View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

September 30, 1991
NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
Sam Y. Cross

Since your August meeting, there has been no intervention in the
foreign exchange market, either by the United States, or by Germany, or
Japan.

Indeed there has not even been any serious consideration of

intervention during the period, which saw the dollar drift down by a little more
than 3 percent compared with its levels after things settled down from the
attempted coup in the Soviet Union.

As you may recall, just before your last meeting, the dollar spiked
upward with the news of the Soviet putsch on August 19 and that event was
still influencing exchange rates when you last met.

But as evidence

accumulated that the attempted right-wing coup would fail, the dollar gave
back all those gains. Thereafter, if there was any residual effect of that
aborted coup, it was mildly negative for the dollar and positive for the mark.
For one thing, the failure removed one major area of concern surrounding
the mark insofar as it revealed the strength of public support for more
democratic government in the Soviet Union. For another, it was also seen

- 2 -

as likely to induce other Western nations to share the burden of assistance
for Eastern Europe, and it increased the likelihood of meaningful economic
reform.

As far-reaching as those developments in the USSR might be, by far
the more immediate factor influencing the dollar during the period was the
perception that the U.S. economy still lacked clear signs of vigor, and that
U.S. monetary policy would continue to be eased in response. These views
seemed to have the greatest impact on dollar exchange rates during the first
half of September. Reports showing continuing low growth in the money
supply, statements by various officials in the Federal Reserve and elsewhere
about the need to address that issue, and the release of the August
employment data, in combination prompted the dollar to decline by almost
two pfennigs on Friday, September 6. During the following week the dollar
continued to decline, with the market anticipating that U.S. producer and
consumer price data would show moderating inflation, and would be
followed by an easing. Thus when the discount rate was cut on September
13, the move had been very widely expected and discounted, and the dollar
did not immediately decline further.

- 3 -

After mid-September, the dollar benefitted from a shift in expectations
about German interest rates. Market observers felt increasingly comfortable
with the view that the Bundesbank would be unlikely to tighten further
following recent favorable news about developments in eastern Germany,
and improved monthly inflation data. Nonetheless the Bundesbank remains
troubled about the current round of wage negotiations, and quite sensitive
to any signs of a nascent wage-price spiral, so that in public comments,
Bundesbank officials have continued to make clear their determination to act
if necessary to contain such a development.

The dollar did not get the same benefit, however, from expectations of
an easing of monetary policy in Japan. Market participants have observed
the recent slowing of the Japanese economy and easing of inflationary
pressures. They have noted the chorus of calls by a range of government
officials for an easing of monetary policy. In these circumstances, many are
expecting the BOJ to move soon to reduce the official discount rate. Yet the
yen has remained firm against the dollar. To some extent, the exchange rate
is benefitting from reduced capital outflows, modest repatriation of funds to
shore up capital positions, and expectations of renewed strengthening of
Japan's current account position. It is also worth noting that the market may

- 4-

be overestimating the likelihood of an imminent cut in the BOJ's discount
rate. The BOJ is telling us there is still room for market rates to go down
before there is any meaningful pressure on the discount rate, and appears
to be encouraging the continuing decline in short term market rates, without
yet moving on the discount rate.

At present, the dollar continues to trade with a soft tone.

Market

participants are speculating about the timing of the Federal Reserve's next
move to ease. Also, President Bush's nuclear arms reduction proposals of
last Friday are generally interpreted as confirmation of declining global
tensions, further lessening dollar support.

Yet up to now, this increased

bearish sentiment has not translated into further significant declines, as the
possibility of further military action in the Middle East, concerns over the
situation in the Soviet Union sparked by Yeltsin's uncertain health, and the
strife in Yugoslavia have reminded market participants of the risks of going
too short dollars. Should some political event of consequence occur when
the market is so overwhelmingly positioned against the dollar, dealers face
the risk that the dollar could shoot up sharply, thereby imposing sizable
losses on large short dollar positions. It may also be that market participants
are cognizant of the fact that the dollar - though significantly above its lows

-5-

of last February -- is still at very low levels in an historical context and
competitive in terms of purchasing power.

