View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

APPENDIX

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
March 30, 1982

Sam Y. Cross
Since your last meeting in February, the dollar has
risen by 1-2 percent against the Swiss franc and the German
mark, by 6 percent against the yen, and by even more against
some other European currencies.

The dollar is now trading

above year-end levels by about 7 percent against the Swiss
franc and German mark and as much as 13 percent against the
Japanese yen.
The dollar's most recent advance, triggered initially
by interest-rate developments early in the year, has by now
been reinforced by an improving swing in market sentiment.
The market is no longer talking about the dollar being undermined by a recession-induced drop in U.S. interest rates and
a deterioration of our balance of payments.

Instead, the

market was impressed during February by the repeated expressions
of Federal Reserve resolve to continue to address the need
for curbing inflationary pressures, and to adhere to its monetary policy appoach even in the face of recession.

Meanwhile,

business credit demands remained strong, efforts to find ways
to reduce the government deficit appeared to bear little fruit,
and concern developed in the market that there might be a
bulge in the money supply in April that would be resisted by
the Federal Reserve.

As a result, the view developed that

U.S. interest rates might remain relatively high for longer
than normal in a recession period.

Other factors favorable

to the dollar included a continuing winding down of inflation,
announcement of moderate wage settlements in several key
industries, and reduced concern that our current account would
move into sizable deficit.
The dollar also benefited from a perception that the
worldwide recession and a shrinking OPEC surplus may be adding to the strains already inflicting Europe and Japan.

Their

exports seem less likely to increase sufficiently to provide
the boost needed to combat the sluggishness of demand and
unemployment problems at home.

Already, figures for Japan

and Germany for the early months of 1982 suggest that the
export performance of those two countries is failing to live
up to expectations.

Moreover, the decline of OPEC's invest-

ible surplus has generated concern that, at current interest
rates and spreads, it may be more difficult than before for
countries to attract capital inflows.
The changing international environment is seen in
the market as increasing trade frictions and competitive pressures generally, and

having an adverse effect on some currencies.

With

Japan, the EC announced it is preparing

re sp ec t

to

to take initiatives against that country under GATT, and legislation requiring "reciprocity" in trade has been proposed in
our Congress.

These developments have had a depressing effect

on the yen, which has weakened more against the dollar than
have most European currencies.

Within Europe, the market

senses that these developments have increased countries' desires

to protect or improve their competitive positions in world
markets.

In this context, a renewed speculative attack developed

within the EMS against the French franc

and, to a lesser extent,

the Belgian franc and Italian lira. These pressures, which
were intense for about two weeks in mid-March, have now been
blunted by the French taking monetary and exchange-control
measures and sizable intervention--but not without dragging
even the strongest currencies within the EMS, the mark and
guilder, down against the dollar.
The more pessimistic outlook for the international
economy also implies that the major countries abroad must
look even more to internal rather than external means for
stimulating their economies.

Already, a generalized lower-

ing of European interest rates late in January had left the
market with the impression that the central banks at home were
prepared to see their interest rates continue to decline even
if U.S. interest rates did not.

Talk spread in the market

of capital or exchange controls that would permit central
banks to cut interest rates.

Then, about the time U.S. interest

rates eased in late February, the authorities in a number of
countries also moved to allow their domestic interest rates
to decline by at least as much.

And, on March 18 central

banks of three countries--Germany, Switzerland, and the Netherlands--dropped their official lending rates by a further 1/2 percentage point.

Thus, by the end of the period, interest rate

differentials favoring the dollar had not narrowed, but in
most cases had widened.

The economic problems are being seen against the
background of continuing political uncertainties in a number
of countries in Europe.

These concerns became more immediate

with the approach of regional elections in Germany and France
in mid-March, elections which in the evert neither government
did very well.
In view of the strength of sentiment for the dollar,
some central banks appear to have scaled back their own intervention activity.

Officials in major countries abroad seem

to feel that without any indication that the U.S. might be
willing to intervene to sell dollars, which they feel might
have an important effect on market psychology, acting on
their own they can achieve little through intervention to
influence the trend of their exchange rate against the strong
dollar.

They tend to operate, if at all, simply to try and

keep the movements orderly.

The central banks of Germany,

Switzerland, and the Netherlands are now also constrained
by the pressures any action they take to sell dollars might
impose on the exchange rate relationships within Europe.
Thus, most of the $11 billion G-10 official intervention
during the intermeeting period was EMS related.

Apart from

these transactions, the Bundesbank has pretty much limited
its activity to operating at the Frankfurt fixing simply to
facilitate the fixing process.

