View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

November 1–2, 2011

1 of 282

Meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee on
November 1–2, 2011
A joint meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee and the Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System was held in the offices of the Board of Governors in Washington,
D.C., on Tuesday, November 1, 2011, at 10:30 a.m. and continued on Wednesday, November 2,
2011, at 8:30 a.m. Those present were the following:
Ben Bernanke, Chairman
William C. Dudley, Vice Chairman
Elizabeth Duke
Charles L. Evans
Richard W. Fisher
Narayana Kocherlakota
Charles I. Plosser
Sarah Bloom Raskin
Daniel K. Tarullo
Janet L. Yellen
Christine Cumming, Jeffrey M. Lacker, Dennis P. Lockhart, Sandra Pianalto, and John C.
Williams, Alternate Members of the Federal Open Market Committee
James Bullard, Esther L. George, and Eric Rosengren, Presidents of the Federal Reserve
Banks of St. Louis, Kansas City, and Boston, respectively
William B. English, Secretary and Economist
Deborah J. Danker, Deputy Secretary
Matthew M. Luecke, Assistant Secretary
David W. Skidmore, Assistant Secretary
Michelle A. Smith, Assistant Secretary
Scott G. Alvarez, General Counsel
David W. Wilcox, Economist
James A. Clouse, Thomas A. Connors, Steven B. Kamin, Loretta J. Mester, Simon Potter,
David Reifschneider, Harvey Rosenblum, Lawrence Slifman, Daniel G. Sullivan, and
Kei-Mu Yi, Associate Economists
Brian Sack, Manager, System Open Market Account
Jennifer J. Johnson, Secretary of the Board, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
Patrick M. Parkinson, Director, Division of Banking Supervision and Regulation, Board
of Governors
Nellie Liang, Director, Office of Financial Stability Policy and Research, Board of
Governors

November 1–2, 2011

2 of 282

Robert deV. Frierson, Deputy Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Board of Governors
William Nelson, Deputy Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Andrew T. Levin, Special Adviser to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
Linda Robertson, Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of Governors
Charles S. Struckmeyer, Deputy Staff Director, Office of the Staff Director, Board of
Governors
Michael P. Leahy, Senior Associate Director, Division of International Finance, Board of
Governors; William Wascher, Senior Associate Director, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors
Ellen E. Meade, Senior Adviser, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Daniel M. Covitz and Michael T. Kiley,¹ Associate Directors, Division of Research and
Statistics, Board of Governors
Christopher J. Erceg,¹ Deputy Associate Director, Division of International Finance,
Board of Governors; Fabio M. Natalucci, Deputy Associate Director, Division of
Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Brian J. Gross,¹ Special Assistant to the Board, Office of Board Members, Board of
Governors
David Lopez-Salido,¹ Assistant Director, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of
Governors
David H. Small, Project Manager, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Mark A. Carlson, Senior Economist, Division of Monetary Affairs, Board of Governors
Penelope A. Beattie, Assistant to the Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Board of
Governors
Sarah G. Green, First Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond
Glenn D. Rudebusch, Executive Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
David Altig, Geoffrey Tootell, and Christopher J. Waller, Senior Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Atlanta, Boston, and St. Louis, respectively
__________________
¹ Attended the portion of the meeting relating to monetary policy strategies and communication.

November 1–2, 2011

3 of 282

Todd E. Clark, Edward S. Knotek II, and Nathaniel Wuerffel, Vice Presidents, Federal
Reserve Banks of Cleveland, Kansas City, and New York, respectively
Deborah L. Leonard, Assistant Vice President, Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Robert L. Hetzel, Senior Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

November 1–2, 2011

4 of 282

Transcript of the Federal Open Market Committee Meeting on
November 1–2, 2011
November 1 Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everybody. This is a joint FOMC–Board
meeting. I need a motion to close the meeting.
MS. YELLEN. So moved.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. We welcome you, Esther George, in your new
capacity as President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Welcome again.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Before launching into our official business, President Fisher
needs to describe an intra–Reserve Bank transaction. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Yes, thank you, Mr. Chairman. Unlike some operators on Wall Street, we
at the Federal Open Market Committee do pay our debts in full. [Laughter] I have a debt that I
need to pay back to the gentleman on my left. [Laughter] I am tempted to claw his eyes out and
scratch his legs during the meeting, but instead, being honorable, this is the bet. [Laughter]
MR. BULLARD. Let the record show—
MR. FISHER. This is beer. This is the elixir of working men and women, and I never
resist giving some facts. Beer is the third-most consumed liquid product in the world after water
and beer. It goes back to at least the Neolithic Period, 9,500 B.C. There was a goddess of beer
that the Sumerians have called Ninkasi. And there is a famous prayer that is called “The Hymn
to Ninkasi.” I evoked it so many times during the sixth game, but I found out that Ninkasi,
whoever she was, gave way to the god of Bud. There it is, Shiner Bock, the best of Texas beers.
I would have brought you a Lone Star, but real men and women don’t drink light beer.
[Laughter]

November 1–2, 2011

5 of 282

Mr. Chairman, thank you for giving us this opportunity. I won’t tell you how I snuck it
into this room. I never want to go through that security procedure again. [Laughter] But you
won, congratulations.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, sir. And a great World Series it was.
MR. FISHER. It was a terrible World Series. [Laughter]
MR. TARULLO. What were you going to pay up if he won?
MR. BULLARD. A six-pack of the local brew.
MR. WILCOX. Bud Light. [Laughter]
MR. BULLARD. Bud Light, Busch.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Meeting is adjourned. [Laughter]
Let’s turn to item 1 on the agenda. The retirement of Dave Stockton opens up a vacancy.
We propose to select David Wilcox as economist for the FOMC, and Larry Slifman as associate
economist, effective until the organizational meeting in January 2012. No objections? [No
response] All right. Thank you very much.
Let’s turn now to item 2 on monetary policy frameworks. Let me begin the discussion by
turning to Michael Kiley, who will lead the staff presentation.
MR. KILEY. 1 Thank you. Early last month, Committee participants received a
memo on “Alternative Monetary Policy Frameworks” that I coauthored with Chris
Erceg and David Lopez-Salido. The memo discussed several policy strategies that
the Committee might wish to adopt that could potentially provide additional stimulus
or protection against especially undesirable outcomes.
As highlighted in the box at the top of your first exhibit, these commitment
strategies are broadly consistent with flexible inflation targeting—that is, with a
policy framework that combines commitment to a medium-run inflation objective
with the flexibility to respond to economic shocks as needed to moderate deviations
of employment from its “full employment” level. In our analysis, we assumed that
the Committee aims to achieve an inflation rate of 2 percent, consistent with the
majority of longer-run projections from the Summary of Economic Projections (SEP)
1

The materials used by Mr. Kiley are appended to this transcript (appendix 1).

November 1–2, 2011

6 of 282

and other communications by the Committee. In addition, the full employment goal
is interpreted as an unemployment rate in the range of 5 to 6 percent, also consistent
with the majority of longer-run projections from the SEP.
Given these objectives, we focused on how strategies that involve making
conditional commitments about how the policy rate will be adjusted going forward
can contribute to improved macroeconomic outcomes relative to the current strategy
of the Committee, which might be described as one of constrained discretion. To
illustrate the role of commitment, we considered two examples of optimal control
simulations of the type presented in the Tealbook using the FRB/US model: One
example, the “discretion” case, assumes that policymakers follow an optimal policy
on a period-by-period basis and are unwilling to promise future accommodation; the
second example, the “commitment” case, assumes that policymakers are willing to
commit (conditional on economic outcomes) to future policies that are potentially
more expansionary than would otherwise be chosen in order to stimulate activity
today.
As shown in the figures in the next three panels (which also include the
projections in the September Tealbook, which are little different from those in the
most recent projection), these different approaches result in notable differences in
outcomes for inflation and unemployment. In the discretion case, policy, as measured
by the federal funds rate (reported in the middle-left panel) is only slightly more
accommodative than in the Tealbook baseline, whereas the commitment approach
involves a plan to maintain the federal funds rate near zero until the end of 2015. In
the simulation, the additional accommodation under the commitment approach brings
about a persistent fall in the unemployment rate (shown in the middle-right panel) and
a sustained rise in inflation (reported at the bottom left) to a little over 2 percent.
Given the tight labor market and slightly above-target rate of inflation in future years
under the commitment strategy, future policymakers would presumably be tempted to
renege on the accommodative policy stance promised, but given their commitment,
they are assumed not to do so.
As highlighted in the memo and noted in the bottom-right box, several features of
the optimal policy evident in the FRB/US simulations appear robust across a range of
models. First, the optimal policy given the baseline outlook involves a commitment
to hold the nominal funds rate near zero roughly until the unemployment rate
approaches its natural rate. Second, unemployment falls below its natural rate and
inflation may rise above its target for a time later in the decade under an optimal
commitment strategy. Third, while the degree of inflation overshooting is larger in
dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models such as EDO and SIGMA than in
FRB/US, optimal policies do not result in inflation substantially above 2½ percent for
a protracted period under the modal outlook in the models we examined.
While there appears to be substantial benefits in principle from following an
optimal commitment strategy, “optimal” policies may be of limited use in FOMC
communications, because they are both complex and model-dependent, and because
they do not provide clear guidance about how the Committee would respond to

November 1–2, 2011

7 of 282

changes in the baseline economic outlook. The next exhibit examines possible
practical strategies that may overcome some of the communications challenges and so
help achieve some of the benefits of commitment I just outlined. As highlighted in
the box at the top left, notable improvements in resource utilization were achieved by
two of the strategies we examined—enhanced forward guidance consistent with an
aggressive response to resource utilization as in an inertial version of the Taylor 1999
rule, and nominal income targeting. However, price-level targeting, strictly
construed, delivered poorer performance in terms of resource utilization in two of the
models we considered, including the FRB/US model. This occurred because a strict
version of price-level targeting would not place any weight on resource utilization
and because plausible assumptions for the current price-level gap would imply little
need for near-term policy accommodation. In contrast, nominal income targeting, by
responding to both the price level and real activity, would imply a sizable gap at the
current juncture under plausible assumptions. This can be seen in the panel at the top
right, which shows the path of nominal GDP in the September staff projection and a
hypothetical target path for nominal income. The latter assumes that the target equals
actual nominal GDP in the fourth quarter of 2007 and then grows at the target rate of
inflation, 2 percent, plus the past and projected growth rate of potential output
estimated by the staff. Based on current estimates of the output gap of around
6 percent, the nominal income gap would be around 7 percent in the third quarter of
2011.
The middle panels report the September Tealbook projection along with the
outcomes (using the FRB/US model) under the approach in which the federal funds
rate is set according to an inertial Taylor rule and nominal income targeting. Key
results are also summarized in the bottom panel. As highlighted in the next bullet
point, the inertial Taylor 1999 interest rate rule brings about a notable improvement in
the unemployment rate, at the cost of somewhat higher inflation. This result—that an
aggressive response to resource utilization as in the inertial Taylor 1999 rule implies
less anchoring of inflation—was apparent in other simulations reported in the memo.
Nominal income targeting also improves outcomes for unemployment while bringing
inflation closer to 2 percent; indeed, the inflation and unemployment outcomes are
fairly similar to those under the optimal commitment strategy shown in the first
exhibit.
Finally, as emphasized in the last set of bullets, each strategy involves a clear and
credible commitment to respond to economic conditions for the next 5 to 10 years in
a particular way, thereby importantly influencing financial market and inflation
expectations. As a result, policy communications that lay out the expected course of
the federal funds rate or communicate the conditions that may trigger the onset of
tightening could facilitate achieving better outcomes. For example, under the
nominal income–targeting approach, the federal funds rate remains at its effective
lower bound until the unemployment rate falls below 7 percent, while under the
inertial Taylor 1999 rule approach, the departure of the funds rate from its effective
lower bound occurs around when inflation is expected to persistently exceed
2½ percent; an incremental step in the direction of communicating these approaches

November 1–2, 2011

8 of 282

could involve specifying triggers such as these (a topic analyzed in greater detail in
the forward-guidance memo sent to the Committee in September).
The third exhibit discusses the robustness of these results across different
scenarios or economic models. In our memo, we examined a recession scenario and
an inflationary scenario; the top and middle of the exhibit focus on the recession
scenario. As highlighted in the top-left box, we considered a recession scenario in
which aggregate demand weakens enough to bring the unemployment rate to over
11½ percent for much of 2012 and 2013 under the baseline strategy (which uses the
outcome-based rule reported in the Tealbook and could be interpreted, roughly, as a
continuation of the Committee’s historical approach).
The federal funds rate (the top-right panel) remains at its effective lower bound
until the end of 2015 under the outcome-based rule (the black line) while core PCE
inflation falls to about 0 percent by 2014. The inertial Taylor 1999 rule (the blue
line) leads to lower unemployment in 2014 and 2015 and also cushions the decline in
inflation, which falls below 1 percent over 2012 to 2014. Nominal income targeting
(the red line) limits the rise in unemployment and better mitigates the decline in
inflation. These effects arise because the nominal income–targeting approach allows
the unemployment rate to eventually fall significantly below the long-run sustainable
rate in order to push nominal income back up to the assumed target. Specifically, the
shortfall in activity implies lower nominal income both directly via a decline in real
income and indirectly via the repercussions for prices of lower economic activity;
nominal income targeting acts to unwind the lower price level induced by the
recession by boosting inflation above target later through policy actions that remain
accommodative for significantly longer than under the estimated historical policy
rule, thereby providing additional stimulus.
Of course, the effectiveness of nominal income targeting in this scenario depends
on the assumption that this strategy credibly influences the public’s beliefs about the
policy approach likely to prevail five or more years ahead. The public may doubt
such long-horizon commitments. Indeed, the credibility of the policy strategy is
central to all the approaches we examined, and the Committee may need to take
several steps related to its internal deliberations and public communications to
achieve even some of the gains in economic performance associated with the
approaches we considered.
As highlighted in the box at the bottom, we also considered an inflationary
scenario in which adverse price shocks and rising inflation expectations bring about a
persistent increase in inflation. Our analysis showed that nominal income targeting
performed well in such a scenario, stabilizing both unemployment and inflation; in
contrast, the approach consistent with the inertial Taylor 1999 rule, by responding
substantially to resource utilization without an anchor for the price level, stabilized
unemployment but amplified the impact on inflation.
Finally, the results emphasized in these exhibits were fairly robust when we
considered the performance of these strategies in models other than FRB/US.

November 1–2, 2011

9 of 282

Nominal income targeting also achieved improvements in inflation and
unemployment in simulations of dynamic stochastic general equilibrium models
(such as SIGMA and EDO, two staff models) and in a small model based on research
by economists throughout the Federal Reserve System. In contrast, price-level
targeting performed poorly in the FRB/US model and the small model. Finally,
price-level targeting performed well in the EDO model. This model is perhaps most
similar to that used in some recent research that suggests price-level targeting can be
a good strategy. As a result, our analysis confirms the support for price-level
targeting provided by some research while highlighting that this result is sensitive to
assumptions regarding the structure of the economy.
Moving to your final exhibit, Committee participants received a set of questions
related to these issues on October 25; for your convenience, these questions are
reproduced here.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. The floor is open for questions. Let
me start with a quick one. In the nominal GDP targeting on exhibit 2 we show a gradual
approach to the target. How quickly do you assume that actual nominal GDP approaches the
trend level, and how do you communicate that to the public?
MR. KILEY. In all of the cases, whether it is nominal GDP targeting or the inertial
Taylor rule approach, policy is actually governed by a rule, not by a pure targeting approach. So,
there is no specific objective for how quickly nominal income approaches its target.
We assumed that the policy strategy would be highly inertial so that policy adjustments
would be very slow. We did that because the policy literature suggests that in many models,
highly inertial policies are a really good idea. Those strategies imply that nominal income hits
the target, depending on which model, late this decade or under some of the models even later.
In the FRB/US model, nominal income would hit the target around, say, 2018 and overshoot. In
the EDO model, it hits around the same time, and there is no nominal GDP overshooting. It
essentially hits that level. In the small model we considered, because inflation is so inertial, it
could take even longer, and nominal GDP wouldn’t hit the target over the next 5 to 10 years.

November 1–2, 2011

10 of 282

The answer to the question depends upon the model and the specific degree to which the nominal
income targeting is inertial.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. How do you communicate how aggressively you are going
to respond to the gap?
MR. KILEY. One way to communicate that would be by laying out a simple policy rule,
and that obviously was what we did in all of the models and is one thing that is robust across
models. It doesn’t depend on when nominal income achieves target. Showing how you would
change policy in response to nominal income doesn’t depend on a specific model’s rate at which
the nominal income gap closes, but, rather, depends on your model. Then, one could explain that
in terms of your baseline outlook for nominal income or—
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. Thank you. Other questions? President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Yes, thank you, Mr. Chairman. I wanted to ask about the optimal policy
under discretion. You say that you assume the Committee aims for a target of 2 percent. I am
wondering, does the policymaker choose what inflation rate we desire in the long run? Or do
you hold that constant?
MR. KILEY. It is a period-by-period choice for the policy rate, given a long-run
objective. The policymaker is trying to choose where inflation and unemployment will go on a
period-by-period basis. They don’t reconsider the 2 percent inflation objective. That is
hardwired into a policymaker’s DNA.
MR. LACKER. In a sense, there is some commitment.
MR. KILEY. That is right.
MR. LACKER. Thus the quotes around “discretion.” So the Taylor rule is not timeconsistent, and it describes what we do pretty well, right? Is that true?

November 1–2, 2011

11 of 282

MR. KILEY. Any simple instrument rule will not be the optimal discretionary policy.
There would be an incentive to deviate from it.
MR. LACKER. Right. The extent to which the Taylor rule captures how we behave
now, is it your judgment that we behave with some greater level of commitment than is
embodied in your optimal policy with discretion?
MR. KILEY. As I noted, we would view the historical approach of the Committee as one
consistent with constrained discretion. Clearly the Committee doesn’t adjust policy willy-nilly
and doesn’t reconsider on a meeting-by-meeting basis every aspect of its strategy. Definitely,
there are commitments.
Indeed, under the discretion case, as you noted, we take a number of commitments off the
table and assume that, for example, an inflation objective of 2 percent is hardwired in the
policymaker’s DNA. In addition, policy communications have given guidance regarding the
outlook for the federal funds rate, for example, and I am sure the Committee and the public view
those as conditional commitments. It would be false to suggest that the policy approach involves
zero commitments. The optimal discretionary case here involves a number of commitments as
well, and the extent to which there could be gains from further commitment is consistent with the
story that we have told in illustrating commitment versus discretion.
MR. LACKER. I have one other question, Mr. Chairman, if I could. You have an
objective function that you carry across these scenarios and across models that has the
policymaker minimizing this weighted sum. On the unemployment side, it is the deviation of
unemployment from a u* that is fixed, that is a constant. Am I right about that, or is it the
Tealbook’s NAIRU?
MR. KILEY. There are the modest movements in the Tealbook’s natural rate.

November 1–2, 2011

12 of 282

MR. LACKER. Is it the natural rate that is adjusted for the extended unemployment
benefits?
MR. KILEY. It is. That is not particularly important, because that is only an adjustment
in the next year.
MR. LACKER. In the model EDO, you start from preferences, endowments, and
technologies, and, principally, you could derive the right loss function, right? And it wouldn’t
have the same property that the u* is some fixed, smooth thing. Am I right about that?
MR. KILEY. Yes, that’s correct.
MR. LACKER. There is this dichotomy here, right? The change in the unemployment
insurance, the richness of those—it is a kind of a shock, right? You guys take that on board for
NAIRU, but you don’t take on board any of the other shocks that have hit the economy in the
past few years. Have you guys thought about that dichotomy, that contrast?
MR. REIFSCHNEIDER. Before this recession we thought the NAIRU was 4¾ percent.
Now we think, leaving aside the effects of extended unemployment benefits, things like that, it is
6 percent. When you ratchet that up, that is a very persistent hit to labor market functioning,
relative to what we thought.
We have also gone back and taken a look at what it was prior to the recession. I don’t
think it was quite as low as 4¾ percent. But we have assumed that—through very persistent
reduced attachment to the labor force, through duration of employment, through long duration of
employment hurting people’s skills, things like that—there are persistent fallout effects, supplyside effects. As Mike said, those effects are taken into account in these analyses.

November 1–2, 2011

13 of 282

MR. LACKER. That results in a figure that is really smooth, and the vision you’d get out
of EDO is that every quarter’s TFP shock should affect the natural rate. There is still a bit of a
bucket of left-out shocks there. Thank you.
MR. KILEY. That is technically true. In much of the literature actually incorporating
unemployment in models like EDO—in practice, that is not the result that comes out. The
natural rate of unemployment is often very smooth. In addition, it is important to be consistent
across all the implications of a model if one wants to push the story that far. For example, in
EDO, given the definition of the natural rate of unemployment that you are suggesting, that
would be higher. It is also the case that there is a natural rate of interest that should be accounted
for in a model like that, and that is actually much, much lower because of the effect on financial
frictions estimated by that model. If you take both of those factors into account, you would want
policy to be even easier than in a model like FRB/US. One shouldn’t cherry-pick a particular
implication of a model. One needs to walk through the analysis very consistently, and it is not
always what one thinks.
MR. LACKER. Perfectly fair.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Raskin.
MS. RASKIN. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. One question, Michael, from an
operational perspective on the nominal income targeting, and that has to do with whether the
activity component of nominal income is known in a timely way and as a reliable data point
sufficient to permit adjustment.
MR. KILEY. One could have different opinions on that. At the current juncture, I think
the answer is clearly yes, the data are timely enough. Over the period that we are considering
these strategies, nominal income would provide a reliable enough signal, because we are not

November 1–2, 2011

14 of 282

talking about whether the federal funds rate should be up or down 25 basis points this quarter,
and then adjusted next quarter. We are looking at a situation in which, in our estimation, a
plausible nominal income gap is about 7 percent. The measurement error or the degree of
revision in nominal income is just not that high, but there are revisions.
It is certainly possible that when the economy is back closer to steady-state conditions
that that type of a consideration would be important from meeting to meeting. I think that’s
something that one wants to consider when one is thinking about whether or not an intermediate
target like nominal income is appropriate for the next 5 to 10 years or is appropriate forevermore.
And the answer to that question is that it doesn’t have to be the same. Right now we are
in extraordinary times. One of the problems with nominal income targeting—that we are not
exactly sure about the level of nominal income this quarter—is actually not that important right
now, even though 10 years from now I hope that that is a really important consideration.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you. I have a question. It seems like the way you
have presented it implies that the nominal GDP targeting implied a lower trigger or a lower
threshold for exit. Do you need the actual framework of nominal GDP targeting to generate
these outcomes? Or could you just actually have the lower trigger threshold? And would that be
sufficient? I mean, how does the staff view the articulation of the framework vis-à-vis how that
maps into the trigger? I am not sure I am being clear.
MR. KILEY. I am not sure that there is a uniform step. The way that I would think
about it is that certainly within a given model, or a given view of the world, specifying a trigger
and an outlook for the funds rate is the same as saying that you want a target for nominal GDP.
But as I noted earlier when we were talking about the rate at which nominal GDP might

November 1–2, 2011

15 of 282

approach its target, those implications are not robust necessarily across different views of the
world; whereas reference to a set of goals—and those could be unemployment goals and
inflation goals, those could be nominal income, those could be something else—may be more
consistent across frameworks.
The way that I would view it is that there is some distinction between simply saying the
funds rate is going to be a certain value for the next X quarters and a framework, because the
framework provides information to individuals who have a different view. And over time they
will learn whether their view is confirmed or disputed by the data and presumably update their
expectations.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I am trying to get at a point—how much of the benefit
do you get by having the trigger values out there versus the framework out there? I am trying to
understand how you parse those two things.
MR. KILEY. Certainly, under the baseline outlook you get some of the benefit from the
trigger and some of the benefit from the overall framework. And then, in the shocks, when
things turn out different than you expect, the triggers don’t necessarily tell you what is going to
happen in all cases, because they may involve differences in policy in periods after the trigger
has happened. The framework provides some of the benefit.
In the simulations, or in the forward-guidance memo, triggers that signal additional
policy accommodation are helpful at the current time, if one wants to improve outcomes for
resource utilization. But there appear to be some gains from moving beyond that.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you.
MR. WILCOX. It would be difficult to analyze that question, in principle, in your
models, because the agents in your models understand exactly what the framework is. I think

November 1–2, 2011

16 of 282

what Michael is saying is that communication clarity is key to the difference between a trigger
strategy and a nominal income-targeting strategy, and communication isn’t an issue that is salient
in the model.
MR. KILEY. Yes, that is the hard part.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. On the other hand, nominal income targeting is only an
approximation of the optimal path, so a lot depends on the quality of the approximation as well.
MR. KILEY. Right. And certainly, across different models is a less-good
approximation. We had one example of nominal income targeting a specific rule, changing those
parameters slightly. It is not going to be quite as good an approximation of the optimal policy
rule.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Thanks for the great memo, and
thanks for the great presentation, Michael. I had two quick questions. One is, in exhibit 3, when
I look at PCE prices under nominal income targeting, the graph ends in 2018, and we are still
above 3 percent. How long do we stay above 2 percent in that simulation?
MR. KILEY. This is a huge shock, so the economy takes a long time to get back to
steady state.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes, I agree with that.
MR. KILEY. It doesn’t actually take that long to get back to 2 percent. This is sort of
the peak, and it starts coming down and will be going back closely to 2 percent in the several
years after that. But the economy won’t settle down. It will undershoot, and then it will come
back up, because the economy under this particular policy strategy, which is just focusing on
nominal income, will be oscillating in toward that steady state for a while under the FRB/US

November 1–2, 2011

17 of 282

model. That is not necessarily true in all the models. But as I noted, part of the success of that
strategy in this scenario is this willingness to have inflation go to 3 percent.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I agree, yes.
MR. KILEY. We certainly did simulations in which, when you see that, you just back off
and want to give up on nominal income targeting. That trims the gains and puts it closer to the
Taylor-type strategy.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thanks. That was useful. This is not my second question. It
is more of a follow-up. I think that this gets back to something that President Lacker was asking
about discretion. One thing that might be interesting to know is the size of the losses that are
being forgone by a discretionary FOMC as we go along these scenarios. If you are in 2017, and
the inflation rate is at 3 percent and unemployment is down under 4, what is that FOMC thinking
about how much they are forgoing in terms of the losses? I think that would help us understand
how credible these kinds of plans are. I don’t know if I was making sense or not.
MR. KILEY. Yes.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. My second question is, what is the size of our shortfall, in
terms of nominal GDP, right now? The staff has an estimate of potential, and I think the
shortfall right now is being calculated relative to that notion of potential GDP, and that comes to
be about 7 percent in the current quarter relative to where we were starting in December ’07 or
something like that, fourth quarter ’07. Many outside observers would say that the gap is
actually 4 percentage points bigger than that because they are using some kind of trend line from
December ’07 to be their guidepost.
The challenge right now is, how do we start to communicate about our nuanced measures
of potential GDP to the public relative to just drawing the straight trend line, which I think is

November 1–2, 2011

18 of 282

more what people are used to? I will speak for myself. When I try to communicate to the public
about how deep this episode has been, I use the trend line. For one thing, I think potential GDP
is Class II FOMC information, so I am not able to talk about it. [Laughter] But more seriously,
it is a challenge for us to say that we are going to do nominal income targeting, but, by the way,
we don’t view ourselves as responsible for 4 percentage points of what you think of as a
shortfall. It is a communication issue that might be hard.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. And thank you, Michael, for the
presentation and the analysis. I love this kind of stuff; I am a big fan.
I have a couple of comments. One is, when we talk about price-level targeting, I thought
it got a little jumbled, because I guess you are talking about what I would call strict price-level
targeting. When I think back to the original Svensson paper on this, he took this objective that
had the output gap and inflation in it, and he replaced inflation with price-level targeting. The
output gap was still there, so to me, when we went to the price-level-targeting argument, it was
all there, and so there wasn’t anything that indicated that price-level targeting means that you are
going to ignore the real side of the economy. There wasn’t anything like that. To have pricelevel targeting get a bad name from this memo, which is what is happening, I think is a little
unfair to the approach. The price level was supposed to substitute for the commitment that
wasn’t there when you had the inflation rates there. That was a pretty good insight and has been
verified in subsequent models.
You can go to nominal income targeting instead, but you could also go to flexible pricelevel targeting. What is the difference between those two is really the question. What is the

November 1–2, 2011

19 of 282

difference between flexible price-level targeting, as I would see it originally envisioned by
Svensson, and nominal income targeting?
MR. KILEY. Nominal income targeting is just one example of flexible price-level
targeting. Because there are an infinite number of examples of flexible price-level targeting, we
picked the polar cases that are easy, round numbers; we picked 0 on the output gap, strict pricelevel targeting, and 1 on the output gap, nominal income targeting. But you are absolutely right
that flexible price-level targeting is the best thing to do in some models, and we just chose to
focus on the one case. People have some empirical papers that have considered flexible pricelevel targeting. For example, the one by Gorodnichenko and Shapiro, let’s say they have a
coefficient of 1 plus some inertia on the price level, and then an even bigger coefficient on the
output gap than 1. They would be even more aggressive than nominal income targeting. So one,
of course, could have a smaller coefficient on the output gap, and performance would be
sensitive to those assumptions. But one would move from “price-level targeting performed
poorly” in a couple of the models we considered to “nominal income targeting performed
reasonably well” in those models. One would move in that direction as one became more
flexible in price-level targeting and put some weight on the output gap.
MR. BULLARD. Okay. Thank you. One thing about this memo that I thought was not
addressed—from the perspective of this Committee—is, what are we really worried about? We
are worried that you are playing with fire, and you might replay a really bad scenario in which
inflation goes up a lot, and you really get into a lot of trouble.
What would it take in this kind of framework to get into that kind of hot water? The
answer might be there is no scenario under which that can happen, but the ’70s did happen. I
think you have to have something in the model that goes too far and really generates a lot of

November 1–2, 2011

20 of 282

problems. Otherwise, the question would be, why don’t you just commit to zero rates out to
2030, if it is all beneficial?
MR. KILEY. I agree. That is a really hard question, and certainly things can go wrong.
It is hard to know what those are. I think if one committed to interest rates of some fixed path
until 2030, things would be very likely to go wrong. That is why we talk about strategies that
would be conditional on economic outcomes.
In terms of what could trigger a repeat of the 1970s, obviously, I don’t know. It is
notable that nominal income targeting was proposed in the late 1970s by people like Jim Tobin
and James Meade, precisely because inflation was a problem. Then, a subsequent analysis by
people in the 1980s—Marty Feldstein, Greg Mankiw, many people—showed it is a good
strategy in response to those kind of shocks. The idea, actually, was to prevent that kind of
outcome.
MR. BULLARD. I just have one more comment, which President Lacker has already
brought up, which is, how fair is it to characterize what the Committee does now as a
discretionary policy? In some sense, if you have a Taylor rule, maybe it is a simple Taylor rule,
maybe it is not the optimal one, but you can pick the coefficients to be as good as they can be for
that particular Taylor rule. That will probably get you pretty close to the optimal outcome. You
are committing to the rule, you always behave like the rule, so in a sense there is a lot of
commitment already there. How much can you really improve on that, as opposed to the
literature, which says that you are always choosing the discretionary solution at every point in
time?

November 1–2, 2011

21 of 282

MR. KILEY. There is one important aspect of commitment that isn’t captured by the
Taylor rule. In all of our baselines, the Committee is committed to following some reasonable
strategy. The baseline is always a simple rule—the outcome-based rule or something like that.
The types of commitment strategies that Dave and Chris and I were talking about move
beyond that simple rule, because they involve some commitment to undo undesirable movements
in the price level. So one is willing to have inflation run at 2½ percent for a while, for example,
if unemployment is very high, to a degree that is greater than embedded in something like a
Taylor rule. That is an insight in the policy literature that can be a good idea, and that is
behavior inconsistent with simple policy rules that involve inflation. That price-level-type aspect
of nominal income targeting or the optimal commitment strategy or price-level targeting does
move beyond the types of commitments that the Committee has, for the most part, been willing
to make in the past.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have two less deep, more mundane
questions about the charts that I’d like to see if I understand. Under nominal GDP targeting,
nominal GDP is the sum of real GDP plus the GDP deflator, and yet you’re talking about what’s
going on with the PCE price index. If you’re really targeting nominal GDP, you’re targeting the
GDP deflator implicitly, right? How in your calculation do you make that translation, and how
do you think about that, again, as another communication device about what we’re doing?
That’s the first question.
MR. KILEY. First, I’ll give you technically what we did. This is a question very similar
to the question Governor Raskin asked in terms of its implications at the current juncture. What
we did mechanically is not be particularly concerned about any trend differences in GDP prices

November 1–2, 2011

22 of 282

and core PCE prices, and we set the target for 2 percent for GDP prices, and that’s slightly
different than a target for 2 percent for core PCE prices or for overall PCE prices.
During normal times—when we are there, 5 to 10 years from now—that would be really
important if one’s very concerned about 2 versus 2.2 percent. If the gap in nominal income is
7 percent, 2 or 2.2 percent just doesn’t matter. It’s not important for the types of simulations
we’re doing right now, but it is important for behavior potentially at other times.
MR. PLOSSER. The second question is sort of related to this. A lot of the level
targeting, whether it be price-level targeting or nominal GDP–level targeting, can be quite
sensitive to where the path begins, whether you start at December ’07 or whether you start at
December 2000 or 2003 or what have you. When we think about targeting the level for
anything, the sensitivity perhaps to that initial condition, how do we think about choosing what
the right initial condition was? Certainly, December 2007 was the peak of the housing bubble
and perhaps some other things that you might want to think about. And yet if you go back
earlier, as President Lacker has talked about, the inflation rates of 2005 and 2006 were high. I’m
thinking about the sensitivity and how we would think about implementing a policy and
choosing the right initial condition to measure what you think, in fact, the gap is.
MR. KILEY. It’s a hard question. The approach we took was simply: I’m on the staff
with the Board, and I think our estimate of the output gap is pretty reasonable. [Laughter]
Taking a view in which it happened to be the case that the output gap was pretty close to zero
before the recession started in our estimation now, and we said, let’s take that as the initial
condition because it might be something that one would want to communicate—that we’ve seen
a bad few years and want to make up for those bad few years—and we came up with a
reasonable number.

November 1–2, 2011

23 of 282

Other people would go back to that same date and just write through a trend line, and
they would have an even bigger gap—not the 7 percent we had, but a 10 or 11 percent gap—
because they wouldn’t be accounting for the unfortunate decline in potential that we’ve seen in
that period. Or you could start from today and say, “the gap is zero, but we’re going to follow
this strategy in the future,” and that would have very different implications.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Any other questions? [No response] Well, we’re about
ready for a go-round and discussion. I’d like to make a couple of framing comments.
First of all, let me thank the staff, for I think we can all agree that their work has been
extraordinarily helpful, really first rate, and it helped me think about this quite a bit. Thanks very
much for that work done under pressure of time.
One might think that a discussion of policy frameworks is a little bit arcane, academic,
and off point, but actually, it’s right at the center of what we’re doing now. We’re in a situation
where the effects of our policy depend at least as much on what people think we’re going to do
in the future as they do on what we do today, and consequently, the framework that we are using
and that we communicate—and the communication is incredibly important—has very real
effects on the efficacy of our policy. This is very much part of the contingency planning effort
that I promised a couple of meetings ago both in the sense of trying to think about our current
framework and thinking about where we might go if things turn much to the worse.
There’s probably a narrow way and a broad way to think about this discussion. The
narrow way is to note that I think it’s not too controversial to describe our behavior as
conforming to a version of flexible inflation targeting, which attempts to achieve a broad
definition of price stability over the forecast horizon, but in the short term allows some flexibility
for stabilization of the real economy.

November 1–2, 2011

24 of 282

Where we deviate to some extent from international practice on inflation targeting is that
we haven’t done everything that some central banks have done in terms of communication,
including specifying a numerical objective, providing a comprehensive, collective forecast,
providing guidance or even forecasts of future rates, et cetera. One way to think about this
discussion is, what additional steps do we want to take, if any, recognizing that we do have a
rather different institutional situation here than in many other countries—a large Committee, a
dual mandate, et cetera? But another way of thinking about this discussion is an issue that we’ve
talked about many times before, that we want to take further steps to solidify and clarify our
flexible inflation-targeting approach, and if so, how could we communicate that?
It’s useful—and one of the things I thought that the memo did very well—to show us that
there really is a broader issue here, which roughly speaking is the difference between
discretionary and commitment-based policy, particularly in a situation where we’re at the zero
bound and conventional signaling by moving interest rates is not available. To the extent that we
can show a committed policy—that we can clarify our future policies will correspond to the
optimal path under commitment, similar and analogous to the path that is presented every
meeting in the Tealbook—the better results we’ll get.
In some sense the broader question is not just about flexible inflation targeting. The
broader question is, can we provide a communications framework that will allow us both to
convey and to commit to a policy path that will deliver potentially better outcomes on both
inflation and growth than the policy framework we have now? I think that’s an open question.
There are a lot of practical issues that come into play, a lot of special issues related to what
model you believe in, and so on, but I would urge us all to think about this in that context, and as
much as possible, to divorce it from the current conjuncture and ask the question that if we’re

November 1–2, 2011

25 of 282

going to adopt some changes in communication, what would serve this Committee well for a
period of time.
Before opening the floor, let me restate the questions that were circulated so they’ll be in
everybody’s mind. Narrowly, to the extent that we’re looking at a flexible inflation targeting
framework, would it make sense to adopt a numerical objective? That would be one way to
clarify our goals. In doing so, of course, we would have to make very clear how that relates to
our dual mandate and why it’s consistent with our dual mandate. The counter argument is that
doing that convincingly is a communications challenge in itself, and that’s one issue to address.
More broadly, again, beyond the flexible inflation-targeting framework is the question of
how we can make better, clearer commitments to future policy, and a number of different
approaches have been suggested. We talked at the last meeting about conditional commitments,
and we showed a few possible examples in the alternative A1 in the statements. Would it be
helpful to specify some conditions under which we change policy, specifying those well in
advance? That is one way to try to approximate an optimal policy in terms of commitment.
An alternative way, as the discussion just illustrated, is by specifying intermediate
targets. Intermediate targets are an old concept in monetary policy. It’s been always used in the
sense of a guidepost or a second pillar, a way of providing additional information about policy.
But in the current context, as the memo shows, it could be that pursuing a particular intermediate
target might be a reasonable approximation to the first-best policy under commitment, and that’s
an empirical question, in part.
I’m sure many of you have seen some of the commentary on, for example, nominal GDP
targets. Christina Romer made the point over the weekend that one potential advantage of
something like a nominal GDP target is that it could be viewed as a regime change, and to the

November 1–2, 2011

26 of 282

extent that it reflects a real change in how the Fed is doing business, it might have a more
dramatic effect on expectations than something more incremental. That being said, of course,
big changes are also dangerous, and that’s something we need to keep in mind.
Now, a fourth question. So—first, inflation targeting; second, conditional commitment;
third, intermediate targets. A fourth question—there was a lot of discussion last time about the
economic projections; can we use those better? I think we’ve made a lot of progress on that
front. In particular, we have a proposal to look at projections of our policy rate. In what way
could that be complementary to an improved communication strategy?
Finally, let’s not forget, it’s important as we talk about these things to keep in mind
process. Is there a way that we can put this all together in a way that will satisfy the appropriate
consultation and discussion within the Committee but also allow us to bring this to the public in
a way that will be better understood and better accepted? In particular, a specific suggestion
that’s been made is that we use the approach we did with our principles of exit strategy, which
we published in June in the minutes. Would it be possible, if we do adopt some changes in our
communication strategy, to agree on a set of principles that would be sufficiently broad to
encompass Committee support, that we could then put out through the minutes or some other
mechanism? I think there’s a whole bunch of interesting questions here, and this is very central
to our current policy decisions. We don’t have to resolve all of these questions today, but I do
think that this is a valuable investment in time, and I look forward to your comments.
Beginning the go-round, I see President Evans is first on the list.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m not sure I was prepared for every one of
those questions, but I certainly appreciate them. Before I simply answer the routine questions,
I’d like to put some of this material in context. My first reaction to the outstanding staff memos

November 1–2, 2011

27 of 282

is extremely positive. As President Bullard said, I’m a big fan. I thought that was a great
presentation, great answers to the questions.
I’m happy to see that there are policy approaches available to us that should produce
economic outcomes that are vastly preferred to our current outlook, and as you just mentioned,
Mr. Chairman, it’s easy to see why there’s a growing clamor among an impressive variety of
outside experts calling for more aggressive action, like Christy Romer, Mike Woodford, Ken
Rogoff, the staff at Goldman Sachs, et cetera.
Outsiders have an easier time advocating these prescriptions. For us insiders, details
matter for the implementation. But before we can even consider technical details, I think the first
major issue to grapple with is this: Has our current policy framework limited our effectiveness
because it’s not properly understood by the Committee in its fullness or by the public, or because
we disagree on the particulars of our framework? I personally think this is a concern. I
mentioned this back in August when I said I thought that there were cracks emerging in our
policy framework. I won’t belabor this issue. I’ve given two speeches on the dual mandate and
my interpretation of its implications for our policymaking.
I don’t believe we all agree on what flexible inflation targeting means and we simply
disagree over many details of our policy objectives. Last week President Kocherlakota offered
an informative and welcome memo on the dual mandate. I disagree with his preferences, but I
welcome the information revelation on these fundamental issues.
Here’s my first takeaway message. Our standard policy framework—one that glosses
over the details of what we mean by flexible inflation targeting within our dual mandate
responsibilities—usually works when the real economy and inflation pressures are within 1 or

November 1–2, 2011

28 of 282

maybe 2 percentage points of our goals. But when our policy differences burst into the open, as
they have given today’s extreme economic circumstances, this ambiguity is not constructive.
My second message is that today we need to adopt a more explicit framework. Even a
complete articulation of our standard approach is unlikely to address the full range of relevant
risk that the economy and monetary policy currently face. This is of enormous importance.
To highlight the potential value of these alternative policy frameworks, I want to focus a
bit on risk-management considerations related to our current economic problems. Since the
spring and summer of 2010, it has become more and more apparent that our macroeconomic
problems are much larger than we had been planning for. There are essentially two story lines
that are used to account for the aberrantly slow growth and high unemployment following the
Great Recession, and I’d like to pick up on one of the themes that President Bullard was
mentioning in terms of how we could get into trouble with some of these approaches.
The first story line I refer to as the “structural impediments” scenario. In this scenario,
the Great Recession was accompanied by an acute period of structural change, labor mismatch,
job-killing uncertainties, and excessive regulatory burdens. As best I can tell, this scenario
consists of lots of conjectures about economic outcomes and potential equilibriums. I would like
to be able to point to macro simulation evidence from empirically relevant general equilibrium
models studied by research economists that support this scenario, but I’m not aware of these
studies. I don’t know where to look, and I’d be happy for anybody to add in a literature list. The
links to the relevant economic literature are unclear to me, at least. Nevertheless, in this story
line, the role for additional monetary accommodation is modest, at best. We are up against a
supply constraint that monetary policy can’t fix. In this scenario, we should be guarding against
a repeat of the 1970s. We should thus revert to what I refer to as “business as usual” monetary

November 1–2, 2011

29 of 282

policies. Accordingly, it’s probably time to begin considering removing excess accommodation
before inflation rises above target and inflation expectations become unhinged.
The second story line I referred to as the “liquidity trap” scenario. In this scenario, shortterm risk-free rates are zero. Actual real rates are modestly negative, but the real natural rate of
interest is strikingly negative. This is due to an abundance of risk aversion, extreme patience,
and deleveraging, and these attitudes are unlikely to disappear any time soon. In this scenario,
we’re in the aftermath of an enormous Reinhart–Rogoff financial crisis, and the resulting drags
on demand are exceedingly large and persistent. The clear and present danger here is that we
repeat the experiences of the U.S. in the 1930s or Japan over the past 20 years. Liquidity traps
have been studied in general equilibrium models by Paul Krugman, Gauti Eggertson, and Mike
Woodford, and also recently by Iván Werning in a continuous-time framework. The conclusions
from this literature indicate that there are monetary policy prescriptions that can vastly improve
outcomes in such an event.
I think the evidence strongly favors the liquidity trap scenario. That’s my opinion. But
rather than putting all of our eggs in one theoretical basket, let’s consider the case where we
don’t know which scenario is really the one we face today. This leads me to think more about a
robust risk-management approach to the dilemma that these two scenarios present. If both are
possible, but we don’t know which one we face, how can we avoid risking a repeat of either the
1970s or the 1930s? Because I put high weight on liquidity trap theories, put me down as being
sympathetic to nominal GDP targeting. I was actually not supposed to say that [laughter], but
anyway I edited that out. The problem is that policies that are optimal for the liquidity trap
scenario would generate high inflation if the structural impediment scenario actually was true. I
think that’s what President Bullard was alluding to. Conversely, policies that are optimal for the

November 1–2, 2011

30 of 282

structural impediment scenario would leave the economy mired in depression and deflation if
applied during a liquidity trap scenario.
Fortunately, even amidst these two extreme scenarios, there is a middle-ground policy
approach. A relatively robust policy approach would be to sharpen forward guidance in two
directions. First, ensure state-contingent accommodative policies as long as unemployment is
somewhat above its natural rate. But second, include an additional safeguard that policy will
pull back if inflation rises above a threshold that would signal the economy is running into
supply constraints, such as those in the structural impediment scenario.
In my opinion, the inflation safeguard threshold needs to be substantially above our
inflation objective, and I’ve said in public perhaps 3 percent. Ken Rogoff has suggested
4 percent, 4 to 6 percent, he even said, and, frankly, Governor Bernanke suggested to Japan also
a very large number when he was offering advice.
This guidance is consistent with the most recent liquidity trap research by MIT Professor
Iván Werning, which shows that improved economic performance during a liquidity trap requires
allowing inflation to run higher than the inflation target. In addition, establishing credible
expectations of these events likely requires overshooting the efficient output level and creating
an output boom, reversing the resource gap once the natural rate of interest returns to positive
territory, and there were many simulations that had those characteristics that Michael was talking
about. Under this trigger threshold policy, if the liquidity trap scenario is indeed true, then the
massive degree of resource slack in the economy means such an output boom could perhaps be
achieved without putting excessive pressure on productive resources. On the negative side, if the
structural impediment scenario was instead true, inflation will rise more quickly and without any
real-side improvements. In such an adverse situation, the inflation safeguard triggers an exit

November 1–2, 2011

31 of 282

from non-evident excessive policy accommodation before inflation expectations become
unhinged.
Accordingly, under either scenario, liquidity trap or structural impediments, this policy
keeps long-term inflation expectations firm. In my opinion, applying this trigger threshold riskmanagement approach to our current economic situation is really just an embodiment of what I
see as our broader flexible inflation-targeting framework. The benefits of this policy draw me to
the structure in alternative A1 with the paragraph 4″ option in the Tealbook. However, as I
mentioned before, I prefer a 3 percent medium-term inflation trigger instead of the 2½ percent
one mentioned there.
According to the logic of the liquidity trap theory, we risk being mired for an
unacceptably long period in recession-like circumstances unless we are willing to voluntarily
embrace and commit to a higher inflation rate than our medium-term objective, at least for a
time. It is against central bankers’ DNA to discuss and acknowledge this, but we should not risk
an outcome like the U.S. in the 1930s or Japan today. Three percent just isn’t such a big number
that we should resist it the way the 1930s Fed adhered to the gold standard.
Now, to quickly wrap up with regard to the specific questions posed to the Committee, I
agree that the flexible inflation-targeting framework described in the memo is consistent with the
Federal Reserve’s dual mandate. I also think we should enunciate such a framework, and that it
would be helpful for the Committee to be explicit in articulating these principles.
To reach a consensus statement, of course, we need to agree on an explicit numerical
target for our inflation objective, and also what that target means operationally. After all, we
should be confident that our choice of inflation target and operating procedure are jointly
consistent with an exceedingly low probability of hitting the zero lower bound over the next

November 1–2, 2011

32 of 282

20 years. We’ve hit it twice in the past 10 years, in my opinion. I answered the second question
extensively. Yes, I think the Committee’s best choice is to announce and commit to the optimal
policy path under commitment.
Finally, I believe that nominal income targeting is a close cousin to the economic
thresholds policies. It is simply bigger and less prescriptive regarding the composition of growth
and inflation. I expect that additional forward guidance combined with further asset purchases
would either increase growth or generate inflation, or both, but just in case, a bigger
communications bazooka is needed. I would prepare the groundwork for introducing nominal
income targeting if it’s needed. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, President Evans. Since you took my name in
vain, I do feel constrained to mention—
MR. EVANS. No, I thought it was good. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. But I do think I need to clarify that those comments were
directed at the country that actually was suffering significant deflation, and so it was failing on
both the price stability and the economic growth.
MR. EVANS. Yes, I think you’re right. I understand that, and in fact, I spent a little
more time reading Friedman and Schwartz and The Great Contraction, and at the end of that
lovely chapter, they had this section on why monetary policy was so inept. And I remember
back to the lovely Milton Friedman celebration of his 90th birthday party where you gave a
speech where—with Milton Friedman in the front row, attentive as always after a very long night
before and that morning and afternoon—you assured him that the Federal Reserve had, indeed,
caused mischief in the ’30s, and that we wouldn’t do it again.

