View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Larry Promisel
Introduction
May 21, 1984

The U.S. External Position
This afternoon we will provide a long-term perspective on the
external position of the United States.

Our presentation will use the

package of materials that has been distributed to you and will be in three
parts.
First, Peter Hooper will analyze how we got to where we are,
focusing on the unprecedented deficit now being observed in the U.S. current
account.
Peter Isard then will discuss where the present high level of the
dollar --

if

it

were maintained --

would take us, in terms of our current

account and our external investment position.
Finally, Dale Henderson will consider the implications of
alternative scenarios --

embodying both exogenous and policy-induced

declines in the dollar.
Let me turn to Mr. Hooper.

Peter Hooper
Part I

The first chart in the package of materials places recent
movements in the U.S. current account in a historical perspective.
shown in the top panel,

As

the United States ran a current account surplus,

on average, during most of the post-war period.
about in balance in 1980, but it

The current account was

has dropped sharply over the past two

years, reaching an estimated deficit of about $85 billion at an annual
rate in the first quarter of this year, more than five times as large as
any annual deficit recorded prior to last year.
panel,

As shown in the bottom

the recent decline in the current account is less dramatic when

expressed relative to GNP,

but it

still

reaches a level that is well

outside the post-war historical range of plus or minus one percent of
GNP.
The top panel of Chart 2 presents two measures of the U.S.
external investment position, or the level of U.S. assets held abroad
minus foreign assets held in the United States.

The solid line shows the

officially recorded external investment position, and the dashed line,
which begins at the recorded position in 1948, shows movements in the
cumulated current account.

By either measure the external investment

position has been substantially positive during most of the past 35
years,

contributing to a comfortable surplus on U.S.

income receipts.

net investment

In recent years, the cumulated current account has

fallen substantially below the recorded series.

This difference largely

reflects recent increases in the statistical discrepancy, or unreported
transactions, in the U.S. international accounts.

The solid line

implicitly treats the discrepancy as unreported current account
transactions,
capital

while the dashed line implicitly treats it

flows.

as unreported

We have reason to believe that much of the discrepancy

does reflect unreported capital flows,

so that the recorded series, or

the solid line in the chart, gives an optimistic picture of our present
external investment position.
In any event, the evidence points to a substantial decline in
the U.S. external position.

The developments underlying this decline can

be analyzed at two levels, as outlined in Chart 3.

The first involves

accounting for the effects of the proximate determinants of the trade and
non-trade components of the current account.
include:

The proximate determinants

(1) changes in U.S. price competitiveness, (2) movements in the

relative cyclical positions of the United Sates and its major trading
partners, and (3) changes in other factors that have directly affected
the current account.

These other factors include international debt

problems, which have affected our exports, and changes in oil prices and
oil consumption,

which have affected our imports.

The second level of

analysis involves accounting for shifts in more fundamental factors that
affect the current account indirectly, through their impacts on the
proximate determinants.

In particular, these include fiscal and monetary

policies--here and abroad--and other exogenous factors affecting
international asset preferences.
Movements in the first proximate determinant,
competitiveness,

U.S. price

are indicated in the top panel of Chart 4, which shows

the weighted average foreign exchange value of the dollar adjusted for
relative consumer prices.

On this index, the dollar rose more than 40

percent between the fourth quarter of 1980 and the first quarter of 1984.

Movements in relative cyclical positions are illustrated in the
bottom panel,
countries.

which shows real GNP in the United States and other G-10
Since the fourth quarter of 1980,

three percent more than foreign GNP.

U.S.

GNP has risen about

Most of this relative increase took

place over the past year, as the U.S. economy recovered faster from a
deeper recession in 1982.
Chart 5 shows U.S.

exports to developing countries.

As

indicated by the solid line, our total exports to this area declined
between 1980 and the first quarter of 1984.

This decline reflects, in

particular, the efforts of countries burdened by debt to cut back on
their imports.

U.S. exports to the ten major countries experiencing

serious debt problems,

indicated by the dashed line, fell by $15 billion

over this period.
Chart 6 provides a summary allocation of the $85 billion
decline in the current account since 1980 among the main proximate
determinants.

Based,

in part, on model simulations, we would allocate

about $70 billion to the decline in U.S. price competitiveness, roughly
$20 billion to the relative strength of the U.S. cyclical recovery, and
another $15 billion to the contraction of demand from developing
countries with debt problems.

Working in a positive direction was a $20

billion effect due to the decline in oil prices during this period and
further declines in domestic oil consumption.
Several fundamental developments underlie the shifts in these
proximate determinants.

The change in U.S. fiscal policy over the past

three years has attracted considerable attention.
7 shows the increase in the structural,

The top line in Chart

or high employment,

budget deficit from its low of $30 billion in 1981.

federal

The structural

deficit in 1984 is expected to have risen by about $100 billion since

The chart also shows model-

1981, or by about 3 percent of current GNP.

based estimates of the effects of that increase.

We estimate that the

U.S. fiscal expansion will increase real GNP to a level

about 2-1/2

percent above where it otherwise would be in 1984, contributing
substantially to the growth of import demand.
growth, the fiscal expansion keeps U.S. real

Assuming unchanged money
interest rates about 2-1/2

percentage points above where they otherwise would be.

Taking into

account some sypathetic increase in foreign interest rates, such a rise
in U.S. interest rates suggests that the dollar is about 8 percent higher
in 1984 as a result of the U.S.

fiscal expansion.

The appreciation of the dollar, in turn, has two effects.
First, by reducing the price of imports,

it

largely offsets the

inflationary effects of the expansion, leaving the path of domestic
prices about unchanged, as shown in line 5.

Second, it contributes,

along with the expansion of real GNP, to the widening of the current
account deficit--shown in line 6. The current account is also affected
by the rise in interest rates, which has a small effect on net investment
income receipts, and which tends to depress exports to countries with
debt problems.

The net impact of the fiscal expansion on the current

account by 1984 is an estimated $30 billion larger deficit.
These estimates leave most of the rise in the dollar and its
impact on the current account unexplained.
at least in part,

This shortfall could reflect,

the limitations of the models employed.

In particular,

the models do not incorporate forward looking expectations and,
therefore, miss the effects of anticipated future budget deficits on real
interest rates and exchange rates.
fundamental

However, it also indicates that other

factors were influencing the dollar.

The price adjusted dollar is shown again as the solid line in
Chart 8.

The dashed line in the chart shows the differential between

a measure of U.S. long-term real interest rates and a weighted average of
foreign long-term real rates.

In theory, this differential provides a

link between the exchange rate and underlying economic policies.