The Bank of Japan sold about

with sizable operations being done through the
U.S. in New York.

But they, too, have been reluctant to try to

dig in to stop the yen from dropping any further.

The Bank of

Canada has also been a substantial seller of dollars.

PETER D.

STERNLIGHT

NOTES FOR FOMC MEETING
MARCH 29-30, 1982

Monetary growth ran somewhat below path during much
of the intermeeting period, though it tended to catch up to
near-path levels by mid-March.

As February progressed, with

a moderate decline in M1 reversing some of the huge January
bulge,

and M2 also a little

below path,

pursuit of the path-

related nonborrowed reserve levels permitted some decline in
borrowings and easing of money market pressures, although the
impact was delayed until late in the month.

Borrowing tended

to run above anticipated levels in mid-February, in the $1.6 $1.7 billion area, while Federal funds moved up from about 14
percent in late February.
In March, while money growth resumed and offset
part of the February decline, the below path level of demand
for reserves permitted borrowing to stay below the $1.5 billion
initial borrowing assumption--largely ranging around $1 1/4
billion.

Federal funds remained about 14 percent in early

March and then crept up to a 14 3/8 - 14 7/8 percent range
later in the month.

So far this week, through the weekend,

the funds rate averaged 14.32 percent, although today's trading
rose to the 15 -

15 1/2 percent area apparently because of

quarter-end statement date pressures.

For the first

four-week subperiod--ending March 3,

total reserves ran about $70 million below path while nonborrowed reserves were about $20 million above their path.
For the second subperiod--the

four weeks ending March 31--it

looks as though demand for total reserves is

running about

$150 million below path, although if all the potential
technical reserve multiplier adjustments were taken the
demand for total reserves would be quite close to path.
However, given the tendency for borrowing to run below
expectations in early March, the full use of the reserve
multiplier adjustments would have imposed an increasing
borrowing gap on the banking system--to well above the
initial $1.5 billion level--which seemed inconsistent with
the basically close-to-path, or even slightly below path,
performance of the monetary aggregates.

Hence, some dis-

cretion was exercised in applying these adjustments.

In

the current week, the anticipated borrowing level is about
$1.4 billion.
Outright Desk activity was fairly moderate and
largely offsetting during the period.

There were purchases

of about $1.5 billion of bills and a few coupon issues from
foreign accounts, more than offset by sales of about $1.9
billion of bills, nearly all to foreign accounts, and redemptions of $600 million in bills and a small amount of
agency issues.

Net, outright holdings were down about $940

million.

Sales and redemptions were concentrated in the

early March period when reserves were being released by
a rundown in Treasury deposits and a reduction in reserve
requirements as part of the Monetary Control Act phase-in.
Short-term reserve adjustments were used actively
to cope with temporary effects of market factors.

A notable

complication in this regard was the very high level of
Treasury balances at the Federal Reserve in late February.
Total Treasury cash outran the capacity of commercial bank
depositories to hold note balances and their balance as the
Fed ran several billions above the normal $3 billion level.
(A similar situation could arise in late April, although
efforts are under way to see if the holding capacity of
the commercial banks can be enlarged to deal with future
situations of this kind.)
Yields on fixed income securities fluctuated fairly
widely over the February-March interval, ending up modestly
lower on balance.

Rates rose in early February in the wake

of concerns about large budget deficits and the absence of a
quick reversal of the early January money bulge--which
observers could see was resulting in increased pressure on
reserve positions.

The Treasury's large February refunding

was received unenthusiastically and the new issues weighed
on the market for a time.

Later in February, and into early

March,

the market rallied briskly, responding to indications

of some reversal of the January money bulge and a spate of
statistics suggesting continued weakening of the economy.
The market had also been encouraged earlier in

February by

Chairman Volcker's statement that the Federal Reserve would
consider money supply in the high portion of the range, or
even temporarily above the range,

to be acceptable.

An

additional plus factor was the unexpectedly high level of
Treasury cash balances in

late February,

leading to some

scaling down of estimated near-term borrowing needs.
rally ran out of steam,

though,

The

as day-to-day money rates

failed to decline as much as had been hoped, and even backed
up somewhat as money growth resumed.

Moreover, as March

proceeded, some of the economic reports looked a bit stronger
even though there was awareness that much of this represented
a bounce back from the impact of especially severe weather
in January.
Meantime, increasing concern developed over the
budget outlook as participants looked past the currently
flush Treasury position to the still very high--and even
growing--estimates of deficits yet to come.

There was dis-

couragement about the lack of visible progress in efforts
to contain the deficits.