November 1–2, 2011

33 of 282

I looked at that chapter, and I totally agree with you that you have been faithful to that.
During the contraction, there were policies that should have been taken that were not, that could
have prevented deflation and the Depression. I agree with that. I think we could do more,
though. That’s all I’m saying. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. A two-handed intervention, President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The dialogue that you and
President Evans just had is relevant when we think about the Eggertson and Woodford model
and the Werning model. I have to admit I understand the Werning model a little better, but in
those models, basically, price-level targeting works extremely well, except for the presence of
the zero lower bound. It means in some settings that you’re not able to keep prices growing at
2 percent or constant. If you’re ever in a situation where you’re meeting your price-stability
mandate in the Werning model, if you’re doing well on that and hitting 2 percent, 2 percent,
2 percent, you do not have a problem in that model. That’s also true in Eggertson and
Woodford.
I think it’s important to make this distinction that you just made between that and Japan
and the U.S. in the ’30s, that those were situations where you could easily point to problems on
the price-stability mandate and see that the central bank is not behaving optimally. I think it’s
more challenging in our current environment where, as you expect in Minneapolis, we’ve done
extremely well on our price-stability mandate—over the past four or five years, we’ve done very
well on it. There are some differences of opinion about how well we’re going to be doing going
forward, but even there the differences of opinion are relatively minor compared to what we saw
in Japan.

November 1–2, 2011

34 of 282

I think when we look at these New Keynesian models—they’re very hard to bring
support for the kind of commitment policies that President Evans has in mind because we’re just
not that far away from our price-stability mandate.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, obviously this will be taken up in some length.
[Laughter] President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. President Evans was quite eloquent and
expansive. [Laughter] I have a great deal of sympathy with his views. I’ll take a different
strategy and use a little more brevity in my remarks.
In terms of question 1, flexible inflation targeting can be consistent with the dual
mandate, but being clear about exactly what is meant is critical. Some use the term to place a
heavy weight on inflation and a small but nonzero weight on employment. Others use it to imply
a lexicographic preference between inflation and unemployment, that is, as long as we are below
the inflation target, we have the flexibility to address large output gaps. I would be opposed to
either of these interpretations of flexible inflation targeting. What I would support is a quadratic
loss function with roughly equal weights on inflation and unemployment as in the optimal policy
simulations in the Tealbook, Book B. Were we close to the inflation target but far from our
estimate of full employment, we would be accommodative to reduce the quadratic loss function.
Were we close to full employment but well above our inflation target, we would have more
restrictive policy to return to our inflation target and reduce our loss function.
In terms of question 2, our current approach of using calendar dates to signal the first
increase in the funds rate is potentially problematic if we are not willing to adjust it to changing
circumstances. For example, significantly greater downside risks or worse-than-expected
economic outcomes after the date is set, so that economic conditions are no longer consistent

November 1–2, 2011

35 of 282

with the original calendar date. I would prefer to announce our intent to remain at the zero
bound until we hit specific economic triggers, such as an unemployment rate at or below
7 percent and an inflation rate of 3 percent or higher. Of course, we would not view such
triggers as absolute and independent of all other economic conditions. For example, a forecast of
exceptionally strong or weak growth as we approached a trigger might force us to take action
earlier or later. I would strongly support moving to conditional commitments, such as the
example in option A.
In terms of question 3, I would support considering moving to nominal GDP targeting if
it is necessary to forcefully convey a change in regime. It would be most appropriate if we want
to signal a regime change that requires more aggressive policies moving forward. I view
nominal GDP targeting as preferable to price-level targeting because it is easier to communicate,
performs better in simulations, and does not emphasize just one element of the dual mandate.
An announcement that nominal GDP targeting was necessary to get much stronger growth in
output is understandable to the public and could be effective if it was conveyed in conjunction
with more aggressive actions.
In terms of question 4, we need to be clear what we’re trying to communicate. If we’re
trying to communicate why we were taking policy actions, then enforcing a common interest rate
path across all participants, such as an assumption of no change in interest rates or the interest
rate path embedded in the futures market, may be appropriate. If our policy differs from the
assumptions, we would show that our forecast with those assumptions is not consistent with our
goals and use that communication to justify a different policy than what was used in the forecast.
A potential problem is that it may be difficult to make clear at times why our forecast deviates
substantially from what we expect. A second potential problem is that an interest rate path alone

November 1–2, 2011

36 of 282

may not be sufficient for describing policy over the next several years, given the prominence that
balance sheet policies have played. If instead we are trying to communicate our best forecast for
important economic variables, I would prefer to use optimal policy as we do now, even though
we might disagree on how we get there. Of the two, my guess is the general public is primarily
interested in our best forecast. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I also want to thank the staff for their
excellent set of memos. They are fascinating and interesting, and I appreciate the discussion and
insights they provided. I will structure my comments around the questions that were posed.
I view flexible inflation targeting, which combines an explicit commitment to a mediumrun inflation objective with the flexibility to respond to shocks to support economic stability, as
fully consistent with the dual mandate. The dual mandate objectives, price stability and
maximum employment, I believe are generally complementary to one another. Price stability is
both a goal and a means through which monetary policy can contribute to the employment
objective. Thus, I see no fundamental inconsistency with us having an explicit numerical
inflation objective and a dual mandate. Indeed, by having accurate inflation expectations, the
explicit inflation objective gives us more flexibility to act to help mitigate the effects of shocks
on real activity.
I am an enthusiastic supporter of monetary policy transparency in viewing
communications with the public about our framework as a further useful step in clarifying our
policy decisionmaking process. The exit statement that we developed earlier in the year was
quite consistent with the earlier steps we have taken toward increased transparency. It would be
very helpful if we tried to formulate a consensus statement on the Committee’s monetary policy

November 1–2, 2011

37 of 282

framework. I suggest that the subcommittee on communications chaired by Governor Yellen be
charged with the task of creating a first draft of such a principles document, which could then be
circulated for review and comments. You will recall that the ad hoc committee on which I
served earlier in the year drafted a document on an explicit numerical inflation objective within
the context of the dual mandate, which we thought was broadly consistent with the description
that the Chairman just gave on flexible inflation targeting. So some progress has already been
made on this initiative, and I think we can build on that foundation and hopefully find a
consensus.
As long as we are on communication, I would like to make another suggestion. It is no
secret that I favor a more rules-based approach to policy as both a disciplining device on our own
actions as well as an effective communication tool to the public and the markets. While we are a
long way from agreeing on what an appropriate rule might be, I think we can make progress
down this path by being clear regarding what the variables are that would appear in such a rule.
We started down this path when we added to our statement in November 2009 that we
considered inflation, inflation expectations, and resource utilization as key factors that would
influence our policy decisions. That was a good start, but we didn’t do much with it. Indeed,
some might even perceive that the changes in forward guidance we made in August/September
as being at odds with the information in those conditioning variables. What would be helpful is
if we could structure a discussion in this Committee on how we might better articulate the
arguments of such a policy function, and then attempt to describe our decisions on an ongoing
basis in the context of how those variables evolve over time, and thus describing how our
decisions evolve over time in a mutually consistent manner. We wouldn’t have to pin down the
precise reaction function, but we would want to couch our decisions in terms of how those key

November 1–2, 2011

38 of 282

policy variables evolve. This could prove to be a useful communication device going forward,
and in fact, aid our own internal deliberations.
Let me turn now to questions 2 and 4. I am much less enthusiastic about the alternative
frameworks—advanced forward guidance, price-level targeting, or nominal GDP targeting—as
discussed in the staff memo. While these frameworks do have logic to them in the context of
some types of models, the benefits of these strategies are highly speculative and very risky from
my perspective.
Let me elaborate briefly. As I discussed in our last meeting, I do not support the idea of
providing policy thresholds or triggers as in alternative A1. I am very supportive of taking a
systematic approach to policymaking, and there is a long literature on the benefits of robust rules
for policymaking. However, the triggers tell us little about the Committee’s reaction function.
The proposed language doesn’t provide any information to help the public infer the path of
interest rates after such triggers are met, or what policies will do if inflation moves somewhat
above the threshold when the employment rate remains above its threshold. More justification
for the specific thresholds, in fact, requires assumptions about loss functions of the Committee
and an underlying policy rule, neither of which the Committee has discussed in depth.
In my view, the best way to do forward guidance at this point is to publish our policy
paths in the SEP, and I very much hope that we will begin that process in January. Increased
transparency about how FOMC participants expect policy to change in light of changes in
economic conditions and the outlook can help the public form expectations about inflation and
future policy. Providing information on FOMC participants’ appropriate policy paths, with their
economic projections, emphasizes that policy is contingent on the evolution of economic
conditions. I believe the results of the trial run of the projections, which we will discuss

November 1–2, 2011

39 of 282

tomorrow, will support this. It isn’t a panacea. It isn’t a solution. We still will have potential
inconsistency problems, because we aren’t revealing how to match up individual forecasts with
particular policy variables. Still, I think in the name of transparency and information and
coherence, it is the right direction to move.
The staff memo notes that, in principle, the best choice is to announce and commit to an
optimal policy path under commitment. I understand why this looks desirable, but is such a
policy choice actually feasible for the Committee? What is the commitment device? There will
be great temptations to engage in time-inconsistent policies later on, as President Bullard
emphasized in his memo. This underlies the extreme uncertainty associated with the projected
benefits of such approaches that are outlined in the staff memo, since they very much depend on
the credibility of this Committee’s commitment to future actions. Even here I am putting aside
the fact that optimal results are based on a particular loss function, as President Kocherlakota
pointed out in his memo, and on a particular Taylor rule implementation. And as I just said,
neither of those has been discussed at great length in this group.
Announcing the policy that we will follow in the future via forward guidance, without
commitment to a time-consistent framework, is a weak commitment device at best. Indeed,
some of the alternatives on the table at this meeting already suggest changing our forward
guidance after just two meetings. In August, we indicated that we thought the outlook would
warrant keeping the funds rate at zero until mid-2013. We reiterated that in September. Now,
alternative A1 suggests that we extend that period to 2014, even though the outlook has actually
improved somewhat since August and September—but not much. We don’t seem to be acting
with much commitment, even in our own language. It is even harder to believe that we have
enough commitment or credibility to follow on a policy path when we discover that it may not be

November 1–2, 2011

40 of 282

optimal at some point in the future. And thus, if we deviate, we risk our credibility. Making
commitments that we or the markets don’t believe we can or will deliver on will not provide the
intended benefits demonstrated in the memo that the staff suggests. And Michael Kiley made
that point in his observations. Without the commitment and the credibility, we don’t get the
benefits.
Similarly, for both nominal GDP targeting and price-level targeting, the question is, do
we have enough credibility and commitment to deliver on it? I, frankly, am very dubious that we
would behave in a time-consistent manner with price-level targeting. Do we really believe that
we would drive inflation down to 1 percent again to make up for overshooting in order to hit our
price-level path? I don’t believe we would. I don’t think the public will believe it either. Some
might, therefore, argue, although I wouldn’t, that what we need to do then is commit to a higher
level of inflation—4 percent or some higher number—so that we don’t have to go too low to
offset our overshooting. Well, that is certainly an interesting argument. I don’t subscribe to it,
but that would be an important conversation to have in weighing the costs and benefits of a
commitment to a permanently higher inflation rate. But that discussion needs to weigh the longterm costs and benefits and not just exploit short-term expediencies driven by the problems at the
zero lower bound. That would be a much more long-run discussion of trading off. The question
I think we must ask ourselves, then, is, what framework gives us the best chance of meeting the
level of commitment that is assumed in that chosen framework? I think that flexible inflation
targeting is likely to be the best that we can deliver on. But there are other potential problems
with some of these frameworks. As I asked the staff, both frameworks depend on some initial
condition, and the degree of undershooting and the target we have depend critically on where
that starting point occurs.

November 1–2, 2011

41 of 282

Michael also discussed the issue of measurement error as a concern, particularly with
nominal GDP targeting. The level formulation—that is, targeting a particular level of nominal
GDP—is worse, in my view, than nominal GDP growth targeting. If we underestimate or
overestimate the appropriate level of potential output and misestimate the so-called gap that
needs to be closed, we could make serious policy errors, and those would accumulate over time.
Even a growth-rate target relies on some estimate of potential growth, which is subject to
significant measurement error and changes over time. Again, if we overestimate potential
growth, a nominal GDP growth target would lead us astray into being too accommodative, and if
we underestimate potential growth, we would be too tight. To avoid this, we still need to focus
on what is happening to inflation. To me, there seems to be little gain over a flexible inflation
targeting regime. It also means that when our estimate of potential growth changes, as the staff
does, we would need to change our target. This poses serious communications problems at best
and risks credibility and the benefit of any commitment derived from specifying that framework.
Finally, it seems to me that switching to a new framework at this time could easily be
viewed by some as an opportunistic way to inflate the economy. In an inflation environment
where fiscal deficits loom large and well-respected economists are advocating inflating our way
out of the problems, changing our framework now risks appearing opportunistic, and that will
undermine our credibility over the long term and undermine the credibility we would need to
actually deliver on the commitments that those frameworks would call for. Undermining our
commitment by appearing opportunistic, by changing our framework, could be undermining the
very benefits that we seek to have. Thus, I would strongly prefer that we concentrate on better
explaining and strengthening our flexible inflation targeting framework that the Committee has
been working toward for the past two decades. This includes an explicit numerical objective,

November 1–2, 2011

42 of 282

explaining why it is consistent with the dual mandate, and publishing our policy paths with the
SEP. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I am going to organize my remarks around
the questions. The first one is about flexible inflation targeting. In the question, it says “the
central bank pursues an explicit inflation objective, maintains the flexibility to stabilize
economic activity, and seeks to communicate forecasts and policy plans as clearly as possible.”
When you define it that way, flexible inflation targeting is a big tent. The main reason we are
not in the tent right now is that we don’t have an explicit inflation objective. It is an implicit one,
and that could be easily remedied. In fact, I would be in favor of doing that. You asked about
that, Mr. Chairman. I have long been on record as favoring adopting a numerical objective and
communicating forecasts and policy plans as clearly as possible. When that is constructive, we
should do that. I am in favor of that as well. I am willing to support describing our policy
framework in terms of flexible inflation targeting. Now, under that definition, it is an awfully
big tent. I am sure that some of us worry that it would include the possibility of taking
stabilizing economic activity too far. I’m sure some of us worry that it would not take stabilizing
economic activity far enough. That is, by way of supporting President Evans’s observations,
about the reality that we have different visions around here. But when you are evaluating these
frameworks, I think it is legitimate to evaluate them from the point of view of what they do for
our credibility, and in particular, the credibility of our commitment to price stability. The same
thing is true with these frameworks. My general observation is that they could cause us trouble
if they are viewed as opportunistic maneuvers to give us the license to raise inflation more. It is
going to be critical to formulate things very carefully.

November 1–2, 2011

43 of 282

The second question asks about the staff’s memo on alternative frameworks. With all
due respect to the obviously huge amount of work and thought that went into the staff’s memo,
for me, it doesn’t provide the kind of quantitative work that I would want to see if we are
evaluating a change in framework. I think a framework is something we adopt once and for all, a
relatively permanent change in how we approach policy. That means we are going to use it to
guide policymaking over the course of many years and several business cycles, hopefully small
ones, but several business cycles ahead.
What kind of analysis would you want there? You would want to know how the strategy
is going to do in a range of circumstances in the future. What the staff did was give us a
quantitative analysis of the first few years of the transition dynamics from where we are now to
our new regime, starting from where we are today. There is some mention of how average
inflation is higher in the alternative frameworks, but there isn’t any quantitative information
about the performance over a complete business cycle or how it does on average, the
unconditional moments of performance under different frameworks. I think we ought to ask
about the variability of the average level over the long haul of inflation, output, consumption,
household welfare, things like that, if we are going to switch policies. That perspective could
well lead to a different ranking of alternative frameworks than one based purely on the short-run
transition dynamics—a fairly general point. I am not asking for anything unusual. This is the
standard way we have in economics of evaluating alternative policy rules, assessing their average
behavior over time.
I mentioned earlier this question about how you calculate optimal policy rules. The staff
has invariably had one argument of a loss function: the deviation of output or unemployment
from a smooth statistical trend that represents the natural rate, a concept like NAIRU. We have

November 1–2, 2011

44 of 282

talked about this many times. President Bullard had a very cogent memo on this several months
ago. We know that is wrong if there are shocks to the economy. And it is wrong in the sense
that in the standard models we have, you have got household welfare right there. You can derive
what the right loss function is for the policymaker to use. When you do that, you don’t get
anything like NAIRU going into the loss function. You evaluate unemployment and output
against something that varies with the shocks to the economy. The shocks affect what is feasible
and what is desirable in the short run, and it is the natural and intuitive thing that you would
expect to get. Monetary policy, if you do it right in those models, maximizes household welfare
over time, and that translates into attempting to stabilize activity around the level that would be
most desirable, taking into account all of the shocks we know have hit the economy. Sure,
models differ, implementing this can give very different results, but I am struck by the absence
of u*, even in the DSGE memos. The first thing I want to know about every one of those models
is: What is u* in the current quarter? We don’t get that out of the DSGE models, and that ought
to be a standard part of the reporting from those frameworks.
The third comment on the second question is that, for me, the practical difficulties of
implementing any of these alternative frameworks are prohibitive. Commitments are simple in
models. They are very easy to achieve. Even complicated and very conditional commitment is
something we all recognize. They are essentially completely credible by assumption, no matter
how complicated. Real life—as we have learned doing policy over the years—is very
complicated. The process of communicating what we intend and getting enough of the people
understanding it and acting accordingly can be time-consuming and fraught with risks, given the
inflation fight of the early ’80s, an obvious example, and going from the ’80s to the ’90s, another
example, where it took some time to get inflation down from about 5 percent to 2 percent. The

November 1–2, 2011

45 of 282

public’s inflation expectations seem pretty well anchored where they are now around 2 percent.
I’m not sure it would be easy to dial those up and down on a year-to-year basis. I think that is
what is at stake here.
Changing inflation expectations, even if we could do that, just doing it once sets a
precedent that is going to color interpretation of our commitments for decades, because we will
have set the precedent that, yes, we say we want the inflation rate to be 2 percent. “They did that
back in the ’90s and the ’00s, but then they changed it on us. They raised their target to 2½ for a
year or two, and so they could do that again.” Forever after, there is going to be a little extra
variability in inflation expectations, a little less precision on the public’s part in their
understanding, and a little less commitment and credibility on our part, just by setting the
precedent, even if we could. To be fair, the staff’s memo acknowledges these difficulties, and
these are all in the realm of the kind of learning that has to go on when you make a choice to
adopt a new framework—you have to go down the path of convincing people you’ve got a new
framework and getting them on board with acting accordingly.
The second question also asks about numerical triggers for inflation or unemployment.
President Evans was passionate about that. I said at the last meeting I think they are a bad idea.
I don’t think it is going to be easy to avoid having them translated for us by the media to the
public as the Fed’s inflation and employment targets. It is hard for me to see how we are going
to avoid the use of the word “target” in the media relative to these things. If the issue is
convincing people that we are willing to tolerate inflation of around 3 percent, inflation averaged
3 percent for four years between ’04 and ’07. We have done a great job of demonstrating our
willingness to tolerate 3 percent inflation. We had 4 percent inflation for half a year earlier this

November 1–2, 2011

46 of 282

year. I don’t think it’s that much of a problem for us, that people don’t think we are going to let
headline inflation go above 2 percent.
The third question is about price-level or nominal income targeting—a lot of the same
things apply. Adopting either of these proposals would be relatively complicated to explain to
the kind of people that attend our speeches. It may be easy for a Goldman Sachs economist to
understand, but I think about the people I talk to—it just seems hard. I often run these things by
my “brother-in-law” test. You know, my brother-in-law sitting in front of his PC with the
retirement planning software, and it prompts him for the inflation rate he would like to assume
for the next 10 or 15 years. I should warn you, I actually don’t talk to him about this—that
would be a violation of our communications policy. [Laughter] But I try to imagine—it is pretty
easy with this guy—and nominal income targeting doesn’t fare very well. To put in an
assumption for the inflation rate, he needs to forecast real GDP, and he is going to call me. A
framework where he has to call me flunks the test. [Laughter]
MR. FISHER. How smart is your brother-in-law?
MR. LACKER. He’s a doctor. I won’t say anything more. [Laughter]
Price path targeting does a bit better, except for the times when the price level is well
below the target path, and then you’d have to do logarithms. Again, he would call me.
[Laughter] I think it would be really hard for him to figure out what number to put in that
software, and that is a test for simplicity and clarity that I am attracted to.
The fourth question: What should we do? I found the document we drafted earlier this
year compelling. It explains the relationship between unemployment and inflation—as best we
can forge a consensus on it within this group—and does a very good job of embodying that
consensus about the relationship. Recasting that document as an explanation of the Federal

November 1–2, 2011

47 of 282

Reserve’s flexible inflation-targeting framework seems like an ideal approach. Using that as a
vehicle for slipping into the public domain our commitment to a numerical inflation objective
seems to me like the best approach going forward. Let me leave it at that. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. You could tell your brother-in-law what his revenue is
going to be in his practice under nominal GDP targeting. [Laughter]
There actually was a good complementarity between your remarks and President Evans’s,
and you talked about the uncertainty of the NAIRU over time.
MR. LACKER. Yes.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Evans’s approach, if I understood it, was to try to
find something that was robust to uncertainty over that particular—
MR. LACKER. Yes, I think robustness has a lot to recommend it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, would like to compliment the staff
on the fine work they did in advance of the meeting. I see this discussion of alternative
frameworks—and I hope I am not getting ahead of the discussion—as boiling down to two
questions. The first is: Should the Committee shore up its existing framework to be more
effective? To that, I would answer yes. The second question is: In light of the extraordinary
circumstances of the economy, should the Committee shake things up, go beyond the existing
framework, and go in another direction? To that question, at the moment at least, I would
answer no. I don’t think the cost-benefit or the risk-reward tradeoffs justify such a move. I do
see that clarification and reaffirmation of the Committee’s basic framework and strategy, and an
explicit inflation target, could serve to make the existing and future policy elements more
effective. It will serve to reassure the public that there is coherence to the Committee’s approach

November 1–2, 2011

48 of 282

and remove some uncertainty at a time when uncertainty is a major negative factor weighing on
the economy.
Now let me turn to the questions posed by the staff, and I will paraphrase these questions.
Is a flexible inflation-targeting framework consistent with the dual mandate? Yes, I think
flexible inflation targeting, with flexibility around the price-stability mandate, allows for
balancing the two objectives in the short term when required while still encompassing the belief
that the two mandates are complementary over the longer term.
Should we enunciate it as our working framework, perhaps in a way similar to the exit
strategy statement? I think it would be constructive to clarify our working framework in a
general sense, and the method used in communication of the exit strategy seems like a reasonable
approach. Also, the consensus-building process that preceded the addendum to the minutes I
thought was quite effective. I also think it would be useful to provide more specifics about
certain operational definitions relating to an inflation objective. We might put more definition
around what is meant by short term, medium term, and long term. For example, we might state
that over a long-term horizon of five years or longer, the Committee believes an average yearover-year growth rate of 2 percent, as measured by the overall PCE index, is consistent with the
price-stability mandate.
We might then state that over a medium-term horizon of three to five years, the
Committee seeks to maintain an average year-over-year growth and overall inflation in a range
—and this is for example only—of 1 to 3 percent. This range reflects the intent to keep overall
inflation reasonably close to the long-term target while maintaining the flexibility to respond to
economic conditions and shocks as required by the other half of the dual mandate. In the short
run—a period of up to three years, and a horizon captured by the Committee’s SEP—the

November 1–2, 2011

49 of 282

Committee, we might say, aims to closely monitor underlying inflation trends and inflation
expectations. In such a scheme, there is a cascading from explicit long-term objective to
performance within a range in the medium term to monitoring underlying inflation expectations
in the short term.
Should the Committee announce conditional commitments? If so, how to communicate
them? It is difficult to argue against the principle of credible commitment to an optimal policy
path. That said, I view an explicit threshold for the unemployment rate as potentially
problematic. Our understanding of participation trends, the equilibrium rate of unemployment,
the lag in unemployment relative to GDP growth, and any number of other recent labor market
developments suggest to me that an explicit threshold for unemployment is risky. I am also
concerned about combining a real-time threshold for unemployment with an inflation threshold
based on forecast, because the realization of an unemployment rate result is immediately
verifiable, while an inflation forecast is inherently speculative. I am concerned that the public
would interpret such conditionality as a de facto subordination of the inflation objective to an
unemployment threshold. I am more comfortable with the communication method used in
paragraph 4′ in this meeting’s proposals, which treats the interest rate, inflation, and
unemployment rate conditionality symmetrically—an approach indicating the Committee’s
expectations of conditions that will prevail prior to commencing exit. If the Committee decides
to be more activist, I think we need a nominal anchor to reassure the public that we have not lost
sight of, and are not jettisoning, the inflation or price-stability objective. The public wants to
know how much tolerance we will admit around the 2 percent inflation objective.
What about price-level targeting or nominal income targeting? Although both of these
options have merit, both entail serious communications challenges, as the staff memos have

November 1–2, 2011

50 of 282

pointed out. My concern is that a shift to either option, but particularly nominal income
targeting, would be viewed as a significant change of the Committee’s approach. This might
introduce more uncertainty about monetary policy and its intent at a time when we should be
trying to reduce uncertainty.
Finally, a more general question: What steps should the Committee take to provide more
information to the public about the expected course of policy? I continue to favor inclusion of
implied policy paths in the quarterly SEPs. If the Committee decides to move in the direction of
explicit employment and inflation thresholds in the statement, then a more complete rethinking
of the SEPs seems necessary. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I apologize if I’m not completely coherent
here. I’ve been enjoying some of the fruits of the Cardinal victory. [Laughter]
As you know, I laid out a number of comments on the Erceg, Kiley, and Lopez-Salido
memo, which was excellent, in my communication to the FOMC on October 27. I will review
and amplify some of those comments here.
In general, I think we’re moving in the right direction in giving serious consideration to
these approaches to policy and to the DSGE models from which they are derived. However,
some of the difficulties seem to me to be very vexing and could lead to very different outcomes
from those envisioned in the memo. As the authors emphasize, policy moves like the ones being
described here put credibility front and center. These are pure expectations plays in which the
Committee promises to behave differently not today but several years in the future. If the private
sector believes this promise, a boom occurs today. However, the future Committee will have
clear incentives to renege on the promise since at that point, according to the model, all will be

November 1–2, 2011

51 of 282

going well. Both output and inflation will be relatively high. Today’s private sector seeing this
will not believe the initial promise. As a consequence nothing happens at all. The policy move
falls flat. This is actually my main concern. You go through a lot of gyrations here; you make
the announcement and nothing happens at all. Could there be partial credibility for the promise?
The memo argues that perhaps if you made the promise, the private sector will put a 50–50
chance on it coming true. I don’t think this is the right way to think about this.
The Committee has repeatedly reassured financial markets over several decades that
interest rates will be raised at an appropriate time in order to keep inflation low and stable.
You’d be coming into a couple decades of that environment and saying that you are now
departing from that policy, rather opportunistically as has been emphasized here, and you are not
doing anything different today, but you will do something different five years in the future or
several years in the future. This would surely not be believed, initially. Credibility would have
to be earned through action. It would be very similar to Chairman Volcker coming in when
inflation is running very high and deciding to change the policy framework. Initially, he is not
believed. He has to earn credibility for that change in policy. The same thing would have to
happen here. Credibility would have to be earned. The way the memo does it, which just
assumes you could make a credible announcement and get something to happen today, is a little
farfetched, but possibly you could earn credibility.
Now, how would you be able to earn credibility? I think we have pretty good ideas about
how this would work. The private sector initially holds a belief that the Committee will never
deviate from its implicit Taylor-type rule. Let’s just suppose that’s a good description of the
behavior of the Committee and the belief of the private sector. The private sector will begin to
adjust its perception of the Committee when the Committee takes actions that deviate from the

November 1–2, 2011

52 of 282

prescriptions of that rule. It’s at that point that they’ll start to believe that maybe something
different is going on with the Committee. That change occurs when the Taylor-type rules
suggest raising the policy rate, but the Committee doesn’t raise the rate and instead leaves the
rate near zero. I could imagine some scenario in the future where we’re looking at the Tealbook
and there’s a whole bunch of Taylor rules in there. They’re all saying we’re supposed to be at a
higher interest rate, but the Committee stays at zero. At that point you would get a boom and a
change in private-sector behavior, because they would at that point learn that the Committee
actually had changed behavior from what was previously believed to be dominating the thinking.
But unfortunately, that sort of event in the scenario we’re talking about here only occurs several
years in the future when Taylor rules are saying we’re supposed to be raising rates and we’re not
raising rates. The boom occurs, but only several years in the future—not today. In short,
learning about the policy by the private sector would dramatically alter the timing of the effects.
In some ways it defeats the purpose of the announcement.
In part because of these considerations, I’ve repeatedly favored balance sheet policies as
a way to ease policy by creating expectations of higher inflation. With balance sheet policies,
clear action is being taken today, which in my view, can influence and has influenced privatesector expectations of Committee behavior.
I agree with President Evans. The question is how to get the expected inflation that the
Committee so desires higher. The question is how to make that happen. One way would be to
make this promise out there in the future. I’m arguing that that would fall flat. I’m saying that
the additional commitment strategy wouldn’t be effective, and therefore, you’re probably better
off with balance sheet policy. That’s as much as I have to say on time consistency.

November 1–2, 2011

53 of 282

As you all know, I remain concerned that we are not putting enough weight on the
possibility that committing to near zero rates for a very long time will simply produce zero rates
for decades. The memo contemplates very long times at a policy rate of zero. It really begins to
sound like we would be creating the worst outcome of all and the importing of the Japanese
situation to the U.S. We should be thinking about the tradeoff between possibly creating a
replication of the Japanese situation in the U.S. versus the relatively minor and uncertain benefits
of promising longer and longer times at a policy rate of zero in the hopes that that would raise
inflation expectations today. In short, and there is a literature on this, it’s going to be SchmittGrohé and Uribe, not Eggertson–Woodford that’s the relevant framework here. Eggertson–
Woodford does not deal effectively with this issue. According to Benhabib et al., commitment to
low nominal interest rates actually creates the problem.
As I discuss in my memo, I did not find the results on price-level targeting very
convincing. This should be close to the fully optimal policy in models of this type. Partly I
agree, based on the earlier comment, that this is because this is a form of strict price-level
targeting, which isn’t what I think of as typically discussed in the literature. The whole idea
behind price-level targeting is that it changes the policymaker objective function in a way that
helps substitute for the missing ability to commit what Peter Howitt once called the “Zen archer”
approach to policy. I’m not quite sure what that meant, but it sounded neat. [Laughter] The
policymaker maximizes an objective that’s a little bit different from the one that the household
would maximize in order to get part of the commitment that the household doesn’t have, and so
you get a little bit better policy through that.
The notion that nominal income targeting respects the dual mandate while price-level
targeting does not seems an odd way to describe the state of affairs to me. The literature is

November 1–2, 2011

54 of 282

talking about models with micro foundations. Households live in the model. They have utility
functions defined over consumption and labor supply. A fully optimal policy maximizes the
utility of these households. As President Lacker was saying, you’ve got the households there—
ask them what they want. Ask them what the optimal policy is. Why come in with other
objectives that we’re imposing from the outside unless you don’t believe your model, in which
case I say go build your model the way you want to build it and get to a different objective. We
cannot do any better than this, maximizing the utility of the households in the model, and
household labor supply is very much part of the story. So it is very much about maximum
employment if you want to talk in those terms.
For both nominal income targeting and price-level targeting, the starting point for
drawing the baseline path is important, as several people have stressed. Many of us have
described the past decade as a housing bubble that burst. I think it is inappropriate to project that
bubble out into the indefinite future and then claim that it’s up to monetary policy to reestablish
the unsustainable path the economy was once on. Fundamental potential output growth was
probably somewhat lower than it appears during the past decade. Embracing this view would
give a more realistic description of the likely outcomes the FOMC would be able to achieve
through an appropriate policy.
So as a bottom line, let me give several brief answers to the questions that were listed on
the exam. Flexible inflation targeting, yes, I’m very much in favor of it. I think we should name
an inflation target to get started. Lots of countries have done this. We’re a laggard on this issue,
and we should go ahead and do that. I would not give the extreme interpretations that President
Rosengren alluded to earlier where you put just a minimal weight. You should put an
appropriate weight on the real side of the economy when you do this.

November 1–2, 2011

55 of 282

The thresholds are intriguing, but I don’t see them popping out as an optimal policy
response in any of the models I’m aware of. I’d be willing to look at ones where they do, and
I’ve argued in previous memos that unemployment as a threshold is problematic. It has behaved
badly as a variable in the G-7 over the past couple of decades and especially in Europe. It
wanders around, and we don’t have good theories of why that happened. We know that other
policies affect the level of unemployment—other labor market policies. I’m not against thinking
about unemployment. I’m against tying monetary policy explicitly, numerically to the level of
the unemployment rate because that would possibly throw monetary policy off for a very long
time if that rate doesn’t behave in the nice, cyclical fashion that we think that it should and
instead wanders off into uncharted territory.
On price-level targeting or nominal income targeting, I’d be worried that if you went this
way, not too much would happen. It would fall flat, and that’s why I’m advocating a balance
sheet policy instead. That being said, they’re actually not too different from Taylor-type policy
rules. In some ways it’s hard to see why you get much of an announcement effect at all because
it would be hard for the private sector to distinguish between existing policy and the new policy.
But my main concern is that if you try to make these commitments out there in the future, it
doesn’t look credible to me, and it’s going to fall flat. I would do balance sheet policy instead.
You’re taking clear actions today that markets understand very well.
On the issue of should we publish more information, I would again advocate that we’re
struggling too much with trying to condense a lot of information about our views about the U.S.
economy into terse statements that just have a few words or a few numbers. I think the way to
get around that is to go ahead and publish the Tealbook or some version of the Tealbook that you
thought was appropriate, perhaps a quarterly report on the state of the U.S. economy. If you did

November 1–2, 2011

56 of 282

it that way, you could have a long document that could put in lots of information and contain
many of the subtleties. You could comment on a lot of the issues that are facing the economy in
a way that you can’t in shorter statements. I’d be an advocate of thinking about going in that
direction, and that will clear up many of our issues about communication. Other countries have
done this, and I think it would be a sensible way to go. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you.
MR. EVANS. Could I ask a clarifying question?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Sure.
MR. EVANS. President Bullard, you often had mentioned the Benhabib–Schmitt-Grohé
paper—and I have to admit that the half-life of my understanding of those analyses is usually
less than a full meeting length when I ask my staff about that—but I thought that that relied on a
Taylor-rule monetary policy, doesn’t it ?
MR. BULLARD. The problem in the model is that you’re fully committed to the Taylortype policy rules.
MR. EVANS. But we’ve been running balance sheet policies and we’re also at the zero
lower bound, so obviously we’re still running that type of policy. Isn’t that the kind of thing that
would tend to break that equilibrium?
MR. BULLARD. Well, I guess in the memos there is a—
MR. EVANS. I mean, usually there’s some threshold.
MR. BULLARD. —certain type of policy rule. If that policy rule is going to tell you
that you’ll never move off zero until certain conditions are met, then the public starts to think,
okay, you’re never going to meet those conditions, so you’re going to stay at zero. One of the
conditions is that inflation is near target, but because of the Fisher relation, inflation expectations

November 1–2, 2011

57 of 282

are low, and so you’re just permanently below the target. That’s what happened in Japan, where
they’ve had mild deflation for 15 years.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me inject here. I don’t want to get into a deep
discussion of this.
MR. EVANS. I didn’t want to get into too much.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think, President Bullard, that some of us are confused
about the dynamics and the inflation-expectation formation process that supports that
equilibrium. In other words, it’s obviously an equilibrium, but is it one that would naturally
occur? Rather than ask you to answer that here, maybe you could help us with some comments.
MR. BULLARD. I can give you a stock answer in one sentence.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay.
MR. BULLARD. It’s fair to say—I wrote it down in my model—that the one
equilibrium is the one that’s the natural one to focus on, but you’ve got a country that’s stuck at
the other equilibrium. Your theory has to tell you why you’re going to be at one equilibrium
versus the other.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Maybe because policy wasn’t easy enough in the first place,
and they got caught.
MS. YELLEN. Exactly.
MR. BULLARD. Well, they were at zero. We’ve been at zero for a long time.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll echo the many thanks that
have gone to the staff for the memos, particularly the Erceg et al. memo that formed the basis of
this conversation, but I see I’m going to be drawing on the other memos as well. Very

November 1–2, 2011

58 of 282

impressive work over a very short period of time. With that said, I think there is room for
considerably more analysis before we decide on a framework that is designed to govern Federal
Reserve actions for the next 8 to 10 years and possibly beyond. Any monetary policy rule has
two linked components, which are the initial level of accommodation it is providing and then a
description of how that accommodation changes over time and responds to changes in
conditions.
Now, the initial level of accommodation that’s being provided by a given rule is a little
arbitrary. Several people have already mentioned this, but I’ll chime in as well. If we target a
price-level path that began in the fourth quarter of 2008, we’ll get a different amount of initial
accommodation than if we target a price-level path that begins in the fourth quarter of 2007. I
don’t think of the initial amount of accommodation as really being a definitive property of pricelevel targeting or any rule. What really is defining a rule is how that accommodation varies in
response to how conditions change.
I’m going to separate two questions in what I’m going to say before I go on. I’ll talk at
some length about these two questions before I go on to the four questions that were posed by the
staff. The first question I’m going to talk about is, what is the current level of accommodation
that we want to provide? And then, second, what kind of rule should govern how that
accommodation varies in response to changes in conditions? It’s very important to do this
separation because there are several Committee members who feel very strongly that the current
level of accommodation is unduly low, and the state of economy is such that this probably needs
to be corrected rapidly. It would be untoward to address this perceived need for an urgent
increase in our current level of accommodation by changing our framework. Rather, we should
be able to figure out how to augment the current level accommodation while retaining the ability

November 1–2, 2011

59 of 282

to be appropriately deliberate in our decisionmaking about a framework designed to govern the
next decade of monetary policy. I’m going to try to sketch one way to answer these two separate
questions—current level of accommodation and then evolution—and then I’ll come back to the
four questions, Mr. Chairman, at the end.
How might we choose an appropriate level of current accommodation? The first thing
we need to do is decide on a loss function, and it’s our job to provide guidance to staff on this
important issue, that is, us as principals, as policymakers around the Committee. In a memo I
circulated last week, I talked about how we might go about structuring this conversation. With
that loss function in hand, we can compute optimal time paths for asset holdings and short-term
interest rates under the staff’s modal forecast. Now, note that in the policy problems solved on
page 3 of the Tealbook, Book B—there are all these nice pictures about what the optimal policy
looks like—the staff fixes what’s going on with asset purchases. They don’t optimize over asset
purchases. Those are just treated as given, and they optimize over the path of the fed funds rate.
What I want to do is start to think about optimizing where the paths include both tools.
This might sound like a complicated problem, but we can immediately translate into a simpler
one. The Reifschneider et al. memo provides the way to do that. It builds on earlier research by
Fed System economists to map that time path of Fed asset holdings into a time path of downward
adjustments to the fed funds rate.
Choosing a path of asset holdings and a path of short-term interest rates is similar to
choosing a path of LSAP-adjusted path of interest rates, and this is a very important point. If
there were no constraints in the size of the balance sheet, then this LSAP-adjusted path of
interest rates could become arbitrarily negative. If we’re willing to have as big a balance sheet as
we want, then we can make those LSAP-adjusted interest rates as low as we want. The policy

November 1–2, 2011

60 of 282

problem then becomes equivalent to the unconstrained optimal problem on page 3 of Tealbook,
Book B. It’s as good as we can do. There is no tension in this problem in terms of the
commitment problems that the staff was pointing to. That kind of reverse time-consistency
problem does not emerge there. There’s no commitment versus discretion issue if we’re solving
that unconstrained problem.
If we were to go in that direction, though, the balance sheet moves are fairly exaggerated.
If you look at the unconstrained optimal policy path on page 3, Tealbook, Book B, it suggests the
appropriate path of LSAP-adjusted interest rates involves cutting them in the near term by
300 basis points. The FOMC could achieve this cut by announcing its intention to buy
something like $3 trillion of longer-term assets. Both of these numbers are quite rough. They’d
have to be filled in with more work. This solution hinges on using a loss function that puts equal
weight on deviations; loss functions that I’ve suggested in my memo would presumably imply a
smaller cut in the LSAP-adjusted rate.
This is all about if you’re willing to do $3 trillion of purchases. If you’re not willing to
do that, that means there are costs or constraints associated with balance sheet policies that aren’t
incorporated into the Reifschneider et al. memo and not really formally incorporated into the
staff’s technical analysis of our policies. For example, the Committee might decide it never
wants to have a balance sheet larger than $3 trillion. This constraint will translate into a negative
lower bound in the LSAP-adjusted interest rate, and then you get to solve a constrained optimal
policy problem on LSAP-adjusted interest rates with this lower bound.
How would this solution work? You can guess the solution. It’s going to look like the
balance sheet being expanded up to its maximal level and then the short-term interest rate being
kept equal to zero for some period of time. I would see the Committee implementing this

November 1–2, 2011

61 of 282

appropriate level of current accommodation by buying more assets and then announcing an
anticipated duration for the zero interest rate policy.
What I’m trying to sketch here is that we can follow a systematic way to identify an
appropriate current level of accommodation without a major change in our policy framework.
Without constraints on the balance sheet, then we can make appropriate adjustments to the
current level of accommodation through asset purchases alone. With constraints on the size of
the balance sheet, that’s what leads us into the need for making these long-term stays at the zero
lower bound. That’s all about choosing the current level of accommodation.
There’s a separate but certainly linked question of how that accommodation should
change over time in response to changes in the state of the economy. I think it’s a good thing for
us to have a determination of how we want that accommodation to change over time. Given that
the zero lower bound is binding, it may well involve making a commitment. One of the reasons
you’re trying to build a rule—as people talk about the Taylor rule—is to try to buy into
commitment. One of the nice things about the rules that the staff sketches is that it gives us a
way to try to buy into the necessary commitment to have those rules be implemented down the
road.
A good rule should satisfy four related criteria. One is consistency—its prescribed
evolution of accommodation under the staff’s modal forecast. It should provide a good
approximation to the solution to the optimal control problems that I’ve discussed above. You
want your rule to match up with what you want to be doing, given what you expect to happen. I
think that’s a relatively easy extension to what the staff has done.
What’s a little harder, and this gets to some of the stuff that President Lacker was talking
about, is that we need to have some notion of expected loss. There’s a good start on this in the

November 1–2, 2011

62 of 282

Erceg et al. memo on scenario analysis, but really we need a full Monte Carlo simulation under
the assumption the Committee is using that rule. We want this notion of the distribution of
outcomes—how likely it is we’re going to go above 2 percent, for how long, those kinds of
questions—and the expected loss under whatever our loss function is.
Third, we really need to think about the robustness of a given rule. What’s the worst-case
macroeconomic scenario for a given rule? How bad are things under that worst-case scenario?
And then think about comparing rules under that basis. Then, credibility matters. A proposed
rule may well imply that some macroeconomic outcomes will lead to high rates of inflation
coexisting with low rates of unemployment for several years at a time. Is such a rule truly
credible or will future Committees simply abandon the rule at that point? Rules are rhetorical
devices to try to convince future Committees to do things that are against their own interest, and
so we want to see how much they have to buy into to do that.
The memo that we have is a great starting point for these kinds of assessments of
consistency, expected loss, robustness, and credibility, but there’s a lot more to be done. That’s
why I think it’s very important to separate these two issues, Mr. Chairman, of what we want to
do today in terms of providing an appropriate level of accommodation, and what kind of rule we
want to adopt for the evolution of that accommodation.
Let me try to answer the four questions. Flexible inflation targeting, it’s a big tent. It’s
pretty hard to see how anyone could say no to it, but I will. [Laughter] I’m certainly on board
with that description of our operating framework, but the word “flexible” is going to require
some definition and some clarity. President Lockhart offered some suggestions, but President
Lockhart’s words (I didn’t catch everything he said, unfortunately) for example, talking about

November 1–2, 2011

63 of 282

2 percent averaging over five years—we explicitly don’t mean that. We explicitly want the
ability not to have that.
We have to be very clear. It probably would be useful to be clear among ourselves, first
of all, about what we mean. What I’ve been talking about over the past couple of meetings is the
need for us to be clear about how much inflation we’re willing to tolerate and over what time
horizon. Some of the staff simulations suggest we’re willing to tolerate up to 3 percent for
several years at a time. We have to be clear among ourselves and with the public that that’s what
our policies include.
President Evans made a good point about risk management and about his proposed
triggers. I thought the implied dialogue between President Evans and President Rosengren is
really interesting about whether these triggers should be evolving over time or fixed in time.
Those are the kinds of things that it would be useful to get sorted out. We should be thinking
about accommodation right now as an anticipation of time we are spending at the zero lower
bound, plus the size of the balance sheet. Those are our two tools to adjust.
Then there’s an issue of a rule about how those things would evolve over time in
response to changes in conditions, and there’s more work to be done on that. There’s a fourth
question, but I think I already answered it by answering the first question.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman, and I appreciate people’s patience in listening to me for so
long, but like several others have mentioned, this is great stuff, and I’m very excited to be able to
talk about it.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you very much. I understand lunch is ready.
I propose that we take half an hour and begin again at 1:15—with trays, if necessary. Thank
you.