Mr. Chairman, there have been no exchange market operations to
request the Committee to approve. I can report that in accordance with
arrangements made earlier in the summer, and which I mentioned at your
last meeting, forward sales of marks by the ESF and the Federal Reserve to
the Bundesbank settled on August 27 and September 27, and a forward sale
of yen to the Bank of Japan settled on September 18. Also as previously
arranged, the ESF used a portion of its share of the proceeds to further
reduce outstanding warehousing on August 22.

Thus, during August

warehousing was reduced by a total of $2.5 billion, and currencies
warehoused by the Federal Reserve for the Treasury currently stand at $2
billion equivalent.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
Peter D. Sternlight
October 1, 1991
For several weeks following the Committee's August 20
meeting, the Domestic Trading Desk sought to maintain the existing
degree of reserve availability, consistent with federal funds trading
in the area of 5-1/2 percent.

In the first half of September, the

path borrowing allowance was reduced in two technical steps, by a
total of $75 million to $300 million, to keep pace with an abatement
of seasonal borrowing.

Then, on September 13, the Federal Reserve

lowered the discount rate from 5-1/2 to 5 percent and, as reviewed in
an FOMC conference call that morning, it was envisioned that half of
that reduction would pass through to the federal funds rate--paring
the expected rate to 5-1/4 percent.

Consistent with the restoration

of a small spread in the expected funds rate over the discount rate,
the borrowing allowance was boosted by $25 million to $325 million.
Actual funds rates and borrowings were fairly close to
expectations.

In the first few weeks of the period, funds averaged

about 5.60 percent, while seasonal and adjustment borrowing was
largely in a $350-$400 million range, boosted somewhat by temporary
special situation borrowing and some tightness at the end of the
August 21 reserve period.

In the weeks since the discount rate

change, funds have traded largely in a 5-1/4 to 5-3/8 percent range
while borrowing has centered around $310-350 million.

Yesterday, some

quarter-end firmness showed through and funds were largely around
5-1/2 percent.
There were sizable reserve needs during the period,
reflecting reductions in the Systems foreign exchange holdings, a
paydown of extended credit, and after the mid-September tax date a

bulge in Treasury deposits.

The level of Treasury deposits was often

a source of major uncertainty and projection error, especially in the
latter part of the period when heavy outpayments by RTC and FSLIC did
not always occur precisely as expected.

The Desk met reserve needs

with a $3.5 billion outright purchase of bills in the market in late
August and a series of outright purchases of bills and notes from
foreign accounts that totaled a little over $2 billion for the period.
In addition, on most days the Desk arranged System or customer-related
repurchase agreements.

The extent of the small easing step on

September 13 was readily conveyed to the market that day through the
execution of a sizable round of customer-related repos at a time when
the funds rate had just edged off to 5-1/4 percent apparently in
anticipation of the System's presumed new posture.
Yields on most fixed income securities declined over the
intermeeting period, responding to the sense of sluggish recovery,
weak money growth and subdued inflation.

The mid-September policy

easing was thoroughly expected by the time it came, but was welcomed
as confirmation of what had already been built into market pricing.
Toward the end of the period, the market began to build up
anticipations of a further easing step--perhaps not to be seen
immediately but likely to unfold in coming weeks.
In the Treasury bill area, rate declines were very modest
over the period, as these rates had dropped sharply just before the
last meeting in a knee-jerk response to the uncertainties about the
Soviet coup attempt then underway.

When the coup failed, bill rates

backed up, but then they worked lower again to end the period just a
bit below where they started.

In yesterday's 3- and 6-month bill

auctions the average rates were 5.11 and 5.14 percent, compared with
5.17 and 5.23 percent just before the last meeting, which was the day

the coup attempt began.

The Treasury has continued to raise money in

this sector--just over $20 billion during the period.
Yields on intermediate and longer-term Treasury coupon issues
were down about 25 to 40 basis points over the period.