Only modest comfort was taken

from the reports of substantial slowdowns in

price increases,

as there was concern that business recovery--even a weak one-along with outsize Federal deficits would bring an early

-5-

resumption of upward price pressures.

My impression is that

most market participants believe the Fed will hold firm in
its anti-inflationary stance but the conviction is not so
universally or deeply held that signs suggesting relaxation
of that stance would not be seized upon fairly quickly as
evidence of a weakened resolve.

Finally, a negative factor

in the near-term rate outlook is the substantial concern
over a big money supply bulge in April.
On balance over the period, bill rates were down
about 25-50 basis points.

Three- and six-month bills were

auctioned today at about 13.40 and 13.25 percent, compared
with 13.85 percent for each issue on February 1.

At one

point during the period, bill rates fell to about 12 percent.
The Treasury raised about $5 billion in the bill market
during the period, although because of their temporarily
strong cash position they made a couple of reductions in
the volume of 3- and 6-month issues being offered each week.
No doubt, they'll have to return to higher amounts in another
month or two.
Rates on other short paper--bank CD's and commercial

paper--come down about similarly with bills, although some
increased concern over quality has been voiced and at times

there was evidence of widening spreads vs. Treasury bills.
The prime rate was a somewhat different story.

The day of

the last Committee meeting, February 2, the prime rate was

just in process of rising from 15 3/4 to 16 1/2 percent.
It rose further to 17 percent later in February and then
came off to 16 1/2 in March, and briefly was at 16 for
several large banks.
For intermediate and longer Treasury maturities,
net yield declines over the interval were on the order of
40 to 75 basis points.

The Treasury raised about $15 billion

through the coupon market, including around $1 1/2 billion
directly from foreign accounts.

Part of the yield decline

in the long end may reflect the Treasury's present inability
to sell bonds until the Congress grants further authority
for issues with yields above 4 1/4 percent.
seems to be in no hurry to do this.

The Congress

The Treasury has already

cancelled the 20 year issue that would have been offered at
this time, and there is increasing doubt about the ability
to include a long bond in the quarterly refunding in May.
Lacking such authority, the Treasury will have to press more
into shorter coupon issues or bills.
Rates on corporate issues also declined over
the interval.

New issue volume picked up in late February

and into March, after very low activity earlier in the year.
More recently, new issue volume has faded again as rates
backed up.
remains.

A heavy pent-up demand for long-term funds

-7Tax exempt yields showed a lesser yield decline
for the period than Treasury or corporate issues.

New

issuance was not as variable as in the corporate market,
but also showed a heavier March volume after a slow February.

James L. Kichline
March 29, 1982
FOMC BRIEFING
Economic activity in the first quarter is estimated
to have declined at a 4
the preceding
off and

quarter.

the drop in

a substantial

percent annual
But final

real

rate, the

sales appear to have leveled

GNP this quarter is

liquidation of inventories.

of the economy overall

same as in

attributable

The staff's forecast

has not been altered in a major way

since the last meeting of the Committee, although
tilted

toward somewhat more real

reflecting
and

in

to

growth and less

particular a reassessment of fiscal

it has been
inflation,
stimulus

the recent and prospective developments in energy prices.
The severe winter weather distorted activity early

this year,

although

the economy has

it

is

clear that the rate of decline

slowed considerably

markets, nonfarm payroll

in

recent months.

and February.

In labor

employment dropped 300,000 per month

during the fourth quarter, but at one-third
December

in

Initial

that rate between

claims for unemployment

compensa-

tion since the February labor market survey have remained high.
and are consistent with further
rate.
suggest
is

increases

in

the unemployment

However, developments in various sectors of the economy
that the bulk of the downward

adjustment

probably behind us,and we are projecting

that

ment rate will

peak around 9 1/4
percent

this spring,

1/2 percentage

point from the rate in

February.

in

labor demands

the unemployup about

-2Industrial production continued to fall

in the early

months of this year, but nothing like the steep declines late
in 1981;

the industrial

production index averaged. 1/2 percent

per month lower in January and February compared with 2 percent
monthly declines in November and December when most sectors
began to adjust to sharply rising inventories.

The only major

component of output that has shown persistent strength

is defense.

Production adjustments have been particularly sharp
in the auto industry, with output reduced to under half of
capacity so far this year.

While producers slashed output,

auto sales picked up in the first quarter in response to various
rebate and incentive programs, and roughly one-half of the
estimated $30 billion runoff of inventories in the first quarter
is in the auto area.

