View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note

The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 1/12/2024.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book A
Economic and Financial Conditions:
Outlook, Risks, and Policy Strategies
October 26, 2018

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Domestic Economic Developments and Outlook
The data on economic activity that we have received in the past several weeks
indicate that the economy is expanding solidly. Real GDP appears on track to rise
3 percent for the year as a whole, bolstered by expansionary fiscal policy and financial
conditions that remain generally supportive despite recent substantial declines in equity
prices. Meanwhile, the labor market tightened further in September, and we continue to
expect robust job gains in coming months, with the unemployment rate edging down to
3.6 percent by the end of this year. Overall, our assessment of the tightness of resource
utilization in the current quarter is not materially different from that in the September
Tealbook. 1
Our medium-term forecast for GDP growth is somewhat lower than in the
September Tealbook, primarily reflecting the recent declines in equity prices. We now
expect the output gap to widen from 2½ percent currently to 3 percent in 2020 before
dropping back—about ¼ percentage point narrower throughout the medium term than in
the September Tealbook forecast. The path for the unemployment rate has
correspondingly revised up slightly, bottoming out at 3.3 percent in 2020. Apart from
equity prices, other influences on the contour of real GDP are mostly similar to our
previous projection. In particular, while rising interest rates appear to be exerting a
modest drag on economic activity to date—largely showing through in declining
residential investment—we expect a more noticeable drag on economic activity over the
next few years as monetary policy tightens further. In addition, we expect the boost from
fiscal policy to wane and recent trade policy actions to restrain growth a little. All told,
real GDP growth is projected to slow steadily from 3 percent this year to 1½ percent
in 2021.
The 12-month change in core PCE prices is estimated to have been 1.9 percent in
September, and we forecast it to remain around that level through the end of this year.
Core PCE price inflation edges up to 2.0 percent over the medium term, as labor and
product markets tighten further. Total PCE price inflation is projected to run slightly
above core inflation through the end of this year and then to run a touch below it
thereafter, as consumer energy prices are forecast to decline in the medium term.
The BEA’s report on third-quarter GDP was released after the close of the Tealbook forecast. As
a result, the exhibits do not reflect these data.
1

Page 1 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Comparing the Staff Projection with Other Forecasts
The October Tealbook projection for real GDP growth lies close to both the Blue
Chip consensus forecast and the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) median
forecast for 2018; all three forecasts step down in 2019 and are within a narrow range.
The staff’s unemployment rate forecast is in line with the others in 2018 and a touch
below the Blue Chip consensus in 2019. The staff projection for measures of price
inflation are close to the Blue Chip consensus and SPF median forecasts in both 2018
and 2019.

Comparison of Tealbook and Outside Forecasts
2018

2019

GDP (Q4/Q4 percent change)
October Tealbook
Blue Chip (10/10/18)
SPF median (08/10/18)

3.0
3.1
2.9

2.4
2.3
n.a.

Unemployment rate (Q4 level)
October Tealbook
Blue Chip (10/10/18)
SPF median (08/10/18)

3.6
3.7
3.7

3.3
3.5
n.a.

CPI inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
October Tealbook
Blue Chip (10/10/18)
SPF median (08/10/18)

2.3
2.5
2.4

2.3
2.3
2.3

PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
October Tealbook
SPF median (08/10/18)

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.1

Core PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
October Tealbook
SPF median (08/10/18)

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

Note: SPF is the Survey of Professional Forecasters, CPI is the consumer price index,
and PCE is personal consumption expenditures. Blue Chip does not provide results for
overall and core PCE price inflation. The Blue Chip consensus forecast includes input from
about 50 panelists, and the SPF about 40. Roughly 20 panelists contribute to both surveys.
n.a. Not available.
Source: Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Page 2 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Tealbook Forecast Compared with Blue Chip
Real GDP

Industrial Production
Percent change, annual rate

Blue Chip consensus
Staff forecast

Percent change, annual rate

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-8

2011

Unemployment Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

Consumer Price Index
Percent

Percent change, annual rate

10

6

8

4
2
0

6

-2

5

2013

2015

2017

2019

8

9

7

2011

12
10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12

-4

4

-6

3

-8

2

2011

Treasury Bill Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

-10

10-Year Treasury Yield
Percent

Percent

4

5.5
5.0

3

4.5
4.0

2

3.5
3.0

1

2.5
2.0

0

1.5
2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-1

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

Note: The yield is for on-the-run Treasury securities. Over
the forecast period, the staff’s projected yield is assumed
to be 15 basis points below the off-the-run yield.
Note: The shaded area represents the area between the Blue Chip top 10 and bottom 10 averages.

Page 3 of 124

1.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Key Background Factors underlying the Baseline Staff Projection

Federal Funds Rate

Long-Term Interest Rates
Percent

Percent

6

Quarterly average

11

Quarterly average
10
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

5

9

Conforming
mortgage rate
4

8

Triple-B
corporate yield

7
6

3

5
2

4

1

2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

0

3

10-year
Treasury yield
2007

Equity Prices

2009

2011

2
2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

1

House Prices
Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100

Quarter-end

Dow Jones
U.S. Total Stock Market
Index

Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100

250
245
230
215
200
185
170
155
140
125

Quarterly

125
120
115
110
105
100
95

110

90

95
CoreLogic
Index

80

85
80
75

65

70
50
2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

2007

Crude Oil Prices

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

65

Broad Real Dollar
Dollars per barrel

2007:Q1 = 100

140

115

Quarterly average

Quarterly average

110

120

Imported oil

105
100
100
West Texas
Intermediate

80
95
60
90
40

2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

20

85

2007

Page 4 of 124

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

80

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Compared with the September Tealbook projection, inflation is a little lower in the
medium term, as resource utilization is a bit less tight.

KEY BACKGROUND FACTORS
Monetary Policy
•

The inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule that we use in our projection
calls for the federal funds rate to step up about ¼ percentage point over the
rest of this year, to increase 1½ percentage points next year, and to rise, on
average, ½ percentage point per year in 2020 and 2021, reaching nearly
5 percent in the fourth quarter of 2021. This trajectory is a little lower than
the one in the September Tealbook because of the narrower projected
output gap.

•

The size of the SOMA portfolio continues a gradual and predictable decline in
a manner consistent with the Committee’s public declarations.

Other Interest Rates
•

The 10-year Treasury yield is projected to rise from an average of about
3¼ percent in the current quarter to 4¼ percent by the end of 2021. This
projected path is similar to the one in the September Tealbook.
o The federal funds rate rises above the 10-year rate in the third quarter of
2020, similar to the September Tealbook.

•

The path of the triple-B corporate bond yield is also similar to the one in the
previous Tealbook, while the 30-year fixed mortgage rate has been revised up
a bit over the next few quarters in response to recent market quotes. Both
interest rates are projected to rise significantly over the medium term.

Equity Prices and Home Prices
•

Equity prices declined substantially in recent weeks amid concerns about
international trade policies, global growth, and potential interest rate
increases. Equity prices are now projected to end the year about 9 percent
below the September Tealbook forecast. 2 Beyond the current quarter, we

As we were finalizing the staff projection, stock market prices were quite volatile. The quotes in
this paragraph are based on the market close on Wednesday, October 24.
2

Page 5 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

expect stock prices to edge up about ½ percent per year, similar to our
previous forecast. Over the medium term, stock price appreciation is held
down, because we judge equity valuations to be elevated even after
considering the recent price declines.
•

The latest housing market data have been softer than expected, and in
response, we have marked down our house price projection. We now expect
house price increases to slow from 6 percent in 2017 to 4 percent this year, a
larger deceleration than in the September Tealbook. We also nudged down
our forecast for house prices over the next three years and expect the rise in
house prices to moderate further, to an average pace of 3 percent; the
slowdown reflects both the ongoing rise in mortgage rates and our assessment
that house prices are modestly elevated relative to rents.

Fiscal Policy
•

We assume that the expansionary fiscal policies enacted over the past year
will continue through the medium term. 3 Given these policy assumptions, we
still estimate that discretionary fiscal policy actions across all levels of
government will contribute a bit more than ½ percentage point to the rate of
growth in aggregate demand in both 2019 and 2020, exclusive of any
multiplier effects and financial offsets. This contribution eases to
¼ percentage point in 2021.

•

We expect the federal budget deficit, which stood at 3½ percent of GDP in
fiscal year 2017, to widen to 5¾ percent by fiscal 2021, primarily reflecting
recent fiscal policy actions and the effects of higher interest rates on debt
service costs. The box “Fiscal Policy and the State of the Economy” provides
some historical perspective on the size of recent and projected deficits relative
to the state of the business cycle.
o We continue to assume that, in the longer run, policymakers will gradually
reduce deficits by an amount sufficient to stabilize the debt-to-GDP ratio.
We expect this ratio to stabilize at around 105 percent of GDP,

In particular, our forecast assumes that the current level of discretionary spending will be
maintained in real terms in fiscal years 2020 and 2021; realization of that forecast will require lifting the
discretionary spending caps for those years, which would be consistent with fiscal policymaker actions in
the recent past.
3

Page 6 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

20 percentage points higher than would have occurred in the absence of
recent and projected policy actions. We anticipate that this increment to
the debt-to-GDP ratio will push up the term premium on 10-year Treasury
yields 50 basis points in the longer run.
o In the near term, legislation to fund roughly one-fourth of federal
discretionary spending for fiscal 2019 remains unresolved, and without
further action, current funding would expire in the first week of
December. The baseline projection continues to assume that funding
legislation will be enacted and there will be no meaningful disruption of
government operations. 4

Foreign Economic Activity and the Dollar
•

Real GDP in the foreign economies is expected to grow 2½ percent in the
second half of this year, similar to its first-half pace. The projection for the
second half is little changed relative to the September Tealbook, as weakerthan-expected third-quarter GDP growth in the emerging market economies
was offset by stronger-than-expected growth in the advanced foreign
economies. For the remainder of the forecast period, we continue to project
GDP growth abroad to be close to its potential pace of around 2¾ percent.

•

Since the September Tealbook, the broad nominal dollar has appreciated
¾ percent. Over the forecast period, we expect the broad real dollar to
appreciate at an annual rate of about 1½ percent as market expectations for the
federal funds rate move up toward the staff’s assumed path. The downward
revision to the staff’s federal funds path implies a little less dollar appreciation
than in the September Tealbook, leaving our projection for the broad real
dollar at the end of the forecast horizon only a touch higher.

Oil Prices
•

The spot price of Brent crude oil is down about $3 per barrel, on net, since the
September Tealbook, closing most recently at $76 per barrel. Brent prices
rose to $86 per barrel on October 3, their highest level in four years, reflecting
concerns about the effects of impending U.S. sanctions on Iranian exports.

A lapse in appropriations that resulted in a short-term partial shutdown of the federal government
would have only minor implications for the outlook.
4

Page 7 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Fiscal Policy and the State of the Economy
The federal fiscal policy assumptions in the staff’s baseline forecast yield primary budget deficits
that average just under 3 percent of GDP between fiscal year (FY) 2018 and FY2021. Here we put
these budget policies in historical perspective using two different measures—the cyclically
adjusted primary (CAP) budget deficit and the staff’s measure of fiscal impetus. During the
FY2018 to FY2021 period, we expect that fiscal policy will result in relatively large deficits and will
provide a modest boost to aggregate demand, both of which—especially the former—are
atypical relative to the state of the business cycle.
The CAP deficit is often used to assess the sustainability of budget policies. The CAP deficit makes
two adjustments to the total federal deficit. First, by focusing on the primary deficit, the CAP
deficit excludes net interest payments associated with servicing existing government debt.1
Second, the CAP deficit removes the transitory effects of the business cycle by estimating what
the primary deficit would be if output were at its potential level. 2
Figure 1 shows the historical relationship between the CAP deficit on the vertical axis and the
output gap on the horizontal axis. The expected CAP deficits for FY2018 to FY2021 (red triangles)
are outliers. Historically, when the output gap has been as large as staff projections for FY2018 to
FY2021, the CAP deficit has been considerably smaller (as in FY1966 to FY1968) or the government
has run a CAP surplus (as in FY1998 to FY2001). The last time the CAP deficit was roughly as large
as staff projections for FY2018 to FY2021 was during the Great Recession, when the output gap
was large and negative.
Figure 1: Cyclically Adjusted Primary Deficits and the Output Gap

Note: The figure displays data for FY1964 to FY2017 and staff estimates and projections for FY2018 to FY2021.
Source: Staff estimates.
1 Persistently balancing the primary deficit implies a stable debt-to-GDP ratio if the pace of nominal GDP

growth is equal to the average nominal rate of interest on the debt.
2 The cyclically adjusted measure removes the deficit effects of automatic stabilizers (for example, lower
taxes in response to reduced incomes or higher income-support payments triggered by a rise in unemployment)
that operate when the economy is not at its potential level. This measure does not remove the effects of
discretionary fiscal policy actions that are in response to the business cycle, such as a reduction in tax rates during
a recession.

Page 8 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Further, the staff projects that the CAP deficit will increase while the output gap increases
between FY2018 and FY2021. This pattern contrasts with the historical relationship, which, on
average, implies that the CAP deficit decreases when the output gap increases. 3
Growth in the CAP deficit beginning in FY2018 largely results from discretionary fiscal policy
actions, specifically tax cuts from the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA) and spending increases from
the Bipartisan Budget Act (BBA 2018). The staff forecast assumes that elevated spending levels
from the BBA 2018 remain in place beyond FY2019, growing with inflation each year (even
though, under current law, appropriations are set to return to lower levels at the end of FY2019).
Figure 2 illustrates how these policies affect aggregate demand. This figure shows fiscal impetus
(FI), the first-round direct effect of discretionary fiscal policy actions on the growth of aggregate
demand, on the vertical axis and the output gap on the horizontal axis. The FI projections imply
that discretionary fiscal policy at the federal level will boost aggregate demand growth by
roughly ½ percentage point per year through FY2020 and then taper off in FY2021 when the tax
and spending policies are fully phased in.
Because FI is measured in terms of aggregate demand growth, it is associated with changes in,
rather than the level of, the CAP deficit. The magnitude of FI depends in part on the type of fiscal
policy that drives the CAP deficit changes. The increase in projected CAP deficits for FY2018 to
FY2021 results largely from the TCJA tax cuts. By comparison, historical CAP deficits in years with
a comparable output gap, such as FY1966 and FY1967, resulted mainly from defense spending
increases and growth in government transfers, which provide a relatively larger boost to
aggregate demand compared to tax decreases. 4

Figure 2: Fiscal Impetus and the Output Gap

Note: The figure displays data for FY1964 to FY2017 and staff estimates and projections for FY2018 to FY2021.
Source: Staff estimates.
3 Excluding FY2009 to FY2011 (which, if included, would make the relationship even more negative), a

1 percentage point increase in the output gap is associated with a 0.15 percentage point reduction in the CAP
deficit.
4 Although a 1 percentage point increase in defense purchases (as a percent of GDP) increases
aggregate demand by 1 percentage point, we estimate that a similarly sized tax cut will boost demand by only
two-thirds that amount.
Page 9 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

More recently, prices retreated on reports of increasing production in Saudi
Arabia, Russia, and the United States. Farther-dated futures prices are about
unchanged, with the Brent futures price for delivery in December 2021 at
$68 per barrel.

THE OUTLOOK FOR REAL GDP AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY
Our Tealbook projection has real GDP growth slowing from an annual rate of
3¼ percent in the first half of this year to a still-solid 2¾ percent pace in the second half.
The BEA’s advance estimate of GDP growth in the third quarter, which was released
after the close of this forecast, was 3.5 percent, 0.6 percentage point above our Tealbook
estimate. Consumer spending was stronger than we had anticipated while business fixed
investment was weaker, leaving private domestic final purchases, or PDFP, close to our
expectations. However, government purchases and inventory investment were above our
expectations. Our preliminary assessment is that some of the third-quarter GDP surprise
will be reversed in the fourth quarter, leaving GDP growth in the second half just a little
stronger than our Tealbook projection. 5 (The accompanying exhibits present the
Tealbook forecast and do not reflect the third-quarter GDP data.)
•

We expect that Hurricanes Florence and Michael will leave essentially no
imprint on GDP growth for the second half overall. Daily retail sales data
from First Data suggest that Hurricane Florence had a very small negative
effect (less than 5 basis points) on PCE growth in the third quarter; the effect
from Hurricane Michael appears even smaller. The effects of the hurricanes
on industrial production are also likely to be small: We estimate that total IP
growth for the second half will be held down by about 0.1 percentage point
because of the hurricanes, with some small manufacturing disruptions from
Hurricane Florence and noticeable but short-lived disruptions to oil and
natural gas production from Hurricane Michael.

•

Recent data on consumer spending continue to point to stronger PCE growth
in the second half of this year than in the first half. Spending continues to be
supported by the recent tax cuts, wealth gains from earlier increases in equity
prices and home values, solid gains in labor income, and favorable consumer

We will provide further details on the implications of the BEA’s report for our projection
next week.
5

Page 10 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

sentiment. The box “Household Wealth and the Personal Saving Rate”
discusses how the composition of household wealth may be affecting
aggregate consumption.
•

The third-quarter data on business fixed investment were disappointing.
Investment in equipment and intangibles slowed from its first-half pace, while
investment in nonresidential structures—especially drilling structures—
declined. Nonetheless, we expect investment growth to pick back up in the
fourth quarter, as we see investment continuing to be supported by solid
business output growth, ample access to financing, still-upbeat readings on
business sentiment, buoyant profit expectations, and the effects of last year’s
tax cuts.

•

With rising mortgage interest rates weighing on the affordability of housing,
residential investment appears on track to continue to decline modestly in the
second half of the year. Relative to the September Tealbook, we weakened
our residential investment forecast for the rest of this year and most of next
year, because recent indicators of housing demand have been weaker than
expected and mortgage rates over the next few quarters have revised up. That
said, we expect residential investment to flatten out next year, with the drag
from mortgage interest rates roughly offset by demand for new construction
driven by population growth, demographic changes, and a strong labor
market.

•

Net exports are projected to subtract about 1 percentage point from GDP
growth for the second half of this year after adding ½ percentage point in the
first half. The swing is partly attributable to soybean exports. In addition,
appreciation of the dollar this year has removed some support to net exports.
Compared with the September Tealbook, the contribution from net exports to
real GDP growth in the second half is about ½ percentage point more
negative.

•

Manufacturing production, which rose at an annual rate of 2¾ percent in the
third quarter, is expected to ease somewhat through the remainder of this year
and early next year. This deceleration mainly reflects a step-down in motor
vehicle production (and the upstream effects on other manufacturers).

Page 11 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Household Wealth and the Personal Saving Rate
The NIPA personal saving rate (left panel of figure 1) is now reported to have remained elevated
over the past few years rather than falling back toward pre-recession levels, as was estimated
prior to the recent BEA comprehensive revision. The right panel of figure 1 shows why this
persistently high saving rate may be a puzzle: Growth of household wealth relative to income
should be pushing the saving rate down.1 Here we explore whether trends in the composition
and distribution of household wealth might currently be holding down aggregate consumption
and raising the saving rate. We focus on differences in borrowing and spending behavior across
age and wealth groups as well as the extent to which net saving (or more importantly, net
dissaving) in particular balance sheet categories has led to movements in the overall saving rate.
The four net worth components we focus on are consumer credit, owner-occupied housing,
retirement accounts, and the residual, labeled “other assets.” Consumer credit includes
nonhousing liabilities such as credit card, vehicle, and student loans. Owner-occupied housing
wealth (or net housing) is the market value of housing less mortgage debt outstanding.
Retirement accounts include traditional defined benefit pensions and account-type 401(k),
403(b), and IRA plans. The residual other assets are mostly closely held businesses and financial
assets like stocks and bonds that are held outside of retirement accounts.
The evolving composition of wealth in the right panel of figure 1 is associated with a shifting
distribution of wealth across types of households. The Board’s Survey of Consumer Finances
(SCF) finds that the share of wealth held by households with a head aged 55 or older increased
from 53 percent in 1989 to 71 percent by 2016. In addition, the share of wealth held by the top
wealth quartile increased from 80 percent to 85 percent for both the young and old.2
Figure 1: Saving and Wealth Relative to Income

1 For additional staff perspective on the effect of wealth on saving and consumption, see

Aditya Aladangady
and Laura Feiveson (2018), “A Not-So-Great Recovery in Consumption: What is Holding Back Household
Spending?” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 8),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/what-is-holding-back-household-spending20180308.htm.
2 The concept of wealth used here includes an estimate of defined benefit pensions. See Sebastian DevlinFoltz, Alice Henriques, and John Sabelhaus (2016), “Is the U.S. Retirement System Contributing to Rising Wealth
Inequality?” Russell Sage Foundation Journal of the Social Sciences, vol. 2 (November), pp. 59–85.

Page 12 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

In order to shed light on movements in the saving rate over time, figure 2 presents annual
changes in the different components of wealth from figure 1 after stripping out the relevant
capital gains from each balance sheet category.
Figure 2 shows that net saving in retirement accounts has fallen in the past decade, from about
10 percent of disposable income in the 1980s and ’90s to less than 5 percent in recent years. The
downward trend in net retirement account saving is attributable to aging, as benefit payments
and withdrawals are rising as a share of income, while new contributions relative to income are
little changed.3 However, in recent years, the decline in net retirement saving has been mostly
offset by increased saving in business and financial assets outside of retirement accounts, which
are held even more disproportionately at the top of the wealth distribution. If older and
wealthier households are less likely to spend out of their wealth than the younger and less
wealthy, this tendency may help explain why the saving rate has remained elevated despite
overall rising wealth relative to income.
Figure 2 also highlights the important role of housing in accounting for movements in the saving
rate over the past two decades. In the lead up to the financial crisis, NIPA saving dipped as
households increased mortgage debt much more than they invested in new housing. More
recently, net saving in owner-occupied housing has moved up and hovered near zero, as net
mortgage borrowing and net residential investment have both remained low.

The pre-recession housing-related dissaving is generally associated with younger and less wealthy
households. Those families borrowed extensively against housing to finance consumption or to
invest in more housing, and those behaviors have fundamentally changed in the past decade.
Younger and less wealthy households now carry more consumer debt and are less likely to have
entered into owning homes and stocks, and one downstream effect is that they have not benefited
from the rebound in asset prices.4 Regardless of whether mortgage demand or supply has shifted, it
is unlikely that we will return to the rates of housing dissaving observed in the pre-recession period.
Figure 2: Balance Sheet Decomposition of NIPA Personal Saving

3 The continued rise in retirement assets relative to income shown in figure 1 is increasingly due to capital

gains and not retirement account saving in the conventional NIPA sense.
4 For a discussion of wealth distribution trends in recent years, see Lisa J. Dettling, Joanne W. Hsu, and
Elizabeth Llanes (2018), “A Wealthless Recovery? Asset Ownership and the Uneven Recovery from the Great
Recession,” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 13),
https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/asset-ownership-and-the-uneven-recovery-from-thegreat-recession-20180913.htm.

Page 13 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Cyclical Position of the U.S. Economy: Near-Term Perspective
(Percent change at annual rate from final quarter
of preceding period except as noted)
Measure

2016

2017

2018

2018
Q2

2018
Q3

2018
Q4

Output gap1
Previous Tealbook

.4
.4

1.2
1.2

2.4
2.4

1.8
1.8

2.2
2.2

2.4
2.4

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

1.9
1.9

2.5
2.5

3.0
3.1

4.2
4.7

2.9
3.0

2.6
2.5

Measurement error in GDP
Previous Tealbook
Potential output
Previous Tealbook

-.3
-.3
1.6
1.6

.0
.0
1.6
1.6

.1
.2
1.7
1.7

.9
1.2
1.7
1.7

-.4
-.2
1.7
1.7

.0
-.2
1.7
1.7

Note: The output gap is the percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating
below potential. The change in the output gap is equal to real GDP growth less the contribution of measurement error less the growth rate of
potential output. For quarterly figures, the growth rates are at an annual rate, and this calculation needs to be multiplied by 1/4 to obtain
the quarterly change in the output gap.
1. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.

Judgmental Output Gap

Model-Based Output Gap
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook
90 percent
70 percent

Percent

5

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook
90 percent
70 percent

4
3

2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions show the distribution of historical
revisions to the staff’s estimates of the output gap.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

5
4
3

2

2

1

1

0

0

-1

-1

-2

-2

-3

2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions denote model-computed uncertainty
bands.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

Unemployment Rate

-3

Core PCE Price Inflation
Percent

Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural rate of unemployment*
Previous Tealbook
90 percent
70 percent

Percent change, 12-month change

7.0

Core
Previous Tealbook
Underlying inflation

6.5
6.0

3.0
2.5
2.0

5.5
1.5
5.0
1.0

4.5

.5

4.0
3.5
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Shaded regions show the distribution of historical
revisions to the staff’s estimates of the natural rate.
*Staff estimate including the effect of extended and emergency
unemployment insurance benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
staff assumptions.

2015
2016
2017
2018
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; staff assumptions.

Page 14 of 124

.0

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Indicators of factory activity from the national and regional manufacturing
surveys remain consistent with further gains in production.
Over the medium term, we project that real GDP growth will slow roughly
½ percentage point per year, from 3 percent this year to 1½ percent in 2021. The gradual
deceleration primarily reflects the ongoing tightening of monetary policy and waning
fiscal impetus.
•

Real GDP growth in this forecast is revised down relative to the September
Tealbook, mainly reflecting the effects of the lower paths of equity prices and
house prices. Partially offsetting these factors, net exports subtract less from
real GDP relative to the September Tealbook projection. 6 In addition, with
the output gap topping out about ¼ percentage point below our previous
projection, we now judge that supply constraints will not materially restrain
output growth. 7

•

In this forecast, we also incorporated the implications of the latest round of
tariffs on Chinese imports, which were put in place after the September
Tealbook closed and were not included in our previous projection. 8 We
expect that the cumulative effect of tariffs imposed this year will be to lower
the level of real GDP by about 0.2 percent over the medium term and raise
core PCE price inflation by less than 0.1 percentage point in each of 2018
and 2019.

•

We continue to assume that potential GDP growth will step up from
1.7 percent in 2018 to 1.9 percent in 2021, as structural productivity
accelerates.

•

With the federal government expected to run historically large and rising
deficits over the medium term, the national saving rate is projected to trend

The revised contribution of net exports to GDP primarily reflects our updated assessment of the
responsiveness of net exports to U.S. GDP, foreign GDP, and exchange rates.
7
That said, if our expectations for aggregate demand were to become more optimistic in
subsequent forecasts, we would likely build back in some small drag from supply constraints.
8
On September 24, the United States implemented an additional 10 percent tariff on about
$180 billion of Chinese imports. In response, China imposed retaliatory tariffs on $60 billion of U.S. goods
and also began to implement some nontariff trade barriers. We have not built into our forecast the
additional 15 percentage points of tariffs on Chinese imports that the United States has announced would
be imposed, in the absence of progress on trade negotiations, on January 1, 2019.
6

Page 15 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Summary of the Near-Term Outlook for GDP
(Percent change at annual rate except as noted)
2018:H1

2018:Q3

2018:Q4

Measure

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Real GDP
Private domestic final purchases
Personal consumption expenditures
Residential investment
Nonres. private fixed investment
Government purchases
Contributions to change in real GDP
Inventory investment1
Net exports1

3.4
3.3
2.3
-2.6
10.2
2.0

3.2
3.1
2.1
-2.4
10.1
2.0

3.0
2.8
2.9
-2.1
3.7
1.1

2.9
3.0
3.2
-5.2
4.0
2.1

2.5
3.4
2.7
-.2
7.9
1.6

2.6
3.3
2.7
-1.3
7.6
1.8

-.3
.6

-.5
.6

1.2
-.8

1.8
-1.8

-.3
-.3

-.4
-.1

1. Percentage points.

Recent Nonfinancial Developments (1)

Real GDP and GDI

Manufacturing IP ex. Motor Vehicles
and Parts
4-quarter percent change

Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income

3-month percent change, annual rate

8

15

6
Q2

20

Sept.

