View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

FEDERAL RESERVE
NEW

BANK OF NEW YORK

YORK 45,

RECTOR

N.Y.

2-5700

October 10, 1955

Hon. James K. Vardaman, Jr.,
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System,
Washington 25, D. C.
Dear

Governor Vardaman:

Last spring a memorandum was prepared by the staff of the Board of
Governors discussing the liquidity needs of the economy and suggesting that the
Treasury might find it desirable, from this standpoint, to increase the supply
of short-term Treasury securities. At about the same time, Treasury officials
were explaining that their first task was to simplify the debt structure by reducing the volume of near-maturity obligations and by lengthening the average
maturity of the outstanding debt.
This difference of approach pointed to a need
for some reconsideration of the ways in which changes in the debt structure induced by Treasury debt management, on the one hand, and by the System's variable
influence upon liquidity and the creation of debt, on the other, might be meshed
more effectively. At a meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee it was suggested that the several Federal Reserve Banks give some thought to the matter
The enclosed memorandum represents some preliminary results of our thinking on
this subject at the New York Bank.
The memorandum is an attempt at an overall approach to the broad problem.
It does not attempt to present final views, but suggests elements of an analysis
that might be employed by the System and the Treasury to pursue the subject further. We hope that a careful study might locate some common ground on which
responsible officials could stand, when debt management and credit policy responsibilities overlap or appear to conflict in this area.
It seems to us that further study of this matter, and perhaps of other
aspects of the relations between debt management and credit policy would be
desirable, in an effort to approximate some general principles, rather than
continuing to deal with isolated incidents as they arise. The attached memorandum
might be considered a contribution to such a study.
Yours faithfully,

Allan Sproul
President
Enclosure

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

C ON FI DE NT IA

L

Notes on Debt Management, the Structure
of the Debt, and Credit Policy

(Paper prepared at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York)

September 29, 1955

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

I.

Statement of the Problem

Debt management and credit policy run into each other from various directions.

Many of the potentialities for conflict or coordination have been studied

for years, both at the Treasury and within the Federal Reserve System, but one important zone has been relatively neglected.

That is the influence of the changes

brought about in the debt structure by debt management, upon the fulfillment of
credit policy objectives.

To be sure, at the time of each Treasury offering, some

consideration is given to the immediate effects of the offering upon the immediate
aims of credit policy,

But no concerted effort has been made by the Treasury or the

System, singly or jointly, toward developing general principles for fitting together
the Treasury's influence on debt structure and the System's variable influence upon
liquidity and the creation of debt--principles that might exert some guiding influence over longer periods of time.
These notes are intended to make a start toward the development of such
principles.

They outline some of the ways in which the selection of issues and

terms by debt management over the years must necessarily exert a profound influence
upon credit markets, credit conditions, and the execution of credit policy, and they
suggest some of the guides that might help debt management and credit policy contribute to economic growth and stability, without impairing the fundamental autonomy
of the Treasury and of the System in the areas where each has prime responsibility.
Essentially, this is a matter of getting both the System and the Treasury to appreciate more fully the reciprocal effects of their actions in their respective fields.
The emphasis in these notes is intentionally on one side: the ways in which debt
management, through its influence upon the maturity structure of marketable debt,
may impinge on credit policy objectives--influencing interest rates and altering
the liquidity of the banking system and of the economy at large.

What credit policy

may do to help or hinder the objectives of debt management is another part of the
story, on which more has been said and to which, for that reason, relatively little
attention is given here.

Any thorough study of the integration of debt management

and credit policy would, however, have to cover both sides, and include operating
mechanics as well as general principles of the kind developed in these notes.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

2
The use of the word, principles, is not intended to suggest that firm and
fast rules of conduct can be applied at all times and under all conditions.

Views

as to what constitutes necessary or desirable liquidity will change with time and
with the swings of credit policy objectives from ease to restraint and back again.
Nor can there be any single determination of "the" pattern or level of interest
rates which is most likely to promote growth and stability at any point in time-the desired direction and degree of change, if any, will be influenced not only
by the state of the economy but also by the slowly changing cluster of habits and
prejudices that dominate the behavior patterns of the capital markets.