In

practice, the relationship between the real interest rate differential
and the real exchange rate has varied considerably in the short run, but
it

is evident that the longer-run movements in the two series have been

fairly consistently correlated over most of the floating-rate period.
Since mid-1979,

U.S.

real interest rates have risen more than

6 percentage points relative to foreign real rates.

Most of this rise

followed the move to greater monetary restraint in the United States than
abroad, beginning in late 1979.

By the time the shift in U.S. fiscal

policy was implemented at the end of 1981, the interest rate differential
had begun to level off.

Some of the effects of the U.S.

could have been anticipated earlier.

fiscal expansion

However, the primary effect of that

expansion, against a background of fiscal restraint abroad,

was to keep

the interest differential from falling to a substantially lower level in
1982 and beyond.
As indicated in the chart, the rise in the real interest
differential since 1979,

has been associated with much of the dollar's

appreciation in real terms.

However, the dollar continued to rise after

the interest differential leveled off in 1982.

A good deal of this

subsequent gap has been attributed to exogenous political and economic
developments abroad,

including "safe haven" considerations, that have

shifted preferences in favor of dollar-denominated assets.

In the

absence of these factors, the dollar would have been noticeably lower and
the interest rate differential somewhat higher.

In conclusion,

a rough accounting of the various fundamental

factors suggests that changes in economic policies in recent years can
explain most of the widening of the current account deficit due to
cyclical factors.

To the extent that these policy changes were

responsible for changes in real

interest rates, they could also explain

more than half of the increase in the deficit due to reduced price
competitiveness.

This combined effect would amount to about two thirds

of the widening of the current account deficit, excluding the favorable
movement in oil imports.

Much of the remaining increase in the deficit

reflects the effects of other exogenous developments that have influenced
international asset preferences.
Mr. Isard will now continue our presentation.

-8-

Peter Isard
Part II

I will focus on the implications for our international accounts
during the rest of the decade if
average value.

the dollar remains around its current

I will also discuss why the staff believes that the

current high level of the dollar is not sustainable.
The top panel of Chart 9 shows a simulation of how the U.S.
merchandise trade and current account deficits would expand through 1990
with the average nominal foreign exchange value of the dollar unchanged
at its recent index level of 130.

The lower panel shows the simulated

values of key explanatory variables.

The simulated values for 1984 and

1985 are based on the staff's current Greenbook projections, but are
adjusted to be consistent with the assumption that the value of the
dollar will remain constant; the Greenbook forecast is that the dollar
will depreciate by roughly 15 percent by the end of 1985.

The simulated

values for 1986 through 1990 were derived by making similar adjustments
to an extrapolation of the Greenbook projections, which assumed fairly
similar growth and inflation rates in the United States and the G-10
countries, and a somewhat higher growth rate for the developing
countries.

The assumption of an unchanged value of the dollar tends to

depress U.S. growth and inflation and to stimulate foreign growth and
inflation relative to the Greenbook forecast and its extrapolation.
Referring to the upper panel,

the simulated values of the

trade and current account deficts widen to around $180 billion in 1990.
Much of the widening of these deficits occurs in 1984.

The diminishing

year-to-year changes in the trade deficit from 1984 through 1987 mainly
reflect three factors:

first, the wearing off of the lagged effects on

trade flows of the dollar's appreciation to date; second,
pick up in foreign activity growth and slowdown in U.S.

a projected
activity growth;

and third, the assumption that the dollar price of oil will remain
constant through 1987, which reduces temporarily the growth in the value
of imports.

Starting in 1988, however, the trade deficit again begins to

widen by $10 to $15 billion a year, and that underlying trend would
continue into the next decade had we extended our simulations.

The

period beginning in 1988 is one in which imports and exports are
simulated to be expanding at fairly similar percentage rates, and the
underlying trend in the trade deficit results from the initial condition
that imports exceed exports by nearly $150 billion in 1988.

It may also

be noted from the chart that the difference between the current account
and the trade balance declines fairly gradually and shows only a small
deficit in 1990.
The explanation for the gradual decline in the current account
relative to the trade balance is summarized in Chart 10, which compares
the simulated values of current account components for 1990 with data for
1983.

The last column shows that under an unchanged dollar, our net

income from portfolio investments (line 4) would decline by $62 billion
from 1983 to 1990, while our net income from direct investments (line 5)
would rise by $21 billion and our net receipts from other services and
transfers (line 6) would increase by $15 billion.

The decline in net

income from portfolio investments mainly reflects the rapid build-up of
our external debt, while a large part of the rise in net direct
investment income reflects a rebound in earnings on our existing stock of

-10-

direct investments overseas as rising foreign economic growth and
capacity utilization rates lead to a substantial pick-up in profits from
levels that recently have been very depressed,

and as foreign inflation

increases the nominal value of those earnings.
Given this simulation of how our external deficits would expand
if

the dollar remained around its current average value, it

is

natural to

ask whether the current strength of the dollar is sustainable.

One

analytic framework for discussing sustainability is to consider whether
variables that seem relevant are projected to get better or worse.

A

starting point is the question of whether the state of U.S tradable goods
industries would get better or worse.
question.

Chart 11 helps to address this

Under the assumptions of a constant nominal exchange value of

the dollar and inflation rates slightly higher in foreign countries than
in the United States, prices of U.S. tradable goods would decline
gradually relative to prices of foreign tradable goods.

In other words,

although the value of the dollar would remain unchanged in nominal terms,
it

would depreciate gradually in real terms.

In this sense, U.S.

tradable goods industries as a group would benefit gradually from an
easing of the pressures that they have been placed under by the
substantial appreciation of the dollar over the past several years.

The

expansion of economic activity abroad would also stimulate the volume of
U.S. exports, which are simulated to recover by 1990 to a volume nearly
20 percent higher than the 1980 peak.

Even though the volume of

merchandise imports after 1984 would rise at almost the same pace as
exports, the continuing growth of the U.S. economy would lead to
continuing expansion in U.S.

tradable goods industries.

-11-

Although the projected state of U.S.

tradable goods industries

does not appear to suggest that the current strength of the dollar is
unsustainable, a different picture emerges from focusing on the extent to
which the United States would be relying on saving from abroad.

In Chart

12, the top panel shows that our current account deficit, or net capital
inflow, would be absorbing a growing proportion of foreign net saving.
Although estimates of foreign saving are necessarily crude,

we estimate

that with an unchanged exchange rate the fraction would rise to about 61/2 percent in 1984 and 7-1/2 percent in 1990.

The lower panel shows

that our current account deficit is expected to expand to about 2-1/2
percent of our GNP this year and would exceed 3 percent of GNP in 1990.
If we extended our simulations beyond 1990, we would expect these ratios
to continue to grow gradually, rather than to move back toward zero.
An important implication is illustrated in Chart 13.

