View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes For FOMC Meeting
May 21, 1985
Sam Y. Cross
In the last eight weeks the dollar has fluctuated
widely.

Against the mark, for example, it has ranged between

DM2.95 and DM3.26.

Over the period as a whole the dollar

declined about 5 percent against most major currencies.
The exchange markets appear to have been reassessing
the economic outlook both here and abroad.

The strength of

the U.S. economy and the outlook for U.S. interest rates has
remained in question, and the expected strengthening abroad
has been slow to materialize.

Thus, the gap in economic

performance that has been favoring the dollar may have
narrowed but apparently has not been reversed.

Moreover,

market participants have expressed doubts about other
countries' ability to sustain their expansion should U.S.
growth remain subdued.

Investment interest in the mark and

the yen, the two currencies usually considered to be the
alternatives to the dollar, appears to have been slack, even
when the dollar has been declining.

With economies abroad

lackluster, the scope for a significant further narrowing of
interest differentials is seen to be limited.

Market

participants anticipate that central banks abroad will take
the opportunity to allow their interest rates to ease in
response to convincing declines in the United States.

- 2 -

The dollar fell to its low point of the period in
mid-April, when it was fully 20 percent below its late
February peak relative to European currencies.

The selling of

dollars that precipitated this decline appears to have
reflected largely professional positioning and hedging of
portfolios.

This selling was perhaps motivated by

expectations that a more generalized sell-off of dollar assets
would follow.

But what is interesting is that many

international portfolio managers appear not to have sold the
dollar assets themselves, but rather to have hedged in forward
markets and elsewhere.

Indeed, the balance of payments

statistics show that new foreign investment continued
When expectations of

throughout the period at a healthy pace.

a larger sell-off did not materialize, the dollar subsequently
stopped falling and recovered somewhat.
Foreign central banks responded in different ways to
the dollar's decline.

There has been little or no net dollar

intervention since your last meeting.

Some countries did
Official rates were

allow a decline in their interest rates.
reduced by the U.K.,

Short-term market

France, and Belgium.

rates for sterling, French franc and Swiss franc assets fell
almost as much as comparable dollar rates.
short-term rates fell by a lesser amount

However,

in Germany and hardly

at all in Japan.
Although exchange rates on balance have showed little
trend during this period, they have exhibited considerable
daily volatility.

Since late February, the dollar/mark rate

- 3 -

has fluctuated about 2 percent on average during each day.
This means that, within an average day, a dealer with a
$5 million position could experience a $100,000 loss.

Over

periods of days, exchange rate moves--and the consequent
risks--have been even larger.
Many banks have responded to the growing risks of
running foreign exchange positions by limiting exposures, and
by limiting direct dealing with interbank counterparties.
As a result,

the exchange market has lost some resiliency and

individual transactions can have greater influence than
before.

In this respect, foreign exchange dealers in

commercial banks have been complaining to us for several
months about

the deteriorating market conditions.

More recently, corporate treasurers active in the
exchange markets have also begun to express concern about the
high degree of short-run exchange rate variability.

They say

they are able to get their required currency transactions
completed, but that the recent day-to-day volatility has
greatly hampered their financial operations and
decision-making processes.

Several corporate representatives

hoped that the central banks could find a way to dampen this
type of short-run volatility. They argued that it is necessary
to bring greater stability to market conditions and deal with
short-run volatility before judgments can be made about what
is an appropriate medium-term exchange rate.

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
May 21, 1985
Peter D. Sternlight
Desk operations

since the March 26 meeting sought

approximately unchanged pressure on
background

complicated by

Treasury balances, and

reserve positions against

a

large and sometimes hard-to-predict moves

in

some distortions to borrowing numbers because

of non-federally insured thrifts.

of problems

to maintain

the economy netted out to a picture of continued modest
contrasting elements of weakness and

on

Mixed information

strength.

growth, with

Growth in M1

from its very rapid rate in the opening months of the year

slowed

and ran

close to the Committee's preferred March-to-June pace in April,

and

just a little stronger in early May, although this meant remaining
well above the annual growth cone and
growth channel.

M2

slightly above the parallel line

and M3 were unexpectedly weak in April,

both these measures well within their annual

leaving

growth cones in that

month.
Reserve paths allowed initially for

$400 million of

borrowing--the center of the $350-$450 million range envisaged at the
last meeting.

At that time, special thrift borrowing in Ohio and

Maryland was just

under $50 million.

borrowing had pushed somewhat
adjustment

By late April, special thrift

over $100

million and the overall

and seasonal borrowing number was raised to

$450 million in

the May 8 reserve period in partial recognition of this.

