View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee
November 12, 1997

A meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee was held in the offices of the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System in Washington, D.C., on Wednesday, November 12, 1997,
at 9:00 a.m.

PRESENT:

Mr. Greenspan, Chairman
Mr. McDonough, Vice Chairman
Mr. Broaddus
Mr. Ferguson
Mr. Gramlich
Mr. Guynn
Mr. Kelley
Mr. Meyer
Mr. Moskow
Mr. Parry
Ms. Phillips
Ms. Rivlin
Messrs. Hoenig, Jordan, Melzer, and Ms. Minehan, Alternate
Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
Messrs. Boehne, McTeer, and Stern, Presidents of the Federal
Reserve Banks of Philadelphia, Dallas, and Minneapolis
respectively
Mr. Kohn, Secretary and Economist
Mr. Bernard, Deputy Secretary
Mr. Coyne, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Gillum, Assistant Secretary
Mr. Mattingly, General Counsel
Mr. Baxter, Deputy General Counsel
Mr. Prell, Economist
Mr. Truman, Economist
Messrs. Cecchetti, Goodfriend, Eisenbeis, Lindsey, Promisel,
Slifman, and Stockton, Associate Economists
Mr. Fisher, Manager, System Open Market Account

11/12/97
Messrs. Madigan and Simpson, Associate Directors, Divisions of
Monetary Affairs and Research and Statistics respectively,
Board of Governors
Messrs. Alexander and Hooper, and Ms. Johnson, Associate
Directors, Division of International Finance, Board of
Governors
Ms. Low, Open Market Secretariat Assistant, Division of
Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Ms. Pianalto and Mr. Rives, First Vice Presidents, Federal Reserve
Banks of Cleveland and St. Louis respectively
Messrs. Dewald, Hakkio, Rolnick, and Sniderman, Senior Vice
Presidents, Federal Reserve Banks of St. Louis, Kansas City,
Minneapolis, and Cleveland respectively
Messrs. Bentley, Meyer, and Rosengren, Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of New York, Philadelphia, and Boston
respectively
Ms. Gonczy and Mr. Koenig, Assistant Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Chicago and Dallas respectively
Mr. Trehan, Research Officer, Federal Reserve Bank of San
Francisco

Transcript of Federal Open Market Committee Meeting
November 12, 1997

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I would like to welcome Governors Ferguson and
Gramlich to their first meeting and offer a preliminary farewell to President Melzer. We will do
the farewell more officially at the next meeting.
MR. MELZER. Thanks, Alan.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Why don't we get started. I request that someone move
to approve the minutes.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. So move.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Peter Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I will be referring to the
package of charts that should be in front of you.' It has a Class I cover and
begins with a color chart showing 3-month deposit rates. Today I will be
going over four distinct subjects. To give you a roadmap: First, I will
discuss market developments in general, focusing particularly on some of the
causes of events in Hong Kong. Second, I will discuss recent open market
operations. Third, I would like to take a few minutes to bring the Committee
up-to-date on the performance of primary dealers. I think it is important for
me to give you a sense of what I have been doing with the dealer community.
After that, I will be seeking two votes. One is the normal vote to ratify the
open market operations since the September meeting. I also will be asking
for an increase in the intermeeting leeway. After that, I will come back and
comment on the swap line renewals, which are a separate agenda item. I will
seek a vote to renew the swap agreements for another year.
Focusing on market developments, the first page of charts shows
3-month deposit rates, including the current rate, 3-month forward, 6-month
forward, and 9-month forward for the United States, Germany, and Japan. In
the first panel, you can see that interest rate expectations began to back up here
in the United States following the Chairman's testimony before the Budget
Committee on October 8. The next day, the Bundesbank hiked their repo rate
by 30 basis points, as you can see in the middle panel. To many people in
financial markets around the world, this indicated, perhaps inaccurately, a
concerted effort by the industrial nations to raise interest rates globally. Many
1 Copies of the charts used by Mr. Fisher are appended to this transcript.

11/12/97

people talked very seriously about how the tide had turned and interest rates
could be expected to go higher in the industrial world. Both in Germany and
the United States, rates continued to back up for several days until the events
beginning on October 23, a date I will come back to in a minute. That was the
day when financial pressures first emerged most acutely in Hong Kong. You
can see that interest rate expectations in both the United States and Germany
came off rather sharply beginning that Thursday, October 23, and bottomed out
on the day of the sharpest U.S. equity market decline the following Monday,
October 27. Forward rate markets were already stabilizing to some extent, at
least here, by the time of the Chairman's testimony before the Joint Economic
Committee on October 29.
I would like to note that U.S. interest rate expectations, as measured by
the forward rate agreements, did not subsequently back up. They stabilized
more or less at levels slightly above the lows reached before the Chairman's
October 8 testimony, whereas German interest rate expectations, reflecting a
rise that occurred in market rates, are still quite a bit higher. I think this goes
a long way toward explaining the relative movements in the dollar and the
mark. One does not need to look anywhere else even though many financial
market analysts are looking under every rock and in every nook and cranny.
You can see in the bottom panel that Japanese interest rates, as measured by
forward rate agreements, are still quite flat. I will come back in a moment to
some events leading up to this morning's developments in Tokyo.
Turning to the charts on page 2, I will focus on the causation of the
events in Hong Kong, or as the Chairman sometimes puts it, a discussion of
who sneezed last. This discussion is not necessarily to point a finger at
anyone but to delineate the series of events that led up to the financial
pressures. The first panel shows the percent changes in the foreign exchange
value of the Taiwan dollar, the South Korean won, and the Hong Kong dollar
since September 30. The middle panel shows 1-month interbank rates for
Taiwan, South Korea, and Hong Kong, and the bottom panel shows percent
changes in key equity indices for those countries and for the United States,
Japan, and Brazil.
Working across the top panel--the Hong Kong government announced
in early October that they would hold another land auction. This is a more or
less routine event for them, but the announcement did indicate they were
coming back to the market and would be putting some pressure on land
prices. They held the auction several days later, on October 15, and found a
bogus bid for one of the largest parcels of land that were up for sale. The
bid was made by a woman in the name of a major firm and she certainly did
not have the billions of dollars necessary to purchase the real estate. The

11/12/97
Hong Kong authorities are reviewing their practices for accepting bids, but it
was rather shocking to think that an auction for this kind of real estate could
involve someone who was a mental patient, quite literally.
Several days later, Taiwan ceased intervening in the exchange market
and allowed its currency to depreciate significantly. This posed a question in
the minds of many foreign exchange market participants the world over--a
profound question. If a country with such a high level of foreign exchange
reserves was not prepared to defend its currency, who would? The Taiwan
government certainly had the capacity to defend their exchange rate, but it
turned out they did not have the will. The question in everyone's mind after
Taiwan's decision was whether the People's Republic of China, and not so
much Hong Kong, would need to devalue. For many people the answer to
that question appeared to come when, on October 23 or late in the evening of
October 22, the People's Bank of China announced a reduction in interest
rates. They reduced their lending rate by 150 basis points and their savings
rate by a little more than 100 basis points. This appeared to answer the
question for many people by showing that China was worried about their
competitiveness. The markets very quickly tried to price that in, but they
could not price it into the yuan. The only place it can be priced is in a proxy
for the yuan, the Hong Kong dollar. So, the pressures began to build and you
can see in the middle column that the Hong Kong monetary authorities
squeezed their money market rather tightly. I don't think they expected
overnight interest rates to go to 300 percent. They expected the rise to be
considerably less than that, but there were a number of players who held onto
long positions hoping to make money in subsequent days. In the bottom
panel, you can see them play through to the equity markets, with whose
performance you are familiar.
Turning to the third page of charts, I want to draw your attention to the
impact of these developments in credit markets. While equity markets had
some sharp losses, the real fear and adjustment that took place in financial
markets seemed to be, as I heard it, in the credit markets. In the first panel,
you can see that absolute spreads of Asian Yankee and stripped Brady Bonds
over U.S. Treasuries backed up rather considerably. These are measured in
hundreds of basis points. The backup was more or less triggered by the
pressures on October 23 and thereafter, obviously with many contributing
events. In the middle panel, in order to get the scaling right, I simply have
the basis point changes in two Merrill Lynch corporate bond indices, one for
high yield and one for investment grade, over Treasuries since September 30.
Clearly, there has been some widening of spreads over Treasuries. What is
worth noting is that the corporate yields have not moved at all; it is the
Treasuries that have moved. As shown in the bottom panel, 10- and 30-year

11/12/97
rates were down 20 basis points over this period, and that was the full extent
of the backup, the widening of the spread if you will, both to junk and
investment grade paper. It was very hard to chart in the bottom panel how
odd the bond market has felt over the last few days because there has been a
tortuous back and forth between those who want to trade on fundamentals
and the flight to quality that seems to be taking place. I cannot show you last
Friday's developments in a chart because the adjustments happened so
quickly. Following the release of the employment data last Friday, bond
market and fed funds futures backed up and then, after about 90 seconds,
came right back down as the market returned to its flight-to-credit posture.
The fourth page displays three charts to make a very simple point.
Each panel shows the percent changes in one of the G3 currencies against the
other two G3 currencies. In the first panel, you can see that the mark has
appreciated against both the dollar and the yen since September 1. In the
middle panel, you can see that the yen has depreciated against both the dollar
and the mark. And in the bottom panel, you can see that the dollar is being
pulled somewhat in two directions. That is, it is considerably weaker against
the mark but a little stronger against the yen, the dollar having been stable for
most of this period.
I want to go back to what I referred to earlier, namely, that I think
interest rate differentials between the United States and Germany explain
most of the movement between the dollar and the mark, although market
participants do look eagerly at the question of whether there is a flight out of
dollars into marks and whether the mark is something of a safe haven. I
think it is reasonable to pause and note that in terms of financial flows, there
probably was some movement out of dollars, given how many of the assets
that have been under pressure are dollar-denominated. So, when portfolio
managers sustained losses on Bradys and Asian Yankees and equities that are
more or less dollar-linked, there was going to be some marginal movement
out of the dollar. That is a very different question from one about the
macroeconomic consequences; this is a financial flows issue. I think Ted
Truman will be coming back to the broader macroeconomic question.
Let me pause here to discuss some of the events of the last few days in
Tokyo. The yen has weakened overnight; it was below 126 this morning.
The Japanese government bond yield is up to 1.70 percent after backing up
10 basis points in just a few days. A week ago, with the announced
bankruptcy of Sanyo, a very profound event happened in Japanese financial
history: The authorities let a major firm go bankrupt. It is something our
colleagues at the Bank of Japan have been working on earnestly for 10 years
and are very proud of. Obviously, the timing was another matter. It took the

11/12/97
markets a few days to begin to price it in. But the number of financial
market participants around the world who have been trading with Japanese
counterparties on the assumption that the government stood behind them is
very large. By Friday of last week, some Japanese names, the weaker ones,
were finding it hard to get quoted in the forward interest rate market in New
York. Today, people are talking about Japanese institutions needing to
liquidate government bonds. The Nikkei was off 434 points earlier and is
now down again. We see a grinding out of some of the worst fears one might
have about the Japanese financial sector. That is beginning to show up in
forward rate markets. For example, in the Euro deposit market as of the end
of October, there was no credit premium in the 3-month rate for Japanese
institutions. This morning, it is already 250 basis points as compared to zero
at the end of October.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. 250 basis points?
MR. FISHER. Excuse me I should have said 25 basis points. I am very sorry. I'm
trying to catch up with everything that happened overnight.
On that note, let me turn to domestic open market operations and try to
get my numbers right. On the fifth page, there are two panels illustrating
developments in the federal funds market. The top panel shows the behavior
of the federal funds rate. The blue lines indicate the daily range of actual
trading, the red vertical lines depict one standard deviation of funds rate
trading on either side of the effective rate, the horizontal red line is the daily
effective rate, and the green dotted line is the Committee's target. In the
upper right of the sub panels for each of the three full maintenance periods,
you can see the period average effective rate. In the lower panel of the chart,
the blue bars show the daily level of free reserves, and the numbers on top of
each of the bars indicate our daily projection misses. There is one exception
related to a labeling problem that I will come back to in a moment.
The intermeeting interval unfolded more or less as we had expected. In
the first biweekly period, September 30, the last day of the quarter, was a
difficult day in the market. The market priced up for that statement date,
initially producing a high rate, and we came in a little later in the day and
added quite a few reserves. That resulted in a very wide standard deviation
in the federal funds rate on September 30. On the last day of the middle
period, the settlement day, the very tall blue bar, is labeled 9.9; that number
does not indicate the size of our miss; it refers to the level of the bar, which
was cut off at the top of the chart. Our miss that day was only 0.3. This was
a day when we supplied quite a few reserves to the market, but given the

11/12/97
skewing up in the rate, we underestimated a bit the demand for excess during
this period. Actually, the point I want to make, which we describe in our
written report, is that the demand for excess reserves has been growing. We
target demand for excess reserves of $1 billion in each reserve maintenance
period on a period average basis, but actual demand has been creeping up on
us. Independent of the turmoil of the last few weeks, the rising demand for
excess reserves is in all likelihood a function of declining operating balances.
Bankers appear to be looking for a little more excess reserves, but this is
something that we are still looking into.
In the final period, you can see that we did have to deal a little with the
effects of the large volume of trading in equities. The largest volume day
was on October 28, and with a 3-day settlement, the settlement of that trading
fell on October 31. That was a month-end, already a slightly complicated
day for us. We more or less had a day that looked like a maintenance period
settlement day where we had to add a sizable amount of reserves and the
funds market had a quite wide standard deviation.
Stepping back, I would like to ask the Committee for an increase in
intermeeting leeway to purchase securities on an outright basis during the
intermeeting period between now and the December meeting. The temporary
increase would be from $8 billion to $12 billion. We began another sequence
of outright coupon purchases last week. We have a significant amount to
execute going forward. We estimate that our holdings will need to grow
about $15 billion by the maintenance period ending around the time of the
Committee's next meeting and that the cumulative need will increase to up to
$20 billion in the period immediately following the December meeting. I
would like to complete the portion we are planning to do on an outright basis
in the market before we get that late in the year. So, by the time of the
December meeting, I expect to want to add around $10 or $11 billion
through outright operations, principally in coupon securities. However,
given that the Treasury issuance of bills seems to be increasing somewhat, I
also hope to buy some bills a little later this month or early in December.
Before turning to your questions and your vote, I would like to talk to
you for a few minutes about the performance of the primary dealers, as
shown on your next page. I will try to go through some of the background on
our primary dealer relations.
Criteria for primary dealers were revised in February 1992, as most
members of the Committee will recall. At that time, we identified some
drawbacks in the existing system. We described as one drawback the public
impression that because the Federal Reserve Bank sets standards for selecting

11/12/97

and maintaining these relationships, the Fed was in effect the regulator of the
primary dealer firms. Another drawback was that the primary dealer
designation was viewed as conferring a special status on these firms in that it
carried with it elements of franchise value. As a consequence, we dropped
the requirement in 1992 that dealers maintain a 1 percent share of total
customer activity. We also discontinued our dealer surveillance activities,
which had led to the impression that we were supervising the dealers. In
1992, we also reiterated our standards for maintaining dealer status. All
primary dealers were told that as in the past they were expected to (1) make
reasonably good markets in their trading relationships with the Fed's Trading
Desk, (2) participate meaningfully in Treasury auctions, and (3) provide the
Trading Desk with market analysis that could be useful to the Federal
Reserve in the formulation of monetary policy. Primary dealers that failed
to meet these standards in a meaningful way over time would have their
designation as primary dealers discontinued by the FRBNY. I think that
spells out, as I have been describing to the dealers, essentially six criteria that
we look at in judging our trading relations with the dealers. As listed at the
bottom of page 6, these include their performance relating to our RP
operations, our outright operations, the Treasury's bill and coupon auctions,
the Desk's trades on behalf of foreign central banks, and the provision of
information to the Desk.
Bluntly put, we have not succeeded in removing the "Good
Housekeeping" seal of approval. There are many customers in the market
who insist that they will only deal with primary dealers. There are
municipalities and other public bodies in this country that have such a
requirement in their enabling legislation, and many other customers follow
that practice informally. So, we have not been successful there. At the same
time, it has been hard to motivate dealers to perform. I frankly face
something of a moral hazard because there is no longer a volume
requirement. Previously, that was an easy thing for the dealers to measure.
They knew that if they maintained their volume, they would be kept on our
dealer list and that kept their minds focused.
What I had hoped to do is provide the dealers with report cards that
they could take home and share with their management and really understand
how we saw them. I then decided that I did not want to read about those in
the Wall Street Journal. So, we came up with a formula for sharing their
relative performance with them, at least on the first four criteria, without
giving them something they could take home. The following four charts give
you some sense of the performance of the individual dealer firms, though
they will not enable you to master the details.

11/12/97
The first panel shows primary dealer performance in financing Desk
transactions. The horizontal axis shows the percent of our volume in repo
operations that any one dealer actually does with us, that is, it measures the
propositions we accept. The vertical axis measures pricing competitiveness
in which zero represents the stop-out rate on our operations, that is, the
lowest rate at which we operate. Plus basis points indicate better yields we
earn and minus basis points measure poorer yields. The vertical axis reflects
all propositions, not just the ones we take. On average, we do not take most
propositions. For example, we may accept only $2 billion when we get $10
billion of propositions. So, on average most prices will fall below the
stop-out. As a first approximation, poor performance is reflected in the lower
left corner; strong performance appears in the upper right corner. However,
there is another twist. If a dealer firm is too much of an outlier and too eager
to price through the stop-out rate, that may say something about its ability to
finance elsewhere and whether there may be something of a credit risk
associated with its name. In some sense, if a firm is in the very lowest
quadrant, it is hard to know whether it has no business at all to be financed or
whether it simply has numerous internal sources of funding that are cheaper
than what we provide them. So, that is another element of interpretation on
this chart.
The next chart illustrates primary dealer performance in Desk outright
transactions. The horizontal axis again shows the percent of volume they
actually do with us. The vertical axis is in effect a pricing competitiveness
index in which zero in this case is a snapshot of the yield curve before we
operate. The prices we then see may give us more yield than the yield curve
or they may give us less yield. Again, the lower left in this chart indicates
poor performance, and obviously something more toward the upper right
indicates a stronger performance from our point of view.
The third and fourth charts show the dealer performance in Treasury
auctions for bill and coupon issues respectively. The horizontal axis
measures awards in their name as a percent of total tenders accepted by the
Treasury, and the vertical axis is a measure of their capital that both we and
the SEC use. We call it "liquid capital;" the SEC calls it "tentative net
capital." This chart again shows, more or less, that the lower left reflects a
weaker performance and the upper right a stronger performance. I chose to
show the information to the dealers in this form because it indicates that there
is not a very strong positive correlation on capital. That is, some dealers that
have relatively low capital can compete rather effectively in underwriting the
Treasury's debt. Their ability to do so is not just a matter of capital.