Based on

the estimate that our recorded external investment position was $135
billion at the end of 1983 (which, as Mr. Hooper suggested, may well
overstate the true position),

and also making the assumption that future

statistical discrepancies in the balance of payments accounts will
average to zero, the simulated stream of current account deficits would
lead to a net debtor position for the United States of around $800
billion by the end of 1990.

Moreover,

as indicated in the lower panel,

the stock of our net external debt would expand by 1990 to about 14
percent of the GNP available to service the debt, and that ratio would
not level off over the foreseeable future.
The prospect of a rising ratio of external debt to GNP over the
foreseeable future is the basis for the staff's view that the current
strength of the dollar is not sustainable over the long run.

As

-12-

highlighted in Chart 14,

in our view, and consistent with analytic models

of steady-state equilibrium, an essential requirement for sustainability
is

that our external investment position relative to GNP must stabilize.

On the assumption that foreign GNP and wealth variables will grow at
about the same rate as U.S. GNP over the long run, our sustainability
criterion is

also a requirement for stabilizing the share of U.S.

the portfolios of foreign wealth holders.

As an approximation, meeting

the sustainability criterion requires that the dollar depreciate,
terms,

debt in

sufficiently to eliminate the trade deficit.

in real

With the trade

accounts roughly in balance, the growth rate of the stock of net external
debt would be approximately equal to the nominal interest rate,

since the

change in the external debt -- namely, the current account deficit -would be approximately equal to net investment income payments, or to the
stock of debt multiplied by the nominal interest rate.

Thus, to the

extent that the nominal interest rate can be expected to be approximately
equal in the long run to the growth rate of nominal GNP, with the trade
accounts roughly in balance over the long run,

the growth rates of

external debt and nominal GNP could be expected to be approximately the
same,

thus satisfying the sustainability criterion.
The issue of sustainability should be distinguished from

considerations of desirability, which are also highlighted in the chart.
In the short run, the strength of the dollar and our current account
deficit provide several benefits.

Our current account deficit reduces

the upward pressure on domestic interest rates that would develop if
large federal budget deficits and growing private domestic demands for
credit had to be financed from domestic saving alone.

Moreover, the

growth of U.S. imports has expansionary effects on economic activity

-13-

abroad and eases the process of adjustment in countries burdened with
debt.

Over the longer run, judgements about desirability can be framed

in terms of two questions.

To what extent is borrowing from abroad

leading to greater capital formation in the United States?

And is

borrowing by the United States consistent with an efficient and equitable
allocation of world saving -- that is,
into countries where it

with world saving being channeled

can be invested most productively,

or where it

desired to support consumption levels that are considered to be
appropriate on the basis of welfare judgements?
While these issues of desirability are important, a more
central focus of our presentation today is on the issue of
sustainability, which Mr. Henderson will now address further.

is

-14-

Dale W. Henderson
Part III

According to the analysis presented by Mr. Isard, if the
foreign exchange value of the dollar were to remain at its current high
level, the U.S. external position would be unsustainable, in the sense
that our net external debt would continue to rise relative to our GNP.
Such analysis has led many observers to conclude that sooner or later
there will be a substantial drop in the exchange value of the dollar.
Therefore,

I will first discuss the implications of two possible paths of

dollar depreciation that are shown in Chart 15.
In each case, the dollar's depreciation is assumed to be caused
by a shift in market sentiment against the dollar with no change in U.S.
or foreign economic policies.

This shift might result from a negative

reappraisal of the U.S. external position or a reduction in "safe haven"
demand for dollar assets.

The path of gradual depreciation is the path

projected by the Staff in the Greenbook plus an extension through early
1988.

Along this path the dollar falls from its current level to about

its average level for the floating rate period through 1980 -- a total
depreciation of about 30 percent.

Depreciation could follow this path if

all private agents gradually revised their views about the prospects for
the dollar or if

some groups revised their views later than others.

Another possible path is the path of rapid depreciation.

Along this

path, the dollar falls over two years from its current level to one that
is

roughly consistent with a sustainable external position -- a total

depreciation of about 45 percent.

This path might be generated by an

abrupt change in opinion about the implications of the current value of
the dollar for our external position.

-15-

The effects of the two depreciations on the U.S.
position are shown in Chart 16.

external

As shown in the top panel,

both the

gradual depreciation and the rapid depreciation contract the current
account deficit relative to the level implied by an unchanged dollar.
However,

as shown in the bottom panel only the rapid depreciation

generates a sustainable U.S.

external position by stopping the decline

in the external investment position relative to GNP.

The depreciation

required for sustainability is larger than the one that would be
necessary to return to historical exchange rate relationships because it
must compensate for a permanently lower level of demand for our exports
by both developed and developing countries.
Chart 17 shows some of the effects of the two hypothetical
depreciation paths on the U.S. economy.

As shown in the top panel, U.S.

real GNP is initially higher with the depreciations than with an
unchanged dollar because the depreciations stimulate demand for U.S.
goods.

However, real GNP is subsequently lower because demand is choked

off by interest rate increases.

The average annual growth rate of real

GNP along all three paths is about 3 percent.
The bottom panel indicates the extent to which the
depreciations affect the rate of consumer price inflation both directly,
through the price of imports,
economic activity.

and indirectly,

through the level of

The inflation rate, like real GNP, is first higher

and later lower than with an unchanged dollar.

In 1985 and 1986,

inflation is 2 percentage points higher with the gradual depreciation and
3 percentage points higher with the rapid depreciation.

For both

depreciations the level of consumer prices is always higher.

As shown in Chart 18, given an unchanged path of money,

the

initial increases in GNP and prices lead to substantial increases
in the Treasury bill rate.

These increases explain why real GNP is

eventually lower for a time than with an unchanged dollar.

The

depreciations have contractionary effects abroad; weighted average
foreign real GNP and consumer price inflation are lower throughout the
simulation horizon.
So far I have discussed the implications of exchange rate
changes that might result from a shift in market sentiment with no change
in economic policies.

The gradual depreciation by itself does not appear

to be enough to stabilize the ratio of the external investment position
to GNP by 1990.

However, the gradual depreciation combined with

plausible policy actions can achieve this result.

I will consider the

implications of two possible policy scenarios.

The first is

contraction with no change in monetary policy.

The second is a change in

a fiscal

the policy mix, that involves the same fiscal contraction accompanied by
a monetary expansion sufficient to keep real GNP roughly unchanged.

In

both cases, the fiscal contraction represents a 40 percent reduction in
the structural budget deficit beginning in 1986.
Chart 19 shows how the two policy actions affect the exchange
value of the dollar.

As you have already seen, the dollar depreciates

significantly along the gradual depreciation path.

Its value is even

lower with the policy actions -- an average of 4 percent lower with the
fiscal contraction and 11 percent lower with the change in policy mix.
The dollar is lower with the policy actions because U.S. interest rates
are lower.

