View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

September 30, 2016
Demand and Supply Considerations in Repo Rate Targeting Regimes
Jeff Huther and John McGowan1

1 Introduction
One of the possible rates the Committee could choose to target in the future is the overnight rate
on Treasury repurchase agreements (hereafter, repo rate).2 As noted in the forthcoming
“Alternative Policy Rates” memo, there are several considerations that might incline the FOMC
to choose the repo rate as a target in the new long-run operating framework. Perhaps most
importantly, the repo rate is a close proxy for the “risk-free” overnight rate that forms the basis
for the pricing of all dollar-denominated financial assets. The repo market is also large, longstanding, and central to the financial system, and has tended to remain active during periods of
financial stress. As a result, targeting the overnight repo rate would provide the Committee with
an important lever for influencing overall financial conditions.
At a high level, through its policy actions and communications, the Federal Reserve would
manage the current and expected future path of overnight repo rates. The expected future path of
overnight repo rates would then influence the yields on longer-term Treasury securities, and the
prices of a range of other asset prices would be affected in the usual way through arbitrage by
market participants.
As discussed in the “Considerations for the Design of Reserves Operating Regimes” memo, the
operational aspects of implementation frameworks aimed at targeting unsecured bank funding
rates often center on issues related to demand and supply in the reserve market. In these
regimes, apart from so-called “autonomous factors,” the Federal Reserve is the sole supplier of
reserves to the banking system. Moreover, the Federal Reserve has a substantial degree of
1

We thank Jim Clouse for valuable comments and Grant Carney for excellent research assistance.

Throughout this memo we refer to a generic “repo rate” on overnight general collateral Treasury repurchase
agreements. In practice there are several repo rates, reflecting market segmentation and different settlement
conventions, including customer tri-party rates and customer bilateral repo rates. These differences would deserve
further staff analysis if policymakers decided to adopt a repo rate as the policy rate, but do not substantively affect
the analysis presented in this memo.
2

Page 1 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

influence over the demand for reserves through reserve requirements and the interest rates on
required and excess reserves. In these types of systems, the Federal Reserve can influence the
level of the federal funds rate or other unsecured bank funding rates by appropriate adjustments
of the supply of reserves and the interest rates on reserves.
As discussed in more detail below, demand and supply conditions in the reserve market certainly
can be a factor influencing outcomes in the repo market. However, the demand and supply of
reserves would likely move to the background as key focus of policy implementation.3 Instead,
the primary focus of policy implementation under a repo rate targeting regime would likely shift
to demand and supply conditions in the repo market. As discussed below, the Federal Reserve
could influence those demand and supply conditions using a variety of tools at its disposal.4
Although this memo presents only very preliminary analysis of the analytical issues that arise in
targeting repo rates, a few general observations are worth highlighting.


Repo rate targeting is a feasible option available to policymakers. There do not appear to
be any operational challenges associated with targeting a repo rate that are beyond the
staff’s ability to work through over time. Policymakers would be able to choose from
several implementation approaches, each likely to provide adequate control over the repo
rate.



The Federal Reserve likely could target repo rates effectively using standard monetary
policy tools. In the current system based on the settings of administered rates, overnight
repo rates have fluctuated more than the effective federal funds rate (EFFR), but have
nevertheless consistently stayed in the target range for the federal funds rate, suggesting
that a system closely resembling the one now in place could provide adequate control
over the repo rate.

Although not discussed in this memo, in principle, the Federal Reserve could target repo rates by focusing on
demand and supply conditions in the reserve market and adjusting the supply of reserves which affects the EFFR
and through arbitrage between markets keeps the repo rate at the desired level. This would be an indirect way of
operationalizing a repo policy rate that might nevertheless provide adequate control over the repo rate.
4
In the following analysis, we use “demand” to describe cash borrowers and “supply” to describe lenders of cash.
3

Page 2 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022



The FOMC could face some tradeoffs between the volatility of the market repo rate and
the frequency and size of Federal Reserve operations necessary to stabilize the rate. Very
tight control of the repo rate in some cases could require very active use of “fine-tuning”
open market operations. On the other hand, if policymakers are willing to accept some
degree of daily variation of the repo rate, including expressing the target rate as a range
potentially supported by standing open market operation (OMO) facilities, then the need
for the Desk to initiate frequent and sizable open market operations would likely be
reduced. This tradeoff between the desired precision of rate control and the frequency
and size of operations required to achieve that precision is broadly similar to the one the
FOMC could face with an unsecured rate target.



