View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

Notes for FOMC Meeting
May 20, 1986
Sam Y. Cross
The dollar has declined
dropping on balance about
currencies.

6-7

further since your April 1 meeting,

percent against the major foreign

In all, dollar exchange rates against those currencies

have now fallen about 35

percent from their peaks

of early 1985.

During the period since you last met, the market has
continued to pay close attention to official attitudes toward the
dollar's fall.

There was

not enough evidence of benefits to the U.S.

economy and trade balance from the dollar's depreciation--as well as
from lower interest rates and oil prices--to allay fears that U.S.
authorities would wish to guide the dollar lower.
participants are well aware of pressures

At the same time,

on foreign governments to

ease the pain for their own industries of too-rapid a fall of the
dollar, and of reservations about the potential inflationary effects
in the United States.

Thus,

before the summit meetings

the dollar paused in its decline just

in Tokyo as traders anticipated the

possibility of some agreement to support

it.

When the Summit passed

with no such announcement, the dollar resumed its
postwar low against the Japanese yen.
dollar firmed somewhat,
by monetary officials

fall,

reaching a new

During the last week, the

partly in response to a number of statements

in the United

States, Japan and Germany which

were seen as indicating a desire for the dollar to stabilize, at least
for the time being.

This morning the dollar

rose 1 percent on the GNP

release.
During the first weeks after your April
declines

of U.S.

1 meeting, further

interest rates were only partly matched abroad and

long-term differentials between U.S. Government

securities as compared

with those of Japan and Germany narrowed at one point to within 200

basis points.

The continuing moderation of global inflation

expectations, in part a response to lower oil prices, provided impetus
to the lowering of interest rates around the world which culminated at
about the time of the Federal Reserve and Bank of Japan discount rate
reductions announced April 18 and 19.
Since then, the momentum for a generalized fall of interest
rates internationally has faded.

Market participants noted that the

Bundesbank, feeling constrained by the weakness of the Deutsche mark
in the EMS, did not join in the mid April round of rate cuts, and
recent statements by Poehl and other Bundesbank officials give little
hope for rate reductions in the near future.

Above-target monetary

growth in several countries, as well as signs that the long-standing
weakness of oil and other commodity prices may have ended, have been
noted.

The dollar's fall itself has been cited as one reason for the

market's revised assessment of the scope for lower U.S. interest
rates.

In fact, as rates in the U.S. have backed up more than

elsewhere in recent weeks, interest differentials have widened again
to end the period slightly more in the dollar's favor than they were
at the beginning of April.

At the same time, some other countries

which had previously kept interest rates high to shore up their
currencies have continued to lower interest rates.

This is true for

the U.K. and Canada, as well as for several countries whose currencies
were devalued in the April 6 EMS realignment.

But exchange market

expectations for further rounds of coordinated discount rate cuts by
the major countries have faded.
The dollar also received some support from the Chernobyl
disaster.
U.S.

That accident raised expectations of increased purchases of

agricultural products.

It has also eroded popular support for

incumbent conservative governments in election campaigns in both

Germany and Holland, a political trend that lowers the attraction of
some of the dollar's principal rivals as an investment currency.
Nevertheless, sentiment towards the dollar remains fragile.
Some market observers expect the dollar to decline further and have
called attention to the combination in recent weeks of a declining
dollar and a widening of interest rate differentials favoring the
dollar which they see as reflecting an underlying weakness of the
dollar.

Notes for FOMC Meeting
May 20, 1986
Peter D. Sternlight
Domestic Desk operations since the last meeting were directed
at maintaining an approximately steady degree of reserve pressure,
with the reserve path allowance for adjustment and seasonal borrowing
remaining at $300 million.

This was done against a background of

increasing growth in monetary aggregates (especially Ml), mixed but
mainly sluggish indicators on the economy, a declining dollar through
much of the period, and subdued inflation data (though the recent
upturn in wholesale oil prices is expected to show up in forthcoming
statistics).

