View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

September 30, 2016

THE FEDERAL RESERVE’S BALANCE SHEET
AND FINANCIAL STABILITY1
Executive Summary
In this memo, we consider possible interactions between the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet,
financial stability, and the functioning of financial markets.
Section 1 considers the potential to use the balance sheet and, in particular, long-term asset
purchases to promote liquidity and functioning in markets during stress periods. The experience
of the financial crisis, during which policymakers deployed the balance sheet to support market
functioning, provided strong evidence that such actions are effective. As a result, operational
capacity to support liquidity and market functioning when needed may be desirable. Such
capacity would not necessarily require the Federal Reserve to maintain large holdings in normal
times. However, a framework in which market participants expected such support in stressful
periods would raise concerns regarding moral hazard.
Section 2 considers the role of Federal Reserve liabilities as a means to mitigate risks associated
with private money creation and maturity transformation. Greater provision of reserves or
reverse repurchase agreements (RRP) by the Federal Reserve could satisfy a larger proportion of
investors’ demand for money-like assets, potentially displacing some unstable privately-created
“money,” reducing maturity transformation, and thereby fostering a more stable financial system.
The available empirical evidence is limited and does not suggest these effects would be large.
Moreover, the literature does not provide much guidance on the optimal degree of maturity
transformation by the private sector or the quantitative effect of any shift in private-sector
maturity transformation on the stability of the financial system.
Section 3 discusses the interaction of safe-asset demand and the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
along another dimension. If the Federal Reserve were to provide more safe, short-term liabilities
to the private sector by holding a balance sheet composed of long-term Treasury securities, the
amount of longer-term Treasury securities available to the public would be reduced. Long-term
Treasury securities allow investors to hedge against certain macroeconomic risks, as the value of
these assets rises during economic downturns, and some research suggests investors have strong
demand for such safe assets. A reduction in the ability of the private sector to hedge
macroeconomic risk via Treasury holdings may lessen risk-bearing capacity, although the related
literature provides limited quantitative evidence on the importance of this channel.
Subgroup: Stefania D’Amico (FRB Chicago), Thomas Eisenbach (FRB New York), Jason Hinkle (FRB BoG),
Sebastian Infante (FRB BoG), Michael Kiley (FRB BoG), Thomas King (FRB Chicago), and Michael Palumbo
(FRB BoG).

1

Page 1 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

The issues discussed in both sections 2 and 3 involve balance-sheet practices that change the
consolidated liability structure of the Federal Reserve and Treasury. Prior to the crisis, the
Federal Open Market Committee preferred a balance sheet structure that was relatively small and
broadly reflective of the liability structure chosen by the Treasury Department. Alternative
balance sheet practices in the future may require coordination with the Treasury and the broader
public.
Section 4 reviews the possibility that changes in Federal Reserve asset holdings could affect
maturity transformation by changing the slope of the yield curve. A flatter yield curve, all else
equal, lowers the incentive to borrow short to invest in long-term assets. Experience with largescale asset purchases and the Maturity Extension Program (MEP) illustrates the ability of
changes in Federal Reserve assets to alter the slope of the yield curve, even without changes in
the size of the balance sheet (absent substantial shifts in the volume or composition of Treasury
issuance). The magnitude of these effects may not be sufficiently large to substantially affect
maturity transformation unless the Committee were willing to entertain larger adjustments in the
balance sheet’s size or composition than in operations such as the MEP, although the evidence is
also very limited in this area.
Section 5 reviews issues that would be associated with adjustments in the size or composition of
the balance sheet to affect mortgage and housing market conditions, which may have
implications for financial stability given the role of real estate in past banking and economic
crises around the world. In principle, the Federal Reserve could try to enhance financial stability
by “leaning against the wind” by selling MBS during periods of exuberant mortgage or housing
market activity, thereby putting upward pressure on mortgage rates. This may require holding a
large stock of MBS, on average, and such holdings may depress mortgage rates and
overstimulate housing finance and real activity. The Federal Reserve’s experience in the MBS
market outside of crisis periods is limited; in particular, it is difficult to assess the degree to
which the stock of asset holdings or the flow of purchases/sales affect mortgage spreads when
investor demand for MBS is strong. Moreover, large-scale sales or purchases of MBS could
affect financial conditions more broadly, potentially working at cross-purposes to policymakers’
macroeconomic objectives.
Several key questions for policymakers lie beyond our discussion: Do financial stability
considerations fall within the FOMC’s statutory mandate? To the degree they do, should related
actions taken by the FOMC be coordinated with other regulatory agencies and the Treasury?
And, finally, what risks to monetary policy independence may accompany such an expansion in
the FOMC’s objectives?