It is

through recognition of some of these, however, and in accommodation to the particular form they may take at any given time, that debt management and credit policy
can find a basis for coordinated action, to try to achieve joint objectives.
Briefly summarized, the conclusions of the present paper are:
1.

The technical task of managing the debt is simplified and the latitude for effective credit policy is increased when maturities are
relatively infrequent.
The policies of the present Treasury administration have worked with some success toward this end. But these
advantages must be weighed against the market's needs for instruments of various maturities, and debt management decisions should
reflect the counter-cyclical aims of over-all economic policy in
supplying these needs.

2.

Debt management decisions in the past two years have had a pronounced influence on economic liquidity. But to appraise the degree
of liquidity in the economy and estimated liquidity requirements,
it is necessary to include all instruments that serve a liquidity
purpose, including "money" and marketable, short-term private instruments, in addition to Treasury debt. Thus, Federal Reserve policy
directed at banks' primary reserves can offset the liquidity effects
of a reduction in short-term Treasury issues (as it did in 1954).
Or, Treasury funding operations may, over time, encourage the issuance of private money market paper to service a larger part of the
economy's liquidity requirements.

3. There is no uniformly adequate measure of liquidity, neither for
the economy at large nor for the banking system, and there are no
reliable guides to the effects that a change in liquidity might have.
Liquidity can be measured in an ordinal sense of "more or less",
but it would be advantageous if, in time, more nearly "standardized"
concepts of liquidity could be worked out.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
3
4.

The definition of the supply of liquid instruments the economy
"needs" is at least partly determined by the subjective element of
what investors think they need, and this is partly a matter of what
they have been accustomed to. Therefore, it might be expected that
the definition of "normal" or "necessary" liquidity would change over
time, and it might be necessary, from time to time, for the debt
management authorities to exercise positive leadership to encourage
such changes.

5.

Debt management decisions also influence the structure of interest
rates, the structure of the Government securities market, and the
ease or difficulty of Federal Reserve operations. The reduction of
the short-term debt, in the face of persistent nonbank demand for
short-term Government issues, has helped to give nonbank corporations
a dominant influence in the short-term Government securities market
and particularly in the Treasury bill market. The Treasury bill
market is no longer primarily a "bankers market", and the direct
and immediate influence upon the money market of System transactions
in Treasury bills has been lessened.

6.

A set of principles for debt management should recognize the
responsibility of the Treasury to schedule its necessary cash and
refunding operations with a view to:
(a) the needs of the economy
and of the market for investments of various maturities, including
a supply of liquid instruments consistent with prevailing economic
and market conditions; (b) the technical advantages of a simplified
debt structure with a relatively small floating debt and relatively
widely-spaced or routine maturities; (c) the occasional need to lead
the market toward different concepts of liquidity requirements when
conflicts arise between (a)

and (b); and

(d)

the consistency of debt

management policies with monetary policy and with general economic
policies.
7.

These principles imply a joint responsibility for monetary policy
and debt management. The two policies should be meshed consciously
and deliberately, on the basis of continuing and focussed consideration of the areas of overlap--including compromise of particular
objectives when compromise is necessary--to the end that the broad
objective of economic stability and secular growth might be furthered.

II.
A.

Debt Management and Liquidity

Role of Liquidity
Treasury debt management decisions as they affect the maturity structure

of assets held by private investors have a pervasive effect upon the liquidity of
the economy.

The importance of liquidity in the economic process derives from its

effect upon the willingness and ability of individuals and businesses to dispose
of assets for the purpose of acquiring other assets, or to incur debt for the same

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
4
purpose.

A holder of cash (the most liquid asset) or short-term marketable debt

instruments, which may be sold or redeemed easily and inexpensively, is able to
generate a demand for goods by spending or lending.Not only is he able to, but
the more of such liquid assets he holds as insurance coverage for possible, unforeseeable needs for funds, the more willing he will be to spend or lend.

Thus,

all else being equal, the greater the supply of liquidity--of cash and short-term,
readily marketable public and private debt instruments--the greater will be the
effective demand for goods.
If the money supply were constant, this process would be reflected in
changes in the velocity of money.

