View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Prefatory Note

The attached document represents the most complete and accurate version available
based on original files from the FOMC Secretariat at the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Please note that some material may have been redacted from this document if that
material was received on a confidential basis. Redacted material is indicated by
occasional gaps in the text or by gray boxes around non-text content. All redacted
passages are exempt from disclosure under applicable provisions of the Freedom of
Information Act.

Content last modified 1/12/2024.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Report to the FOMC
on Economic Conditions
and Monetary Policy

Book A
Economic and Financial Conditions:
Outlook, Risks, and Policy Strategies
April 20, 2018

Prepared for the Federal Open Market Committee
by the staff of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Domestic Economic Developments and Outlook
The information received since the March Tealbook remains consistent with our
view that the economy continues to expand at an above-trend pace. Although the March
employment report was not as strong as we had expected, our broad assessment is that
labor market conditions continued to tighten through the first quarter: The
unemployment rate remained flat, but the labor force participation rate (LFPR) moved up
and payroll employment gains averaged well above the pace estimated to be consistent
with no change in resource utilization. On the spending side, GDP growth appears to
have slowed in the first quarter, but we judge that the slowdown is temporary and expect
that GDP growth will bounce back in the current quarter. Over the first half of the year,
real GDP is projected to increase at an annual rate of 2¼ percent, about ¼ percentage
point less than we had forecast in the March Tealbook but sufficient to further widen the
gap between actual and potential output.
Over the medium term, we continue to project an economy with above-trend
growth and very high resource utilization, buoyed by expansionary fiscal policy and solid
foreign growth. We forecast that real GDP will increase about 2½ percent this year and
next before slowing to a 2 percent pace in 2020 as monetary policy continues to tighten.
By the end of the medium term, the level of real GDP is projected to be 3¼ percent above
our estimate of its potential—nearly ½ percentage point less than in our previous forecast
but still indicative of a very tight economy. Correspondingly, the unemployment rate is
expected to be 3.3 percent at the end of 2020—a little higher than in the March Tealbook
but still 1½ percentage points below our estimate of its natural rate.
The latest monthly readings on prices have come in a touch above our
expectations and provide additional support for our view that the factors that held down
inflation last year were transitory. With the March CPI and PPI now in hand, we estimate
that the 12-month change in core PCE prices stepped up to 1.9 percent last month,
0.1 percentage point above our March Tealbook projection, as the extraordinarily low
reading from March of last year dropped out of the calculation. For the year as a whole,
we expect core inflation to be 2.0 percent—also 0.1 percentage point higher than in our
previous forecast. Core inflation is then projected to edge up to 2.1 percent in 2019 and
2020 as resource utilization tightens further and underlying inflation inches up. Total
PCE prices are expected to increase 2.1 percent this year, a little more than core prices,

Page 1 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Comparing the Staff Projection with Other Forecasts
The staff’s projection for real GDP growth is ¼ percentage point lower than the
projections from both the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) and the Blue Chip
consensus in 2018 and ¼ percentage point higher than the Blue Chip in 2019. The
staff’s unemployment rate forecast is below the outside forecasts in both 2018 and
2019. The staff’s projections for total CPI and PCE inflation are a little higher than the
outside forecasts in 2018 but are about the same in 2019, while the staff forecast for
core PCE inflation is a touch higher than the SPF in both years. (Note that the SPF
projections are more than two months old.)

Comparison of Tealbook and Outside Forecasts
2017

2018

2019

2.6
2.6
2.5

2.6
2.8
2.8

2.6
2.3
n.a.

Unemployment rate (Q4 level)
April Tealbook
Blue Chip (04/10/18)
SPF median (02/09/18)

4.1
4.1
4.1

3.6
3.7
3.8

3.3
3.6
n.a.

CPI inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
April Tealbook
Blue Chip (04/10/18)
SPF median (02/09/18)

2.1
2.1
2.1

2.4
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.2
2.2

PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
April Tealbook
1.7
SPF median (02/09/18)
1.7

2.1
1.9

1.9
2.0

Core PCE price inflation (Q4/Q4 percent change)
April Tealbook
1.5
SPF median (02/09/18)
1.5

2.0
1.9

2.1
2.0

GDP (Q4/Q4 percent change)
April Tealbook
Blue Chip (04/10/18)
SPF median (02/09/18)

Note: SPF is the Survey of Professional Forecasters, CPI is the consumer price index,
and PCE is personal consumption expenditures. Blue Chip does not provide results for
overall and core PCE price inflation. The Blue Chip consensus forecast includes input from
about 50 panelists, and the SPF about 40. Roughly 20 panelists contribute to both surveys.
Source: Blue Chip Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Page 2 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Tealbook Forecast Compared with Blue Chip
Real GDP

Industrial Production
Percent change, annual rate

Blue Chip consensus
Staff forecast

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

Percent change, annual rate

10

12

8

8

6

4

4

0

2

-4

0

-8

-2

-12

-4

-16

-6

-20

-8

2011

Unemployment Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

-24

Consumer Price Index
Percent

Percent change, annual rate

10

8

9

6

8

4
2

7

0
6
-2
5

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-4

4

-6

3

-8

2

2011

Treasury Bill Rate

2013

2015

2017

2019

-10

10-Year Treasury Yield
Percent

Percent

4

5.5
5.0

3

4.5
4.0

2

3.5
3.0

1

2.5
2.0

0

1.5
2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

-1

2011

2013

2015

2017

2019

Note: The yield is for on-the-run Treasury securities. Over
the forecast period, the staff’s projected yield is assumed
to be 15 basis points below the off-the-run yield.
Note: The shaded area represents the area between the Blue Chip top 10 and bottom 10 averages.

Page 3 of 126

1.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Key Background Factors underlying the Baseline Staff Projection

Federal Funds Rate

Long-Term Interest Rates
Percent

Percent

6

Quarterly average

11

Quarterly average
10
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

5

9

Conforming
mortgage rate
4

8

Triple-B
corporate yield

7

3

6
5

2

4

1

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

3

10-year
Treasury yield

0

2008

2010

2
2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

1

House Prices

Equity Prices

Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100

Ratio scale, 2007:Q1 = 100 215
214
200
185
170
155
140

Quarter-end

Dow Jones
U.S. Total Stock Market
Index

Quarterly

120
115
110
105

125

100

110

95
90

95
CoreLogic
Index

80

85
80
75

65

70
2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

50

2008

Crude Oil Prices

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

65

Broad Real Dollar
Dollars per barrel

2007:Q1 = 100

140

115

Quarterly average

Quarterly average
Imported oil

110

120

105
100
100
West Texas
Intermediate

80
95
60
90
40

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

85

20

2008

Page 4 of 126

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

80

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

boosted by an increase in energy prices in the first half of the year. After this year, total
inflation—at 1.9 percent in 2019 and 2.0 percent in 2020—is restrained a bit by declining
energy prices and runs a little below core inflation. Relative to the March Tealbook,
inflation at the end of the projection is a touch lower, reflecting the higher unemployment
rate in this forecast. Finally, as in the March Tealbook, we have not incorporated any
effects on either real activity or inflation from higher import tariffs. 1

KEY BACKGROUND FACTORS
Fiscal Policy
•

We have not changed our fiscal policy assumptions in this projection. We still
estimate that discretionary policy actions across all levels of government will
boost aggregate demand growth ½ percentage point in 2018, ¾ percentage
point in 2019, and ½ percentage point in 2020, exclusive of any multiplier
effects and offsets from reactions in interest rates and the dollar. Roughly
one-half of that medium-term impetus is due to the recent federal tax cuts,
while about one-fourth reflects the recent federal spending legislation; most of
the remainder is due to projected increases in real state and local government
expenditures.

•

The federal deficit is projected to rise from 3½ percent of GDP in fiscal year
2017 to 5¼ percent in fiscal 2020—a step-up that primarily reflects the effects
of the recent tax and spending bills.
o We continue to assume that, in five years, confronted with an elevated and
rising debt-to-GDP ratio, fiscal policymakers will begin to enact deficit
reduction measures that gradually bring annual deficits back to sustainable
levels.

Monetary Policy
•

The inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule that we use to set the path of
monetary policy calls for the federal funds rate to increase nearly
1½ percentage points in total this year and to rise about 1 percentage point per
year, on average, in the next two years, reaching 4.7 percent in the fourth

We estimate that the effects of the new steel and aluminum tariffs, in isolation, will be minimal
for both net exports and prices. Other potential tariff changes remain highly uncertain at this point and are
therefore not included in our projection.
1

Page 5 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

quarter of 2020. This trajectory is a little less steep than in the March
Tealbook, primarily reflecting the slightly lower level of resource utilization
in this projection.
•

The SOMA portfolio continues to shrink as securities are redeemed in a
manner consistent with the Committee’s June 2017 Addendum to the Policy
Normalization Principles and Plans and with the process initiated in
October 2017.

Other Interest Rates
•

The 10-year Treasury yield is projected to rise significantly over the medium
term from an average of 2.9 percent in the current quarter to 4.4 percent by the
end of 2020. This path has been revised down about 25 basis points on
average relative to the March Tealbook, reflecting the lower-than-expected
readings for the 10-year Treasury yield over the intermeeting period along
with the flatter projected trajectory for the federal funds rate.

•

The 30-year fixed mortgage rate and the triple-B corporate bond rate are also
forecast to rise significantly over the medium term. The paths for these two
rates were revised down mostly in line with revisions to the path of the
10-year Treasury yield.

Equity Prices and Home Prices
•

Equity prices are projected to end the current quarter 1½ percent lower than
was projected in the March Tealbook, reflecting the recent declines in broad
equity price indexes. Beyond the current quarter, we project stock prices to
rise at an average annual rate of ¾ percent, similar to our previous projection.

•

We expect annual house price appreciation to slow from 6 percent last year to
an average of about 3¾ percent over the next three years, as interest rates rise.

Foreign Economic Activity and the Dollar
•

We estimate that real GDP in the foreign economies rose 3 percent at an
annual rate in the first quarter, a touch faster than in the second half of last
year. This first-quarter estimate is about the same as in the March Tealbook,
as softer economic indicators in some advanced foreign economies were about
offset by positive surprises in several Asian economies. Foreign growth is
Page 6 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

projected to stay close to this 3 percent pace in 2018 and then edge down
slightly over the remainder of the forecast period to near its potential rate of
2¾ percent in 2020.
•

The broad nominal dollar has depreciated about ½ percent since the time of
the March Tealbook. We project the broad real dollar to appreciate at an
annual rate of about 1¾ percent through the forecast period, as market
expectations for the federal funds rate move up toward the staff forecast. This
rate of appreciation is somewhat lower than in the March projection, reflecting
the downward revision of the staff’s projected path for U.S. policy rates. This
lower rate of projected appreciation, along with the recent realized
depreciation, leaves the broad real dollar about 1¼ percent lower at the end of
the forecast relative to the March Tealbook.

Oil and Commodity Prices
•

The spot price of Brent crude oil has risen $9 per barrel on net since the
March Tealbook, closing most recently at $73 per barrel, while the price of
the December 2020 futures contract rose $4 to $61 per barrel. The increase in
oil prices, especially in the near term, is primarily attributable to heightened
geopolitical risk following recent events in Syria as well as increased tensions
between Saudi Arabia and Iran. Informed by both the futures market and our
forecast of an appreciating dollar, our forecast for the price of imported oil has
been revised up $7 in the near term to $65 per barrel; thereafter, we expect oil
prices to decline about $12 over the remainder of the forecast period, reaching
$53 per barrel by the end of 2020, only $2 higher than in our March Tealbook
forecast.

•

Metals prices have moved up since the March Tealbook. The largest
increases were seen for aluminum, with prices up 21 percent since our March
projection, largely in response to U.S. sanctions on Russia that targeted one of
the world’s largest aluminum producers.

THE OUTLOOK FOR REAL GDP AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY
We estimate that real GDP increased at an annual rate of 1¾ percent in the first
quarter after rising 3 percent in the fourth quarter; this deceleration is more than

Page 7 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Federal Reserve System Nowcasts of 2018:Q1 Real GDP Growth
(Percent change at annual rate from previous quarter)

Federal Reserve Entity

Type of model

Nowcast
as of
April 18,
2018

Federal Reserve Bank
Boston



Mixed-frequency BVAR

2.8

New York



Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination
Factor-augmented autoregressive model combination,
financial factors only
Dynamic factor model

2.3
2.5

Bayesian regressions with stochastic volatility
Tracking model

3.3
0.5



Tracking model combined with Bayesian vector
autoregressions (VARs), dynamic factor models, and
factor-augmented autoregressions (known as
GDPNow)

2.0



Dynamic factor models
Bayesian VARs

2.0
2.0



Dynamic factor models
News index model
Let-the-data-decide regressions

2.8
3.4
2.7



Accounting-based tracking estimate

1.4

Board staff’s forecast (judgmental tracking model)
Monthly dynamic factor models (DFM-45)
Mixed-frequency dynamic factor model (DFM-BM)

1.7
3.2
2.7




Cleveland




Atlanta

Chicago



St. Louis




Kansas City
Board of Governors






Memo: Median of
Federal Reserve
System nowcasts

2.9

2.6

Page 8 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

accounted for by a marked slowdown in real PCE growth. 2 We see the soft PCE reading
in the first quarter as mostly temporary and project real GDP growth to move back up to
a 3 percent pace this quarter. GDP growth over the first half of the year is about
¼ percentage point less than in the March Tealbook but still faster than its trend pace.
Similarly, the recent labor market data, on balance, suggest that resource utilization has
continued to tighten, though by a little less than we had anticipated at the time of the
March Tealbook. All told, we project that output will be 1¾ percent above its potential
level in the current quarter—about ¼ percentage point lower than we had previously
forecast. For the second half of the year, real GDP is projected to rise at an annual rate of
about 3 percent; this rate is also a little lower than in the March Tealbook, largely
reflecting a somewhat slower pace of PCE growth due to weaker incoming indicators of
disposable income. 3
•

After increasing at a 4 percent annual rate in the fourth quarter, real PCE
appears to have risen only 1¼ percent in the first quarter—about ¼ percentage
point less than we had anticipated in the March Tealbook. 4 We continue to
believe that most of the weakness in first-quarter consumption growth reflects
payback for the exceptionally strong fourth-quarter growth and, therefore, see
the slowdown last quarter as mostly transitory. Correspondingly, we
anticipate that PCE growth will step up to a 2¼ percent pace in the current
quarter and then to 2½ percent in the second half, supported by continued job
gains and the boost to disposable income from the recently implemented
personal income tax cuts and consistent with positive readings on consumer
sentiment.

The BEA’s first estimate of GDP growth for 2018:Q1 will be released on Friday, April 27,
before the FOMC meeting.
3
Incoming data on tax collections and transfer payments point to lower disposable income than
we had previously expected, which restrains projected PCE growth throughout the year. (The tax receipts
in the incoming data were stronger than anticipated, which could instead be interpreted as a signal of
stronger income; however, those receipts often fail to track measured income closely at monthly or
quarterly frequencies.) These incoming receipts data are unrelated to the effect of the recently enacted
tax cuts.
4
March retail sales came in weaker than we anticipated. We were expecting a strong rebound in
March because we judged that February retail sales had been held down by a timing shift of income tax
refunds to EITC claimants in that month. We have interpreted some of the March miss as indicating a
smaller and more delayed effect on spending from the timing shift of tax refunds than we had originally
assumed. Accordingly, we took a little bit of signal from the negative surprise for the pace of consumer
spending and nudged down projected PCE growth in the second quarter.
2

Page 9 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Summary of the Near-Term Outlook
(Percent change at annual rate except as noted)
2018:Q1

2018:Q2

2018:H2

Measure

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Current
Tealbook

Real GDP
Private domestic final purchases
Personal consumption expenditures
Residential investment
Nonres. private fixed investment
Government purchases
Contributions to change in real GDP
Inventory investment1
Net exports1
Unemployment rate2
PCE chain price index
Ex. food and energy

2.1
1.6
1.5
-4.4
4.2
-.3

1.7
1.6
1.2
-4.1
5.7
-1.2

3.1
3.4
2.6
2.7
8.2
.8

2.9
2.8
2.2
-2.1
8.0
1.2

3.3
3.4
2.9
4.1
5.9
2.2

2.9
3.1
2.5
5.0
5.6
2.4

.8
.0
4.1
2.5
2.3

1.0
-.5
4.1
2.8
2.5

-.2
.2
3.9
1.5
2.0

.1
.1
4.0
2.2
2.2

-.1
.1
3.5
1.6
1.8

-.4
.2
3.6
1.7
1.7

1. Percentage points.
2. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.
Recent Nonfinancial Developments (1)
Manufacturing IP ex. Motor Vehicles
and Parts

Real GDP and GDI
4-quarter percent change
Gross domestic product
Gross domestic income

3-month percent change, annual rate

8

15

6

Mar.

4
Q4

20

10
5
0

2

-5
0

-10

-2

-15
-20

-4
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

-6

-25
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

Sales and Production of Light Motor
Vehicles
Millions of units, annual rate

Real PCE Growth
6-month percent change, annual rate

22

Feb.

18
Sales

-30

6
4
2

Mar.

14
0
10
-2

Production
6

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Ward’s Communications; Chrysler; General Motors;
FRB seasonal adjustments.

2

-4

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Page 10 of 126

-6

April 20, 2018

Recent Nonfinancial Developments (2)
Single-Family Housing Starts and Permits
Millions of units
(annual rate)
Adjusted permits
Starts

Home Sales
7.5

2.1

Millions of units
(annual rate)

1.8
1.5

1.2

5.5

Mar.

5.0
0.9

4.5

0.6

4.0

0.9
Feb.
0.6

3.5
0.3
2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0.0

0.3

New single-family
homes (right scale)

3.0
2.5

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0.0

Source: For existing, National Association of Realtors;
for new, U.S. Census Bureau.

Note: Adjusted permits equal permit issuance plus starts
outside of permit-issuing areas.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Nondefense Capital Goods ex. Aircraft

Nonresidential Construction Put in Place

Ratio scale, billions of dollars

Orders

1.5

Existing homes
(left scale)

6.0

1.2

2008

1.8

7.0
6.5

2006

Millions of units
(annual rate)

Feb.

Billions of chained (2009) dollars

75
75
70
69

Feb.

450

400

65
65

Shipments

61
60

350

57
55
53

300

50
49

250

45
45
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
Note: Data are 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2018

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Nominal CPIP deflated by BEA prices through
2017:Q4 and by the staff’s estimated deflator thereafter.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

Inventory Ratios

Exports and Non-oil Imports
Months

Billions of dollars

1.9

Feb.

1.7

Feb.
Census book-value data

220
200

1.6
Mar.

260
240

1.8

Staff flow-of-goods system

200

Non-oil imports

180

1.5

160

1.4

140
120

1.3

100
1.2
1.1

2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Flow-of-goods system inventories include manufacturing
and mining industries and are relative to consumption. Census
data cover manufacturing and trade, and inventories are relative
to sales.
Source: U.S. Census Bureau; staff calculations.

Exports
2006
2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Forecasts are linear interpolations of quarterly values.
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; U.S. Census Bureau.

Page 11 of 126

80
60

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Business fixed investment appears on track to rise at a solid annual rate of
about 6 percent in the first quarter, close to last year’s pace. We expect
continued robust growth in coming quarters, consistent with rising business
output, supportive financial conditions, elevated business sentiment and profit
expectations, increases in drilling rigs in operation, and a modest boost from
tax legislation.

•

Residential investment is projected to edge lower, on net, over the first half of
the year. Smoothing through the considerable volatility in these expenditures,
we anticipate that housing investment will increase a modest 1 percent this
year, held back by rising mortgage rates and a constrained supply of
construction workers and developable lots.

•

We expect real government purchases to be flat, on net, over the first half of
this year and then to rise at a 2½ percent pace over the second half of the year.
The acceleration in these purchases largely reflects the recent federal budget
legislation.

•

After being surprisingly weak for much of last year, imports jumped in the
fourth quarter and are estimated to have increased at an annual rate of
5¼ percent in the first quarter. Recent import growth has been broad based,
leading us to expect the level of imports to remain elevated. Net exports are
now anticipated to subtract 0.2 percentage point from real GDP growth in the
first half of the year, compared with a small positive contribution projected in
the March Tealbook.

•

Manufacturing production increased at a solid annual rate of about 3 percent
in the first quarter. Although the national and regional new orders indexes
have moved down a bit in recent months, they remain consistent with
continued expansion in this sector. Accordingly, we expect that
manufacturing output will expand at a moderate pace of about 2½ percent in
the current quarter.

Over the medium term, we project that real GDP growth will slow from about
2½ percent this year and next to 2 percent in 2020, as monetary policy continues to
tighten. GDP growth over the next few years is supported by expansionary fiscal policy
and solid foreign growth.

Page 12 of 126

•

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Compared with the March Tealbook, our forecast for real GDP growth beyond
2018 is unchanged, as revisions to conditioning assumptions have been
offsetting. In particular, the negative effects of the lower trajectory of equity
prices and higher oil prices are offset by the positive effects of the lower
projected paths for interest rates and the dollar.

•

Real GDP growth is projected to outpace potential growth throughout the
medium term, resulting in a further tightening of resource utilization. At the
end of 2020, real GDP exceeds its potential level by 3¼ percent—nearly
½ percentage point less than in the March Tealbook but still indicative of a
very tight economy.

•

Given the high degree of resource utilization in this projection, we continue to
assume that supply constraints will begin to attenuate the transmission of
increased aggregate demand into increased output and will contribute to
slightly higher consumer price inflation and wage growth over the medium
term. With the small downward revision to aggregate demand in this forecast,
we now project these supply constraints to be a little less binding than in the
March Tealbook.

•

With the federal government expected to run historically large and rising
deficits over the medium term, national saving is projected to trend downward
as a share of GDP. Nevertheless, private investment trends upward as a share
of the economy, with the gap between domestic investment and national
saving financed by inflows of foreign capital.

•

The box “Tealbook Forecast Errors: An Update through 2017” reviews recent
errors in the staff’s forecast for GDP, unemployment, and inflation. (In the
Risks and Uncertainty section, we include a related box reviewing the recent
performance of the FRB/US and EDO models.)

THE OUTLOOK FOR THE LABOR MARKET
Although the March employment report was not as strong as we had expected, our
broad assessment is that the labor market continued to tighten in the first quarter.
•

Total nonfarm payrolls rose 103,000 in March after jumping 326,000 in
February. For the first quarter as a whole, payrolls increased at an average
Page 13 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Tealbook Forecast Errors: An Update through 2017
Real activity in 2017 was somewhat stronger than anticipated by Tealbook
forecasts, although the staff’s forecast errors were generally small by historical
standards. Real GDP grew at a slightly faster pace than the staff forecast one and
two years ago, and the unemployment rate was lower at the end of 2017 than
expected. Despite the unexpected strength of real activity, core PCE price
inflation last year was a bit lower than anticipated.
The figure on the next page shows data and Tealbook forecasts for four economic
variables: real GDP growth, the unemployment rate, and total and core PCE price
inflation. For example, the gray bars in the upper-left panel show the currently
published Q4/Q4 percent changes in real GDP from 2014 to 2017. The blue squares
show Tealbook forecasts for GDP growth made in the April Tealbook one year
earlier; green triangles show the forecast from the April Tealbook of the
contemporaneous year. The whisker bands demarcate 70 percent forecast error
bands, and the top edge of a gray bar falling outside of the whisker band
represents an unusually large forecast error. 1 The red dots are BEA estimates of
real GDP growth from mid-April of the subsequent year, and the red 70 percent
bands show the magnitude of revisions to that estimate relative to the BEA’s
current estimate.
Real GDP growth in 2017 is currently estimated to be 2.6 percent, higher than
Tealbook forecasts from April 2016 and April 2017 (2.4 percent and 2.0 percent,
respectively). These forecast errors, however, are historically small, with real GDP
well within the 70 percent whisker bands. A possible explanation for faster-thanexpected real GDP growth last year is that financial conditions were more
supportive of economic growth. For example, the April 2017 Tealbook projected
the 10-year Treasury yield to be 2.9 percent in the fourth quarter of that year,
whereas the 10-year yield averaged only 2.4 percent in 2017:Q4. Likewise, equity
prices ended 2017 roughly 10 percent higher, and investment-grade corporate
bond spreads were narrower, than projected by the staff that April.
Consistent with faster-than-expected real GDP growth last year, labor market
conditions improved more than anticipated. As seen in the top-right panel, the
unemployment rate ended the year at a lower level than the staff had forecast.
Because the April 2017 Tealbook forecast of the labor force participation rate was
on the mark, the greater-than-expected improvement in the labor market is also
reflected in the employment-to-population ratio and private-sector job gains, both
of which were higher in 2017 than was forecast in April (not shown).
The bottom row of the figure shows staff forecasts for total and core PCE price
inflation and their confidence intervals, alongside the latest estimates. Even
1 The whisker bands for real activity variables are calculated using Tealbook forecast errors

since 1980; whisker bands around the inflation projections use forecast errors since 1998.

Page 14 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

though the forecast errors for real GDP growth and the unemployment rate
suggest that the economy tightened more than the staff expected last year, staff
forecasts of the Q4/Q4 percent change in core PCE prices in 2017 were a little too
high, as shown in the bottom-right panel. The error in forecasting core PCE price
inflation is entirely explained by lower-than-expected core goods prices, which fell
notably again last year despite a pickup in core goods import price inflation.2 In
contrast, the staff’s projection of total PCE price inflation in 2017 was accurate, as
higher-than-expected PCE energy prices in the last few months of the year offset
lower-than-expected food and core goods prices.
Finally, the faster-than-expected fall in the unemployment rate occurred at the
same time that core PCE price inflation was lower than the staff could explain. In
response, the staff edged down its estimate of the natural rate of unemployment
last year, 0.2 percentage point cumulatively.

2 The April 2017 Tealbook projection had already incorporated the large downward surprise

to wireless telephone services prices seen in the March 2017 CPI release.

Page 15 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

monthly pace of about 200,000—somewhat faster than last year’s pace and
well above the range of 85,000 to 115,000 that we judge to be consistent with
no change in resource utilization.5 For the current quarter, we now project
that total payroll employment gains will average 195,000 per month—down a
bit from our previous projection.
•

The unemployment rate was 4.1 percent for a sixth consecutive month in
March. In recent months, the unemployment rate has surprised us a little to
the upside. In response, we have raised our near-term projection of the jobless
rate a bit and now expect the unemployment rate to be 4.0 percent in the
current quarter and 3.8 percent next quarter; both rates are 0.1 percentage
point higher than in our previous forecast.

•

The LFPR ticked down in March but has generally surprised us to the upside
in recent months. For the past few years, the participation rate has moved
essentially sideways, on net, indicating some tightening along this margin
relative to its declining trend.

We continue to expect the labor market to tighten further over the medium term in
line with above-trend GDP growth.
•

Total payroll gains are projected to slow gradually from an average monthly
pace of about 195,000 this year to 160,000 in 2020, as GDP decelerates; this
trajectory is a touch lower than in our previous forecast.

•

We project the unemployment rate to decline ½ percentage point this year—
similar to its decline in 2017—and to reach 3.6 percent in the fourth quarter,
0.1 percentage point above our previous projection. The jobless rate moves
down further in 2019, ending the year at 3.3 percent, and then moves sideways
in 2020. The projected unemployment rate at the end of 2020 is
0.2 percentage point higher than in our March Tealbook projection, consistent
with the somewhat narrower output gap at the end of the medium term.

This range assumes that the LFPR declines in line with the staff’s estimate of its trend. With an
unchanged participation rate, the pace of monthly job gains required to keep the unemployment rate
constant ranges from 130,000 to 160,000.
5

Page 16 of 126

•

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

The LFPR is projected to end this year at 62.7 percent and then move
sideways through 2020, as sustained job gains and rising real wages continue
to draw individuals into the labor force while also slowing outflows. At the
end of 2020, the LFPR is 0.6 percentage point above our estimate of its trend
and unchanged from the March Tealbook.

•

We have continued to assume that, in an extremely tight labor market, a
larger-than-usual amount of the tightening in resource utilization over the
medium term will manifest in a higher LFPR and workweek rather than in a
lower unemployment rate. 6

•

We project that labor productivity in the business sector will increase an
average of about 1 percent per year over the forecast period—a touch faster
than its average pace over the past five years, though somewhat less than our
estimate of its structural pace. 7

THE OUTLOOK FOR INFLATION
The incoming information on prices has been consistent with our view that
transitory factors held down inflation last year and that inflation is moving up this year.
On balance, the latest news on prices has been a touch higher than we anticipated.
•

With the March CPI and PPI now in hand and with the low March 2017
reading dropping out of the calculation, we estimate that the 12-month change
in core PCE prices stepped up to 1.9 percent last month, 0.1 percentage point
higher than we had projected in the March Tealbook. We expect the
12-month change to edge up to 2.1 percent by June, also a little higher than in
the March Tealbook.

•

We now estimate that total PCE prices rose 2.1 percent over the 12 months
ending in March, and we expect the 12-month change to move up to
2.5 percent by June. Total PCE price inflation is higher than core inflation,

Were we to maintain our usual Okun’s law relationship, the unemployment rate at the end of the
projection would be ¼ percentage point lower.
7
Productivity tends to grow more slowly than its structural pace when the labor market becomes
tight, possibly because workers hired in a tight labor market have lower productivity, on average, relative to
workers hired during a slack labor market.
6

Page 17 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Survey Measures of Longer-Term Inflation Expectations

CPI Next 10 Years

CPI Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

2.5

Apr.Q1
Mar.

2.0

Q1

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Blue Chip mean, 7 to 11 years ahead
Primary dealers median, 5 to 10 years ahead
Consensus Economics mean, 6 to 10 years ahead

1.5

SPF median
Livingston Survey median
1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: SPF is Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

PCE Next 10 Years

2.5

Mar.

Dec.

3.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Blue Chip
Economic Indicators; Federal Reserve Bank of New York;
Consensus Economics.

2.0

1.5

1.0

PCE Forward Expectations
Percent

Percent

3.0

3.0

SPF median, 6 to 10 years ahead
Primary dealers median, longer run
2.5

2.5

SPF median
Q1

Q1
2.0

2.0

Mar.

1.5

1.0

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.

