View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
May 17, 1988
Sam Y. Cross
Overall, dollar exchange rates have traded within a
relatively narrow range for most of the time since your last
meeting.

An abrupt movement occurred in mid-April when dollar

rates dropped lower in response to the release of disappointing
U.S. trade and price figures.

But the dollar steadied quickly

after concerted intervention by the U.S. and several foreign
monetary authorities.

After that it tended to trade stably but

did jump up by about one percent after the unexpectedly good
trade figures were announced this morning.
Throughout most of this period, the dollar exchange rate has
been held in rough balance by offsetting impulses.
Favoring the dollar, there is a widely held market view that
the G-7 authorities will firmly resist any substantial dollar
slippage, and that has given the dollar some support.

The

successive G-7 statements, most recently after the April 13th
meeting affirming official commitment to exchange rate stability,
have gained greater conviction and credibility, particularly
since we haven't seen in recent months the public bickering among
senior financial officials that was so prevalent last year.

Also

the market was impressed by the forcefulness and effectiveness of
the coordinated intervention operation in early January and again
in mid-April.

In addition, now that U.S. economic growth is

looking more robust and recession is not in the picture, the U.S.
policy stance needed for domestic stability is seen to be

compatible with that needed for external adjustment, and U.S.
policymakers are regarded as facing less of a dilemma.

Indeed,

the exchange market seems to have been reassured by signs that
the Federal Reserve adopted a less accommodative stance.

The

rise in the Fed funds rates in early April, and the further rise
last week, both added to support for the dollar, as short-term
interest differentials favorable to the dollar widened.
Counterbalancing these favorable factors, concerns about the
progress of adjustment and the financing of the current account
deficit are tending to hold the dollar down.

The adjustment

process appears at best to be operating very slowly and unevenly.
With domestic demand in the United States continuing to show
strength, much of the commentary from the press and from the
market focuses on the risks that the adjustment process is
getting off track.

The danger is that domestic demand will

continue to suck in more imports while capacity constraints limit
the growth in exports.

Today's trade figures will be seen as

more reassuring, but of course there have been other occasions
when we've seen good trade figures for a single month.
The market is also uncertain about how the U.S. deficit will
be financed this year.

With the central banks having financed

the bulk of the U.S. current account deficit last year, foreign
dollar reserves are very high.

These foreign central banks may

lose their taste for buying so many dollars in the exchange
market, and indeed there is talk in some quarters of the need to
diversify reserves into other currencies.

So far this year, with

the dollar stable and much less official intervention, it appears

that private flows are financing a much larger share of the
deficit.

Through April, dollar purchases of the G-10 plus the

rest of Europe have been equal to about 30 percent of our
estimated deficit whereas last year they equalled 75 percent.

So

private flows seem to be covering a good share of the financing.
Even so, some private investors express concern about the level
of their dollar-denominated holdings and seem to be looking for
alternative investments, for example in the United Kingdom,
Canada, and Australia.
With these counteracting forces, the dollar has traded in a
relatively narrower range than earlier, but market participants
are watching carefully to see whether the dollar will be kept
attractive enough to bring in the necessary amounts.
I would like to ask your approval for the FOMC operations
undertaken since your last meeting.

The Desk's operations for

the FOMC were conducted on two days, April 14 and 15, in response
to downward pressures coming from worse-than-expected figures on
U.S. trade and producer prices.

These purchases of $240 million

against marks were financed by the Federal Reserve through the
sale of mark balances.

The Desk also operated on behalf of the

U.S. Treasury on three days.

On March 29th, the day of your last

meeting, the Desk bought $50 million against the sale of yen,
financed out of ESF balances.

At the same time that the Desk was

intervening for the FOMC on April 14 and 15, it bought $260
million against yen, financed by the sale of SDR's under
agreement with Japan.

In addition, to replenish reserves, the

System bought $9.4 million equivalent of yen from customers.

PETER D. STERNLIGHT
NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
MAY 17, 1988

The Domestic Trading Desk undertook two small
restraining moves during the past intermeeting period.

The first

was an immediate outgrowth of the March 29 Committee meeting,
entailing a $100 million increase in the path allowance for
seasonal and adjustment borrowing to a level of $300 million.
This was expected to be associated with a rise in typical Federal
funds rates from the area of 6-1/2 percent to about 6-3/4
percent.

The second tug on the reins came in early May, in

response to a sense that recent economic data have been showing
appreciable strength, with possible inflationary implications,
while broad money measures have grown in the upper parts of their
ranges.