-17-

Chart 20 shows how both policy actions reinforce the effects of
the gradual depreciation alone on the U.S. external position.

As

indicated in the top panel, both actions lead to substantial narrowing of
the U.S. current account deficit in the last five years of the decade.
These reductions occur because the value of the dollar and U.S. interest
rates are lower with both actions.

In addition, U.S. GNP and prices are

lower with the fiscal contraction.

The effect of the change in mix is

greater than that of the fiscal contraction because the decreases in the
value of the dollar and U.S.

interest rates are so much larger.

indicated in the bottom panel,

As

combining either policy action with a

gradual depreciation yields a roughly sustainable external position.
With the fiscal contraction the U.S. external investment position
relative to GNP stops declining by the end of the simulation period.
With the change in mix that ratio actually starts to rise.
Some of the effects of the two policy actions on the U.S.
economy are summarized in Chart 21.

As shown in the top panel, with the

change in policy mix, real GNP follows the gradual depreciation path by
assumption.

With the fiscal contraction alone, real GNP is below the

gradual depreciation path from the fourth quarter of 1985 on by an averge
of one percent.

The bottom panel shows the impacts of the policy actions

on the rate of consumer price inflation.

With the fiscal contraction,

inflation is initially higher than without it, because of the additional
depreciation of the dollar.

However, the effects of the additional

depreciation are transitory, and inflation is eventually lower because of
the reduced level of economic activity.

With the change in policy mix,

the increase in inflation is more pronounced and longer lasting than with

-18-

the fiscal contraction because there is even more additional depreciation.
According to the top panel of Chart 22, with the fiscal
contraction the Treasury bill rate is
percentage points.

lower by an amount that reaches two

The bill rate is lower because nominal GNP is

lower.

The change in policy mix generates a much more rapid and larger drop in
the path of the bill rate because interest rates must fall by enough to
keep the path of GNP unchanged in the face of the fiscal contraction.
These decreases in the interest rate explain why both policy actions
cause additional dollar depreciation and why the change in mix causes
more.
The bottom panel of Chart 22 shows that both policy actions
generate significant improvements in the federal budget deficit.
the fiscal contraction the deficit is

With

reduced by an amount that reaches

$95 billion by the end of the simulation horizon.

The reduction in the

actual deficit is less than the reduction in the structural deficit
because the decrease in nominal GNP leads to a loss in tax revenues that
more than offsets the decline in interest payments.

With the change in

policy mix, the deficit is reduced by an amount that reaches $140 billion
by 1990.

The reduction in the actual deficit is greater than the

reduction in the structural deficit because the price level and,
therefore, nominal income and tax revenues are higher and because
interest payments are lower.
Both policy actions have relatively small effects abroad.
U.S.

The

fiscal contraction slightly reduces foreign real GNP and foreign

inflation during the last five years of the decade.

In the case of the

change in the U.S. policy mix -- often suggested by Europeans --

foreign

real GNP is roughly unchanged compared to just a gradual depreciation

-19-

while foreign inflation is reduced by somewhat less than 1 percent on
average over the simulation period.
Let me summarize the presentation we have made this afternoon.
The enlargement of the U.S.

current account deficit in the 1980's can be

directly attributed to the sharp reduction in U.S. price competitiveness
and, to a lesser extent, to the relative strength of the U.S. recovery
and reduced imports by developing countries.

In turn, these developments

can be traced in large part to changes in monetary and fiscal policies at
home and abroad and, in the case of the reduction in price
competitiveness, to a shift in asset preferences in favor of the dollar.
In our view an unchanged dollar exchange rate implies a U.S.
external position that is not sustainable in the long run because our net
external debt would rise faster than our nominal GNP.
Our scenarios illustrate several ways in which the ratio of our
external investment position to GNP could be stablized by 1990.

One

possibility is an abrupt shift in market sentiment away from the dollar
that generates a rapid depreciation of the dollar by 45 percent from its
current high level.

Another possibility is a more gradual shift in

sentiment away from the dollar that takes the dollar down to historical
average levels combined with one or another plausible U.S. macroeconomic
policy action that takes the dollar somewhat lower for a total
depreciation of 35 to 40 percent.
Finally, I would like to emphasize that our scenarios are
intended to be illustrative of the general process of correction:

a

stable ratio of net external debt to GNP could be achieved by other
combinations of changes in sentiment about the dollar and policy actions
here and abroad.

Moreover, a stable ratio need not be achieved by 1990.

STRICTLY CONFIDENTIAL (FR) CLASS II-FOMC

MaterialsforStaff Presentation to the
Federal Open Market Committee

The U.S. External Position
May 21, 1984

Chart 1

U.S. Current Account
Billions of dollars
25

+

0

25

1948-80 Average = $.9 billion

50

75
Q1
100
1955

1950

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

U.S. Current Account Relative to GNP
Percent
2

1

+
0

1

1948-80 Average = .2 %
2

Q1
1950
Note: 1984 data are

1955
Q1

1960

estimates at an annual rate.

1965

1970

1975

1980

Chart 2

U.S. External Investment Position
Billions of dollars

250

-200

Recorded External
Investment Position

-150

-- 1100

Cumulated Current Account*

I

I
1950

I l I I
1955

------------------------

II

I
1960

*From base of 1948 recorded external investment position.
Note: 1984 data are Q1 estimates.

I I l
1965

I
1970

Qt01

II
i
1975

l l

l
1980

I I

Chart 3

ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK

I Proximate Determinants
* Price competitiveness
* Relative cyclical positions
* Other factors
International debt problems
Oil
II Fundamental Determinants
* Economic policies
* Asset preferences

Chart 4

Price Adjusted Foreign Exchange Value of the U.S. Dollar
: :: :::

:

March 1973= 100
::
:
130

::

.

-- 110

:: ... .

Weighted Average Dollar*/

..........

Relative Consumer Prices
1
..........
......

- 100

..

90

1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
Weghted 1974 against or of foreign G-1 countries using total 1972-76 average trade of these countries.
average
1980 Q4= 100
- I
I
I
::1: :: :
::
::: :: : : :
.. 115

u.s
.

...... :....

,III1....... .
....... 1.......
1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

7
1984

Chart 5

U.S. Exports to Developing Countries
-

Countri:::::::::
Total

STen

Debt Problems*

/

Billions of dollars
: : : : : : :
100

:::::::::::::::::::--

...

::::

'i
-

I

SI
1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

:

-

.. ..... .
......
1980

*Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Mexico, Nigeria, Peru, Philippines and Venezuela.
Note: 1984 data are Q1 estimates at an annual rate.

