC
Tealbook baseline

6
5

7
6

4

3

3

2

2

1

1

0

0
2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

Staff’s estimate of the natural rate

6.0

5.5

5.5

5.0

5.0

4.5

4.5

4.0

4.0

3.5

3.5

5

4

2015

Percent

6.0

2021

3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

3.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

Percent

3

2.5 Four-quarter average

2

2

2.0

2.0

1

1

1.5

1.5

0

0

1.0

1.0

-1

-1

0.5

0.5

-2

0.0

3

1.5

3

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Real 10-year Treasury Yield

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

0.0

Employment-to-Population Ratio Gap
Percent

3

2

2

1

1

0

-1

2015

2.5

Percent

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

0.0

0.0

-0.5

-0.5

0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-1

-1.0

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

Note: The lines labeled ‘‘Optimal control (current Tealbook)’’ correspond to the baseline optimal control policy under commitment shown
in the previous exhibit. The lines labeled ‘‘OC: ugap replaced by E/P gap’’ correspond to an optimal control policy that substitutes
the unemployment gap in the loss function with the deviation of the employment-to-population ratio from its trend. The lines labeled
‘‘OC: no weight on ugap’’ correspond to optimal control with a loss function that places no weight on the unemployment gap; the lines
labeled ‘‘OC no weight on ugap with steeper PC’’ further posit a wage Phillips curve that is steeper than under the baseline.

Page 8 of 50

-1.0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternative Labor Market Objectives” displays optimal control simulations for alternative

The blue dotted lines in the exhibit show optimal control policy simulations under
the assumption that policymakers penalize the deviation of the employment-to-population
ratio from the staff’s estimate of its trend rather than the unemployment gap, on the
argument that the former measure encompasses both the unemployment gap and the
deviation of the labor force participation rate from its estimated trend. 7 The employmentto-population ratio this quarter is 0.3 percentage point below its estimated trend,
compared with a current unemployment gap that is essentially closed. These estimates
suggest that there is only limited extra slack in the labor market along the labor force
participation margin and, accordingly, policy is only modestly more accommodative than
under the standard optimal control simulations (the solid red lines) through 2021. 8 As a
result, the unemployment rate falls a touch below the standard optimal control outcomes.
The bottom-right panel shows that policymakers are willing to accept a slightly more
pronounced overshooting of the trend in the employment-to-population ratio in the
medium run in exchange for a moderately lower amount of slack in the short run and for
inflation outcomes that are a touch closer to 2 percent than under the standard optimal
control policy. 9
The magenta dashed lines show the optimal control simulation under the
assumption that policymakers place no weight on measures of labor market slack in their
loss function. In this scenario, policy is considerably more accommodative than in the
standard optimal control case or in the case in which policymakers target the
employment-to-population ratio gap. The lower policy path stems from the willingness
of policymakers who place no weight on labor market outcomes to tolerate undershooting
7

To the extent that all margins of slack move in proportion, including only the unemployment gap
in the loss function is equivalent to penalizing all margins of slack and adjusting the relative weights in the
loss function accordingly.
8
The employment-to-population ratio gap was appreciably larger than the unemployment gap
earlier in the recovery when there was extra slack in the labor market along the labor force participation
margin. Replacing the unemployment gap with the employment-to-population ratio gap was more
consequential for policy at that time. See “Assessing the Recent Decline in the Unemployment Rate and its
Implications for Monetary Policy” sent to the FOMC on June 7th, 2013 by Stephanie Aaronson, Bruce
Fallick, Charles Fleischman, and Robert Tetlow.
9
If policymakers were to replace the employment-to-population ratio gap in the loss function with
the deviation of aggregate hours from the staff’s estimate of its trend, then policy would be less
accommodative than otherwise. The reason is that hours per worker are currently above the staff’s estimate
of their potential level.

Page 9 of 50

Strategies

interpretations of losses associated with slack in the labor market.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

of the natural rate of unemployment. These policymakers are inclined to ease policy
Strategies

aggressively to close the inflation gap more quickly.
A key assumption underlying the results from this simulation is the low sensitivity
of inflation to resource slack in the FRB/US model. This low sensitivity limits the effects
of monetary policy on inflation. To demonstrate the role of this assumption, the green
dash-dotted lines in the exhibit show an optimal control policy simulation in which
policymakers place no weight on measures of labor market slack, but wage inflation is
more sensitive to the unemployment rate gap. In this case, the standard wage Phillips
curve in the FRB/US model is replaced with one in which wage inflation is four times
more responsive to labor market slack. While the calibration is meant to be illustrative, it
is within the range of conventional estimates. 10
Under this alternative specification of the wage Phillips curve, policy is
noticeably less accommodative and closes the inflation gap two quarters earlier than in
the case in which policymakers place no weight on the unemployment gap with the
standard specification of the wage Phillips curve. The less accommodative policy results
in a smaller undershooting of the natural rate of unemployment and a slightly larger
overshooting of the inflation target. 11
The final exhibit, “Outcomes under Alternative Policies,” tabulates the simulation
results for key variables under dynamic simulations of the FRB/US model for each of the
policy rules shown in the exhibit “Policy Rule Simulations” and for optimal control under
commitment.

10

Under this alternative calibration, a 1 percentage point negative unemployment gap leads to an
immediate increase in annualized nominal wage inflation of 0.06 percentage point. This response is within
two standard deviations of the FRB/US model estimate informed by the 1985–2007 subsample. Using a
different model specification, Kumar and Orrenius (2014) report a significantly larger response of wage
inflation to a fall in the unemployment rate when the unemployment rate is low. A similar alternative
calibration was used for a special exhibit in the Monetary Policy Strategies section of Tealbook B in March
2015.
11
This larger overshooting of the inflation target also implies that the time inconsistency problem
is more severe for policymakers facing the steeper wage Phillips curve.

Page 10 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Outcomes under Alternative Policies
2015

Measure and policy
H1

2016 2017 2018 2019

H2

Real GDP
Extended Tealbook baseline1
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

2.2
1.8
1.8
2.2
2.4
1.9

2.0
2.0
1.9
2.0
2.3
1.8

1.8
1.9
1.8
1.8
2.0
1.7

1.7
1.8
1.8
1.7
1.8
1.7

Unemployment rate2
Extended Tealbook baseline1
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

5.4
5.4
5.4
5.4
5.4
5.4

5.0
5.0
5.0
5.0
5.0
5.0

4.9
5.1
5.1
4.9
4.8
5.0

4.7
4.9
5.0
4.8
4.6
5.0

4.7
4.8
4.9
4.7
4.4
5.0

4.7
4.7
4.8
4.7
4.3
5.0

Total PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline1
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1

0.9
0.9
0.9
0.9
0.9
0.9

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.5
1.3

1.7
1.8
1.7
1.8
1.9
1.7

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1
1.8

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
1.9

Core PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline1
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

1.4
1.5
1.4
1.4
1.6
1.4

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.9
1.6

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1
1.8

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
1.9

Effective nominal federal funds rate2
Extended Tealbook baseline1
Taylor (1993)
Taylor (1999)
Inertial Taylor (1999)
First-difference
Optimal control

0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.1

0.2
2.3
2.2
0.5
0.4
0.5

1.4
2.6
2.6
1.6
1.5
1.9

2.4
3.2
3.3
2.5
2.3
3.1

3.2
3.6
3.8
3.2
3.0
3.9

3.7
3.8
4.0
3.7
3.1
4.3

1. In the Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate first departs from an effective lower bound of 12½ basis points
in December of 2015. Thereafter, the federal funds rate follows the prescriptions of the inertial Taylor (1999) rule.
2. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 11 of 50

Strategies

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Strategies

Appendix
POLICY RULES USED IN “MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES”
The table below gives the expressions for the selected policy rules used in “Monetary
Policy Strategies.” In the table, [math] denotes the effective nominal federal funds rate for quarter t,
while the right-hand-side variables include the staff's projection of trailing four-quarter core PCE
inflation for the current quarter and three quarters ahead [math], the output gap estimate
for the current period [math], and the forecast ofthe three-quarter-ahead annual change in the
output gap [math]. The value of policymakers' longer-run inflation objective, denoted [math], is
2 percent.