There are important linkages between the repo market and the reserve market. The
setting of the IOER rate, for example, can affect lenders’ incentives to provide repo
financing. Conversely, Federal Reserve repo operations undertaken to stabilize the repo
rate can have spillover effects in unsecured markets. Some of these effects could likely
be mitigated if a repo rate targeting regime is coupled with a relatively abundant supply
of reserves under which the unsecured bank funding rate would trade close to IOER.

The remainder of this memo is organized as follows. Section 2 below develops a very simple
supply and demand framework for the repo market. Using this basic framework, section 3
describes how the Federal Reserve could employ various mechanisms to help manage the level
of the repo rate. Section 4 offers some general observations regarding repo rate targeting
regimes. Section 5 concludes with a preliminary look at some of the institutional factors
affecting demand and supply conditions in the repo market and the observed behavior of market
repo rates.

2 Demand and Supply in the Repo Market
As noted above, the Federal Reserve can influence the level of overnight repo rates through its
standard tools, such as IOER, discretionary OMOs, and standing OMOs, that affect the demand
and supply conditions in the repo market. The discussion below presents a stylized framework
that is helpful in analyzing how various approaches to targeting the repo rate could work. In this
approach, the repo rate is viewed as determined in a market in which the “demand” for repo
Page 3 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

financing is driven largely by dealers that are financing or borrowing against inventories to meet
customer needs. The private “supply” of repo financing is driven by the behavior of institutional
investors such as non-bank money market mutual funds (MMFs) that seek to invest funds in
short-term overnight instruments.

2.1 A Simple Analytical Framework
Figure 1 presents a stylized textbook framework that helps illustrate the market mechanics in the
repo market when there is an ON RRP facility. The demand curve is downward sloping based
on the assumption that dealers will be willing to hold larger inventories of securities if financing
costs are lower. As discussed in more detail below, various factors could influence the demand
for financing in the repo market, including exogenous changes in dealer repo inventories
resulting from market making activity for customers and supporting new issuance of Treasury
securities.

The supply side of the repo market, currently dominated by nonbanks, is shown as a function of
the spread between the market repo rate and the ON RRP offering rate. Since nonbanks can
deposit their funds at the Fed at the ON RRP offering rate, their supply curve does not fall below
this rate. For banks to participate, the repo rate would have to rise above IOER. That is, no bank
Page 4 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

should be willing to lend in the repo market at a rate below the rate they can earn on balances in
their reserve account.5 Above the IOER rate, the total funds supplied would be the horizontal
sum of the supply curves for banks and nonbanks.
Given the assumed spread between the IOER rate and the ON RRP offering rate, and the
assumed position of the supply and demand curves, the equilibrium repo rate in the diagram
(denoted by the blue dot) is such that only nonbanks supply funds.6
The charts below illustrate the effects of demand and supply shocks on the equilibrium repo rate
and how the Federal Reserve could offset those effects by conducting OMOs to change the
overall supply of repo investments. The shift from the blue supply curve to the red supply curve
in figure 2 shows the case when private lenders in the repo market reduce the supply of financing
available at any given repo rate. Absent any intervention from the Federal Reserve, this shock
would push the equilibrium repo rate upward along the existing demand curve to the yellow dot.
The Federal Reserve could extinguish this effect on the equilibrium repo rate by conducting
discretionary repo operations in order to keep the repo rate at the target. In this case, the quantity
of repo operations required would be given by the distance between the red and blue dots

The slope of banks’ supply curve for repo will depend on whether reserves are abundant or scarce. If banks are
operating on the flat (steep) portion of their reserve demand curve, then it might take a relatively small (large)
increases in the repo rate above the IOER rate to induce banks to lend in the repo market.
6
Take-up at the ON RRP facility is zero in this example. If the demand curve intersected the flat portion of the
supply curve, then private demand for repo would be less than nonbank supply at the ON RRP offering rate, and the
Fed would step in and borrow the additional nonbank funds to keep the market rate at the offering rate.
5

Page 5 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Figure 3 below shows the case when there is an exogenous increase in the demand for repo
financing. In this case, the demand curve shifts to the right as illustrated by the shift from the
blue to the red line. Absent any operations from the Federal Reserve, the equilibrium repo rate
would be pushed up along the existing repo supply curve to the yellow dot. The Federal Reserve
could extinguish this effect on market rates by conducting overnight repurchase operations in an
amount shown by the distance from the blue to the red dots.