At the present time it appears that the

production adjustments have brought stocks into a reasonable
alignment with sales, but it's a fragile situation and the nearterm sales outlook remains poor given sluggish income growth,
high interest rates,
Retail

and high auto prices.

sales other than autos were about flat in

January and February and this is consistent with liquidation
of inventories in the retail trade sector.

The forecast does

not envisage strength in consumer sales until

after midyear

when disposable incomes are boosted by the income tax cuts.
In fact, in order to support consumption during the first quarter,
consumers reduced their saving rate 1 percentage point to around
5 percent.

-3In the housing sector,
February continued

will

grow little

some rise in
real

and permits through

to edge up from the exceptionally

reached last fall.
markets currently

starts

low levels

However, the tight conditions in mortgage
and in

in

prospect suggest housing market activity

coming quarters,

expenditures

but even so this implies

for residential

structures

in

terms following a year of large declines.
Both exports and business fixed investment are areas

where declines occurred in the first quarter and these sectors
are projected

to continue downward

markets have weakened

in

the period ahead.

Export

in response to the high value of the

dollar and poor economic activity abroad.

Business fixed

invest-

ment spending has deteriorated

to declines

final

sales,

underutilization

cost of capital.

in

response

of capacity,

in

sick profits and the high

Orders and contracts are consistent with

additional weakness

in the

investment sector.

Nevertheless,

there does not seem to be a major collapse of investment spending on the horizon,

given survey evidence and qualitative

reports,

but this area of the economy has appreciable downside risks.
In the aggregate

the staff forecast implies

that

the recession has neared

the bottom and for 1982 as a whole

real

at 1 1/2
percent and nearly twice that

growth is

in 1983.
good,

projected

On the price side recent performance has been very

helped

liquidation.

along

of course

by weak markets

and

inventory

For 1982 we are projecting a rise in

product fixed-weighted

deflator

of 6 percent--3

the business

percentage

-4points slower than last
percent is expected.

year--and for 1983 a further decline to 5
The price forecasts have been reduced largely

in response to recent and prospective developments
markets.

While we anticipate

in

energy

that world oil markets will firm

up later this year as excess stocks are worked off and demands
rise, nevertheless oil
fall

and

in

prices in 1982 are now projected to

1983 to rise less than the general

Finally,
the Administration

rate of inflation.

I might note that what the Congress and
may ultimately do with

remains totally unclear.
that roughly one-half

the fiscal

We have maintained the assumption

of the President's

spending cuts and

revenue raising measures will be enacted.
of the Administration's

1983 budget

But an assessment

budget details which became available

after the last meeting of the Committee and other information
has led us to revise
has added
it

some stimulus

entails a deficit

In an environment
is

federal

expected

to demands

of nearly

in

upward.

the forecast

$160 billion

of monetary restraint,

This

although

for fiscal

1983.

financing that deficit

to maintain interest rates at high levels and constrain

interest-sensitive
means that there is

private

sectors of the economy.

considerable

ruptions given the weakened
businesses.

spending levels

potential

It also

for financial

state of nonfinancial

dis-

and financial

S. H. Axilrod
March 30, 1982
FOMC BRIEFING
One of the principal issues before the Committee today is the
question of whether, or how long, M1 should be permitted, or encouraged,
to run above its current long-range target in view of the need to
finance economic recovery.

The response to this question depends in

part on assessment of whether the recent apparent increase in liquidity
preference (relative to income) will be long-lasting or whether it will be
unwound over the next several months.
In a mechanical or arithmetic sense there is scope to finance
percent for the
the staff's projected nominal GNP expansion of about 71/4
percent annual
to 51/2
year with growth of M1 in the upper half of the 21/2
range for M1.

Those relationships imply a rise in the velocity of M1

for the

year on the order of 2 to 3 percent, well within the range of historical
experience. In the first quarter the velocity of M1
at nearly a 10 percent annual rate.

actually declined

Arithmetically, this leaves room for

a rise in velocity over the forthcoming three quarters averaging about
percent at an annual rate (with M1 growth on a quarterly basis
61/2to 71/2
averaging around 3 to 4 percent per annum).
Such a velocity increase is not particularly out of keeping with
experience in the early stages of a recovery, especially the 1975 experience.
But every economic cycle seems to have its own unique characteristics.