4

10
5
0

2

-5
0

-10

-2

-15
-20

-4
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

-6

-25
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

Sales and Production of Light Motor
Vehicles
Millions of units, annual rate

-30

Real PCE Growth
6-month percent change, annual rate

22

6

Aug.
4

18
Sales

2
Sept.

14
0
10
-2

Production
6

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Ward’s Communications; Chrysler; General Motors;
FRB seasonal adjustments.

2

-4

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Page 16 of 124

-6

October 26, 2018

Recent Nonfinancial Developments (2)
Single-Family Housing Starts and Permits

Home Sales

Millions of units
(annual rate)
Adjusted permits
Starts

2.1
1.8

7.5

1.5

6.0

1.2

5.5

0.6

1.2
0.9
Sept.

4.5

0.6

4.0
3.5

0.3
2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

1.5

Existing homes
(left scale)

5.0
0.9

0.0

1.8

7.0
6.5

Sept.

Millions of units
(annual rate)

Millions of units
(annual rate)

0.3

New single-family
homes (right scale)

3.0
2.5

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0.0

Source: For existing, National Association of Realtors;
for new, U.S. Census Bureau.

Note: Adjusted permits equal permit issuance plus starts
outside of permit-issuing areas.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Nondefense Capital Goods ex. Aircraft

Nonresidential Construction Put in Place

Ratio scale, billions of dollars

Billions of chained (2012) dollars

71

Sept.

450

Aug.

Orders
66

400

61

350

56

300

51

250

Shipments

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
Note: Data are 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2016

2018

46

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Nominal CPIP deflated by BEA prices through
2018:Q2 and by the staff’s estimated deflator thereafter.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Inventory Ratios

Exports and Non-oil Imports
Months

Billions of dollars

1.9

July
1.7

Sept.

Aug.

2008

2010

Non-oil imports

2012

2014

2016

2018

180

1.5

160

1.4

140
120

1.3

100

1.2

Census book-value data

220
200

1.6
Staff flow-of-goods system

260
240

1.8

2006

200

1.1

Note: Flow-of-goods system inventories include manufacturing
and mining industries and are relative to consumption. Census
data cover manufacturing and trade, and inventories are relative
to sales.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau; staff calculations.

Exports
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Forecasts are linear interpolations of quarterly values.
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; U.S. Census Bureau.

Page 17 of 124

80
60

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Federal Reserve System Nowcasts of 2018:Q3 Real GDP Growth
(Percent change at annual rate from previous quarter)

Federal Reserve Entity

Type of model

Nowcast
as of
Oct. 24,
2018

Federal Reserve Bank
Boston



Mixed-frequency BVAR

3.1

New York



Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination
Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination,
financial factors only
Dynamic factor model

2.2
1.9

Bayesian regressions with stochastic volatility
Tracking model

2.9
3.0




Cleveland




Atlanta



Tracking model combined with Bayesian vector
autoregressions (VARs), dynamic factor models, and
factor-augmented autoregressions (known as
GDPNow)

3.7

Chicago



Dynamic factor models
Bayesian VARs

4.4
3.1



Dynamic factor models
News index model
Let-the-data-decide regressions

2.2
4.4
2.8



Accounting-based tracking estimate

2.3



Board staff’s forecast (judgmental tracking model)1
Monthly dynamic factor models (DFM-45)
Mixed-frequency dynamic factor model (DFM-BM)

3.0
3.7
2.4



St. Louis




Kansas City
Board of Governors




Memo: Median of
Federal Reserve
System nowcasts

1

2.1

3.0

The October Tealbook forecast, finalized on October 25, 2018, is 2.9 percent.

Page 18 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

downward. Nevertheless, private domestic investment as a share of the
economy is roughly flat over the medium term. The widening gap between
domestic investment and national saving is financed by increased inflows of
foreign capital.

THE OUTLOOK FOR THE LABOR MARKET
Labor market conditions tightened further in September, about in line with our
expectations. 9
•

According to the BLS, total nonfarm payrolls increased 134,000 in
September—about 60,000 less than we had expected, with roughly half of the
downward surprise likely due to disruptions from Hurricane Florence (which
we had not incorporated into the September Tealbook forecast). However,
estimates of job gains in July and August were revised up, and payroll growth
for the three months ending in September averaged 200,000 per month on a
hurricane-adjusted basis, a little higher than in our previous projection.
Excluding the effects of hurricanes, we continue to expect payroll gains to
average about 190,000 per month this quarter, well above the pace that we
estimate is consistent with unchanged resource utilization. 10

•

Data that we analyze from the payroll processing firm ADP (see the exhibit
“Labor Market Developments and Outlook (1)”) point to an average increase
in private payrolls over the three months ending in September of about
240,000. A state-space model, which combines the information from ADP
and the BLS, estimates average monthly private job gains of 210,000 over the
past three months.

•

The unemployment rate edged down to 3.7 percent in September, slightly
lower than we had expected. Because the decline in the unemployment rate
was largely due to an increase in the job finding rate, which tends to have
some persistent influence on the unemployment rate, we nudged down our

The employment report for October will be released on November 2, the Friday before the
FOMC meeting.
10
We estimate that Hurricane Florence depressed job gains in September by 40,000, and that
Hurricane Michael will depress job gains in October by 25,000. After accounting for the employment
bounceback in the months after each storm, we expect that the hurricanes will have no net effect on job
gains in October and that they will boost job gains by 40,000 in November.
9

Page 19 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

forecast for the unemployment rate through the rest of the year. We now
expect it to average 3.6 percent this quarter, 1 percentage point below our
estimate of its natural rate.
•

The labor force participation rate (LFPR) was 62.7 percent in September, the
same as in August, whereas we had expected it to edge up 0.1 percentage
point. However, we are reluctant to take much signal from surprises in the
LFPR during the summer months and expect it to move back to 62.8 percent
for the fourth quarter—the same level it has fluctuated around for the past few
years and currently ¼ percentage point above our estimate of its trend. With
offsetting misses to the unemployment rate and LFPR, the employment-topopulation ratio in September came in at 60.4 percent, the same as in our
September Tealbook forecast.

We continue to expect the labor market to tighten further over the medium term,
consistent with above-trend output growth. Relative to the September Tealbook, job
gains are a little slower, the unemployment rate is a touch higher, and the LFPR is a bit
lower, with these revisions reflecting the slightly slower pace of GDP growth in this
projection. As in previous projections, we continue to assume that, in an extremely tight
labor market, a larger-than-usual amount of the tightening in labor utilization will
manifest in a higher LFPR and a smaller-than-usual amount in a lower
unemployment rate.
•

Average monthly total payroll gains slow gradually in the projection, from
about 195,000 in the second half of this year to about 80,000 in 2021.

•

The unemployment rate is projected to decline from 3.6 percent in the fourth
quarter to 3.3 percent by the middle of next year. The unemployment rate
starts to turn up in 2021 and ends that year at 3.4 percent—still 1¼ percentage
points below its natural rate.

•

The LFPR is projected to remain at 62.8 percent through the end of 2020 and
then gradually decline. With the trend participation rate expected to continue
declining about 0.2 percentage point per year, we project that the LFPR gap
will widen from ¼ percentage point at the end of 2018 to ½ percentage point
in 2020 and narrow thereafter.

Page 20 of 124

•

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

We project that labor productivity will increase a little more than 1 percent per
year, on average, over the forecast period, ¼ percentage point below our
estimate of its structural pace.

THE OUTLOOK FOR INFLATION
Based on our translation of the September CPI and PPI data, we estimate that core
PCE prices increased 1.9 percent over the 12 months ending in September, and that total
PCE prices increased 2.0 percent. Both estimates are as we had expected in the
September Tealbook and continue to indicate that inflation has firmed somewhat relative
to a year ago. We continue to forecast both 12-month changes to remain near their
current levels through the end of this year, about the same as in our September Tealbook
forecast.
•

Core import prices are expected to decline 1¾ percent in the second half of
2018, reversing their increase in the first half. The second-half decline
reflects dollar appreciation and lower commodity prices. Beyond this year,
import price inflation is expected to run at a ¾ percent pace, consistent with
moderate foreign inflation and a gradually appreciating dollar.
o These published import price indexes exclude tariffs. However, tariffs add
to the prices that purchasers of imports actually pay—that is, effective
import prices. We estimate that the tariffs implemented so far this year
will boost effective import price inflation by 1½ percentage points in 2018
and ½ percentage point in 2019.

The latest readings on survey- and market-based measures of longer-term
inflation expectations have been mixed since the September Tealbook but appear
consistent, on balance, with expectations remaining relatively well anchored.
•

In the final October report from the University of Michigan Surveys of
Consumers, the median of inflation expectations over the next 5 to 10 years
was 2.4 percent, near the bottom of the range seen in recent years.

•

In contrast, the September reading on median three-year-ahead expected
inflation from the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Survey of Consumer
Expectations was 3.0 percent, at the high end of recent readings.

Page 21 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Survey Measures of Longer-Term Inflation Expectations

CPI Next 10 Years

CPI Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

2.5

June

Q3
Oct.
Sept.

2.0

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Blue Chip mean, 7 to 11 years ahead
Primary dealers median, 5 to 10 years ahead
Consensus Economics mean, 6 to 10 years ahead

1.5

SPF median
Livingston Survey median
1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: SPF is Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

PCE Next 10 Years

2.5

Oct.

Q3

3.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Blue Chip
Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
Consensus Economics.

2.0

1.5

1.0

PCE Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Primary dealers median, longer run

2.5

3.0

2.5

SPF median
Q3

Q3

2.0

2.0

Sept.

1.5

1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Surveys of Consumers

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Primary dealers data begin in August 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.

1.0

Survey of Business Inflation Expectations
Percent

Percent

4.0

3.5

Sept.

4.0

3.5

Mean increase in unit costs, next 5 to 10 years
3.0

Q4

3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

Oct. (p)
FRBNY median increase in prices, 3 years ahead
Michigan median increase in prices, next 5 to 10 years

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY) Survey
of Consumer Expectations reports expected 12-month inflation
rate 3 years from the current survey date. FRBNY data begin
in June 2013.
(p) Preliminary.
Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers;
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Survey of Consumer
Expectations.

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Survey of businesses in the Sixth Federal Reserve
District. Data begin in February 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

Page 22 of 124

1.5

•

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Meanwhile, TIPS-based measures of inflation compensation have changed
little since the September Tealbook.

We project that core inflation will edge up to 2.0 percent over the next year or so
and remain at that level through 2021. The projected increase primarily reflects further
tightening in resource utilization and our small assumed upward drift in trend inflation.
Total inflation is projected to run slightly below core inflation after this year, reflecting
the declining path for consumer energy prices in the medium term. Relative to the
September Tealbook forecast, both total and core inflation are a little lower in the
medium term, because resource utilization is a little less tight. Offsetting these revisions
somewhat, the additional tariffs put in place since the September Tealbook push up
inflation a little this year and next.
With labor demand remaining strong, we continue to expect that the pace of
increases in hourly compensation will move up through the medium term, as firms try to
retain workers and fill job vacancies in part by raising wages and benefits.
•

Average hourly earnings rose 2.8 percent over the 12 months ending in
September, a bit higher than we projected in the September Tealbook, with the
upward surprise likely attributable to distortions from Hurricane Florence. 11
After adjusting measured wages for the estimated effects of all hurricanes this
year and last, we continue to think the 12-month change in average hourly
earnings from September to December will be flat at 2.9 percent. However,
we project that the measured 12-month change to October and November will
be distorted by hurricanes Florence and Michael.

•

We estimate that the year-over-year change in compensation per hour (CPH)
in the business sector will be 2¾ percent in the third quarter and step up to
3¼ percent in the fourth and first quarters, a slightly faster pace than in the
September Tealbook. We continue to project that CPH will accelerate to a
roughly 4 percent rate from 2019 through 2021.

We think that hurricane-related declines in employment tend to boost measured wages because
these employment distortions are likely to be concentrated in industries with a relatively large number of
low-paid hourly workers, such as leisure and hospitality.
11

Page 23 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

We have not received any new information on the ECI since the September
Tealbook. 12 Given the ECI’s relatively muted cyclical sensitivity, we
continue to expect it to accelerate somewhat from its recent 2½ to 2¾ percent
pace to a 3 percent pace later in the medium term.

•

The September reading of the Atlanta Fed’s Wage Growth Tracker came in at
3.5 percent, near the upper end of the range seen over recent years.

THE LONG-TERM OUTLOOK
•

We continue to assume that the natural rate of unemployment will be
4.6 percent and that potential output growth will be 1.7 percent per year in the
longer run.

•

We have maintained our assumption that the real equilibrium federal funds
rate in the longer run will be ½ percent. The nominal yield on 10-year
Treasury securities is assumed to be 3.4 percent; the term premium gradually
rises toward 90 basis points, lifted in part by the elevated level of federal debt.

•

We expect that the Federal Reserve’s holdings of securities will continue to
put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, though to a diminishing
extent over time. The SOMA portfolio is expected to be at a normal size by
mid-2021.

•

With these assumptions, real GDP growth slows to about 1¼ percent from
2022 to 2024, as the federal funds rate is above its neutral level and the boost
to growth from fiscal policy fades. The unemployment rate moves up
gradually from 3½ percent at the end of 2021 toward its assumed natural rate
in subsequent years. PCE price inflation remains close to 2 percent
throughout the projection.

•

With resource utilization cooling only slowly and inflation remaining close to
the Committee’s 2 percent objective, the nominal federal funds rate moves
down only gradually from its elevated level at the end of the medium term
toward its long-run value of 2½ percent.

12

The ECI for September will be released on October 31.

Page 24 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Projections of Real GDP and Related Components
(Percent change at annual rate from final quarter
of preceding period except as noted)
2018
Measure

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2.8
2.8

3.0
3.1

2.4
2.5

1.9
1.9

1.4
1.5

3.7
3.8

2.1
2.3

2.9
3.0

2.4
2.5

1.9
1.9

1.6
1.6

2.7
2.7

2.1
2.3

3.0
2.8

2.5
2.6

2.4
2.8

2.2
2.5

1.9
2.1

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

3.8
3.8

-2.4
-2.6

-3.3
-1.2

-2.8
-1.9

.5
3.4

.4
.4

1.6
1.3

Nonresidential structures
Previous Tealbook

2.9
2.9

14.2
14.1

-.7
3.9

6.5
8.9

2.6
2.5

-.3
.0

-2.1
-1.8

Equipment and intangibles
Previous Tealbook

7.3
7.3

8.9
9.1

7.8
6.4

8.4
7.7

3.9
4.2

2.0
2.2

1.7
1.7

Federal purchases
Previous Tealbook

1.3
1.3

3.1
3.2

2.5
2.5

2.8
2.8

3.1
3.1

2.9
2.8

1.2
1.3

State and local purchases
Previous Tealbook

-.5
-.5

1.4
1.3

1.6
.7

1.5
1.0

1.2
1.0

1.0
1.0

1.0
1.0

Exports
Previous Tealbook

4.7
4.7

6.4
6.2

.3
1.3

3.3
3.7

2.5
2.9

2.9
2.8

3.2
2.7

Imports
Previous Tealbook

5.4
5.4

1.2
1.2

6.5
4.7

3.8
3.0

2.6
4.8

3.0
4.2

2.8
3.5

H1

H2

2.5
2.5

3.2
3.4

Final sales
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.6

Personal consumption expenditures
Previous Tealbook

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Contributions to change in real GDP
(percentage points)
Inventory change
Previous Tealbook

-.1
-.1

-.5
-.3

.7
.4

.1
.1

.0
.0

.0
.0

-.2
-.1

Net exports
Previous Tealbook

-.2
-.2

.6
.6

-.9
-.5

-.2
.0

-.1
-.4

-.1
-.3

.0
-.2

Real GDP
4-quarter percent change
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 25 of 124

2021

-6

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Components of Final Demand

Personal Consumption Expenditures
4-quarter percent change
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Residential Investment
4-quarter percent change

5

20
15

4

10
3
5
2
0
1

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-5

0

2014

Equipment and Intangibles

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-10

Nonresidential Structures

4-quarter percent change

4-quarter percent change

12

25
20

10

15

8

10

6

5
4

0

2

-5

0
2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-10

-2

2014

Government Consumption and Investment
4-quarter percent change

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-15

Exports and Imports
4-quarter percent change

3

10

2
Imports

1

5

0
-1
-2

0

-3
Exports
-4
-5
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 26 of 124

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-5

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Aspects of the Medium-Term Projection
Personal Saving Rate

Wealth-to-Income Ratio
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Ratio

11
10

7.2
6.8

9
6.4

8
7

6.0

6
5

5.6

4

5.2

3
4.8

2
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

1

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Ratio of household net worth to disposable personal
income.
Source: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Financial
Accounts of the United States; for income, U.S. Dept. of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Single-Family Housing Starts

4.4

Equipment and Intangibles Spending
Millions of units

Share of nominal GDP

2.00

12

1.75
11

1.50
1.25

10

1.00
9

0.75
0.50

8

0.25
2000
2005
2010
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2015

2020

0.00

Federal Surplus/Deficit
4-quarter moving average

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

7

Current Account Surplus/Deficit
Share of nominal GDP

Current
Previous Tealbook

Share of nominal GDP

6
4

1
0

2

-1

0

-2

-2
-3
-4
-4

-6

2000
2005
2010
2015
Source: Monthly Treasury Statement.

2020

-8

-5

-10

-6

-12

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 27 of 124

-7

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Cyclical Position of the U.S. Economy: Longer-Term Perspective
Output Gap

Unemployment Rate
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Percent

8

Unemployment rate
Natural rate of unemployment*

6

14
12

4
2

10

0

8

-2
-4

6

-6

4

-8
-10
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Shaded regions show the 70 percent and 90 percent
confidence intervals of the distribution of historical revisions to the
staff’s estimates of the output gap.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

2
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Shaded regions show the 70 percent and 90 percent
confidence intervals of the distribution of historical revisions to the
staff’s estimates of the natural rate.
*Staff estimate including the effect of extended and emergency
unemployment insurance benefits.
Source: Various macroeconomic data; staff assumptions.

Actual and Structural Labor Productivity

Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Rate
Percent

(Business sector)
90
85

Average rate from
1972 to 2017

Chained (2012) dollars per hour

Actual
Structural

76
72
68

80

64
75
60
70

56

65
2000

2005

2010

2015

2020

52

60

2005

2010

2015

2020

48

Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis;
staff assumptions.

Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Decomposition of Potential Output
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)
Measure
Potential output
Previous Tealbook
Selected contributions1
Structural labor productivity2
Previous Tealbook
Capital deepening
Multifactor productivity
Structural hours
Previous Tealbook
Labor force participation
Previous Tealbook
Memo:
Output gap3
Previous Tealbook

1974-95

19962000

3.1
3.1

3.6
3.6

2.7
2.7

1.9
1.9

1.7
1.7
.7
.8
1.5
1.5
.4
.4

2.9
2.9
1.4
1.1
1.3
1.3
-.1
-.1

2.7
2.7
1.0
1.4
.8
.8
-.2
-.2

-1.2
-1.2

2.5
2.5

.3
.3

2001-07 2008-10 2011-16

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

1.4
1.4

1.6
1.6

1.7
1.7

1.8
1.8

1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
.5
1.1
.4
.4
-.5
-.5

1.2
1.2
.8
.2
.4
.4
-.5
-.5

1.2
1.2
.7
.3
.3
.3
-.3
-.3

1.2
1.2
.7
.3
.7
.7
-.3
-.3

1.3
1.3
.8
.3
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

1.4
1.4
.7
.5
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

1.4
1.4
.6
.6
.5
.5
-.2
-.2

-5.3
-5.3

.4
.4

1.2
1.2

2.4
2.4

3.0
3.2

2.9
3.2

2.4
2.7

Note: For multiyear periods, the percent change is the annual average from Q4 of the year preceding the first year shown to Q4 of the last year shown.
1. Percentage points.
2. Total business sector.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential output in the final quarter of the period indicated. A negative number indicates that the economy
is operating below potential.

Page 28 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

The Outlook for the Labor Market
2018
Measure

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

196
183

207
200

168
177

121
129

82
85

215
215

182
179

198
197

157
166

111
119

72
75

62.7
62.7

62.8
62.8

62.8
62.8

62.8
62.8

62.8
62.9

62.8
62.8

62.5
62.6

4.1
4.1

3.9
3.9

3.6
3.7

3.6
3.7

3.3
3.3

3.3
3.2

3.4
3.4

60.1
60.1

60.4
60.4

60.5
60.5

60.5
60.5

60.7
60.8

60.7
60.8

60.4
60.5

H1

H2

183
183

218
218

180
180

Labor force participation rate2
Previous Tealbook
Civilian unemployment rate2
Previous Tealbook

Nonfarm payroll employment1
Previous Tealbook
Private employment1
Previous Tealbook

Employment to population ratio2
Previous Tealbook

1. Thousands, average monthly changes.
2. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Inflation Projections
2018
Measure

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

1.7
1.8

2.0
2.0

2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0

1.9
2.0

.7
.7

.9
1.3

.8
1.0

2.5
2.4

2.6
2.6

2.3
2.3

8.1
8.1

6.5
6.5

4.4
6.4

5.4
6.5

-.2
-.5

-1.1
-1.2

-1.0
-.8

Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

1.6
1.6

2.1
2.1

1.7
1.6

1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.1

Prices of core goods imports1
Previous Tealbook

1.1
1.1

1.6
1.6

-1.6
-1.5

.0
.0

.6
.6

.8
.8

.7
.7

Sept.
20182

Oct.
20182

Nov.
20182

Dec.
20182

Jan.
20192

Feb.
20192

Mar.
20192

2.0
2.0

2.0
2.0

1.9
2.0

1.9
2.0

1.8
...

1.8
...

2.0
...

1.9
1.9

1.9
1.8

1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9

1.9
...

1.9
...

1.9
...

H1

H2

1.8
1.8

2.2
2.2

Food and beverages
Previous Tealbook

.7
.7

Energy
Previous Tealbook

Percent change at annual rate from
final quarter of preceding period
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook

12-month percent change
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook
Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

... Not applicable.
1. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.
2. Staff forecast.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 29 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (1)

Measures of Labor Underutilization
Percent

Percent
13

U-5*
Unemployment rate
Part time for
economic
reasons**

Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural unemployment rate with EEB adjustment
Previous Tealbook

12
11
10

10
9
8
7

9
8

6

7
Sept.

6

5

5

4

4

3

3
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2

* U-5 measures total unemployed persons plus all marginally attached to the labor force as a percent of the labor force plus persons marginally
attached to the labor force.
** Percent of Current Population Survey employment.
EEB Extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Change in Total Payroll Employment

Level of Payroll Employment
140
135

Millions
Total (right axis)
Previous Tealbook
Private (left axis)
Previous Tealbook

Millions

Sept.

Thousands

160

Total
Previous Tealbook

155

450
400
350

130

150

125

145

300
250
200

120

140

115

135

110

130

150
100
50

2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

0
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Change in Private Payroll Employment

Thousands
BLS CES/staff estimate
Previous Tealbook
FRB/ADP
Pooled estimate

Sept.

450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50

2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
Note: Gray shaded area around blue line is 90 percent confidence interval around pooled estimate.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff calculations using microdata from ADP.

2020

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 30 of 124

2021

0

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (2)
Labor Force Participation Rate*
Percent
67.5
Labor force participation rate
67.0
Previous Tealbook
66.5
Estimated trend**
66.0
Previous Tealbook
65.5

Percent
Labor force participation rate
Previous Tealbook
Estimated trend**
Previous Tealbook

65.0

64.0
63.5
63.0

64.5
64.0
Sept.

64.5

62.5

63.5
63.0

62.0

62.5
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

62.0

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

61.5

* Published data adjusted by staff to account for changes in population weights.
** Includes staff estimate of the effect of extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Initial Unemployment Insurance Claims*
Thousands

Hires, Quits, and Job Openings
700
650
600

Percent
Hires*
Openings**
Quits*

550

400
Oct. 20

3.5
3.0

350

2.5

300

2.0
1.5

200
150

4.5

Aug.

250

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* 4-week moving average.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and
Training Administration.

5.0

4.0

500
450

5.5

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment, 3-month
moving average.
** Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment plus
unfilled jobs, 3-month moving average.
Source: Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey.

1.0

Labor Force Participation Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group, 25 to 54 years old

Unemployment Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group
Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

20
16

Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

86
84
82

12
80
8

4

Sept.

78
76

Sept.
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0

Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Page 31 of 124

74
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (1)
(Percent change from year-earlier period)

Headline Consumer Price Inflation
Percent
CPI
PCE

Percent

6

PCE - Current Tealbook
PCE - Previous Tealbook

5

5
4

4
Sept.

3

3
2

Sept. (e)

2
1
1

0
-1

0
-2
-3
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
Note: PCE prices from July to September 2018 are staff estimates (e).
Source: For CPI, U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Measures of Underlying PCE Price Inflation
Percent
Trimmed mean PCE
Market-based PCE excluding food and energy
PCE excluding food and energy

Percent

4.0

Core PCE - Current Tealbook
Core PCE - Previous Tealbook

3.5

3.0

3.0

2.5

2.5

Sept. (e)
Aug.

3.5

2.0

2.0
1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0
Sept. (e)

0.5

0.5
0.0
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
Note: Core PCE prices from July to September 2018 are staff estimates (e).
Source: For trimmed mean PCE, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; otherwise, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

0.0

Labor Cost Growth
Percent
Employment cost index
Average hourly earnings
Compensation per hour

Percent

7

Compensation per hour - Current Tealbook
Compensation per hour - Previous Tealbook

6
5

Sept.

5
4

4
Q2
Q2

6

3

3
2

2

1

1

0

0
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013
2015
2017
2019
2021
Note: Compensation per hour is for the business sector. Average hourly earnings are for the private nonfarm sector. The employment cost
index is for the private sector.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 32 of 124

-1

October 26, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (2)
(Percent change from year-earlier period, except as noted)

Commodity and Oil Price Levels
2200

Dollars per barrel

1967 = 100

Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)

1680
1420
1200
1000
800
600

1967 = 100

Dollars per barrel

220

700

168
142
120
100
80

600

80

500

60

60

100

Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)

Oct. 23
400

200

Oct. 23

40

400

40

20
300
20
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
Note: Futures prices (dotted lines) are the latest observations on monthly futures contracts.
Source: For oil prices, U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Agency; for commodity prices, Commodity Research Bureau (CRB).

Energy and Import Price Inflation
18

Percent

Percent
PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)

15
12
9
6

Aug.

60

10

50

8

40

6

30

4

20

2

3

10

0

0

0

-2

Sept.