Page 6 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Similar analysis for the counterparts of figures 2 and 3 in the cases in which the supply curve
shifts to the right or the demand curve shifts to the left indicates that the equilibrium repo rate
would tend to fall. However, as in figures 2 and 3, the Federal Reserve could offset the effects of
these shifts on the equilibrium repo rates by conducting open market operations, this time in the
form of overnight reverse repurchase operations. Similarly, in all cases, adjustments to offering
rates on the ON RRP or the IOER could also be used to move the supply curves in ways that
would achieve the desired equilibrium, possibly with smaller changes in the balance sheet.

3 Alternative Mechanisms for Interest Rate Control
The supply and demand framework above suggests that the Federal Reserve can stabilize the
repo rate through appropriate open market operations. A number of mechanisms have been
proposed that would define how operations are conducted. Below we describe four possibilities
that have been widely discussed—judgmental open market operations based on daily supply and
demand estimates, standing repo and reverse repo operations at rates that establish a corridor
around the target repo rate, standing repo and reverse repo operations at the target rate, and
Page 7 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

standing repo and reverse repo operations at the target rate up to a predetermined quantity (the
so-called TARALAC facility). In general, these approaches differ in the degree of interest rate
volatility that is tolerated and whether the Federal Reserve or the market decides on the
appropriate size of the RP or RRP operations.


Judgmental Operations without standing facilities: The operations necessary to target a
particular level of the repo rate could be conducted on a judgmental basis. In this approach,
the Federal Reserve could develop daily estimates of the demand and supply of repo
financing and conduct operations necessary to meet any projected gap between demand and
supply at the target repo rate. Such operations could be conducted multiple times each day if
necessary7. In effect, the Federal Reserve would be acting as described in figures 2 and 3
above. As discussed in more detail below, developing reasonably accurate estimates of the
private demand and supply of repo financing seems feasible. Moreover, the magnitude of
operations required to stabilize repo rates may not be particularly large, at least in normal
times.



Standing ON RP and ON RRP Facilities: As discussed in the memo presented in the July
FOMC meeting on international frameworks, a standard mechanism employed in targeting
rates is to establish standing borrowing and lending facilities around the target rates. This
approach could also be used by the Committee to set a target range for the repo rate with the
ON RP and ON RRP offering rates set at the endpoints of the range. Alternately, the FOMC
could allow the Desk some discretion to move the offering rates within some range to
respond to perceived changes in the supply and demand for repo investments. The
interaction of private demand and supply curves with standing facilities is shown in figure 4
below.

When targeting the federal funds rate pre-crisis with low levels of excess reserves, the Desk conducted an open
market operation in the morning and would not know the extent of market clearing dynamics until between 5:00 and
6:00 pm as the market was closing and banks were settling their end of day positions. At that time, securities and
repo markets were closed making it impossible to do any late day transactions to adjust the final supply of balances.
For the repo market, which closes earlier in the day, it is possible that the Fed could be directly engaged in arranging
clean-up operations late in the session to better target supply in this market. This could improve the daily settlement
dynamics relative to what was experienced in the pre-crisis regime.

7

Page 8 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

In the diagram, a standing ON RP facility provides financing whenever the repo rate rises
above the ON RP rate. As a result, the ON RP facility establishes an upper bound on the
repo rate. For a very large increase in repo demand, depicted by the red curve, the
equilibrium repo rate (absent Federal Reserve operations) could be pushed above the ON RP.
The standing ON RP facility would provide financing in this case equal to the segment AB
that will fill the gap between private demand and supply and the ON RP rate maintaining the
market clearing rate at the level of the ON RP facility. Conversely, if private demand were
to drop sharply as shown by the yellow line, the equilibrium repo rate (absent Federal
Reserve operations) could fall below the ON RRP rate. In this case, the Federal Reserve
would borrow an amount equal to the line segment labelled CD to fill the gap between
private demand and private supply at the ON RRP rate, maintaining the market clearing rate
at the level of the ON RRP facility rate. For smaller shifts in the supply or demand curve that
maintain an equilibrium rate between the two administered rates, the market rate would
simply vary within the range.