Page 2 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

1. Asset Purchases during Periods of Stress
Background
Experience during the financial crisis demonstrated that Federal Reserve balance sheet
operations have the potential to enhance the liquidity and functioning of targeted markets in
times of stress. For example, pronounced effects were observed in the agency MBS market
where, during the first half of LSAP1, the Federal Reserve’s purchases were an important
component in the restoration of market functioning.
Quantitative Assessment
As Figure 1 illustrates, key measures of liquidity in the Treasury market suggest that liquidity
improved between the first and second halves of the first LSAP program. Average trading
volumes increased by 20 percent, the yield premium paid for on-the-run 10-year notes relative to
off-the-run securities with comparable remaining maturities fell by a quarter, and failures to
deliver securities into repurchase agreements on Treasuries dropped 80 percent. The average
yield curve fitting errors declined by about half between the two sub-periods, suggesting
improved arbitrage activity. It is worth bearing in mind that these results occurred with a
relatively small intervention in the market—the first LSAP program purchased only $300 billion
of longer-term Treasuries, although Treasury market liquidity may have benefitted from
“spillovers” associated with the Federal Reserve’s substantial purchases of agency MBS.
Hancock and Passmore (2011) estimate that the MBS purchase program reduced “abnormal
pricing” (the component of the spread by which they measure market dysfunction) by about 70
basis points over its first six months. Other measures of market functioning also improved
notably. For example, the spread on one-month MBS repo over Treasury repo declined by about
60 basis points (to near zero) after the program was announced, and implied financing rates from
dollar roll transactions narrowed by about 300 basis points over the course of the program.
Policy Implications
The apparent and persistent efficacy of the first LSAP program compared with the evident
effects from subsequent programs suggests that an important element of LSAPs operates through
limits to arbitrage that can become pronounced during stressed market conditions.
Consequently, it is reasonable to consider the value of expanding the balance sheet in future
periods of stress to enhance liquidity at such times. Toward this end, it may be important to
maintain some operational capacity to conduct sizable purchases in agency MBS and Treasury
markets. Such flexibility would not necessarily require large Federal Reserve holdings in normal
times.
Any program that sets out to purchase a sizable fraction of the market in a particular type of
security runs the risk of creating moral hazard or going too far and creating distortions and
dysfunction in that market. However, to the extent that interventions of the sort contemplated
Page 3 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

here would be relatively rare, “emergency” measures—only to be enacted when markets are
suffering from insufficient participation and conceivably unwound relatively quickly—this sort
of concern may be mitigated.

2. Federal Reserve Liabilities and the Supply of Money-like Assets
Background
Short-term liquid and “safe” assets, either publicly or privately created, have money-like
properties because they are nearly immune to information asymmetries, making them
particularly useful to investors as a store of value, to facilitate trade as a ready means of
payment, or as collateral to obtain low-cost funding. Consistent with these observations, there is
substantial empirical evidence that the prices of money-like assets incorporate a significant
liquidity premium (or “convenience yield”). That is, investors are willing to accept lower yields
on these money-like assets to receive a nonpecuniary return associated with these other benefits.
Very short-term Treasury bills are a classic example of such assets, and both central bank
reserves and overnight reverse repos from the Federal Reserve may serve similar functions for
eligible institutions or investors.2
The liquidity premium can be seen in Figure 2, which presents an estimate of the excess return
required by investors on Treasury bills with remaining maturities of more than one week.
Researchers have interpreted this premium as signaling that the public sector has not fully met
the demand for money-like assets and thereby left room for the provision of such assets in the
form of private money-like liabilities by financial institutions. Such private money typically
holds the characteristics of public money during normal times—when investors perceive it as
seemingly liquid and safe. The ability to issue such private money at a yield incorporating a
relatively high safety premium and invest the proceeds in higher-yielding, longer duration assets
has provided a strong incentive for the creation of private money and maturity transformation.
Figure 3, which is taken from Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016), provides some evidence on
the rising demand for money-like assets among domestic investors in recent decades. That is,
since the late 1970s, the total amount of money-like assets—including Treasury bills, money
market fund shares, checkable deposits and currency, and other uninsured short-term assets—
held by nonfinancial businesses and households has risen from 28 percent of GDP to 42 percent.
Moreover, a considerable shift in the composition of these holdings of businesses and households
(the shaded areas in the figure) show that privately-produced money-like assets accounted for a
disproportionate share of the growth—until the financial crisis, that is. Between the late 1970s
and the mid-2000s, the share of Treasury bills and checking deposits in businesses’ and
2

See, for example, Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2015).

Page 4 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

households’ holdings of money-like assets dropped, while money market shares and uninsured
deposits became dominant.
Going forward, a variety of institutional and regulatory factors may change the supply of and
demand for these assets over time. For example, the liquidity-coverage ratio better aligns the
liquidity risks associated with short-term bank liabilities, shifting incentives of large bankholding companies (BHCs) away from less stable short-term liabilities and tilting demand
toward asset holdings of specified liquid assets; the supplementary leverage ratio, by not
differentiating by risk, may shift the demand of large BHCs away from low-return liquid assets;
money market fund reform—including floating net asset values—appears to be reducing the
attractiveness of investment in prime funds to some extent, increasing investor demand for
government-only money funds and shifting exposures away from riskier short-term funding
instruments.3 The supply and demand for money-like assets may also shift in response to
changes in issuers’ and investors’ perceptions of, and tolerance for, liquidity risk, particularly
given the experience of the financial crisis.
In quiescent market conditions, privately produced money-like assets can meet investor demand
for liquid assets and provide important liquidity services to private agents. For example, a
traditional role of financial firms in the economy has been the issuance of short-term debt (e.g.
deposits), providing valuable payments services to businesses and consumers and funding
productive investment. Similarly, the commercial paper market provides a source of funding for
nonfinancial firms, and the repo market facilitates a variety of transactions and positions within
the financial system. Nonetheless, seemingly liquid, privately produced money-like assets do
not have the safety of claims against the U.S. government and can become illiquid if investors
suddenly become dubious about the liquidity or safety of such instruments. Such shifts in
investor perceptions were powerful catalysts for instability during the financial crisis, when
investors came to question the worthiness of credit ratings and quickly ran from the short-term
liabilities of institutions perceived to be under strain and soon thereafter ran from private moneylike instruments more generally, leading to government support for money markets along many
dimensions.4
As suggested by Stein (2012), Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgenson (2014), and others,
government liabilities may be able to crowd out excessive private money. An increased supply
of very short-term liabilities by the government would satisfy a larger share of the demand for
safe short-term assets and decrease the liquidity premium, making creation of private money less
attractive to the private sector. For example, Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2015) estimate that
a given increase in short-term Treasury bills tends to crowd out about half as much privately
For a more comprehensive discussion, see Committee on the Global Financial System Markets Committee (2015)
and the Federal Reserve System staff memo on “Money Market Regulations” by Li, et al (2016).
4
For example, see Brunnermeier (2009), McCabe (2010), Gorton and Metrick (2012), and Covitz, Liang, and
Suarez (2013).
3

