View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

SHAxilrod

Introduction
The G-5 foreign exchange market intervention program has given
more immediacy to economic and policy issues involved in a drop in the
dollar on foreign exchange markets.
course necessary and desirable.

Some drop in the dollar is of

It provides a source of stimulus to the

economy that may be needed as other forces work to slow economic expansion,
and it

is integral to correction over time of sectoral imbalances in the

economy and of our unsustainably large deficit on goods and services in
the balance of payments.
But one cannot rule out the risk that a desirable fall in the
dollar could be transformed by an expectational flight from the dollar
into a much sharper and faster drop than may be consistent with reasonably
orderly economic adjustments.

That has not appeared to happen yet, and

confidence in the dollar has been rather well maintained.

Thus far, it

appears to be mainly official holders which have reduced their preference
for dollars--with G-5 countries alone selling $8 billion since the inception of the program to date.
In this presentation we hope to clarify the economic and
monetary policy issues raised by the potential for a weakening dollar,
and in particular the nature of the problems and policy options should
the dollar drop very sharply.
sections.

We have divided the presentation into four

Mr. Hooper will first outline two contours of exchange rate

adjustment--gradual and very rapid--and the associated likely adjustments in our balance of payments and to a degree in foreign countries.
Mr. Stockton will then lay out the associated real adjustments that will
need to be made in the U.S. economy.

Such adjustments will occur over

-2time involving interest rate and price changes and Mr. Slifman will
analyze the dynamics.

Finally, I will attempt to assess the issues

involved in some of the policy options.

Peter Hooper
November 1, 1985
As shown by the red line in the top panel of the first
exhibit, the dollar has fallen about 20 percent on average against the
major foreign currencies, to a level slightly below where it was in

mid-1984 after peaking in February this year.

About one third of the 20

percent decline this year has taken place since the G-5 statement in
late September.
Over much of the period since 1973, changes in the dollar's
spot exchange value have been fairly closely associated with movements
in the relative real rates of return on financial investments in the
United States and abroad.

U.S. long-term real interest rates rose

sharply relative to foreign rates between 1979 and 1982, as indicated by
the black line in the top panel, contributing significantly to the
dollar's rise during that period.

More recently, the decline in U.S.

interest rates relative to foreign rates undoubtedly has contributed to
the dollar's weakening since early this year. However, during some
periods the dollar has moved independently of the real interest rate
differential.

Most notably, the dollar's strengthening between 1982 and

1984 was attributed largely to other factors, often referred to as safehaven factors.
In the bottom panel of the chart are three hypothetical paths
of the dollar for the next five years.

In the top dashed line the

dollar is unchanged at its October average level.
mainly as a point of reference.

This path is given

The next line shows a gradual

depreciation of the dollar (at about a 5 percent annual rate).

This

path extrapolates through 1990 the staff's near-term projection of the
dollar.

-2One should also consider the possibility of an abrupt, adverse
shift in sentiment concerning dollar-denominated investments.

The

dollar's declines both since February and after the G-5 statement
indicate how much exchange rates can change in a relatively brief period.
Moreover, the dollar's rise during 1982-84, relative to an essentially
flat

real interest differential, suggests at least the potential for

large movements in exchange rates resulting from changes in confidence
and other developments affecting markets that are not readily
identifiable or predictable.

Should market forces turn strongly against

the dollar, it could fall a long way in a short time, particularly in an
environment where the market is wary that the underlying trend may be
downward.

It could even fall below a level that eventually would be

consistent with a zero current account balance before investors became
willing to continue to finance the U.S. external deficits that would
persist for at least a while.

As an example of a rapid depreciation,

the lower path shown in the Chart extrapolates over the next year and a
half the dollar's rate of depreciation since February.

Under this

scenario the dollar would fall another 40 percent to a point somewhat
below its low point in 1980, and then begin to rise again gradually.
Chart 2 shows the implications of these alternative paths of
the dollar for the U.S. trade balance and the current account balance.
If the dollar remained at its current level and GNP growth at home and
abroad remained in the 2-1/2 to 3 percent range, the current account
deficit would begin to widen again after the near-term effects of the
recent dollar depreciation were played out while the trade deficit would
remain about unchanged.

However, with a gradual depreciation of the

-3dollar, both deficits would narrow steadily through the projection
horizon.

In the case of the rapid depreciation, the current account

could return to zero balance and move slightly into surplus within about
three years.

If the extrapolated gradual depreciation were carried

beyond 1990 (the last point plotted on the chart) the current account
would reach zero balance within another four to five years.
The next table shows the cumulative effects of the alternative
current account paths on the U.S. net international investment position.
According to official statistics, the United States became a net debtor
earlier this year, for the first time since World War I.

If the dollar

remains unchanged over the next five years, we estimate that by 1990 the
U.S. net debt position would reach something on the order of $700
billion, which is suggestive of an increasingly fragile position for the
dollar.

By way of comparison, this level of debt would be about seven

times as large as Brazil's current net debt, though when expressed as a
percentage of GNP, only one-fourth as large as Brazil's.
falls, less debt will be accumulated.

If the dollar

But even so, by 1990, with a

moderate depreciation the debt would accumulate to $550 billion, and
with a rapid depreciation it would accumulate to $200 billion.
A rapid depreciation of the dollar and a sharp reduction of
the U.S. current account deficit implies major adjustments in the
current account positions of other countries.

In the top half of

Exhibit 4, the black bars show average current account positions from
1980 to 1982 for major regions of the world, and the red bars show
estimates for 1985.

While the U.S. position declined from about a zero

balance to a large deficit, the position of other industrial countries
rose from a sizable deficit to a sizeable surplus.

Among developing

-4countries, the ten major borrowing countries were forced by external
borrowing constraints to reduce their large deficits between these two
periods.

Other developing countries as a group incurred larger

deficits, substantially due to the reduction in surpluses of the oilexporting countries.
Developing countries as a group probably would not be able to
absorb more than a moderate portion of the U.S. deficit.

Countries

already heavily in debt would have difficulty financing substantially
larger deficits.

A sharp drop in the dollar could place significant

pressure on some of these countries at least in the near term.

