View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
Division of Monetary Affairs
FOMC SECRETARIAT

Date:

October 24, 2011

To:

Federal Open Market Committee

From:

Deborah J. Danker

Subject: DSGE Models Update

The attached memo provides a quarterly update on the projections of
the DSGE models that were described at the June FOMC meeting.

1 of 1

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

System DSGE Project Forecasts1
October 24, 2011
Marco Del Negro, Argia Sbordone
Federal Reserve Bank of New York

1

We thank Jeff Campbell, Hess Chung, Vasco Curdia, John Fernald, Jonas Fisher, Marc Giannoni, Alejandro
Justiniano, Michael Kiley, J.P. Laforte, Loretta Mester, and Keith Sill for their contributions.

1 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

This memo describes the economic forecasts of the four models that are currently part of the
System project on dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models. These are the EDO
(Board), PRISM (FRB Philadelphia), FRBNY and Chicago models. Although all four models
share many common features, as described in the presentation at the June FOMC meeting, they
differ in terms of their underlying economic structure, as well as the data used for model
estimation. 2 The structure of the PRISM model is closest to the “canonical’’ New-Keynesian
DSGE model. 3 The FRBNY and Chicago models also incorporate a specific financial sector
along the lines of Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist (1999). 4 The Board EDO model has multiple
sectors and incorporates exogenous risk premia into the pricing of bonds. Finally, the Chicago
model also exploits the information in multiple inflation indicators. This diversity of models is a
strength of the project, since each model provides a potentially different perspective on the
current state of the economy. It is important to remember that the DSGE models will change
over time, as they incorporate developments in research (both in academia and in central banks)
and are estimated on additional series. 5

Forecasts Summary

The current forecasts for real GDP growth, core PCE inflation, and the federal funds rate, as
well as those presented at the June FOMC meeting, are displayed in the table and figure at the
end of this summary section. 6 These forecasts treat 2011Q3 estimates for real GDP growth and
core PCE inflation as data and project beyond 2011Q3. The projections are also conditional on
the anticipation that the federal funds rate will remain near zero through mid-2013, in line with
2

See the “System DSGE Project Documentation“ memo by Dotsey, Del Negro, Sbordone, and Sill, June 2011.

3

See for example Frank Smets and Rafael Wouters, 2007, “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A
Bayesian DSGE Approach, ” American Economic Review; Marco Del Negro, Frank Schorfheide, Frank Smets and
Rafael Wouters, 2007, “On the Fit of New Keynesian Models,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics;
Alejandro Justiniano, Giorgio Primiceri and Andrea Tambalotti, 2010, “Investment Shocks and Business Cycles,”
Journal of Monetary Economics.
4

Ben Bernanke, Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist, 1999, The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business
Cycle Framework”, Handbook of Macroeconomics.
5

Relative to the June memo, for instance, the Chicago model features explicit financial frictions and a timevarying inflation target, as discussed below.
6

The table and figure show the mean forecast for real GDP growth and core PCE inflation, and the modal
forecasts for the federal funds rate. We choose to report the modal forecast for this latter variable in order to
emphasize the zero lower bound. Forecasts for 2014 were not presented in June. A more detailed discussion of the
forecasts and in-depth description of the model structure are available in a memo distributed to the Research
Directors.

2 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

market expectations. A brief description of each model’s forecast can be found at the end of the
memo.

The growth projections for 2011 (Q4/Q4) are similar across the four models and weaker than
those presented in June, as a result of the NIPA revisions and soft recent data. Afterwards, the
projected paths of the recovery differ substantially across the models. Three of the models (EDO,
FRBNY, and Chicago) do not foresee any significant rebound in economic activity, with Q4/Q4
real GDP growth at or below 3 percent through 2014. For FRBNY and Chicago, in particular,
growth remains anemic through the end of the forecast horizon. In these three models the main
drivers of the subdued outlook are the same shocks that generated the recession. These shocks,
generally associated with frictions in financial intermediation, continue to hinder the return of
output to potential. In contrast, the PRISM model sees growth above 4.5 percent in 2012 and
2013. In PRISM the economy is forecast to grow much more rapidly than in the other three
models because it projects a strong recovery in the labor market.