11/12/97

We have shown these charts to dealers in the last few weeks, but with
only their own name indicated and 38 black dots depicting the other dealers.
The charts provide a rather powerful indication of the absolute and the
relative performances of the individual dealers from where we sit. I tried to
calibrate my message to the dealers. When I showed them this information, I
was able to point to both 12-month data, which are depicted on these charts,
and four-quarter data, quarter by quarter, because trends were quite important
for some dealers. I told the dealers that my goal was to improve median
performance. I wanted better performance on their part. I was rather blunt
with eleven dealers in saying that they were not doing much to meet our
current business needs. Of that eleven, I told four flat out that they were not
meeting our business needs currently. However, I proposed that we work
together over the coming six months to enable them to describe to me their
intended business strategy for meeting my business needs and to make an
effort to do so. I will meet with them again two quarters from now to review
fourth-quarter and first-quarter data. I warned them that if they took no
initiative to describe to me how they intended to meet my business needs and
could show no performance over this period, we would discuss at our next
meeting in the spring whether they wished to announce the termination of
their dealer relationship with us or whether they wanted me to announce it.
As I noted, four of the dealers heard that message. Another seven heard a
message that they were near that category. I think they all understood it, and
they all thought the process was reasonable. Again, the pictures on these
charts are rather stark, and the dealers did not have much to argue about in
that sense.
I wanted the Committee to be aware of this process that I am going
through. I think it is reasonable but, obviously, I am sharing it with you to
solicit your views if you have any. I want to emphasize the sensitivity of
these data. I have assured the dealers that I was not going to share it
publicly, and I informed them that I did not want them to share it publicly. I
did not let them take copies with them, but I did let them take notes. I did not
want to read about it in the Wall Street Journal, and I am sure many of them
did not want to either.
Mr. Chairman, we have no foreign exchange operations to report for
this period. I need the Committee's ratification of our domestic open market
transactions. Separately, I would like to seek a vote to increase our
intermeeting leeway from $8 billion to $12 billion. I would be happy to
answer any questions on my report as well as on my memo about our desire
to publish the standard deviation of the federal funds rate for each trading
day.

11/12/97

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I must say that your endeavor to inform the primary
dealers of your likes or dislikes is creating a franchise value for them whether you like it or not.
I think the presumption that they are primary dealers and you are in fact making that an issue
makes it quite impossible to maintain simultaneously that there is no franchise value in their
being primary dealers.
MR. FISHER. I completely agree with you. It is a dilemma, and I think we are stuck
with that dilemma. I personally would rather take a hard look with the Treasury on whether the
primary dealer system makes sense in terms of underwriting Treasury debt issuance. The
Treasury still feels strongly, as it has for many years, that the existing system is important. So,
they wish to retain it. We are going to conduct our operations with someone, and until we can
get to the point where we do not publish a list of the firms we deal with, which is what I would
be happiest with, I think we are in a dilemma. It is very expensive for us to maintain relations
with 38 institutions, some of whom are deadbeats from our perspective. We could create a
two-tier system. I would be happy to talk to the Committee about that. It would involve our
ignoring a lot of firms that provide no value to us but that might continue to sit on our list.
Unfortunately, that does not foster very good performance from anybody. That is the nature of
the dilemma. We get poor performance from everybody or a franchise value, which sets up the
dilemma.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. You mentioned that the yuan was not an attackable
currency, which I have always assumed to be the case largely because it is an essentially illiquid,
controlled, and blocked currency. Can you conceive of any scenario whereby there could be an

11/12/97

11

international attack on that currency? I presume that would require a free market and some
ability to move funds, and I am not sure how that can be done in the yuan.
MR. FISHER. My colleagues and I have thought about that, and we have not come up
with a way that might be done directly. I think there are assets that could be sold-MR. TRUMAN. My guess is that that is the way it would happen. In fact, a country
can always experience the problem of domestic capital flight, of which there is a substantial
amount in China--on the order of $10 billion a year. Another way that domestic residents can
attack the currency is through classical, if I may call it that, leads and lags. There also are certain
foreign investment strategies that could be used. I do not think the yuan can be attacked in a
money market or financial market sense but--while it is much more difficult--pressure can
certainly be brought on yuan asset values, and in some sense that has been going on.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I have been out of contact. What happened in the
financial markets in Brazil and Argentina yesterday?
MR. TRUMAN. Not much happened in Brazil after they announced their program.
Rates were down marginally yesterday; stock markets were flat and are down a little today.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Was it the same in Argentina?
MR. TRUMAN. Yes, both cases.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. Just a question. If all the primary dealers reacted well to your
counseling, Peter, what would be the impact on our operations? What benefit would we see as a
result of that?

11/12/97
MR. FISHER. We would get better prices. We would earn more for the U.S.
taxpayer. We would have more flexibility in our operations the more propositions we received.
I very much hope to avoid the situation that we had in April when we had the large miss in
forecasting Treasury tax flows and an insufficient volume of propositions forced us to go back
into the market to purchase more securities. I want to see a healthier volume of propositions so
we can have much more flexibility. That is very important to me. Frankly, we can operate more
efficiently overall if we get better information from the dealers and they execute our trades more
expeditiously. Our costs should in some sense be covered by the value we produce as a trading
operation.
MS. MINEHAN. Looking at your first chart on primary dealer performance in Desk
financing transactions, that dotted line for the median is -1.8 basis points. Your desire is to move
that up to the stop-out rate?
MR. FISHER. No. In this case, what I would like to see is movement of the median
volume line to the right and a cluster of dealer performance around the intersection of the two
medians. Where the auction falls vis-a-vis the stop-out rate is really a matter of how much we
are doing because we want more propositions than we can use. Forgive me for my analogy, but I
would like to see what Pete Rozelle always said he wanted for the NFL, that on any given
Sunday, any football team could beat any other football team. I would like this money market
operation to be very competitive. We should have every dealer bidding at a reasonable price,
and that would give us the greatest flexibility. So, if we succeeded, we might move the median
volume line to between 2 and 3 percent or maybe all the way to 4 percent, with every one of 30
or 40 dealers getting a roughly equal share of volume. Maybe it would be a 2-1/2 or 3 percent

13

11/12/97

share, and the pricing could be in a tighter cluster on that chart. That is what I would be looking
for, and that is what I told the dealers.
MS. MINEHAN. So, you would like to move that intersection both up and out?
MR. FISHER. Out more than up is what I would expect.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Rivlin.
MS. RIVLIN. This question reflects my lack of understanding, but are you creating
any legal problems for us here? If a team is dropped from the league, can they sue the
commissioner?
MR. FISHER. I referred earlier to the paper that we put out in February 1992 to
establish the current ground rules. That paper indicated that the arrangements between us and
the dealers were business relationships and that we could terminate an individual arrangement if
no business relationship existed. There are a lot of lawyers in the country, and anyone who can
find a lawyer can sue. But I think that the dealers are on notice. I don't want to say that any of
the dealers were happy with the message I was giving them, but as businessmen they understood
it because I was able to document it in black and white. That is what I have been trying to do. I
felt there was no way I could come down hard on them unless I could show them something
concrete. As businessmen, I think they understood that. I have been taking this degree of care to
minimize the risk you are referring to.
MS. RIVLIN. You are a businessman, but they think of you as the government.
MR. FISHER. I have been working very hard for a couple of years in every meeting I
have had with the primary dealers to remind them that ours is a business relationship and that we
want them to treat us as a valued customer. I gave a speech about this business relationship to

14

11/12/97

the Bond Market Association in Phoenix in which I emphasized that they should treat us as a
valued customer, not as a mere regulator.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Did they sniff at that?
MR. FISHER. A little, but it is a language they understand.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. I think that, as a practical matter, the dealers
who decided they did not want to behave according to Peter's desires would probably decide
they did not want to be primary dealers. They would be very unlikely to bring attention to
themselves by suing us. That would be saying, "I have been deemed unacceptable, and I want
the whole world to know about it."
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Broaddus.
MR. BROADDUS. Peter, on the domestic bond markets, the yield spread between the
regular 10-year Treasury note and the inflation-indexed bond has diminished a little over the
intermeeting period. At first glance, that might normally be expected to imply a drop in
longer-term inflation expectations. But I am wondering whether in the flight to quality, more
funds have been directed to the regular nominal note than to the inflation-indexed bond. Would
that be part of what is going on?
MR. FISHER. Yes, I think that is right. I do not want to put too fine a point on it, but
I think most people in the market understand that. I don't think people have been making too
much of the shift in that spread. I agree with you.
MR. KOHN. It is true that the indexed bond went down several basis points,
particularly on the day of the sharp market break. So, I think there was a flight to both of the
securities. It had been our interpretation as well, at least for a while, that if investors were going

15

11/12/97

to get into something liquid, they would choose nominal bonds. But as markets settled over the
next few days--and they are still skittish and volatilities are still a bit higher than earlier--it struck
me that some of that effect would have played out. The fact that this spread may be down 10
basis points on net--and I may be reading this a little too finely--suggests, if anything, that
inflation expectations have come down. There is every reason to think that they might have. All
the external events were playing in that direction, and certainly the tone of the discussions in the
press and in the market was that events were having a disinflationary or even deflationary effect
on the U.S. economy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Melzer.
MR. MELZER. Thanks, Alan. Peter, on the issue of publishing the standard
deviation data, I have no objection to providing that additional information. I think it is probably
a good idea. I guess I would be concerned if I thought the Desk were going to use those data as a
measure of its performance and, specifically, if the Desk were to adopt the perspective that a
lower standard deviation in the funds rate indicates better performance. I say that because I think
we ought to want the market to act as a form of discipline on those banks that have not properly
provided for their reserve needs, particularly for settlements. Some degree of volatility is
desirable from that perspective.
MR. FISHER. I share your view about that. We have developed this measurement for
slightly different purposes. I find it very useful in talking to you about our operations, and I
think it may help you to judge what we are doing. That's how I think of the standard deviation.
As is illustrated in some of those charts, there will be days when the standard deviation is going
to be wide, and we can do nothing about it. It is on days when perhaps we could and should do

16

11/12/97

something about it that I want to focus my attention. The standard deviation does not tell me
anything automatically.
For a long time, people in the market have asked us to publish the underlying data that
we get on trades in the federal funds market. They want us to give them the actual data on how
many trades are done at each rate level. I am very uncomfortable with that, and I think other
people in the market also would be uncomfortable if we started doing that. The reason is that the
data might help market observers figure out who needed to do what volume. They could then
determine at what rates the trades were done even if the names of market participants were not
attached to what we published. I think the standard deviation data give the market a very good
sense of the volume done at various rates, and that matters to them in their effort to understand
trading activity. So, the information on the standard deviation is intended to give the market
something that is helpful to them in return for the statistical information that they provide to us.
I share your view on market volatility.
MR. KOHN. Both the Desk and the Board staff have been using the standard
deviation data for analytical purposes to see whether the character of the market is changing in
any way as reserve balances decline. There is no reason why the market cannot have the same
data for analytical purposes.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Stem.
MR. STERN. Peter, I have a couple of questions on the primary dealer situation. Is it
your impression that the performance of some of the dealers has deteriorated over time?
Secondly, what do we know about the profitability of their current operations?

11/12/97

MR. FISHER. I will respond to the second question first. The Desk collected
profitability data from the dealers for a long time. When I became Manager, I looked at that and
discontinued it. What we were getting was apples and oranges and kumquats. We had no
ability to insure that we were getting apples compared to apples from the dealers. The dealers
were very unhappy with that decision, but I felt that we should not be putting our name behind
something where they had not done the work to develop standard accounting conventions. I
viewed that as a very risky and potentially embarrassing situation for us.
MR. STERN. I assume that you get a sense of what is going on by talking to them.
MR. FISHER. Yes, and I want to distinguish two sorts of information that we get
from the dealers. From our conversations with the dealers, it is clear that there is some disparity
among the firms. There are some firms that are doing rather well and others that are not. What
also comes out in our conversations is that the nature of the underwriting process is changing.
Many of the dealers understand this. With the Treasury's use of Dutch auctions, they already
have been disintermediated in certain sectors and they feel it. I think this is a profound issue that
the Treasury has to grapple with, and Don and I have been urging them to grapple with it.
We have looked at individual firms, and we can see dramatic trends. The
quarter-to-quarter data are very helpful for that. There are some firms with very fine names
globally but whose performance as dealers has deteriorated markedly over the last 12 months
because of business decisions they have made. These firms are profitable as global entities. As I
have explained to all the dealers, we ask them to compete in the thinnest margined, most
competitive sector of global fixed-income markets. It is a tough market, but that is the business I
am in. I cannot change that.

11/12/97
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Parry.
MR. PARRY. Peter, we do not have primary regulatory responsibility for the parents
of some of the primary dealers. Do we have a dialogue with the primary dealers about century
date change compliance and is it an issue?
MR. FISHER. There are numerous efforts. Bill McDonough might be able to say
more about his contacts in New York with the Securities Industry Association. The Federal
Reserve has been talking about those issues in many ways with the securities industry generally.
I have not singled out the dealer community because there are so many initiatives going on in
securities markets.
MR. PARRY. Also, there is the issue of foreign banks, which I think has become
more of an issue in recent months.
MR. FISHER. Yes.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Within the limits of not in effect becoming
their supervisors, which would be inappropriate, we pay as much attention as we can and gather
as much knowledge as possible about the activities of the securities firms and perhaps even more
so of the foreign banks in our market because we do supervise them.
MR. PARRY. Right.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. There is a general move at securities firms in
the direction of policing their activities better in order to run their businesses more soundly.
Needless to say, we have encouraged that effort and applaud it. Some of the time we can get a
point across in a speech that shows an interest in how well they are behaving themselves and
how well they are managing their businesses.

11/12/97
MR. PARRY. Would it be appropriate to have a discussion with the primary dealers
regarding their handling of century date compliance just as we would with banking institutions?
MR. FISHER. On that issue, we are trying to work with the Securities Industry
Association and the Bond Market Association. Again, we do not want to become their regulator
as primary dealers. As securities firms, we are trying to make sure we are talking to them, but it
is a little awkward, qua primary dealer, to discuss the century date change issue with them.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. On century date change, I meet one-on-one two
to three times a year with the heads of insurance companies and securities firms as well as major
banks. At those meetings, we go through all the business concerns on their side and our side.
For the last year, a piece of that agenda has always been century date change.

My impression of

the securities firms is that they are very much on top of it. I think in the case of the foreign
banks, it varies considerably. The Asian banks seem to be less on top of the problem than the
European banks, who are probably six to nine months behind the major U.S. banks. Their
attention was gotten a little bit late, but I think we have it now.
MR. PARRY. Okay.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. You may know that during the annual meetings
in Hong Kong, the Institute of International Finance had a very well attended gathering. I was
asked to give the primary speech and I dedicated all of it to the century date change issue.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Any other questions? Would somebody like to move to
ratify domestic Desk transactions since the last meeting?
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. So move, Mr. Chairman.

11/12/97

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Would somebody like to move to
give Peter Fisher some additional intermeeting leeway?
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Move approval to increase the leeway to $12
billion.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Without objection. Peter, would you move on to the
next item on the swap line renewals?
MR. FISHER. On the last page of my package, there is a list of our
existing swap lines, a note on the Treasury's two swap lines, and the new
maturity date if we go ahead with the normal renewal process. This is the
time of year I ask you for authority to begin that process, which involves a
lot of exchanges of telexes and telephone calls over the next month. I am
asking for your approval to renew our existing swap lines, and I would note
that that includes both the swap lines listed here and the North American
Framework Agreement, which covers the use of our swap lines with Mexico
and Canada in certain circumstances. The two swap lines of those countries
can be used separately. It is a stand-alone framework in the event of
trilateral drawings.
Last year, we had a rather lengthy discussion of our swap line
agreements. We discussed the possibility that some of these swap lines
might fade into the sunset once European Monetary Union proceeds apace.
At that time last year, the members of this Committee agreed that we would
begin discussions with our colleagues at the other central banks in the spring
of 1998, and we intend to do so. I think that will be an uphill struggle given
the relative priority that the ECB and the NCBs will place on this issue
vis-a-vis other issues. But your humble servants will begin that effort in the
spring before we are back here again a year from now with this issue.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Servants?
MR. FISHER. Yes, humble!
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. It is also intended to include "and obedient."
Move approval of the swap line renewals, Mr. Chairman.

11/12/97

MR. BROADDUS. Mr. Chairman, I think my concerns about foreign exchange
operations are well known, and I'm not going to repeat all the arguments I have made earlier. I
am uncomfortable with foreign exchange operations for the reasons that I have stated previously,
and I see the swap lines as our instrument to implement those operations. Accordingly, I am
opposed to their renewal.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Any further comment? Is there a second to President
McDonough's motion?
SPEAKER(?). Second.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN.

All in favor say "Aye."

SEVERAL. Aye.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Opposed?
MR. BROADDUS. No.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Let's move on to the staff economic reports with
Messrs. Prell and Truman.
MR. PRELL. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I want to offer just a few
comments before yielding to Ted for his remarks on the recent turbulence in
the international economy and its implications for the U.S. outlook.
I think it's pretty obvious that we don't share the view that the United
States is going to be sucked into a deflationary whirlpool by the difficulties
encountered abroad. Time will tell just how big the contractionary shock
will be, but it would have to be a large one to override the momentum of
domestic demand in the near term.
All major segments of private spending look strong right now.
Consumers as a group are rich and happy, and it seems likely they will
continue to buy with abandon. Manufacturers of capital goods report heavy
inflows of orders--not just for computers and communications equipment,
but for a wide range of other machinery as well. Commercial property

11/12/97
prices are rising and should buttress nonresidential building activity.
Meanwhile, all indicators of housing demand are giving off positive signals.
As for financing, although the recent upheavals have produced some
widening of risk premia in the securities markets, conditions are still such
that most projects can get funding on what evidently are regarded as
attractive terms.
Absent a sizable shock, then, the economy probably will continue to
power ahead--perhaps not indefinitely, but for long enough to exacerbate
inflationary pressures significantly. In our forecast, the recent developments
abroad are a drag on aggregate demand, but not enough alone to bring a halt
soon to the above-trend growth we have been experiencing. One possible
source of restraint on demand would be a steep decline in the stock market.
It's quite possible that the large equity premiums of the past will not be
restored; however, we do believe that the current price-earnings multiples
incorporate unrealistic expectations about future profits. If we are correct,
the market surely will reflect it at some point, but that might not be soon and
the adjustment might start from still higher levels.
In our forecast, therefore, we have assumed that you will put a damper
on the economic boom by raising the funds rate three-quarters of a point by
the middle of next year. That isn't a lot, but we expect that the effects will
be magnified by some deflation of the stock market bubble. As you know,
we are predicting a drop next year that would take share prices down about
20 percent from Monday's closing level. We make no claim of precision in
that forecast--we are dealing not simply with math but also with mind
reading. In any event, we expect that once people are shaken out of their
complacency about the economic risks, the bond and loan markets will also
be affected--with a further widening of yield spreads and some firming of
loan standards.
With the resultant financial restraint, demand growth weakens and
growth of output falls below potential in our forecast. But this doesn't occur
before the labor market has tightened further. In that regard, a few words
about Friday's labor market data might be in order. According to that
report, the unemployment rate has already traversed some of the distance to
our predicted cyclical low of 4.6 percent. The report also showed the labor
force participation rate slipping further. This suggests that we might,
despite the trimming in our latest forecast, still be on the high side for labor
force growth. This could spell more labor scarcity and greater wage
pressure. We would recommend waiting for another reading or two before
reaching that conclusion, but the data do sound a cautionary note.