Following consultation with the Chairman, the path

borrowing allowance was raised by a further $100 million to $400
million--with an associated expectation that Fed funds would
trade in the area of about 7 percent.
Another path change during the period was the use of a
modestly higher standard allowance for excess reserves -- $950
million rather than $850 million, in recognition of further
increases in typical levels of excess reserve demand.

This

change had little practical impact on reserve pressures, since we
tend to make allowances in each reserve period for the likelihood
that excess reserve demands may run somewhat over or under the
standard path provision.

Using $950 million, there should be

fewer occasions when we would allow for "higher than normal"
excess reserves demands, and some additional times when we would
allow for lower demands.
Borrowing ran a little over the path level in the April
6 and April 20 reserve periods, averaging about $330 million.
There was a further rise to about $440 million in the May 4
period, when the objective was still $300 million, as the Desk
coped with the post-tax-date bulge in Treasury balances and
firmer than desired money market conditions.

So far in the

current reserve period, which ends tomorrow, borrowing has
averaged about $375 million.

Part of the pick-up in borrowing

since March has been in the seasonal component, which tends to
rise in the spring even in the absence of added money market
pressure.

In this sense, the increase in pressure since late

March may be a bit less than might be associated with a $200
million rise in path levels of borrowing.

However, I am not

aware of a simple mechanical adjustment to be made for this socalled "seasonal borrowing" seems to be product both of reserve
pressures and of strictly seasonal factors.
Funds rates tracked fairly close to expected levels,
though with some upward pressures surrounding the tax date.
Average rates hovered in the 6-3/4 - 6-7/8 percent area through
April and the first few days of May, with occasionally higher
rates that elicited fairly aggressive Desk action to help keep
reserve conditions in line with Committee intentions at the time.
Following the early May decision to foster a shade more firmness,

the Desk dragged its feet in meeting reserve needs, and this soon
led to a range of trading around 7 percent or a little above.
As this second move was being undertaken very shortly
before the Treasury began to action its quarterly refunding
issues, a particular effort was made to let the modified System
stance be perceived and digested by the market.

At the same time

it was a delicate undertaking since we wanted to avoid giving an
impression that the move was any greater than the small intended
step noted above.

Uncertain reserve estimates in the wake of

heavy Treasury tax flows added to the complexities.

Briefly,

funds traded up to the 7-1/4-3/8 percent area, but further
reserve injections then brought the trading range back to around
7 or a shade over.

We did see higher rates yesterday, though, as

the Treasury's large quarterly financing was being settled.
morning, funds are back at 7-1/16.

This

Through yesterday, the

average fund rate in this period is 7.08 percent.
The tax flows, with their hard-to-predict daily
patterns, directly complicated the forecasting of Treasury
balances at the Fed--though the problems were much less than a
year ago.

Operations were also complicated by some other, partly

related, developments.

One was changes in required reserves

which stemmed to some extent from build-ups and then run-downs in
transaction accounts to pay taxes.

Another was the varying

volume of extended credit, which partly changed in response to
the ebb and flow of Treasury tax and loan account balances.
However, good communications with the institutions involved

enabled us to cope pretty well with variations in extended
credit.
The increase in outright System holdings over the
period came to a net of about $7.55 billion, the bulk of it
comprising two large purchases of coupon issues in the market
totaling nearly $6.6 billion.

The rest reflected purchases of

bills and notes from foreign accounts, partly offset by some
small redemptions of agency issues.

The concentration on coupon

issues continued to reflect the relative scarcity of bills, as
the Treasury paid down bills while issuing more notes and bonds.
The outright purchases were somewhat less than was
contemplated when we asked for a temporary enlargement of the
leeway to $10 billion.

In part this was because Treasury

balances did not climb quite as high as had been anticipated
earlier.

In addition, since the last part of the run-up in

Treasury balances was expected to be reversed quickly, it seemed
more prudent to meet a sizable part of the need with selfreversing repurchase agreements and thereby lessen the need for
big reductions in outright holdings as the Treasury's balances
worked down.

Thus in the latter part of the period we made

active use of repurchase agreements, both customer-related and
for the Fed's own account.

Repos provided particular flexibility

in the period when we were seeking to convey the extent of the
System's recent slight firming move.
Market yields generally rose about 40 to 50 basis
points over the intermeeting period, through last night.

The

lower trade deficit reported this morning has shaved a few basis
points off that rise.