Surveys of Consumers

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Primary dealers data begin in August 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; Federal
Reserve Bank of New York.

1.0

Survey of Business Inflation Expectations
Percent

Percent

4.0

3.5

4.0

3.5

Mean increase in unit costs, next 5 to 10 years
Q2

3.0

3.0

Mar.
2.5

2.5

2.0

2.0

Apr. (p)
FRBNY median increase in prices, 3 years ahead
Michigan median increase in prices, next 5 to 10 years

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Federal Reserve Bank of New York (FRBNY) Survey
of Consumer Expectations reports expected 12-month inflation
rate 3 years from the current survey date. FRBNY data begin
in June 2013.
(p) Preliminary.
Source: University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers;
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Survey of Consumer
Expectations.

1.5

2008
2010
2012
2014
2016
2018
Note: Survey of businesses in the Sixth Federal Reserve
District. Data begin in February 2012.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta.

Page 18 of 126

1.5

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

reflecting previous large increases in consumer energy prices and our
expectation for further increases over the next few months.
•

We expect core import prices to increase at a 3¼ percent pace in the first half
of 2018—up from 1¼ percent in the second half of 2017—supported by
recent declines in the dollar and consistent with the incoming trade price data.
We project core import price inflation to slow to a 1¼ percent pace in the
second half and to about ½ percent in 2019 and 2020, in line with moderate
foreign inflation, a gradually appreciating dollar, and slowly declining
commodity prices.

•

Incoming data on longer-term inflation expectations have moved little, on
balance, since the March Tealbook. Median expectations over the next 5 to
10 years from the University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers were
unchanged at 2.5 percent in March and edged down to 2.4 percent in the
preliminary April reading, close to where they have been over the past couple
of years. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Survey of Consumer
Expectations reported that the median inflation expectation 3 years ahead was
unchanged in March at 2.9 percent. Finally, the TIPS-based measure of 5-to10-year-forward inflation compensation edged up since the March meeting
and stands at 2.2 percent.

Core PCE price inflation is on track to rise to 2.0 percent in 2018, as the transitory
factors that had been suppressing inflation last year abate and resource utilization
continues to tighten. Core inflation then edges up to 2.1 percent in 2019 and 2020, as the
further tightening of the economy and a gradual increase in our judgmental underlying
inflation trend more than offset restraint from the projected deceleration in core import
prices.
•

With oil prices expected to edge lower over the medium term, we project total
PCE price inflation to run a bit below core inflation after this year and to be
2.0 percent in 2020.

•

Relative to the March Tealbook, the medium-term forecasts for both core and
total PCE price inflation have revised down a touch, reflecting the slightly
lower degree of resource utilization in this projection. Nonetheless, we
continue to assume that the supply constraints that attenuate the transmission

Page 19 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

of aggregate demand into output in an extremely tight economy will also
result in slightly higher inflation than would otherwise be the case.
We received little data on wages since the March Tealbook. 8 Overall, we
continue to view the information on labor compensation as consistent with a gradual
acceleration over the past few years.
•

Average hourly earnings rose 2.7 percent over the year ending in March, close
to our estimate in the March Tealbook. We expect the 12-month change in
average hourly earnings to remain close to this pace through the summer.

•

The Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta’s Wage Growth Tracker ticked up to
3.3 percent in March, near the middle of its range over the past couple of
years but up from before then.

•

Over the medium term, growth in compensation per hour (CPH) is projected
to step up from a pace of 3½ percent this year to around 4 percent in each of
the next two years, as resource utilization tightens further. Meanwhile, the
ECI, which is notably less cyclical than the CPH measure, steps up from a
2½ percent pace this year to 2¾ percent in 2019 and 2020. Compared with
the March Tealbook, these projections are revised down a little, reflecting the
slightly lower level of resource utilization in this forecast.

THE LONG-TERM OUTLOOK
•

We continue to assume that the natural rate of unemployment will be
4.7 percent, and that potential output growth will be 1.7 percent per year in the
longer run.

•

We have maintained our assumption that the real equilibrium federal funds
rate that will prevail in the longer run will be ½ percent. Yields on 10-year
Treasury securities in the longer run are assumed to stand at 3.4 percent.

•

We expect that the Federal Reserve’s holdings of securities will continue to
put downward pressure on longer-term interest rates, though to a diminishing

The ECI for March will be released on April 27. The GDP release on the same day will also
contain information on labor compensation in the first quarter.
8

Page 20 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

extent over time. The SOMA portfolio is projected to have returned to a
normal size by mid-2021.
•

With these assumptions, real GDP growth slows further to 1½ percent in 2021
and 1 percent in 2022 and 2023, as the federal funds rate is above its neutral
level and the support from fiscal policy starts to wane. The unemployment
rate moves up gradually from 3¼ percent in 2020 toward its assumed natural
rate in subsequent years.

•

PCE price inflation hovers around 2.1 percent in 2022 and 2023 before edging
back down to the Committee’s long-run objective in later years.

•

With output materially above its potential level and inflation slightly above
the Committee’s 2 percent objective, the nominal federal funds rate rises to
about 5 percent at the end of 2021—2½ percentage points higher than its
assumed long-run value. Thereafter, the federal funds rate moves gradually
back toward its long-run value.

Page 21 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 22 of 126

April 20, 2018

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Projections of Real GDP and Related Components
(Percent change at annual rate from final quarter
of preceding period except as noted)
2018
Measure

2017
H1

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

2018

2019

2020

H2

2.6
2.6

2.3
2.6

2.9
3.3

2.6
2.9

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1

2.9
2.9

1.7
2.3

3.3
3.4

2.5
2.8

2.7
2.7

2.1
2.1

Personal consumption expenditures
Previous Tealbook

2.8
2.9

1.7
2.0

2.5
2.9

2.1
2.4

2.7
2.8

2.5
2.5

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.5

-3.1
-.9

5.0
4.1

.9
1.6

1.7
.5

3.3
4.2

Nonresidential structures
Previous Tealbook

5.0
4.9

9.5
7.4

5.9
3.4

7.7
5.4

2.0
2.8

.5
.9

Equipment and intangibles
Previous Tealbook

6.7
6.8

6.1
5.9

5.5
6.6

5.8
6.2

4.2
4.1

2.0
2.1

Federal purchases
Previous Tealbook

1.0
1.0

-1.2
-.8

4.8
4.4

1.8
1.8

4.1
4.1

3.3
3.2

.5
.5

.7
.9

1.0
1.0

.9
.9

1.0
1.0

1.0
1.0

Exports
Previous Tealbook

5.0
4.9

4.2
4.1

6.3
6.2

5.2
5.2

5.2
5.0

3.6
3.4

Imports
Previous Tealbook

4.7
4.6

4.4
2.7

3.5
4.1

3.9
3.4

4.4
4.7

4.8
4.9

Final sales
Previous Tealbook

State and local purchases
Previous Tealbook

Contributions to change in real GDP
(percentage points)
Inventory change
Previous Tealbook

-.3
-.3

.6
.3

-.4
-.1

.1
.1

-.1
-.1

.0
-.1

Net exports
Previous Tealbook

-.1
-.1

-.2
.1

.2
.1

.0
.1

.0
-.1

-.3
-.3

Real GDP
4-quarter percent change
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

10
8
6
4
2
0
-2
-4

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 23 of 126

2020

-6

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Components of Final Demand

Personal Consumption Expenditures
4-quarter percent change

Residential Investment
4-quarter percent change

5

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

20
15

4

10
3
5
2
0
1

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

0

2013

Equipment and Intangibles

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-10

Nonresidential Structures

4-quarter percent change

4-quarter percent change

12

25
20

10

15

8

10
6
5
4
0
2

-5

0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-10

-2

2013

Government Consumption and Investment
4-quarter percent change

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-15

Exports and Imports
4-quarter percent change

3

10

2
Exports

1

5

0
-1
-2

0

-3

Imports

-4
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

2013

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Page 24 of 126

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-5

April 20, 2018

Aspects of the Medium-Term Projection
Personal Saving Rate

Wealth-to-Income Ratio
Percent

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Ratio

10
9

7.2
6.8

8
6.4

7
6

6.0

5

5.6

4

5.2

3
4.8

2
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

1

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: Ratio of household net worth to disposable personal
income.
Source: For net worth, Federal Reserve Board, Financial
Accounts of the United States; for income, U.S. Dept. of
Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Single-Family Housing Starts

4.4

Equipment and Intangibles Spending
Millions of units

Share of nominal GDP

2.00

12

1.75
11

1.50
1.25

10

1.00
9

0.75
0.50

8

0.25
2000
2005
2010
Source: U.S. Census Bureau.

2015

2020

0.00

Federal Surplus/Deficit
4-quarter moving average

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

7

Current Account Surplus/Deficit
Share of nominal GDP

Current
Previous Tealbook

Share of nominal GDP

6

1

4

0

2

-1

0

-2

-2
-3
-4
-4

-6

-5

-8

-6

-10
2000
2005
2010
Source: Monthly Treasury Statement.

2015

2020

-12

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 25 of 126

-7

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Decomposition of Potential GDP
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)
Measure
Potential real GDP
Previous Tealbook
Selected contributions1
Structural labor productivity2
Previous Tealbook
Capital deepening
Multifactor productivity
Structural hours
Previous Tealbook
Labor force participation
Previous Tealbook
Memo:
Output gap3
Previous Tealbook

1974-95

19962000

3.1
3.1

3.4
3.4

2.6
2.6

1.6
1.6

1.6
1.6
.6
.7
1.6
1.6
.4
.4

2.9
2.9
1.5
1.0
1.2
1.2
-.1
-.1

2.8
2.8
1.0
1.5
.8
.8
-.2
-.2

-1.9
-1.9

2.4
2.4

.8
.8

2001-07 2008-10 2011-15

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

1.2
1.2

1.4
1.4

1.5
1.5

1.7
1.6

1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9

1.4
1.4
.3
.9
.0
.0
-.5
-.5

.8
.8
.5
.1
.6
.6
-.6
-.6

.8
.8
.5
.1
.8
.8
-.3
-.3

1.0
1.0
.5
.3
.2
.2
-.3
-.3

1.1
1.1
.5
.4
.7
.7
-.3
-.3

1.2
1.2
.6
.5
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

1.3
1.3
.5
.6
.6
.6
-.2
-.2

-4.2
-4.2

-.1
-.1

.3
.3

1.4
1.4

2.4
2.7

3.1
3.5

3.2
3.6

Note: For multiyear periods, the percent change is the annual average from Q4 of the year preceding the first year shown to Q4 of the last year shown.
1. Percentage points.
2. Total business sector.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential GDP in the final quarter of the period indicated. A negative number indicates that the economy
is operating below potential.

Unemployment Rate

Output Gap
Percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Percent

8
Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural rate of unemployment*
Previous Tealbook

6
4
2

14
12
10
8

0
-2

6

-4
4

-6
-8
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Note: The output gap is the percent difference between actual
and potential GDP; a negative number indicates that the
economy is operating below potential.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic
Analysis; staff assumptions.

(Business sector)

90

Chained (2009) dollars per hour

Actual
Structural

85
Average rate from
1972 to 2017

2

Structural and Actual Labor Productivity

Manufacturing Capacity Utilization Rate
Percent

2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
staff assumptions. *Staff estimate including the effect of EEB.

66
64
62
60

80

58
75

56
54

70

52
50

65

48
2000
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: Federal Reserve Board, G.17 Statistical Release,
"Industrial Production and Capacity Utilization."

60

46
2005
2010
2015
2020
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics;
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis;
staff assumptions.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 26 of 126

April 20, 2018

The Outlook for the Labor Market
2018
Measure

2017
H1

Output per hour, business1
Previous Tealbook

2018

2019

2020

H2

.9
.9

.7
.5

1.6
1.9

1.2
1.2

.9
.9

.9
.9

183
183

199
232

191
196

195
214

181
186

160
165

180
180

197
224

180
185

188
205

170
175

150
155

Labor force participation rate3
Previous Tealbook

62.7
62.7

62.8
62.8

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

62.7
62.7

Civilian unemployment rate3
Previous Tealbook

4.1
4.1

4.0
3.9

3.6
3.5

3.6
3.5

3.3
3.1

3.3
3.1

Nonfarm payroll employment2
Previous Tealbook
Private employment2
Previous Tealbook

1. Percent change from final quarter of preceding period at annual rate.
2. Thousands, average monthly changes.
3. Percent, average for the final quarter in the period.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Inflation Projections
2018
Measure

2017

2018

2019

2020

1.7
1.6

2.1
1.8

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

.9
1.4

2.1
2.2

1.5
1.8

2.3
2.4

2.3
2.4

7.6
7.6

7.6
.8

-.4
-1.6

3.5
-.4

-1.9
-.7

-1.1
-.1

Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

1.5
1.5

2.4
2.1

1.7
1.8

2.0
1.9

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.2

Prices of core goods imports1
Previous Tealbook

1.3
1.3

3.2
3.1

1.3
1.1

2.3
2.1

.6
.7

.6
.6

Mar.
20182

Apr.
20182

May
20182

June
20182

July
20182

Aug.
20182

2.1
2.0

2.1
1.9

2.4
2.1

2.5
2.2

2.5

2.4

1.9
1.8

1.9
1.8

2.0
1.9

2.1
1.9

2.1

2.1

H1

H2

1.7
1.7

2.5
2.0

Food and beverages
Previous Tealbook

.7
.7

Energy
Previous Tealbook

Percent change at annual rate from
final quarter of preceding period
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook

12-month percent change
PCE chain-weighted price index
Previous Tealbook
Excluding food and energy
Previous Tealbook

1. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.
2. Staff forecast.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.
Page 27 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (1)

Measures of Labor Underutilization
Percent

Percent
13

U-5*
Unemployment rate
Part time for
economic
reasons**

Unemployment rate
Previous Tealbook
Natural unemployment rate with EEB adjustment
Previous Tealbook

12
11
10
9
8

5
4

4
3
2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

9

6

5

2004

10

7

6

2

11

8

7
Mar.

12

3
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

2

* U-5 measures total unemployed persons plus all marginally attached to the labor force, as a percent of the labor force plus persons marginally
attached to the labor force.
** Percent of Current Population Survey employment.
EEB Extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Level of Payroll Employment*
130

Millions

Millions

Millions
150
Mar.

Total (right axis)
Private (left axis)
125

145

120

140

115

135

Total
Previous Tealbook

155
153
151
149
147
145
143
141

110

130

105

125

139
137

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

135

* 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Change in Payroll Employment*
Thousands

Thousands

400

Mar.

Total
Previous Tealbook

200
0

Total
Private
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

350
300
250

-200

200

-400

150

-600

100

-800

50

-1000

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 28 of 126

2019

2020

0

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Labor Market Developments and Outlook (2)
Labor Force Participation Rate*
Percent
Labor force participation rate
Previous Tealbook
Estimated trend**

Percent

67.5

Labor force participation rate
Previous Tealbook
Estimated trend**

67.0
66.5

64.5
64.0

66.0
63.5

65.5
65.0

63.0

64.5
64.0
Mar.

62.5

63.5
63.0

62.0

62.5
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

62.0

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

61.5

* Published data adjusted by staff to account for changes in population weights.
** Includes staff estimate of the effect of extended and emergency unemployment benefits.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; staff assumptions.

Initial Unemployment Insurance Claims*
Thousands

Hires, Quits, and Job Openings
700
650
600

Percent
Hires*
Openings**
Quits*

550

400
Apr. 14

3.5
3.0

350

2.5

300

2.0
1.5

200
150

4.5

Feb.

250

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* 4-week moving average.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Employment and
Training Administration.

5.0

4.0

500
450

5.5

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
* Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment, 3-month
moving average.
** Percent of private nonfarm payroll employment plus
unfilled jobs, 3-month moving average.
Source: Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey.

1.0

Labor Force Participation Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group, 25 to 54 years old

Unemployment Rate by
Racial/Ethnic Group
Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

20

16

Percent
Asian
Black
Hispanic
White

86
84
82

12
80
8

4

Mar.

78
76

Mar.
2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

0

Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Page 29 of 126

74
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: These categories are not mutually exclusive, as the
ethnicity Hispanic may include people of any race. The Current
Population Survey defines Hispanic ethnicity as those who report
their origin is Mexican, Puerto Rican, Cuban, Central American,
or South American (and some others). 3-month moving averages.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Current Population Survey.

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (1)
(Percent change from year-earlier period)

Headline Consumer Price Inflation
Percent
CPI
PCE

Percent

6
PCE - Current Tealbook
PCE - Previous Tealbook

5

5
4

4
Mar.

3

3
2

2
Mar. (e)

1
1

0
-1

0
-2
-3
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Note: PCE prices from January to March 2018 are staff estimates (e).
Source: For CPI, U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Measures of Underlying PCE Price Inflation
Percent
Trimmed mean PCE
Market-based PCE excluding food and energy
PCE excluding food and energy

Percent

4.0
Core PCE - Current Tealbook
Core PCE - Previous Tealbook

3.5

3.5
3.0

3.0

2.5

2.5

Mar. (e)

2.0
Feb.

2.0
1.5

1.5

1.0

1.0
Mar. (e)

0.5

0.5
0.0
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: Core PCE prices from January to March 2018 are staff estimates (e).
Source: For trimmed mean PCE, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas; otherwise, U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

0.0

Labor Cost Growth
Percent
Employment cost index
Average hourly earnings
Compensation per hour

Percent

7

Compensation per hour - Current Tealbook
Compensation per hour - Previous Tealbook

6
5

6
5
4

4
Mar.

3
3
2

Q4
Q4

2
1

1

0

0
-1
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020
Note: Compensation per hour is for the business sector. Average hourly earnings are for the private nonfarm sector. The employment cost
index is for the private sector.
Source: U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 30 of 126

-1

April 20, 2018

Inflation Developments and Outlook (2)
(Percent change from year-earlier period, except as noted)

Commodity and Oil Price Levels
Dollars per barrel
1967 = 100
220
Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
1680
168
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)
1420
142
1200
120
1000
100
800
80
2200

600
400

Apr. 19

1000

1967 = 100

Dollars per barrel

Brent crude oil history/futures (right axis)
CRB spot commodity price index (left axis)

900

140

800

120

700

100

60

600

80

40

500

60

400
200

160

Apr. 19

40

20
300
20
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
Note: Futures prices (dotted lines) are the latest observations on monthly futures contracts.
Source: For oil prices, U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Information Agency; for commodity prices, Commodity Research Bureau (CRB).

Energy and Import Price Inflation
18

Percent

Percent
PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)

15
12
9

Feb.

6
Mar.

3

60

10

50

8

40

6

30

4

20

2

10

0

0

0

-2

-3

-10

-4

-6

-20

-6

-9

-30

-12

-40

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

Percent

Percent
PCE energy prices (right axis)
Core import prices (left axis)
Feb.

Mar.

-8
-10
2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

30
25
20
15
10
5
0
-5
-10
-15
-20
-25
-30

Source: For core import prices, U.S. Dept. of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics; for PCE, U.S. Dept. of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Long-Term Inflation Expectations and Compensation
Percent
5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

4.0
3.5

Apr. (p)

Percent

4.5

3.0

5-to-10-year-ahead TIPS compensation
Michigan median next 5 to 10 years
SPF PCE median next 10 years

4.0
3.5

Apr. (p)

2.5
Q1
Mar.

2.0

4.5

3.0
2.5

Mar.
Q1

1.5

2.0
1.5

1.0
1.0
2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: Based on a comparison of an estimated TIPS (Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities) yield curve with an estimated nominal off-the-run
Treasury yield curve, with an adjustment for the indexation-lag effect.
(p) Preliminary.
SPF Survey of Professional Forecasters.
Source: For Michigan, University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers; for SPF, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia; for TIPS, Federal
Reserve Board staff calculations.
Note: The gray shaded bars indicate a period of business recession as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.

Page 31 of 126

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

The Long−Term Outlook

(Percent change, Q4 to Q4, except as noted)

Measure

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Longer run

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

2.6
2.9

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1

1.5
1.4

1.0
.9

1.0
.9

1.7
1.7

Civilian unemployment rate1
Previous Tealbook

3.6
3.5

3.3
3.1

3.3
3.1

3.5
3.3

3.8
3.6

4.1
4.0

4.7
4.7

PCE prices, total
Previous Tealbook

2.1
1.8

1.9
2.0

2.0
2.1

2.0
2.2

2.1
2.2

2.1
2.2

2.0
2.0

Core PCE prices
Previous Tealbook

2.0
1.9

2.1
2.1

2.1
2.2

2.1
2.2

2.2
2.2

2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0

Federal funds rate1
Previous Tealbook

2.59
2.66

3.82
4.01

4.66
4.96

4.97
5.35

4.85
5.22

4.48
4.79

2.50
2.50

10-year Treasury yield1
Previous Tealbook

3.6
3.8

4.2
4.3

4.4
4.5

4.3
4.4

4.1
4.2

3.9
4.0

3.4
3.4

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Real GDP

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
4

10
Unemployment rate

3

9

2
1
Potential GDP

0
−1

8

Natural rate
with EEB
adjustment

7
6

−2

5

−3

4

−4

Real GDP

−5
2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

3
2005

PCE Prices

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Interest Rates
4−quarter percent change

Percent
4

Total PCE prices

10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0

Triple−B corporate
3
10−year Treasury
2

PCE prices
excluding
food and
energy

1
0

Federal
funds rate

−1
2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

2005

2008

2011

2014

2017

2020

2023

Note: In each panel, shading represents the projection period, and dashed lines are the previous Tealbook.
Page 32 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Evolution of the Staff Forecast
Change in Real GDP
Percent, Q4/Q4
4

2016

3

2

2017

2018
2019

2020
1

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9

2014

2015

10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9

4/20 6/8

7/20

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

4/21 6/2

7/14

9/8

2017

10/2012/1 1/19 3/9

4/20

0

2018

Tealbook publication date

Unemployment Rate
Percent, fourth quarter
6.0
2016

5.5
5.0

2017

2018

4.5
2019

4.0
2020

3.5
3.0

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9

2014

2015

10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9

4/20 6/8

7/20

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

4/21 6/2

7/14

9/8

2017

10/2012/1 1/19 3/9

4/20

2.5

2018

Tealbook publication date

Change in PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy
Percent, Q4/Q4
2.5
2018

2017

2020

2019

2.0

1.5

2016

1.0

0.5

9/10 10/22 12/101/21 3/11 4/22 6/10 7/22 9/9

2014

2015

10/21 12/9 1/20 3/9

4/20 6/8

7/20

9/14 10/2612/7 1/19 3/3

2016

2017

Tealbook publication date

Page 33 of 126

4/21 6/2

7/14

9/8

10/2012/1 1/19 3/9

2018

4/20

0.0

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Domestic Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 34 of 126

April 20, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

International Economic Developments and Outlook
The foreign economies appear set for another year of strong growth in 2018, with
growth projected to be close to 3 percent, virtually unchanged from 2017. In the
advanced foreign economies (AFEs), we estimate that, after growing a rapid 2½ percent
last year, GDP rose at a still-solid annual rate of 2 percent in the first quarter, and we see
growth maintaining this pace for the remainder of the year. In the emerging market
quarter to almost 4 percent in the first quarter and should come in at nearly that pace in
the next few quarters. Beyond 2018, we see aggregate foreign growth edging down a
touch to settle at around its potential rate of 2¾ percent in 2020.
Our foreign outlook is little changed from the March Tealbook on balance.
Although economic indicators in the AFEs have come in a little weaker than expected,
we have seen positive surprises in some emerging Asian economies. So far this year we
have not seen the sequence of upward revisions to our outlook that occurred last year.
Nevertheless, we cannot exclude the possibility that foreign growth could again exceed
expectations, leading to a weakening of the dollar and a boost to the U.S. economy. We
explore such a development in the “Stronger Foreign Growth and Weaker Dollar”
alternative scenario in the Risks and Uncertainty section.
In the AFEs, rising retail energy prices helped boost headline inflation to an
annual rate of 2½ percent in the first quarter, ½ percentage point higher than projected in
March. AFE inflation in the current quarter has also been revised up to 2 percent on
account of higher oil prices. Core inflation has picked up in Canada over the past few
quarters but remains subdued in the euro area and Japan. With inflation pressures
remaining contained over the next few years, we continue to assume only a gradual
withdrawal of monetary policy stimulus in the AFEs. In particular, the European Central
Bank (ECB) is not expected to raise its policy rate until the second quarter of 2019.
Moreover, we do not see the ECB, the Bank of England (BOE), or the Bank of Japan
(BOJ) starting to reduce the size of their balance sheets any time soon.
In the EMEs, monetary policies are more diverse. Some Asian central banks,
after a period of very low policy rates, are now raising rates with a pickup in growth. In
contrast, some central banks in Latin America, such as Brazil’s, have been cutting their

Page 35 of 126

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

economies (EMEs), GDP growth looks to have picked up from 3.4 percent in the fourth

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

policy rates in response to weakness in their economies. The Bank of Mexico (BOM)
remains in a tightening cycle in response to significant overshooting of inflation relative
to target and is expected to lower its policy rate only next year.
Further monetary policy tightening by the Federal Reserve, as well as eventual
policy normalization by other major central banks, will lead to an increase in global
interest rates. In our baseline, we expect global financial markets to take this
normalization in stride, with sovereign, corporate, and household debtors able to adjust to
higher debt service needs. However, a more substantial policy tightening by the Federal
Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Reserve than in our baseline, perhaps prompted by a faster-than-expected rise in inflation,
could lead to turbulence in global financial markets and create problems for debtors,
especially EME corporates. The consequences of such an outcome are discussed in our
“Global Tightening Tantrum” alternative scenario in the Risks and Uncertainty section;
additionally, the EME corporate debt situation is analyzed in the box “How Risky Is
Corporate Debt in Emerging Market Economies?” Finally, we remain attuned to other
risks, including an eruption of trade wars or a sharp escalation of the geopolitical tensions
in the Middle East that have recently pushed up oil prices.

ADVANCED FOREIGN ECONOMIES


Euro area. Recent indicators, such as industrial production and exports through
February, suggest that real GDP growth stepped down from 2.7 percent in the fourth
quarter to about 2 percent in the first. However, with PMIs and confidence indicators
for March still at levels consistent with solid economic activity, we project GDP
growth to edge up to 2¼ percent in the current quarter. GDP growth should then
gradually slow to 1¾ percent in 2020, a bit above its potential rate. Compared with
the March Tealbook, this forecast is about ½ percentage point lower in the first
quarter of 2018 and little changed thereafter.
Headline inflation increased to 2.1 percent at an annual rate in the first quarter,
temporarily boosted by a surge in energy prices. Core inflation rose to 1.4 percent in
the first quarter from an unusually low print of 0.2 percent in the fourth. We expect
both headline and core inflation to decelerate somewhat and then edge up to
1¾ percent only by 2020, as resource slack gradually diminishes and wage growth
firms. Given this subdued inflation outlook, the ECB has continued to communicate
the need for ample monetary policy accommodation. Accordingly, we expect the

Page 36 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

ECB to continue its asset purchases until the end of 2018 and increase its policy rate
only in the second quarter of 2019 by 0.15 percentage point to negative 0.25 percent.


United Kingdom. U.K. indicators also suggest that GDP growth has slowed a bit, to
1¼ percent in the first quarter from 1.6 percent in the fourth. This estimate is
¼ percentage point lower than in the March Tealbook, on weaker-than-expected
construction and services indicators, partly reflecting adverse weather conditions.
Growth is expected to increase to about 1¾ percent in the current quarter, supported

As we expected, the European Union (EU) and British authorities agreed last month
on a 21-month transition period after the official U.K. withdrawal from the EU next
March. During this transition the United Kingdom will stay in the EU’s customs
union and single market but will be able to negotiate trade deals with other countries.
As Brexit uncertainty fades, supporting business confidence, and with the help of
accommodative monetary policy, economic activity should continue to expand at just
above its potential rate of 1½ percent throughout the forecast horizon. This
projection is a touch weaker than in the March Tealbook, mostly because of
appreciation of the pound.
Inflation in the first quarter declined to 2.5 percent from 3 percent in the fourth,
mainly because of waning effects of past currency depreciation. We continue to
expect that inflation will gradually fall to the BOE’s 2 percent target by the end of
2020. We anticipate that the BOE will gradually raise its policy rate from its current
level of 0.5 percent, reaching 1¾ percent by the end of 2020.


Canada. With the auto industry recovering from earlier strikes and maintenance
shutdowns, we estimate that GDP growth edged up to 2 percent in the first quarter.
Although this pace is somewhat below our March Tealbook forecast—partly owing to
disruptions in the oil industry—recent indicators, including the Labour Force Survey
and manufacturing PMI through March, point to continued solid momentum. We see
growth staying close to 2 percent through the forecast horizon.
Inflation increased to 3.6 percent in the first quarter, reflecting higher retail energy
prices and increasing resource utilization. We expect inflation to remain elevated at
2½ percent in the current quarter before slowing to 2 percent by next year. The Bank

Page 37 of 126

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

by a recent pickup in real wages.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

How Risky Is Corporate Debt in Emerging Market Economies?
Since 2007, nonfinancial corporate (NFC) debt in emerging markets (EMEs) has tripled in dollar
value, reaching $28 trillion in the third quarter of 2017. Although EME corporate debt as a share
of GDP has declined slightly since 2016, it remains elevated at around 110 percent of GDP (figure 1).
A large majority of the increase since 2007 is accounted for by China (the red line), where NFC
debt has risen to 170 percent of GDP. But NFC debt in the other EMEs has also risen notably (note
the different scale). The rapid increase in corporate debt has raised concerns about the risks this
debt might pose to EMEs and the global economy. In particular, rising global interest rates, in
part as advanced economies tighten monetary policy, could lead to higher EME debt‐servicing
burdens, weaker currencies, capital outflows, and lower earnings. Such developments could
weigh on EME corporates, especially those that are highly leveraged or have high levels of dollar‐
denominated debt, potentially triggering loan losses, bond defaults, and broader financial stress.
We evaluate the overall riskiness of EME corporate debt using the interest coverage ratio (ICR),
or the ratio of earnings to interest expense, which measures the capacity of firms to meet their
interest payments out of earnings. Firms that are more profitable, are less leveraged, or have
lower borrowing costs will have higher ICRs, indicating a greater capacity to service their debt.
An ICR of 2 or less is typically associated with an increased likelihood of distress.1 As shown in
figure 2, since 2008, the ICR for EME corporates has declined, on average, amid weaker earnings
and higher leverage. As a result, risky debt of EME corporates—measured as the debt of firms
with ICRs less than 2—has increased as a share of GDP, with most of that rise occurring in China
(figure 3). Over the past two years, the firming of global growth has improved earnings, lowering
the amount of risky debt and facilitating the orderly deleveraging process currently under way.