Interest rates pushed downward early in the period,

continuing the first quarter decline, but once the Federal Reserve's
mid-April discount rate cut to 6-1/2 percent was out of the way, rates
steadied or worked higher to end the period with mixed changes at the
short end and somewhat higher for longer maturities.
All three money measures outpaced the Committee's anticipated
March-June pace in April and early May.

This brought M1 appreciably

above its annual growth cone and even above the more accommodative
parallel bands, but M2, after its slow first quarter, was still low in
its annual range and M3 near the middle of its range.
While focusing on reserve paths that maintained a steady
allowance for $300 million of borrowing, the Desk sought to be
cautious and sometimes a bit sluggish in providing for indicated
reserve needs.

This was especially so around the time of the discount

rate reduction when there seemed to be particular risk of excessively
buoyant financial market sentiment and concern about a gathering
momentum toward dollar weakness.

Close attention to the dollar

continued even after the frothy bond market sentiment had cooled off.

Around the time of the last meeting, with the discount rate
at 7 percent, federal funds tended to fluctuate largely in a range of
7-1/4 - 7-1/2 percent.

In early April as market participants

increasingly anticipated a cut in the discount rate, funds rates edged
off, down to and then slightly below 7 percent.

Following the mid-

April discount rate move, funds have averaged close to 6-7/8 percent.
Borrowing levels for full maintenance periods have come in
close to the $300 million level except for the April 23 period when
exceptionally low borrowing--under $100 million--in the week preceding
the discount rate cut led to a $190 million average for the two-week
Excess reserves have come in close to the recent path

interval.

allowance of $900 million except in the April 9 period when excess was
only about $600 million.

Surprisingly, that was the reserve period

that marked the formal start of a closer monitoring of daylight
overdrafts.
To meet reserve needs over the period, the System bought
about $3.1 billion of bills, nearly $2 billion in a market operation
on April 2 and the rest from foreign accounts spread out over the
period.

There were numerous rounds of System or customer-related

repurchase agreements, especially when the Treasury balance ran high
after the mid-April tax date.

On one occasion, early in the period,

temporarily over-abundant reserves were drained through matched-sale
purchase transactions in the market.

The Treasury balance was

particularly hard to predict from day-to-day, especially just after
the tax date when some changes in IRS procedures apparently
contributed to unusually large projection errors.

One result was a

brief inadvertent overdraft of the Treasury's account at the Federal
Reserve, at a time when the Treasury actually had very large balances
at their commercial bank depositories.

Lower interest rates early in the period reflected a
continuation of the market forces that dominated the previous few
months--chiefly sluggish economic news and low oil prices.

A sense of

accommodativeness at the central bank and strong foreign buying
interest also bolstered sentiment that got to be a bit frenzied at
times.

The mid-April cut in the discount rate came to be widely

anticipated, or even over-anticipated in the sense that some market
rates had moved down to levels that could only be justified by a
greater reduction than 1/2 percent--though few observers really seemed
to expect that larger move in the immediate term.
Once the discount rate was cut, fed funds and some other
short rates were more firmly anchored at a lower level but the
discount rate was no longer there to anticipate as an immediate
expectation, and the Board's announcement itself seemed to provide
little encouragement of further moves to come.
Meantime, some of the earlier underlying factors shifted
course.

Oil prices levelled off and began backing up.

Weakness in

the dollar seemed to be causing increased official concern while
strength in M1 began to gain attention, and these factors were seen as
reducing the likelihood of further near-term central bank
accommodation.

Approaching, and then arriving, large supplies of new

debt from the Treasury was also a factor, as was the huge supply of
corporate issues induced by the rate declines in earlier months.
Just around the time of the discount rate cut, Treasury bills
dropped below 6 percent on a discount basis and two-year Treasury
notes were quoted in the 6.30's--a sharp contrast with their usual
spread above the current funds rate and overnight financing rate.

The

yield on thirty-year Treasury bonds dropped as low as 7-1/8 percent,
partly reflecting an unusual technical scarcity in that issue.

