View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes for FOMC Meeting
November 3, 1987
Sam Y. Cross
Movements in dollar exchange rates during the intermeeting
period largely coincided with shifting assessments of the
interest rate and exchange rate policies of the United States and
other Group of Seven countries.
During the early part of the intermeeting period, the dollar
traded in a narrow range, comfortably above the lows of last
spring.

Interest differentials favorable to the dollar continued

to widen, encouraging investors to maintain funds in dollardenominated assets.

The Group of Seven at its Washington meeting

reaffirmed the Louvre accord commitment to foster exchange rate
stability, and subsequent comments by Chancellor Lawson and
Secretary Baker were interpreted as suggesting that the major
industrial nations were moving towards greater management of
exchange rates.

Market participants felt that the Louvre

understandings were pretty solid, and that interest rates would
be used if necessary to sustain exchange rates at near their then
current levels.
At the same time, however, German short-term interest rates
began to rise in late September.

At first, the firming had

little impact on the dollar/mark rate because even larger
interest rate increases were taking place in the United States.
Then, when the August trade data indicated that the trade
adjustment was still disappointingly slow, U.S. interest rates
1

rose markedly across all maturities.

Soon thereafter, comments

by Secretary Baker, followed by explanatory remarks of an
unidentified senior administration official, signalled
displeasure with interest rate trends in Germany, and there were
press reports suggesting that the target range for the dollar
would be lowered, or even that cooperation among the G-7
countries was breaking down.

The dollar moved down abruptly

against the mark to around DM 1.77 on the weekend of October 17.
The next Monday, as turbulence erupted in stock markets
around the world, market participants looked for some coordinated
official response.

When news came out later that day that

Secretary Baker and German officials had met in Frankfurt, the
dollar bounced back to trade above DM 1.80.

After the Bundesbank

took a step to contain upward pressure on German short-term
interest rates, market participants believed that cooperation was
being restored, and that the authorities would seek to limit
exchange rate movements, at least for the time being.
Thus, fluctuations in dollar exchange rates were relatively
modest in the first several days after "Black Monday".

The

dollar appeared to benefit initially from its traditional role as
a safe haven during times of chaos and fear.

Although many

investors who withdrew from equities markets in the various
financial centers apparently moved into domestic fixed-income
markets in the same centers, there were substantial flows into
the U.S. Treasury market.

At that time market professionals were

reluctant to position aggressively and corporate participants

remained cautious, owing to increased concern over counterparty
credit risk as well as to fears of possible abrupt and
unpredictable exchange rate movements.

As foreign exchange

trading moved to the sidelines, flows into the U.S. Treasury
market continued.

In these circumstances, and with the Federal

Reserve's assurances that it would provide adequate liquidity to
the U.S. financial system necessary to calm the equity and other
markets, there was a decline in short-term dollar interest rates.
Meanwhile, German and Japanese authorities also provided
short-term liquidity assistance to their domestic markets by way
of open-market and other operations.

Short-term interest rates

there also declined, but by amounts one-half to two-thirds the
decline of comparable U.S. rates.

As a result, there was a sharp

narrowing--by at times as much as 100 basis points--in
differentials between the dollar and mark three-month Euro
deposit rates in the first week or so after the stock market
fall.

Thus, in late October, with less support from favorable

interest differentials, and a feeling any accommodative monetary
policy moves abroad would be less vigorous than in the United
States, the dollar became more vulnerable.

At that time,

following a spate of press commentary, to the effect that the
Louvre agreement was falling apart, or that the United States was
again welcoming a lower dollar, heavy selling pressures reemerged.

By the end of October, the press was carrying an

increasingly strident public debate on the advisability of a
continued U.S. commitment to that part of the Louvre accord

calling for exchange rate stability.
As this selling pressure intensified, the United States
intervened in the foreign exchange market, in concert with other
central banks.

These operations were aimed at providing some

stability to the market and resisting downward pressure on the
dollar, but they did not stop the dollar from declining, at times
abruptly.
All of the U.S. intervention activity for the period has
taken place since last Monday.

The Desk bought a total of $425

million against the sale of German marks and $105 million against
Japanese yen.

The total amount of $530 million was shared

between the Treasury and the Federal Reserve, with the Treasury
covering all of the yen sales and the Fed providing a somewhat
larger amount of marks.