1 For example, just before the Asian financial crisis, firms in Korea, Thailand, and Indonesia had an average ICR
of 2; see Michael Pomerleano (1998) “Corporate Finance Lessons from the East Asian Crisis,” Viewpoint: Public
Policy for the Private Sector Note 155 (Washington: World Bank, October),
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/11531.

Page 38 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

How vulnerable are EME NFCs to an increase in borrowing costs, perhaps related to monetary
policy tightening in the advanced economies? To gauge these effects, we use firm‐level data and
stress each firm’s financials by increasing the average borrowing cost 1 percentage point (the
effects of which are shown by the solid red portion of the bars in figure 4).2 Except for China,
where debt at risk is estimated to rise 20 percentage points of GDP, this increase in borrowing
costs by itself would not be problematic. But higher global interest rates might be accompanied
by broader financial stress and slower EME growth, similar to what is presented in our “Global
Tightening Tantrum” alternative scenario in the Risks and Uncertainty section. To model these
effects, we consider two additional shocks: reducing earnings 20 percent (the effects are shown
by the red cross‐hatched portion of the bars) and imposing a 20 percent exchange rate
devaluation on the amount of debt that is denominated in foreign currency (the red hatched
portion of the bars). Taken together, the shocks double the share of overall EME risky debt in
GDP to around the level observed for the East Asian economies before the Asian financial crisis.
The increase mostly reflects China. But even outside of China, the shocks more than double the
amount of risky debt in many EMEs.
All told, a gradual normalization of monetary policy in the advanced economies, driven by faster
economic growth, is not likely to cause significant financing problems for EME corporates. But a
sharper rise in interest rates accompanied by broader financial stress could be quite severe for
EME corporates. Such problems could threaten financial stability if they spill over to banks and
create an adverse feedback loop that the authorities have trouble containing.

2 Although on the face of it this shock does not seem too large, it is applied to the average interest rate on

the entire existing debt, not just on new debt. Given that the average interest rate for EME firms is about
4¾ percent, a 1 percentage point rise increases the interest expense about one‐fifth.

Page 39 of 126

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Nevertheless, the share of risky debt in China remains above what was observed in the East Asian
economies before the Asian financial crisis. In other EMEs, debt at risk appears manageable at
less than 10 percent of GDP. However, the threshold at which debt at risk starts to be
problematic can differ across countries. For example, while a country may not have as much
vulnerability with respect to its corporate debt as, say, China, it may also have relatively less
resources to address problems that may arise.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

of Canada is expected to gradually raise its policy rate from 1.25 percent to 3 percent
by mid-2020.


Japan. Recent readings of industrial production and the manufacturing PMI point to
a step-down in Japanese GDP growth to 1¼ percent in the first quarter from
1.6 percent in the fourth. We see GDP growth edging down further to just below
1 percent, still slightly above its potential rate, by mid-2019 before temporarily
turning negative as a result of a long-planned consumption tax hike. Compared with
the March Tealbook, this projection is just a touch down in the first half of 2018 and

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

unchanged thereafter.
Inflation picked up further to 2.5 percent in the first quarter, as retail energy and food
prices rose rapidly. Still, with core inflation remaining quite subdued, we expect
overall inflation to fall back to ¾ percent over the remainder of the year. Excluding
the effects of the consumption tax hike on inflation in the fourth quarter of 2019,
inflation is expected to stabilize around 1 percent through 2020, well short of the
BOJ’s 2 percent target. We expect the BOJ to keep its deposit rate slightly negative
throughout the forecast period and to continue with asset purchases.

EMERGING MARKET ECONOMIES


China. Real GDP growth picked up to 7.1 percent in the first quarter, ½ percentage
point higher than in the March Tealbook. Growth was boosted by a recovery of
industrial activity, as temporary curbs on production in heavily polluting industries
were lifted. Exports also picked up from an already strong fourth quarter. We expect
growth to slow to 6¼ percent in the second half of the year and to 6 percent by 2020,
as export growth normalizes and as the authorities’ efforts to reduce financial risks
and rein in local government spending weigh on domestic demand.
We estimate that the proposed U.S. section 301 tariffs on imports from China would
have a limited effect on the Chinese economy because the targeted goods, valued
roughly at $50 billion, account for a small share of China’s GDP. (These tariffs
would be on top of the recently levied steel and aluminum tariffs, which should have
even more limited effects.) However, a substantial extension of tariffs—for example,
to all Chinese imports into the United States—would indeed pose a material risk to
the outlook for China and the emerging Asian region as a whole.

Page 40 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Inflation fell to 1.5 percent in the first quarter, almost one-half the fourth-quarter rate,
mainly because of a decline in pork prices. We see inflation moving back up to its
longer-term trend of 2½ percent by the middle of this year. Although China’s
proposed retaliatory tariffs on its imports from the United States add an upside risk to
this forecast, we expect the effect of these tariffs on prices to be limited.


Other Emerging Asia. After slowing significantly at the end of last year as high-tech
exports moderated, real GDP growth is estimated to have jumped to 4½ percent in the
first quarter from 3.2 percent in the fourth, driven by renewed strength in the region’s
recent PMIs point to weaker momentum going into the second quarter. We expect
growth to moderate to a trend pace of 3¾ percent by next year.



Mexico. Recent solid indicators, such as construction through February as well as
both manufacturing and services PMIs, suggest a continued recovery from the
hurricanes and earthquakes that occurred last year. We estimate that GDP expanded
2¾ percent in the first quarter, a small step-down from 3.2 percent in the fourth,
mainly because of a slower expansion of exports through February. We see growth
picking back up to about 3 percent by early 2019, held up by strong external demand,
diminished drag from fiscal consolidation, and stronger private consumption as
falling inflation boosts real wages.
Headline inflation declined to 4.1 percent in the first quarter from over 5 percent in
the second half of last year and nearly 10 percent a year ago. The decline in inflation
over the past few months reflects the effects of monetary policy tightening, peso
appreciation, and the fading effect of previous hikes in food prices. Despite falling
inflation, the BOM kept its policy rate on hold at 7.5 percent in mid-April rather than
cutting rates, citing continued concerns that adverse developments, such as an
unfavorable outcome of NAFTA negotiations or financial volatility associated with
Mexican elections in July, could lead to renewed peso depreciation.



Brazil. After taking a breather in the fourth quarter, Brazil’s economy appears to
have resumed its gradual climb out of the country’s deepest recession on record. We
have penciled in growth of 2¼ percent in the first quarter amid a surge in exports,
solid PMI readings, and improved consumer confidence. We expect the pace of
activity to pick up gradually and reach 3 percent by 2019, supported by global
demand, particularly for Brazil’s commodity exports. Political uncertainty remains

Page 41 of 126

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

overall exports. While export growth and industrial production have been strong,

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

the major downside risk, especially given the urgent need for policymakers to tackle
the country’s fiscal problems amid an unpredictable outcome of the upcoming
October presidential election. The front-runner of this election, former President Luiz
Inácio Lula da Silva, was imprisoned earlier this month for corruption and is likely to
be eliminated from the race.
Amid considerable economic slack, inflation remained subdued at about an annual
rate of 3.1 percent in the first quarter, somewhat below the inflation target. The
central bank is expected to cut its policy rate at its next meeting in May to a record
Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

low of 6.25 percent.

Page 42 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Page 43 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

The Foreign GDP Outlook

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Real GDP*

Percent change, annual rate

H1

2017
Q3

Q4

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

3.2
3.1

2.5
2.5

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

3.1
3.1
4.2
2.8
2.1
1.1

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.2
3.2
7.0
4.2
1.7
3.8

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

Q1

2018
Q2

2019

2020

H2

2.7
2.7

2.9
3.0

2.9
3.0

2.9
2.9

2.8
2.8

2.7
2.7

2.1
2.1
1.5
2.8
2.4
1.9

2.0
1.9
1.7
2.7
1.6
1.6

1.9
2.2
2.0
1.9
1.2
1.3

2.1
2.2
2.3
2.2
1.1
1.7

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
1.0
1.7

1.8
1.8
2.0
1.8
.3
1.6

1.7
1.8
1.9
1.7
.9
1.7

2.8
2.9
6.6
5.1
-.7
1.0

3.4
3.4
6.4
3.2
3.2
.2

3.9
3.8
7.1
4.4
2.7
2.3

3.7
3.7
6.8
3.9
2.8
2.5

3.7
3.7
6.3
4.0
2.8
2.5

3.8
3.8
6.2
3.8
2.9
3.0

3.7
3.7
5.9
3.7
3.0
2.6

* GDP aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. merchandise exports.

Total Foreign GDP

Foreign GDP
Percent change, annual rate

Percent change, annual rate

5.5

Current
Previous Tealbook

8

Current
Previous Tealbook
5.0

7

4.5

6
Emerging market economies

4.0

5

3.5

4

3.0

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

0
Advanced foreign economies

1.0
2010

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

-1
2010

Page 44 of 126

2012

2014

2016

2018

2020

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

The Foreign Inflation Outlook

Consumer Prices*

H1

2017
Q3

Q4

1. Total Foreign
Previous Tealbook

2.5
2.4

2.3
2.3

2.

Advanced Foreign Economies
Previous Tealbook
Canada
Euro Area
Japan
United Kingdom

1.3
1.3
1.4
1.5
-.1
3.4

Emerging Market Economies
Previous Tealbook
China
Emerging Asia ex. China
Mexico
Brazil

3.3
3.2
1.0
2.0
8.0
2.7

3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.

Q1

2018
Q2

2019

2020

H2

3.0
3.0

2.6
2.6

2.6
2.6

2.5
2.5

2.5
2.5

2.4
2.4

1.2
1.2
1.4
1.1
.7
2.4

2.1
2.1
3.0
1.7
1.9
3.0

2.6
2.1
3.6
2.1
2.5
2.5

1.9
1.5
2.6
1.9
.7
2.3

1.6
1.5
2.1
1.4
.7
2.3

1.8
1.8
2.0
1.5
2.3
2.2

1.7
1.7
2.0
1.7
1.0
2.1

3.1
3.1
2.2
2.0
5.4
2.3

3.7
3.7
2.9
3.2
5.0
3.6

2.7
2.9
1.5
2.3
4.1
3.1

3.1
3.4
2.2
3.0
4.0
3.4

3.2
3.3
2.6
3.2
3.7
4.3

3.0
3.0
2.5
3.1
3.3
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.5
3.0
3.2
4.3

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

Percent change, annual rate

* CPI aggregates weighted by shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

Foreign Monetary Policy
AFE Central Bank Balance Sheets

AFE Policy Rates
Percent

Percent of GDP

3.5

EME Policy Rates
Percent

100

3.0

15

Brazil

80

12

60

9

2.5
2.0
1.5

Japan
China*

Canada

40

1.0

United Kingdom

Mexico

0.5
20

Japan

3

United Kingdom

0.0
Euro area

Korea
Canada

-0.5
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020

6

Euro area

0
2010

2012

2014

Page 45 of 126

2016

2018

0
2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020
* 1-year benchmark lending rate.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Recent Foreign Indicators
Nominal Exports

Industrial Production
Jan. 2011 = 100

Foreign
AFE*

Jan. 2011 = 100

125

EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

120
115

125
120
115

110
105

110

100

105

95
100

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

90
85
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

95
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, U.K.
** Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, India, Indonesia,
Israel, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Russia, Singapore,
Taiwan, Thailand.

Retail Sales

Employment
12-month percent change

4-quarter percent change

8

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

Foreign
AFE*
EME**

6

3.0
2.5
2.0

4
1.5
2
1.0
0

0.5

-2
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

0.0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

* Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Korea, Mexico, Singapore, Taiwan.

* Includes Australia, Canada, euro area, Japan, Sweden, Switzerland, U.K.
** Includes Chile, Colombia, Hong Kong, Israel, Korea, Mexico,
Philippines, Russia, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand, Turkey.

Consumer Prices: Advanced Foreign Economies

Consumer Prices: Emerging Market Economies

12-month percent change

12-month percent change

2.5

Headline
Core*

Headline*
Ex. food--Emerging Asia**
Ex. food--Latin America**

2.0

7
6
5
4

1.5

3
1.0

2
1

0.5

0
0.0
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Note: Includes Canada, euro area, Japan, U.K.
* Excludes all food and energy; staff calculation.
Source: Haver Analytics.

2018

-1
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

* Includes Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand.
** Excludes all food; staff calculation. Excludes Argentina and Venezuela.

Page 46 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Evolution of Staff’s International Forecast

Total Foreign GDP
Percent change, Q4/Q4

2017

2018

4

3
2019

2

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22

6/10 7/22

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

2015

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2017

3/8 4/19

1

2018

Tealbook publication date

Total Foreign CPI
Percent change, Q4/Q4

2017

3.0

2019
2.5
2018

2020

2.0

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22

6/10 7/22

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

2015

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2017

3/8 4/19

1.5

2018

Tealbook publication date

U.S. Current Account Balance
Percent of GDP

-2

-3
2020
2017

-4

2019
2018

-5

12/10 1/21 3/11 4/22

2015

6/10 7/22

9/9 10/21 12/9 1/20

3/9 4/20

6/8 7/20

9/14 10/26 12/7 1/18 3/2

2016

2017
Tealbook publication date

Page 47 of 126

4/20 6/1 7/13

9/7 10/19 12/1 1/18

2018

3/8 4/19

-6

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

2020

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Int’l Econ Devel & Outlook

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 48 of 126

April 20, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Financial Market Developments
Domestic equity markets continued to experience heightened volatility over the
intermeeting period as a result of developments in U.S.–China trade policy and the
technology sector, though they were considerably less volatile than in early February. On
net, however, market participants’ outlook for monetary policy and economic growth
appears to be largely unchanged.


A straight read of market quotes shows that the probability of a rate hike at the
June meeting increased somewhat to 85 percent, with two hikes priced in
between now and the end of this year.



The nominal Treasury yield curve continued to flatten, driven primarily by an
increase in short-term yields, as longer-term yields were roughly unchanged.
Carry-adjusted TIPS-based measures of inflation compensation increased over
the period.



Broad U.S. equity price indexes edged down on net. The VIX has declined
since the March FOMC meeting, though it is high compared with last year,
average over the past few years. Credit spreads on investment-grade
corporate bonds were little changed, while those on speculative-grade bonds
narrowed a bit.



Conditions in foreign financial markets were not much changed since the last
FOMC meeting. Foreign equity prices exhibited notable fluctuations and
ended the period modestly higher outside of emerging Asia. Longer-term
foreign sovereign yields moved little, and the broad dollar depreciated
slightly.



Rates in short-term dollar funding markets remained elevated but do not seem
to indicate credit risk concerns. Changes in rates and volumes over quarterend were relatively muted.

Page 49 of 126

Financial Markets

and realized volatility of equity prices remained elevated relative to its

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Policy Expectations and Treasury Yields
Selected Interest Rates
Percent
2.70

Percent

Tariff
announcement
March
Mnuchin
FOMC
comments

2.65
2.60

Dec. 2018
Eurodollar
(left scale)

2.55

3.10

$100 billion
tariff consideration
$50 billion
Employment
Chinese tariffs
report

3.05

March FOMC
minutes

3.00
April 19
4:00 p.m.

Xi speech at
Boao forum

2.95

2.50

2.90

2.45

2.85

2.40

2.80
10−year
Treasury yield
(right scale)

2.35
2.30

2.75
2.70

2.25
Mar. 23

Apr. 3

Mar. 28

Apr. 6

Apr. 11

Apr. 16

2.65

Apr. 19

Note: 5−minute intervals, 8:00 a.m. to 4:00 p.m. Data shown are for 2018.
Source: Bloomberg.

Market−Implied Probability Distribution
of the Timing of Next Rate Increase

Implied Federal Funds Rate
Percent

Percent
100

Most recent: April 19, 2018
Last FOMC: March 20, 2018

5

Most recent: April 19, 2018
Last FOMC: March 20, 2018

90

4

80
With model−based
term premium

70
60

3

50
40
With zero
term premium

30

Financial Markets

20

2

10
May 2

June 13

Aug. 1

0

>= Sept. 26

1
2018

Note: Probabilities implied by a binomial tree fitted to settlement prices on federal
funds futures contracts, assuming the next policy action is either no change or a
25 basis point increase in rates and no intermeeting moves. The effective federal funds
rate until the next FOMC meeting is assumed to be equal to the observed rate
on the previous non−month−end business day.
Source: CME Group; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

2019

2020

2021

2022

Note: Zero term premium path is estimated using overnight index swap quotes
with a spline approach and a term premium of zero basis points. Model−based term
premium path is estimated using a term structure model maintained by Board staff
and corrects for term premium.
Source: Bloomberg; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Option−Implied Volatilities on 10−Year
Swap Rate

Treasury Yield Curve
Percent

Basis points

3.5

Most recent: April 19, 2018
Last FOMC: March 20, 2018

Mar.
FOMC

1 month ahead
1 year ahead

120

100
3.0
80
Apr.
19

2.5

2.0
2

5

10

20
Maturity in years

Note: Smoothed yield curve estimated from off-the-run Treasury coupon
securities. Yields shown are those on notional par Treasury securities with
semiannual coupons.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board staff
estimates.

30

Oct.
2016

Jan.

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

Apr.
Jan.
2018

Note: Implied volatility on the 10−year swap rate 1 month and 1 year ahead is
derived from swaptions.
Source: Barclays; Federal Reserve Board staff estimates.

Page 50 of 126

60

40

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

POLICY EXPECTATIONS AND ASSET MARKET DEVELOPMENTS
Domestic Developments
FOMC communications over the intermeeting period were generally viewed by
market participants as reflecting an overall upbeat outlook for economic growth and as
consistent with a continued gradual removal of monetary policy accommodation. The
FOMC’s decision to raise the target range for the federal funds rate 25 basis points at the
March meeting was widely anticipated. Nevertheless, the market reaction to the March
FOMC communications was consistent with slightly more accommodative policy than
expected, as the median target rate path in the March SEP implied three rate hikes in
2018 whereas some investors had anticipated four rate hikes. Some investors pointed to
the median of participants’ SEP projections for core PCE inflation rising above 2 percent
in both 2019 and 2020 as an indication of the Committee’s willingness to continue along
a gradual path of increases in the target range for the federal funds rate even if inflation
temporarily moves above target. Market reaction to the release of the March FOMC
minutes later in the intermeeting period was minimal.
Domestic data releases over the intermeeting period generally elicited limited
market reaction. Total nonfarm payroll employment in the March Employment Situation
report came in notably below reported market expectations, but market commentaries
component of the March employment report and the March CPI both printed largely in
line with expectations.
A straight read of quotes on federal funds futures contracts shows that the marketimplied probability for the next rate hike occurring at the June FOMC meeting moved up
to around 85 percent since the March FOMC meeting. OIS-implied federal funds rates
unadjusted for term premiums suggest that two rate hikes are priced in between now and
the end of this year, while a staff model that adjusts for term premiums implies three
hikes. Implied rates at the end of 2019 and 2020 were about unchanged.
The nominal Treasury yield curve flattened a bit further over the intermeeting
period, with yields on 2-year Treasury securities up 11 basis points and yields on 10-year
Treasury securities higher by 3 basis points. The spread between 10-year and 2-year
Treasury securities stands at about the 20th percentile of its distribution since 1990. If
adjusted for term premiums, the difference between the two rates is currently at about the

Page 51 of 126

Financial Markets

attributed the weakness in part to weather-related effects. The average hourly earnings

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Corporate Asset Market Developments
S&P 500 Stock Price Index
Mar. 20, 2018 = 100
110

Daily

Mar.
FOMC

S&P 500
S&P Tech
KBW Bank Index

100
Apr.
19

90

80
Oct.

Nov.
2017

Dec.

Jan.

Feb.

Mar.

Apr.

2018

Source: Bloomberg.

Implied Volatility on S&P 500 (VIX)

Equity Risk Premium

Log scale, percent

Percent
18

Monthly
Expected 10-year real equity return
Expected real yield on 10-year Treasury*

Mar.
FOMC

15

50

Mar.
FOMC

Daily
VIX
Realized volatility

12
20
9
Apr.
19

6

+Apr.
19

0

5

-3
2002

2006

2010

2014

2018

Dec.
2016

Note: The equity risk premium is the difference between the two data series.
* Off-the-run 10-year Treasury yield less Philadelphia Fed 10-year expected
inflation.
+ Denotes latest observation using daily interest rates and stock prices as
well as staff forecast of corporate profits.
Source: Bloomberg; Philadelphia Fed; staff estimates; Thomson Reuters
Financial.

S&P 500 Returns vs. HY Spread Changes
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
-10
-20
-30
-40
-50

Past 5 years
Intermeeting period

-8

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

8

S&P 500 returns (percent, 2-day)
Note: Returns and spread changes are calculated over a 2-day interval.
Black line is found by ordinary least squares. Sample uses the past 5
years of data. HY is high yield.
Source: Bloomberg; Merrill Lynch.

Apr.

Aug.
2017

Dec.

Apr.
2018

Source: Chicago Board Options Exchange.

Change in the HY spread (basis points, 2-day)

Financial Markets

+

10

3

10-Year Corporate Bond Spreads
Basis points
400

Basis points
800

Daily

Mar.
FOMC

High-yield
(right scale)
Triple-B (left scale)

350
300

700
600

250
500
200
150

Apr.
19

100
50

400
300
200

2012

2014

2016

2018

Note: Spreads over 10-year Treasury yield.
Source: Staff estimates of smoothed yield curves based on Merrill Lynch
bond data and smoothed Treasury yield curve.

Page 52 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

40th percentile of its distribution since 1990.1 TIPS-based measures of inflation
compensation increased on net.
Measures of option-implied volatility on long-term rates continued to decline over
the intermeeting period after their marked increase earlier this year, and they are now
close to the levels seen late last year.
Following the sharp increase in early February, realized volatility in the equity
market remained somewhat elevated due in large part to news related to trade policy.
However, the S&P 500 index declined only a bit over the period on net. Equity prices
deteriorated as trade tensions between the U.S. and China escalated early in the
intermeeting period, although prices subsequently improved as tensions showed signs of
easing. Additionally, negative technology sector–related news and concerns about
increased government oversight of the sector reportedly weighed on investor sentiment,
though the sector ended the period only slightly lower than the broader index. Bank
equity prices declined about 4 percent over the intermeeting period and underperformed
broad equity indexes, on net, likely reflecting concerns about trade policy, tepid loan
growth, and weaker-than-expected trading revenues. One-month-ahead option-implied
volatility on the S&P 500 index—the VIX—declined but remained at elevated levels

Volatility in the equity market did not spill over into the corporate bond market.
On days with large negative equity returns, spreads on high-yield corporate bonds
changed less than would be expected from their historical relationship with stock prices.
On net, spreads on yields of investment- and speculative-grade corporate bonds over
comparable-maturity Treasury securities increased 3 basis points and declined 13 basis
points, respectively.

For more on the information content of the term premium portion of the term spread for
economic activity, see Peter Johansson and Andrew Meldrum (2018), “Predicting Recession Probabilities
Using the Slope of the Yield Curve,” FEDS Notes (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, March 1), https://www.federalreserve.gov/econres/notes/feds-notes/predicting-recessionprobabilities-using-the-slope-of-the-yield-curve-20180301.htm; and Michael D. Bauer and Thomas W.
Mertens (2018), “Economic Forecasts with the Yield Curve,” FRBSF Economic Letter 2018-07 (San
Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, March), https://www.frbsf.org/economicresearch/publications/economic-letter/2018/march/economic-forecasts-with-yield-curve.
1

Page 53 of 126

Financial Markets

relative to the previous year, ending the period at approximately 16 percent.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Foreign Developments
Equity Indexes

Emerging Market Flows and Spreads
Mar. 20, 2018 = 100
Daily

S&P 500
DJ Euro Stoxx
Nikkei
EME

130
125

Mar.
FOMC

120
115
110
105
Apr.
19

Billions of dollars
Basis points
500
Weekly bond flows (left scale)
Weekly equity flows (left scale)
450
Mar.
EMBI+
(daily)
10
FOMC
400
15

Apr.
19

5

300

100
95

250

0

200

90
Dec.
2017

Jan.

Feb.
2018

Mar.

Apr.

85

350

-5

Dec.
2017

Note: EME stocks represented by MSCI local-currency index.
Source: Bloomberg; MSCI.

Jan.

Feb.
2018

Mar.

150

Apr.

Note: Emerging market bond spreads over zero-coupon Treasury securities.
Flows data exclude intra-China flows. Monthly figures are averaged.
Source: EPFR; J.P. Morgan.

10-Year AFE Sovereign Yields

Implied Volatilities
Percent
VDAX
VIX

Mar.
FOMC

Daily

Percent

45

United States
United Kingdom
Germany
Japan

35

Daily

4.0

Mar.
FOMC

2.5

Financial Markets

25
Apr.
19

Dec.
2017

Jan.

Feb.
2018

Mar.

Apr.

Apr.
19

1.0
15

5

Dec.
2017

Source: Bloomberg.

Jan.

Feb.
2018

Mar.

-0.5

Apr.

Source: Bloomberg.

Exchange Rates

3-Month FX Swap Bases
Mar. 20, 2018 = 100

Broad index
EME index
Canadian dollar
Mexican peso

Mar.
FOMC

Daily

Basis points

115

Japanese yen
Euro

Daily
Mar.
FOMC

110
Dollar
appreciation

Apr.
19

Jan.

Feb.
2018

Mar.

Apr.

125
100

105
Apr.
19

100

75
50

95

Dec.
2017

150

90

25

Jan.

Source: Bloomberg.

Apr.

July
2016

Oct.

Jan.

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

Jan. Apr.
2018

Note: Series are 3-day moving averages. FX is foreign exchange.
Source: Bloomberg.

Page 54 of 126

0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Foreign Developments
Global equity markets were volatile since the March FOMC meeting, with
investors in foreign markets also attuned to developments related to trade policies
between the United States and China and to news about the U.S. technology sector. On
balance, foreign equity price movements were mixed, long-term foreign sovereign yields
were generally little changed, and the broad dollar depreciated slightly over the period.
In Russia, although the currency depreciated sharply and equity prices fell following the
introduction of the new round of U.S. sanctions, stresses in Russian markets did not spill
over to other financial markets.
Net changes in foreign equity prices did not exhibit a strong overall pattern.
Japanese and European broad equity indexes outperformed their U.S. counterparts,
ending the period somewhat higher. Equity price indexes in Mexico and other Latin
American countries were modestly higher, while those in some emerging Asian
countries—which may be more directly affected by a potential deterioration in U.S.–
China trade relations—were lower. On balance, capital continued to flow into emerging
market mutual funds and emerging market bond spreads were little changed. Measures
of implied volatilities of foreign equities fluctuated since the previous FOMC meeting
and ended the period somewhat lower.

generally little changed in the advanced foreign economies, with most of their central
banks still expected to gradually move toward less accommodative monetary policy over
the next couple of years. Long-term sovereign yields in the advanced foreign economies
also showed little movement.
On net, the broad dollar index declined about ¾ percent, largely because
relatively positive news about the current round of NAFTA negotiations led to
appreciation of the Mexican peso and Canadian dollar, two currencies with large weights
in the dollar index.
At the March quarter-end, money market conditions in Europe and Japan were
characterized as in line with expectations and consistent with previous quarter-end
dynamics. Over the intermeeting period, three-month currency swap basis spreads,
which at times have indicated dollar funding pressures abroad, narrowed to the lowest
levels in recent years. Market participants attributed the decline to continued decreases in

Page 55 of 126

Financial Markets

Over the intermeeting period, market-based measures of policy expectations were

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Short−Term Funding Markets and Federal Reserve Operations
Selected Money Market Rates

Basis points

Daily

Mar.
FOMC

Triparty Treasury repo
1−month Treasury bill
Federal funds
Eurodollar

CP and CD rates
Daily

200

3−month CD
Mar.
FOMC
7−day CD
Overnight AA nonfinancial CP

180

Apr.
18

Basis points

220

250
225

160

200
Apr.
19

140

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

150

100

125

80

100

60

75

40

50

20

25
0

Jan.
Apr.
2018

Oct.
Jan.
2016

Note: Federal funds rate is a weighted median. Shaded area is the target range for
the federal funds rate. Repo is repurchase agreement.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Federal Reserve Board,
Form FR 2420, Report of Selected Money Market Rates.

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

Jan.
Apr.
2018

Note: CD rates are a 5−day moving average. CP is commercial paper;
CD is certificate of deposit.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation.

ON RRP Take−Up and Treasury Bills Outstanding

ON RRP Take−Up, by Type

Billions of dollars

Daily

Mar.
FOMC

Government MMFs
Prime MMFs
Other

ON RRP take−up (billions of dollars)

550
500

Daily

2017:Q1
2017:Q2
2017:Q3
2017:Q4
2018:Q1
2018:Q2

450
400
350

Financial Markets

175

120

0
Oct.
Jan.
2016

275

Apr.
19

500
450
400
350
300

300

250

250

200

200

150

150

100

100

50

50

0

0
Jan.

Apr.

July
2016

Oct.

Jan.

Apr.

July
2017

Oct.

1500

Jan. Apr.
2018

1750
2000
2250
Treasury bills outstanding (billions of dollars)

2500

Note: ON RRP is overnight reverse repurchase agreement. Treasury bills
outstanding = gross amount issued − gross amount matured + outstanding;
calculated between Jan. 2017 and Apr. 2018.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York; Department of the Treasury.