In the

current reserve period, developments in Maryland have raised the
special thrift borrowing considerably further--over $450 million in
recent days.

In recognition of this,

while not changing the formal

borrowing allowance again, we have thought of the

special situation

borrowing as providing, on average in the current

reserve period, an

additional $250-$300 million or so of what can be regarded in effect

as "nonborrowed reserves"
Actual borrowing levels have run fairly close to the path
allowance over most of the intermeeting interval--averaging about $480
million and $390 million in the first two reserve periods, and then
about $560 million in the two weeks ended May 8 when we had a
particularly big job to keep up with the soaring Treasury balance and
the thrift borrowing was a little higher.

So far in the current

reserve period borrowing has run considerably higher, averaging about
$800 million for the first 11 days.

This reflected not only the bulge

in Maryland thrift borrowing but also a few instances of overnight
borrowing by money center banks facing unexpected late shortages when
federal funds were apparently not available in size.

For the three

full reserve periods since the last meeting, nonborrowed reserves
averaged a little above path.
For the first few weeks of the period, the funds rate varied
around the 8-1/2 percent level that characterized most of March.

Then

in the latter part of April the rate fell off, slipping below 8
percent for several days and then backing up to a range of 8 to 8-1/4
percent.

The drop after mid-April may have reflected the Desk's

vigorous efforts to offset rising Treasury balances; for a few days
right after the tax date, those balances did not go up as fast as had
been anticipated, so we were temporarily over-providing.

Later, the

rising balances caught up with and exceeded expectations, and the
money market returned to rates somewhat over 8 percent.

So far in the

current reserve period, not counting yesterday when the lower discount
rate took effect, funds averaged about 8-1/8 percent, notwithstanding
the higher borrowing level mentioned earlier.

Yesterday, with the new

discount rate, funds traded largely around 7-5/8 - 7-3/4 percent, but

firmed up late in the day apparently because of problems in the New
York Fed computer that delayed funds and securities transfers until
very late hours.
Desk operations added a net of nearly $6-1/2 billion to the
System's outright securities holdings during the period.

Midway

through the period, with the Treasury balance on its steep rise,
outright holdings were up nearly $7.7

billion, thus using an

appreciable part of the temporarily enlarged $9 billion leeway.
Later, as the balances declined, the portfolio was reduced somewhat
through bill run-offs and sales to foreign accounts.

The big rise in

outright holdings was accomplished through two large bill purchases in
the market totaling about $5.3 billion, a $1.3 billion purchase of
coupon bearing issues in the market and about $1.1
purchases from foreign accounts.

billion of bill

In the second market purchase of

bills, the System bought a record $3.7 billion.

Substantial use was

also made of repurchase agreements, particularly in coping with the
final stages of the huge increase in Treasury balances.

On May 2, the

Desk arranged $11-3/4 billion of one- and four-day repurchase
agreements.

There was an ample $22 billion of offerings presented to

the Desk that morning, probably because we had given the market notice
of the operation the previous afternoon.

Matched sales were used on

two occasions to absorb reserves from the market, around mid-period,
when our heavy preparations for the rising Treasury balances had
produced a temporary overabundance of reserves.
Rates declined across a broad front over the period,
including an extra kick at the end of the interval from the
announcement of a discount rate reduction.

Earlier, the rate

decline was mainly influenced by a perception of sluggish economic
growth (and indeed no growth in manufacturing activity),

reasonably

contained inflation, encouraging signs of progress in trimming the
budget deficit, and a sense that the Fed was responding to these
factors with a somewhat more accommodative stance toward reserve
provision.

Anticipations of a discount rate reduction alternately

waxed and waned over the interval, but had become quite widespread by
the time of last Friday's announcement--though many observers thought
the word might come a few days later.

Market commentators took note

of the strong year-to-date performance of M1 and some found it
troubling, but the more prevalent view was that the economy was
sluggish despite the recent strong growth in M1 and that this seemed
to be another of those periods when vigorous money growth was not all
that clear a prelude to overheating in the economy or resurgent
inflation.

Sentiment was not all one way over the interval; at times

the market was more impressed by signs of continuing gains in the
economy, heavy supplies of new issues, or official comments that
seemed to dampen near-term prospects for greater accommodation.
But overall, the rate trend was down.

For Treasury coupon

issues the yield declines ranged from about 160 or 170 basis points in
the 2-3 year area to about 130 in the 10-year range and 95 or so at 30
years, including around 20-30 basis points in the wake of the discount
rate cut.