Early on,

there was some back-up in rates as participants responded to the sharp
jump reported for new durable goods orders and leading indicators for
July.

The lost ground was more than regained by the time the discount

rate was cut in mid-September as the August employment report was seen
as weak and the market was impressed by the weakness in broad money
measures, weak retail sales, and a better-than-expected PPI.

The

August CPI was slightly disappointing but not enough to dim sentiment.
The Treasury also raised money in the coupon sector--a net of nearly
$19 billion for the period.

The rate decline for longer maturities

brought the 30-year yield down to about 7.80 percent--the lowest since
December 1989,
Treasury auctions proceeded smoothly, even robustly, despite
concerns that adverse effects might develop in the wake of the Salomon
Brothers revelations and investigations.

In particular, there had

been concern that some major participants in recent previous auctions
might shun the process, and that a diminution of so-called "preauction" talk among dealers and customers might lead to a greater
diffusion of pricing ideas with consequent "tails" in the bidding.
There were indeed fewer mammoth-sized bids either from dealers or
customers, but there has been plenty of broad-based dealer and
customer demand--perhaps owing in good measure to the generally
favorable market sentiment.

To be sure, bidding for longer

maturities, especially if it occurred in a less friendly market
environment, could present more of a challenge.

In other markets, yields on investment grade corporates and
municipals declined over the period, but not by as much as on Treasury
issues.

Short-term private instrument yields fell a modest 5-20 basis

points, but the prime rate came down a full 1/2 percentage point just
after the discount rate reduction.
Yield spreads on the paper of several bank holding companies
widened over the period, notably including Continental which announced
a restructuring that included the relinquishment of its primary dealer
role.

S&P downgraded Continental debt.

Citicorp also sustained a

widening yield spread following reports that it took a large loan
charge-off against incorrectly valued assets on a mortgage-backed
deal, and comments by their chairman that real estate problems will
likely linger for it and other financial institutions for many years.
There was also a sharp widening in spreads on Chrysler Financial's
issues to as much as 11 percentage points over Treasuries, as
investors were concerned about the parent company's cash flow and the
financial unit's greater reliance on bank lines as they have lost
effective access to the bond market.
Much attention, of course, has focused on the prospects for
Salomon Brothers as official investigations proceed and the Federal
Reserve weighs the firm's primary dealer status.

The firm has

operated in a defensive posture, shrinking the total balance sheet on
the order of 25-30 percent since the announcements of wrongdoing and
major changes of management.
has run off.

More than half of its commercial paper

While some financing sources and trading partners have

pulled away, and the firm has suffered downgradings from major rating
agencies, day-to-day financing has not been a serious problem.

The

firm has substantial amounts of high quality assets that can still be
put out on repos,

and they have not had to pay up sharply for

-5-

financing.

Still, the firm is deeply concerned about the outcome of

investigations and lawsuits, and of course, any decision on primary
dealer status.

Since the scandal was first reported, the spread on

Salomon's intermediate-term notes over Treasuries has widened by about
230 basis points--and at its worst the widening was by nearly 300
basis points.

Meantime, the firm's stock is off by over 30 percent.

Michael J. Prell
October 1, 1991

FOMC BRIEFING -- DOMESTIC ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

I want to focus this morning on two key issues regarding the
prospects for the economy.

The first is whether the incipient

recovery can be sustained over the next few quarters without
additional exogenous stimulation.

The second is whether it is

reasonable to expect that core inflation will drop significantly below
4 percent over the next year, given our growth forecast.

While the

staff's forecast continues to offer affirmative answers to both of
these questions, it can hardly be said that the information that has
come to us over the past six weeks has done much to resolve the
uncertainties that attend the outlook.
With regard to the real side, the anecdotal evidence has, as
I see it, continued to have a decidedly negative cast to it.

Although

yesterday's Wall Street Journal described a recent Conference Board
survey of business executives that was rather upbeat, there is no
shortage of bleak reports from individual firms.