11/12/97

The sharp increase in average hourly earnings in October was
anticipated in our forecast. Although the recent surge in wages is
attributable in part to the effects of the hike in the federal minimum, we do
believe that there is an underlying tendency toward acceleration associated
with the efforts of businesses to attract and retain workers in a very tight
labor market. Real wage gains have turned up noticeably over the past
couple of years, and the pressure will remain in that direction. We think,
however, that the decline in price inflation and inflation expectations this
year has created a circumstance in which nominal wage increases will be
damped in the short run--enough to offset a pickup in medical insurance
costs that seems to be in the offing.
Our projection shows prices accelerating over the next two years.
However, the pickup is even more gradual than in previous forecasts. The
recent developments in the external sector suggest that the swing from
declining to rising import prices will be of still smaller magnitude than we
anticipated earlier. In addition, our reassessment of the trend in labor
productivity leads us to think that price inflation will rise more slowly. Our
projection of actual productivity growth has not changed much; however,
price setting seems to be influenced more by the trends of productivity and
unit labor costs than by the short-run variations, and so the change in our
trend assumption tends to damp our inflation projection. The end result is a
prediction that the rate of price increase will rise only a little over the next
two years--especially in the published figures, which will be held down by
technical changes to official indexes. But, I would conclude my remarks
with the reminder that we believe this rather benign outcome is probably
contingent on something happening to create a less accommodative financial
environment.
Ted will now say a few words about how we see the external
environment.
MR. TRUMAN. I thought it would be useful to say a few words about
how we have tried, in preparing the Greenbook forecast, to take account of
the recent turbulence in the international economic and financial
environment. I would note at the start that our assessment is very much a
work in progress; in particular, the assumptions, explicit and implicit,
underlying our analysis could be vitiated.
In preparing the Greenbook forecast for the global economy and its
impact on our external sector, we tried to take account of three interrelated
changes in the international environment since the Committee's previous
meeting in September: (1) the evolution of the economic and financial

11/12/97
crises in Asia and the limited spread, so far, to other developing economies,
particularly in Latin America; (2) changes in our outlook for other industrial
economies including the influence on them of Asian and related
developments; and (3) the modest further depreciation of the dollar against
European currencies. The net impact of these changes on our outlook for
real net exports of goods and services has been small; they increase the
negative contribution of the external sector to growth of real GDP by about
two tenths next year and one tenth in the following year. Although we
think that this is a reasonable best estimate, we also believe that the negative
risks to our overall forecast associated with developments in the rest of the
world have increased. Let me touch on each of the three principal sources
of change in our forecast: Asia, the other industrial countries, and the dollar.
We have sliced and diced in a number of different ways the
implications of the financial crises in Asia and hints of their spread to
developing economies elsewhere, but I think the simplest way to understand
the forecast is as follows. In effect, we have taken as a starting point an
assumption that in 1998 the current account deficit of the developing
economies as a group will have to shift toward surplus by a combined total
of $50 billion relative to our baseline in the September Greenbook, which
implied a combined 1998 deficit of about $100 billion. Based on historical
trade patterns, principally with respect to Asian imports, the U.S. share of
such a required external adjustment is about $15 billion, or about two tenths
percent of nominal GDP. In this simple framework, it does not matter
much for U.S. economic activity or prices whether this adjustment is caused
by macroeconomic policies, by collapsing financial systems, or by severely
depressed stock markets, nor does it matter much whether the impact on the
U.S. economy is felt via exchange-rate, other relative-price, or
aggregate-demand channels: as a first approximation, it is the size of the
overall adjustment that counts. We are assuming that most of the
adjustment occurs quickly, by the end of the first half of 1998, and that little
further external adjustment in Asia or elsewhere is required in 1999. Our
basic message, as we see it, is that in terms of deflationary effects on the
U.S. economy, developments in Asia will be more like a ripple than a wave.
With respect to other industrial economies, in our forecast we took into
consideration two influences: the underlying pace of expansion and the
effects of the Asian crises. Excluding the effects of the Asian crises, we
probably would have left our outlook for Japan unchanged because recent
data on the economy have been broadly consistent with what we had
expected, pointing toward a resumption of growth at around 2-1/2 percent in
the second half of the year and extending into 1998. However, mainly
because of Japan's relatively large share of Asian trade and relatively small

11/12/97

GDP (compared with the United States), we have marked down Japanese
growth next year by about half a percentage point due to the Asian crises.
With respect to Europe, recent information on trends in economic activity
have on balance been better than we had anticipated which, other things
being equal, would have led us to edge up projected growth. However,
these economies also will be affected by the economic adjustments in Asia.
Europe's share of Asian imports is essentially the same as ours while its
combined GDP is somewhat larger, suggesting that the direct effect of the
Asian adjustment on European growth should be marginally smaller than on
U.S. growth. The feedback effects on the U.S. economy of lower growth in
Japan and Europe are negative, and they are expected to be somewhat more
spread out over time than the direct Asian effects.
Turning to dollar exchange rates with the other industrial countries, as
Peter Fisher reported, the dollar has appreciated on balance against the yen
over the intermeeting period and it has depreciated against the DM and other
European currencies, with the latter effect outweighing the former effect in
terms of our G-10 average exchange value of the dollar. Broadly speaking,
these movements are consistent with relative trends in economic activity in
these economies and shifts in the market's view of the outlook for monetary
policies: extending the period of easy money in Japan, continuing moves to
withdraw monetary stimulus in Europe, and foreseeing no change in policy
in the United States. Looking ahead over the forecast period, we have left
the dollar unchanged at its recent lower level, on average, in terms of other
G-10 currencies. This has the effect of providing a small net stimulus to
U.S. net exports that partially offsets the negative effects of Asian
developments and their feedback on the U.S. economy through weaker
growth in the other industrial countries, Japan in particular.
Returning to our basic message, the combination of these influences
and considerations has led us, on balance, to increase by a small amount the
negative contribution of the external sector to U.S. growth over the forecast
period. The small downward adjustment in prices of imports, other than oil,
computers, and semiconductors, in the Greenbook forecast for this meeting
is due not to changes in our outlook for the dollar--which on an importweighted basis in terms of both G-10 and non-G-10 currencies is not
projected to change further on average over the forecast period. Rather the
lower import prices are due to the small decline in international commodity
prices that has occurred over the intermeeting period, a decline that may or
may not be attributable to developments in Asia.
The risks to our forecast with respect to the dollar and underlying
growth trends in other industrial countries, we believe, are balanced. In

11/12/97

terms of the Asian crises in all their ramifications, the probability of further
deterioration should be thought of as greater than the risk of a sudden
unexpected improvement. However, it would be a mistake to think that
there are no upside risks involved in the Asian situation. For example, the
news coming out of the deputies' meeting in Manila next week about a new
Asia-Pacific cooperative financing arrangement may be perceived as
sufficiently positive for the region as a whole that net inflows of private
capital will resume and substantially reduce the size of the external
adjustments that we now think will be required.
On the downside, the new government in Thailand may not be able or
willing to deliver quickly on that country's IMF-supported economic and
financial program; the implementation of the Indonesian program also may
get bogged down in domestic or family politics; the storm clouds over
Korea may darken further; and the spread of contagion to Latin America
may intensify. We circulated to the FOMC a note on a so-called "worst
case" scenario in which the negative impact on U.S. growth from the Asian
crises is roughly double what we incorporated in the Greenbook forecast,
largely because of an assumed spread of the turmoil to Latin America. That
scenario might better have been called a "worse case," since it is easy to spin
out scenarios that are more extreme.
Mr. Chairman, I will stop on that pessimistic note.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. What has been happening in the last couple of years to
the statistical discrepancy in the world current account balance?
MR. TRUMAN. It has not moved much. It is still a very big negative or positive
depending upon how you want to think about it.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Is it still $100 billion?
MR. TRUMAN. When we did this calculation, we held that unchanged. We forced
the adjustments to go elsewhere rather than into the statistical discrepancy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I noticed in the most recent labor force data that the
participation rate declined. We usually would expect it to rise in the context of a sharp increase
in economic growth. I gather from the underlying data that there has been a significant increase

27

11/12/97

in school enrollments. One would presume that is occurring because of the need to upgrade
skills and because parents can afford to let their children stay in school. So, the number of
people not in the labor force but in school has been rising very rapidly. This has exactly the
opposite effect on the participation rate from what a strong economy would ordinarily impart.
When you projected the participation rate to get an unemployment rate of about 4-1/2 percent,
did you have any explicit assumptions regarding school enrollment or any other not-in-thelabor-force elements?
MR. PRELL. We have looked at the movements in the labor force in some detail.
Basically, in this latest forecast we backed off from our previous expectation of a significant rise
partly because the incoming data were not moving that way. What we have seen since the spike
in March is a rather broad-based decline involving adult males, adult females, and teenagers.
Certainly, a possible factor affecting school enrollments is the wealth or income effect that you
have noted. One area where we have seen recent increases in participation is among women who
are head of a household, and I think that is consistent with some impact from welfare reform.
Basically, all of the rise in labor force participation in our forecast is related to the anticipated
effects of welfare reform. The latest data put the participation rate at a lower level than we had
anticipated, but there is enough noise in these numbers that we are hesitant to leap to further
conclusions. Even so, the data do tend to underscore the risks to the participation outlook in that
direction.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. What is the effect on the productivity numbers of the
upward BLS revision of payroll employment from the annual survey?

11/12/97
MR. PRELL. All other things equal, it will tend to lower productivity growth over the
period in which they wedge in this increase. We are talking about a 0.1 or 0.2 reduction.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Isn't the BLS revision something like 500,000 workers?
MR. PRELL. I think it was 475,000. If we assess the effect on productivity growth in
terms of gauging the trend over a period of time, it would not be quite so large.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. It will affect the historical data, the 1996 numbers, but
are you suggesting that it will have little effect on the outlook?
MR. PRELL. They will carry something through as well, but there is also the
possibility that by the time we get to the middle of next year other data will have changed too,
perhaps on the output side.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Is there a tendency for that to happen when BEA does
its annual revisions?
MR. PRELL. That is a very interesting question for which I do not have an answer. It
is something that we ought to look into.
MR. STOCKTON. If it were to show up, it probably would be as an additional
increase in the statistical discrepancy. There is no evidence that statistical discrepancies revise
back toward zero when the annual revisions are made. So, you could not necessarily use the
revision to forecast more GDP, but it certainly is a logical possibility.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. It certainly would make BEA look harder.
MR. STOCKTON. Indeed. I think they will undertake a more careful review of the
discrepancy between the income side data and the product side data, and to the extent that they
have some discretion, they might emphasize it that way.

29

11/12/97

MR. PRELL. As I understand it, the only data we are really dealing with are the
revised employment numbers. They will feed that through in estimating total hours, but one
does need to look at the income data themselves.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Mike, I had a question in reading the Greenbook. As you look out
beyond this year, you are forecasting a slowing in GDP growth, and even though you have
reduced the rate of increase in inflation, the inflation trend is still positive. As the Greenbook
explains the surrounding circumstances, it seems that the primary reason for the continuing
inflation is the projected decrease in productivity, which raises costs. Are the inflation numbers
being driven by labor costs?
MR. PRELL. That is a part of the story. We view resource pressures at this point,
particularly in the labor market, as being strong enough to produce some ongoing acceleration in
prices. The fact that productivity growth in the industrial sector is as rapid as it is suggests to us
that, going forward, we are going to have a reasonably comfortable picture in that sector, but
more generally we see ongoing pressures in the labor market. We have the difficult question of
judging what the relative influences are of trend productivity and actual productivity growth. It
is probable that reality lies in some combination of those two elements. Therefore, as we go
forward and the upcreep in compensation is augmented by a decline in productivity growth, we
expect to get a noticeable acceleration in unit labor costs that will put some pressure on profit
margins. In that case, firms may, in what will still be a reasonably tight market overall, try to
extract some price increases along the way.
MR. HOENIG. Even with the GDP numbers coming down markedly?

30

11/12/97

MR. PRELL. One might think that there will be something of a so-called speed effect
as we move into 1999. The other element, though it is a small and uncertain factor, does work in
the direction of tending to raise inflation. It has to do with the fact that we have been benefiting
significantly over the past couple of years from a decline in import prices. Going forward, we do
not anticipate that to continue, so that adds to the acceleration of prices in our forecast.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. Mike, in the corporate profit area, I wonder if you could elaborate a
bit on the basis for the Greenbook's assumption that corporate profit growth slows so
significantly by early 1998.

The labor costs do not seem to accelerate dramatically in this

period, and, of course, if profits come in higher than you anticipate in 1998 and 1999, that could
lead to higher spending on business fixed investment.
MR. PRELL. The numbers do conform arithmetically with the behavior of
compensation and unit labor costs, but there are other factors that play a role such as movements
in interest costs, foreign earnings, and so on. In the short run, we probably will have our greatest
hit to foreign earnings from the problems in Asia in particular. So, there are a number of
elements that tend to put a damper on profit growth in the near term. The profit share begins to
turn down, but the greater damage really occurs as we run through the forecast period. The year
1999 is where we see profits really declining. Indeed, that is one of the reasons we have only the
mildest of declines in the stock market through the first part of next year. Year-on-year
comparisons of earnings in our forecast will still look quite good. Certainly if there is any
continuing inclination for investors to be optimistic, as they clearly have been in recent years, I
do not think reduced earnings will be such a rude shock to the markets that they would have

31

11/12/97

devastating effects on share prices in the early part of our forecast period. Cash flow in the
nonfinancial corporate sector is not growing as fast as capital expenditure, and we are seeing a
widening of the financing gap. As we go out through the forecast period, the financing gap gets
to be sizable enough that at least we would not think that firms will be spending simply because
money is coming into their coffers and they have to do something with it. It begins to be a less
favorable factor as we move out through 1998 and certainly into 1999.
MR. MOSKOW. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Parry.
MR. PARRY. In the Greenbook forecast, the funds rate is kept constant through this
quarter and then begins to move up, rising 75 basis points by the middle of next year. Was there
any thought as to how sensitive the forecast might be to this assumption, in view of recent
developments in Asia? In particular, if this path were embarked upon somewhat sooner than is
assumed in the Greenbook forecast, would you modify the response of the economy in light of
the possibility that it might generate some financial consequences that are not incorporated in the
forecast?
MR. PRELL. I will call on Ted to comment regarding how he thinks other markets
will respond. This is a question that President Jordan asked at the last meeting, and in retrospect
I thought my answer may not have hit on one point that logically would be potentially significant
in our thinking about the forecast. That point is that to the extent that you surprised the market
early on before you saw any evidence of building price inflation, your credibility would be
enhanced. You would not appear to be playing catch-up, and the solidification of low inflation
expectations would be greater. Now, in fact, with the kind of acceleration in prices we

11/12/97

32

anticipate, it might be very hard to explain price developments from month to month. So, I do
not want to draw this distinction too sharply. Certainly, one of the reasons we have share prices
declining is that the markets do not seem to have built in any anticipation of tightening, and an
earlier move, as the Bluebook points out, could have fairly sharp effects on domestic financial
markets.
MR. TRUMAN. It seems to me that two or three points could be made. One is that
there is a sense in which all of this volatility in foreign markets has been associated with some
moves toward tighter policies, as Peter has pointed out. We have had the Canadian moves, the
British moves, the German moves, and although Japanese moves have been postponed, it is fair
to say that the generally benign monetary conditions in the industrial countries have been one
factor that has contributed to the acceleration of capital flows to emerging economies. As we
have commented before, when that comes to an end, there is some risk of a process of
readjustment, some of which may already be under way. I think it is probably a reasonable guess
that if the Committee were to surprise the market and move sooner, or move at all at this point,
there certainly would be some short-run dynamic effects. And no doubt we all would come
under some criticism. That having been said, unless you think that early tightening would set off
some great avalanche that would continue regardless of fundamentals, I don't think the timing
will make much difference in the medium term. I don't think that in any fundamental sense an
earlier policy move will somehow cause political leaders in Southeast Asia to step back from the
things that they have said they were going to do. I might even argue that it could accelerate the
adjustment process, but there might be a lot more broken crockery in the meantime.

11/12/97
MR. KOHN. I would only add that it is always hard to predict how markets are going
to react to a policy move, but if you do something unexpected in a skittish and nervous market, it
would seem to me that predicting the outcome is much more difficult in that case. The chances
of outlier kinds of responses are somewhat higher.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Rivlin.
MS. RIVLIN. This is a version of Tom Hoenig's question. I was quite surprised by
the projected falloff in productivity growth in your forecast for 1998. We have had a gratifying
improvement now for four years, and you reflect that experience in your estimate of increased
trend growth, but then you have a big drop in 1998 to an increase in output of 0.7 percent per
hour. Can you say a few words about why you think it will drop that much?
MR. PRELL. The basic thesis here is that we have had a spurt. We think the
improvement in trend is an element in that, but we also think that, in part, the acceleration of
output has lifted the growth in productivity to substantially above the trend line that we would
draw. As the economy decelerates, we would anticipate a movement back toward the trend line.
That is the pattern that we have here.
MS. RIVLIN. It's not just a movement toward the trend line; it falls below.
MR. PRELL. No. Think of the productivity trend as a line that is rising and current
productivity as moving above the line. The two lines then tend to converge, with actual
productivity converging to trend from above. Now, during past business cycles, this has
occurred irregularly. Certainly, it has occurred at the end of cyclical expansions. To some
extent, that may have reflected a deterioration at the margin in labor quality as new workers were
added to the labor force. In some cases, it may have reflected the need to use less efficient

11/12/97

34

equipment, which does not look to be a very significant problem in this instance. It could be
simply the deceleration in demand and the cutback in output, which is not followed immediately
by a proportionate reduction in hours of labor. It is quite conceivable that not only are we
wrong on the trend, we could be wrong on the shorter-run dynamics too, and we could have a
more sustained growth of productivity. But we think this is a sensible pattern, one that conforms
to experience as we have it embodied in models of productivity behavior.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Guynn.
MR. GUYNN. Mike, I may have misread the analysis in the Greenbook, but I got the
sense that you placed a great deal more importance on the wealth effect in your current forecast
for household consumption. I compared that analysis to your earlier assessment of how much
the wealth effect would affect spending as the stock market rose sharply. Is this simply a matter
of an asymmetrical response to a market correction downward as opposed to what you thought
the wealth effect would be when the market rose sharply? Is there some new work underlying
your current analysis or have I, in fact, just misread the importance that you attach to the wealth
effect in explaining a falloff in the growth of consumer spending?
MR. PRELL. Perhaps because we did not include verbiage in that part of the
Greenbook about a lot of other developments, it may have seemed that there was more focus on
the wealth effect. Since the midyear revisions to the national income accounts that showed a
decline in the saving rate, I think we have used essentially the same logic in terms of assuming
that a good bit of the strength in consumption and decline in the saving rate over the past year is
attributable to the increase in stock market wealth. We also anticipate that, as the market turns
down in our forecast, we are going to see the wealth effect eroding gradually. "Gradual" is the

35

11/12/97

point that we have tried to stress. Some have suggested that the response is almost
instantaneous, but as best we can gauge that response, looking at a variety of econometric
models, it takes a significant span of time for the wealth effect to play out. So, in 1998 we would
still see for most of the year some impetus on balance to consumer spending relative to income
coming from the rise that already has occurred in the stock market. But, by 1999 we have it
turning the other way.
I guess one could say that, anecdotally, we hear increasing reports of people feeling
rather wealthy and deciding that they are not going to leave all of their gains to their kids or the
IRS. They are going to spend some of those gains. Certainly, people in the auto industry believe
that one of the reasons the demand for sports utility vehicles, especially the high-end models, has
been so strong is that people are spending some of this wealth. I think there is some evidence in
the housing market that demand for second homes has firmed in the past year, and people in that
industry seem to feel that the improvement could be a reflection of the stock market. So, this
factor could be having fairly broad and significant effects, which is the reason we feature it so
much in explaining the deceleration in 1998 and 1999.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Minehan.
MS. MINEHAN. I want to go back to Ted's comment about whether or not the paper
we got on the "worst case" scenario was really "worst" or "worse." I noticed that the paper still
foresees some growth in 1998 for Korea, and I must say I am a little concerned that the impact of
the Southeast Asian crisis on Japan may be more significant than the paper anticipates. If you
have any comments, I would like to hear them because I'm a little concerned that our idea of
what is the bottom may not really be the bottom.