Taylor (1993) rule

[math]

Taylor (1999) rule

[math]

Inertial Taylor (1999) rule

[math]

First-difference rule

[math]

The first twoof the selected rules were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999), while the inertial
version of the Taylor (1999) rule has been featured prominently in analysis by Board staff.1 The
intercepts of these rules are chosen so that they are consistent with a 2 percent longer-run
inflation objective and a longer-run real interest rate, denoted [math], of 1 1/4 percent, a value used in
the FRB/US model. The prescriptions of the first-difference rule do not depend onthe levelof
the output gap or the longer-run real interest rate; see Orphanides (2003).
Near-term prescriptions from the four policy rules are calculated using Tealbook
projections for inflation and the output gap. For the rules that include the lagged policy rate as a
right-hand-side variable—the inertial Taylor(1999) rule and the first-difference rule—the lines
labeled “Previous Tealbook outlook” report prescriptions derived from the previous Tealbook
projections for inflation and the output gap, while using the same lagged funds rate value asin the
prescriptions computed for the current Tealbook. When the Tealbook is published early in a
quarter, this lagged funds rate value is set equal tothe actual value of the lagged funds rate in the
previous quarter, and prescriptions are shown for the current quarter. When the Tealbook is
published late in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown forthe next quarter, and the lagged policy
rate, for each of these rules, including those that use the “Previous Tealbook outlook,” is set equal
to the average value for the policy rate thus farinthe quarter. Forthe subsequent quarter, these
rules use the lagged values from their simulated, unconstrained prescriptions.

1 See, for example, Erceg and others (2012).

Page 12 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

The bottom panel of the exhibit “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection” provides an
estimate of one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate, r*. The estimate corresponds to
the level of the real federal funds rate that is consistent with output reaching potential in
12 quarters using an output projection from FRB/US, the staff’s large-scale econometric model of
the U.S. economy. This “Tealbook-consistent” estimate of r* depends on a very broad array of
economic factors, some of which take the form of projected values of the model’s exogenous
variables. It is generated after the paths of exogenous variables in the FRB/US model are
adjusted so that they match those in the extended Tealbook forecast. Model simulations then
determine the value of the real federal funds rate that closes the output gap conditional on the
exogenous variables in the extended baseline forecast.
The estimated current real federal funds rate reported in the panel is constructed as the
difference between the federal funds rate and the trailing four-quarter change in the core PCE
price index. The federal funds rate is specified as the midpoint of the target range for the federal
funds rate on the Tealbook B publication date.
The estimated average projected real federal funds rate reported in the panel is
constructed as the 12-quarter average of the current real federal funds rate described above and its
projections over the next 11 quarters under the Tealbook baseline. This calculation is comparable
to the one used to generate r*. However, while r* and the average projected real federal funds
rate are calculated over the same 12-quarter period, they need not be associated with the same
macroeconomic outcomes even when their values are identical. The reason is that, in the r*
simulations, the real federal funds rate is held constant over the entire 12-quarter period to close
the output gap at the end of this timeframe whereas, in the Tealbook baseline, the real federal
funds rate can vary over time. Distinct paths of real short-term rates can, in turn, generate
differing paths for inflation and economic activity.

FRB/US MODEL SIMULATIONS
The exhibits of “Monetary Policy Strategies” that report results from simulations of
alternative policies are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US model. Each simulated
policy rule is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered by the simulation; this period
extends several decades beyond the time horizon shown in the exhibits. The simulations are
conducted under perfect foresight and are predicated on the staff’s extended Tealbook projection,
which includes the macroeconomic effects of the Committee’s large-scale asset purchase
programs. When the Tealbook is published early in a quarter, all of the simulations begin in that
quarter. However, when the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, all of the simulations begin
in the subsequent quarter.

Page 13 of 50

Strategies

REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE ESTIMATES

Authorized for Public Release

Strategies

COMPUTATION OF THE OPTIMAL CONTROL POLICY UNDER COMMITMENT
The optimal control simulations posit that policymakers minimize a discounted sum of
weighted squared deviations of four-quarter headline PCE inflation [math] from the Committee's
2 percent objective, ofsquared deviations ofthe unemployment rate from the staff's estimate of
the natural rate (this difference is also known as the unemployment rate gap, [math], and of
squared changes in the federal funds rate. The resulting loss function, shown below, embeds the
assumptions that policymakers discount the future using a quarterly discount factor [math] = 0.9963
and placeequal weights on squared deviations of inflation, the unemployment gap, and federal
funds rate changes (that is, [math].
[math]
[math]

[math]

[math]

[math]

The optimal control policyis the path for thefederal funds rate that minimizes theabove
loss function in the FRB/US model, subject to the effective lower bound constraint on nominal
interest rates, under the assumption of perfect foresight, and conditional on the staff's extended
Tealbook projection. Policy tools other than the federal funds rate are taken as given and
subsumed within the Tealbook baseline. The path chosen by policymakers today is assumed to
be credible, meaning that decision makers in the model see this path as being a binding
commitment on the future Committees; the optimal control policytakes as given the lagged value
of the federal funds rate but is otherwise unconstrained by policy decisions made prior to the
simulation period. The discounted losses are calculated over a period that ends sufficiently far
intothe future that extending that period farther would not affectthe policyprescriptions shown
in the exhibits.

References
Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David Lopez-Salido,
Stephen Meyer, Edward Nelson, David Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow (2012). “An
Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in Policymaking in Normal Times and
Under Current Conditions.” Memo sent to the Committee on July 18, 2012.

Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50 (July), pp. 983-1022.

Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretionversus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 195-214.

Taylor, John B. (1999). “A Historical Analysis ofMonetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor,
ed., Monetary Policy Rules. University of Chicago Press, pp. 319-341.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

On the eve of the September FOMC meeting, market participants had placed odds
of about 30 percent on liftoff at that meeting, the highest such reading before any FOMC
meeting in recent years. Against a backdrop of turbulence in financial markets and
concerns about likely and potential spillovers from an economic slowdown in China and
other foreign economies, the Committee decided in September not to change the target
range for the federal funds rate or the forward guidance for when the first increase might
occur. In response, financial market participants shifted expectations about the likely
timing of liftoff toward October and December of this year and later. Following the
September employment report, the perceived probability of liftoff at dates in 2016
increased substantially. Nevertheless, market- and survey-based measures now suggest
that market participants consider the December meeting to be the most likely time of
liftoff, and that they see negligible odds of a rate hike in October.1 Furthermore, the
expected path for the federal funds rate over the next couple of years, derived from
market and survey data, has flattened somewhat. Market participants continue to expect
that normalization of the stance of monetary policy will proceed more gradually than
during the 1994 and 2004 tightening cycles, and more gradually than was anticipated at
the onset of those episodes. Possibly, this shallower path of expected future policy rates
could reflect, at least in part, downward revisions to the path of anticipated equilibrium
real rates as evidenced in the responses to the Desk’s Survey of Primary Dealers and its
Survey of Market Participants.
In its March statement, the Committee introduced two criteria for increasing the
target range: It stated that it wanted to see “further improvement” in the labor market
(amended in July to “some further improvement”) and that it would need to be
“reasonably confident” that inflation will move back to 2 percent over the medium term.
Since then, labor market conditions have improved, on balance, with nonfarm payroll
gains averaging around 190,000 per month and the unemployment rate declining from
5.5 percent in February (the most recent reading available to the Committee in March) to
1

Roughly speaking, futures contracts on the federal funds rate are consistent with mean
probabilities of liftoff in December around 25 percent, while respondents to the Desk’s Survey of Primary
Dealers and Survey of Market Participants on average estimate that probability to be around 35 percent.
The perceived probability of liftoff in March 2016 or later has increased appreciably during the
intermeeting period; the mean probability from the Desk surveys has risen to around 50 percent and the
odds implied by market-based measures have increased to about 60 percent. The “Financial
Developments” section of Tealbook A provides more details.