But in a system with a flexible money supply

based on commercial bank credit, it may be reflected in changes in the money
supply itself as banks add to or reduce their earning assets.

In such a system,

the proximate source of liquidity is the commercial banking system, and the
liquidity of the economy at large rests upon the ability or willingness of the
commercial banks to monetize debt.

But this, in turn, is influenced by the

liquidity of the commercial banks themselves.
In a significant sense, the Federal Reserve System is the ultimate
source of liquidity for the commercial banking system and, through the banks, for
the entire economy.

The existence of a source of ultimate liquidity will not, of

course, lead a bank to ignore liquidity considerations in its portfolio policies.
In the first place, to do so would lead to censure, at least, from the bank
examiners.

And member banks know that while they have the privilege of bor-

rowing from their Reserve Bank, there are reasonable limitations upon that
privilege, and it may not be relied upon always and continuously as the principal source of liquidity.

Also, bankers know from experience that not only

is there less risk of capital loss in liquidating short-term investments than
in selling long-term instruments, but also that short-term investments can more
surely--in an absolute sense--be converted into cash, either at maturity or in

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
5
the broader market that exists in these instruments, than can longer investments.
Therefore, if a bank is to assure itself of easier and less expensive access to
funds to provide for fluctuating loan demands and deposit withdrawals, it should
carry some volume of shorter-term investments.

The actual investment portfolio

structure in any bank at a given time will turn upon that bank's assessment of
the relative importance of the larger returns that have typically been available
on longer investments in recent years, as opposed to the estimated need for
liquidity in the period ahead.
To the extent that debt management policies encourage bankers to hold
relatively more short-term securities, the liquidity of the banking system is
increased and the willingness of bankers to meet demands for credit tends to
be expanded.

Conversely, when debt management policies encourage bankers to

hold relatively more intermediate and longer-term securities, credit availability tends to be tightened.

In both cases, the "encouragement" given by

debt management is through the choice of terms offered on new issues, which in
turn lead to either

a longer or a shorter debt structure and which are reflected

in the relative rates of return on all outstanding issues and in the attractiveness of different maturities.

If the central bank in the execution of its poli-

cies preempts a portion of the supply of short-term issues, the Treasury may find
it

necessary to adjust its policies to account for this influence.
This reasoning does not imply that Treasury debt management completely

regulates

in

the supply of marketable

the supply of private

operations.

instruments

of different

maturities.

Changes

instruments may partly offset the influence of Treasury

But Treasury securities are such a preponderant part of all

market-

able debt, particularly in the "commercial bank area", that Treasury debt management decisions are pervasive influences in the total debt structure.

A policy

of lengthening the debt at a time when the central bank is seeking monetary
restraint, or of shortening the debt when the objective is monetary ease, will

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
6
under most circumstances assist the Federal Reserve System, while the opposite
policies will usually make its task more difficult.
It might be mentioned in passing that commercial banks perhaps should
view all Government securities as relatively liquid, since the possibilities of
capital loss are never as extreme as those involved in issues which also contain
an element of credit risk, and the well developed market offers assurance of continuous and orderly trading.

Nevertheless, when banks hold relatively few short-

term Treasury issues they may be confronted with capital losses if they find it
necessary to liquidate, and they may therefore act as though they were illiquid
and be more cautious toward new credit extensions, whether in an absolute sense
they are illiquid or not.

This reaction on the part of commercial bankers, based

partly on a reluctance to take capital losses, is one element assisting the Federal
Reserve System to maintain effective control of credit availability and the money
supply.

What this means is that liquidity is a matter of degree.

If debt manage-

ment has resulted in banks holding more Governments of longer maturity, and less
of the shorts, it reinforces a restrictive credit policy by reducing the liquidity
of the banks, thereby limiting the readiness of the banks to use funds for other
things.
B.

Measuring Liquidity
One measure that has been used as an indication of the liquidity con-

dition of banks is the total of their holdings of excess reserves, Government
securities maturing within one year and other short-term marketable or callable
instruments as a ratio to their total deposit liabilities or, alternatively, to
their total loans and investments.
table.