11/12/97

36
MR. TRUMAN. There is always that problem, and that is why I made my last

comment. You could always say that if growth is going to be marked down by 5 percentage
points, why not mark it down by 6 percentage points? That is at one level. There is always some
chance of a cumulative process, reminiscent of a lot of economic history. On the other hand, one
also has to think about something from which many tend to abstract, namely, about what might
happen to policy along the line. There likely is some policy whose feedback could prevent the
cumulative effects. So, what may happen is difficult to say. One point to think about, at least in
terms of developing economies, is that many of them are high-growth economies. If they go into
recession, say their GDP declines by 2 or 3 percent, we would not think of that as a big recession
but for them it would represent a very large adjustment from previous growth rates of 6, 7, 8, or
9 percent. The adjustment in growth would be something close to double digits. We might
anticipate that Korean growth would still be 1 or 2 percent, but that would be a decline from 7 or
8 percent, a 6 percentage point change in the trajectory of the Korean economy. Obviously,
there is no magic about zero here, and I think what you are saying is that in some real sense these
economies will be going into some kind of recession.
Such a development could have further feedback effects, especially in Japan which, I
would argue, is hampered principally by their delay in doing something about the problems in
their financial system. That has meant, at least in part, that their standard macroeconomic
measures may have been somewhat less effective than one might otherwise have thought, and
they are to some extent running out of string. I don't think that is true for other industrial
countries as a group. The industrial world seems to have the capacity to take policy steps that

37

11/12/97

would cushion some of these effects and in turn avert feedback effects on the developing
economies. Things could be much worse.
One part of the world that we have left out of our analysis is Eastern Europe. There,
too, some economies have been impacted by at least the financial dimensions of all this turmoil.
Although our trade with Eastern Europe is trivial, Western European trade with Eastern Europe
is not so trivial. If there were dramatic changes in conditions in Eastern Europe, that presumably
would have some impact on Western Europe. While it may be fair to say that Western European
nations have scope to use policy to offset the general macroeconomic effects of such a
development, it is not unreasonable to question whether they would be able to coordinate their
policies to do so. So, I think there is some risk stemming from potential developments in Eastern
Europe that we have not taken account of arithmetically. It is one reason why we probably
should have called our analysis "a worse" rather than "the worst" case scenario. Absolute zero is
difficult to define in this context.
MS. MINEHAN. If you use that "worse" case scenario as a guess, is the impact a
one-half percentage point reduction in our GDP growth over the next couple of years?
MR. TRUMAN. It is a little more.
MS. MINEHAN. Spread over 1998 and 1999?
MR. TRUMAN. It is more like adding 0.2 to 0.5 in 1998 and 0.1 to 0.2 or 0.3 in
1999. I think that is the order of magnitude. There is always a question about multipliers in
these exercises. Now, in fact, when we run these through, the ex post multipliers tend to be close
to 1.0. It is not entirely clear to me whether that is because the true multiplier is close to 1.0 or

38

11/12/97

because either automatic policy responses or discretionary policy responses are such that the
multiplier ends up being close to one.
MS. MINEHAN. Apart from that, how does this scenario play out in terms of
unemployment and downward impact on inflationary pressures?
MR. TRUMAN. That goes to the question of global deflation. Perhaps Mike Prell
and Don Kohn ought to answer this question, but my view is that the fundamental behavior of
the U.S. economy has not changed so much in the last half dozen years that we can no longer
analyze effects of this size through standard aggregate demand approaches. Obviously, the
developments in question would raise our unemployment rate and lower inflation pressures much
as one might argue that the collapse in Latin America in the early 1980s may have affected our
economy. At that time, our economy was recovering from a recession, but it also was a recovery
from a recession with, at least as perceived at the time, remarkably quiescent inflation. Inflation
was then in a 4 to 5 percent range, and that rate of inflation may have reflected some influences
from abroad in terms of downward pressure on commodity prices and related developments. We
are looking at an effect on our macro economy that is marginal rather than large in terms of
fundamental behavior.
MR. PRELL. There is a simple rule of thumb. One has to have a full-fledged
scenario that indicates the circumstances in which, for example, this extra couple of tenths of
GDP restraint might be occurring. If we just had a quarter percentage point more deceleration in
GDP growth for two years, we would end up by Okun's Law with about a quarter percentage
point higher unemployment rate by the end of the second year. The difference in inflation
outcomes would be very small. But if we blend in stories about exchange rate and import price

39

11/12/97

effects and their financial dynamics and so on, one has to step back and think very carefully
about what the outcome might be. Just taking that little bit of arithmetic that Ted was
mentioning, we need to go to a drastically "worse" case scenario to totally change the outcome.
MR. KOHN. As I looked at this analysis in relation to the scenarios at the end of the
Greenbook, it seemed to me that the effects were somewhere between the baseline and the tighter
scenario in terms of GDP growth. Remember that the tighter scenario in effect keeps inflation
from rising. As I will say in my briefing later, it seems to me the "worst" case scenario still
leaves the tightening move an open question.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Broaddus.
MR. BROADDUS. Mike, I was struck by the fact that the projection for the ECI for
next year is the same as the number for this year. I would like to get some sense about how
comfortable you are with that projection because I believe it was made before we had the
October jobs report. Also, we at our Bank get a lot of anecdotal information to the effect that
health care costs will begin to rise at a more rapid pace. That information comes from a fairly
broad range of contacts. As an example, the head of
made a big point of this in a recent meeting. I am wondering
whether you are factoring in that sort of information.
MR. PRELL. As I noted briefly, the average hourly earnings report for October did
not upset us. We anticipated another large number, and it was in line with our expectations. The
forecast of a stable ECI increase in 1998 reflects the expectation that wages will be favorably
affected by the very low rates of consumer and overall price inflation that we've seen in the past
year and the apparent effect of that price behavior on inflation expectations. That effect has been

40

11/12/97

small on the median of such expectations, for example, in the Michigan Survey, but very striking
on the mean. Seemingly, there has been a convergence of expectations to the lower level. We
would anticipate this to have a damping effect on wage increases, and in a sense we are not
looking for the ongoing effect of the minimum wage hikes that have raised the rate of wage
increases in the past year. When we did simulations about a year and a half ago, the simulation
of a minimum wage increase involved some follow-through as higher wages raised prices and
price expectations. But in fact consumer prices have decelerated, so we see that as a favorable
element in the near term.
We have built a significant acceleration of health insurance costs into the ECI forecast.
We have reports of increases in insurance premiums beyond those of CALPERS and the federal
employee health programs. We are fairly well convinced that those increases will happen this
time. They did not happen this year despite some earlier reports, but we feel the evidence is now
tangible enough for us to want to build that into our forecast at least in a moderate way.
I guess my final comment would be that there seems to have been some increase
recently in the anecdotal reports of step-ups in wage increases. It is very hard to read this
information, but I would say that there's a basis for some concern that the increases may be
larger than those we have built into the forecast. I have not seen the actual numbers, but just to
cite something that I have heard, the survey of smaller businesses by the National Federation of
Independent Businesses has evidently shown a noticeable increase in the last few months in the
number of firms reporting that they actually have raised wages and a noticeable increase in the
number of firms saying they plan to raise wages.

11/12/97

In sum, there clearly are risks. I think we followed the logic of the basic model of
how wages are determined, and it just may be that we are going to get increases in this period
that turn out to be greater than we forecast.
MR. BROADDUS. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President McTeer.
MR. MCTEER. I just have a few comments that I'm not sure will be all that helpful
and a question. On the balance of payments arithmetic and the worst case not appearing all that
bad, I think we should not get too complacent. It seems that we are thinking of the transmission
mechanism as being through the trade and the current accounts when it may be that the Asian flu
spreads more through the capital account. On the arithmetic, while the net of the two tends to be
the same, the gross of the capital account has gotten much larger in recent years than the gross on
the current account. So, I think the fact that we have small trading relationships is probably less
important than it was before capital became so notable and so large relative to trade. We should
be careful about that.
My other comment is on the stock market. I thought, when we had the big stock
market decline a couple of weeks ago, that there was a silver lining to it. I thought it would
provide at least part of what Mike Prell was expecting for next year so that he would give us
some relief in his forecast for stock market adjustments in 1998. But it seems as if it didn't
make a dent at all.
MR. PRELL. Before the drop, the market had moved up further. So, as of Monday, I
think the average for the quarter was actually higher than we had predicted in the last
Greenbook. Now, if the market stays at these lower levels, we will come out pretty much in line.

42

11/12/97

The decline from the very peak of the market to the low that we forecast, going by the Wilshire
5000, is about 25 percent. We have about 5 percent under our belts.
MR. MCTEER. In line with Mike Moskow's question earlier, I gather the stock
market is going to fall because you expect higher interest rates and lower profits. I believe you
have profits coming down from a growth rate of 11 percent in the third quarter to only 1 percent
in the fourth quarter. That seems rather abrupt.
MR. PRELL. It could be. We have been wrong previously! We certainly have found
it more difficult in the past couple of years to track from our output forecast to profits, because
the statistical discrepancy has moved substantially. Perhaps that could happen going forward. In
our forecast, we do not have that continuing movement in income relative to expenditures that
we have experienced over the past year or so.
MR. TRUMAN. On your first comment, I would agree with you and maybe I should
have been more clear. It seems to me that in the particular framework that I laid out, which is
not the only way we looked at this, it is the capital account that is forcing the current account
adjustment. As you say, the order of magnitude of those capital flows certainly is larger than the
gross trade flows. But when it comes down to the corrective effect on goods and services-which is what we measure in GDP--we end up wanting to look at that in terms of trade. We
always have this question, much like the question on stock market effects on consumption, about
how to marry something with financial dimensions to how these things play out in real
dimensions, and whether the effects will be cumulative. We have not added that in except, as I
think we mentioned in the Greenbook, that there is a side of this that looks at the implications for
growth in the developing countries. It is hard to make everything consistent. One sense of why

43

11/12/97

you might find less growth in developing countries would be that the cost of capital has gone up,
uncertainty has gone up, and there has been a big drop in investment. It is not only investment
that comes from the public sector, which is supported in these economies, but from the private
sector as well as we go through this financial turmoil. In that sense, we try to take account of
that effect.
MR. MCTEER. I was traveling on the day that the stock market went down over 500
points. I heard about it after it had already happened. I did not get to build up to it gradually.
What I heard on the car radio was that it was because of the Hong Kong stock market. So, it
was stock market to stock market and had nothing to do with anything rational.
MR. TRUMAN. I was traveling, too. I got trapped in Springfield, Illinois.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Any further questions for our colleagues? If not,
would somebody like to start the Committee discussion?
MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, the Tenth District economy continues to perform very
well. I am going to focus my comments on anecdotal information partly because that
information, though not different from the statistical evidence, is in some sense at a higher pitch
as suggested by various stories coming out of our District. First of all, manufacturing continues
to do very well, but there is a very persistent commentary that firms are continuing to do
everything they can to substitute capital for labor. The reason is labor shortages, especially in
the low-paying, repetitive-type jobs.
Members of our advisory groups corroborate our information that loan growth is
moving up. One of our advisory panel members, a CEO, received a call from a major banking
firm that asked whether they should put the firm down for a $50 million or a $100 million line of

11/12/97

44

credit next year. The bank did this without knowing what the firm's plans and loan demands
might be. This story illustrates a very strong desire by banks in our area to increase their loans to
business borrowers. On the other side, there are credit card fish stories that are scarcely
believable. I heard one involving, for me, a new high in indebtedness by an individual. In a
credit check for a new loan application, one of the banks in our region found that the individual
had debts on several credit cards totaling $180,000. The individual was using advances on new
cards to keep them all current. Whether that person was trying to support a business endeavor or
just consumer purchases was a question in the bank's mind, but they did not consider the
application long enough to get into that kind of detail!
With regard to bottlenecks, the Greenbook mentioned some delays in rail
transportation and we are finding evidence of that in our region. One firm in Tulsa leased some
trucks to go to Memphis to pick up some of its raw materials because the railroad bottlenecks
were keeping the firm from getting its supplies on a timely basis.
On the salary issue, we are seeing continued escalation in the high-tech areas. One of
our states was losing their programmers because of an average 25 percent increase in
programmer wages in their job market. With regard to worker benefits, we are hearing from
organizations like PCI in Colorado that they are decreasing the waiting period for their workers
to get into 401(k) programs. Other employers are increasing their use of stock grants to entice
people to stay or to come on board with them. On medical insurance costs, we are hearing from
Kaiser Permanente and Blue Cross/Blue Shield of cost increases of 5 to 10 percent on renewals
and 9 to 12 percent on PPOs for next year. Finally, though on the other side, we had some
meetings with a couple of labor representatives and, for example, the one from the International

11/12/97

45

Brotherhood of Boilermakers was talking about wage increases totaling 2-1/2 to 3-1/2 percent.
However, the contracts were for 5 to 7 years, and the wage portion was not renewable though the
benefits portion was. One of our major companies also indicated that they had now signed a
five-year contract. That says something about future inflation expectations.
Briefly on the national level, the only comment I would make is that we have a very
strong economy and very strong demand for labor. I do not think the Southeast Asian crisis will
necessarily have a contagious effect on our economy. So, we have very strong growth, but in
terms of its potential for inflation, I continue to be struck by a number of offsetting factors: how
well balanced the economy is at present, a core rate of inflation that continues to decline, the
continued absence of pipeline inflation, persisting expectations of stable inflation, and from the
standpoint of monetary policy a historically high real fed funds rate. So, the dilemma on the
national front continues to puzzle me. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Parry.
MR. PARRY. Mr. Chairman, labor markets have remained quite tight in the Twelfth
Federal Reserve District in recent months, as employment growth has proceeded at a strong but
moderating pace. The District unemployment rate fell about 1/2 percentage point in the first half
of the year and remained at this low level through September. With the notable exception of
California, unemployment rates in most District states now are at lows not seen in several
decades. Although California's unemployment rate is still high relative to those in other states, it
has been falling sharply and labor markets in some of the major metropolitan areas are very tight.
Unemployment rates have fallen to new lows in San Diego and the San Francisco Bay area.
Labor market conditions also have improved noticeably in the Los Angeles area, which until

46

11/12/97

recently had been experiencing a strong out-migration of people who lacked good job
opportunities there.
For the District as a whole, although third-quarter employment growth was strong, the
rate of increase was about 1 percentage point lower than the very rapid pace in the first half of
1997. This includes California and Washington where the slowdown follows a pickup in growth
earlier in the year. Moderation in growth rates in the intermountain states of Arizona, Nevada,
and Utah appears to be related to a slowing in population growth. This is partly a result of fewer
new residents relocating from California. Job growth has tapered off this year in the
population-oriented sectors of the economy such as residential construction and state and local
government.
Recent data show that the national economy continues to perform well, with robust
output growth accompanied by low inflation. Traditional models still predict that the economy
will grow at around a 2 percent rate next year, with the slowing based on factors such as high
stocks of real assets, the dollar's appreciation over the last year, and the relatively high level of
real interest rates. The latter have been nudged up a little by recent declines in expected
inflation. I agree that the turmoil in East Asia may contribute a bit to the growth slowdown, but I
think the contribution is unlikely to be large. However, I believe there is plenty of room for
skepticism about whether a slowdown as big as that predicted by traditional models will occur,
especially when one takes into account the inability of these models to predict the robust
performance of the economy over the past year and a half. It is possible that we are experiencing
the effects of a positive supply shock, which means that the uncertainty extends to predicting
inflation as well. The recent moderation in inflation certainly is consistent with a positive supply

47

11/12/97

shock, and some market-based indicators provide room for optimism. For example, the rate
spread between nominal and inflation-indexed bonds has now fallen below 2-1/2 percentage
points; we talked about that a little earlier. But I believe recent data provide reason for concern
as well. For instance, the unemployment rate has fallen even further below most estimates of the
natural rate. This leads me to expect higher inflation, and both ECI and hourly earnings data
show that wages are beginning to move up somewhat. In balancing these considerations, I
would expect the core CPI to rise about 2-1/2 percent in 1998 compared to about 2-1/4 percent
this year. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Jordan.
MR. JORDAN. Thank you. In addition to the usual discussions we have had with
directors and advisory council members since the last FOMC meeting, we also spent some time
visiting communities around southern and western Ohio and central and northern Kentucky. I
came away with an impression similar to the one I felt almost 10 years ago when I was still
traveling around Southern California, namely that I was in a rare part of the world and everybody
else must be suffering because everything was booming where we were. And these are counties
that are not accustomed to experiencing such prosperity.
Bankers reported strong loan demand in all categories, with most getting stronger. Of
course, there has been a surge in mortgage refinancing that I am sure most people are seeing
around the country. In the areas that we visited, people reported that consumer loan demand
was still very strong, especially auto-related. The most prominent stories related to real estate
lending. Our contacts said it was booming everywhere. One banker in Kentucky indicated that
there was more speculative building under construction now than at any time in his memory, and

11/12/97

48

he is certainly older than I am. He commented that in his county if a construction worker were
driving through in a pickup and happened to have a breakdown near a vacant field, by the time
he got the tools out of the back of the truck at least five bankers would stop and offer to finance
the project for him! [Laughter] Just before our visit, one banker saw seven proposals for new
speculative building projects. He said three of the ideas were so poorly justified that they did not
even have a plan, and all the potential borrowers were significantly undercapitalized. There are a
lot of reports that farmland is being acquired for future conversion to either commercial or
residential uses or on the chance that somebody might build an interstate interchange on the land,
making it more valuable. These are not prospects at all, just hopes. In central Kentucky, we
were told that the number of lots developed and ready for construction was triple the number of a
year ago. Bankers said that a sharp net in-migration into the region was expected. I asked them
from where and they didn't know. Obviously, they thought that people were going to move into
their area because the local economies were in such good shape right now. We were hearing the
usual reports of farmland prices well above what crop values would justify. We heard more
stories of residential mortgages being made by nonbanks with 125 percent loan-to-value ratios.
One banker said that one of his nonbank directors indicated that he was strongly opposed to
participation in any economic development efforts by the state or by the county because his
firm's labor turnover was high and he wanted to slow growth.
On the labor side, we were told that entry-level tellers were being paid around $14 to
$15 an hour to start. One reported $20 an hour for a teller trainee. Our contacts said that banks
that advertised in newspapers for employees got no applications at all. Instead, the banks were
resorting to hiring bounties. They were paying existing employees to bring in a friend or a

49

11/12/97

relative and then paying them part of the bonus, depending on how long the new employee
lasted. One new bank said that in their first six months of operations, they had surpassed their
initial three-year plan for earning assets. There were more stories about consumer loans going
from being current to bankruptcy status without the transitory stages of late payments and
delinquencies.
In other reports from directors and advisory council members, like Tom Hoenig we
have heard about the bottlenecks in rail transportation and even about the difficulty of booking
trucking transportation. The claim is that there is a shortage of truck drivers, and our contacts
said that it was common now to pay $40,000 a year or more for truck drivers. We have heard
reports of other worker shortages, including nurses, warehouse workers, computer operators and
programmers, and machinists. Somebody reported to us that pickers and packers were now
getting $14 an hour; I'm not sure exactly what pickers and packers do! One company, a fairly
good-sized shop, said that they had a number of machinists whom they had been paying $18 an
hour, and a group of them walked out and went to a nonunion shop for $21 an hour. The
unionized company cannot find replacements at $18 an hour, and the union will not agree to their
hiring new people at higher wages than the existing workers receive. They are demanding that
the whole pay structure be raised. So, the company's owners are now looking into the option of
simply shutting the plant and moving the whole operation to Mexico. On health care, we heard
from one advisory council member that increases in medical costs are now sticking and that we
should expect such costs to rise for the next several years--the same kind of thing that Al
Broaddus mentioned.