None of the models anticipated the strength in inflation in recent quarters, and therefore the
2011 (Q4/Q4) inflation forecasts are higher than they were in June. The models attribute a
substantial portion of this increase in inflation to temporary factors, possibly capturing the effect
of higher energy prices. As the impact of these factors subsides, all four models project inflation
returning to subdued levels, with Q4/Q4 values between 1 and 1.6 percent from 2012 onward.
For EDO, FRBNY, and Chicago the subdued inflation results from the weakness in the outlook
for real activity. Inflation forecasts are moderate for PRISM as well, in spite of the stronger
projections for real activity, since marginal costs remain subdued because of capital deepening.

In terms of interest rates, all four models project a relatively gradual renormalization after the
liftoff, with rates in the neighborhood of 2 percent by the end of 2014, consistent with the fact
that inflation remains subdued.

3 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

Forecast Summary
Model
EDO - Board of Governors
New York Fed
PRISM - Philadelphia Fed
Chicago Fed
Median Forecast*

New York Fed
PRISM - Philadelphia Fed
Chicago Fed
Median Forecast*

June

Nov

June

Nov

June

Nov

1.7

2.8

1.9

2.6

2.6

2.5

3.0

(0.1,3.4)

(1.8,3.5)

(-0.1,3.9)

(1.1,3.8)

(0.9,4.5)

(1.1,3.9)

(1.3,4.8)

1.8

2.1

2.6

2.0

1.8

1.9

1.8

(1.1,2.4)

(0.7,3.2)

(-0.8,5.0)

(-1.3,4.6)

(-1.8,4.8)

(-1.2,5.2)

(-1.5,5.1)

New York Fed
PRISM - Philadelphia Fed
Chicago Fed
Median Forecast*

June

2.0

3.3

5.0

5.1

4.7

4.7

4.2

(1.3,2.8)

(1.4,6.4)

(1.4,8.9)

(0.9,8.7)

(0.8,9.0)

(0.1,8.3)

(0.2,8.4)

1.5

3.1

2.0

4.5

1.6

4.4

2.1

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

1.8

2.9

2.3

3.5

2.2

3.4

2.5

Inflation (Q4/Q4)
2012
2013

2011

2014

Nov

June

Nov

June

Nov

June

Nov

1.9

1.5

1.4

1.4

1.4

1.4

1.4

(1.7,2.1)

(1.3,1.7)

(0.8,2.1)

(0.8,1.9)

(0.7,2.1)

(0.8,2.0)

(0.7,2.1)

1.8

1.4

1.0

1.1

1.3

1.5

1.6

(1.6,2.0)

(1.0,1.7)

(0.3,1.7)

(0.3,1.8)

(0.4,2.0)

(0.6,2.3)

(0.7,2.4)

June

1.9

1.3

1.5

1.1

1.5

1.3

1.6

(1.6,2.1)

(0.4,2.1)

(0.2,2.8)

(-0.3,2.7)

(0.0,3.1)

(-0.2,3.0)

(0.0,3.1)

1.9

1.4

1.4

0.6

1.2

0.3

1.2

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

1.9

1.4

1.4

1.1

1.4

1.3

1.5

Model
EDO - Board of Governors

2014

Nov

Model
EDO - Board of Governors

Output Growth (Q4/Q4)
2012
2013

2011

Federal Funds Rate (Q4)
2012
2013

2011

2014

Nov

June

Nov

June

Nov

June

Nov

0.1

0.4

0.1

1.6

0.5

2.4

1.8

(0.0,0.7)

(0.2,1.4)

(0.0,1.9)

(0.6,2.9)

(0.0,2.3)

(1.1,3.8)

(0.6,3.6)

0.3

0.3

0.2

0.9

0.9

1.8

1.9

(0.3,0.8)

(0.3,1.1)

(0.3,1.4)

(0.3,2.1)

(0.3,2.3)

(0.5,3.3)

(0.6,3.5)

0.1

0.2

(-0.4,0.7) (0.0,1.2)

0.1

0.6

1.0

1.4

2.1

(-1.5,1.9)

(0.0,2.4)

(-1.4,3.2)

(0.0,3.9)

(-0.2,5.0)

0.1

0.1

0.1

1.0

1.5

2.6

2.6

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

(.,.)

0.1

0.2

0.1

0.9

1.0

2.1

2.0

For each individual forecast, the numbers in parentheses represent 68% probability bands.
* The median forecast is calculated as the median of the Q4/Q4 projections from the forecasters.