-3

-10

-4

-6

-20

-6

-9

-30

-8

-12

-40

-10

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Percent

Percent

PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)

2015

2016

2017

30
25
20
15
Aug.
10
Sept. 5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
-25
-30
2018

Source: For core import prices, U.S. Dept. of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Long-Term Inflation Expectations and Compensation
Percent
5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

4.5
4.0
3.5

Oct. (p)

Percent
5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

3.0

4.0
3.5
Oct. (p)

2.5
Sept.
Q3

2.0
1.5

4.5

3.0
2.5

Sept.
Q3

2.0
1.5

1.0
1.0
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Based on a comparison of an estimated TIPS (Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities) yield curve with an estimated nominal off-the-run
Treasury yield curve, with an adjustment for the indexation-lag effect.
(p) Preliminary.
SPF Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: For Michigan, University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; for SPF, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; for TIPS, Federal
Reserve Board staff calculations.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 33 of 124

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

The Long−Term Outlook

(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)

Measure

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

Longer run

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

3.0
3.1

2.4
2.5

1.9
1.9

1.4
1.5

1.2
1.2

1.2
1.1

1.3
1.2

1.7
1.7

Civilian unemployment rate1
Previous Tealbook

3.6
3.7

3.3
3.3

3.3
3.2

3.4
3.3

3.7
3.6

4.0
3.9

4.2
4.1

4.6
4.6

PCE prices, total
Previous Tealbook

2.0
2.0

2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.0

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0

Core PCE prices
Previous Tealbook

1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0

Federal funds rate1
Previous Tealbook

2.29
2.35

3.65
3.71

4.49
4.63

4.81
5.00

4.67
4.90

4.34
4.57

3.96
4.16

2.50
2.50

10-year Treasury yield1
Previous Tealbook

3.2
3.1

4.0
4.0

4.2
4.3

4.2
4.2

4.0
4.1

3.9
3.9

3.8
3.8

3.4
3.4

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Real GDP

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
10

4
Unemployment rate

3

9

2

8

1
Potential GDP

7

0
6

−1

5

Natural rate
with EEB
adjustment

−2
−3

4

−4
2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

2021

2024

3
2006

PCE Prices

2009

2012

2015

2018

2021

2024

Interest Rates
4−quarter percent change

Percent
4

Total PCE prices

10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0

Triple−B corporate
3
10−year Treasury
2

Core
PCE
prices

1
0

Federal
funds rate

−1
2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

2021

2024

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

2021

2024

Note: In each panel, shading represents the projection period, and dashed lines are the previous Tealbook.
Page 34 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Evolution of the Staff Forecast
Change in Real GDP
Percent, Q4/Q4
4

3

2017
2
2018
2019

2020

9/10 10/2212/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/2112/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20 9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2014

2015

2016

2021

4/21 6/2 7/14 9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2017

7/20 9/14 10/26

1

2018

Tealbook publication date

Unemployment Rate
Percent, fourth quarter
6.0
2017

5.5
5.0
2018

4.5
2019

4.0
2020

3.5
2021

9/10 10/2212/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/2112/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20 9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2014

2015

2016

4/21 6/2 7/14 9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2017

7/20 9/14 10/26

3.0
2.5

2018

Tealbook publication date

Change in PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy
Percent, Q4/Q4
2.5

2021
2018

2017

2020

2019

2.0

1.5

9/10 10/2212/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9 10/2112/9 1/20 3/9 4/20 6/8 7/20 9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2014

2015

2016

2017

Tealbook publication date

Page 35 of 124

4/21 6/2 7/14 9/8 10/2012/1 1/19 3/9 4/20 6/1

2018

7/20 9/14 10/26

1.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 36 of 124

October 26, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Our foreign outlook continues to be positive despite a plethora of downside risks.
Economic growth abroad remains solid, picking up to an estimated 2½ percent at an
annual rate in the third quarter after dipping to 2 percent in the second. Indicators
suggest a notable pickup in Latin America, notwithstanding continued stress in
Argentina, with Mexico reversing its second-quarter contraction and Brazil rebounding
from a nationwide truckers’ strike. Conversely, growth slowed in China, and we estimate
that it moderated in the advanced foreign economies (AFEs) from an unusually strong
second quarter, largely reflecting a return to a more sustainable pace in Canada
and Japan.
We see foreign growth remaining near 2½ percent over the forecast period, about
in line with its potential. Overall, our forecast is little changed from the September
Tealbook, as a small upward revision to the AFEs in the near term was mostly offset by a
small downward revision to the emerging market economies (EMEs), including China.
Against the background of nearly closed output gaps, inflation has been picking
up around the world. However, most of the rise in headline inflation is due to higher oil
prices, which hit their highest level in four years before retracing some in recent weeks.
In the AFEs, aggregate four-quarter inflation rose to 2 percent in the third quarter, but
core inflation only edged up to 1.2 percent. Moreover, there is substantial variation
across the AFEs, with core inflation running close to the 2 percent targeted by central
banks in the United Kingdom and Canada and lingering at much lower rates in the euro
area and Japan. Inflation also rose in the EMEs, reflecting higher energy prices, past
currency depreciations, and a surge in food prices in China.
With inflation picking up and financial pressures increasing in EMEs, several
EME central banks have tightened monetary policy in recent months. In Argentina,
interest rates rose to over 70 percent after the central bank, under a revised program with
the IMF, switched to a monetary targeting regime with a 0 percent money growth target.
And central banks in Chile, India, Indonesia, the Philippines, Russia, and Turkey have all
raised policy rates. We generally expect most EMEs to tighten monetary policy further
over the forecast period, albeit at a measured pace, as U.S. monetary policy normalization
continues and global financial conditions tighten. In the AFEs, monetary policy
normalization promises to be very slow in the face of relatively subdued inflationary

Page 37 of 124

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

International Economic Developments and Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

pressures, uncertainties about the outlook, and headwinds that likely continue to weigh on
r*’s. Our assumptions about monetary policy in the AFEs are little changed, and even at
the end of the forecast period, we see policy rates at levels well below historical values.
The prominent risks we highlighted in September are still on our radar. First,
financial distresses in EMEs—which have largely been confined to Argentina and Turkey
thus far and have left only a small imprint on our baseline forecast—could become more
widespread, perhaps triggered by problems in China or rising global interest rates. The
consequences of such an outcome are described in our “EME Financial Turbulence”
alternative scenario in the Risks and Uncertainty section of the Tealbook. Second,
negotiations over the Italian budget and Brexit, which have not gone well of late, could
fall apart and exert a greater drag in Europe than the still relatively modest effects
currently built into our baseline. Third, tensions over trade policy could intensify and
lead to greater disruptions to global trade than we are currently assuming. Fourth, higherthan-expected inflation in the United States and abroad, perhaps triggered by a rise in oil
prices, could push up interest rates around the world. This risk is discussed in our
“Inflation-Driven Global Tightening” alternative scenario. Finally, although the equity
declines registered abroad of late—which in part reflect concerns about the risks just
discussed—have not been large enough to weigh much on the foreign outlook, a more
substantial global market correction obviously would have more adverse effects.

ADVANCED FOREIGN ECONOMIES
•

Euro area. Available indicators, such as industrial production through August,
suggest that economic activity slowed from an upwardly revised 1.8 percent in the
second quarter to a still-solid 1½ percent in the third. In Italy, financial tensions
increased after the government presented its budget proposal for 2019. The targeted
deficit is significantly wider than previously agreed with the European Commission,
reinforcing concerns about the sustainability of Italian public finances and straining
the country’s relations with the European Union. With rising financial tensions
around Italy and PMIs declining noticeably in October, we project growth in the euro
area to slow a bit further to 1¼ percent in the first half of 2019. Thereafter, we expect
growth to edge up to 1½ percent by 2020 and hover around that pace through 2021.
Headline inflation increased to 2.5 percent at an annual rate in the third quarter
because of a sharp increase in retail energy prices, but core inflation edged down to
1.1 percent. As energy prices stabilize, headline inflation should fall just below

Page 38 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

•

United Kingdom. Incoming data are consistent with a rise in real GDP growth from
1.6 percent in the second quarter to 2½ percent in the third, ¾ percentage point higher
than estimated in September, partially reflecting favorable weather conditions. We
project that growth will fall back to 1½ percent (still slightly above our estimate of
potential) in the current quarter and remain around this pace through the end of the
forecast period. This outlook is conditional on our view that the United Kingdom and
the European Union will eventually reach an agreement before the March 29, 2019,
deadline. That said, with negotiations stalling on the Irish border issue, there is some
risk that Brexit could occur without a deal in place, resulting in substantial disruptions
to European supply chains and global financial markets.
Inflation rose to 2.9 percent last quarter from 2 percent in the second, mostly
reflecting higher retail energy prices. We have inflation gradually edging down to the
Bank of England’s (BOE) 2 percent target, as energy inflation eases and pass-through
from past pound sterling depreciation fades. Given better-than-expected activity data,
we moved the next rate hike to the second quarter of 2019, one quarter earlier than
assumed in September. Even so, we still see the BOE normalizing policy only very
gradually, raising the Bank Rate from the current 0.75 percent to 1¾ percent in 2021
and waiting until then to start reducing the size of its balance sheet.

•

Canada. Recent indicators, such as monthly GDP for July and manufacturing PMI
through September, point to 2¼ percent growth in the third quarter, about the average
pace over the first half of the year and somewhat faster than forecast in September.
The addition of now-legalized cannabis-related activity to the official data will
provide a one-time kick to GDP, adding an estimated ½ percentage point to fourthquarter growth, now projected at 2½ percent. With solid momentum in the economy,
we expect growth to average just over 2 percent in 2019 before settling at its potential
pace of 1¾ percent by mid-2020.
After slowing to 1.1 percent in the second quarter, inflation bounced back to
2.6 percent in the third, as core inflation recovered from earlier one-off price declines
in a few categories and airfares surged. Amid reports of rising input costs and solid
wage growth, we expect inflation to remain somewhat above the 2 percent target in
Page 39 of 124

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

1½ percent before edging up as resource slack is eliminated. With our growth and
inflation outlooks little changed, we continue to assume that the European Central
Bank will cease net asset purchases in December, wait until late 2019 to begin raising
its deposit rate, and then increase it to ¼ percent in 2021.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

2019 before edging down to its target level by the end of 2020. Citing reduced trade
policy uncertainty after a deal was reached to replace NAFTA with the new U.S.Mexico-Canada Agreement, or USMCA, the Bank of Canada (BOC) raised its policy
rate 25 basis points to 1.75 percent on October 24. As resource utilization continues
to increase, the BOC is expected to raise its policy rate to 3 percent by mid-2020.

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

•

Japan. Real GDP growth is estimated to have moderated to ¾ percent in the third
quarter from a blistering 3 percent pace in the second. This estimate is ¼ percentage
point lower than in the September Tealbook, reflecting weaker-than-expected data on
household consumption and net exports. Growth should remain near its potential rate
of ¾ percent, abstracting from substantial fluctuations around the consumption tax
hike planned for October 2019.
Inflation swung from negative 2.3 percent in the second quarter to positive
2.7 percent in the third, in part reflecting pickups in food and retail energy prices.
Core inflation also turned positive but only to a meager 0.4 percent. We continue to
see core inflation edging up further, reflecting elevated resource utilization, and total
inflation settling near 1 percent over the remainder of the forecast period. With
inflation well below the Bank of Japan’s (BOJ) 2 percent target, we expect the BOJ to
maintain a highly accommodative stance, waiting until the end of 2020 to lift its
target for the 10-year Japanese government bond yield to around ¼ percent.

EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES
•

China. Bucking the trend in most other EMEs, real GDP growth in China fell in the
third quarter to just below 6 percent, down from 6½ percent in the second quarter and
a touch weaker than our September Tealbook forecast. The slowdown was led by
weaker investment, particularly in infrastructure, suggesting that earlier policy
tightening continues to exert a drag on growth. Exports remained relatively strong,
even in the face of escalating trade tensions with the United States. With tariffs now
in effect on about half of Chinese exports to the United States, we expect export
growth to slow somewhat going forward, although the effect of the tariffs will likely
be mitigated by the nearly 8 percent depreciation of the renminbi against the dollar,
which began in mid-June. In addition, we expect domestic demand to strengthen as
the authorities shift to a more accommodative policy stance. Indeed, the People’s
Bank of China recently cut the reserve requirement ratio an additional 100 basis
points, supporting credit growth. All told, we see growth picking back up to
6¼ percent this quarter before slowing gradually to 5¾ percent by the end of the
Page 40 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

forecast period. Relative to the September Tealbook, this forecast is down a touch
through the end of 2019, reflecting the latest round of U.S. tariffs on Chinese goods,
which were announced on September 17.

•

Other Emerging Asia. A recovery in the region’s exports, which had slowed
markedly in the second quarter, is expected to push growth up to 3½ percent in the
third, despite a somewhat weak preliminary GDP release from Korea. We expect
growth to edge up to 3¾ percent in 2019 and 2020. Although U.S.–China trade
barriers implemented to date should have a negligible effect on growth in other
emerging Asian economies, a further escalation of trade tensions remains a clear
downside risk.

•

Mexico. Recent data on retail sales and consumer confidence suggest that real GDP
expanded at a 2 percent pace last quarter after a second-quarter contraction. Even so,
construction activity has been weaker than expected, causing us to revise down our
forecast for third-quarter growth ¼ percentage point. We see growth rising to nearly
3 percent by mid-2019, supported by robust U.S. demand and the dissipation of traderelated uncertainties after a deal was reached on the USMCA. Most Mexican
producers are already close to meeting the stricter rules of origin and labor content
requirements in the revised agreement, so we do not expect the new accord to result
in a material shift in production from Mexico to the United States. A deal was
already factored into our baseline and did not change our forecast.
Headline inflation moved up to 5 percent on a 12-month basis in September on the
back of energy price increases and base effects (transportation tariffs were cut in
September 2017 after a series of earthquakes). In October, the Bank of Mexico
(BOM) kept its policy rate at 7.75 percent, noting concerns about the slower-thanexpected decline in inflation and potential second-round effects from higher energy
prices. Assuming EME financial stresses abate, we see the BOM easing its monetary
policy in mid-2019 as inflation moderates.

•

Brazil. We estimate that real GDP growth jumped to 4 percent in the third quarter
from a tepid ¾ percent in the second, largely reflecting a recovery from the May

Page 41 of 124

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Inflation stepped up from ¾ percent in the second quarter to around 4 percent in the
third as an outbreak of African swine fever and adverse weather conditions caused
pork and vegetable prices, respectively, to spike. As these temporary factors fade, we
expect inflation to settle at 2½ percent.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

truckers’ strike. Recent data have been mixed but suggest that the economy’s
momentum is somewhat stronger than we anticipated in the September Tealbook,
which led us to revise up the third-quarter forecast ½ percentage point. We expect
growth to step back to 2¼ percent in the fourth quarter and then rise gradually to
2¾ percent in 2019, helped by a pickup in private investment once political
uncertainty stemming from the presidential election fades. In the first round of the
election, the right-wing candidate Jair Bolsonaro came in first with a large lead over
the runner-up Fernando Haddad of the Workers’ Party. The next president will be
determined by a second-round runoff on October 28, and polls indicate a double-digit
lead for Bolsonaro. Our baseline forecast assumes that the incoming government will
push through an urgent social security reform in 2019 and thus avoid a heightening of
fiscal and financial stresses. However, considerable uncertainty remains around the
policy outlook.
Headline inflation accelerated to 6.6 percent in the third quarter, pressured by the
lagged effects of the truckers’ strike and the pass-through from currency depreciation.
With the dissipation of these transitory effects, we expect inflation to fall to 4 percent
in the fourth quarter before stabilizing at 4¼ percent—the central bank’s target for
2019. Citing anchored inflation expectations and considerable resource slack, the
Central Bank of Brazil did not change its policy rate in its September meeting.
•

Argentina. On September 26, Argentine authorities agreed on a revised program
with the IMF intended to restore market confidence and allay growing concern about
government financing needs in 2019. The new program, which now awaits approval
by the IMF Executive Board, envisions a larger and more front-loaded disbursement
of IMF resources and features significantly tighter fiscal targets, strict limits on
foreign exchange intervention, and a switch to a temporary monetary targeting regime
in which the growth of the money supply is sharply reduced. As a result of both
tighter fiscal and monetary policies and a sharp tightening of financial conditions in
recent months, we now expect a much deeper recession, with four-quarter growth
contracting nearly 8 percent this year. We expect a rebound in agricultural
production from this year’s drought to push overall GDP growth into positive
territory next year, but outside of agriculture, the recession is expected to continue.

Page 42 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Page 43 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

The Foreign GDP Outlook
Real GDP*

Percent change, annual rate

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

2017
Q1

2018
Q2
Q3

Q4

2019

2020

2021

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

2.9
2.9

3.0
3.1

2.0
2.0

2.5
2.5

2.6
2.6

2.7
2.7

2.7
2.7

2.6
2.6

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

2.6
2.6
3.0
2.7
2.0
1.4

1.3
1.4
1.4
1.6
-.9
.4

2.5
2.4
2.9
1.8
3.0
1.6

1.9
1.7
2.2
1.6
.7
2.5

1.9
1.7
2.5
1.5
.5
1.6

1.7
1.7
2.1
1.4
.1
1.6

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.6
.8
1.7

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.6
.8
1.6

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.2
3.2
6.8
4.2
1.6
2.1

4.7
4.7
7.2
5.6
4.0
.6

1.5
1.6
6.5
2.5
-.6
.7

3.1
3.3
5.9
3.5
2.1
4.0

3.4
3.5
6.3
3.8
2.6
2.3

3.7
3.7
6.1
3.7
2.8
2.6

3.7
3.7
5.9
3.7
2.9
2.8

3.6
3.6
5.7
3.5
2.9
2.8

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

* GDP aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. merchandise exports.

Total Foreign GDP

Foreign GDP
Percent change, annual rate

Percent change, annual rate

5.0

Current
Previous Tealbook

7

Current
Previous Tealbook
4.5

6

Emerging market economies

4.0

5

3.5

4

3.0

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

0
Advanced foreign economies

1.0
2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

-1
2011

Page 44 of 124

2013

2015

2017

2019

2021

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

The Foreign Inflation Outlook

Consumer Prices*
2017
Q1

2018
Q2
Q3

Q4

2019

2020

2021

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.6

2.6
2.7

1.7
1.7

3.7
3.5

2.9
2.7

2.6
2.7

2.4
2.4

2.4
2.4

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

1.5
1.5
1.8
1.4
.6
3.0

2.6
2.6
3.6
2.0
2.5
2.4

1.0
1.0
1.1
2.2
-2.3
2.0

2.5
2.3
2.6
2.5
2.7
2.9

2.1
1.8
2.4
2.3
1.2
2.4

1.9
1.9
2.3
1.5
2.3
2.3

1.7
1.7
2.1
1.5
1.0
2.2

1.7
1.7
2.0
1.7
1.1
2.1

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.4
3.4
1.8
2.3
6.6
2.8

2.7
2.7
1.5
2.2
4.1
3.1

2.2
2.2
.7
1.4
3.8
4.3

4.6
4.4
4.1
1.5
6.8
6.6

3.5
3.3
2.9
2.4
3.9
4.0

3.1
3.2
2.5
2.8
3.4
4.3

2.9
3.0
2.5
2.8
3.2
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.5
2.8
3.2
4.3

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Percent change, annual rate

* CPI aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

Foreign Monetary Policy
AFE Policy Rates

AFE Central Bank Balance Sheets
Percent

Percent of GDP

3.5

EME Policy Rates
Percent

120

15

3.0
100
2.5

12
Brazil

80
2.0

9
60

1.5
Canada

China*

Japan

6

1.0
40

Mexico

Euro area
United Kingdom

0.5
0.0

Euro area

United Kingdom

Korea

Canada

-0.5
2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021

3

20

Japan

0
2010

2012

2014

2016

Page 45 of 124

2018

0
2011 2013 2015 2017 2019 2021
* 1-year benchmark lending rate.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Recent Foreign Indicators
Nominal Exports

Industrial Production
Jan. 2011 = 100

Foreign
AFE*

Jan. 2011 = 100

125

EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

120
115

125
120
115

110
105

110

100

105

95
100

90

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

85
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

95
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, India, Indonesia,
Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Russia, Singapore,
Taiwan, Thailand.

Retail Sales

Employment
12-month percent change

4-quarter percent change

8

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

6

3.0
2.5
2.0

4
1.5
2
1.0
0

0.5

-2
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

0.0
2013

2018

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Korea, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan.

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, Israel, Korea, Mexico,
Philippines, Russia, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey.

Consumer Prices: Advanced Foreign Economies

Consumer Prices: Emerging Market Economies

12-month percent change

12-month percent change

2.5

Headline
Core*

Headline*
Ex. food--Emerging Asia**
Ex. food--Latin America**

2.0

7
6
5
4

1.5

3
1.0

2
1

0.5

0
0.0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Note: Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, U.K.
* Excludes all food and energy; staff calculation.
Source: Haver Analytics.

2018

-1
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.
** Excludes all food; staff calculation. Latin America excludes Argentina
and Venezuela.

Page 46 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Evolution of Staff’s International Forecast

Total Foreign GDP
Percent change, Q4/Q4

3.2

3.0

2.8
2017

2019
2020
2021

2.6

2.4

12/9 1/20

3/9

4/20

6/8

7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18

2016

3/2

4/20

6/1

7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1

2017

1/18

3/8

4/19

6/1

7/20

9/13 10/25

2.2

2018
Tealbook publication date

Total Foreign CPI
Percent change, Q4/Q4

3.0

2.8

2.6

2019
2021

2.4

2017

2018

2020
2.2

12/9 1/20

3/9

4/20

6/8

7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18

2016

3/2

4/20

6/1

7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1

2017

1/18

3/8

4/19

6/1

7/20

9/13 10/25

2.0

2018
Tealbook publication date

U.S. Current Account Balance
Percent of GDP

-2

-3

2017

2020

2021

-4

2018
2019

12/9 1/20

2016

3/9

4/20

6/8

7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18

3/2

4/20

6/1

7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1

2017

1/18

2018
Tealbook publication date

Page 47 of 124

3/8

4/19

6/1

7/20

9/13 10/25

-5

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 48 of 124

October 26, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Financial Market Developments
Concerns about ongoing international trade tensions, the global growth outlook,
and rising interest rates weighed on equity market sentiment over the intermeeting period.
Stock prices declined substantially on net, equity market volatilities rose notably, and the
dollar appreciated. Treasury yields were little changed, as increases early in the period
were offset by decreases owing to flight-to-safety flows associated with large equity
market declines later in the period.


Broad U.S. equity price indexes declined about 7 percent on net. The VIX
increased significantly to levels that are notably elevated compared with its
historical distribution.



Despite the substantial declines in stock prices, credit spreads on investmentand speculative-grade corporate bonds widened by modest amounts.



A straight read of market quotes implies that the probability of a 25 basis
point rate hike occurring at the December FOMC meeting stands at
75 percent, little changed since the September meeting, while the probability



Nominal Treasury yields were little changed on net. TIPS yields rose, leaving
TIPS-implied inflation compensation moderately lower, with some of the
decline occurring after the softer-than-expected September CPI data release.



The trade-weighted dollar index increased 2 percent against AFE currencies
and 1¼ percent against EME currencies. Major foreign equity price indexes
declined between 7 and 12 percent, on net, amid heightened tensions between
the U.S. and China, Italian budget negotiations, and spillovers from U.S.
markets.

DOMESTIC DEVELOPMENTS
During the intermeeting period, broad equity prices declined substantially, on net,
amid unusual day-to-day volatility. At one point, prices had declined nearly 10 percent,
on net, erasing all gains logged earlier in the year, before partly retracing near the end of
the period. News related to ongoing international trade tensions, and investors’ concerns

Page 49 of 124

Financial Markets

of a rate increase at the November FOMC meeting is negligible.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Policy Expectations and Treasury Yields
Market−Implied Probability of Rate Increase

Implied Federal Funds Rate

Percent
Most recent: October 25, 2018
Last FOMC: September 25, 2018

Percent

100

5

Most recent: October 25, 2018
Last FOMC: September 25, 2018

90
80

4

70

With model−based
term premium

60

3

50
40
With zero
term premium

30

2

20
10
0
Nov. 8

Dec. 19

1
2018

Jan. 30
2019

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

Note: Zero term premium path is estimated using overnight index swap quotes
with a spline approach and a term premium of zero basis points. Model−based term
premium path is estimated using a term structure model maintained by Board staff
and corrects for term premium.
Source: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Note: Probabilities implied by a binomial tree fitted to settlement prices on federal
funds futures contracts, assuming the policy action at each meeting is either no change
or a 25 basis point increase in rates and no intermeeting moves. The effective federal
funds rate until the next FOMC meeting is assumed to be equal to the observed rate.
Source: CME Group; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Selected Interest Rates
Percent

Percent
Employment Situation report
Chair Powell's remarks
Sept. CPI

2.95

Sept. FOMC

ISM nonmanufacturing

3.35
10−year
Treasury yield
(right scale)

Sept.
FOMC minutes

3.25
3.15
October 25
4:00 p.m.

3.05

Financial Markets

2.85
2.95
2−year
Treasury yield
(left scale)
2.75

Sept. 27

Oct. 2

Oct. 5

2.85

Oct. 11

Oct. 16

Oct. 19

2.75

Oct. 25

Note: Data are for 2018 and spaced at 5−minute intervals from 8:00 a.m. to 4:00 p.m.
Source: Bloomberg.

Long−Term Yield Spread and
Near−Term Forward Spread

TIPS−Based Inflation Compensation
Percent

0−to−6−quarter
forward spread

Monthly

2−to−10−year
yield spread

1971

1980

1991

4
3
2
1
0
−1
−2
−3
−4
−5

Oct.

2000

2011

Percent

2018

Note: The 0−to−6−quarter forward spread is the difference between the 3−month
yield and the implied forward rate between 6 and 7 quarters ahead based on a
smoothed Treasury yield curve. Data are monthly averages. Data for October 2018
based on values through October 25th.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Daily

5 to 10 years ahead

Sept.
FOMC
Oct.
25

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.0

Next 5 years*
Jan. May Sept. Jan. May Sept. Jan. May Sept.
2016
2017
2018

0.5

Note: Estimates based on smoothed nominal and inflation-indexed Treasury yield
curves.
* Adjusted for lagged indexation of Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities (carry effect).
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board
staff estimates.

Page 50 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

over potential further increases in interest rates and the sustainability of strong corporate
earnings growth, appeared to weigh on investor sentiment. Stock prices of the basic
materials and industrial sectors underperformed the broader market, reportedly reflecting
an increase in trade tensions with China. More broadly, investors seemed to reassess
equity valuations that appeared elevated. Investors also reacted to some large firms
raising concerns about the effect of rising costs on their future profitability in their latest
earnings reports. One-month option-implied volatility on the S&P 500 index (VIX)
increased significantly to levels that are notably elevated compared with its historical
distribution, though it remained below those seen in early February.
Despite the significant declines in stock prices, spreads of yields on investmentand speculative-grade corporate bonds over yields on comparable-maturity Treasury
securities widened only modestly. Overall, yields and spreads on both investment- and
speculative-grade corporate bonds remained low compared with their respective
distributions over the past several years. As we look ahead, however, yields and spreads
on corporate bonds could potentially be boosted by a decrease in holdings by
corporations, as recent tax law changes have provided incentives for corporations to
reduce the size of their overseas financial portfolios and shift those holdings into moreliquid asset categories. The box “Recent Developments in Corporate Financial

Market-implied measures of monetary policy expectations for the remainder of
2018 were little changed over the intermeeting period. Federal funds futures contracts
currently imply a 75 percent probability that the FOMC will raise the target range for the
federal funds rate by 25 basis points at its December meeting, while the probability of a
rate increase at the November meeting remained close to zero.1 Beyond 2018, federal
funds rate expectations implied by OIS quotes—unadjusted for term premiums—
decreased slightly over the intermeeting period and currently appear to embed about
50 basis points of additional tightening in 2019. A staff model that adjusts for term
premiums implies an increase in the effective federal funds rate of roughly 75 basis
points over the course of 2019.

1

Of note, the calculation of the probability of a rate increase for the November meeting and for
the December meeting does not take into account a potential technical adjustment to the IOER rate.
Assuming no adjustment at the November FOMC meeting and a 5 basis point adjustment at the December
meeting would imply a 90 percent probability of a rate hike at the December meeting.