And there certainly

hasn't been a rising tide of confidence among households in recent
months; opinion polls reveal that the vast majority of people perceive
no improvement in the economy.
surprising:

Perhaps all this should not be

layoffs still are numerous, unemployment remains high,

and many businesses have yet to approach their pre-recession levels of
output or profitability.
Arrayed against this negative sentiment, though, is a
substantial amount of statistical evidence that the moderate upswing
in activity that most of us predicted is on course.

To be sure, given

the inherent noisiness of most of the data series--as well as the
tepidness of the overall growth--the patterns are not clear-cut.

- 2

October FOMC

Michael J. Prell

-

Indeed, it would not be at all difficult to construct a more negative
case out of some of the recent zigs and zags in the monthly time
series.

But it is the staff's view that the odds at this point favor

a continuation of the recovery rather than a stall-out or a second
dip.
What is the basis for this judgment?

An important

consideration is that we believe we've already built into our
Greenbook scenario allowances for a lot of the negative factors in the
economic environment.

Our projection includes a further sharp decline

in the level of commercial construction activity.

It also

incorporates the drags stemming from increased taxes and weak defense
and state and local spending.

And we think that we have made due

allowance for the financial stresses in the system, although
admittedly this is an influence much less susceptible to
straightforward quantification.

For what it's worth, our flow of

funds forecast provides what I think is a plausible picture of how the
limited growth in spending that we've projected can be financed
without heavy reliance on banks and other troubled intermediaries.
On the more positive side, unless one is strongly inclined to
focus entirely on the empty portion of the recent glass of statistical
indicators, there are favorable trends emerging in the data for a
number of sectors.

For example, despite all of the talk of weak

consumer demand, real consumer outlays have been trending upward since
February, and the slight decline in August still left the level well
above the second-quarter average.

Moreover, the latest data on motor

vehicle sales suggest that September will see a good bounceback from
the August decline.

Neither the sentiment measures nor the figures on

household saving and financial health would suggest that we should
look for spending to outstrip income in the coming months, but
consumers have been providing support to this recovery and, barring

- 3 -

October FOMC

Michael J. Prell

some new adverse shock, it seems unlikely that they will retire from
the scene.
Before leaving the household sector, I should take note of
the developments in the residential real estate market.

Housing

starts actually came in a little higher in July and August than we had
expected, but declines in permits and sales suggest that the recovery
in homebuilding might have been losing steam this summer.

However,

mortgage rates have come down quite a bit recently, appreciably
enhancing affordability.

Thus, we think it likely that the uptrend in

housing starts will soon be reestablished--although, until there is
more consistent employment and income growth, that uptrend is likely
to be a very gradual one.
Meanwhile, in the business sector, orders for durable goods
The

fell off some in August, but from a vastly improved July level.

upswing in orders since the early spring has been mirrored in a string
of healthy increases in industrial production, and, with motor vehicle
assemblies rebounding very strongly from an August dip, it appears
that we are likely to see another large gain in IP in September.

This

pattern is suggested as well by the various surveys of purchasing
managers, which have been flashing clear recovery signals in recent
months.
Looking at the nondefense capital goods component of the
durables figures, we can also see hints of a firming in spending on
business equipment.

The revised second-quarter GNP data show real

equipment outlays to have increased at a 6 percent annual rate, an
upward revision based on a higher estimate of aircraft purchases.

The

flat trend of computer orders should translate into hefty gains in
real outlays in the near term, and the orders pattern for industrial
equipment seems to point to a bottoming out in that category.

Thus,

- 4 -

October FOMC

Michael J. Prell

we expect to see continued gains in equipment spending over the second
half.
The last positive element I'll note is the inventory
situation.

Businesses have continued to trim inventories at a pace

greater than we anticipated, and thus stocks look even leaner at this
point than we had predicted.