The Fed's total was $260 million.

In addition to U.S. intervention, there have been heavy
dollar purchases by others since last week.
has bought about
almost

for yen.

The Bank of Japan

The Bundesbank has bought

for marks, and other Europeans bought about
for marks.

In addition the U.K. and other European

countries have bought very large amounts of dollars for their own
currencies.
In the meantime, with the sharp rise of the mark against the
dollar, strains within the European Monetary System (EMS) reemerged.

While the Louvre accord was viewed as in place and the

exchange rate structure reliable, the higher yielding currencies
within the EMS had benefited from the atmosphere of stability.

Once this atmosphere was shaken, the perceived exchange risk for
these currencies increased enormously and they declined against
the mark even though they rose against the dollar.

In

particular, the French franc moved down within the EMS band as
both foreign speculators and French companies sold francs in
anticipation of an imminent realignment.

In addition to the

dollar intervention in the past ten days, there have been very
heavy sales of German marks -- about DM 12 billion last week by
France and others, in response to EMS pressures.
Thus we close this period with the dollar down around 6
percent since the last Committee meeting, despite substantial
intervention.

The mood is extremely bearish, with the news media

filled with reports of official interest in a lower dollar.
In closing, Mr. Chairman, I recommend that the Committee
approve the intervention undertaken during the period.

In

addition, I would like to seek the Committee's approval for
renewing the Federal Reserve swap agreements with other central
banks and the BIS, all of which come up for renewal in December.
Aside from the swap drawings by Mexico, these facilities have not
been drawn on for several years, either by the Federal Reserve or
any of the counterparties.

Although they cannot be drawn except

by reciprocal agreement, of course, it is important to keep these
facilities in place and available in case of need.

I recommend

that the Committee authorize their extension for a further period
of one year, without substantial change.

PETER D. STERNLIGHT
NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
NOVEMBER 3, 1987
The latest intermeeting period saw a dramatic shift in
the financial market climate following a record drop in equity
market prices on October 19.

Up to that point, the Domestic

Trading Desk was seeking to implement the policy adopted at the
September meeting of the Committee, aiming for reserve pressures
associated with $600 million of adjustment and seasonal borrowing
at the discount window.

In line with the Committee's September

discussion we sought to bring about those reserve pressures,
which entailed a slight firming in comparison with conditions
prevailing before the September meeting, in a relatively
unobtrusive fashion.

In fact, the market's perception and

reaction became somewhat accentuated because of pressures
associated with the September quarter-end, debt limit disruptions
to Treasury financing, a significant computer problem at the New
York Fed, and a market sense that policy was edging firmer in key
foreign countries as well as in the U.S.

Borrowing rose from

$470 million in the period ending just a day after the September
meeting to $726 million in the first full period of the new
intermeeting interval--i.e., the period ended October 7.

About

$100 million of that borrowing appeared to be attributable to
special factors, particularly the New York computer problem, and
market participants had a sense of this, but they were left with
a feeling that some slight policy firming might well be taking

place.

The average funds rate edged up in that period to 7.50

percent from about 7-1/4 in the two previous periods--a bit more
of a move than we had anticipated in conjunction with the soughtfor reserve pressures.
Fresh pains were taken in the next period to avoid
confirming market anticipations of a firmer move than was
actually sought--although we were conscious that it could be
misleading to dispel market ideas that there had been any move at
all.

Borrowing fell back to $525 million in that period and

would have been even lower but for an unexpected bulge on the
October 21 settlement date, reflecting a miss in projections and
some maldistribution of reserves.

Indeed, by the time of that

next settlement date, the Desk's posture had already shifted to
one of essentially accommodating the economy's liquidity needs in
the wake of the extraordinary stock market plunge on October 19.
Fed funds again averaged about 7-1/2 percent in the period, with
a 7-5/8 percent first week offset by a 7-3/8 second week as
market participants were already gaining a sense of greater
accommodation.
Pursuing that more accommodative approach, the
borrowing level built into the path for next reserve period--the
one ending tomorrow--was reduced to $500 million and then $450
million.

But these were more notional changes than binding

targets or expectations, as the thrust of the Desk's operational
approach has been to provide significant liquidity to relieve the
turbulence and tension in the wake of the financial market

upheaval.