November 1–2, 2011

64 of 282

[Lunch recess]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much for your promptness. Let’s
recommence with our discussion of the frameworks, and I will turn to President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I appreciate the Board staff’s analysis of
these alternative policy frameworks, as others have noted. Looking at ways to strengthen our
framework and strategies for the longer term certainly is worthwhile, given the importance of our
credibility to effective monetary policy.
I do support efforts that strive to make monetary policy transparent, credible, and clearly
communicated. But in reading the alternatives and how they are interpreted in the Tealbook,
transparency appears to be equated to additional stimulus when, in fact, the two strike me as
separate concepts. In my view, adopting new strategies to achieve additional stimulus in the near
term is unlikely to accelerate the broad and necessary process of deleveraging and rebalancing
now under way in the economy without risking the low and stable inflation we have worked to
achieve, sometimes at great cost, over the past 30 years.
Looking ahead to the long-term application of these alternative frameworks, I also see
potential practical problems with their implementation, even though they appear to work well in
simulations. In particular, the communication challenges associated with changing our policy
framework now would be tremendous, raising the possibility of increasing rather than decreasing
uncertainty in what are already uncertain times.
Let me turn briefly to my comments on the specific questions raised. While the general
concept of flexible inflation targeting seems innocuous, there are a number of definitional issues
I find that are unresolved. How would the explicit inflation objective be defined? What inflation
rate, what horizon, what numerical value? And specifying an inflation target also raises the

November 1–2, 2011

65 of 282

question of how the Committee would define “maximum employment”—the other component of
the dual mandate.
Second, the concept of optimal policy under commitment depends on a model, which
immediately leads to questions about how different models reflect reality, and thus, produce
different optimal policies. Some have noted how different preferences can contribute as well.
For instance, I differ from the authors and would argue that inflation of 2½ percent over several
years is more costly than inflation of 1½ percent, because of the risk of longer-term inflation
expectations becoming unhinged. Commitment is elusive, because we cannot bind ourselves, or
our successors, to carry through on any forward guidance we provide today. As economic
circumstances change, the temptation to deviate in the future from today’s promises will be
significant.
Regarding strategies for price-level or nominal income targeting, I am concerned with
basing policy decisions on only one or two variables. The financial crisis reminded us that
policy decisions should be based on a range of data that can inform us about the state of the
economy and the outlook. While our primary objectives are inflation and employment, financial
stability is both important and consistent with our long-run mandate. A narrower focus on
inflation and employment in the medium term could lead to a costly miss of our financial
stability objective in the longer term.
Finally, I would be interested in exploring the idea of augmenting the SEP to include
more information about our expected policy paths. Adding such information to the SEP has the
potential to enhance transparency and provide more flexibility, in my view, than incorporating
specific funds rate projections associated with unemployment and inflation triggers. Since the

November 1–2, 2011

66 of 282

public is beginning to be more familiar with the SEP, the communications challenges may be
easier to overcome. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I also want to thank the staff for the
excellent work they did on this important issue. I am going to focus my comments on the
questions.
My answer to all parts of the first question is yes. I view flexible inflation targeting as
consistent with our dual mandate, and I think that we should enunciate this framework. As I
have indicated in past meetings, I think that adopting an explicit numerical objective for inflation
would enhance our accountability, our transparency, and our communications. We can and
should go farther than simply saying the Committee seeks price stability, and we should define
numerically what price stability means.
I would also be comfortable with indicating that the Committee estimates an
unemployment rate of, say, around 6 percent to be consistent with maximum employment, as
long as we make it clear that monetary policy does not determine what rate of unemployment is
consistent with full employment. It would be helpful to try to formulate a consensus statement
on the Committee’s monetary policy framework as we did with our exit strategy.
Moving to the second set of questions, broadly, I see some form of conditional
commitment as having value for improving our communications by providing more information
on the policy reaction function. In principle, I think we could help the public to better
understand how the Committee is likely to respond by using the SEP to provide the economic
conditions underlying our forward guidance.

November 1–2, 2011

67 of 282

Paragraph 4′ in policy alternative A1 strikes me as presenting an approach that could be
helpful. I think it would be more difficult to go further, as paragraph 4″ does, to set policy
thresholds, because simple thresholds cannot capture the range of factors we will want to
consider in determining the future course of policy.
Moving to question 3, of the options considered, I agree with the Board staff assessment
that targeting the level of nominal income appears to work well in some challenging scenarios.
But I would reserve a change in our operating procedure for an extreme event, such as a
significant risk of deflation or another recession. Should we face such prospects, I think that
nominal income targeting would be our best option for providing significantly more policy
accommodation while making clear our commitment to both components of our dual mandate.
Finally, in response to question 4, as I have already suggested with my responses to the
other questions, to improve our communication and effectiveness of policy, I would favor
enunciating our flexible inflation-targeting framework and adopting an explicit numerical
objective for inflation. I would also favor providing forward guidance more clearly linked to our
SEP. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Successful communication of our policy
framework is especially important as we navigate uncharted waters of unconventional policies.
A critical goal of our communication, to me, is to maintain well-anchored inflation expectations.
During the past few years, the anchoring of inflation expectations has paid huge dividends. It
stemmed what could have turned into a sustained deflationary dynamic, and it also provided
monetary policy with greater maneuvering room for extraordinary accommodation with less

November 1–2, 2011

68 of 282

danger of high inflation. To further reinforce the anchoring of inflation expectations, I strongly
favor publicly stating an explicit inflation objective in the context of our dual mandate.
I should say that I am one of the latter participants to go in this round, so many of my
further comments are going to echo comments of other participants. In particular, I noticed that
some of my comments are very closely aligned with President Rosengren, and some of my other
comments are very closely aligned with President Plosser. I am not sure how often that sentence
is uttered. [Laughter]
MR. PLOSSER. We will watch this with great interest. [Laughter]
MR. WILLIAMS. I, too, think it would be useful to make a general statement of the
Committee’s policy framework that we all agree on, and to publish that in the minutes, as was
done with the exit strategy. I actually think flexible inflation targeting is a good framework for
thinking about that. It is a big tent, as many people have already mentioned, but with this group
you may need to have a big tent like that, and so that is a good approach. As President Plosser
earlier said, the work that was done by the ad hoc group on putting together a one-pager about
the framework around a numerical inflation objective is a good place to start on that. I will add
that inflation targeting has proven to be a very highly successful strategy that has been used in
many countries.
I do think we have to be careful in how we publicly describe our current policy
framework if we were to describe it as flexible inflation targeting. The problem, which has
already been mentioned by a number of people—and this is where President Rosengren’s
comments and mine overlap—is that flexible inflation targeting is a very elastic term. It means
different things to different people. For example, some inflation-targeting central banks have a
hierarchical mandate in which price stability is the prime goal. That is not how I interpret our

November 1–2, 2011

69 of 282

dual mandate or our framework. Explicitly identifying ourselves as an inflexible inflation
targeter could be misperceived as tipping the balance of our dual mandate strongly toward price
stability. This could complicate already daunting communications challenges, and it could be
seen as inconsistent with the mandate given to us by Congress. If we were to publicly describe
our framework as flexible inflation targeting, which I do support in principle, it is important that
we do so along the lines that Lars Svensson has done, and that is as a balanced approach, with a
significant weight on both parts of the dual mandate.
With regard to communicating the optimal policy under commitment, such an approach
is attractive for the reasons that were laid out in the staff memos. Unfortunately, for similar
reasons that President Bullard mentioned, I think it is an unrealistic benchmark. In the jargon of
academics, our commitment technology is very limited. It is simply impossible for us to set a
predetermined course of policy that will bind future Committees.
Another comment I will make on the staff presentations, which were really helpful, is that
the differences in the outcomes under the different policies that they look at—nominal income
targeting or inertial Taylor rule or optimal policy—depend critically on the expectations of
events that are many years in the future, another point that President Bullard and others have
made. For example, if you look at exhibit 2 from Mike Kiley’s presentation, it is striking that the
inertial Taylor rule and the nominal income-targeting rules actually yield essentially the same
unemployment paths, as I see it, up until 2017, yet the inflation rates starting from 2012 are very
different. I have dabbled in the dark arts of large-scale macro models, so I have some
understanding of how these models work. Events way out in the future can really feed back into
the present in a very strong way, and there is a lot of uncertainty about how strong the feedback
effects are of events five, six, seven years in the future on the actual inflation and unemployment

November 1–2, 2011

70 of 282

rates today. I am not sure if, in reality, the simulations may exaggerate the benefits of
differences in policy regimes. As President Bullard said, these simulations assume rational
expectations, and that everybody instantly knows the change in the policy regime. In practice, I
think there would be some learning and adjustment that would again reduce the differences in the
policy alternatives.
Instead of thinking of optimal control as being the approach that we should be
concentrating on, we should aim to communicate as clearly as possible our current reaction
function. Policy thresholds could help in this communication. Alternatively, as Governor
Tarullo and I argued last time, and a number of participants have already mentioned, we could
include our individual projections about the appropriate path of monetary policy in the published
SEP. Then, as our forecasts for economic activity, inflation, and the funds rate evolve, the public
would get a clear picture of the state-contingent nature of our policy reaction function. Although
I have not yet studied the results that we were sent this weekend from the trial run of the SEP,
my reading of the SEP answers is that these are consistent with what I think of as a pretty clear
view of where policy is expected to evolve, with a liftoff apparently in early 2014 or so, with a
range of views on that. That range of views in the SEP about when liftoff is and what the policy
will look like going forward is consistent with the range of views on inflation and economic
activity. That would benefit transparency, and it would be consistent with our policy framework
and communication.
Finally, I don’t believe this is now the time to switch to a price-level or nominal income
target. In theory, these approaches can work very well. President Lacker, and I think President
Kocherlakota, brought up the issue that you should be really evaluating policy frameworks in an
unconditional stance, thinking about how they perform on average. I and many other people

November 1–2, 2011

71 of 282

have actually looked at that issue in different models and under different assumptions. The way
I would summarize is that a very good monetary policy rule—a well-calibrated Taylor rule, or an
optimal control policy, or a nominal income-targeting policy, or a flexible price-level targeting
policy—all of these do really well if they are well designed. They do roughly equivalently well
in normal conditions. Looking at that question doesn’t give you an answer about which
framework you want. You really do have to think about the communications issues and also the
unusual circumstances that we are in today. At this time, switching horses in the middle of the
stream could confuse more than clarify, and ultimately could backfire. In particular, nominal
income targeting seems to muddy the waters. Investors care separately about prices and about
quantities. And, importantly, we care separately about prices and about quantities. Looking at
only nominal income, which mashes together prices and quantities, seems to me at this time to be
counterproductive and could undermine the anchoring of inflation expectations. Thanks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I am going to start and conclude where President Williams
concluded. That is, I don’t think now is the time, but I do think it is a subject we are studying.
First, I want to thank the staff for their good work. I also want to thank them for their
honesty. I thought section 4 about the risks of our models at least, and the faulty potential of our
models, was frank and honest. I do want to have submitted for the record a particularly pungent
sentence, which says, “Given that the strategies we consider lack historical precedent, and even
the tools used to implement the strategies are relatively unconventional, there is considerable risk
that our model results may prove faulty in some respect.” Indeed, any policy outside the range
of historical experience, ranging from the strategies considered here to balance sheet adjustments
and macroprudential regulation, could have unintended consequences for economic welfare, for

November 1–2, 2011

72 of 282

better or for worse. Your section 4 expands upon that somewhat. I thank you for the good work
that you have put together.
I am in favor of at least more discipline, if not a rule. I think we have been a little bit
spastic in the way we have developed policy, a little bit reactionary, and we have sent signals to
the marketplace, which then seem to be built into expectations. I would like to see a little bit
more discipline as we go through time.
I am in favor of the exercise. I boil it down to two simple principles: We have to be
realistic, and we have to be credible. What I mean by realistic is that we know that we have
more influence on inflation as a monetary phenomenon than we do on employment. What I
mean by credible is that shifting horses, whether we do it midstream or whenever we do it,
cannot be viewed as a weakening of our commitment to price stability, and cannot be viewed as,
in particular, a weakening of our commitment to long-term price stability.
I thought President George’s comments were interesting. To me, the key variable is to
identify a longer-term inflation target. I am in favor of doing that. President George pointed out
some issues around that—which target do we pick, under what conditions, and so on—but
talking about having one is a worthwhile exercise.
Then, I would want to understand better within this Committee what the bands of
tolerance are around that target if we are going to talk about flexible inflation targeting. Once we
have achieved that understanding, then I think we need to explain to the public that as long as we
have a dual mandate we have to deal with both inflation and unemployment variables. And as
long as we have that mandate, then it may be desirable, if we decide that is the case at this
table—once we have agreed on a long-term inflation target, and our tolerance bands around it—

November 1–2, 2011

73 of 282

that we may have to deviate occasionally from our target on maybe the high or the low side in
order to deal with our employment mandate.
This is something that we should take some time to consider. I started this meeting by
giving President Bullard a six-pack of Shiner Bock beer.
MR. BULLARD. Three left.
MR. FISHER. There are only two left, actually. [Laughter] Shiner Bock beer, by the
way, Mr. Chairman, was picked because the Shiner brewery was founded in 1913, fitting for the
Federal Reserve. But if you look at the way beer is made, out of hops and grains, the standard
formula has been in place since the year 1541 under a ruler of Bavaria named Henry IV. Now,
there have been improvements made to beer, but I think it is something that you would have to
proceed with extremely slowly.
I am not suggesting we take another 500-and-some-odd years to change our rule or our
discipline, but I do think that we need to vet the thoughts that have been circling around this
table. Reference has been made to Ms. Romer. I thought that was an interesting article.
However, I must tell you that all I got out of it was, “Be bold.” That was what her message was.
I wasn’t convinced by her argumentation. I have listened very carefully to Ken Rogoff, who is
on our advisory committee at the Dallas Fed and our Globalization and Monetary Policy
Institute. I respect him enormously. And then, I observed the pushback that came from another
person I respect enormously named Paul Volcker. I understand that Tobin made the arguments
in the 1970s, but I also understand that no other central bank has attempted what we are talking
about. You had a slight variation of price-level targeting in 1930 by the Swedes. We love to
evoke the Scandinavians at this table. But it was not held for very long, and it was a variation of

November 1–2, 2011

74 of 282

price-level targeting. To my knowledge, no central bank has adopted nominal income targeting.
It is true that Tobin made the argument in 1970. It is true that Martin Feldstein agreed with it.
I did have Professor Feldstein down the other day to the Dallas Fed. He is completely
against it presently. Why? Because he doesn’t think we are quite credible yet in having
anchored—and this is his own personal view—our commitment to long-term price stability. I
come back to long-term price stability. To me, that is the key variable. The flexibility around it
is something that we need to define, and then we need to socialize it. Despite the interest that
has been shown by Goldman Sachs and Christy Romer and others, I think we need to socialize it
further. I would say at a minimum I would take the theoretical work that has been done, and
some of the studies that we are doing, and at least get these out into academia and into a more
serious discussion, so that we can evaluate these alternative policy rules and see what kind of
criticisms come forward.
Mr. Chairman, in short, I am in favor of trying to achieve greater discipline. I would like
to come up with a rule that is more modernized. I am willing to change the formula to the beer
that we brew, but we should take our time. I would like to suggest that we look at a time horizon
that doesn’t have to be infinite. I would be against changing this horse in midstream now, as
President Williams mentioned. But I would at least like to have these questions discussed and
vetted and thought through—including the risks that I mentioned at the very beginning—over the
course of the next several months, if not half a year. I think it is a worthwhile exercise. Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I thought the staff work was
excellent and thank them for all their efforts.

November 1–2, 2011

75 of 282

I am not convinced our current framework is obviously inferior to some of the alternative
frameworks that have been proposed. I think market participants do know what our long-term
inflation objectives are. If you look at the SEP’s long-term inflation, it is in a very narrow range.
I think market participants have a pretty good understanding that we have something close to a
quadratic loss function. All you have to do is compare and contrast how we have reacted to the
inflation and unemployment news in the U.S. compared to Europe, and you see quite a bit
different path.
What we should be focusing on is not so much frameworks but providing more insight to
the public about what our reaction function is. My emphasis would be on reducing the
uncertainty about how we would likely react under a wide range of circumstances. By doing
that, we can accomplish two things. One, we can reduce uncertainty about how monetary policy
is likely to evolve, which should have favorable implications for risk premiums, therefore,
making financial conditions more accommodative. And, two, it would help markets to think
along better with us, so it may enable market participants to better anticipate our future actions.
That means prices could adjust more rapidly to the receipt of new information on the economy or
political developments that might affect the outlook.
Now, having said that, I want to provide more information about our reaction function. I
don’t think that is a very simple task. Not only are there 17 different reaction functions around
the table, but it is also difficult to reduce those reaction functions into a simple two- or threeparameter mapping. For example, specifying what the unemployment rate and the inflation rate
forecast is likely to be as a precondition for exit, is probably too simplistic for most of us; other
parameters might also be important, for instance, speed limits—how fast the unemployment rate

November 1–2, 2011

76 of 282

is falling or inflation is rising—or the risk around the central forecast—if there is a very big skew
in the outlook.
Despite this, I think we can do more to overcome some of these problems. First, we can
provide greater detail about our individual forecasts, and we could aggregate this detail into
consistent central tendency projections with respect to the inflation rate, unemployment rate, and
the path of the federal funds rate.
Second, we can explore in greater detail the degree of agreement within the Committee
about what parameter values would be important in their view in influencing when exit might be
likely. If the dispersion turns out to be relatively narrow, then we could actually move down this
path, hopefully over the next couple of meetings. In this respect, in terms of the trigger values, I
would much prefer escape clauses rather than triggers, because it gives us a little bit more
flexibility. It allows a little bit more nuance. The fact that you only have two parameters with
escape clauses is implicitly saying that those aren’t the only things that are important to you. In
my mind, expressing parameters with respect to inflation and unemployment is quite a bit
superior to a date. For one thing, we are probably going to move the parameters around a lot less
frequently than we want to move around a date. I have a lot less uncertainty about what my
parameter values on unemployment and inflation are likely to be than I do about the date. I have
no idea when we are actually going to exit. I have a point forecast, but there is a wide range
around that. Conversely, I have a relatively narrow range around the parameter values of
unemployment and inflation that might trigger an exit.
In terms of the types of foreign commitments discussed in the staff memo, I am skeptical
that there are significant benefits, because I don’t know how we can tie our hands credibly—a
point that many others have made—and I don’t think the model assumptions about how market

November 1–2, 2011

77 of 282

participants form their expectations is necessarily correct, coming to the point about your
brother-in-law.
Finally, I worry that making binding commitments might be viewed as potentially
reckless in a world where the outlook is highly uncertain. If people thought we were making
binding commitments and then we got a very bad draw relative to our modal forecast, we would
then be committed to generating something that could be potentially a very unpleasant outcome.
Market participants would price that in immediately as a potential risk.
In terms of the alternative frameworks, I have some skepticism about a nominal GDP
targeting regime. It is very difficult to explain, and it seems to bless outcomes in terms of
growth and inflation combinations that we might not be happy with. It seems to suggest that
5 percent real GDP growth and 0 percent inflation is equivalent to 0 percent real GDP growth
and 5 percent inflation. The former would be terrific, and the latter would be pretty horrible.
Explaining that in the context of nominal GDP target would be very difficult.
In terms of price-level targeting, I see some value in environments in which deflation
expectations are a problem. The PLT could be helpful in those particular circumstances in
anchoring inflation expectations. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, want to thank the staff. I greatly
appreciate their thorough analysis of alternative policy frameworks.
Let me turn to the questions. On the first question, I think that a flexible inflationtargeting framework would be fully consistent with our dual mandate. As I noted at our
September meeting, I’ve been a long-time advocate of establishing a specific numerical inflation
objective as a means of facilitating our internal decisionmaking and augmenting transparency

November 1–2, 2011

78 of 282

and accountability to the public. Under current circumstances, a clear long-run inflation goal
would help ensure that transitory supply shocks don’t shift inflation expectations, and it would
underscore our determination to minimize the risks of deflation. A consensus statement about
our policy framework could be an ideal means of enunciating an explicit inflation goal because
such a statement of principles could emphasize our commitment to both parts of our dual
mandate. The statement could specifically indicate our judgment that the mandate-consistent
inflation rate is 2 percent, while noting that our estimates of the longer-run sustainable
unemployment rate are regularly conveyed through the SEP. In my view, it would be also
essential to clarify that the time horizon over which inflation is expected to converge to the
longer-run goal would depend on economic conditions and would reflect the Committee’s
judgments about the path of policy that most effectively promotes both parts of our dual
mandate.
Turning to the second question, a long and distinguished literature shows that central
banks can foster better macroeconomic outcomes by making conditional commitments about the
future path of policy rather than by following a discretionary approach of re-optimizing at every
meeting. I think commitment strategies are particularly beneficial when the current setting of the
policy rate is constrained by the zero lower bound, because the central bank can provide extra
accommodation by promising a shallower interest rate trajectory than would be implied under a
purely discretionary approach.
The conditionality is a crucial element of commitment strategies because an
unconditional commitment could result in very poor, even disastrous outcomes under some
circumstances. In theory, the ideal Ramsey planner would formulate and communicate a
complete set of state-contingent commitments. He would spell out exactly how the path of

November 1–2, 2011

79 of 282

policy would unfold under every conceivable scenario. In reality, of course, the idea of a policy
committee agreeing to a myriad of policy paths and seeking to communicate all of that
information to the public is completely impractical.
The staff memo mainly focuses on one approach to addressing this problem—namely, the
use of simple rules that specify how the central bank will respond to observable economic
variables. In my view, such rules can serve as very useful benchmarks for assessing the stance
of monetary policy and for helping the public understand how policy may evolve under
alternative scenarios. But it would be highly inadvisable to make a binding commitment to
follow one particular rule, because there are surely contingencies under which any given rule
might perform quite poorly. I, therefore, consider it preferable to take a more pragmatic
approach, one that involves communicating our modal expectations about the path of policy and
conveying the conditionality of that path by specifying thresholds for key economic variables, in
effect, the approach illustrated in the final variant for paragraph 4″ in alternative A1. And here I
agree completely with President Evans and others, and I agree exactly with his analysis of why
this type of approach would be robust and beneficial. As an alternative, the Committee could
indicate its modal expectations for policy and the associated paths of economic variables as is
proposed in 4′, the second variant of paragraph 4 in alternative A1. But this approach would
seem to me to be at least somewhat less effective in communicating conditionality.
Turning to the third question, I’ll devote most of my comments to nominal income
targeting. There is a significant body of research that highlights the extent to which this
framework can facilitate the stability of prices and the real economy, and a number of prominent
economists who have recently been urging the Fed to consider adopting it as a means to respond
more forcefully to current economic circumstances.

November 1–2, 2011

80 of 282

The staff memo shows that nominal income targeting could be quite helpful in promoting
our dual objectives under the modal outlook in a range of alternatives. Nonetheless, as I’ve
contemplated the possibility of a nominal income target, I’ve become increasingly convinced
that there would be enormous practical challenges in implementing this framework, and that may
help explain why no other central bank has ever followed such an approach. Let me highlight a
few specific concerns.
First, as is noted in the staff memo, it would not be appropriate for the target path to be
permanently fixed. Rather, it would need to be revised whenever there were significant changes
in the estimated level or growth rate of potential output. Importantly, such revisions would need
to be retrospective as well as prospective. For example, last August’s NIPA re-benchmarking
led to a substantial revision of the estimated path of potential output that would have required a
corresponding change in the target path. I can easily imagine the public confusion on such
occasions. People would complain the Federal Reserve is changing the goal posts.
Second, the target path by itself doesn’t provide a full description of this framework.
Rather, the central bank must also specify and communicate the rule it will follow in bringing
nominal income back to that target path. That choice may have non-trivial implications for the
stabilization performance of the framework. For example, it might seem intuitive to follow a
rule that prescribes monotonic convergence back to the target path, but such a rule would
generate macro outcomes that are much less appealing than those obtained in the staff memo,
which uses a rule that implies substantial overshooting. Nevertheless, I suspect it would be
much more difficult to explain the overshooting rule to the public, and of course, the whole
rationale for this approach could be undermined if wage and price setters and financial market
investors didn’t fully understand it.

November 1–2, 2011

81 of 282

A third pitfall of nominal income targeting—this is something that Presidents Williams
and Kocherlakota have been commenting on—is that the strategy may involve a very long
process of convergence to the balanced growth path, not just 5 or 6 or 8 years, as described in
many of our SEP narratives, but perhaps stretching out as long as 15 or 20. For example, in the
FRB/US simulation of the recession scenario with policy remaining highly accommodative
through 2018, the unemployment rate, as Mike noted, drops to close to 3 percent. Inflation peaks
around 2¾ percent, and nominal income overshoots its target path by around 2 percentage points.
At that point, though, monetary policy can’t just shift back to being neutral. Rather, to bring
nominal income back to target, the stance of policy gradually becomes contractionary. By 2024,
the economy is in mild recession with unemployment rising back up to 6 percent and inflation
running around 1¼ for a few years until the path finally settles down around 2030.
In effect, the strategy succeeds in dampening the near-term consequences of the recession
shock by providing a clear and credible commitment to a policy path stretching out over nearly
two decades. From an aesthetic viewpoint, the dynamic elegance of this policy is breathtaking.
[Laughter] I spent the weekend contemplating potential analogies, deciding that the best
comparison would be to an Olympic figure skater who leaps in the air for a triple Salchow. We
all hold our breath until she lands gracefully to complete the rest of her performance. However,
we should remember that the figure skater’s routine is one she’s practiced hundreds of times
[laughter] until she could execute it as flawlessly as possible. Even if she has an awkward
landing, the worst case is that there’s no gold medal, but surely no champion skater would
introduce a routine for the very first time right in the middle of an Olympic performance. And
like the practical complexities of nominal income targeting, it would only be prudent to develop,
implement, and carefully communicate this approach over a course of a number of years. This is

November 1–2, 2011

82 of 282

the approach that’s been taken by the Bank of Canada, which has spent the past half-decade
exploring alternative monetary policy frameworks in close consultation with the public and the
Canadian parliament. In the near term, however, we might consider making more frequent
references in our monetary policy communications to the level of nominal income and its
relevance in guiding our thinking, in effect, turning it into a second pillar of policy.
More broadly, the conditional commitments may be the most potent tool in our toolbox at
this stage, but we need to be mindful of the intrinsic limits on our ability to make credible
promises over time horizons that extend beyond several years. We need to follow a pragmatic
approach for promoting the stability of economic activity and inflation, recognizing the limits of
our understanding of the structure and evolution of the economy and of our ability to anticipate
or plan for all possible contingencies. This inclines me, as I said, toward enhancing our forward
guidance, ideally along the lines that President Evans has articulated or, alternatively, through an
approach that would involve our projections.
On the final question about projections, I do strongly favor publishing information on
policy projections in the SEP. Our subcommittee will be happy to work with staff to develop
specific approaches to circulate to the Committee for your consideration if the Committee wants
to go in this direction, and I certainly think that it’s something that we should carefully consider.
I look forward to working on that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I, too, want to thank the staff for the quality of
thought and work that went into the memos and for the time they spent with me answering my
questions. I also want to apologize to that same staff because my comments are going to take the
intellectual level of this discussion down a number of notches, but I’ll remind you that the

November 1–2, 2011

83 of 282

intended audience for any communication that we might make includes a lot more people like
me than it does people like you. [Laughter]
I am in no position to question the theory, the assumptions, the thought, the quantitative
analysis, the simulations, or the academic literature that underpin the framework memos. As I
thought about these over the weekend, I was reminded of a story that I first heard when I was in
college, and maybe some of you heard it as well. It’s the story of the physicist and the economist
who were stranded at sea with nothing but a single can of beans to eat, and the physicist took the
can of beans and applied precisely the right amount of force at exactly the right location and still
couldn’t open the can of beans, despite having used the heat of the sun and the coldness of the
water to soften up the metal. So he asked the economist if he thought he could open the can of
beans, and the economist looked at it and said thoughtfully, “Assume we had a can opener.” So I
focused on two aspects of execution, credibility and clarity, because all of the expected results
depend critically on the assumption of a can opener—that is, absolute credibility and clarity.
The Federal Reserve already enjoys a high degree of credibility stemming from its
demonstrated commitment to containing inflation. This credibility comes not so much from
what we say, but from what we have done for many years, and the public has learned our ways.
For the most part, the public still trusts us to control inflation, and those who pay the most
attention to what we say have come to understand that we will control it at a level of 2 percent or
a bit less. If we’re going to convince the public that we’re going to act differently in the future,
especially far into the future, we will first need unanimous or near unanimous agreement and
steadfast conviction that it’s the right course for us to follow, and we would need to speak with
one voice to communicate clearly how we were changing and why. Without near unanimity and
one voice, the public could focus on the potential for the rotation of voters to change the path or

November 1–2, 2011

84 of 282

the potential for the two open seats and the upcoming term endings on the Board to bring about a
philosophical change or, in the worst case for credibility, the political debate could become
fixated on effecting such a change through legislation or personnel changes.
Finally, in order to protect the hard-won credibility that we already have, we must be
absolutely clear about our intentions and our reasoning, and one carefully worded and
unanimously supported statement is a start, but it has to be reinforced through repetition and
explanation. As an example, there’s already much confusion in the public about the difference
between guarding against deflation and inflating our way to growth. To return to the questions
we were asked to address, I’m supportive of an effort to create a document that addresses our
framework as long as it addresses both parts of our dual mandate. I’m not opposed to making a
clear statement about our objectives or even an explicit inflation target as long as we also
articulate the way that the employment level influences our decisions. It would be helpful if we
could also articulate the way that asset purchases fit into our strategy and how the size of our
balance sheet interacts with the federal funds rate and our policy objectives.
Moving on to the question about using policy thresholds to explain our strategy, I used
the fed funds rate in the alternative simulations to help me with my fed funds projections in this
round, my understanding being that these are fed funds rates that most closely correspond with
the historical behavior of the Committee if each of these scenarios were to unfold. But when I
tried to find the common thresholds in those simulations, I couldn’t do it, which underlined, for
me at least, the need to think carefully about how we express ourselves. In August we started
down the path of using a date for forward guidance. Then in September, with no one especially
pleased with the idea of using a date, we discussed several alternative ways of providing
guidance. Before we change this again, I hope we’ll work very hard to forge agreement on the

November 1–2, 2011

85 of 282

language, such as date, time, or threshold; the vehicle, such as statement, SEP, or separate
document; the frequency with which we plan to adjust it; and whether we do it as a commitment
or a forecast.
As to changing frameworks altogether, such as a move to targeting nominal income or a
price level, I found the discussion of risk in the memo quite persuasive and would hope that we
could keep these weapons in reserve unless we see a recession scenario in which a dramatic
change might better justify the risks. In the meantime, it could help with clarity if we could work
to educate the public about why we might make this choice.
Here’s what I would most like to see us do: Rather than each trying to convince the
others that his or her approach is the best, maybe we could think about what it is that we all do
agree on. If President Williams agreed with both President Plosser and President Rosengren, that
proves that this is possible, [laughter] and then we could work to explain that to the world.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll begin where Esther began, with the
observation that people’s preferences with respect to things we call framework or quasiconstitutional changes are almost always connected to substantive policy preferences. I very
much think that’s the case here, and so in part that leads me to want to bypass a lot of this
discussion in order to focus on the question of what should we be doing given the fact that we
have somewhat differing analyses of where the economy is. I think that leads to more need for
communication, but it pushes me away from a preference for structural or quasi-constitutional
changes because of my observation that writing constitutions or frameworks tends to become
more complicated precisely because there’s a different set of debates going on underneath, which

November 1–2, 2011

86 of 282

are substantive policy debates. And, while I wouldn’t foreclose any of that, having listened to
most of the conversation already today, it doesn’t strike me that there’s been an enormous
amount of convergence thus far around any new framework.
The second introductory observation I’d make is that the more I’ve read in the
intermeeting period about the way other central banks do everything, do inflation targeting and
economic projections and the monetary policymaking in general, the more I have been impressed
with the—how shall I put this neutrally?—peculiarity of the Federal Reserve System. Thus the
tentative conclusion that much of what may work in other countries, in other monetary policy
committees in other systems, may not work particularly well precisely because of the different
institutional characteristics that the Federal Reserve System has.
Turning to the questions that the staff put in front of us, I’m going to change the order
somewhat and start with the framework question. To Richard, I would say that the possibility of
unanticipated negative consequences is a sobering one to be sure, but one always has to balance
that with what the costs of the status quo are, and that’s where we get to substantive issues again.
My own view, which won’t come as a surprise to anyone, is I am deeply distressed with the
status quo. I fear, as an increasing number of people do, that we are sliding into a period of
stagnation, which will become ever more difficult to extract ourselves from. As an ex ante
matter, I wouldn’t dismiss something just because there probably will be negative unanticipated
consequences. However, I think Janet and a number of others have pointed to anticipated
negative consequences, which could be associated with some of the framework changes, and add
to that the communications difficulties that a number of you have pointed out, and it seems to
me—again, like many, though not everybody here—that these things are worthy of continual
consideration in the event that the economy deteriorates further or, regrettably more likely

November 1–2, 2011

87 of 282

perhaps today than a few days ago, we get a major external shock sometime in the not-toodistant future.
I’m going to pair the threshold proposal with the SEP because I think they are both about
communications. As everybody knows from the last meeting, John and I were trying to push
forward onto the table the use of the modified SEP as a surrogate for the use of the thresholds,
and I continue to think that bears consideration, but I’m going to place two qualifications on my
own predisposition.
First, I read the results of our initial foray here as posing more of a communication
problem than I had anticipated, and I am of the provisional conclusion that aggregating the
17 individual results is not going to do the trick. We may want to think about some alternatives,
again, taking into account the peculiar institutional characteristics of the Fed for this purpose, the
fact that we are a very large group compared with other central banks that have this kind of
exercise. The academics with whom I’ve spoken about these sorts of exercises all point to the
value of the discussion whereby the monetary policy committee critiques, and comes eventually
to some consensus, on the projected path of interest rates. I have a vivid imagination, but I have
had difficulty conjuring up the scenario in which the 17 people around this table come to a
consensus view on a projected path of interest rates. But it seems at least plausible that if staff
could construct three scenarios—one, relatively higher inflation; two, their baseline scenario;
three, relatively lower inflation—we might have the opportunity to get most members of the
Committee signing onto the proposition that if this, in fact, is the way that the economy evolves
over the next eight quarters or whatever the projection period would be, then the anticipated
federal funds rate path associated with that movement in the economy would be appropriate. I
don’t know if that’s possible either, but it seems to me worth thinking about.

November 1–2, 2011

88 of 282

The second problem, which somebody alluded to earlier, and I did note this in my memo
last time, is that at present we’ve got the big balance sheet in addition to the zero interest rates.
As many of us have said many times, beginning to draw down the balance sheet would be the
equivalent of a tightening move and thus would be relevant to market actors and somehow that
would be need to be factored in.
Moving now to the flexible inflation approach, Jeff is absolutely right. You state the
proposition broadly enough, everybody can agree with it, and that allows everybody to tweak the
particular clauses or phrases in the formulation in order to make it fit their policy predisposition.
As I’ve said before on this Committee, I was substantially more open-minded on stating an
explicit inflation target when I walked in here two years and nine months ago than I am now, and
the reason for that gets back to Esther’s observation. I think to a considerable extent, it reflects,
and would be perceived publicly as reflecting, a fairly strong, substantive preference for an
inflation target over the other side of the dual mandate.
I have listened to some of us around the table who basically say that if you do price
stability well, you will promote maximum employment, which to me is very close to reading half
the dual mandate out of the statute. It is a coherent view of the world, but it’s not either what the
statute says or my view of the world, and thus I have some substantial resistance to it. There are
some environments in which the establishment of an explicit inflation target, along with the kind
of explanations of unemployment or maximum employment or output gaps that people have
mentioned, could be perceived as a balanced embodiment of the dual mandate. I don’t think that
this is one of them. Although I’m not closed-minded on the proposition, I have to say that
there’s a substantial hurdle that I feel has to be overcome before I would be comfortable with it.

November 1–2, 2011

89 of 282

My last comment would be that one way to potentially make me comfortable with an
inflation target—contrary to what Esther said, as opposed to agreeing with her—is if it were put
in place as part of an exercise that was actually accommodative. That is, if the inflation target
were put in place and the rest of the explanation of the dual mandate made an effort to
communicate as clearly and credibly as we could a medium-term inflation target, while at the
same time taking the kind of substantive policy accommodation steps which I think are needed,
then it would be a different story. But as Esther’s comment reflects and as I’ve heard others
speak, it seems to me that a lot of people want actually to pull those apart because, quite
legitimately, they have a substantive policy preference for not taking further accommodative
action and, thus, don’t want to tie those two things together. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Raskin. I’m sorry. President
Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Just a quick gloss on what Governor Tarullo said about the
SEP paths of the target funds rates. There was a lot of heterogeneity. I was struck by that.
I will say for myself, the question was about what I viewed as the optimal path of the fed
funds rate. The question was not about asking me to forecast what the fed funds rate was going
to be—what the likely outcomes of these Committee deliberations would be. My guess is that
President Evans and I might come much closer on that calculation than we would if we were
asked to be in charge of setting the fed funds rate.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Raskin.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. First, I think flexible inflation targeting can
be consistent with the dual mandate. Unlike the Committee’s current approach of constrained
discretion, flexible inflation targeting is more optimal if it involves conditional commitments

November 1–2, 2011

90 of 282

referencing both parts of the dual mandate and indicating how policy rates will be adjusted going
forward. Constrained discretion, on the other hand, means that the Committee proceeds on a
meeting-to-meeting basis and remains unwilling to promise future accommodation via
communication. With this current approach, the Federal Reserve will not meet its employment
goal for a long time and may be at risk of undershooting its inflation goal as well. Moreover, the
continued use of constrained discretion means that the funds rate begins to increase in 2014 even
though unemployment is well above the natural rate and inflation is below 2 percent. I respond
to question 1 by believing a framework of flexible inflation targeting can be structured to be
better aligned with the dual mandate and more likely to lead to optimal results that are better
achieved with commitment strategies that reference both employment and inflation. In terms of
articulating a framework, I see no downside and can imagine developing a statement on the
policy framework similar to that used for the exit strategy statement.
The staff memo on alternative frameworks describes the superiority of commitment
strategies. The memo makes clear that there are risks in such strategies, most notably risks
related to the possibility that the commitment strategies would perform less well if their
credibility were significantly questioned, and that there are challenges in the use of such
strategies, most notably the challenge of communication. Even the most stimulative policies
considered do not imply significant overshooting of inflation above a possible long-run goal of
2 percent. I believe that the commitment strategies are superior, but only with a strong caveat.
That caveat is the imperative of a well-developed and well-tested and multifaceted
communication strategy. Unfortunately, to date we have not put enough effort into framing such
a communication strategy, and the results have been negative and troubling to this institution and

November 1–2, 2011

91 of 282

to the Committee. The launch of the second LSAP, for example, was met with a barrage of
mostly uninformed negativity, which may have undermined its effectiveness.
Paragraph 4 in alternative A1 presents three strategies with increasing commitment and
accommodative value. The first option is the least transparent, contains the lowest commitment,
and accordingly, would provide the least accommodation. The third option is the most
transparent, contains the greatest commitment, and accordingly, I would expect it to provide the
most accommodation. The latter two options could bring about a noticeably faster fall in
unemployment than under the baseline outlook while keeping inflation in the neighborhood of
2 percent. Whichever of these options is chosen, there should be a corresponding
communication program set forth for the Committee to discuss and debate. In addition to this
enhanced forward guidance, which looks more like the third option for paragraph 4 in alternative
A1 and less like the first option for paragraph 4 in alternative A1, the staff memo describes two
other commitment strategies: price-level targeting and nominal income targeting. Both of these
strategies are shown by staff to be more optimal under various models, including FRB/US, than
the Committee’s existing strategy. I appreciate how critical credibility is to the execution and
success of these commitment strategies and appreciate the scale and creativity that would be
involved in the crafting of a comprehensive communication strategy.
Again, I don’t view the communication challenge as insurmountable. Rather, I would
venture to say that communication thought of as a strategy is a challenge that needs more serious
debate and piloting. From this perspective, I believe the communication challenge to be just as
intense for our current framework and choice of policy actions. There’s continued risk to the
credibility of the Federal Reserve in a decision to continue to engage in constrained discretion

November 1–2, 2011

92 of 282

because we have not described to the public why we are choosing to engage in what we have
decided is a suboptimal strategy.
Model simulations suggest that nominal income targeting could provide considerable
stimulus under the modal outlook and would perform well in a severe downturn or in response to
an unexpected sustained rise in inflationary pressures. Accordingly, if the credibility challenges
could be overcome with a meaningfully robust and comprehensive communication program, I
would view us as remiss in meeting the dual mandate if we were not to consider it.
Finally, I should attempt to be concrete about what I think a communication plan
includes. At the very least, we need to be able to explain the expected transmission of the action.
I was stunned when talking to a group of bankers after one of them said to me, “Please stop. Just
stop. What can we do to get you all to just cease?” This kind of question makes it obvious that
our actions are not completely understood and suggests that we focus resources on a
communication plan both through the SEP and through a coordinated strategy that can explain
how our policy actions are expected to work and how they may fall short. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much, and thank you all for your
thoughtful comments. Let me make a couple of suggestions and summary remarks. First, on the
intermediate targets like nominal GDP and price-level targeting, I didn’t hear much enthusiasm
for any near-term adoption, although I think there was at least some interest in continuing to
think about these issues perhaps in the context of a significant change in the environment.
Just for interest, I do raise one point, which is that a number of people have mentioned
Christy Romer’s piece, and she talked about the 1979 regime change. I actually think that’s the
wrong example. As President Bullard pointed out, when Chairman Volcker changed the policy
regime, in fact, it took a long time for people to appreciate it and understand it, and one

November 1–2, 2011

93 of 282

implication of that is there was a long recession and real interest rates remained very high, and so
on. But there are other examples, like 1933, when Roosevelt took the U.S. off the gold standard,
and prices and asset prices changed almost overnight. There are other examples like the end of
hyperinflations, and so on. There’s something sometimes about regime changes that has
remarkable effects on an economy. I’m not saying that we know how to predict that, but that’s
something that we haven’t really understood or really explored in this conversation. That being
said, I think that there was a lot of agreement that there are a lot of practical issues associated
with implementing such an intermediate target, including both the very long horizons over which
they have to operate and the issues of communication and credibility.
There was considerably more support for two specific things. First would be formulating
some statement of principles in the same mode as the exit strategy principles, to try to formalize
a bit more our flexible inflation-targeting framework. One element of that would be a numerical
inflation objective, but I think it was made clear that other important elements would be a clear
explanation of how this framework is consistent with the dual mandate: in particular, why it is
that we have a number for inflation and not for unemployment, how those two things differ, how
we think about the horizon under which we take various actions, and so on. I would ask the
subcommittee, if Governor Yellen is willing, to begin a process of trying to put together such a
document. The work that President Plosser and his group did, and President Plosser is a member
of the subcommittee, is obviously a starting point for that, and—we’re not making any
commitment, to coin a phrase [laughter]—we should see what kind of agreement we can get on
such a statement. Incidentally, I thought a useful addendum to the Plosser et al. document was a
set of Frequently Asked Questions, which might be a useful thing to work on as well in order to
explore and illuminate some of the issues.

November 1–2, 2011

94 of 282

The other thing for which I heard reasonable support was for further implementation and
use of the SEP as a means of policy guidance. In particular, we’ll hear today a report on the trial
run on the policy projections, and I would propose—contingent on the discussion that follows
that presentation, if people are willing—to again ask the subcommittee with a lot of staff support
to try to develop some possible presentation approaches, some mock-up SEPs, and so on for our
consideration to see if we find that a useful mechanism.
If we can do these things, let me suggest a very ambitious way of putting this all together,
and of course, which can always be extended. If we were able to get an agreed upon statement
of principles on the framework by the next meeting, by mid-December, and if we were also able
to get to some agreement about the use of our policy rate projections, then we could review those
issues at the December meeting. If we were comfortable with where we were at that point, we
could then have a plan to consider at least ratifying these items as part of a communications
package perhaps as early as our January organizational meeting. If we were to agree to do that,
then we could try to prepare the ground for that in various ways. One thing, for example, would
be that I could give a speech a couple of weeks before the January meeting and outline some of
the ideas that are being discussed, and that would give us a chance to get some public feedback
on the ideas, and we could also do some consultation. But it seems to me possible, if things go
well, that we might consider trying to put together a package by the end of January. Two weeks
after that or so is my Humphrey–Hawkins testimony, which would be another opportunity to
explain this.
I think some of these things are better as part of a package of communications ideas
rather than a discrete change in one aspect of our communications. Again, this is just a proposal.