To the

extent that U.S. interest rates rose, the major borrowing countries
would be facing higher net interest payments on their debt -- as shown
at the bottom of the exhibit, about $2 1/2 billion per year for every 1
percentage point rise in dollar interest rates.

Over time, however, the

rise in dollar prices would tend to reduce the real value of their debt.
For other developing countries a rapid drop in the dollar would be more
manageable.

Based on historical experience, a fall in the dollar would

tend to raise the dollar prices of developing country exports more than
the prices of their imports. The situation would be much more serious,
however, if the general level of demand in industrial countries fell,
which could significantly depress the export revenues of developing
countries.
Given the current position of developing countries, most of
the global adjustment would have to take place in the current account
positions of other industrial countries.

In 1985 the surpluses of

Japan, Germany and three other European countries, -- shown in Exhibit 5

-5-- will probably sum to about half the projected U.S. deficit.

A sharp

reduction or elimination of the U.S. deficit would entail moving the
current accounts of some of these countries significantly into deficit.
Such declines in net exports would have substantial negative impacts on
the economies of a number of countries.

To achieve this adjustment

without a significant reduction in the growth of GNP, these countries
would have to respond by lowering interest rates or adopting more
expansionary fiscal policies, as we have assumed they would.
The implications of a reversal of the U.S. current account
deficit for the U.S. domestic economy, to be discussed by Mr. Stockton,
would depend in part on its implications for the sectoral composition of
U.S. trade flows.

The three panels of Exhibit 6 show historical

movements in U.S. real net exports of finished manufactured goods,
industrial supplies and materials and food and agricultural products.
downturn since 1980 is evident in all three sectors.

A

In absolute terms,

the largest drop by far has been in the finished manufactured goods
sector, although as a proportion of domestic output, the decline has
been even greater in the agricultural sector.

A number of factors have

contributed to these declines in net exports, but the rise in the dollar
over this period appears to have been the most important proximate cause.
A reversal of the dollar's appreciation clearly would improve our net
export performance in all three areas, with the largest absolute change
coming in the manufacturing sector.

D. Stockton
October 31, 1985

In this section, I will discuss the adjustments required of the
domestic economy in response to a drop in the dollar and the approximate
magnitudes of these adjustments,

both in absolute terms and relative to

previous historical experience.

Exhibit 7 presents a hypothetical example

designed to illustrate the dimensions of the adjustments in the composition
of real demands on domestic production that would accompany elimination of the
current account deficit.

Although the adjustments would be smaller if

the

deficit were not fully eliminated, any substantial move towards balance
would require significant changes in existing patterns of domestic demands.
I should note that the table calculates changes in terms of the
composition of current real GNP-line 1-in an effort to clarify the
the actual adjustment would

shifts in resource use involved.

However,

likely occur over several years.

Thus, the percentage change figures

shown in the third column should be interpreted as reflecting shifts
in the level of domestic demands relative to what otherwise would occur,
growing fast or growing slowly.

whether economic activity was unchanged,

Turning first to the external sector, a depreciation of the dollar
stimulates real net exports--line 4 in
competitiveness of U.S.

producers.

the table-by improving the price

However,

prices of imports and exports
In

are not likely to change by the full extent of the depreciation.

order to calculate the effect on real net exports of eliminating the
current account deficit, it
experience--that

is

assumed-consistent with historical

foreign exporters absorb roughly half of the drop in the

dollar by reducing their profit margins.

At the same time, U.S.

firms

take the opportunity to raise somewhat the profit margins on their foreign

although the bulk of the depreciation will likely be reflected in

sales,

lower foreign currency prices for U.S.
in

exports.

The accompanying decline

the volume of imports and rise in the volume of exports is

estimated

to increase real net exports by about $77 billion.
As shown on line 2,

such an expansion of real net exports requires

an offsetting reduction in gross domestic purchases-the sum of consumption,
investment, and government purchases-of about 4-1/2 percent if
of GNP is
if

to be unchanged from what it

government purchases are not lowered,

the path

otherwise would have been.

Furthermore,

the decline must occur exclusively

among private domestic purchases-line 3--which would drop 5-1/2 percent.
It

is

implausible to expect the current account deficit to be eliminated

in

a single year.

of three years,

If

it

is

assumed that balance is

achieved over a period

as Mr. Hooper indicated was possible,

then it

necessary for real domestic purchases to grow, on average,

would be

about

1-1/2

percentage points per year less than production.
Although the magnitude of this adjustment of domestic demands relative
to production is

the same whether the economy is

capacity or near its

potential,

operating below full

the characteristics of the adjustment process

are likely to differ depending on existing economic conditions.
substantial

excess capacity,

With

the production of traded goods can expand

with substantially less upward wage and price pressures because resources
are readily available to meet the increased demand.
economy close to potential output,

In contrast, for an

the redirection of resources towards

the traded goods sector may generate much greater pressure on wages and
prices,

as it

employment in

will be necessary for resources to be bid away from current
the production of nontraded goods.

The upper panel of exhibit 8 places the magnitude of a three-year
adjustment to current account balance in

some historical perspective.

Annual growth rates of real GNP-the black line-and real gross domestic
purchases--the red line--are plotted in

the chart,

assuming that GNP

growth averages 3 percent at an annual rate over the next three years.
Nearly all previous periods during which purchases grew less than
production-shown by the red shading--were associated with recessions.
An adjustment of the magnitude and duration depicted in this panel, or
even one somewhat smaller, would be unprecedented in

a period of economic

expansion and suggests there may be considerable tensions created in
achieving the necessary suppression of domestic demands.
Accompanying the expansion of net exports and the decline in domestic
purchases will be a shift in

the composition of production.

A disproportionate

share of traded goods are produced in the manufacturing sector.

As a

consequence, the shift in production towards traded goods and away from
nontraded goods will lead to an expansion of foreign demands in the
manufacturing

sector.

This increase will most likely only be partially

offset by a reduction of domestic demands on manufacturing, because a
large share of the crowding out of domestic demands will occur outside of
the manufacturing sector.