Standing Operations at the Target Rate: Another type of framework that could be used to
target the repo rate is to simply stand ready to meet any demand for overnight financing or
repo investments at the target repo rate. In this case, shifts in the private demand and supply
Page 9 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

curves shown above would be “automatically” addressed by standing overnight and reverse
operations at the target rate. This type of system would likely be quite effective in stabilizing
the repo rate but could imply a fairly central role for the Federal Reserve in the repo market,
potentially including operations on both sides of the market on the same day.


TARALAC Facility: A related type of framework is the Target Rate-Limited Access
(TARALAC) facility described recently by Ulrich Bindseil at the Jackson Hole conference.
In a TARALAC facility, the Federal Reserve would again stand ready to conduct overnight
repo lending and borrowing operations, as necessary, at the target repo rate. However, the
quantity of such operations would be limited. In this case, a sufficiently large shift in private
demand or supply could push the repo rate above or below the target rate. Of course, the
TARALAC facility could be bundled with discretionary OMOs or could be bundled with
standing RP and RRP facilities (at less attractive rates and larger caps) to dampen the effects
of large demand and supply shocks. More details of how the TARALAC facility can affect
market rates are discussed in the appendix.

4 Observations
While the framework described above is simplistic in many dimensions, it does highlight some
of the basic issues that could arise in repo rate targeting and linkages to conditions in the banking
sector.
Rates and Quantities: One observation is that the inherent volatility in the equilibrium repo
rate (in the absence of Federal Reserve operations) and equilibrium level of repo financing would
be importantly affected by the slopes of the private supply and demand curves. If the demand
curve is relatively steep, any given increase or decrease in private supply will show through as a
relatively large effect on the equilibrium repo rate but a relatively small effect on the equilibrium
quantity of repo financing. Thus, when the demand curve is steep, the size of Federal Reserve
operations necessary to dampen such effects on the repo rate would be relatively small.
Conversely, if the supply curve is relatively steep, any given shift in the demand curve will imply
a relatively large move in the equilibrium repo rate and a relatively small change in the
equilibrium quantity of repo financing. Again, in this case, the magnitude of Federal Reserve

Page 10 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

operations necessary to counter these shifts in demand and supply through open market
operations would be relatively modest.
The mirror image cases arise when the demand and supply curves are relatively flat. If the
demand curve is relatively flat, then any given upward shift in the supply curve will generate a
relatively small increase in the equilibrium repo rate and a relatively large decline in the
equilibrium quantity of repo financing. Similarly, when the supply curve is very flat, any given
increase in the demand for repo will elicit a relatively small response in the equilibrium repo rate
and a relatively large response the equilibrium quantity of repo financing.
In considering a regime like this, it would be important to gain some understanding of the factors
affecting the slope of both the supply and demand curves in these markets. For example, if the
level of reserves or the levels of administered rates affected the slope of these curves, it would
complicate the simple analytical framework laid out above.
Connections with the Unsecured Market: The analysis above highlights some of the potential
interactions between a repo rate targeting regime and conditions in the unsecured market. One
type of connection is illustrated by the repo supply curve shown in figure 1. In that diagram,
banks’ willingness to supply financing in the repo market is heavily influenced by the level of
the IOER rate relative to repo rates. If IOER is set well above the target repo rate, as it currently
is, then banks will not ordinarily provide large amounts of financing in the repo market,
consistent with current behavior. In this case, the setting of IOER effectively removes bank
participation in the repo market.
Another connection can be illustrated by an example. In cases when the Federal Reserve is
providing repo financing, there will be a corresponding increase in the quantity of reserves. This
increase in reserves could then put downward pressure on the federal funds rate and other bank
funding rates. The opposite situation would occur when the Federal Reserve conducts RRP
operations to target the repo rate. In this case, other things equal, the supply of reserves would
fall and there could be some degree of upward pressure on the federal funds rate and other bank
funding rates.