Page 5 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

produced safe assets, and Carlson, et al. (2016), show that the supply of private money-like
assets responds in just a matter of weeks following unanticipated changes in governmentprovided securities. This evidence focuses on changes in volume of short-term wholesale
funding of financial institutions, particularly commercial paper. More broadly, large changes in
the supply of short-term government liabilities in a manner designed to substantially alter the
volume of public and private money-like assets from the trends observed over decades would
represent a policy effort well outside the historical experience embedded in the empirical
analysis of previous authors, and the effects on the supply of alternative money-like assets is
difficult to assess.
While the empirical evidence has primarily examined the role of short-term Treasury securities,
Federal Reserve liabilities such as reserve balances and ON RRPs could also satisfy investor
demand for such assets. Figure 4 shows the take-up of ON RRPs over time. At least two
features of this graph are consistent with ON RRP playing a role as a money-like asset. First,
ON RRP balances spike on every quarter end, a time when the desire of foreign banks (largely)
to deleverage temporarily at financial disclosure dates (so-called “window dressing” activities)
decreases their demand for short-term funding and, thus, lowers the supply of money-like assets
available to U.S. money market funds. In response, it appears that money funds have shifted
their demand to the ON RRP facility around these dates. Second, take-up increased
significantly, hovering near $200 billion, around the tax date of April 15, 2014. During this
period, Treasury bill issuance had declined due to the Treasury's reduced borrowing needs (as
often occurs during tax season), and investors apparently substituted their demand for Treasury
bills with demand for Fed ON RRPs.
Quantitative Assessment
The potential for publicly-produced money to substitute for privately produced money is an
ongoing area of research, and the literature has not settled on the strength of these linkages.
Furthermore, whether Federal Reserve liabilities, rather than Treasury bills, can effectively
crowd out excessive private money is an even more-open question. Reserves can only be held
by the banking sector, and the degree to which their liquidity is transmitted to the rest of the
economy depends on their intermediation, suggesting that they may not be as effective as
Treasury bills in crowding out private short-term debt. Indeed, Figure 3 evinces only a little net
decline in private money since 2007, a period during which reserves increased by over $3
trillion, and some of the decline that did occur was likely due to regulatory reform and other
factors. Nagel (2016) studies the introduction of interest on reserves (IOR) in the United
Kingdom and Canada and does not find evidence that its implementation changed the
liquidity/safety premium, casting further doubt on this channel.5

Bowman, Gagnon, and Leahy (2010) study the implementation of IOR by foreign central banks and find that
although in some cases policy tightening was accompanied by declines in balances, these declines seem small

5

Page 6 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

On the other hand, the ON RRP program is open to a larger set of counterparties than the
reserves market and so may be able to provide money-like assets that could circulate beyond the
commercial banking sector.6 Infante (2016) provides evidence that Term and ON RRP take up
increases with the level of the safety premium, whereas private tri-party repo decreases with the
level of the safety premium. This evidence suggests that the ON RRP may be more effective
than reserves at crowding out excessive private money. Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016)
also emphasize the potentially broader reach of ON RRP.
Policy Implications
In terms of providing liquidity services, the Federal Reserve’s liabilities may play a similar role
to that of Treasury bills, since both reserves and RRP balances provide a safe store of value.7 In
addition, reserves may also have a convenience yield since they can be used as a means of
transaction. Any Federal Reserve policy or operating regime that maintained a large balance
sheet might therefore produce some of the “crowding out” effect discussed above, and such a
reduction in private-money creation could be beneficial for financial stability. Greenwood,
Hanson, and Stein (2016) emphasize these effects as a motivation for a larger steady-state
balance sheet, a point also emphasized in Cochrane (2014). Other researchers—including
Kashyap and Stein (2011), Stein (2012), Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016), and Woodford
(2016)—have gone further and suggested, on theoretical grounds, the Committee might consider
actively using changes in the size or composition of the Federal Reserve’s liabilities to target the
level of private-money creation as perceptions of fragility change over time. That said,
researchers have not pin-pointed the amount (or range) of private money-like assets that might be
consistent with a stable financial system or whether the Federal Reserve (or the Treasury) should
aim to displace essentially all of that private activity. The latter approach, of course, could
require a very large Federal Reserve balance sheet.
Nevertheless, even if the stock of private money was seen as too larger, it is not clear the Federal
Reserve needs to take responsibility for displacing private money-like assets. In principle,
Treasury could probably entirely satiate investor demand for safe short-term assets by issuing a
mix of bills and floating-rate notes. Moreover, the fact that bills, unlike reserves and RRPs, can
circulate freely suggests that the Treasury may have an advantage in doing so. However,
Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016) argue that, unlike the Federal Reserve, the Treasury faces
the risk that its auctions of bills could fail, and that, therefore, it may be more advantageous for
the Federal Reserve to supply money-like assets. These authors also note that the money
premium accrues largely to assets of very short duration, and the Federal Reserve could increase
relative to the increase in rates induced by the IOR. This suggests that the IOR controls rates through prices and not
quantities.
6
Although it does not emphasize financial stability considerations, the recent paper by Duffie and Krishnamurthy
(2016) does underscore market segmentation and the ability of the ON RRP to improve the pass-through of
monetary policy rates to wholesale money market rates.
7
See Carlson et al. (2016), which analyzes the possible monetary policy option of providing short-term safe assets.