Assuming growth in manufacturing capacity at

about a 3 percent annual rate-the long run trend-the expected shift in
the composition of production towards traded goods could be expected to
boost the manufacturing capacity utilization rate 4-1/2 percentage points
during the adjustment process.

As shown by the red line in the lower

panel of exhibit 8, starting from where we are now, the manufacturing
utilization rate would rise to 84-1/2 percent.

-4Of course, capacity growth could be greater or less than the
assumed 3 percent annual rate, even with GNP growth unchanged,
on the relative importance of two opposing effects.

depending

Increased relative

prices in the manufacturing sector should act to boost profitability and
encourage investment in that sector.

In opposition, the higher interest

rates resulting from the depreciation are likely to damp demands for
investment in new capacity.

The shaded area in the lower panel represents

manufacturing capacity utilization rates that would occur with annual
rates of capacity growth between 2-1/2 percent-shown as the upper black
line--and 3-1/2 percent--the lower black line.

Levels of capacity utilization

in the upper half of this range would likely generate persistent upward
pressure on prices in

the manufacturing sector.

Finally, additional risks would arise if domestic demands on the
manufacturing sector are not reduced as foreign demands are expanded.
rapid expansion of demands from abroad could temporarily lift

A

the manufacturing

capacity utilization rate above 90 percent if domestic demands were
unaltered.

Capacity utilization at this level would almost certainly

imply production bottlenecks in

some sectors.

Elimination of the current account deficit also has an important
influence on the availability of saving needed to finance both private
investment and the federal budget deficit.

column of exhibit 9

The first

presents our current estimate of the sources and uses of saving.

In the

which it is

assumed

second column a hypothetical example is

developed in

that the current account is brought into balance, thus eliminating net
foreign investment-line 4-as

a source of saving.

If

the federal

government's demands on saving were unchanged-line 2-the decline in
investment by foreigners would have to be met by some combination of a
reduction in private domestic investment and an expansion of domestic
saving.

the

Based on statistical analysis of historical relationships,

higher interest rates generated by a dollar depreciation could depress
net private investment-line

1 in

line 3--by roughly equal amounts.

the table--and boost domestic savingAs a result,

percent of disposable income-shown in
percent average level in

personal saving as a

line 5--could rise from its

1985 to about 6-1/2 percent.

4

I should mention

that, if the economy were operating substantially below its full potential,
sustainable economic growth would constitute an additional source of
saving to offset diminished capital inflows from abroad.
The chart in the lower panel of exhibit 9 places the projected
behavior of saving in some historical perspective.

It is again assumed, for

purposes of illustration, that the current account is brought into balance
over a period of three years.

Although the personal saving rate-shown as

the red line in the chart--would not be at an historical high, a 2-1/2
percentage point rise would be a significant increase for a period of
economic expansion.

The black line plots net domestic nonfederal

saving,

which includes undistributed corporate profits and state and local government
surpluses,

in

addition to personal saving.

As a percent of GNP,

climb to nearly 9-1/2 percent over the period,

it

would

reaching a postwar high.

Of course, historical relationships may not prove to be an accurate guide
to future behavior.

A failure to generate an increase in

saving of the

quantity depicted in exhibit 9 would lead to greater pressures on interest

-6-

rates and thus further crowding out of investment expenditures.
be stressed,

however,

It

should

that significant progress towards reduction of the

federal budget deficit would ease substantially the burden of adjustment on
the private sector and lessen the strains attendant in
Mr.

this process.

Slifman will now discuss the process of adjustment that would

occur over time.

L. Slifman
October 31, 1985
In this section we will contrast possible responses in the economy
over time to a gradual depreciation and to a rapid depreciation.
general,

In

a rapid fall in the dollar would necessitate the more extreme

shifts in resources and patterns of saving and investment that Mr.

Stockton

indicated.
As a benchmark, exhibit 10 lays out an illustrative path for
key economic variables on the assumption of a 5 percent annual drop in
the dollar beginning next year.

Because our purpose is to contrast the

economic effects of alternative exchange rate movements, we have assumed
at this point a monetary policy that is--so to speak--neutral, with money
growth (abstracting from demand shifts) constant from year to year.

By

setting aside the question of the policy adjustments needed to reduce
unemployment or inflation significantly further, this policy assumption
allows us to highlight exchange rate impacts.

In terms of fiscal policy,

we have assumed a narrowing of the structural budget deficit by about $60
billion during the projection period, reflecting the spending objectives
of the latest Congressional budget resolution.

This assumption differs

the one used in Mr. Stockton's tables, where the structural deficit
was held constant.
Given these policy assumptions, real GNP is assumed to rise
about 2-3/4 percent annually; but growth could be faster if our long-term
productivity performance were to improve.

The critical element, though,

is that throughout the five-year horizon growth of domestic purchases
would have to be suppressed relative to the growth of real GNP.

In

effect, a substantial move toward external balance requires that we give
up some of the excess growth in the standard of living we enjoyed during

- 2 the period of appreciation from 1980 to 1985.

At the same time, inflation

is projected to pick up as a result of increases in the prices of traded
goods.

Nominal interest rates begin to rise after 1986; but the rise is

quite modest reflecting our assumed narrowing of the structural deficit.
If the budget deficit were not reduced, however, interest pressures would
be even higher.
The effects of a more rapid depreciation--assuming the same
monetary and fiscal policies--are illustrated in red in the next exhibit.
These alternative projections are based on a judgmental interpretation of
the results from the staff's quarterly econometric model of the U.S.
economy and our multi-country model.
Focusing on the upper panels, the models suggest that a faster
drop in the dollar would require an even greater suppression of domestic
purchases over the projection period.

During 1986, the stimulus to

domestic production arising from an increased demand for traded goods
would be about offset by reduced growth of domestic purchases, with
little

net effect on GNP growth,

shown in the upper left panel.

By 1987,

however, the continued rapid improvement in our trade balance would be
expected to provide a sizable boost to GNP.

However, growth of domestic

demand--the upper right panel--would remain depressed.
accomplished,

as indicated in the lower left panel,

This would be

at the cost of faster

price increases and a sharp rise in interest rates (the lower right
panel).