Such a measure is presented in the attached

It indicates that bank liquidity recently has been lower than it was for

a considerable number of years.

However, it is a commonplace that banks were

unnecessarily liquid during most of the 1930's, and during the war and early postwar years, as a result of a large influx of gold, the financing policies of the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
7
Government, and other sweeping economic influences of those two decades. Therefore,
the recent condition of commercial bank liquidity, fostered by debt management
policies and induced by credit policy, may simply have been a return to a more
reasonable adjustment of bank portfolios as between the two alternatives of
income and liquidity--bringing the banks more closely and continuously in contact with the effects of action taken by the System to influence credit growth.
Even now there are no objective standards upon which to base a firm conclusion
that commercial bank holdings of liquidity instruments, though lower than in
other recent years, are so low as to reflect an "undesirably" illiquid position.
This is particularly true in view of the present direction of credit policy.

The inadequacy and noncomparability of the data in the table make the
construction of such a liquidity ratio extremely difficult, and there cannot be
Liquidity will vary bank by bank, depending

too much confidence in the results.

upon the varying policies of the individual banks, and there is serious question
as to how much meaning an aggregate measure can have.

The liquidity ratio is

an important tradition in British banking and fairly predictable effects can be
induced by a change in the ratio.

In a unit banking system, however, it probably

will be difficult to establish a uniform standard.

It might be possible, however,

after careful study to establish a ratio along the lines of the attached table and
to develop concepts of a range over which this ratio might be induced to move
through the various phases of credit policy.

Such a measure might offer hope for

some quantification of liquidity measurements as a partial guide to coordinated
debt management-credit policy.
C.

The Responsibility for Liquidity
The Treasury has responsibility for the management of the public debt

in a manner that will be most conducive to the development of sound financial
markets and the maintenance of general economic stability and growth.

By re-

structuring the debt in such a manner as to reduce the volume of short-term debt

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
8
and minimize the number of times the Treasury must come to the market to finance,
the policies followed during the past two years have lessened the unstabilizing
influence that debt management can have in the capital markets.

Also, Federal

Reserve credit policy has been able to exert a restraining effect upon bank credit
availability more rapidly and with less pressure on reserve balances as a result
of the reconstruction of the debt.

However, it may be true, as is sometimes

claimed, that debt management policies have not always given enough attention to
the second responsibility, that of promoting conditions of stability in a growing
economy.

The attached data on liquidity might suggest that debt management has

been partly responsible for lowering bank liquidity to a point that may not be
consistent with the liquidity needs of the economy, even after allowance has been
made for changing views as to adequate liquidity
The Treasury has a public responsibility to maintain a debt structure
that neither reduces the liquidity of the banking system below a point consistent
with broad policy objectives nor adds to it beyond the point called for by policy
objectives.

It is necessary to recognize, however, that the Treasury's responsi-

bility encompasses more than merely providing the securities that can be most
easily sold, i.e.,

those which conform with the market's current evaluation of

what it would like to have.

If, as appears to be the case, the Treasury debt

until recently was concentrated too heavily at the short end, then it was appropriate that the distorted structure should have been corrected through a policy of
moving part of the short debt into longer areas.

Furthermore, it is consistent

with reasonable debt management principles that policy should have led the market
by whittling the supply of short debt below what the market desired.

That is to

say, debt management has the right and responsibility to correct investment practices that are not necessary and may not be conducive to sound economic conditions,
so long as such action from the point of view of those responsible for managing
the debt is consistent with the objective of a more rational debt structure.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
9
Although Treasury debt management decisions influence liquidity in the
banking system and the economy at large, the primary responsibility for liquidity
conditions traditionally has rested with the central bank.

As mentioned earlier,

the Federal Reserve System is the ultimate source of liquidity in the economy and
has the power to create a desired degree of liquidity regardless of debt management policies.

The liquidity effects of changes in the structure of the Treasury

debt can be offset by properly graduated actions of the Federal Reserve System
aimed at adjusting the banking system's supply of cash reserves, to create whatever degree of bank liquidity was sought (though perhaps with effects on the
precision with which the System is able to regulate credit conditions).