Page 7 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

the supply of such assets while also reducing the amount of current duration (and therefore
fiscal) risk in its asset holdings by concentrating asset holdings in securities with duration
between 2 and 6 years.
To the extent that the Federal Reserve does supply such assets in the form of ON RRPs, it may
wish to do so in a way that is less than perfectly elastic. While the complete displacement of
runnable private money would eliminate run risk, incomplete displacement and the availability
of an elastic supply of safe assets from the Federal Reserve could exacerbate run risk on the
remaining private money. If ON RRP supply were elastic, the program would provide cash
investors with an investment opportunity (a truly safe asset) which could quickly replace
previously-held liabilities of the private sector. Consequently, the perception among investors of
a highly elastic (and unconditional) supply of Federal Reserve-backed assets could be a source of
destabilizing run-risk in private wholesale markets.
Frost et al. (2015) discuss some design considerations for the RRP program that could mitigate
run risks. In particular, predetermined “dynamic” caps on the aggregate amount of RRP balances
could substantially limit cash investors’ ability to rapidly shift a large portion of their portfolio to
the facility. Such caps, in conjunctions with an auction mechanism to allocate take-up, would
limit rapid changes in volumes and take advantage of the price-sensitivity of cash investors’
decisions, thereby providing some discipline particularly at times of stress. That said, Frost et al.
(2015) caution that a tendency for investors to become rate-insensitive during episodes of
financial panic may limit the ability of a well-designed auction mechanism for RRP to
effectively mitigate run risk once panic begins to take hold.
Substantial provision of Federal Reserve liabilities to crowd out excessive private money may
require very large holdings of Treasury securities (or MBS). Such large holdings could have
implications for the functioning and liquidity of the Treasury (or MBS) market. For example,
the reduction in the amount of Treasury securities in private hands, in the face of strong postcrisis demand for such assets owing to risk management and regulatory changes, could reduce
trading activity and lead to increases in liquidity premiums or other changes in market structure.
That said, the supply of Treasury securities has expanded substantially since 2008. Overall, it is
not clear that a potential shortage of supply poses a material risk to market functioning.
A large balance sheet could also have adverse financial stability implications if it causes the
interbank market to atrophy. All else equal, an active interbank market provides a means of
flexibility, funding diversification, and information generation that could deteriorate in a world
in which most banks always held significant excess reserve positions (see Bindseil, 2016). On
the other hand, ongoing RRPs broaden the set of Federal Reserve counterparties—and, perhaps,
ultimate investors with nearly direct access to Federal Reserve liabilities—which could entail
certain benefits for financial stability. For example, ongoing interactions with a broader set of
counterparties may provide valuable information on market conditions. Such benefits might be
analogous to the considerable information about Treasury and tri-party repo pricing and market

Page 8 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

functioning that the Federal Reserve has traditionally accessed as a consequence of its ongoing
operations.

3. Federal Reserve Holdings of Long-Duration Assets and Private Sector RiskBearing Capacity
Background
While the previous section and Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016) touch on one strand of the
safe-asset literature—the provision of safe money-like liabilities by the Federal Reserve to
reduce maturity transformation—an alternative strand emphasizes a broader notion of safe assets,
and this literature may also have implications for the interaction of balance sheet policies and
financial stability. Research suggests that long-maturity Treasury securities, though not moneylike, also earn a convenience yield.8 Moreover, Gorton, Lewellen, and Metrick (2012) and
Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2012) have emphasized the notion of investor demand
for safe assets defined broadly to include long-duration assets such as Treasury bonds. Under
this view, the Federal Reserve would have very limited ability to affect the net supply of safe
assets by changing the size of its balance sheet because, for example, increased issuance of
reserves or ON RRP would also require an increase in holdings of Treasury securities (and a
corresponding decrease in safe Treasury securities available in the market).
One reason for this may be that long-maturity Treasury securities provide a unique benefit: They
have a “negative beta” and thus provide investors a valuable hedge against a range of
macroeconomic risk factors. Caballero and Farhi (2016) suggest that this negative-beta
characteristic allows private-sector participants to hedge some macroeconomic risk. If this is the
case, diminished availability of longer-term Treasury securities brought about by an expansion of
the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet (all else equal) could would be expected to decrease the
ability of the private sector to hedge macro risks.9
The Federal Reserve’s holdings of long-term Treasury securities could also have consequences
for financial institutions’ management of liquidity risks as well as certain aspects of the reformed
regulatory regime. For example, under the Basel III rules, both Treasury securities and reserves
(as level-1 assets) count equally as high-quality-liquid assets (HQLA) under the liquidity
coverage ratio (LCR). As a result, larger balance sheet holdings of Treasuries to back reserves
would have essentially no effect on the net supply of HQLA. In contrast, MBS are level-2
assets, which face haircuts and quantitative limits. Thus, the Federal Reserve could adjust the
volume of HQLA available to satisfy the LCR by, for example, taking MBS onto its balance
8
9

See Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2012).
See Greenwood and Vayanos (2014).