Page 15 of 50

Alternatives

Monetary Policy Alternatives

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternatives

5.1 percent in August and September. However, the pace of payroll gains slowed to
about 140,000 per month in August and September, and the broad range of labor market
indicators, taken together, showed little, if any, improvement in labor market conditions.
Even though industrial production has been weak and net exports have continued to
decline, real GDP has been expanding at a moderate pace, on average, with notable
strength in domestic final sales, suggesting labor market conditions are likely to continue
to improve. During the intermeeting period, core and headline inflation have continued
to run below 2 percent, and market-based measures of longer-term inflation
compensation declined slightly further, while longer-term survey expectations remained
stable.
The three draft alternative statements presented below—labeled Alternative A,
Alternative B, and Alternative C—offer different assessments of realized and expected
progress toward the Committee’s dual mandate objectives and its two criteria for liftoff,
along with a range of corresponding policy choices. While noting some softness in
recent labor market data, Alternative B would convey that the Committee is less worried
about global economic and financial developments than it was in September. The
Committee would reaffirm that the current target range remains appropriate, and the
liftoff criteria would remain unchanged. However, instead of focusing on “how long to
maintain this target range” (as in recent statements), the Committee would, under
Alternative B, indicate that it will consider whether to increase the target range “later this
year” (or “at its next meeting”), “based on incoming data.” Under Alternative C, the
Committee would state that both of the criteria for raising the federal funds rate have
been met and would therefore announce an increase in the target range; this Alternative
would also indicate that the observed improvement in the labor market this year supports
the Committee’s expectation for a rise in inflation over the medium run. Furthermore,
Alternative C would shift the emphasis of policy communication from “how long to
maintain” the target range to “the timing and size of future adjustments” to the target
range. While that new language would be read, initially, as pointing to the likelihood of
further increases in the target range, it would also allow for reductions in the target range,
if necessary. By contrast, Alternative A would signal that the Committee believes the
conditions for policy firming are unlikely to be met in the near future, primarily because
inflation continues to run appreciably below 2 percent, may well decline further, and now
seems likely to remain below 2 percent longer than previously expected.
Alternative B indicates that recent data suggest that economic activity “has been
expanding at a moderate pace,” and provides a slightly more upbeat assessment of

Page 16 of 50

October 22, 2015

household spending and business fixed investment than in September. The statement for
Alternative B acknowledges that the pace of job gains “slowed” while the unemployment
rate “held steady” but states that, “Nonetheless, labor market indicators, on balance, show
that underutilization of labor resources has diminished since early this year.” Against
these guardedly optimistic descriptions of economic activity and the labor market,
Alternative B observes that inflation “has continued to run below” 2 percent, in part
because of recent and earlier declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy
imports. The statement also recognizes that market-based measures of inflation
compensation “moved lower” or “moved slightly lower” while reiterating that surveybased measures of longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable. Alternative
B leaves the Committee’s characterization of expected economic conditions over the
medium run unchanged relative to September. It downgrades the concerns about the
implications of recent global economic and financial developments expressed in the
September statement, but notes that the Committee “is monitoring” these developments.
Finally, Alternative B points to the possibility of liftoff at the December meeting,
depending on the implications of “incoming data” for realized and expected progress
toward the Committee’s objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation.
Taken as a whole, Alternative B likely would be read by market participants as indicating
that a December liftoff is still on the table but is not locked in.
In Alternative C, the Committee would announce that its criteria for policy
firming have been met and that it is increasing the target range for the federal funds rate
by 25 basis points. The Committee would retain the assessment that economic activity
has been “expanding at a moderate pace.” Moreover, it would upgrade its
characterization of labor market developments, stating that labor market indicators have
shown “further improvement,” which “confirms” that underutilization of labor resources
has diminished “appreciably” since early this year. Alternative C would acknowledge
that inflation “has continued” to run below 2 percent, that it will likely remain low in the
near term, and that market-based measures of inflation compensation “remain near the
low end of the range seen in recent years.” Despite these concerns, the Committee would
emphasize that the factors that have been generating below-target inflation will dissipate,
and that, with the labor market continuing to improve and surveys of longer-term
inflation expectations remaining stable, it is “reasonably confident” that inflation will rise
to 2 percent over the medium term.
Alternative A provides largely the same characterization of recent data on
economic activity, unemployment, and payroll employment as Alternative B. However,

Page 17 of 50

Alternatives

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Alternatives

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternative A notes that net exports and inventory investment have been “a drag on
economic growth” (instead of just net exports having been “soft”). In addition,
Alternative A sees the unemployment rate as having “leveled out.” Also, Alternative A
signals that the Committee is still a long way from being reasonably confident that
inflation will move back to 2 percent over the medium run. In particular, Alternative A
notes that “gains in labor compensation have remained subdued” despite the reduction in
underutilization of labor resources; that “overall and core inflation” have been running
below 2 percent; and that measures of inflation compensation are “at” or “near” multiyear
lows. In response to the lack of progress on the inflation front and the risk that inflation
might linger below the Committee’s objective, Alternative A states that “If incoming
information does not soon indicate that inflation is beginning to move back toward
2 percent, the Committee is prepared to use all tools necessary to return inflation to
2 percent within one to two years.” Alternative A would also indicate that economic and
financial developments abroad have “tilted somewhat to the downside” the risks to the
Committee’s outlook for economic activity and the labor market.
Under Alternative A and Alternative B, the Committee would retain the “balanced
approach” language that it has provided for quite some time to characterize how it plans
to conduct policy once tightening begins. Under Alternative C, the Committee would
state that, in determining future adjustments to the target range, it will assess “realized
and expected economic conditions” relative to its mandated objectives, and that the path
of the federal funds rate will “depend on the incoming data.” This draft statement also
offers the option of indicating that the Committee “will take a balanced approach” to
pursuing its objectives. Regarding the Committee’s balance sheet policies, Alternatives
A and B would continue the Committee’s existing reinvestment policy, while
Alternative C would indicate that the Federal Reserve will continue to roll over maturing
Treasury securities and to reinvest principal payments from its agency debt and
mortgage-backed security holdings “at least during the early stages of normalizing the
level of the federal funds rate.” All three alternatives retain language indicating that,
even once employment and inflation are close to mandate-consistent levels, economic
conditions may, for some time, warrant keeping the federal funds rate below levels the
Committee views as normal in the longer run.
The next pages contain the September postmeeting statement, the three alternative
draft statements, and summaries of the arguments for each alternative statement. These
elements are followed by the draft directive for Alternative A and Alternative B, a draft
“Implementation Note” that includes the directive for Alternative C, as well as a “Desk

Page 18 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternatives

Statement” regarding overnight reverse repurchase operations that would be released
shortly after the FOMC postmeeting statement if the Committee adopted Alternative C.

Page 19 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

.

SEPTEMBER 2015 FOMC STATEMENT

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in July suggests
that economic activity is expanding at a moderate pace. Household spending and
business fixed investment have been increasing moderately, and the housing sector
has improved further; however, net exports have been soft. The labor market
continued to improve, with solid job gains and declining unemployment. On balance,
labor market indicators show that underutilization of labor resources has diminished
since early this year. Inflation has continued to run below the Committee’s longerrun objective, partly reflecting declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy
imports. Market-based measures of inflation compensation moved lower; surveybased measures of longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. Recent global economic and financial developments
may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward
pressure on inflation in the near term. Nonetheless, the Committee expects that, with
appropriate policy accommodation, economic activity will expand at a moderate pace,
with labor market indicators continuing to move toward levels the Committee judges
consistent with its dual mandate. The Committee continues to see the risks to the
outlook for economic activity and the labor market as nearly balanced but is
monitoring developments abroad. Inflation is anticipated to remain near its recent
low level in the near term but the Committee expects inflation to rise gradually
toward 2 percent over the medium term as the labor market improves further and the
transitory effects of declines in energy and import prices dissipate. The Committee
continues to monitor inflation developments closely.
3. To support continued progress toward maximum employment and price stability, the
Committee today reaffirmed its view that the current 0 to ¼ percent target range for
the federal funds rate remains appropriate. In determining how long to maintain this
target range, the Committee will assess progress—both realized and expected—
toward its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation. This
assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including measures of
labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation expectations,
and readings on financial and international developments. The Committee anticipates
that it will be appropriate to raise the target range for the federal funds rate when it
has seen some further improvement in the labor market and is reasonably confident
that inflation will move back to its 2 percent objective over the medium term.
4. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of longer-term securities
at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative financial conditions.
5. When the Committee decides to begin to remove policy accommodation, it will take a
balanced approach consistent with its longer-run goals of maximum employment and
inflation of 2 percent. The Committee currently anticipates that, even after

Page 20 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternatives

employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels, economic conditions
may, for some time, warrant keeping the target federal funds rate below levels the
Committee views as normal in the longer run.