We could be surprised yet again, but we

think that--barring another severe shock to business confidence--it is
most likely that we'll be getting a moderate impetus from an abatement
of destocking over the next several months.
All in all, then, many of the familiar elements of cyclical
recovery would appear to be at work, and we think they will continue
to override the unusual drags on aggregate demand we are experiencing
in this episode.

The risks in the outlook may well be somewhat

asymmetric to the downside, but we don't view them as totally one-way:
As has happened in the past, this recovery could yet surprise us on
the upside, as some other forecasters are predicting.
I'd like to turn briefly, now, to the inflation outlook.

If

you examine the most recent poll of the Blue Chip forecasters, from
early September, our projection of real output growth stands well up
in their distribution.

Yet our forecast of inflation, with the CPI

increasing 3.6 percent in 1992, is a shade below the average.

Most of

those who have lower inflation forecasts have appreciably more subdued
expectations for output as well.
relative optimism?

Is there a justification for our

I think so, but I also would have to grant that I

have some concerns.
First, on why we may be differing from the Blue Chip
consensus:

As I read and listen to many private analysts, I perceive

a couple of major points in their arguments for less favorable
inflation outlook.

One is that the amount of slack in the economy

isn't all that great, and the other is the thought that, once the

- 5 -

October FOMC

Michael J. Prell

economy has been growing for a while, inflation is likely to turn up-even if some slack remains.

Our analysis of history suggests that,

with the unemployment rate at 6-1/2 percent plus, we have an
appreciable amount of slack and that disinflationary pressures should
be substantial.

Admittedly, the restructuring occurring in many

industries could cause frictions in the labor market that raise the
natural rate, but we don't think this is greatly affecting the
situation.

As to the conflict between growth and disinflation, the

econometrics certainly can't be said to rule out the possibility that,
once sales and jobs are perceived to be on a solid growth path,
progress in lowering wage and price inflation may become more
difficult to achieve, but our reading of history suggests that the
existence of slack is the more important force.
Perhaps my greatest concern about our seemingly optimistic
inflation forecast derives simply from the difficulty in reading the
price figures we have in hand to discern what the trends to date are.
If one looks to the CPI ex food and energy for a rough guide to the
trends in core inflation, for example, one sees that this measure rose
4.6 percent in the year ended this August, after having accelerated to
5.5 percent in the year ended August 1990.

This suggests that there

already is a distinct disinflationary trend in process as a result of
the recession.

A 3-3/4 percent increase in these prices in 1992, our

current forecast, looks quite reasonable.

But when I look closely at

the composition of the price deceleration to date, I find some rather
disconcerting elements.

First, in contradiction to what most people

would anticipate, the commodities component of the core CPI actually
has increased faster than in the previous year, and the deceleration
is more than accounted for by the services component.

Second, within

the services component, the bulk of the slowing is accounted for by a
reversal of what seemed like an inexplicably high rate of increase in

October FOMC

- 6 -

owners' equivalent rents last year.

Michael J. Prell

These patterns raise some

question in my mind as to whether some flukes of measurement might be
distorting the trends and whether the probability distribution around
our inflation forecast might not be skewed somewhat toward the high
side.
Mr. Promisel will now add a few words about the role of the
external sector in our forecast.

Larry J. Promisel

BRIEFING FOR FOMC, OCTOBER 1, 1991

I would like to review some of the international statistics
released since the last meeting that bear on our view of the prospects
for U.S. exports and imports.
With respect first to exports, we have seen some surprises in
terms of foreign demand.

Most notably, data showed that GDP in Canada

rose at about a 5 percent annual rate, following four quarters of
Canadian exports were especially strong, but final domestic

decline.

demand grew 6 percent, as well.

Inventories dropped sharply.

We had thought that Japanese GNP had fallen back slightly in the
second quarter following the 11 percent annual growth rate in the first
But GNP was reported to have increased at a 2 percent annual

quarter.

rate in the second quarter, with the growth of domestic demand slowing
only from about 5 percent to about 4 percent.

The main factor behind the

slowing of overall growth in the second quarter was a decline in exports
at more than a 10 percent rate -- some part of which seems to have been a
seasonal adjustment problem.
In contrast, in Germany, GNP did fall back as anticipated,
following its first-quarter surge.