Note: ON RRP is reverse repurchase agreement; MMF is money market fund.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

RRP Take−Up on Quarter−Ends
Billions of dollars
Overnight tenor
Term tenor

600

Drops in Outstanding Volumes on Quarter−Ends,
by Foreign Banks and Dealers
Billions of dollars

550

10
0

500

−10

450
−20

400
350

−30

300

−40

250

−50

200

−60

150
−70

100

−80

50
0

−90

Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: RRP is reverse repurchase agreement.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Q1
2015
2016
2017
2018
Note: The drop in outstanding volumes equals the sum of triparty Treasury repo
and federal funds volumes. The drop on quarter−end is calculated as positions on
quarter−end less positions on the business day immediately before quarter−end.
This graph considers March 29, 2018, as the quarter−end date of 2018:Q1.
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

Page 56 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

demand for dollar hedges by foreign investment accounts, as well as reduced dollar
borrowing through the currency swap market by foreign banks.

SHORT-TERM FUNDING MARKETS AND FEDERAL RESERVE OPERATIONS
Conditions in short-term funding markets remained generally stable over the
intermeeting period despite the continuation of notably elevated spreads in segments of
the money market (see the box “Recent Pressures in Money Markets”). Both the
effective federal funds rate and the overnight bank funding rate continued to trade in the
upper third of the target range, while repo and Treasury bill rates remained elevated.
Because elevated rates on other short-term investments offered an attractive alternative
for market participants, take-up at the Federal Reserve’s ON RRP facility remained
subdued, averaging about $7 billion per day excluding quarter-end.
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York began publishing three new overnight
Treasury repo rates on April 3, 2018 (see the box “New Overnight Treasury Repo
Rates”).
Money market dynamics over quarter-end were muted relative to previous
quarter-ends. The effective federal funds rate dropped only 1 basis point, in contrast to
usually reduce their activity in funding markets on quarter-end to improve their
regulatory ratios around reporting dates. Such behavior was muted at the end of March,
which reportedly led to relatively small movements in rates and volumes, and contributed
to the all-time-low quarter-end ON RRP take-up of $33 billion.
The Federal Reserve’s balance sheet normalization has continued as scheduled.
Market participants reported no notable effect on money markets, Treasury yields, or
option-adjusted spreads on current-coupon MBS as a result of the normalization process.
Since the start of balance sheet normalization through March 2018, the Federal Reserve’s
holdings of Treasury securities have decreased by $40 billion, and its holdings of agency
securities have decreased by $16 billion. Consistent with the Committee’s Policy
Normalization Principles and Plans, the monthly caps on reductions of Treasury and
agency securities increased in April to $18 billion and $12 billion, respectively.

The Good Friday market holiday on March 30 coincided with the March quarter-end and could
have contributed to these atypical dynamics.
2

Page 57 of 126

Financial Markets

the typically observed decline of around 9 basis points.2 Foreign banks and dealers

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Recent Pressures in Money Markets
The upward pressure on private money market rates, beyond that driven by expected monetary
policy, persisted over the intermeeting period. In unsecured markets, the London interbank
offered rate (LIBOR) and rates on commercial paper (CP) and negotiable certificates of deposit
(CDs) remained abnormally high relative to overnight index swap (OIS) rates of comparable
maturities, particularly at tenors exceeding one month. In secured markets, Treasury repo rates
remained elevated relative to the effective federal funds rate, and the spread is also very high by
historical standards. Table 1 shows that a variety of private spreads are currently near the top ends
of their historical ranges. Since the March FOMC meeting, however, spreads on Treasury bills
narrowed some, widening the gap between private money market rates and those on Treasury
bills, as shown in figure 1.
Several factors may have contributed to the wide spreads for private instruments, although none
appears to fully explain the unusually high level of current spreads. First, the surge in Treasury bill
supply in the first quarter appears to have pushed Treasury and unsecured private rates higher, and
the effects on private rates may be lingering temporarily even as bill issuance has slowed and rates
have edged down. Consistent with such a view, spreads on forward rate agreements, or FRAs, over

Financial Markets

Table 1. Current Private Spreads and Historical Ranges
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.

Spread
3m LIBOR—3m OIS
3m T-bill—3m OIS
3m A2/P2 nonfin CP—3m OIS2
3m AA nonfin CP—3m OIS
3m CD—3m OIS
BBG: 3m CD—3m OIS
PD Treas. Repo—EFFR
1
2

Value as of 4/16/2018
(bps)
59
-3

Percentile of Historical
Distribution (%)1
90
92

94
20
57
56
4

92
96
99
88
90

The sample periods begin on 12/4/2001 for lines 1 to 4 and line 6, 12/14/2015 for line 5, and 1/3/1972 for line 7.
Data as of 4/9/2018.

Note: BBG is Bloomberg, PD is Primary Dealer, and EFFR is effective federal funds rate.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation; Federal Reserve Board, H.15.

Figure 1

Page 58 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Figure 2

In unsecured markets, a second possible factor is that anticipated tax-induced repatriation flows
may have reduced offshore demand for private money market securities with longer tenors, and
aggregate demand for these securities would fall if repatriated cash is put to other uses. Anecdotal
reports from dealers suggest that cash-rich nonfinancial firms have shifted holdings toward very
short-dated instruments. In contrast, data from the offshore money market fund (OMMF) sector
only weakly support the repatriation story. OMMF assets under management have declined in
recent weeks, but the funds do not appear to be shifting away from longer-dated assets in
anticipation of further outflows, as weighted average maturities are little changed.
Other possible explanations are less compelling. Some market participants have suggested that
the base erosion anti-abuse tax, or BEAT, which may effectively penalize foreign banks that raise
funds through foreign affiliates—and thus encourage raising short-term funds in U.S. markets—
might eventually boost unsecured rates. But the effects of the tax are unlikely to have materialized
yet, and issuance of CP and CDs has not increased in recent months. Another possibility is that
credit risk has driven rates higher. However, staff analysis of the historical relationship between
changes in three-month LIBOR–OIS spreads and aggregate credit default swap (CDS) spreads of
the largest banks indicates that the recent modest widening of these CDS spreads explains only a
trivial fraction of the LIBOR–OIS widening. Moreover, conversations with market participants have
not suggested any heightened credit-risk concerns.

Page 59 of 126

Financial Markets

OIS, shown in figure 2, suggest that the LIBOR–OIS spread is expected to narrow in coming months.
Increased Treasury supply also appears to be an important factor in pressuring secured rates
higher, as dealers had to finance sizable issuance in February and March.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

New Overnight Treasury Repo Rates
On April 3, 2018, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York began publishing three new overnight
Treasury repo rates. The purpose of the new rates is to increase the transparency of repo market
trading by providing interest rate and volume measures that cross the major repo market
segments. All of the repo rates exclude transactions in which the Federal Reserve is a
counterparty, such as take‐up at the ON RRP facility.
The Tri‐Party General Collateral Rate (TGCR) covers the “triparty” segment in which securities
dealers borrow cash directly from investors, including money market funds, in trades facilitated
by a third‐party clearing bank. The Broad General Collateral Rate (BGCR) includes all transactions
in the TGCR and also includes blind‐brokered transactions between dealers that occur on the
Fixed Income Clearing Corporation’s (FICC) GCF Repo service.

Financial Markets

The Secured Overnight Financing Rate (SOFR)—the blue line in the chart—measures the general
cost of financing Treasury securities overnight across all repo market segments for which data are
available, providing the broadest coverage of the repo market. A broad Treasury repo rate was
previously not available to the public. The SOFR is calculated from all transactions in the BGCR, as
well as bilateral transactions that are cleared by the FICC. The SOFR excludes bilateral
transactions that are executed at very low rates because such trades tend to be motivated by the
lender’s need to obtain a specific security as collateral rather than the need to invest cash.
In June 2017, the Alternative Reference Rates Committee selected the SOFR as its recommended
alternative to U.S. dollar LIBOR, which is currently referenced in derivatives contracts with about
$190 trillion of notional value as well as $10 trillion of loans and securities. The transition from
LIBOR to SOFR is expected to take a number of years, and daily publication of the rate is a key
step in the process.

Page 60 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Financing Conditions for Businesses and Households
Data received over the intermeeting period continue to indicate that financing
conditions for businesses and households remain supportive of economic activity.
•

Financing conditions for nonfinancial corporations remained accommodative.
Gross issuance of corporate bonds and leveraged loans was strong in March,
and equity issuance was robust. The extension of bank credit to businesses
increased following relatively weak growth in January and February.

•

Conditions in the residential mortgage market remained supportive of financing
for most borrowers. For borrowers with low credit scores, conditions remained
tight but have continued to ease gradually.

•

Growth in consumer loans moderated early this year from the more rapid pace
seen late last year, and banks responding to the April Senior Loan Officer
Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices (SLOOS) reported tighter standards
for both credit card and auto loans. Nonetheless, on the whole, financing
conditions in consumer credit markets remained largely supportive of growth in
household spending.

BUSINESS FINANCING CONDITIONS
Financing conditions for nonfinancial corporations remained accommodative over
the intermeeting period. Corporate bond spreads continued to be low by historical
standards, and following a somewhat subdued start to the year, gross issuance of
investment-grade corporate bonds was strong in March. 1 Issuance of speculative-grade
debt was also solid in March, in line with its average volume over the past few years.
Institutional leveraged loan issuance in February and March was strong, largely reflecting
strength in demand from investors, including considerable funding for M&A activity.
Spreads on new issues of lower-rated institutional loans were roughly unchanged over the
intermeeting period, while spreads for higher-rated loans narrowed a little further.

In particular, one very large M&A-related issue of $40 billion was reportedly well received by
investors, suggesting that substantial market demand remains for investment-grade corporate debt.
1

Page 61 of 126

Financing Conditions

Nonfinancial Corporations

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Business Finance
Selected Components of Net Debt Financing,
Nonfinancial Firms

Gross Issuance of Nonfinancial
Corporate Bonds

Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars
80

Monthly rate
C&I Loans*
Institutional leveraged loans
Bonds

120

Monthly rate

70

Mar.

Mar.

Speculative-grade
Investment-grade

60

100
H1

50
Q3

Feb.

60

Jan.

30

Jan.

80

Q4

40

Feb.

H1

Q3

20

Q4

40

10

20

0
-10
2012

2014

2016

0

2018

2012

Note: C&I is commercial and industrial.
* Period-end basis.
Source: Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation; Mergent Fixed Income
Securities Database; Federal Reserve Board.

2014

2016

Note: Bonds are categorized by Moody's, Standard & Poor's, and Fitch.
Source: Mergent Fixed Income Securities Database.

Institutional Leveraged Loan Issuance,
by Purpose

Commercial and Industrial Loans

Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars
100

Monthly rate

Feb.

Mar.

25

Monthly rate, s.a.

H1

Refinancings
New money

2018

20

Large banks
Small banks
Foreign banks

80

H2

Mar.

15

60
10
40

Jan.

Jan.
H1

Feb.

5

H2

20

0

0
2012

2014

2016

-5

2018

2012

Source: Thomson Reuters LPC LoanConnector.

2014

2016

2018

Source: Staff calculations, Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2644, Weekly
Report of Selected Assets and Liabilities of Domestically Chartered Commercial
Banks and U.S. Branches and Agencies of Foreign Banks.

Commercial and Industrial Loans:
Changes in Standards and Demand

Announced Share Repurchases,
Nonfinancial Firms

Jan.
survey

Quarterly
Standards
Demand

Billions of dollars
100
80

60

Monthly rate

60
40

Q4

40
Q1

20
H1

0

Easing/weaker

Tightening/stronger

Net percent

20

-20

Q3

-40
-60
2012

2014

2016

2018

0
2012

Note: Banks' responses are weighted by their sizes in the relevant loan
categories.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices.

2014

Source: Securities Data Company.

Page 62 of 126

2016

2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Growth in banks’ commercial and industrial (C&I) loans strengthened in March,
following relatively weak growth in January and February. Nonetheless, respondents to
the April SLOOS reported that C&I loan demand continued to weaken over the first
quarter. Banks that experienced subdued demand often reported that businesses were
generating more funds internally or shifting their borrowing to other lenders. (For a
discussion of the effect of the recent rise in short-term funding rates on financing
conditions more generally, see the box “Possible Effects of the Recent Increase in ShortTerm Funding Rates on Financing Conditions for Businesses and Households.”) SLOOS
respondents continued to report easing standards and terms on C&I loans, most often citing
increased competition from other lenders as the reason for doing so.
The credit quality of nonfinancial corporations was essentially stable over the
intermeeting period, although the ratio of aggregate debt to assets remains near
multidecade highs. The six-month trailing bond default rate ticked up in March to a level
in line with that seen about a year ago, while the KMV expected year-ahead default rate for
March was roughly unchanged from February and stood just below the median of its
historical range. The outlook for corporate earnings remains very favorable. Wall Street
analyst forecasts imply that earnings for S&P 500 firms are expected to be about
20 percent higher in 2018 than in 2017, with part of the increase reflecting lower
corporate taxes.
The pace of equity issuance through initial and seasoned offerings was robust in the
first quarter. Announced stock repurchases over the past two quarters were at their highest
levels in two years, suggesting that companies are expecting to distribute to shareholders at
least part of the increased cash they anticipate from lower corporate taxes and repatriation
of earnings held abroad.

Small business credit conditions remained fairly accommodative over the
intermeeting period. Standards for C&I loans to small businesses eased modestly in the
April SLOOS. Although credit demand remains weak relative to pre-crisis levels, it has
shown signs of strengthening, and lending activity has increased in recent months. Loan
originations—as measured by the three-month moving average of the Thomson
Reuters/PayNet Small Business Lending Index—rose in February, leaving the series about
10 percent higher than a year ago. Loan performance in this sector remains strong.

Page 63 of 126

Financing Conditions

Small Businesses

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Possible Effects of the Recent Increase in Short-Term Funding Rates on
Financing Conditions for Businesses and Households
The elevated level of short-term funding rates relative to what would normally occur with
monetary policy tightening—as discussed in the box “Recent Pressures in Money Markets” in
the Financial Market Developments section—could serve to tighten financing conditions for
business and households. Here we assess the channels through which this might occur.
One potential channel is an increase in the direct cost of borrowing new funds or servicing
existing debt. Borrowers’ financing costs could increase in short-term funding markets, such
as commercial paper, or on financing instruments whose costs are tied to short-term rates,
such as floating-rate loans or lines of credit. 1 Longer-term borrowing rates could also
increase if lenders expect short-term rates to remain elevated over a longer period. To date,
longer-term borrowing rates have not appeared much affected by recently elevated shortterm spreads. Moreover, forward contracts suggest that investors do not expect the elevated
spreads to persist for long.
For households, a relatively modest share of debt is tied to short-term rates that have
experienced abnormal upward market pressure. Fewer than 20 percent of outstanding
residential mortgages have adjustable rates, and fewer than 10 percent of new originations
have adjustable rates. The majority of adjustable-rate mortgages are indexed to LIBOR, and a
minority of households with adjustable-rate mortgages could experience higher costs as their
loan rates reset. In contrast, floating interest rates on credit cards and home equity lines of
credit are typically indexed to the prime rate—an administered rate that has risen with the
federal funds rate but has not experienced abnormal upward market pressure. Most of the
outstanding auto and student loans have fixed rates and, thus, do not have rates that would
directly increase along with recently elevated short rates.
For businesses, direct borrowing in commercial paper represents a very small proportion—
around 2 percent—of total borrowing by nonfinancial firms. However, floating-rate loans are
common for businesses, and costs on such loans have increased with elevated short rates. As
the table on the next page shows, around 80 percent of commercial and industrial (C&I) and
commercial real estate (CRE) loans outstanding at the largest banks have floating rates. The
majority of these floating-rate loans are tied to LIBOR—typically, the three-month LIBOR.
While borrowing through floating-rate debt is more common for businesses, for many firms it
still represents a relatively small share of their total borrowing. Over 60 percent of borrowing
by large firms occurs through corporate bond markets in which interest rates are longer-term
fixed rates, and around one-third of CRE borrowing occurs though nonbank loans or CMBS
with fixed rates. Smaller firms tend to be more dependent on bank loans for financing.

1 Higher short-term rates could also serve to boost the income of investors in these funding instruments.
The extent to which this extra investment income serves to offset higher borrowing costs of businesses and
households depends on the marginal propensities of these investors to spend additional investment income
relative to the marginal propensities of the borrowers to spend.

Page 64 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Overall, while some businesses have experienced higher financing costs, the recent increase in
some short rates will not likely result in a large, direct increase in debt service burdens. Staff
analysis on the potential effects of a larger and more persistent rise in short-term rates than
has actually occurred indicates that debt service burdens for businesses and households
would only rise a modest amount. 2 Moreover, borrowers who do rely more heavily on
floating-rate debt could potentially substitute toward fixed-rate debt or switch to floating-rate
debt tied to short-term rates not experiencing the same upward pressures, such as the onemonth LIBOR, serving to reduce the effects of elevated short-term spreads on direct
financing costs.
A second, less direct channel through which the recent upward pressure on short-term rates
could tighten financing conditions is reduced lending or higher-cost lending by financial
institutions experiencing higher funding costs. For example, financial institutions originating
new loans could set loan rates higher to offset any increase in their funding costs or could
choose to originate less loans. The extent to which this may occur depends on how much of
an increase in funding costs financial institutions experience. At present, it does not appear
that banks’ funding costs have risen appreciably, as most such funding comes in the form of
deposits, but banks and other financial institutions that are more reliant on wholesale funding
could see an increase in their funding costs.
Overall, the recent upward pressure on short-term rates does not appear to have affected the
borrowing costs or capacity of most households and businesses, and staff analysis suggests
that elevated short-term rates will not have a long-term effect on financing conditions. The
staff will continue to track developments in short-term funding markets and monitor changes
in financing conditions.

Percentage of Outstanding Bank Business Loans with Floating Rates
C&I Loans
CRE Loans
Share of outstanding loans with floating rates

78

80

Share of loans with floating rates indexed to:
LIBOR
Prime rate
Treasury index
Other

83
6
1
10

91
4
1
4

2 See John Driscoll, Aurel Hizmo, Ashish Kumbhat, Francisco Palomino, Ander Perez-Orive, and Maya

Shaton (2017), “The Response of Consumer and Corporate Debt Interest Payments to Changes in the Target
Range for the Federal Funds Rate,” memorandum, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Divisions of Monetary Affairs and Research and Statistics, April 7; and Christine Dobridge, Francisco Palomino,
Ander Perez-Orive, Charles Press, Gustavo Suarez, and Jason Wu (2018), “Assessing Vulnerabilities in
Nonfinancial Corporate Credit,” memorandum, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Divisions
of Monetary Affairs and Research and Statistics, April 13.

Page 65 of 126

Financing Conditions

Note: Figures have been weighted by loan amounts outstanding.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Form FR Y-14Q, Capital Assessments and Stress
Testing, as of 2017:Q4.

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Small Business Finance and Commercial Real Estate Lending
Thomson Reuters/PayNet Small Business
Lending Index

Commercial Real Estate Loans

Jan. 2005 = 100
Monthly, n.s.a.
Feb.

Billions of dollars

150

Monthly rate, s.a.

Construction and land development
Multifamily
Nonfarm nonresidential

145
140

H2

130

Jan. Feb.

Mar.

2016

2017

2018

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

Note: 3-month moving average.
Source: Thomson Reuters, Thomson Reuters/PayNet Small Business
Lending Index.

Source: Staff calculations, Federal Reserve Board, Form FR 2644, Weekly
Report of Selected Assets and Liabilities of Domestically Chartered
Commercial Banks and U.S. Branches and Agencies of Foreign Banks.

Changes in Standards for CRE Loans

Changes in Demand for CRE Loans

Tightening

Construction and land development
Nonfarm nonresidential
Multifamily

Net percent

100
80
60
40

Jan.
survey

Quarterly

20
0

-40
2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

-60

Note: Banks' responses are weighted by their sizes in the relevant loan
categories. CRE is commercial real estate.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank
Lending Practices.

200

Mar.
FOMC

Triple-B 10-year
(right scale)

2013

2014

2015

2016

-60
-80

2017

2018

Billions of dollars

850

Annual rate

750

Multifamily
Nonresidential
Q3

650

150

Q4

Mar.
Feb.

550

Triple-A 10-year senior
(left scale)

50

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

Note: CMBS is commercial mortgage-backed securities.
Source: J.P. Morgan.

Apr.
13

2018

150
125
100
75

H1

450
100

-100

Non-agency CMBS Issuance

Basis points

Weekly

-40

Construction and land development
Nonfarm nonresidential
Multifamily

Note: Banks' responses are weighted by their sizes in the relevant loan
categories. CRE is commercial real estate.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices.

10-Year CMBS Spreads over Swaps
Basis points

-20
Weaker

Easing

-20

80
40

20
0

-5

60

Stronger

Quarterly

Jan.
survey

10

0

120

Net percent

20

5

125
2015

25

15

H1

135

30

50

350
Jan.

250
150

2014

2016

2018

Note: Multifamily excludes agency issuance. CMBS is commercial
mortgage-backed securities.
Source: Consumer Mortgage Alert.

Page 66 of 126

25
0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Commercial Real Estate
Conditions for commercial real estate (CRE) financing remained accommodative
over the intermeeting period. CRE loan growth at banks ticked up in the first quarter,
driven mainly by strong growth at small domestic and foreign banks. Regarding the
components of CRE loans, construction and land development loan growth weakened,
while growth in nonfarm nonresidential loans and in multifamily property loans rose.
Respondents to the April SLOOS reported easing standards on multifamily and nonfarm
nonresidential loans, along with somewhat weaker demand for nonfarm nonresidential
loans and construction and land development loans.
Taking a longer-term view, banks responding to special questions in the April
SLOOS about changes to CRE lending policies and demand over the past year reported
having eased lending terms, including offering lower spreads of loan rates over the cost of
funds and larger maximum loan sizes, across all three major CRE loan categories. Almost
all banks that eased CRE credit policies cited more aggressive competition from other
institutions as an important reason. Banks reporting weaker demand for CRE loans cited
shifts in borrowing to other credit sources and rising interest rates as prominent reasons.
Spreads on commercial mortgage-backed securities (CMBS) were little changed
over the intermeeting period and remained near their post-crisis lows. CMBS issuance has
continued to be strong through March, although the low volume of loans maturing in
coming quarters may reduce demand for refinancing (and hence issuance) going forward.

Credit conditions in municipal bond markets remained accommodative, on balance,
over the intermeeting period. Spreads on general obligation bonds over comparablematurity Treasury securities were roughly unchanged. Gross issuance of municipal bonds
in March recovered a bit from its low January and February levels but was still somewhat
below levels typically seen in March. The weak municipal bond issuance so far this year
likely is a consequence of very high December issuance, which was driven by concern that
pending tax legislation would remove the tax-exempt status of private activity bonds. (The
final legislation did not alter the tax status of such bonds.)

Page 67 of 126

Financing Conditions

MUNICIPAL GOVERNMENT FINANCING CONDITIONS

Authorized for Public Release
Household Finance

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Mortgage Rate and MBS Yield

Purchase and Refinance Activity
Percent

Daily

Mar.
FOMC

6.0
5.5

30-year conforming
fixed mortgage rate

5.0
4.5
Apr.
18

4.0
3.5
3.0
2.5

MBS yield

2.0
1.5

2014

2015

2016

April 20, 2018

2017

700

Thousands of originations

Thousands of originations

Monthly

600

2000

500

Home purchase
(left scale)

1500

400

Feb.

1000

Refinance
(right scale)

300
200

Mar.

100

2018

2006

2009

2012

2015

2018

Note: The mortgage-backed securities (MBS) yield is the Fannie Mae 30-year
current-coupon rate.
Source: For MBS yield, Barclays; for mortgage rate, Optimal Blue.

Note: The data are seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve Board staff.
Source: For values prior to 2017, data reported under the Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act of 1975; for values in and after 2017, staff estimates.

Maximum Allowed Debt-Service-to-Income
Ratio for Residential Morgages

Consumer Credit Flows

Quarterly

Billions of dollars

90

Monthly rate

80
FICO >= 720

Student loans
Auto loans
Credit cards

70

Q1

20
H1 Q3

Jan.
Feb.

2006

2010

2014

10

40

5

30

0

20

-5

10

-10
-15

2018

2008

Changes in Standards for Consumer Loans
Jan.
survey

Quarterly
Tightening

Credit card
Auto

100
80
60

Easing

2014

2015

2016

2017

2014

2016

Percent

16

2018

0

13

-20

12

Percent
Mar.
FOMC

Credit cards (left scale)
New auto loans (right scale)

15

20

-60

2013

17

14

-40

2012

2012

Consumer Interest Rates

40

2011

2010

Note: The data are seasonally adjusted by Federal Reserve Board staff.
Source: Federal Reserve Board.

Source: For frontiers shown with circles, McDash and CoreLogic; for frontiers
shown with solid lines, Optimal Blue.

Net percent

15

50

0
2002

30
25

Q4

60
FICO <= 620

500
0

2003

DTI ratio

2500

Apr. 1

6.0
5.5
5.0

Q1

4.5
4.0

11

-80

10

-100

9

2018

3.5
3.0
2012

Note: Banks' responses are weighted by their sizes in the relevant loan
categories.
Source: Federal Reserve Board, Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on
Bank Lending Practices.

Page 68 of 126

2013

2014

2015

2016

2017

2018

Note: Credit card data reflect rates at commercial banks on all credit card
plans; data are reported quarterly and not seasonally adjusted. Auto loans
data are reported weekly and seasonally adjusted.
Source: For credit cards, Federal Reserve Board; for auto loans, J.D.
Power.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

HOUSEHOLD FINANCING CONDITIONS
Residential Real Estate
Financing conditions in the residential mortgage market remained accommodative
for most borrowers. For borrowers with low credit scores, conditions have continued to
ease. For example, the maximum debt-service-to-income ratio that low-score mortgage
borrowers can obtain has risen steadily for the past several years. However, credit still
remains relatively tight for these borrowers, and the volume of mortgage loans extended to
this group remains low. For the overall mortgage market, rates on 30-year conforming
mortgages edged down about 5 basis points since the March FOMC, roughly in line with
yields on longer-term Treasury securities. However, mortgage rates remained around
60 basis points higher than in December and more than 100 basis points higher than in the
fall of 2016. Consistent with these higher rates, refinancing activity continues to be muted,
and the growth in mortgages for home purchases has slowed over the past year. Banks
responding to the April SLOOS reported weaker demand across most residential real estate
(RRE) loan categories, while standards were reportedly about unchanged for most RRE
loan types.

Consumer Credit
Financing conditions for consumer credit have, on balance, remained supportive of
growth in household spending. However, some indicators continue to point to a tightening
trend in the past several quarters.

Respondents to the April SLOOS continued to report tighter standards and terms on
auto loans at banks as well as weaker demand. That said, across all lenders, growth in auto
loan balances remained solid over the past few months, although originations of auto loans
to consumers with nonprime credit scores appeared to continue to shrink. In addition,
evidence from the Michigan survey suggests that only a modest share of consumers cited
tightening credit conditions or rising interest rates as factors discouraging car purchases.
Page 69 of 126

Financing Conditions

Growth in consumer loan balances has moderated from the more rapid pace seen
late last year. In particular, credit card loan growth slowed significantly in early 2018 after
growing briskly in the fourth quarter of 2017. Indeed, respondents to the April SLOOS
reported that standards and terms on credit card loans tightened further, and demand for
these loans weakened in the first quarter. In addition, interest rates on credit card accounts
continued to trend up, reflecting in part pass-through from tightening monetary policy.
Nonetheless, on balance, credit card debt remained readily available to prime-rated
borrowers but tight for subprime borrowers.

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

(This page is intentionally blank.)

Page 70 of 126

April 20, 2018

April 20, 2018

Risks and Uncertainty
ASSESSMENT OF RISKS
As in the March Tealbook, we view the uncertainty around our forecast of
economic activity as being in line with the average over the past 20 years, the benchmark
used by the FOMC. Although financial market volatility remains elevated—reportedly
reflecting, in part, uncertainty about trade policy—uncertainty about fiscal policy has
diminished with the enactment of the appropriations bill that funds government
operations through September.
We continue to judge the risks around our projection for real GDP growth as
being balanced. On the upside, recent fiscal policy changes could lead to a greater
expansion in economic activity than expected in the baseline. On the downside, given
that the economy is already operating above its potential level and resource utilization is
projected to tighten further, those fiscal policy changes could provide less impetus to the
economy than assumed in the baseline. Similarly, we see the risks around our
unemployment rate forecast as balanced. Although we assume, with the economy
operating above the level associated with full employment, that the unemployment rate
will decline a bit less than would be expected given the rise in the output gap, the shift
toward other margins of resource utilization could be greater than we anticipate.
Alternatively, it is possible that the unemployment rate will exhibit a more typical
relationship with the output gap—or decline even more if the high-pressure economy
leads to a further reduction in the natural rate of unemployment.
Consistent with our judgmental assessment, estimates of the distribution of risks
around our GDP and unemployment rate forecasts conditional on available indicators,
shown in the exhibit “Time-Varying Macroeconomic Risk,” are not particularly wide or
skewed. Indeed, one important source of downside risk to real activity has diminished
significantly in recent years: As presented in the exhibit “Effective Lower Bound Risk
Estimate,” stochastic simulations around the baseline path in the FRB/US model indicate
that the risk of returning to the effective lower bound (ELB) sometime over the next three
years is only about 9 percent. If the ELB risk were computed around the median federal
funds rate path from the FOMC’s March SEP, the estimated probability would be
17 percent.