Alterna-

tivelyif the circumstances warranted such action, the Federal Reserve System
might use maturity adjustments in the System Open Market Account as a balancing
device to offset undesirable liquidity effects of Treasury debt operations,
assuming that System holdings of various maturities were large enough to permit
such action.
Present operating policies of the Federal Open Market Committee would
not, of course, permit the latter operation.

However, if the banking system is

presently or should become too illiquid in the sense that it holds too few shortterm Government securities, and if the principle is accepted of the primacy of
Federal Reserve responsibility in liquidity matters, then the Federal Reserve
System might at some time wish to employ the System Open Market Account for purposes of liquidity adjustment.

The importance of improved control of the

liquidity of commercial banks' secondary reserves would in each instance have to
be weighed against any disadvantages that might be associated with recognition of
a broader function for open market operations.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
10

III.

Interest Rates and Market Practices

Treasury debt management decisions have a direct influence upon the
structure of market rates of interest.

When debt management is pushing toward

longer maturities the interest curve may tend to become steeper, all other things
being equal, and when operations are centered in the short-term area it may tend to
become flatter.

Policies of the past two years have, therefore, generally tended

to widen the spread between shorter and longer rates or, more accurately, to limit
the squeezing together that would have been made more striking if debt-lengthening had not been pursued so actively.

Two questions emerge:

particular shape or kind of rate curve that is, per se,

first, is there any

"best" in the sense that

it is most conducive to secular growth and cyclical stability; second, how
important is it from the point of view of credit conditions that debt operations
be varied counter-cyclically?
On the first question, there is certainly no single shape or level for
the rate curve that is "best" under all conditions.

Since steady expansion of

productive facilities is necessary in a secularly expanding economy, the thesis is
sometimes advanced that policy should press constantly for relatively low longerterm rates of interest.

But this ignores the fact that marginal returns on

capital investment fluctuate with the business cycle.

An anchored long-term rate

would provide greater incentive for borrowing in booms and less in recession, an
economically unstabilizing pattern.
rates.

Cyclical stability is promoted by fluctuating

There may be influences upon the shape or level of the curve that will be

better than others, and much can be done to further credit policy by influences
that cause changes within the "curve" without any pronounced change in level at
all--but these are matters of degree and of emphasis--not "pinpointing".
It is usually assumed that the level of rates on long-term funds has a
greater influence upon the demand for credit than does the level of rates in the

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
11
short-term market.

If this reasoning is accepted, and if it is granted that a

principal objective of economic stabilization policy is to encourage investment
at times of declining business activity and discourage excessively heavy or
speculative investment at times of boom, then it follows that a well coordinated
approach for debt management and credit policy will have the effect of causing
long-term rates to move over a relatively wide range during the business cycle.
Short-term rates will usually be moving in the same direction, though perhaps
with less regularity, and typically short rates may move further, so that the
rate curve might become flatter under restrictive credit policies and steeper
under easy credit policies.

However, there may be changes in the level of the

whole rate curve, with shifts over so relatively wide a range that the question
of the slope of the curve (i.e. steeper or flatter) may be academic.

To recog-

nize the great variety of possibilities is not to imply that there must be
perpetual bewilderment.

The point is that, at any time, some of these kinds of

changes will be detrimental, others helpful.

And both debt management and

credit policy should see the need to appraise, and to act, on the same side-rather than as opposites.
On the second question, concerning the importance of contra-cyclical
debt management, the answer must depend partly, of course, upon the extent to
which credit policy does what debt management might do.

That is to say, for

example, if the Federal Reserve System for over-riding reasons is unable to act
directly to force long-term rates higher in a boom, or to ease them lower in a recession, it becomes more important that debt management be used to accomplish
some effect of this kind.

To bring about lower rates in recession, for example,

the Treasury could avoid financing in the long market and even provide attractive conversion options if necessary; in boom periods, directly opposite policies
would presumably be called for.