Growth in the rest of Europe on

average was pretty much in line with our expectations, that is, it
remained subdued -- perhaps a little more strength than some had feared
in France, but also not the recovery in the United Kingdom that some had
hoped for.
Adding all that together, using U.S. nonagricultural export
weights, the level of GNP in major foreign industrial countries was 1/2

- 2 percent higher in the second quarter (not annual rate) than we had
previously estimated (and also 1/2 percent higher than in the first
However, this development does not significantly alter our

quarter).

forecast for U.S. exports.

The higher level of foreign demand enables us

to explain more easily the strength of nonagricultural exports in the
second quarter, when they rose 4 percent in real terms (not annual rate).
The higher level of foreign demand itself does not in our view have
significant implications for the future growth of U.S. exports.
Moreover, those second-quarter statistics on foreign activity,
coupled with fragmentary indicators for the third quarter, have not
caused us to revise upward our forecast for growth of GNP in the foreign
industrial countries.

We continue to forecast growth at an average

annual rate of about 2 1/2 percent from the second quarter of 1991 to the
end of 1992 -- somewhat higher when account is taken of forecast growth
in major developing countries, as well.

For the near term, this average

results from some expected sluggishness in activity in Japan and Germany
offset by strength elsewhere.

The second-quarter data reduce to some

extent our perception of the degree of downside risk, particularly for
this year.
On the import side, we were impressed by the strength in the
quantity of U.S. nonoil imports in July, following their 3 1/2 percent
rise (not annual rate) in the second quarter.

Very tentative indicators

suggest to us that a good deal of the July increase will be sustained in
August, implying at least as large an increase in nonoil imports in the
third quarter as in the second.

We have assumed that most of the

stronger imports reflects some combination of the strengthening of U.S.
final demand and a planned buildup of inventories of imported goods.
Some portion of the notable increase in imports of computers in the

- 3second quarter and in July seems to have represented a one-time shift in
the level of such imports related to the imposition of a high tariff on
U.S. imports of active matrix liquid crystal displays, used in advanced
laptop computers.

We have revised upward by about 3 percent the path of

nonoil imports, leaving the growth rate from the third quarter about the
same as in the August forecast.
In terms of real net exports, the basic thrust of our forecast
remains about unchanged.

A positive contribution to U.S. GNP growth that

we had anticipated for the third quarter has disappeared.

On the other

hand, the subsequent path of real net exports is a little less negative
than we had previously forecast, largely reflecting a slight lowering of
the path for the exchange value of the dollar.

We continue to expect

that the change in net exports will be an essentially neutral element in
the growth of GNP over the projection period, with an anticipated strong
growth in exports being offset by strong growth in imports.
I might note, finally, that our forecast makes little reference
to the remarkable and historic events unfolding in the Soviet Union.
While the Soviet Union is a large geographic region, and ultimately
should play an important role in the world economy, it is symptomatic of
the Soviet Union's isolation from the West over the past 70 years that,
barring some kind of major further disruption to its oil production, what
happens to that economy is not likely to have a significant direct impact
on the U.S. or world economy over anything like the projection period.
However, we cannot exclude the possibility of an indirect influence
through financial markets of political developments in the former Soviet
Union.
Mr. Chairman, that concludes our report.

September 30, 1991
FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

As Mike noted, the issue for policy at this time seems to be
whether additional monetary policy stimulus is needed to achieve
something like the Committee's objective for a sustained moderate
expansion accompanied by declining inflation.

With regard to develop-

ments in financial markets, since the last meeting, we have seen continued anemic flows of money and private credit, along with declining
interest rates all along the yield curve.

This combination of slug-

gish flows and falling interest rates is potentially troubling, since
the most obvious explanation is downward shifts in demand associated
with a weak economy, thereby weighing in the side of the need for
additional ease.