At the same time, it was not meant to be a totally

unlimited flood of reserves--we have sought to relate our
provisions to the standard framework though in quite flexible
fashion.

Thus, we have been making a generous allowance for what

we believe to be substantially enlarged excess reserve desires.
So far in this period, through Sunday, borrowing has averaged a
little over $300 million while Fed funds averaged about 6-7/8
percent.
Early in the period, the postponement of a Treasury
bill auction because of debt ceiling constraints forced the
System to run off a $3.7 billion holding of Treasury bills.

This

was partly offset by outright purchases of about $1.4 billion of
bills and notes from foreign accounts in varying day-to-day
amounts.

Meantime, except for a few days in early October, the

Desk has arranged repurchase agreements for its own or customer
accounts each business day.

From October 15 through 30, the

repos done each day were for the Federal Reserve's own account.
Yesterday we arranged a moderate volume of customer repos.

Total

System repos over the period came to $102 billion while another
$20 billion was done for customer account.

On several occasions

the Desk entered the market an hour or more earlier than usual to
underscore its intention to provide liquidity, and on one
occasion we notified dealers the previous afternoon that System
repos would be arranged the following morning.
Through about mid-October, most interest rates pushed
higher, responding, at least in part, to perceptions or

expectations of firmer monetary policies in the U.S. and some
other major countries.

Expectations of discount rate increases

in the U.S. and abroad were widespread, while official comments
to the effect that inflation fears were overblown seemed to have
little calming effect.

Reported inflation rates remained

moderate while business news continued to suggest a moderate to
somewhat strengthening pace of advance.

More unsettling to the

markets, it seemed, was the continuing prospect that the dollar
would be under downward pressure in coming months, given the
discouragingly high international payments deficit.

There was

particular disappointment in the reported trade deficit for
August, published October 14, showing a much smaller than
expected narrowing from the July record.

A further point of

concern was the sense of lessened international cooperation in
dealing with world financial problems.

Some satisfaction was

taken in the Congress's passage of Gramm-Rudman budget deficit
restraints (along with action to lift the debt ceiling), and with
the President's willingness, after a little delay, to sign the
measure, but a good deal of skepticism soon returned as to how
meaningful the budget reduction plans would prove to be.
Indicative of the broad upward rate move, the yield on 30-year
Treasury bonds pushed above 10.40 percent by mid-October,
compared with 9.62 just before the last meeting.

The 3-month

bill rate had climbed to about 7.30 percent compared with about
6.50 before the last meeting.

Banks generally raised their prime

rates by 1/2 percentage point to 9-1/4 percent in early October

and several banks posted a further 1/2 percent rise toward midmonth.
All of these developments were part of the background
for the dramatic stock market collapse on October 19.

It should

be noted, though, that the stock market had already lost ground
through September and early October, with the popular DJ index
off 17-1/2 percent from its late August high through October 16.
The 500 point plunge on the 19th (a further 22-1/2 percent drop)
saw extremely heavy trading--about double the previous record
volume for a day--and noticeably changed the economic and
financial climate.

Not only were estimates on the economic

growth outlook revised significantly lower but also there were
widespread concerns about the very functioning of the financial
system as worries developed that steep losses would disable major
market participants.
In the changed market environment, aided as well by the
Federal Reserve's statements and actions with respect to
liquidity, market rates

fell sharply and more than reversed the

rise earlier in the period.

Government securities benefited not

only from a sense of more accommodative monetary policy and a
softer economic outlook, but also from a flight to quality as
many investors switched from equities to fixed income issues, and
within the fixed income area to higher grade securities.

Earlier

in the period, as noted, concern that the dollar would weaken was
a significant negative for the bond market.

Later, when the

dollar did decline appreciably, the effect on the bond market was

relatively muted--apparently because in the changed environment a
softer dollar was deemed less likely to produce an immediate
policy tightening.

Some dollar-bond market linkage does remain,

however, if only because a weaker dollar is seen as discouraging
foreign participation in our market.
Again citing the 30-year Treasury bond, that yield
plummeted from over 10.40 percent in mid-October to around 9-1/8
percent by the period's end, and for a time the yield fell below
The 3-month bill, a particularly favorite storm

9 percent.

shelter, plunged from 7.30 to below 5 percent at one point.