Page 51 of 124

Financial Markets

Investments” discusses these changes in corporations’ investment strategies.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Recent Developments in Corporate Financial Investments
Nonfinancial firms (hereafter, firms) have substantially increased their holdings of financial assets
over recent years. Since the first quarter of 2011, the total financial assets of the 10 firms with the
largest financial investment portfolios have nearly doubled, to $800 billion; these assets have
grown from about one-third to almost one-half of total assets (table). 1 This growth suggests that
the investment decisions of firms could have a substantial effect on the markets in which they
invest. In this discussion, we explore recent changes in firms’ financial investment strategies
following the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act (TCJA).
When managing their financial assets, firms typically report that they prioritize capital
preservation and liquidity over risk-adjusted return and thus prefer to hold portfolios of highquality, short-duration securities. That said, firms with the largest portfolios appear to hold a
relatively wide range of financial securities and products. For example, the top 10 firms have
sizable positions in long-term corporate bonds (greater than one year) while holding relatively
little in short-term investments, such as CP, CDs, and MMFs (figure 1). Moreover, these firms have
historically held a large fraction of their financial assets in offshore accounts. For instance, just
before the passage of the TCJA, three-fourths of the top 10 firms’ financial assets were held
offshore. 2

Financial Markets

While firms are still evaluating the longer-term implications of the TCJA, recent data suggest
three emerging trends in how they might be restructuring their financial asset holdings.

1 The management of firms’ excess cash is part of their treasury functions, and these investors are typically

referred to as “corporate cash managers.”
2 Estimates are based on SEC filings as of late 2017 and early 2018. Firms in our sample have since stopped
reporting the size of their offshore holdings.

Page 52 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

First, the TCJA reduced the incentive for firms to keep sizable holdings of financial assets
offshore. Consistent with this development, we observe a substantial drawdown in the
combined financial asset holdings of the largest 10 firms since the passage of tax reform
(figure 1). 3
Second, in light of the TCJA, firms are likely to treat their onshore and offshore financial asset
holdings as close substitutes and as a result may demand higher liquidity in their offshore
accounts. It is unclear how this will affect firms’ offshore holdings of short-term money market
instruments, given the offsetting effects of (1) a reduction in overall financial asset holdings and
(2) a composition shift into more liquid investments. In any case, firms may reduce their illiquid
financial investments, such as corporate bonds, abroad. Indeed, the reduction in the top 10 firms’
financial asset holdings has been concentrated in U.S. Treasury securities and long-term
corporate bonds, both of which fell 15 percent over the first two quarters of 2018. 4 The reduction
in corporate bond holdings has coincided with an increase in trading of U.S. investment-grade
corporate bonds between dealers and their foreign affiliates. Such trading increased by 5 percent
and 20 percent year-on-year in the first and second quarters of 2018, respectively, consistent with
dealers intermediating the rebalancing of firms’ more illiquid offshore holdings.

Going forward, we intend to monitor changes in firms’ financial asset management. Their sizable
holdings of financial assets, unique investment objectives, and status as counterparties to large
financial firms are likely to have ongoing implications for a range of financial markets.

3 The July Tealbook box “U.S. Corporations’ Repatriation of Offshore Profits” discusses how U.S.

nonfinancial firms with large holdings of cash abroad appeared to deploy those funds after the passage of
the TCJA.
4 Investments in short-term instruments also dropped 15 percent over the same period, but those
investments represent a significantly smaller portion of their aggregate holdings.

Page 53 of 124

Financial Markets

Finally, foreign offices of domestic banks appear to have become more reliant on their home
offices for funding, as large U.S. banks’ net lending to their foreign offices has increased
substantially (figure 2). This increase in lending may in part reflect banks’ needs to replace
offshore funding they previously received from firms, which may have been significant when all
firms are considered.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Corporate Asset Market Developments

Intraday S&P 500 Index
Sept. 25, 2018, 4:00 p.m. = 100
Chairman Powell's
remarks
ISM
Employment
Nonmanufacturing Situation
report

USMCA

Sept.
FOMC

September CPI

104
102
100
98
96

Oct.
25

94
92
90
88

Sept. 27

Oct. 2

Oct. 5

Oct. 11

Oct. 16

Oct. 25

Oct. 19

Note: Data are for 2018 and spaced at 5-minute intervals from 9:30 a.m. to 4:10 p.m.
Source: Bloomberg.

Implied and Realized Volatilities
on S&P 500

Selected Stock Indexes

Log scale, percent

Sept. 25, 2018 = 100
120

Daily
S&P 500
Russell 2000
NASDAQ 100

Daily

Sept.
FOMC

50
Implied volatility (VIX)
Realized volatility

Sept.
FOMC

110
20
100
Oct.
25

Financial Markets

Oct.
25

10

90
5
80

Oct.
2017

Feb.

June
2018

Oct.

2015

10-Year Corporate Bond Yields

2018

10-Year Corporate Bond Spreads
Percent

Basis points
11 500

Sept.
FOMC

High-yield
Triple-B

Oct.
25

2015

2017

Note: Dashed line represents the historical median of VIX.
Source: Chicago Board Options Exchange; Bloomberg.

Source: Bloomberg.

Daily

2016

2016

2017

700

Daily

High-yield (right scale)
Triple-B (left scale)

10 450
9

400

8

350

7

300

6

250

5

200

4

150

3

100

Sept.
FOMC

600
500
400
Oct.
25

300
200

2018

Source: Staff estimates of smoothed yield curves based on Merrill Lynch
bond data.

Basis points

2015

2016

2017

2018

Note: Spreads over 10-year Treasury yield.
Source: Staff estimates of smoothed yield curves based on Merrill Lynch
bond data and smoothed Treasury yield curve.

Page 54 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

The nominal Treasury yield curve was little changed, on net, since the September
FOMC meeting amid some moderate volatility over the period, which market participants
struggled to attribute to a clear catalyst. ISM nonmanufacturing data that came in above
investor expectations and, to a lesser extent, FOMC participants’ communications were
cited as two potential factors contributing to a notable rise in yields early in the
intermeeting period. However, market participants viewed neither factor as being able to
explain much of the move in yields. Later in the period, yields declined in response to
flight-to-safety flows associated with a drop in broad equity price indexes and a rise in
market volatility. With yields little changed, on net, the spread between 10- and 2-year
Treasury yields remained around the 25th percentile of its distribution since 1971, while
the near-term forward spread stands near its 45th percentile.2 Since the previous FOMC
meeting, TIPS-implied inflation compensation over the next 5 years and 5-to-10-year
inflation compensation have declined moderately, with some of the decline occurring
after the September CPI came in below market expectations.

FOREIGN DEVELOPMENTS
Since the September FOMC meeting, global markets have been unsettled, with
particularly notable declines in equity markets. Although there have been no clear
drivers of the movements, foreign market participants have been focused on changes in
States and China, and uncertainty regarding budget negotiations between the Italian
government and the European Union.
Major foreign equity indexes fell 7 to 12 percent over the intermeeting period.
Option-implied measures of foreign equity volatility spiked as equity indexes fell in the
United States and around the world, but such measures remained well below levels seen
in February.
AFE 10-year government yields generally declined over the period, in contrast to
U.S. yields. On net, yields fell 15 to 19 basis points in Germany and the United

2

The near-term forward spread in this context is defined as the difference between the current
implied forward rate on three-month Treasury bills six quarters from now and the current yield on a threemonth Treasury bill. For analysis of the information content of these spreads, see Eric Engstrom and
Steven Sharpe (2018), “(Don’t Fear) the Yield Curve,” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, June 28), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/dont-fearthe-yield-curve-20180628.htm.

Page 55 of 124

Financial Markets

U.S. equity prices and U.S. interest rates, ongoing trade tensions between the United

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Foreign Developments
Equity Indexes

Implied Volatilities
Sept. 25, 2018 = 100

Daily

S&P 500
DJ Euro Stoxx
DJ Euro Stoxx Banks
MSCI EME
Shanghai

Percent

130

Daily

Daily
VIX
VDAX

120

45

Sept. FOMC

35
Sept. FOMC

Oct.
25

110

25
Oct.
25

100
15
90

May

June

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

80

Note: Indexes denominated in local currency.
Source: Bloomberg.

Mar.

May

July

Sept.

Source: Bloomberg; Haver.

10-Year AFE Sovereign Yields
Daily

5
Jan.

Euro-Area Peripheral Spreads
Percent

Percentage points

4

Daily

Sept. FOMC

Sept. FOMC

Italy
Spain
Portugal

United States

3.5

3
2.5

Canada
Oct.
25

Financial Markets

United Kingdom

Oct.
25

2

1.5
Germany

May

June

1

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

0

Mar.

May

July

Sept.

0.5

Source: Bloomberg.

Source: Bloomberg.

Exchange Rates

EME Exchange Rates
Sept. 25, 2018 = 100

Daily

Jan.

Broad
AFE
EME

Sept. 25, 2018 = 100

104

Daily

Turkish lira
Chiniese renminbi
Mexican peso
Brazilian real

103
Sept. FOMC

102
101

120
Sept. FOMC

Oct.
25

100
Oct.
25

100

99
98

90

97
Dollar
appreciation

110

Dollar
appreciation

96

80

95
May

June

Source: Bloomberg.

July

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

94

May

Page 56 of 124

June

July

Source: Bloomberg.

Aug.

Sept.

Oct.

70

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Kingdom, respectively, in part following weaker-than-expected inflation data and
European political developments. Canadian 10-year yields were little changed, and
short-term yields rose, bolstered by the announcement of the U.S.-Mexico-Canada trade
agreement, or USMCA, and a policy rate hike by the Bank of Canada.
Ten-year Italian spreads widened about 76 basis points over the period as the
Italian government proposed a budget with a wider deficit than market participants had
expected. The proposed budget was rejected by the European Commission, raising the
likelihood of a prolonged period of political confrontation. Other euro-area peripheral
spreads widened 9 to 31 basis points, and there were significant outflows from funds
focused on the euro-area periphery.
The dollar strengthened 2 percent against AFE currencies, including a 3½ percent
appreciation against the euro, amid wider differentials between U.S. yields and AFE
yields as well as concerns over Italian budget negotiations. The dollar appreciated
1¼ percent against EME currencies. While most EME currencies are down against the
dollar, the EMEs that had experienced financial pressures earlier this year strengthened.
The Brazilian real appreciated 9 percent as Jair Bolsonaro, perceived to be the relatively
more market-friendly candidate, won the first round of the Brazilian presidential election
with a larger-than-expected margin. Similarly, the Turkish lira retraced some earlier
the United States. EME-dedicated funds experienced small outflows over the
intermeeting period.
The three-month FX swap basis for the euro, the Swiss franc, and the Japanese
yen increased discretely about 30 basis points at the end of September and remained
elevated as the three-month contracts started to cross year-end (for more details, see the
box “Recent Developments in Offshore Dollar Funding Markets”).

SHORT-TERM FUNDING MARKETS AND FEDERAL RESERVE OPERATIONS
Overnight rates in short-term funding markets rose in line with the increase in the
target range announced at the September FOMC meeting. The distribution of federal
funds trades shifted steadily to slightly higher rates over the intermeeting period, with the
spread between the effective federal funds rate (EFFR) and the interest on excess reserves
(IOER) rate narrowing from 2 basis points to 0 basis points. To date, there has been no
marked change in the behavior of market participants as the EFFR rose to the IOER rate.

Page 57 of 124

Financial Markets

declines and rose 8½ percent over the period on declining tensions between Turkey and

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Recent Developments in Offshore Dollar Funding Markets
Market participants outside the United States can obtain dollar funding by exchanging foreign
currency for dollars in the FX swap market or, if available to them, by borrowing dollars directly. 1
The difference in annualized costs between the two funding sources is the FX swap basis,
typically quoted using LIBOR as a borrowing cost. In a frictionless world, the FX swap basis
should be close to zero (as implied by “covered interest rate parity”), but dollar funding via the
FX swap market has been more costly since the Global Financial Crisis (GFC).
For much of this year, however, the FX swap basis has been at its lowest level since the GFC,
reflecting generally benign conditions in offshore dollar funding markets. One factor behind the
low basis has been the flatter Treasury yield curve, which has likely reduced demand for dollar
funding and hedging via FX swaps. 2
On September 27, however, the first day that a new three-month FX swap contract would mature
after the end of 2018, the three-month FX swap basis jumped 20 to 30 basis points in most major
currencies (figure 1). There were no concurrent jumps in domestic dollar funding markets, such
as the commercial paper market.

Financial Markets

A discrete jump in the three-month FX basis also occurred in recent years when the contract first
spanned the year-end. But the increase this year was larger, although it began from a lower level.
This year’s increase has raised concerns about an outsized spike at the end of 2018 in the cost of
shorter-tenor dollar funding via FX swaps, perhaps even larger than the substantial spike that
occurred last year (figure 2). It could also mean, however, that sensitized by last year’s
experience, more market participants are obtaining their dollar funding earlier.

1 In an FX swap transaction, an investor buys dollars with foreign currency in a spot transaction while at

the same time agreeing with the seller on a date and a forward exchange rate to reverse the transaction.
2 Foreign investors often use dollar funding obtained via short-maturity FX swaps (and therefore hedged
against FX risk for that maturity) to invest in longer-term dollar-denominated securities. A flatter Treasury yield
curve reduces the return on that strategy.

Page 58 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

FX swaps on the books of banks potentially affect all five risk categories used to calculate the
G-SIB surcharge scores. Specifically, besides increasing the size of the balance sheet, FX swap
transactions are conducted over the counter, are usually cross-jurisdictional, often involve other
financial institutions as counterparties, and may have the dollar leg funded in the wholesale
market. In addition, many FX swap contracts have very short maturities, which means they can
quickly roll off the books of dealers. Thus, FX swap activity may be a prime target for a sudden
year-end pullback by institutions acutely concerned about capital requirements.
The substantial spike in the FX basis currently priced by FX swap markets for the year-end reflects
the high probability that some market participants will pay very high dollar funding costs for a
short period at that time. We note, however, that previous year-end spikes have not resulted in
widespread stresses in offshore dollar funding markets or been accompanied by unusual sales of
U.S. assets, as most market participants likely anticipated such events. Of course, the cost of
being prepared is the higher basis paid even now on contracts spanning the year-end, with the
burden falling on counterparties swapping foreign currency liquidity for dollar liquidity.
Finally, as with previous year-end spikes in the FX basis, we expect to see an associated rise in
draws from our central bank dollar swap lines at the European Central Bank and the Bank of
Japan. But these draws will likely again be far smaller than those seen in the GFC or the European
Sovereign Debt Crisis. 4

3 G-SIB reporting is based on pure year-end readings for banks in continental Europe, while for U.S. and

U.K. banks, for certain items, “year-end” reporting is based on a Q4 daily average or an average of the three
month-ends in Q4.
4 At the end of 2017, draws from our central bank swap lines peaked at $11.9 billion at the European
Central Bank and $160 million at the Bank of Japan.

Page 59 of 124

Financial Markets

An important factor explaining the spike in the basis at the end of 2017 was a temporary pullback
from the FX swap market by several large banks, including U.S. institutions, that are important
intermediaries and providers of dollar funding. The pullback reportedly reflected balance sheet
constraints driven by concerns over capital requirements based on year-end reporting. Among
these concerns is that of being placed in a higher global systemically important bank (G-SIB)
surcharge bucket. 3

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Short−Term Funding Markets
Distribution of Fed Funds Rate across Trades

Selected Money Market Rates

Billions of dollars

Basis points

275

Sept
FOMC

Daily
Triparty general collateral
IOER
Federal funds
1−month T−bill

< IOER − 3bp
IOER − 3bp
IOER − 2bp

Daily

250

IOER − 1bp
IOER
Sept.
> IOER
FOMC

Median volume

90
80

225

Oct.
25

100

70

200

60

175

50

150

40
30

125

20

100

10
75
July

Sept. Nov.
2017

Jan.

Mar.

May
July
2018

Sept.

0
Aug. 1

Aug. 15 Aug. 29 Sept. 13 Sept. 27 Oct. 12

Note: Federal funds rate is a weighted median, and shaded area is the target range for the
federal funds rate. IOER is interest on excess reserves.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2420, Report of Selected Money Market Rates.

Note: IOER is interest on excess reserves.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2420, Report of Selected Money Market
Rates.

ON RRP, Take−Up by Type

Nonfinancial CP Spreads
Billions of dollars

Daily

Sept.
FOMC

Other
Prime MMFs
Government MMFs

Basis points

450

Overnight double−A
1−month double−A
Overnight A2/P2
1−month A2/P2

Daily

400
350

Sept.
FOMC

100
80

300

60

250
200

40
Oct.
25

Financial Markets

150

0

50
0

Oct.
2017

Jan.

Apr.

2018

July

−20

Oct.

Oct.
Dec.
2017

Feb.

Apr.

June
2018

Aug.

Oct.

Note: ON RRP is overnight reverse repurchase agreement; MMF is money market
fund.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Note: Overnight commerical paper (CP) spreads are to federal funds rate.
1−month CP spreads are to the overnight index swap rate (OIS).
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

CD Spreads to OIS

Prime and Government MMF Assets under
Manangement
Basis points

Daily

Sept.
FOMC

1−month
3−month

20

100

Oct.
25

July

120

Billions of dollars
Weekly

80

Government
Prime

Sept.
FOMC

3000
2500

60
2000
40
Oct.
25

1500

20

1000
Oct.
24

0
−20
Oct.
Dec.
2017

Feb.

Apr.

June
2018

Aug.

Note: Certificate of deposit (CD) rates are a 5−day moving average.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

Oct.

500
0

Oct.
2015

Apr.

Oct.
2016

Apr.

Note: MMF is money market fund.
Source: Investment Company Institute.

Page 60 of 124

Oct.
2017

Apr.
Oct.
2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Federal funds volume declined to $63 billion per day from $70 billion in the previous
intermeeting period. ON RRP take-up has remained low, averaging $4 billion per day
excluding the September quarter-end.3
Since the previous FOMC meeting, overnight nonfinancial commercial paper
(CP) rates are up about 25 basis points, while rates on longer-dated instruments, such as
one-month to six-month negotiable certificates of deposit, are up about 15 basis points.
The spreads of overnight CP rates over the EFFR were little changed; longer-dated
unsecured short-term spreads over OIS increased somewhat but less than the three-month
FX swap basis. Assets under management in money market funds (MMFs) were little
changed over the intermeeting period, and net yields on taxable MMFs increased, on
average, 16 basis points. Rates paid by banks on retail deposit products were also little
changed, on average, over the intermeeting period and have increased only 1 to 14 basis

Financial Markets

points since last December.

3

If test operations are ignored, October marks the first investment period since July 2010 that the
Federal Reserve has purchased neither Treasury securities nor MBS. It completed September MBS
purchases on October 11. The Desk, however, conducted small-value exercises. It rolled $26 million of
Treasury bills, sold $47 million of Treasury bills, and purchased $139 million of MBS.

Page 61 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Financial Markets

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 62 of 124

October 26, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Financing Conditions for Businesses and Households
While rising interest rates in recent months appeared to have reduced demand for
credit by some borrowers, a continued easing of lending standards and terms for
businesses and still generally accommodative supply conditions for households have
served to support growth in borrowing and spending.
•

Spreads on corporate bonds and loans have remained low relative to their
average levels over the past several years, and banks reported further easing of
standards and terms for C&I loans.

•

Business financing flows have remained strong, especially for investmentgrade corporate bonds and leveraged loans. However, banks reported weaker
demand and lower loan volumes for both C&I and CRE loans.
Mortgage credit supply conditions for households remained accommodative,
but mortgage originations for home purchase have remained flat. Refinancing
activity continues to be subdued due, in part, to rising mortgage rates.

•

Credit card loan growth showed signs of moderation amid rising interest rates
and reported tightening of lending standards at the largest credit card banks.
Other types of consumer credit, including student and auto loans, continued to
grow at a solid pace.

•

The October 2018 SLOOS asked a set of special questions on the effects of
movements in the yield curve on banks’ lending policies. A summary of
banks’ responses to those questions is discussed in the box “Bank Lending
Policies and the Yield Curve” at the end of the section.

Financing Conditions

•

Page 63 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Business Finance
Average Spreads of New-Issue
Institutional Leveraged Loans

Selected Components of Net Debt
Financing, Nonfinancial Firms
Basis points

Billions of dollars
800

Monthly

700

B+/B
BB/BB-

100

Monthly rate
Commercial paper*
C&I loans*
Bonds
Institutional leveraged loans
Total

600

80
60

Q1

500

Q2 Q3

40

400
Sept.

20

300

0

200
100
2012

2014

2016

-20

2018

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: Breaks in the series represent periods with no issuance. Spreads are
calculated against 3-month LIBOR. The spreads do not include up-front fees.
Source: S&P LCD.

* Period-end basis.
Source: Mergent Fixed Income Securities Database; Thomson Reuters LPC;
Federal Reserve Board; Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

C&I Loan Terms: Changes in Loan
Spreads

C&I Loans
Net percent

Billions of dollars
30

100

Tightening

Quarterly

Monthly rate, s.a.

80

Large/middle-market firms
Small firms

25

Large banks
Small banks
Foreign banks

60
40

20

20

Q2

0
-20

Easing

Q3

15
Q3

Q1

-40

5

-60

0

-80

-5

-100

2012

2014

2016

2018

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: Plotted are the net percentage of banks reporting increasing spreads
on C&I loans. Banks' responses are weighted by the outstanding amount of C&I
loans on their balance sheets at the end of the previous quarter.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices.

Note: Large banks are defined as the largest 25 banks by assets.
Source: Staff calculations, Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2644, Weekly
Report of Selected Assets and Liabilities of Domestically Chartered Commercial
Banks and U.S. Branches and Agencies of Foreign Banks.

CRE Loans: Changes in Standards

CRE Loans
Net percent

Construction and land development
Nonfarm nonresidential
Multifamily

Easing

Q3

2014

2015

2016

2017

Billions of dollars
100
80
60
40
20
0
-20
-40
-60
-80
-100

Quarterly
Tightening

10

Monthly rate, s.a.

Q1

2018

2012

Note: Plotted are the net percentage of banks reporting tighter standards on
CRE loans. Banks' responses are weighted by the outstanding amount of CRE
loans on their balance sheets at the end of previous quarter.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices.

Construction and land development
Multifamily
Nonfarm nonresidential

2014

2016

Q2

Q3

2018

Source: Staff calculations, Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2644, Weekly
Report of Selected Assets and Liabilities of Domestically Chartered Commercial
Banks and U.S. Branches and Agencies of Foreign Banks.

Page 64 of 124

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

BUSINESS FINANCING CONDITIONS
Nonfinancial Corporations
Financing conditions for nonfinancial firms remained supportive of borrowing
and spending over the intermeeting period. Spreads of yields on corporate bonds and
institutional leveraged loans over those on three-month LIBOR remained low relative to
their average level over the past several years but have drifted up in recent weeks. In the
October 2018 SLOOS, banks, on net, reported easing standards and terms for C&I loans
to large and middle-market firms over the past three months, and all banks that eased
cited increased competition from both bank and nonbank lenders as an important reason.
Other reasons provided by a significant fraction of banks that eased standards and terms
on C&I loans included increased liquidity in the secondary market for these loans, a more
favorable or less uncertain economic outlook, and an increased tolerance for risk.
Net debt financing of nonfinancial firms was robust in the third quarter, as weak
speculative-grade bond issuance was largely offset by high leveraged loan issuance,
reportedly reflecting investors’ stronger demand for floating-rate products. Although the
volume of leveraged loans held by nonbanks continued to grow steadily, C&I loan
growth at banks slowed in the third quarter, especially at large and foreign banks,
consistent with responses to the October 2018 SLOOS that demand for C&I loans had
weakened over the third quarter on balance.
The pace of gross equity issuance through initial public offerings was solid in
September and so far in October despite notable recent declines in stock prices. In
contrast, the pace of seasoned equity offerings has slowed a bit in October, following
strong issuance in September.
The credit quality of nonfinancial corporations remained solid, though modest
signs of deterioration continued, as the volume of nonfinancial corporate bond
downgrades somewhat outpaced that of upgrades in September. On net, the KMV
near the middle of its historical range.
The outlook for corporate earnings remained favorable on balance. During the
current earnings reporting season, some large firms raised concerns about their future
profitability due to increasing costs. Even so, projections by Wall Street analysts for
year-ahead earnings for S&P 500 firms were, in aggregate, little changed over the

Page 65 of 124

Financing Conditions

expected year-ahead default rate for nonfinancial firms increased somewhat and stayed

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

intermeeting period and continued to call for a healthy five percent growth in year-ahead
earnings.

Small Businesses
Financing conditions for small businesses remained generally accommodative.
Conditions have been stable in recent months, with the October 2018 SLOOS
respondents reporting little change, on net, in bank lending standards to small firms over
previous months. In the National Federation of Independent Business monthly member
polls, the fraction of respondents with planned capital expenditures in the next six months
has climbed in recent months, although it remains below its levels in the years leading up
to the financial crisis. Lending volumes to small businesses have leveled out after rising
over much of the past year.

Commercial Real Estate
Financing conditions in CRE markets remained accommodative. CMBS spreads
remained near their post-crisis lows, and spreads on CRE loans at banks also remained
low. The largest banks reported an easing of standards on all three major categories of
CRE loans over the third quarter of 2018 on net. Banks also reported somewhat weaker
demand for nonfarm nonresidential and construction and development loans. Consistent
with these reports, growth of CRE loans on bank’s balance sheets slowed a bit, driven
primarily by a slowdown at large banks. Issuance of non-agency and agency CMBS was
stable in recent months, similar to previous year levels.

MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT FINANCING CONDITIONS
Credit conditions in municipal bond markets remained accommodative on
balance. Yields on 20-year municipal bonds in the primary market increased slightly
more than yields on Treasury securities, leaving spreads over comparable-maturity
Treasury securities slightly higher. In the third quarter, the credit quality of state and
local governments improved a bit as the number of upgrades was somewhat larger than
that of downgrades. Gross issuance of municipal bonds in September and October was
strong, much of which raised new capital.

Page 66 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

HOUSEHOLD FINANCING CONDITIONS
Residential Real Estate
Although financing conditions in the residential mortgage market continued to be
accommodative for most borrowers, the increase in mortgage rates since 2016 has
appeared to have reduced demand, and financing conditions remained somewhat tight for
borrowers with low credit scores. Refinance activity continued to be very muted, and the
growth in purchase mortgage originations has slowed over the past year as mortgage rates
remained near their highest level since 2011.

Consumer Credit
Financing conditions in consumer credit markets, on balance, remained
supportive of growth in household spending, although interest rates for consumer loans
continued to rise and appeared to have a greater bearing on consumer sentiment for large
purchases. The share of respondents in the University of Michigan Surveys of
Consumers that noted high interest rates as a reason for not making large purchases was
larger in the most recent survey than in surveys conducted earlier in the year. Credit card
loan growth showed signs of moderating amid rising interest rates and reported tightening
of lending standards at the largest credit card banks. According to the October 2018
SLOOS, banks were less willing to make credit card loans as compared with the
beginning of this year for borrowers across the credit spectrum, though the tightening was
more pronounced for borrowers with lower credit scores.
Other types of consumer credit, including student and auto loans, continued to
grow at a solid pace. Conditions in the consumer ABS market remained stable, with
spreads hovering near historical lows and year-to-date issuance outpacing that in recent

Financing Conditions

years.

Page 67 of 124

Authorized for Public Release
Household Finance

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Maximum Allowed Debt-Service-to-Income
Ratio for Residential Mortgages
DTI ratio
Quarterly

Mortgage Rate and MBS Yield
Percent

90

Daily

80
FICO >= 720

30-year conforming
fixed mortgage rate

60
50

Oct.
24

40
30
FICO <= 620

7.5
7.0
6.5
6.0
5.5
5.0
4.5
4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5

Sept.
FOMC

70

Q3

October 26, 2018

MBS yield

20
10
0

2008

600

2010

2012

2014

2016

2008

2018

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: DTI is debt service to income.
Source: For frontiers shown with circles, McDash and CoreLogic; for frontiers
shown with solid lines, Optimal Blue.