Alternatively, however, weak money and credit may

primarily reflect balance sheet restructuring with minimal implications for aggregate demand, and the declines in interest rates may
simply reflect market anticipation and then digestion of the policy
easing combined with the belated recognition by bond holders that
inflation is not likely to accelerate appreciably in the next few
years.
In the interests of truth in labeling, let me begin by noting
that the staff has no new insights that will clearly sort among competing explanations for the extraordinary weakness in financial flows
or draw obvious implications.

Still, the phenomena are so striking

and potentially important--partly because the Committee does have
publicly announced ranges for money and credit--it might be worthwhile
reviewing the outlines of the issues as background for the Committee's
decision.

One way to look at the restructuring argument is to view a
great deal of what is going on today as an unwinding of some of the
financial developments that occurred in the expansion of the 1980s.
Those years saw an unusually rapid expansion of debt relative to income or net worth.

On the household side this involved a simultaneous

build-up of financial assets; for businesses it arose importantly from
a substitution of debt for equity.

Today's sluggish flows are consis-

tent with both assets and liabilities being reined in relative to
income and with the cessation of borrowing to retire equity.

Under

these circumstances, slow growth of credit and money need not necessarily indicate damped expansion of income or downward shifts in
demands for goods and services--only that spending is being financed
more by drawing on financial assets than by taking on new debt, and
that some old debt is being repaid out of existing assets and new
equity.
In addition, the borrowing that is occurring is being concentrated in instruments whose rates are fixed over the longer term.
This is the case not only for businesses issuing large volumes of
bonds, but for households as well who are showing a distinct preference for fixed-rate mortgages despite the much lower current rates on
floating rate instruments.

This shift, along with the greater em-

phasis on equity financing, implies that what funds flows there are
have tended to bypass depository intermediaries, so that money stock
measures, which concentrate on the liabilities of these
intermediaries, are especially depressed.

In effect, through

purchases of bond funds and other capital market instruments,
households are meeting the demands for long-term funds.
The shifts toward lower borrowing levels and longer maturity
debt have been overlaid on the phasing down of a major intermediary

class--the thrifts--whose liabilities are among those counted as
"money".

It is probably not mere happenstance that the recent run of

shortfalls in money relative to expectations began around mid-year
1990, when the RTC first became active, and that the major surprise in
the third quarter of this year coincided with a marked step-up in RTC
activity.

The channels for the influence of RTC activity on M2 are

not obvious.

But the disruption of depositor relationships from clos-

ing thrifts may accelerate portfolio reallocations outside of M2, as
would the termination of brokered deposits at these institutions.
To a considerable extent, these restructuring processes may
not be having adverse effects on the economy--indeed, they may be
quite healthy for the longer-run strength of the financial system and
the ability of nonfinancial sectors to fund future spending.

However,

from some other perspectives the impulses behind the restructuring and
the associated weakness in money and credit may not be entirely benign.

Over the past year or so, shortfalls in money growth have been

accompanied by slower than expected expansion of the economy.

Some of

the balance sheet restructuring has been prompted by difficulties at
financial intermediaries, even apart from the special case of the
thrifts.

Those difficulties have been reflected in cutbacks in credit

supplies and widening margins of lending over borrowing rates, which
have contributed to the propensity to use M2 to finance purchases or
pay down debt.

The widening intermediation spread, though bolstering

the income of the owners of the intermediaries, raises the effective
cost of spending financed by borrowing.

Moreover, some of the demands

for longer-term credit, which themselves may have tended to keep
longer-term interest rates relatively elevated, may also reflect concerns about the future availability of funds from banks or in the
commercial paper market.

To an extent, therefore, the weakness in

money and credit probably has signified greater tightness in effective
financial conditions than might be indexed by the federal funds rate.
Still, there is highly unlikely to be a one for one correspondence
between shortfalls in growth of money and credit and in income or
spending.
Looking ahead, this story of "on the one hand", "on the
other", doesn't provide much guidance for policy.