If pursued very far, however, such policies might

not only become costly to the Treasury--by causing it to lose opportunities for

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
12

funding at lower (depression) rates, and by placing its main funding effort in
boom periods of high rates--but it would also raise questions as to where the
real locus for credit policy had come to be.
In appraising the respective roles of debt management and credit policy
in influencing interest rate patterns, an important consideration is the greater
flexibility of Federal Reserve action as contrasted with Treasury action in both
timing and amount.

Another practical consideration is the difficulty of managing

a debt that automatically moves closer to maturity with the passage of time.

It

requires almost constant effort by the debt managers to prevent the average
maturity of the debt from shortening and to avoid excessive bunching in the shortterm area.

To slacken the efforts to float intermediate and long-term issues

during recessions would lead to periodic massive movements of debt into the shortterm area, which would need to be followed later by equally massive movements out,
just at the times when it would be most difficult.

The disturbing effects on the

market of such large alterations in the debt structure seem clear, and must
greatly modify the possible theoretical conclusion that the Treasury should vary
its debt operations countercyclically.

It seems more likely that the Treasury

will tend toward the issuance of longer rather than shorter maturities, in all
phases of the busincess cycle, just because of the "passage of time" problem.
Given this premise, however, it would be possible to achieve a synchronized relationship with credit policy by pressing relatively less energetically in recessions
and relatively more energetically in booms.
The attempt to reconstruct the debt toward a relatively smaller supply
of short-term securities and more orderly spacing in the longer areas has had
several discernible effects upon the market for Government securities.

It would

appear that even if the Treasury may not have gone too far in its debt lengthening
program, it has perhaps at times gone too fast.

narily is

most fluid,

The

short-term market, which ordi-

has at times during the past year developed "knots", perhaps partly

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
13

because of an inadequate supply of shorter instruments to meet demand at going
rates, despite the tighter credit conditions and the massive unloading of shortterm securities by banks that tighter credit has occasioned.

That is to say,

there have developed elements of administrative rationing rather than price
rationing in the short-term market as dealers have declined to make markets in
large amounts rather than assume the risks involved in lowering yield quotations
to what they believed were unrealistically low levels at the time.

To the extent

that this has happened, it is indicative of a situation in which realistic prices
on these issues in terms of existing credit conditions were not equilibrium
prices in terms of equating supply and demand.

That is, at times the limited

supply of Treasury bills, for example, would have resulted in a price so high
(yield so low) that the market simply would not "take" such an adjustment in the
face of large, but brief, demands.
This situation may reflect unreasonable notions of investors as to
what is a necessary short--term portfolio for liquidity purposes, and it reflects
the high and rising tax liabilities of corporations during the business recovery
which have been a source of insistent demand draining these securities from the
banks.
with the

(It might be noted that on present tax schedules the latter process moves
cycle and may be of some influence in helping to adjust bank portfolios

in a manner consistent with the objectives of System policy.)

And, in any event,

it is difficult and logically questionable in a market of freely moving prices,
although recognizing that price distortions do appear, to judge that supply is
"too large" or "too small".
market has grown used to"

But the fact remains that the factor of "what the
should be included as one of the determinants of what

is an adequate supply of short debt and of a desirable degree of liquidity.

And

there have been the signs, mentioned above, that the short-term market has been

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
14
functioning imperfectly at the present level of short debt.

Therefore, it may

be true--with all the necessary qualifications--that at times recently there has
"not been enough" of at least one particular type of short-term debt.
As banks have liquidated their holdings of short-term Government securities under the various pressures of attractive refunding opportunities into
longer maturities, restrictive Federal Reserve credit policies, and a voracious
nonbank demand for short-term Governments, the balance in the market has shifted
to the point where commercial bank participation is now much less important than
formerly.

The nonbank corporations have become the principal participants in the

bill market.

In a real sense, the bill market no longer lies at the heart of the

money market since the bulk of commercial bank reserve adjustments are no longer
made there.

To the extent that this is true, Federal Reserve operations in bills

are not directly centered in the area of the market where money market adjustments are being made and their effect upon the money market is, therefore, more
indirect.

But it probably lies in the hands of the Treasury to correct that

situation, if its other debt management considerations could permit that to be
done.

That is, more Treasury bills would eventually sate the demand and leave

something over for bank reserve adjustments.