50

11/12/97

Three years ago I asked the members of my small business advisory council if they
could contemplate still being in business in five years if they were not able to increase the prices
of their products or services at all over that period. The response was a unanimous "yes," and
they explained to us how they could do that. When I asked the same question recently, the
responses were almost all "no" or "doubtful." The reasons they give are that labor costs have
risen much more than they had expected, the quality of the labor force has fallen more than they
had anticipated, and the easy steps to increase productivity have already been taken. Moreover,
they now expect more labor militancy, work stoppages, and competition from nonunion
operations. Some commented that they thought the unions were going to demand catch-up
raises. As the unions view developments, business earnings have been so good because the
benefits of increased productivity and efficiency have all gone to owners and not to workers, so
now it is the workers' turn.
We heard some general comments to the effect that compensation data understate
actual labor costs. It is an interesting phenomenon that nobody thinks that their situation is
normal. It will be interesting as we go around the table to see how others view this phenomenon.
If all of us are operating above average, it is going to be hard to know what is really going on.
No one thinks that the unemployment numbers reflect what they are seeing in their communities
and their counties; nobody thinks that the inflation data reflect what they are seeing; no one
thinks that the compensation numbers reflect what they are experiencing; nobody thinks that
their labor turnover experience is reflected in the statistics. Generally, our directors believe that
there is a buildup of inflationary pressures and that the inflation risks are decidedly on the

11/12/97

51

upside. They report that sectors of the regional economy such as construction are operating flat
out, constrained only by the availability of financing.
I have a couple of thoughts on the national economy. One relates to the wealth effect
that Mike Prell mentioned. Mike referred to high-end SUVs and second homes. We surveyed
boat builders and found that luxury boats are doing very well. The recent International Boat
Show in Annapolis was said to have been the best in over 10 years. It is the high-end boats, both
power and sailboats, that are selling extremely well. As we were driving around in Kentucky,
one banker reported that cars with license plates from New York and Massachusetts sometimes
pull into a farmhouse driveway and offer to pay cash for the farm.
It appears that we have been in a virtuous phase of the cycle during the last few years,
with strong growth in income, output, and employment, good productivity, and falling inflation.
It seems to me that the risks are rising that we are going to experience the mirror image of those
favorable developments including slower economic growth with possible declines in income,
output, and employment, and rising inflation. On the outlook for corporate earnings and the
stock market, I was surprised that the Greenbook talks about a decline of only 20 percent in stock
prices because it also says that we have seen the peak level of corporate earnings in the third
quarter of this year. According to the Greenbook, corporate earnings will be essentially flat from
this quarter through the second quarter of next year and will then decline for the subsequent six
quarters. By the first quarter of the year 2000, the level of corporate earnings will be below
where it is today. I think that if the standard view in the stock analyst community were that the
level of corporate earnings early in the next millennium would be below today's level, we would
have a more severe correction than the staff is talking about.

11/12/97

52
The notion that any policy action would be viewed as preemptive is true only from the

perspective of the national statistics, such as the consumer price index, but not from the
standpoint of Main Street. Wall Street might think so; I do not think Main Street would. I
believe that when people on Main Street look at asset prices, not just equities but assets in local
communities such as those they are seeing in the housing market and the farmland market, the
anecdotal reports would not say that a policy action would be viewed as preemptive. Their
reaction would be that it was warranted in current economic circumstances.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Broaddus.
MR. BROADDUS. Mr. Chairman, by all accounts, activity in the Fifth District has
continued to expand strongly since our September meeting. By now, tight labor markets are
obviously old news but, if anything, our sense is that they have tightened even further. Several
manufacturers in our region told us over the last several weeks that they had accelerated their
purchases of equipment because of the difficulty they are having in finding new workers. In
general, the consensus among nearly all our contacts is that just about everybody who is willing
and able to work is already working. Anecdotally, I have a little direct personal experience with
this. I have two sons. The older one graduated from college back in 1992, and it took him
almost a year to get a paying job. The younger one graduated this year, and he already has two
jobs. While he was on one of them the other day, someone came up and offered him another,
better job.
Elsewhere, and somewhat related to what I just said about labor markets, there is
evidence of some precautionary inventory building in our area, especially at the factory level.
The delays in rail deliveries are causing some manufacturers to stockpile raw materials because

53

11/12/97

of the difficulty they are having with those deliveries. And some factories are stockpiling
finished products since it's hard to find additional workers to raise production when demand
increases unexpectedly.
Despite this evidence of strong demand and tight labor markets, the reports we are
getting on final prices are still generally mixed. Trucking rates have been rising this year. As I
mentioned earlier, it is generally expected that health care costs will rise appreciably over the
course of the next 12 months or so, but goods prices at both the wholesale and retail level
generally have been flat recently.
Finally, like Jerry Jordan, we are seeing evidence of booming real estate conditions in
the District, especially commercial real estate. That is especially true right here in the
Washington metropolitan area. And we are beginning to hear comments that developers are now
making some of the same kinds of mistakes as were made back in the 1980s. We have a lot of
pickup trucks in our District, too!
At the national level, we have a lot of new information since our September meeting.
I think the headline of 3-1/2 percent growth in real GDP in the third quarter indicates clearly that
the economic momentum we have seen for a year is continuing. Indeed, the growth rate in that
quarter, as we all know, would have been even stronger had it not been for a slackening in
inventory accumulation. And it appears that the fourth quarter is starting off on a strong note if
the job report and the purchasing managers' reports are any indication. We had a big increase in
employment in October. The increase was well above the average monthly increase for the first
three quarters of the year.

54

11/12/97

In short, as I see it, the economy currently appears to be growing at a rate well above
the staff's estimate of potential longer-term growth of 2-1/2 percent, and we are projecting that
such growth will continue roughly through the second quarter of next year. Beyond this, the
demand for labor nationally appears to be outstripping the sustainable supply currently by a
factor of maybe 2 or 3. That is certainly consistent with what we hear in our District about the
difficulty of finding employable people. Factory utilization rates, according to the Greenbook,
are currently above past noninflationary levels.
Against this background of quite robust economic activity, the recent stock market
volatility, as I see it, is being widely viewed in the markets as precluding any Fed policy
tightening for the time being. And what I think is more important is that because the Fed is
expected to remain on the sidelines for a while, even very strong economic reports like the
third-quarter GDP report and the job report are not getting much reaction in bond markets. They
are having little effect on longer-maturity rates. This insensitivity of longer-term rates to the
gathering momentum in the economy--and I worry about this--may prevent them from playing
their usual role as an automatic stabilizer for the economy. In that sense, one might make the
case that the recent market volatility has caused a de facto easing of monetary policy.
Bottom line, I see a number of factors that increase the upside risks in the near-term
outlook. These include the accommodation of an economy growing well above potential, labor
demand outstripping labor supply, factory utilization rates at high levels, and the short-circuiting
of the usual automatic restraining force of increases in longer-term interest rates due to the
market expectation that the Fed is on hold. We have heard a lot about downside risks, and they
are certainly there, but the developments I noted certainly increase the upside risks. In my view,

11/12/97

55

they also increase the danger that we could get behind the curve, as I think one could argue we
did in at least somewhat similar circumstances back in 1988 and 1989.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Moskow.
MR. MOSKOW. Mr. Chairman, the economic conditions in the Seventh District are
quite similar to what I have been reporting for several meetings. Our regional economy
continues to operate at very high levels, but it is expanding at a slower rate than the nation. Our
housing and manufacturing sectors are prime examples of this.
As I have noted before, labor supply constraints seem to be trimming growth in our
region. Labor markets remain very tight. The unemployment rate in District states has been
below 4 percent since May. One of our directors noted that his firm is paying bonuses to retain
computer-related staff, and salary increases of one-third for these skills are not uncommon now.
Many retailers express concern about not having enough staffing for the holiday shopping
season. Moreover, based on the unpublished results from the latest Manpower employment
survey, labor demand continues to be quite robust. Hiring plans are the strongest for any first
quarter since 1989, with hiring intentions remaining uniformly high in all geographic regions of
the nation. This survey is not going to be made public until Monday, November 24, so this
information is confidential until then. For some time, I have reported that wage rates in the
Midwest had not risen appreciably faster than in the rest of the nation despite our having the
tightest labor markets in the country. However, the latest ECI data show that over the past year,
total compensation costs as well as the wage and salary component were up considerably more in
the Midwest than in any other region in the country.

56

11/12/97

In terms of consumer spending trends, retailers report that sales improved over the
month of October as the weather got cooler. Reports were mixed concerning whether there has
been any impact from the recent stock market volatility. For example, a very large retailer and
one of the Big Three automakers reported that sales actually improved in the last week of
October. Another of the Big Three showed no noticeable impact. In contrast, the last of the Big
Three attributed a sales decline to the stock market. So, on this question, reports of the Big
Three clearly are mixed.
Competition in the auto industry is described as brutal, and at least one major
automaker, General Motors, will be doing more discounting in the near term. You will recall
that GM starting offering end-of-model-year discounts in July this year rather than in the usual
October time frame. This, in our view, was the major reason that GM's October sales were weak
rather than any serious problems associated with Union Pacific. People we talk to at GM and
other companies generally said that while the Union Pacific situation posed some temporary
difficulties, it was not having a significant impact on deliveries or sales. The trucking industry is
seeing very strong demand, and it is not just a result of the Union Pacific problems, as strength is
apparent in areas of the nation not served by the railroad.
The steel industry also faces strong demand, but with new capacity having come on
stream, prices for a wide variety of steel products are expected to drop next year. On the other
hand, prices for corrugated and paper products have been increasing and further increases are
expected in November.
Turning to the national outlook, despite a good deal of financial market uncertainty,
the economic situation has not changed greatly since our last meeting. The news on inflation

57

11/12/97

continues to be good, but the long-awaited slowing in aggregate demand seems to be yet further
out on the horizon. Even factoring in a larger trade deficit due to the recent events in Southeast
Asia, our forecast sees above-potential growth this quarter and out into 1998. The most recent
data suggest that labor demand continues to grow more rapidly than the working-age population
and that the increase in participation rates has at least temporarily ended. Thus, the tightening in
labor markets that occurred early this year may be further intensified. Perhaps the investment
boom has increased our productive capacity enough to avoid a buildup in inflationary pressures,
but still the resource utilization numbers suggest that the increase in demand may have exceeded
the growth in capacity.
On balance, I feel that the risks have increased and are still on the upside. There is
one other recent event relevant to our economy that I want to mention. That is the defeat--or I
guess more accurately the withdrawal--of the fast track trade legislation several days ago. Short
term, that prevents the United States from negotiating free trade agreements with Chile, other
Latin American countries, and the APEC nations. Longer term, it will inhibit our nation's
progress in expanding trade, which we all know increases our standard of living. My overriding
concern is that the United States has been a leader throughout the world in multi and bilateral
negotiations to open markets and expand trade, and we are now taking a major step backward. I
understand that there is some chance that the fast track legislation will be reintroduced next year,
possibly in a more limited form. But 1998 is an election year, which poses another set of
difficulties in getting this type of legislation enacted. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Minehan.

11/12/97

58
MS. MINEHAN. Mr. Chairman, there is not a whole lot that is really new in New

England. In a nutshell, our unemployment rates remain well below the national rate. The rate of
job growth also remains below the national rate, but it finally has been sufficient to bring the
region back to its pre-recession employment levels. This has occurred about a year earlier than
most forecasters had been expecting, so it is very good news for the region as a whole. Our state
economies are all quite healthy. Their tax revenues in fiscal year 1997 provided all of them with
surpluses somewhere between 2 and 5 percent of their spending bases. Inflation remains
subdued, as evidenced both by anecdotal reports and the CPI for the Boston area. Increasingly,
we hear the lament in a variety of forms that economic conditions are so good they can only get
worse.
I want to comment on a couple of developments of a local nature with some national
implications. First of all, loan growth at the four large First District banking organizations that
are tracked on a weekly basis accelerated to an annual rate of about 18 percent most recently.
That increase is well above national trends and well above what it has been locally. This was a
result of solid commercial loan growth at the District's two largest banks as well as concerted
efforts to expand real estate portfolios, both residential and commercial. Banks in the District, as
elsewhere, remain very profitable. They are well capitalized and their stock prices are as high as
three to five times book value. However, the CEO of one of our banks in the $10 to $20 billion
range--we don't have many of them, but we have one or two--told me last week that his
institution, which had been increasing in size basically by acquiring smaller, mostly thrift,
depository organizations, was now in a holding mode because he felt the prices of those smaller
institutions were getting much too rich for such acquisitions to be sensible investments. He

59

11/12/97

characterized this as a "very dangerous time" when the availability of cash and the outrageous
price tags on smaller depository institutions could lead some organizations, his not included, to
very poor acquisition decisions.
As everybody knows, we have a large confluence of mutual funds in the First District.
Our employment numbers in the finance, insurance, and real estate sectors in Massachusetts
have grown almost 4 percent over the last year. The mutual fund industry is seen as one of the
main reasons for the tight Boston office market, which is getting tighter every week that goes by,
and more generally for the city's currently strong vitality. We have been doing some research
over the last year or so in combination with people at the New York and the Cleveland Reserve
Banks on what the reaction would be in the mutual fund industry and more broadly to a sizable
stock market correction. Lo and behold, about the same size correction that we had been asking
our contacts about actually occurred, at least for a day or so. So, we went to all the mutual funds
and banks that had been part of our earlier study to see how they felt they had weathered the
crisis. In general, the mutual funds believed that they had weathered the experience fairly well.
Redemptions were considerably higher than normal on both October 27 and 28, but purchases
were also higher, especially on the second day. Outflows were within the volumes that could be
financed from cash reserves. Some funds needed to draw on lines of credit, but those that tried
to access uncommitted lines of credit found that they probably would be better off paying the
extra price to get their lines of credit on a committed basis. Funds reported no major liquidity
problems and no significant problems executing payments, but they did experience a degradation
in response time to shareholder calls. Banks serving the mutual funds industry also reported no
significant delays, and one contact observed that the increased transaction volumes were likely to

60

11/12/97

be highly profitable to the banks in question. So, maybe the next time we go out and talk to the
funds, we need to consider asking them about a bigger stock market correction!
Turning to the national forecast, I guess all of us around the table have been
impressed, as I know we have been in Boston, by the continuing strength of the economy and the
continuing environment of a low and even declining inflation experience as reflected in broad
measures of prices. While we have observed this favorable economic performance, we also have
found that we are unable with our current forecasting methods to project both the strength of the
GDP and the quiescence of inflation.
As a response to our own sense of uncertainty about these developments, we invited a
few fairly well known forecasters to talk about inflation and how we might better forecast it. As
one can imagine, there was a considerable divergence of opinion as there always is when such
people are brought in to talk about something so close to their hearts as the way they forecast
inflation. There was, however, a good deal of focus by two or three of these forecasters on the
impact of the change in relative prices of computers--something that Bob Parry talked about a
little earlier--in creating a positive supply shock with sufficient feedback effects to account for
much of our inflation success. Now, they recognize that it is possible that the relative change in
the prices of computers and its impact on our overall inflationary trends is temporary, somewhat
like health care cost changes or import price changes, but forecasting how temporary it is really
presents a conundrum. It would seem that the relative changes in computer prices might be
much longer-lived and have a much greater impact on the overall trends in inflation than changes
in either health costs or import prices. Maybe this is just the other side of the new paradigm

11/12/97

61

economy, or whatever. There did seem to be a sense among these forecasters of a much less
temporary impact and a potential for a much longer-run effect on our inflation numbers.
We talked a little about the uncertainties stemming from the turmoil in Southeast Asia,
its impact on Korea and Japan, and the potential for a broadening of that impact. I sense that
many of you are much more sanguine about that impact than I am getting to be. I think that this
development inserts an element of downside risk that I did not see earlier, or perhaps it generates
a greater appreciation of the downside risk than I have had over the course of the last several
FOMC meetings. While I don't think we would disagree with the Greenbook's baseline forecast
that the economy is very strong--nearly all the incoming data suggest that it is--I do have a little
more question about whether we're going to see that transmitted as strongly to the inflation
numbers as traditional models would suggest. Also, I think I now have a slightly sharper sense
of concern about the situation in Southeast Asia and its impact more generally. So, I guess I
have moved out of the climate, or the attitude, of seeing all the risks only on the upside to where
I now sense a greater balancing of risks in this forecast than I did in previous ones.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President McTeer.
MR. MCTEER. The Eleventh District economy continues to expand rapidly.
Recently, we have had some upward revisions in Texas employment, which have put the state's
employment growth at over 4-1/2 percent for the last 12 months. This is about twice the national
rate and the strongest we have seen in Texas since before the 1986 oil price bust. Employment
growth in the third quarter averaged a slightly more moderate 3.7 percent, but it appears to have
accelerated as the quarter progressed. Even 3.7 percent is remarkably robust, given the very tight
regional and national labor markets. We are not sure that we know where all the new labor is

11/12/97

62

coming from. Relevant to its sustainability, growth has been evenly balanced across different
metropolitan areas and across different industries. This balance has allowed growth to continue
longer, at a stronger pace, and with fewer wage and price pressures than we might have thought
possible when this expansion began about six years ago. Also relevant to sustainability, some of
the sectors that were showing symptoms of overindulgence--construction, electronic equipment,
and instrument manufacturing--have seen growth decelerate in recent months, and sectors that
were lagging have begun to pick up. The border region, which was hit hard by the peso
devaluation in late 1994, has benefited greatly from the turnaround in the Mexican economy.
Meanwhile, strong worldwide energy demand and Mideast tensions have brought
boom times to the oil and gas exploration industry, placing the Houston economy on the same
growth track as the rest of Texas. Oil and gas well drilling was operating near 70 percent
capacity as recently as late 1996. It surged to over 108 percent of capacity this summer.
Although it was back down to 93 percent in September, the high level of drilling activity has
been putting substantial upward pressure on labor and equipment costs in that industry. Oil
exploration is a much more sophisticated and high-tech business than it was 15 years ago.
Consequently, the industry can remain profitable with oil prices as low as $17 a barrel, and some
would say lower than that. But the technological sophistication of the industry means that it is
also subject to bottlenecks when demand for oil rises. The supply of labor with the skills needed
to work with the new technology is not very elastic.
If we look hard enough, though, we can find some things to worry about. Hiring
problems are now widespread, and reports of wage increases are common in retail trade, business
services, and among skilled workers in construction. In the retail trade sector, markdowns and

63

11/12/97

discounting have become rarer. Business services firms find that they are able to pass on more
of their rising costs to their customers. However, these upward wage and price pressures have
not yet shown up much in the aggregate statistics. I have an anecdote that I think will win as the
most unbelievable anecdote of the day, [laughter] but I hesitate to give it to you because you
will not believe it.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Try us.
MR. MCTEER. We double-checked this one. One Dallas real estate concern has not
increased its secretaries' base pay in seven years, but business is so good that each secretary now
receives $5,000 per month in incentive bonuses. See, I told you!
MS. RIVLIN. Where do we apply?
SEVERAL. Yes.
MR. MCTEER. Just don't tell my secretary! The point is that some of these
profit-sharing bonuses do not end up in the wage data.
I was going to say that some of you know about "the little engine that could" and tell
you that in Texas we have the "big railroad that could not." [Laughter] I did mention last time
that this problem was creating some fairly serious bottlenecks in the Southwest, and Tom
Hoenig, Jerry Jordan, and Mike Moskow have already mentioned it here today. Those problems
are rooted in the botched merger between the Union Pacific and the Southern Pacific railroads.
They have been exacerbated by strong shipping demand. Southern Pacific stopped basic
maintenance and cut workers in anticipation of the merger, and Union Pacific was slow to
recognize the situation. Production at Eleventh District manufacturing firms has not been
significantly disrupted, but costs have risen due to late, diverted, and lost shipments. Accidents