Underlying the rise was a sense that the

economy is continuing to show solid growth--not very rapid, but
at a pace that is narrowing appreciably the margins of slack in
human and physical capacity resources.

Current price news

remained mixed, but a number of anecdotal reports suggested that
producers have been able to put through increases and make them
stick, while many analysts have tended to raise their estimates
of the pace of likely price pressures in coming quarters.

In

part, rates moved up because of perceived or anticipated steps to
firm monetary policy--but we have also heard comments to the
effect that the markets, especially longer term markets, welcomed
signs of Federal Reserve resistance to inflation, and might have
reacted more negatively to an absence of policy response.

There

was particular market discouragement with the February trade
figures, reported just a month ago, given their indication of
continued strength in imports.

There seems to be a growing

realization that domestic demands must be held to a slow growth
track if the trade deficit is to be overcome.

The markets did

take some heart last Friday with the report of a modest rise in
April producer prices (except food and energy), especially as
this coincided with the conclusion of bidding on the Treasury
quarterly refunding package, but the underlying mood remains
quite cautious, with participants tending to interpret incoming
information on the side that would lead to higher rates.

Thus a

large part of last Friday's price gains eroded on Monday as the

popular CRB commodity index pushed higher.

This morning bond

prices gapped up about a point on the trade deficit number but
then gave back about half the gain.
In the Treasury market, yields on most short to
intermediate issues were up by about 45-50 basis points over the
period, while long-term issues were up a slightly more modest 40
basis points or so.

The Treasury raised about $14 billion in the

coupon market, mostly in the mid quarter refunding package of 3,
10, and 30-year issues that settled yesterday.

Those issues were

pretty well bid for, especially the two longer ones where
Possibly adding to

Japanese interest was very substantial.

interest in the 30-year bond is the prospect that the Treasury
may have to skip this maturity in the next refunding as it has
now almost exhausted its authority to sell bonds at rates above
4-1/4 percent and sees only slim likelihood of getting new
authority in the next few months.

It is not yet clear how well

the new refunding issues are distributed.

At present they are

trading above issue price but there has been no real test of the
market since they were sold last week.

A particularly intriguing

question is the solidity of placement with Japanese buyers.
These were once considered good solid "going away" sales, but
there is more question nowadays as to whether these buyers may
not have acquired more of the "trading mentality" now typical of
many U.S. buyers.
In the bill market, rates rose about 45-50 basis
points, following along with higher Fed funds and financing

costs, even though the Treasury was continuing to pay down bills-by about $9 billion during the interval, including a chunk of
cash management bills repaid after the April tax date.

In

yesterday's auctions, 3- and 6-month bills went at average rates
of 6.28 and 6.50 respectively, compared with 5.69 and 6.00
percent just before the last meeting.
Various private short-term market rates, such as on
commercial paper and bank CDs, also rose on the order of 1/2
percentage point over the period, and in response major banks
raised their prime lending rates by 1/2 point to 9 percent.
In the Federal agency sector, I should mention that the
market perception of FICO issues improved perceptibly over the
period.

This is not because market participants have felt any

better about the underlying situation of thrifts, which is still
seen as very grim indeed, but because of some innovative
financing in which a dealer took down a sizable block of FICO
bonds, separated the coupons from the corpus and placed the
stripped issues with investors who seemed to find the separate
pieces more appealing than the whole.

This relieved the imminent

overhang of new FICO issues and caused the spreads on earlier
whole issues to narrow from about 115 basis points to something
just under 100.

One has to wonder how durable this improvement

will be, but for the moment that market feels better.
As to the market's outlook more generally, it seems to
me that most observers have now folded in the System's latest
slight firming fairly completely.

They seem to anticipate funds

trading around 7 percent or a shade higher.

Most participants

look for little further change immediately but do seem to expect
further firming moves as the year progresses.

Fewer participants

now seem to look for rate declines than was the case a month or
two ago, though the increases expected by many others are of
rather moderate size.

Michael J. Prell
May 17, 1988
FOMC Briefing--Economic Outlook

This morning's trade data are the last major piece in the
first-quarter GNP puzzle.
later.

Ted will be saying a few words about them

Combined with the other items that have become available

recently, they suggest that the Commerce Department next week may well
be doubling its initial Q1 growth estimate of 2-1/4 percent.

Such a

number would be more in line with the labor market data, the continuing
strength of which, as you know, was the main factor leading us to raise
our projection of GNP growth in the second quarter to 3-1/2 percent.
The staff has consistently been above the average of private
forecasters in our expectations of growth since last fall, but we, too,
have been surprised by the pace of expansion thus far this year, and by
the size of the drop in the unemployment rate.