As

the stock market turbulence abated and prices recovered somewhat,
the flight to quality also subsided, and 3-month bills closed
yesterday around 5.65 percent while the newly auctioned 3-month
issue was around 5.80 this morning.
The few banks that had raised their prime rate to 9-3/4
at mid-October quickly reversed that move, and later in the month
banks generally lowered their prime rate 1/4 percent to 9
percent.

One bank went back down to 8-3/4 yesterday.

In the

corporate market, rates had moved up along with Treasury rates
early in the period, but the subsequent decline has been less
steep, thus widening the yield spread of higher grade corporates
to Treasuries by some 20-50 basis points, depending on maturity
and quality.

Lower grade corporate issues were hit particularly

hard, first by the rate rise and then by the stock market plunge,
and remain in quite feeble condition.

Tax-exempts also showed

less of a yield decline than Treasury issues after mid-October.

This sector was also jolted by announced cutbacks in market
participation by some major underwriting firms.
In addition to providing substantial day-to-day
liquidity to the market, the Federal Reserve has also assisted
the Treasury market by relaxing some of the constraints on our
temporary lending of Treasury securities.

With Committee

approval, we suspended the per issue and per dealer limits on the
amount of loans as well as the requirement that loans not be made
to facilitate a short sale.

Loans, of course, continue to be

collateralized by Treasury issues of greater market value.

Use

of the liberalized lending program has in fact been relatively
moderate, largely because the System has only modest holdings of
the issues in tightest supply.

Given continued supply shortages

and nervousness in the market about the volume of fails, I
believe it is useful to continue the more liberal lending rules
for a while longer.

Apart from the lending, we have also sought

to alleviate market concerns--and our own concerns--about ongoing
market development with a more comprehensive and timely
monitoring of exposures in the when-issued market for Treasuries.
This refers to the increased exposures incurred in volatile
markets in trading securities a number of days in advance of
delivery, including trades through the brokers' market.

We are

also monitoring the fail situation more closely in certain
particularly scarce issues, and are working with the dealer
community to explore possibilities for reducing outstanding
delivery "fails" through some sort of netting procedures.

Finally, we've been encouraging market participants to free up
scarce issues and have sought to encourage banks and other major
lenders of funds or securities not to act too hastily in pulling
back from customary counterparty relationships--asking them to
keep in mind the functioning of the system as a whole as well as
their own prudential concerns.

Obviously, it's a delicate line

to walk!
We have, of course, been closely monitoring the
financial health of dealers, and keeping in close touch with such
official regulators as the SEC, NASD, CFTC, NY Stock Exchange and
Treasury.

A number of firms have incurred losses in the recent

period, but at least among primary dealers we're not at present
aware of life-threatening losses.

Some of the more significant

ones have been publicly reported.

Generally, they related to the

equity market activity of diversified firms.

A few small firms--

not including any primary dealers--have closed up or
substantially contracted operations.
Returning finally to current market views on monetary
policy, as might be expected there is a fairly wide range now,
both as to where we are and where we might be headed.

Some

participants had looked for more dramatic and overt easing moves
in the immediate wake of the stock market plunge, but that view
seems to be fading now as people wait a clearer fix on the broad
economic effects.

The current more accommodative stance is seen

by some as likely to lead to a funds rate settling in around 7
percent; others, perhaps a majority, would expect rates more

consistently somewhat below than above that level.

Only a few, I

think, look for rates significantly lower, and few see any early
return to the higher rates of several weeks ago, although some
voices express concern about longer-run consequences of too much
ad hoc liquidity.

A consensus, I suppose, is that the situation

is still seen as fluid, with traditional "objectives" either in
abeyance or subject to short run change as the market situation
evolves.

FOMC BRIEFING -- THE ECONOMIC OUTLOOK

MICHAEL J. PRELL
NOVEMBER 3, 1987

As you know, all of the data received since the last Committee
meeting relate to the performance of the economy prior to the recent
financial upheaval.

Those data were in broad conformity with the pattern

of developments anticipated by our previous forecast: output was growing
briskly, paced by strong real exports and domestic capital spending; price
inflation was below the first-half rate, while wage inflation was showing
the first tentative signs of picking up.
But all that now is history.