64

11/12/97

have become a concern too, as long hours have caused railway workers to quite literally fall
asleep at the switch. So far, rail customers have absorbed increased shipping costs. However,
recent reports suggest that companies plan to begin passing these costs along to their customers.
Strains are expected to ease early next year.
Disruptions to coal shipments, caused in large part by these railroad shipping
problems, have contributed to the extraordinarily high natural gas prices, as have temporary
operational problems at one producer's offshore wells in the Gulf. The bad news is that natural
gas prices may remain high and volatile over the winter. The good news is that gas prices are
expected to come down as the rail snafu unwinds and operational problems in the Gulf of
Mexico are resolved. Over the long term, the news on natural gas prices becomes very good.
As many as a dozen natural gas pipelines are under construction or being planned to bring
Canadian natural gas into the Chicago and New England markets. This gas will begin to enter
the United States by the end of 1998 and will mean lower gas prices in the United States for
several years. That is bad news for Texas for these years ahead but good news for the U.S.
economy.
Mideast uncertainties cloud the outlook for crude oil prices. Crude oil accounts for a
much larger fraction of the energy market than does natural gas. The collapse of several
Southeast Asian currencies will reduce the cost of electricity to high-tech manufacturing firms in
the Eleventh District. On the other hand, it may have a significantly adverse effect on our
chemical industry, which before the crisis had already found itself facing increasing competition
from chemical producers in Southeast Asia. Moreover, the downward pressure on Latin

65

11/12/97

American currencies generally, and the Mexican peso in particular, may cut into future growth of
the District's exports. We don't expect this effect to be large, but the level of uncertainty is high.
As for the national economy, I have no unique information to impart. All my
comments on that are more in the area of interpretation and probably should best be left for later.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Guynn.
MR. GUYNN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Since the last meeting, the new data and
anecdotal information from our region seem to confirm that the Southeast is now settled into a
pace of economic growth that is very similar to that of the nation. That is occurring after our
regional economy had led the nation for several years. I suspect that experience colors our view
of the world, since we have watched our business people work through tight labor markets for
some years now.
Retail sales in the region have been very uneven, but much of that seems attributable
to the change in the opening dates of schools and some unusual weather. We talked to retailers
about the upcoming holiday season. They now describe their outlook as one of cautious
optimism, and that is a retreat from the unguarded optimism that they were expressing in late
summer. Manufacturing activity has slowed in the District. Not surprisingly, apparel continues
to be the weakest segment. According to our survey of manufacturing in the Southeast, which is
to be released tomorrow, production in October was little changed from September. The backlog
of orders has risen for two consecutive months. On the other hand, outlook indices for
shipments, new orders, and backlogs will be reported as having declined after large increases in
September. The anecdotal reports that we had been getting prior to that survey were more
positive, with pulp, paper, and building materials leading the way and with extremely strong

66

11/12/97

reports from the aerospace and oil-related industries. Speaking of oil, and building on what Bob
McTeer reported, oil and gas exploration continues to expand in Louisiana. The already high rig
count rose somewhat more in October. In fact, the pace of oil field leasing and exploration has
caused the day rental rates for rigs and service boats to increase by 50 percent over the last year
or so.
Residential construction in the Southeast has now slowed somewhat, but there is a
noticeable shift in commercial construction from office and industrial structures toward retail
space. Commercial space remains tight. Tourism continues to be one of the District's strengths,
with tight bookings both for hotels and cruise ships. District job growth was marginally less
strong than the national average in September. I believe this is the first time job growth in our
region has been below the national average during this business expansion. Wage and price
pressures remain modest, and expectations regarding future increases have not changed
significantly since the last meeting. In fact, we have seen some easing of compensation
premiums in construction in some areas. While the Southeast has lost jobs in the apparel
industry, the displaced workers have been able to move to higher-paying, although low-skilled,
jobs. [Laughter] That is a true story!
Nationally, I see a continuation of the good growth we have observed in overall
employment and modest price movements. Clearly, consumer spending is going to bear
watching, and I think it is yet to be seen how much the wealth effect or uncertainty concerning
financial markets will damp spending in the fourth quarter and beyond. Our own reading of the
evidence sees somewhat less of a wealth effect behind consumer spending than is reflected in the
Greenbook and hence less sensitivity to stock market changes over the forecast period.

67

11/12/97

Investment spending has remained stronger than I expected, but anecdotal reports link more of
that spending to projects that substitute capital for labor, motivated specifically by the rise in
labor costs rather than the anticipation of increases in productivity or sales. One would probably
expect to see this pattern when labor markets are tight and labor remains relatively more
expensive than other inputs. To the extent this investment pattern is widespread, we may see
stronger investment spending for a while longer than might be suggested by the capacity
utilization numbers and commensurately greater GDP growth in the near term than might
otherwise be the case.
On the inflation front, I see the outlook for prices, as measured by the implicit GDP
deflator, about the same as the Greenbook, but that is without assuming a 75 basis point increase
in the funds rate and without a major stock market correction. While I feel strongly that we
should not lose the inflation gains that have been made, I am not quite as certain as the
Greenbook that we are on an imminently inflationary path. I see little hard evidence to date that
this is the case or that immediate and aggressive policy actions are necessarily needed to get us
back on path. Indeed, the forecasts of the broader indices of inflation show less acceleration than
does the CPI. The CPI, we have to remember, reflects the effects of the energy price swings in
1996 and 1997, which lowered the CPI earlier during that period, leading to greater projected
relative upticks going forward.
Of course, any judgment on the probability of deterioration in inflation depends on an
assessment of the current stance of policy. While the monetary aggregates have been somewhat
expansionary over the past two years, the evidence for the past couple of months is that growth
of the aggregates has declined somewhat. Moreover, real interest rates, as we interpret them, do

68

11/12/97

not seem unusually expansionary, at least by historic standards, nor is this signaled in the
exchange rate movements. With policy not accommodative, the individual price movements,
including wages, should be viewed as relative price changes that need not necessarily feed
through to higher price inflation.
As has been discussed this morning, the wild card in the economy at this time is, in
fact, the volatility in the financial markets worldwide. Our own estimate, done before we got the
Board staff's work, also suggests a 0.2 to 0.3 percent markdown of real GDP growth. I remain
concerned, as does Cathy Minehan I believe because she explored this risk to the expansion
when she questioned Ted Truman about the secondary spillover effects, especially from Japan.
Less well publicized, even in Japan, until the last couple of days has been the pressure on the
Brazilian and Argentine currency and equity markets. I believe the Brazilian market actually has
declined more than the Hong Kong market over the last four or five weeks. This point was
driven home to me last week when I had a visit from Argentina's ambassador to the United
States. Should there be significant problems in Brazil, the fact that over 30 percent of
Argentina's exports are to Brazil could put additional pressure on the Argentine economy. I see
the risks not only in how much our real GDP growth may be marked down, but also in the
possibility that the United States will have to step in and support the economies of one or another
of those countries. Mr. Chairman, these are certainly interesting times. Thank you very much.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Indeed they are, and I think that is one of the reasons
we are running so late. Let's take a very short coffee break at this stage. I mean short because
we really are tight on time.

69

11/12/97

[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Stem, you have the podium but don't hold
onto it any longer than necessary! [Laughter]
MR. STERN. I will try to be concise. As far as the District economy is concerned, I
can say the same thing that Mike Prell said about the national economy: virtually all sectors are
strong. Labor continues to be in very short supply. I think there has been some upcreep in the
rate of wage increases, but it certainly has not been dramatic, and it does not seem to have
affected pricing as yet.
Just a couple of other comments about the region: Hotel occupancy rates in
Minneapolis are quite high. We know first-hand that they are high not only currently but
prospectively as well. We have been trying to book dates next year for director and other
meetings, and we are running into difficulty. There are two new hotels under construction in
downtown Minneapolis and two or three major commercial office towers, so we clearly are
seeing some step-up in commercial construction activity in the largest metropolitan area of the
region. The other comment I would make is that retail sales recently have been quite healthy,
and if traffic in the malls is any indicator, the holiday spending season looks promising.
As far as the national economy is concerned, if I assume that the Greenbook has the
various repercussions of what has been happening in Southeast Asia and elsewhere about right,
then it seems to me that we face greater risks than are indicated in the Greenbook numbers. Let
me explain what I mean by that. I think the immediate risk is for more of an acceleration of
inflation than is projected in the Greenbook. I say that because it seems to me that there is a
good deal of momentum to aggregate demand. There are gathering cost pressures. Labor is in

70

11/12/97

even more short supply than was the case earlier, and credit availability is ample. But longer
term, I think the risks may be on the other side. I say that because it seems to me that if we carry
out the policy envisioned in the Greenbook and we get the assumed decline in stock values and
associated negative wealth effects, the resulting sluggish growth in real GDP in 1999 and
perhaps beyond will occur according to the Greenbook forecast in an environment where the
saving rate stays at a quite low level. I can imagine circumstances where that saving rate may
bounce up, if not in 1999 then certainly thereafter. If so, it seems to me that the higher rate of
saving would add to the risks of an even more sluggish economic performance. So, my sense of
the situation is that perhaps we are facing, both near term and longer term, greater risks than the
Greenbook numbers suggest.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Melzer.
MR. MELZER. Thanks, Alan. The economic news from the Eighth District
continues to be remarkably good. Business contacts in the District remain very optimistic about
future economic prospects. However, tight labor markets are a concern. The District's sevenstate unemployment rate, at 4.6 percent in September, remained below the national average.
Payroll employment growth continues to slow, in part because of a shortage of available
workers. Payroll employment grew at a 0.5 percent annual rate in the third quarter, well below
the nation's 2.3 percent annual rate. District banks have been pumping a great deal of liquidity
into the regional economy. Commercial and industrial lending has been strong as firms
increasingly have turned to banks to finance investment in inventories and plant and equipment
or to finance mergers and acquisitions. Although there has been some slowing in consumer
installment lending, the most recent state sales tax data for the District suggest, on balance,

11/12/97

71

moderate to strong growth in consumer spending. Mortgage lending has held up well in the
District, even though overall levels of new residential construction remain below last year's high
levels.
The national economy continues to expand at a rate above most estimates of long-run
potential. An average of over 230,000 nonfarm payroll jobs per month has been added so far in
1997, a pace well in excess of long-run trends in labor force growth. Unemployment has been
low by postwar standards for some time. There are signs of mounting wage pressures, including
the $.13 increase in average hourly earnings in the manufacturing sector, which brought the pace
of growth there to 7-1/2 percent at an annual rate over the last three months.
The third-quarter advance GDP report indicates substantial underlying strength in the
economy. Final sales increased at a 5 percent annual rate and personal consumption
expenditures at a 5.7 percent annual rate in the latest quarter. That is more demand pull than the
economy can likely continue to supply. Further, we appear poised for a robust fourth quarter,
notwithstanding the turmoil in Southeast Asian currency and equity markets. The fundamental
effects on the U.S. economy of these international developments should be small.
Good news on inflation and declining inflation expectations have been major factors
in producing the excellent economic performance so far in 1997. Nonetheless, I remain
concerned that some of this year's good news on inflation has been due to factors that may soon
abate. Most forecasters expect somewhat higher inflation in 1998. In the postwar era, when
inflation has been lowered and then begins to turn up, it has often turned up quite sharply in the
following 12 months. That could happen again, forecasts notwithstanding. Rapid M2 growth

11/12/97

72

and even more rapid M3 growth over the past two years suggest that the stance of policy is not
appropriately restrictive to lock in low inflation.
The question in my mind is surely when, not whether, inflation will escalate more
rapidly. The fundamentals have not changed much since the Chairman's House testimony before
the Committee on the Budget on October 8, which seemingly was made to prepare markets for a
possible tightening. If anything, unsettled markets aside, given a high level of demand growth
and accelerating wages, the situation has worsened from an inflation risk standpoint. Market
conditions may cause us to defer any action today, but it seems to me that the challenge for
monetary policy could be far greater going into 1998 and beyond if economic growth tapers off
and inflation picks up as expected. We may be running out of room for continued deferral in
taking an appropriately anti-inflationary policy stance.
Certainly, there have been some opportunities this year and last when the stance of
policy could have been firmed without surprising the markets. Yet, it is hard to quibble with
results so far, and inflation is unlikely to rise at the rate it did in 1990 and 1991. But I wonder,
had we been more explicit among ourselves, if not the public, about our objectives, whether we
could have locked in CPI inflation at 2 percent or less when the economy was expanding
strongly. In my opinion, it will be very difficult to act opportunistically and lock in lower
inflation in a weaker economy because of pressures to focus monetary policy on the real side,
even if inflation pressures continue to mount. We cannot do much about the real economy, but
we can and should use the current opportunity to lower the inflation trend a notch. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Boehne.

11/12/97
MR. BOEHNE. In the interest of brevity, I will touch on only a few highlights. The
economy in the Philadelphia District is operating at a high level with tight labor markets, but the
pace of demand has moderated some, notably in retailing and manufacturing. There are several
other areas, however, that suggest that new attitudes are developing. Business demand for new
office space is very strong, and landlords clearly are in the driver's seat. Commercial loan
demand is also very strong, but the competition to make loans is intense. As a result, bank
margins are thin and the terms are very liberal. Lenders, if reminded, remember the lessons of
the late 1980s and early 1990s, but that influence on their current decisions is weakening. REITs
have a lot of money. Armed with a lot of cash, they are bidding up the prices of almost any
property that has some value. They still seem, at least in the Third District, to be more interested
in buying than building, although I think that will change as prices exceed reproduction costs. In
the credit card area, although there is justifiably a lot of concern, delinquencies have stabilized,
albeit at a higher level than a year ago. Anecdotally, the credit card issuers have been trying to
do something about the quality of their new issues. But I don't think what we're seeing suggests
that they are successful because the new issues seem to have about the same quality as the older
vintages.
In our market, wages had been going up in the 3-1/2 to 4 percent range. I think the
typical increase is now settling in at a fairly solid 4 percent growth rate and labor markets are
tight. Nonetheless, the familiar story is still there about the inability to raise prices, and I think
that is holding overwhelmingly. I do not sense an increase in inflationary psychology.
Turning to the nation briefly, the situation is that demand was supposed to moderate
but it has not, just as the inflation rate was supposed to accelerate but it has not. When we throw

74

11/12/97

in the market turmoil that we have had, I think recent developments point at least to deferring a
decision today. Nonetheless, given all the uncertainties as we look forward and weighing all the
pros and cons, it does seem to me that the risks of overheating have increased somewhat. In
particular, one is beginning to see some attitudes that could very well become excessive on the
bullish side. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Meyer.
MR. MEYER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The outlook for monetary policy has
become more complex since our last meeting. On the one hand, the slightly stronger-thanexpected third-quarter GDP report, indications that the momentum in economic activity has
carried into the fourth quarter, and a decline in the unemployment rate in October all underscore
and reinforce concerns voiced at the last meeting about the threat of higher inflation and the
convergence of growth and utilization risks. On the other hand, the developments in Southeast
Asia suggest a new downdraft on growth next year and further restraint on inflation, reducing the
degree of tightening that would otherwise have been appropriate and adding an important
element of downside risk that perhaps was absent previously.
How do these things balance out? Given the staff's judgment about the implications
of developments in Southeast Asia, the dominant concern in my judgment is the momentum in
demand and the recent and prospective declines in the unemployment rate that continue to point
to a growing risk of higher inflation. While I am comfortable with the staff forecast of growth, I
am concerned, as I was at the last meeting, that the unemployment rate might drift lower than
projected by the staff and that inflation might rise more than they anticipate, reflecting my
somewhat less optimistic assessment of trend productivity growth.

11/12/97

One doubt sometimes expressed about the need for further tightening in this
environment is the possibility that increases in real interest rates this year have already imposed
the requisite degree of restraint. Although the nominal federal funds rate has increased only
slightly, the sharp slowing in overall CPI inflation this year has raised real short-term interest
rates--computed by subtracting 12-month CPI inflation from nominal rates--by more than a
percentage point. This method of computing real short-term rates is used by the staff, for
example, in international comparisons of real short-term interest rates. The effect is qualitatively
similar though somewhat smaller if real interest rates are computed, as in the Taylor Rule, by
subtracting core CPI inflation from nominal interest rates. Should we therefore conclude that, in
effect, a sufficiently aggressive tightening in monetary policy already has occurred to inoculate
the economy against the risk of higher inflation? The most important considerations may be that
the current level of real short-term interest rates, however high and however much they may have
increased this year, does not appear to be restraining demand growth and that credit availability
in general appears to be supportive of continued strong growth.
But the key to why overall financial conditions still seem to be highly supportive may
be that real long-term interest rates, generally viewed as the more important force in aggregate
demand, appear to have declined over the year, even predating the decline in long-term
government rates during the current turmoil. The contrast between the increase in real
short-term rates and the decline in real long-term rates reflects both differences in the movements
in short-term versus long-term inflation expectations and differences in the movements in shortand long-term nominal rates. Long-term inflation expectations as measured, for example, by the
median expected long-term inflation measure in the Michigan survey and inflation expectations

76

11/12/97

in the Philadelphia Fed survey have not changed much over this year, in contrast with the sharp
decline in actual CPI inflation and the smaller but still significant decline in other measures of
short-term inflation expectations. Also, nominal long-term rates have declined compared to the
small increase in short-term nominal rates. This is reinforced by the comments of President
Broaddus about the recent de facto easing produced by the further decline in long-term rates.
Two other developments have reinforced the effect of the small decline in real
long-term interest rates on the real cost of capital. First, there has been a further increase in
equity prices this year, contributing to a further decline in the cost of financing capital spending.
Second, the sharpest slowdown in inflation has been that for durable goods. Indeed, outright
declines have occurred in the prices of some durable goods, and in comparison with the prices of
overall output, the reduction in the relative prices of durable goods has further lowered the real
cost of capital for such goods.
My message is that we should not take too much comfort in the rise in real short-term
interest rates that has been produced by a decline in actual inflation and an accompanying
decline in measures of short-term inflation expectations. The financial conditions that are most
important in underpinning real economic activity continue to be highly supportive, indeed more
supportive than at the beginning of the year. I conclude that if we want financial conditions to
become less supportive, we will have to do the dirty work ourselves.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Reports on the
Second District economy have had a somewhat firmer tone in recent weeks: employment growth
has accelerated; retail sales have picked up in mid-to-late October; retail inventories are in good

11/12/97

77

shape; wage pressures are reasonably moderate; housing markets have strengthened; the New
York City boom in tourism continues, and hotels are full and the rates are very high. Local
banks report that demand for most types of loans is increasing at a steady pace, but I am happy to
say that bankers seem to be showing somewhat greater restraint in the credit area.
Looking ahead at the national economy, I find myself mainly focused on what we
know now that is different from what we knew at the last meeting. At that time, the likelihood of
the emergence of inflationary pressures seemed sufficiently great that a monetary policy
tightening seemed both likely and imminent. Our forecast for the fourth quarter is a little weaker
than the Greenbook staff forecast but not very much. Next year and the following year continue
to look quite positive in terms of growth, though a little less robust than 1997. Our staff forecast
is based on some return to dependency on traditional models, and it therefore says that inflation
will accelerate to a bit greater degree than does the Greenbook. But it is the inflation forecast
that I find most problematic, both in the Greenbook and our own work. Since price stability is
what we are trying to achieve, uncertainty about the inflation forecast is particularly challenging.
The unusually good price performance of the last few years is capable of being fully explained
by the combination of a stronger dollar, wage restraint, and the slow growth of health benefit
costs. We all have been worried about how long those trends can continue. Obviously, wages
and benefit costs could rise more without increasing inflationary pressures if productivity
increases were to, in a sense, finance the faster rise in wages and benefit costs. Lo and behold,
productivity does seem to be improving quite significantly; at least it was improving quite
significantly in the second and third quarters. But again we do not know how long that will
continue.