Note: The mortgage-backed securities (MBS) yield is the Fannie Mae 30-year
current-coupon rate.
Source: For mortgage rate before 2010, Freddie Mac, after 2010, Loansifter;
for MBS yield, Barclays.

Purchase and Refinance Activity

Consumer Interest Rates

Thousands of originations

Thousands of originations

Monthly

1000

17

Percent

Refinance
(right scale)

400

800
Home purchase
(left scale)

600
400

Sept.

200

200

8

15
14
13

300

9

Sept.
FOMC

Credit cards (left scale)
New auto loans (right scale)

16
500

Percent

Q3

7

Oct.
14

6

12

5

11
4

10
100

0
2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

9

2018

Note: The data are seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve Board staff.
Source: For values before 2017, data reported under the Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act of 1975; for values in and after 2017, staff estimates.

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: Credit card data reflect rates at commercial banks on all credit card
plans; data are reported quarterly and not seasonally adjusted. Auto loans data
are reported weekly and seasonally adjusted.
Source: For credit cards, Federal Reserve Board; for auto loans, J.D. Power.

Likelihood of Approving Credit Card Applications,
by FICO Score

Consumer Credit
Percentage change from previous year
Student loans

Monthly

3
2008

12

Aug.

Auto loans

Percent of respondents

18
Somewhat more likely
About as likely

Somewhat less likely

100
75

6

50

0

25

-6
Credit cards
2008

2010

-12
2012

2014

2016

2018

0
A borrower with a FICO
score (or equivalent)
of 620

A borrower with a FICO
score (or equivalent)
of 680

A borrower with a FICO
score (or equivalent)
of 720

Note: Compared with the beginning of the year. Individual bank responses have
been weighted by the outstanding amount of the relevant loan category
on the bank's balance sheet at the end of the previous quarter.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices.

Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Page 68 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Bank Lending Policies and the Yield Curve
The October 2018 SLOOS asked banks’ loan officers a set of special questions on changes
in lending policies in response to movements in the yield curve. Loan officers were first
asked about changes in their lending policies in response to the flattening of the yield
curve since the beginning of this year, independent of other factors that have influenced
those policies. Loan officers were then asked to assess potential changes in their lending
policies in response to a sustained hypothetical moderate inversion of the yield curve. 1
Banks’ loan officers generally reported that the recent flattening in the yield curve has
not affected their standards or price terms across major loan categories (figure 1). In
contrast, in response to a hypothetical moderate inversion of the yield curve, banks
responded that they would tighten somewhat standards or price terms across every
major loan category (figure 2). The vast majority of respondents interpreted this scenario
as a signal of a future deterioration in economic conditions. Specifically, major shares of
respondents indicated that they would anticipate such a scenario to be accompanied by a
less favorable or more uncertain economic outlook, a likely deterioration in the quality of
their bank’s loan portfolio, and a reduction in their risk tolerance (figure 3).
About half of loan officers who indicated that their banks would tighten lending
standards or price terms in response to a moderate yield curve inversion also said that
less profitable lending relative to their banks’ cost of funds and, relatedly, less aggressive
competition from other banks and nonbanks under this scenario would be important
reasons for tightening. Because bank lending may become less profitable when the yield
curve inverts (due to banks obtaining funding at short-term interest rates but lending at
longer-term interest rates), these responses suggest that a yield curve inversion could, by
itself, act as a headwind to economic activity by causing some banks to pull back from
lending, independent of changes in economic conditions.
Relatedly, the September 2018 SCOOS provides one source of analogous information
regarding the likely response of nonbanks to a hypothetical yield curve inversion; that
survey focuses on securities dealers and the terms they offer to their institutional
investor clients. 2 On balance, a modest net fraction of SCOOS respondents indicated that
they would tighten their credit terms somewhat under this scenario. The most cited
reasons for that outcome were that the scenario would be associated with higher dealer
funding costs, a general worsening in the liquidity and functioning of securities markets,
and a deterioration in the financial strength of counterparties associated with a general
deterioration in macroeconomic conditions. 3

below the 3-month Treasury bill, and that this inversion prevails over the next year.
2 Securities dealers extend financing to investors who, in turn, hold securities that are backed by
loans to businesses and households. As such, the terms at which securities dealers engage with clients
indirectly affect credit conditions for businesses and households.
3 For more details on responses to the SLOOS and SCOOS special questions on movements in the
yield curve and changes in banks’ and dealers’ credit standards and terms, see the following memos:
Robert Kurtzman (2018), “October 2018 Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices,”
memorandum to the FOMC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary
Affairs, October 25; and Michael Gordy (2018), “September 2018 Senior Credit Officer Opinion Survey on

Page 69 of 124

Financing Conditions

1 The hypothetical moderate inversion scenario assumes the 10-year Treasury yield falls moderately

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Dealer Financing Terms,” memorandum to the FOMC, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, Division of Research and Statistics, September 13.

Page 70 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Risks and Uncertainty
ASSESSMENT OF RISKS
We continue to view the uncertainty around the staff forecast of economic activity over
the next year or so as being in line with the average over the past 20 years, the benchmark used
by the FOMC. In addition, we still judge the upside and downside risks around the projections
for real GDP growth and the unemployment rate over that period as being balanced. On the
upside, the underlying fundamentals for household spending and business investment remain
strong—bolstered in part by the tax cuts enacted last year—and readings on household and
business sentiment generally remain upbeat. In these circumstances, spending and investment
could expand faster than in the staff projection. On the downside, foreign economic
developments and trade policies could move in directions that have significant negative effects
on U.S economic growth. These overall assessments are consistent with the four-quarter-ahead
estimates of forecast risks around GDP growth and the unemployment rate presented in the
exhibit “Time-Varying Macroeconomic Risk.”
We remain concerned about recession risks during the period beyond the next year or so.
In our baseline outlook, the economy is projected to move further beyond its potential over the
next two years. If that forecast is correct, then we anticipate that a significant slowing in the
pace of economic growth, along with a gradual increase in the unemployment rate, will be
necessary to return the economy to a sustainable position in the longer run. During the period of
subpar growth, the economy will be more susceptible to being pushed into a recession by
negative shocks. Neither we nor anyone else have clear insight as to the precise timing of when
a recession could occur, but the period of adjustment back to sustainability will be a time of
heightened downside risk.
With regard to inflation, the staff still sees average uncertainty and balanced risks around
the projection over the next year or so. To the downside, longer-run inflation expectations
relevant for wage and price setting could currently be lower than assumed in the baseline or may
not edge up in the coming years. Also, the exchange value of the dollar could appreciate more
than expected and put downward pressure on inflation. To the upside, with economic activity
projected to move further above its potential, inflation could increase more than in the staff
forecast, consistent with the predictions of models that emphasize nonlinear effects of resource
utilization on inflation. In addition, an unexpectedly widespread and sustained increase in trade

Page 71 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Risks & Uncertainty

Time-Varying Macroeconomic Risk
Unemployment Rate

Percentage points

90%
70%
50%

6

October 2018

5

95th

0.3

4

85th

0.1

2

50th

-0.2

1

15th

-0.6

5th

-0.9

3

0
-1
-2
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

GDP Growth

2015

Percentage points

October 2018

4
2

95th

2.0

0

85th

1.3

-2

50th

0.2

-4

15th

-0.9

-6

5th

-1.4

-8
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

CPI Inflation

1990

1995

2000

2005

2015

Percentage points

2010

7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3

October 2018
95th

1.6

85th

1.1

50th

0.1

15th

-0.8

5th

-1.3

2015

Note: The exhibit shows estimates of quantiles of the distribution of errors for four-quarter-ahead staff
forecasts. The estimates are conditioned on indicators of real activity, inflation, financial market strain,
and the volatility of high-frequency macroeconomic indicators. The tables show selected quantiles of the
predictive distributions for the respective variables as of the current Tealbook. Dashed lines denote the
median 15ᵗʰ and 85ᵗʰ percentiles. Gray shaded bars indicate recession periods as defined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Page 72 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Effective Lower Bound Risk Estimate

ELB Risk since Liftoff
Percent

50

40

Current-quarter ELB risk = 6%
30

20

10

0
Apr. 2016

Nov. 2016

May 2017

Nov. 2017

May 2018

Nov. 2018

ELB Risk over the Projection Period
Percent

20

15

10

5

0
2018:Q4

2019:Q2

2019:Q4

2020:Q2

2020:Q4

2021:Q2

2021:Q4

Note: The figures show the probability that the federal funds rate reaches the effective lower
bound (ELB) over the next 3 years starting in the given quarter. Details behind the computation of
the ELB risk measure are provided in the box "A Guidepost for Dropping the Effective Lower
Bound Risk from the Assessment of Risks" in the Risks and Uncertainty section of the April 2017
Tealbook A. The lower panel computes ELB risk over a forward-looking moving 3-year window
using stochastic simulations in FRB/US beginning in the current quarter. The simulations are
computed around the Tealbook baseline.

Page 73 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

barriers could lead to higher inflation. These assessments are consistent with the statistical
estimates of the time-varying risks for the inflation forecast over the next year. Of course, if the
risks to the forecast for economic activity beyond a year or so are tilted to the downside, then the
risks to the inflation projection would also tend to have a downward skew at that time.
Our view of the risks to the economic outlook is informed by the staff’s quarterly
quantitative surveillance (QS) assessment, which judges the overall financial vulnerabilities in
the United States to be moderate. Vulnerabilities from leverage and maturity transformation in
the U.S. financial system appear low. Banks look to be well capitalized and hold substantial
amounts of high-quality liquid assets, while liquidity risk associated with money market funds
remains much reduced owing to the SEC reforms implemented a couple of years ago. In the
household sector, debt has increased only moderately and primarily among prime-rated
borrowers. However, in the nonfinancial corporate sector, borrowing by highly levered and
lower-rated firms is elevated, suggesting that a weakening in economic activity could be
amplified by strains within this sector. Asset valuation pressures also continue to be elevated
despite the recent substantial declines in equity prices. In addition, term premiums on nominal
Treasury securities, along with spreads on corporate bonds and on leveraged loans, have
remained low. Although some indicators suggest that the pace of house price appreciation has
slowed recently, house values increased substantially over the past year and still appear to be
somewhat elevated relative to rents. Existing domestic financial vulnerabilities could amplify
shocks from a marked jump in Treasury yields, which could be caused by an increase in
concerns about the current high level and unsustainable trajectory of federal government debt. In
addition, existing vulnerabilities could amplify shocks from abroad, including from
developments associated with international trade policies, emerging market economies (EMEs),
or Brexit.

ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS
To illustrate some of the risks to the outlook, we construct alternatives to the baseline
projection using simulations of staff models. The first scenario posits that increases in interest
rates could restrain household and business spending by more than is assumed in the baseline. In
the second scenario, higher realized inflation puts upward pressure on inflation expectations,
which leads to persistently higher inflation and also slower output growth. The third scenario
considers a downside risk from an increase in financial market concerns about federal
government debt, which results in a larger and faster increase in term premiums on longer-term
Treasury securities and higher borrowing rates. The fourth scenario posits that the natural rate of

Page 74 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

unemployment is lower and structural productivity growth is faster than assumed in the baseline.
The fifth scenario traces out the consequences of a sizable increase in financial market stress in
China. Finally, the sixth scenario illustrates the effects of a large increase in oil prices that
triggers a sharp rise in inflation in advanced economies and a tightening of global financial
conditions.
The first four scenarios are simulated with the FRB/US model; the last two scenarios use
the SIGMA model.1 In all of the scenarios, the federal funds rate is governed by the same policy
rule as in the baseline. Additionally, the size and composition of the SOMA portfolio are
assumed to follow the baseline paths in all of the scenarios.

Greater Interest Rate Sensitivity [FRB/US]
The baseline forecast shows a large positive output gap for a number of years despite
increases in the federal funds rate to about 2¼ percentage points above its long-run value.
However, there is a risk that the projected tightening in monetary policy will weigh on economic
activity more than is assumed in the baseline. In this scenario, we explore the possibility that
household and business spending, along with equity prices, are more sensitive to interest rates
than in the baseline.2
With household spending and business investment more responsive to the path of real
interest rates and equity prices being lower by as much as 25 percent, real GDP growth is weaker
than in the baseline until 2022. The unemployment rate is higher than in the baseline and moves
above 4 percent in 2021; inflation remains close to baseline, reflecting the very flat Phillips curve
in the FRB/US model. Resource utilization is much less tight than in the baseline, and inflation
is little changed, which results in the federal funds rate being notably below the baseline path,
peaking at 3¾ percent in early 2021.

Inflation Fears [FRB/US]
In recent years, private-sector expectations of future inflation have been formed in an
environment mainly characterized by low and stable inflation, generally at or below the FOMC’s
1
FRB/US is a large-scale macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy, and SIGMA is a calibrated
multicountry DSGE model.
2
Specifically, the magnitude of the peak output response to a monetary policy shock of 1 percentage point
on the federal funds rate is amplified from 0.2 percent in the baseline projection to 0.8 percent in this scenario, a
value more consistent with some DSGE models.

Page 75 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Alternative Scenarios
Risks & Uncertainty

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

2018
Measure and scenario
H2

2019 2020 2021 2022 202324

Real GDP
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears
Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side
EME financial turbulence
Inflation-driven global tightening

2.8
2.3
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.8
2.7

2.4
1.5
1.3
1.9
2.9
1.9
1.5

1.9
.9
1.3
1.5
2.6
1.4
.7

1.4
1.2
1.1
1.4
2.1
1.4
1.2

1.2
1.4
1.0
1.3
1.7
1.4
1.4

1.2
1.7
1.2
1.4
1.5
1.4
1.5

Unemployment rate1
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears
Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side
EME financial turbulence
Inflation-driven global tightening

3.6
3.7
3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6

3.3
3.7
3.7
3.5
3.2
3.5
3.6

3.3
4.0
4.0
3.6
3.1
3.7
4.1

3.4
4.2
4.2
3.7
3.1
3.9
4.4

3.7
4.3
4.5
4.0
3.4
4.1
4.6

4.2
4.3
5.1
4.3
4.0
4.5
4.7

Total PCE prices
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears
Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side
EME financial turbulence
Inflation-driven global tightening

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.7
1.7
1.6
2.2

2.0
2.0
2.4
2.0
1.9
1.3
3.4

1.9
1.9
2.8
1.9
1.9
1.6
2.6

1.9
1.9
3.1
1.9
1.8
1.8
2.2

2.0
1.9
3.4
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.0
3.4
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1

Core PCE prices
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears
Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side
EME financial turbulence
Inflation-driven global tightening

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.7
1.7
1.6
1.8

2.0
2.0
2.5
2.0
2.0
1.6
3.1

2.0
2.0
2.9
2.0
2.0
1.7
2.8

2.0
2.0
3.2
2.0
1.9
1.9
2.3

2.1
2.0
3.5
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1

2.1
2.0
3.5
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1

Federal funds rate1
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears
Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side
EME financial turbulence
Inflation-driven global tightening

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.2
2.3
2.3

3.6
3.3
3.5
3.5
3.2
3.2
4.3

4.5
3.7
4.3
4.1
4.0
3.8
4.7

4.8
3.6
4.7
4.2
4.4
4.2
4.1

4.7
3.3
4.7
4.0
4.4
4.1
3.5

4.0
3.2
4.2
3.5
3.8
3.6
3.2

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 76 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

2 percent objective. As a result, there is considerable uncertainty as to how these expectations
might change if inflation were to run persistently and significantly above that objective. In
particular, an extended period of inflation above 2 percent may cause longer-run inflation
expectations to move upward and also raise the perceived riskiness of nominal assets, thus
increasing term premiums.
In this scenario, we assume a steeper Phillips curve such that the tight economy leads to
higher inflation than in the baseline, possibly as a result of nonlinearities in the relationship
between resource utilization and inflation. Moreover, it is assumed that, in forming their
inflation expectations, households and businesses put more weight on recent inflation experience
than in the baseline. Finally, in this environment of heightened inflation risk, Treasury term
premiums rise persistently to a level about 1 percentage point above their baseline values.
Under these assumptions, inflation runs substantially above the Tealbook forecast for
several years. Yields on Treasury securities and corporate bonds rise in response to the assumed
increase in inflation risk premiums, causing GDP growth to be about 1 percentage point slower
than in the baseline in 2019. The unemployment rate increases slowly throughout the simulation,
ending almost 1 percentage point above the baseline (though still only a little above its assumed
natural rate by the end of the simulation period). The response of the federal funds rate in this
scenario is initially dominated by the lower level of real GDP rather than by the higher path of
inflation; as a result, the federal funds rate is slightly below baseline until early 2022.
Thereafter, however, the influence of higher inflation dominates, and the federal funds rate is
¼ percentage point above baseline by 2024 as inflation is slowly brought back down toward the
2 percent objective.

Federal Debt Concerns [FRB/US]
In response to the enactment of expansionary fiscal policies over the past year and the
resulting higher projected level of the federal debt-to-GDP ratio, the baseline projection has
assumed that term premiums on Treasury securities will gradually rise further than they would
otherwise. However, as noted in the QS assessment, an increase in concerns about the current
high level and unsustainable trajectory of the U.S. federal government debt could lead to a larger
and significantly more rapid increase in term premiums than assumed in the baseline. This
scenario explores the implications of that outcome.3 In particular, higher term premiums on
In the scenario, the 10-year Treasury term premium is about 75 basis points above its baseline value by
the end of 2019.
3

Page 77 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Forecast Confidence Intervals and Alternative Scenarios
Confidence Intervals Based on FRB/US Stochastic Simulations
Tealbook baseline and extension
Greater interest rate sensitivity
Inflation fears

Federal debt concerns
Stronger supply side

Real GDP

EME financial turbulence
Inflation−driven global tightening

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
5

7.5
7.0

4

6.5

70 percent
interval

6.0

3

5.5
2

5.0
4.5

1
4.0
3.5

0

3.0
−1
90 percent
interval

2.5
2.0

−2

1.5
−3

2016

2018

2020

2022

1.0

2024

2016

PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy

2018

2020

2022

2024

Federal Funds Rate

4−quarter percent change

Percent
4.5

8

4.0

7

3.5

6

3.0

5

2.5

4

2.0
3
1.5
2
1.0
1
0.5
0
0.0
2016

2018

2020

2022

2024

2016

Page 78 of 124

2018

2020

2022

2024

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Treasury securities show through to higher borrowing rates for both households and businesses,
which restrains their spending and investment.
Given the higher borrowing costs, real GDP growth slows to ½ percentage point below
the baseline in 2020, at which time the unemployment rate has risen about ¼ percentage point
above the baseline. Inflation remains close to baseline levels, and consequently the federal funds
rate is about ¼ percentage point lower, on average, over the medium term. The negative effects
of a larger and faster increase in longer-term Treasury rates could be greater than illustrated in
this scenario if, for example, they were to be amplified by financial sector vulnerabilities not
reflected in this simulation.

Stronger Supply Side [FRB/US]
Although the unemployment rate is currently about 1 percentage point below our estimate
of its natural rate, wage gains have remained modest. One way of reconciling modest wage
gains with a very low unemployment rate is that the natural rate could be lower than in the
baseline. In this scenario, we assume that the natural rate of unemployment has been lower in
the past two years than assumed by the staff and that it continues to fall, possibly reflecting
positive hysteresis. The natural rate is assumed to reach 4.1 percent at the end of 2019,
½ percentage point lower than in the baseline. In addition, we assume that structural
productivity growth will be about ¼ percentage point faster than in the baseline. Finally,
policymakers and the private sector are assumed to fully recognize these changes in supply-side
conditions.
As a result, in this scenario, real GDP growth is, on average, ½ percentage point above
the baseline, and the unemployment rate declines faster, reaching about 3 percent in 2021.
Inflation rises more slowly than in the baseline, reflecting faster productivity growth, with core
PCE inflation hovering around 2 percent in the medium term. With a narrower output gap
persisting for several years and lower inflation, the federal funds rate is 4 percent at the end of
2020, ½ percentage point below the baseline.4

In this scenario, resource utilization is less tight than in the baseline entering the projection period because
the level of potential output is assumed to be higher over recent history.
4

Page 79 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Selected Tealbook Projections and 70 Percent Confidence Intervals Derived
from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors and FRB/US Simulations
Measure
Real GDP
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Civilian unemployment rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices, total
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices excluding
food and energy
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Federal funds rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
FRB/US stochastic simulations

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

3.0

2.4

1.9

1.4

1.2

1.2

1.3

2.4–4.2
2.8–3.1

1.2–4.0
1.2–3.8

-.2–3.7
.3–3.6

-1.0–3.1
-.3–3.2

...
-.7–3.0

...
-.8–3.1

...
-.7–3.2

3.6

3.3

3.3

3.4

3.7

4.0

4.2

3.4–3.7
3.5–3.7

2.4–3.7
2.6–3.9

2.2–4.3
2.2–4.1

2.1–4.9
2.1–4.6

...
2.3–5.1

...
2.5–5.5

...
2.7–5.7

2.0

2.0

1.9

1.9

2.0

2.1

2.1

1.8–2.3
1.9–2.0

1.4–3.4
1.0–2.8

1.2–3.6
.8–2.9

1.3–3.4
.8–3.0

...
.8–3.1

...
.8–3.2

...
.8–3.2

1.9

2.0

2.0

2.0

2.1

2.1

2.1

1.7–2.2
1.9–2.0

1.6–2.6
1.2–2.7

1.5–2.9
1.0–2.9

...
1.0–3.0

...
1.0–3.0

...
.9–3.1

...
1.0–3.2

2.3

3.6

4.5

4.8

4.7

4.3

4.0

2.3–2.3

3.2–4.2

3.4–5.7

3.2–6.6

2.6–6.8

2.0–6.7

1.5–6.4

Note: Shocks underlying FRB/US stochastic simulations are randomly drawn from the 1969–2017 set of model equation residuals.
Intervals derived from Tealbook forecast errors are based on projections made from 1980 to 2017 for real GDP and unemployment
and from 1998 to 2017 for PCE prices. The intervals for real GDP, unemployment, and total PCE prices are extended into 2021
using information from the Blue Chip survey and forecasts from the CBO and CEA.
. . . Not applicable.

Page 80 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Prediction Intervals Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors

Q4 Level,
Percent

Unemployment Rate
Historical
revisions

Tealbook
forecasts

Augmented
Tealbook 1

median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
data/forecast
range

Q4/Q4,
Percent

PCE Inflation

13

Risks & Uncertainty

Historical
Distributions

Forecast Error Percentiles

4

11

3

9
2
7
1
5
0

3

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

1

2015

1980 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Real GDP Growth

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-1
1998 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Core PCE Inflation

8

4

6

3

4
2
2
1
0
0

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-4

2015

1980 to 2017

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

-1
1998 to 2017

Historical Distributions
Unemployment Rate

PCE Inflation

Real GDP Growth

Annual, Percent
25
median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
20
2.5% to 97.5%
range

Annual, Percent

Annual, Percent

20

16

12

12

12

8

8

4

4

0

0

-4

-4

-8

-8

-8

-12

-12

-12

0
-4

5
0
1980 to
2017

Annual, Percent

4

10

1930 to 1947 to
2017
2017

16

16

8

15

Core PCE Inflation

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1980 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

Note: See the technical note in the appendix for more information on this exhibit.
1. Augmented Tealbook prediction intervals use 2- and 3-year-ahead forecast errors from Blue Chip, CBO, and CEA to extend the Tealbook prediction
intervals through 2021.

Page 81 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

EME Financial Turbulence [SIGMA]
A number of developments could trigger an increase in EME stresses over the forecast
period, including a larger-than-expected increase in global interest rates, an escalation of global
trade disputes, or a financial crisis in China. Although we expect that activity in China will
decelerate only modestly over the forecast period, China’s vulnerabilities have increased in
recent years amid high private-sector debt levels and a still heavily leveraged shadow banking
sector. Against this backdrop, adverse developments could put China’s prospects in doubt and
cause a deterioration of financial conditions, with knock-on effects to other EMEs. Such
developments would likely cause flight-to-safety flows into dollar-denominated assets and put
downward pressure on the renminbi and other EME currencies.
This scenario assumes that such a risk materializes. GDP in China and other EMEs falls
by 4 percent and 2 percent relative to baseline, respectively, by 2020, as EME corporate
borrowing spreads increase 150 basis points and confidence declines. The financial turbulence
in EMEs and worries about future growth in global demand trigger a moderate rise in borrowing
spreads in the United States and in the advanced foreign economies. Flight-to-safety flows cause
the dollar to appreciate 10 percent and depress term premiums on U.S. government bonds.
Despite weakening macroeconomic conditions, EME central banks are assumed to tighten
monetary policy to mitigate upward pressure on inflation arising from the depreciation of their
currencies.
The appreciation of the dollar, weaker foreign activity, and adverse financial spillovers
cause U.S. GDP growth to moderate to just under 2 percent in 2019 and the unemployment rate
to rise to 3¾ percent in 2020. Lower resource utilization and falling import prices reduce core
PCE inflation to about 1½ percent in 2019. The federal funds rate follows a shallower path than
in the baseline, rising to 3¾ percent by the end of 2020.

Inflation-Driven Global Tightening [SIGMA]
Oil prices rose to well over $80 per barrel early in the intermeeting period before
subsiding more recently, and geopolitical tensions could push prices up substantially. Amid
historically low unemployment rates in several major advanced economies, additional oil price
increases could not only directly raise production costs but also boost inflation expectations and

Page 82 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

set in motion a spiral of rising wages and prices.5 Concerns about rising inflation could then
prompt central banks to quickly increase policy rates and induce some tightening of global
financial conditions.
Specifically, this scenario assumes that oil prices rise to $120 per barrel. In the context of
very tight labor markets, and coming on the heels of previous large increases in oil prices, the
cost increases pass through to prices to a much larger extent than in recent decades. Headline
inflation in the advanced economies jumps to nearly 3½ percent in 2019 and core inflation
3 percent. Term premiums on government securities in the advanced economies rise 50 basis
points above baseline, while private-sector borrowing spreads increase almost 40 basis points.
Financial conditions in the EMEs are assumed to deteriorate a bit more than in the advanced
economies.
Higher inflation and tighter financial conditions depress U.S. domestic demand, while
lower foreign activity weighs on net exports. All told, U.S. GDP growth is, on average, a full
percentage point below baseline in 2019 and 2020, and the unemployment rate reaches 4 percent
in 2020. In response to the abrupt rise in inflation, the inertial Taylor rule prescribes that the
federal funds rate rises 50 basis points above baseline in 2019. After peaking at around
4¾ percent in 2020, the federal funds rate declines below baseline as inflationary pressures wane
and resource slack widens.

It is also plausible that the increased market power of firms could lead to larger and more persistent passthrough of higher oil prices into inflation. For evidence of increased market power in the advanced economies, see
Jan De Loecker and Jan Eeckhout (2018), “Global Market Power,” NBER Working Paper Series 24768 (Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research, June), https://www.nber.org/papers/w24768. For a discussion of
the implications for monetary policy, see Andrew G. Haldane (2018), “Market Power and Monetary Policy,” speech
delivered at “Changing Market Structure and Implications for Monetary Policy,” a symposium sponsored by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, held in Jackson Hole, Wyo., August 23–25,
https://www.kansascityfed.org/~/media/files/publicat/sympos/2018/papersandhandouts/market-power-andmonetary-policy-speech-by-andy-haldane.pdf.
5

Page 83 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Assessment of Key Macroeconomic Risks

Probability of Inflation Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the 4-quarter change in total
PCE prices will be . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Greater than 3 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.10
.10

.08
.07

.03
.02

.04
.03

Less than 1 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.13
.12

.17
.18

.10
.12

.23
.26

Probability of Unemployment Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the unemployment rate
will . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Increase by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.00
.00

.09
.11

.19
.18

.03
.03

Decrease by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.23
.26

.01
.01

.02
.03

.09
.08

Probability of Near-Term Recession
Probability that real GDP declines in
the next two quarters
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Factor
Model

.01
.01

.02
.02

.05
.04

.02
.02

.03
.00

Note: “Staff” represents stochastic simulations in FRB/US around the staff baseline; baselines for FRB/US, BVAR, EDO, and
the factor model are generated by those models themselves, up to the current-quarter estimate. Data for the current quarter are
taken from the staff estimate for the second Tealbook in each quarter; if the second Tealbook for the current quarter has not yet
been published, the preceding quarter is taken as the latest historical observation.