Page 71 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Risks & Uncertainty

Time-Varying Macroeconomic Risk
Unemployment Rate

Percent

90%
70%
50%

6

April 2018

5

95th

0.4

4

85th

0.2

2

50th

-0.2

1

15th

-0.6

5th

-0.9

3

0
-1
-2
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

GDP Growth

2015

Percent

April 2018

4
2

95th

1.9

0

85th

1.2

-2

50th

0.1

-4

15th

-1.0

-6

5th

-1.7

-8
1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

CPI Inflation

1990

1995

2000

2005

2015

Percent

2010

7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
-2
-3

April 2018
95th

1.8

85th

1.2

50th

0.1

15th

-0.8

5th

-1.3

2015

Note: The exhibit shows estimates of quantiles of the distribution of errors for four-quarter-ahead staff
forecasts. The estimates are conditioned on indicators of real activity, inflation, financial market strain,
and the volatility of high-frequency macroeconomic indicators. The tables show selected quantiles of the
predictive distributions for the respective variables as of the current Tealbook. Dashed lines denote the
median 15ᵗʰ and 85ᵗʰ percentiles. Gray shaded bars indicate recession periods as defined by the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
Page 72 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Effective Lower Bound Risk Estimate

ELB Risk since Liftoff
Percent

50

40

Current-quarter ELB risk = 9%
30

20

10

0
Jan. 2016

Apr. 2016

July 2016

Nov. 2016

Feb. 2017

May 2017

July 2017

Nov. 2017

Jan. 2018

May 2018

ELB Risk over the Projection Period
Percent

20

15

10

5

0
2018:Q2

2018:Q4

2019:Q2

2019:Q4

2020:Q2

2020:Q4

Note: The figures show the probability that the federal funds rate reaches the effective lower
bound (ELB) over the next 3 years starting in the given quarter. Details behind the computation of
the ELB risk measure are provided in the box "A Guidepost for Dropping the Effective Lower
Bound Risk from the Assessment of Risks" in the Risks and Uncertainty section of the April 2017
Tealbook A. The lower panel computes ELB risk over a forward-looking moving 3-year window
using stochastic simulations in FRB/US beginning in the current quarter. The simulations are
computed around the Tealbook baseline.

Page 73 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

With regard to inflation, we still see average uncertainty and balanced risks
around our projection. With the estimated 12-month change in core PCE prices having
moved up to 1.9 percent in March, the risk that last year’s softness in inflation could
prove to be more persistent than we assumed has abated somewhat. However, there is
still a risk that the inflation expectations relevant for wage and price setting could
currently be lower than in the baseline or may not edge up in the coming years as we
have assumed. To the upside, with the economy projected to be moving further above its
long-run potential, inflation may increase more than in the staff forecast, consistent with
the predictions of models that emphasize nonlinear effects of economic slack on inflation.
Our judgmental assessments of typical uncertainty and balanced risks are consistent with
the statistical estimates of the time-varying risks for the inflation forecast.
Our view of the risks to the economic outlook is informed by the staff’s quarterly
quantitative surveillance (QS) assessment, which judges the overall financial
vulnerabilities in the United States and overseas to be moderate. Vulnerabilities from
leverage in the U.S. financial system, as well as from liquidity and maturity
transformation, appear low; in particular, banks are highly capitalized and hold
substantial amounts of high-quality liquid assets. However, asset valuation pressures in
the U.S. are elevated despite easing since early February’s period of increased market
volatility, and they also appear stretched in a number of foreign economies. In addition,
there are some potential sources of vulnerability in the U.S. nonfinancial corporate
business sector. In particular, corporate debt relative to nominal GDP is at the upper end
of historical experience and risk premiums on corporate bonds are compressed relative to
their average since the mid-1990s.

ALTERNATIVE SCENARIOS
To illustrate some of the risks to the outlook, we construct alternatives to the
baseline projection using simulations of staff models. The first scenario illustrates the
outcomes of a recession in which the effects are amplified by leverage constraints on
financial intermediaries that curtail the supply of credit. The second scenario examines
the negative consequences of supply constraints that could arise when labor markets are
very tight for an extended period. In contrast, in the third scenario, running the economy
“hot” for a while leads to persistent positive effects on the productive capacity of the
economy—a form of “positive hysteresis.” In the fourth scenario, we illustrate a
downside risk to inflation associated with the possibility that households and businesses

Page 74 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

have lower inflation expectations than in the baseline because they perceive that
monetary policy will be too tight to sustainably return inflation to the FOMC’s 2 percent
objective over the medium term. In the fifth scenario, we consider the possibility that
faster tightening in U.S. monetary policy, prompted by a pickup in inflation, leads to
financial turbulence in vulnerable emerging market economies and a stronger
appreciation of the dollar. The sixth and last scenario analyzes the effect of stronger
foreign growth and a weaker dollar.
We simulate each of these scenarios using one of five staff models that embed
different macroeconomic structures and dynamics.1 (For a discussion of forecast errors
over the past year from two staff models, see the box “FRB/US and EDO Forecast
Errors” at the end of this section.) In all scenarios, the federal funds rate is governed by
the same policy rule as in the baseline. In addition, the size and composition of the
SOMA portfolio are assumed to follow the baseline paths in all of the scenarios.

Financial-Based Recession [Gertler, Karadi Model]2
The last three QS reports have highlighted that asset valuations are elevated and
that leverage in the nonfinancial business sector is an area of potential vulnerability,
although overall financial vulnerabilities are judged to be moderate and commercial
banks are well capitalized. In this scenario, we move beyond regulated deposit-taking
institutions and consider risks to the intermediation sector, including shadow banks. We
assume that there is a correction in asset prices that reduces intermediaries’ capital, which
tightens leverage constraints and further disrupts the supply of credit. In addition, this

The five models used are: (1) a version of the model by Mark L. Gertler and Peter Karadi
(2011), “A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 58 (1),
pp. 17–34; (2) a calibrated New Keynesian DSGE model with search and matching frictions in the labor
market similar to that described in Mark L. Gertler, Luca Sala, and Antonella Trigari (2008), “An
Estimated Monetary DSGE Model with Unemployment and Staggered Nominal Wage Bargaining,”
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 40 (8), pp. 1713–64; (3) an estimated medium-scale New
Keynesian DSGE model of the U.S. economy based on Marco Del Negro, Marc P. Giannoni, and Frank
Schorfheide (2015), “Inflation in the Great Recession and New Keynesian Models,” American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics, vol. 7 (January), pp. 168–96; (4) FRB/US, which is a large-scale
macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy; and (5) SIGMA, which is a calibrated multicountry DSGE
model.
2
In this scenario, the model is augmented with search and matching frictions in the labor market
as in Mark L. Gertler, Luca Sala, and Antonella Trigari (2008), “An Estimated Monetary DSGE Model
with Unemployment and Staggered Nominal Wage Bargaining,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
vol. 40 (8), pp. 1713–64.
1

Page 75 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Alternative Scenarios
Risks & Uncertainty

(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

2018

Measure and scenario
H1

2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

H2

Real GDP
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial-based recession
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations
Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

2.3
1.8
2.3
2.3
1.8
2.2
2.3

2.9
.7
2.9
2.9
2.7
2.1
3.3

2.6
.5
2.8
2.9
2.7
1.1
3.1

2.1
2.7
2.0
2.5
2.1
1.6
2.3

1.5
1.5
.8
2.0
1.5
1.8
1.3

1.0
.8
.7
1.3
1.0
1.5
.7

1.0
.9
.9
1.1
1.0
1.4
.8

Unemployment rate1
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial-based recession
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations
Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

4.0
4.0
4.1
4.0
4.1
4.0
4.0

3.6
4.1
3.9
3.6
3.7
3.7
3.5

3.3
6.7
3.9
3.2
3.4
4.0
3.0

3.3
4.9
3.9
3.1
3.4
4.3
2.8

3.5
4.3
4.2
3.1
3.5
4.4
3.0

3.8
4.4
4.5
3.4
3.8
4.5
3.4

4.1
4.7
4.8
3.8
4.1
4.6
3.7

Total PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial-based recession
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations
Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

2.5
2.5
2.6
2.5
2.3
2.6
2.6

1.7
1.5
2.2
1.7
1.3
2.3
2.2

1.9
1.7
2.9
1.9
1.6
2.3
2.5

2.0
1.9
3.1
2.0
1.6
2.2
2.3

2.0
1.9
2.9
2.1
1.7
2.2
2.2

2.1
2.0
2.8
2.1
1.8
2.2
2.2

2.1
2.0
2.8
2.1
1.8
2.2
2.2

Core PCE prices
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial-based recession
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations
Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

2.4
2.3
2.5
2.4
2.2
2.5
2.4

1.7
1.6
2.3
1.7
1.4
2.5
2.1

2.1
1.8
3.0
2.1
1.7
2.7
2.5

2.1
2.0
3.2
2.1
1.7
2.3
2.4

2.1
2.0
3.0
2.2
1.8
2.2
2.3

2.2
2.0
2.9
2.2
1.8
2.2
2.3

2.2
2.0
2.9
2.2
1.8
2.2
2.3

Federal funds rate1
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial-based recession
Supply constraints
Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations
Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8

2.6
2.3
2.5
2.6
2.4
3.0
2.8

3.8
.7
3.9
3.8
3.4
4.1
4.5

4.7
1.0
4.9
4.6
4.1
4.0
5.5

5.0
2.1
5.0
4.9
4.4
3.8
5.8

4.9
2.6
4.7
4.8
4.3
3.8
5.5

4.5
2.7
4.2
4.3
3.9
3.7
5.0

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 76 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

credit crunch is accompanied by a loss in confidence by businesses that is reflected in the
model by exogenous shocks to investment.
Under these circumstances, intermediaries’ net worth falls 20 percent and
corporate bond spreads increase 200 basis points during 2018. Investment drops
10 percent and GDP contracts at the end of this year and continues to fall until the end of
2019 before rebounding. The unemployment rate rises ½ percentage point above the
baseline at the end of 2018 and peaks at 7 percent in 2019 before slowly returning toward
the baseline. Inflation slows only a little relative to the baseline, because the Phillips
curve is flat and monetary policy provides substantial accommodation. Even under the
inertial Taylor rule assumed here, the federal funds rate decreases 2 percentage points in
response to the rapid increase in slack and comes within 25 basis points of the ELB.

Supply Constraints [Gertler, Sala, Trigari Model]
In the baseline projection, the unemployment rate declines to 3¼ percent by the
end of 2019 and remains below the staff’s estimate of the natural rate for a number of
years. However, with the economy operating so far above its potential, it is possible that
supply constraints will begin to emerge and that these constraints are not fully captured in
the baseline projection. In particular, when the unemployment rate is unusually low,
filling a vacancy becomes more difficult, which could imply a reduced pace of hiring and
a substantially steeper rise in wage growth. In this scenario, we illustrate these risks
using simulations from a nonlinear New Keynesian model with costly search and
matching frictions in the labor market.3 In this model, recruiting costs and wages are
higher when the unemployment rate is low because firms have to spend more time and
resources looking for workers and have to raise wages to attract them.
In such an environment, the unemployment rate stays roughly constant at
4 percent until the end of 2020, ½ percentage point above the baseline; thereafter, it
returns to its natural rate. GDP growth is close to the baseline until the end of 2020
because, in this model, more-intense utilization of capital compensates for the reduction
in labor input. Growth slows after 2020 as the unemployment rate rises toward its natural
3
See also Nicolas Petrosky-Nadeau and Lu Zhang (2017), “Solving the Diamond-MortensenPissarides Model Accurately,” Quantitative Economics, vol. 8 (2), pp. 611–50, who show that simulations
from a standard search-and-matching model deliver state-dependent responses to shocks: The
unemployment rate responds less to shocks when the initial state of the economy is “hot” compared to an
initial state with substantial labor market slack.

Page 77 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Forecast Confidence Intervals and Alternative Scenarios
Confidence Intervals Based on FRB/US Stochastic Simulations
Extended Tealbook baseline
Financial−based recession
Supply constraints

Positive hysteresis
Lower inflation expectations

Real GDP

Global tightening tantrum
Strong foreign growth and weaker dollar

Unemployment Rate
4−quarter percent change

Percent
5

7.0
6.5

4
6.0
3

5.5
5.0

2
4.5
70 percent
interval

1

4.0
3.5

0
3.0
−1

90 percent
interval

2.5
2.0

−2
1.5
−3
2017

2019

2021

1.0

2023

2017

PCE Prices excluding Food and Energy

2019

2021

2023

Federal Funds Rate

4−quarter percent change

Percent
4.5

9

4.0

8

3.5

7

3.0

6
5

2.5

4

2.0

3
1.5
2
1.0
1
0.5
0
0.0
2017

2019

2021

2023

2017

Page 78 of 126

2019

2021

2023

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

rate. Inflation is significantly higher because of stronger wage growth and peaks at
3¼ percent in 2020. Monetary policymakers are assumed to infer resource slack from the
unemployment rate, and consequently the federal funds rate is kept close to the baseline
as the effects of higher inflation and less tightness in the labor market are largely
offsetting.

Positive Hysteresis [FRB/US]
In contrast to the previous scenario, the hot labor market in the baseline projection
is assumed in this scenario to have persistent positive effects on the productive capacity
of the economy, a phenomenon often referred to as “positive hysteresis.” Specifically,
we assume that persistent exposure to a hot economy reduces exits from the labor force
and generates additional entrants, causing the trend labor force participation rate to rise
about 1 percentage point above the baseline by the end of 2023. Furthermore, we assume
that the experience that workers gain through greater employment lowers the natural rate
of unemployment ½ percentage point by the end of 2023. Both of these favorable
developments are assumed to be recognized in real time by monetary policymakers.4
In this scenario, potential output rises, on average, about ¼ percentage point more
per year over the projection period than in the baseline. This additional room to grow
allows real GDP growth to run at a similar increment above the baseline. As a result, the
output gap is little changed. The unemployment rate is close to the baseline until the end
of 2019 because increases in labor force participation offset gains in employment. After
2019, the unemployment rate follows a lower trajectory and is about ¼ percentage point
below the staff projection by 2023. With inflation and the output gap roughly at the
baseline, the federal funds rate is little changed.5

We modeled this alternative scenario by augmenting the usual specifications in FRB/US for the
natural rate of unemployment and the trend labor force participation rate with endogenous hysteresisgenerating components.
5
If we instead assumed that policymakers learn only slowly about the improvement in potential
output, the federal funds rate would follow a steeper trajectory than shown in this scenario, reaching
5¼ percent by the end of 2021. In that case, real GDP growth would be ¼ percentage point lower, on
average, between 2020 and 2023 than in this scenario, with the unemployment rate ¼ percentage point
higher than in this scenario. Inflation would still remain close to the baseline.
4

Page 79 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Selected Tealbook Projections and 70 Percent Confidence Intervals Derived
from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors and FRB/US Simulations
Measure
Real GDP
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Civilian unemployment rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices, total
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
PCE prices excluding
food and energy
(percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
Tealbook forecast errors
FRB/US stochastic simulations
Federal funds rate
(percent, Q4)
Projection
Confidence interval
FRB/US stochastic simulations

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.6

2.6

2.1

1.5

1.0

1.0

.9–4.2
1.8–3.6

.1–4.0
1.2–4.1

-.9–3.4
.5–3.6

...
-.2–3.1

...
-.7–2.8

...
-.8–2.8

3.6

3.3

3.3

3.5

3.8

4.1

3.1–4.1
3.1–3.9

2.5–4.2
2.4–4.0

2.1–4.7
2.2–4.3

...
2.2–4.7

...
2.4–5.2

...
2.7–5.6

2.1

1.9

2.0

2.0

2.1

2.1

1.3–2.6
1.4–2.6

1.1–3.5
.9–2.8

1.2–3.4
.9–3.0

...
.9–3.1

...
.9–3.2

...
.9–3.3

2.0

2.1

2.1

2.1

2.2

2.2

1.6–2.5
1.5–2.5

1.4–2.9
1.2–2.9

...
1.1–3.0

...
1.1–3.1

...
1.0–3.2

...
1.0–3.3

2.6

3.8

4.7

5.0

4.9

4.5

2.3–2.9

3.0–4.8

3.4–6.2

3.3–6.9

2.8–7.0

2.2–6.8

Note: Shocks underlying FRB/US stochastic simulations are randomly drawn from the 1969–2016 set of
model equation residuals. Intervals derived from Tealbook forecast errors are based on projections made
from 1980 to 2016 for real GDP and unemployment and from 1998 to 2016 for PCE prices. The intervals
for real GDP, unemployment, and total PCE prices are extended into 2020 using information from the
Blue Chip survey and forecasts from the CBO and CEA.
. . . Not applicable.

Page 80 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Prediction Intervals Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors

Q4 Level,
Percent

Unemployment Rate
Historical revisions

Tealbook forecasts

Augmented
Tealbook 1

median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
data/forecast
range

Q4/Q4,
Percent

PCE Inflation

13

Risks & Uncertainty

Historical
Distributions

Forecast Error Percentiles

4

11

3

9
2
7
1
5
0

3

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

1

2015

1980 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Real GDP Growth

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-1
1998 to 2017
Q4/Q4,
Percent

Core PCE Inflation

8

4

6

3

4
2
2
1
0
0

-2

2015

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-4

2015

1980 to 2017

2016

2017

2018

2019

2020

-1
1998 to 2017

Historical Distributions
Unemployment Rate

PCE Inflation

Real GDP Growth

Annual, Percent
25
median
15% to 85%
5% to 95%
20
2.5% to 97.5%
range

Annual, Percent

Annual, Percent

20

16

12

12

12

8

8

4

4

0

0

-4

-4

-8

-8

-8

-12

-12

-12

0
-4

5
0
1980 to
2017

Annual, Percent

4

10

1930 to 1947 to
2017
2017

16

16

8

15

Core PCE Inflation

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1980 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

-16
1930 to 1947 to 1998 to
2017
2017
2017

Note: See the technical note in the appendix for more information on this exhibit.
1. Augmented Tealbook prediction intervals use 1- and 2-year-ahead forecast errors from Blue Chip, CBO, and CEA to extend the Tealbook prediction
intervals through 2020.

Page 81 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Lower Inflation Expectations [Del Negro, Giannoni, Schorfheide Model]
Headline inflation, as measured by the change in PCE prices, has been below the
Committee’s 2 percent objective for most of the past five years and averaged only about
1¼ percent during that period. In the baseline projection, we have assumed a small,
gradual rise in inflation expectations. However, in light of the persistently low inflation
of the past several years, there is a risk that the public perceives the stance of monetary
policy as being too tight to sustainably achieve the 2 percent objective. In this scenario,
we assume that current longer-run inflation expectations are ¼ percentage point lower
than in the baseline and remain that low for an extended period of time.
Lower inflation expectations cause actual inflation to run ¼ percentage point
below its baseline path during the simulation period. Consequently, the federal funds rate
increases less than in the baseline; even so, expected real interest rates are initially
slightly higher because inertia in the assumed policy rule prevents the federal funds rate
from adjusting more rapidly. As a result, real GDP growth is a touch lower in 2018 than
in the baseline, and the unemployment rate runs slightly higher through 2023.

Global Tightening Tantrum [SIGMA]
In our baseline, we see the spillovers of ongoing U.S. policy tightening as likely
to be manageable for most foreign economies. However, there remains a significant risk
that faster U.S. policy tightening than investors expect could exert sizable disruptive
effects on global financial markets and the global economy. This scenario considers the
possibility that higher-than-expected U.S. inflation causes investors to quickly revise
their expectations about the stance of U.S. monetary policy, causing global bond term
premiums to rise and the prices of risky assets to decline, with pronounced adverse
spillovers especially to emerging market economies (EMEs).
Specifically, our scenario assumes that U.S. core PCE inflation runs at around
2½ percent through 2018 and prompts the FOMC to remove policy accommodation
somewhat faster than in the baseline.6 These developments boost term premiums on
longer-term government bonds as well as spreads on corporate bonds in both the United
States and abroad. Tighter global financial conditions weigh on foreign economies and
The scenario embeds transient monetary policy shocks, which allow for a somewhat faster initial
rise in the federal funds rate than implied by the inertial Taylor rule.
6

Page 82 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

progressively turn investor attention to underlying EME vulnerabilities, including
stretched asset valuations and elevated corporate debt levels in some economies. EMEs
experience large capital outflows and sizable depreciations of their currencies later this
year as declining confidence fuels an ongoing flight from EME assets. All told, foreign
GDP growth runs 1½ percentage points below the baseline in 2019, while the broad real
dollar appreciates by about 7 percent.
Weaker foreign activity, the appreciation of the dollar, and tighter financial
conditions restrain the pace of economic expansion in the United States. U.S. GDP
growth moderates to 1 percent in 2019, about 1½ percentage points less than in the
baseline. Core PCE inflation peaks at 2¾ percent in 2019 and then moves down toward
the 2 percent target. Starting in 2020, the federal funds rate edges down, falling below
the baseline path.

Stronger Foreign Growth and Weaker Dollar [SIGMA]
Over the past year, the dollar has fallen despite higher U.S. interest rates and
prospects for substantial U.S. fiscal stimulus. In part, this depreciation reflects solid
foreign growth and the anticipation of policy normalization abroad. Going forward, our
baseline forecast is for the dollar to appreciate, as the federal funds rate rises more steeply
than markets expect. However, it is possible that foreign growth will exceed expectations
and put further downward pressure on the dollar. In this scenario, we assume that foreign
GDP growth rises to about 3½ percent in 2018 and 2019, and thus averages about
¾ percentage point higher per year than under our baseline projection. Increased
optimism about the durability of the foreign expansion—and the perception of
diminished tail risks—cause the broad dollar to depreciate by 10 percent relative to
baseline by the end of 2019, reversing most of the rise in the dollar that began in
mid-2014.
U.S. real GDP expands around 3 percent in 2019, about ½ percentage point more
than in the baseline, as the weaker dollar and stronger foreign growth boost U.S. real net
exports. The unemployment rate falls to 2¾ percent by the end of 2020. Higher import
prices and heightened resource pressures cause core PCE inflation to reach 2½ percent in
2019. The federal funds rate rises more quickly than in the baseline, increasing to
5½ percent by the end of 2020.

Page 83 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

FRB/US and EDO Forecast Errors
This discussion reports real‐time forecast errors for the FRB/US and EDO models over the
past four years and compares them with the errors in the judgmental Tealbook
projection. The forecast errors from the models are then decomposed into contributions
from the structural shocks inferred by the models to identify the key drivers of the
misses.
The figure reports the point forecasts and 70 percent confidence intervals of the
Tealbook projection and of the FRB/US and EDO model projections of real GDP growth,
the unemployment rate, and total and core PCE inflation for 2014 through 2017,
computed using the Tealbook and model forecasts as of the April Tealbook of the
corresponding year.

Page 84 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

In the figure, the gray bars represent the currently published data, the purple squares
and whisker bands show the real‐time forecasts and 70 percent confidence intervals of
FRB/US, the blue circles and whisker bands show the counterparts for EDO, and the
green triangles and whisker bands show the counterparts for the Tealbook forecasts.1
The FRB/US and EDO forecast errors are, on average, somewhat larger than the Tealbook
forecast errors, and neither model uniformly dominates the other one in forecasting
performance. Overall, like the Tealbook forecast, both models underpredicted real GDP
growth and overpredicted the unemployment rate in 2017, with the largest error for GDP
growth found in FRB/US and the largest error for the unemployment rate found in EDO.
These forecast errors are within the 70 percent real‐time confidence intervals of these
models as indicated by the whisker bands. However, the realized unemployment rate is
located very close to the lower bounds of the 70 percent confidence intervals of all the
forecasts, including the Tealbook projection.2
FRB/US did well in forecasting both total and core PCE inflation. From 2014 to 2017, its
root mean squared errors are 0.2 percentage point and 0.3 percentage point,
respectively, which are smaller than or equal to those of the EDO and Tealbook
projections. That said, both models viewed inflation as having been surprisingly weak in
2017 and to a greater extent than the judgmental projection, particularly in the case of
core inflation. It is notable that both models made forecast errors for core PCE inflation
outside of or very close to the lower bounds of the 70 percent confidence intervals.3
The FRB/US model attributes the higher‐than‐expected GDP growth in 2017 to stronger‐
than‐expected private spending and stronger foreign factors, such as a weaker dollar and
stronger net exports. The EDO model largely attributes the upward surprise in GDP
growth last year to a low risk premium and a somewhat stronger transient improvement
in productivity. Because the two sources of stronger GDP growth have opposite
implications for slack, the EDO model attributes the bulk of the forecast errors in both
total and core PCE inflation to “own” shocks in the non‐energy price equations; in other
words, the surprise could not primarily be explained by the forecast errors in other
conditioning variables such as slack. The FRB/US model also views the downside
surprises in inflation as originating directly from the price equations.

1 The confidence intervals for EDO and FRB/US are generated via stochastic simulations. For
FRB/US, the simulations sample from historical equation residuals. For EDO, they draw from the
distributions of shocks, model parameters, and latent state variables.
2 The improvement in the forecasting accuracy for unemployment in the EDO model in 2016 relative
to the two previous years is linked to a revision of the assumed steady‐state level of unemployment to
align it with the Tealbook assumptions about the natural rate of unemployment at that time.
3 Note that the staff had seen the very low March CPI by the time of the April Tealbook in 2017, even
though the PCE prices for March were not themselves published yet, so that information was built into
the Tealbook projection. While the staff took on board the implication of the weak incoming data for
the second quarter core PCE inflation, the models did not, which could be one source of the larger
model forecast errors for core PCE inflation.

Page 85 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Assessment of Key Macroeconomic Risks

Probability of Inflation Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the 4-quarter change in total
PCE prices will be . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Greater than 3 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.06
.05

.07
.05

.05
.04

.09
.07

Less than 1 percent
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.13
.19

.10
.15

.06
.09

.12
.15

Probability of Unemployment Events
(4 quarters ahead)
Probability that the unemployment rate
will . . .

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Increase by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.00
.00

.02
.01

.16
.20

.06
.06

Decrease by 1 percentage point
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

.35
.45

.04
.07

.05
.03

.02
.03

Probability of Near-Term Recession
Probability that real GDP declines in
the next two quarters
Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

Staff

FRB/US

EDO

BVAR

Factor
Model

.01
.00

.02
.02

.05
.06

.05
.04

.02
.00

Note: “Staff” represents stochastic simulations in FRB/US around the staff baseline; baselines for FRB/US, BVAR, EDO, and
the factor model are generated by those models themselves, up to the current-quarter estimate. Data for the current quarter are
taken from the staff estimate for the second Tealbook in each quarter; if the second Tealbook for the current quarter has not yet
been published, the preceding quarter is taken as the latest historical observation.

Page 86 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Appendix
Technical Note on “Prediction Intervals Derived from
Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors”
This technical note provides additional details about the exhibit “Prediction Intervals
Derived from Historical Tealbook Forecast Errors.” In the four large fan charts, the black dotted
lines show staff projections and current estimates of recent values of four key economic variables:
average unemployment rate in the fourth quarter of each year and the Q4/Q4 percent change for
real GDP, total PCE prices, and core PCE prices. (The GDP series is adjusted to use GNP for
those years when the staff forecast GNP and to strip out software and intellectual property
products from the currently published data for years preceding their introduction. Similarly, the
core PCE inflation series is adjusted to strip out the “food away from home” component for years
before it was included in core.)
The historical distributions of the corresponding series (with the adjustments described
above) are plotted immediately to the right of each of the fan charts. The thin black lines show
the highest and lowest values of the series during the indicated time period. At the bottom of the
page, the distributions over three different time periods are plotted for each series. To enable the
use of data for years prior to 1947, we report annual-average data in this section. The annual data
going back to 1930 for GDP growth, PCE inflation, and core PCE inflation are available in the
conventional national accounts; we used estimates from Lebergott (1957) for the unemployment
rate from 1930 to 1946.1
The prediction intervals around the current and one-year-ahead forecasts are derived from
historical staff forecast errors, comparing staff forecasts with the latest published data. For the
unemployment rate and real GDP growth, errors were calculated for a sample starting in 1980,
yielding percentiles of the sizes of the forecast errors. For PCE and core PCE inflation, errors
based on a sample beginning in 1998 were used. This shorter range reflects both more limited
data on staff forecasts of PCE inflation and the staff judgment that the distribution of inflation
since the mid-1990s is more appropriate for the projection period than distributions of inflation
reaching further back. In all cases, the prediction intervals are computed by adding the percentile
bands of the errors onto the forecast. The blue bands encompass 70 percent prediction-interval
ranges; adding the green bands expands this range to 90 percent. The dark blue line plots the
median of the prediction intervals. There is not enough historical forecast data to calculate
meaningful 90 percent ranges for the two inflation series. A median line above the staff forecast
means that forecast errors were positive more than half of the time.

Stanley Lebergott (1957), “Annual Estimates of Unemployment in the United States,
1900–1954,” in National Bureau of Economic Research, The Measurement and Behavior of Unemployment
(Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press), pp. 213–41.
1

Page 87 of 126

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Risks & Uncertainty

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Because the staff has produced two-year-ahead forecasts for only a few years, the
intervals around the two-year-ahead forecasts are constructed by augmenting the staff projection
errors with information from outside forecasters: the Blue Chip consensus, the Council of
Economic Advisers, and the Congressional Budget Office. Specifically, we calculate prediction
intervals for outside forecasts in the same manner as for the staff forecasts. We then calculate the
change in the error bands from outside forecasts from one year ahead to two years ahead and
apply the average change to the staff’s one-year-ahead error bands. That is, we assume that any
deterioration in the performance between the one- and two-year-ahead projections of the outside
forecasters would also apply to the Tealbook projections. Limitations on the availability of data
mean that a slightly shorter sample is used for GDP and unemployment, and the outside
projections may only be for a similar series, such as total CPI instead of total PCE prices or
annual growth rates of GDP instead of four-quarter changes. In particular, because data on
forecasts for core inflation by these outside forecasters are much more limited, we did not
extrapolate the staff’s errors for core PCE inflation two years ahead.
The intervals around the historical data in the four fan charts are based on the history of
data revisions for each series. The previous-year, two-year-back, and three-year-back values as
of the current Tealbook forecast are subtracted from the corresponding currently published
estimates (adjusted as described earlier) to produce revisions, which are then combined into
distributions and revision intervals in the same way that the prediction intervals are created.

Page 88 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Monetary Policy Strategies
In this section, we discuss a range of strategies for setting the federal funds rate
and compare the associated interest rate paths and macroeconomic outcomes with those
in the Tealbook baseline projection. In the near term, the revisions to the strategies’
prescriptions are small. Over the medium term, the Tealbook baseline projection features
slightly lower levels of resource utilization and inflation than the projection made in
March; consequently, all strategies call for lower policy rates during coming years than
their counterparts in the previous Tealbook. A special exhibit reports the prescriptions of
several flexible price-level targeting rules.