11/12/97

The changes in financial markets that already have occurred and the contagion effect
that definitely is still going around the world are developments that are likely to reduce growth,
and they may do so with a somewhat greater impact if they have a seriously adverse effect on
consumer confidence. In my view, the result of all this is that the degree of uncertainty has
increased. However, I believe that the urgency that I felt at the last meeting for an imminent
change in monetary policy has been very considerably reduced.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Rivlin.
MS. RIVLIN. We find ourselves in a new situation. For many months, we as a group
have recorded our awe and wonder at the continued strong performance of the U.S. economy and
our varying degrees of concern about future wage and price inflation. We have shared our
evolving theories about why there has been so little increase in wages in the face of low
unemployment and why there has been no price pressure at all. And we have shared our guesses.
The Chairman does not like me to use the word "guesses" so I will not use it publicly anymore,
[Laughter] but it's okay to use it here.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. I "guess" that is all right! [Laughter]
MS. RIVLIN. We have shared our guesses about when the world as we thought we
knew it was likely to reappear. But we have not worried much about the rest of the world except
to note that global competitiveness and the strong dollar were helping us fight inflation, and that
the dollar was unlikely to go on rising much longer. Otherwise, the world economies seemed to
be just perking along, indeed growing well enough to buy increasing amounts of our exports and
all too willing to feed the voracious American appetite for imports. This month, however, we
have been forcefully reminded that the increasing interconnections of global economies and

11/12/97

79

capital markets were not just some cliche we all put in our speeches. Those interconnections are
real and have added greatly to the uncertainty about our own economic future.
As I look at the Greenbook, I find myself a bit more optimistic than the Greenbook
staff about the domestic economy and a bit more pessimistic about the international situation.
My optimism about the domestic economy relates mostly to productivity. The Greenbook
assumes that at least a substantial fraction of the recent good news on productivity is temporary
and that it will revert to trend quite forcefully in 1998 because of the slowing of growth and
because of very tight labor markets. I increasingly think it is possible that the confluence of tight
labor markets, high investment, and technological change have come together to give us at least
a sustained spurt in productivity increases. So, I am less sure than the Greenbook seems to be
that we will need to raise interest rates in the near term.
Incidentally, I imagine myself making a speech a couple of years from now that would
talk about what we did on the assumption that the Greenbook lays it out absolutely right. It is a
hard speech to make. It says: we raised interest rates, we tanked the stock market, we cut the
growth rate to less than half what we ourselves thought the potential growth rate was, we raised
unemployment, and yes by then we are admitting that we overshot because we are beginning to
lower the interest rate again. We did this because we were worried about inflation, which even
in the Greenbook forecast was quite modest. Then we have to explain that although we were on
the forefront of arguing that the CPI was overstated and should be corrected, it is really
misleading to leave that correction in when we look at inflation. So, I would find this a very
hard speech to make, but maybe we will not have to. [Laughter]

11/12/97

On the other hand, as I said, my pessimism about the rest of the world is a little greater
than the Greenbook's. This is based on no real knowledge, just a feeling that there is a great
potential for snowballing weakness around the world and that our immune systems in the United
States may not be quite as good as we thought. We might get that stock market correction not by
raising interest rates but simply by the contagion from abroad. If I am right, we also might face a
much greater potential conflict between our domestic and our foreign responsibilities over time.
We will be wondering what we ought to do if the U.S. economy is still growing very strongly
and the rest of the world is a lot weaker.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Phillips.
MS. PHILLIPS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. For the United States, October turned out
to be an Octoberfest of sorts. There was plenty of activity, or froth, but it is still hard to tell if all
that market activity is only foam or if there is something of more substance underneath. Like the
fall event in 1987, we may be witnessing another departure of Wall Street from Main Street, but
some stock market events do have real effects. At this point, I think the jury is still out. We are
all struggling to assess the depth and extent of the Asian flu, but practically speaking, the
forecast errors are extremely high. The outcome is going to depend on how the various players
conduct their business going forward. I think that to say much else would only add to the
speculation. While it may be too early to diagnose the severity of the Asian flu affecting Wall
Street, we can make some comments about the health of Main Street.
In short, the economy is doing extremely well in all sectors. Business fixed
investment has been strong. Inventory even appears low enough relative to sales that producers

81

11/12/97

should remain busy at least for the near term. The labor market has remained strong.
Consumers returned in the third quarter after the second-quarter pause.
While the Main Street economy looks good, I cannot believe that the current rate of
economic growth is sustainable. As I said at the last meeting, U.S. demographics will not
accommodate forever the filling of 200,000 or more new jobs per month. Strains are starting to
show up. ECI wages and salaries have been increasing somewhat. Reports of supply
bottlenecks are becoming a bit more frequent, for example, in transportation, at Boeing, and for
specialty skill workers. Increased stock market volatility may be a sign of a fundamental
reassessment of the outlook for earnings by market participants. If we get a 20 percent stock
market correction, economic growth will be slowed by reduced consumer spending from wealth
effects and by reduced business fixed investment as the cost of equity capital increases. In
addition, profit pressures more generally may slow business fixed investment. Moreover, the
Asian problems that we know about are likely to increase the drag that the external sector has on
U.S. GDP growth.
So far, the pressures on resources from strong economic growth have not shown
through to price inflation. Recent statistics have been quite impressive, especially the deflators
reported in connection with the third-quarter GDP statistics. Improved productivity undoubtedly
has contributed to this performance. We also have to recognize that some of the credit for the
improving inflationary environment could be attributable to such temporary factors as the strong
dollar, the international competitive situation, and the lack of supply pressures. The balance of
these factors may be shifting in light of an international situation that remains quite tenuous.
Although arguments can be made that point to differing outcomes, I tend to think that, on

11/12/97

82

balance, inflationary pressures could be held at bay a while longer by the Asian turmoil. To be
sure, inflationary pressures are still there, perhaps just below the surface.
It is interesting to see discussions of deflation appearing more and more in press
analyses, and it is not just a few extremists who are putting forward arguments of worldwide
deflation. I have a hard time buying into these arguments on a wholesale basis since so much of
the U.S. economy is domestically driven and involves the services sector, which is less subject to
the effects of worldwide excess capacity. I do, however, think that the people pressing the
deflation thesis raise some interesting points. For example, how do we adapt to an environment
with upward price pressures in some sectors but falling prices in others? Also, what are the
effects of excess capacity in countries not dominated by market forces and thus less subject to
competitive cost and price pressures? I suspect that these may be topics for future discussion.
In sum, however, the risks have shifted somewhat since the last meeting. The real
economy is doing well and there is significant momentum in the short run, but some slowdown
must be coming. Financial markets are unsettled. The question, of course, remains whether this
is a temporary financial market event or whether there will be real effects not now anticipated.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Kelley.
MR. KELLEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Most of the incoming evidence we have
been talking about suggests that the economy is continuing to grow very robustly, quite likely
well beyond what even an optimist like me would like to think of as sustainable growth.
Certainly, it is true that there are widespread and credible expectations of a more or less
spontaneous slowdown. Inflation indexes continue to come in remarkably subdued, and I must
say that it is hard to see how monetary policy could be falling behind the curve, at least so far.

83

11/12/97

Nonetheless, absent extraordinary circumstances, I for one would be wrestling strenuously this
morning with a question of whether or not the time had arrived for preemptory action.
However, as we know and have been discussing, extraordinary circumstances do exist
in the form of turbulence in Asia and excessive volatility in many financial markets. We will not
be able to judge for some time what the fallout of all these events may be, but it is certainly
highly likely that they will act to some degree to damp the pace of the expansion. I can readily
envision the possibility that the impact, once all of these dominoes have fallen, would be at or
perhaps beyond the severe end of the range that we presently envision. If those events were
coupled with a policy tightening, this instability could easily ignite a very undesirable and
excessive chain reaction. This concern, together with the comforting belief that our policy is not
falling behind the curve at this time--although I must say I am not nearly so sanguine as I was
earlier about that--presents anew the line of reasoning that leads me to the same old conclusion,
"steady as she goes."
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Ferguson.
MR. FERGUSON. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. As has already been said in this room,
many reports suggest that the economy was very strong in the third quarter. However, the
reports also indicate that inflation remains quite quiescent. Going forward, I think there are
many reasons to be concerned that this good news on prices may soon come to an end. We are
well aware of the labor market tightness from the latest BLS report and from the reports of the
Reserve Bank presidents today. I also would note that a number of indicators suggest an upcreep
in both wages and benefits. I admit that some of those indicators are anecdotal at this point, but
we all recognize that anecdotal evidence is sometimes a leading indicator for developments that

84

11/12/97

eventually show up in the aggregate statistics. Capital has been readily available to borrowers on
very reasonable terms, and as Governor Meyer indicated, long-term interest rates, both real and
nominal, have retained much of their recent declines.
However, some countervailing forces exist at this time. We have talked a great deal
about the instability in Asia and the resulting fluctuations in our own stock markets. In this
regard, I would associate myself with those who said they had some concern that perhaps the
Greenbook forecast may be a bit optimistic in terms of both the rapid recovery of Asian markets
and the limited spillover. I will admit that the only obvious evidence I have for this is the
Brazilian austerity package.
More fundamentally, we have had two quarters of productivity growth in the range of
2-1/2 to 3 percent. The measured increase in productivity will obviously slow if economic
growth moderates. But in the long run, capital deepening and the possibility of some
improvement in the quality of the labor force provide a reason to hope for some continued good
news on the productivity front.
In sum, as others have said, we are in a challenging and complex period. Several
factors indicate that the risks are on the upside for inflation. However, recent instabilities in
financial markets may well result in some slowdown in the U.S. economy and a slight decrease
in risks for general price increases. Indeed, some of these instabilities create the likelihood of a
heightened reaction to any policy move that we may make today. For the longer term, while I
recognize that there clearly are some limits on capacity and we may be close to them, I am also
mindful that we may be seeing some evidence of a payoff from capital deepening. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Gramlich.

11/12/97
MR. GRAMLICH. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I would like to break my remarks into
a comment on our overall policy stance and another on the question of timing.
On the issue of the overall policy stance, I have become persuaded that, if anything,
the present federal funds rate is a little on the low side. I say that for three reasons. One is that
in the staff forecast the unemployment rate is low and inflation is heating up. It is heating up at a
very slow rate that is hard to observe, but it is heating up. The direction is clear. I believe
monetary policy should stay ahead of the game in cases like this. Secondly, this is the first
opportunity that I have had to listen to a go-around of the Reserve Bank presidents, but I think
most of you were supporting that conclusion. Now, I know enough about the law of averages to
realize that what the national statistics indicate will be reflected on balance in what Reserve
Bank presidents say, but a lot of you were providing anecdotal evidence that is not necessarily
apparent in the aggregate statistics at this point. I think there are indications in that evidence that
some overheating may be on the way. Thirdly, I want to refer to some calculations that the staff
has done on the Taylor Rule. As I understand at least the fitted version of that rule, it, too,
suggests that the funds rate is a bit on the low side.
Having said that, let me turn to timing. There I find a real quandary because from the
standpoint of domestic management alone, I think that the proper course would be to raise the
funds rate promptly by--I don't know the amount--3/4 percentage point or whatever and that
would be that. But then the international issue creeps in. There I think there are two
considerations--one that a number of you mentioned and another that I have not heard mentioned
too often. The one that a number of you have mentioned is that there are some risks that things
could turn out to be a little worse than we have seen so far, and that might argue against a funds

86

11/12/97

rate increase. The second is that I would be a little worried in terms of a concept that I will call
"international citizenship." We are trying to "unruffle" or stabilize world currency markets, and
if the United States were to raise its short-term rates at this time, that might put even more
pressure on some of these struggling currencies. I worry about that both from the
macroeconomic point of view and also in terms of what it says about international leadership and
responsibility.
These considerations define what I consider to be a difficult balancing act, but I would
join most of my fellow Governors in saying that I think this probably is not a good time to act
even though we might favor some action from the standpoint of domestic management alone.
So, I would be on the side of delaying a bit. I would also like to have the directive say
something about international events because that is a major reason why I am coming out with
this suggestion. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Let's move forward with Don Kohn.
MR. KOHN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. At your last meeting, many
Committee members were concerned that financial conditions were too
accommodative to prevent strength in aggregate demand from raising
resource utilization from already elevated levels, and hence imparting--or
perhaps accentuating--an upward trend to inflation in 1998 and 1999.
Indeed, there was a sense that tightening would be needed soon, perhaps at
this meeting, if the expansion in economic activity did not demonstrate signs
of slowing to a more sustainable pace.
In fact, the information becoming available since the meeting has
shown economic growth continuing to exceed the growth of potential and
utilization rates rising. As a consequence, a number of market
commentators have suggested that, in the absence of financial market
turmoil, the Committee would have been highly likely to tighten at this
meeting. In my remarks, I will begin by examining some of the arguments
behind this proposition, before turning to possible implications for policy of
the turmoil itself.

11/12/97

Strong growth and rising utilization rates would weigh on the side of
policy firming. Not only has the unemployment rate fallen, and to the
lowest level in several decades, but manufacturing capacity utilization has
risen to its highest level in 2-3/4 years. Moreover, with final demand
exceptionally robust, prospects are good that the expansion of output will
continue to exceed the growth of potential, as indeed it does for a while in
the staff forecast. However uncertain the Committee might be about the
NAIRU or the level of potential output, the chance that inflation will
increase goes up with the level of resource utilization. From this
perspective, if the Committee were concerned about the stance of policy
before, other things equal it ought to be more so when the unemployment
rate falls and capacity utilization rises, especially since the movements in
both variables were larger than anticipated. As the Chairman has pointed
out, a track for economic growth that continues to erode slack in available
resources is, by definition, not sustainable. It was concern about a similar
set of circumstances that led to the policy tightening of last March, and a
forecast that resource utilization would continue to rise would be the
strongest argument for a near-term tightening of policy, even before early
signs of cost and price pressures began to emerge.
But, of course, other things have not been equal, and not only in
worldwide financial markets. On the economic side, inflation continues to
decline by many measures, generally falling short of expectations. One
reason for this has been an uptick in productivity growth, which is holding
down unit labor costs. These developments have contributed to a marking
down of the staff forecast for future inflation, and they provide some offset
in several respects to the signal for higher rates coming from robust
increases in output. First, policy need not be as tight as it otherwise might
be because lower inflation means the Committee is not as far above price
stability--or any interim inflation objective--as it previously might have
thought, both now and likely prospectively.
Second, improved price and productivity performance has boosted
estimates of the growth of the economy's potential and shaded down notions
of the range of unemployment rates that might be associated with rising
inflation. As a consequence, at least in the Greenbook, the surprisingly
strong expansion of real output and the decline in the unemployment rate so
far this year have not resulted in as large an output gap as might have been
expected from previous estimates of potential output. Moreover, continuing
surprises in the output-inflation nexus suggest that high levels of uncertainty
about underlying relationships persist and may indicate added caution before

11/12/97

tightening in the absence of more concrete signs of oncoming cost or price
pressures.
Third, the recent inflation performance has probably fed through to
lower inflation expectations. It does appear that inflation expectations have
been edging lower--at least judging from the behavior of nominal Treasury
interest rates relative to rates on inflation-protected securities. Decreases in
inflation expectations, if prevalent among households and businesses as well
as among bond investors, would themselves tend to hold down any incipient
increase in inflation, at least for a time. Moreover, declining inflation
expectations have raised real short-term rates as the Committee has held the
nominal funds rate unchanged.
Thus, recent domestic macroeconomic developments by themselves-encompassing the news on prices and productivity as well as on resource
utilization--would not suggest that the case for a rise in the nominal federal
funds rate had gotten overwhelmingly stronger, even in the absence of
market turmoil.
In the staff forecast, the current level of the nominal funds rate was too
low to contain inflation in the September Greenbook, and it remains so in
the projections for the current meeting. An important reason for this is that
financial conditions, broadly defined, do not appear restrictive or moving
very much in that direction, even after recent market movements. It is
difficult to see evidence that higher short-term real rates are being reflected
in most other financial variables in the transmission channel or are
restraining interest-sensitive spending. Intermediate- and longer-term real
rates, for example, appear to be unchanged or even a little lower over recent
months, judging either from the rates on inflation-protected securities or
from real yields calculated by subtracting survey-based measures of
inflation from nominal yields. And funds continue to be available to
businesses on favorable terms in equity and bond markets and at financial
intermediaries. In sum, there does not appear to have been any appreciable
change in the interest rates or credit conditions that have fueled continued
above-trend growth. Moreover, without trying to put too fine a point on it,
the recent behavior of money does not suggest that households or
depositories are facing any greater constraints on their liquidity. While
money growth has been moderating in recent months, it has been doing so
from unusually rapid rates earlier in the summer, and the deceleration is in
line with expectations for M2 based on the Greenbook forecast, and
somewhat less than expected for M3.