1982

1984

20

Chart 6

Allocation of Decline in Current Account
Among Proximate Determinants
Billions of dollars

1. Decline in Current Account, 1980 to 1984 Q1

-85

2. Decline in U.S. Price Competitiveness

-70

3. Cyclical - Relative Strength of U.S. Recovery

-20

4. International Debt Problems

-15

5. Decline in Oil Prices and Consumption

+20

Chart 7

Estimated Impacts of
Increase in Structural Budget Deficit
Calendar Years
1982

1. Increase in Structural Deficit
from 1981 Level ($ billions)

1983

35

66

1984

102

Impact on Levels of:
2. Real GNP (percent)

11/4

21/2

21/2

¾

2

2 1/2

8

3. Treasury Bill Rate
(percentage points)

4. Exchange Rate (percent)

3

6

5. Prices (percent)

0

0

6. Current Account Balance
($ billions)

-8

-17

1/4

-30

Chart 8

Price Adjusted Dollar and Long-Term Real Interest Rate Differential

Percentage points

March 1973= 100

S-

120

6-

Price Adjusted
Dollar
-110

3

-100

-90

Interest Rate
Differential*
3-80

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

*Differential between U.S. and weighted average foreign long-term government bond yields minus differential between 12-quarter centered
moving averages of U.S. and foreign consumer price inflation rates.

Chart 9

U.S. Merchandise Trade and Current Account Balances

1990

1988

1986

1984

1982

1980

Billions of dollars

Explanatory Variables

Simulated With Unchanged Dollar
1984

1. Exchange Rate Index

1985

Annual
Average
1986-1990

130

130

130

Percent change, Q4/Q4

Real GNP Growth Rates
2. United States

5

21/2

3

3. G-10 Countries

2¾

3

31/2

4. Developing Countries

31/2

41/2

5

5. United States

5

5¼

5

6. G-10 Countries

5¾

6 1/2

63/4

Inflation Rates*

*Based

on consumer price indexes.

Chart 10

Current Account Components
Simulated with Unchanged Dollar
Billions of dollars
1983

1990

Change

1. Current Account

-41

-183

-142

2. Merchandise Trade

-61

-177

-116

3. Net Investment Income
4.

24

-17

-41

9

-53

-62

Portfolio

5. Direct

6. Other Services and Transfers

15

-4

36

21

11

15

Chart 11

Volume of Merchandise Exports and Imports
Ratio scale, 1980= 100

180
Simulated with unchanged dollar

SActual

170

SO-

160

-

-150

Imports
-

140

-

130

-120

S- 110

Exports

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

Chart 12

U.S. Current Account Relative to Foreign Net Saving*
F

1980

Actual

1982

Simulated with unchanged dollar

1984

U.S. Current Account Relative to U.S. GNP
Percent

*Estimated

gross saving less capital consumption.

Chart 13

U.S. External Investment Position

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1988

1990

U.S. External Investment Position Relative to GNP
Actual

1980

1982

Simulated with unchanged dollar

1984

1986

Chart 14

SUSTAINABILITY
*

External investment position relative to GNP must stabilize.

DESIRABILITY
*

Short run benefits
* Current account deficit reduces upward pressure on domestic
interest rates.
* Growth of U.S. imports has expansionary effects on economic activity
abroad and eases current account adjustment in countries burdened
with debt.

*

Long run questions
* To what extent is borrowing from abroad leading to greater capital
formation in the United States?
* Is borrowing by the United States consistent with an efficient and
equitable allocation of world saving?

Chart 15

Foreign Exchange Value of the U.S. Dollar
March 1973= 100
130

Unchanged Dollar
-120

110

Gradual Depreciation

\

\ 100

-

90

\

80

-

Rapid Depreciation

\

L -------------------

1986

1988

70

1990

Chart 16

Effects on U.S. External Position
Current Account
Billions of dollars

External Investment Position Relative to GNP
Percent

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

Chart 17

Effects on U.S. Economy
Real GNP
Billions of 1972 dollars

/

-

1950

-11900

/0/

-- 1850

-- 1800

Rapid Depreciation

-1750

radual Depreciation

-- 1700

Unchanged Dollar

-11650

1600
1984

1986

1988

1990

Inflation
Rapid Depreciation
Gradual

1984

Unchanged Dollar

1986

1988

1990

Chart 18

Treasury Bill Rate
Percent
116

Rapid Depreciation

-- 14
1

---

--

12

Gradual Depreciation

-10

-

1984

98

198

1986

198

1988

1990
1990

8

Chart 19

Foreign Exchange Value of the U.S. Dollar
March 1973= 100

--

-130

-120

Gradual Depreciation
Plus Fiscal Contraction
-110

-

100
\

S\

Gradual Depreciation

-

- 90

Gradual Depreciation
Plus Change in Policy Mix

----80

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

Chart 20

Effects on U.S. External Position
Current Account
Billions of dollars

0

Plus Change in
Policy Mix 0

; -Plus

40

Fiscal Contraction

S 80

Gradual Depreciation
120

160

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1988

1990

External Investment Position Relative to GNP

1980

1982

1984

1986

Chart 21

Effects on U.S. Economy
Real GNP
Billions of 1972 dollars

I
1950

--

Gradual Depreciation

Plus Change in
Policy Mix

/

1900

-1850

-- 1800

/

-1750

/

Plus Fiscal Contraction

/
1700

-11650

L

I

I
1986

1988

1

1

1600
1990

Inflation
Percent
8

Plus Change in
Policy Mix

7

Gradual Depreciation
6
5

Plus Fiscal Contraction
1984
1984

1986
1986

1988
1988

1990

1990

Chart 22

Treasury Bill Rate
Percent
1 11

Gradual Depreciation
10

9

Plus Fiscal Contraction

8

Plus Change in
Policy Mix
7

I

L

1984

1986

I

I

1988

I

Federal Budget Deficit

I

6
1990

Billions of dollars
-100

Plus Change in
Policy Mix

-

--

-140

---180

Plus Fiscal Contraction

-- -220

Gradual Depreciation

1984

198

198
1986

198
1988

-260

190
1990

-300

Notes for F.O.M.C. Meeting
May 22, 1984
Sam Y. Cross
Since your last FOMC meeting the dollar has risen by
6 percent against the European currencies and 4 percent
against the Japanese yen.

It has regained most of the

decline registered in February and early March, and now
stands only a few percentage points below the highs of last
January.
The dollar started rising right after the last FOMC
meeting, and the rise continued through most of the period.
The main factor buoying the dollar was the fresh evidence of
robust expansion in the U.S. economy.

The prospect of heavy

private credit demands,along with continuing large government
financing needs, led exchange market participants to expect
U.S. interest rates to be under upward pressure, perhaps
strong upward pressure, and the dollar moved upward in
response.
The rises in U.S. interest rates which occurred were
not equaled by increases elsewhere.