The reduced slack in the

economy has been reflected in a slightly higher projected rate of wage
and price increase in coming months.

However, we have not carried that

higher inflation rate through 1989; instead, on the basis of the
sentiment expressed by Committee members at the March meeting, we have
assumed that monetary policy imposes greater restraint on aggregate
demand.

In this forecast, the federal funds rate moves into the 8-1/2

to 9 percent range by early 1989, and the long Treasury bond edges above
10 percent; the rise in short rates is a percentage point more than

-2

-

contemplated in the last Greenbook, so that it is now more discernibly
an increase in real as well as nominal terms.
Whether such a rise in rates will be needed to contain
inflation is, of course, far from
raises two separate questions:

certain.

Basically, our projection

first, how much slowing in output growth

is needed to prevent a pickup in inflation, and, second, is that slowing
likely to occur in the absence of greater monetary restraint?
In addressing these issues, let me begin by noting that, until
recently, indications

of significant pressure on resources and of

consequent price acceleration were limited largely to crude and
intermediate materials.

Compensation trends were fairly stable, even

though rising living costs were eroding real wages.

It is the staff's

assessment, however, that we have entered a new phase in which the labor
markets have reached a degree of tautness that is likely to be
associated with a fuller pass-through of price increases into wages and
thus with an appreciable acceleration of labor costs.
To be sure, the available evidence on this score is still not
clearcut.

The most notable piece of information, we think, is the

marked rise in the Employment Cost Index in the first quarter.

This put

the increase in compensation over the year ended March at about 4
percent--1/2 to 3/4 of a point more than the twelve-month changes had
been running.

Because the first-quarter number was affected by a jump

in employers' contributions for social security, one must look beneath
the totals to determine whether there are signs of more general marketrelated pressure.

We went through the dissection in the Greenbook.

In

- 3 -

a nutshell, our sense from all the statistical and anecdotal information
is that there has been an overall firming, with the pickup in
manufacturing activity showing through in some convergence of the
compensation increases in the goods-producing and service sectors.
Admittedly, the step-up in pay has been surprisingly mild to
date.

But, given the lags in the process, we have yet to see the full

consequences of the drop in the jobless rate that has occurred since
last fall.

It is with this in mind that we have put together a forecast

that implies a need to move the unemployment rate back up if wage
pressures are to be held in check.

You will note that we do project

some further rise in wage inflation, with compensation accelerating into
the 4-1/2 percent neighborhood, even though the unemployment rate rises
to 6 percent by the end of 1989.

This is because consumer price

inflation is expected to run in the 5 percent range for a while, as a
result of continued increases in import prices, a rise in energy prices,
and some pass-through of higher materials costs.
If, then, it is necessary to restore somewhat greater slack to
the labor markets in order to contain inflation, the next question is
what growth rate of output is consistent with that objective.
believe the answer is:

less than 2-1/2 percent.

We

The steepness of the

drop of the unemployment rate over the past year and a half would
suggest that the number might even be lower than that.

A pattern of

outsized declines in unemployment relative to GNP growth could be
symptomatic of a deterioration in productivity as less skilled workers
a're put on payrolls in a tight labor market.

But we believe that GNP

- 4 -

growth actually has been stronger than estimated, and that later
revisions of the data will tend to move things into closer alignment
with the previous Okun's Law relationship.
Moving now to the second issue I raised earlier, what are the
chances that the required moderation of output growth would occur
without restrictive policy action?

There are, after all, respected

analysts who are projecting that this expansion will slow soon of
natural causes, so to speak--although I might note that some of them are
nonetheless pessimistic about the chances of avoiding a pickup in
inflation.

The focus of the endogenous slowdown argument most often is

the rapid growth of nonauto inventories since the latter part of 1987.
We believe there is something to this view, but not enough.
Although the recent pace of inventory accumulation is
unsustainable over the longer haul, the undesired portion of the stockbuilding seems to have been small to date, and pretty much limited to
some segments of retail trade.

In the manufacturing and wholesale

sectors, the accumulation that has occurred appears to have been mainly
intentional, and related in large part to the rising demand for capital
equipment and other traded goods.

With the prices of materials and

components rising rapidly, and delivery times lengthening, there
probably has been a good deal of precautionary or speculative stockbuilding going on, and some firms would be happy with even more
inventory than they have.

Especially in manufacturing, the current

stock-to-sales ratio is low.