Page 9 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

sheet and issuing reserves. While this possibility exists, current estimates suggest that HQLA are
available in more-than-sufficient supply.
Policy Implications
The idea that longer-term Treasury securities provide a useful risk-hedging device for the private
sector implies that the Federal Reserve could enhance financial stability by ensuring that the
private sector had access to as many of these securities as possible. In other words, one cost of a
large balance sheet—or, at least, a balance sheet more tilted toward longer-duration safe assets—
would be that it increases the costs of macroeconomic hedging and therefore increases the
private sector equilibrium exposure to aggregate risk. Similarly, if a shortage of HQLA were to
arise, the liquidity considerations just mentioned suggest that, all else equal, the Federal Reserve
may want to tilt its asset portfolio toward less-liquid assets (e.g., MBS), leaving as great a supply
of liquidity as possible to satisfy regulatory requirements and investor demand stemming from
other sources.

4. Federal Reserve Assets and the Incentives for Maturity Transformation
Background
Excessive private maturity transformation contributed significantly to the financial crisis. By
financing longer-term assets with short-term debt, financial intermediaries subject themselves to
significant interest-rate risk, as well as to risks stemming from the typical liquidity differentials
between long- and short-term contracts. The incentive to take these risks, of course, is that
longer-duration assets typically compensate investors more, through term and liquidity
premiums. The size of term premiums—which, in principle, can be influenced by the
configuration of the consolidated government balance sheet—thus helps to determine the extent
of maturity transformation in the economy and thus its sensitivity to fluctuations in interest rates.
By purchasing longer-term securities, the Federal Reserve affects the slope of the yield curve and
thus can potentially reduce the amount of maturity transformation taking place in the private
sector. Moreover, the slope of the yield curve can be affected by balance sheet actions that alter
the composition, but not the size, of the balance sheet: For example, Operation Twist in 1961
and the Maturity Extension Program (MEP) initiated in 2011 altered the slope of the yield curve
without changing the total supply of Treasury securities held by the public; both programs
involved sizable increases in Federal Reserve holdings of longer-term Treasury securities
accompanied by an increased supply of shorter-term Treasury securities to the private sector.
(In Operation Twist, the Treasury Department increased the supply of shorter-term Treasury
securities as the Federal Reserve purchased long-term securities; during the MEP. The Federal
Reserve sold shorter-term securities as it purchased longer-term securities.) Actions that flatten

Page 10 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

the yield curve may reduce maturity transformation, as a flatter yield curve implies less incentive
to borrow via short-term debt to invest in long-term assets.
Quantitative Assessment
There is limited direct evidence on the degree to which the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet has
actually affected private sector maturity transformation. The literature has focused more directly
on the effects of balance sheet actions on the yield curve, with much less focus on any
accompanying shifts in behavior by investors or financial institutions. Theoretical models that
have been calibrated to match the observed behavior of the yield curve have trouble generating
large duration effects (King, 2016), and the cleanest empirical estimates suggest that duration
effects are likely to be relatively modest in size.10 Li and Wei (2013) estimate that actions on the
scale of the Federal Reserve’s asset purchase programs through 2012 (equivalent to about
$1 trillion in ten-year equivalent Treasuries in addition to $1.25 trillion of MBS) lower the tenyear nominal yield by about 100 basis points on average. The estimates of Greenwood and
Vayanos (2014) are of similar magnitudes.11
Operation Twist and the MEP attempted to alter the slope of the yield curve by changing the
duration of Treasury securities held by the public rather than the overall quantity of such privatesector holdings. Swanson (2011) estimates that Operation Twist, which involved approximately
5 percent of outstanding Treasury debt at the time, reduced the slope of the yield curve by
approximately 25 basis points (with roughly equal declines in long-term yields and increases in
short-term rates). The MEP (which on announcement equaled a bit less than 5 percent of
outstanding Treasuries at the time, totaling $400 billion) had a similar or somewhat smaller
effect (Ehlers, 2012, and Cahill et al., 2015).12 As can be seen in Figure 5, yields on Treasury
securities with duration up to 3 to 4 years increased by up to 5 basis points, while yields at the
10- or 15-year horizon declined by 10 or more basis points.
It is not clear that changes of this magnitude would have a significant effect on the amount of
maturity transformation taking place in the financial sector. Adrian and Shin (2010) note that
broker-dealers’ use of repo, for example, is an increasing function of the slope of the yield curve;
while this reduced-form result loosely suggests some reduction in maturity transformation could
accompany a flatter yield curve, a fair number of other financial factors, which may also change
Empirical studies that have found sizeable effects of asset purchases have frequently interpreted their results as
supporting the importance of the duration channel (e.g., Gagnon et al., 2012), but it is not always clear that this is the
only possible interpretation since it can be difficult to disentangle the duration channel from other channels
discussed below. D’Amico et al. (2012) and Cahill et al. (2015) attempt this sort of decomposition and conclude
that the scarcity channel, for instance, is of comparable importance to duration.
11
As a caveat to these estimates, asset purchases may operate through both stock effects and flow effects, these
effects may be different for asset purchases and asset sales, and their potency is likely to vary depending on market
conditions and other circumstances, such as whether short-term interest rates are constrained by the effective lower
bound.
12
While the MEP was initially announced to be $400 billion in size, the amount was later increased to $627 billion.
10