4 of 11

June

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

Percentage Points (SAAR)

Real GDP Growth
8.0

8.0

6.0

6.0

4.0

4.0

2.0

2.0

0.0

0.0

-2.0

-2.0

-4.0

-4.0

-6.0

-6.0

-8.0

-8.0

-10.0
07Q1 07Q3 08Q1 08Q3 09Q1 09Q3 10Q1 10Q3 11Q1 11Q3 12Q1 12Q3 13Q1 13Q3 14Q1 14Q3

-10.0

Percentage Points (SAAR)

Core PCE Inflation
3.5

3.5

3.0

3.0

2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0

0.5

0.5

0.0
07Q1 07Q3 08Q1 08Q3 09Q1 09Q3 10Q1 10Q3 11Q1 11Q3 12Q1 12Q3 13Q1 13Q3 14Q1 14Q3

0.0

Percentage Points

Federal Funds Rate
6.0

6.0

5.0

5.0

4.0

4.0

3.0

3.0

2.0

2.0

1.0

1.0

0.0
07Q1 07Q3 08Q1 08Q3 09Q1 09Q3 10Q1 10Q3 11Q1 11Q3 12Q1 12Q3 13Q1 13Q3 14Q1 14Q3

0.0

EDO

New York

PRISM

5 of 11

Chicago

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

Detailed Model Forecasts
The EDO model

The EDO model projects that real GDP will advance at a pace modestly above trend going
forward -- about 2¾ percent, on average, over 2012-2014. This slightly above-trend pace of
growth is accompanied by an inflation forecast of about 1½ percent per year, below the target of
2 percent. The subdued inflation forecast reflects the labor market slack apparent in the shortfall
of output relative to its estimated long-run trend. The model attributes most of the recent increase
in core inflation to mark-up shocks, which capture transitory movements in inflation and have
very little estimated persistence. Consequently, these shocks have a limited effect on inflation
projections beyond 2011.

The projected recovery remains strongly influenced by the unwinding of the adverse shocks
to financial conditions in 2008 and early 2009. With the waning of these shocks, households
restrain consumption while increasing labor supply in order to rebuild wealth. These efforts
would typically produce a fairly strong recovery, but have been offset by weak productivity
growth, a binding lower bound constraint on monetary policy accommodation, and the lingering
effect of economy-wide risk premium shocks, which capture strains in financial intermediation.

The impact of these last two factors is intensified by conditioning the forecast on a policy
rate lift off that takes place in 2013Q3, substantially later than would be estimated from the
model’s usual information set. The model interprets the low expected path of the interest rates
through mid-2013 as an endogenous response of policy to continued strains in financial
conditions going forward. Indeed, the economy-wide risk premium remains at its current level
for the first two years of the projection instead of gradually falling as its pre-crisis dynamics
would have implied. The low expected path of the interest rates also reflects a more
accommodative stance of monetary policy over the projection, essentially offsetting the impact
on real activity and inflation of higher risk-premiums. The federal funds rate gradually rises after
2013Q3 to reach 1¾ percent by the end of 2014.

6 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

The FRBNY Model

The FRBNY model forecast is obtained using data released through 2011Q2, augmented for
2011Q3 with observations on the federal funds rate and the spread between Baa corporate bonds
and 10-year Treasury yields, and the NY Fed staff forecast for real GDP growth, core PCE
inflation and hours.

The model projects weak growth in economic activity, as it did in June. The projection for
output growth in 2011 (Q4/Q4) is 1.8 percent, not too different from the June projection of 2.1
percent. Growth picks up in 2012 (Q4/Q4) to 2.6 percent, and returns to roughly 2 percent in
2013-2014. Inflation is 1.8 percent in 2011 (Q4/Q4), higher than in the June projections, due to
the recent strong readings for core PCE inflation. In spite of this, inflation forecasts from 2012
onwards are actually lower than in June, due to the projected weakness in economic activity. In
fact, real marginal costs, which are the key determinant of the evolution of inflation in the model,
are currently roughly 3 percent below the historical mean and projected to remain below average
through the end of the forecast horizon.

There is significant uncertainty around the real GDP forecasts, and the risk of a recession is
far from negligible: the chance of negative readings for growth is larger than 20 percent in any
given quarter. As far as inflation is concerned, for both 2012 and 2013 the 68 percent probability
bands for Q4/Q4 inflation are within the 0-2 percent interval, implying that the model places
great probability on inflation realizations below the implicit FOMC target at least through 2013.