- 5 -

In our forecast, there is a gradual slowing in inventory
investment.

It is led initially by retailers, who may have to cut

prices and trim their ordering plans because consumer demand is unlikely
to be strong enough to clear up all of their problems.

By the latter

part of the year, manufacturers are expected to moderate their
accumulation, when slower growth of final sales becomes evident and the
pressures on materials supplies begin to ease.
The keys to the strength of final demand still appear to be
exports and business fixed investment.
addressing the trade picture.

As I noted earlier, Ted will be

As regards plant and equipment spending,

we have raised our projection of 1988 real outlay growth by a couple of
percentage points.

This change is almost entirely accounted for by the

great-than-anticipated surge in spending in the first quarter.

If our

forecast is realized, nominal spending for the year will exceed somewhat
the increases indicated by the winter McGraw-Hill and Commerce surveys.
One would have to assign a wide range of uncertainty to our
forecast at this point.

The first-quarter strength in BFI reflected in

good part an extraordinary spurt in computer shipments, which may have
been a fluke, or may have been a precursor of another wave of

computer

acquisitions, perhaps stimulated by the attractiveness of new products.
More generally, there is a growing view that businesses are scaling up
investment plans and that we may be seeing the kind of capital spending
boom that has come at the mature phases of other cyclical expansions.
At the same time, though, there are continued reports of companies being
hesitant to make major commitments, in'light of their fears that there

- 6-

will be a recession in the next year or so, or that the dollar might
rebound.
Our capital spending forecast is, as best one can define it, in
the middle of this road.

If a boom is under way, however, inflationary

pressures could well be more intense in the near term than we have
forecast and interest rates could have to rise even more than we have
indicated, given that investment activity historically has proven to be
very interest-inelastic in the short run.
As it is, in our forecast, the higher interest rates damp the
demand for housing most noticeably in the near term, and then leave
their imprint more broadly on domestic demand, in part through some
negative effect on wealth as well as on financing costs.

But besides

simply limiting pressures on labor and capital resources, the rise in
interest rates is assumed to reduce the tendencies toward dollar
depreciation, and consequently import
our previous forecast.

prices rise less in 1989 than in

Weaker output growth and less dollar weakness

also should help damp oil price increases.

It is because of these less

direct effects that we get a fairly substantial inflation-reducing
effect from a modest alteration in the growth path of GNP and only a
slight increase in unemployment relative to our last forecast.

E.M. Truman
May 17, 1988

FOMC Presentation-International Developments
This morning, as has already been reported, the Commerce
Department released its report on U.S. merchandise trade in March on a
not-seasonally adjusted, c.i.f. basis.

The deficit was $9-3/4 billion.

The staff had expected a deficit of just under $12 billion. Exports,
which are seasonally strong in March, were at a record of almost $30
billion, somewhat higher than the staff had expected.

An unanticipated

part of the increase was a surge in exports of non-monetary gold.
Imports were about $39 billion, about in line with our expectations.

Oil

imports declined in both quantity and price, generally consistent with
our preliminary estimate.

Non-oil imports increased further in March,

though less than implied by seasonal factors.

Today's data together with

an anticipated upward revision in the deflator for non-oil imports in the
first quarter (based on the BLS price information released in late April)
suggest, as we have already discussed, a substantial upward revision in
real net exports of goods and services in the GNP accounts in the first
quarter.
However, the March trade data do not suggest a substantial
revision in the May Greenbook's outlook for balance of the forecast
period, except to reinforce our view about the underlying strength of
non-agricultural exports.

That outlook is not significantly different

from the one presented in the March Greenbook, but it incorporates the
net effect of several different factors.
First, the higher path of U.S. interest rates now assumed in the
forecast would normally be expected to increase slightly the current

-2-

account deficit because our portfolio liabilities exceed our portfolio
assets.

However, the effects in the forecast of the higher interest

rates were more than offset by other changes in our analysis of portfolio
receipts and payments that were produced by a closer examination of this
increasingly sensitive aspect of our accounts.
Second, the assumed higher path of U.S. interest rates-real and
nominal-caused us to reduce somewhat our projection of the rate of
depreciation of the dollar in terms of other G-10 countries' currencies
over the forecast period.