November 1–2, 2011

95 of 282

I’ll give people a chance to react after I finish these remarks, but there’s no commitment being
made until we see how things go and how comfortable people are.
I have one other set of comments, which has to do with the discussions we had on
conditional commitments. There was a lot of interesting discussion on that issue. I will say for
myself that I think this is something we should keep on the table. First of all, forward guidance
is not something we’re contemplating; we’re well into the forward-guidance game. In fact, that
was something that was part of my predecessor’s legacy—“a considerable period” and
“measured pace,” you remember all those things. We have, for better or worse, given an
estimate of the date at which policy will begin to tighten, and it would be very desirable for us to
think about ways to improve our forward guidance, particularly in light of the fact that we’re at
the zero lower bound and communication is an important part potentially, at least, of our toolkit.
Forward guidance is also, again, one way, and President Evans made a couple of good
points. One is that many of the properties of the optimal control path that the staff discussed, or
at least some of them, could be replicated by an appropriately calibrated forward guidance,
where there was a commitment or just a forecast. There’s that advantage, and then President
Evans also made the point that by having triggers or escape clauses, you can protect yourself
against uncertainty about the underlying source of the problem. His example was if we don’t
know whether the problem is a collapse of potential output or a collapse of aggregate demand, if
we have sufficient conditionality, we are protected against both approaches. Again, that’s
something we ought to consider.
I do think that some of the discussion helps us address some of the concerns that people
have. Let me mention a few things. In our discussion of the strategies at the last meeting, one of
the concerns people had was that the public would misinterpret a trigger or an escape clause as a

November 1–2, 2011

96 of 282

target. Obviously, if we put this in the context of a broader communications strategy, that would
reduce that risk considerably. Another concern that was raised was that we certainly can’t
estimate the natural rate of unemployment, even if it’s not time-varying, with any accuracy. And
if it’s time-varying, that makes it even more difficult. But I would point out that the kind of
language we have in the statement A includes both an unemployment trigger, but also an
inflation trigger, and that would be a protection against a mistake in terms of where the
unemployment rate should be. Yet another concern about these conditional commitments is that
they involve very long time frames. President Bullard made the very good point that we should
be at least combining with, or maybe just focusing on, asset purchases as being a more active
type of policy action that would be more likely to affect expectations. I make the point that if
our optimal policy involves a commitment which is very long in terms of the interest rate, we
could at least consider combining that with asset purchases as a way of bringing that rate closer
to the present.
So there are some issues here that we need to discuss, but some of them may be at least
addressable. Now, having said that, I recognize there are lots of different ways to do this. The
alternative statement A gave three different types of language. It could go into the statement, but
some people have talked about the use of the SEP, and there are a variety of modifications that
could be contemplated. I put this out there as something I will ask the staff—and Reserve Bank
presidents might want to ask their own staffs—to look at, and we should try to make some
progress on this over the next couple of meetings.
Any comments or reactions, particularly on the plan to try to get something together by
January? Again, this will be contingent on it working. I should say that these framework
changes are constitutional-type changes, and I’m certainly going to be looking for a very broad

November 1–2, 2011

97 of 282

agreement before we make any of these changes. [No response] Let’s turn next then to item 3
on our agenda, financial developments and open market operations; and we’ll turn to Brian Sack.
MR. SACK. 2 Thank you. The exhibits are coming, but I wanted to say a few
words before actually getting to the handout. Frankly, after hearing about what’s
taken place in financial markets over the past couple of days, you may actually need a
drink. [Laughter] So I think the innovation of beer at the FOMC meeting is a good
one. [Laughter].
Movements in markets yesterday and today have been dramatic. Let me give you
a few numbers: The S&P 500 index is off about 5 percent, European stocks are off
about 8 percent, some U.S. financial companies, such as Morgan Stanley, have their
equity prices off 15 to 20 percent, and the 10-year Treasury yield has plummeted
about 30 basis points. My point is that, once again, the world appears to be shifting
under our feet pretty dramatically.
One consequence of this volatility is that it actually makes it quite hard to prepare
a briefing that is timely. I think you will find that my prepared briefing provides very
accurate and insightful information about financial market movements through last
Friday [laughter], but I will do my best to modify accordingly. You’re going to
notice some tension here and there.
The story from my briefing, and that was presented in the Tealbook, is that
financial market participants had generally become more optimistic about the outlook
over the intermeeting period in response to the perception of progress toward a
comprehensive policy solution in Europe and generally better-than-expected
economic data. This improved sentiment had lifted the prices of most risky assets
and had caused interest rates to rise. However, I had planned to note that the financial
environment remains volatile, and that it is uncertain whether this enthusiasm would
last. The sharp downturn in markets that we saw yesterday and so far today has
brought that point forward with an exclamation point.
Let me turn to the exhibits. As shown in the upper-left panel of your first exhibit,
Treasury yields had increased significantly over the intermeeting period, with yields
at intermediate maturities moving up 25 to 40 basis points through last Friday. As
suggested by the news index shown to the right, the incoming economic data has
generally been better than expectations, supporting the upward movement in yields.
In addition, developments in Europe have been an important driver of market
movements, with perceived improvements in the policy outlook usually associated
with increases in Treasury yields. However, taking into account the sizable decline
so far this week, Treasury yields are now only modestly higher, on net, over the
intermeeting period.

2

The materials used by Mr. Sack are appended to this transcript (appendix 2).

November 1–2, 2011

98 of 282

The pattern of yield movements also reflects the impact of the policy decisions
that the FOMC announced at the September meeting. The decision to extend the
maturity of the SOMA portfolio appeared to pull down Treasury yields, with the
largest effects at longer maturities, as suggested by the pattern of forward rate
changes shown in the middle-left panel. When combined with the other
developments over the intermeeting period, the net effect through last Friday was to
leave forward rates out to 10 years somewhat higher, and forward rates beyond that
point somewhat lower, than they were at the time of the last FOMC meeting. And, of
course, with the events in recent days, that structure will be lower.
The table to the right takes a closer look at the effects of the recent policy actions.
As shown in the first column, longer-term Treasury yields declined substantially
immediately surrounding the September FOMC announcement. Moreover, this
movement passed through strongly to the 30-year swap rate, suggesting that the
effects of the program were not limited to only Treasury yields.
Of course, the movement in a window around the FOMC announcement is not
necessarily an accurate measure of the impact of the policy actions, for two reasons.
First, the policy actions were anticipated, and hence much of the effect was likely
incorporated into asset prices in advance of the meeting. Second, market participants
became more pessimistic about economic growth prospects in response to the
description of the economy in the FOMC statement, which likely contributed to the
decline in rates.
To arrive at a better measure, the Desk’s survey of primary dealers asked for
estimates of the effects of the policy actions, controlling for these other factors. The
median response, reported in the second column of the table, shows that dealers
believe that the policy actions pulled down longer-term Treasury yields by 10 to
20 basis points, roughly in line with the staff’s estimates ahead of the actions.
Dealers also thought that the maturity extension program had raised the two-year
yield by 7 basis points, apparently because of the additional supply coming from our
sales of Treasuries with maturities of three years or less. However, market
participants still expect short-term interest rates to remain at their current levels for a
very long period, which should limit any upward movement in the two-year yield.
Indeed, as shown in the bottom-left panel, dealers see a greater than 50 percent
chance that the first increase in the federal funds target rate will not occur until 2014
or later.
The figures reported in the table also show the effects of the FOMC’s decision to
shift SOMA reinvestments back into agency mortgage-backed securities. Dealers
estimate that this decision narrowed the option-adjusted spread on current-coupon
MBS by 15 basis points. This policy step came as a surprise to market participants,
and hence the effect on the spread occurred immediately after the FOMC statement.
As shown in the bottom-right panel, that narrowing of the MBS spread reversed some
of the increase that had been observed since the summer, but the MBS spread remains
quite elevated compared with its levels early in the year.

November 1–2, 2011

99 of 282

Before leaving this panel, it is worth noting that the MBS market has also been
affected by the FHFA’s announcement of upcoming changes to its HARP program.
As summarized in the Tealbook, the FHFA made a set of changes that it estimates
will cause an additional 1 million mortgages to be refinanced. Not surprisingly, the
announcement led to a significant widening of the spreads on higher-coupon MBS
due to greater prepayment risk, and these spreads experienced considerable volatility
as market participants debated the potential scope of the program. Nevertheless, the
current coupon MBS yield was not strongly affected by the announcement,
suggesting that it did not have detrimental effects on current mortgage conditions.
Your second exhibit turns to broader financial market developments and recent
events in Europe. European leaders have been working to put forward a more
comprehensive policy solution to address concerns about the capital needs of
European financial institutions and the sustainability of the fiscal situation in
particular European countries, including Spain and Italy. The news about these
policy actions and the associated shifts in investor sentiment have been the most
important factors affecting broader financial markets over the intermeeting period.
Steve Kamin will review the policy announcements that have been made to date.
I will simply note that they have fallen short of offering many of the details that will
be critical to their success. Nevertheless, markets were apparently reassured by the
willingness of European policymakers to consider comprehensive policy actions,
leading to considerable gains in the prices of risky assets ahead of and immediately
after the announcements. As shown in the upper-left panel, equity prices increased
sharply, with the S&P 500 index gaining nearly 7 percent through last Friday.
European markets turned around even more aggressively, with the Euro Stoxx index
gaining nearly 12 percent over the period. However, the tone has turned negative in
recent days, including the sharp selloff in markets yesterday and today that has
reversed a large portion of the earlier gains.
The improvement in risk sentiment had also been apparent in corporate bonds, as
shown to the right. Corporate bond spreads widened sharply into October, especially
for lower-quality issuers, and issuance slowed markedly. In recent weeks, however,
the high-yield bond spread sharply retraced some of its earlier widening, and
investment-grade spreads also narrowed.
The reversal of safe-haven flows had unwound some of the appreciation of the
dollar that had been observed ahead of the last FOMC meeting. Through last Friday,
the dollar had depreciated against a broad set of currencies, particularly those that are
more sensitive to global growth prospects. The dollar’s depreciation against the yen
had been relatively modest, but that movement was enough for Japanese officials to
begin intervening again in the dollar–yen currency pair. The Bank of Japan entered
the market yesterday at the direction of the Ministry of Finance, executing over
$100 billion of dollar purchases on the day, which weakened the yen about 3 percent.
Amid the volatility in recent days, the dollar has been appreciating again, leaving the
broad dollar index somewhat stronger over the intermeeting period.

November 1–2, 2011

100 of 282

Even though the policy measures announced in Europe were met with a positive
initial reception in many markets, they did not put to rest the uncertainties
surrounding the situation. One worrisome sign is that sovereign debt spreads for
Spain and Italy did not improve meaningfully after the announced policy steps, with
Italian spreads actually touching new highs last week, as shown in the middle-right
panel. Those spreads have increased further today.
As discussed in the briefing from two weeks ago, these broader market strains
have had important implications for short-term funding markets. The situation in
funding markets is largely similar to what I described in that briefing. In particular,
many European institutions face constraints on their short-term funding in both euros
and dollars, with limited access or high costs for funding at maturities beyond the
very near term. By comparison, most U.S. institutions have not faced constraints on
term funding to the same degree as European firms. As shown in the bottom-left
panel, the spread of the three-month U.S. LIBOR rate over OIS has continued to edge
higher, but a forward measure of this spread has been holding fairly steady.
Moreover, some of the concerns about particular U.S. institutions that had
intensified in September and early October have eased in recent weeks. As I had
previously noted, investors became focused on the vulnerabilities of several firms
with large trading operations and a heavy reliance on short-term wholesale funding,
including Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs. However, sentiment toward those
firms has improved in recent weeks, as reflected in the sharp narrowing of the CDS
spreads in the lower-right panel. In response to the earlier pressures, U.S. financial
firms had stopped issuing longer-term unsecured debt, but in recent weeks we have
seen them step back into this market, albeit at higher rates than were available several
months ago. Overall, financing conditions for U.S. financial firms do not appear to
be deteriorating, but a number of uncertainties remain that warrant close monitoring.
Your final exhibit focuses on recent Desk operations and the evolution of the
SOMA balance sheet. The Desk has been implementing the range of policy decisions
that the FOMC made at its September meeting. In particular, we have begun the
Treasury purchases and sales associated with the maturity extension program as well
as the MBS purchases associated with the shift in the reinvestment strategy.
To date, the Desk’s operations in these areas have proceeded smoothly, and there
are no signs that our activity is having detrimental effects on market functioning.
Liquidity in the Treasury market has held steady, as indicated by the measures of the
cost of transacting in Treasury securities shown in the upper-left panel. Similarly,
liquidity in agency MBS markets has remained quite good, with a substantial majority
of our transactions taking place at prices below the indicative offer prices shown on
Tradeweb.
These outcomes are encouraging, especially considering the magnitude of our
operations in these markets. As shown in the upper-right panel, our purchases
through June 2012 are expected to represent a sizable portion of the gross issuance of
Treasury securities and agency MBS over this period.

November 1–2, 2011

101 of 282

Going forward, market participants are not convinced that the balance sheet
policies currently being implemented will be the final steps toward monetary policy
accommodation. Instead, as shown in the middle-left panel, respondents to the
primary dealer survey see about a 50 percent chance that the FOMC over the next
year will implement a further increase in the balance sheet or change its guidance
about the path of short-term interest rates. Considerable odds are also assigned to the
possibility of the FOMC offering balance sheet guidance, whereas respondents see a
cut in the interest rate on reserves or a further extension of SOMA duration as
unlikely. Respondents do not place high odds on any policy actions occurring at this
meeting.
The panel to the right shows the primary dealers’ projections for the path of the
SOMA balance sheet. The median survey response has the balance sheet remaining
at its current size and then beginning to decline gradually in 2014—a path that turns
down only slightly in advance of the assumptions made in the Tealbook. However, as
can be seen from the 25th and 75th percentiles, the distribution of expected paths is
skewed to the upside, as more market participants anticipate an expansion of the
balance sheet over the next several years than an early decline in the balance sheet.
Lastly, I want to highlight two other important developments regarding recent
operations by the Desk. The first of these is a structural change to our euro reverse
repurchase agreement portfolio. The Desk conducts reverse repurchase agreements in
euros using the sovereign debt from six countries as collateral, including Germany,
France, the Netherlands, Belgium, Spain, and Italy. As you may recall from an
earlier memo to the FOMC, the approach that had been in place did not differentiate
across this collateral in terms of the rates that we accepted for lending funds. Because
the market has increasingly differentiated the funding rates for this collateral, the
Desk was receiving increasing proportions of Spanish and Italian debt in its
operations.
Last week, we began to implement our new approach of accepting rate offers that
are specific to each of the six types of collateral. The results from our first operation
are shown in the bottom-left panel. As can be seen, the offers that we received
demonstrated notable differentiation across the collateral types, with market
participants willing to pay more to fund Spanish and Italian securities. This new
approach will allow us to be more confident that the Desk is receiving fair market
compensation for the collateral that we accept and will allow us to better control the
allocation of this collateral for the SOMA portfolio.
The second recent development to be highlighted involves MF Global. As you
know, MF Global experienced a rapid deterioration that led the firm, and the U.S.
broker–dealer subsidiary that is a primary dealer, into bankruptcy. In short, investors
became skeptical about the viability of the firm given the size of its exposures to
European sovereign debt markets, its weak earnings for the third quarter, and the
associated downgrades of the firm by several rating agencies. With these events, the
firm found itself unable to sustain sufficient financing, even as it attempted to rapidly
sell parts of its business and shed assets.

November 1–2, 2011

102 of 282

The path of MF Global serves as an example of the vulnerability of firms that are
heavily reliant on short-term wholesale funding. As shown in the bottom-right panel,
the firm had a narrow equity buffer, and its liability structure was relatively unstable.
Indeed, the firm had little longer-term unsecured debt and, since it was not a bank, no
retail deposits. Instead, the firm had 61 percent of its liabilities in the form of repo
transactions and other trading liabilities. This structure left the firm very susceptible
to a liquidity run in response to any emerging questions about its capital adequacy.
Of course, this is the same issue that I noted earlier in the discussion of investor
concerns about Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs. However, as can be seen in the
table, Morgan Stanley has a much larger share of long-term debt as well as some
retail deposits. The table also shows the figures for JP Morgan to offer a comparison
to an institution with a larger banking operation.
The problems experienced by MF Global raised risks to the Federal Reserve
through our counterparty relationship with the firm. Our potential exposures were
associated with MF Global’s participation in our securities lending operations, in our
operations in Treasury securities, and in our operations in agency mortgage-backed
securities. The Desk began to exclude MF Global from some operations last
Wednesday and from all operations last Thursday. Yesterday, the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York announced that it had terminated its primary dealer relationship
with MF Global.
Heading into the market open yesterday, our only exposure to the firm was from
seven unsettled MBS purchase transactions. These transactions, which totaled about
$950 million, were due to settle as far out as mid-January. To limit the risk to the
Federal Reserve from these transactions, on Friday we established a special
arrangement for the firm to post collateral to us on a daily basis. Based on
yesterday’s events, we exercised our legal authority to terminate the seven trades, and
we conducted trades with other counterparties to reestablish the same positions, using
the collateral that had been posted by MF Global to cover the additional expense of
those replacement trades. Given these steps, we do not expect to realize any losses
from our counterparty exposures to MF Global. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Questions? I’m sorry. President
Lacker, do you have a question?
MR. LACKER. Thank you. I have two questions. Brian, as this chart shows, we’ve
been buying a lot more nominals than TIPS, and under the same theory that lengthening our
maturity of our portfolio twists the curve, that would also affect the breakeven spreads. Do you
think that’s happening? And do you have a quantitative estimate of how much?

November 1–2, 2011

103 of 282

MR. SACK. It could be happening. We don’t have a good quantitative estimate. The
reason we include TIPS is we don’t want to distort the decomposition of nominal rates into their
breakeven and real components. We want to have some presence in that market, and, of course,
when we calibrate the pace of purchases or the allocation of our purchases, we look at a variety
of measures to try to judge how much we could buy without causing market strains.
Here I’m showing gross public issuance. When you compare it to gross issuance, it looks
quite small, but I think we did have some concerns that going too fast could disrupt the markets,
since this is a less liquid market anyway and there are a lot of buy-and-hold investors. Having
said all that, it’s possible we undershot, and indeed there were some commentaries by market
participants, such as Barclay’s, talking about our programs actually putting downward pressure
on breakeven inflation rates.
MR. LACKER. You gave us an estimate of the effect on the 10-year yield, but it would
be nice to have an estimate of this as well.
The second question is about Treasury debt issuance plans. Is there anything you can tell
us about what you know about their plans for next year and the extent to which they may be
contemplating or may have embarked on a path that would to some extent offset what we’ve
done?
MR. SACK. I believe they have not made debt management decisions in response to the
effects of our program that would undo our program. They are certainly not looking at rates and
opportunistically saying, “Given what the Fed has done to the yield curve, we want to move
further out in our issuance.” Having said that, they were already on a course that was
lengthening the average duration of their issuance, and I think that lengthening will continue
over the near term. At one of the recent meetings, we talked about Treasury expecting to be on a

November 1–2, 2011

104 of 282

path toward a weighted-average maturity of about 70 months, the market having anticipated that,
and I think the discussion at Treasury essentially is not whether to go beyond 70, but whether to
stop at 70 or stop somewhat below that.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. It’s fair to say that we don’t think Treasury has adjusted
their behavior in response to our behavior. It sounds like that’s the key point.
MR. SACK. They’re also considering a debt management innovation that would
probably reduce the amount of duration that they issue. They’ve asked the TBAC to consider the
appeal of floating-rate securities, which of course would allow the Treasury to reduce rollover
risk while not introducing duration into the market. If that were a product that they brought on
line and used in any size, that would actually help in terms of keeping duration out of the market.
MR. LACKER. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a quick question, Brian. In
terms of table 18, what would Goldman Sachs look like if we looked at their liability structure?
MR. SACK. I initially had Goldman Sachs on the table. I am contemplating whether to
dig through my notes. It looks a lot like Morgan Stanley. I can send you the details. The point
is, both Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs look different from institutions with larger banking
operations in the sense that they both have some retail deposits but much less in the banking
operation, and hence they rely more intensively on repo financing. The point of this table is to
say that was true for MF Global as well, but of course to a much more extreme degree.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. So, long-term unsecured debt would look roughly the same,
you think, for Goldman Sachs in terms of percentage?
MR. SACK. I think it would be in the same ballpark now that the figures show.

November 1–2, 2011

105 of 282

MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Deposits would probably be a little less. Their bank is
probably a little smaller.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thanks.
MR. PLOSSER. Mr. Chairman?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’m sorry. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I want to follow up with a question that Brian may not be able to
answer, but I’m just curious. If I looked at JPMorgan three years ago, before the crisis, roughly
what percentage would they have had in repo and trading liabilities—just ballpark? Twice this
or 50 percent more or about the same?
MR. SACK. I will have to check on that.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I would guess more, because remember, they bought
Washington Mutual, which had a lot of core deposits. The repo books have generally come
down over the past couple of years. I would guess more, but I don’t think it’s so significant that
you’d think they were in a very different position.
MR. PLOSSER. Okay. That’s kind of where I was.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. All right. Let me go to President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. First, I want to congratulate you on handling MF Global the way you
handled it. I have a question about that, and I have two other questions. But on this front, any
other trip bars that might ensue from MF’s failure that you’re monitoring in terms of its impact
on the system—not the Federal Reserve System, but on the fixed-income markets and on
financial stability?

November 1–2, 2011

106 of 282

MR. SACK. Yes, there are several areas we’re monitoring. MF Global, of course, had
essentially a large brokerage unit into futures markets. One area we’re watching is whether their
customers will experience any period of disruption and confusion about their ability to change
positions. There could potentially be odd short-term dynamics for futures markets.
The second area is questions about whether the customers’ assets are truly fully there at
the institution, and if there were problems in that regard, you could see a loss in confidence in
other types of custodial arrangements or intermediaries.
And the third area is whether there would be any consequences for repo financing, not
necessarily direct consequences associated with the unwinding of MF Global’s positions, but
broader concerns about whether repo funding for less liquid assets is as stable as the market had
assumed.
I’m sure there are others, but those are three areas that we’re watching. Not having the
benefit of seeing markets today, but through yesterday, it looked like the markets were not overly
concerned with any of those systemic consequences, but that’s what we’ll continue to monitor.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman, you wanted to add to that?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes, just a few things. This is the first significantly
sized FCM, futures commission merchant, that’s failed in a way that they didn’t actually port the
customer accounts off smoothly to some other entity. There’s a little bit more uncertainty here
because it has never happened like this before. In the past, there has always been a smooth
transfer of accounts.
The second thing I would say is that it underscores how fast liquidity can dry up for a
firm. This is another firm that, while I wouldn’t say they were fine a week ago, they didn’t look
like they were headed to collapse, and a week later they’re dead. That is going to reinforce

November 1–2, 2011

107 of 282

people’s anxiety about firms that are wholesale funded without any obvious lender-of-last-resort
support from the central bank. I think as long as other firms stay out of trouble, it’s not an issue,
but if they get into trouble, people may actually pull back faster as a consequence.
And the third thing, of course, is that this was triggered in part by, as Brian mentioned,
European sovereign debt exposure. To the extent that things in Europe deteriorate, other firms
are viewed as having exposure to Europe, and that’s another aspect of this. But so far we would
say, and I think Brian and I would both agree, that the selloff in the market today really has very
little to do with MF Global.
MR. FISHER. I would add a fourth factor, which is humility versus arrogance and
balanced risk. The principals involved here were extremely arrogant, taking the positions that
they had, and were imbalanced in terms of their judiciousness of risks, and I think the markets
are well aware of that.
The second area of inquiry I have, Brian, if you look at your chart 1 and chart 8, is with
regard to the way Treasuries have moved and the initial way that corporate bond spreads
moved—remember those spreads are relative to an increase in the yields as shown in chart 1.
Can you separate out for me the Operation Twist impact versus the impact of Europe in terms of
influencing the way yields have moved? The question really deals with the efficacy of Operation
Twist—and mind you, we’re just starting this process—and trying to separate out the seesaw
effect and the whipsaw effect of what’s happening in Europe.
MR. SACK. Are you specifically raising the question of whether Operation Twist passed
through to the private borrowing rates? Or do you—
MR. FISHER. What I care about is whether it passed through to private borrowing rates.
That’s my priority—how it impacts the market for private debt. Because chart 1 doesn’t indicate

November 1–2, 2011

108 of 282

what one might have expected, but I care more about what happens in terms of private debt.
That should be our objective—affecting the real economy. I am curious as to your judgment at
this stage, and mind you, it is initial. And then, how are you able to separate out the seesaw
effect we have gotten from the standpoint of enthusiasm over Europe and then sudden
disappointment on the details?
MR. SACK. My assessment would be that Operation Twist put downward pressure on
Treasury yields, as I said in the briefing. All else being equal, the majority of that would have
passed through to private borrowing rates—maybe not the entirety of it, but the large majority of
it.
What actually happened on the FOMC announcement was that private borrowing rates
did not go down for lower-quality issuers, that spreads widened immediately. But I would
interpret that spread widening as more of a reaction to the concerns about the economy and the
pessimism that was in the FOMC statement that apparently surprised market participants, rather
than a lack of pass-through from the Twist action itself.
It wasn’t that Twist only affects Treasuries and nothing else. We do think that arbitrage,
all else being equal, would have pulled down the private borrowing rates. You see that in the
reaction of the 30-year swap rate. The 30-year swap rate, in terms of credit risk, is somewhat
complicated. It does have a credit risk premium in it related to the LIBOR that it is referenced
to. It is not the credit risk of lending to a firm for 30 years, but it is essentially the credit risk of
promising to lend to a bank that will be in the LIBOR panel for those 30 years. That means it
has a much smaller credit risk component than corporate yields. You can look at this and
basically, from the relative movement of swaps and Treasuries, assess whether Treasury yield

November 1–2, 2011

109 of 282

movements pass through to private rates, all else being equal, and then add on top of that the
effects on credit quality.
In terms of assessed credit quality, for sure it has been a seesaw. The market repriced to
much wider credit spreads through early October associated with pessimism about the economy
and concerns about risks emanating from Europe. It is the same pattern we saw with the
financials and their CDS spreads, and so on. Then, as sentiment improved—which was the old
theme of the briefing, as Europe seemed a little better and the data came in—that is really what
led to a substantial narrowing of the corporate bond spreads. But my guess is, as we seesaw
here, if this pessimism we have seen in the past two days persists, we will again start to see some
upward pressure on corporate yield spreads.
MR. FISHER. Thank you. And then, one last quick question. Do we know why the
Norwegians liquidated their MBS portfolio entirely on Friday?
MR. SACK. No, I don’t. We didn’t run down that story.
MR. FISHER. It might be interesting to get as much as we can. They are running a
$500 billion plus sovereign fund. They do interact with the central bank. I haven’t seen an
explanation yet as to why they would liquidate their entire MBS portfolio. If you can just follow
up, I would be very grateful.
MR. SACK. Yes, that would be very easy for us to ask about. We just haven’t done it
yet.
MR. FISHER. Thank you.
MR. EVANS. I thought you spoke Norwegian.
MR. FISHER. They didn’t explain it in Norwegian or English. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Governor Duke.

November 1–2, 2011

110 of 282

MS. DUKE. My question goes back to the impact on customers of MF Global, and this
question may not make sense because I wasn’t sure I understood the article I read just before I
came in here. But it was something about either clearinghouses or exchanges freezing customer
transactions, customers of MF. And then, I was remembering how some of the people who came
through here were really unhappy in the Lehman bankruptcy about their collateral getting tied up
in pieces. Is there anything in moving derivatives to central counterparties that we should be
aware of in connection with this?
MR. SACK. That is related to one of the three broad concerns I talked about: Would
there be uncertainty about the client’s ability to change positions? Would there be confusion
about what the status of their assets was or not? And as Vice Chairman Dudley mentioned,
without the quick transfer of the client accounts, it leaves this uncertainty. I don’t know enough
about the legal arrangements to answer the questions you raise. But how long that will take and
how transparent it will be in terms of when the customers will be able to reaccess their positions
is one of the big areas of uncertainty here.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. SIPC is on the case now as a trustee, so they are trying
to manage these accounts. But I think there is definitely some freezing of assets and people not
being able to execute this stuff.
MR. TARULLO. It’s CFTC rules, though, right?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. FTC rules on it for the FCM. And they were not a big
firm, about $40 billion or $45 billion in assets, but they were very big in the commodities space.
MS. DUKE. Is there anything in that that would cause potential customers of, say,
Morgan Stanley not to want to be customers of Morgan Stanley for just that reason?

November 1–2, 2011

111 of 282

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I think this is probably viewed as a pretty idiosyncratic
case. But, like I said before—wholesale funding model, dependence on repo, exposure to
Europe—our base case is that the contagion channel should be small, but there is some risk.
Brian, would you agree with that?
MR. SACK. Right, exactly. You have these relationships not only at FCMs but also
through prime brokers, and so on. When we saw some of the pressure on the financials, such as
Morgan Stanley, through early October, there was a lot of focus on the prime-brokerage
relationships. We talked to some hedge funds who were actually trying to figure out how to
hedge those exposures, so generally, that is a piece of the story about stress at any institution.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. If you feel we are going in the right direction rather than
seeming to go in the wrong direction in terms of market sentiment, you would probably be less
nervous about this.
MR. TARULLO. But, Bill, when you said it was idiosyncratic, did you mean
idiosyncratic to the underlying problems at MF Global?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes.
MR. TARULLO. But in answer to Betsy’s question, were another firm that was a
commodities merchant to get in trouble, there is no reason to expect that the exchange treatment
of collateral would be different for them than it was in this case, right?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. What was unusual in this case was the fact that in the
segregation of the customer accounts there was a shortfall, and that is gumming up the works, in
a different way than you would expect in a normal case.
MR. TARULLO. Are those the same accounts, or was the action on the Chicago
Mercantile independent of the private customers’ accounts?

November 1–2, 2011

112 of 282

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I don’t know. I think there was a press report about the
CME saying that they were aware of problems with the customer—
MR. TARULLO. So maybe it is related.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. —segregated assets, but I don’t have any details on that.
MR. TARULLO. If it is related, then it is purely idiosyncratic. If it’s not related, then it
gets to the way they conduct themselves.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Just to continue on the question of MF
Global, a couple of weeks ago, as you see on chart 12, there was—and I hesitate to call it a “run”
—but certainly a lot of pressure on Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs, which has eased. Then,
we get the first casualty with MF Global. My broad question, Brian, is: Are you more or less
concerned about financial instability now than two weeks ago? How is that trending?
MR. SACK. At best slightly more comfortable, but actually probably about the same.
As I noted, what happened a few weeks ago with Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs was the
same dynamic. Taking Morgan Stanley as an example, based on their discussions about the
firm’s exposures, I think market participants weren’t convinced that the firm actually had
problematic exposures, but what they were convinced about was the fact that if the market got
too concerned, they could put Morgan Stanley out of business because of their reliance on shortterm funding markets. I think that contributed a lot to the jitters that emerged in early October,
and it is the same dynamic that ultimately brought down MF Global. But I do want to emphasize
that MF Global is a very different case than a Morgan Stanley, in terms of the aggressiveness—
relative to its size—of how MF Global was positioned.
MR. LOCKHART. But their reliance on short-term funding is a lot different, too.

November 1–2, 2011

113 of 282

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Yes. Morgan Stanley, we believe, has a very large
liquidity cushion. The MF Global experience showed you that whatever liquidity cushion you
have can run off a lot faster than you expect. Morgan Stanley is starting with a much better
balance sheet than MF Global was, and they have been actually earning money. One of the
precipitating events for MF Global was that they took a very large loss in the most recent quarter.
That was really what started this thing spinning last Tuesday.
MR. LOCKHART. Do you see any dynamic of predatory market players essentially
gaining any victory with this one and moving on to the next most vulnerable?
MR. SACK. No.
MR. LOCKHART. No, we don’t see anything like that?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I don’t think this was about people shorting the CDS and
driving down the stock price. This is all about the fundamentals of the company; that would be
my opinion.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’ve got President Bullard and President Lacker.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. On MF Global—it became a primary
dealer this year, is that correct?
MR. SACK. Right.
MR. BULLARD. Are we happy with our expanded criteria for primary dealers? And
does this give you any pause about that new, more expansive definition?
MR. SACK. The new primary dealer policy just increases the transparency about the
requirements. There was no reduction in the requirements to be a primary dealer. When we look
at the primary dealers as candidates, there is an extensive review. It covers quality of
management, the quality of their systems, their financial health, and so on. But we are at a

November 1–2, 2011

114 of 282

disadvantage. We are not a supervisor of this firm. There is a credit review. They passed the
credit review. But that doesn’t guarantee that they can’t go downhill. As we see in the market
price and everything, they went downhill very quickly and very unexpectedly.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Yes, a question about MF Global, and then I want to follow up on a
question from President Fisher. MF Global is insolvent, I take it? Is that our best information?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I don’t think we know whether they are insolvent or not.
We know they can’t meet their obligations, but that doesn’t mean when they are all liquidated
that the value of the assets couldn’t be a lot greater than the value of the liabilities. We don’t
know that. The fact is that their long-term debt, which they have a small piece of, is trading at
about, last time I saw, in the 35 to 45 percent per dollar range, which suggests that the market
thinks that they are most likely to be insolvent. But we are not going to know for a while.
MR. LACKER. Okay. Do you view how it has played out as inefficient ex post?
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. It was inefficient in the sense that there was not an
orderly bankruptcy process. It would be much better if there had been a way to move the
customer accounts to new firms, so that they didn’t get trapped. It was messier than optimal. Is
it systemic or not? Fingers crossed, we hope not.
MR. LACKER. About Richard Fisher’s question about corporate debt spreads—this
actually came up at the last meeting. We are operating under this habitat theory, and there is this
question: Is 10-year corporate debt in the same habitat as 10-year Treasuries? Or is it in a
separate habitat, and its yield doesn’t move? And the data look like it is in a separate habitat, but
you are saying that there was some offsetting move and some expectation.

November 1–2, 2011

115 of 282

MR. SACK. Right, that’s what I’m saying. Equity prices went down sharply on the
FOMC announcement. If the story were just a preferred habitat, so that Operation Twist only
affected Treasuries and didn’t affect corporates and that explained the widening of spreads, that
alone wouldn’t cause a big decline in equity prices. Clearly the market read the FOMC
statement as more pessimistic than expected and repriced equities and corporate bonds
accordingly.
MR. LACKER. The question I want to ask is about 2-year versus 10-year corporates.
Do you view the impediments between those two markets as similar to the impediments between
2-year Treasuries and 10-year Treasuries? Or are they in the same habitat? And, in particular,
does the fact that a corporation can operate in its own debt make it different from Treasuries?
And would that short-circuit the effect you want to have on the shape of the yield curve in the
Treasury market?
MR. SACK. I would argue that what we have seen from the experiences with the Federal
Reserve policies is that there clearly is preferred habitat across the Treasury curve, across
maturities. I would imagine that, to a large degree, you would see some of that preferred habitat
pass through on the corporate side as well. I wouldn’t view corporates as a single asset class
where duration doesn’t matter. Are you asking if the degree of market segmentation is greater in
Treasuries than in corporates across maturities? That is a bit harder.
MR. LACKER. The intuition in habitat theory is the costliness or riskiness of arbitrage.
A corporation can scoop up its own debt pretty easily.
MR. SACK. Right. Maybe I’m missing the connection there, but—
MR. REIFSCHNEIDER. Another way of saying it is in the Treasury market we expected
there to be a twisting of the yield curve; we weren’t particularly surprised that the two-year

November 1–2, 2011

116 of 282

yields went up a little bit and then the longer-term yields came down. Ceteris paribus, we would
have expected to see a similar effect in the corporate bond market for the same reasons. I don’t
know if they did, but if two-year corporates did go up, that wouldn’t be at odds with what we
expected. Whereas, we would have expected 10-year corporates that have—
MR. SACK. I’m not sure what the corporate arbitrage is here. I don’t think there is an
incentive for them to equalize their corporate yields across the yield curve or something, if that’s
what you mean.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I wonder if there is a constituency for taking a vote on
domestic open market operations. [Laughter] Without objection. It is 3:15. Let’s take
20 minutes for coffee. Thank you.
[Coffee break]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Why don’t we recommence. The next item on the agenda is
the economic situation, and I will call on David Wilcox.
MR. WILCOX. 3 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be referring to the first exhibit
in the package called “Forecast Summary.”
A long time ago, when I was sitting at the breakfast table this morning [laughter],
I was reminded once again of the value of a supportive home environment. One of
my daughters attempted to bolster my confidence by helpfully observing, “Just keep
in mind, Dad, that they’re much more likely to remember you today for whether
you’re wearing a good tie and whether you’ve got any good jokes to tell. At least
Mom has picked out a good tie for you.” [Laughter]
In a departure from recent practice, the outlook for real activity that we provided
you in the Tealbook last week was not a marked downgrade of its immediate
predecessor. Indeed, as Bob Tetlow discussed in his briefing for the Board yesterday,
most of the spending indicators that became available during the intermeeting period
surprised us to the upside. The favorable news included better-than-expected retail
sales in September and a stronger report on orders and shipments of capital goods in
August, and even some surprising further signs of life in the nonresidential
construction sector.

3

The materials used by Mr. Wilcox are appended to this transcript (appendix 3).

November 1–2, 2011

117 of 282

In response to this news, as shown in the upper-left panel of the “Forecast
Summary” exhibit, the Tealbook forecast that we put to bed last Wednesday showed
slightly stronger growth of real GDP over the second half of this year and the first
quarter of next year than we anticipated in our September forecast.
On the surface, last Thursday’s GDP release also looked like it might be mildly
encouraging of a little greater momentum in the recovery. At 2½ percent, the
headline number was a shade weaker than we had forecast in the Tealbook, but the
estimated increase in final sales was considerably stronger than expected, while
inventory investment was lower—a mix that oftentimes in the past has augured well
for near-term production prospects.
As is shown in the upper-left panel, however, we did not mark up our mediumterm projection in the Tealbook and would not be inclined to do so in response to the
news in the GDP release either. A fair question is why not.
Let me proceed in reverse order, beginning with the GDP release. Part of the
upside surprise in final sales was in federal purchases—a source of strength that we
think, for obvious reasons, has no staying power. More fundamentally, however,
Thursday’s report showed a much lower level of disposable personal income in the
third quarter than we had expected in the Tealbook. While we think some of that
downside surprise might be transitory, we’re estimating that perhaps half of it might
persist, a factor that caused us to temper the extent to which we extrapolated forward
the recent strength in consumption spending.
Moreover, the broader pattern of the available data suggests to us that maintaining
our medium-term outlook is the best approach for now. The spending data provide a
little brighter perspective on the underlying state of the economy; at the moment,
however, other perspectives are not as encouraging. For one, the labor market still
shows no signs of an appreciable pickup. As shown in the bottom-left panel of the
“Forecast Summary,” the three-month moving average of private payroll employment
gains has backed off considerably from the pace that was evident around the turn of
the year; initial claims for unemployment insurance continue to hover just north of
400,000—a level consistent with only modest employment gains in the next few
months—and job openings and help-wanted advertising have edged lower in recent
months. Likewise, the data on industrial production are less suggestive of strength
than they might first appear. Overall manufacturing IP increased more than 4 percent
during the third quarter, but a chunk of that gain seems to have reflected a recovery
from the supply chain disruptions that stemmed from the earthquake in Japan. While
we cannot parse the upstream effects of the rebound in motor vehicle production with
any precision, we think that IP outside of motor vehicles and related upstream
industries decelerated noticeably during the third quarter and is likely to maintain that
slower pace during the fourth quarter.
A range of “soft” indicators remain remarkably downbeat. Most soberingly, as
shown in the lower-right panel of your exhibit, consumer sentiment—whether
measured by the University of Michigan or the Conference Board—has sunk once

November 1–2, 2011

118 of 282

again to the severely depressed levels it occupied during the most intense phase of the
financial crisis.
Finally, the factors we treat as conditioning variables are, on net, a little less
supportive of growth now than they were at the time of the September projection: the
dollar is a little higher; oil prices have moved up somewhat—especially the prices of
imported grades; and risk spreads had widened a bit as of the middle of last week. In
addition, the net movement in equity prices from Tealbook to Tealbook was small.
Since last Wednesday’s close of the Tealbook, financial market conditions have
remained unsettled. Given the volatility of the past two days that Brian noted, I
would hesitate to draw any inferences for the economic outlook at this juncture.
All told, therefore, we are inclined to brighten our assessment of the prospects for
economic activity only a little in the near term, and not at all in the medium term.
With the basic contour of the medium-term projection unrevised, we continue to
anticipate a recovery that is subpar by historical standards, with the unemployment
rate still above 8 percent at the end of 2013. As you can see from the middle-left
panel in the summary exhibit, the trajectory for the unemployment rate in our current
projection is virtually indistinguishable from the one we showed in September,
though I would hasten to add that this may be an aspect of the forecast with a
particularly short shelf life, pending Friday’s release of labor market data for October.
As we noted in the Tealbook, the gap in resource utilization remains wide. We
estimate that the unemployment rate is about 2½ percentage points above the shortrun effective NAIRU today. By the end of 2012, in our baseline projection, the
unemployment rate will have come down about a percentage point, but half of that,
we estimate, will have reflected the expiration of the emergency unemployment
compensation programs. As a result, the unemployment rate gap is still 2 percentage
points in the baseline projection at the end of 2013.
We think that there are a number of good reasons for expecting the pace of
recovery to remain subpar by historical standards. The housing sector—often a
locomotive of recovery after previous recessions—remains moribund today due to the
oversupply of houses, a huge backlog of homes in the foreclosure process, the
prevalence of underwater mortgage borrowers, and fears of further price declines—
factors that we think are unlikely to dissipate quickly. Access to credit remains
restricted. As Kathleen Johnson showed in her briefing yesterday, a stunning number
of banks are not offering mortgages to households with even the slightest blemishes
on their credit histories, despite the fact that mortgages extended to such borrowers
would be eligible for sale to the GSEs. A similar segmentation seems to prevail in
the market for credit cards as well. In the baseline forecast, we assume that credit
access improves only gradually from here forward. Pessimism appears likely to
remain a factor as well. Although households and firms have solid reasons to be
pessimistic and uncertain about the future—dismal job prospects, the situation in
Europe, and unresolved fiscal problems at home, to name a few—their malaise may
also, to some extent, be a self-fulfilling prophecy. An additional factor slowing the

November 1–2, 2011

119 of 282

recovery is the fiscal position of state and local governments. These governments
continue to face severe budget pressures that have forced them to cut back on their
spending and workforces, and we expect these pressures to ease only slowly.
A key consideration in gauging the likely speed of recovery is the health of
financial institutions. Banks and the shadow banking sector face severe challenges
even absent further shocks, and these challenges appear to have intensified over the
course of the year. Given the weaker economic outlook, the flatter yield curve, and
the prospect that shorter-term interest rates will remain near zero for some time,
financial institutions’ ability to earn their way to higher capital ratios now appears to
be noticeably more limited than it did earlier this year.
Another factor that we have wrestled with, and that Governor Raskin noted in a
recent speech, is the possibility that the current settings on the monetary dials may be
generating less support for real activity than would normally be the case. For
example, the restricted access to credit probably means that many households and
bank-dependent firms cannot take advantage of low interest rates to the degree that
they would have prior to the recession. And heightened uncertainty about the outlook
has probably decreased the responsiveness of all forms of investment, including
outlays for consumer durable goods, to low interest rates.
Although we suspect that the force of monetary policy is attenuated at present, we
also think that it is not blunted entirely. In particular, we hope and suspect that the
stimulus imparted by monetary accommodation through increases in wealth and the
depreciation of the dollar is probably about normal at present, and these two channels
are important. In FRB/US, for example, they account for roughly two-thirds of the
overall stimulus provided by an easing in the stance of monetary policy. In the case
of depreciation effects, the recent declines in the foreign exchange value of the dollar
have clearly stimulated production in the manufacturing sector, and further
depreciation would presumably raise global demand for U.S. products even more.
The remaining one-third—the direct response of spending to changes in interest
rates—may not be working with its usual force, but it is not entirely shut down either.
Credit access may be restricted for many households, but it should not be impeding
the spending response to low interest rates of relatively affluent households. And
even for less well-to-do households, credit does seem to be available to support the
purchase of motor vehicles, so they too are probably responding to low interest rates
at least to this extent. Moreover, a limited number of households have been able to
refinance their mortgages and so improve their monthly cash flow, even if many
others have been prevented from doing so.
Down the road, we expect that some of the attenuation in the monetary
transmission mechanism will reverse itself endogenously as the recovery gradually
proceeds. In the absence of further adverse shocks, uncertainty about the outlook
should diminish. We continue to think that the financial accelerator will someday
kick in in a favorable way, with improved balance sheets and reduced uncertainty
feeding the willingness to lend of financial institutions, improved confidence of

November 1–2, 2011

120 of 282

households and businesses leading to increased spending and hiring, and a stepped-up
pace of activity bolstering the condition of the financial sector and easing the strains
on state and local governments.
But we think that all that is likely to be a process measured in years, not quarters.
In the meantime, you all will face the difficult question as to whether the possibility
that policy may be attenuated today implies that you should adopt an even more
aggressive posture or stay your collective hand.
On the inflation front, I have relatively little news to report. As you can see from
the upper-right and middle-right panels in the summary exhibit, our medium-term
projection is essentially unrevised from the September meeting, both for overall PCE
inflation and for the core. I will just briefly touch on two developments in the past
few months in this regard. First, the anticipated deceleration in import prices now is
more decisively evident in the data. Core goods import prices increased 2½ percent
at an annual rate in the third quarter, in line with our September projection, down
from 7¼ percent in the second quarter. Partly for that reason, we think, core PCE
prices also have decelerated. Indeed, last month, the three-month change in core PCE
prices converged back down to its rate of change over the past 12 months, with both
coming in at about 1½ percent. In other words, our outlook for core PCE inflation
survived the two price releases since the September meeting broadly intact.
The other point I would highlight has to do with energy prices. We marked up
our near-term projection for retail energy prices for two reasons. First, crude oil
prices came in a little higher than we had expected, especially for imported grades of
crude. Second, we have now taken on board the likelihood that the unusual oil supply
conditions prevailing in the midsection of the country are likely to persist for longer
than we had previously assumed. If our revised assessment is correct, the prices of
retail energy products like gasoline are more likely to be effectively keyed off of
higher-priced imported grades of crude for the next quarters than we thought earlier.
This adjustment to our forecast for energy prices accounts for the small upward
revision to our forecast for topline PCE prices in the first quarter, shown in the upperright panel. Steve Kamin will continue our presentation.
MR. KAMIN. I will not be referring to charts. Last week, even as millions of
children were eagerly anticipating Halloween, Christmas came early for equity
investors. Santa left them a package of new measures to address Europe’s fiscal
crisis, beautifully wrapped in shiny paper bearing the seals of the 17 euro-area
nations. Once the package was unwrapped, however, it turned out that a lot of
additional assembly was required, many parts were missing, and no one was sure
whether, once the whole thing was put together and plugged in, it would work at all.
In fact, this week’s market movements suggest people are becoming more convinced
that it won’t.
The announced package contained three main elements. First, in order to bring
down Greece’s debt burden to sustainable levels, representatives of private creditors
have agreed in principle to participate in a debt exchange that would reduce the face

November 1–2, 2011

121 of 282

value of their claims by 50 percent, a much larger haircut than the 20 percent agreed
to in July. This would open the door for a new loan package for Greece, to be
provided by European countries and the IMF, which would provide critically needed
financing until 2014.
Second, having failed to assuage market concerns about European banks in July,
when the authorities released a stress test requiring almost no increases in capital,
European leaders have now agreed to more stringent standards. These include a
demonstrably higher minimum capital-to-asset ratio and a marking-to-market of bank
holdings of sovereign debt. Preliminary reports suggest banks will be asked to raise a
little over €100 billion in additional capital, with banks failing to raise these funds by
June of next year being forcibly recapitalized by national governments.
Finally, European leaders announced two complementary approaches to what is
arguably their most urgent task, providing financial backstops to vulnerable European
governments—especially Italy and Spain—to protect them from market contagion.
One scheme involves the European rescue facility, the EFSF, providing the resources
to guarantee a fraction—perhaps 20 to 25 percent—of the value of new government
bonds. In the other scheme, the resources of the EFSF would be used to take a firstloss position in a special purpose vehicle, or SPV, that would seek financing from
investors—including sovereign wealth funds from China and the Middle East—and
channel it to borrowing governments. In either case, the intent of European leaders,
having rejected both an enlargement of the EFSF and direct use of the ECB as a
lender of last resort to governments, is to leverage less than €300 billion in the
EFSF’s uncommitted resources into over €1 trillion in new lending capacity.
As Brian discussed earlier, that the European leaders were able to agree at all on
these measures came as a pleasant surprise to many observers, as it provided hope
that the leaders were taking their predicament more seriously. However, the next
several months present a series of risk events as European authorities attempt to
implement their proposals. The first such event unexpectedly materialized last night,
when the Greek prime minister announced a parliamentary confidence vote in his
government and popular referendum on the loan package, putting the plan in jeopardy
and causing European markets to plunge this morning. Looking a bit further down
the road, the haircut on Greek debt is intended to be achieved through a voluntary
bond exchange, partly in order to avoid triggering credit default contracts, but it is
questionable whether the deal will attract sufficient participation. By the same token,
many details of the financial backstop plans remain to be worked out, and the
participation of sovereign wealth funds from China and the Middle East seems mainly
wishful thinking at this point.
A second and more worrisome concern is that, even if the plan announced last
week is fully implemented, it may well fail to quell market pressures. Even under the
European authorities’ optimistic scenario, Greece’s net debt remains above
120 percent of GDP for the rest of this decade, and servicing that debt burden will
require continued draconian fiscal austerity measures. Thus, Greece may well fail,
again, to meet its performance goals and threaten renewed default. Were such an

November 1–2, 2011

122 of 282

event to trigger renewed flight from risk, it is doubtful that the new financial
backstops announced last week would suffice to protect Italy or Spain. These
arrangements might guarantee only a quarter to a third of the value of new bonds
issued by vulnerable governments, and in the midst of a financial panic, that may be
entirely inadequate to attract investors.
Accordingly, with observers well aware of these concerns, the most likely
scenario is that markets will remain jittery and funding restricted for some time to
come. This distasteful outlook is reinforced by the fact that, in response to financial
strains and the additional budget cutting that those strains have engendered, the euro
area’s economy has weakened even further in recent months. Banks have tightened
lending standards, measures of manufacturing activity have deteriorated, and business
and consumer confidence have slid sharply. We now expect euro-area GDP to
contract slightly this quarter and next—a markdown of 1 percentage point from our
September forecast—before edging up to a still-tepid 1½ percent pace by 2013. This
miserable performance should keep unemployment firmly above 10 percent and, by
making it even more difficult for economies to meet their fiscal targets, continue to
keep markets on edge.
Outside of Europe, the economic picture is brighter but by no means exuberant.
Aggregate foreign GDP growth rose from only 2¼ percent in the second quarter to an
estimated 3½ percent in the third, but that acceleration owed exclusively to Japan’s
recovery from its March earthquake and the associated restoration of global supply
chains. Recent data have been mixed. Japan’s economy has bounced back more
quickly than we had anticipated; Chinese GDP grew 9½ percent in the third quarter,
well above expectations; and the Canadian economy also expanded briskly.
However, third-quarter GDP growth appears to have moved down in some other
countries—notably Korea and Brazil—and the scant data for the current quarter are
fairly subdued.
All told, we now estimate that aggregate foreign GDP growth will fall back to
2¾ percent in the current quarter, reflecting the contraction in euro-area GDP, the
effects of this contraction on the export sectors of other countries, and the completion
of the bounceback of global production from the Japanese earthquake. Going
forward, projected foreign growth edges back up to nearly 3½ percent by 2013 as
Europe’s economy regains its footing and U.S. activity accelerates.
With the global economic outlook remaining relatively subdued, non-fuel
commodity prices declined further since your last meeting. By contrast, crude oil
prices in the spot market moved up a bit, but this was mainly in response to tighter
inventories, and oil prices remain below their earlier peaks. Thus, even as 12-month
headline inflation rates moved up in September to 3 percent in the euro area and over
5 percent in the United Kingdom, quarter-to-quarter rates of inflation in these and
other advanced economies continued to move down from their highs at the beginning
of the year. In the EMEs, a similar downtrend in inflation was interrupted in the third
quarter by rising food prices in some countries, but this uptick should prove
transitory, and we expect further disinflation in the region going forward.