The main drivers of the subdued real GDP and inflation outlook are the same forces that were
responsible for the Great Recession, namely the two shocks associated with the financial system:
spread and MEI (marginal efficiency of investment) shocks. Spread shocks raise credit spreads,
hence the cost of capital, hindering the entrepreneurs’ ability to channel resources to the
productive sector. MEI shocks directly affect the technological ability of entrepreneurs to
transform investment goods into productive capital. They capture financial headwinds that are
not reflected in the spread, and have a negative impact on economic activity. The impact of these
shocks on the level of output is very long-lasting, implying that output is below trend throughout
the forecast horizon. In turn, the fact that economic activity is well below trend pushes down
7 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

inflation and consequently interest rates (given the Fed’s estimated reaction function). Shifts in
the trend growth of productivity (and hence in the trend of potential output) play only a minor
role in the FRBNY forecasts. The model attributes the pickup in core inflation in 2011 to markup shocks. These shocks push inflation above marginal costs, and capture swings in inflation
such as those due to oil price fluctuations. Their estimated impact on inflation is however only
transitory, so that they have almost no effect on the inflation forecasts for the subsequent periods.

Finally, imposing near-zero expectations for the federal funds rate through mid-2013 has
only a modest impact on the forecasts for output and inflation. The model does not view the
federal funds rate at the zero lower bound as deviating significantly from the estimated policy
rule, at least through the end of 2012. After this, however, the federal funds rate in 2013 and
2014 is forecast to be about 75bp lower than implied by the historical rule. Note that this policy
accommodation is not sufficient to bring economic activity back to trend, at least through the end
of the forecast horizon.

The PRISM Model

The Philadelphia Intertemporal Stochastic Model (PRISM) forecast is constructed using data
through 2011Q2 that are then supplemented with 2011Q3 projections of output, consumption,
investment, wages, and hours worked from the most recent Macroeconomic Advisors forecast,
(which forecasts 2011Q3 real GDP growth of about 2.4 percent).

PRISM continues to forecast a fairly strong recovery with real GDP growth at about 5
percent (Q4/Q4) in 2012 and 2013, falling to about 4.2 percent in 2014. While output growth is
projected to be fairly robust, inflation remains contained at about 1.5 percent through the forecast
horizon. By the end of 2013Q4, the funds rate is projected to increase to about 1 percent. By the
end of 2014, the funds rate stands at a bit over 2 percent.

According to PRISM, negative TFP, marginal efficiency of investment (MEI), and labor
market shocks have been key factors accounting for below-trend real output growth in 2011. The
uptick in core PCE inflation in 2011 is largely driven by temporary factors, captured by mark-up
shocks, and to some extent by accommodative monetary policy. Going forward, the model
8 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

predicts a decline in core PCE inflation. The rise in real output growth in 2012 and 2103 is
driven by consumption growth, which is projected to be a bit above 4 percent over the next three
years, and to a less extent by investment growth, which is expected to run at an above-trend pace.

Shocks that capture frictions in the labor market play an important role in explaining the
recent recession. The model expects the impact of these shocks to wane considerably over the
forecast horizon, and consequently projects a strong rebound in the labor market. This rebound in
aggregate hours lies behind PRISM’s strong growth forecasts for output, and at the same time
puts upward pressure on inflation. Such pressure is offset by changes in the savings behavior of
households, which the model captures via exogenous changes in the household’s discount factor.
An increase in the discount factor – a shift in preferences toward future consumption -- leads in
this model to lower consumption, increased savings, and higher investment. The ensuing capital
deepening lowers marginal costs and therefore helps to keep inflation in check.

Conditioning on the policy rate remaining at the zero lower bound through 2013 has a
significant impact on the forecasts. Were the federal funds rate expectations not used as
conditioning information for the forecast, PRISM would project a significantly stronger path for
core inflation, a moderately stronger path for real output growth, and consequently a much more
aggressive monetary policy tightening over the next 3 years. This is because the model captures
the exceptionally low expectations for the nominal rate via discount factor shocks that induce a
lower expected path for the real rate. As explained above, absent these shocks, the inflation
projections would be higher.