The adjustment, which amounts to about 3

percent on the average level of the dollar by the end of 1989, depresses
real net exports a bit, but the muted J-curve implies a limited net
effect on the nominal current account balance during the forecast period.
I would note that the staff's projection for the dollar is based
primarily on a longer-term view of what is likely to be involved before
equilibrium is restored to our external accounts rather than a firmly
held view about developments over the next 6-8 quarters.
Third, the lower level of U.S. economic activity now projected
for 1989 tends to improve the outlook for our external accounts,
partially offseting the effects of the smaller depreciation of the dollar
over the projection period.
Fourth, economic expansion in the foreign industrial countries
appears to have been somewhat stronger in the first quarter than we had
earlier anticipated, with output growing on average at an annual rate of
about 2-1/2 percent.

However, the pace of expansion in some countries-

in particular, in Canada, the United Kingdom, and to a lesser extent
Japan-along with rapid money growth in most of these countries have
added to concerns of foreign officials about inflation.

Higher interest

-3-

rates in this country and the reduced downward pressure on the dollar
that we are now projecting increase the likelihood that these concerns
will give rise to somewhat tighter monetary conditions abroad.

Along

with slower growth in the United States next year, the net result is
expected to be slightly less growth on average in the other industrial
countries over the balance of the forecast period-averaging a bit under
2 percent at an annual rate.
Finally, as Mike mentioned, we have incorporated into the
forecast a slightly lower price of imported oil in 1989 in recognition of
weaker demand and the higher level of the dollar and of dollar interest
rates.

Largely as a consequence, U.S. oil imports are projected to be

about $4 billion lower in 1989 than in the last Greenbook.
On balance, however, the basic contour of our forecast has not
changed significantly from that contained in the March Greenbook.
Propelled in large part by rising exports, we expect a marginally
improving trade balance in nominal terms over the remaining quarters of
this year and a larger improvement next year.

Because of the

deterioration in non-trade current account transactions-largely
reflecting lower capital gains due to the dollar's projected much slower
rate of depreciation-the current account is expected to show little
improvement this year but greater improvement next year, declining to a
deficit of about $130 billion at an annual rate by the fourth quarter.
Meanwhile, net exports of goods and services in real terms should improve
substantially in both years; much of the improvement in nominal terms
continues to be masked by the projected faster rise in prices of imports
than in prices of exports.
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.

May 17,

1988

Policy Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

As background for the Committee's consideration of its policy
options today, I thought it might be useful to review possible interpretations of financial developments since the last FOMC meeting in terms of
their implications for the thrust of monetary policy, to look at certain
key financial variables in a longer-term perspective, and to relate this
perspective to the monetary policy assumptions behind the Greenbook outlook
as already outlined by Mike and Ted.
In terms of developments since the last meeting, increases in
reserve pressures--or at least the market's perception of them--and in the
federal funds rate generally were preceded by upward movements in other
market interest rates, and the actual tightening moves had little market
effect.

This, by itself, has little import, except to suggest that we were

doing about what the market thought we would do, given the incoming data on
the economy and prices.

Whether the firming of policy represents, or was

seen as representing, increased real restraint on the economy is an open
question.

The slight firming of the dollar on foreign exchange markets and

small decline in many broad measures of stock prices suggest that real
interest rates may have risen a bit over the intermeeting period.

How-

ever, with long-term rates increasing about in line with short-term rates,
the firming undertaken since the last meeting seems only to have kept pace
with changing market perceptions of the strength of demands on the economy
and the potential for greater inflation.

Judging from the still fairly

-2-

steep slope of the yield curve, markets apparently continue to expect
substantial further upward movements in short-term rates over coming
quarters.
The markets' expectations in this regard, as well as the staff
forecast, seem to be supported by the behavior of interest rates and other
key financial variables over the past year or so and their apparent relation to the economy.

Nominal interest rates have fluctuated over a fairly

wide range over the past year, but on balance are now 1/4 to 1/2 percentage
point above their levels of a year ago.

Real interest rates are far more

difficult to judge, given the problems of discerning inflation expectations.

But surveys from both the University of Michigan and Richard Hoey

indicate that movements in these expectations have broadly tracked variations in nominal rates over the last year or even longer.

Inflation expec-

tations had risen substantially in April and May of 1987, dropped a bit
following the stock market crash, but by April of this year had rebounded
to levels of about last May.

The pattern of expectations tracking with

nominal rates also can be seen in the tendency of long-term rates to move
up and down with short-term rates; over the past year the slope of the
yield curve has changed very little on balance.