11/12/97

The staff forecast does embody some effects on U.S. economic
performance from the recent worldwide market turmoil, but those effects are
limited and they do not damp activity enough to forestall a rise in inflation.
Indeed, the need for eventual policy tightening would still be a close call in
the staff's "worst case scenario."
If, in light of the risk of increasing inflation pressures, the Committee
were inclined to tighten at an early date, global financial developments
might still suggest reasons to postpone action, at least for a short time, to
assess ongoing market conditions here and abroad and their economic
implications. The effects of recent developments abroad on the United
States depend importantly on how political and economic systems in
affected countries respond and to what degree skepticism about the
prospects for emerging markets spreads to other countries, some of whom
are important to us as financial and trading partners. As Ted noted, the
course of events abroad appears to present a greater risk of damping than of
boosting economic growth relative to the Greenbook forecast.
Right now, a firming would come as a complete surprise to market
participants. Partly, this reflects the fact that the FOMC's assessment of
inflation risks is not generally shared by investors. Not only do futures
market rates indicate that markets do not expect tightening in the near term,
but the flat yield curve can be read as expressing very low odds on rising
interest rates for some time to come.
Market participants also perceive the skittishness of markets
themselves as another impediment to tightening at this meeting. It is
difficult to predict the response of nervous markets to an unanticipated
policy action. I suspect that interest rates would ratchet substantially higher
across the yield curve, as investors reassessed not only their read on Federal
Reserve intentions but also perhaps marked up their evaluation of the risk of
inflation itself, given the Federal Reserve's evident concern. The chance of
outsized spillovers to markets abroad--with feedback perhaps to the United
States--would seem to be magnified in the current situation, especially
because such an action, coming on the heels of the Canadian, German, and
British tightenings, might suggest to markets a general trend of rising rates
in industrial countries.
By themselves, skittish markets and unpredictable effects are not
reasons to avoid firming policy if the Committee saw appreciable inflation
pressures developing fairly soon, particularly as those pressures would only
build if needed action were postponed. In such a situation, a sizable
correction in debt and equity markets would be an integral aspect of

11/12/97

90

monetary restraint. Delaying action might only impose more disruptive
adjustments later, especially if it were feared that delay would only feed the
over-optimism of markets. In that regard, one lesson from the turbulence of
recent weeks is the resilience of U.S. asset markets, undergirded by the
apparently deep-seated optimism of investors. The wild swings in financial
prices and the front-page coverage they received would seem to have given
investors reason enough to re-examine risks and risk-adjusted returns. Yet
the net change in equity prices and risk spreads in the United States has
turned out to be quite small. If the FOMC believes that financial conditions
broadly defined are independently restraining demand, sufficiently less
accommodative conditions are unlikely to evolve by themselves. Still, if
economic circumstances were not seen as indicating a pressing need for
action in the near term, the Committee very well could favor waiting a bit.
Delay would give it the opportunity to see where and whether markets do
settle down and to better assess spillover effects on the U.S. economy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Thank you. Questions for Don? If not, let me move
forward.
Something unusual is going on in our numbers system that I think has a bearing on
issues I have raised in FOMC meetings over the last two or three years. The important and
striking statistic relates to the issue that Governor Rivlin raised, namely that the staff is
projecting a slowing in productivity growth in its Greenbook forecast. That slowing in and of
itself is the major force that is engendering an increase in inflation. I think it is important to ask
ourselves what evidence we have one way or the other on this issue.
First of all, if we disaggregate the staff's forecast of labor productivity into capital
deepening, changes in labor quality, and total factor productivity, we will find that total factor
productivity--the usual residual that all of us have been taught to interpret as an embodiment of
technological gain--appears to have risen in 1997. Indeed, if the synergies that we have been
observing in different segments of the capital goods markets continue to materialize, we could
very readily expect that residual to grow even more rapidly in the years ahead. But even if total

91

11/12/97

factor productivity stabilizes, then the labor productivity numbers that are in the Greenbook, as
best I can judge, are probably much too low. Just using the internal data that are not exactly built
into the Greenbook forecast but are incorporated in the Board staff's evaluation of productivity
associated with capital deepening, the residual actually goes down significantly in 1998 and
1999. And if one were merely to assume that total factor productivity remains at the 1997 level,
then instead of getting productivity increases of 1.6 percent in 1997, 1.2 percent in 1998, and 0.9
percent in 1999, productivity would rise from 1.6 percent in 1997 to 2.0 percent in 1998 and 2.3
percent in 1999.
I do not know what the actual productivity data will turn out to be. I don't think the
staff can predict this; I don't think we can; I don't think anybody on the outside can. But it is
very important to recognize, as Governor Rivlin has indicated, that a significant part of the
pressures implicit in the price forecast, to which we are responding, rests on an evaluation of
what that residual will be. I would suggest that if we look at the data on the current underlying
cost structure, it is clear that the evidence, if anything, has been indicative of very constrained
cost pressures. You may recall that earlier this year when we were looking at the quite
remarkable and persistent rise of profit margins, we also were looking, given that prices were not
increasing very much, at very slow rates of increase in total unit costs, about two-thirds of which
are unit labor costs. Those data have not changed at all. Unit labor cost increases for
nonfinancial corporations are roughly estimated by the staff to have been approximately 0.2
percent in the third quarter. The unit labor cost increases for nonfinancial corporations are at an
annual rate of something less than 1 percent. While we do not as yet have any firm data on
nonfarm productivity, though we will get a preliminary estimate shortly for the third quarter, the

11/12/97

92

staff estimate is a rate of increase of approximately 3 percent following a rise almost that large in
the second quarter. Compared with the nearly 4 percent advance expected for the third-quarter
productivity of nonfinancial corporations, that implies what we previously knew, namely, that
noncorporate productivity is very badly underestimated. Indeed, the actual productivity
numbers for nonfarm businesses are doubtless much larger than the increases being reported.
Needless to say, all of this is important because it suggests that we may in fact finally
be getting some acceleration of productivity in the statistics after observing, as I had indicated in
earlier meetings, a very significant pickup in plant and equipment expenditures. This can be
looked at in two ways: one, as an indication of very significant increases in prospective earnings
starting in 1993 when the acceleration in investment spending began; and two, as evidence--after
the continued strong growth and indeed further acceleration of such investments in recent
months--that after a number of years we may finally be getting sufficiently higher profit rates
from new facilities to suggest that the previously prospective increases in earnings have indeed
begun to materialize. Those prospective increases were based on evaluations by plant managers
of various new technologies that have become available and the ability of those technologies to
increase factory floor productivity and its equivalent in the nonmanufacturing area.
So, we are looking at an acceleration of investment in capital goods, which
presumably are being purchased because the required rate of return is there. And as some of you
have mentioned, part of that acceleration probably stems from an endeavor to replace labor,
whose availability is diminishing rapidly. I think this type of productivity increase is real in the
sense that it is not inconsistent with the anecdotal reports. Indeed, it's the earlier data that were

93

11/12/97

inconsistent. The statistics we are seeing now seem to square readily with what we observe is
going on in most companies.
Of course, this is important because we can have an increase in compensation per
hour, which indeed I suspect the numbers are showing, without unit labor costs moving up to a
point where they are pressing on profit margins or affecting the price level. I know we had a
significant increase in average hourly earnings in October, but a good part of that was the result
of overtime and of mix shifts, which I gather brings the published 0.5 percent monthly figure
down to 0.3 percent on an adjusted basis. And we probably are still picking up some spillover
from the rise in the minimum wage. So while I believe there has been some acceleration in
compensation per hour, certainly in the ECI and especially in wages and salaries, I still see it as
rather modest and unit labor costs being held in check to a significant extent by what appears to
be accelerating growth in productivity.
At the last meeting, I looked at what was a very poor trend in labor availability, and I
suggested that by this meeting there would be a 50/50 probability that we would have to move.
The argument I was making then, before we had a reasonable fix on the third-quarter
productivity numbers, was that we were running out of available labor at a particularly rapid
pace. Not only was unemployment falling, but the number of people not in the labor force who
wanted jobs was declining quite appreciably. The October labor market figures, which were just
released, made that far worse. The decline in the number of people in the labor force who
wanted to work but did not have a job was quite pronounced in October and the "not in the labor
force" group who wanted a job also dropped quite appreciably, seasonally adjusted. In effect,
we are confronted with an extremely tight labor market, one that will inevitably continue to lead

94

11/12/97

to movement on the wage side. But it is unclear at this stage which is moving faster,
productivity or wage acceleration. At the moment, I do not think we can tell.
I'm not sure, even without the Asian financial turbulence, that I would have argued for
a rate increase at this meeting largely because the developments that are emerging are of such an
interesting, if not important, magnitude that it will take one or two more months of CPI and other
price measures to see what is going on. Also, not insignificantly, we are waiting for a decline in
profit margins, which I must say we have been projecting now quarter by quarter, Greenbook by
Greenbook going back seemingly to the 19th century! [Laughter] I suspect that is not literally
true, but I think it is a very important issue because, as I have said earlier, the first sign that we
will see is that profit margins will begin to be squeezed. If that happens, we are going to get a
nice, fat contraction in the stock market. I am not sure how this process is playing out, but in any
event to quote Governor Kelley, "We do not have to 'wrassle' with it at this point." You didn't
put it quite that way; I'm paraphrasing!
MR. KELLEY. Wrestle.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Okay, wrestle.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. He is from the sophisticated part of Texas.
MR. KELLEY. I am sensitive to that!
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. In any event, as I judge our discussion, we are not going
to have a serious problem in reaching a decision on whether we move today. As nearly all of
you have indicated in one way or another, moving today given the Asian situation would invite
extraordinary financial disruption. Whatever we believe we may have to do in December or
later, I think it is quite appropriate for us to stand pat today. But I still think that with the

95

11/12/97

asymmetry of pressures in the labor markets, we have no real choice about maintaining an
asymmetric directive toward tightening. As I read what all of you have been saying to a greater
or lesser extent, that seems to be where most of you stand. Vice Chair.
VICE CHAIRMAN MCDONOUGH. I stand exactly where you do, Mr. Chairman,
"B" asymmetric.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Meyer.
MR. MEYER. Let me offer at least a slightly different perspective. In the absence of
developments in Southeast Asia and the related turmoil in world financial markets, I believe a
1/4 percentage point increase in the funds rate would have been justified today. In my judgment,
this move would have been consistent with the concerns voiced at the last meeting, concerns that
were reinforced by the stronger-than-expected growth of GDP in the third quarter, the decline in
the unemployment rate in October, and the upward revision to the GDP forecast for the fourth
quarter. Such a move would have insured the procyclical movement in short-term interest rates
that I believe is so important to achieving our macroeconomic objective.
Let me comment a little on my views on productivity. I frankly do not see anything
amiss in the staff forecast of a sharp slowing in productivity growth next year. GDP growth
slows in that forecast from 3.8 percent to 2.2 percent. If we get the slowing in GDP growth
anticipated by the staff, then actual productivity growth should be quite sharply below trend
productivity growth. The staff estimate of that trend may be a little high, but I think it is
defensible. I would not want to go higher than it is.
The second point I would make is that I do not believe the anticipated reduction in
productivity growth would be an important factor contributing to higher inflation. The reason is

96

11/12/97

that I think pricing is done more off trend productivity than off actual productivity. I believe the
slowdown in productivity growth is the key story behind the projected downturn in profits. So,
the behavior of productivity is really more of a profits story than an inflation story. But I
certainly agree that there is a lot of uncertainty about what that productivity trend is going to be,
and that is why I focus on utilization rates. From the standpoint of monetary policy, I think that
is really what needs to be kept in mind. Utilization rates continue to increase, but I think it
would be prudent to accompany that increase in utilization rates with a somewhat firmer
monetary policy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. In manufacturing?
MR. MEYER. I think we have to look two-fold: I am focusing more on the labor
markets for all the reasons that you suggested, but I also agree that the gap between capacity
utilization and the unemployment rate is important. If that gap widens further, then my view
would be altered a little. There is also no question in my mind that developments in Southeast
Asia and to a lesser extent the stock market correction and the uneasiness in world financial
markets fully support delaying any move to a tighter policy. The reason is not only because of
the turmoil in financial markets but because of some uncertainty about just how sharp the
economic impact is going to be in Southeast Asia and what the spillover effects to other
developed economies and therefore to the United States are going to be. So, I think there is a
premium on additional information that comes only from waiting. In my view, that does caution
some patience, but again I would be concerned if we did not respond over the longer term to
increases in utilization rates.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Minehan.

11/12/97

MS. MINEHAN. I am in basic agreement with you, Mr. Chairman. I want to add a
couple of thoughts even though I know the time is late. I want to make clear my thinking
because it has undergone a bit of a change.
My comments on a set of more balanced risks notwithstanding, I do believe there are
real inflationary concerns about the underlying momentum of the economy. These relate to tight
capacity constraints, the momentum in both consumer and business spending, the absence of any
real sign of a drag from fiscal policy, and very accommodative capital markets. But I have
begun to ask myself whether I really believe that this combination of factors will cause inflation
to tick upward so that growth needs to be reined in at this point. We have not seen inflation
actually change; in fact, it has gone down over the past year by most broad measures. I still hear
anecdotally from almost everybody I talk to in the First District a marked unwillingness to raise
prices even though there is a sense that wage pressures are growing. I think this pricing restraint
is only going to be intensified in the near term by the Southeast Asian turmoil both because of
reduced prices for competitive products and actual reductions in the cost of components for U.S.
goods.
I still think the best guess is the traditional one, the one that is embodied in the
Greenbook, that we need to move to tighten policy fairly soon to head off a strong inflationary
impulse. But I for one would like to do that on the basis of something more than a blip in wages
that can be, at least in part, attributed to minimum wage impacts. I would like to see more
evidence of rising inflationary pressures to strengthen my confidence that after a fairly long
period of getting inflation trends wrong, we finally got them right. In that regard, I am in full
agreement with your recommendation, Mr. Chairman.

11/12/97

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Hoenig.
MR. HOENIG. Mr. Chairman, I agree with your policy conclusion. I would point
out, though, that I do not agree with you because of the Southeast Asian uncertainty. I agree
simply because, although I am very concerned about the momentum in the economy, I do not
think that we can offer an explanation for raising interest rates today that would be acceptable to
the public, given the price data and the analysis behind those data. So, I agree with you on
policy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Broaddus.
MR. BROADDUS. Mr. Chairman, it seems to me that, even taking account of the
market turmoil and what is happening in Asia, the basic economic case for tightening policy is
considerably stronger today than it was at the time of our last meeting or even a few weeks ago.
My view is that our best course of action is to go ahead and raise the funds rate modestly today.
A modest tightening would have the great advantage of putting the Fed back into play and it
would allow long-term interest rates to resume their role as automatic stabilizers.
I recognize that an action like this carries significant risk. It could produce a very
adverse market reaction. We could be blamed for that, and that possibility obviously is an
argument for delaying any move. But I think the key point is that delaying a move also involves,
in my view at least, significant risk. In particular, if the economy continues to strengthen at
anything like the pace we have seen recently, then I believe we have to face the possibility of a
significant inflation scare. If that happens, the markets will get a "double whammy." First, as
interest rates begin to rise and the discount factor on equity prices rises along with it, that would
have a negative impact on markets. Second, if we ultimately have to play catch-up and take

99

11/12/97

strong action, which risks a recession, that obviously could have doubly adverse effects. It is this
latter possibility that really frightens me. To be sure, the probability of that outcome may be less
than 50 percent--maybe it is well below 50 percent--but I don't think it's negligible in the current
environment and the consequences of that kind of outcome would be very undesirable. To me,
that would be the worst case scenario, the one we really need to avoid. I would not want to write
Alice Rivlin's speech, but I wouldn't want to write this speech either. It is a tough call.
So, I strongly favor a modest tightening move today. Yes, there are risks in moving
today, but in my view there also are significant risks in not moving. It seems to me that the
recent, at least relative, market calm might give us a brief window to act. I believe we need to
take advantage of it today.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Boehne.
MR. BOEHNE. I concur with your recommendation, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Kelley.
MR. KELLEY. I concur with your recommendation, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Rivlin.
MS. RIVLIN. So do I.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Parry.
MR. PARRY. Mr. Chairman, some indicators show that the economy is experiencing
a positive supply shock. For instance, despite the robust growth in real GDP, nominal GDP
growth since early 1996 has not been that much higher than its average since the end of the last
recession. At the same time, other indicators such as the unemployment rate suggest that we
have overshot potential and risk a sustained increase in inflation. I believe one way to balance

11/12/97

100

these conflicting signals is to look at the recommendation from a policy rule that takes into
account both risks in inflation and output behavior. Our version of the estimated Taylor Rule
suggests that tightening policy by roughly 50 basis points by next quarter would be appropriate.
Ordinarily, this would make me vote for an increase in rates as a form of insurance against rising
inflation, and it is very tempting to take that position today. However, given the recent
instability in financial markets, I would be willing to wait a while before raising interest rates.
Consequently, I support alternative "B" with asymmetry.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Stern.
MR. STERN. I, too, support your recommendation, Mr. Chairman. It seems to me
that financial markets are too sensitive at this point for an action on our part. Having read
recently about some previous financial episodes in Southeast Asia and elsewhere, I also have a
suspicion that that circumstance may turn out to be a bit worse than we currently expect, with
implications both for financial markets and perhaps for somewhat greater spillovers to the real
economy.
Having said that, though, if we were in more normal circumstances--and clearly we
are not--I think I would want to get started with a little more restraint today. I say that because
as I assess the risks, as I discussed earlier, it seems to me that the value of some restraint today
would be that we would get a more favorable inflation performance than the one we are
otherwise risking and perhaps a smoother path for the economy as well.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Moskow.

11/12/97

101
MR. MOSKOW. Mr. Chairman, I agree with your recommendation, but I would add

that were it not for the financial volatility stemming from events in Southeast Asia, I think we
would be much more likely to act today based on developments in the real economy.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President McTeer.
MR. MCTEER. I agree with your recommendation.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Melzer.
MR. MELZER. Thanks, Alan. I favor alternative C, like Al Broaddus, but I could
accept "B" on the basis of unsettled market conditions. I believe inflation is likely to rise in the
near future as I mentioned in my earlier comments, and I think, as Al does, that there are risks in
waiting. So, I believe it is very important that when the Committee becomes convinced that
inflation will rise, it must be prepared to act promptly and forcefully. Strong actions like those
taken in 1994 send a message that the FOMC will not tolerate rising inflation. In my view, such
actions would encourage markets to build in expectations of permanently lower inflation.
Let me close with a longer-term thought expressed in the form of a few questions.
What are the FOMC's intentions? Do we like seeing inflation below 2 percent? Does the public
know it? I think, as I have said before, that we ought to be more explicit about our longer-term
objective. In that event, it would be much less likely that our actions would be misinterpreted as
being anti-jobs or anti-growth. I believe the last five years of relatively low and stable inflation
have demonstrated to businesses and consumers the desirability of relative price stability. It
comes back to a comment that Jerry Jordan made about how "Main Street" would perhaps be
more supportive of our moving than we might think. I also believe that long-term interest rates
likely would be lower because of a reduced inflation risk premium. And finally, I think it would

102

11/12/97

probably take less forceful actions to contain inflation and inflation expectations because of
enhanced credibility. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Gramlich.
MR. GRAMLICH. I concur with your recommendation, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Jordan.
MR. JORDAN. This expansion will ultimately come to an end when the speculative
excesses and imbalances have built to a point where we have no choice but to take strong action
to deal with them and put the economy into a recession. The speech I would not want to have to
write is one saying we never saw it coming and when we finally recognized it, we had to take
much stronger actions and cause a recession. Apparently, I am not as convinced as others that
the problems to which we ultimately will have to react will be in consumer prices or even in
wages or other measures of labor costs. The problem may not be in output markets but in asset
markets as suggested by historical episodes in this country, notably in the 1920s, and in Japan in
the late 1980s. In those episodes, inflation was never apparent in consumer prices or wholesale
prices, and the policy reactions were too late. I think we have to think more broadly about where
we see the signs of the excesses that we need to deal with.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. President Guynn.
MR. GUYNN. I support your recommendation, Mr. Chairman. I agree with those
who say we have not given up terribly much today by allowing ourselves a little more time.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Phillips.
MS. PHILLIPS. I also concur for the reasons that Mr. Guynn just expressed.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Governor Ferguson.

11/12/97
MR. FERGUSON. I concur with your recommendation.
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Let me ask the Secretary to read a "B" asymmetric
directive for purposes of voting.
MR. BERNARD. I will be reading from page 14 in the Bluebook. Page 14 follows
several pages of tables and charts: "In the implementation of policy for the immediate future, the
Committee seeks conditions in reserve markets consistent with maintaining the federal funds rate
at an average of around 5-1/2 percent. In the context of the Committee's long-run objectives for
price stability and sustainable economic growth, and giving careful consideration to economic,
financial, and monetary developments, a somewhat higher federal funds rate would or a slightly
lower federal funds rate might be acceptable in the intermeeting period. The contemplated
reserve conditions are expected to be consistent with moderate growth in M2 and M3 over
coming months."
CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Call the roll, please.
MR. BERNARD.
Chairman Greenspan
Vice Chairman McDonough
President Broaddus
Governor Ferguson
Governor Gramlich
President Guynn
Governor Kelley
Governor Meyer
President Moskow
President Parry
GovernorPhillips
Governor Rivlin

Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

11/12/97

104

CHAIRMAN GREENSPAN. Thank you very much. Our next meeting is on
December 16th. We will now adjourn for lunch.
END OF MEETING