By the

end of the period, bills had backed up to around 6.20-6-3/8 percent-actually quite close to the quotes just before the last meeting.

The

two-year rate moved up to about 7.20 from 6.85 at the start, while a
ten-year Treasury issue yielded around 8 percent compared with 7-3/8
when the period began.

Thirty-year Treasury issues are something of a

story unto themselves because of heavy Japanese purchases, but that
sector showed a similar pattern with the Treasury's new 30-year bond
ending the period around 7-3/4 compared with about 7.45 for what was
the longest Treasury issue at the start of the period.
The Treasury raised about $16 billion in new money during the
period, nearly all of it in coupon issues and the great bulk of that
(some $13

billion) in the mid-May refunding.

In that operation, they

sold $9 billion each of 3, 10 and 30-year issues, particularly
stepping up the amounts in 10 and 30 years, compared with past
financings, in light of their decision to discontinue quarter-end
offerings of 20-year bonds.

Despite the huge size, the offerings went

quite well, notably the 30-year of which around half went to Japanese
buyers.

The 10-year note in which the Japanese were a moderate

factor, seems to be the least well distributed of the three, although
all three issues are currently below issue price, and their yields are
about 40-50 basis points above the auction averages.
As for the current state of market sentiment, one gets the
feeling that the great rally momentum of the last several months has
been spent.

Some participants expect more easing "down the road"

which could move rates back toward their recent lows, but then quite
possibly followed by firmer rates in the context of a strengthening
economy.

Many others see a near balanced situation for the time being

with the Fed content to sit back and weigh developments.

Few would

look for significant near-term firming efforts, though some would not

-5-

rule out seeing the market firm on its own in response to stronger
news on the economy, stronger money growth or stirrings on the price
front.

J. L. KICHLINE
May 20, 1986

FOMC BRIEFING

The basic contour of the staff's forecast for the
economy remains unchanged from that presented at the last
meeting of the Committee.

Real GNP is expected to rise at a

2 percent annual rate in the current quarter and to
accelerate to a 4 percent plus rate in the second half of
the year.

However, there is as yet not much to show for

the faster growth we believe to be in prospect, and we still
need to rely mainly upon our assessment of the fundamental
forces driving activity.

On the inflation side, we have

lowered projected inflation somewhat in both 1986 and 1987,
but have maintained the pattern of rising inflation next
year.
For the current quarter, the available information
relates largely to developments in April, and the data
present an uneven pattern.

Employment rose moderately owing

to gains in service, trade, and construction sectors while
employment in manufacturing and mining continued to

contract.

Industrial production increased 0.2 percent after

deep declines in the preceding two months; oil and gas
drilling activity continued to plunge, but in a number of
other areas output increases were suggestive of a somewhat
improved situation.

- 2 -

In the consumer sector, total retail sales rose 1/2
percent in April.

Unit car sales were up considerably given

a return of financing incentives, and domestic model sales
rose further early in May.

Aside from autos, gasoline, and

nonconsumer items, retail sales actually declined.

The

housing sector has responded strongly to the drop in
mortgage interest rates and starts were at a high 2 million
unit annual rate in April.

At this point we do not have

firm data on business fixed investment spending, but believe
equipment spending will rise from the depressed firstquarter pace.

The first quarter evidently was influenced by

efforts to take delivery of equipment before year-end in
light of possible tax reform.
The rate of growth of real GNP this quarter is
being damped by two major forces.

The domestic automobile

sector is being hampered by excessive inventories and the
staff forecast incorporates a sizable reduction in auto
production this quarter.

Developments in the auto sector

are expected to cut about 1-1/2 percentage points off real
GNP growth.

We also have built in further reductions of

structures spending in the energy industry which takes off
roughly 1/2 percentage point of real GNP expansion.
Beyond the current quarter, these negative
influences on activity are expected to wane, and the

- 3 -

stimulative effects of the lower levels of interest rates,
oil prices, and the foreign exchange value of the dollar are
forecasted to show through in stronger economic growth.
Unfortunately, the only clear evidence of strengthened
performance to date is in the housing sector, and the
generally high level of activity there is projected to
persist.