On balance, comparing one-

year ahead inflation expectations to one-year bill rates, real interest
rates appear to be a little over 2 percent or so, perhaps slightly above
their levels of one year ago, which in turn were not much different from
real rates over the previous several quarters.
The significance of this observation is that these levels and
movements in real rates were consistent with growth in the economy over

recent quarters at a pace that is not likely to be sustainable without
leading to accelerating inflation.

Whether the, at most, modest increase

in real rates over the last year has been enough to contain price pressures
depends not only on the potential strength of those pressures, but also on
the influence of other key financial variables that affect spending
decisions.

In this regard, the evidence is mixed.

The dollar has fallen

about 7 percent over the last year against other G-10 currencies, but stock
prices also have moved lower.

The slow money growth of 1987 does not seem

to have been reflected in subsequent weakness in demand, and following its
pickup early this year M2 by April was about 5 percent above its level of
a year ago.

With considerable support for expansion coming from the

external sector, relatively tight monetary policy involving high real
interest rates may be necessary to get the required restraint on domestic
demand, in

the context of little additional help on the fiscal side.

In

the staff forecast, rates are not yet at the requisite levels, and as a
consequence, nominal and real rates are projected to rise further.
The specific course of rates over the near-term is not crucial to
the staff's forecast, as Mike indicated, but alternative C might be considered broadly consistent with something like this process of rising rates
envisioned in that forecast.

All the alternatives are expected to involve

some deceleration of money growth from recent rates, given the ebbing of
tax effects and the impact of the recent turnaround opportunity costs.

But

that deceleration would be greatest under C, and the firming of reserve
pressures under that alternative would establish conditions for damped
money growth in the third quarter. The monetary restraint embodied in the

staff forecast implies a marked slowing of money growth over the balance of
the year.

For the year as a whole, M2 growth would be expected to be

around the middle of its range, but given its growth rate thus far this
year, this will require expansion at only a 4-3/4 percent rate from April
through December.

Our econometric models actually suggest that growth a

little below the midpoint for the year could be consistent with the staff's
GNP and interest rate paths.

Given its greater interest elasticity, M1

would be expected to decelerate even more than M2 over the balance of 1987.
In fact, the

narrow aggregate might show little net growth on balance from

the second to the fourth quarters of this year.
Alternative B would be consistent with delaying further action
until the tightening of recent weeks has had a chance to have some effect
on the economy and prices, or at least until incoming data suggest that
other forces already at work aren't themselves
expansion.

moderating the pace of

The current structure of rates does not suggest the markets

expect much if any immediate further tightening, though that could change
if incoming data continue to show strength in the economy or prices.

If

there were concerns that the risks lay more on the side of strength in the
economy and greater price pressures, the Desk could be instructed, using
the usual collection of mights and woulds, to be especially alert to
indications that a tighter policy was appropriate.
With respect to other language in the directive, the Committee
may again want to consider whether it wants to retain the sentence on
additional flexibility in operations--shown in brackets in the draft
directive.

While operations have been sensitive to the level of the

-5-

federal funds rate at times over the recent intermeeting period, this was
mostly in the context of conveying as clearly and promptly as possible the
sense of a change in policy stance, rather than to deal with concerns about
market fragility.

Interest rates and even stock prices in recent months

have not been substantially more volatile than before the October crash,
and risk premia in credit markets are comparable to earlier in 1987.

More-

over, the economic outlook probably is no more uncertain than at many other
times in recent history.

Even so, one has a sense that there is a

potential for large, disruptive market reactions to small events.

Even

without special instructions, the Desk probably has scope in its operations
to deal with such circumstances, but if the Committee wished to stress
the possibility of a flexible approach to policy implementation, the
sentence might be retained.

May 17,

1988

Base Briefing
Donald L. Kohn

President Melzer makes a good case for some limit or binding
constraint on the Federal Reserve's provision of liquidity to the
economy under conditions when, judged by historic relations, that
provision is deviating very substantially from what would be considered
consistent with steady, noninflationary growth.

In effect he has

proposed a policy regime that would have elements of both rules and
discretion.

Discretion would be exercised so long as growth of the

nominal anchor was within a fairly wide band.

But when growth got to

one side of the band, a rule would be followed to keep the anchor within
or return it to the band.

The objective is to prevent very large,

cumulative errors in policy in either direction.
The key question is whether the monetary base, his proposed
nominal anchor, is sufficiently reliable to play the role of constraint
in that regime.

Because his plan involves relinquishing discretion in

adjusting reserve positions under some circumstances, the Committee
ought to be reasonably confident that a growth band for the base,
however wide, generally would become binding only when the response
triggered would be stabilizing for the economy.
As a general proposition, the various statistical tests done on
the base suggest that it is no worse a guide to policy than the other
money and debt aggregates, and probably a little better.