Page 11 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

These types of feedback effects on unsecured rates may need to be accounted for in the operating
regime. An increase in reserve supply from a repo facility, for example, could be offset through
term deposit operations or an adjustment to the level SOMA holdings. Alternatively, if the
Federal Reserve operated with a floor system in the reserve market, marginal changes in reserve
supply stemming from Federal Reserve repo operations would likely have only muted effects on
bank funding rates. The Committee may also feel that some volatility in the unsecured market
rate can be tolerated, especially if it is transitory. In the pre-crisis regime, the EFFR was kept
very close to its target and the repo rate was allowed to fluctuate freely, with repo rates typically
trading close to the federal funds rate.

5 Some Empirical Evidence on Demand and Supply Conditions in the
Repo Market
The discussion above highlights that repo rate targeting is a feasible option available to the
Committee, and it does not appear that there are operational challenges that are beyond the staff's
ability to work through over time. That said, there are several aspects of private demand and
supply that may be useful to consider. This section provides some empirical background on the
institutional and environmental factors affecting supply and demand conditions in the repo
market and how those conditions are reflected in observed market repo rates.

5.1 Demand for Financing
Borrowing in the repo market is largely driven by dealers in Treasury securities. Dealer
financing demand stems from the need to fund awards from periodic Treasury auctions, to
maintain trading inventories, and to provide intermediation services to their clients who are
active in Treasury markets, such as hedge funds or foreign central banks. One marked feature of
the repo market since 2014 has been that dealers’ willingness to maintain sizable inventories and
borrow in the repo market depends in large part on their perceptions of balance sheet availability
within the context of capital regulations.
Figure 5 displays net primary dealer financing in the repo market. Dealers have expanded their
repo financing activity since 2014 (red line). Some of that financing activity is driven by the

Page 12 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

evolution of their outright positions in Treasury securities (blue line). In addition to the factors
already mentioned, these positions are also affected by the willingness of dealers to assume
proprietary positions to manage interest rate risk.

While changes in dealers’ financing needs from Treasury issuance are regular and generally
predictable, other changes in dealers’ holdings of Treasury securities could be less predictable.
Dealer intermediation on behalf of hedge funds, for example, likely varies with yield curve
expectations. Foreign central bank efforts to influence exchange rates are often supported by
buying or selling Treasuries which can lead to large changes in dealers’ holdings of Treasury
securities. Concerns about regulatory capital requirements reportedly led to declines in repo
trading in 2014 but those concerns have abated some starting in 2015, suggesting that dealer
responses to regulatory requirements are still evolving.

5.2 Supply of Repo Financing
A broad range of entities provide repo financing. The elasticity of supply is likely to depend on
the various motives for different classes of firms to lend in short-term repo. Government-only
MMFs, for example, are highly restricted in terms of the investments they can make and, as a
result, hold large volumes of Treasury repos. However, other asset managers may have choices
that range from low-risk Treasury securities to uninsured deposits at banks. And while repo

Page 13 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

demand from, say, pension funds may be relatively stable and predictable, other entities such as
MMFs and sec lenders may exhibit less predictable repo market investment behavior.
Preliminary Estimates of Triparty Overnight Treasury Market Participation
Lender Type
Mutual Fund

Typical Motivation

Share (%)

Investment

58.0 Primary Dealers

Asset Manager

Investment/Cash Management

Custodial Bank

Arbitrage

7.1

GSE

Cash Management

5.6

Pension Fund

Cash Management

4.4

Sec Lender

Arbitrage

4.0

Primary Dealer

Arbitrage

3.8

Cash Management

2.9

Customer Accommodation

1.3

Clearing Bank

Cash Management

1.3

Insurance

Cash Management

0.7

Investment

0.1

Cash Management

0.1

Municipality
Bank

Borrower

9.9 Non-Primary Dealers

Share (%)
82.5
17.5

Company
Foreign Official
Corporation

That said, total overnight repo lending, shown in figure 6, has been fairly stable over time. As
with dealer repo financing needs, the week to week volatility in the level of total repo lending is
not particularly large. The average absolute weekly change over the period shown is $13 billion
and the maximum absolute weekly change, which occurred around 2014 year end, is $72 billion.