In the Euromarkets,

differentials in favor of the dollar over both mark-and
yen-denominated deposits increased by about 1 percentage
point
period.

and ranged between 5 and 6 points at the end of the
These widening interest rate differentials, at a

time when price data showed little or no acceleration of

U.S. inflation, appear to have restored the dollar's
attractiveness for investment.

The deterioration in the long

term credit markets both in the U.S. and abroad, associated
with uncertainties about the interest rate and economic
outlook, has led many investors to liquidate long-term
fixed-rate securities and park funds temporarily in high
yielding short term dollar instruments.

And the talk about

portfolio shifts out of dollars that was so prevalent earlier
in the year- has subsided.
There were also factors tending to depress investor
interest in major foreign currencies, particularly the mark
and the yen.

Labor problems in Germany raised questions

about the sustainability of that country's outstanding
industrial performance.

Recently, the yen declined

reflecting Japan's particular dependency on the Persian Gulf
and concern about the choking off of oil supplies from that
region.

In both countries, recent weakness in stock prices

appears to have been associated with renewed inflows into
U.S. equities.
With the German mark weakening during much of the
intermeeting period, pressures against the other EMS
currencies subsided.

Their central banks took advantage of

the opportunity to rebuild official reserves, and to reduce
domestic interest rates in some cases so as to encourage
economic recovery.

In April as the dollar continued to move higher, the
Bundesbank sold dollars occasionally and sometimes in size to
resist the dollar's rise.

In early May the Bundesbank

stepped up its intervention, and on May 10 enlisted the
cooperation of several other European central banks in
coordinated dollar sales of nearly
Following that day's operations, the dollar eased
back against the European currencies for several days.

That

easing reflected some wariness in the market that the central
banks might be gearing up for major and concerted
intervention to push the dollar lower.

In addition, it

reflected some skittishness that developed in the exchange
markets over the emerging funding problems of Continental
Illinois

and also concerns over the effect of rising

interest rates on heavily indebted LDCs.

These developments

were seen in the exchange markets as possible constraints on
U.S. monetary policy.

Today the dollar is slightly below the

levels reached in early May against the major currencies.
There were no Treasury or Federal Reserve operations
during the period.

There was an arrangement, announced at

the end of March, under which a temporary bridging credit of
$500 million was provided to the Government of Argentina to

enable that country to repay certain bank interest arrears
while it negotiates with the IMF on an adjustment program.
Within the credit package, the Governments of Mexico,
Venezuela, Brazil and Colombia provided

with an

understanding that after Argentina signs a letter of intent
with the IMF, the U.S. Treasury will provide $300 million in

temporary swap credits which can be used to repay the four
Latin American lenders.

Any credit provided by the Treasury,

in turn, will be repaid from Argentina's IMF drawings.
arrangement was proposed by the Mexican authorities,
regard it

This

and we

as a very constructive move, designed to encourage

agreement between Argentina and the IMF.

Discussionsare

still continuing between Argentina and the IMF on an adjustment
program, and also between Argentina and the commercial banks
on a rescheduling and financing agreement.

May 21,

Mr.

1984

Sternlight made the following

statement:

Domestic open market operations during the past
inter-meeting interval were driven by a huge run-up and then sharp
decline in Treasury balances at the Federal Reserve.
complications arose in
the huge rise in

Further

the final two weeks of the period because of

discount window borrowing by Continental Illinois

National Bank, which faced severe funding problems.

Throughout the

period the Desk was aiming essentially for a steady degree of
restraint on bank reserve positions, about unchanged from the degree
of reserve availability prevailing shortly before the late March
meeting, and deemed to be consistent with the Committee's preferred
growth rates for monetary aggregates for the March-to-June period.
Taken together,
track.

the monetary aggregates seemed

to be reasonably on

Questions about the appropriate seasonal adjustments made

the data for M1 difficult to interpret, although by mid-May it
looked as though M1 was coming back to around the middle of its
annual growth range after slipping quite low in its
April.

M2 seemed to grow in the lower part of its

while M3 was pushing a little

range in late
annual range

over the upper bound of its

range.

Notwithstanding the approximately steady reserve pressures sought
during the period-associated with seasonal and adjustment borrowing
of

$1 billion and excess reserves of $600 million-most market

interest rates increased sharply.
The Federal funds rate edged up irregularly through most of
the period,

advancing from an average ranging around 10 percent in

the latter half of March to roughly 10 1/4 percent up to late April

-2-

and closer to 10 1/2 percent from late April to mid-May.
reflected the discount rate increase in

The rise

early April and then

particular reserve stringencies when the Treasury balance was
peaking in

late April and early May.

In the last few days the rate

fell off again to the 9 - 10 percent area reflecting the bulge in
reserves produced by Continental's borrowing,

not all

of which the

Desk mopped up immediately.
In the first

two maintenance periods, nonborrowed reserves

came in below path and borrowings somewhat above.

In the April 11

period there was substantial discount window borrowing possibly in
anticipation of a discount rate hike; this produced an abundance of
reserves and Desk action to meet the path in full would have caused
a misleading over-abundance.

In the April 25 period,

the undershoot

resulted from an inability to provide as many reserves as had been
intended, as Treasury balances soared on the final day.
borrowed and nonborrowed reserves were close to path in
period,

but fresh problems arose in

Both
the May 9

this final period-the one

ending May 23-as borrowing began to be inflated by Continental's
large-scale use of the window.

While the path was not formally

changed because of this special borrowing,

the Account Management

increasingly regarded the special borrowing as closely

akin to

nonborrowed reserves, and therefore aimed in effect for an
undershoot of the formal path.
To meet the huge reserve need occasioned by the run-up in
Treasury balances at the Federal Reserve from a customary $3 billion
in early April to over $16 billion late in

that month,

the Desk used

-3-

a combination of bill and coupon issue purchases in
purchases from foreign accounts,

At the peak point at the

the Desk had added nearly $6.4 billion to outright

System holdings,
Committee.

bill

and both System and

customer-related repurchase agreements.
end of April,

the market,

making use of the enlarged leeway approved by the

As the Treasury balance dropped, and later as the

special borrowing augmented reserves, the System sold bills to
foreign accounts and ran off bills in several auctions.

For the

whole period, outright holdings were up a net of just $2.1 billion,
including $1.5 billion in
bills.

Treasury coupon issues and the rest in

Repurchase agreements were used heavily in

late April as

Treasury balances peaked, but also at other times to smooth out
reserve flows.

Matched sales were employed on the first

then more extensively

in

day, and

the last few days to help cope with the

bulge in reserves from Continental's borrowing.
The steep rise in market interest rates since late March
rested on several factors, but chiefly the press of heavy credit
demands from the private sector, augmented by unrelenting Treasury
demands.