The errors in

its demand relationships are considerably less than for M1-A and M1, and

about in line with M2.

Like all the aggregates it has undergone some

change in the 1980s, reflecting in particular deregulation of deposit
rates, which affects the demand for the base through its impact on the
derived demand for reserves.

As a consequence, its demand relationship

probably has become a bit more interest sensitive since 1980.

However,

the empirical tests also are consistent with a reasonably stable demand
once these changes are taken into account.

And, because of the high

weight of its currency component, it remains considerably less interest
sensitive than M1 or M2, probably making it a better guide to policy
than either over the intermediate term, when disturbances to spending
are likely to be more important than disturbances to its demand.
At the least, these considerations may argue for including the
base among the aggregates for which we announce annual ranges.

There

is a sense in which the base is not a very satisfying concept; it does
not coincide even theoretically with the public's transaction balances,
or a reasonably comprehensive collection of its savings instruments.
Moreover, we do not know who is holding a significant part of its
currency component.

But its statistical properties may make a range for

it an attractive substitute for M1 as a narrow aggregate.

Its range

could be treated like the current ranges for M2 and M3--reset each year,
and open to being violated, for example in response to unanticipated
shifts in demands for currency or reserves relative to GNP.
Whether the base is sufficiently immune to major disturbances
in its demand to serve as the trigger for the giving up of discretion
under some circumstances is a more difficult question.

The relatively

small errors in its demand equation predictions give some comfort in
this regard.

These result to some extent from the tendency of errors in

currency and deposit equations to be offsetting.

For example, despite a

major miss in the currency equation in 1987, base growth was only 1.7
percent above what was predicted by the combined currency and deposit
equations.

Thus demand side shocks, by themselves, are unlikely to

cause the base to breach a 4 or 5 percentage point band.

On balance,

even making allowance for some unexplainable perturbations to demands
for currency or reserves, very strong growth in the base probably would
be associated with at least some strength in the economy.

Similarly,

substantial weakness in the base would usually signal some softness in
the economy.
However, there is some irreducible risk that considerable
strength or weakness in the base would occur in circumstances in which a
response would not necessarily be appropriate.

It is tempting to make

such judgments on the basis of past growth in the base relative to
President Melzer's or some other ranges.

In a sense this is not a

legitimate test, since as soon as the base triggered a different
monetary policy, the subsequent paths of the base as well as the economy
would have been altered.

Even so, Chart 3 following p. 11 in the Board

staff memo or the chart enclosed with President Melzer's memo provides
the raw material for such an exercise.

In recent years, the base

bounds suggested by President Melzer raise the question of whether the
Federal Reserve should have reduced the degree to which it was
tightening in 1981 or easing in 1983 or 1986.

In fact, each of these

episodes was followed, with some lag, by a policy reversal.

But a base

constraint would have had policy responding sooner, assuming the
situation would have developed in any case.
And once the bounds were hit, the response likely would have
been quite strong, at least in interest rate terms, potentially
involving sharp reversals of previous rate movements.

This results from

the interest inelasticity of the base, which implies that rate movements
might have to be substantial if the base were to be contained within the
range in the face of strong impulses to move outside.

In some cases

such a response might be appropriate--that is, stabilizing for the
economy.

But in other cases the implied response may seem to involve

inappropriate movements in interest rates--at least in terms of degree.
If the Committee wanted to adopt something like President Melzer's
proposal, at some point it would need to consider a number of subsidiary
issues.

One, should it use quarterly growth rates as in his proposal,

or a moving average over several quarters?

The latter might avoid

reacting to transitory shocks to the economy or base demand, but it
would risk delaying response to an emerging trend.

Two, exactly how

should policy react to a potential or actual breach of the ranges?

The

total base is not directly controllable, and some sort of reaction would
have to be decided on--for example holding nonborrowed reserves constant
or even adjusting them depending on the size of the deviation in the
total base from its range.

A nonborrowed base objective would obviate

the need for such a decision, since it could be directly controlled and
kept within the limits.

The nonborrowed base also is a little more

-5-

interest sensitive, implying that rate movements at the limits might be
a little smaller than if the Committee tried to keep the total base from
moving outside its range in the short run.

Three, what should the range

be; and assuming the range was initially set around recent base growth
rates, should there be a plan to reduce the range over several years by
a preset formula to something more consistent with price stability?