Page 11 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

should policy actions attempt to manipulate the yield curve, are also included. Foley-Fisher,
Ramcharan, and Yu (2016) find some increase in the issuance of long-term debt and in
investment in productive capacity by nonfinancial corporations following the MEP, consistent
with a reduction in the maturity mismatch between their borrowing and investments. But they
also find some increase in reach-for-yield behavior by institutional investors that increased their
exposure to risky corporate debt, and weighing the financial stability implications of these
countervailing forces is difficult. That said, the effects in either direction seem likely to have
been modest.
Policy Implications
A reasonable conjecture is that an investor facing both higher costs of short-term borrowing and
lower yields on longer-duration assets would be less likely to engage in maturity transformation.
Thus, to the extent that an elevated spread of long rates over short rates encourages maturity
transformation, MEP-type operations could affect the volume or profitability of maturity and
liquidity transformation activity. One could envision a situation in which the FOMC might wish
to cut short-term rates to provide stimulus to the economy but simultaneously be worried that
doing so would steepen the yield curve and give rise to an undue amount of maturity mismatch
on investors’ books. Accompanying the rate cut with a bond-buying program has the potential to
engineer more of a parallel shift in the term structure of Treasury yields. This sort of mechanism
has been suggested, for example, by Stein (2013).
A shift of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet toward longer maturities entails certain risks.
Interest-rate risk taken out of the market by the central bank does not disappear; it is transferred
to the central bank’s balance sheet and is ultimately borne by taxpayers. Moreover, if the Fed
removes interest-rate risk from the market, yield-oriented investors could end up taking on risk
in other ways, for example, by increasing their own financial leverage or their exposures to credit
risk. Such concerns are palpable in current discussions of the potential effects of low long-term
interest rates on the profitability—and risk-taking behavior—of banks, insurers, and pensions
funds around the world. These concerns are reminiscent of the “reach for yield” incentives
sometimes pointed to as a potential cost of maintaining a low policy rate. Such incentives could
offset the benefits of any reduction in maturity transformation, leaving the ultimate impact on the
stability of the financial system unclear. An important difficulty is that we do not currently have
a robust framework for gauging how much maturity transformation is appropriate for a wellfunctioning financial system.

Page 12 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

5. MBS Holdings and the Housing Market
Background
The experience of the first LSAP program, announced in late 2008, showed that the Federal
Reserve could drive down spreads in the MBS market by purchasing agency mortgage-backed
securities in strained market conditions. Subsequent research, such as Hancock and Passmore
(2011), showed that this narrowing of spreads passed through significantly to primary mortgage
rates, thereby materially lowering the costs of home-buying and encouraging borrowers to
refinance their loans on more attractive terms. While the literature has not produced conclusive
results on the degree to which the MBS LSAP program boosted the market for residential real
estate, circumstantial evidence suggests that at a minimum it helped to stem its rapid
deterioration; indeed, house prices leveled off in early 2009, shortly after the program became
operational. So one could ask whether the Federal Reserve, by significantly adding to or
reducing its MBS holdings, could materially affect the housing market even in normal times.
Quantitative Assessment
Hancock and Passmore (2011) argue that the Federal Reserve’s 2009 purchases of $1.25 trillion
of agency MBS reduced mortgage rates by 100 to 150 basis points. The extent to which this
experience can be extrapolated to non-crisis periods is far from clear, however. The effects of
MBS purchases on mortgage rates depend upon (among other factors) the liquidity of the MBS
market and the willingness of banks to undertake new lending. Furthermore, the pass-through of
lower mortgage rates to increased prices of residential real estate—which is difficult to evaluate
even during the LSAP period—depends on (among other factors) the creditworthiness of
potential borrowers and the elasticity of housing supply. There is no particular reason to expect
these factors to be symmetric for MBS purchases versus MBS sales or to be similar in crisis
versus non-crisis periods.13 For example, an important part of the sizable effect of purchases in
the stressed period of 2009 likely reflected highly impaired liquidity and market functioning.
Consequently, it is difficult to say to what extent the Federal Reserve would put upward pressure
on housing markets by maintaining a sizeable stock of MBS on its balance sheet. Likewise, the
degree to which targeted sales of MBS securities could put downward pressure on the residential
real estate market is highly uncertain.
Policy Implications
Some commentators have suggested that adjustments in the Federal Reserve’s holdings of MBS
may be a useful tool in mitigating boom/bust cycles in the housing market; given the role of
While there is no comprehensive research examining possible asymmetries between the effects of asset purchases
and asset sales, flow-effect regressions based on the MEP program suggest that such asymmetries were small in the
cash market. However, sales appear to have had smaller effects on the repo market than purchases did. (See
D’Amico et al., 2015.)
13