A number of market observers have commented that the

long-awaited clash of private and public sector demands is now here
and is producing its

expected result.

business news has continued robust.

In the background,

the

Market participants discounted

signs of weakness in the data for March as partly weather-related,
while the expected bounce-back in data for April has at least
equaled expectations.

The market remains skeptical about

Congressional action to trim the deficit-questioning

whether

it

will be enough in

total and particularly whether it will be

enough in the next year or so to be of significant help near-term.
Inflation is

seen as not bad at the moment but prospectively

troublesome as the economic

expansion continues and takes up slack

in productive capacity and employment.
narrow money supply in

The flat performance of

April gave only modest comfort,

attributed to seasonal adjustment problems,

being widely

while there is

some

concern that growth in May could more than offset the earlier
weakness.
Against this background, investors had minimal appetite for
intermediate and longer term issues, so that sizable new Treasury
coupon issues had to be crammed into an exceptionally unreceptive
market.

As auctions approached, market rates backed up to levels

where dealers anticipated that investors might have an interest, but
time and again that appetite failed to develop and rates had to move

still higher before supplies could be moved off the street.

For the

whole interval, Treasury yields on intermediate and longer issues

rose about 80-100 basis points.

Thirty-year Treasury bonds, which

yielded around 12 1/2 percent in late March, pushed up to about
12 7/8 percent by the time the Treasury mid-quarter financing was
announced in

early May.

13.32 but in

the poor after-market sold off to yield as high as

The new bonds were actually auctioned at

13.75 - 80 briefly before backing down again to about 13 1/2 percent
by the end of the period.

In the course of these rate moves, some

dealers have taken painful losses, although our tracking of the
primary dealers does not suggest that the losses

have been beyond

their capacity.

The liquidation of Marsh-McLennan's large positions

added to market supplies at an inopportune time.

Two small

non-reporting dealer firms, Lion Capital Group and RTD Securities,
filed for bankruptcy, leaving a wake of problems in the repo market.
Rate moves were more moderate in the Treasury bill area,
especially in the case of short bills which showed little net change
or even some declines for the very shortest maturities.

This

pattern reflected the Treasury's sizable bill paydowns, engineered
in order to provide debt limit room to accommodate the regular
schedule of intermediate and longer term issues.

Also, in the

latter part of the period, the lower rates on short bills partly
reflected some flight to quality stemming from Continental's funding
difficulties.

In today's three-and six-month bill auctions, the

average issuing rates were about 9.95 and 10.38 percent, compared
with 9.76 and 9.88 percent just before the last meeting.
In contrast with the moderate rise in bill rates, bank CDs
pushed up fairly substantially over the period.

This partly

reflected the different supply situation-paydowns of bills as
against some net issuance of CDs in the latter part of the period,
possibly to fund loan demands.

Later, the widening differential of

CDs over bills also reflected quality concerns.

As we measure it,

the spread of 3-month CD yields over bills widened from 43 basis
points at the start of the period to a high of 137 on May 11 and a
reading this morning (May 21) of about 110 basis points.

Consonant

with rising costs, banks raised their prime rate twice during the
interval to a current level of 12 1/2 percent.

Given the press of recent events, it is difficult to gauge
what monetary policy
point.

"stance" the market is attuned to at this

Host observers probably expect to see Federal funds around

10 1/2 percent given their assessment of our recent objectives.
Meantime, the intermediate and longer maturities may have gotten a
bit ahead of themselves

perhaps being priced to something more like

an 11 percent rate even though I don't believe that such a rate is
an imminent market expectation.
market view is

Indeed,

that a tightening is

if

anything,

the current

not likely for the moment

because of the Continental Illinois and perhaps the LDC situations,
and there could even be a nod to the accommodative side because of
these factors.
Finally, touching on developments in the Government
securities market surveillance area, I'd like to inform the
Committee that the Subcommittee on Domestic Monetary Policy of House
Banking Committee plans to hold hearings at the end of this month on
the capital adequacy of Government securities dealers.

A particular

focus, I understand, is to be on a proposed approach to the
standards of capital adequacy that the New York Fed sent out for
comment to the dealer community a few months ago.

We are now in the

midst of a dialogue with the dealer community on this topic.

JLKichline
May 22, 1984

FOMC BRIEFING

Economic activity on average has remained strong in
recent months while inflation has held to around the same rate
as last year.

Since the last meeting of the Committee a good

deal of information on the economy has become available,
including data for March and April as well as two official
readings on GNP in the first quarter.

The first-quarter growth

of real GNP is now reported to have been 8-3/4 percent, somewhat above the staff's last forecast of 8 percent.

The staff

has made only small adjustments to its projection for subsequent periods, and essentially interprets most of the available
information as consistent with its earlier view on the outlook.
That view is one of still strong, but moderating, growth of
real GNP in the current quarter and further moderation of
growth later this year.
The information on March and April for many sectors of
the economy points to considerable weakening in March and a
rebound in April, a pattern that seems to reflect the effects
of bad weather in March and in a few cases faulty seasonal
adjustment.

Cutting through the monthly gyrations, in the

labor market there were continuing sizable increases of employment, a very high level of the workweek, and a pickup of growth

-

2 -

in the labor force; faster growth of the labor force has led to
an unchanged rate of unemployment of 7.8 percent since February.
Industrial production has continued to grow rapidly,
averaging 1 percent per month during the March-April period,
with large increases in output of business equipment, defense
products, and materials and intermediate products.

Given the

strong start on the second quarter, a slackening in the rate of
expansion of production, which is built into the forecast,
would still yield growth during the second quarter of 11 to 12
percent annual rate--the same as in the first quarter.

The

fast growth of production has been absorbing unutilized capacity, of course, and in April capacity use in manufacturing was a
little above 82 percent.
Consumers have been very willing to spend in recent
months, with personal consumption expenditures up at nearly a 7
percent annual rate in the first quarter, a rate marginally
above the fourth-quarter pace.

The fastest growing major cate-

gory of outlays has been automobiles, an item that we expect
will exhibit much less growth this quarter and throughout the
projection.

After all, auto sales now are at high levels--the

first-quarter rate was 2 million units annually above the year
earlier and there are capacity constraints for the more popular

-

models.

3 -

More generally, however, consumer spending is pro-

jected to slow as many urgent pent up demands probably have
been satisfied, consumer loan rates are on the rise, and developments in other sectors point to a moderation of income
growth.
In the housing market, starts declined 15 percent
during March and April from the very elevated pace earlier in
the year.

The staff forecast implicitly has starts remaining

around the recent average of 1.8 million units annual rate for
the next couple of months and then drifting lower as mortgage
interest rates restrain activity.