November 1–2, 2011

123 of 282

Amid diminishing inflation pressures and economic growth that is too slow to
significantly erode resource slack, several major central banks announced further
stimulus measures during the intermeeting period. The Bank of England expanded its
asset purchase program by £75 billion (or 5 percent of GDP), while the Bank of Japan
expanded its program by ¥5 trillion (or 1 percent of GDP). The ECB held its policy
rate constant at 1½ percent but announced additional purchases of covered bonds and
brought back auctions of one-year money. In the EMEs, the pace of monetary
tightening has clearly diminished in the face of concerns about weak global growth—
notably, Brazil lowered its policy rate by another 50 basis points over the
intermeeting period, even as 12-month inflation breached 7 percent.
Against the background of weak foreign economic growth, exports grew at only a
4 percent pace during the second and third quarters. Import growth has been running
even slower, however, so net exports made a small positive contribution to U.S. GDP
growth of about a quarter of a percentage point. During the next two years, we expect
export growth to step up to an average of nearly 7 percent, in part as foreign growth
firms; the dollar also supports export growth, as even after rising a bit over the
summer, it remains well below its values in recent years. In consequence, the
contribution of net exports to U.S. GDP growth rises slightly next year, but this
contribution dwindles in 2013 as the pickup in the U.S. economy leads to faster
imports.
Deborah will now continue our presentation.
MS. LEONARD. 4 I will be referring to the package labeled “Material for
Briefing on FOMC Participants’ Economic Projections.”
Exhibit 1 depicts the broad contours of your current projections for 2011 through
2014 and over the longer run. As shown, you now see real GDP growth—the top
panel—to be appreciably slower this year than its pace in 2010 and then to pick up
gradually through the end of the forecast period. The unemployment rate—shown in
the second panel—declines slowly over the next three years, yet remains notably
higher than your estimates of its longer-run, mandate-consistent level. With regard to
inflation—the bottom two panels—the central tendency of your projections for PCE
inflation indicates a sizable, but transitory, increase this year before settling back
down next year and remaining at levels roughly consistent with, or slightly below,
your estimates of its longer-run, mandate-consistent level. Your projections of core
inflation generally remain at or somewhat under 2 percent over the forecast period.
Exhibit 2 reports summary statistics regarding your projections for 2011. Your
previous projections, collected in June, are shown in italics, and the current and June
Tealbook projections are included as memo items. The central tendency of your
current projections for real GDP growth this year, shown in the first column in the top
panel, is 1.6 to 1.7 percent, down more than 1 percentage point from your projections
in June. As shown in the middle column, you now judge there to have been
4

The materials used by Ms. Leonard are appended to this transcript (appendix 4).

November 1–2, 2011

124 of 282

considerably slower real GDP growth in the first half of 2011 than you or the staff
had previously thought, in large part in reaction to the BEA’s annual benchmark
revisions and the second-quarter data that were published after you submitted your
June projections. That information, together with subsequent data on economic
activity that were softer than you expected in June, led you to lower your implicit
projections for GDP growth in the second half of this year. As shown in the third
column, the central tendency of your second-half projections is centered on
2½ percent, down from about 3¼ to 3½ percent in June. As shown in the second
panel, the central tendency of your projections for the unemployment rate in the
current quarter moved up to about 9 percent, versus just over 8½ to almost 9 percent
in June.
Your expectations for overall and core PCE inflation are summarized in the
bottom two panels. The central tendency of your projections of overall inflation in
the second half of this year, shown in the right-hand column of the third panel, is now
significantly higher than in June; the central tendency of your projections of core
inflation, shown in the bottom panel, also moved up but by less.
Exhibit 3 reports the central tendencies and ranges of your projections for 2012
through 2014 and over the longer run. You generally see a weaker recovery in real
activity and labor market conditions in 2012 and 2013 than you did at the time of the
June meeting, but your forecasts for inflation have not significantly changed on
balance. In your forecast narratives, many of you indicated that these revisions were
the result of this year’s disappointing economic data, as well as a reassessment of the
strength of the headwinds facing the recovery. These forces include fiscal contraction
at all levels of government, ongoing deleveraging of household balance sheets,
depressed housing markets, weak consumer and business sentiment, and uncertainties
associated with the European situation and domestic tax and regulatory policies.
As reported in the top panel, most of you now expect GDP growth next year to be
between 2½ and 3 percent, followed by increases of 3 to 3½ percent in 2013 and of
3 to 4 percent in 2014. The Tealbook projections are within your central tendencies,
but they show a somewhat larger acceleration over the course of the forecast period.
Your write-ups indicate that you expect the expansion to be supported by
accommodative monetary policy, declining risks of a tail event, reduced commodity
cost pressures, strengthening household balance sheets, improving financial and
credit conditions, and exports.
Your unemployment rate projections are summarized in the second panel.
Reflecting the currently elevated level of the unemployment rate and your weaker
projections for economic growth, nearly all of you raised your forecast for the
average unemployment rate in the fourth quarters of 2012 and 2013. The central
tendency of your projections for 2012 runs from 8½ to 8¾ percent, and most of you
now project that the unemployment rate will remain centered around 8 percent in late
2013, about ¾ of 1 percentage point higher than your previous projections. The
central tendency of your forecasts for the unemployment rate at the end of 2014 is
6¾ to 7¾ percent—still well above your estimates of the unemployment rate that

November 1–2, 2011

125 of 282

would prevail over the longer run with appropriate monetary policy and in the
absence of further shocks (shown in the far right-hand column). The revisions to the
Tealbook forecasts of the unemployment rate over the projection period were roughly
similar to those you made.
Turning to inflation—the bottom two panels—the central tendencies and the
ranges of your projections for total PCE inflation in 2012 and 2013 changed little.
Most of you anticipate that headline inflation will fall back from the somewhat
elevated level seen this year to levels between about 1½ and 2 percent in each of the
next three years. The step-down in your forecasts reflects the further waning of
temporary factors that boosted inflation earlier this year—including higher
commodity prices and supply chain disruptions related to the events in Japan. In
addition, a number of you reported that you expected an extended period of economic
slack to restrain inflation. The low ends of the central tendencies for 2012 to 2014
are a bit below the central tendency of your estimates of the longer-run, mandateconsistent inflation rate. The central tendencies of your core inflation projections for
2012 through 2014 are about the same as those for headline inflation, as most of you
see the effects of the rise in commodity prices earlier this year dissipating. However,
the top end of the range of your projections of headline inflation is as much as ½ to
¾ of 1 percentage point higher than the top end of the central tendencies, suggesting
that a few of you have significant concerns about the possible effects of commodity
prices on headline inflation over the projection period. The Tealbook forecasts for
both total and core inflation in each of the next three years are at the lower end of
your central tendencies.
The central tendencies of your longer-run projections—detailed in the column to
the right—show that over time, the annual rate of increase in real GDP is expected to
converge to just under 2½ to 2¾ percent. The unemployment rate is generally
expected to settle between 5¼ and 6 percent, a somewhat higher upper bound than
projected in June. Your longer-run projections for total PCE inflation suggest that
most of you see PCE inflation between about 1¾ and 2 percent as consistent with
your dual mandate, the same as in your last projections.
The final exhibit summarizes your assessments of the uncertainty and risks that
attend your projections. As indicated in the four panels on the left-hand side, a
sizable majority of you continue to judge that the levels of uncertainty associated with
your projections of real GDP, the unemployment rate, and inflation are greater than
the average levels that have prevailed over the past 20 years. Your narratives
highlighted developments in Europe and the unprecedented nature of the current
economic cycle and extraordinary monetary policy accommodation as factors
contributing to this uncertainty. Of note, a few of you raised your assessment of the
level of uncertainty associated with projections of real GDP growth since June; in
contrast, a couple of you downgraded the level of uncertainty associated with
headline inflation from “higher” to “broadly similar.”
The panels on the right-hand side illustrate the balance of risks associated with
your projections. On net, most of you continue to view the balance of risks to GDP

November 1–2, 2011

126 of 282

growth (shown in the upper-right panel) to be weighted to the downside, while a
larger majority than in June see the risks to the unemployment rate as weighted to the
upside. Many of you continue to view the risks to inflation (shown in the two
bottom-right panels) to be broadly balanced, while the number indicating upside risks
fell and those indicating downside risks increased.
As the communications subcommittee recommended, the staff plans to include
this exhibit showing histograms of the responses regarding uncertainty and risks in
the SEP that will be published with the minutes of this meeting in three weeks. The
information contained in this exhibit previously had only been described in the SEP
text.
This concludes my presentation. Loretta Mester will now provide a summary of
the projections you submitted for the trial run.
MS. MESTER. 5 I will be referring to the exhibits in “Material for Briefing on
Trial-Run Policy Projections.”
As part of its exploration into various approaches for enhancing the Committee’s
communications, the subcommittee on communications asked FOMC participants to
provide information on their individual assessments of appropriate monetary policy.
More specifically, participants were asked to provide projections for the average level
of the federal funds rate target in the fourth quarter of each calendar year through the
forecast horizon of 2014 and over the longer run. These projections correspond to the
appropriate policy that participants incorporated into their November SEP
submissions. Participants who see the first policy firming occurring after 2014 were
asked to provide their assessments of the likely year of liftoff, as well as their
economic projections for that year.
I have divided the handout’s exhibits into those similar to the ones seen in the
standard SEP release (these are exhibits 1 and 2) and those that might be useful for
internal discussions (these are exhibits 3 and 4).
As shown in exhibit 1, participants’ funds rate projections have a central tendency
of 13 to 67 basis points in the fourth quarter of 2012. Beyond 2012, differences in
views about the timing and pace of tightening can be seen in the widening of both the
central tendency and the range of projections. By the end of 2014, the central
tendency for the funds rate is 13 to 250 basis points. Thus, participants agree that by
the end of the forecast period, the policy rate will remain considerably below its
projected longer-run value, whose central tendency is 400 to 450 basis points. The
longer-run projections represent the value of the funds rate to which the economy will
converge over time in the absence of further shocks. This longer-run value depends
on both the longer-run inflation rate, which the central bank can determine, and the
equilibrium real interest rate, which it cannot.

5

The materials used by Ms. Mester are appended to this transcript (appendix 5).

November 1–2, 2011

127 of 282

Exhibit 2 provides histograms of the trial-run responses. As shown, there is
somewhat less disagreement about the appropriate path of policy—at least over the
next couple of years—than the central tendencies and ranges might suggest. A large
majority of participants—11 of 17—see the funds rate remaining at current levels
through 2013, consistent with the Committee’s current forward guidance that
economic conditions are likely to warrant exceptionally low levels for the federal
funds rate at least through mid-2013. In contrast, by 2014, only 5 participants see the
funds rate still at current levels, and the range of projected values is quite wide. This
result suggests that, while participants are in fairly close agreement about their longrun objectives, they differ more significantly in their assessments of the economy and
about how monetary policy can influence economic outcomes.
As shown in exhibit 3, there is considerable disparity in views about when
appropriate policy would require the funds rate to move off the zero bound. The
modal year is 2014, but three participants project no change until 2015 and one
projects no change until 2016. In contrast, one participant judges that the appropriate
year of policy liftoff is this year, and three others, in 2012.
Participants cited several factors that informed their policy judgments. Those
favoring liftoff in 2014 or later cited slow growth and high unemployment coupled
with moderate inflation, high and persistent resource slack, and the effects of the zero
lower bound in limiting monetary policy accommodation. Those favoring an earlier
liftoff cited the need to forestall inflation pressures and financial and structural
imbalances, and the need to keep inflation expectations anchored. More generally,
some participants indicated that their views of appropriate policy included further
clarification of the Committee’s forward guidance, and some noted a relationship
between the Fed’s balance sheet and their funds rate paths.
The trial run provided information on economic projections beyond the standard
forecast horizon for those participants anticipating that the first funds rate increase
would occur after 2014. This allows us to look at participants’ projections of
economic activity aligned on the year of the first increase rather than on a calendar
year. This is a step toward gaining a better understanding of participants’ views of
the economic conditions that underlie their assumed policy paths. Participants could
find such information useful in their internal discussions of policymaking and
communications issues, such as clarifying the conditionality of the Committee’s
forward guidance.
It is important to remember that we do not know the exact timing of a
participant’s first rate increase—the collected information reveals only the level of
the funds rate in the fourth quarter of each year, and a participant could be
anticipating the first change in the funds rate early in that year or late in the year. So,
to get a sense of expected economic conditions and the expected change in economic
conditions at the time of the first projected rate increase, the top panel of exhibit 4
shows the central tendency and range of projections of real GDP growth, the
unemployment rate, and PCE inflation for the current year (2011), for the year prior
to liftoff, and for the year of liftoff.

November 1–2, 2011

128 of 282

As indicated, in the year prior to their first rate increase (the middle bar in each
forecast panel), the central tendency of participants’ projections is for economic
growth to pick up from the current level of around 1¾ percent to between 2½ and
3¾ percent; for the unemployment rate to decline from around 9 percent this year to
between 7¾ and 9 percent; and for total PCE inflation to decline from around
2¾ percent this year to a range of 1½ to 2¾ percent.
Then in the year of liftoff (the third bar in each forecast panel), participants
generally anticipate a slight acceleration in GDP and that the unemployment rate will
continue to move down—but the central tendency is fairly wide at 6½ to 8 percent.
The central tendency of the inflation projection in the year of liftoff is about 1½ to
2¼ percent.
Of course, while the central tendencies and ranges give summary information,
they don’t reveal the connections between an individual participant’s policy
assessment and his or her economic projections. The bottom panel of exhibit 4
displays some of that information in a set of scatter plots of pairs of variables from
each individual forecaster in his or her year of liftoff. It is important to note that
forecasters can have similar views of the economic conditions needed to spur liftoff,
but their views on the timing of when those conditions will be reached can differ
substantially. I’ve highlighted two points in the first scatter plot as an example. Each
of these two forecasters sees growth around 3 percent and the unemployment rate
around 8 percent when the fed funds rate moves away from the zero bound, but one
thinks this will happen in 2012 and the other thinks it won’t occur until 2014.
As seen in the first plot, several participants are projecting that the first rise in the
funds rate will need to occur before the unemployment rate falls to 7½ percent and
with growth at 3½ percent or less. As shown in the bottom-right plot, all participants
anticipate that liftoff will need to occur even though inflation is under 3 percent and
the unemployment rate is at or above 6½ percent.
These exhibits and those distributed on Monday are meant to illustrate how
information about participants’ policy expectations might facilitate the Committee’s
internal deliberations. If it would be helpful, the staff could collect and present this
information on an ongoing basis and assist in exploring approaches for disseminating
such information to the public through the SEP. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. These are some interesting ideas on
how to present the information on projections.
It’s been our practice four times a year to have a briefing on financial stability. Given
that we had a videoconference a couple of weeks ago and given how full the agenda is, we’ve
decided not to have that briefing. But Nellie Liang is here and Pat Parkinson is here, and if

November 1–2, 2011

129 of 282

anyone has any further questions relating to financial stability or wants to make any comments or
raise any issues, I hope you will feel free to do that. We’re ready for questions for the staff.
President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Yes. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I have a brief question
related to our discussion of nominal income targeting. Looking not just at the change in real
GDP in the year of liftoff—it might be interesting to look at the cumulative output gap of real
GDP or nominal GDP at the time of liftoff. So maybe we’re at minus 7 percent now—just
thinking about putting in the Tealbook estimates of potential GDP and then thinking about how
the forecasts of real GDP have evolved relative to that. I don’t know if I’m making sense.
MS. MESTER. Yes, you are. One thing is in the handout that we distributed on
Monday—we did deviations from the long run—an individual’s forecast of long run. You can at
least see how far away they are from where they think the long-run gap is. But I would direct
you to look at those, and maybe that’ll give you some insight.
The other thing we thought about doing is amending the one chart that is basically “Year
of Liftoff” in levels. You could imagine doing changes and then doing a central tendency and
the range of that. But derivatives of derivatives of derivatives get to me, although I read your
memo, and you have a third derivative in your loss function. [Laughter]
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. A lot of functions have a third derivative. [Laughter]
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Just a point for David and the international side—to tie them together. In
talking to the oil companies—which include Exxon; it has pretty good information—what they
note is that gasoline–diesel demand is off 2 percent year to date. But what has occurred is that
with the slowdown in European growth, there is less refinery output, meaning less exports to the

November 1–2, 2011

130 of 282

East Coast of the United States. As a result, they haven’t seen the decrease in motor gas prices
that they had expected. So there is this odd phenomenon. It is an international market. It’s
marked off of Brent, by the way, not off of WTI. But it’s a refinery concept. The slowdown in
Europe is actually affecting supply in the United States, even though demand has come up
somewhat. The same is true for av gas—that, in the parlance of business, the crack spread has
just not narrowed. The question is, when will it happen? But the pressures are moving in that
direction from a demand standpoint. I wanted to make that point.
On food prices, the entire structure seems to be supported by Chinese demand. Soybean
oil, for example, which is the most important—10 years ago, they imported 5 million tons; this
year, they’ll import 60 million tons. I mention that because, if you look at the headline PCE
number, Mr. Chairman, of that 2 percent, 1.7 percent was either gasoline or food—1.4 was gas
and 0.3 was food—and the rest, the core, of course, was flat, in keeping with what the trimmed
mean was forecasting, as I’ve said, at a six-month run rate.
For what it’s worth, I think you need to take note of that phenomenon. The international
side is definitely impacting, in both gas and food, what is happening here in the United States.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I have a question for Steve. I want to clarify something
you said. When you were talking about the bank capital issue in Europe, you said “asked to
raise.” I’m not sure I would characterize it quite that way—in the sense that it’s a shortfall based
on a 9 percent capital ratio, but they’re not really forced to raise it; they’re just supposed to get to
a 9 percent capital ratio.

November 1–2, 2011

131 of 282

MR. KAMIN. Oh, right. What I thought I said—but I might have erred in my reading—
was that they are required to raise it one way or another.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Okay.
MR. KAMIN. Their first option will be to go to the private markets.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. They’re not really raising.
MR. TARULLO.

They can cut assets, too.

VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. All they have to do is get to the right ratio at the end of
the day. They could shrink to get to that ratio; they can change the risk-weighted assets. I just
wanted to clarify that.
MR. KAMIN. Thank you—that’s correct. In their statements and in their discussion,
they are very eager that that target not be achieved through deleveraging.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. But that’s a loose EBA instruction.
MR. KAMIN. Exactly. That is, indeed, a loose instruction. And so they’re trying not to
have that be the case. They have talked about restricting dividends and things like that in order
to achieve that, but thank you for that clarification.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. My question is for Steve, but it’s a financial stability question,
which is: You highlighted the 50 percent voluntary write-down, and the CDSs presumably are
not going to be triggered; I wonder if you have any views on what that means for the CDS
market going forward? If you thought you were being hedged against sovereign debt default,
then not only for Greece but also for all your sovereign debt, all of a sudden it looks as though
that hedge isn’t a very good hedge. And if you think that sovereigns could play that game not
only for sovereigns but also possibly for bank debt if the bank was large relative to the size of the

November 1–2, 2011

132 of 282

country, you start wondering whether that contract any longer has viability. But all of a sudden
then, do you want to hold sovereign debt if you can’t hedge it? So it starts having implications
for the yields going forward. So I was wondering if you have views on that. Then I think this is
really a question for another time, maybe, that the financial stability people could pick up on.
But given how often the CDSs are cited, I wonder if you have any views on that—or Nellie or
anybody else.
MR. KAMIN. I’ll just start by saying that’s an excellent point, and it’s something that
people have raised as an issue. It is interesting that those same concerns came up after the July
agreement by Europeans to impose a haircut of only 20 percent on private creditors. And in the
event, that concern seems to have been shrugged off, but it’s come up again with this much
larger haircut. One could imagine a situation after this, especially if it goes through, where
indeed the role of CDSs could diminish.
MR. SACK. My sense is that it’s not being shrugged off as easily this time. There is a
lot of discussion about this, and it’s a serious potential problem. You see it in the prices. The
CDS spreads have come in much more or have come in even in cases where the cash spreads
have not, so I think you’re already starting to see some slippage in the prices. And if they are no
longer effective as a hedging instrument, it would have the implications that you raised.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Are there any other staff who want to comment?
MS. LIANG. I don’t think I’m going to add too much to that. That is an issue that was
raised very quickly, and so that is something we’re reviewing to see if there’s any measurable
effect on the cash spreads and the CDS. But as Steve pointed out, in July and last year, when
they talked about extending maturities, it appeared to get shrugged off, though the effects on

November 1–2, 2011

133 of 282

CDS values were a big concern at the time. This time we’re starting to see a little bit of an
effect, but it’s a hard question to answer. We’ll try to come back with something.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Other questions? President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. I want to turn to the trial run. I want to make a comment and maybe
even ask a question here. One of the things I find interesting about this is the difference in part
between exhibit 1 and exhibit 2. As Loretta pointed out, if you look at exhibit 1, it looks as
though there are huge spreads about what people expect. I think it’s important we remember two
things about that. One is that this is appropriate policy and not a forecast. I think that’s
important to understand what we’re doing. But also, as she pointed out in exhibit 2, the modal
forecasts here reveal a somewhat different story than you’d get by just looking at the first chart.
And the modal forecasts are much closer to what the Committee has been signaling through its
forms of forward guidance.
I think the other thing that’s important to remember about this is that the value of this, as
I see it, is not just as a snapshot in time, but it’s also to watch how this exercise would evolve
every quarter as the economy evolved, and therefore how this shape would evolve. And that’s
part of the information, rather than a point in time. It’s the evolution of that that would be very
revealing, I think, over time. So from my perspective, this could be a very valuable exercise for
the Committee to undertake.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. First time anybody ever estimated a Taylor rule on panel
data. [Laughter] Any other questions? Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. I think I drew a somewhat different inference than Charlie did, because
I found myself focused on panel B in exhibit 4, which had quite a bit of variance. If at some

November 1–2, 2011

134 of 282

level the most relevant piece of information for markets is when the Fed will begin to exit—if I
looked at that, I’m not sure I would be too confident in drawing any conclusions. Go ahead.
MR. PLOSSER. I think the question might then be to look at that in the same sort of bar
chart—in other words, looking at the modal numbers on that chart rather than just the spread and
central tendency.
MR. LACKER. Which chart are you talking about?
MR. TARULLO. I’m talking about the lower right-hand column of panel B.
MR. PLOSSER. Oh, I’m sorry. I misunderstood. I thought you were looking at
panel A.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Exhibit 4.B—PCE inflation versus unemployment rate.
MR. TARULLO. Very last page, very last panel, very last graph.
MR. LACKER. It would be hard to pick a consensus trigger out of that or a threshold. Is
that what you take from this?
MR. TARULLO. Yes. That returns me to the question I had earlier, which was whether,
if there were three kinds of scenarios, there would be more convergence. And this graph at least
suggests that there might not be a whole lot more convergence.
MR. LACKER. You can make them into three clumps.
MR. TARULLO. Maybe that’s right.
MR. LACKER. Maybe not. I don’t know.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Yes, I wanted to build on
something I had said earlier after Governor Tarullo’s earlier remarks. Frankly, when I speak
about the economy, I’m not sure people are all that interested in what I would do with the fed

November 1–2, 2011

135 of 282

funds rate if I were in charge—they want to know what I expect this Committee to do. And
when we use the SEP, I’m not sure we want to be thinking about it as conveying the full richness
of all of our views about the economy, as opposed to trying to use it to convey what we think is
going to be happening to policy tools.
I think it’s right to condition our long-run forecasts on optimal monetary policy. That
gives the people the right idea of what the long-run target is. Conditioning our forecast for the
fed funds rate and for inflation and unemployment on that—I don’t think that’s going to convey
the right kind of information to markets. Markets want to know where we think those variables
are going to go and how we think policy is going to respond to that and what we think policy will
be, as opposed to under what we think optimal policy should be.
MR. TARULLO. Narayana, there’s insight in that observation. How, in practical terms,
then, do you think one gets from the manifestation of everybody’s individual inclinations, which
this graph shows, on the one hand, to something resembling more of a consensus, which, I read
into your remarks, you would expect to actually be way less divergent.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I would be interested to see a different trial run where we
make a forecast predicated on what we think the Committee will do, what the evolution of
inflation, unemployment, and real GDP will be, on the one hand, and what the evolution of the
fed funds rate will be, on the other hand. And we’ll see—maybe I’m wrong. Maybe there won’t
be more convergence on that, but my suspicion is that there would be a lot more convergence.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. This is important information, though—what people’s
preferences are.
MR. TARULLO. Yes, I was going to ask you about that.

November 1–2, 2011

136 of 282

MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. It’s very reasonable for us internally to have that information.
I will say for myself, I don’t think it’s as important for the public. I’m all in favor of
transparency, but I have many vehicles to inform the public of my personal preferences over
these variables. I’m not sure that seeing them in this bar chart form is all that valuable. It’s
valuable for us to know—panel 4.B is really useful for us to know in our own internal dialogue.
But it doesn’t necessarily mean that’s going to be what we should share with the public.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Pages 3 and 4 were intended for internal use.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. And that’s very valuable, but when we go out and talk about
what we want to share with the public, what’s going to be useful in terms of shaping policy, I
think it’s more about trying to tell the people what we think the Committee is going to be doing,
as opposed to what we would do if we were in charge of the Committee.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I’m not sure I agree with that. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. No, I’ll pass.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I just wanted to follow up on that. There
is literature that looks at the forecasts by the group here. They treat them as unconditional
forecasts, and they look at whether it’s accurate or not. They forget all about the “appropriate
policy” assumption, and so I think there are a lot of subtle issues here. If you think the
Committee is off on the wrong path, you might forecast that inflation is going to go way down or
way up—way far away from target, for instance. And do you want that?
Other central banks have wrestled with this. They’ve done the projection based on the
market expectation, which is a reasonable compromise. Or they’ve allowed the staff forecast to

November 1–2, 2011

137 of 282

go out and have let the principals just comment on the staff forecast. So I’m not sure—this is a
difficult issue, I think.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Anyone else? [No response] Okay. We’re ready for our
go-round, and let’s start with President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll do my best to ensure that we
complete this meeting by nine o’clock tonight. [Laughter]
In our recent round of board meetings and contacts, the majority of directors and business
contacts in the Sixth District described activity as expanding at a slow pace. While most reports
were a bit more upbeat than before the last FOMC, a plurality of directors and their contacts
stated that they had revised down expectations for their firms’ performance. Two directors
representing the country’s second-largest retailer and largest airline expressed pessimism about
the business outlook, citing continuing uncertainty and weak confidence emanating particularly
from the political process. Overall, I would characterize what we heard over the past two weeks
as falling in a range from “still somewhat pessimistic” to “very cautiously optimistic.” In our
questioning of directors and other contacts, we asked about intentions to hire or reduce staffing
in the coming months. Although we heard some rumblings about reducing employment, the
modal response was no near-term intention either to hire beyond replacement requirements or
seasonal needs or to downsize staffing. Most firms seem to be holding steady as regards staffing.
In our formal survey of business inflation sentiment—this time, it involved
164 respondents—we detected less pressure on input costs than earlier in the year. Also, no
significant wage pressures were noted. However, the vast majority of respondents noted that
they intended to pass on at least some of any cost increase to their customers. Businesses in the

November 1–2, 2011

138 of 282

transportation sector noted that they have faced little resistance to surcharges to cover fuel cost
increases.
Turning to my sense of the outlook, Atlanta’s forecast is very similar to the Tealbook’s
through 2013. In the last year of the forecast horizon—2014—we depart from the Tealbook’s
trajectory and project flatter growth, reflecting the weight of fiscal drag, continued deleveraging,
and restrained consumer confidence. Our forecast has unemployment above the Tealbook’s
2014 projection and above the 6½ to 7 percent projections suggested in version A1 of the
Tealbook draft statements. At the same time, our inflation forecast stays in the neighborhood of
2 percent over the forecast horizon, while the Tealbook numbers stay south of 2 percent.
Therefore, we have assumed less slack in the economy than the Board staff.
To be more specific, I have a strong sense that the labor market involves much more in
the way of inchoate rigidities, inefficiencies, and behavioral impediments than fully appreciated.
Now, admittedly, I am basing this sense on a lot of anecdotal input, but here is some of what
we’re picking up. With respect to the relatively slow pace at which reported job openings are
being filled, we are in fact told that some vacancies are so-called purple squirrel openings: If a
purple squirrel shows up, the company will hire; otherwise, the company waits. [Laughter] My
sense is that this employer attitude will change if confidence increases and demand picks up.
But we are also consistently told of many skills mismatches. These mismatches are related to
hard skills in specific industries and job types, but we hear much more broadly of issues related
to soft skills, such as basic work habits, attitudes, and expectations. I frequently hear of jobs
going unfilled because a large number of applicants have difficulty passing basic requirements
like drug tests or simply demonstrating the requisite work ethic. As an example, one contact in
the staffing industry told us that during their pretesting process, a majority—actually, 60 percent

November 1–2, 2011

139 of 282

of applicants—failed to answer “0” to the question of how many days a week it’s acceptable to
miss work. [Laughter] Now, I am not suggesting that these are necessarily new phenomena.
But for a variety of reasons, employers seem to be paying much more attention to the quality of
prospective hires than pre-recession. We also hear that job requirements have been updated to
combine a wider spectrum of performance competencies, such as those that are required for
receipt of the ACT’s National Career Readiness Certificate.
There is anecdotal evidence of structural shifts. Companies of various sizes in various
industries report moving to increase their permanent part-time workforce, typically as a way to
manage uncertainties about health-care expenses and requirements. Now, I stress that these are
anecdotal accounts, and the effects are difficult to quantify. But combining these and other
inputs with the somewhat confusing participation data suggests to me that a great deal is going
on in labor markets that we don’t fully grasp. And I am not quite ready to argue that all this
means the structural rate of unemployment is permanently higher, but I am inclined to think that
clear progress in the labor market will lag economic growth more than usual. Further, I am
somewhat skeptical of the capacity of monetary policy measures to speed up the process.
Let me conclude with comments on the balance of risks. I see risks to growth to the
downside. Financial market volatility, slow jobs growth, and weak confidence make the
economy vulnerable to any number of adverse shocks. Regarding inflation, I judge the risks to
be broadly balanced, reflecting some ambivalence on the question of the amount of slack in the
economy. It is possible that the high unemployment rate reflects more slack than I have assumed
in my inflation outlook. But as my earlier recitation of anecdotal input suggests, the labor
market could be struggling under the weight of forces that have raised the natural rate of
unemployment for at least some time. I also think there is a chance that the influence of

November 1–2, 2011

140 of 282

commodity prices and other pressures on core inflation numbers could play out over a longer
period than I have assumed, and inflationary sentiment could be adversely affected as a result.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The markets seem to have initially
taken some solace in the Europeans having an outline of actions with no details and in U.S.
economic data consistent with growth that does not improve the employment situation. That
such diminished expectations can generate a market rally is hardly encouraging. As Brian
highlighted, it is even less encouraging that a referendum in a small country can offset much of
those gains. This highlights the fragile financial condition as we try to make our own forecast.
My forecast, like that in the Tealbook, provides little to celebrate—positive but weak
growth given the sizable output gap, positive but weak employment growth that leaves us far
from full employment, and inflation that remains below 2 percent. By mid-2013, I expect we
will still have an unemployment rate above 8 percent and an inflation rate well below 2 percent.
The Tealbook has a similar forecast. If these forecasts are right, we will be missing on both
elements of the mandate two years from now.
Financial market participants remain concerned. Liquidity in many markets is sporadic at
best. Financial institutions, worried about their own liquidity risk, are not supporting markets to
the same degree, making financial market participants less willing to take positions that may be
difficult to exit. My own interpretation is that in many markets, European and American
institutions that have been dependent on wholesale financing are pulling back from activities,
resulting in marketmakers less willing to make markets.

November 1–2, 2011

141 of 282

While there has been some increased refinancing activity, and the newly announced
HARP changes are positive, both the movement in mortgage rates and the fiscal willingness to
encourage refinancing remain too timid to have much macroeconomic effect. Our econometric
equations imply that we are well below the level of construction implied by fundamentals at this
time. And buyer concern about future prices and the tightness of credit conditions make a very
gradual return to normal in housing the most likely outcome.
My business contacts indicate widespread caution. Given the possibility that deficit
discussions remain dysfunctional and European brinkmanship remains the negotiating tool of
choice, businesses would prefer to defer hiring and investment decisions until there is more
clarity in the outlook.
Given the weak performance we have experienced and the weakness in our forecast, our
incremental policy is not the best approach. Critics of Japanese policymakers focus on a slow,
deliberate approach that led to very suboptimal outcomes, with 20 years of slow growth and
inflation below targets. If we do not start seeing more-robust improvement, then the likely fiscal
austerity and continued downside risk from Europe put such improvement at significant risk.
We will need to decide whether incremental policies are likely to return us to either element of
our mandate in the medium term. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Ninth District economy
continues to perform better than the nation as a whole. The overall unemployment rate in the
Ninth District is under 7 percent. Per capita income has risen slightly faster for the past two
years than in the nation as a whole. That said, the rate of progress within the District has still
been painfully slow. The unemployment rate in Wisconsin, Minnesota, and South Dakota in

November 1–2, 2011

142 of 282

September 2011 is essentially no different from a year earlier, although, as I mentioned,
markedly better than in the nation as a whole. The unemployment rate in Montana has actually
risen over the past year. Nor do I see any impulses for big changes in the near term. Ninth
District business respondents remain cautious, although I will not be able to achieve the level of
nuance that President Lockhart was able to obtain; their level of cautiousness is perhaps a shade
lower than in the fall of 2010, and it’s certainly a couple of shades lower than in the fall of 2009.
So the economy is improving, but the pace of recovery is distressingly slow.
My outlook for the real economy is consistent with what’s happening in the Ninth
District and is, consequently, not all that different from the Tealbook. The good news is that the
near-term downside risk—this sentence is out of date. I was about to say that the near-term
downside risk from Europe has receded some in the intermeeting period. I wrote this on
Saturday. [Laughter] I apologize. But my outlook, nevertheless, remains subdued. I expect that
real GDP will grow at 2.6 percent in 2012 and only slightly faster in 2013. This is too slow to
make rapid inroads into unemployment, and I’m anticipating that unemployment will be around
8½ percent at the end of 2012 and around 8.1 percent by the end of 2013.
Where I differ from the Tealbook is in my forecast for inflation. Core inflation has
stabilized in the past couple of months. Nonetheless, I am expecting that core inflation will
remain at or above 2 percent over the next two or three years. Obviously, the difference in my
forecast for inflation is predicated on a different view of slack. There are, I think, reasons to
believe that slack is large. As captured in the Tealbook, detrended real GDP in the third quarter
of 2011 is over 10 percent lower than in the fourth quarter of 2007. The employment–population
ratio remains well below its December 2007 level. But there are also reasons to think that slack
is smaller than these observations might suggest. Detrended real GDP and the employment–

November 1–2, 2011

143 of 282

population ratio have been disturbingly steady over the past two years despite variations in
monetary policy and fiscal policy. And a theoretical statistician looking at the recent data on
detrended real GDP or on the employment–population ratio would not be led to the obvious
conclusion that further stimulus would lead these time series to turn north.
As I mentioned at our last meeting, I think the comparisons with June 2004 are
informative. The capacity utilization rate is about the same as in June 2004. The short-term
unemployment rate, the fraction of the labor force that has been unemployed for less than
15 weeks, is only slightly higher than in June 2004. Along the same lines, I believe that it is
instructive to compare the matching efficiency of the labor market in mid-2004 with what it is
today. If you look at the vacancy–unemployment ratio in August 2011, it is about half of what it
was in mid-2004 during the midst of a jobless recovery. Typical estimates of the elasticity of the
matching function are usually around a half. So this fall of the vacancy–unemployment ratio of
50 percent from mid-2004 to mid-2011 should have resulted in a fall of the job-finding rate of
about 30 percent. And in fact, the steady-state job-finding rate is more than 50 percent lower
than in mid-2004. The matching function seems to have shifted in this sense, so that it is now
considerably harder for good matches to form than in June 2004. If this shift had not taken
place, the unemployment rate would be just 6.1 percent—only slightly higher than it was in June
2004.
None of these observations can be viewed as being more than suggestive. My point is
certainly not that I know for sure that slack is as low as in June 2004. But we need to keep in
mind that the events of the past four years may well have had significant adverse effects on the
supply side. This hypothesis is consistent with the uptick in core inflation that we have observed
over the past year. And those effects will worsen the tradeoff between unemployment and

November 1–2, 2011

144 of 282

inflation that we face in formulating policy, in the sense that any given level of unemployment
will lead to higher inflation. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. That’s all I have to say.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. After all of the bad economic news
throughout much of this year, it’s refreshing to have intermeeting data that surprise to the upside,
albeit relative to very modest expectations. The inflation data have also been encouraging, with
core inflation trending lower.
A key question for the outlook and monetary policy that we have actually been discussing
for a few years now is to what extent the modest growth we are seeing reflects a slowdown in the
growth rate of potential output. My trusty staff has reexamined this issue using a variety of
methods. The bottom line of their analysis is that the underlying growth rate of potential output
since the start of the crisis appears to be slower than we previously thought and still assumed in
the Tealbook. Specifically, we estimate that potential output will grow about 1.9 percent per
year, on average, over 2011 to 2014, and this slower rate of potential output growth primarily
reflects slower labor productivity growth owing to both a lower estimate of trend total factor
productivity growth and the subdued pace of capital accumulation by businesses. This finding of
slower potential growth obtains both from a careful bottom-up approach, similar to that
employed by the Board staff, and a top-down Kalman-filter approach to estimating potential
output. Looking further ahead, we estimate the long-run growth of potential output to be
2.2 percent. That’s 0.3 percentage point lower than in the Tealbook.
As a result of this revision to our estimate of potential output, the level of potential at the
end of 2014 looks to be about 5½ percent lower than what we expected on the eve of the Great
Recession. So this gets back to President Kocherlakota’s point about, if you were to extend a

November 1–2, 2011

145 of 282

line from late 2007, where that would be. But nonetheless, actual output remains well below
even that reduced level of potential. And our estimate of the current output gap is around
5 percent. That’s about 1 percentage point smaller than in the Tealbook.
The key factors underlying this large output gap are on the labor side. For example,
despite the steady growth in the working-age population, hours worked today are more than
5½ percent lower than in the fourth quarter of 2007. My staff’s analysis, along with the analyses
of many other economists in the System, consistently finds that this shortfall is primarily
cyclical, not structural.
My near-term outlook has real GDP growth of about 2.3 percent next year—and careful
study of the tables we got shows that that is the slowest rate of growth projected for next year
among the participants—and about 3 percent in 2013. I think, again, this slower rate of potential
growth that we are assuming actually explains the fact that my forecast is somewhat lower than
typical. With output increasing somewhat faster than potential over the next two years, I expect
the unemployment rate to end this year at about 8.7 percent and to be 8 percent at the end of
2013, which is roughly comparable to the Tealbook.
I think it’s important also to note something that Dave Stockton—David Wilcox—I don’t
know how I did that—[laughter]—something that David Wilcox pointed out earlier—several
hours ago. And that is, in our forecast, similar to the Tealbook, more than half of the decline in
the unemployment rate over the next two years is met with a decline in the natural rate of
unemployment. So the closing of the gap is actually quite modest.
Another question that we’ve been grappling with is, if the unemployment gap is so large,
why haven’t wages fallen more over the past few years? This question was taken up by several
leading economists at a recent symposium on U.S. wage dynamics hosted by my staff at the San