Page 21 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

ALTERNATIVE A FOR OCTOBER 2015

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in July
September suggests that economic activity is has been expanding at a moderate
pace. Household spending and business fixed investment have been increasing
moderately at solid rates in recent months, and the housing sector has improved
further; however, net exports have been soft and inventory investment have been a
drag on economic growth. The labor market continued to improve, with solid job
gains and declining unemployment. On balance, labor market indicators show that
underutilization of labor resources has diminished since early this year, but the pace
of job gains has slowed and the unemployment rate has leveled out. Both overall
and core inflation has have continued to run below the Committee’s longer-run
objective, partly reflecting declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy
imports. Market-based measures of inflation compensation moved lower are [ at |
near ] multiyear lows; survey-based measures of longer-term inflation expectations
have remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. Recent global economic and financial developments
may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward
pressure on inflation in the near term. Nonetheless, the Committee expects that, with
appropriate policy accommodation, economic activity will expand at a moderate pace,
with labor market indicators continuing to move toward levels the Committee judges
consistent with its dual mandate. However, in light of economic and financial
developments abroad, the Committee continues to see sees the risks to the outlook
for economic activity and the labor market as nearly balanced tilted somewhat to the
downside but is monitoring developments abroad. Inflation is anticipated to remain
near its recent low level in the near term but the Committee expects inflation to rise
gradually toward 2 percent over the medium term as the labor market improves
further and the transitory effects of declines in energy and import prices dissipate.
The Committee continues to monitor inflation developments closely.
3. To support continued progress toward maximum employment and price stability
With inflation, core inflation, and gains in labor compensation all subdued, and
with market-based measures of inflation compensation very low, the Committee
today reaffirmed its view judges that the current 0 to ¼ percent target range for the
federal funds rate remains appropriate. In determining how long to maintain this
target range, the Committee will assess progress—both realized and expected—
toward its objectives of maximum employment and 2 percent inflation. This
assessment will take into account a wide range of information, including measures of
labor market conditions, indicators of inflation pressures and inflation expectations,
and readings on financial and international developments. The Committee anticipates
that it will be appropriate to raise the target range for the federal funds rate when it
has seen some further improvement in the labor market and is reasonably confident
that inflation will move back to its 2 percent objective over the medium term. If
incoming information does not soon indicate that inflation is beginning to move
back toward 2 percent, the Committee is prepared to use all tools necessary to
return inflation to 2 percent within one to two years.

Page 22 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

4. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of longer-term securities
at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative financial conditions.

Alternatives

5. When the Committee decides to begin to remove policy accommodation, it will take a
balanced approach consistent with its longer-run goals of maximum employment and
inflation of 2 percent. The Committee currently anticipates that, even after
employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels, economic conditions
may, for some time, warrant keeping the target federal funds rate below levels the
Committee views as normal in the longer run.

Page 23 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

ALTERNATIVE B FOR OCTOBER 2015

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in July
September suggests that economic activity is has been expanding at a moderate
pace. Household spending and business fixed investment have been increasing
moderately at solid rates in recent months, and the housing sector has improved
further; however, net exports have been soft. The labor market continued to improve,
with solid pace of job gains slowed and declining the unemployment rate held
steady. On balance Nonetheless, labor market indicators, on balance, show that
underutilization of labor resources has diminished since early this year. Inflation has
continued to run below the Committee’s longer-run objective, partly reflecting
declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy imports. Market-based
measures of inflation compensation moved [ slightly ] lower; survey-based measures
of longer-term inflation expectations have remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. Recent global economic and financial developments
may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward
pressure on inflation in the near term. Nonetheless, The Committee expects that, with
appropriate policy accommodation, economic activity will expand at a moderate pace,
with labor market indicators continuing to move toward levels the Committee judges
consistent with its dual mandate. The Committee continues to see the risks to the
outlook for economic activity and the labor market as nearly balanced but is
monitoring global economic and financial developments abroad. Inflation is
anticipated to remain near its recent low level in the near term but the Committee
expects inflation to rise gradually toward 2 percent over the medium term as the labor
market improves further and the transitory effects of declines in energy and import
prices dissipate. The Committee continues to monitor inflation developments closely.
3. To support continued progress toward maximum employment and price stability, the
Committee today reaffirmed its view that the current 0 to ¼ percent target range for
the federal funds rate remains appropriate. In determining how long to maintain this
target range whether it will be appropriate to raise the target range [ later this
year | at its next meeting ], the Committee will, based on incoming data, assess
progress—both realized and expected—toward its objectives of maximum
employment and 2 percent inflation. This assessment will take into account a wide
range of information, including measures of labor market conditions, indicators of
inflation pressures and inflation expectations, and readings on financial and
international developments. The Committee anticipates that it will be appropriate to
raise the target range for the federal funds rate when it has seen some further
improvement in the labor market and is reasonably confident that inflation will move
back to its 2 percent objective over the medium term.
4. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s holdings of longer-term securities
at sizable levels, should help maintain accommodative financial conditions.

Page 24 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternatives

5. When the Committee decides to begin to remove policy accommodation, it will take a
balanced approach consistent with its longer-run goals of maximum employment and
inflation of 2 percent. The Committee currently anticipates that, even after
employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels, economic conditions
may, for some time, warrant keeping the target federal funds rate below levels the
Committee views as normal in the longer run.

Page 25 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

ALTERNATIVE C FOR OCTOBER 2015

Alternatives

1. Information received since the Federal Open Market Committee met in July
September suggests that economic activity is has been expanding at a moderate
pace. Household spending and business fixed investment have been increasing
moderately at solid rates in recent months, and the housing sector has improved
further; however, net exports have been soft. The labor market continued to improve,
with solid job gains and declining unemployment. On balance, labor market
indicators show A range of recent labor market indicators, including ongoing job
gains, shows further improvement and confirms that underutilization of labor
resources has diminished appreciably since early this year. Inflation has continued
to run below the Committee’s longer-run objective, partly reflecting declines in
energy prices and in prices of non-energy imports. Although market-based measures
of inflation compensation moved lower; remain near the low end of the range seen
in recent years, survey-based measures of longer-term inflation expectations have
remained stable.
2. Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Committee seeks to foster maximum
employment and price stability. Recent global economic and financial developments
may restrain economic activity somewhat and are likely to put further downward
pressure on inflation in the near term. Nonetheless, The Committee expects that, with
appropriate adjustments in the stance of monetary policy accommodation,
economic activity will expand at a moderate pace, with and labor market indicators
continuing to move toward will reach levels the Committee judges consistent with its
dual mandate. The Committee continues to see sees the risks to the outlook for both
economic activity and the labor market as nearly balanced but is monitoring
developments abroad. Inflation is anticipated to remain near its recent low level in
the near term, reflecting declines in energy prices and in prices of non-energy
imports, but the transitory effects on inflation of these declines will dissipate.
With the labor market continuing to improve, and with survey measures of
longer-term inflation expectations remaining stable, the Committee expects is
reasonably confident that inflation to will rise gradually toward to 2 percent over
the medium term. as the labor market improves further and the transitory effects of
declines in energy and import prices dissipate. The Committee continues to monitor
inflation developments closely.
3. To support continued progress toward maximum employment and price stability, the
Committee today reaffirmed its view that the current 0 to ¼ percent target range for
the federal funds rate remains appropriate. In light of the improvement in labor
market conditions this year, and the Committee’s expectation that inflation will
rise, over the medium term, to its 2 percent objective, the Committee decided to
raise the target range for the federal funds rate to ¼ to ½ percent.
4. In determining how long to maintain this the timing and size of future adjustments
to the target range, the Committee will assess progress—both realized and
expected—toward economic conditions relative to its objectives of maximum
employment and 2 percent inflation [ , and will take a balanced approach to
pursuing those objectives ]. This assessment will take into account a wide range of
information, including measures of labor market conditions, indicators of inflation

Page 26 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

5. The Committee is maintaining its existing policy of reinvesting principal payments
from its holdings of agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency
mortgage-backed securities and of rolling over maturing Treasury securities at
auction, and anticipates doing so at least during the early stages of normalizing
the level of the federal funds rate. This policy, by keeping the Committee’s
holdings of longer-term securities at sizable levels, should help maintain
accommodative financial conditions.
6. When the Committee decides to begin to remove policy accommodation, it will take a
balanced approach consistent with its longer-run goals of maximum employment and
inflation of 2 percent.

The directive for Alternative C appears later in this section of Tealbook B as part of a
draft “Implementation Note” that would be released as an addendum to the Committee’s
postmeeting statement at the time of liftoff. That directive directs the Desk to undertake
open market operations as necessary to maintain the federal funds rate in the new ¼ to
½ percent target range, including overnight reverse repurchase operations at an offering
rate of 0.25 percent “and in amounts limited only by the value of Treasury securities held
outright in the System Open Market Account that are available for such operations.”
The Implementation Note is followed by a draft of a Desk statement regarding overnight
reverse repurchase agreements that provides an estimate of “the value of Treasury
securities held outright in the System Open Market Account” that will be available to
support reverse repurchase operations in the aftermath of the initial increase in the
target range. If the Committee adopts Alternative C, the Desk would release that
statement shortly after the FOMC issues its postmeeting statement.