IV.

Conclusions

Study and discussion should be able to broaden the area of common
understanding, as between the Treasury and the

of debt management and credit policy.

System, on the

interrelationships

As a first approximation,it might be

suggested that the Treasury's responsibility is, in a sense, a negative one.

It

is the responsibility to establish and maintain a debt structure that neither
goes too far toward funding the debt and toward creating illiquid conditions in
the banking system and other financial institutions, nor too far toward creating
excessive liquidity (perhaps by always following the easy course of selling what

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
15
the market will most readily absorb).

One implication of this approach would be

that the Treasury should plan to increase the supply of short-term issues as time
goes on if the steady growth of the economy seems to require a larger stock of
secondary reserve assets.

Rather than driving steadily toward debt lengthening,

the Treasury might at some point stabilize the supply of bills and certificates,
automatically rolling over the maturing certificates into new one-year issues in
the same way bills are now rolled over and adding to the total supply of bills
and certificates only to meet the secular growth requirements of the economy.
The relatively infrequent note and bond maturities could then be handled in such
a way that debt management would be pushing strongly toward longer maturities
(less liquidity) when credit policy was restrictive and less aggressively toward
longer maturities when credit policy was easy.

The term "pushing toward" is

important since the practical market situation will, of course, set limits to
what can be done.

But, if debt management and credit policy are working hand in

hand, even an offering of 3-year notes in a period of restraint--if that is the
longest issue the market will take in volume--will exert more pressure on
liquidity than an offering of a somewhat longer issue in a period of ease, if
that issue is substantially shorter than might have been sold.
With debt management setting the general framework, the Federal Reserve
System might then have the responsibility for making the necessary period-toperiod adjustments that could not easily be made with the cumbersome debt management mechanism.

If economic conditions called for an increase in liquidity, the

Treasury would not be able to bring about rapid shortening of the outstanding
Treasury debt, or to make the change with appropriate diffusion among various
shorter and longer maturities within a brief period of time, and the Federal
Reserve System would be responsible for the needed adjustments.

These operations

by the System should, of course, be integrated with operations aimed at
influencing reserves.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020
16
A final note should be included on the influence that general budgetary
developments can have upon debt management-credit policy relationships.

A

Treasury deficit in a period of full employment or a surplus in a period of recession, of course, have broad effects on income and on bank credit that run
counter to the economic stability objectives of credit policy.

In addition these

developments, particularly a Treasury deficit during a boom, create the need
for debt operations that will frequently make the meshing of debt management and
credit policy more difficult.

Particularly when the Federal Reserve System is

attempting to maintain a carefully regulated degree of restraint on money and
credit, the more frequent financings (during which the System may be more-orless immobilized) and the sledge-hammer effect on the market of any sizable cash
operation can seriously hamper the adaptability and effectiveness of credit
policy.

The apparent results of the Treasury's cash operations in the second

quarter of 1953 are a case in point.
deficits and

Compensatory fiscal policy, with budget

surpluses occurring contracyclically, clearly would provide the

best environment for successful integration of debt management and credit policy.
It is neither necessary nor would it be appropriate to attempt to
spell out in detail the precise areas of responsibility under the sort of
coordinated debt management-credit policy outlined above.

It would appear that

in defining functions and responsibilities, and in the interest of the most
efficient working out of controls, a sharing of responsibilities along the
general lines described may offer hope for more effective economic policy.

What

it is important to recognize is that credit policy and debt management are not
independent and should, within rather broad boundaries, be consciously
coordinated for maximum effectiveness-not necessarily as to precise details,
but as to the direction and emphasis that will help to make one reinforce the
other, at each phase of economic activity.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

Liquidity Ratios of Member Banks
1925-1954, End of Year data
(Amounts in millions of dollars, ratios in per cent)

(6)

(2)
(1)
Open
Year

1928
1929
1930
1931

1932
1933
1934

1935
1936
1937
1938
1939

market
paper

602

554

582
736

249

443

723
604
752
651
634
642
442

1940
1941

455
456
607

1942

n.a.