Page 14 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

5.3 Equilibrium Repo Rate
Figure 7 shows two repo rates—the tri-party GC repo rate and the primary dealer survey rate—
since the beginning of 2014 as well as the EFFR.8 These two rates have moved together closely,
generally hovering 5 to 15 basis points above the ON RRP rate. Importantly, the ON RRP rate
has established a firm floor on both measures of the repo rate. Absent any facility to cap the
level of the repo rate, there has been one case in which repo rates have moved noticeably
higher—the period in June of this year just ahead of the Brexit vote. At that time, many lenders
wished to reduce their exposures to financial firms and pulled back from lending in the repo
market. Roughly speaking, this might be viewed as corresponding to the case shown in figure 2
above.

Recall that ON RRPs began in September 2013. ON RRP parameters and learning by participants, however,
probably limit the relevant ON RRP period to 2014 and later (prior to December 23, 2013, individual fund caps
limited meaningful participation).

8

Page 15 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

The figure above illustrates one of the observations noted above about a repo rate targeting
regime: The need for Desk discretionary operations would depend on the FOMCs tolerance for
fluctuations in the policy rate. If the Committee were comfortable with letting the repo rate
fluctuate in a 25 bps range, discretionary operations could be quite rare. If, in contrast, the
FOMC desired to target a specific rate, then the Desk would need to take steps to dampen recent
levels of volatility. As described above, the magnitude of the open market operations necessary
to maintain the target repo rate is a function of the elasticities of the supply and demand curves.
Very “flat” curves will tend to require relatively large operations to tightly control the repo rate
while relatively steep curves would imply only small sized operations to target the repo rate.
Additional work would be beneficial before one could confidently assess the behavior of the
supply and demand curves in the market as well as the effect that changing the RP and RRP
offering rates would have on private market rates in a dynamic setting. The relatively modest
weekly variation in equilibrium quantities and rates in the market suggests that the demand and
supply curves are reasonably stable over time and not especially steep or flat.

Page 16 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Appendix – TARALAC Facility
As noted in the main text, an operating regime could include a Target Rate-Limited Access
facility where the Federal Reserve would stand ready to conduct overnight repo lending and
borrowing operations, as necessary, at the target repo rate in limited quantity. In this case, for
sufficiently small shifts in supply or demand, the facilities will anchor market repo rates at the
target. However, for sufficiently large shift in private demand or supply, the TARALAC will
dampen the movement in the market repo rate, but it will move above or below the target. The
following figures show how the TARALAC would work in these cases.
Figure 8a illustrates how the TARALAC facility might be established with an upper limit on the
quantity of repo financing that the Federal Reserve is willing to supply. In this case, the
effective total supply of repo financing available to the market (private plus Federal Reserve) is
given by the line segments connecting the points ABCD. For relatively modest shifts in the
demand curve, the equilibrium rate would be determined at the target rate along the flat segment
of the supply curve BC. For larger shifts in the demand curve (shown by the red line), the
quantity constraint on Federal Reserve repo lending (BC) would be binding, and the equilibrium
repo rate would be determined along the CD segment of the repo supply curve. The resulting
market repo rate would lie above the ON RP offering rate but to a lesser extent than if there was
no facility.

Page 17 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Similarly, figure 8b illustrates how the TARALAC facility might be established with an upper
limit on the quantity of repo borrowing that the Federal Reserve is willing to do. For relatively
small shifts to the left in private demand for repo financing, the Federal Reserve would fill in the
gap between private demand and supply and the equilibrium repo rate would be determined
along the flat portion of the total repo demand for financing (private plus Federal Reserve). For
larger shifts to the left in the private demand of repo financing, as shown by the yellow line
EFGH, the quantity available from the Fed (FG) will not be sufficient to fill the gap between
private demand and supply at the target rate. In this case, the equilibrium rate could be
determined along the GH portion of the total demand for financing curve. Here the market repo
rate lies below the ON RRP offering rate but to a lesser extent than if there was no facility.

Page 18 of 19

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 1/14/2022

Page 19 of 19