Page 84 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Appendix
Technical Note on “Prediction Intervals Derived from
Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors”
This technical note provides additional details about the exhibit “Prediction Intervals
Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors.” In the four large fan charts, the black dotted
lines show staff projections and current estimates of recent values of four key economic variables:
average unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of each year and the Q4/Q4 percent change for
real GDP, total PCE prices, and core PCE prices. (The GDP series is adjusted to use GNP for
those years when the staff forecast GNP and to strip out software and intellectual property
products from the currently published data for years preceding their introduction. Similarly, the
core PCE inflation series is adjusted to strip out the “food away from home” component for years
before it was included in core.)
The historical distributions of the corresponding series (with the adjustments described
above) are plotted immediately to the right of each of the fan charts. The thin black lines show
the highest and lowest values of the series during the indicated time period. At the bottom of the
page, the distributions over three different time periods are plotted for each series. To enable the
use of data for years prior to 1947, we report annual-average data in this section. The annual data
going back to 1930 for GDP growth, PCE inflation, and core PCE inflation are available in the
conventional national accounts; we used estimates from Lebergott (1957) for the unemployment
rate from 1930 to 1946.1
The prediction intervals around the current and one-year-ahead forecasts are derived from
historical staff forecast errors, comparing staff forecasts with the latest published data. For the
unemployment rate and real GDP growth, errors were calculated for a sample starting in 1980,
yielding percentiles of the sizes of the forecast errors. For PCE and core PCE inflation, errors
based on a sample beginning in 1998 were used. This shorter range reflects both more limited
data on staff forecasts of PCE inflation and the staff judgment that the distribution of inflation
since the mid-1990s is more appropriate for the projection period than distributions of inflation
reaching further back. In all cases, the prediction intervals are computed by adding the percentile
bands of the errors onto the forecast. The blue bands encompass 70 percent prediction-interval
ranges; adding the green bands expands this range to 90 percent. The dark blue line plots the
median of the prediction intervals. There is not enough historical forecast data to calculate
meaningful 90 percent ranges for the two inflation series. A median line above the staff forecast
means that forecast errors were positive more than half of the time.

Stanley Lebergott (1957), “Annual Estimates of Unemployment in the United States,
1900–1954,” in National Bureau of Economic Research, The Measurement and Behavior of Unemployment
(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press), pp. 213–41.
1

Page 85 of 124

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Because the staff has produced two-year-ahead forecasts for only a few years, the
intervals around the two-year-ahead forecasts are constructed by augmenting the staff projection
errors with information from outside forecasters: the Blue Chip consensus, the Council of
Economic Advisers, and the Congressional Budget Office. Specifically, we calculate prediction
intervals for outside forecasts in the same manner as for the staff forecasts. We then calculate the
change in the error bands from outside forecasts from one year ahead to two years ahead and
apply the average change to the staff’s one-year-ahead error bands. That is, we assume that any
deterioration in the performance between the one- and two-year-ahead projections of the outside
forecasters would also apply to the Tealbook projections. Limitations on the availability of data
mean that a slightly shorter sample is used for GDP and unemployment, and the outside
projections may only be for a similar series, such as total CPI instead of total PCE prices or
annual growth rates of GDP instead of four-quarter changes. In particular, because data on
forecasts for core inflation by these outside forecasters are much more limited, we did not
extrapolate the staff’s errors for core PCE inflation two years ahead.
The intervals around the historical data in the four fan charts are based on the history of
data revisions for each series. The previous-year, two-year-back, and three-year-back values as
of the current Tealbook forecast are subtracted from the corresponding currently published
estimates (adjusted as described earlier) to produce revisions, which are then combined into
distributions and revision intervals in the same way that the prediction intervals are created.

Page 86 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Monetary Policy Strategies
In this section, we discuss a range of strategies for setting the federal funds rate
and compare the associated interest rate paths and macroeconomic outcomes with those
in the Tealbook baseline projection. Compared with the September Tealbook, inflation is
projected to be a little higher in 2019, while the output gap is about ¼ percentage point
narrower throughout the medium term. Overall, in response to these revisions, most of
the strategies prescribe about the same path for the federal funds rate in the near term as
in the previous Tealbook and a slightly lower path thereafter. A special exhibit illustrates
how macroeconomic outcomes under flexible price-level targeting (FPLT) depend on the
way the public forms expectations.

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED SIMPLE POLICY RULES
The top panel of the first exhibit shows near-term prescriptions for the federal
funds rate from four simple policy rules: the Taylor (1999) rule (also known as the
“balanced approach” rule), the Taylor (1993) rule, a first-difference rule, and an FPLT
rule. These near-term prescriptions take as given the Tealbook baseline projections for
the output gap and core inflation, shown in the middle panels. 1 The top and middle
panels also provide the staff’s baseline path for the federal funds rate, which is
constructed using an inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule. 2
Relative to the September Tealbook, the staff projects resource utilization to be a
little less tight and inflation to be a little higher in the near term. Because the effects of
these changes to the forecast mostly offset each other, the prescriptions of all of the
policy rules are little changed from the previous Tealbook.
•

The prescriptions of the Taylor (1999) and Taylor (1993) rules, which do not
feature interest rate smoothing terms, remain well above the corresponding
policy rates in the Tealbook baseline. The near-term prescriptions of the first-

1

Because the FPLT rule responds to the gap between the unemployment rate and the natural rate
of unemployment, this rule takes as given the Tealbook baseline projections for these variables instead of
the output gap.
2
Except for the first-difference rule, which has no intercept term, the simple rules examined here
use intercept terms that are consistent with a real federal funds rate of 50 basis points in the longer run.

Page 87 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection
Near−Term Prescriptions of Selected Simple Policy Rules1

Monetary Policy Strategies

(Percent)

2018:Q4

2019:Q1

Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook

4.71
4.69

4.90
4.87

Taylor (1993) rule
Previous Tealbook

3.53
3.49

3.62
3.56

First−difference rule
Previous Tealbook projection

2.25
2.31

2.52
2.66

Flexible price−level targeting rule
Previous Tealbook projection

1.77
1.75

1.66
1.62

Addendum:
Tealbook baseline

2.29

2.66

*
Key Elements of the Staff Projection
Federal Funds Rate

PCE Prices ex. Food and Energy

GDP Gap
Percent

Percent
7

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

4

Percent

4−quarter change

3.0

6

5

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

4

3

2

1

0
2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024

0
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

1.0

2024

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

A Medium−Term Notion of the Equilibrium Real Federal Funds Rate2
(Percent)

Current
Value

Current−Quarter Estimate
Based on Previous Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Tealbook baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

3.29
1.85

3.47
1.94

3.29
1.70

SEP−consistent baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

1.92
1.00

*
1. For rules that have a lagged policy rate as a right−hand−side variable, the lines denoted "Previous Tealbook projection"
report prescriptions based on the previous Tealbook's staff outlook for inflation and the output gap, but conditional on the
current−Tealbook value of the lagged policy rate.
2. The "FRB/US r*" is the level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12−quarter period (beginning in the
current quarter) in the FRB/US model, sets the output gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period given either the
Tealbook or SEP−consistent projection. The SEP−consistent baseline corresponds to the September 2018 median SEP responses.
The "Average projected real federal funds rate" is calculated under the Tealbook and SEP−consistent baseline projections
over the same 12−quarter period as FRB/US r*.

Page 88 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

difference rule, which only responds incrementally to the change in economic
conditions, essentially coincide with those of the Tealbook baseline.
•

The FPLT rule, in an effort to eliminate the cumulative shortfall in the core
PCE price index of about 2¼ percent since the end of 2011, prescribes setting
the federal funds rate below the current target range.

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL
FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the first exhibit reports estimates of a medium-term concept
of the equilibrium real federal funds rate generated under two baselines: the Tealbook
baseline and a projection consistent with the medians in the September 2018 Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). 3 In both cases, simulations of the FRB/US model are used
to generate an estimate of r*. This concept of r*, labeled “FRB/US r*,” corresponds to
the level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period starting
in the current quarter, would bring the output gap to zero in the final quarter of that
period. This concept of r* is a summary of the projected underlying strength of the real
economy and does not take into account considerations such as achieving the inflation
objective or avoiding sharp changes in the federal funds rate.
•

At 3.29 percent, the current-quarter estimate of the Tealbook-consistent
FRB/US r* is 18 basis points lower than the value based on the September
Tealbook projection, reflecting the staff’s slightly lower output gap projection.

•

At 1.92 percent, the SEP-consistent FRB/US r* is significantly lower than the
Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*. The difference stems from the fact that the
SEP-consistent projection has output exceeding potential by a considerably
smaller amount over the medium term than does the current Tealbook
forecast. This smaller anticipated output gap occurs despite the fact that the
median path for the real federal funds rate implied by the SEP projections

3

To construct a baseline projection consistent with median SEP responses for the FRB/US model,
the staff interpolated annual SEP information to a quarterly frequency and assumed that, beyond 2021 (the
final year reported in the September 2018 SEP), the economy transitions to the longer-run values in a
smooth and monotonic way. The staff also posited economic relationships to project variables not covered
in the SEP. For example, the staff assumed an Okun’s law relationship to recover an output gap from the
deviation of the median SEP unemployment rate from the median SEP estimate of its longer-run value.

Page 89 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

averages almost 1 percentage point less than the corresponding path in the
Tealbook.

SIMPLE POLICY RULE SIMULATIONS
The second exhibit reports results from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model under the Taylor (1999) rule, the Taylor (1993) rule, the first-difference rule, and
the FPLT rule. These simulations reflect the endogenous responses of the output gap and
inflation to the different federal funds rate paths implied by the policy rules. 4 The
Monetary Policy Strategies

simulations for each rule are carried out under the assumptions that policymakers commit
to following that rule in the future and that financial market participants, price setters, and
wage setters correctly anticipate that monetary policy will follow through on this
commitment and are aware of the implications for interest rates and the economy.
•

Under the Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate steps up about
¼ percentage point over the rest of this year, increases 1½ percentage points
next year, and rises, on average, ½ percentage point per year in 2020 and
2021, reaching nearly 5 percent in the fourth quarter of 2021. This trajectory
is a little lower than the one in the September Tealbook because of the
narrower projected output gap.

•

The Taylor (1999) rule calls for an immediate and substantial increase in the
federal funds rate, and the prescribed values remain above the corresponding
Tealbook baseline values until early 2022. This higher path is associated with
only a modestly higher trajectory for the real 10-year Treasury yield than in
the baseline until mid-2020 and a slightly lower path thereafter, because the
Taylor (1999) rule calls for somewhat lower values of the federal funds rate
beyond the period shown. For the same reason, inflation is somewhat higher
than in the baseline projection. The path for the unemployment rate lies above
the Tealbook baseline path over the next few years, but it subsequently lies
below and takes a bit longer to return to its natural rate. 5

4

Because of the endogenous responses of the output gap and inflation to the different federal
funds rate paths, the near-term prescriptions from the dynamic simulations can differ from those shown in
the top panel of the first exhibit.
5
The result that inflation runs above the baseline projection in this and the Taylor (1993) rule
simulations, despite higher levels of the federal funds rate in the near term, depends on the assumption that

Page 90 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

The Taylor (1993) rule also calls for an immediate sharp increase in the
federal funds rate. Because the Taylor (1993) rule responds less strongly to
output exceeding its assumed potential level over the projection period, the
prescriptions of this rule are lower than those of the Taylor (1999) rule over
the period shown. The prescriptions from the Taylor (1993) rule are higher
than the Tealbook baseline over the next two years, but, starting at the end of
2020, the path for the federal funds rate falls below the baseline path for a
sustained period. As a result, inflation is higher, and the real 10-year Treasury
yield is lower, than their corresponding values in the Tealbook projection.
The more accommodative conditions also engender a lower unemployment
rate than in the Tealbook projection beyond the medium term.

•

The path for the federal funds rate prescribed by the first-difference rule lies
somewhat above the path in the Tealbook baseline through 2020 but then runs
below the baseline path for some years, during which the rule reacts to the
projected decline in the output gap. 6 The associated lower path for the federal
funds rate and the expectation of higher inflation in the future imply lower
longer-term real interest rates, higher inflation, and lower unemployment than
in the Tealbook baseline.

•

The FPLT rule responds to, and seeks to eliminate, the shortfall that has
cumulated since the end of 2011 between core PCE inflation and an annual
rate of 2 percent. This rule’s prescription generates a higher rate of inflation
in coming years that eventually undoes the current 2¼ percentage point
shortfall of the core PCE price index. The FPLT rule calls for keeping the
federal funds rate somewhat below the current target range until the first
quarter of 2020 and for keeping it below the federal funds rate path in the
Tealbook baseline through mid-2027. Because the simulation embeds the
assumptions that policymakers can credibly commit to closing this gap over
time and that financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters

price and wage setters perfectly anticipate the more accommodative path of the federal funds rate beyond
the next several years and factor these future monetary policy conditions into today’s price and wage
setting decisions. The box “Learning and Misperceptions of Policy Strategies” in the Monetary Policy
Strategies section of the June 2018 Tealbook A presented results under a scenario in which price and wage
setters lack such a perfect understanding. In that scenario, the switch from an inertial to a non-inertial
policy rule led to a significant decline in inflation and a rise in the unemployment rate at the start of the
simulation in response to an unexpected jump in the federal funds rate.
6
The first-difference rule responds to the expected change in the output gap rather than its level.

Page 91 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Simple Policy Rule Simulations
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
8

Tealbook baseline
Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
First−difference rule
Flexible price−level targeting rule

5.5

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
7
5.0

6
5

4.5
4

Monetary Policy Strategies

3
4.0
2
1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
4

2.5

3
2017

2
1

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

0

2.5

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
3.0
2.5
2.0
1.5

1.5
1.0
0.5
0.0
−0.5
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−1.0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation rather than to
headline inflation. This choice of rule specification was made in light of a tendency for current and near−term core
inflation rates to outperform headline inflation rates as predictors of the medium−term behavior of headline inflation.

Page 92 of 124

2024

1.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

correctly anticipate the ensuing long period of a low federal funds rate, the
path of the real 10-year Treasury rate drops below the Tealbook baseline for
the next six years. The unemployment rate is substantially lower than in the
Tealbook baseline and all other simulations shown, dropping below
2½ percent in 2020.

OPTIMAL CONTROL SIMULATIONS UNDER COMMITMENT
The third exhibit displays optimal control simulations under various assumptions
about policymakers’ preferences, as captured by three specifications of the loss function. 7
The concept of optimal control employed here corresponds to a commitment policy under
which the plans that policymakers make today constrain future policy choices; such a
constraint may improve economic outcomes. 8
The first two of the three optimal control policies prescribe much higher paths for
the federal funds rate than the path in the baseline projection, for two reasons. First, high
levels of the real federal funds rate are necessary to push the unemployment rate up to its
natural rate, because, consistent with recent historical experience, the unemployment rate
does not respond strongly to changes in real interest rates in the FRB/US model. Second,
because monetary policy actions are assumed to be understood and fully credible, the
front-loading of policy tightening is not disruptive. In practice, however, if the FOMC
were to raise the real federal funds rate as abruptly as in these simulations, wage and
price setters and financial market participants could misinterpret policymakers’ intentions
and may anticipate tighter monetary policy than policymakers envision, leading to less
benign macroeconomic outcomes than shown here. 9 By contrast, the third optimal
control policy allows the unemployment rate to decline to levels not experienced since
the 1950s. Such a development might likewise entail outcomes different from those
predicted by the simulations.

7

The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the Monetary Policy Strategies section of
the June 2016 Tealbook B offers motivations for these specifications. The appendix in this Tealbook
section provides technical details on the optimal control simulations. Previous Tealbooks also included a
simulation labeled “Large weight on inflation gap,” which has been dropped in this Tealbook.
8
Under the optimal control policies, policymakers achieve the displayed economic outcomes by
making promises that bind future policymakers to take actions that will not be optimal from the perspective
of those future policymakers (that is, the promises are time inconsistent). It is assumed that these promises
are taken as credible by wage and price setters and by financial market participants.
9
See note 5 for a related discussion in the context of simple policy rules.

Page 93 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
5.5

18

Tealbook baseline
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap

Staff's estimate of the natural rate

16
14

5.0

12
10

4.5

Monetary Policy Strategies

8
6

4.0

4
2
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
10

2.5

8
2017

6
4
2

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

2.5

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
4

3

2

1.5

1

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

1.0

Note: Each set of lines corresponds to an optimal control policy under commitment in which policymakers minimize a
discounted weighted sum of squared deviations of 4−quarter headline PCE inflation from the Committee's 2 percent objective,
of squared deviations of the unemployment rate from the staff's estimate of the natural rate, and of squared changes in the
federal funds rate. The weights vary across simulations. See the appendix for technical details and the box "Optimal Control
and the Loss Function" in the June 2016 Tealbook B for a motivation.
Page 94 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

The first simulation, labeled “Equal weights,” presents the case in which
policymakers are assumed to place equal weights on keeping headline PCE
inflation close to the Committee’s objective of 2 percent, on keeping the
unemployment rate close to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate of
unemployment, and on keeping the federal funds rate close to its previous
value. Under this strategy, the path for the federal funds rate is significantly
higher than the Tealbook baseline path. This strategy is designed to temper
the projected sizable undershooting, over the next several years, by the
unemployment rate of its natural rate that occurs in the Tealbook baseline—an
outcome that policymakers with the equal-weights loss function judge to be
costly. The smaller unemployment gap generates only moderately lower
inflation because, as already indicated, the response in the FRB/US model of
inflation to the current level of resource utilization is small.

•

The second simulation, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” uses a loss
function that assigns only a very small cost to changes in the federal funds rate
but that is otherwise identical to the loss function with equal weights. This
simulated policy seeks to return the unemployment rate to its natural rate even
faster than under the equal-weights specification. The federal funds rate soars
to 11 percent by mid-2019 and then averages around 7½ percent from 2020
through 2024.

•

The third simulation, “Asymmetric weight on ugap,” uses a loss function that
assigns no cost to deviations of the unemployment rate from the natural rate
when the unemployment rate is below the natural rate, but the loss function is
identical to the specification with equal weights when the unemployment rate
is above the natural rate. Under this strategy, the path for the federal funds
rate is considerably below the path in the optimal control simulation with
equal weights and below the Tealbook baseline path until 2024; it then
exceeds the policy rate paths implied by the other two optimal control
strategies and the Tealbook baseline starting in mid-2025. With the
asymmetric loss function, policymakers choose this more accommodative
path for the policy rate because their desire to keep inflation close to 2 percent
is not tempered by an aversion to undershooting the natural rate of
unemployment. The tighter labor market keeps inflation closer to 2 percent
than in the case of equal weights. Beyond the period shown, the

Page 95 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

unemployment rate runs a little above its natural rate for several years as
policymakers act to contain the inflationary pressures stemming from the
prolonged period of elevated resource utilization.

THE IMPLICATIONS OF EXPECTATIONS FOR FLEXIBLE PRICE-LEVEL
TARGETING: A RECESSION SCENARIO
In the September Tealbook, we illustrated that the effectiveness of an FPLT rule
in stabilizing the economy in a demand-driven recession varies depending on the initial
Monetary Policy Strategies

price-level gap specified in the rule. The exhibit “The Implications of Expectations for
Flexible Price-Level Targeting: A Recession Scenario” in this Tealbook clarifies that this
effectiveness also depends on the ability of price and wage setters to anticipate changes in
future policy.
In the FRB/US model and other models used for monetary policy analysis, current
inflation is influenced by monetary policy through two distinct channels. The first
channel operates through the current level of resource utilization, while the second
channel operates through expectations of future inflation. To illustrate the importance of
the second channel, we compare results from simulations of an FPLT rule under two
different assumptions about expectations formation. In the first simulation, price and
wage setters correctly anticipate the future course of monetary policy as well as the
evolution of the economy, whereas in the second simulation, they form expectations
using small-scale statistical models based on historical relationships. 10 By contrast, in
both simulations financial market participants correctly anticipate future monetary policy
and its economic implications. The FPLT rule sets the reference date for the target path
of the price level to 2011:Q4, resulting in an initial price-level gap in 2018:Q4 of
2¼ percent. 11 The implications of these expectations formation assumptions are
illustrated using the same recession scenario as in the Monetary Policy Strategies section
of the September Tealbook. 12

10

Expectations formed in this way are often described as “VAR-based expectations” and are
regularly used in the Risks and Uncertainty section of Tealbook A.
11
The coefficient on the unemployment gap of the FPLT rule in these simulations is chosen to
deliver the same marginal response to resource utilization as the inertial Taylor (1999) rule and is almost
double the size of the coefficient used in the FPLT rule shown in the exhibit “Simple Policy Rule
Simulations.” The appendix in this Tealbook section contains the precise form of the rule.
12
To construct the scenario, the current Tealbook baseline is subjected to a sequence of negative
spending shocks starting in 2018:Q4 that raise the unemployment rate by close to the median increase of
past recessions.

Page 96 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

In the recession scenario baseline, the unemployment rate rises to almost
6 percent by mid-2020. PCE inflation drops quickly below 2 percent and remains below
the Committee’s objective for an extended period. The federal funds rate is set according
to the inertial Taylor (1999) rule.
In the simulation “FPLT, model-consistent price and wage expectations,” the
policy rate path prescribed by the FPLT rule and its economic implications are correctly
anticipated by wage and price setters.
•

Given the large inherited price-level gap (shown in the bottom-right
panel), the FPLT rule prescribes a much lower path for the federal funds
rate than the inertial Taylor (1999) rule in the recession baseline.

•

The path of PCE inflation is markedly higher than in the recession
baseline, and the price-level gap narrows to negative 1¼ percent by the
end of 2024. The increase in inflation is achieved mainly through higher
expectations of future inflation, as price and wage setters anticipate that
the path of the federal funds rate will remain low in the future until the
price-level gap has been closed.

•

With a more accommodative policy stance than in the recession baseline,
real 10-year Treasury yields are lower and the peak unemployment rate is
reduced to 5½ percent. The unemployment rate then falls below its
natural rate for an extended period as the FPLT rule continues to prescribe
accommodative policy in order to offset past shortfalls in inflation.

The simulation “FPLT, VAR-based price and wage expectations” is generated
under the assumption that the expectations that underlie price- and wage-setting decisions
are formed using small-scale statistical models based on historical relationships, while
financial market participants, as before, correctly anticipate the future evolution of the
economy and monetary policy. 13 Expectations of this nature can be thought of as arising
from a situation in which price and wage setters do not understand policymakers’
intention to pursue a target path for the price level.
•

Under these assumptions, price and wage setters fail to anticipate the full
extent of policy accommodation prescribed by the FPLT rule in the future,

13

These statistical models are held fixed throughout the simulation and, in particular, do not
change in response to the adoption of the FPLT rule.

Page 97 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

The Implications of Expectations for Flexible Price−Level Targeting
A Recession Scenario
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
5

Recession scenario (inertial Taylor (1999) rule)
FPLT, model−consistent price and wage expectations
FPLT, VAR−based price and wage expectations

7
Staff's estimate of the natural rate

4

6

3
5

Monetary Policy Strategies

2
4
1
3

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

2

PCE Inflation

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent

4−quarter average

2

2.5

1
2.25
0
2.0
−1
1.75
−2

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−3

2017

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

1.5

Price−Level Gap
Percent

Percent
1

2.0

1.5

0

1.0
−1
0.5
−2
0.0
−3

−0.5

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

−1.0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

Note: The FPLT rule used herein responds to the unemployment gap with a coefficient of −1.85. We constructed the
recession scenario in the FRB/US model by subjecting the Tealbook baseline to a sequence of negative spending shocks
starting in the fourth quarter of 2018, the first quarter in the simulation.
Page 98 of 124

−4

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

and thus inflation expectations are lower than in the previous simulation.
As a result, PCE inflation stays below 2 percent until 2024, and the core
PCE price-level gap does not narrow until 2023.
•

Given the slower progress in closing the price-level gap, the FPLT rule
under VAR-based price and wage expectations prescribes an even lower
path for the nominal federal funds rate than in the previous simulation.
With financial market participants correctly anticipating this lower path,
real 10-year Treasury yields and the unemployment rate are considerably
lower than in the previous simulation.

•

The higher levels of resource utilization are insufficient to offset the
effects of the lower inflation expectations of wage and price setters
relative to the previous simulation, because the response of both current
and expected inflation to current resource utilization is small. Even with
an unemployment rate far below its natural rate through most of the
simulation period, inflation does not rise enough to fulfill the promise of
closing the price-level gap for more than a decade.

Overall, these simulations highlight that the effectiveness of flexible price-level
targeting depends crucially on expectations formation. When price and wage setters do
not understand the future effects of policy changes, announcing an FPLT strategy with a
relatively large price gap at the onset of a recession requires a prolonged period of policy
accommodation and very low levels of unemployment later on, with little gain in terms of
higher inflation. The simulations provide an example of a commitment-based policy that
is designed to achieve sizable stabilization benefits by steering expectations, yet may turn
out to be undesirable if expectations fail to respond as intended, because the policy then
induces substantial labor market overheating.
The final four exhibits tabulate the simulation results for key variables under the
policy rules and optimal control simulations described previously.