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED SIMPLE POLICY RULES
The top panel of the first exhibit shows near-term prescriptions for the federal
funds rate from four policy rules: the Taylor (1999) rule (also known as the “balanced
approach” rule), the Taylor (1993) rule, a first-difference rule, and a nominal income
targeting (NIT) rule. These near-term prescriptions take as given the staff’s baseline
projections for the output gap and core inflation, shown by the black lines in the middle
panels. The top and middle panels also provide the staff’s baseline path for the federal
funds rate, which is constructed using an inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule. 1
•

The near-term prescriptions of the Taylor (1999) and the Taylor (1993) rules
are about unchanged from their March Tealbook levels because the effects of
the staff’s small downward revision to the output gap offset those of the
staff’s modest upward revision to inflation in coming quarters.

•

The prescriptions of the Taylor (1999) and Taylor (1993) rules, which do not
feature interest rate smoothing terms, remain well above the corresponding
policy rates in the Tealbook baseline.

We provide details on each of these simple rules in the appendix to this section. Except for the
first-difference rule, which has no intercept term, the simple rules examined here use intercept terms that
are consistent with a real federal funds rate of 50 basis points in the longer run.
1

Page 89 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Policy Rules and the Staff Projection
Near−Term Prescriptions of Selected Simple Policy Rules1

Monetary Policy Strategies

(Percent)

2018:Q2

2018:Q3

Taylor (1999) rule
Previous Tealbook

4.12
4.14

4.57
4.67

Taylor (1993) rule
Previous Tealbook

3.30
3.23

3.60
3.58

First−difference rule
Previous Tealbook projection

1.94
2.04

2.38
2.57

Nominal income targeting rule
Previous Tealbook projection

1.52
1.52

1.64
1.65

Addendum:
Tealbook baseline

1.81

2.22

*
Key Elements of the Staff Projection
Federal Funds Rate

PCE Prices ex. Food and Energy

GDP Gap
Percent

Percent
4

7

Current Tealbook
Previous Tealbook

4−quarter change

Percent
3.0

6
5

3

2.5

2

2.0

1

1.5

4
3
2
1

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

0

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

0

2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023

A Medium−Term Notion of the Equilibrium Real Federal Funds Rate2
(Percent)

Current
Value

Current−Quarter Estimate
Based on Previous Tealbook

Previous
Tealbook

Tealbook baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

3.40
1.53

3.83
1.71

3.62
1.45

SEP−consistent baseline
FRB/US r*
Average projected real federal funds rate

1.49
.61

*
1. For rules that have a lagged policy rate as a right−hand−side variable, the lines denoted "Previous Tealbook projection"
report prescriptions based on the previous Tealbook's staff outlook for inflation and the output gap, but conditional on the
current−Tealbook value of the lagged policy rate.
2. The "FRB/US r*" is the level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12−quarter period (beginning in the
current quarter) in the FRB/US model, sets the output gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period given either the
Tealbook or SEP−consistent projection. The SEP−consistent baseline corresponds to the March 2018 median SEP
responses. The "Average projected real federal funds rate" is calculated under the Tealbook and SEP−consistent baseline
projections over the same 12−quarter period as FRB/US r*.
Page 90 of 126

1.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

The prescriptions of the first-difference rule are a bit lower than in March
because the output gap is now projected to widen at a slower rate over the
coming year.

•

Under the NIT rule, the federal funds rate responds to the output gap and the
shortfall of the GDP price deflator from the level it would have attained had it
increased at an annual rate of 2 percent since the end of 2011; the shortfall in
the GDP price deflator in coming quarters is about 2¼ percent. Unlike the
other rules and the Tealbook baseline policy, which call for raising the federal
funds rate in the near term, the NIT rule, in an effort to eliminate the shortfall
in the GDP price deflator, prescribes a level for the federal funds rate in the
second and third quarters that remains within the current target range.

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL
FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the first exhibit reports estimates of a medium-term concept
of the equilibrium real federal funds rate generated under two baselines: the Tealbook
baseline and a projection consistent with the medians in the March 2018 Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). 2 In both cases, simulations of the FRB/US model are used
to generate an estimate of r*. The r*concept, labeled “FRB/US r*,” corresponds to the
level of the real federal funds rate that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period starting in
the current quarter, would bring the output gap to zero in the final quarter of that period.
This concept of r* is a summary of the projected underlying strength of the real
economy; because it is based on a single criterion, it does not take into account other
considerations, such as achieving the inflation objective or avoiding sharp changes in the
federal funds rate.
•

At a bit under 3½ percent, the estimate of Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r* in
this quarter is almost ½ percentage point below the corresponding value
computed using information from the March Tealbook. The downward
revision reflects the fact that the projected output gap in the current Tealbook

To construct a baseline projection consistent with median SEP responses for the FRB/US model,
the staff interpolated annual SEP information to a quarterly frequency and assumed that, beyond 2020 (the
final year reported in the March 2018 SEP), the economy transitions to the longer-run values in a smooth
and monotonic way. The staff also posited economic relationships to project variables not covered in the
SEP. For example, the staff assumed an Okun’s law relationship to recover an output gap from the
deviation of the median SEP unemployment rate from the median SEP estimate of its longer-run value.
2

Page 91 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

is a bit more than ¼ percentage point lower, on average, through 2021 than in
the March Tealbook.
•

At about 1½ percent, the SEP-consistent FRB/US r* is significantly lower
than the Tealbook-consistent FRB/US r*. The difference stems from the fact
that the SEP-consistent projection has output exceeding potential by a
considerably smaller amount over the medium term than does the current
Tealbook forecast. This smaller anticipated output gap occurs despite the fact

Monetary Policy Strategies

that the median path for the real federal funds rate implied by SEP projections
averages almost 1 percentage point lower than the corresponding path in the
Tealbook.

SIMPLE POLICY RULE SIMULATIONS
The second exhibit reports results from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model under the Taylor (1999) rule, the Taylor (1993) rule, the first-difference rule, and
the NIT rule. These simulations reflect the endogenous responses of the output gap and
inflation to the different federal funds rate paths implied by the policy rules. 3 The
simulations for each rule are carried out under the assumptions that policymakers commit
to following the prescriptions of that rule in the future and that financial market
participants, price setters, and wage setters anticipate that monetary policy will follow
through on this commitment and are aware of the implications for interest rates and the
macroeconomy. 4 The exhibit also reports the extended Tealbook baseline projection.
•

Under the Tealbook baseline, the federal funds rate rises to about 2½ percent
by the end of this year. Over the subsequent two years, it increases by about
1 percentage point per year, bringing the rate close to 4¾ percent in the fourth
quarter of 2020.

•

The Taylor (1999) rule calls for an immediate and substantial increase in the
federal funds rate, and the prescribed values remain above the corresponding

Because of the endogenous responses of the output gap and inflation to the different federal
funds rate paths, the near-term prescriptions from the dynamic simulations can differ from those shown in
the top panel of the first exhibit.
4
In generating these simulations, we assume that the public immediately and correctly
understands the implications of the FOMC adopting a particular policy strategy. In the real world, the
adoption of a particular policy strategy by the FOMC might well entail a period during which the public
learns the new strategy and its macroeconomic implications. We abstract from considerations of this kind.
3

Page 92 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Tealbook baseline values through early 2022. This higher path is associated
with only a modestly higher trajectory for the real 10-year Treasury yield than
in the baseline through the middle of 2020, as the Taylor (1999) rule calls for
somewhat lower values of the federal funds rate for a sustained period later in
the simulation period. Because wage and price setting today is influenced by
expected future outcomes in FRB/US, current inflation is a touch higher as a
result of the somewhat more accommodative policy stance later in the
simulation relative to the Tealbook baseline projection. The resulting path for
the unemployment rate lies above the Tealbook baseline path over the next
few years, but subsequently takes a bit longer to return to its natural rate.
•

The Taylor (1993) rule also calls for an immediate sharp increase in the
federal funds rate. Because the Taylor (1993) rule responds less strongly to
projected output exceeding its assumed potential level, the prescriptions of
this rule are lower than those of the Taylor (1999) rule over the period shown,
though they are higher than the Tealbook baseline over the next two years.
Starting in the fourth quarter of 2020, the path for the federal funds rate falls
below the baseline path for a sustained period. As a result, current inflation is
higher, and the real 10-year Treasury yield is lower, than their corresponding
values in the Tealbook projection. The more accommodative conditions
engender a more pronounced undershooting of the unemployment rate below
its natural rate beyond the medium term.

•

The path for the federal funds rate prescribed by the first-difference rule is
somewhat above the path in the Tealbook baseline through early 2020 but
runs below the baseline path for some years thereafter. The latter divergence
occurs because the first-difference rule, which responds to the expected
change in the output gap rather than to its level, reacts to projected output
exceeding its assumed potential level by progressively smaller amounts
beyond the next three years. The associated lower path of the federal funds
rate, in conjunction with expectations of higher inflation in the future, implies
lower longer-term real interest rates than in the Tealbook baseline and
therefore higher levels of resource utilization and inflation. Thus, the firstdifference rule generates outcomes for the unemployment rate that are lower,
and outcomes for inflation that are higher, than the corresponding outcomes in
the Tealbook baseline projection.

Page 93 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Simple Policy Rule Simulations
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
8

Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
First−difference rule
Nominal income targeting rule
Tealbook baseline

5.5

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
7
5.0

6
5

4.5
4

Monetary Policy Strategies

3
4.0
2
1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
4

2.5

3
2017

2
1

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

0

2.5

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
3.0

2.5

2.0
1.5
1.5

1.0

0.5

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

0.0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Note: The policy rule simulations in this exhibit are based on rules that respond to core inflation rather than to
headline inflation. This choice of rule specification was made in light of a tendency for current and near−term core
inflation rates to outperform headline inflation rates as predictors of the medium−term behavior of headline inflation.

Page 94 of 126

1.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

•

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

The NIT rule seeks to compensate for the cumulative shortfall of inflation (as
measured by the rate of increase in the GDP price deflator) from an annual
rate of 2 percent since the end of 2011. Compared with the Tealbook
baseline, the NIT rule calls for a markedly slower pace of increases in the
federal funds rate in order to generate a somewhat higher rate of inflation in
coming years and thereby gradually undo the 2¼ percent cumulative shortfall
of inflation from 2 percent since the end of 2011. Because the simulation
embeds the assumptions that policymakers can credibly commit to closing this
gap and that financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters
correctly anticipate the ensuing long period of low federal funds rates, the
path of the real 10-year Treasury rate is lower than under the other policy
rules and the Tealbook baseline for several years. Accordingly, the path for
the unemployment rate is substantially lower than in the Tealbook baseline
and all other simulations shown, dropping to 2¾ percent in 2021.

•

Relative to the March Tealbook, the prescriptions of the simple rules are
between ¼ and ½ percentage point lower by the end of 2021 because of the
lower projected path of the output gap.

OPTIMAL CONTROL SIMULATIONS UNDER COMMITMENT
The third exhibit displays optimal control simulations under various assumptions
about policymakers’ preferences, as captured by four specifications of the loss function. 5
The concept of optimal control employed here corresponds to a commitment policy under
which the plans that policymakers make today constrain future policy choices; such a
constraint may result in improved economic outcomes. 6
Three of the four optimal control policies prescribe much higher paths for the
federal funds rate than the path in the baseline staff projection, for two reasons. First,
high levels of the real federal funds rate are necessary to push the unemployment rate up
to its natural rate, because in the FRB/US model, the unemployment rate does not
The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the Monetary Policy Strategies section of
the June 2016 Tealbook B offers motivations for these specifications. The appendix in this Tealbook
section provides technical details on the optimal control simulations.
6
Under the optimal control policies, policymakers achieve the displayed economic outcomes by
making promises that bind future policymakers to take actions that will not be optimal from the perspective
of those future policymakers (that is, the promises are time inconsistent). It is assumed that these promises
are taken as credible by wage and price setters and by financial market participants.
5

Page 95 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
5.5

18

Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Tealbook baseline

Staff's estimate of the natural rate

16
14

5.0

12
10

4.5

Monetary Policy Strategies

8
6

4.0

4
2
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

3.5

0
3.0

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
10

2.5

8
2017

6
4
2

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.0

PCE Inflation
Percent

4−quarter average

2.5

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−2

2.0

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield
Percent
4

3

1.5
2

1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

0

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

1.0

Note: Each set of lines corresponds to an optimal control policy under commitment in which policymakers minimize a
discounted weighted sum of squared deviations of 4−quarter headline PCE inflation from the Committee's 2 percent objective,
of squared deviations of the unemployment rate from the staff's estimate of the natural rate, and of squared changes in the
federal funds rate. The weights vary across simulations. See the appendix for technical details and the box "Optimal Control
and the Loss Function" in the June 2016 Tealbook B for a motivation.
Page 96 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

respond strongly to changes in real interest rates, a feature that is consistent with recent
historical experience. Second, because monetary policy actions are assumed to be
understood and fully credible, the front-loading of policy tightening is not disruptive.
However, in practice, if the FOMC were to raise the real federal funds rate as high and as
quickly as prescribed by the first three optimal control policies, macroeconomic
outcomes could be less benign than shown here because of the confusion and financial
market disruption that such an abrupt change in policy might engender. 7 In contrast, the
fourth optimal control policy allows the unemployment rate to decline to levels last
experienced during the 1950s; such a development might also entail outcomes different
from those predicted by the simulations.
•

The first simulation, labeled “Equal weights,” presents the case in which
policymakers are assumed to place equal weights on keeping headline PCE
inflation close to the Committee’s 2 percent objective, on keeping the
unemployment rate close to the staff’s estimate of the natural rate of
unemployment, and on keeping the federal funds rate close to its previous
value. Under this strategy, the path for the federal funds rate is significantly
higher than the Tealbook baseline path in order to temper the projected sizable
undershooting by the unemployment rate of its natural rate over the next
several years in the Tealbook baseline—an outcome that policymakers with
the equal-weights loss function judge to be costly. 8 The small projected
deviations of inflation from 2 percent in the Tealbook baseline entail
relatively small losses and so have little influence on optimal policy.
Moreover, a relatively rapid closing of the unemployment gap generates only
slightly lower inflation because, in the FRB/US model, the reaction of
inflation to the level of resource utilization is limited.

•

The second simulation, “Large weight on inflation gap,” is based on a loss
function that assigns a cost to deviations of inflation from 2 percent that is five
times larger than the specification with equal weights but is otherwise

The simulation results hinge on the assumptions that agents in the model have perfect foresight
and are certain that policymakers will implement the prescribed path for the federal funds rate. While these
assumptions may be reasonable approximations under some circumstances, they may not be valid for
historically extreme changes in the federal funds rate, particularly those prescribed by the optimal control
exercise that places only a minimal penalty on adjustments in the federal funds rate.
8
When we use the March 2018 SEP-consistent baseline as the underlying projection, the federal
funds rate under the optimal control simulation with equal weights peaks at around 5 percent, compared
with about 8 percent under the Tealbook baseline.
7

Page 97 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

identical to that specification. The resulting optimal strategy is only
marginally more accommodative than in the “Equal weights” case, even
though the losses associated with undershooting the inflation objective are
larger in coming years. There are two reasons that the prescribed path for the
federal funds rate is not materially altered even though the weight on inflation
losses is substantially higher than in the “Equal weights” case. First, inflation
is already close to the Committee’s 2 percent objective, and, second, in the
FRB/US model, policymakers face an unappealing tradeoff because inflation

Monetary Policy Strategies

responds only weakly to resource utilization.
•

The third simulation, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” uses a loss
function that assigns only a very small cost to changes in the federal funds rate
but that is otherwise identical to the loss function with equal weights. This
simulation seeks to return the unemployment rate to its natural rate even faster
than under the equal-weights specification. As a result, the federal funds rate
soars to about 11½ percent at the end of 2018 and then averages around
7 percent from 2020 through 2023.

•

The fourth simulation, “Asymmetric weight on ugap,” uses a loss function
that assigns no cost to deviations of the unemployment rate from the natural
rate when the unemployment rate is below the natural rate, but the loss
function is identical to the specification with equal weights when the
unemployment rate is above the natural rate. Under this strategy, the path of
the federal funds rate is considerably below the path in the optimal control
simulation with equal weights and below the Tealbook baseline path
throughout the period shown. With the asymmetric loss function,
policymakers choose this initially more accommodative path for the policy
rate because their desire to raise inflation to 2 percent is not tempered by an
aversion to undershooting the natural rate of unemployment. The tighter labor
market helps bring inflation to 2 percent more quickly than in the case of
equal weights. Starting in the middle of the 2020s (not shown), the
unemployment rate runs a little above its natural rate for several years as
policymakers act to contain the inflationary pressures stemming from the
prolonged period of elevated resource utilization.

Page 98 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

ILLUSTRATING FLEXIBLE PRICE-LEVEL TARGETING RULES
The following pages discuss several monetary policy rules that target the price
level rather than the inflation rate. Price-level targeting rules aim to reverse deviations of
inflation from policymakers’ objective rather than letting “bygones be bygones.” Such
rules have been studied as a form of commitment to making up shortfalls of policy
accommodation following an episode when the policy rate was constrained by the lower
bound or, more generally, as a means for increasing the predictability of future price
levels. The NIT rule discussed earlier is an example of a flexible price-level targeting
(FPLT) rule that not only seeks to stabilize an aggregate price index around a target path
but also responds to a measure of resource slack. The nominal income gap can be
decomposed into the sum of a price gap (the difference between the output price index
and a target path) and the output gap; under the NIT rule, by design, equally sized
movements in these gaps call for the same adjustments in the federal funds rate. 9 In the
NIT rule simulation shown in the exhibits, the target path for prices is anchored in
2011:Q4, just before the Committee announced its 2 percent inflation objective, and
grows at a 2 percent annual rate thereafter. 10
Because it is derived from nominal GDP, the NIT rule uses a GDP-based price
measure for its price gap along with the output gap as its measure of real activity.
However, under FPLT rules, the interest rate could respond to other price indices or
measures of resource utilization. As an illustration, the fourth exhibit considers three
FPLT rules that respond to the price gap measured using core PCE prices and to the
unemployment rate gap. 11 The three FPLT rules vary in their response coefficients to the
price gap and the unemployment rate gap and in the reference date for their target path
for the price level. The first rule, “FPLT, large response to ugap (2011:Q4),” responds
twice as much to the unemployment rate gap as to the price gap, while the second rule,
“FPLT, equal responses,” reacts to both gaps in equal measure. As in the NIT rule, both
Under this implementation of the NIT rule, the target path of nominal GDP is adjusted for
changes in potential output growth. Nominal GDP targeting is sometimes understood as targeting a path
for nominal GDP that grows at a constant rate, in which case variations in potential output would call for
offsetting adjustments in inflation.
10
As shown in the appendix to this section, these assumptions imply that the price gap can be
expressed as the cumulative miss of output price inflation from 2 percent since the beginning of 2012.
11
The unemployment rate gap is defined as the unemployment rate minus the natural rate of
unemployment. The FPLT rules respond to this gap with a negative coefficient, so that when the
unemployment rate is higher (lower) than its natural rate, the FPLT rule prescribes a lower (higher)
interest rate.
9

Page 99 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Illustrating Flexible Price−Level Targeting Rules
Unemployment Rate

Nominal Federal Funds Rate

Percent

Percent
8

Nominal income targeting rule (2011:Q4)
FPLT, large response to ugap (2011:Q4)
FPLT, equal responses (2011:Q4)
FPLT, large response to ugap (2017:Q4)
Tealbook baseline

5.5

Staff's estimate of the natural rate
7

5.0

6
4.5
5
4.0
4
3.5

Monetary Policy Strategies

3
2

3.0

1

2.5

0
2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

2.0

PCE Inflation

Real Federal Funds Rate

Percent
4

Percent

4−quarter average

2.5

3
2

2.0

1
0

1.5

−1

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−2

Real 10−Year Treasury Yield

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2018

2019

2020

2021

1.0

Price−Level Gaps
Percent

2017

2023

2022

2023

Percent
3.0

1.0

2.5

0.5

2.0

0.0

1.5

−0.5

1.0

−1.0

0.5

−1.5

0.0

−2.0

−0.5

−2.5

−1.0

Page 100 of 126

2017

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

−3.0

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

of these FPLT rules seek to make up deviations in inflation from its 2 percent objective
since the beginning of 2012. 12 The third rule, “FPLT, large response to ugap (2017:Q4),”
reacts to the unemployment rate and price gaps as in the “FPLT, large response to ugap
(2011:Q4) rule,” but seeks to make up deviations in inflation from 2 percent only since
the beginning of this year. The panels in the fourth exhibit report results from dynamic
simulations of the FRB/US model under the FPLT rules, the NIT rule, and the Tealbook
baseline rule.
•

The economic outcomes under the “FPLT, large response to ugap (2011:Q4)”
rule are very close to those under the NIT rule because the initial price gaps
measured using core PCE prices and GDP prices are very similar, at about
2¼ percent, and because these two rules respond roughly equivalently to the
cyclical position of the economy. 13 Both FPLT rules call for a more gradual
increase in the federal funds rate than the Tealbook baseline projection.
Given a more accommodative policy—and because, in these simulations,
policymakers credibly commit to sustaining accommodation until the price
gap is significantly reduced—inflation increases immediately and runs higher
than in the Tealbook baseline for a number of years. Low real interest rates
also spur faster growth of economic activity, and the unemployment rate
undershoots the baseline projection by about ½ percentage point in 2021.

•

Under the “FPLT, equal responses (2011:Q4)” rule, the path for policy is even
more accommodative than the path under the “FPLT, large response to ugap
(2011:Q4)” rule because policymakers lean less strongly against the
unemployment rate undershooting its natural rate. As a result, inflation rises
and real activity booms, with the unemployment rate dropping to nearly
2¼ percent in 2021, about 1 percentage point below the baseline projection.
The price-level gap is closed notably more rapidly in this instance than under
the “FPLT, large response to ugap (2011:Q4)” rule.

•

The “FPLT, large response to ugap (2017:Q4)” rule prescribes a path for the
federal funds rate that is nearly identical to the Tealbook baseline path.

The appendix to this section details the calibration of the FPLT rules.
In particular, the FRB/US model roughly satisfies the empirical regularity known as Okun’s law
by generating changes in the unemployment gap that are roughly half as large and of the opposite sign as
changes in the output gap. Hence, a coefficient of negative 2 on the unemployment gap has similar
implications to a coefficient of 1 on the output gap in a FPLT rule.
12
13

Page 101 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Unlike the rules with a 2011:Q4 anchor date for the price level, there is only a
small initial price gap to which policymakers would respond. Moreover, in
the baseline projection, inflation remains close to 2 percent, and the
responsiveness of this FPLT rule to resource slack is about the same as in the
inertial Taylor (1999) rule that is used to construct the baseline projection. As
a result, the paths for the unemployment rate and inflation under this FPLT
rule and the baseline rule are very similar. Relative to the policy prescriptions
from the other two FPLT rules, the path of the federal funds rate is

Monetary Policy Strategies

considerably higher.
•

While the outcomes for the “FPLT rule, large response to ugap (2017:Q4)”
and the inertial Taylor (1999) rule under the baseline projection are very
similar, the prescriptions from these two rules could diverge markedly in other
scenarios. For example, in the face of a large and negative demand shock, the
FPLT rule shown here would be considerably more accommodative than the
inertial Taylor (1999) rule, leading to higher output and lower unemployment
for some time after the shock. 14

•

Overall, the simulations show that the FPLT rules that respond to a price gap
measured using core PCE prices and the unemployment rate gap can give rise
to a variety of economic outcomes, including outcomes similar to those under
the baseline Tealbook projection. In a downturn with a prolonged period of
inflation below the 2 percent target, all of the FPLT rules would provide a
large amount of accommodation compared with rules in which inflation
bygones are bygones, such as the inertial Taylor (1999) rule. Of course, the
efficacy of FPLT rules relies heavily on the assumptions that policymakers
can not only credibly commit to such policies and communicate them clearly
but also that the public understands and anticipates their effects.

The final four exhibits tabulate the simulation results for key variables under the
policy rules and optimal control simulations described previously.

The March 2016 Monetary Policy Strategies section of Tealbook B examined flexible pricelevel targeting rules in the context of a recession scenario.
14

Page 102 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations
(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.5
3.7
3.0
1.8
2.6

5.1
4.3
4.4
2.7
3.8

5.4
4.5
5.0
3.6
4.7

5.2
4.5
4.7
4.2
5.0

4.8
4.2
4.1
4.2
4.9

4.3
3.9
3.7
4.0
4.5

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.3
2.5
2.6
2.8
2.6

2.4
2.8
2.7
3.1
2.6

2.1
2.3
2.2
2.3
2.1

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.5
1.5

1.2
1.1
1.2
.9
1.0

1.2
1.1
1.2
.9
1.0

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.8
3.6
3.6
3.5
3.6

3.5
3.3
3.3
2.9
3.3

3.5
3.1
3.2
2.8
3.3

3.6
3.1
3.2
3.0
3.5

3.7
3.4
3.4
3.4
3.8

3.9
3.7
3.7
3.8
4.1

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
1.9

2.0
2.2
2.1
2.1
2.0

2.1
2.3
2.2
2.2
2.0

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.2
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.1

2.1
2.3
2.2
2.2
2.1

2.2
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.1

2.2
2.4
2.3
2.3
2.2

2.2
2.4
2.3
2.3
2.2

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 103 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Outcomes of Simple Policy Rule Simulations, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

Monetary Policy Strategies

Outcome and strategy
Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

4.1
3.3
2.0
1.5
1.8

4.4
3.6
2.5
1.7
2.2

4.5
3.7
3.0
1.8
2.6

4.5
3.7
3.5
2.0
2.9

4.6
3.8
3.9
2.2
3.2

4.9
4.1
4.2
2.5
3.5

5.1
4.3
4.4
2.7
3.8

Real GDP
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.7
2.7
2.7
2.7
2.7

2.6
2.6
2.6
2.6
2.6

2.4
2.6
2.6
2.7
2.6

2.3
2.5
2.6
2.8
2.6

2.5
2.8
2.9
3.3
2.9

2.4
2.8
2.9
3.3
2.8

2.4
2.8
2.8
3.3
2.7

2.4
2.8
2.7
3.1
2.6

Unemployment rate¹
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1

4.0
4.0
4.0
4.0
4.0

3.9
3.8
3.8
3.8
3.8

3.8
3.6
3.6
3.5
3.6

3.7
3.5
3.4
3.3
3.4

3.6
3.4
3.3
3.1
3.3

3.5
3.3
3.3
3.0
3.3

3.5
3.3
3.3
2.9
3.3

Total PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

2.4
2.4
2.4
2.4
2.4

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1

1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.8

1.8
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.8

1.9
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.8

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
1.9

Core PCE prices
Taylor (1999)
Taylor (1993)
First-difference
Nominal income targeting
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.1
2.1
2.1

2.1
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.0

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
1.9

1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0
1.9

2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1
2.0

2.1
2.2
2.2
2.2
2.1

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 104 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment
(Percent change, annual rate, from end of preceding period except as noted)

Outcome and strategy

2018

2019

2020

2021

2022

2023

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.3
4.2
11.4
1.9
2.6

6.7
6.6
8.6
2.5
3.8

7.6
7.5
6.9
3.1
4.7

7.6
7.3
7.0
3.6
5.0

6.8
6.5
7.8
4.1
4.9

5.8
5.5
6.6
4.3
4.5

Real GDP
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.1
2.1
1.3
2.8
2.6

1.4
1.5
1.0
3.1
2.6

1.5
1.5
2.1
2.3
2.1

1.4
1.5
1.9
1.4
1.5

1.4
1.4
1.5
.7
1.0

1.4
1.4
1.3
.7
1.0

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

3.8
3.8
4.3
3.5
3.6

4.1
4.0
4.7
2.9
3.3

4.4
4.3
4.7
2.8
3.3

4.7
4.5
4.7
2.9
3.5

4.7
4.5
4.6
3.4
3.8

4.7
4.5
4.6
4.0
4.1

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.0
2.0
1.9
2.1
2.1

1.7
1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.7
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.0

1.9
2.0
1.9
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.1
2.1

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.1

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.1

1.9
2.0
1.9
2.1
2.1

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
2.2

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.2
2.2

1. Percent, average for the final quarter of the period.

Page 105 of 126

Authorized for Public Release

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

April 20, 2018

Outcomes of Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment, Quarterly
(4-quarter percent change, except as noted)

2018

2019

Monetary Policy Strategies

Outcome and strategy
Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Q1

Q2

Q3

Q4

Nominal federal funds rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4
1.4

2.5
2.5
7.6
1.6
1.8

3.4
3.4
10.5
1.7
2.2

4.3
4.2
11.4
1.9
2.6

5.0
5.0
11.2
2.0
2.9

5.7
5.6
10.3
2.2
3.2

6.2
6.2
9.4
2.3
3.5

6.7
6.6
8.6
2.5
3.8

Real GDP
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

2.7
2.7
2.7
2.7
2.7

2.7
2.7
2.7
2.6
2.6

2.3
2.4
2.0
2.7
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.3
2.8
2.6

2.0
2.1
1.0
3.3
2.9

1.7
1.8
.5
3.3
2.8

1.6
1.7
.7
3.2
2.7

1.4
1.5
1.0
3.1
2.6

Unemployment rate¹
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1
4.1

4.0
4.0
4.0
4.0
4.0

3.9
3.9
4.2
3.8
3.8

3.8
3.8
4.3
3.5
3.6

3.8
3.8
4.5
3.3
3.4

3.9
3.8
4.6
3.1
3.3

4.0
3.9
4.7
3.0
3.3

4.1
4.0
4.7
2.9
3.3

Total PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8
1.8

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3
2.3

2.3
2.3
2.3
2.4
2.4

2.0
2.0
1.9
2.1
2.1

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.9
1.8

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.8
1.8

1.6
1.6
1.6
1.9
1.8

1.7
1.7
1.7
2.0
1.9

Core PCE prices
Equal weights
Large weight on inflation gap
Minimal weight on rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight on ugap
Extended Tealbook baseline

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7
1.7

2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0
2.0

2.0
2.1
2.0
2.1
2.1

1.9
1.9
1.9
2.1
2.0

1.7
1.8
1.7
2.0
1.9

1.7
1.7
1.7
1.9
1.9

1.7
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.0

1.8
1.9
1.8
2.1
2.1

1. Percent, average for the quarter.

Page 106 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Appendix
Implementation of the Simple Rules and Optimal Control Simulations
The monetary policy strategies considered in this section of Tealbook A typically fall into
one of two categories. Under simple policy rules, policymakers set the federal funds rate
according to a reaction function that includes a small number of macroeconomic factors. Under
optimal control policies, policymakers compute a path for the federal funds rate that minimizes a
loss function meant to capture policymakers’ preferences over macroeconomic outcomes. Both
approaches recognize the Federal Reserve’s dual mandate. Unless otherwise noted, the
simulations embed the assumption that policymakers will adhere to the policy strategy in the
future and that financial market participants, price setters, and wage setters not only believe that
policymakers will follow through with their strategy, but also fully understand the
macroeconomic implications of policymakers doing so. Such policy strategies are described as
commitment strategies.
The two approaches have different merits and limitations. The parsimony of simple rules
makes them relatively easy to communicate to the public, and, because they respond only to
variables that are central to a range of models, proponents argue that they may be more robust to
uncertainty about the structure of the economy. However, simple rules omit, by construction,
other potential influences on policy decisions; thus, strict adherence to such rules may, at times,
lead to unsatisfactory outcomes. By comparison, optimal control policies respond to a broader set
of economic factors; their prescriptions optimally balance various policy objectives. And,
although this section focuses on policies under commitment, optimal control policies can more
generally be derived under various assumptions about the degree to which policymakers can
commit. That said, optimal control policies assume substantial knowledge on the part of
policymakers and are sensitive to the assumed loss function and the specifics of the
particular model.
Given the different strengths and weaknesses of the two approaches, they are probably
best considered together as a means to assess the various tradeoffs policymakers may face when
pursuing their mandated objectives.