In approaching the task of putting

together a forecast for this meeting, I was inclined to lament those
earlier times when we described the outlook as being "clouded by unusual
uncertainties."

One clearly is well advised to save such phrases for when

they are truly needed.
After initially questioning whether a quantitative forecast would
be sensible in the present circumstances, we decided that we should take a
stab at it, if only to offer a reference point for your discussions.

It

seemed reasonable to assume that the drop in stock prices would have a
negative effect of some magnitude on aggregate demand, and we sought to
adjust our previous projection on that basis.
The result was a forecast of real GNP growth of about 2 percent
at an annual rate over the next five quarters, a little more than 1/2
point below our previous projection.

At the same time, the projected

-2

-

pickup in inflation has been moderated by about a quarter point, with the
1988 rise in GNP prices now put at 4-1/4 percent.
The adjustment to the forecast would have been considerably
larger had we not assumed that monetary policy will cushion the shock from
the stock market plunge.

Our projection now includes a decline in short-

term interest rates of around a percentage point over the next six months,
rather than the rise of comparable magnitude contained in the previous
forecast.

Moreover, our presumption that this easing action will not be

matched abroad led us to lower somewhat further our path for the dollar,
thereby providing a little added boost to net exports.

Just how far the

dollar might fall--and how fast--in these circumstances was, to be sure, a
key uncertainty in the outlook; the events of the past few days seem to be
resolving those uncertainties on the side of faster.
Pinning down the effects of stock price movements on demand isn't
an easy matter.

Conventional econometric models like those used here at

the Board, rooted in the life-cycle theory of consumption, suggest that as
household net worth falls relative to income, the personal saving rate
should tend to rise.

Translated into numbers, our model says a $1 drop in

stock market wealth will cut around a nickel from consumer spending.
Some skepticism has been expressed about such results because a
sizable portion of household stock holdings are indirect--through pension
funds, for example--and because direct holdings are highly concentrated.
But that concentration doesn't rule out a substantial effect on spending,
so long as the wealthy do adjust their lifestyles to their financial
resources.

And the events of recent years probably have, if anything,

heightened people's awareness of the potential implications of changes in

-3

-

the value of their indirect holdings; I have in mind the publicity about
pension funding and the increasing use of defined contribution pension
plans, 401(k)s, and so on.

In this regard, you may have noted the reports

of an episode last Friday, that illustrates the subtle ways in which the
stock market drop could affect the economy, even on the supply side.
Lockheed Aircraft evidently experienced hundreds of early retirements,
because Friday was the last day employees could cash out their thrift plan
holdings based on a September 30 valuation.
And even if the effects of the stock market on a large part of
the population are primarily psychological, the magnitude of the recent
drop and the heavy media attention to its international scope must raise
the odds of significant adverse shock effect.

National surveys taken late

last month did in fact point to a sudden drop in household confidence in
the business outlook.

I suspect, also, that even if the market recovers

moderately in the coming year, as we've assumed, shareholders will respond
to the recent experience by applying a greater mental haircut to their
stock portfolios when they gauge their permanent wealth.
Our forecast is, in this context, a moderate one, in that we have
assumed that the August stock market highs were not fully incorporated in
consumer expectations.

And, while we have projected a relatively prompt

response of demand to the stock plunge, we have not assumed that the
effects are magnified by any extraordinary psychological damage.
It is lower consumption, especially on discretionary purchases of
autos and other durables, that accounts for the major share of the
reduction in the forecasted level of GNP, especially in the next several
months.

In time, business capital spending takes a hit, too; this

-

4 -

primarily reflects the "accelerator" influence flowing from weaker
consumer demand, for lower interest rates offset the financing cost effect
of the lower stock price path.

State and local revenue losses put a small

dent in government spending, while housing is buoyed by the reduction in
mortgage rates.

As I noted earlier, real net exports also look a bit

better, partly because of the exchange rate effect on U.S. competitiveness, but also because of the effect of weaker domestic demand on the
volume of imports.
The lower output path results, in our projection, in a small
backup in the unemployment rate.

It is primarily that development that

explains the trimming in the wage inflation forecast.