The Chicago model

The Chicago Fed model has undergone two significant changes since the June FOMC
meeting. First, the model now incorporates a financial accelerator mechanism, as in Bernanke,
Gertler and Gilchrist (1999). Observations of private balance sheets and interest rate spreads
inform this mechanism. Second, the Taylor rule’s intercept is allowed to slowly drift. This
intercept shift is referred to as the inflation drift shock, as it dominates changes in long-run
expected inflation. This drift is disciplined by equating model-based average expected consumer
price inflation over the next 40 quarters with ten-year ahead core CPI forecasts derived from a
9 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

reduced form affine term structure model. The use of long-term inflation expectations shapes the
model’s forecast for inflation by anchoring a time varying end-point. Expected core CPI inflation
is currently at roughly 1.75 percent, well below the model's 2.5 percent steady state level. 7

Regarding the first modification, introducing the financial accelerator allows the model to
account for the influence of private balance sheets in macroeconomic performance. In this way,
fluctuations in the external finance premium, private net worth and the state of the economy as
well as the policy stance are explicitly linked. To complement this change, the model now has
two financial disturbances. The spread shock generates fluctuations in the external finance
premium beyond the level warranted by current economic conditions, and the net worth shock
generates exogenous fluctuations in private balance sheets.

To identify parameters governing the financial accelerator the set of observables for
estimation is modified by including data on borrowing, and by changing the measure of spreads.
Nonfinancial borrowing is measured as the log first difference of the ratio of private credit to
nominal GDP. 8 The High Yield/AAA corporate bond spread is replaced with a broader measure
that includes spreads on Asset backed securities.

The Chicago model forecasts a return of real GDP growth to near trend, estimated at roughly
2.6 percent, in the fourth quarter of 2011, with 2011 Q4/Q4 growth at 1.5 percent. The near-term
outlook is characterized by slightly above-trend growth in investment, and a very slight increase
in nondurables and services consumption growth by the end of the year. Going forward, the
model forecasts investment growth to continue near its trend until increasing in late 2013, while
consumption growth is projected to steadily decline over this period. This leads to an expected
path for Q4/Q4 real GDP growth that peaks at 2 percent in 2012 and then drops to 1.6 percent in
2013 before rebounding to 2.1 percent in 2014. Consistent with the projections for real activity,
the outlook for hours is muted, suggesting protracted weakness in the labor market.
Furthermore, with resource slack remaining elevated, the model projects core PCE inflation to
7

Until recently, inflation expectations had recovered from their relatively low readings through early 2011. In
the last two quarters however, the measure of expected long–term inflation has edged down. The model interprets
this development as negative realizations of the inflation drift shock.
8

The numerator sums two components: Nonfinancial Business and Household Credit Market Debt Outstanding,
each taken from the Flow of Funds accounts. The inclusion of non-corporate and household credit market debt in the
measure of nonfinancial borrowing is consistent with the model’s definition of investment, which includes consumer
durables and residential investment in addition to business fixed investment.

10 of 11

Authorized for public release by the FOMC Secretariat on 02/09/2018

steadily decline from a peak of 2.1 percent in 2011Q3 to 1.4 percent in 2012 (Q4/Q4) and 1.2
percent in 2013 (Q4/Q4).

The model interprets the history of output, consumption, investment, and hours over the last
four quarters as stemming primarily from adverse demand shocks which reduce output and
inflation. In particular, positive shocks to the households' discount factor are primarily
responsible for the recent weakness in consumption growth. These disturbances depress
household spending, output and hours, as well as inflation. Furthermore, adverse spread and
private net worth shocks account for the muted growth of investment. Both of these negative
disturbances also drag down output, hours, and inflation. Meanwhile, a shock capturing
fluctuations in net exports, government spending and changes in the valuations of inventories
further depressed output, hours, and prices, particularly at the beginning of the year, while
slightly boosting consumption. The combined effect of these demand disturbances has been to
lower four quarter GDP growth and core PCE inflation as of 2011Q3 by almost 1 and 0.2
percent, respectively.

On the supply side, over the last four quarters positive shocks to wage and price markups
pushed annual core PCE inflation higher by roughly half percent. Meanwhile, adverse shocks to
neutral technology have also somewhat boosted inflation, as well as hours, while contributing
negatively to output, consumption and investment growth since 2010Q3. All of these
contractionary forces have been partially offset by monetary policy signals, which in our model
capture the effects of forward guidance regarding the path of the federal funds rate over the next
seven quarters. According to the model, forward guidance added about 2 percent to four quarter
output growth from 2010Q3 through 2011Q3, and roughly 0.6 percent to core PCE inflation over
the same time period. Policy signals supported consumption and investment growth, as well as
hours. Spread and net worth shocks have particularly persistent effects on economic activity, so
their recent realizations strongly influence the forecast. Nevertheless, the forward guidance in
place moderates their impact on investment and prevents a steeper decline in consumption
growth.

11 of 11