Page 13 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

housing in banking and financial crises, such mitigation may promote financial stability. For
example, the FOMC could sell MBS during a period of rapid growth in mortgage debt and home
prices, thereby tightening conditions in mortgage markets and leaning against the increase in
risks associated with an exuberant housing market (Friedman, 2014). Inverting this idea, if, for
whatever reason, the Federal Reserve were to maintain a portfolio of MBS as a permanent
component of its balance sheet, it would most likely put continual downward pressure on
mortgage rates and upward pressure on house prices. In the extreme, therefore, such a policy
could run the risk of over-stimulating housing market activity and amplifying a debt-fueled
cycle.
At this stage, it is difficult to assess the possible efficacy of these channels in affecting mortgagemarket conditions. Most research has emphasized stock effects in gauging the impact of Fed
MBS holdings on mortgage market conditions, but it is hard to disentangle the effects of the flow
of purchases. Moreover, sales of MBS may have different effects than purchases.
Further, attempts to cool the housing market by selling MBS would generally require the FOMC
to maintain a large position in MBS. If the sale of MBS tightened mortgage market conditions to
the same extent that the first LSAP program eased mortgage market conditions, the balance sheet
adjustment required to raise mortgage rates by 100 basis points would be on the order of $1
trillion dollars. Since MBS tend to prepay relatively quickly, the Federal Reserve would likely
have to maintain a more or less continual presence in the market to sustain such a reserve. It
would be worth monitoring the extent to which that purchase activity was putting downward
pressure on mortgage rates and leading to some overheating in the housing market.
In addition to the effects on housing markets, a balance sheet policy that involved the Federal
Reserve routinely in the MBS market could also have implications for the functioning and
liquidity of that market. Kandrac (2016), for example, finds that the Fed’s MBS purchases after
2011 led to a deterioration in measures of liquidity and market functioning, particularly at the
beginning of new purchase programs (although these effects appeared to have been fairly shortlived).

Page 14 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

References
Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin (2008). “Financial Intermediaries, Financial Stability, and
Monetary Policy,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports 346 (September).
Adrian, Tobias, Karen Kimbrough, and Dina Marchioni (2010). “The Federal Reserve’s
Commercial Paper Funding Facility.” FRB New York Staff Report 423, June.
Bindseil, U. (2016). “Evaluating Monetary Policy Operational Frameworks.” Paper presented at
FRB Kansas City Jackson Hole Conference, Augsust.
Bowman, David, Etienne Gagnon, and Mike Leahy (2010). “Interest on Excess Reserves as a
Monetary Policy Instrument: The Experience of Foreign Central Banks,” working paper, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Brunnermeier, Markus K. (2009). “Early Stages of the Credit Crunch: Deciphering the Liquidity
and Credit Crunch, 2007-2008”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, iss. 1 (Winter), pp. 77100.
Caballero, Ricardo and Emmanuel Fahri (2016). “The Safety Trap,” Harvard University working
paper.
Cahill, Michael, Stefania D’Amico, Canlin Li, and John Sears (2013). “Duration Risk versus
Local Supply Channel in Treasury Yield: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s Asset Purchase
Announcements,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013-35 (April), Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Carlson, Mark, Burcu Duygan-Bump, Fabio Natalucci, William Nelson, Marcelo Ochoa, Jeremy
Stein, and Skander Van den Heuvel (2016). “The Demand for Short-Term, Safe Assets and
Financial Stability: Some Evidence and Implications for Central Bank Policies,” International
Journal of Central Banking.
Cochrane, John (2014). “Monetary Policy with Interest on Reserves,” NBER working paper
20613 (October).
Committee on the Global Financial System Markets Committee (2015). “Regulatory change and
monetary policy,” CGFS papers no. 54 (May).
Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang, and Gustavo Suarez (2013). “The Evolution of a Financial Crisis:
Collapse of the Asset-Backed Commercial Paper Market,” Journal of Finance 68, iss. 3 (June),
pp. 815-48.
D’Amico, Stefania, William English, David Lopez-Salido (2012). “The Federal Reserve’s LargeScale Asset Purchase Programmes: Rationale and Effects,” Economic Journal 122, iss. 564
(November), pp. F415-F446.
Page 15 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

D’Amico, Stefania, Roger Fan, Yuriy Kitsul (2014). “The Scarcity Value of Treasury Collateral:
Repo Market Effects of Security-Specific Supply and Demand Factors,” Finance and Economics
Discussion Series 2014-60 (August), Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
D’Amico, Stefania, and Thomas B. King (2013). “Flow and Stock Effects of Large-Scale
Treasury Purchases: Evidence on the Importance of Local Supply,” Journal of Financial
Economics 108, iss. 2 (May), pp. 425-48.
Dreschler, Itamar, Alexi Savov, and Philipp Schnabl (2014). “A Model of Monetary Policy and
Risk Premia.” NBER working paper 20141, May.
Duffie, Darrell, and Arvind Krishnamurthy (2016). “Passthrough Efficiency in the Fed’s New
Monetary Policy Setting,” presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium on
Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the Future.
Ehlers, Torsten (2012). "The effectiveness of the Federal Reserve's Maturity Extension
Program—Operation Twist 2: the portfolio rebalancing channel and public debt management,"
BIS Papers chapters, in: Bank for International Settlements (ed.), Threat of fiscal dominance?
Volume 65, pages 245-255 Bank for International Settlements.
Foley-Fisher, Nathan & Ramcharan, Rodney, and Yu, Edison (2016). "The Impact of
Unconventional Monetary Policy on Firm Financing Constraints: Evidence from the Maturity
Extension Program," Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2016-025, Board of Governors
of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).
Friedman, Benjamin M. (2014). “Has the Financial Crisis Permanently Changed the Practice of
Monetary Policy? Has It Changed the Theory of Monetary Policy?” NBER Working Paper No.
20128 (May).
Frost, Joshua, Lorie Logan, Antoine Martin, Patrick McCabe, Fabio Natalucci, and Julie
Remache (2015). “Overnight RRP Operations as a Monetary Policy Tool: Some Design
Considerations,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2015-010 (February), Washington:
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack (2012). “Large-Scale Asset
Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?” Economic Policy Review 17, iss. 1 (May),
pp. 41-59.
Gorton, Gary (2016). “The History and Economics of Safe Assets,” NBER Working Paper No
22210 (April).
Gorton, Gary, Stefan Lewellen, and Andrew Metrick (2012). “The Safe-Asset Share,” American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 102, iss. 3 (May), pp. 101-6.