It is conceiv-

able that, if economic uncertainties are perceived to be heightened, it
will give employers some enhanced leverage in dealing with wage demands;
however, real wages already have been considerably eroded and are likely
to continue to be by rising import prices, so we are still looking for an
acceleration in nominal wages in the year ahead.

The price picture could

worsen relative to our projection if the current deficit reduction effort
puts heavy weight on excise taxes, but at this point we have no special
insights into how that exercise between the Congress and the President
will turn out.

This is, of course, a disturbing uncertainty in a number

of respects, when one considers how much attention has been focused here
and abroad on the outcome of those deliberations.

We've in essence

assumed that a way will be found to avoid the Gramm-Rudman sequester, and
that total deficit reducing actions for FY 1988--including asset sales-will somewhat exceed the required $23 billion.

I suppose I'd have to

characterize us as agnostic on the question of whether a major multi-year

- 5 package will be assembled, but a failure to achieve that probably would
not come as a shock to a skeptical financial community.

FOMC Briefing
Donald L. Kohn
November 3, 1987
The stock market collapse has created a number of uncertainties for
monetary policy.

Chief among them are those discussed by Mike--that is what

will be the effect on spending and inflation from the stock price decline.

On the financial side, interest rates and money and credit flows are likely to
be affected by shifting demands for liquidity and safety, potentially distorting

a number of the usual indicators of the underlying thrust of policy and its
interaction with the economy.

And the dollar and its relationship to domestic

financial developments may also be affected by the consequences of the equity
market decline.
This state of financial markets will be a key factor influencing these
indicators and the response of the real economy, as well as bearing directly
on the conduct of policy.

In preparing background materials for this meeting,

the staff's working hypothesis was that the functioning of these markets
would continue to return more toward normal, with the most extreme fears and
reactions that produced outsized price movements and extraordinary transactions
volumes abating further.

However, some residual volitility and caution would

remain, reflecting a heightened sensitivity of market participants to incoming
information about the economy, markets, and their counterparties, and the
fundamental price movements in the stock and bond markets would not be reversed.
For interest rates,

this is seen as implying the same realignment of rates,

with yield spreads between government and private instruments narrowing,
though not to the levels of last summer; under the current conditions
assumption of alternative B this narrowing probably would be accomplished
largely by a rise in Treasury yields, especially at the short end, as an
unchanged federal funds rate tended to anchor interest rates to private
borrowers.

-2-

The outlook for money growth in these circumstances is subject to a
number of cross currents.

Among the usual factors affecting money demand,

market interest rates have declined, and with deposit offering rates likely
to lag as usual, opportunity costs are expected to remain appreciably below
levels earlier in the fall.

This would have its largest impact on flows

into M1 and other liquid components,

potentially boosting their growth quite

substantially as the effects of earlier increases in opportunity costs fade.
On the other hand, slower income growth and a decline in wealth should act
over time to depress demands for money.
In addition, two special factors related to recent market
developments may be augmenting demands for money, at least temporarily.
One of these is the effect on transactions balances of the
surge in financial transactions.

Ordinarily the turnover in stock and bond

markets--even when very high--would not be expected to affect transactions
balances, given the sophistication of those involved.

The jump in demand

deposits in the second half of October coincided with the price movements
themselves, suggesting that it may have geen generated in part by margin
payments rather than only by needs at settlement, which routinely occurs
with some lag.

In our projections, demand deposits related to this factor

drop off rather quickly, damping growth of M2 as well as M1 in November and
December but with little

net effect on money growth measured from September

to December--the period used in bluebook specifications.

The second factor

is the impact of any increase in demands for liquidity and safety.
there is only limited evidence of such a shift.
strong.

So far,

Currency demands have been

In addition, assets of money market mutual funds rose sharply in the

week the market plunged, but it may be too soon to tell whether this is the

-3precursor of further subsequent large increases or only temporarily related
to one-time transfers from stock mutual funds.

A much smaller increase in

the funds was registered in the week after the crash.

In the bluebook paths

we have allowed for some unusual demands for liquidity.

The 6 percent growth

of M2 in the fourth quarter under alternative B is around one percentage
point more than would be predicted by money demand models.