The approach the

Committee has followed so far has been to give the behavior in money
and credit heavy, but not a dominant, weight in policy decisions.
This suggests sufficient doubts about the significance of particular
growth rates for money and credit to deter acting on them alone, but
sufficient worries to prompt unusually rapid responses when other
indicators also tend to point toward weaker than desired track for the
economy.
In the context of the continuing weakness in money and credit, this approach might still call for alternative B, with asymmetrical wording toward ease on intermeeting adjustments.

The unchanged

conditions of alternative B would be appropriate if the Committee were
of the view that recent easing most likely had been adequate to assure
satisfactory expansion of the economy.

The asymmetry toward ease

would connote that the Committee was more concerned that the lack of
money and credit growth meant that financial markets might be tighter
and the economy might be on a weaker path than desirable.

Such judg-

ments are complicated by the recognition that the easing actions of
August and September have not yet had an opportunity to affect
economic or financial data.
There are at least some reasons to believe the recent declines in interest rates have a significant real component that will
bolster the economy ahead.

Real rates are impossible to measure with

-5-

confidence, but a weakish

dollar,

especially against the yen given

interest rates in Japan, and at least a fairly level stock

declines in

market in the face of widely expressed doubts about the strength of

the economy,

suggest some declines in real rates.
some expectation of future easing,

have built in

relatively recent phenomenon,
dollar weakness are not.
easings was in

While markets may
that appears to be a

while the stock market stability

A sense that appreciable

and

stimulus from past

train might argue for a more balanced approach to

incoming data over the intermeeting period--that

is,

a symmetrical

directive.
The recent declines in
money growth,

nominal

although the fairly

deposit rates and the effects

prompt adjustment of small time

of even greater

deposit holders will limit the drop in
effects.

Nonetheless,

under alternative B,

rates also should help to buoy

opportunity costs and their

we are projecting some strengthening in

quarter.

M2

to a 3 percent pace from September to December,

leaving this aggregate at the lower end of its
reflects in

"sticker shock" by time

range.

The

pickup

part stronger nominal GNP growth projected for the fourth

More important,

unusual weakness in

however,

we are assuming that some of the

money growth seen in

the third quarter abates.

To

the extent the unusual weakness reflected a rethinking of portfolio
allocation,

those M2 holders with very liquid assets have already had

a chance to act on their impulses.
The three percent projection leaves M2 just at the lower
bound of its

growth range in

the fourth quarter--a

deliberate aspect of the projection.

convenient,

but not

If the Committee were of the

view that slower money growth were an unavoidable by-product of ap-

propriately gauged policies in reserve markets, it is under no obligation under the law to achieve those targets.

The law does call for

explanations of the reasons for revisions to or deviations from plans
in subsequent reports to Congress.

In the past, we have occasionally

notified Congress when we have made major changes in targets, but we
have not followed a consistent practice of giving warning of misses,
even when they appeared inevitable some time before year-end.
If the sluggish performance of money and credit was of considerable concern to the Committee, or significant weight was being
placed on recent softer indicators and suggestions of eroding business
and consumer confidence, then an immediate easing, as under alternative A, would be appropriate.

Such a policy would be consistent with

a somewhat more activist stance by the Federal Reserve to assure an
adequate expansion of the money stock and the economy, but raises the
odds that a tightening might be needed at some point to keep price
pressures on a downward trajectory.
There is some question about the extent to which lower interest rates would in fact boost money growth, especially if the decline
in rates were at the same time to steepen the yield curve.

Bowing in

this direction, the staff trimmed the difference between money growth
under bluebook alternatives A and B.

Nonetheless, it is our judgment

that the effects of lower market rates on the opportunity costs of
holding liquid deposits, whose rates are unlikely to change very much,
will more than offset the negative effects of a steeper yield curve,
other things equal.

Given the response of liquid deposits to an eas-

ing, lower rates will almost certainly involve faster growth of Ml and
reserves.

In any case, in the short run it would be easier to defend

and explain any shortfall from target if the Committee had actively
eased reserve conditions to hit the range.