Page 27 of 50

Alternatives

pressures and inflation expectations, and readings on financial and international
developments. The Committee anticipates that it will be appropriate to raise the
target range for the federal funds rate when it has seen some further improvement in
the labor market and is reasonably confident that inflation will move back to its 2
percent objective over the medium term. The Committee currently anticipates that,
even after employment and inflation are near mandate-consistent levels, economic
conditions may, for some time, warrant keeping the target federal funds rate below
levels the Committee views as normal in the longer run; however, the actual path of
the target for the federal funds rate will depend on the incoming data.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternatives

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE B
The Committee might see information received during the intermeeting period as
suggesting a continuation of moderate growth in real GDP, supported by solid gains in
household spending, business investment, and the housing sector, but with ongoing drag
from the external sector. In the labor market, while gains in payroll employment slowed
somewhat over the last two months, other indicators—the number of people who were
unemployed for 15 weeks or longer and who were employed part time for economic
reasons, in particular—showed further improvement, and the unemployment rate
continues to lie in the central tendency of FOMC participants’ assessment of its longerrun normal level as reported in the September Summary of Economic Projections.
Nonetheless, the Committee may see room for further improvement in the labor market
along margins such as labor force participation or the number of persons employed part
time for economic reasons, and may judge that such a reduction in labor underutilization
will help speed the return of inflation to the 2 percent objective. Furthermore,
policymakers may judge that headline inflation is likely to remain below 2 percent for a
while, and they may remain concerned that the tightening in domestic financial
conditions over the last few months, in conjunction with recent global financial
developments related to worries about economic activity in emerging markets, may put
downward pressure on U.S. inflation in the near term through their influence on
commodity prices and the exchange rate. Although policymakers may expect the effects
of foreign developments on the U.S. economy to be limited, they might still want to see
whether the data that will be released during the coming intermeeting period appear
consistent with their projections that the economic expansion will support further
improvement in the labor market and that inflation will return to 2 percent over the
medium term. For these reasons, participants may deem it appropriate to continue a
meeting-by-meeting approach and preserve policy options going forward. If so, they may
choose to issue a statement like Alternative B, which acknowledges the positive data on
spending and investment, notes steady labor market conditions and remaining concerns
about foreign developments, and reaffirms the Committee’s medium-run outlook and
characterization of associated risks.
With the unemployment rate at 5.1 percent, some policymakers may judge that
the economy is already at maximum sustainable employment. With moderate growth in
real GDP and appreciable improvement in labor market conditions since earlier this year,
these policymakers may deem it likely that a solid economic expansion is under way,
which, together with stable longer-run inflation expectations, should move inflation back

Page 28 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Other participants may be concerned that inflation will not move back to
2 percent over the medium term, perhaps because they judge that there is still appreciable
slack in labor markets and anticipate only a slow reduction in that slack. Alternatively,
they may point out that substantial improvement in labor markets over the past few years
has not prevented inflation compensation from falling, and argue that the seemingly low
sensitivity of price and wage inflation to slack might require a period of unemployment
well below its longer-run normal rate to ensure a return of inflation to the Committee’s
longer-run goal. And with U.S. financial conditions somewhat tighter than earlier this
year and foreign demand for U.S. exports likely to remain weak, some participants may
see a non-negligible probability that the Committee will eventually need to provide
further policy accommodation to achieve its mandate. These participants may
nonetheless judge that, with GDP expanding moderately and the labor market improving,
it would be premature to announce additional stimulus. Moreover, they may take some
reassurance from the observation that survey measures of longer-term inflation
expectations remain within the range observed in recent years. These policymakers may
thus choose to forego additional accommodation for now, but be alert to the possibility
that the economy might require further support at a later date.
Respondents to the Desk’s Survey of Primary Dealers and its Survey of Market
Participants currently perceive only a negligible probability that the Committee will raise
the target range for the federal funds rate in October, but they see a 35 percent chance of
liftoff in December and see the December meeting as the most likely time of liftoff.
While most respondents expect only small changes to the Committee’s statement and its
forward guidance, many expect the Committee to downgrade its assessment of labor
market conditions a little and to acknowledge an increase in downside risks to the outlook
for economic growth. Accordingly, market participants could read a statement like

Page 29 of 50

Alternatives

to 2 percent over the medium term. But with both headline and core inflation still
running below the Committee’s objective, the softening in the most recent readings of
payroll gains and retail sales, and remaining concerns about the risks for domestic
economic activity posed by global economic and financial developments, policymakers
may prefer to monitor economic data a little longer before taking the first step in raising
rates. Moreover, signs of excessive risk-taking are not widespread, and indicators of
leverage and of reliance on short-term financing instruments have, to date, remained at
moderate levels. Policymakers might therefore judge that a statement like Alternative B,
including the new language in paragraph 3, preserves the Committee’s ability to tighten
policy at upcoming meetings without appreciably elevating the risks to financial stability.

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Alternative B, especially the new language in paragraph 3, as suggesting a somewhat
higher likelihood of liftoff at the December meeting than they currently perceive. To the
extent that statement language as in Alternative B raises the perceived likelihood that
policy firming will begin before the end of the year, medium- and longer-term real
interest rates might rise somewhat, and the dollar could appreciate a bit. If investors read
the statement as suggesting more confidence in economic conditions, equity prices and
inflation compensation might rise; otherwise they might fall.

Alternatives

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE C
Policymakers may view the ongoing job gains and the improvements in a range of
labor market indicators, as well as solid consumer spending, the pickup in business fixed
investment, and improvements in the housing sector as confirmation that recent global
economic and financial developments are not putting in jeopardy the expansion currently
under way in the domestic economy. Furthermore, with the unemployment rate at
5.1 percent, policymakers may conclude that slack in the labor market has essentially
been absorbed and that tighter resource utilization will soon begin to put at least some
upward pressure on inflation. Policymakers may be reasonably certain that, with stable
longer-run inflation expectations and the recent uptick in core inflation, headline inflation
will move back to the Committee’s 2 percent objective over the medium term as the
downward pressure on domestic consumer prices from the pass-through of broad-based
declines in global commodity prices and appreciation of the dollar dissipates. That is,
policymakers might view the two criteria for policy firming introduced in the
Committee’s March statement and amended during the summer as having been met. In
addition, policymakers may note that, for about a year now, most of the simple policy
rules and the optimal control simulations in the “Monetary Policy Strategies” section of
Tealbook B have called for policy tightening to begin. Therefore, they may support
Alternative C, which announces a 25 basis point increase in the target range for the
federal funds rate to ¼ to ½ percent.
Given the lags in the transmission of monetary policy, some policymakers may be
concerned that delaying the initial firming of policy any longer could unduly raise the
risks of overshooting the Committee’s maximum employment and 2 percent inflation
objectives. They may expect that, with the economy at or near full employment, wage
pressures will build, contributing to a fairly prompt increase in inflation to 2 percent or
higher. Because trend productivity growth appears to have stepped down from its

Page 30 of 50

October 22, 2015

pre-crisis value, some policymakers may argue that price and wage pressures could arise
even if economic activity were to continue to expand at what is a modest pace by
historical standards. Some policymakers may be particularly concerned that, if the
unemployment rate is allowed to undershoot its longer-run normal level appreciably,
inflation could rise persistently above 2 percent—for example, along the lines of the
alternative scenario “Fast Growth with Higher Inflation” in the “Risks and Uncertainty”
section of Tealbook A—and seemingly well-anchored longer-run inflation expectations
could begin drifting up. Moreover, some policymakers might judge that delaying
tightening longer will make it necessary to raise the federal funds rate rapidly in the
future to prevent too-high inflation, and that a steeper path for the policy rate would
increase the risks of a period of very slow economic growth and rising unemployment.
Policymakers might also worry that further delaying the firming of policy could
exacerbate risks to financial stability. In particular, they may see the path for the federal
funds rate currently expected by market participants as too shallow, a situation that could
leave leveraged investors unduly exposed should interest rates rise faster than they
anticipated. Although these risks may not feature prominently in policymakers’ baseline
forecasts, they might judge that the adverse consequences would be sufficiently severe to
justify policy firming at this time.
According to the Desk’s Survey of Primary Dealers and its Survey of Market
Participants, the average of respondents’ perceptions of the probability of tightening at
this meeting is slightly below 5 percent. A decision to increase the target range at this
meeting would thus be surprising. Medium- and longer-term real interest rates would
most likely rise, equity prices and inflation compensation would likely decline, and the
dollar would appreciate. If market participants conclude that the Committee is intent on
pursuing a less accommodative stance of policy going forward than had been expected,
then the market reaction could be sizable. However, if investors see a statement like
Alternative C as reflecting a more upbeat assessment for global economic conditions,
then equity prices and inflation compensation might increase.