November 1–2, 2011

146 of 282

Francisco Fed. Although the participants came from different traditions and used varied
approaches, a number of common themes surfaced. There was general agreement that wage
growth has been firmer than expected during the recent recession and recovery. Still, none of the
participants concluded that this signaled an absence of slack. Instead, the participants pointed to
an upward shift in the skill composition of those employed as an explanation for the resilience of
real wage growth. They also cited downward nominal wage rigidities, which are more likely to
be binding in a low-inflation environment, as a potential explanation of the relative strength in
wage growth.
This situation is likely to continue, and my business contacts report little or no upward
pressure on wages. Similarly, I see no pressure for an acceleration in prices. Commodity price
pressures have come down, and inflation expectations remain well anchored. Furthermore, the
recent readings on core PCE inflation have come down from somewhat elevated levels seen
earlier this year, as expected. Over the past three months, core PCE inflation is about
1½ percent, and over the past 12 months, core prices increased 1.6 percent. Looking forward, I
expect PCE inflation to be around 1½ percent both next year and in 2013.
Let me turn to the risks to the outlook. I regard the risks to my inflation forecast as
broadly balanced, which clearly puts me in the minority, with about equal risk of inflation
running at 1 percent or at 2 percent next year. Despite the sizable swings in commodity prices
and the worst recession in decades, inflation expectations have remained remarkably well
anchored, and core inflation has been stable through this period. I will mention a paper that
Dave Reifschneider and two of his colleagues here at the Board did, looking at what were the
surprises of the past few years in terms of output, unemployment, and inflation. What was
probably one of the most striking results is how stable inflation has behaved over the past few

November 1–2, 2011

147 of 282

years relative to a variety of DSGE or empirical models or FRB/US. The big surprise, in some
sense, is that inflation has been so stable despite all of the shocks that we’ve had. For that
reason, I view the inflation risk as broadly balanced but the uncertainty as not larger than history.
The risks to the outlook for economic activity appear to be larger than average and
skewed to the downside. For example, our outlook assumes further improvements in credit
conditions and consumer and business confidence. Instead, the recent subpar growth and
elevated financial market volatility have, if anything, increased uncertainty. U.S. fiscal policy
also remains a source of downside risk, and progress in Europe on solving several difficult
problems, notably bank recapitalization and debt sustainability, has been halting at best. And
this was written on the weekend.
The recent uncertainty appears to be particularly pernicious in character. It’s not just
unusually large shocks to our models that I worry about, but it’s also the stuff that isn’t even in
our models—so Knightian uncertainty. And I have to say that purple squirrels were not in our
model, so that’s just one aspect of that. Let me see if I can read this: It’s not just the known
unknowns but also the unknown unknowns that seem to have persisted at a high level. For
example, the risks of a full-blown financial crisis in Europe are not well captured by our models,
and I have a hard time formulating precise risks to our economy in that scenario.
Finally, Governor Raskin and I are just back from a trip to both China and Japan, but I’ll
comment on what we heard in Japan that made me especially drawn to the Tealbook “Lost
Decade” alternative simulation. In fact, many of the people we talked to in Japan predicted that
the U.S. would soon, or within a few years, be talking about a lost decade for the U.S. In this
scenario, “persistently sluggish growth . . . has a corrosive effect on the supply side of the
economy.” Governor Raskin and I encountered people, as I said, who warned that these risks

November 1–2, 2011

148 of 282

were developing for the U.S. And based on their own agonizing experience, they stressed the
difficulties of pulling an economy out of a protracted slump. The large downward revisions to
U.S. potential that I mentioned earlier reinforce such concerns.
In summary, the outlook is one of sluggish growth and frustratingly slow progress on
reducing unemployment. Inflation looks to be trending to levels somewhat below my preferred
long-run goal of 2 percent.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My assessment of the economic outlook has
not changed meaningfully over the past few meetings. I do not see any evidence that the U.S.
economy is poised to achieve escape velocity anytime soon. We’ve experienced periods when
the balance of the incoming data had been negative. More recently, the news has been somewhat
better. I made it a point not to overreact to the weaker monthly data we saw this summer, and so
I’m not overreacting to the more positive numbers we’ve seen of late. The best-case outlook
seems to be simply muddling along. The recent, more positive data are still only indicative of an
economy that’s just treading water. The 2½ percent growth rates we’re looking at over the near
term are just not enough to make meaningful headway into the substantial resource gaps we see
in the economy today.
Commentary from my business contacts continues to support this assessment. Indeed,
there really wasn’t that much new in their reports this round. Overall, most say things are
moving sideways at this time. They just don’t see the demand in place to justify expanding
workforces or capacity. Many of my contacts said they were demanding contingency plans from
their staffs to slash expenditures 5 to 30 percent if needed, and I continue to hear many say they
are making plans to promptly cut spending at the first sign of a downturn in demand. These are

November 1–2, 2011

149 of 282

hardly the plans of business leaders who are contemplating an acceleration in their activities. I
expect more of the same. The ups and downs in the national data did show through in our
contacts’ commentaries about the automotive industry. The OEMs and their suppliers are
expecting continuing modest improvement in auto sales and production, but they don’t see things
taking off, either.
Everyone continues to be concerned about Europe. This report seems stale. The reports
from my staff, who talk to people in the Chicago markets—the report seemed stale on Friday, but
it seems a little fresh today. Prior to last week’s announcement, the financial-sector contacts said
that uncertainty and caution were freezing up some markets. That said, there was little evidence
of panic. Our contacts also said that they would view any European debt package with some
skepticism. They seem to be on target with that one. They question the Europeans’ ability to
execute whatever immediate plans they come up with, as well as the prospects for a longer-term
resolution given the impediments to growth in the region.
Turning to the macro outlook for the U.S., our growth forecast is similar to the
Tealbook’s. We also think that the reductions the Board staff has made to potential output are
plausible, and these reductions are not small. They cut nearly 3 percent from the level you
would get by simply extrapolating forward a modest 2½ percent growth trend from the beginning
of the recession—not as much as the 5½ percent growth that President Williams was talking
about. But even with this substantial reduction in potential, we’re still looking at large output
gaps and growth forecasts that leave resource utilization at very low levels throughout the
projection period.
To sum up, all of the incoming data and anecdotal reports point to an economy that’s just
sputtering along. We’re generating growth, but it falls far short of the pace we need given the

November 1–2, 2011

150 of 282

size of the resource gaps that must be closed. With regard to the two scenarios I discussed this
morning, in my opinion, the U.S. economy is entangled in a liquidity trap with amplification
from a large Reinhart–Rogoff financial crisis. We could be staring at a lost decade, the way
President Williams was suggesting from his comments on Japan. Even if this is only an
exaggerated risk—I don’t think it is—if we fail to take further actions, owing to credibility risks,
we end up with about as much credibility as the Bank of Japan has, I worry. Like President
Rosengren, I worry about too slow, incremental policies. I think we need to continue to add
more accommodation. There are alternatives in the Tealbook, A1 and A2, and I’m
uncomfortable with stasis. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Let me ask you, President Evans and President Williams—
I’m a little confused: If potential output is 5 percent lower, how can the output gap still be
comparably large?
MR. WILLIAMS. This was a comparison—I should have spelled this out a little more
carefully—of what our forecast or view of potential output was in 2007, before the recession.
Basically, it was that trend line and seeing how much the decline in the level of potential output
in the end of 2004 is relative to that in 2007. It’s not just in the past six weeks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. So what is your potential output relative to the Tealbook?
MR. WILLIAMS. It’s 1 percent because our output gap is 5 percent. The Tealbook, I
think, is 6 percent in Q3. So it’s just a 1 percentage point difference.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I was listening to President Evans. My summary of the
economy is not that we’re sputtering, but we’re loping along rather than galloping, to use a

November 1–2, 2011

151 of 282

Texan term. And I’ll basically say that things are not that much different, but they’re slightly
improved.
With regard to my own District, we continue to create private-sector jobs. We created
204,000 private-sector jobs year to date, and lost 41,000 government jobs. Twenty-three
thousand of those were lost in September alone, and yet we still have net job creation. I find it
interesting that there is a disparity between the private sector and the public sector, with the
private-sector job creation growing at a pretty steady 3 percent, but clearly we have an offset
from the public sector.
In the District, conditions in housing are improving. We have increased home sales,
lower inventories. Prices, however, are flat, somewhat stagnant. Our construction job growth
has been weak this year, but we’re seeing significant investment in multifamily units and very
robust demand translating into the price of rentals. Overall, price pressures are moderate in our
District; wage pressures remain subdued.
All three of our indexes—which we’re constantly working to perfect—in terms of
manufacturing services and retail, continue to point to continued economic growth in the next six
months. So from a District standpoint, we’re not quite in the parallel universe that President
Kocherlakota’s District is, but it’s pretty much the same story. We just have a higher
unemployment rate, but things are proceeding progressively.
From the standpoint of my business contacts and broader anecdotal evidence, the general
claim is that business is slightly better than what we read in the press. For example, one of my
business contacts is a large trucking company. In fact, it’s the largest trucking company not
located in my District, which runs 16,000 trucks—the largest in the country. They surveyed their
customers. Eighty-five percent of their customers feel good about the fourth quarter and feel

November 1–2, 2011

152 of 282

better about it than they did—that is, they expect better growth in the fourth quarter than they did
in the third, which I found different from almost every other economic forecast I have heard.
One of the key worries that seems to be vexing for the private sector, particularly retailers, is a
fear of understocking—that is, running under inventoried for the year-end season; based on last
year’s experience, there’s no question people are running extremely tight inventories. The real
issue is whether you’ll see a pop at year-end or not. In terms of looking at rail activity, trucking
activity, there appears to be a little bit of a pickup to hedge that risk, but it’s not very strong.
From the standpoint of overall cap-ex, the best way it was described to me is, people are
still finding that there is a benefit to the cheap money that we provided and abundant liquidity,
but the use of it is hampered by the constant concerns we hear at this table about fiscal policy
and regulation. And cap-ex is being deployed but “with a string.”
From the standpoint of inflation, I said earlier that the trimmed mean is still running at a
2.1 percent six-month run rate given that the BEA upward adjusted the last two to 2.1—but fairly
constant. We expect the headline PCE to trend in that direction.
Without exception, in every sector for the CEOs that I speak with, this money is being
used, and the conditions in the economy are being used, to drive additional productivity
investment. Whether you talk to the telecoms, or you talk to the manufacturers, or you talk to
almost any sector, given the uncertainty that surrounds fiscal and regulatory policy, there is an
effort to make sure that risk is reduced by driving productivity significantly through technology
investment—not a good picture for unemployment; maybe a good picture for inflation. I remain
concerned as to the efficacy of policy as it treats unemployment, and I still, despite my hawkish
reputation, am less concerned about immediate inflationary pressures.

November 1–2, 2011

153 of 282

I am concerned, however—and I mentioned this last time—about the effect that low
interest rates are having on pensions. I asked our staff to analyze the Fed’s own pension system.
I referenced that last point. The data reveal that the pension discount rate within the System has
fallen 100 basis points since the beginning of the year, and this would mean that we would have
to reserve another 9 percent. I’m not sure whether that would apply through the rest of the
economy. I heard cases, in terms of my anecdotal go-round with my CEOs, from an extra
reserve of $1.7 billion to several hundred million dollars, but there’s no question that anybody
who has a tail end of a defined-benefit program is going to have to recalculate the expense ratio
that they’ve imputed.
In terms of the insurance industry, I think this is something that we need to at least be
aware of. Insurance is the most basic savings product that most ordinary Americans do utilize.
I’m hearing increasing reports again that the profitability of the life insurance industry—I’m not
talking about the demonized health insurance industry—is coming under increasing pressure and
may result in a different sort of product that they are able to offer and disappointing returns to
those who use that as a method of long-term savings and also protection.
Finally, with regard to the banks, they continue to report about margin suppression. I
heard a new term. It’s a bit earthy, but I’m a Texan. The new term in local and community
banking is “cashtration,” meaning that they are being squeezed by too many deposits—it’s worse
than being squeezed—and not enough demand for loans. The margins continue to flatten, and
basically, in the words of Jamie Dimon, they’re being crushed.
Let me make one last comment. I really don’t see a need for change in policy at this
juncture. If anything, the conditions are slightly better than they were the last time we met, and

November 1–2, 2011

154 of 282

I’ll talk more about that in the next round. So, Mr. Chairman, that is the extent of my report.
Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. For the first time since last March, I’ve
been encouraged by some of the economic news that we got during the intermeeting period.
That news has lessened the odds of another recession, but with so many indicators still weak, the
bit of good news we received hasn’t been sufficient to change my baseline outlook beyond this
year, and I’ll explain the basis of this assessment.
Like the Tealbook, since our last meeting I have edged up my forecast for GDP growth in
2011 but otherwise left my growth forecast essentially unchanged. From the fourth quarter of
this year onward, I expect GDP to grow at a moderate rate of about 2½ percent through the end
of next year and about 2¾ percent in 2013 and 2014. With this growth profile, unemployment
will decline slowly by roughly ½ percentage point per year, leaving it at 7½ percent at the end of
2014.
In my judgment, there was enough strength in the third-quarter figures to make the risk of
recession lower than I feared at the time of our last meeting. I have also been somewhat
encouraged by reports from my business contacts that bankers have become more optimistic and
are a little more willing to lend. As one example, a builder of commercial properties reported
that he is now starting to see a renewed willingness on the part of bankers to extend loans for the
value of a project rather than the cost, allowing the borrower to take away cash, which then can
be invested in other projects.
Despite this good news, a range of concerns lead me to believe that the pace of recovery
is likely to remain slow over the next few years, with risks to my outlook that are still higher than

November 1–2, 2011

155 of 282

historical norms. Some of those concerns include, first, that the economy continues to see
considerable headwinds, including the ongoing woes of the housing sector, consumer
deleveraging, and cutbacks in state and local government spending. A second concern is that,
based on the most recent purchasing managers survey, Europe now seems likely to be headed for
recession. And third, the overall stress in financial markets seems likely to remain elevated until
the European situation is fully resolved. This stress is going to continue to impair credit market
functioning and hold back growth. I am also concerned that the continued high level of
uncertainty, which others have mentioned, is holding back the pace of recovery by restraining
business spending. Virtually every CEO I talk with has said that uncertainty is preventing some
projects from going forward. Among the uncertainties they mention are weak sales outlooks, the
direction of health-care requirements, the broader regulatory environment, and future tax rates.
That said, even though uncertainty is limiting the expansion of capacity, it doesn’t seem to be
detracting from earnings and profits. Many companies in my District are reporting record
earnings and profits, apparently because they have figured out how to manage their business to
stay profitable in this environment.
Turning to the inflation outlook, I have made little change to my forecast of inflation. I
continue to expect core inflation of about 2 percent from 2011 through 2014. As pressures from
energy prices continue to dissipate, the rate of headline inflation should slow to the core rate by
the end of next year. As others have mentioned, I saw some good news in the September CPI
and PCE releases. The headline rate of inflation continued to drift downward. Surprisingly, the
core CPI inflation rate dipped below 1 percent on an annualized basis, but the decline in core CPI
inflation is probably overstating the slowing of the underlying trend. The core CPI was pulled
down by significant reversals of apparel and auto prices, which finally dipped in September after

November 1–2, 2011

156 of 282

rising unusually sharply for much of the year, and these were likely relative price movements
that don’t tell us much about the underlying inflation rate. Consistent with this reasoning, the
Cleveland Fed’s median trimmed-mean and sticky price measures of underlying price trends
didn’t slow nearly as sharply as the core CPI did.
Still, I think the most likely outcome is for a gradual decline in inflation to about
2 percent, reflecting several forces. Critically, inflation expectations remain low and stable. The
inflation expectations model that we maintain at the Cleveland Fed shows that inflation
expectations over the next few years are still below 2 percent. The other important forces giving
me some confidence in my inflation forecast are for continued slow growth of labor costs and
reduced pressures from commodity prices.
Putting all of this together, while there was important good news in the economic
information received since the last meeting, the news hasn’t been sufficient to materially change
my outlook for the economy. I continue to think that the most likely outcome is for slow growth
and inflation stable at about 2 percent. While the risks to the economy now seem somewhat
lower than they did a meeting ago, they remain considerable, particularly with respect to the
European crisis. So I still see that the risks to growth are primarily to the downside, while the
risks to unemployment are primarily to the upside, and the risks to inflation still seem balanced
to me. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Economic activity in the Tenth District has
continued to expand moderately, and contacts generally expect similar or perhaps slightly faster
growth ahead. Manufacturing activity picked up in September and October. Inflationary

November 1–2, 2011

157 of 282

pressures have eased a bit and are expected to be moderate in coming months as the effects of
higher commodity prices recede.
Recent job growth in the District as a whole has been similar to that in the nation, but the
rate of growth continues to vary widely across District states. Energy and agriculture states have
expanded rapidly, while other District states have shown little growth, if any. Many contacts
express difficulties finding skilled workers, but wage pressures remain muted.
Energy drilling continues to boost economic activity in many areas of the District. Oil
production remains highly profitable, and natural gas firms continue to have easy access to cheap
capital. Continued rapid expansion of oil production in the central United States has put more
pressure on pipelines and maintained the sizable spread between U.S. and world oil prices. This
has caused some firms to ship oil by rail or even truck to coastal refineries rather than through
pipelines to the hub in Cushing, Oklahoma.
Land values in the District continue to grow rapidly, particularly in northern parts of the
region. Non-irrigated farmland values in the third quarter were up nearly 40 percent from a year
ago in Nebraska, about 20 percent in Kansas, and over 10 percent in the rest of the District. Over
the past five years, land values have increased over 100 percent in Nebraska and almost
80 percent in the District as a whole. Moreover, institutional investors are showing increasing
interest in making these land purchases.
With respect to the national economy, recent data suggest that the near-term outlook has
improved and the risk of the U.S. economy tipping back into recession has receded. Thirdquarter real GDP growth came in stronger than I expected in September, as the temporary factors
weighing on growth dissipated.

November 1–2, 2011

158 of 282

Over the medium term, my views are largely unchanged from September. I expect that
the economy will maintain the momentum evident in the third quarter and will gradually move to
a growth rate that will lead to modest reductions in the unemployment rate. Factors supporting
growth include pent-up consumer and business demand, exports, and monetary policy that is
highly accommodative. Nevertheless, several factors will weigh on growth over the next few
years, including uncertainty, ongoing deleveraging, an anemic housing market, and an increasing
drag from fiscal policy. In addition, the extended period of highly accommodative monetary
policy could lead to a buildup of financial imbalances that could threaten the longer-run stability
of the economy.
On a more positive note, the near-term outlook for inflation has improved. Inflation is
likely to recede over the next several quarters to 2 percent or less. With a gradually rebounding
economy, a depreciating dollar, and inflation expectations that appear to be well anchored, there
is little risk that inflation will fall much below 2 percent over the medium term. In fact, the
extended period of highly accommodative monetary policy, combined with our long-term fiscal
imbalance and the possibility of a rebound in commodity prices, poses significant upside risk to
inflation.
In summary, I expect that the recovery will continue at a moderate pace, with inflation
remaining near 2 percent. While the risks to output growth have become somewhat more
balanced, the risks to inflation remain to the upside. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The Eighth District economy continues to
expand at a modest pace. The Eighth District unemployment rate based on 16 metropolitan

November 1–2, 2011

159 of 282

statistical areas is somewhat lower than the national rate, at 8.7 percent. Payroll employment in
the District was approximately flat during the most recent reporting period.
Large firms in the District remain optimistic and plan to expand in some cases.
Profitability remains strong. Cash holdings are high. Many large firms have a strong presence in
Asia, and in almost every case, the growth strategy is based on Asian demand. In this sense, the
European sovereign debt crisis is not upsetting business planning or entering corporate thinking
as anything more than a general risk factor, and Asian growth is still considered mostly
unassailable at this juncture.
District agriculture continues to do well. Relatively high prices, even with higher input
prices, mean farm income will likely remain strong this year. As an indicator, some farm
equipment dealers are reportedly sold out through the spring of 2012.
Commercial real estate conditions are variable across the District. Residential real estate
continues to be lackluster in many areas. Banks continue to report very weak loan demand.
The national economy now appears to have avoided the recession scare that gripped
financial markets during the August time frame, even though the level of global financial stress
remains high. If a recession was developing during the September–October time frame, the hard
data would have been considerably worse than they were. My sense is that market expectations
outran actual economic developments. As it stands, I expect moderate growth during the
remainder of 2011, with reasonably good prospects for improved growth during 2012, provided
that significant financial stress can be mitigated.
The types of risk events that occurred during the past several months have apparently not
been of a variety that might cause households and businesses to pull back spending sharply and
set off a recessionary event. For households, the European sovereign debt crisis is worrying but

November 1–2, 2011

160 of 282

too distant to cause immediate changes in spending patterns. For large businesses, the EU crisis
is, again, very worrying, but much of their growth strategy is in Asia so that both growth and
profitability remain on track for them. For both businesses and households, the debt ceiling
debate only confirmed the political realities in the U.S. concerning the difficulty of dealing with
medium- and longer-term fiscal issues. Despite the contentiousness of the debate, there was no
real news about the U.S. fiscal situation.
The July 29 revisions to GDP, as we have noted here on several occasions, were indeed
significant and did lead to legitimate worry of a further slowdown or outright recession. But the
Q3 hard data did not confirm this view, so now I think we’re in a position to expect reasonable
but not stellar growth going forward.
In the meantime, headline and core inflation have not subsided to the extent that one
might have predicted based on the estimated size of the output gap. One reasonable
interpretation is that the output gap is not nearly as large as suggested by conventional analysis.
Reverse engineering the output gap using the method of Laubach and Williams—our colleague
just to my left here—for instance, suggests that movements in core inflation are indicating a gap
of about 2 to 3 percent, much smaller than suggested by other metrics. This makes a lot of sense
if one is willing to attribute some of the growth in the past decade not to fundamental factors but
to an unsustainable bubble in housing and real estate more generally. Indeed, this fits with our
rhetoric about the past decade very well. I think this hypothesis bears careful watching during
the coming quarters and years. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The incoming data since the last meeting
have generally confirmed my previous views about the outlook. Growth picked up a bit after

November 1–2, 2011

161 of 282

having slowed in the first half in response to several temporary factors. I was particularly
pleased by the strong growth in final demand in Q3. I think 3.6 percent was more than a lot of
economists expected.
Certainly, some of the rebound represented the passing of the effect of energy price
increases and supply chain disruptions that held down spending earlier in the year. I’m struck,
though, by the disconnect between household and business spending and the general
despondence expressed on surveys and in conversations with our contacts. Given the news and
commentary on the debt ceiling negotiations and European debt crisis beginning at the start of
August, I might not have been surprised if falling confidence had led to a general free fall in
spending in August and September, but instead, both retail sales and business fixed investment
made decent advances last quarter. Consumers and firms seem to be expanding their spending
based more on their individual economic fundamentals than on broader, more media-driven
worries. Having said that, these fundamentals are by no means ebullient, and there still seem to
be serious impediments to a more robust pace of economic expansion. I’ve talked before about
what seems to me to be restraining the recovery, and I don’t have much to add. I was impressed
with President Lockhart’s account.
The only thing I will add is that we continue to hear new anecdotal reports related to
these impediments, and I’m going to share two with you. One is from an employment agency in
West Virginia saying that unquestionably the biggest problem in hiring skilled and unskilled
workers was the inability to pass a drug test. Other firms in the area have reported the same
thing. We’ve gotten some reports, not quite as prevalent, outside of West Virginia. Many say
that the problem has gotten worse recently. I asked someone to look into this to try to get a sense
of whether this has become a bigger problem recently. Apparently the big increase in the

November 1–2, 2011

162 of 282

prevalence among firms of drug screening was in the late 1980s and early 1990s in response to
new, low-cost screening tests and some new federal regulations that were related to safety. So it
doesn’t look as if we’ve had a technology shock or rapid decline in the cost of drug screening or
anything like that. Now, illicit drug use, though, is more prevalent among the unemployed. Of
those who are unemployed or not working, 17.3 percent are drug users, compared with
7.9 percent of full-time workers. So forget the worries about full-time workers. The increased
incidence of unemployment by itself would increase the frequency of bad drug tests. One
suspects that usage increases the longer one is unemployed. You also expect the other
causality—that usage would cause a lower exit rate from unemployment, but I’m not aware of
any data on that, so I can’t really say I’ve been able to document that. There also may be a
regional component to this. Industries in which screening is more prevalent are mining, utilities,
and transportation, and they’re much more prevalent in the West Virginia economy. That might
be why it’s more of a problem in West Virginia. Now, usage doesn’t appear to be higher than
the national norm in West Virginia—we checked that. But we do hear widespread reports about
hard drug use, OxyContin and methamphetamine, in Appalachia and other rural parts of our
District—in particular, Appalachia. And there could be a demographic angle to this. Some of
our contacts say that drug use is more of a problem with the younger generation, versus alcohol
being the predominant problem among older workers. Obviously, demographic characteristics
associated with higher drug use are also associated with higher unemployment. Drug abuse and
the hardship involved in unemployment aren’t really laughing matters; it’s hard to pin this down
quantitatively, but it strikes me that there could be something meaningful there as a contributor
to impediments to labor market functioning.

November 1–2, 2011

163 of 282

I’ll pass on just one other comment, and this is from a business owner who notably—it
became quite obvious in our advisory council discussion; he’s a member of one of our advisory
councils—is a staunch Democrat. We asked at the very end of the council, “What’s your number
one worry about your business going forward?” And he said, “Obamacare.” He has a brewery
and a 56-employee restaurant, and he said he was thinking of “playing games,” as he put it, to
get his employees down under the 50 mark, where a bunch of things kick in. We’ve heard
similar concerns from others in our District, and this could be a widespread concern, obviously,
among small businesses.
So those are my two anecdotes of the meeting. I realize anecdotes are murky as
evidence. You have to look for an accumulation of these things, see if there’s a tenor to them.
But we’re struggling to understand what’s impeding growth, and what you can torture out of the
macrodata is fairly limited at times, so I think it’s useful to buttress our understanding with these,
judiciously interpreted. My best guess is that no one single problem is holding things back. It’s
a combination of a bunch of things that people have mentioned at many of our recent meetings.
My growth projection is relatively guarded, like the Tealbook’s. I think growth is most
likely to rise, but only gradually over the next few years. I wrote down 3½ percent for 2014, but
without much conviction. I put significant probability on a soggier path. I think growth could
well average more like 2½ percent for the next few years.
I’m less pessimistic on inflation, but I don’t see a lot of evidence of a decline anytime
soon. Headline inflation numbers remain high. The PCE figure for September was 2.9 percent
year over year and 3.3 percent over the previous months. It’s true that the core index was flat for
September, but that was largely due, as President Pianalto said, to volatile components, like
apparel and autos, that were high earlier in the year. I think it’s too soon to say we’re seeing a

November 1–2, 2011

164 of 282

downward trend in core inflation in the data so far. Futures markets prices for Brent crude
indicate only modest reversal of the run-up in prices that started in late 2010. As a result, I see
little chance that a decline in energy prices is going to help us out by dragging down the headline
inflation numbers and maybe passing through to core. I expect core and headline inflation to run
around 2 percent, maybe even a little bit higher, going forward. I think that’s an inflation
outlook that, according to our SEP responses, most of us would be pretty happy with. I, of
course, put down 1½ percent for my SEP response under appropriate policy. So I’m one of those
people with diverging forecasts and SEP responses.
All in all, the outlook for the real economy is disappointing, to be sure, but I remain in
the camp that ailments are largely beyond the power of monetary policy to correct. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, it sounds as though your drug use anecdote could
argue either way. It could argue for more stimulus to get more people off the streets, right?
MR. LACKER. Get them off the street?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Well, off their drug use.
MR. LACKER. I think a lot of people use in their homes.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Economic activity in the Third District has
picked up a bit since our last meeting. And although downside risks remain, I think tail risks
have lessened somewhat, and the risk of recession has diminished. But events in Europe today—
you never know. Wait until tomorrow; something else will happen.
Our Business Outlook Survey of regional manufacturing showed a rebound into positive
territory in October after two months of negative readings. The general activity index actually

November 1–2, 2011

165 of 282

rose from minus 30 in August, to minus 17 in September, to plus 8 in October. I think that’s a
remarkable swing in the period of three months, and part of that is related to what I mentioned
here last time—that in October, the survey week was the week of the S&P downgrade of the U.S.
debt, and the week of the September survey was the week of the hurricanes and floods in New
Jersey and western Pennsylvania, which had a dampening effect, so to speak, on the outlook.
But consistent with this improvement in general activity, both shipments and orders turned up as
well. Employment readings remain positive, although weaker than they were earlier in the
year—there’s no question about that. We did ask a special question on our October survey about
employment. The good news is that far more firms reported they had increased employment this
year than had cut staffing: Indeed, nearly half—46 percent—had increased employment, and
less than 25 percent had decreased employment. Less-good news was that most of that occurred
in temporary employment.
Contacts with directors and the business community echoed many of President
Lockhart’s comments about jobs and challenges. It’s not just mismatch; it’s also the problems
that—whether it be drug testing, which is a very common theme I hear. The other common
theme I heard is work ethic. An employer in the Third District who owns, I think, 60-some-odd
McDonald’s restaurants in southeastern Pennsylvania and New Jersey says passing drug tests,
passing literacy tests, and work ethic are the primary problems he has in hiring people, as far as
he’s concerned. It’s also true in the city. I have an anecdote from my wife, who attended a
meeting in the city of Philadelphia of a group that was engaged in trying to encourage both the
city and businesses in Philadelphia to hire more people. Unemployment in Philadelphia is quite
high, obviously, and our mayor, Mayor Nutter, in responding to this group, said, interestingly,
“We have over 1,000 job openings in the city of Philadelphia, and the problem is not that there

November 1–2, 2011

166 of 282

are not people hiring. One report is that we can’t find enough people who understand that
literacy, work ethic,”—again—“and drug testing are a big impediment to this city actually hiring
people.” He made a very impassioned plea about that, and of course, it turned into a discussion
of education and other things. So I think that’s not an uncommon thing to hear these days among
employers.
On the other hand, employers who are hiring high-skilled workers—engineers,
technicians, and computer people—are clamoring for employees. One person told me that when
they hire an engineer, they rarely hire him or her out of the unemployment pool; they’re actually
hiring the engineer from other firms, and that seems to be a very common theme as well.
Nevertheless, the weak indicators of employment in our manufacturing survey are
consistent with weakness in labor markets overall. Payroll employment in our three-state region
dropped over 1 percent on an annualized basis in the past three months, compared with nearly a
1 percent increase in the nation. In our District, state and local government downsizing has
played a big role in the reductions in overall jobs.
Residential real estate markets remain weak. Market delinquencies and new foreclosures
continued to improve in the second quarter, but coping with the growing inventories of
foreclosures remains a serious problem, especially in New Jersey. According to RealtyTrac, the
foreclosure process for loans foreclosed on during the third quarter averaged 974 days in New
Jersey, compared with 336 days nationally. The long process time in New Jersey stems from the
superior court decision in December 2010 to review bank foreclosure practices, and that was not
lifted until mid-August. In the meantime, most banks stopped filing new foreclosures in New
Jersey, and so we have an unusually high level of foreclosure, which will continue to burden
house prices, particularly in New Jersey, because of this process. In contrast to the residential

November 1–2, 2011

167 of 282

sector, commercial real estate markets seem to have steadied somewhat and even improved
slightly in the region. Indeed, in some submarkets of commercial real estate, rents have risen
and vacancy rates have come down.
Retail sales in the region were mixed over the past few months. Our contacts expressed
hopeful optimism for strong holiday sales but weren’t sufficiently convinced to commit much to
building inventories. Car dealers appear to be more optimistic. With supply surges, they have
been able to raise prices and sell cars without promotions. I also have a contact at a very large
New York retailer, and she reports to me that at this large store, retail sales have been
surprisingly good—which is consistent with the data we got—and that they continue to be good
going into October. And they are actually looking for a reasonably positive holiday season.
That suggestion is consistent with other traffic on transportation that’s been referred to. I have a
director of a company that both builds and leases railroad cars nationwide. They report that the
demand for railroad cars is very high and leases are high, and they’re raising prices on a fairly
steady basis.
The outlook is for continued modest recovery in our District. It’s nothing to get excited
about. They expect slow recovery in activity over the next six months but are not predicting a
recession. Contacts there say that they are waiting for more substantive and persistent signs of
growth before taking on any more risk.
On balance, the national economy appears to be weathering the heightened level of real
and financial uncertainty unleashed by the growing fiscal problems in both Europe and the U.S.
The data over the intermeeting period have come in somewhat more positive and are consistent
with our forecast that growth will strengthen after the temporary factors holding back the
economy in the first half of the year. So far, the economy, I think, is showing more resilience in

November 1–2, 2011

168 of 282

the second half than many anticipated. Third-quarter GDP, as many have mentioned, was quite
good relative to the dire expectations of August and early September. Labor market indicators
have stabilized rather than deteriorated as some had feared. Consumer confidence remains low,
but retail sales have been somewhat stronger than expected. And production and investments
continue to grow.
Overall, recession risks have receded considerably since our last meeting, but as we
know, the risk and uncertainties remain high. News from Europe has been the dominant driver
of financial markets over the intermeeting period, swamping the effect of Operation Twist, in my
mind, and more-positive underlying data on the domestic economy. The European fiscal
situation remains precarious, but some positive steps have been taken. However, it remains to be
seen, as has been reported, whether it will all hang together in some form or not. In the U.S., the
“supercommittee” deadline looms large on our fiscal policy, and the outcome of that will also
likely affect consumer and business confidence in the coming months. We’ll need to see
whether that is positive or negative.
Nonetheless, my modal forecast is that the economy is poised to grow just slightly above
trend, maybe, from 2012 through 2014. That suggests a growth rate of about 3 percent. With a
moderate pace of growth over that horizon, labor market recovery is going to be gradual, and it’s
going to be painfully slow and unsatisfactory to many people. The unemployment rate will
move down but very, very slowly.
I anticipate that headline inflation will pull back a little bit, with about a 2¼ percent
increase in 2012, and then focus around 2 percent from 2013 through 2014. But in my view,
that’s predicated on a somewhat tighter monetary policy than is in the Tealbook forecast. In

November 1–2, 2011

169 of 282

order to keep expectations of inflation well anchored, the Committee will likely need to
commence policy tightening before mid-2013. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you. The way I would characterize the outlook
is, we got a little bounce that we were hoping for. The positive of that is that the sharp drop we
saw in household and business confidence does not seem to have led to a pullback in hiring or
spending, but I think we shouldn’t get overimpressed by 2½ percent growth in the third quarter.
Some of the bounce was due to temporary factors such as autos, and the increase in consumption
was accompanied by a pretty big drop in the household saving rate, which may indicate that
there is actually some stress on household balance sheets. And finally, some significant
obstacles to growth remain.
In my mind, there are three key determinants of the outlook over the next few quarters.
The first one is Europe, and we saw earlier how powerful the contagion was back to the U.S.,
especially in terms of those financial intermediaries, like Morgan Stanley, that have very limited
access to the Fed’s lender-of-last resort function. If Europe goes badly, then there is a real risk to
the U.S. financial system; and then, by extension, to financial conditions; and then to the real
economy. So although the bilateral exposures don’t look so great, the actual consequence would
be quite severe. On Europe, I agree with Steve’s characterization that there is lots of assembly
required, probably a few missing parts, and no real assurance that it’s going to work in practice.
A couple of things I would note. The first thing about the Greek restructuring that’s
really quite interesting is that even with a 50 percent haircut, full participation of all of the
private-sector participants, optimistic assumptions on growth, and the fiscal austerity package
being implemented, they still end up with a debt-to-GDP ratio of 120 percent in 2020. Now, the

November 1–2, 2011

170 of 282

reason why this is happening is that as more and more Greek debt gets socialized into official
hands like the ECB and the IMF, the haircuts to the private sector have very diminished
consequences to the total Greek debt burden. So I think that really raises a question: Is
50 percent restructuring enough, or is this the first in a series of Greek restructurings? Or is
Greece ultimately going to default?
The second issue associated with the Greek restructuring that’s noteworthy is, it’s not
clear that this is being done in a way that actually makes other sovereign debt look more
attractive. You could argue that it makes it look less attractive because, one, you now have the
precedent of restructuring in place, and, two, as we discussed earlier, if the CDS are not
triggered, then you no longer have a way of hedging your sovereign debt. So I think in some
ways, this actually makes the rest of the European debt look a little bit less attractive. If you can
subordinate the Greek debt holders, the more that the ECB buys of Irish, Portuguese, Spanish,
and Italian debt, you’re essentially de facto subordinating those holders as well. And I think at
some point, they’re going to catch on to that.
The second thing I would say about Greece—we talked about this before: the bank
recapitalization. They have a €106 billion shortfall. But press reports indicate that very little of
this is expected to be met by new investor equity. In fact, most of it’s going to be done by
retained earnings, changing business model, and deleveraging. I think one of the real key
questions is, how does that deleveraging hurt economic growth—and then does that feedback
make it more difficult to make progress in terms of fiscal consolidation?
Lastly, there are two more issues with Europe—the next one is, does the EFSF actually
have enough capacity to do all the things that they need to do? The reason we have this
20 percent first-loss piece is that the EFSF has only €440 billion of capacity, and a lot of that

November 1–2, 2011

171 of 282

capacity is already spoken for in terms of Greece, Ireland, and Portugal. So you have a pretty
Rube Goldberg type of machine, and nobody really knows if investors are actually going to have
much appetite for this debt that has a 20 percent first-loss piece. And then the final thing, the
thing I think was probably the most disappointing regarding the European announcement—
there’s really no vision yet at all about where Europe is headed over the medium to longer run.
What’s the exit strategy of all of these programs? How are they going to enforce conditionality
in terms of fiscal consolidation on an ongoing basis? How do these countries reenter the market
and actually issue debt to private investors two, three, four years down the road? I’m pretty
pessimistic about what’s actually going to transpire in Europe. So that’s issue number one.
Issue number two is housing, and I think there are a lot of problems there. Obviously, the
first problem is the high loan to value. Mortgage holders are locked into high-coupon
mortgages, and that’s basically impeding the power of monetary policy to actually support the
housing sector and household consumer spending. The second problem is the slow pace of
foreclosures that you highlighted, which is bad in itself, but it also creates a greater incentive to
default because if you already know it’s—what was it, 397 days until the foreclosure actually is
ended?
MR. PLOSSER. In New Jersey, it was 900 days.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Sorry—900 days. You can live in the house for a long
time rent free before they actually catch up with you. Also, you have the problem of getting the
Real Estate Owned once it’s foreclosed back into the market. We have a very peculiar situation
right now where rents are rising despite the fact that we have a glut of unsold homes. And that’s
a really peculiar situation. Now, the good news, of course, is that the Administration is taking
another stab at helping high-loan-to-value households refinance. But as I read it, the program

November 1–2, 2011

172 of 282

seems pretty limited in scope, and the terms are not as generous as they could be. Also, the
Administration program is focused just on that one aspect of housing.
I view housing as really essential because if you stabilized housing and housing prices
did stop falling, not only would that be good for the housing sector itself in terms of provoking
more demand for housing, but I think it would also be very important for household wealth and
household confidence. So it could actually have pretty significant effects for consumer
spending. But I don’t think we’re there yet.
The last issue is fiscal policy. There are two real issues here. First, fiscal policy, in the
absence of policy action, is going to be turned sharply restrictive at the start of 2012. I think
we’re understating the potential significance of that. Second, we have policy dysfunction in
Washington, and that’s also important because it has an independent effect on household and
business confidence. In this respect, the outcome of the supercommittee deliberations is
important, not just for what they do or don’t do in terms of long-term fiscal consolidation—but
also, if they do something tangible, it will actually be good for household and business
confidence, and if they don’t, it won’t, because then we’ll just be on hold through the next
election.
My view is that we’re going to see moderate growth over the near term. But until these
three issues—Europe, housing, and fiscal—are addressed in a way that takes them off the table, I
view the risk as very much tilted to the downside. Now, if all of them were addressed positively,
I could actually see the economy surprising on the upside. And the reason for that is, a lot of
people are on the sidelines, holding back, because they’re uncertain about the outlook. When I
talk to businesses, especially small businesses, I actually hear a lot of people say, “I’m okay, but
I’m not doing anything right now.” So if we could just take care of these three problems, we

November 1–2, 2011

173 of 282

could actually have a pretty good outlook. But unfortunately, there’s not a lot of power in this
room to do much about it. My own view is, we should be highlighting these three issues, and,
especially on housing and fiscal, we should be pressing the Washington policymakers, both
publicly and privately, to do something about these things. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Three working hypotheses have guided my
thinking about the economic outlook. All three received support from the data during the
intermeeting period. The first is that growth during the first half of 2011 was significantly
depressed by transitory factors: sharp increases in the prices of imports and commodities and
disruptions in global automotive supply chains. That hypothesis is consistent with the recent
rebound in the spending data.
The second hypothesis is that those transitory factors also boosted consumer inflation.
Thus, with well-anchored inflation expectations and subdued growth in compensation, I expected
that as those transitory factors waned, inflation would subside to levels at or below the mandateconsistent rate. This hypothesis has also been confirmed by recent readings on consumer prices.
In fact, the prices of core goods have been practically flat, rising at an annualized rate of only
0.2 percent over the three months ending in September, compared with a rate of about
3½ percent over the prior three-month period. Meanwhile, services prices have been rising
steadily at a 2 percent pace over the past year. The latest three-month reading on core PCE
inflation is now back down to 1½ percent and seems likely to decline a bit further going forward.
My third hypothesis is that economic growth has only limited upside potential due to the
persistent headwinds that are restraining aggregate demand. Because the odds are so low that the
recovery will gather any real head of steam, unemployment seems likely to linger at dismally

November 1–2, 2011

174 of 282

high levels for many years to come. Incoming data suggest that spending in the third quarter was
somewhat stronger than I had anticipated, and the composition of growth may foreshadow
slightly stronger growth in the fourth quarter as well. That said, nothing in the data dissuades me
from the view that growth will gain momentum only gradually, and that view is also evident in
the Tealbook and in the consensus outlook of professional forecasters. The key factors holding
back spending are well described in the Tealbook and include unusual pessimism among
households about their future income and financial prospects, declines in the values of homes
and financial assets, still-elevated debt levels, and reduced access of households, particularly
those under water on their mortgages, to credit.
The daily readings on consumer sentiment from the Gallup and Rasmussen surveys did
point to some improvement over the past few days in the wake of Europe’s announcement of
measures to address its financial crisis and the attendant rebound in the stock market. I’ll report
tomorrow morning on how things look. But even with that slight rebound, consumer sentiment
has simply reverted to exceptionally low levels that were seen in late July.
Other drags on the recovery include persistent dysfunction in the housing and residential
mortgage markets and budget pressures that are restraining spending at the federal and state and
local levels. Moreover, incoming information points to a more significant slowdown in
European growth, a development that’s having spillover effects on the global economy and is
likely to damp the U.S. economic outlook.
Turning to risks to the outlook, I still see those risks as weighted to the downside,
although there’s slightly more balance than in our last meeting. Incoming data diminish the odds
that the economy is about to slip into recession. But the odds still remain very high, in my view,
that there will be negative spillovers from the European debt and banking crises, and I consider

November 1–2, 2011

175 of 282

this the number one risk affecting the outlook. European developments could still derail our
recovery, and I think this is a scenario that’s very well illustrated by an alternative simulation in
the Tealbook.
My long-standing concerns about the ability and willingness of European policymakers
to address their sovereign debt and banking issues effectively were reinforced 10 days ago, when
I attended the meetings of the G-20 governors and ministers and their deputies in Paris. I had a
chance to see, up close and personal, that the key players were still very far from having nailed
down crucial elements of the deal only days before their self-appointed deadline. Glimpsing
how the sausage was made was not at all reassuring. Of course, like many others around the
world, I did breathe a huge sigh of relief when the euro-area leaders announced agreement last
Thursday on a comprehensive package of measures to address Greece’s unsustainable debt
situation and the vulnerabilities of European banks and sovereigns, and presented a road map for
stronger coordination and constraints on fiscal policy. But I’m not at all surprised to see a
turnaround in market sentiment, and I fully expect that the road ahead will be long and will
involve lots of scary turns and steep cliffs along the way. As Brian noted, of course, spreads on
the debt of most peripheral countries barely budged, even after the agreement was announced,
and at this point, spreads on Italian debt have reached new highs.
Here I’m going to pick up on some themes that Bill and Steve mentioned, but in my
view, there are a number of reasons why substantial downside risks are likely to continue not for
months but for years to come. In the first place, Greece, Ireland, Spain, Portugal, and Italy have
all committed to further deficit reduction, and the adjustments called for by Greece and Ireland
are exceptionally large. Fiscal contraction on this grand scale, at a time when economic activity
in Europe is already weakening, will further undermine growth. From the perspective of

November 1–2, 2011

176 of 282

markets, this creates severe implementation risk. And as Bill and Steve noted, if you just take
the case of Greece, even with a 50 percent haircut, the troika plan to stabilize Greece’s debt-toGDP ratio near 120 percent involves very tough fiscal targets, which are quite likely to be missed
if growth falls only slightly short of the pace assumed in the analysis. Historically, large fiscal
adjustments have typically occurred in situations where higher real export growth, reflecting a
depreciation of the country’s real exchange rate, could compensate at least partially for fiscal
drag. No mechanism other than slow growth of wages and prices, along with structural
adjustments that tend to be difficult and slow, is available here to restore competitiveness.
A second concern of mine—and Bill mentioned this—is the potential for a European
credit crunch. The funding pressures currently afflicting European banks have already caused
them to restrict credit and to delever, and these pressures may intensify as growth slows, as
European banks experience pressures on their earnings and higher losses on their nonsovereign
assets, and as banks struggle to meet the higher capital standards called for by European leaders
and banking authorities. The leaders’ statement, as Steve and Bill noted, does stress the
importance of ensuring that capital raising not cause excessive deleveraging, but there is no
mechanism in place to prevent banks from shedding assets. Moreover, even with more capital,
European banks remain highly vulnerable to further sovereign debt problems given their
enormous exposures. So the soundness of the banking system can be assured only if the
sovereign debt issues are decisively addressed. Negative feedbacks between economic
performance, the health of the banking sector, and the default risk of sovereigns that stand
behind their banking systems create the potential for vicious downward spirals.
A third concern is that no matter how clever the arrangements to leverage the EFSF,
without substantial participation by the European Central Bank, the underlying funding may

November 1–2, 2011

177 of 282

simply be insufficient to cover a new Greek package, to backstop bank recapitalization, and to
offer credit enhancements sufficient to ring-fence Italy and Spain, given the enormous borrowing
needs of those countries over the next two years. To me, it’s highly questionable whether
investors, including banks, will be willing to buy Italian and Spanish debt at yields that don’t
threaten debt sustainability.
And finally, with respect to European politics, as the European leaders’ statement
emphasized, progress on fiscal integration in Europe is necessary to the success of the euro, but
exceptionally difficult politically. And the governments, as we can see in Greece and Italy,
already seem close to the breaking point.
In summary, my modal outlook is that the European leaders will succeed in addressing
these challenges, but only over a painful and protracted period. In the meantime, we’ll need to
monitor European developments closely and stay alert to the associated risk to financial stability
and economic growth.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I used the “Extended Tealbook Baseline”
forecast in my projections, but unlike the Tealbook and most of you, I see the risks to growth as
balanced—sort of. [Laughter] I can’t discount the potential for a really bad shock coming from
Europe. If rumors that someone has a plan to make a plan can brighten markets considerably,
then all of the nasty realities that are sure to unfold over time can’t be good for Europe or for us.
In fact, even without actual spillover from actual crisis conditions, the headlines so far have been
enough to swamp or at least mask the effects of our own policy actions. So that’s the obvious
downside.