The models suggest that over time the contractionary effects of

higher inflation and interest rates would begin to play a larger role,
and the growth of real GNP would become depressed for a while.
The necessary reductions in domestic demand weigh most heavily
on the interest-sensitive sectors of the economy.

This is illustrated in

-3-

exhibit 12.

Hardest hit would probably be the housing sector--the upper

left panel.

Business fixed investment--especially for new structures

such as office buildings and stores--also would be sensitive to the
higher interest rates.
In the consumer sector--the lower panels--the initial rise in
borrowing costs, and the reduction in the value of household financial
assets associated with higher interest rates, would have retarding effects
on purchases of durable goods.

In addition, because prices tend to be

more flexible than wages in the short run, a drop in the exchange rate
restrains real wage growth and boosts profits.
additional influence depressing consumption.

This could act as an
All of these factors would

tend to boost the saving rate. However, once households have adapted their
level of spending to the new lower levels of real income and wealth, the
growth of consumption would be expected to pick up.
The preceding two exhibits have illustrated the dimensions of
the macroeconomic adjustments that would likely occur if the dollar were
to depreciate rapidly.

These projections are based on average historical

relationships, which implicitly assume that the underlying microeconomic adjustments needed to redirect resources could be made relatively
smoothly.

Even so, as you can see, a sharp depreciation of the dollar

entails considerable distortions and disturbances in the behavior of
key variables.

Clearly, significant risks and uncertainties would arise

if the economy were subjected to a large exogenous depreciation shock,
and there could well be disruptions at the microeconomic level that would
lead to larger and even more volatile macroeconomic adjustments than we
have shown on the charts.

-4A number of these risks are summarized in the next exhibit.
A major problem is whether it would be physically possible to reallocate
quickly the resources needed to accommodate the shift in the composition
of output toward the traded goods sector.

If not, the result could be

bottlenecks, constraints and materials shortages in some specific industries,
as well as the emergence of labor market shortages for certain skills or
in particular geographic locations.

In addition, a sharp rise in capacity

utilization rates, with associated bottlenecks and constraints, also
could occur if less domestic demand were to be crowded out than our
models are showing.

If such constraints or shortages were to develop,

they could have adverse effects on prices and price expectations that
would impede the adjustment process.
Another major risk is the possibility that developments in
credit markets associated with rapid depreciation might generate a recession.
if domestic demand is extremely sensitive to the rise in interest rates.
The negative effects of rising interest rates could, in fact, be relatively
strong under current circumstances because of the particularly sensitive
position of many depository institutions.

Borrowers--especially households,

who have sustained spending recently through a rapid build-up in debt and
and a consequent reduction in the personal saving rate--also could be quite
sensitive to credit market conditions.

As a result, significant interest

rate increases may lead to unusually large cutbacks in lending and borrowing
Indeed, these negative financial market effects could well be

activity.

strong enough to offset the positive effects on activity of a decline in
the dollar.
Mr. Axilrod will now discuss the policy implications of these

risks.

Concluding remarks
The balancing of recessionary and inflationary risks that are
involved in the process by which the economy adjusts to a drop in the
dollar, particularly to a very sharp and rapid decline, poses difficult
judgmental issues for monetary policy.

With regard, first, to the risks of

recession, under present circumstances given the possibility of unusually
adverse institutional and borrower reactions to significant interest rate
increases, an accomodative policy that holds rates down and accelerates
money growth for a while might be considered for purposes of averting a
significant weakening in economic activity.

Such an approach would, however,

raise the odds that inflationary pressures would be unduly encouraged as the
added expansionary effect of a sharp depreciation of the dollar is not offset
by an effort to squeeze out purely domestic demands on capacity.
Of course one can debate exactly how tight resource availability
is at present, and thus how much scope there would be to expand output in
face of a falling dollar without undue inflationary risk.

An unemployment

rate near 7 percent and manufacturing capacity utilization around 80 percent
probably leaves some room for real GNP growth above potential without that
growth itself triggering a significant rise in inflationary expectations, but
as Mr. Stockton's presentation makes clear whatever margin of unused resources
there is would be rather quickly eroded by the added resource needs for
export and import-competing industries.

As that happens wage and price

pressures would tend to be generated on top of the inflationary pressures
directly related to the exchange rate induced rise in import prices.
those circumstances,

Under

inflationary expectations would be likely to rise, and a

return to slower money growth consistent with reasonable price stability over
time would then entail very considerable costs in unemployment and financial
disruption.

Since a policy of initial monetary accommodation to limit the risk
of recession in the short run may involve a substantial inflationary potential
and the likelihood of a later recession, one might as an alternative consider
a restrictive policy approach that takes the risks of weakness in economic
activity sooner but minimizes the potential for inflation-on the grounds
Such a

that such a policy approach would be less costly over the longer run.

policy of lowering money growth, at least by a little and for a while, and
thereby exerting more upward pressure on interest rates initially could under
present circumstances rather promptly weaken the economy.
and inflationary expectations would remain subdued.
income growth would work to hold down imports.

However, inflation

In addition, lower

Such a rather "classical"

method of reducing trade deficits by lowering domestic demand would
moderate downward pressures on the exchange value of the dollar.
The FOMC

of course does not necessarily have to prejudge whether

policy should be tilted in one direction or another in light of the various
risks.

An intermediate approach that keeps monetary policy unchanged (as

indexed by money targets no different from what they otherwise would be) in
the face of a sharp drop in the dollar can be viewed as weighting equally the
risks of recession or inflation and letting the degree of interest rate
pressure that emerges from market forces serve as the balance wheel.

Policy

could be shaded to the more accommodative or restrictive sides as market and
economic responses to a sharp drop in the dollar evolve.
Basically, however, I suspect that there is little chance of a
very satisfactory econonomic outcome to a sharp drop in the dollar under current
circumstances, no matter how well tuned is monetary policy.

We would be

very likely to experience inflation or recession or possibly both.