THE CASE FOR ALTERNATIVE A
Some policymakers may see substantial risk that inflation will not rise over the
medium term to the Committee’s longer-run goal. Both core and headline inflation have
run below 2 percent over the past few years, and continued declines in global commodity
prices, along with downward pressure on import prices from the appreciation of the

Page 31 of 50

Alternatives

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Alternatives

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

dollar, suggest that headline inflation will linger at very low levels well into 2016.
Furthermore, these policymakers may point to the absence of broad-based wage
pressures, and the depressed labor force participation rate, as evidence that, in the current
environment, measures of the unemployment rate understate the amount of slack in the
labor market. In addition, they may consider the slowing job gains in recent months and
disappointing data on retail sales in September as signs of some loss of momentum in the
economy. Overall, these policymakers may see average GDP growth during this
economic recovery as having been lackluster, and judge that the already prolonged period
of low inflation indicates that the economic expansion is not sufficiently robust to support
further improvement in the labor market and raise inflation to 2 percent. Some
policymakers may also point to the fact that a number of survey-based measures of
longer-run inflation expectations have been clustering on the low end of their historical
ranges, and that measures of inflation compensation are close to multiyear lows, as signs
that the credibility of the FOMC’s commitment to achieving 2 percent inflation is at risk.
Moreover, for some policymakers, mounting concerns about a slowdown in the
global economy might have tilted to the downside their perception of the balance of risks
to the outlook for the economic activity and the labor market. These policymakers may
worry that deteriorating financial conditions and consumer confidence in China could
cause a marked slowdown in real output growth throughout Asia, which would then
lower the demand for U.S. exports and cause the dollar to appreciate. In fact, these
policymakers may point to disappointing incoming data on economic activity in
emerging markets and declines in commodity prices as a sign that global demand is
already weakening. Additionally, these policymakers may fear a resurgence of financial
stresses in Europe and beyond. As such, they might see the alternative scenarios
“Emerging Market Economy Slump” or “Financial Turbulence” in the “Risks and
Uncertainty” section of Tealbook A as encompassing some of the risks that they have in
mind. If either scenario plays out, policymakers may judge that the Federal Reserve will
need to provide greater policy accommodation in order to offset the likely adverse effects
on the domestic economy. Participants might therefore favor including language as in the
second paragraph of Alternative A, which indicates that, “in light of economic and
financial developments abroad, the Committee sees the risks to the outlook for economic
activity and the labor market as tilted somewhat to the downside.”
For all the above reasons, some policymakers may see the unemployment rate
falling below its longer-run normal level for a while as desirable to achieve the dual
mandate and thus may want to offer a more stringent criterion for policy firming than

Page 32 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

No respondent to the Desk’s Survey of Primary Dealers or its Survey of Market
Participants anticipates that the Committee would indicate the possibility of greater
accommodation. In response to a statement along the lines of Alternative A, investors
would likely push out their expectations about the most probable date of the first increase
in the target range for the federal funds rate; they would also likely revise down their
expectations of how quickly the Committee will raise the target range thereafter. Longerterm real yields would likely decline, and equity prices and inflation compensation could
rise. However, if investors see a statement like Alternative A as reflecting a downbeat
assessment for global economic conditions, equity prices and inflation compensation
might increase less than otherwise, or even fall.

Page 33 of 50

Alternatives

those in past FOMC statements and in Alternative B. Furthermore, they may support a
statement like Alternative A, which emphasizes that the Committee “is prepared to use all
tools necessary” to achieve its inflation objective within one to two years if “incoming
information does not soon indicate that inflation is beginning to move back toward
2 percent.”

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

SEPTEMBER 2015 DIRECTIVE
Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Federal Open Market Committee seeks
monetary and financial conditions that will foster maximum employment and price
stability. In particular, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
undertake open market operations as necessary to maintain such conditions. The
Committee directs the Desk to maintain its policy of rolling over maturing Treasury
securities into new issues and its policy of reinvesting principal payments on all agency
debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities. The
Committee also directs the Desk to engage in dollar roll and coupon swap transactions as

Alternatives

necessary to facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve’s agency mortgage-backed
securities transactions. The System Open Market Account manager and the secretary
will keep the Committee informed of ongoing developments regarding the System’s
balance sheet that could affect the attainment over time of the Committee’s objectives of
maximum employment and price stability.

Page 34 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

DIRECTIVE FOR OCTOBER 2015 ALTERNATIVE A AND ALTERNATIVE B
Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Federal Open Market Committee seeks
monetary and financial conditions that will foster maximum employment and price
stability. In particular, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. The Committee directs the Desk to
undertake open market operations as necessary to maintain such conditions. The
Committee directs the Desk to maintain its policy of rolling over maturing Treasury
securities into new issues and its policy of reinvesting principal payments on all agency
debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgage-backed securities. The
Committee also directs the Desk to engage in dollar roll and coupon swap transactions as
securities transactions. The System Open Market Account manager and the secretary
will keep the Committee informed of ongoing developments regarding the System’s
balance sheet that could affect the attainment over time of the Committee’s objectives of
maximum employment and price stability.

Page 35 of 50

Alternatives

necessary to facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve’s agency mortgage-backed

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

IMPLEMENTATION NOTE AND DESK STATEMENT FOR OCTOBER 2015
ALTERNATIVE C
The draft directive for Alternative C, which raises the target range, is included in
an implementation note, shown on the next page, that would be released with the
FOMC’s policy statement to communicate actions the Federal Reserve was taking to
implement the Committee’s decision.1 This implementation note is the same as the note
that was shown in the July Tealbook for Alternative C, except that the dates have been
changed from July to October. (Struck-out text indicates language deleted from the
current directive; bold-red-underlined text indicates language added to the current
directive.) The Desk would release, separately, a statement regarding overnight reverse

Alternatives

repurchase agreements; a draft of the Desk statement is shown on a following page.

1

The July Tealbook was the first to include a draft implementation note for Alternative C, and that
Tealbook included some explanatory information regarding the evolution of the text of the note since it was
first proposed to the Committee in June (see the memo sent to the Committee on June 10, 2015, titled
“Proposal for Communicating Details Regarding the Implementation of Monetary Policy at Liftoff and
After” by Deborah Leonard and Gretchen Weinbach).

Page 36 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Implementation Note for October 2015 Alternative C

The Federal Reserve has taken the following actions to implement the monetary policy stance
adopted and announced by the Federal Open Market Committee on October 28, 2015:
 The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System voted [ unanimously ] to raise the
interest rate paid on required and excess reserve balances to [ 0.50 ] percent, effective
October 29, 2015.
 As part of its policy decision, the Federal Open Market Committee voted to authorize and
direct the Open Market Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, until instructed
otherwise, to execute transactions in the System Open Market Account in accordance
with the following domestic policy directive:
“Consistent with its statutory mandate, the Federal Open Market Committee seeks
monetary and financial conditions that will foster maximum employment and price
stability. In particular, the Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with
federal funds trading in a range from 0 to ¼ percent. Effective October 29, 2015, the
Committee directs the Desk to undertake open market operations as necessary to maintain
such conditions the federal funds rate in a target range of [ ¼ to ½ ] percent,
including: (1) overnight reverse repurchase operations (and reverse repurchase
operations with maturities of more than one day when necessary to accommodate
weekend, holiday, or similar trading conventions) at an offering rate of [ 0.25 ]
percent and in amounts limited only by the value of Treasury securities held
outright in the System Open Market Account that are available for such operations;
and (2) term reverse repurchase operations as authorized in the resolution on term
RRP operations approved by the Committee at its March 17–18, 2015, meeting.
“The Committee directs the Desk to maintain its policy of continue rolling over maturing
Treasury securities into new issues and its policy of to continue reinvesting principal
payments on all agency debt and agency mortgage-backed securities in agency mortgagebacked securities. The Committee also directs the Desk to engage in dollar roll and
coupon swap transactions as necessary to facilitate settlement of the Federal Reserve’s
agency mortgage-backed securities transactions.” The System Open Market Account
manager and the secretary will keep the Committee informed of ongoing developments
regarding the System’s balance sheet that could affect the attainment over time of the
Committee’s objectives of maximum employment and price stability.
More information regarding open market operations may be found on the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York’s website.1


The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System voted [ unanimously ] to approve
a [ ¼ ] percentage point increase in the primary credit rate to [ 1.00 ] percent, effective
October 29, 2015. In taking this action, the Board approved requests submitted by the
Boards of Directors of the Federal Reserve Banks of….