1943
1944
1945

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

1946

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

1947

1948
1949
1950
1951
1952

1953
1954

Short-term Gov'ts
Bills
Total Gov'ts
maturing
and
(3)
in less
certifVault
than 1 yr. cash
icates

369
679
795
927
1,030
1,192

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

1,053
662
286
563
652
971

n.a.
n.a.
n.a.

10,648

564
558
593
523

(5)
Loans to
brokers
(4)
Free
and
reserves dealers

-1,085
-

704

-

155
660

Total
liquid
assets
(col 1
to 5

3,531
2,463
2,173

4,166
3,148

(8)

(7)
Net
demand
deposits

(col 6 y
col 7)

19,944

20.9

15.9
19.6

423
471

342

966
598

1,951
2,881

19,797
18,969
16,067
15,193

762

1,006

3,770

14,821

609
665
697
589
746

1,807
2,840
1,981

1,030

5,228

18,851

1,243
1,410

6,591
5,775

22,169

1,202
3,201

4,045

3,716

Liquidity
ratio

12.1

19.0
25.4

27.7
29.7

25,450
23,741

22.7
21.7

17.0

841

5,207

950
973
790

6,613

642

n.a.

991
1,087

5,648
7,856
9,354

3,082

594

6,341

25,983
30,326
35,262
39,708

n.a.

1,019

1,985

934

14,586

55,326

26.4

19,979
21,858
29,275
15,489
15,643
16,360
22,664
18,998
28,882
27,153
23,493

1,132
1,271

1,231

1,398

23,740

2,249

1,438

3,133

26,923
35,115

1,576

546

1,506

19,117

57,990
63,088
70,918
76,540

40.9

1,545
1,269

1,672
1,486

1,464
1,169
1,010
1,105

811
1,324

19,590
20,339
26,932
23,516
32,865
30,569

n.a.

n.a.

14,648

n.a. - Not available.
(See notes on following page)

1,521

1,643
2,062
2,081

1,870
1,843

370
697
750
248

1,737
1,770
1,551
2,032
2,321

2,881

28,434
19,620

80,822
80,210

81,263
87,160
92,770
96,786
96,507
100,477

25.9
26.5
16.0

42.7

49.5
25.0
24.2
25.4

33.1
27.0

35.4
31.6
29.5
19.5

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 2/25/2020

Explanatory Footnotes

1.

Open market paper

Statistics on the amount of open market paper held by member banks are
available only from 1928 through 1941 inclusive. Open market paper was so important a part of total liquid holdings during the period in which it was reported
that it should, nonetheless, be included.
2.

Short-term Government securities

Data on holdings of Treasury bills and certificates are available from
1928 to the present but data on holdings of Treasury securities maturing in less
than one year are available only since 1943. Series for securities maturing in
less than one year are used in the totals when available.

3. Vault cash
Data on vault cash are available from 1914 through the present and
are included throughout.
4.

Free reserves

A case might be made for including excess reserves in place of free
reserves. However, a bank which has excess reserves only because of borrowing
is currently less liquid than one which has such an excess without borrowing,
and free reserves are therefore included in the series.

5.

Loans to brokers and dealers

Loans to brokers and dealers have been included though this procedure
might be debated. There are other short-term loans which could claim equal
right to be regarded as highly liquid assets. The argument for including loans
to brokers and dealers lies partly in the fact that data on other very shortterm loans are not available and partly on the fact that liquidity ratios,
particularly in the earlier years, suggest that banks must have regarded these
loans as a significant part of their secondary reserves. The liquidity ratio
excluding these loans gyrated widely and at times fell very low from 1928
through 1930, whereas the liquidity ratio including these loans was much more
stable.
6.

Balances with banks

Balances with banks have been excluded since these assets probably
should be offset against the current liabilities of the banks holding the
deposits. This again introduces the problem of implicit deduction of shortterm liabilities from liquid asset holdings, but it seems the best procedure.
Net demand deposits have been used as the base for the liquidity
7.
ratio since these represent the major liability subject to immediate payment,
but inter-bank deposits and items in process of collection have been excluded
and both are likewise omitted from the asset side of the liquidity ratio.