And

the economic question at issue is whether such a rise in velocity can take
place without attendant upward interest rate pressures that might in practice
restrain the pace of recovery below what the Committee views as acceptable.
If the recent increased preference for liquidity is not longlasting, the odds are pretty good that a reasonable economic recovery

can be financed within the Committee's present targets.
happen,

it

probably requires the build-up in

For that to

liquidity of late last year

and early this year to be at least partly unwound--with those funds
willingly used to support a rebound in spending or invested in
assets.
in

Such a development,

if

it

happens,

longer-term

would be reflected, most likely,

a marked further slowing in expansion of the NOW account component of M1

and,

probably along with that, a return to a substantial rate of decline

in outstanding savings deposits.
Should the public, on the other hand, want to continue saving
in

the highly liquid form of NOW accounts at something like the pace of

the last month or two it

greatly diminishes the odds on financing reasonable

economic recovery within the constraints of the present monetary targets,
especially the M1 target.
circumstances,

For M1 growth to be within target under the

there would need to be offsetting shifts out of demand

deposits or NOW accounts because of, say,

increased use of sweep accounts

or some new decision by DIDC creating a highly liquid short-term account
that is not directly a transactions account.
in

(Or, parenthetically, growth

NOW accounts could be relatively high but matched by a corresponding

weakness in

demand deposits if

there were greater continuing shifts into

NOW accounts out of existing assets than we have assumed; our assumption, of
course,

is

that the remaining shift is
Should the recent increase in

quite modest).
liquidity preference not be

unwound--or not be offset in measured M1 by adaptations to new financial
innovations--the Committee might necessarily again be faced with the

question of whether the base for the 1982 target should be the lower limit
of last year's target band rather than the actual QIV '81 level.
would make a difference in

This

allowable growth for the year 1982 of about

one percentage point.

Such a higher base, incidentally, would place the

level of M1 in March within the 21/2
to 51/2
percent range.

Growth by

March '82 from the lower limit of the 1981 range is at just under a 5 percent
annual rate.
Problems raised by the recent apparent changes in liquidity
preference also raise questions for the interpretation of M2, whose velocity
also declined sharply, by about a 91/4
percent annual rate in the first
quarter.

The M2 target for the year can be comfortably attained with

economic recovery if such a decline is followed by an enhanced willingness
to spend out of the assets built up in the first quarter; this seems to require
not only that growth in its M1 component slows as income growth accelerates
but also that growth in its nontransactions component slows somewhat from the
first quarter pace. While similar issues in connection with liquidity preference
behavior of the public can be raised for both M2 and M1, such preference
changes may have a more diluted effect on M2 because some shifts toward
and away from liquidity are more likely to represent internal shifts among the
components of M2 whereas they may have a full effect on M1.
Of the alternatives presented to the Committee, alternative A
is most consistent with a view that the public's shift toward liquidity
late last year and early this year may be relatively long lasting--or at
least it is most consistent with a view that more time is needed before
coming to a determination that the accumulated liquidity is being unwound.
Alternative B may be thought of as an intermediate course, moving back
toward the current long-run range but not reaching even the upper limit
before around mid-year.

Alternative C would be consistent with a rapid

unwinding of the recent liquidity build-up to finance a rebound in nominal
GNP growth.

But, given the projected GNP growth of the second quarter,

this alternative would require a more rapid abatement in liquidity demand
than we think likely and thus is the alternative that would most
probably entail rising interest rates from current levels in the months
ahead.
A word probably needs to be said, Mr. Chairman, about the very
short-run problem of money growth in April.

The problem with the seasonal

for that month is explained in general terms in the bluebook.

To provide

some dimension to the question of how much of an understatement in April
growth might be involved in the current seasonal, we looked at some
alternatives to the current methodology and came up with an answer of
2 to 7 percentage points (annual rate).

We have made an allowance for an

error in that range in the proposed money paths.

But there is also the

chance that the present seasonal is right or that growth in April will be
slowed below our path assumtions for other reasons--in connection perhaps
with unpredictable behavior in the largest month by far for tax payments
and refunds.
These uncertainties argue, I believe, for a certain flexibility
in the setting of reserve paths over the next few weeks.

For example,

consideration might be given to tolerance for M1 growth at least in the
8 to 10 percent range that represents the range of April growth rates
presented in the alternatives before the Committee--so long as M2 growth
is not, say, staying above its current longer-run range.

The Committee

may also wish to accommodate to a certain amount of weakness in M1 growth
should it develop in April because of the various uncertainties I've noted.
However, if M2 were also running below the path set for the period ahead,

-5there would be much less of an argument for accommodation to weakness
since it would then be presumptive that money demand as a whole was
running weak relative to the Committee's underlying money supply objective.

The optional language in the directive represents an effort to
give some weight to M2 as a balance wheel in judging the influence on the
composition and level of reserves of behavior in M1--in connection not
only with April aberrations but also with longer-run asset shifts generated
by liquidity preferences.