This information will be updated as appropriate to reflect decisions of the Federal
Open Market Committee or the Board of Governors regarding details of the Federal
Reserve’s operational tools and approach used to implement monetary policy.
1

When this document is released to the public, the blue text will be a link to the relevant page on
the FRBNY website.

Page 37 of 50

Alternatives

Release Date: October 28, 2015
Actions to Implement Monetary Policy

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Desk Statement for October 2015 Alternative C
Release Date: October 28, 2015
Statement Regarding Overnight Reverse Repurchase Agreements

Alternatives

During its meeting on October 27-28, 2015, the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) authorized and directed the Open Market Trading Desk (the Desk) at the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, effective October 29, 2015, to undertake open
market operations as necessary to maintain the federal funds rate in a target range of ¼ to
½ percent, including overnight reverse repurchase operations (ON RRPs) at an offering
rate of 0.25 percent and in amounts limited only by the value of Treasury securities held
outright in the System Open Market Account (SOMA) that are available for such
operations.
To determine the value of Treasury securities available for such operations, several
factors need to be taken into account, as not all Treasury securities held outright in the
SOMA will be available for use in ON RRP operations. First, some of the Treasury
securities held outright in the SOMA are needed to conduct reverse repurchase
agreements with foreign official and international accounts.1 Second, some Treasury
securities are needed to support the securities lending operations2 conducted by the Desk.
Additionally, buffers are needed to provide for possible changes in demand for these
activities and for possible changes in the market value of the SOMA’s holdings of
Treasury securities.
After estimating the effects of these factors, the Desk anticipates that around $2 trillion of
Treasury securities will be available for ON RRP operations to fulfill the FOMC’s
domestic policy directive.3 In the highly unlikely event that the value of bids received in
an ON RRP operation exceeds the amount of available collateral, the Desk will allocate
awards using a single-price auction based on the “stop-out” rate at which the overall size
limit is reached, with all bids below this rate awarded in full at the stop-out rate and all
bids at this rate awarded on a pro rata basis at the stop-out rate.
The operations will be open to all eligible RRP counterparties, will settle same-day, and
will have an overnight tenor unless a longer term is warranted to accommodate weekend,
holiday, and similar trading conventions. Each day, individual counterparties are
permitted to submit one proposition in a size not to exceed $30 billion and at a rate not to
exceed the specified offering rate. The operations will take place from 12:45 p.m. to
1:15 p.m. (Eastern Time). Any changes to these terms will be announced with at least
one business day’s prior notice on the New York Fed’s website.
The results of these operations will be posted on the New York Fed’s website. The
outstanding amount of RRPs is reported on the Federal Reserve’s H.4.1 statistical release
as a factor absorbing reserves in Table 1 and as a liability item in Tables 5 and 6.

The outstanding amount of RRPs with foreign official and international accounts is
reported as a factor absorbing reserves in Table 1 in the Federal Reserve’s H.4.1 statistical release
and as a liability item in Tables 5 and 6 of that release.
1

2

When this document is released to the public, the blue text will be a link to the relevant page on
the FRBNY website.

This amount will be reduced by any term RRP operations outstanding at the time of
each ON RRP operation.
3

Page 38 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Projections
BALANCE SHEET, INCOME, AND MONETARY BASE
The staff has developed a projection of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and
income statement that is broadly consistent with the monetary policy assumptions
incorporated in the staff’s forecast presented in Tealbook A. We assume that the
Committee will decide to commence policy normalization at its December meeting and
that reinvestments of maturing Treasury securities and the reinvestment of principal
received on agency debt and agency MBS will continue through the second quarter of
2016. Once reinvestments cease, the SOMA portfolio shrinks through redemptions of
maturing Treasury and agency debt securities as well as paydowns of principal from
agency MBS. Regarding the Federal Reserve’s use of its policy normalization tools, we
assume that the level of overnight reverse repurchase agreements (ON RRPs) runs at
$100 billion through the end of 2018 and then falls to zero by the end of 2019, and that
term deposits and term RRPs are not used during the normalization period. 1,2 The bullets
below highlight some key features of the projections for the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet and income statement under these assumptions.
•

Balance sheet. As shown in the exhibit “Total Assets and Selected Balance Sheet
second quarter of 2021, nearly unchanged from the September Tealbook. 3 Once
reserve balances reach their steady-state level, total assets stand at $2.4 trillion,
with about $2.2 trillion in total SOMA securities holdings. Total assets and
SOMA holdings increase thereafter, keeping pace with growth in currency in
circulation and Federal Reserve Bank capital and surplus.

•

Federal Reserve remittances. The exhibit “Income Projections” shows the
implications of the balance sheet projection and interest rate assumptions for
1

Use of term RRPs or term deposits would result in a shift in the composition of Federal Reserve
liabilities—a decline in reserve balances and an equal increase in term RRPs or term deposits—but would
not produce an overall change in the size of the balance sheet.
2
We also assume that RRPs associated with foreign official and international accounts remain
around (their September 30, 2015 level of) $191 billion throughout the projection period.
3
The size of the balance sheet is considered normalized when reserve balances reach an assumed
$100 billion steady-state level.

Page 39 of 50

Projections

Items” and in the table that follows, the size of the portfolio is normalized in the

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Total Assets and Selected Balance Sheet Items
October Tealbook

Total Assets

September Tealbook

Reserve Balances
Billions of dollars

Monthly

Billions of dollars

5500

Monthly

3500

5000
3000
4500
4000

2500

3500
2000

3000
2500

1500

2000
1000

1500
1000

500
500
0

SOMA Treasury Holdings

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

SOMA Agency MBS Holdings
Billions of dollars

Monthly

3000

Billions of dollars

Monthly

2200
2000

2500

1800
1600

2000

1400
1200

1500
1000
800
1000
600
400

500

200
0

Page 40 of 50

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

2010

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

0
2010

Projections

2012

2010

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

2010

0

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
End-of-Year Projections -- October Tealbook
(Billions of dollars)

Sep 30, 2015
Total assets

4,484

2015

2017

2019

2021

2023

2025

4,444 3,891 2,829 2,404 2,596 2,812

Selected assets
Loans and other credit extensions*
Securities held outright
U.S. Treasury securities

3

0

0

0

0

0

4,238

4,216 3,698 2,666 2,263 2,466 2,691

2,462

2,462 2,198 1,442 1,261 1,651 2,034

Agency debt securities
Agency mortgage-backed securities

0

35
1,741

33

4

2

2

2

2

1,721 1,495 1,222

999

813

655

Unamortized premiums

194

189

151

117

93

81

71

Unamortized discounts

-17

-17

-13

-10

-8

-7

-6

47

48

48

48

48

48

48

Total other assets

Total liabilities

4,426

4,385 3,822 2,742 2,295 2,457 2,637

1,342

1,370 1,544 1,702 1,841 2,004 2,184

Federal Reserve notes in circulation
Reverse repurchase agreements
Deposits with Federal Reserve Banks
Reserve balances held by depository institutions
U.S. Treasury, General Account

641

291

291

191

191

191

191

2,435

2,718 1,982

843

256

256

256

2,198

2,561 1,825

687

100

100

100

199

150

150

150

150

150

150

38

6

6

6

6

6

6

2

0

0

0

0

0

0

59

59

68

86

109

138

175

Other deposits
Interest on Federal Reserve Notes due to U.S.
Treasury

Total capital

Source: Federal Reserve H.4.1 statistical releases and staff calculations.
Note: Components may not sum to totals due to rounding.
*Loans and other credit extensions includes primary, secondary, and seasonal credit; central bank liquidity swaps; and net portfolio holdings of Maiden Lane LLC.