Page 99 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations

Monetary Policy Strategies

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.7
3.5
2.4
1.8
2.3

5.1
4.2
4.0
1.8
3.6

5.2
4.4
4.6
2.3
4.5

4.9
4.3
4.3
2.8
4.8

4.6
4.0
3.8
3.0
4.7

4.2
3.8
3.4
3.1
4.3

3.8
3.6
3.2
3.2
4.0

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0

1.9
2.4
2.6
3.5
2.4

2.0
2.2
2.2
2.7
1.9

1.6
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.4

1.4
1.3
1.4
1.0
1.2

1.3
1.2
1.2
.8
1.2

1.3
1.3
1.3
1.2
1.3

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6

3.5
3.3
3.2
2.8
3.3

3.5
3.2
3.1
2.5
3.3

3.5
3.1
3.1
2.4
3.4

3.6
3.4
3.3
2.8
3.7

3.8
3.6
3.5
3.3
4.0

4.0
3.8
3.7
3.6
4.2

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.2
2.2
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.2
2.2
1.9

2.0
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.0

2.1
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

2.1
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.3
2.3
2.0

2.1
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 100 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

2020

Outcome and strategy
Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

4.7
3.5
2.4
1.8
2.3

4.7
3.7
2.9
1.7
2.7

4.8
3.8
3.3
1.7
3.0

4.9
4.0
3.7
1.7
3.3

5.1
4.2
4.0
1.8
3.6

5.1
4.2
4.2
1.9
3.9

5.1
4.3
4.4
2.0
4.1

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9

3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0

2.9
3.0
3.1
3.3
3.1

2.3
2.6
2.7
3.2
2.6

2.1
2.5
2.6
3.3
2.5

1.9
2.4
2.6
3.5
2.4

2.0
2.4
2.5
3.3
2.2

2.0
2.3
2.4
3.1
2.1

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6

3.7
3.6
3.5
3.4
3.6

3.6
3.5
3.4
3.2
3.4

3.6
3.4
3.3
3.0
3.3

3.5
3.3
3.2
2.8
3.3

3.5
3.3
3.2
2.7
3.3

3.5
3.2
3.2
2.6
3.3

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
1.9

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Flexible price-level targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9
2.0
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.2
2.2
2.0

2.0
2.2
2.2
2.3
2.0

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 101 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment

Monetary Policy Strategies

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2024

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.9
8.1
2.0
2.3

5.9
9.8
2.4
3.6

7.4
8.0
2.9
4.5

7.7
7.9
3.3
4.8

7.1
7.4
3.6
4.7

6.0
6.6
3.9
4.3

4.7
4.9
4.0
4.0

Real GDP
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0

1.2
-.1
2.9
2.4

1.1
1.4
2.3
1.9

1.2
1.7
1.5
1.4

1.4
1.7
.9
1.2

1.7
1.8
.8
1.2

1.5
1.5
1.0
1.3

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6

3.8
4.6
3.1
3.3

4.2
4.6
2.8
3.3

4.4
4.6
2.9
3.4

4.5
4.5
3.3
3.7

4.6
4.5
3.8
4.0

4.6
4.5
4.1
4.2

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.1

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.1
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.1
2.0

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 102 of 124

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

October 26, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

2020

Outcome and strategy
Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

2.9
8.1
2.0
2.3

3.8
10.5
2.1
2.7

4.6
11.0
2.2
3.0

5.3
10.5
2.3
3.3

5.9
9.8
2.4
3.6

6.4
9.2
2.5
3.9

6.8
8.6
2.7
4.1

Real GDP
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.9
2.9
2.9
2.9

3.0
3.0
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.3
3.2
3.1

2.1
1.2
2.9
2.6

1.6
.4
2.9
2.5

1.2
-.1
2.9
2.4

1.1
.2
2.8
2.2

1.0
.6
2.6
2.1

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.6
3.6
3.6
3.6

3.7
4.0
3.5
3.6

3.7
4.3
3.3
3.4

3.7
4.4
3.2
3.3

3.8
4.6
3.1
3.3

3.9
4.6
3.0
3.3

4.0
4.6
2.9
3.3

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.2
2.2
2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.9
1.9
2.1
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.8
2.1
2.0

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 103 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Appendix

Monetary Policy Strategies

Implementation of the Simple Rules and Optimal Control Simulations
The monetary policy strategies considered in this section of Tealbook A typically fall into
one of two categories. Under simple policy rules, policymakers set the federal funds rate
according to a reaction function that includes a small number of macroeconomic factors. Under
optimal control policies, policymakers compute a path for the federal funds rate that minimizes a
loss function meant to capture policymakers’ preferences over macroeconomic outcomes. Both
approaches recognize the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate. Unless otherwise noted, the
simulations embed the assumption that policymakers will adhere to the policy strategy in the
future and that financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters not only believe that
policymakers will follow through with their strategy, but also fully understand the
macroeconomic implications of policymakers doing so. Such policy strategies are described as
commitment strategies.
The two approaches have different merits and limitations. The parsimony of simple rules
makes them relatively easy to communicate to the public, and, because they respond only to
variables that are central to a range of models, proponents argue that they may be more robust to
uncertainty about the structure of the economy. However, simple rules omit, by construction,
other potential influences on policy decisions; thus, strict adherence to such rules may, at times,
lead to unsatisfactory outcomes. By comparison, optimal control policies respond to a broader set
of economic factors; their prescriptions optimally balance various policy objectives. And,
although this section focuses on policies under commitment, optimal control policies can more
generally be derived under various assumptions about the degree to which policymakers can
commit. That said, optimal control policies assume substantial knowledge on the part of
policymakers and are sensitive to the assumed loss function and the specifics of the particular
model.
Given the different strengths and weaknesses of the two approaches, they are probably
best considered together as a means to assess the various tradeoffs policymakers may face when
pursuing their mandated objectives.

POLICY RULES USED IN THE MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES SECTION
The table “Simple Rules” that follows gives expressions for four simple policy rules
reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section. It also reports the expression for the inertial
version of the Taylor (1999) rule; the staff uses that inertial version, augmented with a small
temporary intercept adjustment, in the construction of the Tealbook baseline projection. 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡
denotes the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by a strategy for quarter t; for quarters prior to
the projection period under consideration, 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 corresponds to the historical data in the economic
projection. The right-hand-side variables of the first four rules include the staff’s projection of
trailing four-quarter core PCE price inflation for the current quarter and three quarters ahead (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡
and 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 ), the output gap estimate for the current period (𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 ), and the forecast of the threePage 104 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

quarter-ahead annual change in the output gap (𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 − 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡−1 ). The value of
policymakers’ longer-run inflation objective, denoted 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , is 2 percent. In the case of the flexible
price-level targeting rule, the right-hand-side variables include an unemployment rate gap and a
price gap. The unemployment gap is defined as the difference between the unemployment rate,
𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 , and the staff’s estimate of its natural rate, 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ . The price gap is defined as 100 times the
difference between the log of the core PCE price level, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , and the log of the target price-level
path, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ . The 2011:Q4 value of 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is set to the 2011:Q4 value of the core PCE price index, and,
subsequently, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is assumed to grow at a 2 percent annual rate.
Simple Rules

Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
First-difference rule
Flexible price-level
targeting rule

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 0.5𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 )
𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.5�𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 � + 0.5Δ4 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + (𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 − 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ ) − (𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 − 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ ))

The first two rules in the table were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999), whereas the inertial
version of the Taylor (1999) rule and rules that depend on a price gap like the FPLT rule have
been featured prominently in analysis by Board staff. 1 An FPLT rule similar to the one above is
also analyzed by Chung and others (2014).
Where applicable, the intercepts of the simple rules, denoted 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , are constant and chosen
so that they are consistent with a 2 percent longer-run inflation objective and an equilibrium real
federal funds rate in the longer run of 0.5 percent. The prescriptions of the first-difference rule do
not depend on the level of the output gap or the longer-run real interest rate; see
Orphanides (2003).

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED POLICY RULES
The “Near-Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules” reported in the first exhibit are
calculated taking as given the Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap. When the
Tealbook is published early in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the current and next
quarters. When the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the
next two quarters. Rules that include a lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable are
conditioned on the lagged federal funds rate in the Tealbook projection for the first quarter shown
and then conditioned on their simulated lagged federal funds rate for the second quarter shown.
To isolate the effects of changes in macroeconomic projections on the prescriptions of these
inertial rules, the lines labeled “Previous Tealbook projection” report prescriptions that are

1

For applications, see, for example, Erceg and others (2012).

Page 105 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

conditional on the previous Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap but that use the
value of the lagged federal funds rate in the current Tealbook for the first quarter shown.

Monetary Policy Strategies

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the exhibit “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection” provides
estimates of one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate that uses alternative baselines:
the Tealbook baseline and another one consistent with median responses to the latest Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). The simulations are conducted using the FRB/US model, the staff’s
large-scale econometric model of the U.S. economy. “FRB/US r*” is the real federal funds rate
that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period (beginning in the current quarter), makes the output
gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period, given either the Tealbook or the SEPconsistent economic projection. This measure depends on a broad array of economic factors,
some of which take the form of projected values of the model’s exogenous variables. 2 The
measure is derived under the assumption that agents in the model form VAR-based
expectations—that is, agents use small-scale statistical models so that their expectations of future
variables are determined solely by historical relationships.
The “Average projected real federal funds rate” for the Tealbook baseline and the SEPconsistent baseline reported in the panel are the corresponding averages of the real federal funds
rate under the Tealbook baseline projection and SEP-consistent projection, respectively,
calculated over the same 12-quarter period as the Tealbook-consistent and SEP-consistent
FRB/US r*. For a given economic projection, the average projected real federal funds rates and
the FRB/US r* may be associated with somewhat different macroeconomic outcomes even when
their values are identical. The reason is that, in the FRB/US r* simulation, the real federal funds
rate is held constant over the entire 12-quarter period, whereas, in the economic projection, the
real federal funds rate can vary over time.

FRB/US MODEL SIMULATIONS
The results presented in the exhibits “Simple Policy Rule Simulations” and “Optimal
Control Simulations under Commitment” are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model. Each simulated policy strategy is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered
by the simulation; this period extends several decades beyond the time horizon shown in the
exhibits. The simulations are conducted under the assumption that market participants as well as
price and wage setters form model-consistent expectations and are predicated on the staff’s
extended Tealbook projection, which includes the macroeconomic effects of the Committee’s
large-scale asset purchase programs. When the Tealbook is published early in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in that quarter; when the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in the subsequent quarter.

2

For a discussion of the equilibrium real federal funds rates in the longer run and other concepts
of equilibrium interest rates, see Gust and others (2016).

Page 106 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

COMPUTATION OF OPTIMAL CONTROL POLICIES UNDER COMMITMENT
The optimal control simulations posit that policymakers choose a path for the federal
funds rate to minimize a discounted weighted sum of squared inflation gaps (measured as the
difference between four-quarter headline PCE price inflation, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 , and the Committee’s
2 percent objective), squared unemployment gaps (𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , measured as the difference between
the unemployment rate and the staff’s estimate of the natural rate), and squared changes in the
federal funds rate. In the following equation, the resulting loss function embeds the assumption
that policymakers discount the future using a quarterly discount factor, 𝛽𝛽 = 0.9963:
𝑳𝑳𝒕𝒕 = �

𝑇𝑇

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃
𝜷𝜷𝝉𝝉 �𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋 (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏
− 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 (𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿 (𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉 − 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉−𝟏𝟏 )𝟐𝟐 �.

𝝉𝝉=𝟎𝟎

The exhibit “Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment” considers three
specifications of the weights on the inflation gap, the unemployment gap, and the rate change
components of the loss function. The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the
Monetary Policy Strategies section of the June 2016 Tealbook B provides motivations for the
three specifications of the loss function. The table “Loss Functions” shows the weights used in
the three specifications.
Loss Functions

Equal weights
Minimal weight on
rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight
on ugap

𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋
1

1

1

𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 < 0

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 ≥ 0

1

1

1

0

1

1

𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿
1

0.01
1

The first specification, “Equal weights,” assigns equal weights to all three components at
all times. The second specification, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” places almost no
weight on changes in the federal funds rate. 3 The third specification, “Asymmetric weight on
ugap,” uses the same weights as the equal-weights specification whenever the unemployment rate
is above the staff’s estimate of the natural rate, but it assigns no penalty to the unemployment rate
falling below the natural rate. The optimal control policy and associated outcomes depend on the
relative (rather than the absolute) values of the weights.
For each of these three specifications of the loss function, the optimal control policy is
subject to the effective lower bound constraint on nominal interest rates. Policy tools other than
the federal funds rate are taken as given and subsumed within the Tealbook baseline. The path
chosen by policymakers today is assumed to be credible, meaning that the public sees this path as
a binding commitment on policymakers’ future decisions; the optimal control policy takes as
3

The inclusion of a minimal but strictly positive weight on changes in the federal funds rate helps
ensure a well-behaved numerical solution.

Page 107 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

given the initial lagged value of the federal funds rate but is otherwise unconstrained by policy
decisions made prior to the simulation period.

THE IMPLICATIONS OF EXPECTATIONS FOR FLEXIBLE PRICE-LEVEL
TARGETING: A RECESSION SCENARIO
The FPLT rule used in the special exhibit is of the form

Monetary Policy Strategies

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + (𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 − 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ ) − 1.85(𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 − 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ )).

The 2011:Q4 value of 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is set to the 2011:Q4 value of the core PCE price index, and,
subsequently, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is assumed to grow at a 2 percent annual rate. We set the coefficient on the
unemployment gap to -1.85, which would imply a coefficient of 1 on the output gap under the
Okun’s law relationship assumed by the staff in constructing the Tealbook projection.

REFERENCES
Chung, Hess, Edward Herbst, and Michael T. Kiley (2014). “Effective Monetary Policy
Strategies in New Keynesian Models: A Reexamination,” NBER Macroeconomics
Annual, vol. 29 (1), pp. 289−344.
Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David López-Salido,
Stephen Meyer, Edward Nelson, David Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow (2012). “An
Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in Policymaking in Normal Times and
Under Current Conditions,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market Committee, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Divisions of International Finance,
Monetary Affairs, and Research and Statistics, July 18.
Gust, Christopher, Benjamin K. Johannsen, David López-Salido, and Robert Tetlow (2016).
“r*: Concepts, Measures, and Uses,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market
Committee, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary
Affairs, October 13.
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983−1022.
Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (December), pp. 195−214.
--------- (1999). “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed.,
Monetary Policy Rules. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 319−41.

Page 108 of 124

4.3
8.1
4.7
4.4
4.8
5.1
4.6
4.3
4.2
4.4
4.0
3.8

6.2
4.5
5.0
4.5
4.3
3.9

4.5
5.3
4.7
4.1
3.6

Quarterly
2018:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2019:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2020:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Two-quarter2
2018:Q2
Q4
2019:Q2
Q4
2020:Q2
Q4

Four-quarter3
2017:Q4
2018:Q4
2019:Q4
2020:Q4
2021:Q4

Page 109 of 124

4.5
5.2
4.6
4.1
3.5

5.9
4.5
4.8
4.3
4.2
4.0

4.3
7.6
4.3
4.6
4.7
4.9
4.4
4.2
4.1
4.3
4.1
3.8

10/25/18

2.5
3.1
2.5
1.9
1.5

3.4
2.8
2.7
2.4
2.1
1.8

2.2
4.7
3.0
2.5
2.7
2.6
2.4
2.3
2.1
2.0
1.8
1.7

09/14/18

2.5
3.0
2.4
1.9
1.4

3.2
2.8
2.5
2.2
2.0
1.8

2.2
4.2
2.9
2.6
2.6
2.4
2.3
2.2
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.8

10/25/18

Real GDP

1.8
2.0
1.9
2.0
2.0

2.2
1.8
2.0
1.9
2.0
2.0

2.5
1.9
1.5
2.1
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

09/14/18

1.8
2.0
2.0
1.9
1.9

2.2
1.7
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.9

2.5
2.0
1.5
1.9
2.1
2.0
1.9
1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.9

10/25/18

PCE price index

1.6
1.9
2.0
2.1
2.1

2.1
1.6
2.1
2.0
2.1
2.1

2.2
2.1
1.5
1.8
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

09/14/18

Greensheets

1.6
1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0

1.6
1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0

2.1
1.7
2.1
2.0
2.0
2.1

2.2
2.1
1.5
1.8
2.2
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

10/25/18

4.4
3.9
3.4
3.2
3.3

-.6
-.4
-.4
-.1
.2

-.2
-.2
-.3
-.1
-.1
.0

4.1
3.9
3.8
3.7
3.6
3.4
3.3
3.3
3.2
3.2
3.2
3.2

09/14/18

4.4
3.9
3.4
3.3
3.4

-.6
-.5
-.3
.0
.1

-.2
-.3
-.2
-.1
.0
.0

4.1
3.9
3.8
3.6
3.6
3.4
3.3
3.3
3.3
3.3
3.3
3.3

10/25/18

Core PCE price index Unemployment rate1

Authorized for Public Release

Annual
2017
4.2
4.2
2.2
2.2
1.8
1.8
1.6
2018
5.3
5.1
2.9
2.8
2.1
2.1
1.9
2019
4.9
4.8
2.8
2.6
1.9
1.9
1.9
2020
4.3
4.2
2.1
2.1
2.0
1.9
2.1
2021
3.7
3.7
1.6
1.6
2.0
1.9
2.1
1. Level, except for two-quarter and four-quarter intervals.
2. Percent change from two quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.
3. Percent change from four quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.

09/14/18

Interval

Nominal GDP

Changes in GDP, Prices, and Unemployment
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

Page 110 of 124

-37
-23

Change in priv. inventories2
Previous Tealbook2
56
37

2.1
1.1
2.3
3.0
1.3
1.9

-939
-887
-2.6
9.9

4.0
3.7
7.4
4.1
-6.5
2.5

-5.2
-2.1

3.2
2.9
4.5
4.8
2.6

1.1
1.8
3.0
2.8

2.9
3.0

Q3

20
14

1.8
1.5
2.7
3.0
2.3
1.2

1.8
1.6
2.6
3.4
1.5
1.3
33
21

-944
-920
2.7
1.9

4.8
5.2
5.3
5.7
3.1
3.5

-.3
5.1

2.7
2.8
3.2
3.3
2.5

2.8
2.9
2.9
3.3

2.6
2.7

Q1

-945
-907
3.4
3.1

7.6
7.9
8.3
8.8
5.4
5.2

-1.3
-.2

2.7
2.7
6.1
3.7
1.8

3.0
2.8
3.3
3.4

2.6
2.5

Q4

19
19

1.8
1.6
2.8
3.0
2.6
1.3

-952
-952
2.4
2.7

4.0
4.4
4.3
4.9
3.1
2.8

.7
5.8

2.4
2.8
1.9
2.5
2.5

2.5
2.5
2.6
3.2

2.4
2.6

Q2

2.4
2.3
2.6
2.6
1.9
1.4

1.0
.4

2.2
2.8
1.7
2.3
2.3

2.1
2.3
2.2
2.6

2.2
2.3

Q4

27
29

1.9
1.8
3.3
3.9
2.5
1.1

29
29

2.0
2.0
3.5
4.1
2.6
1.1

-967 -973
-984 -1001
2.6
2.1
3.6
2.2

3.0
3.4
3.2
3.7
2.4
2.2

.5
2.2

2.3
2.8
1.8
2.4
2.3

2.1
2.3
2.3
2.9

2.3
2.4

Q3

2019

1.5
1.7
2.0
2.1
-.2
.2

.2
.4

2.2
2.5
1.6
2.3
2.3

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.3

1.9
2.0

Q2

1.4
1.7
1.9
2.3
-.5
-.4

.3
.2

2.1
2.4
1.6
2.2
2.2

1.7
1.7
1.9
2.2

1.9
1.8

Q3

1.3
1.6
1.9
2.3
-.8
-.7

.5
.3

2.1
2.3
1.5
2.2
2.2

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1

1.8
1.7

Q4

30
31

1.7
1.6
3.0
3.3
2.6
1.0

32
31

2.0
2.3
3.8
4.4
3.0
1.0

41
39

1.9
1.8
3.4
3.3
3.6
1.0

33
29

1.1
1.1
1.2
1.0
1.6
1.0

-979 -990 -1007 -1004
-1019 -1042 -1075 -1083
2.6
2.9
3.0
3.2
2.5
3.3
4.1
1.9

1.7
1.9
2.1
2.2
.3
.8

.6
.7

2.2
2.7
1.7
2.3
2.2

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.4

2.0
2.1

Q1

2020

21
16

2.0
1.7
2.8
3.8
1.4
1.5

-907
-885
3.3
3.8

7.9
8.0
8.4
7.7
6.5
8.9

-2.8
-1.9

2.5
2.6
4.2
3.1
2.1

2.9
3.0
3.1
3.2

3.0
3.1

20181

24
23

1.9
1.8
3.1
3.5
2.5
1.2

-959
-964
2.5
2.6

3.6
3.8
3.9
4.2
2.6
2.5

.5
3.4

2.4
2.8
2.1
2.6
2.4

2.4
2.5
2.5
3.0

2.4
2.5

20191

34
32

1.7
1.7
2.9
3.0
2.7
1.0

-995
-1055
2.9
3.0

1.5
1.7
2.0
2.2
-.3
.0

.4
.4

2.2
2.5
1.6
2.3
2.2

1.9
1.9
2.0
2.3

1.9
1.9

20201

15
16

1.1
1.1
1.2
1.0
1.6
1.0

-1018
-1121
3.2
2.8

.8
.9
1.7
1.7
-2.1
-1.8

1.6
1.3

1.9
2.1
1.3
2.0
1.9

1.6
1.6
1.7
1.9

1.4
1.5

20211

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Billions of chained (2012) dollars; annual values show annual averages.

2.5
2.4
3.7
6.0
.5
1.8

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

8.7
8.9
7.1
7.3
14.5
14.4

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-841
-844
9.3
-.6

-1.3
-1.8

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports2
Previous Tealbook2
Exports
Imports

3.8
4.2
8.6
4.0
3.0

5.4
5.6
4.3
4.6

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

4.2
4.7

Q2

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

2018

Greensheets
Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

Page 111 of 124

71
71

Change in priv. inventories1
Previous Tealbook1

109
109

-2.4
-2.4
-6.1
-6.5
-5.5
.2

-533
-533
6.0
3.0

5.4
5.4
5.1
5.1
6.7
6.7

7.1
7.1

1.9
1.9
5.0
2.8
1.1

2.0
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.6
2.6

2013

87
87

.2
.2
-1.2
-3.6
2.7
1.1

-578
-578
3.0
6.7

6.4
6.4
5.6
5.6
8.8
8.8

7.8
7.8

3.8
3.8
9.2
3.0
3.2

3.0
3.0
4.3
4.3

2.7
2.7

2014

129
129

2.2
2.2
1.2
-.2
3.4
2.8

-725
-725
-1.6
3.4

-.7
-.7
2.6
2.6
-10.7
-10.7

8.9
8.9

3.0
3.0
6.0
3.0
2.6

1.9
1.9
2.7
2.7

2.0
2.0

2015

Greensheets

23
23

.9
.9
.2
-.7
1.5
1.4

-786
-786
.8
3.1

1.8
1.8
1.6
1.6
2.5
2.5

4.5
4.5

2.8
2.8
6.8
2.0
2.4

2.1
2.1
2.7
2.7

1.9
1.9

2016

23
23

.1
.1
1.3
1.3
1.3
-.5

-859
-859
4.7
5.4

6.3
6.3
7.3
7.3
2.9
2.9

3.8
3.8

2.7
2.7
7.7
3.0
1.8

2.6
2.6
3.3
3.3

2.5
2.5

2017

21
16

2.0
1.7
2.8
3.8
1.4
1.5

-907
-885
3.3
3.8

7.9
8.0
8.4
7.7
6.5
8.9

-2.8
-1.9

2.5
2.6
4.2
3.1
2.1

2.9
3.0
3.1
3.2

3.0
3.1

2018

24
23

1.9
1.8
3.1
3.5
2.5
1.2

-959
-964
2.5
2.6

3.6
3.8
3.9
4.2
2.6
2.5

.5
3.4

2.4
2.8
2.1
2.6
2.4

2.4
2.5
2.5
3.0

2.4
2.5

2019

34
32

1.7
1.7
2.9
3.0
2.7
1.0

-995
-1055
2.9
3.0

1.5
1.7
2.0
2.2
-.3
.0

.4
.4

2.2
2.5
1.6
2.3
2.2

1.9
1.9
2.0
2.3

1.9
1.9

2020

15
16

1.1
1.1
1.2
1.0
1.6
1.0

-1018
-1121
3.2
2.8

.8
.9
1.7
1.7
-2.1
-1.8

1.6
1.3

1.9
2.1
1.3
2.0
1.9

1.6
1.6
1.7
1.9

1.4
1.5

2021

Authorized for Public Release

1. Billions of chained (2012) dollars; annual values show annual averages.

-2.1
-2.1
-2.6
-4.7
1.2
-1.7

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

5.6
5.6
6.1
6.1
4.0
4.0

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-569
-569
2.1
.6

15.4
15.4

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports1
Previous Tealbook1
Exports
Imports

1.6
1.6
6.3
.7
1.2

1.9
1.9
2.6
2.6

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

1.5
1.5

2012

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

Page 112 of 124

.4
.4
.2
.2
.0
.2
-1.2
-.9

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

Change in priv. inventories
Previous Tealbook

1.8
1.2

.4
.2
.2
.1
.0
.2

-1.8
-.8
-.3
-1.5

.5
.5
.8
.4
-.2
.1

-.2
-.1

2.2
2.0
.3
.7
1.2

1.1
1.9
2.5
2.4

2.9
3.0

Q3

-.4
-.3

.3
.3
.2
.1
.0
.1

-.1
-.3
.4
-.5

1.0
1.1
.9
.9
.2
.2

.0
.0

1.8
1.8
.4
.5
.9

3.0
2.8
2.8
2.9

2.6
2.5

Q4

-.3
-.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

.0
-.2
.3
-.3

.7
.7
.6
.6
.1
.1

.0
.2

1.8
1.9
.2
.5
1.2

2.8
2.9
2.5
2.8

2.6
2.7

Q1

.0
.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.1
-.5
.3
-.4

.6
.6
.5
.5
.1
.1

.0
.2

1.7
1.9
.1
.4
1.2

2.5
2.5
2.2
2.7

2.4
2.6

Q2

.2
.2

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.2
-.5
.3
-.5

.4
.5
.3
.4
.1
.1

.0
.1

1.6
1.9
.1
.3
1.1

2.1
2.3
2.0
2.5

2.3
2.4

Q3

2019

.0
.0

.3
.3
.2
.2
.1
.1

-.1
-.3
.3
-.3

.3
.3
.3
.3
.1
.0

.0
.0

1.5
1.9
.1
.3
1.1

2.1
2.3
1.9
2.2

2.2
2.3

Q4

.0
.0

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.1
-.3
.3
-.4

.2
.3
.2
.2
.0
.0

.0
.0

1.5
1.8
.1
.3
1.1

2.0
2.1
1.8
2.1

2.0
2.1

Q1

.0
.0

.4
.4
.2
.2
.1
.1

-.2
-.4
.3
-.5

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.0
.0

1.5
1.7
.1
.3
1.1

1.9
2.0
1.7
2.0

1.9
2.0

Q2

.2
.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.3
-.5
.4
-.6

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.0
.0

1.5
1.6
.1
.3
1.0

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.9

1.9
1.8

Q3

2020

-.1
-.2

.2
.2
.1
.0
.0
.1

.1
-.1
.4
-.3

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.0
.0

1.4
1.6
.1
.3
1.0

1.9
1.9
1.6
1.8

1.8
1.7

Q4

.1
.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.0
.2

-.2
.0
.4
-.6

1.1
1.1
.9
.8
.2
.3

-.1
-.1

1.7
1.8
.3
.4
1.0

2.9
3.0
2.7
2.7

3.0
3.1

20181

.0
.0

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.1
-.4
.3
-.4

.5
.5
.4
.4
.1
.1

.0
.1

1.6
1.9
.2
.4
1.1

2.4
2.5
2.2
2.6

2.4
2.5

20191

.0
.0

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.1
-.3
.4
-.4

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.0
.0

1.5
1.7
.1
.3
1.0

1.9
1.9
1.7
1.9

1.9
1.9

20201

-.2
-.1

.2
.2
.1
.0
.0
.1

.0
-.2
.4
-.4

.1
.1
.2
.2
-.1
-.1

.1
.0

1.3
1.4
.1
.3
.9

1.6
1.6
1.4
1.6

1.4
1.5

20211

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.