Consumer spending has been rising about 3 percent

on average over the past year and is expected to increase at
about the same rate in coming quarters.
Two key areas where major questions remain are
business fixed investment and net exports.

We are counting

on both areas to contribute importantly to activity later
this year and in 1987.

The indicators of business

investment generally remain weak and there are uncertainties
as to the effects, if any, of prospective tax reform on
business plans.

For net exports, the available data do not

yet provide evidence of substantial improvement.

In any

event, if we have correctly assessed the timing and
magnitude of the projected pickup in growth of real GNP the
evidence will need to emerge in the indicators over the next
couple of months.
With regard to wage and price developments,
incoming information has been about in line or better than
anticipated.

Wage and compensation growth still seems to be

- 4 -

slowing a little and we have reduced somewhat expected
future acceleration in labor costs.

The monthly price

indexes have been influenced heavily by declining energy
prices, but also seem to be rising a little less rapidly
overall than had been expected.

The GNP fixed-weighted

price index is projected to rise 2-1/2 percent in 1986-one-half percentage point less than in the previous
forecast.

For 1987, we project the inflation rate to move

up close to 4 percent associated with ending of oil price
declines, tighter labor markets, and especially the price
effects of the lower value of the dollar.

FOMC BRIEFING
Donald L. Kohn
May 21, 1986

The period since the last meeting has been marked by a substantial
surge in money--extending beyond Ml to the broader aggregates.

The bluebook

alternatives contemplate some moderation in money growth over the balance
of the quarter, but given the growth thus far in the quarter, all three
alternatives specify growth rates for all three measures of money that are
above the short-run paths set by the Committee at its last meeting.

The

paths for M2 and M3 would leave these broader aggregates reasonably close
to the midpoints of their respective ranges in June.

Growth rates specified

for M1, however, would all place this aggregate above its upper parallel
line in June.

In this situation, a key question before the Committee is

how to react, if at all, to these growth prospects for money, especially
Ml.

While the current decision involves only a mid-quarter review of growth

paths, it could have implications for the situation facing the Committee
when it

reconsiders its longer-term objectives in July.
It

seems clear that a major reason for the rapid money growth,

and accompanying steep decline in velocity, is the downward movement in
interest rates of recent months.

With the yield curve flattening at the

same time, the decrease in the opportunity costs of holding the most liquid
monetary assets has been especially marked.

Econometric model results

suggest that up to 5 percentage points of growth of Ml expected in the
second quarter can be attributed to the effects of lower interest rates.
However, interest rate effects alone do not seem to be able to
explain all of the 13 percent money growth and 9 percent velocity decline,
at least based on historic relationships.

In part, the models may not be

capturing the full interest sensitivity of money demand at the historically

-2low opportunity costs that have come to be associated with holding NOW
accounts.

And in this regard, very rapid growth of OCD, such as the 30

percent pace recorded in April may not be all that surprising.

But the

degree of strength in demand deposits through early May is somewhat puzzling.
It

could be that business cash management is being pursued less aggressive-

ly--in light of E.F. Hutton and other uncertainties as well as lower opportunity costs--or that these deposits are being boosted by a large volume of
purely financial transactions, or that interest-sensitive compensating
balances have come to represent a higher proportion of demand deposits as
households shift to NOW accounts and businesses pare excess cash holdings.
In any event, the extraordinary growth of demand deposits, as well as the
size of the decline in Ml velocity more generally in the current quarter,
raise questions as to whether some of this surge might not be reversed, or
at least whether a period of considerably more restrained Ml expansion
might be in the offing.

The bluebook alternatives assume no reversal over

the balance of the quarter, but they do presume an abatement of unusually
strong growth--especially in demand deposits.
Even if

the expansion of Ml is

seen to be primarily interest rate

related, that does not go far in telling us the degree to which the rapid
money growth may be providing stimulus to the economy.