The Treasury raised a hefty $25 billion in the coupon

market over the period, including $10 billion in the record mid-May
financing.

The market did back up a bit as this financing approached,

but good bidding and follow-up interest developed, lifting the new
issues to sizable premiums.
In the Treasury bill market, where net new issuance was a
modest $2 billion over the period--and the Federal Reserve was a
sizable net buyer--the rate declines were actually somewhat less
than for shorter coupon issues, though still an appreciable 120 to 145

Three- and six-month bills were

basis points for key issues.

auctioned yesterday at about 7.28 and 7.43 percent, down from 8.41 and
8.86 percent just before the last meeting.

Other money market rates

declined by roughly similar magnitudes, in the area of 1-1/4
percentage points for commercial paper and acceptances and 1 to 1-5/8
percentage points for CDs.

One large money center bank cut its prime

rate 1/2 percent to 10 percent shortly before the discount rate cut,
and most others followed suit afterward.
By and large, the Government securities market has continued
to function pretty normally despite the failures of several nonprimary
dealer firms in recent months.

Anecdotally, we get the impression of

some dealers and customers becoming more selective about their trading
partners--and indeed some of these upgradings may have played a role
in uncovering some of the additional problems that emerged after the
ESM collapse--but it's hard to put one's finger on specific measurable
effects.

Indirectly, the fall-out of ESM and other dealer failures

caused some anxious moments last week with respect to the monthly
settlement for mortgage-backed securities.

Growing out of the dealer

failures and the disposition of securities involved in certain
repurchase agreements, a number of adverse action claims were filed
where ownership of mortgage-backed securities was in dispute.

These

claims could have the effect of stopping the transfer of particular
certificates if they turned up in the general monthly settlement.

In

turn, this threatened the orderly conduct of the settlement, as well
as ordinary day-to-day repo financing of mortgage-backed securities,
and in effect the overall liquidity of the mortgage-backed securities
market.

As it turned out, the settlement process and repo financing

proceeded smoothly after tense meetings with market representatives
and the Federal mortgage guaranteeing agencies, pointing toward some

longer-run relief measures, and also with the help of the fact that
few, if any, of the tainted securities showed up in the settlement
process.

The longer-run measures are still being pursued.

In the

meantime, we were prepared at the Desk in case of a serious threat to
the liquidity of the financial markets, to make repurchase agreements
against mortgage-backed securities.

Fortunately, we didn't have to--

just mechanics alone would be quite cumbersome, never mind the policy
implications of stepping in seemingly to aid a particular sector.
Finally, I'd like to mention that the New York Fed has now published
its guidelines for capital adequacy of government securities dealers.
It is designed for a voluntary framework but could also fit into one
or another of the mandatory reforms now under discussion.

Michael J. Prell
May 21, 1985

FOMC Economic Briefing

Incoming data since the last meeting suggest that the economy
is expanding, but not very rapidly.

The Commerce Department released

revised first-quarter GNP data this morning, and they showed a 0.7 percent
rate of growth in real GNP, about 1/2 point less than the preliminary
estimate.

The revision reflected the netting of small changes in all the

major components.

Our best guess is that real GNP is rising at something

over a 2 percent annual rate in the current quarter.

Beyond the current

quarter, the projected pace of expansion is the same as we previously
forecast, but the recent shortfall in the level of output is not made up
and this prevents the unemployment rate from moving below 7 percent.
The unemployment rate stayed at 7.3 percent last month.

Nonfarm

payrolls rose about 215,000--an appreciable gain, but considerably smaller
than the average in prior months.

Manufacturing employment fell for the

third straight month, and this was reflected in a decline of 0.2 percent
in industrial production.
Although the less robust growth in employment limited wage and
salary growth in April, total personal income was reported to be up 0.6
percent.

Moreover, disposable income rose strongly because of the tax

refund catchup.

It is our assessment that the drop in disposable income

in the first quarter that resulted from delays in refunds cut primarily
into saving rather than spending and that a good share of the refunds now
being received will be used to repay debt or otherwise boost measured
saving.

The few data we have on second-quarter spending appear consistent

with this thesis.

The level of overall consumption expenditures in April,

though up 0.7 percent after a slight March dip, was only moderately above
the first-quarter average.

And car sales--which rose appreciably in the

-2-

first part of the year--have shown no signs of rising further.

On the

whole, personal outlays probably are now on a less vigorous growth track,
with a lessening impetus from pent-up demands for durables.
On the investment front, residential construction appears to be
a particular source of strength at present.
million unit rate in March and April.