1.2
1.2
1.1
.1

1.2
1.2
.7
.8
.4
.4

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook

Net exports
Previous Tealbook
Exports
Imports

-.1
-.1

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.9
.6
.6
1.4

5.3
5.6
3.7
4.0

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

4.2
4.7

Q2

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

2018

Contributions to Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product
(Percentage points, annual rate except as noted)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

Page 113 of 124

1.7
1.7
1.8
1.8
2.4
2.4
3.4
4.2
2.3
2.3
-1.1
-1.8

CPI

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

ECI, hourly compensation2
Previous Tealbook2

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook
-2.2
-2.2

1.4
1.5
3.4
2.9
2.0
1.4

2.3
2.3

2.0
2.2
2.0
2.1

1.5
1.5
3.5
5.0
.4
.6
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.9
1.6

Q3

-1.1
-.9

1.1
.8
3.2
3.2
2.1
2.3

2.3
2.3

2.2
2.6
2.0
2.1

1.9
2.1
5.3
7.9
1.3
1.9
1.8
1.8
1.6
1.7

2.0
1.8

Q4

.1
.2

.7
1.3
3.9
3.9
3.1
2.6

2.8
2.8

2.4
2.1
2.6
2.2

2.1
2.0
-.4
1.0
2.1
2.0
2.2
2.1
2.1
1.9

2.1
2.0

Q1

.6
.6

1.2
1.2
3.9
4.0
2.7
2.8

2.8
2.8

2.3
2.2
2.4
2.4

2.0
1.9
.4
-.8
2.2
2.2
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.8

2.4
2.4

Q2

.9
.8

1.1
1.0
4.1
4.1
2.9
3.1

2.9
2.9

2.2
2.2
2.4
2.4

1.9
1.9
-.8
-1.2
3.0
3.0
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.8

2.0
2.0

Q4

Greensheets

1.0
.8

1.0
1.1
4.0
4.1
3.0
2.9

2.8
2.8

2.2
2.2
2.4
2.4

1.9
1.9
-.2
-.9
2.6
2.6
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.8

2.1
2.1

Q3

2019

.9
.9

1.1
1.1
4.0
4.1
2.8
3.0

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

2.0
2.0
-1.0
-1.2
2.8
2.8
2.0
2.1
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.1

Q1

.8
.7

1.2
1.2
4.0
4.2
2.7
3.0

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

1.9
2.0
-1.1
-1.2
2.6
2.6
2.0
2.1
1.9
2.0

2.3
2.4

Q2

.8
.7

1.3
1.2
4.0
4.2
2.7
2.9

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.5

1.9
2.0
-1.2
-1.3
2.5
2.5
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

Q3

2020

.7
.7

1.2
1.2
4.0
4.1
2.7
2.9

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.5

1.9
2.0
-1.1
-1.2
2.4
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

Q4

.0
.0

1.6
1.8
3.3
3.2
1.7
1.4

2.8
2.8

2.3
2.5
2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0
5.4
6.5
.8
1.0
1.9
1.9
1.7
1.8

2.2
2.1

20181

.6
.6

1.0
1.1
4.0
4.0
2.9
2.8

2.8
2.8

2.3
2.2
2.5
2.3

2.0
1.9
-.2
-.5
2.5
2.4
2.0
2.0
1.9
1.8

2.1
2.1

20191

.8
.8

1.2
1.2
4.0
4.2
2.7
3.0

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

1.9
2.0
-1.1
-1.2
2.6
2.6
2.0
2.1
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.2

20201

.7
.7

1.1
1.1
3.9
4.0
2.7
2.8

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

1.9
2.0
-1.0
-.8
2.3
2.3
2.0
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

20211

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Private-industry workers.
3. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

.6
.5

2.0
1.9
.7
.6
1.2
1.2
2.1
2.1
2.2
2.2

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index3
Previous Tealbook3

3.0
3.0

Q2

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

2018

Changes in Prices and Costs
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

1.8
1.8
2.1
2.1
1.3
1.3
1.8
1.8
1.5
1.5
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.8
1.8
.2
.2
5.9
5.9
5.7
5.7
-.4
-.4

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

CPI

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

ECI, hourly compensation1
Previous Tealbook1

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook

Page 114 of 124

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index2
Previous Tealbook2
-2.2
-2.2

1.8
1.8
-.3
-.3
-2.0
-2.0

2.0
2.0

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-2.9
-2.9
.7
.7
1.6
1.6
1.1
1.1

1.8
1.8

2013

-.4
-.4

.1
.1
2.8
2.8
2.7
2.7

2.3
2.3

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-6.9
-6.9
2.8
2.8
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.6
1.6

2014

-4.4
-4.4

.7
.7
2.5
2.5
1.8
1.8

1.9
1.9

.4
.4
2.0
2.0

.3
.3
-16.4
-16.4
.3
.3
1.2
1.2
1.1
1.1

.9
.9

2015

-.7
-.7

1.1
1.1
2.1
2.1
1.0
1.0

2.2
2.2

1.8
1.8
2.2
2.2

1.6
1.6
2.1
2.1
-1.8
-1.8
1.8
1.8
1.5
1.5

1.5
1.5

2016

1.1
1.1

.8
.8
3.0
3.0
2.3
2.3

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.7
1.7

1.8
1.8
8.1
8.1
.7
.7
1.6
1.6
1.2
1.2

2.0
2.0

2017

.0
.0

1.6
1.8
3.3
3.2
1.7
1.4

2.8
2.8

2.3
2.5
2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0
5.4
6.5
.8
1.0
1.9
1.9
1.7
1.8

2.2
2.1

2018

.6
.6

1.0
1.1
4.0
4.0
2.9
2.8

2.8
2.8

2.3
2.2
2.5
2.3

2.0
1.9
-.2
-.5
2.5
2.4
2.0
2.0
1.9
1.8

2.1
2.1

2019

.8
.8

1.2
1.2
4.0
4.2
2.7
3.0

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

1.9
2.0
-1.1
-1.2
2.6
2.6
2.0
2.1
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.2

2020

.7
.7

1.1
1.1
3.9
4.0
2.7
2.8

2.9
3.0

2.3
2.3
2.5
2.6

1.9
2.0
-1.0
-.8
2.3
2.3
2.0
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

2021

Authorized for Public Release

1. Private-industry workers.
2. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

2.1
2.1

2012

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

Greensheets
Changes in Prices and Costs
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

1.3
17.2
7.6
2.5
2.4
6.8
6.7
12.5
10.8
18.7
3.5

Housing starts6
Light motor vehicle sales6

Income and saving
Nominal GDP5
Real disposable pers. income5
Previous Tealbook5
Personal saving rate3
Previous Tealbook3

Page 115 of 124

Corporate profits7
Profit share of GNP3

Gross national saving rate3
Net national saving rate3
19.0
4.1

8.9
11.0

4.3
2.3
2.3
6.6
6.6

1.2
16.9

3.3
3.0
2.8
2.8
75.8
75.8

2.2
2.2

60.4
59.7

190
3.8
3.8
4.6
4.6

Q3

19.0
4.0

3.8
11.0

4.6
2.3
2.6
6.5
6.5

1.2
17.1

2.0
1.9
1.9
2.5
75.9
76.0

2.4
2.4

60.5
59.7

201
3.6
3.7
4.6
4.6

Q4

18.7
3.5

1.3
10.9

4.7
2.7
3.4
6.5
6.7

1.2
17.0

1.5
2.4
.8
2.0
75.8
76.1

2.6
2.7

60.6
59.6

187
3.6
3.6
4.6
4.6

Q1

18.7
3.5

2.4
10.9

4.9
2.4
2.5
6.5
6.6

1.2
17.0

2.2
2.7
1.8
2.7
76.0
76.4

2.7
2.9

60.7
59.6

171
3.4
3.4
4.6
4.6

Q2

2019

18.7
3.4

-.6
10.7

4.4
2.3
2.3
6.5
6.5

1.2
17.0

2.0
2.5
1.9
3.0
76.1
76.8

2.9
3.0

60.7
59.6

163
3.3
3.3
4.6
4.6

Q3

18.7
3.3

-1.9
10.6

4.2
2.4
2.4
6.5
6.4

1.2
17.0

1.8
2.3
1.3
2.4
76.2
77.0

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.5

149
3.3
3.3
4.6
4.6

Q4

18.5
3.1

-1.6
10.4

4.1
3.7
3.7
6.9
6.6

1.2
16.9

1.7
2.0
1.1
1.7
76.3
77.2

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.5

136
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

Q1

18.6
3.0

1.7
10.4

4.3
2.3
2.3
6.9
6.6

1.2
16.8

1.1
1.4
1.1
1.5
76.4
77.3

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.4

123
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

Q2

2020

18.5
2.9

1.1
10.3

4.1
1.6
1.6
6.7
6.4

1.2
16.8

1.1
1.3
1.2
1.4
76.5
77.4

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.4

114
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

Q3

18.5
2.8

-.1
10.2

3.8
2.1
2.2
6.8
6.4

1.2
16.7

.9
1.0
.8
1.0
76.5
77.5

2.9
3.2

60.7
59.4

110
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

Q4

Greensheets

19.0
4.0

7.5
11.0

5.2
2.9
2.9
6.5
6.5

1.3
17.1

3.3
3.1
2.2
2.4
75.9
76.0

2.4
2.4

60.5
59.7

206
3.6
3.7
4.6
4.6

20181

18.7
3.3

.3
10.6

4.6
2.4
2.7
6.5
6.4

1.2
17.0

1.9
2.5
1.5
2.5
76.2
77.0

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.5

167
3.3
3.3
4.6
4.6

20191

18.5
2.8

.3
10.2

4.1
2.4
2.4
6.8
6.4

1.2
16.8

1.2
1.4
1.1
1.4
76.5
77.5

2.9
3.2

60.7
59.4

121
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

20201

18.3
2.5

.1
9.9

3.5
1.9
1.8
6.7
6.1

1.3
16.6

.5
.7
.4
.7
76.5
77.5

2.4
2.7

60.4
59.2

82
3.4
3.4
4.6
4.6

20211

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise indicated.
2. Average monthly change, thousands.
3. Percent; annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
5. Percent change, annual rate.
6. Level, millions; annual values are annual averages.
7. Percent change, annual rate, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

5.3
5.1
2.3
2.3
75.5
75.5

Industrial production5
Previous Tealbook5
Manufacturing industr. prod.5
Previous Tealbook5
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.3
Previous Tealbook3

60.4
59.8

Employment-to-Population Ratio3
Employment-to-Population Trend3
1.8
1.8

217
3.9
3.9
4.6
4.6

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment2
Unemployment rate3
Previous Tealbook3
Natural rate of unemployment3
Previous Tealbook3

Output gap4
Previous Tealbook4

Q2

Item

2018

Other Macroeconomic Indicators

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

58.7
60.3
-3.7
-3.7
2.2
2.2
1.4
1.4
74.7
74.7
.8
14.4
3.6
4.9
4.9
10.2
10.2
.7
11.9
18.8
3.7

Employment-to-Population Ratio2
Employment-to-Population Trend2

Output gap3
Previous Tealbook3

Industrial production
Previous Tealbook
Manufacturing industr. prod.
Previous Tealbook
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.2
Previous Tealbook2

Housing starts4
Light motor vehicle sales4

Income and saving
Nominal GDP
Real disposable pers. income
Previous Tealbook
Personal saving rate2
Previous Tealbook2

Page 116 of 124

Corporate profits5
Profit share of GNP2

Gross national saving rate2
Net national saving rate2
19.2
4.0

3.9
11.8

4.4
-2.5
-2.5
6.3
6.3

.9
15.5

2.3
2.3
1.1
1.1
75.1
75.1

-2.8
-2.8

58.5
60.2

192
7.0
7.0
5.4
5.4

2013

20.2
5.1

5.9
12.0

4.4
5.2
5.2
7.4
7.4

1.0
16.5

3.4
3.4
1.4
1.4
76.3
76.3

-.8
-.8

59.3
60.1

250
5.7
5.7
5.1
5.1

2014

19.4
4.3

-10.7
10.4

2.9
3.1
3.1
7.4
7.4

1.1
17.4

-3.3
-3.3
-1.6
-1.6
75.4
75.4

-.2
-.2

59.4
60.0

226
5.0
5.0
4.9
4.9

2015

18.3
3.0

7.6
10.8

3.4
1.6
1.6
6.4
6.4

1.2
17.5

-.5
-.5
-.1
-.1
74.4
74.4

.4
.4

59.8
59.9

195
4.7
4.7
4.8
4.8

2016

18.3
3.1

3.3
10.7

4.5
2.8
2.8
6.3
6.3

1.2
17.1

3.0
3.0
1.9
1.9
75.2
75.2

1.2
1.2

60.1
59.8

182
4.1
4.1
4.6
4.6

2017

19.0
4.0

7.5
11.0

5.2
2.9
2.9
6.5
6.5

1.3
17.1

3.3
3.1
2.2
2.4
75.9
76.0

2.4
2.4

60.5
59.7

206
3.6
3.7
4.6
4.6

2018

18.7
3.3

.3
10.6

4.6
2.4
2.7
6.5
6.4

1.2
17.0

1.9
2.5
1.5
2.5
76.2
77.0

3.0
3.2

60.7
59.5

167
3.3
3.3
4.6
4.6

2019

18.5
2.8

.3
10.2

4.1
2.4
2.4
6.8
6.4

1.2
16.8

1.2
1.4
1.1
1.4
76.5
77.5

2.9
3.2

60.7
59.4

121
3.3
3.2
4.6
4.6

2020

18.3
2.5

.1
9.9

3.5
1.9
1.8
6.7
6.1

1.3
16.6

.5
.7
.4
.7
76.5
77.5

2.4
2.7

60.4
59.2

82
3.4
3.4
4.6
4.6

2021

Authorized for Public Release

1. Average monthly change, thousands.
2. Percent; values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential output; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Level, millions; values are annual averages.
5. Percent change, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

179
7.8
7.8
5.6
5.6

2012

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment1
Unemployment rate2
Previous Tealbook2
Natural rate of unemployment2
Previous Tealbook2

Item

Greensheets
Other Macroeconomic Indicators
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

.9
.9
.7
1.8
1.6
.3
-.1
3
14
.4
.3
.3
.0
.1
.1
-.1
.2

Government in the NIPA2
Purchases
Consumption
Investment
State and local construction
Real disposable personal income
Contribution from transfers3
Contribution from taxes3

Government employment
Federal
State and local

Page 117 of 124

Fiscal indicators2
Fiscal effect (FE)4
Discretionary policy actions (FI)
Previous Tealbook
Federal purchases
State and local purchases
Taxes and transfers
Cyclical
Other
.1
.2
.2
.1
-.1
.1
-.1
.1

-1
3

.1
-.1
1.4
-2.9
2.8
.2
-.6

-3.5
-3.5
-2.1
1.4
-3.7
76.1

3,316
3,982
-665

2017

2021

3,716
5,037
-1,320
-5.7
-5.5
-3.3
2.4
-7.1
83.3

1.7
1.2
3.4
1.0
2.4
.6
-.6

1.1
.8
2.1
1.0
1.9
.6
-.7

Q2

2.5
1.9
5.3
6.3
2.4
.4
-.2

-.1
-.1
1.8
2.0
-.9
77.4

1,044
1,051
-7

Real percent change, annual rate

-5.3
-5.0
-3.0
2.3
-6.6
80.3

Percent of GDP

3,586
4,752
-1,166

Nominal dollars, billions

2020

2
9

1
9

1
9

1
7

Average net change in monthly payrolls, thousands

1.9
1.3
4.3
2.5
2.4
.8
-.7

-4.5
-4.4
-2.7
1.8
-5.7
78.0

3,443
4,407
-964

2019

-0
19

2.1
1.3
5.3
5.0
2.3
.3
-.8

-3.4
-3.3
-2.2
1.2
-4.3
77.9

788
960
-172

Q3

.5
.7
.6
.2
.2
.4
-.2
.0

.7
.6
.6
.2
.1
.3
-.2
.3

.6
.5
.5
.2
.1
.2
-.1
.2

.4
.2
.2
.1
.1
.0
.0
.2

.6
.8
.8
.2
.2
.4
-.2
.0

.6
.7
.5
.1
.2
.4
-.2
.1

Percentage point contribution to change in real GDP, annual rate

0
8

2.0
1.5
4.1
4.3
2.9
.5
-.2

-3.9
-3.8
-2.2
1.6
-4.5
77.9

3,329
4,108
-779

2018

2018

.6
.7
.6
.2
.1
.4
-.2
.1

2
7

1.8
1.1
4.5
3.0
2.3
.4
-.7

-6.5
-6.5
-4.4
2.1
-7.5
78.6

782
1,117
-335

Q4

.8
.7
.6
.2
.1
.4
-.2
.3

3
9

1.8
1.1
4.3
3.0
2.7
1.7
-.3

-7.8
-7.6
-5.9
1.9
-8.9
78.5

715
1,119
-404

Q1

2019

Greensheets

Authorized for Public Release

1. Annual values stated on a fiscal year basis. Quarterly values not seasonally adjusted.
2. Annual values refer to the change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
3. Percentage point contribution to change in real disposable personal income, annual basis.
4. The FE measure captures the total contribution of the government sector to the growth of aggregate demand (excluding any multiplier effects and financial
offsets). It equals the sum of the direct contributions to aggregate demand growth from all changes in federal purchases and state and local purchases, plus
the estimated contribution to real household consumption and business investment that is induced by changes in transfer and tax policies. FI (fiscal impetus)
is the portion of FE attributable to discretionary fiscal policy actions (for example, a legislated change in tax revenues).

-3.2
-3.2
-1.9
1.3
-3.1
76.4

3,268
3,853
-585

2016

Surplus/deficit
Previous Tealbook
Primary surplus/deficit
Net interest
Cyclically adjusted surplus/deficit
Federal debt held by public

Unified federal budget1
Receipts
Outlays
Surplus/deficit

Item

Staff Projections of Government-Sector Accounts and Related Items
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

2.6
2.7
2.6
3.6
2.5
2.4
2.0
1.2
2.7
1.8
1.6
1.5
4.8
4.1
3.1

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil
1.7
1.7
1.0
1.1
-2.3
2.0
2.2
2.5
2.2
1.0
1.8
.7
4.9
3.8
4.3

2.0
2.0
2.5
2.9
3.0
1.6
1.8
1.8
1.5
4.1
2.4
6.5
-1.0
-.6
.7

3.7
3.5
2.5
2.6
2.7
2.9
2.5
2.5
4.6
3.1
2.4
4.1
8.0
6.8
6.6

2.5
2.5
1.9
2.2
.7
2.5
1.6
1.8
3.1
4.4
2.3
5.9
1.8
2.1
4.0

2.9
2.7
2.1
2.4
1.2
2.4
2.3
2.8
3.5
2.7
2.6
2.9
5.4
3.9
4.0

2.6
2.6
1.9
2.5
.5
1.6
1.5
1.7
3.4
4.8
3.3
6.3
2.1
2.6
2.3

2.6
2.6
1.8
2.3
1.2
2.4
1.6
2.5
3.2
2.5
2.2
2.4
4.8
3.7
4.3

2.6
2.7
1.7
2.2
.5
1.6
1.3
1.5
3.6
4.7
3.1
6.2
2.6
2.7
2.5

2.5
2.6
1.6
2.2
.9
2.2
1.4
2.1
3.2
2.6
2.1
2.5
4.4
3.5
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
2.1
.7
1.6
1.4
1.5
3.6
4.6
3.1
6.1
2.8
2.7
2.5

2.5
2.5
1.7
2.2
1.0
2.2
1.4
2.2
3.1
2.6
2.1
2.5
4.2
3.3
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.0
2.1
3.1
1.6
1.3
1.5
3.7
4.7
3.1
6.1
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.6
2.2
6.3
2.2
1.5
2.3
3.1
2.6
2.1
2.5
4.1
3.3
4.3

2.5
2.5
1.3
2.1
-3.8
1.6
1.6
1.6
3.7
4.6
3.1
6.0
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.4
1.6
2.1
1.0
2.2
1.5
2.3
3.0
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.7
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
2.0
.9
1.7
1.6
1.5
3.7
4.6
3.0
6.0
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.4
1.7
2.1
1.0
2.2
1.5
2.3
2.9
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.6
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.8
.8
1.7
1.7
1.5
3.7
4.6
3.0
6.0
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.4
1.7
2.1
1.0
2.2
1.5
2.2
2.9
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.5
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.8
.8
1.7
1.6
1.4
3.7
4.5
3.0
5.9
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.4
1.7
2.0
1.0
2.1
1.6
2.2
2.9
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.5
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.8
.8
1.7
1.6
1.4
3.7
4.5
3.0
5.9
2.9
2.9
2.8

Authorized for Public Release

Page 118 of 124

1. Foreign GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
2. Foreign CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

3.0
3.1
1.3
1.4
-.9
.4
1.6
1.5
4.7
6.2
4.1
7.2
3.3
4.0
.6

Q1

Real
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

GDP 1

Measure and country

------------------------------------------------Projected-----------------------------------------------2018
2019
2020
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Quarterly percent changes at an annual rate)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

2.2
2.2
.3
.7
.3
1.6
-1.1
.2
4.1
5.8
2.1
8.0
2.9
3.0
2.2
2.3
2.3
1.3
1.0
-.2
2.6
2.3
1.9
3.1
2.6
1.7
2.1
4.4
4.1
5.6

Real GDP 1
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil
2.4
2.4
1.0
1.0
1.4
2.1
.8
1.4
3.4
3.1
1.1
2.9
4.2
3.6
5.8

3.0
3.0
2.5
3.6
2.8
2.6
.7
1.6
3.5
5.4
3.5
7.6
1.7
1.2
2.6

2013

2.0
2.0
1.2
2.0
2.6
.9
.1
.4
2.7
1.8
1.0
1.5
4.9
4.2
6.5

2.8
2.8
2.0
2.5
-.3
3.1
1.6
2.3
3.6
5.0
2.8
7.1
2.5
3.4
-.1

2014

Page 119 of 124

Greensheets

1.4
1.4
.4
1.3
.1
.1
.2
.2
2.1
1.5
.9
1.5
3.4
2.3
10.4

2.1
2.1
1.2
.3
1.2
2.2
2.0
1.3
2.9
4.5
3.2
6.8
1.6
2.8
-5.5

2015

1.9
1.9
.9
1.4
.3
1.2
.7
1.0
2.7
2.0
1.5
2.1
4.3
3.3
7.1

2.7
2.7
1.9
2.0
1.5
1.7
2.1
1.9
3.4
4.9
2.6
6.8
2.1
3.3
-2.1

2016

2.6
2.6
1.5
1.8
.6
3.0
1.4
1.6
3.4
2.0
1.5
1.8
6.7
6.6
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.6
3.0
2.0
1.4
2.7
2.8
3.2
5.2
2.8
6.8
1.5
1.6
2.1

2017

2.7
2.6
2.1
2.4
1.0
2.4
2.3
2.2
3.2
2.1
2.1
2.3
5.8
4.6
4.5

2.5
2.5
1.9
2.3
.8
1.5
1.6
1.7
3.2
4.9
3.0
6.5
1.5
2.0
1.9
2.6
2.7
1.9
2.3
2.3
2.3
1.5
2.3
3.1
2.6
2.1
2.5
4.4
3.4
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
2.1
.1
1.6
1.4
1.5
3.7
4.6
3.1
6.1
2.8
2.8
2.6
2.4
2.4
1.7
2.1
1.0
2.2
1.5
2.2
2.9
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.6
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.8
.8
1.7
1.6
1.4
3.7
4.6
3.0
5.9
2.9
2.9
2.8

2.4
2.4
1.7
2.0
1.1
2.1
1.7
2.0
2.9
2.6
2.1
2.5
3.5
3.2
4.3

2.6
2.6
1.7
1.8
.8
1.6
1.6
1.4
3.6
4.4
2.8
5.7
2.9
2.9
2.8

Authorized for Public Release

1. Foreign GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
2. Foreign CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

2012

Measure and country

-----------------Projected-----------------2018
2019
2020
2021

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
October 26, 2018

Page 120 of 124

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

-426.2
-426.2
-2.6
-2.6
-536.8
216.1
285.5
-69.4
-105.5

2012

-486.8
-489.9
-2.4
-2.4
-616.0
258.2
310.4
-52.2
-129.1

Q1

Q3

-349.5
-349.5
-2.1
-2.1
-461.9
215.4
283.3
-67.9
-103.1

Q4

2014

-564.7
-551.8
-2.7
-2.6
-633.6
181.8
295.7
-113.9
-113.0

-365.1
-365.1
-2.1
-2.1
-489.5
229.0
284.2
-55.3
-104.6

-519.8
-494.6
-2.5
-2.4
-627.7
224.9
309.4
-84.5
-117.0

2013

-405.8
-409.4
-2.0
-2.0
-535.2
256.9
309.9
-53.0
-127.5

Q2

-608.9
-638.2
-2.9
-3.0
-620.6
122.6
281.0
-158.4
-110.9

-409.7
-409.7
-2.2
-2.2
-500.4
214.7
284.6
-70.0
-123.9

Q3

2017

-638.3
-685.8
-3.0
-3.2
-626.0
104.7
287.0
-182.3
-117.0

-434.3
-434.3
-2.3
-2.3
-503.5
205.7
272.6
-66.9
-136.6

-449.1
-449.1
-2.3
-2.3
-552.3
235.1
298.4
-63.3
-132.0

Billions of dollars

2016

Annual Data

-608.6
-610.1
-2.9
-2.9
-635.1
148.4
284.4
-135.9
-121.9

2015

Q2

Q4

-691.5
-769.9
-3.1
-3.5
-639.0
69.4
298.2
-228.8
-121.9

Q1

-689.9
-780.6
-3.1
-3.5
-631.6
52.6
304.7
-252.1
-110.9

Q2

-715.2
-822.1
-3.2
-3.6
-639.6
41.5
316.7
-275.2
-117.0

Q3

-714.9
-834.6
-3.1
-3.7
-633.8
31.9
328.7
-296.9
-113.0

Q4

-494.3
-486.4
-2.4
-2.4
-603.1
230.5
306.4
-75.9
-121.7

-628.5
-663.8
-2.9
-3.1
-628.0
115.2
285.9
-170.7
-115.7

-702.9
-801.8
-3.1
-3.6
-636.0
48.8
312.1
-263.2
-115.7

-729.1
-880.7
-3.1
-3.8
-632.1
18.7
360.1
-341.4
-115.7

------------------Projected------------------2018
2019
2020
2021

-658.3
-720.9
-3.0
-3.3
-630.2
85.0
291.2
-206.2
-113.0

Billions of dollars, s.a.a.r.

Q1

-----------------------------------------------Projected------------------------------------------------2018
2019
2020

Quarterly Data

U.S. Current Account

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release
October 26, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

Abbreviations
ABS

asset-backed securities

AFE

advanced foreign economy

BBA

Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018

BEA

Bureau of Economic Analysis

BLS

Bureau of Labor Statistics

BOC

Bank of Canada

BOE

Bank of England

BOJ

Bank of Japan

BOM

Bank of Mexico

CAP

cyclically adjusted primary

CD

certificate of deposit

C&I

commercial and industrial

CMBS

commercial mortgage-backed securities

CP

commercial paper

CPH

compensation per hour

CPI

consumer price index

CRE

commercial real estate

DSGE

dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

ECI

employment cost index

EFFR

effective federal funds rate

EME

emerging market economy

FI

fiscal impetus

FOMC

Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee

FPLT

flexible price-level targeting

FRB/US

A large-scale macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy

Page 121 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

FX

foreign exchange

FY

fiscal year

GDP

gross domestic product

GFC

Global Financial Crisis

G-SIB

globally systemically important bank

IMF

International Monetary Fund

IOER

interest on excess reserves

IP

industrial production

IRA

individual retirement account

ISM

Institute for Supply Management

LFPR

labor force participation rate

LIBOR

London interbank offered rate

MBS

mortgage-backed securities

Michigan survey

University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers

MMF

money market fund

NAFTA

North American Free Trade Agreement

NBER

National Bureau of Economic Research

NIPA

national income and product accounts

OIS

overnight index swap

ON RRP

overnight reverse repurchase agreement

PCE

personal consumption expenditures

PDFP

private domestic final purchases

PMI

purchasing managers index

PPI

producer price index

QS

quantitative surveillance

SCF

Survey of Consumer Finances

SCOOS

Senior Credit Officer Opinion Survey on Dealer Financing
Terms

Page 122 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

October 26, 2018

SEC

Securities and Exchange Commission

SEP

Summary of Economic Projections

SIGMA

A calibrated multicountry DSGE model

SLOOS

Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices

SOMA

System Open Market Account

S&P

Standard & Poor’s

SPF

Survey of Professional Forecasters

TCJA

Tax Cuts and Jobs Act

TIPS

Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities

USMCA

U.S.-Mexico-Canada Agreement

VAR

vector autoregression

VIX

one-month-ahead option-implied volatility on the S&P 500 index

Page 123 of 124

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 124 of 124

October 26, 2018