November 1–2, 2011

178 of 282

But beyond the risks coming from Europe, I think there’s a good case to be made for the
“Faster Snapback” scenario. Admittedly, the faster snapback results have gotten progressively
less snappy over recent months, but I think there are elements of balance sheet repair,
confidence, and credit conditions that can be viewed optimistically. Beginning with balance
sheet repair, business balance sheets might be in the best shape ever. Debt has been reduced or
refinanced at ever-lower rates. Companies are awash in cash. Continuing and growing cash
mergers and stock repurchases signal that production-related uses of cash are not yet attractive,
but provide evidence of the temptation to employ that cash opportunistically. And banks that
have seen growth in C&I lending report that the borrowers are still keeping high cash balances
rather than using their own cash before tapping bank lending. Finally, commercial deposits at
banks continue to grow at an astonishing pace.
Even household balance sheets are in better shape than they appear. With the exception
of mortgage debt, consumer debt has been reduced significantly. Admittedly, much of the
reduction has come through charge-off and bankruptcy, but that’s exactly the point of
bankruptcy—a fresh start. And even though overall debt to income is still high, much of that
debt is in mortgages with long amortization schedules. So the burden of debt, the monthly
payments compared with net income, is at levels not seen since 1994. Delinquency rates on auto
and credit card debt are at the bottoms of their historical ranges, indicating that those who still
have credit are carrying it pretty comfortably. For mortgages, despite repeated calls for principal
write-downs, I don’t see that happening in any meaningful way, but foreclosure represents an
absolute write-down of principal in the same way that charge-offs and bankruptcy wiped out
other consumer debt. Mortgage modifications have leveled off at low but steady rates, and redefault rates on modified loans are improving. Rates of transition into delinquency status are

November 1–2, 2011

179 of 282

also improving, and the size of the foreclosure pipeline is beginning to gradually decline as
foreclosures in nonjudicial states have resumed and foreclosures in judicial states begin to trickle
through. Policy focus has finally moved from an emphasis on loan modifications to dealing with
the impact on housing values and neighborhood stabilization issues that result from large
numbers of distress sales. Lower mortgage rates, combined with an easing of credit standards
for refinance and purchase mortgages and responsible REO disposition, could actually speed the
final completion of household balance sheet repair. I’m optimistic that there are policy paths that
could accomplish this.
Finally, financial institution balance sheets are the mirror image of those of businesses
and households. Loans are down and deposits are up, leading to loan-to-deposit rates that are
lower than they’ve been in decades. Deposits have been used to pay off wholesale funding, and
all measures of liquidity look strong. Problem assets are steadily coming down, and those that
remain seem more heavily weighted toward long-term workouts than losses waiting to happen.
Capital levels are strong, and with credit losses posing less of a threat to capital, most banks
returning to positive earnings, and a regulatory lid on payouts of capital, this capital strength
seems more real than it did in 2008.
Turning, then, to sentiment, it’s true that measures of business and consumer sentiment
turned sharply negative, but it’s not as clear that the change in sentiment led to equally sharp
changes in behavior. A number of bankers I spoke with noted that from their perspective and the
perspectives expressed by their customers if they hadn’t listened to the news or read a
newspaper, they wouldn’t have noticed that anything had changed. Incoming business financials
still show strong or at least improving results. Businesses are cautious about investing and hiring
but are not necessarily pulling back. Business customers report already being fully prepared for

November 1–2, 2011

180 of 282

weaker or even double-dip conditions. And finally, consumer credit and debit transaction data
didn’t show any change that would correspond to the drop in confidence. It seems to me entirely
plausible that consumers and businesses that hunkered down in the face of the Great Recession
have not yet unhunkered and that they are still ready for the worst. If it comes, if pessimistic
forecasts are correct, it won’t really change anything in their behavior. On the other hand, if
there were somehow to be some sustained good results, such as strength in sales or improvement
in consumer income, I think that could translate into some positive change in behavior, and as
we’ve all experienced in the past few weeks, the good news doesn’t have to be all that good to
surprise you if your expectations are low enough.
Let me turn now to the final headwind that I can envision dissipating more quickly and
creating the condition for a faster snapback, and that’s credit conditions. The number one
financial problem faced by banks is a declining net margin. Many of them blame this on us and
the low level of rates, but I believe it’s due to the mix of assets on the balance sheet—
specifically, the dearth of good lending opportunities. Competition is fierce for C&I loans.
Banks are chasing them with rates, terms, and calling officers. When they find a good credit,
they’re willing to hold a much bigger piece of it. Appetite for commercial real estate loans now
follows the fundamentals, vacancies and rent levels, which will in turn follow the economy.
More banks are entering the auto finance business, where competition is also strong. Credit card
solicitations are picking up, even though the Credit Card Act has likely changed credit terms
permanently in this space. Banks are holding onto more of their mortgage production, even
though most of them are not willing to offer the full spectrum of credit eligible for GSEs or the
FHA. And credit is still tight for small businesses, especially those that have struggled over the
past few years. But there’s room for policy to improve credit conditions in both small business

November 1–2, 2011

181 of 282

and mortgage. Indeed, we have “blue sky” groups here at the Board thinking about both of
these, and if we can figure out a way to improve conditions in these two markets, then I think we
could cause this headwind to dissipate more rapidly.
So while I recognize that the economy is vulnerable to shocks and that there are many
potential shocks, including the looming potential in Europe, I think we’re closer than we might
realize to completing the debt burden cycle. And there are some possible policy actions that
could speed us closer to some potential positive shocks as well. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO: Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m going to jettison most of the notes that
I had prepared because someone has said most of these things—though not with the literary
allusions that were included in my notes—and I want to address instead labor market issues.
I think it’s worthwhile looking at the data rather than just relying on anecdotes, and as we
think about what’s happened in the labor market over the past few years, it’s important to draw a
distinction between what has happened in the past few years, presumably as a result of the
recession and its aftermath, on the one hand, and the very real long-term problems that we’ve got
in the labor market in this country, on the other hand. Basically, we’ve got to look at the delta,
and I think once we try to look at the delta rather than to absolute numbers or anecdotes that can
be drawn from one source or another, the picture becomes rather more clear.
There are a variety of hypotheses about why structural problems may be greater and
greater as the result of the recession. One that has been alluded to today is, we had a bunch of
bubble sectors where there was a lot of lost employment, and so one would expect that people in
those sectors would have difficulty becoming reemployed. In the mid-’70s, we had a very
serious recession with a lot of lost employment in the Midwest in manufacturing. There were

November 1–2, 2011

182 of 282

concerns then about whether there was going to be increased structural unemployment, but a
retrospective look suggests that that was not the case. There are always some sectors in a serious
recession that suffer significantly, and at least to date in the experience since World War II, we
haven’t seen a particular impact on long-term structural unemployment increases. Something
may be different this time, but we’ve got to point to whatever it is that’s different this time than
in the mid-’70s or early ’80s.
Second, we have the concern that because there’s been long-term unemployment of an
unusual and, indeed, unprecedented—since the data series was developed—nature, it seems
logical to infer that there’s going to be more structural unemployment there, that people are
going to have more trouble getting back to work. I think at some point, that is going to become a
phenomenon, but again, the data to date suggest or allow us to conclude, perhaps a tad
counterintuitively, that the probability of reemployment declined in about the same amounts for
the short-term unemployed and the long-term unemployed and has since risen in about the same
amounts for the short-term unemployed and the long-term unemployed. So, to date at least, this
hasn’t happened.
Third, we’ve got a Beveridge curve phenomenon, which I refer to as shorthand for a lot
of the points about vacancies and mismatch and the like. Economists at the Federal Reserve
Banks of Cleveland and San Francisco have done a very nice job of going back pre–data series,
pre–JOLTS series to try to construct from other data approximate Beveridge curves that, again,
cover the two serious post–World War II recessions. And just as we saw this time, the
Beveridge curves get pushed out, and each time, the Beveridge curve comes back. There’s still
debate apparently among the labor economists, including the very good labor economists at the
Cleveland and San Francisco Feds, as to exactly why that was, but it does seem as though, when

November 1–2, 2011

183 of 282

you have an awful lot of unemployment growing pretty quickly, there’s a generalized disruption
in labor markets, which makes employers more likely to wait longer to fill vacancies, in
particular. It may turn out, Dennis, that the purple squirrel phenomenon is more widespread than
people think, because there does seem to be some sense that standards for hiring go up during
periods of high unemployment since employers are saying, “Gee, there must be somebody good
out there somewhere.”
Finally, to the phenomena of a lack of literacy and of drug use, these are not new
phenomena. These are not deltas from the recession. We had these problems 25 years ago when
I was working on the Senate Labor and Human Resources Committee. I spent time in the city of
Philadelphia with a school-to-work program, in which the greatest problem identified was the
failure of individuals to understand they had to show up to work every day. We had that
problem 25 years ago, 20 years ago, 10 years ago; we have it today; and we’re going to have it
5 years from now. It is a real problem for the productive potential of the country. It is not an
argument for the proposition that structural unemployment has increased during and as a result of
the recession. I do believe that structural unemployment has increased some, and I was actually
a bit surprised when we went through all the data, that the data don’t suggest it has increased
even more so far.
The last point I would make, which I think is very important and gets to what John was
referring to earlier, is that at some point, all of this becomes a self-fulfilling prophesy. If there is
no aggregate demand, if there isn’t increased employment, if the productive facilities in both the
manufacturing and service sectors that are lying fallow now do not get back into use, the
productive capacity of the country and structural unemployment will go in the wrong direction.
We are fortunate in that it doesn’t seem as though we are there yet, but it also strikes me that the

November 1–2, 2011

184 of 282

tipping point may not be that far away. And I think we can’t continue to come here as we have
for the past two years, straining to see green shoots coming out of the ground—saying, “Oh, the
signs of spring are now here”—and therefore to say we need not take any more action, only to
see another snowfall the next month. I hope Betsy is right. I hope that the underlying structural
conditions are getting closer to the point where there’s more self-sustaining momentum in the
economy, but even if there is some of that, it’s not going to move us very far or very fast in the
face of an awful lot of cyclical unemployment.
What we should do about it—I guess I’m supposed to save that for tomorrow, so I will.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Raskin.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. The economy remains mired in the worst
slump since that of the 1930s. While recent readings on retail sales, capital goods orders and
shipments, and nonresidential construction have turned up, important indicators of near-term
economic activity remain downbeat. Business surveys point to continued caution, conditions in
the labor market have not brightened, and gains in industrial production, excluding the motor
vehicle supply chain, remain sluggish. These disappointing indicators likely reflect the fact that
the factors that have been restraining the pace of the recovery are still in place. The large
overhang of vacant housing units remains, credit availability remains impaired, and risk
premiums remain elevated. In the interest of time, I won’t comment on the European situation or
the housing situation or the fiscal situation. I also won’t comment on drug use among non–
purple squirrels. Instead, I just want to talk for a minute about consumer sentiment, which is
another factor likely continuing to hold back the recovery.

November 1–2, 2011

185 of 282

Confidence measures are at historic lows, and recent measures of confidence remain
exceedingly low, probably due to households’ concerns about low future income and wealth,
which tend to depress consumption. Despite last week’s report showing a 0.5 percent increase in
real consumer spending in September, a welcome surprise for sure, I’m not optimistic that
households are ready to be an engine of growth for this economy. For one thing, the September
increase was not accompanied by rising incomes. Rather, real disposable income edged down in
September and has increased only very modestly over the past 12 months. The resulting
downdrift in the saving rate to around 4 percent in the third quarter might be interpreted as a sign
that households are feeling optimistic again, but the lousy consumer sentiment numbers and the
lack of any improvement in home equity values suggest that this is very unlikely to be the case
and that consumer spending will be subdued going forward.
The lack of any meaningful increase in real incomes for the vast majority of households
suggests that many are feeling pretty strapped, even those who have jobs and are not under
water. This is evident in the spreading discourse about income inequality in the country, which
the Chairman has been asked about. Many of us are receiving personally addressed letters to our
homes from protesters, and I have the one that I received just yesterday. Page 1 reads, “End the
Fed.” This is typical because I do get one a day, and this is Occupy Muskegon. Many of the
Reserve Bank presidents, too, I know, are dealing with Occupy Wall Street protesters in their
cities and at their Banks. Regardless of how any of us feel about the merits of the 99–1 critique,
we have to acknowledge that this is not only a cost of a lack of aggregate demand, a cost of longterm unemployment, but also an additional factor that is affecting social cohesion, dignity, and
American optimism.

November 1–2, 2011

186 of 282

In sum, the pace of consumer spending is up, but the low level of sentiment, volatility in
the stock market, and tepid gains in employment and income projected for the coming years
continue to weigh on consumer spending and thus on overall economic activity. It’s hard to see
what string of events will eventually break this cycle, and as a consequence, I continue to expect
the pace of the recovery to be subpar. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Thank you, all, for a long but
productive day. We have a reception upstairs, followed by an optional dinner, for those who are
interested in staying around, and we will recommence in the morning at 8:30.
[Meeting recessed]

November 1–2, 2011

187 of 282

November 2 Session
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Good morning, everybody. Let me start with a summary of
the discussion I heard yesterday. I had more time than usual, so it’s a little bit longer than usual.
[Laughter] You may want to pull out a pillow or something.
Participants took note of somewhat better data over the intermeeting period, reflecting in
part the reversal of temporary factors that had depressed GDP growth in the first half. Final
demand in the third quarter was stronger than expected, and near-term recession risks appear to
have declined. There are some positive factors that may continue to support growth, including
pent-up demand, accommodative monetary policy, and balance sheet repair by both households
and businesses. However, most participants saw near-term growth as likely to be slow to
moderate, held back by continued problems in the labor and housing markets, low confidence,
financial market volatility, and fiscal restraint. With relatively modest economic growth will
come only a very slow decline in unemployment. The downside risks to growth appear to have
become somewhat less severe since the last meeting, but that assessment depends very much on
European developments. Potential output may also be lower than had been thought, and the risk
of a lost decade has risen. Inflation will moderate with commodity prices, although core
inflation has come down more slowly than expected. Most participants expect inflation to
moderate to 2 percent or below in the medium run, with many seeing the risks as approximately
balanced.
Households remain very pessimistic and expect little to no improvement in their financial
conditions. Income growth has also been tepid, reflecting in part the relatively slow pace of
employment growth. Notwithstanding these factors, consumer spending has recently been
stronger, and there is scattered optimism about holiday sales. However, some of the strength in

November 1–2, 2011

188 of 282

spending reflected lower saving rates, casting doubt on its sustainability. Some indicators of
labor market performance have been slightly better, but the job situation remains very difficult.
There was an extensive discussion of the degree to which unemployment reflects structural
factors. Employers complain about unqualified applicants, including those lacking basic skills,
and some will hire only so-called purple squirrels. [Laughter] Skilled workers are in high
demand. Reverse engineering slack from core inflation suggests that the gap is lower than
estimated by the Tealbook. On the other hand, many of the problems regarding the workforce
are of long standing, and the Beveridge curve estimates for earlier recessions show that the
pattern of vacancies and unemployment this time is not so unusual. Long-term unemployment
may ultimately lead to more structural unemployment, but we may not yet have reached that
point.
The housing market remains lackluster in most areas, except for some improvement in
multifamily construction. Foreclosures remain a serious problem, and there are long delays to
resolution. Mortgage eligibility conditions remain tight, notwithstanding some government
initiatives, and LTVs are high in many cases, both of which are impeding purchases and
refinancing. However, attention to factors affecting the housing market, such as REO
management, refinancing by high-LTV borrowers, and neighborhood stabilization, could help
this situation.
Reports on businesses are mixed. Some firms are pessimistic and cautious about the
outlook. There are continued complaints about economic and political uncertainty, including
uncertainty about fiscal policy, regulatory policy, demand, and the European situation. Hiring
plans are on hold, or firms are looking to use temporary or part-time workers. Capital
investment to increase productivity continues, however, benefiting from low interest rates. Input

November 1–2, 2011

189 of 282

cost pressures have abated somewhat, and wage costs are low. Profits and balance sheets are
healthy. Autos are seeing modest improvement in sales and production, agriculture and energy
are doing well, and there were some positive anecdotes from retailers and transportation firms.
Asian demand remains strong, though Europe is slowing. Low interest rates are increasing
pension contributions.
Fiscal policy is becoming more restrictive, with state and local governments continuing
to shed jobs. Much attention will be paid to the report of the congressional supercommittee; its
importance is not just the substantive outcome, but also the demonstration of whether the
government can work.
Financial conditions remain quite volatile. The recent actions taken by European leaders
to address their banking and sovereign debt problems were initially well received. However,
whether their actions will be successful in ending the crisis remains uncertain, as many details of
the plans remain to be worked out and there are questions about whether the resources being
devoted will be sufficient to provide adequate firewalls for major debtors. Sovereign spreads
continue to rise, and it is questionable whether European banks can raise private capital. U.S.
banks are doing relatively better, with improved capital and earnings, better asset quality, and
high deposits. However, loan demand is weak, and competition for good borrowers is keeping
net interest margins low. Liquidity has worsened in some markets, including wholesale funding
markets. Farmland prices continue to rise with agricultural prices.
Finally, inflation appears likely to moderate as commodity price declines are passed
through to the retail level. Core inflation is also slowing, though possibly more slowly than
expected. Growth in wages and benefits remains subdued, although wage data are affected by
skill composition and nominal downward rigidity. Inflation expectations are well anchored at

November 1–2, 2011

190 of 282

low levels. Measures of inflation trends, such as the trimmed mean or median, suggest relative
stability. On the other hand, if slack is lower than believed, downward pressure on core inflation
will be limited. Moreover, there is some ongoing pass-through of input costs, such as fuel
surcharges. Overall, most saw the risks to inflation as roughly balanced.
Let me stop there and see if there are any comments, omissions. [No response] Okay. If
not, let me make a few comments, always from the disadvantage of having to follow many good
discussions.
I led off my discussion last time with a review of the European situation, and many of
you have talked about it. I’m not going to go into much detail. I think there’s a lot of agreement
that the latest plan at least addresses the right issues, notably the Greek sustainability, the
banking system, and the firewalls for the major debtors.
There’s also been some attention to the longer-term solutions: How will they ultimately
achieve a degree of fiscal integration that will prevent similar problems from happening in the
future? I think the consensus around the table, and what appears to be in the markets, though, is
that there’s considerable question about the details and the firepower behind the plans that have
been put forward. I can add one small observation, which is that there’s a fundamental
misconception in the way they’re thinking about this, particularly with reference to the ECB.
The function of a lender of last resort is to provide unlimited firepower, unlimited lending
against collateral, and that’s what the ECB is doing for the banking system by lending against
sovereign debt. What’s happening now, though, is that the ECB is purchasing sovereign debt,
which is evidently a fiscal action and probably not appropriate for the central bank given the
credit risk associated with those obligations, but political opinion is preventing it from doing
what it would naturally do, which would be to lend to a bank or some facility that was using the

November 1–2, 2011

191 of 282

sovereign debt as collateral. The ECB is effectively the only institution that can provide
unlimited firepower and therefore can be a completely persuasive lender of last resort, and so I
think that until that intellectual confusion is sorted out, it’s not clear that this is going to work.
Moreover, it’s going to get harder and harder, of course, because Europe is slowing, and that’s
not an accident. Austerity, tighter monetary policy, a credit crunch, financial volatility—all of
those things are obviously not going to be good for European growth, and that makes the fiscal
issues worse and worse. This is a very troubling situation, and I can only feel that while this is
partly political, it’s also partly a question of appropriate conception of the problem and the
solution.
We are innocent bystanders, but we are very severely affected by what’s happening there.
In my dreams, I’d like to know what the U.S. economy could do if financial markets were in a
more placid state. Given the kind of volatility we’re seeing, though, that’s obviously a very
negative factor. So we’ll continue, obviously, to watch. The G-20 meeting is coming up. I’m
sure that the U.S. and other countries will press the Europeans for further action, but this is, in
some sense, the key issue for us.
Turning to the U.S. economy, I think the evidence is that the near-term performance has
been a little better than expected. Notably, we saw, as people have noted, good final demand in
the third quarter. Consumption was relatively strong. Total nonresidential investment, including
structures, grew 16 percent at an annual rate. That was fairly strong. We had good final
demand, less inventory billed than expected. All that is positive for the fourth quarter. Beyond
that, the September consumption reading was quite strong, putting consumption above the
average of the third quarter already. The ambiguities associated with the measurement of auto
production suggest that there will be less payback in autos in the fourth quarter. For a number of

November 1–2, 2011

192 of 282

technical reasons, I think the fourth quarter is likely to be a decent headline number again. So
that is good.
In the longer term, I think we continue to have legitimate concerns about sustainability of
the recovery. I’d note a couple of points. One is the point that was emphasized in the Tealbook
about the striking discrepancy between the recent relatively stronger economic news and the
continued weakness in sentiment. I think there’s a very interesting question here, which research
might be able to address at some point—that is, to the extent that sentiment has information in it,
is it because sentiment is what economists would call a sunspot, a random thing that relates to
how Lindsay Lohan is doing or something like that, which then in turn affects the economy? Or
is it reflective of the fact that consumers and businesses have much more micro information, and
that’s being aggregated in some way through sentiment indicators, which is not showing up in
the macrodata? It’s not clear.
I would note again that consumer sentiment remains very low, and there are indications
now that business sentiment has also weakened. President Plosser noted that the Philly FRB
business outlook improved a little bit last month but is still well below where it was earlier in the
year. We’ve seen very big declines in, say, the Business Roundtable CEO survey. We’ve seen
analysts’ expectations for capital-goods-producing firms drop quite considerably. So there is
clearly a sentiment issue in business as well as in the household sector. Sentiment is like the
stock market—it predicts about nine out of every five recessions. So I don’t think we should
overstate that, but it does remain a concern.
Another issue related to sustainability has to do with income and saving. This point was
made by a couple of people. I have some sympathy for Governor Duke’s view that balance sheet
deleveraging factors may be running their course to some extent or may be less powerful than we

November 1–2, 2011

193 of 282

thought. We have a discussion of that planned for January, as I recall. But one indicator of that
is the fact that household saving rates remain quite low, which would not be what you would
expect if they were making massive efforts to rebuild their balance sheets. Instead, it feels more
like consumption is being constrained by income rather than by balance sheet considerations.
Notably, the September saving rate was 3½ percent. Obviously, these numbers are frequently
revised, but nevertheless, we’ve seen relatively low saving rates, and we’ve seen very weak
income growth. In particular, for one illustration, the NBER, in picking its business cycle dates,
uses two indicators of aggregate activity. One is employment; the other is something called real
income less government transfers, which is a broad measure of income being generated in the
economy. That measure of real income less government transfers is basically flat since the
second quarter. It declined from the second to third quarters, and if the payroll tax cut extension
is not passed, then we’ll see further pressure on that indicator. So the sustainability of household
spending depends on continued generation of income.
That brings us, of course, to labor markets. I thought we had a very good discussion of
what’s going on in labor markets. It’s obviously important to think about these things at the
microlevel. I think I would express caution about overinterpreting anecdotes on this issue. We
talked about some of the social issues that have affected labor supply. I was just checking the
Statistical Abstract before I came in here, though, and if you check, you’ll see that drug use,
crime, and a number of other similar social dysfunctions surprisingly have declined in the past
couple of years and certainly are on a downward trend over a longer period. So it may be that
what’s happening there is that rather than those things causing unemployment, unemployment is
causing those behaviors, in which case that would actually be an argument for expansion rather
than for nonresponse. In terms of the sectoral components, Governor Tarullo gave some

November 1–2, 2011

194 of 282

interesting observations on that. I would note that the unemployment increases are very broadly
distributed between men and women, between college graduates and high school graduates,
which makes it difficult to pin this on, say, construction, if women or college graduates are
having the same proportional increases in unemployment as high-school-educated men, for
example. So I think there are still some very open issues there. I guess the last observation I
would make is the historical observation that between 1939 and 1941, after a decade of high
unemployment rates and all of the social implications of that, in a society that was much less
educated than we have today, unemployment dropped from 17 percent to whatever it was, 1 or
2 percent, in the war. Clearly, there is capacity for reemployment. That’s, of course, an extreme
situation, but sometimes demand can generate more jobs.
Again, to summarize, it looks to me as though—forecasting, of course, is always
difficult—the near-term numbers ought to continue to be moderately acceptable. But I think,
particularly given the uncertainties in the financial markets, there should be a very wide
confidence band around our forecast for growth in 2012.
A couple of words on inflation. Generally speaking, there was a lot of agreement that
inflation is under pretty good control for the moment, although perhaps not coming down as
quickly as some expected. I would note, again, the absence of wage pressure. The ECI just
came out for the third quarter, and the employment cost index showed total labor costs on a
quarter-on-quarter basis of 0.3 percent, which was the lowest in some time. And I thought that
was interesting in that among the costs included in that number are pension costs, and we had
some discussion about the effects of low rates on pension underfunding and the like. It is true
that pension contributions are up, according to the ECI, 9 percent on a 12-month basis. So there

November 1–2, 2011

195 of 282

has been some increase in pension funding. But if you think about that as part of the total wage
bill, you’re still not getting any significant increases in the cost of labor.
I would end this by offering a hypothesis I’ve proposed before, which is a suggestion that
we do need to think about the Phillips curve in an international context, as President Fisher and
the Dallas Fed have talked about before. In particular, there’s an awful lot of correlation
between growth rates across the world. That, in turn, drives globally traded commodities, and so
moderate growth in the U.S., to the extent that it feeds through, via a variety of mechanisms, into
growth in the emerging world, for example, tends to lead to higher commodity prices. It’s
interesting that the investment interest in commodity prices was sparked a few years ago by
some papers that suggested that commodity prices were pretty uncorrelated with stock prices.
That seems hardly to be the case anymore. Commodity prices have become a very sensitive
indicator of global growth expectations, the result being that even if growth in the U.S. remains
subpar, increases in growth expectations or even monetary policy ease can generate some
inflation pressure indirectly through this global commodity price nexus. So that, I think,
probably explains part of the reason why inflation has been less sensitive to domestic slack than
our traditional models would suggest and why there’s more sensitivity to global conditions than
is traditionally the case. The effect of that is going to make inflation more volatile and more
difficult to predict, more linked to global conditions, and that’s going to complicate our lives
going forward as we seek to manage both inflation and inflation expectations.
But again, near term, we’ve seen a little bit better data, and that’s good, but going
forward, I think we still face very significant uncertainties, not least those in the financial
markets. Any final observations or comments on the outlook? [No response] If not, let me turn
to Bill English to introduce the monetary policy go-round.

November 1–2, 2011

196 of 282

MR. ENGLISH. 6 Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be referring to the handout
labeled “Material for FOMC Briefing on Monetary Policy Alternatives,” which was
distributed earlier. The handout contains the policy alternatives as well as the
associated draft directives. There’s only one change, which is shown in blue in
alternative B, from what you saw in the Tealbook; I’ll come to that in a minute.
Including the various toggle switches, the staff provided a total of nine statement
options in the Tealbook this round—I’m told by the Secretariat staff that this is easily
our new all-time record. So staff productivity is high at least. [Laughter] To help
guide you through the options, I’ve reproduced the summary table that was included
in the Tealbook on the first page of your handout.
Turning first to alternative B, on page 7, the Committee may see the somewhat
stronger-than-expected economic data received over the period as having reduced the
odds of a new recession but may continue to view the still-modest underlying pace of
economic growth and the continued downside risks as warranting the accommodation
provided at your previous two meetings. If so, members may wish to adopt a
statement like alternative B, which contains no new policy action and uses language
similar to that of the September statement.
The first paragraph of the statement for alternative B would be updated to reflect
the recent economic data. The second paragraph would note the expected “moderate
pace of economic growth over coming quarters” and might indicate “downside risks
to the economic outlook” rather than “significant downside risks to the economic
outlook.” Dropping the word “significant” might seem appropriate if you see the
economy as more likely to be on a sustainable track than was the case in September
and think that the European leadership, on balance, has made progress in addressing
their banking and fiscal strains. The third paragraph would indicate that the
Committee was continuing the maturity extension program (MEP) announced in
September and maintaining the existing reinvestment policies.
In the fourth paragraph, the statement offers two options for the forward guidance.
On the one hand, the Committee could retain the reference to “exceptionally low
levels for the federal funds rate at least through mid-2013” from the September
statement. On the other hand, some participants might feel that a better way to
communicate the Committee’s expectations would be to indicate that the federal
funds rate was expected to remain exceptionally low “for the next six to seven
quarters.” The latter approach might be seen as desirable because leaving those
words unchanged from one meeting to the next would, all else being equal, maintain a
constant degree of monetary accommodation. However, if the economy evolves
about as expected, the Committee would need over time to reduce incrementally the
number of quarters specified in the statement, while a fixed date such as “mid-2013”
could remain unchanged in that case.
The statement would end by indicating that the Committee “is prepared to employ
its tools to promote a stronger economic recovery in a context of price stability.”
6

The materials used by Mr. English are appended to this transcript (appendix 6).

November 1–2, 2011

197 of 282

A statement along the lines of alternative B would be roughly consistent with the
market expectations captured by the Desk’s survey of primary dealers last week and
would likely have only modest effects on asset prices. Market participants would
probably note the deletion of “significant” from the reference to “downside risks.”
Alternatively, participants’ assessments of the economic outlook may suggest that
additional policy accommodation would be appropriate to promote outcomes that are
more consistent with the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate. Even after the monetary
policy steps taken in August and September, your SEP forecasts for the
unemployment rate at the end of 2013 are generally about ¾ of 1 percentage point
higher than in the June SEP, while your inflation projections for 2013 are little
changed and mostly at or below your estimates of the mandate-consistent inflation
rate. Moreover, as discussed yesterday, many of you see downside risks to economic
growth going forward.
Thus, the Committee might want to provide additional monetary policy
accommodation at this meeting. The Tealbook provided two ways of doing so—by
making a change to the forward guidance, as in alternative A1, or by implementing a
new balance sheet program, as in alternative A2. Participants may prefer alternative
A1 if they judge that greater clarity about the Committee’s policy intentions is likely
to provide additional accommodation at relatively low cost and risk. In particular,
policymakers may see a further increase in the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance
sheet as potentially making the timely removal of policy accommodation more
difficult, or as increasing the possibility that the value of the Federal Reserve’s
holdings of securities could fall significantly when interest rates move higher.
However, policymakers might prefer alternative A2 if, for example, they were
concerned that providing additional forward guidance about the federal funds rate
path a few years hence might not be seen by investors as credible given the likely
turnover on the Committee over time, and so might not have meaningful economic
benefits.
Turning first to alternative A1, on page 3, the first, second, and third paragraphs
of the statement would be similar to those under alternative B, though paragraph 1
would put more emphasis on the reversal of temporary factors in explaining the
somewhat stronger growth in the third quarter. Paragraph 2 would reiterate that there
are “significant” downside risks to the economic outlook.
The variants of paragraph 4 would reinforce the forward guidance provided in the
September statement in one of three ways. First, it could simply push back the date
through which the Committee anticipates that economic conditions will warrant
exceptionally low levels for the federal funds rate at least through mid-2014. Second,
as in 4′, it could indicate that low funds rates are anticipated through the end of 2014
and provide projections of the inflation and unemployment rates at that time to give
investors a sense of what economic conditions were likely to be associated with an
initial move toward tighter policy. Finally, as in 4″, it could provide clearer guidance
about the economic conditions that could lead the Committee to tighten policy by
giving numerical threshold values for the unemployment rate and projected inflation.

November 1–2, 2011

198 of 282

On the other hand, participants may prefer to provide additional accommodation
by further increasing the size of the Federal Reserve’s securities holdings, as in
alternative A2, on page 5. Paragraphs 1, 2, 4, and 5 under alternative A2 are quite
similar to those for alternative A1. However, under A2, the second paragraph would
indicate that the Committee expected only “relatively modest” growth rather than “a
moderate pace of economic growth” over coming quarters as a way to justify taking
an additional balance sheet action.
In paragraph 3, the Committee could choose to announce either the purchase of
$600 billion of longer-term Treasury securities by the end of next September or the
purchase of $300 billion of longer-term Treasury securities and $300 billion of
agency MBS by the end of next June. Participants may prefer to purchase only
Treasury securities because they see MBS purchases as risking an undesirable
distortion in the allocation of credit and as delaying the Committee’s return to an allTreasury portfolio. However, the mixed option might be seen as attractive if the
Committee thought that the ongoing weakness in the housing sector was a critical
contributor to the slow economic recovery and so wanted to purchase additional MBS
as a way of providing support more directly to that sector. In addition, some
participants may be concerned that purchasing another $600 billion of Treasury
securities would potentially have adverse effects on Treasury market functioning.
The staff also included in alternative A2 the possibility of a reduction in the
interest rate paid on reserve balances. As was discussed at your last meeting, such a
decision would need to balance the benefits of a modest reduction in money market
rates against the risk that lower rates could lead to disruptions in short-term credit
intermediation that could adversely affect the economy, for example, by accelerating
the decline in the size of the money fund sector. If participants thought that this
policy would be helpful, on balance, the Board could adopt such a reduction, and that
step could be noted in the press release containing the FOMC statement.
Market participants would be surprised by the adoption of either alternative A1 or
alternative A2. Longer-term yields would likely decline, equity prices would
probably rise, and the foreign exchange value of the dollar fall.
Alternative C, on page 9, would be appropriate if participants believed that the
monetary policy steps taken at the past two meetings risked boosting inflation to
undesirable levels without providing a substantial reduction in unemployment. For
example, some participants may think that the current level of potential output is
significantly below the level in the staff’s baseline scenario and may thus view the
accommodation currently in place as more likely to result in inflationary pressures
than in significant improvements in output and employment. Those members might
note that measures of overall inflation have eased only somewhat since earlier in the
year despite declines in the prices of energy and other commodities, and they may be
concerned that inflation, over the medium term, could persist at levels above those
consistent with the dual mandate unless action is taken fairly soon to reduce monetary
accommodation. They may also conclude that the current stance of monetary policy,

November 1–2, 2011

199 of 282

including the MEP, poses an unacceptably large risk to the stability of inflation
expectations.
Much of the statement under alternative C would be close to the draft for
alternative B. However, the first paragraph of alternative C would suggest greater
confidence about the recent improvement in economic growth and less confidence
about the moderation in inflation. The outlook for unemployment in the second
paragraph would be slightly more upbeat, and the reference to downside risks would
be dropped.
In paragraph 3, the statement would note that “in light of the recent improvement
in the economic outlook,” the Committee decided to reduce the size of the MEP to
$200 billion of purchases and sales, and that the MEP would be completed by the end
of March 2012. In paragraph 4, the statement would shorten the period during which
the Committee expected economic conditions to warrant an exceptionally low federal
funds rate by about two quarters, by indicating that the period runs either “at least
through 2012” or “at least for the next four quarters.”
The adoption of alternative C would greatly surprise investors and would likely
have outsized effects in financial markets.
The draft directives for the four alternatives are presented on pages 12 through 16
of your handout. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. That completes my prepared remarks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Are there questions for Bill? President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, can I ask Brian a question? Yesterday in his presentation,
he said that it was our description of the economy that you felt was a little harsher than markets
expected. I’m interpolating your words. The operative word here is “significant.” Is that what
you were referring to in terms of statement B as it’s drafted?
MR. SACK. I think that’s what received a lot of attention in markets. Just to be clear, I
had thought the first two paragraphs of that statement were essentially marking to market in a
way that was pretty obvious. But market participants actually took a more negative signal from
it than I had anticipated.
MR. FISHER. Well, have they digested that word “significant” by now in your opinion?
MR. SACK. Yes, I would imagine their expectation is that that clause would be
repeated. We didn’t ask that explicitly, but certainly given the volatility in markets and the

November 1–2, 2011

200 of 282

uncertainties that they see, I think they wouldn’t be surprised to have that sentence repeated with
the word “significant.”
MR. FISHER. Thank you. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Any other questions for Bill? [No response]
All right. Let’s begin our go-round with President Williams.
MR. WILLIAMS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B. I also favor
maintaining the “at least through mid-2013” forward guidance and including the word
“significant” in describing the downside risks. I think that’s accurate. In my view, appropriate
policy entails liftoff of the funds rate from its current level around mid-2014. This is similar to
the median of market participants’ expectations, so I don’t see a compelling need at this time to
try to move market expectations by changing our policy guidance.
In thinking about the appropriate stance of monetary policy, I find it useful to consider a
variety of simple estimated and calibrated monetary policy rules. I’m less swayed by the optimal
control simulations, which are highly sensitive to the model and underlying forecasts, and I don’t
think they’re as reliable a guide for policy. But currently, with considerable slack, slow growth,
and fairly low inflation, the central tendency of these policy rules is completely consistent with
the current very accommodative stance of monetary policy. Furthermore, the central tendency of
these policy rules doesn’t predict lifting off from the zero lower bound until around mid-2014.
Of course, simple rules are only partial guides to our policy decisions, and there are three
key reasons why we may want to adjust the prescriptions from these rules. First, because of the
zero lower bound, we haven’t been able to follow the prescriptions of the policy rules into
negative territory. So there’s no reason to think that we should follow them regarding the policy
liftoff. Indeed, much research, including work I’ve done with Dave Reifschneider, suggests that

November 1–2, 2011

201 of 282

policy should stay at zero longer than standard policy rules would suggest following an episode
at the zero bound. A policy rule based on our analysis suggests liftoff in early 2015.
Furthermore, the normal channels of monetary transmission remain unusually clogged. Many
businesses and households are unable to take on new debt or want to shed existing debt, muting
the effects of monetary policy stimulus. If this reduced effectiveness persists, additional policy
accommodation is needed, and liftoff should be delayed relative to the simple rules’ prescription.
However, working in the opposite direction, the simple rules ignore the sizable additional
accommodation from our unconventional monetary policies. The additional stimulus from lower
term premiums and longer-term yields suggests that our short-term policy could lift off
somewhat earlier than the simple rules suggest.
I view these and other arguments that deviate from the policy rules as roughly canceling
out. So I remain fairly comfortable with the rules-based prescription of a mid-2014 liftoff as a
modal forecast. Importantly, I foresee a relatively modest pace of increases after liftoff, with the
funds rate ending 2014 at only 75 basis points.
Finally, there are significant downside risks to the outlook for the economy, as we
discussed yesterday, and I therefore recognize that the date of liftoff could be significantly later
than mid-2014. And obviously, depending on the actual evolution of the forecast for economic
activity and inflation, we may need to change our policy guidance and use further large-scale
asset purchases or lower the reserve rates as needed, but right now I see alternative B as
appropriate.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I wasn’t ready, but here we go. I
am willing to support alternative B. I proposed the language of “for the next six to seven

November 1–2, 2011

202 of 282

quarters” in alternative B. So let me explain why I did that. In the frameworks go-round, I
described a rule, which I could alternatively describe as a reaction function, as a mapping from
changes in economic conditions to the changes in the level of accommodation. And when I did
that, I didn’t mention calendar time. That’s because reaction functions really should be
intrinsically dateless. They should work exactly the same in 2011 as in 2012. This formulation
of a dateless rule-based approach to policy argues in favor of our communicating our level of
accommodation in a way that is just as dateless. And I believe that we should make it easy for
the public to understand how the level of accommodation is evolving over time, and that would
mean we should describe our policy stance in a dateless fashion so that it is readily comparable
from one meeting to the next or, indeed, from one year to the next.
Now, I’ll talk about the impact on the public, and then I’ll talk about the impact on our
own thinking. This issue is not an academic one to the public. I read several news stories that
predicted the Fed would leave its policy statement unchanged and concluded from that that the
Fed is also leaving its policy stance unchanged. This inference is a logical one, but it is actually
incorrect given the current form of the statement, which would involve actually, the Fed reducing
the level of accommodation in place by leaving the date “mid-2013” in place with the passage of
six to seven weeks.
I’ll come back to this point about using the duration as opposed to a date as our lever of
changing accommodation now, because I want to talk about something I feel is very important.
We talk a lot about policy uncertainty, and I believe that we are right now, unfortunately, a
source of that policy uncertainty. What I mean by that is that I think that we really have to be
more systematic in our thinking about how to build a reaction function. This is not just about
what triggers to pick or anything like that, which is really more about what level of

November 1–2, 2011

203 of 282

accommodation we want in place today—an important question and one that we should be
thinking about all the time—but we also want to be thinking about how that level of
accommodation is going to be changing over time in response to changes in conditions. For
example, suppose next year, a year from now, unemployment is at 9 percent and inflation is
running around 1.6 percent. What are we going to do in those circumstances? I’m including
only inflation and unemployment, but basically my idea is, the outlook is remaining the same as
now. We’re in a sort of stasis, which is not my modal forecast by any means, but it’s certainly, I
think, a relatively likely outcome. Taking a dateless reaction function approach to thinking about
policy would argue for doing the same, having the same level of accommodation. It wouldn’t
mean having this year, “mid-2013,” in there, of course, but it would mean arguing for the same
level of accommodation in terms of how long we’re going to be to liftoff.
Some of my concerns about Committee decisionmaking over the past two meetings have
been that I don’t think this discipline of dateless decisionmaking has carried through, and it’s not
a hawkish or a dovish comment. It’s basically, if you want to add accommodation a year from
now when the conditions are the same as today, you should be asking yourself, why didn’t you
put that accommodation in place now when actually there is a year that will go by in which you
could be helping people with it? So it’s really about consistency, and failure to be consistent
over time adds to policy uncertainty in the current environment. It’s very important for us to be
more structured and more deliberate in our thinking about how we’re going to react to changes in
conditions. Now, I’m merely channeling the words that President Bullard has uttered on many
occasions. So I’m probably scooping some of the things he’s—yes. But even though that’s true,
that doesn’t mean that what I’m saying isn’t right. [Laughter]

November 1–2, 2011

204 of 282

Having said all of that, it’s not going to be true at all times that you would never, ever
deviate from your reaction function. It’s not as though you want to commit to something and
leave it there and go home for the rest of all time. Governor Raskin has offered some real
reasons that right now we might be thinking that maybe we should change our reaction function.
Why is that? Well, maybe monetary policy is not as effective as it once was. Maybe we’re more
worried about unemployment because we might be more on the verge of triggering more social
unrest than we thought a year ago. So there might be reasons to change, but we should have in
place the structure from which to change before we change. We should have in place a
structured, disciplined approach to thinking about reacting to change in the economy. We might
come to that point and say, “Look. The way we’d been thinking about monetary policy a year
ago wasn’t right. It’s just not as effective as we thought it was.” Or we might get to that point a
year from now when unemployment is still at 9, and we could have much more Depression-like
civil unrest. We might have a different way of weighting inflation and unemployment at that
point. These will be good reasons to be revisiting the situation. But I think it’s important for us
to have something to deviate from and so to have a reaction function in place.
Those are words for the future. Right now, as I said, Mr. Chairman, I’m happy to
support—willing to support, I should say—alternative B.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Rosengren.
MR. ROSENGREN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Yesterday I discussed the Boston
forecast and talked about inflation being at 1½ percent, roughly where the Tealbook was, by
mid-2013. Both the Boston forecast and the Board forecast come from a particular econometric
tradition, so I thought it was noteworthy to at least look at the memos on DSGE models. And
interestingly, from all four of those banks, they came up with roughly the same estimate that both

November 1–2, 2011

205 of 282

the Tealbook and the Boston Fed forecast, which was roughly 1½ percent. In fact, I think 1½ is
a high rather than a low for both those four banks and those coming from a different econometric
tradition.
What that would seem to say is that there is some flexibility, if we are going to have an
inflation rate below 2 percent two to three years out, to do more accommodation in order to get a
better result on the unemployment rate. The reason you wouldn’t do that is, one, you might think
that we couldn’t affect the interest rate, or, two, if we did affect interest rates, it would have no
impact. Brian yesterday showed the percent of Treasuries that we’re buying, and showed that in
a number of issues, we’re buying a very significant amount. I have no doubt that if we’re willing
to buy a very significant amount, we have the ability to move down both Treasury rates and
mortgage-backed securities rates. It’s a question of will, not whether we can do it or not. It isn’t
a question of whether we can move those interest rates.
So then the question is, if we can move those interest rates, what is the likelihood it
would have any impact? Some analysts have argued that pushing long rates down through
quantitative easing would have no effect. No effect is a very restrictive assumption, but it has
been cited by a wide number of analysts. That assumption means that housing is unresponsive to
lower rates; that consumption, including autos and durables, is unresponsive to interest rates; that
exchange rates in the foreign sector are unresponsive despite the complaints by many of our
foreign trading partners about the quantitative easing; and that investment is unresponsive to
lower rates.
I asked the people who do our model to test the assumption of whether the interest
responsiveness of each of these components is really zero. Not surprisingly, my prior was that
they wouldn’t find that zero was the right answer. And when they did that, they did find that in

November 1–2, 2011

206 of 282

housing, the coefficient was much lower, but they didn’t find that the coefficient was 0—which
is, housing is responsive; it’s not as responsive as it would be without all of the various
headwinds. But in those other sectors, they couldn’t reject the assumption that in the past several
years, interest rates have affected those sectors in the same way that they did prior to the past
several years. So it is interesting that it does seem, from at least the econometric analysis done at
the Boston Fed, that in using the model that we use for the forecast, we actually do find that if we
chose to push interest rates lower, it would have an impact on the economy, contrary to what at
least some analysts have argued.
When I look at alternative B, which maintains the exceptionally low rates “at least
through mid-2013,” our forecast implies that the language in alternative A would actually be
more appropriate. Should we leave policy unchanged when both elements of the mandate are
missed in the medium term? We’re not at full employment, and we’re lower than 2 percent for
the inflation rate. My preference would be to use this meeting to clearly communicate that rates
will remain exceptionally low until unemployment is 7 percent or the inflation rate exceeds
2½ percent in the medium term. At our next meeting, if the outlook once again envisions
unacceptable progress toward our primary goals, we need to consider taking more forceful
action.
Were we to have a shock from a large bank failure here or abroad, a European crisis, or
the inability to reach agreement on our debt problems, aggressive monetary actions, perhaps
coupled with a move to nominal GDP targeting to signal a regime change, would clearly be
appropriate. But even our baseline forecast implies a lost decade for many people in the
workforce. We should consider soon whether more vigorous policies are necessary. Thank you,
Mr. Chairman.