In the context of current

and prospective mortgage rates, residential construction
activity after this quarter will be a drag on real economic
growth.
Fixed investment by the business sector, however,
seems sure to continue contributing in a substantial way to
overall economic expansion.

New commitments for equipment and

structures continue to rise, and reported business plans for
expansion seem consistent with the staff's forecast of a 12
percent increase during the year.

In contrast, investment in

inventories seems unlikely to contribute much if anything to
economic growth later this year and in 1985.

Inventories grew

rapidly in the first quarter and aside from autos may evidence
some further growth this quarter.

But the level of short-term

-

4 -

interest rates should reinforce the desire of firms to keep
inventories in line with sales.

For autos, the early model

changeover at some General Motors plants this quarter is
expected to depress inventories, knocking about 3/4 percentage
point off growth of real GNP and adding about as much next
quarter.
Recent developments in the wage-price arena have been
in line with the staff forecast or, especially for prices,
somewhat better.

Over the first four months of this year hour-

ly earnings were up at a 4 percent annual rate, the same as
last year; the forecast entails a rise in wage and price
increases later this year and in 1985 as labor and product
markets tighten further.

FOMC Briefing
S. H. Axilrod
5/22/84

Since the last FOMC meeting, M1 and M2 have been running quite
close to the March-to-June path set by the Committee, although M1 has done
so only in an erratic way, presumably the result mostly of seasonal adjustment
difficulties.

There have, however, been rather less expected, and in a

sense, less assuring developments.
The rise in money market rates in general has been roughly in
line with what might have been expected from the reserve path set following
the meeting.

But within the short-term rate structure, there has been a

deterioration in quality spreads, particularly as judged from the spread of
CD rates over bill rates.

The Continental Illinois episode made all bank

CDs relatively more expensive, and the guarantee offered by the FDIC has
not yet occasioned any marked narrowing of spreads.
Another somewhat unexpected development, perhaps, since the last
meeting has been a rise in long-term interest rates of about the same
dimension as the rise in short rates-and greater than the rise in the
funds rate.

Same market observers conclude from

the prevailing steepness

of the yield curve that monetary policy is not yet sufficiently restrictive-a conclusion that would seem to depend in some part on observing that a
downward sloping yield curve has normally developed at same sort of
culminating point.

But, however that may be, I would not interpret the

recent failure of the yield curve to flatten in face of a further rise in
the funds rate as somehow indicating that some additional monetary restraint
has not taken hold.

For that to be the case, one would have to believe

that inflationary expectations have also worsened over the past few weeks

-2by a percentage point or so.

They have probably worsened some,

but I doubt

to that extent given the absence of evidence in wages, commodity prices, or
the foreign exchange market of incipient inflationary pressures.

What I

suspect is that uncertainties in general have increased-perhaps partly in
response to the raft of official statements in an election year, growing
doubts about whether the budget situation can or will be resolved, and
various pieces of evidence that all may not be well in financial marketsso that many investors have siply decided to stay short for a while until
the atmosphere clears.
The deterioration of quality spreads and rise in long-term rates
in my view would, if sustained without a further worsening of inflationary
expectations, have restrictive effects beyond what would be expected from
changes ordinarily associated with a 1/2 point rise in the funds rate.
Mortgage rates have been steadily creeping up and would be expected to rise
a bit further perhaps.
lenders.

And at the margin banks should become more cautious

However, it may well be that, given money market conditions indexed

by a federal funds rate on the order of 10-1/2 percent, we could see same
narrowing of quality spreads and a minor bond market rally, should we have
a passage of several generally quiet weeks.
In any event, the credit market has not to date witnessed any
significant lessening of credit demands.

We expect a 12-1/4 percent rise

in total domestic nonfinancial debt over the first quarter to be followed
by a rise of about 13 percent over the second.

This has been accompanied

by above target growth in M3 as depository institutions have financed a
good share of the credit growth.
The private debt component of the total is expected to increase
at about an 11-1/2 percent annual rate in both the first and second quarters.

This would be about the same rate of increase as in the fourth quarter of

1983,

but would be noticeably more rapid than over any year of the first

four years of the 1980's.

The relatively rapid increase has been absorbed

with what seem only moderate upward real interest rate pressures since the beginning of the year because of the substantial rise in the volume of domestic
saving generated by the relatively large increase in real income made possible by an economy starting well below its capacity,
rise in the personal savings rate),

(as well as a recent

crucially supplemented by the enlarged

inflow of saving from abroad.
We are projecting a substantial slowing in debt formation during
the second half of the year.

The question naturally arises whether such

a slowing does or does not imply further interest rate increases, especially since it

is unlikely that we will have sufficient growth in the

volume of real saving to finance continued rapid credit growth given that
the expansion of real income will be retarded as capacity limitations are
approached.

In that context, if real interest rates are not to rise over

the period ahead, real demands must moderate.

Whether they readily will

or not more or less in line with the slower increase in saving depends in
large part on how restrictive the present level of real interest rates may
be.

Our forecast of a slowing in growth of both nominal and real GNP, as

the second half progresses, does assume that present market conditions are
at least working in the direction of restraint, as Jim indicated with
respect to housing and consumer durables.
The behavior of M1 and M2 thus far this year, which traditionally have more predictive value than M3 or credit, are not inconsistent
with a slowing of the economy and of credit demands.

But a principal

policy question at this time would be what should be the response if M1 and

-4-

M2 were to begin accelerating relative to the Committee's desired pace.
Given the restraining effects implicit in the deterioration of quality
spreads and the sharp recent further rise of long-term rates, and assuming
that these are not soon reversed, there is an argument for being accommodative for a time-at least for a sufficient time to determine whether or not
there may be any shift toward greater demand for liquidity in an uncertain
environment on the part of the public.

Absent that, however, the evidence

of the past few months--where it seems apparent that M1 velocity is on a
fairly strong rising trend-suggests that continued moderate growth in M1
and M2 would increase the odds on a reduction in credit growth.
Perhaps I should point out, Mr. Chairman, that the suggested
directive language to take account of "any unusual financial strains" in
the implementation of open market operations was not meant to be necessarily
interpreted as indicating any change in the Committee's basic policy thrust
toward more concern with, say, interest rates or a greater willingness to
accommodate money behavior; rather it was meant to provide a handle for
undertaking day-to-day actions perhaps temporarily inconsistent with reserve
paths should something like disorderly market conditions emerge, as they
certainly threatened to at times in recent weeks.

It would, if adopted as

presented, be applicable whether the reserve path came to imply unchanged,
higher, or lower interest rates.

It would seem more likely to be relevant,

of course, should higher rates begin to emerge, either as a product of a
deliberate reserve path change or, perhaps more relevantly, from a distinct
further worsening in market attitudes.