Page 16 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Gorton, Gary, and Andrew Metrick (2012), “Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo,” Journal
of Financial Economics 104, iss. 3 (June), pp. 425-51.
Greenwood, Robin, Samuel G. Hanson, and Jeremy C. Stein (2015). “A Comparative-Advantage
Approach to Government Debt Maturity,” Journal of Finance 70, iss. 4 (August), pp. 1683-1722.
Greenwood, Robin, Samuel G. Hanson, and Jeremy C. Stein (2016). “The Federal Reserve’s
Balance Sheet as a Financial-Stability Tool.” Paper presented at FRB Kansas City Jackson Hole
Conference, August.
Greenwood, Robin and Dimitri Vayanos (2014). “Bond Supply and Excess Bond Returns,”
Review of Financial Studies.
Hancock, Diana, and Wayne Passmore (2011). “Did the Federal Reserve’s MBS Purchase
Program Lower Mortgage Rates?” Journal of Monetary Economics 58, iss. 5 (July), pp. 498-514.
Infante, Sebastian (2016). “Private Money Creation with Safe Assets and Term Premia,” mimeo,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Kandrac, John (2016). “The Costs of Quantitative Easing: Liquidity and Market Functioning
Effects of Federal Reserve MBS Purchases,” mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System.
Kandrac, John, and Bernd Schlusche (2013). “Flow Effects of Large-Scale Asset Purchases,”
Economic Letters 121, iss. 2 (November), pp. 330-35.
Kashyap, Anil K. and Stein, Jeremy C. (2012). “Optimal Conduct of Monetary Policy with
Interest on Reserves.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4(1): 266-82.
Kim, Don and Jonathan Wright (2005). “An Arbitrage-Free Three-Factor Term Structure Model
and the Recent Behavior of Long-Term Yields and Distant-Horizon Forward Rates.” FEDS
working paper 2005-33.
King, Thomas B. (2016). “Expectation and Duration at the Effective Lower Bound.” Working
paper (August).
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2011). “The Effects of Quantitative
Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity 43 (Fall), pp. 215–287.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2012). “The Aggregate Demand for
Treasury Debt,” Journal of Political Economy 120, iss. 2 (April), pp. 233-67.

Page 17 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Krishnamurthy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgensen (2015). “The Impact of Treasury Supply
on Financial Sector Lending and Stability,” Journal of Financial Economics 118, iss. 3
(December), pp. 571-600.
Li, Ada, Matthew Lieber, William O’Boyle, and J. Christina Wang (2016). “Money Market
Regulations,” Federal Reserve System staff memo (July).
Li, Canlin and Min Wei (2013). “Term Structure Modeling with Supply Factors and the Federal
Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs,” International Journal of Central Banking 9,
iss. 1 (March) pp. 3-29.
McCabe, Patrick E. (2010). “The Cross Section of Money Market Fund Risks and Financial
Crises,” Finance and Economics Discussion Papers 2010-51 (September) Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Meaning, J., and Zhu, F. (2011). “The Impact of Recent Central Bank Asset Purchase
Programs.” BIS Quarterly Review.
Nagel, Stefan (2016). “The Liquidity Premium of Near-Money Assets,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics (published online, July).
Swanson, Eric T. (2011). “Let’s Twist Again: A High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis of
Operation Twist and Its Implications for QE2.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1):
151-207.
Stein, Jeremy C. (2012). “Monetary Policy as Financial Stability Regulation,” Quarterly Journal
of Economics 127(1): 57-95.
Stein, Jeremy C. (2013) “Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and Policy
Responses.” Speech at the "Restoring Household Financial Stability after the Great Recession:
Why Household Balance Sheets Matter" research symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, Missouri, February 27.
Svensson, Lars (1994). “Estimating and Interpreting Forward Rates: Sweden 1992 – 1994.
Working paper.
Woodford, Michael (2016). “Quantitative Easing and Financial Stability,” NBER working paper
22285 (May).

Page 18 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 1. Measures of Treasury Market Liquidity around the First LSAP Program
Date

Daily
volume

10Y on-therun prem

Fails to deliver

Ave. abs. fitting
error*

3/17/09

$83 bil

54 bp

$109 bil

10.6 bp

3/25 – 7/6/09

$100 bil

39 bp

$73 bil

6.4 bp

7/6 – 10/29/09

$120 bil

29 bp

$15 bil

3.3 bp

*Based on the Svensson (1994) model.
Source: D’Amico and King (2013).

Figure 2. Excess Returns on Treasury Bills, Relative to One-Week Rate

Source: Carlson et al. (2016)

Page 19 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 3. Short-Term Safe Assets Held by the US Nonfinancial Sector

Source: Financial Accounts of the United States via Greenwood, Hanson, and Stein (2016).

Figure 4. Total Volume of the Reverse Repo Facility

Horizontal line represents $300 billion aggregate cap on the facility that was in place from September 22, 2014,
through December 16, 2015.

Page 20 of 21

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 5. Event Study around the announcement of the Maturity Extension Program

Source: Cahill et al. (2015)

Page 21 of 21