To the extent that

interest rate declines have primarily been associated with sluggish investment demand or reduced inflation expectations,

the surge in money may have

served primarily to keep real interest rates sufficiently low to sustain
economic expansion.

On the other hand, a simultaneous increase in money

and reduction in interest rates obviously may be largely a result of a
more stimulative policy of reserve provision by the Federal Reserve, which
in time will boost economic activity.

-3Alternative A would seem most consistent with the view that the
expansion of Ml has primarily reflected relatively permanent additions to
highly liquid balances as nominal interst rates decline in response to lower
inflation and weaker final demands.

In this context, the more moderate

growth in M2, at least for the year-to-date, could be seen as reinforcing
the notion that Ml growth represents more a shift in the location of savings
than a general build-up of liquidity that is likely to spur future spending.
Indeed choice of alternative A would seem to imply a judgment that there is
a risk that underlying demands in the economy remain relatively weak, and
monetary expansion has not been sufficient to reduce real interest rates to
levels that will assure a stronger economic performance in the second half
of this year and next.
However, the specifications of alternative A put Ml in June at a
very high level, and the delayed effects of still

lower interest rates on

money demand in the second half of the year would seem to imply a substantial
probability of growth for the year in excess of the long-run range.

The

possibility of such an outcome would be less of a concern to the extent the
decline in rates was seen as leading only to moderate economic expansion and
the heightened interest sensitivity of money demand resulted in a further
weakness in velocity in the second half.
Alternative C is more consistent with a view that money growth
has been--or is quickly becoming--excessive,

increasing the risk of a very

sharp snap back in the economy later in the year with potentially adverse
effects on underlying inflation pressures.

In this view, the elements for

such a substantial strengthening of the economy are in place, stemming in
large measure from factors that traditionally have suggested an expansive

-4monetary policy--lower interest rates, higher stock prices and a declining
dollar.
The firming in interest rates implied by the reserve specifications
of this alternative could be viewed as a step toward restraining Ml to the
Committee's current 3 to 8 percent long-run range.

This might be considered

particularly appropriate if an especially vigorous economic expansion were
expected in the second half; under those conditions velocity might very
well rebound.
Alternative B might be characterized as consistent with the view
that accomodation of recent money growth has been appropriate and necessary
to assure a stronger economy in the second half, but further very rapid
money growth may prove to be excessive.

Given the huge build-up in liquidity,

a substantial slowing of Ml growth would be welcomed and accommodated under
this alternative by holding reserve conditions unchanged.

The staff has

projected such a slowing, based in part, as I have already noted, on expectations that the unusual surge in the volatile demand deposit component
will not continue and some gradual moderation in OCD growth as both depositors and depositories adapt to the lower level of market rates.
of M2 growth from its

A moderation

recent rapid pace also would seem appropriate, and

has been built into the alternative B path.

Although this aggregate is now

in the lower portion of its range, continued strong growth at the same time
that Ml was running above its range might suggest more cause for concern.
With regard to yearly growth paths, alternative B could be considered as
something of a holding action.

Ml would be above the upper parallel line

associated with its annual range in June under this alternative, and a
considerable slowing of its growth and moderate rise in velocity would
be required for the second half to achieve its annual objective.

Yet,

-5particularly if the expected slowing materialized over coming weeks,
an outcome would still

be a possibility, although it

such

could require some

upward movement of interest rates as the economy strengthened in the
second half.
Finally, Mr.

Chairman, I would like to draw the Committee's

attention to the directive language suggested for Committee consideration.
Variants II and III of the directive

acknowledge and react to the recent

overage in money growth relative to the Committee's short-run path.

Both

emphasize the expected slowing in money growth over the balance of the quarter.
With respect to policy implementation over the coming intermeeting period,
variant II retains the current laundry list of criteria for tightening reserve
availability, while spelling out a little more explicitly the circumstances
under which availability could be eased.
the easing criteria from II,

but clarifies that a tightening of reserve

conditions could be acceptable if
not materialize.

Variant III carries over much of

the expected slowing of money growth does