Sub-

stantial real adjustments in the balance of domestic saving and investment

and in resource reallocation of the magnitude required by a closer balance in
our international position probably cannot be accomplished in an orderly
fashion in a relatively short period of time, given rigidities in the
economy and lags in response rates to changes in relative prices.
Attempts to achieve those large real adjustments quickly would
probably entail considerable upward wage and price pressures, which would in
themselves work to erode the real effect on our international competitiveness
of any given nominal decline in the exchange rate, with the potential then
for an even larger drop in nominal terms.

At the same time, economic activity

probably could not be adequately sustained in face of the relatively substantial rise of interest rates that may be needed to squeeze out domestic
demand in the process, given the comparative fragility of domestic and world
financial conditions, including debt burdens of borrowers and the balance
sheet position of financial institutions.

Finally, significant cuts in

the federal budget deficit are not assured, and those cuts can make a more
direct contribution than monetary policy to the real adjustments in the
balance of saving and investment and real resource availability that are
needed as the current account returns nearer to balance.

But even if cuts

were assured, they would take place over an extended period, and would be of
little immediate help, except possibly through expectational effects.

It is, therefore, at least in my view--and absent a miracle of
fiscal restraint or a considerably weaker economy than now envisageddesirable to avert a sharp decline in the dollar.

On the other hand, it is

also desirable to keep the dollar from being excessively high because of the
risks involved in postponing the adjustment process.

If postponed unduly,

the subsequent dollar decline may be extremely large and economic adjustments may occur at a time when domestic resources are even more highly

-4utilized than at present, when upward price expectations may be less subdued, and when needed plant capacity and labor skills for internationallycopetitive industries have rusted further from disuse.

That leaves a

gradual downward adjustment in the dollar, particularly as it is accompanied
by increasing fiscal restraint over time, as having the best odds for promoting
an orderly process of economic adjustment.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS I-FOMC

Materialsfor Staff Presentation to the
Federal Open Market Committee

Economic and Policy Implications
of Exchange Rate Adjustments
November 4, 1985

130

Exhibit 1

Foreign Exchange Value of the U.S. Dollar
Quarterly
March 1973 =100
-160

Percentage points

Weighted Averaige Dollar
-

150

9
-140

6

-130

October

-120
3
-110

Long-term Real Interest
Rate Differential*

0

- 100
- 90

3
-

1973

1973

1975

1975

1977

1977

1979

1979

1981

1981

1987

1983

80

S70
1989

March 1973=100
160

ge Dollar
-

150
-140

i Dollar

reciation
-120
-

110

-. 100
ation
90
'

-

80
70

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

*Difference between long-term government bond yields of the U.S. and a weighted average of other G-10 countries plus Switzerland,
minus the difference between 12-quarter centered U.S. and foreign inflation rates at annual rates.

Exhibit 2

U.S. External Balances
Quarterly
Merchandise Trade Balance

Current Account Balance

Exhibit 3

U.S. Net International Investment Position
End of Year

Billions of Dollars

Percent of GNP

1950

13

4.5

1960

45

8.9

1970

58

5.8

1980

106

4.0

1984

28

0.1

1985

-63

-1.6

1990:
With Unchanged Dollar

-700

-13.0

With Gradual Depreciation

- 550

-10.0

With Rapid Depreciation

- 200

-3.5

Exhibit 4

Global Current Account Balances
Billions of dollars

U

19 80 -82

U13 1985 Projected (Second bar)

40

Other OECD

I-

0

Ten Major

Borrowing Countries*

40
40

Other Developing
Countries
-

80

-120

United States

Billions of Dollars
Impact of one percentage point higher dollar interest
rates on the net interest payments of:
All developing countries,
of which:
Ten major borrowing countries*
OPEC

* Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Korea, Mexico, Nigeria, Peru,
Philippines, and Venezuela.

Exhibit 5

Current Account Balances of Major Industrial Countries
1985 Projected

Japan

Germany

Netherlands

Switzerland

U

United Kingdom

I

Canada

France

Italy
--

I

10

-0+

I

I

10
20
Billions of dollars

I

30

I

40

I

Exhibit 6

U.S. Real Net Exports by Sector
Finished Manufactures
Billions of 1972 dollars

-20

10

0

10

20

30
40

1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

Industrial Supplies and Materials
Billions of 1972 dollars

Im
I
1973

1975

1977

1979

1981

F IF
1983

I
1985

Food and Agricultural Products
Billions of 1972 dollars

1973
1973

1975
1975

1977
1977

1979
1979

1981
1981

1983
1983

1985
1985

Exhibit 7

Composition of Current Real GNP and
Hypothetical Real GNP Scaled to 1985 Magnitudes
Billions of 1972 Dollars

Staff
Estimate¹
1985

Hypothetical
Example

Percentage
Change

(1)

(2)

(3)

1. Gross national product
(C+I+G +X- M)

1679

1679

0

2. Gross domestic purchases
(C + I +G)

1711

1634

-41/2

3. Gross private domestic
purchases (C + I)

1392

1315

-51/2

4. Net exports
(X-M)

-33

1. Staff estimate for 1985 in 1972 dollars (October Greenbook).

Exhibit 8

Real GNP and Gross Domestic Purchases
Percent change from year earlier

1954

1959

1964

1969

1974

1979

1984

1989

Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Rate
Percent

1973 Peak
/

- 85

h

3 Percent
Capacity Growth

80

-- 75

-170

I
1970

III
1975

II I
1980

I
1985

1990

Exhibit 9

Demands on and Sources of Net Saving
Billions of Current Dollars

Staff Estimate¹
1985

Hypothetical
Example

(1)

(2)

Demands on net saving
1. Net private investment

223

169

2. Federal budget deficit

194

194

3. Net domestic nonfederal saving

298

363

4. Net foreign investment

119

0

4

61/2

Sources of net saving

Memo:
5. Personal saving rate
1. Staff estimate for 1985 in current dollars (October Greenbook).

Personal Saving and Net Domestic Saving
Percent of disposable income

Percent of GNP

Net Domestic*

8
6

S8

-

7

Personal

/

/

/

/

'I

V

I I I I I I I I I I II I
1954

1959

* Net domestic nonfederal saving.