November 1–2, 2011

207 of 282

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Evans.
MR. EVANS. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Today I support further actions by the
Committee to provide additional significant monetary accommodation. I am not arguing that
economic conditions have deteriorated further and thus require this additional action. I am
arguing that the progression of adding stimulus needs to continue. In my assessment, there are
significant benefits to credibly solidifying expectations that policy will continue to be
extraordinarily accommodative as long as conditions warrant. I spoke about the riskmanagement benefits at length yesterday, and I hope that the record properly reflects those
comments here as well in the interest of time.
As I’ve stated here and in public, I interpret our dual-mandate responsibilities to be
closely associated with minimizing a quadratic policy loss function, which puts equal weights on
price stability and maximum employment as captured by unemployment deviations from a pretty
conservative and time-varying natural rate. Given such a loss function, the staff analysis shows
clear value in strengthening our forward guidance. I agree with President Rosengren very much.
There are also considerations not captured by the staff analysis that I think add to the case
for further accommodation. Some of this came up yesterday. The longer we go with very high
unemployment and output far below its potential, the more we risk actually eroding that
potential. President Williams mentioned the supply effects the Japanese perceive. Some of the
reductions that we have already made to our estimates of potential are due to decreased capital
deepening that is actually a fallout of weak demand suppressing capital investment.
Mr. Chairman, your speeches have highlighted the corrosive effects of long-term
unemployment, and Governor Tarullo did a great job of explaining how we may be on the cusp

November 1–2, 2011

208 of 282

of finally significantly raising the natural rate of unemployment. I think those considerations add
some urgency to this situation.
In favoring more policy accommodation in the form of certain variations of alternative A,
I expect that I will be outside the consensus policy decision today. Since July 2010, I’ve
advocated aggressive forms of additional policy accommodation. I argued for state-contingent
price-level targeting in the fall of 2010. I was pleased to support QE2 as a further substantial
step along the way, and I hoped that that would be enough. In August of this year, I argued for a
version of the trigger threshold strategy similar to the language in alt A1, paragraph 4″.
Yesterday’s discussion clearly indicates that, at least for now, I’m outside of the Committee’s
consensus regarding such policy clarifications of our “mid-2013” forward guidance—that is, if in
fact there is a consensus regarding interpreting and clarifying “mid-2013.” We’re going to have
to deal with that soon. It’s not really optional.
In any event, it’s my judgment that we need another substantial step toward additional
accommodation in order to solidify expectations. Accordingly, I favor alternative A1, with a
variation of paragraph 4″ included. I think that our exceptionally low range for the federal funds
rate will be appropriate, at least as long as the unemployment rate exceeds 7 percent or unless
medium-term PCE inflation exceeds 3 percent and longer-term inflation expectations become
unanchored. Just to be clear, my preferred strategy for delivering additional accommodation in
the most credible fashion would be to pursue additional asset purchases regularly at subsequent
meetings until the outlook for hitting either of these thresholds increased commensurately with
these additional actions.

November 1–2, 2011

209 of 282

As I said, Mr. Chairman, on the basis of yesterday’s commentaries, I expect that my
policy position is simply too far outside the consensus, and I cannot support alternative B today.
Thank you.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Can I ask a clarifying question?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. President Evans, in buying more assets, do you have a
preference in terms of what you would buy?
MR. EVANS. I would clearly support MBS. I think that that would be very helpful for
the housing market. And I also would say that if a consensus was to emerge—which I am not
anticipating—that some sort of asset purchasing today could be adopted, then I could be
prepared to support that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lockhart.
MR. LOCKHART. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m going to support alternative B. I do
not support alternative A2 because I don’t favor additional asset purchases at this time. But I do
have to express some sympathy for alternative A1, with its policy thrust of pushing the funds rate
guidance further out to 2014.
My own forecast projects a funds rate near zero at least through mid-2014. Considering
the language options for paragraph 4 of alternative A1, I am sympathetic to the first option
because, as I said, it reflects my forecast. I’m also sympathetic to the second option for
paragraph 4 because, in my view, it makes sense to move in the direction of policy conditionality
in terms of projected economic outcomes, versus guidance based only on a calendar date. I am
less sympathetic to the third option in paragraph 4 because I think its introduction of an explicit
unemployment threshold could prove to be a step too far. For reasons that I expressed yesterday,

November 1–2, 2011

210 of 282

I am concerned that the unemployment problem is multifaceted, not well understood, and quite
possibly not as responsive as we might hope to a sustained accommodative monetary policy
stance. I am reluctant to connect the path of policy so concretely to what might show itself as
time passes to be a problematic number that is taken as a trigger. Despite my sympathy for
alternative A1, paragraphs 4 and 4′, I lean to alternative B at this meeting. I would prefer a “stay
the course” approach for the time being. The economy is improving, and I think we would be
prudent to take a breather and see how the European and congressional fiscal stories play out and
the economy evolves.
I think it would be best to avoid the impression of a policy change, and the easiest way to
do that is to stick with our previous language. I say this because I do not really think the
presumption of a very low funds rate through mid-2014 is a change from the consensus view that
has prevailed since August. Because alternative A1, with the first paragraph 4 option, does
reflect this reality, I do not strongly object to it in substance but advise against it at this meeting
as a matter of tactics. If the Committee goes in that direction, I would hope we might convey
that pushing the horizon of the current funds rate policy to mid-2014 is more an extension and
continuation of the August policy decision than a change in the implied degree of stimulus
relative to September. This could perhaps be done through the Chairman’s comments on the
SEP.
As regards the language of alternative B, I prefer no change at this meeting. As I already
implied, I do not object strenuously to the change that comes off a date and allows a rolling
approach. It does suggest an extension, as I said, which is consistent with my forecast, but that
may be too narrow a point. It’s early enough, it seems to me, to treat this tactically at this

November 1–2, 2011

211 of 282

meeting. So all things considered, I prefer the existing “mid-2013” language. Thank you, Mr.
Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Did you want to say anything about
“significant”? Were your comments meant to encompass that or not?
MR. LOCKHART. The dropping of “significant” is okay with me, I think, at this time
because of the slight improvement in the economy.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B today. Since our
last meeting, we received some good news on the economy that signals a reduced chance of
recession. But as I said yesterday, the news hasn’t been sufficient to change my view of the most
likely path of the economy, which is for slow growth in the 2½ to 2¾ percent range through
2014. We also had a bit of good news on inflation, although not enough to be certain that we are
seeing a reduction in the underlying trend of prices. Nonetheless, I continue, as I said yesterday,
to expect inflation of about 2 percent for the next few years. With my outlook little changed
since we eased policy at our last meeting, it makes sense to me to keep policy unchanged at this
meeting.
As we move forward, I think the course of policy is going to be highly dependent on how
the considerable risks to the outlook play out. While the risks don’t look as dire today as they
did at our last meeting, they may yet pose some challenges for policy. For example, we could
easily face circumstances in which risks to price stability prevent us from easing in response to a
faltering recovery or circumstances in which rising inflation prevents us from maintaining the
current degree of policy accommodation in response to a still-weak recovery.

November 1–2, 2011

212 of 282

In terms of the language, I wouldn’t change the “mid-2013” date at this meeting. In
paragraphs 1 and 2 of alternative B, we are making comments that show somewhat improved
economic conditions, and we didn’t really change our economic outlook very much since our last
meeting. Drawing on yesterday’s discussion of policy frameworks, though, I would prefer to use
the SEP to clarify the forward guidance in alternative B by referring to our forecast for
unemployment and inflation in mid-2013. Adding some form of the language in the last
sentence in paragraph 4′ in alternative A1, I think, could help the public better understand our
reaction function.
Mr. Chairman, because you’re going to have a press conference after this meeting, I
would encourage you to use that opportunity to draw the public’s attention to what we expect
economic conditions are going to be in 2013, if we don’t use that language in our statement
today. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Fisher.
MR. FISHER. Mr. Chairman, I support alternative B, with maintaining the language
“through mid-2013.” Mr. Evans may be surprised that I agree with him completely—that the
longer we go with high unemployment, the more we undermine potential. I just don’t believe
that our monetary accommodation has been all that useful in assisting the reduction of
joblessness, given the uncertainty that is posed by the fiscal and regulatory morass that we see on
Capitol Hill. And I believe we’re pushing on a string on that front.
I have been outspoken on this publicly and within this room. I did not support the
extension to mid-2013. I voted against it. I still—despite, I think, Brian’s very good briefings—
view Operation Twist as incomplete. I suspect it was good for the rich. As a former trader,
having learned very well to operate on “buying on the rumor and selling on the news,” I think we

November 1–2, 2011

213 of 282

did end up enriching certain swift and capable money operators. It’s not clear to me that in the
end it will benefit the cost of business borrowing. I do believe very firmly that we have
significant liquidity in the economy.
I found all the interventions yesterday to be quite brilliant, but I was particularly struck
by Governor Duke’s, in terms of some of the improvements that have been made regarding
balance sheets and the potential that exists out there. I wouldn’t say that I want to completely
embrace the “Tigger” scenario, nor am I willing to embrace the “Eeyore” scenario, but I found
that to be a sobering assessment in contrast to what everybody else was talking about at the table,
and it’s something we should bear in mind.
I continue to believe that we should harbor our ammunition. We have few bullets left. I
referred to them in the last meeting—in reference to your initials, Mr. Chairman—as BBs. But
whatever we have left we need to use under dire circumstances. I am still of the belief that we
could see an S&P 500 trading at 600 under very easy circumstances if we have the horrific
scenario that some fear obtained in Europe and just because of the nature of the skittishness of
markets.
I continue to worry about the impact of what we have wrought on those who played by
the rules, saved their money, and are being hurt by low interest rates. I do believe this is not
constructive from the standpoint of the 6,000-plus community banks we have in this country in
terms of squeezing their profitability.
I do believe that this has a negative impact related to the resetting of pension fund
liabilities, which takes away from investment that might otherwise go into job-creating capital,
and I worry about the consequence of our low-interest-rate policy.

November 1–2, 2011

214 of 282

These are costs that are involved. There are certainly benefits that accrue. But I don’t
think one of the benefits is that we impact the too-high unemployment levels in this country if
we just act as a substitute for fiscal policy.
We’ll have more information by December in terms of knowing what the supercommittee
is likely to do, and in my book, as long as we provide accommodative monetary policy, we give
them an excuse not to act. It is time for them to act, and I would urge you, in your press briefing,
to underscore what you have said publicly—and Mr. Dudley, the Vice Chairman of this
Committee, mentioned yesterday—that we should stress regarding the need for fiscal policy to
get its act together.
Mr. Chairman, I would support statement B. With regard to the word “significant,” I am
somewhat indifferent. I would prefer not to use it, but if the Desk tells us that it’s been digested
by the market, then I could swallow it. I didn’t think it was in blue, by the way—I thought it was
in purple, Mr. Lockhart, just to satisfy you. And I would suggest that those who are seeing
purple squirrels may be taking the drugs that Mr. Lockhart and Mr. Lacker have been talking
about. [Laughter] So that’s it, Mr. Chairman. I support statement B as drafted, with “through
mid-2013.” Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President George.
MS. GEORGE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. My preference is to take no further action at
this meeting. Since September, the moderate recovery has continued, and although far from
robust, GDP growth has been resilient, and the third-quarter reading came in slightly better than I
had previously expected, thanks to strong business investment.
While I understand the desire to do something to address high unemployment, I don’t
think our current problems can fundamentally be solved with monetary policy alone.

November 1–2, 2011

215 of 282

Deleveraging and rebalancing take time to achieve, and monetary policy has only a limited
ability to speed these processes without risking low and stable inflation, which we have worked
hard to achieve. Moreover, we normally believe it takes some time for monetary policy
decisions to affect economic activity. The Committee has taken action at each of the past two
meetings, partly in response to a deteriorating outlook and downside risk, but conditions have not
worsened, and in fact have improved a bit, since then.
So I favor no further action. I would like to leave the language unchanged and to
eliminate the word “significant” from “downside.”
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’ll be brief. I support alternative B. The
data have been somewhat stronger than expected. The recession scare that was around during
the August time frame has been mitigated, at least for now.
It’s true that sentiment is down at both the household level and the firm level. I consider
this a headline phenomenon for right now. There is very real risk to the U.S. from Europe, but
it’s only a risk at this point, and it’s not enough to change household behavior or business
behavior for a couple of reasons. The households, I think, see themselves as too far removed
from Europe to actually change behavior, despite the fact that they’re reporting bad feelings. For
the large businesses, they’re also worried about developments in Europe, but they are also
profitable and cash rich. Their business growth strategies are not centered in Europe but in Asia,
and Asian growth is projected to continue unabated. These are two good reasons to think that the
sentiment numbers are not affecting actual household and business behavior in the U.S. at this
point, and so I think that that helps explain why we’re not getting significant downturn based on
sentiment alone.

November 1–2, 2011

216 of 282

The Committee has taken easing actions at the August and September meetings,
strengthening the commitment to maintain the policy rate near zero and undertaking Operation
Twist. Both of these are operating today. Given the improved hard data on the economy, I
counsel patience at this point.
I also counsel against the use of the word “significant” in paragraph 2 of alternative B.
The tradition of central bankers is to be appropriately fair but understated to avoid frightening
the financial markets. It’s a serious problem. They think that we know something that they
don’t know, and we have to be very careful about sending any signals of that nature. I think it’s
fine as originally written: “Moreover, there are downside risks to the economic outlook,
including strains in global financial markets.” Certainly there are. Everyone knows what we’re
talking about. Putting “significant” in there may otherwise create more problems than it solves.
So I would use the original wording in paragraph 2.
If the Committee wishes to ease aggressively at future meetings, I suggest that asset
purchases are the most potent tool available to the Committee. Partly based on the discussion
yesterday, I would recommend the incremental balance sheet policies, such as those described in
the excellent memo of October 24 by Dave Reifschneider, John Roberts, and Jae Sim. We
haven’t discussed that memo very much at this meeting, but I thought it was very good, and I
recommend that we take a look at it. I’ve also described my own views on this issue in previous
discussions with the Committee. An incremental approach would have a great advantage of
allowing the Committee to make decisions in a manner analogous to interest rate decisions in
ordinary times. Also, the open-ended nature of this approach potentially promises substantial
additional easing while still giving the Committee the ability to pause or reverse the policy as the
macroeconomic situation changes. I counsel purchasing Treasuries versus MBS.

November 1–2, 2011

217 of 282

Other methods of easing did not strike me as being nearly as effective as they are
sometimes portrayed, partly for the reasons I outlined yesterday. The trigger strategy approach
seems questionable to me. I do not see why this is a good way to commit to longer periods of
zero rates relative to other methods of committing to longer periods of zero rates. I do not think
much would happen initially if we took this approach, and it might complicate our strategies
down the line if either or both of the thresholds were violated. Furthermore, trying to tie
monetary policy directly to unemployment strikes me as very questionable given the state of
knowledge of hysteresis in unemployment as experienced in Europe in recent decades. It’s not
that we shouldn’t think about unemployment—we should think about unemployment. The
question is, should you tie the policy lever directly to a number that we probably don’t
understand as well as we would like to understand? Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Plosser.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Mr. Chairman? Sorry.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Kocherlakota.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. I want to clarify something in my own mind. The word
“significant” was in the September FOMC statement, right?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Right.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. So taking it out is a change from the September FOMC
statement.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. That’s correct.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Okay. Just to be clear.

November 1–2, 2011

218 of 282

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. The sentence is reoriented a little bit so that it’s not quite so
obvious, but yes, it is in fact the case, and the September statement is, of course, at the beginning
of your handout.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Thanks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. This Committee has been aggressive and
creative at fulfilling its dual mandate. Over the past three and a half years, we have reduced the
policy rate from 5¼ percent to 0, where it’s been now for three years. We have purchased nearly
$2 trillion worth of assets on our balance sheet, including MBS. We have targeted spreads. We
have targeted risk premiums. We have targeted assets for moving their prices around. It is hard
for me to imagine that this Committee could be accused of not making every effort in its power
to fulfill our dual mandate.
The fact of the matter is that we are all frustrated and disappointed that unemployment
rates remain stubbornly high, and we’re all deeply concerned about that. I think we have to keep
in mind, though, that policy actions by this Committee are not free. They carry costs as well as
benefits, and it is our duty to keep evaluating those costs and benefits of our actions. And I
think, as President Lockhart said yesterday and repeated today, it is troubling that despite our
best efforts and very aggressive efforts, the labor market hasn’t responded in ways that we
normally think it might. That should give us some pause regarding how we think about
proceeding going forward.
In thinking about the costs of aggressive action, we need to be concerned that it’s about
the future—it’s not about today. Low interest rates for three years and longer—President
Bullard has expressed concerns about that. But distorting interest rates, twisting curves, and

November 1–2, 2011

219 of 282

targeting asset prices of different classes of assets risk creating distortions, inefficiencies, and
potentially, bubbles down the road that we have no control over or no ability to foresee with
great foresight. That is a risk that we must take as real. President Hoenig for all of last year
cautioned us about those risks—the unknowns that they may carry with them and therefore the
risks for the future. As President Fisher just said, low interest rates punish savers as another
form of distortion.
Our policy actions also have risks for the future as well in undermining our own
credibility. I’ve raised this point before. We continue to take actions in an environment where
our actions will not help the unemployment rate or will have very de minimis effects on the
unemployment rate. We undermine our credibility as an institution, and when we need that
credibility, perhaps in the exit, we may suffer from it.
And finally, of course, there is the potential risk of inflation down the road. Inflation
may not be in our future in the near term or even maybe in the medium term, but we put
ourselves in a position where managing that future inflation could be extremely difficult. And
undermining our credibility by taking actions that don’t work makes managing that inflation exit
that much more difficult. So these are real costs to our actions today, and we have to place
judgments on how to balance those future costs that are not knowable completely. But we have
to make judgments about those.
I am worried that we continue to take actions in ways that have no real coherence to
them. I fully support our conversations yesterday about inflation targeting. I put myself in the
camp of President Kocherlakota—his discussions about systematic policy—and even President
Williams with respect to thinking about more systematic ways of guiding our policy decisions. I
made a suggestion yesterday that this Committee work over time in developing what the

November 1–2, 2011

220 of 282

arguments of that systematic policy ought to be and using those arguments to explain to the
public what our actions are in terms of how those arguments evolve. So I’m very much in favor
of that approach, and I’m very much in favor of not only inflation targeting in articulating our
framework, but also using that framework and potentially the SEPs as a way to provide more
information, more transparency about forward guidance, as opposed to using the calendar.
Those would all be steps forward. I was encouraged by our conversation yesterday about that,
and I think those steps will help us mitigate some of the risks that I pointed to—the risks of our
policies down the road.
To me, the economy looks, if anything, slightly better, as many people have said, than it
did in August and September when we undertook those actions. The dire prognoses of a lot of
people that we were about to fall off a cliff have not come to pass. That’s not to say they might
not at some future date, but clearly, there’s a little more confidence, I think, that that will not
happen at least in the near term.
From my perspective, given our actions in the past two meetings, I am hard pressed to
figure out a justification for further accommodation at this point. I do not believe the maturity
extension program is very effective. I didn’t think it was going to be effective. I was opposed to
it, and I was opposed to the dates. However, the progress we made yesterday and the prospects
that we can strengthen our framework, improve the way we do forward guidance, and push
toward a more systematic approach to policy give me hope that we can manage our way through
this.
At this meeting, Mr. Chairman, I’m willing to go along with alternative B. I would prefer
that the word “significant” be dropped. I don’t feel terribly strongly about that. Obviously,
there’s a part of me that very much would like to see alternative C, but I am hopeful that some of

November 1–2, 2011

221 of 282

the conversations and progress we made yesterday can translate into a way that will make our
policymaking better and more transparent and help us avoid the kinds of risks that I see of our
policies undertaken in the future. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I’m willing to support following through on
our maturity extension program, which I opposed at the last meeting, but I’m willing to support
that.
As I said in the economic go-round, I think the forecast for inflation—people’s around
this table and my own—is good, one that I’m very pleased with. The risks around inflation are
heightened. If you look at a picture of inflation over the past several years, you’ll notice the
significant increase in volatility this past decade over the decade before, and I think that volatility
is likely to be with us for some time. It is possible that the broader inflation trend could
moderate a bit, as in the Tealbook and many of your forecasts, but I worry that a forecast of
moderating inflation relies overly much on the effect of slack, whose downward effect on
inflation has disappointed us several times in the recent past. I think inflation could accelerate,
and it could do so rapidly. I don’t see that on the horizon right away, but it’s well within the
realm of possibility. I’d note the continuing buildup of bank balances and the huge amount of
reserves, and I’d question whether two-year Treasuries are any less effective as inflationary
tinder than bank balances. So it’s conceivable that with the spark of a commodity price increase
or an oil price increase of a substantial magnitude, we could get a broader acceleration of
inflation.
Growth is certainly extremely disappointing, but as I’ve said and many others have said
around here, it’s a fairly nonmonetary phenomenon. I think the natural rate, thinking in those

November 1–2, 2011

222 of 282

terms, is fairly high and fairly close to the unemployment rate we have. Further stimulus on our
part could well affect growth, but I can’t see it affecting growth without also pushing inflation
up. It’s one thing, when inflation is running below where we’d like it to average, to be willing to
run that risk for the sake of stimulating employment, but it’s entirely different when inflation is
where we want it. And it’s one thing to tolerate shocks that temporarily push headline inflation
well above where we’d like it, in a situation where we have good reason to believe that that
effect will reverse shortly and we’ll get back down to where we want it; it’s quite another thing
to attempt to deliberately engineer an increase in inflation trends. I just don’t think that our
ability to manage the movement upward in inflation and a controlled movement downward
warrants as much confidence as I’d require to get over the hump to support that. It would be a
terribly risky maneuver to attempt.
Looking forward, I think the more stimulus we provide, the quicker we’re going to have
to be ready to take it out. The deeper we get into this, the quicker we’re going to have to move
to take it out. So I worry that we’ll face a situation with rising inflation and terribly
disappointing growth still, or growth picking up but still disappointing on the labor market
side—a dilemma that will be tough for this Committee to grapple with, that will really expose a
lot of differences of opinion in this Committee.
On the statements, I think “significant downside risks” was a mistake, in hindsight. I
believe that markets already thought there were significant downside risks, they read our
statement as gloomier than they already were, and they read it as gloomier than we really were.
So I’d favor dropping the word “significant.” I realize that the past few days’ events in Europe
may make that a discordant, dissonant move; therefore, I could support leaving it in as well.
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.

November 1–2, 2011

223 of 282

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you, President Lacker. Governor Yellen.
MS. YELLEN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. We’ve taken a number of important steps to
ease monetary policy in recent meetings. Even so, absent further accommodation, the outlook is
unacceptably weak. Under current policy settings, the Tealbook forecast and the Committee’s
central tendency projections show unemployment remaining exceptionally high for years to
come and inflation running below the 2 percent level that most Committee members consider
consistent with our dual mandate. A central bank that practices flexible inflation targeting would
be looking for ways to provide further accommodation.
In my view, it would be feasible to foster a more satisfactory recovery, without pushing
inflation above 2½ percent, by using communication strategies like those illustrated in
alternative A1—namely, strategies that would convey the Committee’s intention to exit from the
zero lower bound at a somewhat later date, and to firm policy at a somewhat more gradual pace,
than financial markets currently anticipate. Such a strategy is embedded in the projection that I
submitted for this meeting, and hence my forecasts for both of the dual objectives are more
appealing than in the extended Tealbook baseline. In particular, my preferred policy path is
associated with a faster pace of economic growth over the next few years, a significantly lower
rate of unemployment by late 2014, and a trajectory for inflation that stays very close to its
mandate-consistent rate. Among the specific variants of paragraph 4 in alternative A1, the
thresholds in version 4″ are very appealing to me as a way of conveying quantitative information
about the conditionality of forward guidance, and I agree with the comments and discussion that
President Evans has given of why this is a good approach. The formulation in version 4′ based
on projections, however, could also be workable.

November 1–2, 2011

224 of 282

Nonetheless, as we have discussed, it makes eminent sense to make adjustments to our
forward guidance in the context of a clear expression of our overarching goals and strategy. I’m
hopeful that we can reach a broad consensus on a statement of principles over the next couple of
months. I look forward to working with the subcommittee on communications to find a
formulation that fully respects our dual mandate. I also hope we’ll be able to move forward with
incorporating policy projections into the SEP. As a matter of fact, I became even more
persuaded of the merits of publishing our funds rate projections as I filled out my survey for this
round and discovered that my rosy economic forecasts could easily be misinterpreted in the
absence of information on my judgment about appropriate policy.
Regarding alternative A2, I’m also open to additional LSAPs, especially as a complement
to providing additional accommodation through our forward guidance. I would be particularly
supportive of MBS purchases to help foster recovery in the housing sector, especially since
dysfunction in mortgage markets is attenuating the effectiveness of monetary policy
accommodation. A pickup in the housing sector could make a substantial contribution to the
recovery if starts were to rebound toward more normal levels. Moreover, house prices have
significant effects on spending via wealth, cash flow, and collateral effects, and a stronger
housing market would also improve the health of the banking system. So initiatives along these
lines certainly deserve further consideration.
In summary, rather than changing our forward guidance or engaging in further LSAPs at
the current meeting, I’m supportive of adopting alternative B today. With respect to the specific
language, I strongly prefer to stick with the current wording of “at least through mid-2013”
rather than substituting the phrase “for the next six to seven quarters.” The phrase “at least”
conveys that policy firming might not commence until significantly later than mid-2013, and this

November 1–2, 2011

225 of 282

phrasing has already been helpful in guiding financial markets, as Brian noted in his briefing
yesterday. The Desk survey suggests that investors now see liftoff as most likely in early 2014.
Moreover, from the standpoint of effective communications, I consider it preferable to formulate
our forward guidance in terms that can be reiterated at each meeting as long as there isn’t any
substantial change in the economic outlook. In effect, we should lay out the anticipated path of
policy as clearly as possible based on our economic forecast, and we should follow that path
unless there’s a good reason to change it. Finally, on the language concerning “significant,” I
could, frankly, go either way on this. The current language, the language that was incorporated
initially in B, seemed acceptable to me based on the data suggesting less risk of inflation and the
fact that there has been some progress on Europe, but I could certainly live also with including
“significant,” especially if, as Brian says, it’s been digested by markets at this point.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Duke.
MS. DUKE. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. I support alternative B with the language “at
least through mid-2013,” not because I think that’s optimal, but because, as I said yesterday, if
we made a change to it this time, it might be considered, given all the discussion about
communication in the intermeeting period, our final choice, and I don’t think we’ve made a final
choice. In making a final choice, I could support one that referenced time, such as the six to
seven quarters. I could support one that was formulated as a prime or a double prime as long as
we all agreed that that’s how we were going to do it going forward. I do have some preference
for referring it to the projections, the SEP, in some way and tying it to those.
With regard to the word “significant,” I think the risks are significant, and taking that
word out, it seems to me, would be a standing down from that position. So I would prefer to
leave it in.

November 1–2, 2011

226 of 282

As to additional asset purchases, and specifically MBS, I would very much be in favor of
weighting any purchases we were going to do toward MBS, but that goes only part of the way.
That affects the spread between Treasuries and the MBS securities. It’s not as effective at this
point in affecting the spread between Treasuries and the rates that are actually offered to
homeowners, and paying more attention to that piece also makes sense. We have within this
System probably the largest collection—certainly of economic research resources that are
available to the government, and I think making our assets available as technical assistance to
parts of the government that can actually make changes that will improve the housing market and
the ability of borrowers to access the low rates that we’re working on is something that we can
do. And certainly, anywhere that our regulatory supervisory policies can be supportive, that’s an
important thing to do as well. Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Tarullo.
MR. TARULLO. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. A week and a half ago, I gave a speech in
which I suggested that additional purchases of mortgage-backed securities should be put back on
the top of our agenda. I carefully phrased that speech and that particular suggestion so as to say
that if things did not improve over the next couple of months, I thought we should consider it. I
qualified the formulation, really out of respect for the decisionmaking process of the Committee.
In fact, I think that there is a good case to be made right now for additional MBS purchases.
Before I get to that reasoning, though, I wanted to say a couple of things about the
general environment in which we’re making this decision today. First, we’re not just talking
about unemployment here. Had it been a circumstance in which the economy was growing
3½ percent a year but unemployment was remaining stubbornly high, it would have been one
thing. But that is not the circumstance that we confront. We have now had a several-year

November 1–2, 2011

227 of 282

pattern of growth that has little spurts and then reverts back to a very tepid pace. So the failure
to create more jobs seems quite logically tied to the performance of the economy as a whole. Of
course, there are some uncertainties about exactly how some sectors of the labor market would or
would not react to improved growth. But if one looks at the data, the importance of aggregate
demand and of cyclical unemployment as explanatory variables is as strong as virtually anything
that we look at in this Committee. So I do think it’s a red herring to talk about structural
unemployment or drug problems or something of the sort when we’re talking about what impact
may be had by further monetary stimulus. I appreciate Jeff’s formulation, which was basically
saying, “Yes, of course there’s room for more stimulus.” But Jeff assesses the risks of inflation
versus the stimulus, and I think that’s a legitimate conversation. I would come out on the other
side, but it does seem to me that’s the conversation we should be having.
I think the case is actually quite strong, and it’s quite strong right now. Why MBS?
Well, people have already mentioned several of the reasons. The spreads are obviously one of
those reasons and the fact that we’re getting to the point where there may be some impact on
market functioning of further Treasury purchases. But I would also point to something that has
been reflected in a number of your comments over the past couple of days—that the suboptimal,
subexpected performance of the economy over the past few years, with the very disappointing
trajectory of the recovery, seems in retrospect pretty obviously tied to debt overhang, the
Reinhart–Rogoff kinds of factors that people have been citing for a while now. And the housing
sector is clearly at the center of all of that. As Betsy was indicating, in other areas there’s been a
good bit of working down of debt. Housing is what has continued to be dysfunctional. That’s
where the debt is; that’s where the failure of markets to clear is. Again, as Betsy was just
mentioning, that’s where prices and quantities don’t quite seem to be in the kind of equilibrium

November 1–2, 2011

228 of 282

that we would expect. So I think action we would take in the housing area with MBS purchases
would not only be efficacious in the way that all large-scale, long-term asset purchases would be,
but could also have a particular impact on the major impediment to the kind of recovery that
would more resemble past recoveries out of recessions.
I know that a lot of people, myself included, are frustrated with the failure of the political
branches of government to take appropriate action to provide more clarity and stimulus for the
economy. But this is an instance in which there could be some synergy. Some modest steps
have already been taken to make refinancing more readily available. If we were to act by
announcing a large-scale asset purchase, I think both the public sector and the banks themselves
would see more opportunities again to leverage what we were doing to have a greater economic
impact.
So the case is actually quite strong, and thus I’m very much tempted to join President
Evans in dissenting from alternative B, because I think alternative B does not accurately reflect
the state of the economy. Having said that, I believe there are a couple of reasons not to move
right now. One is the point that Narayana and John made earlier, and which Bill Dudley has
made, I think, on a number of occasions in the past several meetings—that we do need to get the
communications and the framework and the sense that we think in terms of multiple meetings
(and not just one meeting) more clear than we have. And there are some reasonable grounds for
arguing that an action by us today, whether it was A1 or A2, would once again be difficult for
markets and other observers fully to comprehend. They wouldn’t quite know how it was that we
were making decisions and why.

November 1–2, 2011

229 of 282

Second, and someone alluded to this earlier also, I do think that the risks of a significant
adverse event in Europe are as high as they have been since May 2010. The risks are not just
significant—whatever the adjective above “significant” is, that’s the one we should have.
MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. “Very significant.”
PARTICIPANT. “Humongous.” [Laughter]
MR. TARULLO. “Humongous”—that’s the one that belongs in the statement as an
actual reflection of reality. Because of the increased possibility of something seriously adverse
happening, it might be prudent to withhold for now a significant additional policy initiative,
which is what I might otherwise favor, and then to assess the state of our communications, the
state of the economy, and the state of Europe over the next couple of meetings.
So with considerable reluctance, I can support alternative B today. Mr. Chairman, one
probably shouldn’t make one’s support or nonsupport based on any single word, except maybe
the insertion or omission of “not” in certain places. [Laughter] But I do think that omitting
“significant,” given that it’s in the statement now and given what I regard as the increase in
financial risk since the last meeting, would be a mistake. Thanks.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Governor Raskin.
MS. RASKIN. Thank you, Mr. Chairman. Some of the incoming data indicate that the
downside risks have receded somewhat. But unemployment is still projected to decline only
gradually, and inflation is still projected to settle at or below mandate-consistent levels. The
economy is still in dire straits, with sentiment highly pessimistic. Again, I am not optimistic that
households, many of which have lower levels of disposable income, are yet ready to be an engine
of growth for this economy. We have not fallen off the cliff, but the margin of safety is not
wide. Downside risk is significant.

November 1–2, 2011

230 of 282

First, I think that early cessation of the maturity extension program, as suggested in
alternative C, would be premature. It also would challenge the credibility of the Committee to
reverse a decision so quickly when economic indicators have not materially changed. In my
view, early cessation of the maturity extension program requires more-definitive data confirming
that the recovery has strengthened and that unemployment has begun to decline.
I’m instinctively drawn to alternative A1 because, with the federal funds rate constrained
by the zero lower bound and with elevated downside risks to output, stronger forward guidance
seems prudent. But stronger forward guidance of any type requires a communication strategy in
order to be effective. In order to maximize the benefits of accommodation promised by such
stronger forward guidance, I’d like to understand what communication efforts would accompany
such an action. Once these communication plans are developed and considered, the option in
alternative A1 will be more credible to the public. Until then, staying the course, as in
alternative B, seems appropriate. But I am drawn to the need to update our reaction function in
paragraph 4 by reflecting the “six to seven quarters” language, which I think is more
commensurate with at least my economic outlook. I’m sensitive to President Kocherlakota’s
argument that keeping the “through mid-2013” language reduces the level of accommodation.
So I look forward to the work of the subcommittee on communications to create for the full
Committee’s consideration a framework for enhanced forward guidance. Thank you.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you. Vice Chairman.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Thank you. First, I want to talk a little bit about the
“significant” point. I feel really strongly that it has to stay in, because if you take it out, you’re
basically saying that you now think the downside risks are insignificant. Does anyone around
the room think that the downside risks are now insignificant? I agree that we were surprised by

November 1–2, 2011

231 of 282

the reaction of the markets last time to putting “significant” in. But it’s very different keeping it
in as opposed to taking it out. If you’re taking it out, you’re trying to make a statement that you
think the risks have really declined significantly.
I just don’t see any evidence that the downside risks have declined significantly—in fact,
at all. The European situation is probably at the worst place that it’s been. It’s also completely
inconsistent with what we’re saying in the SEPs. If you look at the SEP results, uncertainty
about GDP growth went up compared with June; downside risks to GDP growth are the same as
June—11 versus 6. If you look at the risks to unemployment, they have gone up since June. So
how do you reconcile taking “significant” out here, and then you have all of this uncertainty that
you’re going to discuss in the SEP results? I just don’t see the benefit. I think it could be really
embarrassing for the Committee if you take it out, Europe falls apart, and people go back and
say, “Well, what were you thinking? Didn’t you see what was going on in Europe as you were
going into the meeting?”
Now, in terms of other things, obviously I’m going to support alternative B. I prefer to
stick with the date rather than move to the quarters. I understand the argument for the quarters,
but we’re on a trajectory here where we’re hoping—at least some of us around the table are
hoping—that by January we can arrive at a framework where we actually specify triggers or
thresholds. And in that case, the thresholds will be the key thing, and then the date will follow
from that. I don’t think it really makes sense to go to quarters and then go to this new thing—
you’re going in a zigzag pattern. So I don’t really oppose the idea of the quarters conceptually,
but I don’t think it really fits in, in terms of the trajectory of how we might like to move through
the meetings.

November 1–2, 2011

232 of 282

MR. KOCHERLAKOTA. Could I just say one thing to that, Bill? For this meeting, I
understand the arguments for staying the same as we were, and I appreciate that. But even if
you’re thinking about alternative A1 down the road, in December or January, we will have to
communicate information about timing in some way. And I think saying something about the
duration, as opposed to a date, would be a better way, even in that context. So I don’t think of
them as being inconsistent. That’s all I would say.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. Okay. Well, let me continue. The other thing I want to
talk about is, we need to really think clearly through what our escalation options are in the near
term, because there are significant downside risks. So I think we could actually not have the
luxury of getting all the way to January to pursue the thresholds approach. Regarding the nearterm escalation option, there are really two things that I would favor if we had to go down this
path. One is that I much prefer MBS over Treasuries at this point, subject to the capacity
constraints in terms of how much we can do without disrupting market function. And the reason
why I favor MBS over Treasuries is, it’s easier to make the case that this is more directly tied to
one of the key issues that we’re facing, which is housing. It’s easier to tie it more directly to
private-sector financial market conditions, and it also would have less political noise associated
with it. I don’t think that we should pay that much attention to the political noise per se, but the
political noise can make policies less effective. So to the extent that there’s less political noise of
doing MBS versus Treasuries, I think it is significant in terms of the efficacy of the policy
choice.
Regarding where we’re heading over the next couple of meetings, I very much hope that
we can get to the point where we can actually turn the date into thresholds, with the date actually
following from the thresholds rather than just standing out there in space. As I said yesterday,

November 1–2, 2011

233 of 282

I’m very uncertain about what the date is. I’m considerably less uncertain about the thresholds,
so I think the thresholds are, in some way, a better metric to give the markets. The second thing
with thresholds is that they give the market the ability to update its view of how long policy is
going to stay accommodative dynamically as it gets new information and the outlook changes.
So that’s something that I’m hoping we can work toward. Obviously, I think it’s going to be
difficult.
The second thing I think we need to think about—and this is something that we talked
about; we got a briefing from the staff at the videoconference—was that we may need to think
about bringing back a better liquidity backstop for our financial system if Europe really gets into
great difficulty. The very rapid failure of MF Global underscores the fact that the broker–dealers
in the United States do not have a credible lender-of-last-resort backstop. And so it’s very
possible that we may have to do something very quickly on the liquidity front to backstop the
financial system. One thing I think that it’s very important for us to stress in our public remarks
is that despite the Dodd–Frank Act, we still have both the ability and the will to perform our
lender-of-last-resort function, because I think there’s a little bit of confusion in the market about
whether we would actually be willing to act. Obviously, we didn’t have a discussion at that
videoconference, but my reading of the body language is that there’s quite a bit of support on the
Committee that lender of last resort is a legitimate central banking function. I think we should
make it clear to people where the Committee stands on that in our public commentary. Thank
you, Mr. Chairman.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Thank you very much. Thank you, all, for your comments.
We are still at a difficult juncture. There is certainly a case, I think, for further action. The best
way to say it is that our medium-term forecasts have inflation below target or at target and

November 1–2, 2011

234 of 282

unemployment well above what most people consider to be the long-run equilibrium level. And
I think it’s pretty straightforward to show that that can’t be a feature of optimal policy. That
said—well, there are responses to that, of course. One can argue that the actions that we could
take at this stage are ineffective or have unintended side effects. So it’s a complex debate and
one that’s been going on in this room for some time.
For this meeting, I would propose that we not take new action, and that’s based more on
trying to get our framework clarified than on a clear decision on the need for or efficacy of
further action. We took important actions at each of the past two meetings. Both of these, I
think, were well grounded in theory. But President Kocherlakota and others have a point that
there was some ad hoc feel to those actions, and probably their impact is somewhat less than it
could have been if they had been better cast in the context of a framework and better prepared for
the markets.
For those who are advocating more expansionary policy, I would just point out that our
toolkit is not infinite, that our capacity is not infinite, and that we’ll be more effective if we can
use the ammunition we have left in the most focused way. And the best way to do that is to have
a strong communication program that will help people understand what we’re doing, why we’re
doing it, and help guide expectations in both the markets and the public.
So I would propose not to take new action today. I leave aside the question of whether
new action is justified. I see a case for new action. But whatever we choose to do, it’ll be more
effective if we are able to provide a more coherent framework for communication. Again, I
think that we should not introduce yet additional policy actions today. We have several things
already in play. Therefore, I do support alternative B, which most people around the table were
comfortable with. I think the majority of people in that statement were in favor of retaining the

November 1–2, 2011

235 of 282

“through mid-2013” language. Whatever the merits may be of the alternative, there’s a case for
waiting until we get to a new communication strategy before making changes, and then we can
consider how to incorporate different considerations into that. So I propose that. “Significant”
is—I got a very divided response on that. Bill.
MR. ENGLISH. I’m sorry, but I wanted to suggest one possibility because the response
was so divided, which was to use exactly the words from last time rather than changing the
structure of the sentence. It might be that the market would be less likely to notice and think
about the word “significant” if it’s in the context of exactly the same words as used before.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. I think that’s right. I would say the two options are, in
alternative B, either striking the bracketed word “significant” and leaving the sentence as it is:
“Moreover, downside risks to the economic outlook remain, including strains in global financial
markets”—I think the case for doing that is, first, there’s this mysterious overinterpretation of the
word in the markets, and we’re not quite sure what all that means. But more substantively, even
though Europe remains very troubled, there has been at least a little reduction in downside risk in
the near-term U.S. economic data. The case on the other side is that we have already used this
language. And as the Vice Chairman and Governor Tarullo and others point out, we are facing
downside risks that could be significant or worse from European developments. Frankly, I’m
willing to go either way. I think if we do retain “significant,” we ought to go back just to the
language of September, so there’s no need to change.
PARTICIPANT. I agree with that.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Lacker.
MR. LACKER. I found Vice Chairman Dudley compelling, so I agree we should leave it
in. Going back to the old language makes sense.

November 1–2, 2011

236 of 282

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. President Bullard.
MR. BULLARD. Yes, I agree—we could just keep it the way it was. Let me just say,
though, that as a matter of style, you always want to be understated as a central bank. People are
imputing that we have some really detailed knowledge about what’s going to happen or that we
have a special crystal ball, and they’re imputing the probability of disaster to be higher than it
otherwise is.
MR. LACKER. You could say “somewhat significant.” [Laughter]
MR. BULLARD. I’m happy to leave the sentence the way it is, but let me just say, the
Wall Street Journal is a master of understatement. They have the small headlines. It says,
“Nixon Resigns; Ford Takes the Oath of Office.” They don’t blare it at you the way the other
newspapers do. I think that’s the style that we should have in describing the situation.
MR. FISHER. So you would caution against “humongous”?
MR. BULLARD. I would caution against “humongous.”
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Now, on the other side of that, “significant” is not exactly a
word that would blow most people away. [Laughter] It is significant, certainly.
MR. LACKER. “Notable”?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. “Significant.” [Laughter] I’m not suggesting any change.
All right. President Plosser.
MR. PLOSSER. Just a comment. It’s fine to leave as in the original sentence. However,
in listening to what people said about “significant,” in some sense, the significant risk
domestically, as you point out, has actually mitigated somewhat. What is really true about the
risk is what’s going to happen in Europe. Being more specific—that is the source of the
significant risk, rather than being something else—would be clearer in some way about what

November 1–2, 2011

237 of 282

we’re saying. So that’s just a thought, maybe, for the future. Or maybe instead of saying
“including global financial,” we could say “particularly from global financial markets.” But I
don’t want to gum up the works.
VICE CHAIRMAN DUDLEY. I think this is a really great question. You really don’t
want to point fingers.
MR. FISHER. It’s implicit in what we’re saying.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Right, I guess. President Pianalto.
MS. PIANALTO. Just a question, though. When you say we’re going to keep it the
same as the last meeting, does that mean the word “remain” comes out?
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. No. Replace the sentence that currently has the word
“significant” in it with—
MS. PIANALTO. The exact same statement from last—
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Exact same: “Moreover, there are significant downside
risks to the economic outlook, including strains in global financial markets.”
MS. PIANALTO. So “remain” comes out.
CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Yes, it’s exactly identical to the last—in September. All
right. I think I’m getting agreement. President Lockhart agrees. Okay, good. So we’re ready to
take a vote.
MS. DANKER. Okay. This vote covers alternative B as in the handout, with the
substitution of the “Moreover” sentence from the September statement: “Moreover, there are
significant downside risks to the economic outlook, including strains in global financial
markets.” And in paragraph 4, it retains “through mid-2013.” It encompasses the associated
directive as well.

November 1–2, 2011

Chairman Bernanke
Vice Chairman Dudley
Governor Duke
President Evans
President Fisher
President Kocherlakota
President Plosser
Governor Raskin
Governor Tarullo
Governor Yellen

238 of 282

Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes

CHAIRMAN BERNANKE. Okay. Thank you very much. A few announcements.
First, I do have a press conference at 2:15. It will be the usual format. It’ll be screened in the
Special Library, if anybody has nothing better to do. [Laughter] As has been the case, I will
focus on our projections and talk about our policy stance in the context of those projections. I’m
going to say that we discussed communications frameworks today. I will say we didn’t come to
any conclusions. I was thinking of saying that there was a sense that there was no need for a
fundamental change in framework, that we were looking within the context of our current
framework to try to find ways to better explain our policy expectations and outlook. Any
concern about that? [No response] Okay. So that’s at 2:15.
Coffee is available for those who would like to have some coffee, and there will be lunch
served in the anteroom at 11:30. The next meeting is on December 13. Thank you.
END OF MEETING