Housing starts rose to a 1.9

Although we expect that mortgage

rates will decline somewhat further, slower income and employment growth
are likely to temper expansion in housing demand over the projection period;
moreover, the recent pace of multifamily building seems unsustainable,
given rental vacancy rates.
The indicators of near-term nonresidential investment are quite
ambiguous at this point.

Construction activity was up strongly on average

in the first quarter, especially in the commercial area, but there are some
hints of a flattening in new contracts.

We expect the glut of office space

in many cities to produce a downturn in the commercial building cycle before
long, and we are projecting a leveling out of overall nonresidential
construction in coming quarters.
With regard to equipment spending, trends in orders placed with
domestic producers have been obscured in recent months by wild gyrations in
the computer category.

Big increases in capital goods shipments in February

and March have, however, set the stage arithmetically for a considerable rise
in the average level of outlays in the current quarter.

Thereafter, we

expect that desires to adopt up-to-date technologies will still be strong enough

to support continuing appreciable growth in equipment spending through
1986--albeit at a rate far below that of 1983-84, and with imports absorbing
a sizable share of the outlays.

In the government sector, a spurt in defense spending is expected
in the current quarter--a catchup after a fluky drop in the January-to-March
period, but over the next year and a half the picture is one of slowing
growth in federal and state and local purchases.
Focusing on the near term, while real domestic final demand appears
to be growing at a fairly good clip, the projection for GNP growth hinges
importantly on assessments of inventory behavior and of tendencies in the
external sector.

We are anticipating continued caution toward stock accumu-

lation, but the key factor in the current quarter is a probable swing in
auto dealers' stocks associated with model changeovers.

Whether it is in

fact reflected in reduced stocks or instead in weaker sales, the lower auto
assembly schedules imply a 1-1/2 percent drag on GNP growth in this quarter.
On the external side, there have been wide quarterly fluctuations
in net exports over the past year, and the first quarter saw another big
negative swing.

Real GNP less net exports (that is, domestic purchases)

actually rose at a 4 percent annual rate.

There was a massive increase

in nonoil imports--indeed, one so large that we think it likely that
there will be a small drop-back in -the current quarter.

The effects of

the projected dollar depreciation will not really begin to leave their
mark until the end of this year; consequently,

the external sector does not

become a consistent contributor to GNP growth until 1986.
Similarly, the domestic price impact of a declining dollar is not
expected to be appreciable until next year, when it will be the major force
behind the projected acceleration of inflation from the 3-1/2 percent area to
around 4 percent.

The inflation forecast is essentially unchanged from

March's, as the effects of a lower dollar are offset by the somewhat greater
degree of slack in the domestic economy.

-4-

I should say, though, that incoming data have led us to lower
the probability of price developments turning out more favorably than we
have projected.

The 6 percent first-quarter increase in hourly compensation

was exaggerated by payroll tax increases and perhaps by other special
factors; the series also is susceptible to substantial revision.

However,

the faster growth of manufacturing production worker wages in the hourly
earnings index and the pickup in nonunionized manufacturing wages in the
employment cost index at least suggest that wage deceleration may have run
its course for the time being.

Moreover, recent productivity performance

has been no better than expected, and with a lessened offset to wage increases,
the pressures of labor costs on profit margins are likely to be more substantial.
Finally, recent producer and consumer price increases--including the 0.4
percent April CPI rise announced the morning--have tended to run above the
trends the past couple of years.

Some transitory influences have been

involved--especially a spike in gasoline and fuel oil prices--and the
markets for basic commodities have remained soft.

Nonetheless, we are

hesitant to discount entirely the overall firmness displayed of late by
final goods prices.

FOMC Presentation
S.H. Axilrod
5/20/85

The alternatives presented to the Committee all specify growth
in the broader aggregates--M2 and M3--well within their long-run growth
cones, largely the result of the unexpected weakness of these aggregates
last month.

Growth of M1, on the other hand, is expected to remain

somewhat above the upper limit of its parallel band.

Indeed it appears

likely that growth of M1 over the three-month period from March through
June will be somewhat higher than the 6 percent growth path adopted by
the Committee at its last meeting, assuming pressures on bank reserve
positions--as gauged by the level of adjustment plus seasonal borrowing
are about unchanged from those prevailing over recent weeks.
The strength of M1 has been accompanied by declines in its
income velocity.
annual rate.

In the first quarter the drop was at about a 4 percent

In the second quarter a decline of close to 2 percent

annual rate can be expected based on current estimates of growth in
nominal GNP and M1.