1964

I I
1969

i I II
1974

I I I I I I
1979

--

I I I I
1984

1989

4

Exhibit 10

Assumed Paths of Key Variables
with a Gradual Depreciation
Percent Change; Fourth Quarter to Fourth Quarter

1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990
1. Real GNP

2.0

2.4

2.7

2.7

2.7

2.7

2. Domestic purchases (C + I + G)

3.2

1.9

1.9

2.2

2.3

2.5

3. GNP deflator

3.6

3.7

4.4

4.7

4.8

4.8

4. Treasury bill rate (level in Q4)

7.2

6.5

6.8

7.0

7.0

7.0

Key assumptions
Monetary policy: Constant money growth rate (abstracting from
shifts in money demand)
Fiscal policy:

Narrowing of the structural deficit consistent with
the objectives of the Congressional budget
resolution

Exchange rate:

5 percent per year depreciation, 1986- 1990

Exhibit 11

Impact of a Rapid Depreciation
Domestic Purchases

Real GNP

Percent change

Percent change

I
--

4

Rapid
-3

--

3

-2

--

2

Gradual

I

I

I
1987

1985

I

I

I *, l
1985

1989

GNP Deflator

I

I

I
1989

1987

Treasury Bill Rate
Percent

Percent change

--

6

-111

-

2

I

I I
1985

1987

1989

I
1985

I
1987

1989

Exhibit 12

Impact of a Rapid Depreciation on Spending and Saving
Housing Expenditures

Business Fixed Investment
Percent change

Percent change

r

-

-1
-

6

Gradual

- 3

I
1985

1987

1989

1985

I
1987

1989

Personal Saving Rate

Consumption

Percent

Percent change

F

Rapid
-- 7

-- 3

-- 6
--

2

Rapid
-14

I
1985

I

I
1987

I

I
1989

I
1985

I1
1987

1I
9
1989

Exhibit 13

Risks to the Adjustment Process

* It may not be physically possible to reallocate sufficient
resources to the traded goods sector.
- Bottlenecks and capacity constraints
- Labor market shortages
* Sharp increases in capacity utilization rates could occur if
domestic demand were not crowded out sufficiently.
* Interest rate effects could be relatively strong because of the
sensitive position of many depository institutions.
* Household borrowers also could be quite sensitive because of
high debt burdens and low saving rate.
* Negative financial market effects could be strong enough to
offset the positive trade effect associated with a decline in the
dollar.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
November 4-5, 1985
Sam Y. Cross
Mr. Chairman, perhaps it would give a clearer perspective if
I reviewed developments over the entire six-week period since
September 22, when the G-5 made its pronouncements about exchange
market intervention, although that goes back a week or so before the
last FOMC meeting. As a benchmark, during the week before the G-5
meeting, the dollar was trading around 2.90 DM and 2.42 yen.
You will recall that on the first day after the G-5
communique there was a sharp decline in the dollar, which closed on
Monday at 6 to 7 percent below those benchmark levels. The market
noted that the U.S. had taken the lead in forging the G-5 agreement.
and took seriously the fact that the Administration had shifted its
attitude both with respect to intervention and with respect to the
implications of a strong dollar. Thereafter the market became
impressed by the willingness of the authorities to intervene, in
particular, the Japanese authorities, who on their first business day
spent $1.2 billion, accounting for more than 25 percent of the Tokyo
market's gross dollar sales, on the day of the market's largest
turnover in history. The dollar continued to trend lower through the
first week in October. With pressures relatively light, after the
Japanese action, U.S. intervention totalled less than $500 million in
the first two weeks after the September 27th announcement.
In the second two weeks, the dollar came under upward
pressures, reflecting strong commercial and investor demand. The
demand for dollars was spurred by the passing of the IMF meeting
without announcement by any of the countries of any new economic
policy initiatives to reinforce the intervention. Also, there were
statements by foreign officials that were interpreted as expressing
satisfaction with the extent of the dollar's decline, and suggesting
that it would not fall much farther. In addition, there were
expectations developing of stronger U.S. economic growth.
While we felt that some recovery of the dollar was
appropriate in the circumstances and should be allowed, we did act to
resist sustained upward pressures by selling substantial amounts of
dollars, both through agents and directly in our own markets and
abroad. As these upward pressures intensified around mid-October, we
sold dollars openly and aggressively against both the mark and the
yen. On October 16, as the dollar reached its highs for the period,
we sold almost $900 million, and on the next day we openly sold an
additional $170 million as the dollar was easing back from its highs
after a disappointing GNP figure. Others cooperated in resisting the
strong upward pressure on the dollar, and we were in frequent,
sometimes around-the-clock contact with our colleagues at the Bank of
Japan, the Bundesbank, and elsewhere to coordinate intervention
operations. During that second two weeks of the six-week period, the
U.S. sold more than $2 billion ($2.167 billion) and the other G-5
countries sold almost another $2 billion ($1.898 billion).

Over the last two weeks of the six-week period, in response
both to the intervention operations and the less optimistic outlook
for U.S. economic activity, much of the upward pressure on the dollar
relative to the European currencies abated, although the market
continued to sense a strong potential demand for dollars by Japanese
investors. Consequently, our dollar sales were much more modest and
generally concentrated against yen. For the most part, these
operations were designed to defuse pressures before they could build,
on occasion nudging the exchange rate when a good opportunity
presented itself. Toward the end of the period, the Bank of Japan,
responding to the continuing underlying investment demand for dollars,
acted conspicuously to guide Japanese market rates significantly
higher. Many market participants viewed this action as the first of a
series of steps to be taken by the G-5 countries to lower interest
rate differentials favorable to the dollar. The Bundesbank, when it
offset a seasonal overabundance of liquidity from its markets, was
viewed as also changing its policy toward the same objective.
Although the idea of a G-5 interest rate agreement has been denied by
many sources, the dollar has declined further in this environment and
now stands at just below 2.66 DM and 2.08 yen.
The dollar is now 10-1/2 percent below the pre-September 22
benchmark figure for the DM I mentioned earlier, and 14 percent below
the figure for the yen. Dollar sales by the United States in the sixweek period amounted to $3.2 billion. Dollar sales by other members
of the G-5 totalled $4.9 billion during the six-week period. Of the
$3.2 billion in U.S. sales, a total of $2.8 billion took place since
the last FOMC meeting--$1.65 billion against DM and $1.14 billion
against yen. All of these sales of dollars by the U.S. were divided
equally between the Federal Reserve and Treasury.
These increases in Treasury and System holdings of foreign
currency have been invested using existing facilities, as always
aiming to obtain market related rates of return along with the
required high degree of liquidity and safety. In the case of our yen
acquisitions, all have been invested through the Bank of Japan in