Reflecting

transaction effects during October on M1 growth, the projected expansion of
the aggregate on a quarterly average basis is even stronger relative to the
econometric results.
Under our usual operating procedures,

any shifts in demands for

money deriving from financial transactions or liquidity preferences would be
accommodated by the Desk, as would seem appropriate.

That is,

increased

demands for reserves associated with higher money balances would be automatically
met through open market operations to keep borrowing at a given level.

This

would also insulate the federal funds market, unless the increase in liquidity
demands also affected attitudes toward the discount window.
Judgments about the level of borrowing or the federal funds rate
at which such an accommodation might occur depend importantly on an assessment
of the economy and risks in the outlook following the the developments of
recent weeks.
Alternative B would retain the easing that has occurred since the
stock market collapse with borrowing of $450 million and federal funds trading
expected to center just below 7 percent.

The decline in rates relative to

several weeks ago can be seen as at least an initial step in adapting policy
to the damping of spending and fall in inflation expectations that seem
likely to have resulted from recent events.

Given all the uncertainties

about the outlook, alternative B could be viewed as a holding action, pending
receipt of additional information about the economy and financial markets.

-4If the Committee felt the risks were on the side of weakness in the economy,
this could be accommodated through a tilt

toward ease in the language

concerning the intermeeting adjustments.

A need for such ease might be

signaled in financial markets by further sharp declines in stock prices or
long-term rates or even weakness in money growth, as well as by incoming
economic and price data.
If

the recessionary risks to the economy or structural risks to

financial markets were considered to be sufficiently large, a further
easing at this time as under alternative A, might be considered appropriate.
In some respects this alternative is consistent with the staff GNP forecast,
which, as Mike has noted, presumes a further noticeable easing at some point.
While any additional easing might put further pressure on the dollar, the
repercussions of this for inflation expectations or the bond markets would
be muted if market participants also saw the outlook as weak, with little
sign of price pressures.

The current term structure of interest rates does

not suggest strong expectations of an easing of policy, but one suspects
that market expectations are not very firmly held these days, and the
response to further ease will very much depend on the surrounding circumstances.
Alternative C in the bluebook involves only a slight tightening
of policy, leaving borrowing below where it was after the last FOMC meeting.
While even a mild tightening at this time might seem difficult to contemplate,
the possibility that such a move might have to be considered at some point
over the intermeeting period cannot be ruled out, if for example there were
a general flight from dollar assets, and indications of significant inflationary
pressures arising therefrom.

Of course, this possibility could be dealt with

by retaining a tightening option in the language on intermeeting adjustments.

In any case, the uncertainties involved not only with the economic
outlook, but with interpreting developments in financial flows and markets
would seem to call for some degree of continued flexibility in the implementation of policy over coming weeks.

Recently, such operations have been

keyed toward a fairly open-ended provision of liquidity, with reference at
least as much to the federal funds rate and market conditions, especially
in the RP market, as to the formal borrowing objectives.

This has been

necessary in a crisis period in which the underlying demands for liquidity
in markets has been uncertain and in which markets needed clear signals
about policy intentions.
they can be a little

A characteristic of borrowing objectives is that

ambiguous in their implications for interest rates.

Operating under such an objective, the level of the federal funds rate may
be affected not only by borrowing, but by changes in the willingnesss of
depository institutions to be seen at the discount window, and by temporary
shifts in market expectations,
unanticipated changes
times,

in demands for short-term funding, or in

in desires to hold excess reserves.

In more usual

changes in the funds rate may have important information for the

Federal Reerve about underlying market forces or expectations, which is
lost when markets realize we are trying to control interest rate.

Those

forces frequently have, in effect, moved the rate in a stabilizing direction,
anticipating the next move in policy.

Focussing on the funds rate can impart

rigidity and inertia to the conduct of policy.
Market conditions remain quite sensitive, and among the uncertainties
is the relationship between borrowing and the federal funds rate.

But as

conditions stabalize and that relationship clarifies, the Committee may

-6want to consider how and under what conditions it wants to return to its
previous approach to policy implementation.
Variant I of the directive also attempts to take into account
explicitly the possible need for flexibility in meeting liquidity needs and
conducting policy over the intermeeting period, along with the possibility
of more frequent consultations in such circumstances.

At the same time,

it would allow for a transition back toward more normal operating procedures
if market conditions warranted.