Thus, there will have been two consecutive quarters

of negative velocity following its rebound in growth at a relatively
rapid pace since late 1983.
The recent velocity experience resembles on a much more limited
scale the sustained weakness in M1 velocity during 1982 and early 1983.
What they have in common is an apparent increase in the amount of money
demanded in lagged response to a substantial decline in short-term interest
rates.

From mid-summer of 1984 to early 1985 the 3-month bill rate had

dropped close to 3 percentage points, or about 30 percent.

That is why

both our monthly and quarterly models were predicting sizable growth of
Ml in the first half of this year despite quite moderate growth in nominal
GNP.

There are of course substantial differences between this year
and 1982-early 1983.

The main difference stems from an economy that is

operating now at a much higher level of activity.

Most of the earlier

drop in velocity occurred during the recession, when there appeared to be
a considerable reduction of inflationary expectations that was reflected
in a sustained lower level of nominal interest rates.

Lower interest

rates appeared to induce a relatively "permanent" downward shift in the
level of velocity--corresponding to an upward shift in the demand for
money--that needed to be accommodated.
It seems possible that further downward shifts in velocity
may become evident at some point as interest rates drop because more
progress toward price stability is in fact made, or because real rates
need in any event to decline from current relatively high levels to support
satisfactory real economic growth.

If and as rates phase down, velocity

could be expected to grow less than its trend annual rate of expansion-which we tentatively place at 1 to 2 percent--and probably to decline at
times.

But to decide whether weakness in velocity over any relatively

short period, like the last two quarters, reflects a "permanent" upward
adjustment in the amount of money demanded or a transitory effect of a
burst in money growth or a temporary dip in GNP is a difficult judgment.
If there is no lasting upward adjustment in money demanded, the decline
in nominal and real rates associated with expanding money supply may in
time trigger a greater than desired expansion of demand for goods and
services, a resurgence of inflationary pressures, and a sharp turnaround
to expansion in velocity.
The incoming economic evidence at present suggests, however,
that the present seemingly large gap between actual and potential real

-3-

GNP will not be narrowing over the period immediately ahead-not a condition
that normally would accelerate inflationary pressures.

On the other

hand, there can be doubt about what is the economy's potential and also
about the size of the gap.

Skepticism about the prospects for improvement

in productivity performance would tend to lower the potential for growth,
and there is also uncertainty about the unemployment rate that can with
reasonable certainty be characterized as the natural rate-that is, the
rate below which inflation will tend to accelerate.

If that rate is

higher than most now suppose and the potential growth rate of GNP is
lower, it would not take particularly strong demands for goods and services
at this point to generate untoward upward price pressures.

But, with

respect to the underlying strength of demand, it must be noted that if
the House goes along with something like the Senate's budget cuts, there
will be no further increase in fiscal stimulus over the next several
quarters, leaving even more scope for the negative impact on economic
activity from the high real exchange rate and any continuing associated
rise in the trade deficit to work through the economy.
Many of these issues about the relationship of money growth to
velocity trends, inflationary expectations, and the economy's growth
potential will be particularly relevant at the July meeting when the
Committee reconsiders its long-run targets for 1985 and establishes
tentative ranges for 1986.

At present, as I noted at the beginning, we

expect maintenance of existing, in the sense of prevailing over recent
weeks, reserve pressures to lead to slightly faster M1 growth than adopted
at the previous FOMC meeting.

If our projection is correct, that would

put M1 only about 0.3 of a percent above the upper parallel line of the
band by June.

That means, arithmetically speaking, that 5-1/2 percent

growth from then on would yield 7.3 percent for the year.

Such growth

over the balance of the year, or even somewhat lower, cannot be said to
be unmanageable if something like more usual tendencies in velocity were
to emerge, though that might entail an edging up of interest rates at
some point in the context of a reasonably strong economy.
A word, if I may Mr. Chairman, about why we believe the $300 to
$350 million borrowing level of alternative B does characterize existing
or recent reserve pressures.

At the last FOMC meeting, the Committee

indicated that the reserve path should be initially set on the basis of
adjustment plus seasonal borrowing of $350 to $450 million.

At the time

special situation thrift borrowing amounted to around $50 million.

Thus,

excluding that borrowing, the range could be construed as $300 to $400
million.

Actual borrowing other than for special situations over the three

complete reserve maintenance periods since then averaged $380 million,
reasonably close to 300 to 350 given the vagaries in excess reserves and
seasonal borrowing under the more liberalized program, and has run around
$300 million over the past few days.

I would expect the federal funds

rate under those conditions to be somewhere between the old discount rate
of 8 percent and the new rate of 7-1/2 percent, [probably more often closer
to the latter than the former.]