For the German marks we have acquired, the Bundesbank
requested that
all of the increase has gone into mark deposits
held with the BIS. The Bundesbank's request to us is similar to those
we understand it has made of other central banks buying large amounts
of marks in the last year or so, and stems from

As you know, the level of our intervention activity resulted
in our approaching our limit on the maximum change in the Federal
Reserve's foreign currency balances between FOMC meetings, and the
Committee approved a $500 million increase in this limit to $2
billion. As it developed, we did not have to use this additional
leeway, and the limit automatically reverts to $1.5 billion.

-3Mr. Chairman, at the last meeting, the Committee approved a
maximum overall position limit of $10 billion. Within that $10
billion overall limit, there are informal limits on individual
currency holdings--at the level of $6 billion equivalent in DM, $3
billion in yen, and $1 billion in other currencies. At present, we
have ample room under the overall formal limit of $10 billion--we are
about $3 billion below that limit. But we may need to change some of
the informal limits, depending on developments in the weeks ahead.
Mr. Chairman, I recommend that the Committee ratify the
transactions since the October meeting that I have described. My only
other recommendation is that the Committee approve renewal of the
System's reciprocal foreign currency arrangements with foreign central
banks and the BIS, as these come up for renewal in December. We are
suggesting no change in any of the agreements.

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
November 5, 1985
Peter D. Sternlight

Domestic Desk operations since the October 1 meeting sought to
maintain the same degree of reserve pressure intended at the time of that
meeting.

Narrow money growth halted in October, on average a sharper slowdown

than had been anticipated a month ago, but this still left the M1 measure far
above the Committee's intended range from the second to fourth quarter.

The

broader aggregates also slowed in October, reflecting both the stall-out in M1
and some slowing in time deposit components.

This brought M2 just back within

its annual growth cone in October, after having been above its range in
September, while M3 remained near the middle of its annual range.

Against

this background, the slowdown in October growth was not seen as calling for a
change in planned reserve pressures, particularly against the background of
continued moderate growth in the economy and for the most part a weakening in
the dollar internationally.
Accordingly, reserve paths continued essentially to incorporate a
$500 million allowance for seasonal and adjustment borrowing, although in the
early part of the interval as we proceeded through the maintenance period
ending October 9, an allowance was made for relatively high borrowing in the
early part of that period traceable to hurricane disruptions and statement
date pressures at the end of September.

There were also unusual pressures on

October 9 itself, when the Treasury, steering its tortuous way between the
Scylla of debt limit and Charybdis of zero cash balances, scheduled a cash
management bill for auction and payment that same day.

Together, those

factors boosted borrowing in the October 9 period to about $770 million.

In

the next full period, borrowing averaged a close-to-path $470 million while so

far in the current period it has averaged a below path $385 million (through
last weekend).
Fed funds have averaged close to the expected eight percent area,
looking at full weeks or reserve periods, but there were some significant
departures on particular days.

Most notable, on October 9, when the Treasury

sold its same day cash management bill, there was small-scale late trading at
rates of 10 to 40 percent.

On the other hand, early in the current reserve

period, there was substantial trading in the 7 1/2 to 7 3/4 percent range as
excess reserves were temporarily over-abundant.

So far in the current reserve

period, funds have averaged 8.02 percent.
Outright operations were relatively light for the Domestic Desk,
including the sale of $265 million of Treasury bills to foreign accounts and
purchases of about an equal amount of bills from those accounts late in the
period.

This would ordinarily be a period of moderate reserve provision, but

that was being accomplished through Foreign Desk currency purchases and
somewhat lower than normal Treasury balances as the debt limit problem dragged
on.

We did have a number of occasions to inject reserves temporarily by

passing through customer repurchase agreements--eight times-and five
occasions when we withdrew reserves for short periods through matched sale
purchase transactions.
The uncertain timing of action on the debt ceiling remains a
complication for reserve management--as well as in other respects--for the
period ahead.

As you know, there was one day last month, October 8, when the

Treasury ran a small inadvertent overdraft which was plugged to zero the next
morning through an accounting adjustment.

After some unusual use of the

Federal Financing Bank and certain trust funds, their balance is probably okay

for about the next 10 days, though perhaps with some close calls and
occasionally lower than normal balances.

The so-called "drop-dead" date now

is November 15 when massive new cash is needed for interest payments.

Without

uncorking still new gimmicks, which the Administration has professed an
unwillingness to use, we don't think they can get past November 15 and would
have to default at that time unless the Congress has acted.
Financial markets responded to diverse and often confusing signals
over the period, with uncertainty about the Treasury's financing plans a
continuous background factor.

For intermediate and longer-term Treasury

issues there was a net yield decline of about 20 to 35 basis points.

It

stemmed essentially from a prevalent view that the economy was expanding only
modestly, with inflation in a state of remission, and a fair likelihood that
monetary policy could turn more accommodative in coming months--partly in
furtherance of the G-5 efforts to strengthen the major nondollar currencies.
This view prevailed even though at times there was also a sense that the
System was aiming, short-run, for slightly more cautious conditions of reserve
availability.

With pent-up appetite for long-delayed coupon issues, the

market bid vigorously last week for four-and seven-year notes, and pretty well
also for twenty-year bonds.

The Treasury raised nearly $18 billion through

these issues, the bulk of the $19 billion raised through coupon issues during
the period.

It remains to be seen whether the market appetite will also be

good for the three-, ten-, and thirty-year issues that normally make up the
Treasury's mid-quarter financing and would be up for auction this week but for
the debt limit hang-up.