Page 41 of 50

Projections

Selected liabilities

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Income Projections

October Tealbook

Interest Income

Interest Expense

60

60

40

40

20

20

0

0

Billions of dollars

140

Annual

140
120

40

20

20

0

0

−20

−20

Memo: Unrealized Gains/Losses
Billions of dollars

Page 42 of 50

2024

2022

2020

2018

End of year

2016

120
110
100
90
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

End of year

2012

Billions of dollars

2014

Deferred Asset

2024

40

2022

60

2020

60

2018

80

2016

80

2014

100

2012

100

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

120

2014

2024

80

2022

80

2020

100

2018

100

2016

120

2012

Annual

2014

140

Remittances to Treasury
Billions of dollars

2012

Annual

120

Realized Capital Gains

2012

Billions of dollars

140

2024

2022

2020

2018

2016

2014

2012

Annual

2014

Billions of dollars

Projections

September Tealbook

400
300
200
100
0
−100
−200
−300
−400
−500
−600

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Federal Reserve income. 4 Remittances to the Treasury are projected to be about
$98 billion this year, close to their $100 billion peak in 2014, and then to decline
further over the next few years. Annual remittances reach their trough of roughly
$30 billion in 2019; no deferred asset is recorded. 5 The Federal Reserve’s
cumulative remittances from 2009 through 2025 are about $1 trillion,
approximately $250 billion above the staff estimate of the amount that would
have been observed had there been no asset purchase programs; the projection for
cumulative remittances is nearly unchanged from the September Tealbook
projection. 6
•

Unrealized gains or losses. The unrealized gain or loss position of the SOMA
portfolio is influenced importantly by the level of interest rates. The staff
estimates that the portfolio was in an unrealized gain position of about
$165 billion as of the end of September. 7 Reflecting the assumed rise in longerterm interest rates over the next several years, the position is projected to shift to
an unrealized loss by late 2016 and record a peak unrealized loss of about
$225 billion in 2018, little changed from the September Tealbook. At the end of
2018, roughly $100 billion of the unrealized losses can be attributed to the
portfolio of Treasury securities and $125 billion to the portfolio of agency MBS.
The unrealized loss position then narrows through 2025, as the value of securities
securities approach maturity and then mature, and new securities are added to the
portfolio at par.

4

We assume the interest rate paid on reserve balances remains at 25 basis points as long as the
federal funds rate remains at its effective lower bound. In addition, we assume that, once firming of the
policy rate begins, the spread between the interest rate paid on reserve balances and the ON RRP rate is
25 basis points. Moreover, we assume that the effective federal funds rate will average about 15 basis
points below the interest rate paid on reserve balances and about 10 basis points above the ON RRP rate.
5
In the event that a Federal Reserve Bank’s earnings fall short of the amount necessary to cover
its operating costs, pay dividends, and equate surplus to capital paid-in, a deferred asset for interest on
Federal Reserve notes would be recorded.
6
The staff estimate of remittances had there been no asset purchase programs is based on a linear
interpolation from 2006 to 2025 of actual 2006 income and projected 2025 income.
7
The Federal Reserve reports the level and the change in the quarter-end net unrealized gain/loss
position of the SOMA portfolio to the public in the “Federal Reserve Banks Combined Quarterly Financial
Reports,” available on the Board’s website at
http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/bst_fedfinancials.htm#quarterly.

Page 43 of 50

Projections

acquired under the large-scale asset purchase programs returns to par when these

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Projections for the 10-Year Treasury Term Premium Effect
(Basis Points)
Date

October
Tealbook

September
Tealbook

Quarterly Averages
-108
-103
-99
-94
-90

-109
-104
-100
-95
-91

2017:Q4
2018:Q4
2019:Q4
2020:Q4
2021:Q4
2022:Q4
2023:Q4
2024:Q4
2025:Q4

-74
-62
-52
-44
-37
-32
-26
-20
-15

-75
-62
-52
-44
-37
-32
-26
-20
-15

Projections

2015:Q4
2016:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Page 44 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

•

October 22, 2015

Term premium effects. As shown in the table “Projections for the 10-Year
Treasury Term Premium Effect,” the Federal Reserve’s elevated stock of longerterm securities is estimated to hold down the term premium embedded in the
10-year Treasury yield in the fourth quarter of 2015 by 108 basis points. Over the
next couple of years, the estimated term premium effect diminishes at a pace of
about 5 basis points per quarter, reflecting in part the projected shrinking of the
portfolio. This projection is roughly unchanged from the September Tealbook.

•

Monetary base. As shown in the final table, “Projections for the Monetary Base,”
once policy firming begins in the fourth quarter of 2015, the monetary base still
increases during that quarter, but shrinks starting from the third quarter of 2016
through the second quarter of 2021, primarily because redemptions of securities
generate corresponding reductions in reserve balances. Starting around mid-2021,
after reserve balances are assumed to have stabilized at $100 billion, the monetary

Projections

base begins to expand in line with the increase in currency in circulation. 8

8

The projection for the monetary base depends critically on the FOMC’s choice of tools during
normalization. In this projection, a steady $100 billion take-up in an ON RRP facility is assumed, and
therefore, the level of the monetary base is lower than it would be absent this take-up until 2019 (when the
facility is assumed to be phased out). The projected growth rate of the monetary base, however, is
generally unaffected by this assumption. If the FOMC employs additional reserve-draining tools during
normalization or ON RRP take-up is larger than assumed, the projected level of reserve balances and the
monetary base could decline quite markedly.

Page 45 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

Projections for the Monetary Base
(Percent change, annual rate; not seasonally adjusted)
Date

October
Tealbook

September
Tealbook

39.0
5.3
0.0
-2.1
-8.0

4.6
-0.2
-0.1
-2.5
-8.4

Annual
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2024
2025

-9.3
-14.3
-13.1
-12.4
-5.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.4

-10.2
-15.9
-14.8
-14.4
-8.0
3.9
4.0
4.0
4.0

Projections

Quarterly
2015:Q4
2016:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Note: For years, Q4 to Q4; for quarters, calculated from corresponding average levels.

Page 46 of 50

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

MONEY
M2 is expected to increase more rapidly than nominal GDP in the fourth quarter
of 2015, in part reflecting a large, albeit temporary, surge in deposit balances related to
debt ceiling concerns. 9 The contour of the path for money growth thereafter is about
unchanged relative to the projection in the September Tealbook: We continue to project
that M2 will contract for several quarters in response to increases in the opportunity cost
of holding money (M2OC) related to the assumed increase in the target range for the
federal funds rate. This restraint is expected to continue to hold M2 growth below that of
nominal GDP in 2017 and 2018, although the restraint is projected to diminish over this
horizon. In contrast with the September projection, however, we now expect that the rise
in M2OC will not begin to notably restrain money demand until the beginning of 2016, in
line with the later projected timing of liftoff in the current forecast.
M2 Monetary Aggregate Projections
(Percent change, annual rate; seasonally adjusted)*
2015:
2016:

2017:

2018:

Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

6.2
6.2
-0.5
-4.3
-3.0
-0.1
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.9
2.1
2.4
2.5
2.9

2015
2016
2017
2018

6.3
-2.0
1.4
2.5

Annual

Note: This forecast is consistent with nominal GDP and interest rates in the
Tealbook forecast. Actual data through October 12, 2015; projections thereafter.
*Quarterly growth rates are computed from quarterly averages. Annual growth
rates are calculated from quarterly averages using the change from fourth
quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.

9

This projected rise in deposits stemming from debt ceiling concerns is based on the deposit flows
that are estimated to have been associated with the 2013 debt ceiling episode. See Tealbook A box “Debt
Ceiling Update and Review of 2013 Episode” for additional detail on these dynamics.

Page 47 of 50

Projections

Quarterly

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Projections

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 48 of 50

October 22, 2015

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

Abbreviations
ABS

asset-backed securities

BEA

Bureau of Economic Analysis, Department of Commerce

BHC

bank holding company

CDS

credit default swaps

C&I

commercial and industrial

CLO

collateralized loan obligation

CMBS

commercial mortgage-backed securities

CPI

consumer price index

CRE

commercial real estate

Desk

Open Market Desk

ECB

European Central Bank

EDO

Estimated, dynamic, optimization-based model

EME

emerging market economy

FDIC

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation

FOMC

Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee

GCF

general collateral finance

GDI

gross domestic income

GDP

gross domestic product

GSIBs

globally systemically important banking organizations

HQLA

high-quality liquid assets

ISM

Institute for Supply Management

LIBOR

London interbank offered rate

MBS

mortgage-backed securities

MMFs

money market funds

NIPA

national income and product accounts

OIS

overnight index swap

ON RRP

overnight reverse repurchase agreement

Page 49 of 50

October 22, 2015

Authorized for Public Release

Class I FOMC - Restricted Controlled (FR)

October 22, 2015

PCE

personal consumption expenditures

repo

repurchase agreement

RMBS

residential mortgage-backed securities

RRP

reverse repurchase agreement

SCOOS

Senior Credit Officer Opinion Survey on Dealer Financing Terms

SEP

Summary of Economic Projections

SFA

Supplemental Financing Account

SLOOS

Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices

SOMA

System Open Market Account

TBA

to be announced (for example, TBA market)

TGA

U.S. Treasury’s General Account

TIPS

Treasury inflation-protected securities

TPE

Term premium effects

Page 50 of 50