POLICY RULES USED IN THE MONETARY POLICY STRATEGIES SECTION
The table “Simple Rules” that follows gives expressions for four simple policy rules
routinely reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section. It also reports the expression for the
inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule; the staff uses that inertial version, augmented with a
small temporary intercept adjustment, in the construction of the Tealbook baseline projection. 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡
denotes the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by a strategy for quarter t; for quarters prior to
the projection period under consideration, 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 corresponds to the historical data in the economic
projection. The right-hand-side variables include the staff’s projection of trailing four-quarter
core PCE price inflation for the current quarter and three quarters ahead (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 and 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 ), the
output gap estimate for the current period (𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 ), and the forecast of the three-quarter-ahead
Page 107 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

annual change in the output gap (∆4 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 ). The value of policymakers’ longer-run inflation
objective, denoted 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , is 2 percent.

Monetary Policy Strategies

The nominal income targeting rule responds to a nominal income gap, which is defined
as the difference between nominal income, denoted 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡 and measured as 100 times the log of the
level of nominal GDP, and a target value, denoted 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡∗ and measured as 100 times the log of
target nominal GDP. Target nominal GDP in 2011:Q4 is set equal to the staff’s current estimate
of potential real GDP in that quarter multiplied by the GDP deflator in that quarter; subsequently,
target nominal GDP grows 2 percentage points per year faster than the staff’s estimate of
potential GDP. These assumptions imply that the nominal income gap can be approximated as
the sum of the current estimate of the output gap and the shortfall of the GDP deflator from the
level it would have attained had it grown at a 2 percent annual pace since 2011:Q4. 1
Simple Rules
Taylor (1999) rule
Taylor (1993) rule
Inertial Taylor (1999) rule
First-difference rule
Nominal income targeting
rule

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 0.5𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 0.5(𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 ) + 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 )
𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.5�𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡 − 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 � + 0.5Δ4 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+3|𝑡𝑡
𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡 − 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡 ∗ )

The first two of the selected rules were studied by Taylor (1993, 1999), whereas the
inertial version of the Taylor (1999) rule and the nominal income targeting rules have been
featured prominently in analysis by Board staff. 2
Where applicable, the intercepts of the simple rules, denoted 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 , are constant and chosen
so that they are consistent with a 2 percent longer-run inflation objective and an equilibrium real
federal funds rate in the longer run of 0.5 percent. 3 The prescriptions of the first-difference rule
do not depend on the level of the output gap or the longer-run real interest rate; see
Orphanides (2003).

1

1

That is, these assumptions imply that 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡 − 𝑦𝑦𝑛𝑛𝑡𝑡∗ ≈ 𝑦𝑦𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 + ∑𝑡𝑡𝑠𝑠=2012:𝑄𝑄1(∆𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝑠𝑠 − 2),
4

where ∆𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝑠𝑠 denotes the annualized quarterly rate of growth of the GDP deflator for quarter s.
2
For applications, see, for example, Erceg and others (2012).
3
All nominal and real federal funds rates reported in the Monetary Policy Strategies section are
expressed on the same 360-day basis as the published federal funds rate. Consistent with the methodology
in the FRB/US model, the simple rules are first implemented on a fully compounded, 365-day basis and
then converted to a 360-day basis.

Page 108 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

NEAR-TERM PRESCRIPTIONS OF SELECTED POLICY RULES
The “Near-Term Prescriptions of Selected Policy Rules” reported in the first exhibit are
calculated taking as given the Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap. When the
Tealbook is published early in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the current and next
quarters. When the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, the prescriptions are shown for the
next two quarters. Rules that include a lagged policy rate as a right-hand-side variable are
conditioned on the lagged federal funds rate in the Tealbook projection for the first quarter shown
and then conditioned on their simulated lagged federal funds rate for the second quarter shown.
To isolate the effects of changes in macroeconomic projections on the prescriptions of these
inertial rules, the lines labeled “Previous Tealbook projection” report prescriptions that are
conditional on the previous Tealbook projections for inflation and the output gap but that use the
value of the lagged federal funds rate in the current Tealbook for the first quarter shown.

A MEDIUM-TERM NOTION OF THE EQUILIBRIUM REAL FEDERAL FUNDS RATE
The bottom panel of the exhibit “Policy Rules and the Staff Projection” provides
estimates of one notion of the equilibrium real federal funds rate that uses alternative baselines:
the Tealbook baseline and another one consistent with median responses to the latest Summary of
Economic Projections (SEP). The simulations are conducted using the FRB/US model, the staff’s
large-scale econometric model of the U.S. economy. “FRB/US r*” is the real federal funds rate
that, if maintained over a 12-quarter period (beginning in the current quarter), makes the output
gap equal to zero in the final quarter of that period, given either the Tealbook or the SEPconsistent economic projection. 4 This measure depends on a broad array of economic factors,
some of which take the form of projected values of the model’s exogenous variables. The
measure is derived under the assumption that agents in the model form VAR-based
expectations—that is, agents use small-scale statistical models so that their expectations of future
variables are determined solely by historical relationships.
The “Average projected real federal funds rate” for the Tealbook baseline and the SEPconsistent baseline reported in the panel are the corresponding averages of the real federal funds
rate under the Tealbook baseline projection and SEP-consistent projection, respectively,
calculated over the same 12-quarter period as the Tealbook-consistent and SEP-consistent
FRB/US r*. For a given economic projection, the average projected real federal funds rates and
the FRB/US r* may be associated with somewhat different macroeconomic outcomes even when
their values are identical. The reason is that, in the FRB/US r* simulation, the real federal funds
rate is held constant over the entire 12-quarter period, whereas, in the economic projection, the
real federal funds rate can vary over time.

FRB/US MODEL SIMULATIONS
The results presented in the exhibits “Simple Policy Rule Simulations” and “Optimal
Control Simulations under Commitment” are derived from dynamic simulations of the FRB/US
model. Each simulated policy strategy is assumed to be in force over the whole period covered
For a discussion of the equilibrium real federal funds rates in the longer run and other concepts
of equilibrium interest rates, see Gust and others (2016).
4

Page 109 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

by the simulation; this period extends several decades beyond the time horizon shown in the
exhibits. The simulations are conducted under the assumption that market participants as well as
price and wage setters form model-consistent expectations and are predicated on the staff’s
extended Tealbook projection, which includes the macroeconomic effects of the Committee’s
large-scale asset purchase programs. When the Tealbook is published early in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in that quarter; when the Tealbook is published late in a quarter, all of the
simulations begin in the subsequent quarter.

Monetary Policy Strategies

COMPUTATION OF OPTIMAL CONTROL POLICIES UNDER COMMITMENT
The optimal control simulations posit that policymakers minimize a discounted weighted
sum of squared inflation gaps (measured as the difference between four-quarter headline PCE
price inflation, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 , and the Committee’s 2 percent objective), squared unemployment gaps
(𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , measured as the difference between the unemployment rate and the staff’s estimate of
the natural rate), and squared changes in the federal funds rate. In the following equation, the
resulting loss function embeds the assumption that policymakers discount the future using a
quarterly discount factor, 𝛽𝛽 = 0.9963:
𝑳𝑳𝒕𝒕 = �

𝑇𝑇

𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃
𝜷𝜷𝝉𝝉 �𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋 (𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏
− 𝜋𝜋 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 (𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 )𝟐𝟐 + 𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿 (𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉 − 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡+𝝉𝝉−𝟏𝟏 )𝟐𝟐 �.

𝝉𝝉=𝟎𝟎

The exhibit “Optimal Control Simulations under Commitment” considers four
specifications of the weights on the inflation gap, the unemployment gap, and the rate change
components of the loss function. The box “Optimal Control and the Loss Function” in the
Monetary Policy Strategies section of the June 2016 Tealbook B provides motivations for the four
specifications of the loss function.
The first specification, “Equal weights,” assigns equal weights to all three components at
all times. The second specification, “Large weight on inflation gap,” attaches a relatively large
weight to inflation gaps. The third specification, “Minimal weight on rate adjustments,” places
almost no weight on changes in the federal funds rate. 5 The fourth specification, “Asymmetric
weight on ugap,” uses the same weights as the equal-weights specification whenever the
unemployment rate is above the staff’s estimate of the natural rate, but it assigns no penalty to the
unemployment rate falling below the natural rate. The table “Loss Functions” shows the weights
used in the four specifications. The optimal control policy and associated outcomes depend on
the relative (rather than the absolute) values of the weights.

The inclusion of a minimal but strictly positive weight on changes in the federal funds rate helps
ensure a well-behaved numerical solution.
5

Page 110 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Loss Functions

Equal weights
Large weight
on inflation gap
Minimal weight on
rate adjustments
Asymmetric weight
on ugap

𝜆𝜆𝜋𝜋
1

5

1

1

𝜆𝜆𝑢𝑢,𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 < 0

𝑢𝑢𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡+𝜏𝜏 ≥ 0

1

1

1

1

0

1

1

1

𝜆𝜆𝐿𝐿
1

1

0.01
1

For each of these four specifications of the loss function, the optimal control policy is the
path for the federal funds rate that minimizes the loss function in the FRB/US model, subject to
the effective lower bound constraint on nominal interest rates, under the assumption that market
participants and wage and price setters employ model-consistent expectations and conditional on
the staff’s extended Tealbook projection. Policy tools other than the federal funds rate are taken
as given and subsumed within the Tealbook baseline. The path chosen by policymakers today is
assumed to be credible, meaning that the public sees this path as a binding commitment on
policymakers’ future decisions; the optimal control policy takes as given the initial lagged value
of the federal funds rate but is otherwise unconstrained by policy decisions made prior to the
simulation period. The discounted losses are calculated over a horizon that ends sufficiently far
in the future so that extending the horizon further would not affect the policy prescriptions shown
in the exhibits.

FLEXIBLE PRICE-LEVEL TARGETING RULES
The table “FPLT Rules” shown below gives expressions for two flexible price-level
targeting rules reported in the exhibit, “Illustrating Flexible Price-Level Targeting Rules.” In the
table, 𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 denotes the nominal federal funds rate prescribed by a rule for quarter t. The right-handside variables include the staff’s projection of trailing four-quarter core PCE price inflation for
the current quarter, 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 , and the longer-run real interest rate, 𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 . The price gap is computed as
the difference between the core PCE price level, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 , and the target path, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ . For the rules in the
exhibit with the 2011:Q4 anchor date, the 2011:Q4 value of the target path is set to the 2011:Q4
value of the core PCE price level, and, subsequently, 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ is assumed to grow at a 2 percent annual
rate. The target path is set in an analogous fashion for the rule with the 2017:Q4 anchor date.
The unemployment gap is the difference between the unemployment rate, 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 , and the staff’s
estimate of its natural rate, 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ .
FPLT Rules

FPLT, large response to
ugap
FPLT, equal responses

𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + (𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 − 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ ) − 2(𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 − 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ ))
𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡 = 0.85𝑅𝑅𝑡𝑡−1 + 0.15(𝑟𝑟 𝐿𝐿𝐿𝐿 + 𝜋𝜋𝑡𝑡 + (𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡 − 𝑔𝑔𝑡𝑡∗ ) − (𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡 − 𝑢𝑢𝑡𝑡∗ ))

Page 111 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

REFERENCES

Monetary Policy Strategies

Erceg, Christopher, Jon Faust, Michael Kiley, Jean-Philippe Laforte, David López-Salido,
Stephen Meyer, Edward Nelson, David Reifschneider, and Robert Tetlow (2012). “An
Overview of Simple Policy Rules and Their Use in Policymaking in Normal Times and
Under Current Conditions,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market Committee, Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Divisions of International Finance,
Monetary Affairs, and Research and Statistics, July 18.
Gust, Christopher, Benjamin K. Johannsen, David López-Salido, and Robert Tetlow (2016).
“r*: Concepts, Measures, and Uses,” memorandum to the Federal Open Market
Committee, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Division of Monetary
Affairs, October 13.
Orphanides, Athanasios (2003). “Historical Monetary Policy Analysis and the Taylor Rule,”
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 50 (July), pp. 983−1022.
Taylor, John B. (1993). “Discretion versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, vol. 39 (December), pp. 195−214.
--------- (1999). “A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules,” in John B. Taylor, ed.,
Monetary Policy Rules. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 319−41.

Page 112 of 126

3.3
4.1
5.3
5.3
4.4
4.9
5.3
5.1
5.1
4.8
4.6
4.4

3.7
5.3
4.6
5.2
5.0
4.5

3.4
4.5
4.9
4.7
4.3

Quarterly
2017:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2018:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
2019:Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Two-quarter2
2017:Q2
Q4
2018:Q2
Q4
2019:Q2
Q4

Four-quarter3
2016:Q4
2017:Q4
2018:Q4
2019:Q4
2020:Q4

Page 113 of 126

3.4
4.5
4.7
4.7
4.2

3.7
5.3
4.6
4.8
4.9
4.5

3.3
4.1
5.3
5.3
4.4
4.7
4.8
4.7
5.1
4.8
4.7
4.3

04/19/18

1.8
2.6
2.9
2.6
2.1

2.1
3.0
2.6
3.3
2.8
2.4

1.2
3.1
3.2
2.9
2.1
3.1
3.3
3.2
2.9
2.7
2.5
2.3

03/09/18

1.8
2.6
2.6
2.6
2.1

2.1
3.0
2.3
2.9
2.8
2.4

1.2
3.1
3.2
2.9
1.7
2.9
3.0
2.9
2.9
2.7
2.6
2.3

04/19/18

Real GDP

1.6
1.7
1.8
2.0
2.1

1.2
2.1
2.0
1.6
1.9
2.0

2.2
.3
1.5
2.7
2.5
1.5
1.7
1.6
1.9
2.0
2.0
2.0

03/09/18

1.6
1.7
2.1
1.9
2.0

1.2
2.1
2.5
1.7
1.9
1.9

2.2
.3
1.5
2.7
2.8
2.2
1.8
1.5
1.9
1.9
1.9
2.0

04/19/18

PCE price index

1.9
1.5
1.9
2.1
2.2

1.4
1.6
2.1
1.8
2.0
2.1

1.8
.9
1.3
1.9
2.3
2.0
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1

03/09/18

Greensheets

1.8
1.5
2.0
2.0
2.1

1.9
1.5
2.0
2.1
2.1

1.4
1.6
2.4
1.7
2.1
2.1

1.8
.9
1.3
1.9
2.5
2.2
1.8
1.7
2.0
2.1
2.1
2.1

04/19/18

4.9
4.4
3.8
3.2
3.1

-.3
-.6
-.6
-.4
.0

-.4
-.2
-.2
-.4
-.3
-.1

4.6
4.3
4.3
4.1
4.1
3.9
3.7
3.5
3.3
3.2
3.2
3.1

03/09/18

4.9
4.4
3.9
3.3
3.3

-.3
-.6
-.5
-.3
.0

-.4
-.2
-.1
-.4
-.3
.0

4.6
4.3
4.3
4.1
4.1
4.0
3.8
3.6
3.4
3.3
3.3
3.3

04/19/18

Core PCE price index Unemployment rate1

Authorized for Public Release

Annual
2016
2.8
2.8
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2
1.8
2017
4.1
4.1
2.3
2.3
1.7
1.7
1.5
2018
4.9
4.8
2.9
2.6
1.9
2.1
1.9
2019
4.9
4.8
2.9
2.8
1.8
1.8
2.0
2020
4.4
4.4
2.2
2.2
2.0
2.0
2.1
1. Level, except for two-quarter and four-quarter intervals.
2. Percent change from two quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.
3. Percent change from four quarters earlier; for unemployment rate, change is in percentage points.

03/09/18

Interval

Nominal GDP

Changes in GDP, Prices, and Unemployment
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 114 of 126

5
5

Change in priv. inventories2
Previous Tealbook2
39
39

.7
.7
1.3
2.4
-.2
.2

-598
-598
2.1
-.7

4.7
4.7
8.4
8.4
-7.0
-7.0

16
10

3.0
3.0
3.2
5.5
-.1
2.9

-654
-653
7.0
14.1

6.8
7.1
7.0
7.4
6.3
6.2

12.8
12.4

4.0
4.2
13.7
4.8
2.3

3.4
3.6
4.8
5.0

2.9
2.9

Q4

58
44

-1.2
-.3
-3.8
-5.3
-1.6
.3

-676
-654
2.9
5.3

5.7
4.2
5.8
4.5
5.6
3.4

-4.1
-4.4

1.2
1.5
-1.4
-1.2
2.3

.7
1.3
1.6
1.6

1.7
2.1

Q1

62
38

1.2
.8
1.4
2.4
.0
1.0

-671
-647
5.5
3.5

8.0
8.2
6.4
7.2
13.5
11.6

-2.1
2.7

2.2
2.6
4.2
1.0
2.2

2.8
3.3
2.8
3.4

2.9
3.1

Q2

47
37

2.2
1.8
4.0
5.2
2.4
1.1

-663
-643
7.1
4.3

6.2
6.2
5.8
6.8
7.5
4.0

5.0
4.0

2.6
2.9
4.6
2.3
2.3

3.3
3.3
3.2
3.4

3.0
3.3

Q3

2018

30
28

2.7
2.7
5.6
7.0
3.5
1.0

-651
-637
5.5
2.7

5.0
5.5
5.3
6.4
4.2
2.8

5.1
4.1

2.5
2.9
3.8
2.7
2.2

3.3
3.5
3.0
3.3

2.9
3.2

Q4

20
24

1.7
1.7
3.0
3.1
2.8
1.0

-642
-638
5.8
3.3

4.7
4.9
5.5
5.5
2.3
3.1

1.6
2.5

2.8
2.8
2.3
2.8
2.8

3.1
3.0
3.0
3.1

2.9
2.9

Q1

16
22

2.3
2.3
4.6
5.8
2.9
1.0

-650
-649
5.3
5.2

4.3
4.3
4.8
4.6
2.7
3.5

1.6
.3

2.7
2.8
2.2
2.8
2.8

2.8
2.7
2.9
2.9

2.7
2.7

Q2

18
18

2.2
2.2
4.2
5.1
3.0
1.0

-659
-657
5.3
5.4

3.5
3.4
4.0
3.7
1.8
2.5

1.8
-.1

2.6
2.7
2.1
2.7
2.7

2.5
2.6
2.7
2.7

2.6
2.5

Q3

2019

10
14

2.4
2.4
4.7
5.5
3.5
1.0

-663
-661
4.4
3.9

2.3
2.4
2.6
2.4
1.4
2.1

1.8
-.8

2.5
2.6
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.5
2.4
2.5
2.4

2.3
2.3

Q4

15
14

.7
.7
1.0
2.3
-.9
.5

-622
-622
5.0
4.7

6.3
6.4
6.7
6.8
5.0
4.9

2.6
2.5

2.8
2.9
7.3
3.1
2.1

2.9
2.9
3.3
3.4

2.6
2.6

20171

49
37

1.2
1.2
1.8
2.2
1.1
.9

-665
-645
5.2
3.9

6.2
6.0
5.8
6.2
7.7
5.4

.9
1.6

2.1
2.4
2.8
1.2
2.3

2.5
2.8
2.6
2.9

2.6
2.9

20181

16
19

2.2
2.1
4.1
4.9
3.0
1.0

-654
-651
5.2
4.4

3.7
3.8
4.2
4.1
2.0
2.8

1.7
.5

2.7
2.8
2.1
2.7
2.7

2.7
2.7
2.8
2.8

2.6
2.6

20191

5
8

1.9
1.8
3.3
3.6
2.7
1.0

-696
-702
3.6
4.8

1.7
1.8
2.0
2.1
.5
.9

3.3
4.2

2.5
2.5
1.9
2.6
2.5

2.1
2.1
2.4
2.5

2.1
2.1

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Billions of chained (2009) dollars.

-.2
-.2
1.9
4.7
-1.9
-1.5

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

6.7
6.7
6.6
6.6
7.0
7.0

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-614
-614
3.5
1.5

-7.3
-7.3

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports2
Previous Tealbook2
Exports
Imports

2.2
2.2
8.6
2.3
1.1

3.3
3.3
7.6
4.2
2.3

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services
-4.7
-4.7

2.4
2.4
2.2
2.2

3.0
3.0
3.3
3.3

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

3.2
3.2

Q3

3.1
3.1

Q2

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

2017

Greensheets
Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 115 of 126

38
38

Change in priv. inventories1
Previous Tealbook1

55
55

-2.2
-2.2
-2.1
-3.9
1.0
-2.3

-447
-447
2.2
.3

5.2
5.2
5.5
5.5
4.1
4.1

15.7
15.7

1.3
1.3
7.2
.8
.6

1.7
1.7
2.3
2.3

1.3
1.3

2012

79
79

-2.8
-2.8
-6.7
-7.1
-6.0
-.1

-405
-405
5.9
2.5

4.8
4.8
4.5
4.5
5.8
5.8

6.8
6.8

2.0
2.0
5.2
2.6
1.3

2.0
2.0
2.6
2.6

2.7
2.7

2013

Greensheets

68
68

.5
.5
-1.2
-4.0
3.5
1.5

-428
-428
3.0
6.2

6.1
6.1
5.3
5.3
8.8
8.8

6.3
6.3

3.6
3.6
8.7
2.8
3.0

2.9
2.9
4.1
4.1

2.7
2.7

2014

101
101

1.6
1.6
1.2
.0
2.9
1.9

-545
-545
-1.8
2.9

.3
.3
3.3
3.3
-9.1
-9.1

10.3
10.3

3.0
3.0
6.4
2.8
2.6

2.0
2.0
2.9
2.9

2.0
2.0

2015

33
33

.4
.4
-.3
-1.4
1.2
.8

-586
-586
.6
2.7

.7
.7
-.1
-.1
3.5
3.5

2.5
2.5

2.8
2.8
7.0
2.5
2.3

1.9
1.9
2.5
2.5

1.8
1.8

2016

15
14

.7
.7
1.0
2.3
-.9
.5

-622
-622
5.0
4.7

6.3
6.4
6.7
6.8
5.0
4.9

2.6
2.5

2.8
2.9
7.3
3.1
2.1

2.9
2.9
3.3
3.4

2.6
2.6

2017

49
37

1.2
1.2
1.8
2.2
1.1
.9

-665
-645
5.2
3.9

6.2
6.0
5.8
6.2
7.7
5.4

.9
1.6

2.1
2.4
2.8
1.2
2.3

2.5
2.8
2.6
2.9

2.6
2.9

2018

16
19

2.2
2.1
4.1
4.9
3.0
1.0

-654
-651
5.2
4.4

3.7
3.8
4.2
4.1
2.0
2.8

1.7
.5

2.7
2.8
2.1
2.7
2.7

2.7
2.7
2.8
2.8

2.6
2.6

2019

5
8

1.9
1.8
3.3
3.6
2.7
1.0

-696
-702
3.6
4.8

1.7
1.8
2.0
2.1
.5
.9

3.3
4.2

2.5
2.5
1.9
2.6
2.5

2.1
2.1
2.4
2.5

2.1
2.1

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Billions of chained (2009) dollars.

-3.0
-3.0
-4.0
-4.1
-3.9
-2.3

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

9.0
9.0
9.2
9.2
8.0
8.0

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook
-459
-459
4.2
3.5

6.0
6.0

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

Net exports1
Previous Tealbook1
Exports
Imports

1.5
1.5
4.8
.4
1.4

1.5
1.5
2.6
2.6

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

1.7
1.7

2011

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook

Item

Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product and Related Items
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 116 of 126

.0
.0
.1
.2
-.1
-.2
.1
.1

Gov’t. cons. & invest.
Previous Tealbook
Federal
Defense
Nondefense
State & local

Change in priv. inventories
Previous Tealbook

.8
.8

.1
.1
.1
.1
.0
.0

.4
.4
.3
.1

.6
.6
.8
.8
-.2
-.2

-.2
-.2

1.5
1.5
.6
.3
.5

-.5
-.6

.5
.5
.2
.2
.0
.3

-1.2
-1.2
.8
-2.0

.8
.9
.7
.7
.2
.2

.5
.5

2.8
2.9
1.0
.7
1.1

3.4
3.6
4.1
4.2

2.9
2.9

Q4

1.0
.8

-.2
.0
-.2
-.2
.0
.0

-.5
.0
.4
-.8

.7
.5
.6
.4
.2
.1

-.2
-.2

.8
1.0
-.1
-.2
1.1

.7
1.3
1.4
1.4

1.7
2.1

Q1

.1
-.2

.2
.1
.1
.1
.0
.1

.1
.2
.7
-.5

1.0
1.0
.6
.7
.4
.3

-.1
.1

1.5
1.8
.3
.1
1.1

2.7
3.2
2.4
2.9

2.9
3.1

Q2

-.3
.0

.4
.3
.3
.2
.1
.1

.2
.1
.9
-.7

.8
.8
.6
.7
.2
.1

.2
.2

1.8
2.0
.3
.3
1.1

3.3
3.3
2.7
2.9

3.0
3.3

Q3

2018

-.4
-.2

.5
.5
.4
.3
.1
.1

.3
.2
.7
-.4

.6
.7
.5
.6
.1
.1

.2
.2

1.7
2.0
.3
.4
1.0

3.3
3.4
2.6
2.8

2.9
3.2

Q4

-.2
-.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

.2
.0
.7
-.5

.6
.6
.5
.5
.1
.1

.1
.1

1.9
2.0
.2
.4
1.3

3.1
3.0
2.6
2.7

2.9
2.9

Q1

-.1
.0

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.1
-.2
.7
-.8

.6
.6
.5
.5
.1
.1

.1
.0

1.9
1.9
.2
.4
1.3

2.7
2.7
2.5
2.5

2.7
2.7

Q2

.0
-.1

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

-.2
-.1
.7
-.8

.5
.4
.4
.4
.1
.1

.1
.0

1.8
1.9
.2
.4
1.3

2.5
2.6
2.3
2.3

2.6
2.5

Q3

2019

-.2
-.1

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

.0
-.1
.5
-.6

.3
.3
.3
.2
.0
.1

.1
.0

1.7
1.8
.1
.4
1.2

2.5
2.4
2.1
2.1

2.3
2.3

Q4

-.3
-.3

.1
.1
.1
.1
.0
.1

-.1
-.1
.6
-.7

.8
.8
.6
.6
.1
.1

.1
.1

2.0
2.0
.5
.5
1.0

2.9
2.9
2.8
2.9

2.6
2.6

20171

.1
.1

.2
.2
.1
.1
.0
.1

.0
.1
.6
-.6

.8
.8
.6
.6
.2
.2

.0
.1

1.4
1.7
.2
.2
1.1

2.5
2.8
2.3
2.5

2.6
2.9

20181

-.1
-.1

.4
.4
.3
.2
.1
.1

.0
-.1
.6
-.7

.5
.5
.4
.4
.1
.1

.1
.0

1.8
1.9
.2
.4
1.3

2.7
2.7
2.4
2.4

2.6
2.6

20191

.0
-.1

.3
.3
.2
.1
.1
.1

-.3
-.3
.4
-.7

.2
.2
.2
.2
.0
.0

.1
.2

1.7
1.7
.1
.4
1.2

2.1
2.1
2.0
2.1

2.1
2.1

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.