Last week's auctions have filled in a lot of short

positions, and fresh demand may depend on the market's finding further cause
for optimism that rates will decline in coming months.

The bill market turned in a more staid performance over the period,
with some short maturities rising in rate and longer ones edging off only
slightly.

The bill market seemed to be responding more than coupons to the

perception that Fed funds would likely vary around 8 percent--perhaps in a
"broad" range of 7 3/4 to 8 1/8 percent.

Three- and six-month bills were

auctioned today at about 7.22 and 7.30 percent compared with 7.07 and
7.24 percent just before the last meeting.

The Treasury will have raised

$8 billion in the bill market over the period in the form of short-term cash
management bills including $5 billion on October 9 and another $3 billion just
announced today for auction and payment tomorrow.
The Federal agency market attention continued to focus on the
beleaguered Farm Credit System.

Through most of the period, spreads of

Farm Credit paper over Treasuries tended to widen in response to, or
anticipation of, adverse news reports, including a GAO report projecting
multi-billion dollar losses for the year ending next June, and FCA's own
report of a half-billion loss in the latest quarter.

By late October, the

spreads were largely around 100 basis points or somewhat more.

The spreads

narrowed temporarily by about 20 basis points last week following press
reports that the Administration was leaning toward some sort of back-up plan,
and FCA got the benefit of that temporary narrowing in pricing a six-month
issue about 85 basis points over Treasuries.

The next day, Administration

testimony seemed to shy away from any near-term aid plan and also forecast a
heavy fourth-quarter loss for the System that sent spreads back to the
100 basis point area.

Market participants did not seem excessively disturbed

by these events, though, essentially, I think, because there is a persistent
underlying belief that the Farm Credit System won't be allowed to fail.

Elsewhere, I should just mention the tax-exempt market where rates
declined considerably more than for Treasury issues.
about 60 basis points.

One broad index fell

A few months ago, exceptionally heavy issuance in this

market caused rates to back up compared with Treasury issues.

Much of the

heavy issuance was undertaken to get ahead of possible Congressional
restrictions on certain types of tax-exempt financing starting next year.
More recently, given the development of unusually attractive rates compared
with taxable bonds, demand picked up substantially.

Some of it has come,

reportedly, from investors that don't normally seek tax-exempt income but are
attracted to the current spreads as a short-term holding.

Also, we hear of

some bank buying on the basis that subsequent legal changes may make it more
costly on an after tax basis for them to carry tax-exempt investments
purchased after year-end.

JLKichline
November 4-5, 1985

FOMC Briefing

The staff's forecast of the economy prepared for this
meeting of the Committee is little changed, although we have
shaded a few tenths off projected growth of real GNP for this
quarter and next year.

Economic activity is expected to

advance at a 2-1/2 percent annual rate over the forecast
period, which is thought to be consistent with an unemployment
rate that is stuck at a bit over 7 percent.
Information on developments in the current quarter is
quite limited; essentially all we have in hand is the October
labor market reports, a tentative reading on industrial
production, and partial data on October auto sales.

The labor

market surveys were upbeat in October as payroll employment
rose more than 400,000.

Employment gains were widespread among

sectors, including growth in manufacturing and construction as
well as trade and services.

Owing to seasonal adjustment

problems, it would seem better to average October with the
weaker September report and doing that still provides growth of
employment somewhat above the experience earlier in the year.
Given the labor market information and some physical product
data, it appears that industrial production was about unchanged
in October, held down in part by the Chrysler strike which came
after the employment surveys.

Domestic auto sales in the first

- 2 20 days of October plunged as expected following the end of
most cut-rate financing incentives, and auto inventories are
now in the process of being rebuilt.
On the whole it seems that moderate growth this
quarter is a good bet, but in our thinking some additional
caution flags have been raised as we focused on the forecast
through next year.

In the consumer sector, spending attitudes

are reportedly good and outside the auto sector we have been
seeing moderate gains in spending in recent months.

However,

future gains in spending would seem to be constrained by the
prospect of limited expansion in real disposable income--a bit
over 2 percent in the forecast--high debt burdens and a very
low saving rate.

I might note that the 4 percent saving rate

in the forecast takes off from currently published data, and it
appears likely there will be a sizable upward revision to the
data but that will still leave us significantly below historical norms.
Developments in the investment sectors in the forecast
contribute to holding down prospective gains in income.
Housing, frankly, has been a puzzle for some time, but clearly
housing starts have yet to show a response to the earlier
decline in mortgage interest rates; starts edged lower in the
spring and declined on average for the third quarter.

We have

reduced our expectations for this sector a little but continue
to forecast some pickup in starts over the course of the

- 3 forecast, partly in response to some further drifting down of
mortgage interest rates.
We have also lowered our expectations somewhat for
business fixed investment spending.

New orders for nondefense

capital equipment rose 5 percent last quarter, but the bulk of
the increase was for aircraft and parts which have long lead
times; excluding aircraft, nondefense capital goods orders have
been about flat this year.

Survey evidence on 1986 capital

spending plans has become available to us on a confidential
basis since the last Committee meeting and both the McGraw Hill
survey (down 1 percent in nominal terms) and the Merrill Lynch
survey ( up 3 percent) are weak.

Even after allowing for their

tendency to underpredict, the surveys suggest cautious business
planning for next year.

Our forecast is somewhat above these

surveys, but with ample capacity, moderate growth of final
sales, and uncertainty over tax reform, there do not seem to be
any particular sources of strength available.
On a more positive note, the decline in the foreign
exchange value of the dollar that has occurred and assumed to
continue at a more moderate rate should produce an improvement
in net exports.

For 1986, net exports are projected to

contribute to growth of real GNP for the first time since 1980.
Also positive has been the continuing generally good
performance of wages and prices.

Although some transitory

factors--the ending of cut-rate auto financing and higher meat

- 4 -

prices, for example--could boost near-term monthly price
indicators, inflation this year is expected to be around 3-1/2
percent, the same or better than last year depending on the
measure used.

Only a small acceleration is expected next year,

in response to a weaker dollar.