.2
.2
.4
-.2

.8
.8
.6
.6
.2
.2

Nonres. priv. fixed invest.
Previous Tealbook
Equipment & intangibles
Previous Tealbook
Nonres. structures
Previous Tealbook

Net exports
Previous Tealbook
Exports
Imports

-.3
-.3

Residential investment
Previous Tealbook

2.2
2.2
.6
.6
1.1

2.9
2.9
2.8
2.8

Final sales
Previous Tealbook
Priv. dom. final purch.
Previous Tealbook

Personal cons. expend.
Previous Tealbook
Durables
Nondurables
Services

3.2
3.2

3.1
3.1

Real GDP
Previous Tealbook
2.4
2.4
1.9
1.9

Q3

Q2

Item

2017

Contributions to Changes in Real Gross Domestic Product
(Percentage points, annual rate except as noted)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

2.2
2.2
1.6
1.6
.5
.5
-1.0
-1.0
2.5
2.5

ECI, hourly compensation2
Previous Tealbook2

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook

Page 117 of 126

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index3
Previous Tealbook3
1.1
1.1

3.2
3.2
4.1
4.1
.9
.9

3.1
3.1

2.1
2.1
1.8
1.8

1.5
1.5
8.4
8.4
.2
.2
1.3
1.3
1.0
1.0

2.1
2.1

Q3

1.5
1.6

-.4
-.6
1.7
1.7
2.2
2.3

1.9
1.9

3.3
3.3
2.2
2.2

2.7
2.7
27.7
27.6
.2
.2
1.9
1.9
1.5
1.5

2.3
2.3

Q4

2.8
2.8

.8
.4
3.9
3.5
3.0
3.1

2.6
2.7

3.5
3.6
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.5
12.7
11.5
.2
.9
2.5
2.3
2.3
2.2

2.7
2.3

Q1

3.6
3.4

.7
.6
2.7
3.0
2.0
2.4

2.4
2.4

2.2
1.6
2.3
2.5

2.2
1.5
2.6
-8.9
1.6
1.9
2.2
2.0
2.2
2.0

1.8
1.7

Q2

.9
.9

1.6
1.9
3.8
4.0
2.1
2.0

2.4
2.4

1.8
1.9
2.1
2.1

1.5
1.6
-2.2
-1.6
2.3
2.3
1.7
1.7
1.4
1.5

1.8
1.8

Q4

Greensheets

1.8
1.3

1.6
2.0
3.8
4.0
2.2
2.0

2.4
2.4

2.2
1.9
2.3
2.2

1.8
1.7
1.4
-1.7
2.0
2.1
1.8
1.8
1.7
1.5

1.8
1.9

Q3

2018

.7
.7

.9
1.2
3.9
4.1
2.9
2.9

2.6
2.7

2.1
2.1
2.4
2.4

1.9
1.9
-2.3
-1.2
2.3
2.4
2.0
2.0
1.8
1.8

2.2
2.2

Q1

.6
.7

1.0
.9
3.9
4.1
2.9
3.1

2.7
2.7

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.4

1.9
2.0
-1.8
-.6
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.1

Q2

.6
.6

.9
.8
3.9
4.1
3.0
3.3

2.7
2.8

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.4

1.9
2.0
-1.7
-.5
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

Q3

2019

.5
.6

.6
.6
3.9
4.1
3.3
3.4

2.7
2.8

2.2
2.3
2.5
2.5

2.0
2.0
-1.6
-.5
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.0
2.0

Q4

1.3
1.3

.9
.9
2.7
2.7
1.8
1.8

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.7
1.7

1.7
1.7
7.6
7.6
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.9
1.9

20171

2.3
2.1

1.2
1.2
3.5
3.6
2.3
2.4

2.5
2.5

2.4
2.3
2.4
2.5

2.1
1.8
3.5
-.4
1.5
1.8
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.8

2.0
1.9

20181

.6
.7

.9
.9
3.9
4.1
3.0
3.1

2.7
2.8

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.4

1.9
2.0
-1.9
-.7
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

20191

.6
.6

.9
.9
3.9
4.3
3.0
3.4

2.7
3.0

2.3
2.4
2.5
2.6

2.0
2.1
-1.1
-.1
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.2
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.2

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
2. Private-industry workers.
3. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

.1
.1
.8
.8

.3
.3
-16.0
-16.0
2.0
2.0
.9
.9
.3
.3

1.0
1.0

Q2

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

CPI

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

2017

Changes in Prices and Costs
(Percent, annual rate except as noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

2.2
2.2
-.1
-.1
.5
.5
.6
.6
4.3
4.3

ECI, hourly compensation1
Previous Tealbook1

Business sector
Output per hour
Previous Tealbook
Compensation per hour
Previous Tealbook
Unit labor costs
Previous Tealbook

Page 118 of 126

Core goods imports chain-wt. price index2
Previous Tealbook2
.1
.1

-.1
-.1
5.9
5.9
6.0
6.0

1.8
1.8

1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.8
1.8
2.3
2.3
1.2
1.2
1.8
1.8
1.5
1.5

1.9
1.9

2012

-1.5
-1.5

1.9
1.9
-.1
-.1
-2.0
-2.0

2.0
2.0

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-2.5
-2.5
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.1
1.1

1.6
1.6

2013

.3
.3

.1
.1
2.9
2.9
2.8
2.8

2.3
2.3

1.2
1.2
1.7
1.7

1.2
1.2
-6.5
-6.5
2.6
2.6
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.6
1.6

2014

-3.7
-3.7

.7
.7
3.1
3.1
2.4
2.4

1.9
1.9

.4
.4
2.0
2.0

.4
.4
-16.2
-16.2
.3
.3
1.3
1.3
1.1
1.1

1.0
1.0

2015

-.2
-.2

1.0
1.0
-.2
-.2
-1.2
-1.2

2.2
2.2

1.8
1.8
2.2
2.2

1.6
1.6
2.2
2.2
-1.7
-1.7
1.9
1.9
1.5
1.5

1.5
1.5

2016

1.3
1.3

.9
.9
2.7
2.7
1.8
1.8

2.6
2.6

2.1
2.1
1.7
1.7

1.7
1.7
7.6
7.6
.7
.7
1.5
1.5
1.2
1.2

1.9
1.9

2017

2.3
2.1

1.2
1.2
3.5
3.6
2.3
2.4

2.5
2.5

2.4
2.3
2.4
2.5

2.1
1.8
3.5
-.4
1.5
1.8
2.0
1.9
1.9
1.8

2.0
1.9

2018

.6
.7

.9
.9
3.9
4.1
3.0
3.1

2.7
2.8

2.2
2.2
2.5
2.4

1.9
2.0
-1.9
-.7
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.1
1.9
1.9

2.1
2.1

2019

.6
.6

.9
.9
3.9
4.3
3.0
3.4

2.7
3.0

2.3
2.4
2.5
2.6

2.0
2.1
-1.1
-.1
2.3
2.4
2.1
2.2
1.9
2.0

2.1
2.2

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Private-industry workers.
2. Core goods imports exclude computers, semiconductors, oil, and natural gas.

3.3
3.3
2.2
2.2

2.7
2.7
12.0
12.0
5.1
5.1
1.9
1.9
1.9
1.9

1.9
1.9

2011

Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook

CPI

PCE chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook
Energy
Previous Tealbook
Food
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy
Previous Tealbook
Ex. food & energy, market based
Previous Tealbook

GDP chain-wt. price index
Previous Tealbook

Item

Greensheets
Changes in Prices and Costs
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

60.1
59.8

Employment-to-Population Ratio3
Employment-to-Population Trend3

1.2
16.8
4.1
2.7
2.7
3.7
3.7
2.8
10.9
17.2
2.0

Housing starts6
Light motor vehicle sales6

Income and saving
Nominal GDP5
Real disposable pers. income5
Previous Tealbook5
Personal saving rate3
Previous Tealbook3

Page 119 of 126

Corporate profits7
Profit share of GNP3

Gross national saving rate3
Net national saving rate3
17.7
2.6

18.1
11.2

5.3
.7
.7
3.4
3.4

1.2
17.1

-1.5
-1.2
-2.1
-2.0
74.4
75.2

1.2
1.2

60.2
59.7

142
4.3
4.3
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.7
1.6

-.2
11.1

5.3
1.1
1.1
2.6
2.6

1.3
17.7

7.8
8.3
5.5
6.3
75.2
76.3

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

221
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

Q4

17.0
2.0

3.6
11.1

4.4
4.3
6.4
3.3
3.7

1.3
17.2

4.5
5.0
3.1
4.3
75.6
76.8

1.5
1.6

60.3
59.6

202
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

Q1

17.0
2.0

3.7
11.0

4.7
1.7
3.0
3.2
3.8

1.3
17.2

4.4
4.4
2.5
2.9
75.8
77.1

1.7
1.9

60.3
59.6

195
4.0
3.9
4.7
4.7

Q2

2018

16.8
1.8

3.9
11.0

4.8
2.5
2.1
3.2
3.6

1.3
17.3

2.9
3.4
2.7
2.9
76.0
77.4

2.1
2.3

60.4
59.5

190
3.8
3.7
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.8
1.8

4.0
11.0

4.7
2.0
2.2
3.1
3.5

1.3
17.3

2.9
2.5
2.1
2.3
76.2
77.5

2.4
2.7

60.4
59.5

191
3.6
3.5
4.7
4.7

Q4

16.7
1.7

5.9
11.1

5.1
4.9
4.5
3.6
3.9

1.3
17.2

2.0
2.1
1.9
2.2
76.3
77.7

2.6
3.0

60.5
59.5

187
3.4
3.3
4.7
4.7

Q1

16.7
1.6

5.8
11.1

4.8
2.1
2.2
3.5
3.8

1.3
17.1

1.5
1.6
2.1
2.2
76.5
77.9

2.8
3.2

60.6
59.4

184
3.3
3.2
4.7
4.7

Q2

2019

16.6
1.5

6.3
11.2

4.7
1.8
1.8
3.3
3.6

1.4
17.0

.9
.9
1.7
1.8
76.7
78.0

3.0
3.3

60.7
59.4

178
3.3
3.2
4.7
4.7

Q3

16.6
1.4

3.9
11.2

4.3
1.9
2.2
3.1
3.5

1.4
16.9

1.0
1.3
1.2
1.4
76.7
78.1

3.1
3.5

60.7
59.4

174
3.3
3.1
4.7
4.7

Q4

Greensheets

16.7
1.6

2.7
11.1

4.5
1.8
1.8
2.6
2.6

1.2
17.1

3.0
3.5
1.9
2.2
75.2
76.3

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

182
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

20171

16.8
1.8

3.8
11.0

4.7
2.6
3.4
3.1
3.5

1.3
17.2

3.7
3.8
2.6
3.1
76.2
77.5

2.4
2.7

60.4
59.5

194
3.6
3.5
4.7
4.7

20181

16.6
1.4

5.5
11.2

4.7
2.7
2.7
3.1
3.5

1.3
17.0

1.4
1.5
1.7
1.9
76.7
78.1

3.1
3.5

60.7
59.4

181
3.3
3.1
4.7
4.7

20191

16.2
.8

3.7
11.1

4.2
2.2
2.1
3.0
3.2

1.4
16.7

1.3
1.5
1.3
1.3
77.1
78.3

3.2
3.6

60.7
59.2

160
3.3
3.1
4.7
4.7

20201

Authorized for Public Release

1. Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise indicated.
2. Average monthly change, thousands.
3. Percent; annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Percent difference between actual and potential GDP; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Annual values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
5. Percent change, annual rate.
6. Level, millions; annual values are annual averages.
7. Percent change, annual rate, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

5.0
5.6
2.4
2.6
74.9
75.7

Industrial production5
Previous Tealbook5
Manufacturing industr. prod.5
Previous Tealbook5
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.3
Previous Tealbook3

.8
.8

190
4.3
4.3
4.8
4.8

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment2
Unemployment rate3
Previous Tealbook3
Natural rate of unemployment3
Previous Tealbook3

Output gap4
Previous Tealbook4

Q2

Item

2017

Other Macroeconomic Indicators

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

58.5
60.7
-3.7
-3.7
3.2
2.8
2.8
2.5
74.5
74.4
.6
12.7
3.6
1.7
1.7
5.8
5.8
6.8
12.3
16.1
.8

Employment-to-Population Ratio2
Employment-to-Population Trend2

Output gap3
Previous Tealbook3

Industrial production4
Previous Tealbook4
Manufacturing industr. prod.4
Previous Tealbook4
Capacity utilization rate - mfg.2
Previous Tealbook2

Housing starts5
Light motor vehicle sales5

Income and saving
Nominal GDP4
Real disposable pers. income4
Previous Tealbook4
Personal saving rate2
Previous Tealbook2

Page 120 of 126

Corporate profits6
Profit share of GNP2

Gross national saving rate2
Net national saving rate2
18.0
2.9

.6
12.0

3.2
5.1
5.1
9.2
9.2

.8
14.4

2.2
2.3
1.4
1.7
74.7
74.6

-3.7
-3.7

58.7
60.3

179
7.8
7.8
5.6
5.6

2012

18.2
3.1

4.7
12.0

4.3
-2.8
-2.8
4.7
4.7

.9
15.5

2.3
2.2
1.1
.9
75.1
74.7

-2.5
-2.5

58.5
60.2

192
7.0
7.0
5.4
5.4

2013

19.5
4.7

7.4
12.4

4.3
4.9
4.9
5.9
5.9

1.0
16.5

3.4
3.4
1.4
1.5
76.3
75.9

-.9
-.9

59.3
60.1

250
5.7
5.7
5.1
5.1

2014

19.0
4.1

-11.1
10.7

3.1
3.2
3.2
6.1
6.1

1.1
17.4

-3.3
-2.7
-1.6
-.6
75.4
75.4

-.1
-.1

59.4
59.9

226
5.0
5.0
4.9
4.9

2015

17.2
2.1

8.7
11.3

3.4
.2
.2
3.6
3.6

1.2
17.5

-.5
-.1
-.1
.3
74.4
75.1

.3
.3

59.8
59.8

195
4.7
4.7
4.8
4.8

2016

16.7
1.6

2.7
11.1

4.5
1.8
1.8
2.6
2.6

1.2
17.1

3.0
3.5
1.9
2.2
75.2
76.3

1.4
1.4

60.1
59.7

182
4.1
4.1
4.7
4.7

2017

16.8
1.8

3.8
11.0

4.7
2.6
3.4
3.1
3.5

1.3
17.2

3.7
3.8
2.6
3.1
76.2
77.5

2.4
2.7

60.4
59.5

194
3.6
3.5
4.7
4.7

2018

16.6
1.4

5.5
11.2

4.7
2.7
2.7
3.1
3.5

1.3
17.0

1.4
1.5
1.7
1.9
76.7
78.1

3.1
3.5

60.7
59.4

181
3.3
3.1
4.7
4.7

2019

16.2
.8

3.7
11.1

4.2
2.2
2.1
3.0
3.2

1.4
16.7

1.3
1.5
1.3
1.3
77.1
78.3

3.2
3.6

60.7
59.2

160
3.3
3.1
4.7
4.7

2020

Authorized for Public Release

1. Average monthly change, thousands.
2. Percent; values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
3. Percent difference between actual and potential GDP; a negative number indicates that the economy is operating below potential.
Values are for the fourth quarter of the year indicated.
4. Percent change.
5. Level, millions; values are annual averages.
6. Percent change, with inventory valuation and capital consumption adjustments.

174
8.7
8.7
5.9
5.9

2011

Employment and production
Nonfarm payroll employment1
Unemployment rate2
Previous Tealbook2
Natural rate of unemployment2
Previous Tealbook2

Item

Greensheets
Other Macroeconomic Indicators
(Change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated, unless otherwise noted)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 121 of 126

.4
.4
.4
.1
.2
.1
-.2
.2

Fiscal indicators2
Fiscal effect (FE)4
Discretionary policy actions (FI)
Previous Tealbook
Federal purchases
State and local purchases
Taxes and transfers
Cyclical
Other
.4
.1
.1
.0
.1
.1
.0
.2

3
14

2020

3,611
4,774
-1,164
-5.3
-4.9
-2.9
2.4
-6.4
81.9

2.2
1.6
4.4
1.0
2.7
.9
-.7

1.9
1.4
3.7
1.0
2.2
.7
-.7

Real percent change, annual rate

-4.9
-4.8
-3.0
1.9
-5.7
79.5

Percent of GDP

3,435
4,460
-1,025

Billions of dollars

2019

.7
1.6
-1.5
-4.2
.7
.3
-1.5

-2.9
-2.9
-2.0
.9
-3.0
75.2

807
950
-143

Q3

0
6

2
9

1
9

-1
5

Average net change in monthly payrolls, thousands

1.2
.8
2.8
1.0
2.6
.5
-.1

-3.9
-4.0
-2.3
1.6
-4.2
78.0

3,310
4,093
-783

2018

-3
1

3.0
1.3
10.6
20.6
1.1
-.1
-1.2

-4.6
-4.6
-2.9
1.7
-4.8
75.0

770
994
-225

Q4

-.1
.2
.2
.1
.1
.0
-.2
-.3

.4
.6
.6
.1
.1
.4
-.2
.0

.9
.8
.8
.3
.1
.4
-.2
.4

.7
.5
.5
.2
.1
.2
.0
.3

-.1
.2
.2
.1
.0
.1
-.3
-.1

.1
.6
.6
.2
.3
.1
-.2
-.4

Percentage point contribution to change in real GDP, annual rate

-1
3

.7
.4
2.4
-1.9
1.8
.2
-1.1

-3.5
-3.5
-2.1
1.4
-3.3
76.5

3,316
3,982
-665

2017

2017

-.4
.1
.3
-.2
.0
.3
-.1
-.5

-2
0

-1.2
-.8
-2.9
-1.5
4.3
.7
1.6

-7.5
-7.8
-5.9
1.6
-7.7
77.2

727
1,102
-375

Q1

Q2

.6
.6
.5
.1
.1
.4
-.1
.1

-1
6

1.2
.6
3.7
2.2
1.7
1.3
-.4

.2
.0
2.1
1.9
-.2
76.8

1,038
1,029
10

2018

Greensheets

Authorized for Public Release

1. Annual values stated on a fiscal year basis. Quarterly values not seasonally adjusted.
2. Annual values refer to the change from fourth quarter of previous year to fourth quarter of year indicated.
3. Percentage point contribution to change in real disposable personal income, annual basis.
4. The FE measure captures the total contribution of the government sector to the growth of real GDP (excluding multiplier effects). It equals the sum
of the direct contributions to real GDP growth from all changes in federal purchases and state and local purchases, plus the estimated contribution to real
household consumption and business investment that is induced by changes in transfer and tax policies. FI (fiscal impetus) is the portion of FE attributable
to discretionary fiscal policy actions (for example, a legislated change in tax revenues).

3
10

1.6
1.9
.4
.0
3.2
.7
-1.4

Government in the NIPA2
Purchases
Consumption
Investment
State and local construction
Real disposable personal income
Contribution from transfers3
Contribution from taxes3

Government employment
Federal
State and local

-3.2
-3.2
-1.9
1.3
-2.8
76.7

-2.4
-2.4
-1.2
1.2
-1.9
72.9
.4
.6
-.5
-2.3
.2
.3
.2

3,268
3,853
-585

2016

3,250
3,688
-438

2015

Unified federal budget1
Receipts
Outlays
Surplus/deficit
Percent of GDP
Surplus/deficit
Previous Tealbook
Primary surplus/deficit
Net interest
Cyclically adjusted surplus/deficit
Federal debt held by public

Item

Staff Projections of Government-Sector Accounts and Related Items
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

3.0
2.9
2.2
2.6
-.3
3.7
2.7
2.2
3.5
1.2
2.6
.0
9.2
9.3
3.2

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

Page 122 of 126

2

2.3
2.3
1.2
1.4
.7
2.4
1.1
1.7
3.1
2.1
2.2
2.2
5.5
5.4
2.3

2.5
2.5
2.1
1.5
2.4
1.9
2.8
3.0
2.8
5.7
5.7
6.6
.0
-.7
1.0

Q3

GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
Foreign CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

2.0
2.0
.4
.2
.1
3.0
.2
.3
3.1
1.6
.7
2.1
6.8
6.7
2.3

3.1
3.1
3.3
4.4
2.4
1.0
2.9
2.6
2.9
5.1
2.6
7.0
1.1
1.0
2.3

Q2

3.0
3.0
2.1
3.0
1.9
3.0
1.7
2.3
3.7
3.0
.5
2.9
5.4
5.0
3.6

2.7
2.7
2.0
1.7
1.6
1.6
2.7
2.5
3.4
4.5
-.8
6.4
2.5
3.2
.2

Q4

2.6
2.6
2.6
3.6
2.5
2.5
2.1
1.2
2.7
1.8
1.6
1.5
4.7
4.1
3.1

2.9
3.0
1.9
2.0
1.2
1.3
1.9
1.9
3.9
5.4
4.0
7.1
2.4
2.7
2.3

2.6
2.6
1.9
2.6
.7
2.3
1.9
2.1
3.1
2.5
2.7
2.2
4.5
4.0
3.4

2.9
3.0
2.1
2.3
1.1
1.7
2.2
2.0
3.7
5.0
3.3
6.8
2.6
2.8
2.5

2.6
2.6
1.6
2.2
.7
2.3
1.4
1.7
3.3
2.8
3.3
2.6
4.5
3.9
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.0
2.1
1.0
1.7
2.2
1.9
3.7
4.9
3.5
6.3
2.6
2.8
2.5

2.5
2.5
1.5
2.1
.8
2.2
1.4
1.8
3.2
2.8
3.3
2.5
4.1
3.4
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.0
2.1
1.0
1.6
2.1
1.7
3.7
4.9
3.5
6.3
2.7
2.8
2.5

2.4
2.5
1.6
2.1
.9
2.2
1.4
1.9
3.1
2.8
3.2
2.5
3.8
3.4
4.3

2.9
2.9
1.9
2.1
.9
1.6
2.0
1.6
3.8
4.8
3.2
6.3
3.0
2.9
3.0

2.4
2.5
1.6
2.0
1.0
2.2
1.4
2.0
3.0
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.7
3.4
4.3

2.8
2.8
1.9
2.1
.9
1.6
1.9
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.2
6.2
2.9
2.9
3.0

2.4
2.4
1.6
2.0
1.1
2.3
1.5
2.1
3.0
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.6
3.2
4.3

2.9
2.9
2.1
2.0
3.3
1.6
1.8
1.4
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.2
2.9
3.0
3.0

2.8
2.8
2.6
2.0
6.4
2.2
1.6
2.2
2.9
2.7
3.1
2.5
3.4
3.2
4.3

2.5
2.6
1.3
2.0
-3.6
1.6
1.7
1.4
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.1
2.9
3.0
3.0

------------------------------------Projected-----------------------------------2018
2019
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4
Q1
Q2
Q3
Q4

Authorized for Public Release

1 Foreign

3.2
3.2
3.0
4.0
1.9
1.3
2.6
3.6
3.5
5.4
4.0
6.9
2.3
2.5
5.3

Q1

Real
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

GDP 1

Measure and country

2017

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Quarterly percent changes at an annual rate)

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 123 of 126

3.4
3.4
2.2
2.7
-.3
4.6
2.9
2.6
4.3
4.4
3.9
4.6
4.1
3.5
6.7

Consumer prices 2
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

2 Foreign

2.3
2.3
1.3
1.0
-.2
2.6
2.3
1.9
3.1
2.6
1.7
2.1
4.4
4.1
5.6

2.2
2.2
.3
.7
.3
1.5
-1.1
.2
4.2
5.8
2.1
8.0
3.1
3.0
2.6
2.4
2.4
1.0
1.0
1.4
2.1
.8
1.4
3.4
3.1
1.1
2.9
4.2
3.6
5.8

3.0
3.0
2.5
3.6
2.8
2.6
.8
1.6
3.5
5.4
3.5
7.6
1.7
1.2
2.6

2013

2.0
2.0
1.2
2.0
2.6
.9
.2
.4
2.7
1.8
1.0
1.5
4.9
4.2
6.5

2.8
2.8
2.0
2.5
-.3
3.3
1.5
1.9
3.6
5.0
2.8
7.1
2.5
3.5
-.1

2014

Greensheets

GDP aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. exports.
CPI aggregates calculated using shares of U.S. non-oil imports.

3.2
3.2
1.8
3.1
.2
1.3
.5
2.4
4.6
5.1
2.9
8.7
4.0
3.9
2.6

Real GDP 1
Total foreign
Previous Tealbook
Advanced foreign economies
Canada
Japan
United Kingdom
Euro area
Germany
Emerging market economies
Asia
Korea
China
Latin America
Mexico
Brazil

2012

1.4
1.4
.4
1.3
.1
.1
.2
.2
2.1
1.5
.9
1.5
3.4
2.3
10.4

2.1
2.1
1.2
.3
1.2
2.1
2.0
1.3
2.9
4.5
3.2
6.8
1.6
2.7
-5.5

2015

1.9
1.9
.9
1.4
.3
1.2
.7
1.0
2.7
2.0
1.5
2.1
4.3
3.3
7.1

2.7
2.7
1.9
2.0
1.5
2.0
1.9
1.9
3.4
4.9
2.6
6.8
2.1
3.2
-2.4

2016

2.6
2.5
1.5
1.8
.6
3.0
1.4
1.6
3.4
2.0
1.5
1.8
6.7
6.6
2.8

2.9
2.9
2.6
2.9
2.1
1.4
2.8
2.9
3.2
5.2
2.8
6.8
1.5
1.5
2.2

2017

2.6
2.6
1.9
2.6
1.2
2.3
1.7
1.7
3.0
2.5
2.7
2.2
4.4
3.8
3.8

2.9
3.0
2.0
2.1
1.1
1.6
2.1
1.9
3.8
5.1
3.5
6.6
2.6
2.8
2.4
2.5
2.5
1.8
2.0
2.3
2.2
1.5
2.0
3.0
2.8
3.2
2.5
3.6
3.3
4.3

2.8
2.8
1.8
2.0
.3
1.6
1.8
1.5
3.8
4.7
3.1
6.2
2.9
2.9
3.0

2.4
2.4
1.7
2.0
1.0
2.1
1.7
2.2
2.9
2.7
3.0
2.5
3.4
3.2
4.3

2.7
2.7
1.7
1.9
.9
1.7
1.7
1.4
3.7
4.6
3.0
5.9
2.9
3.0
2.6

-------------Projected------------2018
2019
2020

Authorized for Public Release

1 Foreign

2011

Measure and country

Foreign Real GDP and Consumer Prices: Selected Countries
(Percent change, Q4 to Q4)
Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)
April 20, 2018

Page 124 of 126

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

U.S. current account balance
Previous Tealbook
Current account as percent of GDP
Previous Tealbook
Net goods & services
Investment income, net
Direct, net
Portfolio, net
Other income and transfers, net

-444.6
-444.6
-2.9
-2.9
-548.6
219.2
288.7
-69.5
-115.1

2011

-451.5
-453.1
-2.4
-2.4
-551.4
215.2
297.3
-82.1
-115.3

Q1

Q3

-426.2
-426.2
-2.6
-2.6
-536.8
216.1
285.5
-69.4
-105.5

Q4

2013

-512.6
-509.0
-2.6
-2.6
-615.5
243.7
310.5
-66.8
-140.8

-349.5
-349.5
-2.1
-2.1
-461.9
215.4
283.3
-67.9
-103.1

-405.9
-405.9
-2.1
-2.1
-541.1
248.9
318.1
-69.2
-113.8

2012

-495.0
-496.5
-2.6
-2.6
-565.8
217.8
294.3
-76.5
-147.0

Q2

2017

-548.3
-538.9
-2.7
-2.7
-661.8
242.8
334.9
-92.1
-129.3

-373.0
-373.0
-2.1
-2.1
-489.5
221.3
276.7
-55.4
-104.8

Q3

2016

-564.4
-553.9
-2.8
-2.7
-649.6
220.7
336.2
-115.5
-135.4

-434.6
-434.6
-2.4
-2.4
-500.4
192.7
266.5
-73.8
-126.9

-451.7
-451.7
-2.4
-2.4
-504.8
186.8
258.8
-72.0
-133.7

Billions of dollars

2015

Annual Data

-565.1
-574.0
-2.8
-2.9
-672.2
247.4
324.1
-76.7
-140.3

2014

Q2

Q4

Q1

-466.2
-466.1
-2.4
-2.4
-568.4
231.4
305.1
-73.7
-129.2

-641.8
-654.8
-3.0
-3.1
-629.1
116.6
303.3
-186.8
-129.3

Q2

-670.5
-681.6
-3.1
-3.2
-627.9
92.8
304.1
-211.3
-135.4

Q3

-696.5
-707.9
-3.2
-3.3
-636.6
71.6
307.1
-235.5
-131.4

Q4

-565.4
-562.7
-2.8
-2.8
-656.1
224.9
330.7
-105.8
-134.1

-662.0
-673.1
-3.1
-3.2
-635.8
108.0
307.0
-199.1
-134.1

-787.6
-803.2
-3.5
-3.6
-670.4
16.9
309.9
-293.0
-134.1

-------------Projected------------2018
2019
2020

-639.2
-648.0
-3.1
-3.1
-649.8
150.9
313.6
-162.7
-140.3

2017

-583.7
-584.0
-2.8
-2.8
-640.8
188.6
327.6
-139.0
-131.4

Billions of dollars, s.a.a.r.

Q1

------------------------------------Projected-----------------------------------2018
2019

Quarterly Data

U.S. Current Account

Greensheets

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release
April 20, 2018

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

Abbreviations
AFE

advanced foreign economy

BEA

Bureau of Economic Analysis

BEAT

base erosion anti-abuse tax

BGCR

Broad General Collateral Rate

BOE

Bank of England

BOJ

Bank of Japan

BOM

Bank of Mexico

CD

certificate of deposit

CDS

credit default swap

C&I

commercial and industrial

CMBS

commercial mortgage-backed securities

CP

commercial paper

CPH

compensation per hour

CPI

consumer price index

CRE

commercial real estate

DSGE

dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

ECB

European Central Bank

ECI

employment cost index

EDO model

Estimated Dynamic Optimization-based model (a medium-scale
New Keynesian DSGE model of the U.S. economy)

EITC

earned income tax credit

ELB

effective lower bound

EME

emerging market economy

EU

European Union

FICC

Fixed Income Clearing Corporation

FOMC

Federal Open Market Committee; also, the Committee

FPLT

flexible price-level targeting

FRA

forward rate agreements

FRB/US model

A large-scale macroeconometric model of the U.S. economy

Page 125 of 126

Class II FOMC – Restricted (FR)

Authorized for Public Release

April 20, 2018

GCF

General Collateral Finance

GDP

gross domestic product

ICR

interest coverage ratio

LFPR

labor force participation rate

LIBOR

London interbank offered rate

M&A

mergers and acquisitions

MBS

mortgage-backed securities

Michigan survey

University of Michigan Surveys of Consumers

NAFTA

North American Free Trade Agreement

NFC

nonfinancial corporate

NIT

nominal income targeting

OIS

overnight index swap

OMMF

offshore money market fund

ON RRP

overnight reverse repurchase agreement

PCE

personal consumption expenditures

PMI

purchasing managers index

PPI

producer price index

QS

quantitative surveillance

repo

repurchase agreement

RRE

residential real estate

SEP

Summary of Economic Projections

SIGMA

A calibrated multicountry DSGE model

SLOOS

Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices

SOFR

Secured Overnight Financing Rate

SOMA

System Open Market Account

S&P

Standard & Poor’s

SPF

Survey of Professional Forecasters

TGCR

Tri-Party General Collateral Rate

TIPS

Treasury Inflation-Protected Securities

VIX

one-month-ahead option-implied volatility on the S&P 500 index

Page 126 of 126